Revisiting Inflation Theories: Limitations and Prospects for Forecasting Contemporary Inflation Trends Anushka V. Bagde ECN 497 Professor Terzi June 12, 2023 Abstract This paper aims to assess the adequacy of current inflation theories in explaining and predicting modern inflationary trends. The introduction begins with an overview of the present state of inflation following the COVID-19 pandemic, emphasizing its impact on the economy and living standards. It also discusses the measures taken by central banks in response to this situation. The theoretical framework examines various theories of inflation, particularly focusing on the monetarist and New Keynesian perspectives. The methodology incorporates Weber's influential concept of systemically significant prices to analyze the limitations of traditional frameworks in addressing inflation in the current context, emphasizing the need for consideration of additional factors. The primary objective of this research paper is to evaluate existing inflation theories, propose novel perspectives, and enhance our comprehension and management of inflation in the contemporary economy. 1 In the aftermath of the COVID-19 pandemic, inflation has emerged as a dominant economic force, capturing headlines and eliciting significant concern among individuals, businesses, and governments globally. This phenomenon is at its highest levels since the 1980s and has plunged several countries into prolonged periods of instability, raising fears of a recession and prompting a concerted effort to address its underlying causes and mitigate its impact (IMF). Inflation, as defined by the Federal Reserve, refers to the "general increase in the overall price level of goods and services in the economy," and is widely regarded as a "cost of living crisis." This is because inflation leads to a rise in the cost of essential goods and services, thereby eroding the standard of living (Investopedia). Due to the significant impact of inflation, several countries have made numerous attempts to mitigate its effects. The most common or widespread response by central banks is to raise interest rates, in order to dampen or slow down the economy (IMF). The Federal Reserve alters the range of the federal funds target rate depending on the economic situation, done to fulfill their dual mandate of maintaining stable prices and achieving maximum employment levels. To achieve this, the Fed raises interest rates when inflation becomes too high due to an overheated economy, and lowers them when the economy appears weak, resulting in high unemployment rates (Forbes). Currently, the US central bank is increasing interest rates at a gradual and careful pace. In March, they raised the benchmark borrowing rate by 0.25%, which resulted in a new target range of 4.75-5%. This is the first time interest rates have reached this level since the mid-2000s (Bankrate). The ECB similarly has upped its main rate up to 3.5% (The Guardian). 2 Despite these efforts, inflation continues to pose a formidable challenge as many have failed in anticipating inflation trends, thereby necessitating a critical evaluation of the adequacy of prevailing theories used to measure and address this phenomenon. For example, Fed Chair Jerome Powell consistently referred to the current inflation period as "transitory" in its early stages, asserting an expected drop in inflation by the end of 2021 (Forbes). Similar claims were made by other central banks, such as ECB board member Fabio Panetta, who stated, "the current inflation spike is temporary and driven largely by supply factors." He further emphasized the importance for central banks to exercise patience and look past these effects (Reuters). These claims can be seen to be clearly wrong now, as inflation in the US remained around 5.3% through September 2021, before surging to over 7% by December, and eventually reaching a four-decade high of approximately 9% six months later. This paper will evaluate the adequacy of prevailing inflation theories in accounting for and forecasting inflation trends in the contemporary economy, arguing that existing theories are insufficient in comprehensively elucidating and anticipating inflation patterns. The paper will emphasize the need to adopt fresh perspectives and novel approaches to overcome this limitation, specifically from Isabella Weber’s paper on measuring systemically significant prices from an input-output perspective. In order to accomplish this objective, this research paper is structured into multiple sections that seek to investigate and assess the existing dominant hypotheses of inflation, specifically in the aftermath of the pandemic. The segment on theoretical framework will scrutinize two major theories of inflation: the monetarist approach and the new Keynesian Phillips curve. The section on analysis will introduce Weber's notion of systemically significant prices as a determinant of inflation, while the discussion section will emphasize Weber's ideas 3 and propose why conventional frameworks for addressing inflation are constrained in the present circumstances, necessitating the consideration of