THE ECONOMIC RECORD, VOL. 78, NO. 1, MARCH, 2002, 79–96 The Effect of Alcohol Consumption on Earnings* GARRY F. BARRETT Department of Economics, University of New South Wales Sydney, NSW 2052 The effect of alcohol consumption on the earnings of full-time male workers is analysed using the Australian National Health Survey 1989–90. A multinomial logit choice model is used to explain workers’ choice of drinking status and to correct for selection bias in the earnings equation estimation. It is found that moderate drinking leads to a significant earnings premium relative to abstention and heavy drinking. The results are consistent with moderate drinking improving individual’s health and hence productivity and earnings. depression and improved cognitive performance (such as problem solving and short term memory) (Baum-Baicker 1985b). By the same token, the negative health effects of heavy or excessive alcohol consumption have long been known. The harmful health consequences of heavy drinking and alcohol dependence range from gastrointestinal diseases (such as cirrhosis) to endocrine and metabolic disorders and behavioural problems (Last 1998). Recently researchers have begun to examine whether the health effects of drinking patterns translate into labour market outcomes. The potential impact of health status on earnings represents a straightforward extension of the human capital framework of earnings determination2 which has been confirmed in numerous empirical studies.3 More specifically, current alcohol consumption can influence contemporaneous health status (such as through the beneficial psychological effects of moderate drinking, or the immediate after effects of heavy drinking), as may drinking behaviour over an extended period of time (through the physiological effects of long term moderate and heavy I Introduction In recent years numerous reports have appeared in the popular press highlighting the health benefits of moderate alcohol consumption. There is a substantial body of medical research examining the health consequences of drinking behaviour, and the beneficial effects of moderate alcohol consumption are well established. For example, moderate drinking is associated with a lower risk of coronary heart disease, due to increases in the level of beneficial cholesterol (HDL) in the bloodstream, and a lower risk of mortality in general (Baum-Baicker 1985a; Shaper 1993)1 Psychological benefits from moderate alcohol consumption have commonly been found, including reduced stress, anxiety and *I wish to thank Martin Browning, Bruce Chapman, Tom Crossley, Catherine de Fontenay, David Green, Bob Gregory, P.J. O’Reilly, Adrian Pagan, Craig Riddell, Michael Veall, Jenny Williams, seminar participants at the Australian National University, McMaster University, the University of Adelaide, the University of New South Wales, participants at the Australian Labour Econometrics Workshop and two anonymous referees for constructive comments on a previous draft. Research support through the UNSW ARC Small Grants Scheme is gratefully acknowledged. The usual disclaimers apply. Email: g.barrett@unsw. edu.au 1 The American Journal of Public Health 1993 vol.83(6) issue contains a series of editorials reviewing the literature on the health effects of alcohol consumption. 2 Grossman (1972) was the first to formally incorporate the impact of health status and health risk/ maintenance behaviour in the human capital model of earnings determination. 3 Smith (1999) provides an overview of recent research on the relationship between health and economic status. 79 Ó 2002. The Economic Society of Australia. ISSN 0013-0249. 80 ECONOMIC RECORD drinking). The health consequences of drinking may then affect productivity at work (such as through absenteeism, reliability and overall job performance). In competitive labour markets workers receive a wage reflecting their productivity, hence alcohol consumption patterns may ultimately be reflected in individual earnings. A number of studies have examined the effect of alcohol consumption on earnings while treating drinking status as exogenous. Mullahy and Sindelar (1991, 1993) have shown that extremely heavy alcohol consumption, as evidenced by alcoholism, is associated with substantially lower earnings and income. French and Zarkin (1995) analysed data from a special company-based survey in the United States and found a significant wage premium for drinkers, although the premium declined for the most frequent drinkers. However, in an attempt to replicate these results with a nationally representative sample, Zarkin et al. (1998) found no evidence of an inverse U-shaped relationship between alcohol use and wages. They found that drinkers received approximately 7 per cent higher wages and that premium was received across a very wide range of average daily alcohol consumption levels. Lye and Hirschberg (1999) used the Australian National Health Survey for 1995 to examine the effects of drinking, smoking, exercise and weight gain on earnings. They found that drinking yielded an earnings premium, and the earnings premium for both men and women was maximised at an average daily consumption level of approximately four drinks. A limitation of these studies is that the estimated earnings impact of drinking may simply reflect the reverse effect of income on alcohol consumption levels. Indeed, the finding of higher earnings for drinkers is consistent with the alternative hypothesis that alcohol is simply a normal good. To isolate the effect of alcohol consumption on earnings it is necessary to control for the potential endogeneity of an individual’s drinking status. Several studies have addressed the endogeneity of drinking status in analysing the effect of alcohol on earnings. The first was Berger and Leigh (1988), which was also the first study to analyse the link between alcohol consumption and earnings. Using United States data for 1972– 1973, Berger and Leigh estimated separate earnings equations for drinkers and non-drinkers, after estimating a first-stage probit equation to account for the endogeneity of drinking status. They found that drinkers earned a substantial MARCH wage premium relative to non-drinkers, and the premium did not diminish for the most frequent, heavy drinkers. Kenkel and Ribar (1994) used data from the US National Longitudinal Survey of Youth and implemented a range of estimators to examine the earnings effect of heavy drinking4 and alcohol abuse.5 In their preferred specification which used instrumental variable methods they estimated that heavy drinking led to a 12 per cent earnings penalty (and alcohol abuse to a 30 per cent penalty) for young men. Hamilton and Hamilton (1997) analysed Canadian data and divided the population of male workers into non-drinkers, moderate and heavy drinkers. They estimated separate wage equations after controlling for an individual’s selection of drinking status using a multinomial logit choice model. Hamilton and Hamilton found that moderate drinkers received a wage premium relative to non-drinkers while heavy drinkers received a substantial wage penalty. This study contributes to this body of literature by examining earnings differentials across drinker types using the Australian National Health Survey for 1989–1990 (NHS89). Following Hamilton and Hamilton (1997) the population of male workers is divided into three groups (non, moderate and heavy drinkers) to differentiate between the health and hence productivity and earnings consequences of different drinking patterns. The multinomial logit model is used to control for the choice of drinking status. The empirical framework explicitly addresses the endogeneity bias that may arise through the simultaneity of drinking status and earnings, due to the reverse causation from income to alcohol consumption or unobserved heterogeneity. The NHS89 contains detailed information on respondents’ alcohol consumption and socioeconomic backgrounds and is representative of the national population, unlike the data utilised by Kenkel and Ribar (1994) which was for a cohort of youths. The NHS89 has the additional advantage of providing both a substantial sample 4 Defined as drinking six or more drinks on at least one day during the reference month. 