Uploaded by lilolal24

Macroeconomics Summary

advertisement
Inhaltsverzeichnis
1
Introduction, GDP, Inflation, Unemployment ........................................................................................... 3
1.1
Gross domestic product ........................................................................................................................... 3
1.1.1
Calculation of GDP ........................................................................................................................... 3
1.1.2
Nominal vs Real ............................................................................................................................... 3
1.1.3
Gross national product .................................................................................................................... 4
1.1.4
Problems with GDP ......................................................................................................................... 4
1.1.5
Growth rate of GDP ......................................................................................................................... 4
1.2
Unemployment rate ................................................................................................................................ 4
1.2.1
Okun’s Law ...................................................................................................................................... 4
1.3
Inflation (๐…)............................................................................................................................................. 4
1.3.1
GDP deflator .................................................................................................................................... 4
1.3.2
Consumer Price index (CPI) ............................................................................................................. 5
1.3.3
Why do they differ?......................................................................................................................... 5
2
SHORT RUN (1): Goods market ................................................................................................................. 6
2.1
The different variables............................................................................................................................. 6
2.1.1
Private consumption C .................................................................................................................... 6
2.1.2
Investment I .................................................................................................................................... 6
2.1.3
Government spending G and taxes T .............................................................................................. 6
2.2
Equilibrium .............................................................................................................................................. 6
2.2.1
Out of equilibrium ........................................................................................................................... 7
2.3
Alternative interpretation of the goods market equilibrium ................................................................... 7
2.3.1
Private savings ................................................................................................................................. 7
2.3.2
Public savings .................................................................................................................................. 7
2.3.3
Equilibrium ...................................................................................................................................... 7
3
SHORT RUN (2): Financial markets ............................................................................................................ 8
3.1
Functions of money ................................................................................................................................. 8
3.2
Money demand ....................................................................................................................................... 8
3.3
Money supply without commercial banks ............................................................................................... 8
3.3.1
Instruments of monetary policy by the central banks .................................................................... 8
3.3.2
Bonds ............................................................................................................................................... 8
3.4
4
Money supply with commercial banks .................................................................................................... 9
SHORT RUN (3): IS-LM-Model ................................................................................................................... 9
4.1
IS Relation on the goods market ............................................................................................................. 9
4.2
LM curve in the financial market ........................................................................................................... 10
4.2.1
With money supply control ........................................................................................................... 10
4.2.2
With interest rate control ............................................................................................................. 11
4.3
Combining IS and LM ............................................................................................................................. 11
4.4
Fiscal Policy in the IS-LM model............................................................................................................. 11
4.4.1
Ricardian equivalence ................................................................................................................... 12
4.5
Monetary Policy in the IS-LM model...................................................................................................... 12
4.5.1
Liquidity Trap ................................................................................................................................. 12
5
MEDIUM RUN (1): Labor Market ............................................................................................................ 13
5.1
Perfect Labor Market ............................................................................................................................ 13
5.1.1
Labor Supply .................................................................................................................................. 13
5.1.2
Labor Demand ............................................................................................................................... 13
5.1.3
Labor Market Equilibrium ............................................................................................................. 13
5.2
Labor Market dynamics ......................................................................................................................... 14
5.3
Imperfect Labor Market ........................................................................................................................ 14
5.3.1
Wage setting ................................................................................................................................. 14
5.3.2
Price setting ................................................................................................................................... 14
5.3.3
Labor market equilibrium .............................................................................................................. 15
5.4
6
Natural level of production (output potential) ...................................................................................... 15
Medium Run (2): Inflation ...................................................................................................................... 16
6.1
Equation of Exchange ............................................................................................................................ 16
6.2
Phillips Curve ......................................................................................................................................... 16
6.3
Modified Phillips Curve .......................................................................................................................... 16
6.4
Natural Rate of unemployment (NAIRU) ............................................................................................... 17
6.5
Extension of the IS-LM model ................................................................................................................ 17
6.5.1
Real Interest Rates ........................................................................................................................ 17
6.5.2
Taylor rule ..................................................................................................................................... 17
6.5.3
Risk Premium................................................................................................................................. 18
7
Medium Run (3): IS-LM-PC-model........................................................................................................... 18
7.1
PC curve ................................................................................................................................................. 18
7.2
IS-LM-PC model ..................................................................................................................................... 19
7.3
Monetary Policy .................................................................................................................................... 19
7.3.1
The CB chooses the nominal interest rate .................................................................................... 19
7.3.2
The CB chooses the real interest rate ........................................................................................... 20
7.3.3
The CB chooses the inflation rate ................................................................................................. 20
7.4
8
Fiscal policy ........................................................................................................................................... 20
Open Economy ....................................................................................................................................... 21
8.1
Open goods market ............................................................................................................................... 21
8.1.1
Nominal exchange rate ................................................................................................................. 21
8.1.2
Real exchange rate ........................................................................................................................ 21
8.1.3
Purchasing Power Parity (PPP) ...................................................................................................... 21
8.2
Open financial markets ......................................................................................................................... 22
8.2.1
Balance of Payments ..................................................................................................................... 22
9
International Macroeconomics ............................................................................................................... 23
9.1
Interest Rate Parity ............................................................................................................................... 23
9.1.1
Empirical example ......................................................................................................................... 23
9.2
Demand for goods in an open economy (IS-Curve) ............................................................................... 23
1
Introduction, GDP, Inflation, Unemployment
Macroeconomics basically knows three main figures
1.1
Gross domestic product
Measures the value of all final goods/services (not intermediary goods!) produced within an economy during a
specific period of time (usually year)
Or
Measures the sum of value added in the economy during a specific period
1.1.1
Calculation of GDP
1.
GDP by expenditure
The GDP measures the total demand within an economy:
Y = C + I + G + (X – Im)
๏‚ท
๏‚ท
๏‚ท
๏‚ท
๏‚ท
2.
(Y = Total consumption (GDP))
C: Consumption by private households (excluding buying a house (I))
I: Investments into capital goods (e.g. machines), inventories, and residential property
G: Goods and services consumed by the government (however, no transfers!)
X: Exports
Im: Imports
GDP by income
The GDP is also the sum of all incomes earned within an economy
(In principle, we also have to add taxes (income for the government) and subtract subsidies)
GDP = labor income + capital income
๏‚ท
๏‚ท
3.
Labor income: wages, salaries
Capital income: profits, interests, dividends
GDP by production
GDP is the total value added in all sectors in an economy
GDP = value of produced output – value of used inputs
๏‚ท
๏‚ท
1.1.2
Outputs: production of goods and services
Inputs: raw materials., intermediate inputs
Nominal vs Real
Nominal GDP: quantities produced * market prices (current)
Real GDP: quantities produced * prices of base year (constant prices)
๏ƒ  shows actual increase in production
1.1.3
Gross national product
While the GDP follows the country territory-based principle, the GNP follows the resident principle.