supplementary factors. Overall, this paper aims to provide a comprehensive analysis of inflation theory and its limitations in the contemporary economy. By examining various inflation theories and their shortcomings, this paper seeks to provide insights for policymakers, researchers, and practitioners in the field of macroeconomics. It is hoped that this paper will contribute to the ongoing debate on inflation theory and encourage new approaches to the study of inflation. Theoretical Framework The literature review section of the paper analyzes different theories of inflation, beginning with an exploration of the monetarist perspective, particularly the quantity theory of money, along with the corresponding policy implications. Furthermore, the review examines the New Keynesian approach, specifically focusing on the 3-equation model. When discussing the causes of inflation, it is important to understand two terms: cost-push inflation and demand-pull inflation. Cost-push inflation occurs when prices rise due to increased costs of wages and raw materials. This leads to a decrease in the overall supply of goods and services while the demand remains the same. As a result, the increased production costs are passed on to consumers, resulting in cost-push inflation (Investopedia). On the other hand, demand-pull inflation happens when prices increase due to a shortage in the supply of goods. This is often described as a situation where there are "too many dollars chasing too few goods." Essentially, when there is more demand for goods and services than what is available, prices tend to rise (Investopedia). 4 The core belief in economics is that inflation is primarily influenced by monetary factors. This suggests that inflation is ultimately a result of how monetary policy is conducted. The monetarist theory, popularized by Milton Friedman in his influential book co-written with Anna Schwartz A Monetary History of the United States, highlights the crucial role of the money supply as a primary determinant of price levels and inflation and asserts that an excess money supply leads to an increase in aggregate demand, ultimately resulting in inflation. This aligns with the concept of demand-pull inflation. This theory finds its roots in the Quantity Theory of Money (QTM), which establishes a direct relationship between the money supply and the general price level of goods and services. According to the QTM, there is a direct proportionality between the general price level of goods and services and the money supply in an economy. In simpler terms, if the money supply doubles, assuming all other factors remain constant, price levels will also double. The underlying rationale for this relationship lies in the role of money as a medium of exchange. Money acts as a means for facilitating transactions in an economy. When there is an increase in the money supply, more money is available to be used in exchange for goods and services. However, if the quantity of money becomes relatively larger compared to the amount of goods and services available, it can lead to an imbalance in the economy. With an excess supply of money relative to the available goods and services, individuals and businesses have more money to spend. This increased demand for goods and services can drive up prices, resulting in inflation. To mathematically express this relationship, economists use the Fisher Equation (MV=PQ) to express the relationship between the money supply, price levels, and the quantity of goods and services produced in an economy. Proposed by Irving Fisher, an American economist 5 in the early 20th century, this equation provides a formal representation of the connection between these variables. The equation states that the money supply (M) multiplied by the velocity of circulation (V) is equal to the price level (P) multiplied by the quantity of goods and services produced (Q). The money supply (M) represents the total amount of money available in the economy, including physical currency and demand deposits in banks. The velocity of circulation (V) refers to the speed at which money changes hands and measures the frequency of transactions involving money. The price level (P) reflects the average prices of goods and services in the economy, indicating the purchasing power of money. The quantity of goods and services produced (Q) represents the total value of all final goods and services produced within a specific time period and is influenced by factors such as labor productivity, technology, and resource availability. The Fisher Equation assumes that the velocity of money and the quantity of goods and services produced remain relatively stable in the long run. This assumption allows economists to focus on the relationship between the money supply and the price level. Changes in the money supply are believed to primarily impact the price level rather than the real output of the economy. When it comes to policy making, the Quantity Theory of Money (QTM) suggests that central banks should regulate the money supply to ensure stable inflation levels. In the past, central banks placed significant emphasis on monetary aggregates when formulating monetary policies. A notable example is the German Bundesbank, which effectively tackled inflationary pressures resulting from the oil price shocks of the 1970s by using monetary targets. Similarly, the U.S. Federal Reserve, under Chairman Paul Volcker in 1979, highlighted the role of monetary aggregates to overcome the great inflation in the United States (Beck). 