5 Alcohol abuse was defined as a ‘maladaptive pattern of alcohol use evidenced by (self-reported) continued drinking despite a persistent social, occupational, psychological or physical problem related to drinking.’ 2002 81 ALCOHOL CONSUMPTION AND EARNINGS of observations and a large array of covariates. In particular, the NHS89 includes a number of potential instruments for drinking status and contains detailed information on job characteristics. These attributes make the NHS89 a richer data source than that examined by Hamilton and Hamilton (1997), providing potentially stronger identification of the effect of alcohol consumption on earnings. Two sets of instruments for identifying individuals’ choice of drinking status are used in the main part of the analysis presented in this paper. The instruments are a dummy variable indicating whether the individual smoked when 18 years of age (providing a retrospective measure of an individual’s attitude toward risk) plus a set of variables measuring drinking patterns in an individual’s local region (which capture social influences on drinking behaviour).6 The major finding from the analysis is that there is a significant, positive earnings differential for moderate drinking and a significant earnings penalty for heavy drinking. These earnings effects are masked by important selection bias effects in the raw data which highlights the salience of controlling for the endogeneity of individuals’ drinking behaviour. The earnings premium for moderate drinkers, relative to both abstainers and heavy drinkers, is predominantly due to greater returns to personal and job characteristics rather than to differences in the level of those characteristics. This finding is consistent with the hypothesis that moderate alcohol consumption has beneficial health and hence labour market productivity effects. The results are somewhat mixed regarding the abstention-heavy drinking earnings differential. However, based on the specification of the earnings equations most strongly supported by the data, abstainers are found to receive an earnings premium relative to heavy drinkers that is consistent with the negative productivity and earnings consequences of excessive alcohol consumption. This paper is organised as follows. The next section outlines the empirical model used to analyse worker selection of drinking status and to isolate the independent effect of drinking on earnings. In section III the data used in the analysis are detailed. The results of the earnings equation estimation, earnings decompositions and specification tests are presented in section IV. Finally, section V briefly summarises the major results and offers concluding comments. II Empirical Model The objective of the analysis is to test whether alcohol consumption has an impact on individuals’ earnings while allowing for the endogeneity of drinking status. Assume that the potential earnings for individual i with drinking status j is given by lnwij ¼ x0i bj þ eij ; j ¼ 1; 2; 3 ð1Þ where xi is vector of human capital and demographic characteristics and eij Nð0; r2j Þ: This specification is very general, allowing the labour market returns to individual characteristics to differ by drinking status. By comparing the estimated b across drinker types it is possible to gauge whether the labour market rewards for observed productivity-related characteristics are greatest for moderate drinkers, and lowest for heavy drinkers, as implied by the medical research on the health effects of alcohol consumption. Individuals are assumed to select the earningsdrinking status combination that maximises expected utility. The ith individual’s expected utility from an earnings-drinking status combination is modelled by the index function Vij ¼ z0i cj þ tij ; j ¼ 1; 2; 3 ð2Þ The vector of individual characteristics, zi , includes all the variables that may determine earnings (xi ) plus additional variables that solely reflect the individual’s preferences over levels of alcohol consumption. Assuming the tij error terms are distributed according to the type I extreme value distribution gives the standard multinomial logit choice model PrðIi ¼ jÞ ¼ expðz0i cj Þ P expðz0i cs Þ 3 ð3Þ s¼1 6 It is noted that the variables in the NHS89 used to construct the instruments for drinking status (age first commenced smoking, and location by health region) are not available in the NHS95. The earnings equations are estimated using an extension of the generalised two-step procedure presented in Lee (1982, 1983). The appropriate specification of the earnings equation conditional on alternative j being chosen is: 82 ECONOMIC RECORD lnwij ¼ x0i bj rj qj /fU1 ½F ðz0i cj Þ g þ nij F ðz0i cj Þ ð4Þ where F denotes the multinomial logit distribution function, U and / denote the standard normal distribution and density functions, respectively, qj is the correlation coefficient between the unobservables in the earnings and selection equations and Eðnij jIi ¼ jÞ ¼ 0: The second term on the right-hand side of equation (4) controls for the truncated mean of the observed residual in the earnings equations arising from individuals selecting their preferred drinking status. The truncated mean is a generalisation of the standard Heckman correction term (inverse mills ratio) to the situation where individuals choose over multiple alternatives.7 In the NHS89 data earnings are censored into discrete intervals and an indicator variable denoting that earnings fall into a specific interval is reported. The income range is divided into K intervals, the kth given by ðAk1 ; Ak ; with A0 ¼ 1 and AK ¼ 1: The observed earnings information is lnwij ¼ ki iff Ak1 < lnwij Ak: This data structure corresponds to the grouped regression model examined by Stewart (1983). The log-likelihood function for the grouped regression model extended to control for selectivity bias with a polychotomous choice model is given by: LLFj ¼ K X X ln U ðAk x0i bj þ rj qj MARCH tion coefficient qj < 0 ð> 0Þ implies that individuals who chose drinking status j have unobserved characteristics which lead them to earn more (less) than a person randomly drawn from the population and assigned drinking status j. Alternatively, qj ¼ 0 implies no correlation in the residuals of the earnings and choice equations and hence there is no apparent selection bias in the observed earnings for drinker type j. III Data The data analysed in this study are from the Australian National Health Survey 1989–1990 conducted by the Australian Bureau of Statistics. The NHS89 is a large, nationally representative survey which collected information by personal interview on individuals’ health status, health risk factors, including detailed information on alcohol consumption, as well background information on labour market activity over the previous year. The sample that is analysed is restricted to men aged between 25 and 59 years,8 who are full-time9 wage and salary workers10 and whose usual major activity is working.11 The earnings variable available in the NHS89 is gross personal income annualised for the year prior to the survey date.12 The sample restrictions are to ensure the income measure corresponds to earnings as closely as possible. Additionally, focussing on full-time employees will ensure that the predominant source of variation in the income measure will be hourly earnings.13 One advantage of the NHS89 over other data k¼1 i2k ð5Þ /ðU1 ðF ðz0i cj ÞÞ=F ðz0i cj ÞÞÞ=rj 1 U ðAk1 x0i bj þ rj qj /ðU ðF ðz0i cj ÞÞ= F ðz0i cj ÞÞÞ=rj g; j ¼ 1; 2;3 Estimating equation (5) provides consistent estimates of bj . The first step is to estimate the multinomial logit model of equation (3) to obtain ^c. In the second step, the ^cj are substituted for c in (5) and the grouped regression models are then estimated. It is then possible to formally test for the presence of selectivity bias. An estimated correla- 7 This empirical model has also been used by Trost and Lee (1983) to examine the returns to education, and by Gyourko and Tracy (1988) to analyse union and public sector wage differentials, while controlling for sample selection. 