GNP =
GDP
+ profits/income generated by residents abroad
– profits/income generated by foreigners in the country
๏ƒ  net income and dividends from foreign assets (NIFA)
1.1.4
Problems with GDP
๏‚ท
๏‚ท
๏‚ท
๏‚ท
1.1.5
GDP flawed/incomplete
o Black market not measured
o Unpaid, non-market-based work not recorded (e.g. architect building for himself,
unpaid housework, etc.)
Questionable whether it actually measures “welfare” as in happiness
Says nothing about the distribution of monetary welfare
Doesn’t consider factors such as environmental quality ๏ƒ  non-monetary social costs not
included in calculation
Growth rate of GDP
๐‘”๐‘ฆ =
๏‚ท
๏‚ท
1.2
๐‘Œ๐‘ก − ๐‘Œ๐‘ก−1
๐‘Œ๐‘ก−1
If g > 1 ๏ƒ  GDP growth (expansion or even boom)
If g < 1 ๏ƒ  GDP decline (recession, often only after two consecutive periods of negative growth)
Unemployment rate
๏‚ท
1.2.1
Ratio between number of unemployed people U and the total labor force L
o Labor force = employed workers N + unemployed workers U
Okun’s Law
States that unemployment rate u decreases with fast GDP growth and that u increases with very slow
or even negative GDP growth
1.3
Inflation (๐…)
Shows the growth rate of the price level compared to the previous price level
๐œ‹๐‘ก =
๐‘ƒ๐‘ก − ๐‘ƒ๐‘ก−1
๐‘ƒ๐‘ก−1
There are two ways to measure the price level
1.3.1
GDP deflator
If the price level increases, the nominal GDP grows faster than the real GDP. Hence the ratio between
those two is equal to the GDP deflator (Pt, equal to 1 in base year (GDPnom = GDPreal)
Growth rate of GDP deflator ๏ƒ  inflation
-
Growth rate of GDPnom – Pt = Growth rate of GDPreal
-
GDPnom = Pt * GDPreal
It is a Paasche price index, as it uses variable quantities and constant prices
1.3.2
Consumer Price index (CPI)
While the GDP deflator looks at the average price of the good produced, the Consumer price index
look at the average price of the good consumed ๏ƒ  more value to consumers
The CPI looks at a certain basket, a selection of relevant consumer goods, and checks their prices
regularly. It compares it to the base year to create an index. Hence it is calculated as follows
๐ถ๐‘ƒ๐ผ =
๐ต๐‘Ž๐‘ ๐‘˜๐‘’๐‘ก ๐‘๐‘Ÿ๐‘–๐‘๐‘’ ๐‘–๐‘› ๐‘๐‘’๐‘Ÿ๐‘–๐‘œ๐‘‘ ๐‘ก
๐ต๐‘Ž๐‘ ๐‘˜๐‘’๐‘ก ๐‘๐‘Ÿ๐‘–๐‘๐‘’ ๐‘–๐‘› ๐‘๐‘Ž๐‘ ๐‘’ ๐‘ฆ๐‘’๐‘Ž๐‘Ÿ
However, the CPI as a such is irrelevant. What counts is its growth rate ๏ƒ  inflation
It is a Laspeyres price index, as it uses constant quantities of a base year but current/variable prices
1.3.3
Why do they differ?
o
o
o
o
GDP deflator doesn’t include only the goods that are consumed by the private households
but also the goods that are sold to the government
The GDP deflator automatically adjusts the good and the quantities whereas the CPI has this
constant basket
The basket of the CPI also includes foreign, imported goods (e.g. oil), whereas the GDP
deflator only looks at domestically produced goods
The CPI ignores the fact that consumers can substitute certain good by alternatives, hence it
is usually am overestimated rate of inflation
2
SHORT RUN (1): Goods market
Supply = Y + Im
Total aggregate demand: Z = C + I + G + X
Total income (equal to GDP): Y = T + C + S (S for savings)
This chapter looks at a closed economy. Hence Exports and Imports are equal to zero. It follows that:
Supply = Y
and
aggregate demand: Z = C + I + G
2.1
The different variables
2.1.1
Private consumption C
In the real world, demand is influenced by a lot of factors. To keep it simple, we assume that demand
is mainly determined by disposable income: YD
YD = Y – T = C + S
What that means is that the disposable income is the income minus the net taxes (T = taxes –
transfers)
Or in other words
The consumption plus the savings
It follows that the private consumption C is a function of the disposable income:
C = C(YD)
As it is increasing in the disposable income, the first derivative of C(YD) must be greater than zero. This
marginal effect of an increase in YD is called the marginal propensity to consume (MPC)
We use the following linear consumption function:
C(YD) = c0 + c1YD
with c0 < 0, 0 < c1 < 1
C0 = autonomous consumption (consumption of households if the disposable income is 0)
C1 = marginal propensity to consume (MPC), shows by how much consumption increases if the
disposable income increases by one unit
2.1.2
Investment I
In this chapter, it is assumed that Investment is exogenous (hence given)
2.1.3
Government spending G and taxes T
As they are both set by the government, we treat them as exogenously given
2.2
Equilibrium
Supply = Demand
Y = Z, hence we have
Y = C + I + G, inserting the things we described above we get:
Y = c0 + c1(Y – T) + I + G
Remember that income equals GDP, that’s why we have a Y for income
Solving for Y, we get the following equation:
๐’€=
๐Ÿ
(๐’„ + ๐‘ฐ + ๐‘ฎ − ๐’„๐Ÿ ๐‘ป)
๐Ÿ − ๐’„๐Ÿ ๐ŸŽ
For this level of income/GDP the production is equal to demand. The formula can be divided into two parts:
๏‚ท
๏‚ท
(๐’„๐ŸŽ + ๐‘ฐ + ๐‘ฎ − ๐’„๐Ÿ ๐‘ป) is autonomous spending, which is independent of the income of the economy
๐Ÿ
๐Ÿ−๐’„๐Ÿ
is the multiplier. We assume that 0 < c1 < 1, such that the multiplier will always be larger than 1.
The closer c1 is to 1, the larger the multiplier. What this shows is that an increase in any of the
variables of the autonomous spending leads to an over proportional increase of the equilibrium
output Y.
2.2.1
Out of equilibrium
If supply is above demand, the excess supply will be treated as involuntary investments (into
inventory). As we have seen above, this is part of the actual investment I, which again is part of the
aggregate demand. Hence, thanks to this effect demand rises again to equal supply. However, firms
cannot increase the inventories forever and thus this is not treated as an equilibrium.
Rather, firms will eventually adjust their production/output to the planned demand form the initial
situation. This brings the economy back into equilibrium. The same thing applies vice versa to excess
demand.
This shows that the equilibrium output is mainly determined by the demand side. Eventually, the
actual production will adjust to the demand. ๏ƒ  Keynesian economics
2.3
Alternative interpretation of the goods market equilibrium
Above, we have looked at supply = demand for goods and services. However, we could also look at the same
relation but with supply and demand for capital, that is, savings and investments.