6 However, the importance of monetary aggregates has diminished in central bank strategies since then. The U.S. Federal Reserve, for instance, began reducing the significance of monetary aggregates in the early 1990s, primarily due to empirical challenges rather than new theoretical frameworks. Presently, no central bank follows a monetary targeting strategy, and the Bundesbank also faced difficulties in meeting short-term monetary growth targets during the 1990s (Beck). This is where the New Keynesian school comes in. In contrast to QTM from the monetarists, New Keynesians attribute the causes of inflation to factors beyond changes in the money supply alone. While their views draw inspiration from monetarists, they believe that inflation can emerge due to a range of factors, encompassing both demand-pull and cost-push influences (Carlin). Building upon the principles of John Maynard Keynes, modern monetary macroeconomics relies on what is commonly referred to as the 3-equation model known as IS-MP-PC. This model consists of the IS curve, interest rate-based monetary policy rule, and Phillips curve. The IS curve, which forms the foundation of the model, illustrates the intricate relationship between aggregate output and the interest rate. It highlights the interplay between investment and saving decisions, which significantly shape a country's overall economic activity. Specifically, the IS curve demonstrates that higher interest rates lead to lower output levels. It is worth noting that the IS curve focuses on the connection between output and real interest rates rather than nominal rates. Real interest rates account for the impact of inflation by subtracting it from the headline (nominal) interest rate. Ultimately, it is the real interest rate that influences consumers' perception of the attractiveness of saving versus spending. When real interest rates increase, borrowing becomes more expensive, discouraging businesses from investing. 7 Consequently, this reduction in investment spending ripples through the economy, leading to an overall decline in output. Higher interest rates also affect consumption patterns. As the real interest rate rises, the cost of borrowing for households increases, making it more expensive to finance purchases through credit. Consequently, consumers may choose to save more and reduce their spending, further contributing to the decrease in aggregate demand and output. Thus, the IS curve captures the equilibrium relationship between aggregate output and the real interest rate, representing the various combinations of output and interest rates at which the goods and services market is in balance. Secondly, the Phillips curve (PC) illustrates the trade-off between inflation and unemployment, suggesting that policymakers face a choice between these two variables in the short run. This curve, originating from A.W. Phillips' 1958 study at LSE, played a crucial role in the early development of macroeconomics. Phillips observed a strong negative correlation between wage inflation and unemployment, and subsequent research by MIT economists Robert Solow and Paul Samuelson confirmed this relationship for both wage and price inflation in the United States. The Phillips curve is a macroeconomic concept that describes the relationship between inflation, inflation expectations, and the output gap. It provides a framework for understanding the tradeoff between unemployment and inflation in an economy. The curve suggests that there is a positive relationship between inflation and the output gap (figure 1), which represents the difference between actual output and the "natural" level of output associated with full employment or the so-called natural rate of unemployment. The Phillips curve quickly became a foundation for macroeconomic policy discussions, with economists advising governments to consider the tradeoff between achieving lower unemployment and the potential for higher inflation. 8 Figure 1: The Phillips Curve The last component, monetary policy (MP), refers to the actions taken by a country's central bank to control the money supply and interest rates in order to influence economic conditions. It plays a crucial role in the modern monetary macroeconomics framework. The interest rate-based monetary policy rule represents the central bank's strategy for adjusting interest rates in response to changes in economic conditions. In this framework, the central bank adjusts the nominal interest rate upwards when inflation goes up and downwards when inflation goes down and it does so in a way that means when inflation equals a target chosen by the central bank, real interest rates will be equal to their natural level. The central bank adjusts the target interest rate