Candidate ID: AD02159 Submission Date: 2nd May 2023 Word Count: 1327 1. Use a diagram of a market with an external cost to show that private bargaining between the parties involved will result in a Pareto-efficient allocation, regardless of which party has the property rights (in the absence of transactions costs). Is the fairness of the allocation reached affected by which party has the property rights? What are some of the barriers to this type of private bargaining? When markets allocate goods in a way which is not pareto efficient, it is called market failure. These decisions fail to consider the effect of decisions on others, hence, consider the costs or benefits to parties that are neither the buyer or the seller. When an effect is termed as ‘external’, it refers to something that is not specified as a benefit or liability in the contract. External cost refers to a negative externality. To graphically explain this market failure, we consider the market of a mango plantation, which utilises a harmful pesticide to aid growth of their mangoes. However, these chemicals flow downstream and affect a village of fishermen. Thus the pollutants have created external costs in the name of ‘environmental spill overs’, by bringing benefit to the people who utilize them but ultimately harming the environment and those who rely on these resources. From an economic point of view, there is market failure as the pesticide is overused and the associated goods (mangoes) oversupplied. In a competitive market, a horizontal line will show the market price as all firms are price takers, thus, the mango plantation will choose a price where this line intersects its marginal private costs, in order to remain profitable. However, this allocation is pareto inefficient as the fishermen bear losses equal to the shaded area in Diagram 1. The pareto efficient output would be at the point where market price is equal to the marginal social cost, at which the quantity of mangoes is reduced. Both plantation owners and fishermen will be better off as the fishermen can pay off the firms with a portion of their savings (as their loss has decreased) and the owners will still be making a profit as their MPC will still be less than price. The solution above of paying off the mango owners to reduce output is called private bargaining, or Coasean bargaining. Assuming one individual from each group negotiates and only the mango output can be changed, both sides should realise that be reducing it to the pareto efficient level, both parties can gain. As per Diagram 2, the gain for fishermen is equal to the loss of profit and the net social gain when output is reduced. Reducing output leads to a loss of producer surplus and profit and finally the net social gain is the total gain for fishermen minus the loss of profit. Since clearly the gain for fishermen is greatest, they would be willing to pay off the mango plantation owners to reduce their output. The minimum acceptable offer from the fishermen would depend on what the owners would get in the existing situation, which is their reservation profit, or loss of profit. The maximum the fishing industry would be willing to pay is determined by their fallback, or reservation option in which they pay their entire gain off. If this were to happen, owners would get the entire net social gain and the fishermen would be no better off. The final compensation the two parties agree on, depends on their bargaining power. Many may view the pareto efficient level as unfair as the fishermen have to pay to reduce the owners pollution, however, it is assumed that the plantation has legal rights over the usage of pesticides. An alternative scenario is one in which it is assumed one of the parties has property rights over the resources. For example, if the fishermen had legal rights over clean water, then the plantation owners wishing to use the pesticide would have to propose a bargain to pay off the fishermen to give up their rights. In either scenario, market failure tends to get rectifies but the distribution of benefits differ. However, there are some barriers to this type of bargaining. Firstly, the implications of collective actions, that is that private bargaining may only be possible if both parties have a representative body to reflect the beliefs and make agreements for the entire body, this can be problematic when there are too many people. Secondly, decision a payment scheme requires measuring the cost of the pesticide for each fishermen affected and also locating the source of each pollutant which is too time consuming, cost ineffective and tough to achieve with missing information. Thirdly, the barraging relies on a strong legal framework to protect and enforce their deal of reducing output or trading property rights, so the government needs to have clear and final contracts. Lastly, if the fishermen or affected party have limited funds, they may not be able to pay off the owners to reduce output. Word Count: 763 5. Use a Lorenz curve diagram to show how labour market segmentation can lead to increased income inequality. How might the government and labour unions try to reduce segmentation? Do all workers benefit from eliminating segmentation? Labour segmentation is the division of the labour market according to a principle such as occupation, geography and industry, that cannot be attributed to differences in productivity alone. For example, in the primary labour market, workers tend to be represented by trade unions and enjoy high wages and job security. They also have the opportunity to use ‘job ladders’ to get promoted and increase these benefits. These are the ‘good jobs’. On the other hand, workers in the secondary market are on short term contracts with limited wages and security. The majority of these workers tend to be young and from discriminated or minority ethnic or race groups. There are several informal names given to this section of the economy, including ‘zero hour contract’, which reflect how there is no commitment by the employer to provide extended periods of work and pay. In a nutshell. For any given skill or endowment, the primary workers tends to reap the benefits with higher pay, which ultimately adds to increasing income inequality. The Diagram on the left shows the impact of a reduction in labour market segmentation. Initially the secondary labour workers receive just 10% of the output, whereas, the same proportion of primary labour workers received 50% of output. When the segmentation is removed, all workers, primary or secondary, receive the same pay and as a whole receive 60% of the income. The line (Lorenz curve) is a smooth and upward sloping. In both scenarios, unemployed workers receive no income and the owners receive 40% of total income. The Gini coefficient, which is calculated by dividing the area between the Lorenz curve and perfect equality line by the total area under the perfect equality line, falls from 0.52 to 0.36. This indicates a greater level of equality within the economy as the absolute value approaches 0. There will be an outward shift of the curve in the case of increased segmentation, indicating more inequality. The government contributes to reducing labour market segmentation using pre-redistribution strategies. This entail affecting the endowments that people have and their value, leading to reduced inequality as peoples qualities and productivity enhance, leading to less discrimination based on superficial aspects. It alters a person’s wages prior to taxation. One such example of a policy is the anti-discrimination policy, this increases the value of the labour endowment of those targeted by discrimination. Furthermore, there is the minimum wage act which legally requires employers to pay above a certain amount and prevent exploitation. This raises the income of poor and targeted groups and reduces income of the employers, reducing overall inequality. However, these polices and reduction in segmentation may not benefit all workers. Due to the increases costs to employers of hiring workers from the secondary labour market, due to acts such as minimum wages, they may wish to cut back employability in order to cut costs and increase profits. This may lead to unemployment amongst poorer working class groups. Furthermore, due to increased costs, firms may have to increase markup on their goods in order to remain profitable, leading to cost push inflation. This would ultimately eat into the disposable income of the working class and leave them no better off. In conclusion, while reduction in segmentation of the labour market may help reduce the economies overall inequality, there will be people who will be made worse off due to certain policy implementations. Word Count: 564 Bibliography: CORE. (2017). CORE - Economics for a changing world. [online] Available at: https://www.core-econ.org/.