2.3.1
Private savings
We know that private savings S are equal to the share of the disposable income that is not consumed
S = YD – C
Whereas disposable income is income Y minus taxes T. Hence,
S=Y–T–C
2.3.2
Public savings
Public savings are by definition taxes (net of transfers) minus government spending.
๏‚ท If the government spending exceeds taxes, the government is running a budget deficit.
๏‚ท If taxes exceed government spending, a budget surplus.
Public saving = T – G
2.3.3
Equilibrium
We know that Y = C + I + G
Now we subtract taxes from both sides and move consumption to the left. We get
Y–T–C=I+G–T
The left side of the equation is simply the private saving. Hence:
S=I+G–T
Or, equivalently
I = S + (T – G)
On the left we have investments; on the right we have the sum of private and public spending.
3
SHORT RUN (2): Financial markets
3.1
Functions of money
๏‚ท
๏‚ท
๏‚ท
3.2
Medium of exchange
Unit of accounting
Store of value
Money demand
We assume that people can either hold
๏‚ท Money, that doesn’t pay any interest, but can be used to buy goods
๏‚ท Bonds that pay interest rate i, but cannot be used to buy goods
The demand of money MD is written as
๐‘€๐‘‘ = ๐‘ƒ๐‘Œ ∗ ๐ฟ(๐‘–)
๏‚ท
๏‚ท
3.3
P is the price level. Y is the income. Hence PY is the nominal GDP. If the prices for goods increase,
more money is needed. Also, when the income increases and thus the demand for goods.
L(i) is a function of the interest rate i. When the interest rate increases, the demand for money drops
because bonds become more attractive. Hence, L(i) is decreasing in i.
Money supply without commercial banks
For money supply, we distinguish to cases. First, we look at money supply without commercial banks.
In this world, money supply can directly be influenced by the central bank. We write M s, or simply M.
3.3.1
3.3.2
Instruments of monetary policy by the central banks
Bonds
๏‚ท
Open market operations: buying and selling assets (i.e. ForEX, bonds, etc.)
๏ƒ  “quantitative easing” for long-term bonds
๏‚ท
Expectation management: sending a message that you will continue with low interest
rates to convince companies to invest ๏ƒ  not subgame perfect
๏‚ท
Reserve rate
๏‚ท
Helicopter Money
If central banks buy bonds, the demand for bonds increases and hence the price. This drops the
interest rate and increases the money supply.
The relationship between bond prices and interest rates can be written as follows (assuming a nominal
value of 100)
100 − ๐‘ƒ๐ต
๐‘–=
๐‘ƒ๐ต
Alternatively, we can write
๐‘ƒ๐ต =
3.4
100
1+๐‘–
Money supply with commercial banks
Now, as we have commercial banks, the money supply is not only the money the central bank supplies (cash in
circulation, CU) but also the deposits the clients have in the bank. Hence money supply is
๐‘€ = ๐ถ๐‘ˆ + ๐ท
The commercial banks don’t keep all of their deposits. Rather, they further lend it to other people. The
percentage which the banks keep as reserves is called θ (theta).
Hence, the reserves we have are R = θ*D.
The reserves are kept in “accounts” in the central bank. Together with the cash in circulation/currency CU, this
constitutes the monetary base H.
๐ป = ๐ถ๐‘ˆ + ๐‘… = ๐ถ๐‘ˆ + ๐œƒ๐ท
Further, we assume that b is the share of the total money supply which is kept as currency CU. ๐ถ๐‘ˆ = ๐‘๐‘€
(b-1) then constitutes the share of money that is held as deposits. ๐ท = (1 − ๐‘)๐‘€
We can write:
๐ป = ๐‘๐‘€ + ๐œƒ(1 − ๐‘)๐‘€
Solving this equation for the money supply M, we get M as a multiplier of the monetary base H:
๐‘€=
1
∗๐ป
๐‘ + ๐œƒ(1 − ๐‘)
This is the so-called money supplier
What is says is that if the monetary base increases by a certain amount, the actual money supply increases by
even more.
4
4.1
SHORT RUN (3): IS-LM-Model
IS Relation on the goods market
Before, we said that for equilibrium in the goods market we have the Is relation (investments = savings)
๐ผ = ๐‘† + (๐‘‡ − ๐บ)
Now we change the assumption that investments are given. We say they are dependent on two factors:
Production Y: If a firm produces more, it needs higher investments
Interest rate i: if the interest rate rises, the Investments go down
๐ผ = ๐ผ(๐‘Œ, ๐‘–)
Hence, for every given Production and Interest rate, we have an equilibrium in the goods market. If the interest
rate increases, the GDP Y decreases, mainly due to the lower investments. Hence the so called IS-curve is
downwards sloping:
The slope of the curve is determined by how strongly demand reacts to changes in interest rates.
The position of the curve is determined by the exogenous parameters c 0,c1, G and T. All changes that increase
the GDP shift the curve to the right (e.g. higher government spending)
4.2
4.2.1
LM curve in the financial market
With money supply control
We know that for equilibrium in the money market the following equation holds:
๐‘€ = ๐‘ƒ๐‘Œ ∗ ๐ฟ(๐‘–)
If we divide both sides by the price index P, we get that real money supply = real money demand
๐‘€
= ๐‘Œ ∗ ๐ฟ(๐‘–)
๐‘ƒ
This step is important, as in the goods market the income is in real terms too.
Now, we know that, for a given real money supply, the equilibrium
depends on the income/GDP Y and the interest rate. The LM-curve
depicts all the combinations of Y and i for which the money market is in
equilibrium.
The slope of the LM-curve is determined by the effect of an increase of
interest rates on the demand Y
The position of the curve is dependent on the real money supply, hence
either P or the nominal money supply M. If the real money supply
increases, the curve shifts to the right.
4.2.2
With interest rate control
In case of interest rate control, the central bank simply adjusts the money supply in a way that the interest rate
stays constant. Thus, the LM-curve is simply denoted as
๐‘– = ๐‘–0
The LM-curve looks like this
4.3
Combining IS and LM
The combination of Y and i that satisfies this set of equations, show us the equilibrium in the IS-Lm model:
๐‘Œ = ๐ถ(๐‘Œ๐‘‡ ) + ๐ผ(๐‘Œ, ๐‘–) + ๐บ
๐‘€
= ๐‘Œ ∗ ๐ฟ(๐‘–) ๐‘œ๐‘Ÿ ๐‘– = ๐‘–0
๐‘ƒ
The graph on the right Is more relevant as it shows the LM-curve with interest rate control
4.4
Fiscal Policy in the IS-LM model
Fiscal policy is a term used for changes in G and T.
It affects the IS-curve, not the LM-curve
Assume G is increased. The demand increases. Hence also Money demand.
With interest rate control (left graph), the central bank will increase money supply to match the demand.
With money supply control, the central bank would increase the interest rate to match the money demand
with the given supply. The rising interest rates reduce investments. Hence the increase of GDP is smaller for
money supply control than for interest rate control.