based on its assessment of the current state of the economy and its desired policy objectives. The monetary policy rule is a significant component of the IS-MP-PC model because 9 it helps determine the position of the aggregate demand curve. Changes in the interest rate can affect investment and consumption decisions, which, in turn, influence aggregate demand and output levels. When the central bank raises interest rates, it aims to reduce aggregate demand and inflationary pressures The 3-equation model has gained prominence in the field of monetary economics and has significantly influenced contemporary central bank policies. This model advises policymakers to determine short-term interest rates, which serve as the primary policy tool for central banks, based on inflation forecasts and output gaps. By emphasizing the importance of these factors, the model reduces the significance of monetary aggregates derived from Friedman's monetarist perspectives, as these aggregates do not directly affect the transmission of monetary policy to output and inflation in the New-Keynesian model. Instead, monetary policy decisions are made in consideration of the nominal interest rate, which indirectly affects the real interest rate due to the inflexibility and delayed adjustment of some prices. Overall, the 3-equation model has emerged as the leading approach in the realm of monetary economics, guiding central bank policies by focusing on inflation forecasts, output gaps, and short-term interest rates. Methodology This section introduces a forward-looking approach to policy responses to inflation, based on Isabella Weber's influential working paper titled "Inflation in Times of Overlapping Emergencies: Systemically Significant Prices from an Input-output Perspective," published in 2022. It has been mentioned in the mainstream including Bloomberg, The New Yorker, the Financial Times. The key points of Weber's paper, including the utilization of the Leontif price 10 model, the definition of systemically significant prices, and her empirical findings, will be described. By adopting Weber's perspective on inflation, this research aims to assess the limitations and gaps in the standard inflation theories within the context of the contemporary economy. Weber's paper becomes increasingly significant in light of the ever-changing circumstances brought about by the COVID-19 pandemic. These times are unparalleled, both for the world as a whole and for the global economy. Initially, price surges were primarily concentrated within specific sectors before permeating the broader economy. The aftermath of the pandemic has revealed that these sector-specific price increases can be attributed to various factors, including disruptions in the supply chain and volatility in global commodity markets, which were further amplified by the ongoing conflict in Ukraine (Bank of International Settlement, 2022). In an era characterized by overlapping global emergencies, it is reasonable to anticipate more frequent shocks specific to certain sectors. This raises the question of how these shocks impact overall price stability and whether specific sectors play a more substantial role in maintaining such stability. Weber's paper introduces an innovative approach to targeting micro policies that can complement existing macroeconomic stabilization efforts. Weber begins by defining the concept of "systemically significant prices." This term, borrowed from the Financial Stability Board's definition of systemically important financial institutions based on their potential to disrupt the wider financial system and economic activity, is extended by Hockett and Omarova to include non-financial prices that can acquire systemic significance. Building upon this idea, Weber argues that systemically significant prices are not only crucial for financial stability but also for monetary stability. 11 To operationalize the notion of systemic significance and identify prices that have the most impact on inflation, Weber employs the Leontief price model. She conducts simulations of price shocks to a single industry in a single period within the Leontief price model. The resulting change in the synthetic Consumer Price Index (CPI) when the price of a specific industry is shocked by a certain amount is referred to as the inflation impact. In Weber's framework, the most systemically significant prices are those that exert the greatest influence on the general price level as measured by the CPI. By identifying the most vulnerable points in the price system, she argues that they possess the potential to acquire systemic significance for overall monetary stability. These vulnerable points are often found in the most pervasive industries, those whose output holds the utmost importance for the entire economic system in terms of direct and indirect input value. In examining the significance of specific industries for overall monetary stability, Weber focuses not only on the structural importance of an industry, as indicated by the ubiquity of its products, but also on the degree of price fluctuation within that industry. Price volatility varies