8 Prime age men were chosen in order to avoid having to model participation decisions. 9 The NHS contains a limited amount of information on hours worked per week, and individuals who worked less than 35 hours per week were dropped from the sample. 10 The self-employed are therefore excluded. 11 Students are excluded through this restriction. 12 Gross income per pay period (the latter measured in weeks) was recorded in the survey and the annualised amount was reported in the public release version of the NHS89. 13 It is possible that alcohol consumption, especially extremely heavy drinking and alcoholism, may affect an individuals’ hours of work. The NHS89 has limited information on labour supply, and it is not possible to adequately analyse the effect of drinking on both earnings and labour supply. 2002 ALCOHOL CONSUMPTION AND EARNINGS examined in this literature is that is contains relatively rich information on individuals’ job characteristics, including industry, occupation and sector of employment. The NHS89 reports detailed information on individuals’ drinking patterns. The survey records the period since the respondent last had a drink and, for those who drank in the week prior to the survey, details the types and number of drinks consumed on each day of the reference week. The ABS collected the information on the consumption of specific types of alcoholic beverages in terms of regular measures and then translated this into units (ml ) of pure alcohol. Through these procedures the NHS89 provides reliable information on the quantity of alcohol consumed during the reference period. A limitation of the NHS89 is that the reference period for the detailed information on drinking behaviour is only 1 week. Ideally, information on an individual’s history of drinking behaviour would be available and used to control for impact of long-term drinking patterns as well as current behaviour. Because the NHS89 measures only contemporaneous drinking behaviour, the short-term effects of drinking on productivity and earnings should be captured in the empirical analysis. To the extent that there is persistence in drinking behaviour over time, contemporaneous drinking behaviour will also proxy longer-term drinking patterns and the empirical analysis may capture any systematic relationship between long-term drinking behaviour and earnings.14 The sample of workers is divided into three drinker types: non-drinkers, moderate drinkers and heavy drinkers. Non-drinkers are defined as those individuals who have never drank or who did not have a drink in the month prior 14 Cook and Moore (2000) examined the persistence of drinking patterns using the NLSY panel which surveyed alcohol consumption patterns in 4 consecutive years 1982–1985. There was strong evidence of persistence in drinking behaviour. For instance, the probability an individual abstained in 1985 given 3 consecutive years of abstinence was 0.84. The probability of drinking (bingeing) in 1985 given 3 successive years of drinking (bingeing) was 0.90 (0.45). Although these data are from a youth cohort in the USA, they suggest that the contemporaneous drinking information in the NHS89 may reflect longterm drinking patterns. 83 to the survey.15 The demarcation between moderate and heavy drinking adopted in this study follows that used by Hamilton and Hamilton (1997) drawn from the medical research literature. This research has shown that the intensity of drinking (the amount consumed on 1 day or at a single sitting) is more strongly related to problem drinking and tangible health effects than either the average amount consumed over a period of time or simply drinking frequency. As Hilton (1987: 172) found, ‘‘high maximum [binge] drinking bears a much stronger relationship to drinking problems than does the frequency of drinking’’ which supported Knupfer’s conclusion (Knupfer 1984) that it is the incidence of intoxication rather than drinking per se that places an individual at risk of drinking problems. Based on this body of work, a heavy drinker is defined as someone who drank eight or more standard drinks16 on at least one day during the reference week. Therefore moderate drinkers are defined as anyone who had a drink in the last month and did not drink more than seven standard drinks on any given day during the reference period. There are a range of alternative definitions of heavy versus moderate drinking available in the literature. For instance, Kenkel and Ribar (1994) also associate heavy drinking with binge drinking but define a lower threshold for heavy drinking at six or more drinks on any one day. Alternatively, the National Health and Medical Research Council (NHMRC) (1992) has published guidelines for ‘responsible daily alcohol consumption levels’. The NHMRC guidelines identify low, medium and high risk average daily consumption levels.17 The medium risk consumption level is defined as four to six standard drinks per day on a regular basis, and high risk is defined as more than six drinks per day on a regular basis. The NHMRC definition of high risk requires both intense drinking and a high 15 This is the standard definition of non-drinker used in the literature: see, e.g., Zarkin et al. (1998). 16 One standard drink corresponds to 10 grams (or 14.286 mL) of pure alcohol. 17 The NHMRC (1992, 2) defines the medium and high risk categories as synonymous with ‘‘hazardous’’ and ‘‘harmful’’ consumption levels, respectively. The NHMRC recommendations correspond to those of the World Health Organization. 84 ECONOMIC RECORD average consumption level, whereas in the classification system adopted in this study, intense drinking on an infrequent basis (with possibly low average consumption levels) is sufficient for categorising someone as a heavy drinker. To check the sensitivity of the results to the classification of drinking patterns, the analysis was also implemented using these alternative categorisations of drinking patterns and the results are discussed in section IV. The explanatory variables assumed to influence earnings include age, educational attainment, marital status, state of residence, industry and occupation of employment and an indicator for whether an individual works in the public or private sector. In order to control for the effect of income on drinking behaviour, all the variables that determine earnings are also included in the drinking status choice equation. To identify the selectivity correction terms (SCT) in the earnings equations it is necessary to include additional variables in the drinking status choice model that are excluded from the earnings equations.18 Two sets of variables are used as instruments for drinking status. The first is motivated by the idea that alcohol is usually consumed in a social context and that the