4.4.1
Ricardian equivalence
The idea behind Ricardian equivalence is that if the government spends more than it receives in revenue and
thus goes into deficit, people will realize that they will have to pay more taxes in the future to repay the debt.
As a result, they will reduce their current consumption and increase their savings to prepare for higher future
taxes. What that implies is that financing government spending via current tax increases or without tax
increases does not make any difference, because the latter case would simply lead to future tax increases and
thus reduce current consumption.
4.5
Monetary Policy in the IS-LM model
Monetary policy encompasses all the actions that the central bank takes in order to change the equilibrium:
change in interest rate/change in money supply. Both shift the LM curve.
4.5.1
Liquidity Trap
If the central bank has consecutive measures of expansionary monetary policy, they will eventually end up at
an interest rate close to 0. If they further increase money supply or lower the interest rate, it will never go
below 0. This is because as soon as the interest rate reaches zero, the households will simply hold all their
money in cash, hence money demand is infinite (IS-curve goes to infinity). If no one holds bonds, the interest
rate is de facto 0. Households can thus avoid negative interest rates by simply holding cash. Hence further
expansionary policy would have zero effect. This is called the liquidity trap.
5
MEDIUM RUN (1): Labor Market
So far, we have implicitly assumed constant prices for the goods market. We assumed that firms can simply
adjust the supply to the demand. However, in the real world there is limits to that. Namely, resources are
scarce, especially the resource labor.
We denote the following variables:
Labor force L: all individuals participating in the labor market
Employed N: the part of the labor force that is employed
Unemployed U: all people that would like a job but don’t have one
Unemployment rate u: ratio between unemployed U and the labor force L
๐‘ข=
5.1
๐‘ˆ
๐‘
= 1−
๐ฟ
๐ฟ
Perfect Labor Market
Assuming a labor market with many sellers and many buyers.
5.1.1
Labor Supply
The Labor Supply is determined by the utility maximization of the households. They can choose between
Consumption and Leisure. The utility function of a household thus depends positively on consumption, and
negatively on labor supply N ๏ƒ  U (C, N)
In order to maximize it, it must be solved mathematically. We find the marginal rate of substitution, which
must be equal to the price ratio:
−
๐‘ˆ๐‘ (๐ถ, ๐‘) ๐‘Š
=
๐‘ˆ๐ถ (๐ถ, ๐‘)
๐‘ƒ
The marginal utility of another hour worked, UN(C,N), is negative!
5.1.2
Labor Demand
In the perfect market, firms observe the real wage, W/P, and decide how much labor N they want to hire. Their
goal is profit maximization. The profits are denoted as the difference between revenues and the wage:
๐‘ƒ๐‘Ÿ๐‘œ๐‘“๐‘–๐‘ก = ๐‘ƒ ∗ ๐น(๐‘) − ๐‘Š๐‘
Taking the first order condition to find the profit maximum, we find that the marginal product of labor must be
equal to the real wage:
๐‘Š
= ๐น๐‘ (๐‘)
๐‘ƒ
5.1.3
Labor Market Equilibrium
The real wage adjusts such that demand and supply are equal.
The individuals who don’t have a job in the perfect labor market equilibrium prefer not to work ๏ƒ  voluntary
unemployment (natural rate of unemployment)
Fixed wages can lead to involuntary unemployment.
5.2
Labor Market dynamics
What the perfect market doesn’t consider is that it takes time for an unemployed worker to find a job, likewise
for a firm to find a new worker.
Out of the employed workers N, the share p loses its job in period t. Thus, p*N workers enter unemployment in
each period.
Out of the unemployed workers U, the share s finds a new job in period t. This, s*U people leave
unemployment each period.
โˆ†๐‘ˆ = ๐‘๐‘ − ๐‘ ๐‘ˆ
In an equilibrium, โˆ†๐‘ˆ stays constant (โˆ†๐‘ˆ = 0):
๐‘ ๐‘ˆ = ๐‘๐‘
If we do some rewriting, knowing that ๐‘ข =
๐‘ˆ
๐‘ˆ+๐‘
, we find that the unemployment rate is equal to:
๐‘ข=
5.3
5.3.1
๐‘
๐‘+๐‘ 
Imperfect Labor Market
Wage setting
The wage setting equation depends on various factors.
If unemployment is lower, wages are higher because workers are in a better position for bargaining. Wages are
decreasing in u.
Also, wages are increasing in z. Z includes a lot of factors.
๐‘Š
= ๐น(๐‘ข, ๐‘ง)
๐‘ƒ
5.3.2
Price setting
We know how the wages are set. Now we want to know how the prices are set. These depend on the
production cost of the firm, which in turn depend on wages.
We assume that each worker produces output A. Thus, a firm’s output is equal to:
๐‘Œ =๐ด∗๐‘
We know that firms usually add a mark-up to their production cost. This mark-up is denoted as follows:
๐œ‡=−
1
1+๐œ€
Through differentiation we get to the profit maximization, and we obtain the price setting equation to be:
๐‘Š
๐ด
=
๐‘ƒ
1+๐œ‡
5.3.3
Labor market equilibrium
In the equilibrium, the real wages from the price setting must be equal to the one from the wage setting:
๐น(๐‘ข๐‘› , ๐‘ง) =
๐ด
1+๐œ‡
Where un is the natural rate of unemployment:
๐‘ข๐‘› (๐‘ง, ๐œ‡)
It increases in both factors
5.4
Natural level of production (output potential)
Using the natural rate of unemployment, one can deduce the natural rate of employment:
๐‘๐‘› = ๐ฟ(1 − ๐‘ข๐‘› )
The natural level of production is thus
๐‘Œ๐‘› = ๐ด ∗ ๐‘๐‘› (๐‘ง, ๐œ‡)
6
6.1
Medium Run (2): Inflation
Equation of Exchange
The velocity of money shows, how often each unit of money is spent in one year:
๐‘‰=
๐‘ƒ๐‘Œ
1
=
(๐‘–๐‘›๐‘ฃ๐‘’๐‘Ÿ๐‘ ๐‘’ ๐‘œ๐‘“ ๐ฟ๐‘€ ๐‘๐‘ข๐‘Ÿ๐‘ฃ๐‘’)
๐‘€
๐ฟ(๐‘–)
We can rewrite it to get the equation of exchange
๐‘€๐‘‰ = ๐‘ƒ๐‘Œ
Then we take the total differential. Now, through some remodeling and assuming that the change in velocity
(dV) is constant, we obtain that the growth rate of prices (= inflation) is equal to the difference between the
growth rate of money supply and the real economic growth:
๐‘‘๐‘ƒ ๐‘‘๐‘€ ๐‘‘๐‘Œ
=
−
๐‘ƒ
๐‘€
๐‘Œ
6.2
Phillips Curve
Basically, the Phillips curve shows the relationship between unemployment rate and inflation.