significantly across different sectors. Hence, an industry that produces a widely used input but experiences minimal price fluctuations may have a lesser impact on overall monetary stability compared to a less prevalent industry with higher price volatility. Instead of excluding goods with high price volatility from the core CPI, as is commonly done in economic analysis, Weber considers the systemwide implications of price volatility transmitted through input-output relationships within her simulation-based approach. The core model employed by Weber is the Leontief price model, which rests on the fundamental premise that the entire economy constitutes an extensive intersectoral network of cost-price connections. This implies an "interdependence among wage rates, profits earned, and 12 taxes paid per unit of output in each of the many separate industries on the one hand and the prices of all different kinds of goods and services sold by these industries on the other" (Leontief, 1947). By modeling prices as interconnected, Weber is able to simulate how an increase in a specific price "is transmitted to the rest of the economy step by step via the chain of transactions that links the whole system together" (Leontief, 1951), ultimately resulting in a rise in the general price level. In essence, this allows Weber to simulate cost-push inflation. When the price of any input rises, it directly affects the prices of industries utilizing that input, as well as indirectly impacts the costs of other industries reliant on the output of the directly affected sectors. It is important to note that Weber's model assumes constant wages and profits in nominal terms. This implies that real wages and the profit share in total output of each sector decline as prices increase due to a cost shock. By abstracting from nominal wage and profit adjustments in the baseline model, Weber isolates the cost-push impact of systemically significant prices from phenomena such as profiteering or wage-price spirals. Weber then presents the results of her simulations of price shocks. She simulates shocks to each of the 71 industries in the input-output table published by the U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis, identifying the industries that have the greatest total inflation impact and are thus systemically significant for price stability. She utilizes the magnitudes of average price volatilities between 2000 and 2019 as shocks in the simulation to identify latent systemically significant prices in the two decades prior to the current inflation context. Subsequently, she compares these latent systemically significant prices with the sectors that acquire systemic significance when the price shocks are applied based on the post-shutdown inflation and the context of the war in Ukraine. 13 The magnitude of the price shocks to each industry, represented by a green dot, reflects the average annual price change of each industry between 2000 and 2019, which is referred to as the "sectoral price volatility." Figures 2.2 and 2.3 illustrate the annual price changes of each industry between 2020-Q4 and 2021-Q4 (post-pandemic context) and between 2021-Q2 and 2022-Q2 (Ukraine war context), respectively. The yellow share indicates the direct inflation impact, while the purple share represents the indirect inflation impact. The direct inflation impact depends solely on the weight in the CPI and the magnitude of the price shock. On the other hand, the indirect inflation impact captures an industry's position in the input-output network, measured by the number of forward linkages. The combined length of the purple and yellow bars reflects the total inflation impact on a synthetic CPI generated by a price shock to each industry. Figure 2.1 Sectoral Price Volatility 2000-2019 The inflation impact varies widely, with certain industries exerting a more significant influence than others. Notably, the "Petroleum and coal products" industry stands out, with a latent inflation impact of 0.42 percent, more than twice as large as the next most important industry. This industry alone accounts for almost one-quarter of the Fed's target interest rate. 14 Following this industry, the next eight industries in the ranking of inflation impact form a distinct group with a notably greater impact than the industries further down the list. In contrast, the rest of the ranking shows less segmentation. This suggests the presence of a group of industries that possess a distinctly high level of latent systemic significance. Figure 2.2 Yearly Price Change from 2020 Q4 to 2021 Q4 In the analysis of the post-shutdown inflation impact, it is observed that the magnitude of the total inflation impact has tripled compared to the latent inflation impact calculation from 2000 to 2019. However, the sectors that have the most significant impact on inflation remain largely the same. Except for the "Motor vehicle and part dealers" industry, which experienced a pandemic-related price increase of almost 40%, the other eight industries in the top nine most significant prices were also identified as having latent systemic significance. Once again, the "Petroleum and coal products" industry stands out as the most potent industry for price stability, with an inflation impact of 1.48%, resulting from a substantial price increase of 75.66%. The next most important industry has about half the impact of the petroleum industry. 