drinking behaviour of an individual may be influenced by their social environment. The importance of social influences on drinking behaviour has long been recognised by behavioural scientists (Last 1998; NHMRC 1992) but has only recently begun to be incorporated into economic analyses (Cook and Moore 1999, 2000). An important avenue of social influence is the local, or neighbourhood, network19 through which beliefs, norms and practices are communicated. These factors help determine the ‘wetness’ of the local social environment which may influence individual’s drinking behaviour. For example, a preponderance of neighbours 18 The SCT may be identified through the nonlinearity of its functional form rather than through exclusion restricitions. This strategy is not followed here because it is based on ad-hoc distributional assumptions and empirically such identification often proves to be very weak. 19 Social networks may be based on other bonds, such as religion, ethnicity or occupation. Last (1998) provides a detailed discussion of these factors in relation to health behaviours and specifically alcohol consumption. MARCH who are heavy drinkers may increase the probability an individual is a heavy drinker.20 To capture these social influences, the proportion of sample members in the individual’s local area (excluding that individual) who are abstainers and who are heavy drinkers are calculated and included in the estimation of the choice model.21 The NHS89 records an individual’s location in one of 47 health regions. The health regions are based on contiguous local government areas and are taken as an approximation to an individual’s local area. The second instrument for drinking behaviour is a variable indicating whether the individual smoked at age 18.22 The rationale for this instrument is that, like alcohol consumption, smoking is a health risk behaviour that, in part, reflects an individual’s attitude toward risk (because the activity affects the probability of different health outcomes). In a similar vein, Hersch and Viscusi (1990) used contemporaneous 20 Manski (1993) examines the related problem of the identification of endogenous social effects and shows that it is difficult to distinguish such effects from exogenous contextual or correlated effects (eg. common responses to the relative price of alcohol in the local product market). Although the presence of the latter social effects are important for the interpretation of the local area variables in the drinking choice equation, they do not affect the consistent estimation of the earnings equations unless they capture components of individual unobserved heterogeneity. Tests of the validity of excluding the local area variables from the wage equations should safeguard against this possibility. 21 Formally, for individual i in region k, the proportion of the population in thePlocal region who are abstainers is calculated as: j2Nk ;j6¼i 1( j=abstainer)= ðNk 1Þ, where 1(.) is the indicator function which is equal to 1 whenever the condition (that observation j is an abstainer) is true and is equal to 0 otherwise, and Nk is the number of individuals in local region k . The proportion of the population in the individual’s local area who are moderate and heavy drinkers is calculated analogously. Note that by omitting an individual’s own drinking status from the calculation of the local area (reference group) variables they are not definitionally related to the individual’s choice of drinking status. 22 Evans and Montgomery (1994) provide an indepth analysis of the validity of the ‘smoked at age 18’ indicator variable as an instrument for educational attainment of men. Evans and Montgomery (1994, 33) also suggest the potential usefulness of it as an instrument for heavy drinking. 2002 ALCOHOL CONSUMPTION AND EARNINGS smoking behaviour as a proxy for individuals’ attitudes toward risk in estimating wage differentials for risk of lost work-day injury. Consistent with smoking behaviour reflecting an individual’s willingness to bear risk, they found that smokers received lower wage compensation per unit of risk relative to non-smokers. In the NHS89 data, whether a person smoked at age 18 is strongly correlated with current drinking status. However, to be a valid instrument, whether a person smoked at age 18 must not directly affect their current earnings. Note that this is a retrospective measure of tobacco consumption and even if current smoking behaviour affected current earnings, whether a person smoked in the distant past is unlikely to influence current earnings. Indeed there is considerable churning of individuals’ smoking status between age 18 and the survey date, with approximately 43.2 per cent who reported to be smokers at age 18 having quit by the time of the survey while 27.1 per cent of individuals who were smokers at the time of the survey had started after age 18.23 The substantial changes in smoking status between age 18 and the date of the survey suggests that past smoking is not directly related to current earnings; this conclusion is confirmed by specification tests presented below. The sensitivity of the results to the choice of instruments and sample composition are reported in section IV. Because two sets of instruments are used to identify individuals’ choice of drinking status, the SCT in the earnings equation are overidentified and the overidentification restrictions are used to formally test (and confirm) the validity of each instrument. The consequences of using alternative instruments and model specifications are also reported in section IV. Summary statistics for the sample are presented in Table 1.24 The sample consists of 5705 individual observations, of which 14 per cent are 23 Interestingly, Evans and Montgomery (1994, 9) report very similar changes in smoking status between age 18 and the survey date for respondents to the USA 1987 National Medical Expenditure Survey. 24 The NHS89 data file contains record weights derived by the ABS, based on the sampling frame, which make the data representative of the Australian population. The summary statistics in Table 1, and all of the subsequent analysis, take the record weights into account. 85 non-drinkers, 67 per cent are moderate drinkers and 19 per cent are heavy drinkers. Moderate drinkers earn approximately 4 per cent more than heavy drinkers who, in turn, earn 8 per cent more than abstainers.25 Compared to moderate drinkers, the group of non-drinkers has a greater proportion of older workers while there is a concentration of younger workers in the heavy drinker category.26 Moderate drinkers tend to have higher levels of educational attainment, while trade qualifications are most common among the heavy drinkers. Moderate drinkers also have the greatest probability, and heavy drinkers the lowest probability, of being married.27 Non-drinkers are more likely to be employed in manufacturing industries and as plant operators or manual labourers. Moderate drinkers tend to be employed in manufacturing and service industries and in administrative or professional occupations, while heavy drinkers are relatively more likely to work in the construction and trade industries as either tradesmen or in other blue-collar occupations. The smoked at age 18 variable indicates that a large portion of the full sample were smokers at 18, the incidence of which was lowest among current non-drinkers and highest among heavy drinkers. The sample means for the proportion of the local area population in each drinker type indicates that abstainers reside in areas where there is a slightly above average fraction of abstainers. Similarly, moderate drinkers tend to be located in areas where there is a marginally higher proportion of moderate drinkers, and heavy drinkers tend to be located in areas with an above average proportion of heavy drinkers. 