Uploaded by mmlaouhi

Labor and productivity

advertisement
According to economic theories, productivity rises together with income. Because greater
spending is possible with higher income, this relationship occurs. The optimal number of hours
worked will depend on one's position in the wage distribution if a person's productivity is
influenced by his or her relative position in the wage distribution. People whose wages are
declining relative to others may try to enhance their wages by putting in longer hours and being
more productive. According to the article, both in absolute numbers and in comparison, to the
median salary, “minimum” wages in Italy are considered to be rather high. However, In Italy,
there is no statutory minimum wage at the federal, state, or local levels; nevertheless, sectoral
wage floors are established by collective bargaining agreements between employers' and labor
organizations. This structure dates back to the early 20th century, when the first territorial or
company-level collective agreements in manufacturing and agriculture were adopted. The
average gross minimum salary under collective agreements in 2015 was 9.41 euros per hour,
including the 13th and 14th month (if paid), which is a 17.7% increase from 2008 when it was
roughly 8 euros per hour. The hourly minimum wage varied from 7.47 to 13.89 euros.
Interesting evidence that the negotiated minima evolved similarly in all sectors comes from the
fact that the distance between the lowest minimum and the maximum stayed largely constant
over time (1.87 in 2008 vs. 1.85 in 2015). Nevertheless, despite various reforms, Italy's labor
market productivity has been flat for the previous ten years. The paper provided a justification
for this. Incentives have been largely disregarded in previous labor market changes, which have
only focused on flexibility. The Italian labor market suffers from acute allocative dysfunction.
In short term, wages did not mirror sector productivity; yet, over time, they increase in sectors
where productivity declines. Consequently, the collective bargaining system needs to be
completely reformatted. Nonetheless, in contrast to what happened in Germany, the wages have
risen in sectors, such as manufacturing, where productivity has decreased in relative terms. To
recapitulate, a 1%-point growth in relative productivity in one industry in Italy has little impact
on that sector's relative wages. In Italy, a 1 percent increase in a sector's relative productivity
over time causes the relative wage to decline by roughly 0.4 percentage points. Additionally,
when the relative sectorial productivity increases, Italian employment shares have a tendency
to decline by approximately 1:1. Although this "labor misallocation" effect exists in Germany
as well, it is four times more obvious there. In neither country are the long-term effects of
productivity on labor shares meaningful. To further simplify the data mentioned above, while
salaries in Italy tend to upsurge in sectors with declining productivity over the long course, they
do not significantly, in the short term, echo sectoral productivity. Finally, Italy's employment
tends to shift toward less productive industries. The labor market's "allocation failure" raises
concerns about the viability of the established wage-bargaining system. It is clear that Italy,
among OECD nations, has experienced the slowest rise in labor productivity between 2000 and
2016. As studied in class, The value of the output generated per unit of labor input, or labor
productivity, is a key long-term driver of employees' real earnings. In the end, employees cannot
profitably earn more than they generate. However, the relative contributions of the various
economic sectors in Italy are unclear. The only industries with a trend toward diminishing labor
productivity growth rates are trade, transportation, lodging, and food services, as well as
technology and communication. To relate the article to our studies, we can take a look at a
simplified world with two sectors, 1 and 2, where businesses manufacture 1 and 2 different
items and only use 1 factor of production, labor, which is presumptively homogeneous and
fixed in supply. Within each sector, businesses are the same, although there may be differences
between them. In both industries, a firm's need for labor declines as the relative wage rises.
Additionally, we assume that people hunt for employment in businesses or industries that pay
the greatest wages, but that switching between industries takes time because of search frictions
and the requirement to learn new, sector-specific skills. To put it into perspective, let's assume
that labor costs in Italy are between 40% and 45% of wage, with the employer paying 30% to
35% of the cost and the employee 10%. The business must also pay the employee's severance
pay, which is equivalent to an annual wage increase of about one extra month. This approach
is significantly different from, say, the German system, where there is no severance
compensation required and the labor cost is approximately 40% of the wage, shared equally by
the business and the employee. This majorly gives Italy a relative advantage over Germany
since the costs beard by the worker are significantly less.
References:
Manasse, P., Manfredi, T., (2014), “Wages, productivity, and employment in Italy: Tales from
a distorted labour market”, VoxEU Center for Economic Policy Research, 19/04/2014,
available at: https://cepr.org/voxeu/columns/wages-productivity-and-employment-italy-talesdistorted-labour-market, Accessed on: 27/09/2022.
Download