15 Additionally, the relative importance of each industry has shifted slightly compared to the latent inflation impact analysis. One notable change is the rise of the "Wholesale trade" sector, which has become the third most important industry for total inflation. The pandemic-induced supply chain issues presented opportunities for wholesale traders to increase their prices significantly, with an annual price increase of 9.56%, more than five times the average price volatility of the previous two decades. The "Chemical products" industry has also risen to rank 4 in terms of total inflation impact, with prices increasing by an astonishing 18.13%, almost four times the average volatility. Figure 2.3 Yearly Price Change from 2021 Q2 and 2022 Q2 The results of the inflation impact analysis following the war in Ukraine closely resemble those of the post-shutdown phase. The "Petroleum and coal products" industry remains the most important sector by a significant margin, reflecting its latent importance in the global energy crisis. The price increase in the "Utilities" sector further climbed to 26.81%, placing it at rank four in terms of total inflation impact. "Wholesale trade" climbed to the second rank due to a substantial annual price increase of 10.97%. The "Housing" sector became even more important, ranking third in terms of inflation impact, with prices continuing to rise in a heated housing 16 market, reaching an annual increase of 5.24%. The "Farms" sector experienced a price increase of 25.92% due to the war in Ukraine's impact on global food markets, placing it at rank seven in terms of inflation impact. The "Chemical products" sector's prices eased somewhat, leading to a fall to rank nine. Two new sectors joined the top ten ranks: "Food services and drinking places" at rank eight, reflecting high food prices and the return of eating out after COVID-19 shutdowns, and "Truck transportation" at rank ten, likely influenced by high fuel prices. Isabella Weber's paper presents a groundbreaking approach to identifying prices that have significant implications for price stability. Her findings demonstrate that the sectors that are most important in this regard remain consistent when considering both pre-pandemic average price volatilities and the price shocks experienced during the current inflation period. However, the overall impact of inflation has significantly increased during the post-shutdown and Ukraine war inflation, approximately tripling in magnitude compared to latent inflation impact simulations. In essence, the pre-pandemic economy's latent systemic significance has materialized in the form of post-shutdown and Ukraine war inflation. Several sectors have been identified as having systemic significance, including "Petroleum and coal products," "Oil and gas extraction," "Farms," "Food and beverage and tobacco products," "Chemical products," "Housing," "Utilities," and "Wholesale trade." Notably, these sectors that gained systemic significance during the post-shutdown period and in the aftermath of the Ukraine war align with those identified as systemically significant in simulations using average price volatilities from 2000 to 2019. This observation suggests that had appropriate institutions and policies been in place to stabilize these prices of systemic importance, the current inflation crisis could have been proactively managed. 17 Discussion To address inflation effectively in the current context, it is necessary to move beyond traditional frameworks and consider additional factors. Most economists have traditionally viewed inflation as a macroeconomic phenomenon, with monetarists attributing it to "too much money chasing too few goods" and New Keynesians linking it to the relationship between aggregate demand and capacity utilization. These traditional approaches focus on controlling macroeconomic variables such as the quantity of money and government spending. However, recent inflationary pressures have revealed the limitations of these approaches, especially in dealing with commodity-specific price shocks, energy crises, input shortages, and environmental shocks. Central banks, responsible for maintaining monetary stability, have struggled to address these challenges, as acknowledged by Federal Reserve Chair Powell during a Congressional Hearing in 2022. Consequently, policymakers have implemented reactive measures like windfall profit taxes, anti-trust measures, price gouging policies, and direct price stabilization. However, these measures have been ad hoc and often implemented only when inflation reaches unprecedented levels. Considering the likelihood of more systemic shocks and overlapping emergencies, there is a need for economic disaster preparedness to protect against vulnerabilities that could destabilize monetary stability beyond the current inflationary environment. Responding