25 The descriptive statistics for income were derived by taking the log of the midpoint of an individual’s earnings category. The analysis that follows takes into account the censoring of earnings into groups. 26 By taking the midpoint of the age category for an individual, the average age of non-drinkers is 40.1 years, for moderate drinkers is 38.0 years and for heavy drinkers is 35.2 years. 27 It is possible that marital status is endogenous to the drinking decision. The analysis was also conducted excluding marital status from the drinking choice and wage equations: all of the results reported were not sensitive to the treatment of marital status. 86 ECONOMIC RECORD MARCH TABLE 1 Descriptive statistics Variable Ln Earnings Age Age Age Age Age Age Age 25–29* 30–34 35–39 40–44 45–49 50–54 55–59 Not complete high school Complete high school* Trade qualification Post-secondary certificate University degree Abstainer Drinker-type Moderate Heavy 10.1812 10.2982 10.2571 0.1601 0.1676 0.1754 0.1536 0.1527 0.1096 0.0811 0.1860 0.2006 0.1668 0.1579 0.1292 0.0905 0.0690 0.3243 0.2360 0.1669 0.1148 0.0842 0.0447 0.0291 0.1085 0.3463 0.2610 0.1754 0.1088 0.0807 0.3282 0.2958 0.1604 0.1349 0.0586 0.3970 0.3308 0.1474 0.0662 Married 0.7530 0.8179 0.6610 NSW* Vic Qld SA WA Tas NT ACT 0.3541 0.3024 0.1581 0.0730 0.0643 0.0275 0.0126 0.0080 0.3379 0.2671 0.1573 0.0933 0.0928 0.0286 0.0071 0.0159 0.3686 0.2290 0.1957 0.0762 0.0742 0.0231 0.0197 0.0135 Primary Manufacturing* Utilities Construction Trade Transportation Communications Finance Public Administration Community Services Recreation 0.0496 0.3063 0.0273 0.0727 0.1257 0.0909 0.0466 0.0523 0.0742 0.1261 0.0283 0.0539 0.2532 0.0371 0.0815 0.1416 0.0799 0.0375 0.0746 0.0747 0.1293 0.0368 0.0694 0.2145 0.0310 0.1141 0.1566 0.0791 0.0417 0.0816 0.0795 0.0864 0.0460 Administration Professional Para-professional Tradesperson Clerical Sales and personal services Plant operator Labourer* 0.0560 0.1184 0.0671 0.2379 0.0878 0.0351 0.1773 0.2205 0.1044 0.1356 0.0862 0.2422 0.0805 0.0744 0.1292 0.1475 0.0917 0.0768 0.0786 0.2616 0.0841 0.0783 0.1558 0.1731 Public Sector 0.3491 0.3344 0.2834 Local abstainers Local moderate drinkers* Local heavy drinkers 0.1409 0.6644 0.1947 0.1364 0.6670 0.1966 0.1336 0.6571 0.2092 Smoke18 0.3544 0.4416 0.6199 777 3824 1104 Observations Note: An * indicates the omitted category in the estimation of the earnings equations. 2002 ALCOHOL CONSUMPTION AND EARNINGS IV Empirical Results (i) Drinking Status Choice Model Estimates The estimates for the drinking status choice model are presented in Table 2. To aid interpretation, the marginal effect of the covariates on the predicted probability of each drinker-type are also presented in Table 2. The estimates show that age is strongly related to the choice of drinking status. Older men are significantly more likely to be nondrinkers, with individuals in the 45–54 age groups having the highest probability of abstaining. Similarly, older men are progressively less likely to be heavy drinkers. The relationship between age and drinking status reflects an important life-cycle pattern of drinking behaviour – young men, other things equal, are more likely to drink heavily and that likelihood decreases as they age. Education does not appear to be strongly related to drinker-type, except that individuals with a university degree are significantly less likely to be heavy drinkers. Being married is associated with a significantly greater probably of being a moderate drinker, and lower probabilities of being either a non-drinker or heavy drinker. Employment in the utility (electricity, water and gas) supply industries is associated with a significantly lower probability of being a non-drinker while working in communications, finance and public administration is associated with a greater probability of being a heavy drinker. There is a strong relationship between occupation of employment and drinking status. Individuals in the omitted occupation of manual labour, other things equal, have the highest probability of being non-drinkers while individuals in white collar occupations are most likely to be moderate drinkers. Other things equal, public sector employees are significantly less likely to be heavy drinkers compared to their private sector counterparts. Included in the drinking status choice model is the smoked at age 18 indicator variable. The coefficient estimates are large and precisely estimated (with z-statistics of 5.306 and 9.891 in the nondrinker and heavy-drinker equations respectively).28 28 The likelihood ratio test statistic for the null hypothesis that coefficients on the smoked at age 18 dummy are jointly equal to 0 is 155.5, which is distributed chi-squared with two degrees of freedom. The critical value at the 1 per cent level of significance is 9.21 and hence the hypothesis is decisively rejected. 87 Individuals who smoked at age 18 are substantially less likely to be non-drinkers and much more likely to be heavy drinkers, which is consistent with this variable proxying an individual’s attitude toward risk. The drinking status choice model also included the proportion of the population in the individual’s local area who were abstainers and who were heavy drinkers. Living in an area with a higher concentration of heavy drinkers is associated with a lower probability that the individual abstained and an increased probability of heavy drinking, which is consistent with a demonstration effect of heavy drinking within an individuals local area. The coefficient on the proportion of the local population who were abstainers was individually insignificant. However, the hypothesis that the two measures of neighbourhood drinking behaviour are jointly insignificant is strongly rejected.29 Both the set of variables measuring neighbourhood drinking behaviour and the smoked at age 18 dummy variable are highly significant and represent potentially strong instruments for identifying the effect of drinking status on earnings. (ii) Grouped Earnings Regression Estimates The grouped regression model for earnings was first estimated using the pooled sample with separate dummy variables for abstainers and heavy drinkers included as control variables and assuming exogenous selection. The estimates show that after controlling for differences in age, human capital and other demographic and job characteristics, non-drinkers earn 5.9 per cent less,30 and heavy drinkers 1.6 per cent more,31 than moderate drinkers. These results replicate the findings of Berger and Leigh (1988) and Zarkin et al. (1998) who found no evidence of a wage penalty for the highest levels of alcohol consumption. However, the higher earnings associated with greater levels of drinking may reflect the reverse effect of income on alcohol 29 The likelihood ratio test statistic is 19.80. The critical value of the test statistic at the 1 per cent level of significance is 13.28. 30 The coefficient on the non-drinker dummy variable is significant at the 1 per cent level. 31 The coefficient on the heavy-drinker dummy is only significant at the 15 per cent level. 