If we substitute the wage setting relation from above into the price setting relation, we get:
๐‘ƒ๐‘ก = ๐‘ƒ๐‘ก๐‘’ (1 + ๐œ‡) ∗ ๐น(๐‘ข๐‘ก , ๐‘ง)
Dividing both sides by Pt-1 , we find
๐‘ƒ๐‘ก
๐‘ƒ๐‘ก๐‘’
(1 + ๐œ‡) ∗ ๐น(๐‘ข๐‘ก , ๐‘ง)
=
๐‘ƒ๐‘ก−1
๐‘ƒ๐‘ก−1
Using the definition of the inflation, this gives us the Phillips Curve:
1 + ๐œ‹๐‘ก = (1 + ๐œ‹๐‘ก๐‘’ ) ∗ (1 + ๐œ‡) ∗ ๐น(๐‘ข๐‘ก , ๐‘ง)
However, this is a bit complicated to understand. Assume, ๐น(๐‘ข๐‘ก , ๐‘ง) = 1 − ๐›ผ๐‘ข๐‘ก + ๐‘ง. Through some tricks, we
will end up with this (counts only for small values):
๐œ‹ = ๐œ‹ ๐‘’ + ๐œ‡ + ๐‘ง − ๐›ผ๐‘ข๐‘ก
This is an easier version of the Phillips Curve.
Note: The traditional Phillips Curve assumes inflation expectations of zero!
6.3
Modified Phillips Curve
The modified Phillips Curve assumes adaptive inflation expectations. What that means is that the expected
inflation of year t is somewhat related the actual inflation from the previous year t-1.
Additionally, the parameter ๐œƒ is introduced, describing how strongly the previous inflation affects the
expectations:
๐œ‹๐‘ก − ๐œƒ๐œ‹๐‘ก−1 = ๐œ‡ + ๐‘ง − ๐›ผ๐‘ข๐‘ก
If ๐œƒ = 1, the expected inflation of year t is exactly equal to the inflation of the preceding year. This is what
happened since the 1970s. This modified Phillips Curve looks like this:
๐œ‹๐‘ก − ๐œ‹๐‘ก−1 = ๐œ‡ + ๐‘ง − ๐›ผ๐‘ข๐‘ก
This represents reality more than the “traditional” Phillips curve. Namely, in the 1970s you had high inflation as
well as high unemployment (= stagflation). How is this possible, assuming the traditional Phillips curve?
This is where the modified version steps in. Changes in the expectations lead to an upwards shift of the Phillips
curve and thus high inflation and high unemployment are both possible.
6.4
Natural Rate of unemployment (NAIRU)
In the labor market chapter, the natural unemployment rate was already discussed. However, it can also be
looked at from the point of view of the Phillips curve. We know that at the natural unemployment rate, the
economy is neither in a boom nor in a recession. In this medium run equilibrium, the inflation must be equal to
the inflation expectation. If we substitute it into the Phillips curve, we get:
๐œ‹ − ๐œ‹ ๐‘’ = ๐œ‡ + ๐‘ง − ๐›ผ๐‘ข๐‘ก
0 = ๐œ‡ + ๐‘ง − ๐›ผ๐‘ข๐‘ก
The unemployment rate in this equation is the natural rate, as we are in the medium run equilibrium:
๐‘ข๐‘› =
๐œ‡+๐‘ง
๐›ผ
As we now know that ๐›ผ๐‘ข๐‘› = ๐œ‡ + ๐‘ง, we can rewrite the whole Phillips curve as:
๐œ‹ = ๐œ‹ ๐‘’ + ๐›ผ๐‘ข๐‘› − ๐›ผ๐‘ข๐‘ก
๐œ‹ = ๐œ‹ ๐‘’ + ๐›ผ(๐‘ข๐‘› − ๐‘ข๐‘ก )
This gives us the Phillips dependent on the difference between natural and actual unemployment
๏ƒจ The NAIRU corresponds to the natural rate of unemployment, that is, to the unemployment rate at
which price and wage decisions are consistent.
6.5
6.5.1
Extension of the IS-LM model
Real Interest Rates
So far, as we have ignored the existence of inflation, we only assumed a real interest rate in the IS-LM model.
Now, we consider this effect by differentiating between:
Real interest rate (r) determining the real investments I on the goods market
Nominal interest rate (i) determining the nominal money demand on the money market
Thereby, the Fisher equation tells us that the real interest rate is approximately the nominal rate minus
expected inflation.
6.5.2
Taylor rule
So far, we have assumed that the central bank, no matter the output Y, always changes money supply to
maintain a certain interest rate. However, in real life, central banks do care about the output. Namely, if the
output is above its natural level the central banks increase the nominal rate to avoid the economy to overheat.
Same counts vice versa.
Thereby, price stability serves as the overarching goal. Hence, if inflation is above target, interest rates will be
increased. This usually goes hand in hand with the higher output Y described above.
Thus, in order to determine the central bank’s target interest rate, the Taylor Rule gives us this formula:
๐‘–๐‘ก = ๐‘Ÿ๐‘ก + ๐œ‹๐‘ก + ๐‘Ž(๐œ‹๐‘ก − ๐œ‹ ∗ ) + ๐‘(๐‘Œ๐‘ก − ๐‘Œ๐‘› )
6.5.3
Risk Premium
So far, we have assumed that all assets and investments are completely risk free and thus traded at the same
interest rate. However, some are riskier than others leading to investors demanding a higher return for their
risk. This risk premium is denoted by the letter “x”. It can be calculated by:
๐‘ฅ=
(1 + ๐‘Ÿ)๐‘
1−๐‘
Whereby r refers to the risk free rate and p to the probability of the investment plus interest to be paid back.
The new IS-LM model is:
๐‘Œ = ๐ถ(๐‘Œ − ๐‘‡) + ๐ผ(๐‘Œ, ๐‘Ÿ + ๐‘ฅ) + ๐บ
๐‘Ž๐‘›๐‘‘
๐‘Ÿ = ๐‘–0 − ๐œ‹ ๐‘’
An increase in the risk premium can be seen by a downward shift of the IS curve.
7
Medium Run (3): IS-LM-PC-model
We need to rewrite the Phillips Curve in a way, so it fits the IS-LM model. Namely, output must be included. As
we know, there is a direct relationship between output Y and the unemployment rate. Thus, there must also be
a relation between output and inflation. This gives us our PC curve
7.1
PC curve
The PC curve show how a change in production affect a change in inflation.