to significant price shocks before they trigger broader inflation dynamics is crucial. Examining historical examples, the use of price controls during World War II in the United States emerged as an effective strategy when inflation rates were close to two percent. Industry-specific price controls prevented companies from raising prices above certain levels, containing consumer costs while encouraging companies to increase sales volume to boost 18 profits. This approach limited inflation without resorting to layoffs and wage cuts. Comparing the economic conditions of the forties to the present, similarities like high consumer demand, record corporate profits, and production bottlenecks suggest that strategies like price controls from the wartime period could be relevant and effective today. Contrasting with the conventional tactic of raising interest rates, which could harm employment and industrial activity during wartime, industry-specific price controls manage consumer costs while enabling companies to maintain profitability through increased sales volume. Therefore, policymakers can explore the implementation of industry-specific price controls, considering the historical success of price controls and recognizing the similarities between past and present economic conditions, to contain inflation while supporting economic stability. Additionally, relying solely on raising interest rates can make borrowing more challenging for businesses, potentially leading to cost-cutting measures like layoffs. Larry Summers, former United States Secretary of the Treasury, even proposed aiming for a ten-percent unemployment rate, resulting in sixteen million people losing their jobs. However, this approach is considered painful. Comparing the pandemic relief spending of the United States to that of Japan, it becomes evident that excessive government spending is not the sole cause of inflation. Japan experienced inflation peaking at only 4.3 percent despite significant spending. This challenges the assumption that excessive government spending always leads to high inflation. Moreover, if excessive household wealth were the primary driver, one would expect a uniform rise in prices across all consumer goods. However, inflationary pressure has mostly originated from specific products and commodities, such as natural gas, which have experienced significant price spikes. This observation challenges the notion that households are directing all 19 their stimulus checks towards raising thermostat settings or increasing consumption across the board. By questioning the proposed solution of inducing mass layoffs and considering these counterpoints, a more nuanced understanding of inflation drivers emerges. Factors like specific supply and demand dynamics for certain products and commodities play a significant role. In highly concentrated industries, companies have demonstrated the ability to prioritize price increases over changes in volume, even in situations where demand is declining. The understanding that competitors are likely to adopt similar pricing measures to protect their profit margins further incentivizes coordinated pricing behavior. This has led firms across various industries to inflate prices during the chaotic pandemic circumstances, exploiting customers who were already expecting price hikes due to disruptions. This phenomenon, termed "sellers' inflation," contrasts with the traditional model of inflation where excess consumer purchasing power is typically seen as the cause. Additionally, Weber highlights that disruptions occurring further upstream in the supply chain have a more significant impact on consumers. For instance, if the price of electricity or oil rises, it becomes harder to produce or transport various goods. The same principle applies to essential commodities like chemicals, metals, and lumber, which are necessary for manufacturing more complex products. Preventing these crucial component prices from spiraling out of control could help mitigate inflationary pressures. Considering the likelihood of more systemic shocks and overlapping emergencies, there is a need for economic disaster preparedness to protect against vulnerabilities that could destabilize monetary stability beyond the current inflationary environment. Weber suggests targeting micro policies that complement macroeconomic stabilization efforts. She argues that 20 vulnerabilities for price stability existed before the pandemic, and actual inflation involves not only a change in the average price level but also a change in relative prices. Cost increases in certain sectors lead to price increases through input-output relationships. This aligns with Keynes's view that inflation involves far-reaching redistribution, with unequal incidence of price level shifts. Swift implementation of targeted measures is crucial to prevent price shocks from propagating and contributing to inflationary pressures. This requires monitoring systemically significant prices and having contingency plans for price stabilization, enhanced oversight, and regulation in these sectors to discourage drastic price increases. Price