88 ECONOMIC RECORD MARCH TABLE 2 Multinomial Logit drinking status choice model Model estimates1 Variable Abstainers Coefficient Std.err. Constant )0.3776 (0.3516) )0.7349** (0.3072) Age 30–34 Age 35–39 Age 40–44 Age 45–49 Age 50–54 Age 55–59 Not complete high sch. Trade qualification Post-secondary cert. University degree Married Vic Qld SA WA Tas ACT NT Primary Utilities Construction Trade Transportation Communications Finance Public administration Community Services Recreation Administration Professional Para-professional Tradesperson Clerical Sales and personal serv. Plant operator Public Sector Smoked at age 18 Local abstainers Local heavy drinkers 0.0705 0.3330* 0.2533 0.4496** 0.4333** 0.3408 0.0422 0.1426 )0.1963 )0.1170 )0.4119** 0.0238 0.0066 )0.3407* )0.4139* )0.1181 )0.5491 0.8353* )0.2559 )0.5913* )0.2611 0.0208 )0.1561 )0.0073 )0.3498 )0.2751 )0.1679 )0.2855 )1.0971** )0.6078** )0.7459** )0.3401** )0.4143** )1.2142** )0.0811 0.1931 )0.4521** )0.3681 )1.5895 (0.1394) (0.1404) (0.1461) (0.1479) (0.1635) (0.1803) (0.1516) (0.1243) (0.1155) (0.1746) (0.0983) (0.1042) (0.1244) (0.1700) (0.1809) (0.2528) (0.4402) (0.4211) (0.1972) (0.2702) (0.1660) (0.1419) (0.1655) (0.2360) (0.1962) (0.2059) (0.1747) (0.2487) (0.1932) (0.1878)‘ (0.1872) (0.1321) (0.1735) (0.2323) (0.1344) (0.1276) (0.0852) (1.2052) (0.9005) )0.2981** )0.4387** )0.7015** )0.9015** )1.1861** )1.3421** )0.1407 )0.0507 0.0677 )0.5438** )0.7103** )0.1929* )0.0134 )0.3103* )0.4070** )0.2340 )0.4154 0.5518 0.2123 0.3775** 0.3911** 0.2078 0.1585 0.4969* 0.4540** 0.5271** 0.2353 0.1801 0.0195 )0.1872 )0.0236 )0.0833 0.0367 )0.0986 0.1486 )0.2469* 0.7328** )1.4717 1.8141* (0.1010) (0.1109) (0.1230) (0.1360) (0.1707) (0.2039) (0.1582) (0.1124) (0.0964) (0.1687) (0.0818) (0.0979) (0.1027) (0.1459) (0.1526) (0.2360) (0.3152) (0.3353) (0.1613) (0.2340) (0.1350) (0.1258) (0.1557) (0.2207) (0.1559) (0.1889) (0.1711) (0.1907) (0.1524) (0.1810) (0.1643) (0.1217) (0.1601) (0.1668) (0.1291) (0.1209) (0.0741) (1.0690) (0.7558) LLF Heavy drinkers Coefficient Std.err. Marginal effect on probabilities2 Moderate Heavy Abstainers drinkers drinkers Predicted Probability 0.2332 0.4907 0.2761 0.0314 0.0941 0.0905 0.1443 0.1516 0.1349 0.0166 0.0299 )0.0372 0.0085 )0.0354 0.0163 0.0020 )0.0401 )0.0472 )0.0071 )0.0664 0.1234 )0.0549 )0.1069 )0.0667 )0.0104 )0.0364 )0.0363 )0.0824 )0.0772 )0.0431 )0.0573 )0.1416 )0.0832 )0.1062 )0.0509 )0.0677 )0.1477 )0.0236 0.0527 )0.1109 )0.0090 )0.2168 Marginal Effect 0.0281 0.0029 0.0381 0.0160 0.0343 0.0602 0.0132 )0.0106 0.0111 0.0809 0.1377 0.0220 0.0010 0.0805 0.1015 0.0448 0.1169 )0.1652 )0.0061 )0.0108 )0.0357 )0.0315 )0.0066 )0.0734 )0.0404 )0.0586 )0.0176 0.0017 0.0865 0.0889 0.0727 0.0481 0.0362 0.1150 )0.0125 0.0053 )0.0864 0.2091 )0.0745 )0.0595 )0.0970 )0.1286 )0.1604 )0.1859 )0.1951 )0.0298 )0.0193 0.0261 )0.0894 )0.1023 )0.0382 )0.0031 )0.0404 )0.0543 )0.0377 )0.0504 0.0419 0.0610 0.1178 0.1024 0.0419 0.0430 0.1098 0.1228 0.1358 0.0607 0.0556 0.0551 )0.0057 0.0335 0.0028 0.0315 0.0327 0.0361 )0.0581 0.1973 )0.2002 0.2913 )4596.43 Note 1. * and ** denote significance at the 5 percent and 1 percent levels, respectively. 2. The reference group (omitted category) for the estimation and calculation of the marginal effects corresponds to males aged 25–29 years, who had completed high school, were single, resided in NSW, were employed in the private sector, in manufacturing as a labourer, did not smoke prior to age 18 and the proportion of abstainers (moderate) and heavy drinkers in the local area corresponded to the sample average. 2002 ALCOHOL CONSUMPTION AND EARNINGS consumption or unmeasured worker characteristics correlated with drinking status. The objective of the analysis is to test whether the earnings premium for drinkers persists after controlling for the endogenous relationship between alcohol consumption and earnings. The grouped regression models where then estimated separately by drinker type allowing for self selection of drinking status. The estimation results for the separate earnings equations are presented in Table 3.32 These models allow the returns to age, human capital characteristics and job attributes to differ by drinker type. The likelihood ratio test rejects the restrictions imposed by pooling across all drinker types in support of the models where all the coefficients are allowed to vary by drinking status.33 The age-earnings profiles for each drinker type generally have the usual concave shape, although the profile for non-drinkers is relatively flat and not precisely estimated. The age-earnings profile is steepest for heavy drinkers, peaking at age 30–34 years and declining steeply over older age intervals. The age-earnings profile is smoother for moderate drinkers, with a lower peak occurring at the 45–49 year age bracket, and a slower decline over later years. The returns to education are relatively uniform across the drinker-types, with a significant earnings premium for having a university degree for all drinker types. There is also a uniform, positive marriage premium for each drinker type. The lower panel of Table 3 reports the returns to job characteristics by drinking status. The coefficients on the industry, occupation and public sector dummy variables may capture the returns to industry and occupational specific human capital or perhaps job rents. There are significant differences in earnings across industries for each drinker type. 32 Wald tests, based on pairwise comparisons of the coefficients estimates in Table 3 (excluding the intercept, the coefficient on the selection term and the standard deviation of the residual), reject the hypothesis that the returns to individual characteristics and job attributes are equal for any two drinker types. The P-values for the test statistics are all less than 1 per cent. 33 The test statistic for null hypothesis that the returns to the demographic, human capital and job characteristics are the same for the three drinker types is 130.75 (P-value ¼ 0.000 17). The test statistic is distributed chi-squared with 78 degrees of freedom. 89 However, the differences by occupation are more economically important. Indeed, the coefficients on the occupation dummy variables are almost an order of magnitude greater than the coefficients on the industry dummies. The general pattern of occupational earnings differentials are consistent across the three drinker types; administrative and professional occupations receive the highest earnings, and clerical and service occupations pay higher earnings than the blue-collar jobs. The magnitude of the occupational earnings differences are substantially lower among non-drinkers while the returns to white-collar occupations are greatest for moderate drinkers. After conditioning on other observable factors, non-drinkers receive a substantial public sector earnings premium while heavy drinkers receive a large public sector earnings penalty. The final set of controls are the state dummy variables that capture differences in earnings across the states of Australia. The earnings differentials by state are less pronounced among the abstainers. For moderate and heavy drinkers, Queensland and South Australia workers earn less than their counterparts in New South Wales. A noticeable finding is that differences in returns to observable characteristics are generally less pronounced among non-drinkers. This is consistent with non-drinkers being risk-averse and tending to work in jobs where there is less variation in compensation by personal characteristics or job attributes. The lower average earnings of non-drinkers may partly reflect the payment of an insurance premium by nondrinkers. The earnings equations included the SCT which correct for endogeneity bias arising from individuals choosing their drinking status. The coefficients on SCT in the non-drinker and moderate drinker earnings equations are statistically insignificant.34 The coefficient on SCT in the heavy drinker earnings equation is significant35 and indicates that workers who self select 34 The P-value for the coefficient on the SCT for nondrinkers is 0.236 and for moderate drinkers is 0.705. Note the equations are consistently estimated even if the coefficients on the selectivity correction terms are insignificant. 