We know from above that:
๐œ‹ = ๐œ‹ ๐‘’ + ๐›ผ(๐‘ข๐‘› − ๐‘ข๐‘ก )
If we assume that Y = N (thus A=1), we find that
๐‘Œ = ๐‘ = ๐ฟ(1 − ๐‘ข)
๐‘Ž๐‘›๐‘‘
๐‘Œ๐‘› = ๐‘๐‘› = ๐ฟ(1 − ๐‘ข๐‘› )
The output gap is then given by
๐‘Œ − ๐‘Œ๐‘› = ๐ฟ(1 − ๐‘ข) − ๐ฟ(1 − ๐‘ข๐‘› ) = ๐ฟ(−๐‘ข + ๐‘ข๐‘› )
๐‘™๐‘’๐‘Ž๐‘‘๐‘–๐‘›๐‘” ๐‘ก๐‘œ
๐‘ข๐‘› − ๐‘ข =
๐‘Œ − ๐‘Œ๐‘›
๐ฟ
This we can plug in for (un – u) in our modified Phillips curve and get the PC curve:
๐œ‹ − ๐œ‹๐‘’ =
7.2
๐›ผ
(๐‘Œ − ๐‘Œ๐‘› )
๐ฟ
IS-LM-PC model
In our medium run equilibrium, the following holds:
1.
2.
3.
4.
7.3
Production is equal to natural: ๐‘Œ = ๐‘Œ๐‘›
Unemployment is equal to natural: ๐‘ข = ๐‘ข๐‘›
Expected inflation is equal to actual inflation: ๐œ‹ = ๐œ‹ ๐‘’
Real interest rate is equal to the natural rate
Monetary Policy
There are three strategies the central bank can pursue when faced with expansionary policy.
7.3.1
The CB chooses the nominal interest rate
In this case, after the expansionary policy interest rate drop, the central bank stays with this exact nominal
interest rate. Due to the expansionary policy, inflation rises. Eventually, consumers will adjust their inflation
expectations to the new inflation. That implies that the real interest rate must decrease (see Fischer Equation).
Therefore, the LM curve (which depicts the real interest rate) shifts downwards, leading to even stringer
expansionary effects (๏ƒ  TEUFELSKREISLAUF)
7.3.2
The CB chooses the real interest rate
In this case, the increased inflation expectations must be compensated by an increase in nominal rates. This, so
it reaches the level of the stimulating real rate chosen for the expansionary policy. At this level (being
expansionary), inflation is increasing. Due to the constantly adjusting expectations, nominal rates must be
increased again (๏ƒ  TEUFELSKREISLAUF)
7.3.3
The CB chooses the inflation rate
This is the only way that the CB does not cause inflation to rise continuously. In the short run, the economy is
stimulated. However, at some point the nominal rate is adjusted in such a way that it matches the natural rate
again. This keeps inflation at a constant level, but higher than before the expansionary measures.
7.4
Fiscal policy
In case of fiscal policy, say increased government spending, a very interesting effect can be observed.
Therefore, we assume a central bank that chooses the inflation rate (see 7.3.3).
Namely, if G increases the IS curve shifts to the right. Y goes beyond natural, thus inflation is higher. As the
central bank wants to keep the inflation at its chosen rate, it will react to this increase in inflation by raising the
nominal rate such that the real interest rate reaches neutral again.
The G, however, has still increased. But output is not bigger than before as it is back to natural. Thus,
something in the IS equation must’ve decreased ๏ƒ  INVESTMENTS
This is because the neutral rate is now higher than before. As we are at neutral level in the medium-run
equilibrium, the real interest rate is also higher than before. Thus, investments must be lower. This is known as
the crowding out effect
Government spending has crowded out private investments!
8
Open Economy
From now on, we will no longer assume that imports and exports are equal to zero.
8.1
Open goods market
If the net exports are positive, then our country has a trade surplus
If the net exports are negative, then our country has a trade deficit
Now that the economy is not closed, individuals can choose between domestic and foreign goods. This decision
is dependent on the price of domestic goods relative to the price of foreign goods (๏ƒ  exchange rate).
Thereby, we distinguish between real and nominal exchange rate
8.1.1
Nominal exchange rate
The nominal exchange rate E is simply the rate at which currencies are exchanged. It is defined as the price of
the domestic currency in terms of foreign currency.
Nominal depreciation: E becomes smaller, currency less expensive
Nominal appreciation: E becomes bigger, currency more expensive
8.1.2
Real exchange rate
The real exchange rate ๐œ€ is the price of domestic goods in terms of foreign goods.
For example, if ๐œ€ = 1, foreign countries pay exactly one unit of their goods for one unit of ours.
๐œ€=
EP
๐‘ƒ∗
Where P* is the foreign price level
Usually, the real exchange rate considers the relative price of all foreign goods in terms of all domestic goods.
Therefore P* as well as P is usually indicated by the GDP deflator.
Real depreciation: ๐œ€ becomes smaller, foreign countries must pay fewer units of their goods for one of ours.
Real appreciation: ๐œ€ becomes bigger, foreign countries must pay more units of their goods for one of ours.
Note: the real exchange rate itself is not super interesting, but the change in it!
8.1.3
Purchasing Power Parity (PPP)
PPP is based on the law of price. It states that identical goods should have the same price, no matter where
they are bought. In other words, ๐œ€ = 1 ๏ƒ  exact purchasing power parity
This exact PPP, however, only holds under three assumptions:
1.
2.
3.
Zero transportation costs
No trade barriers
No regulations
Further effects can be observed:
4.
Rich countries usually have higher prices ๏ƒ  Penn effect
5.
Non-tradeable goods (e.g. hairdresser) must be produced in the domestic country itself at high wages
(high wages because of highly productive export industry) – but the productivity advantage is usually
lower than in the export-industry ๏ƒ  Balassa-Samuelson effect
Although exact PPP never holds, it can be used for comparison between countries. Thereby, one basket of
goods is looked at and compared between countries. For each country a price for the basket is determined.
Based on the price difference, the PPP exchange rate can be determined.
Thus, it is the exchange rate at which purchasing power parity would hold (๐œ€ = 1)
8.2
Open financial markets
Not only goods and services can be traded internationally, but also capital.
If a Swiss person buys stocks or other assets from a firm abroad, or gives a loan to some foreign firm (e.g.
bond), this is called a capital export.
Accordingly, capital imports exist.
Capital Exports – Capital Imports = Net Capital Exports
It is important to note the relationship between open financial and open goods markets. Namely, if a country is
running a trade deficit, it can only do so if it receives a “loan” from the other countries. Thus, it must also be
running on negative net capital exports.
8.2.1
Balance of Payments
All the flows of goods and services as well as the flows of capital are reported in the balance of payments.
It is divided into two accounts: Current Account and Capital Account
Both accounts have to be equal!