stabilization policies can take various forms, including strict price gouging legislation, automatic taxes on windfall profits for systemically significant prices during emergencies, or strategic price caps. Regulations on financial speculation and anti-trust legislation can also play important roles in stabilizing prices in systemically significant sectors. The specific mechanisms and forms of price stabilization measures should be tailored to the realities of each sector, considering physical, institutional, and social factors. For instance, (international) buyer stocks and central bank-style open market operations have been suggested for important commodities. Investment encouragement programs may be necessary in underinvested areas, and measures to enhance supply chain resilience, such as minimum inventory requirements for systemically important goods, can help mitigate supply shocks. In conclusion, understanding inflation as a multifaceted dynamic involving economic and psychological factors reveals the mechanisms behind coordinated pricing behaviors. Policymakers have resorted to ad hoc price stabilization measures, but swift implementation is crucial to prevent price shocks from driving up inflation. Effective price stabilization policies 21 should be tailored to systemically significant sectors and complemented by enhanced oversight, regulation, and contingency plans. Further research is needed to refine these policies and develop a comprehensive framework for addressing inflationary challenges. Bibliography Adrian, Tobias, and Vitor Gaspar. “How Fiscal Restraint Can Help Fight Inflation.” IMF, November 21, 2022. https://www.imf.org/en/Blogs/Articles/2022/11/21/how-fiscal-restraint-can-help-fight-infla tion. Agarwal, M. “Quantity Theory of Money and Its Assumptions – Explained !” Economics Discussion, August 10, 2015. https://www.economicsdiscussion.net/money/quantity-theory-of-money/quantity-theory-of -money-and-its-assumptions-explained/8075. Alloway, Tracy, and Joe Weisenthal. “Isabella Weber Explains Why We’re Rethinking the Way Inflation Works.” Bloomberg.com, June 8, 2023. https://www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/2023-06-08/isabella-weber-explains-why-we-rerethinking-the-way-inflation-works. Banton, Caroline. “Cost of Living: Definition, How to Calculate, Index, and Example.” Investopedia, October 14, 2022. https://www.investopedia.com/terms/c/cost-of-living.asp. Beck, Günter W., and Volker Wieland. “Money in Monetary Policy Design: Monetary Cross-Checking in the New-Keynesian Model.” ECB Working Paper Serie, No. 1191, May 2010. https://doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.1599640. Carlin, Wendy, and David Soskice. “Teaching Intermediate Macroeconomics Using the 3-Equation Model.” Macroeconomic Theory and Macroeconomic Pedagogy, 2009, 13–35. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-0-230-29166-9_2. Carter, Zachary. “What If We’re Thinking about Inflation All Wrong?” The New Yorker, June 6, 2023. https://www.newyorker.com/news/persons-of-interest/what-if-were-thinking-about-inflatio n-all-wrong. Chen, James. “What Is Demand-Pull Inflation?” Investopedia, May 28, 2023. https://www.investopedia.com/terms/d/demandpullinflation.asp. “ECB Sticks with Transitory Description of Inflation.” Reuters, December 2, 2021. https://www.reuters.com/world/europe/ecb-sticks-with-transitory-description-inflation-202 1-12-02/. Foster, Sarah. “How Much More Will the Fed Raise Rates in 2023?” Bankrate, May 16, 2023. https://www.bankrate.com/banking/federal-reserve/how-much-will-fed-raise-rates-in-2023/ . Inman, Phillip, and Kalyeena Makortoff. “ECB Raises Eurozone Interest Rate despite Banking Sector Fears.” The Guardian, March 16, 2023. https://www.theguardian.com/business/2023/mar/16/ecb-raises-interest-rates-despite-banki ng-fears-credit-suisse#:~:text=The%200.5%20percentage%20point%20rise,the%20ECB% 20increases%20to%203%25. Kenton, Will. “Cost Push Inflation: When It Occurs, Definition, and Causes.” Investopedia, May 11, 2023. https://www.investopedia.com/terms/c/costpushinflation.asp. “Monetarist Theory.” Corporate Finance Institute, December 27, 2022. https://corporatefinanceinstitute.com/resources/economics/monetarist-theory/. Tepper, Taylor. “Federal Funds Rate History 1990 to 2023.” Forbes, May 3, 2023. https://www.forbes.com/advisor/investing/fed-funds-rate-history/. Tretina, Kat. “Transitory Inflation: A Short History.” Forbes, August 22, 2022. https://www.forbes.com/advisor/investing/transitory-inflation/#:~:text=According%20to% 20Powell%2C%20soon%20everything,the%20end%20of%20the%20year. Weber, Isabella M., Jesus Lara Jauregui, Lucas Teixeira, and Luiza Nassif Pires. "Inflation in Times of Overlapping Emergencies: Systemically Significant Prices from an Input-output Perspective." Economics Department Working Paper Series, no. 340, 2022. Accessed June 12, 2023. https://doi.org/10.7275/0c5b-6a92. “What Is Inflation and How Does the Federal Reserve Evaluate Changes in the Rate of Inflation?” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, September 9, 2016. https://www.federalreserve.gov/faqs/economy_14419.htm.