35 The P-value for the coefficient on the selection correct term for heavy drinkers is 0.029. 90 ECONOMIC RECORD MARCH TABLE 3 Earnings equation estimates with selectivity corrections Variable Constant SCT Non-Drinkers Coefficient Std.err. 9.7399 (0.1332) Moderate Drinkers Coefficient Std.err. 9.9470 Heavy Drinkers Coefficient Std.err. (0.0761) 9.7885 (0.0643) )0.1072 (0.0905) 0.0321 (0.0847) )0.1184 (0.0541) 0.0283 0.0772 0.0051 0.0512 )0.0891 )0.0457 (0.0421) (0.0450) (0.0469) (0.0497) (0.0533) (0.0575) 0.0712 0.0782 0.1015 0.1188 0.0921 0.0350 (0.0165) (0.0172) (0.0192) (0.0201) (0.0235) (0.0267) 0.0347 0.1231 0.0707 0.0584 0.0882 )0.0524 (0.0270) (0.0311) (0.0383) (0.0437) (0.0563) (0.0668) Not complete high sch. Post-secondary cert. Trade qualification University degree )0.0838 0.0985 0.0952 0.2806 (0.0443) (0.0373) (0.0350) (0.0538) )0.0668 0.1056 0.0633 0.2345 (0.0203) (0.0156) (0.0140) (0.0223) )0.0436 0.1385 0.0754 0.2288 (0.0438) (0.0305) (0.0260) (0.0496) Married Vic Qld SA WA Tas NT ACT 0.0541 0.0242 )0.0279 0.0288 0.0190 )0.0291 )0.0438 0.0902 (0.0303) (0.0298) (0.0365) (0.0497) (0.0525) (0.0739) (0.1102) (0.1364) 0.0562 0.0029 )0.0743 )0.0607 0.0371 )0.0112 0.0570 0.0198 (0.0209) (0.0131) (0.0150) (0.0197) (0.0206) (0.0306) (0.0626) (0.0408) 0.0451 )0.0384 )0.0555 )0.0970 )0.0193 )0.0245 0.1490 0.0233 (0.0249) (0.0265) (0.0268) (0.0390) (0.0393) (0.0648) (0.0712) (0.0854) Primary Utilities Construction Trade Transportation Communications Finance Public administration Community services Recreation 0.0991 0.0765 0.0969 )0.0697 )0.0584 )0.1526 0.0764 )0.0973 )0.1172 0.0036 (0.0621) (0.0859) (0.0521) (0.0421) (0.0499) (0.0711) (0.0624) (0.0639) (0.0513) (0.0772) 0.0815 0.0498 0.0821 )0.0619 0.0708 )0.0079 0.0910 )0.0411 )0.0830 )0.1183 (0.0237) (0.0306) (0.0202) (0.0178) (0.0212) (0.0314) (0.0220) (0.0260) (0.0217) (0.0279) 0.0680 0.0634 0.1321 )0.0282 0.1246 0.1424 0.0978 0.1190 0.0677 )0.0619 (0.0429) (0.0634) (0.0371) (0.0344) (0.0425) (0.0617) (0.0427) (0.0525) (0.0485) (0.0510) Administration Professional Para-professional Tradesperson Clerical Sales and pers. services Plant operator 0.3747 0.2829 0.1925 0.0740 0.1977 0.2225 0.1531 (0.0728) (0.0599) (0.0622) (0.0401) (0.0548) (0.0842) (0.0391) 0.4818 0.3752 0.3212 0.1277 0.2118 0.2199 0.1043 (0.0242) (0.0252) (0.0246) (0.0184) (0.0231) (0.0283) (0.0190) 0.4420 0.2767 0.3243 0.1606 0.2069 0.2101 0.1470 (0.0422) (0.0506) (0.0442) (0.0325) (0.0427) (0.0447) (0.0345) Public Sector 0.1025 (0.0382) )0.0475 (0.0160) )0.1366 (0.0341) 0.3188 (0.0086) 0.2941 (0.0036) 0.3063 (0.0070) Age Age Age Age Age Age 30–34 35–39 40–44 45–49 50–54 55–59 Sigma LLF )1450.24 )6973.03 Note: The standard errors are calculated using White’s (1980) method. )2054.36 2002 ALCOHOL CONSUMPTION AND EARNINGS into heavy drinking earn 15.12 per cent more on average than what an individual with identical observable characteristics drawn at random from the workforce would earn as a heavy drinker.36 This positive selection into heavy drinking reveals that individuals with unobserved characteristics associated with a higher probability of heavy drinking are also associated with higher earnings as a heavy drinker. This suggests that, other things equal, individuals with a stronger preference for high levels of alcohol consumption also tend to be individuals who are better able to handle the health effects of heavy drinking thereby minimising the apparent adverse effects of heavy drinking on earnings. The earnings equations were also estimated separately assuming exogenous selection.37 The exclusion of SCT from the non- and moderate drinkers earnings equations affected the estimate of the constant terms and had little affect on the estimated returns to personal or job characteristics. However, the exclusion of the SCT from the heavy drinker earnings equation also affected the coefficient estimates for age. Specifically, the definitive early peak and concavity of the heavy drinking age-earnings profile in Table 3 was masked in this model (due to the correlation between age and selection into heavy drinking). Overall, important differences in the returns to demographic, human capital and job characteristics by drinker type were found. However, it is not clear from the coefficient estimates what effect the differences in returns imply for earnings differentials. In order to draw out these effects, earnings decompositions are presented next. (iii) Earnings Differentials The grouped regression results in Table 3 are used to decompose the predicted earnings differentials between drinker types. Following the empirical literature on wage differentials, two earnings decompositions are considered. The first is the unconditional earnings differential which is 36 The selection effect is calculated as the selection coefficient, -ðrj qj Þ, multiplied by the mean of the selectivity correction term, /j ð:Þ=Fj ð:Þ. 37 Due to space constraints the detailed estimation results for this specification of the earnings equations are not presented, but are available on request from the author. 91 calculated by the following extension of Oaxaca’s method (Oaxaca 1973): E½ln wj jxj E½ln wk jxk bj þ bk xj þ xk ¼ ðxj xk Þð Þ Þ þ ðbj bk Þð 2 2 ð6Þ The unconditional earnings differential measures the difference in earnings between two workers who have observable characteristics identical to the average person of each drinker type. This earnings differential is unconditional in that the predicted earnings are calculated independently of the worker’s actual choice of drinking status, and hence the earnings differences are independent of selection effects (equivalently, the effects of unobservables). The earnings differential may be divided into a component due to differences in characteristics between the two drinker-types (corresponding to the first term on the right-hand side of (6)) and a component due to differences in the labour market returns to those observable characteristics (corresponding to the second term on the right-hand side of (6)).38 It is this latter component of the unconditional earnings differential which isolates the effect of alcohol consumption on earnings. The second earnings differential of interest is the conditional earnings differential which is calculated as: bj þ bk Þ 2 /j xj þ xk / þ ðbj bk Þð Þ ðrj qj rk qk k Þ Fk 2 Fj E½ln wj jxj E½ln wk jxk ¼ ðxj xk Þð ð7Þ For this decomposition earnings are predicted taking into account the self-selection by workers of their preferred drinking status, and hence expected earnings includes the product of the mean of the unobserved characteristics and the returns to those unobserved characteristics. This 38 In the decomposition presented in equation (6) the differences in mean characteristics are weighted by the arithmetic average of the returns to the two drinkertype, and the differences in returns are similarly weighted by the arithmetic average of the characteristics of the two drinker-types. This is only one of the many possible weighting schemes. The results of the wage decompositions are not sensitive to the reference group/weighting scheme adopted. 92 MARCH ECONOMIC RECORD TABLE 4 Earnings decompositions (and standard errors) Wa – Wm Wh – Wm Wa – Wh 1. Endogenous selection: Unconditional earnings decompositions Total difference )0.2893 (0.0050) )0.2049 (0.0022) Total characteristics )0.0481 (0.0002) )0.0415 (0.0002) Total returns )0.2413 (0.0052) )0.1634 (0.0024) )0.0844 (0.0054) )0.0118 (0.0003) )0.0726 (0.0056) 2. Endogenous selection: Conditional earnings decompositions Total difference )0.1085 (0.0004) Total characteristics )0.0481 (0.0002) Total returns )0.2413 (0.0052) Total selection 0.1808 (0.0050) )0.0717 )0.0118 )0.0726 0.0127 )0.0368 )0.0415 )0.1634 0.1681 (0.0003) (0.0002) (0.0024) (0.0022) 3. Preferred specification: Unconditional earnings decompositions Total difference )0.1086 (0.0117) )0.1880 (0.0002) Total characteristics )0.0536 (0.0029) )0.0428 (0.0002) Total returns )0.0549 (0.0120) )0.1452 (0.0022) (0.0004) (0.0003) (0.0056) (0.0054) 0.0795 (0.0118) )0.0180 (0.0044) 0.0975 (0.0127) Notes: 1. Asymptotic standard errors are in parentheses. 