Current Account
The current account is calculated as follows:
๐ธ๐‘ฅ๐‘๐‘œ๐‘Ÿ๐‘ก๐‘ 
− ๐ผ๐‘š๐‘๐‘œ๐‘Ÿ๐‘ก๐‘ 
= ๐‘๐‘’๐‘ก ๐ธ๐‘ฅ๐‘๐‘œ๐‘Ÿ๐‘ก๐‘ 
+ ๐‘–๐‘›๐‘๐‘œ๐‘š๐‘’ ๐‘Ÿ๐‘’๐‘๐‘’๐‘–๐‘ฃ๐‘’๐‘‘ ๐‘“๐‘Ÿ๐‘œ๐‘š ๐‘Ž๐‘๐‘Ÿ๐‘œ๐‘Ž๐‘‘
− ๐‘–๐‘›๐‘๐‘œ๐‘š๐‘’ ๐‘๐‘Ž๐‘–๐‘‘ ๐‘ก๐‘œ ๐‘œ๐‘กโ„Ž๐‘’๐‘Ÿ ๐‘๐‘œ๐‘ข๐‘›๐‘ก๐‘Ÿ๐‘–๐‘’๐‘ 
A positive current account implies a trade surplus (e.g., Switzerland)
Capital Account
The capital account reports all changes in foreign holdings of domestic assets minus changes in domestic
holdings of capital abroad. If it is positive, it implies that other countries invest in country A’s assets more than
country A invests in other countries.
Negative capital account (trade deficit) must be financed through positive capital account balance (net capital
flows)
9
9.1
International Macroeconomics
Interest Rate Parity
Even more important than imports and exports for the exchange rate are financial investments in different
countries. If I want to buy a German bond, I have to first buy Euros. If I invest one franc in German bonds now,
1
in one year I’ll have ๐ธ๐‘ก (1 + ๐‘– ∗ ) in Euros, or ๐ธ๐‘ก (1 + ๐‘– ∗ ) ∗
in francs.
๐ธ๐‘ก+1
In an equilibrium of the financial markets, the money I get in Switzerland after one year must be equal to the
money I get in Germany. This is because if one country would pay higher interest rate, everyone would buy it,
which again would increase the prices and drop the interest rates such that they’re equal again.
Thus, the following equation must hold. It is called (uncovered) interest parity:
(1 + ๐‘–) = (1 + ๐‘– ∗ )
๐ธ๐‘ก
๐‘’
๐ธ๐‘ก+1
Note that we now used expected exchange rate for the next year, because at this moment, we couldn’t know
what the exchange rate will be in a year!
For small values, we can simplify this relation to
๐‘– ≈ ๐‘–∗ −
Thereby, the last term
๐‘’
(๐ธ๐‘ก+1
−๐ธ๐‘ก )
๐ธ๐‘ก
๐‘’
(๐ธ๐‘ก+1
− ๐ธ๐‘ก )
๐ธ๐‘ก
is the expected growth rate of the nominal exchange rate E
๐‘’
In contrast, the covered interest parity uses the forward rate instead of ๐ธ๐‘ก+1
9.1.1
Empirical example
From the uncovered interest parity relation, we can derive that if the domestic interest rate is lower than the
foreign interest rate, the difference is the appreciation of the domestic currency. We get compensated for the
lower interest rate in Switzerland by the appreciation of the Swiss franc.
For example, we can observe that for a 10 year Swiss government bond we get 1.1%, whereas for US
government bonds we get 3.6%, Thus there must be a 2.5% yearly appreciation of the Swiss franc, if the
interest parity holds.
9.2
Demand for goods in an open economy (IS-Curve)
Demand for domestic goods:
๐ผ๐‘€
๐œ€
๐ผ๐‘€
Whereby refers to the imports in units of domestic goods (that’s why real exchange rate).
๐‘ =๐ถ+๐ผ+๐บ+๐‘‹−
๐œ€
๐ท๐ท = ๐ถ + ๐ผ + ๐บ refers to the domestic demand
๐ด๐ด = ๐ถ + ๐ผ + ๐บ − ๐ผ๐‘€ refers to the domestic demand for domestic goods
Imports increase in domestic income Y and in the real exchange rate. Thus: ๐ผ๐‘€ = ๐ผ๐‘€(๐‘Œ, ๐œ€)
Exports increase in foreign income Y* and decrease in the real exchange rate. Thus: ๐‘‹ = ๐‘‹(๐‘Œ ∗ , ๐œ€)
9.2.1
Equilibrium in the Open Goods Market
The goods market is in equilibrium when the domestic production Y is equal to the demand for domestic goods
Z (again, take 45° line)
๐‘Œ = ๐‘ = ๐ถ(๐‘Œ − ๐‘‡) + ๐ผ(๐‘Œ, ๐‘Ÿ + ๐‘ฅ) + ๐บ + ๐‘๐‘‹(๐‘Œ, ๐‘Œ ∗ , ๐œ€)
๏ƒ  increase in domestic demand increases Y, and reduces NX (as imports get bigger)
๏ƒ  increase in foreign demand increases Y, and increases NX (as exports increase)
9.3
Marshall-Lerner condition
The Marshall-Lerner condition is about the effect of a decrease in the real exchange rate ๐œ€ on the net exports.
As we know, exports depend negatively on ๐œ€, while imports depend positively on ๐œ€. Thus, if the real exchange
rate decreases, exports go up, while the imports decrease.
However, we also know that a decrease in ๐œ€ leads to an increase in prices of the imports in terms of domestic
๐ผ๐‘€
goods ( ). Thus, while we import less, the prices for these imports are more expensive, which again increases
๐œ€
imports in a way (quantitatively).
So the question arises: What is the net effect?
Because you have a positive quantity effect (in terms of NX), but a negative price effect.
The Marshall-Lenner condition states that the net exports, NX, increase if the real exchange rate ๐œ€ depreciates
(decreases) ๏ƒ  reduce trade deficit by depreciating ๐œ€
9.4
Implications for government intervention
A goal of the government is to reduce the trade deficit. As we have seen above, it can do that by depreciating
๐œ€. However, this would also increase Y.
Shall the government not wish for an increase in Y, it can reduce that effect by reducing government spending.
What happens is that the government was able to reduce the trade deficit, while keeping the GDP at its original
level.
9.5
IS-LM model
For the IS curve:
-
Real depreciation and increase of Y* increase NX ๏ƒ  IS curve shifts to the right
Appreciation and decrease of Y* decrease NX ๏ƒ  IS curve shifts to the left
LM curve not looked at!
9.6
Investment equals Savings in the open economy?
By rearranging, we obtain:
๐‘๐‘‹ = ๐‘† + ๐‘‡ − ๐บ − ๐ผ
In other words: Net exports are equal to the sum of private and public savings minus the domestic investments.
๏‚ท
That means that if a country has a current account surplus (NX > 0), the savings are higher than the
domestic investments. Hence, it must be that the country invests (gives loans) in other countries.
๏‚ท
If a country is running a deficit, savings are lower than domestic investment. Hence, it must be that the
country receives loans (investments) from abroad
๏‚ท
If domestic investments increase, then either domestic savings must increase or NX must decrease
๏‚ท
A country that increases its government deficit must have increasing private savings, or decreasing
investments, or decreasing net exports.
๏‚ท
A country with high savings either has high domestic investments or a high current account surplus
10 Growth
10.1 What is growth and why is it important?
In the medium run, we have recessions and boom phases. If you look at it in the bigger picture, an increasing
trend line can be observed. This trend line reflects the development of the potential output in an economy.
What follows is that long term growth has nothing to do with the demand side, but with the supply side.
The fact that this line is upwards sloping cannot be taken for granted. Only since recently such a development
can be observed, and that counts only for the richer countries!
It is however very important that we have long-term growth rather than stagnation. First, per capita income
correlates strongly with life expectancy, child mortality rates, or education. Second, in a stagnation economy A
can only become richer if B becomes poorer (zero sum game), while in a growing economy A can become richer
without B suffering a loss. This is important for the societal and political climate.
10.2 Theoretical Growth Model: Solow
In the long term, it is all about the aggregate output/production Y. The Solow model assumes that Y is defined
by two factors only: capital K and labor N.
๐‘Œ = ๐น(๐พ, ๐‘)
This production function satisfies some very relevant properties:
1. Constant returns to scale: If we double the amount of K and N, we also double Y
๐œ†๐‘Œ = ๐น(๐œ†๐พ, ๐œ†๐‘)
2.
Decreasing marginal product: If we increase K or N by 1, Y increases. If we increase K or N further, Y
increases by less
๐‘“๐พ′ > 0 ๐‘Ž๐‘›๐‘‘ ๐‘“๐พ′′ < 0
๐‘“๐‘′ > 0 ๐‘Ž๐‘›๐‘‘ ๐‘“๐‘′′ < 0
With these properties we can rewrite our production function to get to the capital per worker (capital
intensity) and the output per worker
๐‘˜=
๐พ
๐‘Œ
๐‘Ž๐‘›๐‘‘ ๐‘ฆ =
๐‘
๐‘
From this, a production function can be derived relating capital intensity to output per worker
๐‘Œ
๐พ
= ๐‘“( )
๐‘
๐‘
It looks like this
So how can we increase output per worker (i.e. GDP per capita)?
1.
2.
If the capital per worker increases ๏ƒ  movement along the curve
If productivity increases ๏ƒ  upwards shift of the curve
Hence growth can be generated either through capital accumulation or through technological progress.
10.3 Growth through Capital Accumulation
This is where the Solow model sees itself. Namely, it describes growth as a result of capital accumulation.
It is an exogenous growth model. Hence, N is constant and there technological progress is exogenous.
Underlying is a very simple cycle. With my capital stock K, I can produce output Y today. This output translates
into income, of which I can save a portion s, which lead to my investments I. Of these investments, a part d gets
lost due to depreciation of my existing capital K. The rest is added to my capital K, such that:
๐พ๐‘ก+1 = ๐พ๐‘ก + โˆ†๐พ๐‘ก = ๐พ๐‘ก + (๐ผ๐‘ก − ๐›ฟ๐พ๐‘ก )
โˆ†๐พ๐‘ก = ๐ผ๐‘ก − ๐›ฟ๐พ๐‘ก = ๐‘ ๐‘Œ๐‘ก − ๐›ฟ๐พ๐‘ก
Thus, the change in capital stock per worker (capital intensity) is equal to the savings per worker minus the
depreciation per worker:
โˆ†๐พ๐‘ก
๐‘Œ๐‘ก
๐พ๐‘ก
=๐‘  −๐›ฟ
๐‘
๐‘
๐‘
At the point where the savings per worker are higher than the depreciation the capital stock is still growing.
At the point where depreciation surpasses savings the capital stock is decreasing.
Hence, the long term equilibrium is where the growth of capital stock is zero, or, in other words, savings are
equal to depreciation.
As
๐‘Œ๐‘ก
๐‘
๐พ
= ๐‘“( ๐‘ก) we can say that for the capital intensity the steady state is where:
๐‘
๐พ๐‘ก
๐พ๐‘ก
๐‘ ๐‘“ ( ) = ๐›ฟ
๐‘
๐‘
10.4 Golden Rule
We see that by increasing the savings rate we can increase our output per capita, thus our steady state.
However, we should also keep in mind that if we save more, less will be spent thus GDP is also partly negatively
affected. So, what is the optimal savings rate?
The optimal savings rate is where our consumption is maximal. That is, the difference between the production
function and the investment function is maximal in the steady state. Mathematically speaking, the slope of the
depreciation curve (depreciation rate) must be equal to the slope of the production function
๐พ๐‘”๐‘œ๐‘™๐‘‘
๐‘“′ (
)=๐›ฟ
๐‘
10.5 Growth Accounting with a Cobb Douglas Function
๐‘Œ = ๐พ ๐›ผ ๐‘ ๐›ผ−1
Just memorize this formula for all growth accounting exercises:
๐‘”๐‘Œ = ๐‘”๐ด + ๐›ผ๐‘”๐พ + (1 − ๐›ผ)๐‘”๐‘
11 The Solow Model but extended with Productivity and Population Growth
In the previous chapter, we have said that population stays constant and productivity is exogenous thus only
leads to a shift of the production curve.
In reality, population and productivity are both constantly growing. We extend our model:
๐‘Œ = ๐น(๐พ, ๐ด๐‘)
Where A is a factor for productivity.
-
Population N grows each period by gN percent
Productivity A grows each period by gA percent
-
Thus, capital K grows each year by ๐‘”๐พ = ๐‘”๐‘˜ + ๐‘”๐‘ + ๐‘”๐ด =
(๐ผ−๐›ฟ๐พ)
๐พ
In the steady state, the capital growth per effective worker gk must be equal to zero.
Hence, we write:
๐‘”๐พ = ๐‘”๐‘ + ๐‘”๐ด
The actual capital must grow at the same rate as population and productivity to maintain the steady state.
This means that Investments must be exactly high enough to maintain the capital per effective worker. We find
it with the following condition:
๐‘”๐‘ + ๐‘”๐ด =
(๐ผ − ๐›ฟ๐พ)
๐พ
๐ผ = (๐›ฟ + ๐‘”๐‘ + ๐‘”๐ด ) ∗ ๐พ
๐ผ
= (๐›ฟ + ๐‘”๐‘ + ๐‘”๐ด ) ∗ ๐‘˜
๐ด๐‘
11.1.1
Growth rates in the steady state
In the steady state, the following growth rates apply:
๏‚ท
๏‚ท
๏‚ท
๏‚ท
๏‚ท
๏‚ท
๏‚ท
๏‚ท
๏‚ท
Capital per effective worker ๏ƒ  0
Output per effective worker ๏ƒ  0
Capital per worker ๏ƒ  gA
Output we worker ๏ƒ  gA
Productivity A ๏ƒ  gA
Labor N ๏ƒ  gN
Effective Labor AN ๏ƒ  gA + gN
Capital K ๏ƒ  gA + gN
Production Y ๏ƒ  gA + gN
11.1.2
Golden Rule
For the golden rule, see above, the slope of the production function must be equal to the slope of the breakeven investments
๐›ฟ + ๐‘”๐‘ + ๐‘”๐ด = ๐›ผ ∗ ๐‘˜ ๐›ผ−1
This also translates into the following
๐‘ ๐‘”๐‘œ๐‘™๐‘‘ = ๐›ผ
Download