2. The preferred specification corresponds to the earnings models based on exogenous selection into the nondrinker and moderate drinker groups, and endogenous selection into the heavy drinker group. method decomposes the earnings differences observed in the raw data and includes an additional component due to differences in worker self-selection of drinking status (the third term on the right-hand side of (7)).39 An additional earnings differential is also calculated. The SCTs were insignificant in the earnings equations for non-drinkers and moderate drinkers. Inclusion of the SCT in these two models mainly affected the estimate of the constant term which is reflected in the component of the earnings differentials (involving these two drinker types) due to differences in returns. Because the data supported exogenous selection for the non-drinker and moderate drinker earnings equations, the unconditional earnings differentials are recalculated using the estimates based on exogenous selection for these two groups. Because the data also supported the hypothesis of endogenous selection for heavy drinkers, the estimates of the heavy drinker earnings equation in Table 3 are used. These specifications of the earnings equations are referred to as the Ôpreferred specificationsÕ. 39 Papers which discuss the interpretation and merits of unconditional and conditional wage decompositions include Duncan and Leigh (1980), Trost and Lee (1984), Gyourko and Tracy (1988) and Idson and Feaster (1990). The results of the earnings decompositions (and asymptotic standard errors40) are reported in Table 4. The unconditional earnings decompositions reveal a large earnings premium for moderate drinkers relative to both abstainers and heavy drinkers.41 The earnings differentials, and each component, are statistically significant.The predominant proportion of the earnings premium is due to differences in the labour market reward to worker characteristics, which is consistent with the hypothesis that moderate drinking is associated with better health and hence greater worker productivity and earnings. However, heavy drinking is found to yield an earnings premium over abstaining, mostly due to differences in returns, which is not consistent with the health and productivity-earnings hypothesis. It is possible to break down the contribution of overall differences in characteristics into differences in specific sets of worker characteristics. 40 The asymptotic standard errors are calculated using the delta method: Rao (1973, 388). 41 Although the unconditional wage differentials are quite large, they are smaller than the 45 per cent unconditional wage differential between drinkers and non-drinkers found by Berger and Leigh (1988) and the 77 per cent unconditional wage differential between moderate and heavy drinkers implied by the results in Hamilton and Hamilton (1997: 147). 2002 ALCOHOL CONSUMPTION AND EARNINGS Although not reported in Table 4, disaggregating the differences in characteristics reveals that differences in the distribution of workers across occupations is by far the most important factor contributing to the differences due to characteristics. Even so, the aggregate effect of differences in characteristics is minor compared to differences in returns.42 The second panel of Table 4 reports the conditional earnings decompositions. The conditional earnings differences across drinker-types are much smaller than the unconditional earnings differences implying that selection bias substantially masks the earnings effects of alcohol consumption. This is confirmed in the bottom line of the panel, where the total effect of worker self-selection substantially decrease the observed earnings differential between moderate drinkers and the other two drinker-types. The direction of these selection effects reinforce each other in reducing the observed earnings differential between moderate drinkers and both abstainers and heavy drinkers. However, the selection bias effects for abstainers and heavy drinkers counteract each other, accounting for the smaller contribution of the total selection effect to the conditional earnings difference between abstainers and heavy drinkers. The bottom panel of Table 4 reports the unconditional earnings decomposition based on the preferred specification of the earnings equations. The earnings premium for moderate drinkers over abstainers is approximately 11 per cent, half of which is due to differences in returns and hence may be attributed to the health and productivity enhancing effects of moderate drinking. A much larger earnings penalty for heavy drinkers relative to moderate drinkers (19 per cent) and a significant earnings penalty for heavy drinking relative to abstention (8 per cent) is found. These earnings penalties for heavy drinkers are predominately due to differences in returns rather than worker characteristics. The latter finding of an earnings penalty for heavy drinking relative to abstention 42 Jones (1983) showed that the disaggregation of the wage differential due to differences in specific sets of coefficients will be sensitive to the reference category chosen for the dummy variables. Given the inherent arbitrariness of such a disaggregation, it is not performed here. 93 is consistent with the health and productivity implications of heavy drinking. The counterintuitive earnings premium for heavy drinking over abstention found for the unconditional earnings differential in the top panel of Table 4 reflects the sensitivity of the estimate of the constant term in the earnings equation for nondrinkers when the (insignificant) SCT is included in that model. Overall, the earnings decompositions do reveal a significant earnings premium to moderate drinking, and a significant earnings penalty to heavy drinking. (iv) Specification Tests The results in Tables 3 and 4 show that there is a positive labour market return to moderate drinking and a penalty to heavy drinking. Because the magnitude of these effects were masked by selection effects in the raw data, the sensitivity of the findings to the identification of the drinking status selection model was examined. The identification of the drinking choice equation was based on two sets of variables. Because only one instrument is required to formally identify the drinking choice model, the model is overidentified and hence it is possible to test the validity of each instrument separately. Under the maintained assumption that the proportion of the local population who are abstainers and who are heavy drinkers are validly excluded from the earnings equation, the validity of the smoked at age 18 dummy variable as an instrument for drinking status can be tested. The earnings equations were estimated with the smoked at age 18 variable included43 and Durbin-Wu-Hausman (DWH) specification tests were used to test the validity of their exclusion. The DWH test statistics of 0.102, 0.009 and 1.496 for the non-, moderate and heavy drinking earnings equations, respectively, were well below the chi-squared critical values at conventional levels of significance44 43 The point estimates (and asymptotic standard errors) for the smoked at age 18 dummy variable were 0.0098 (0.0358), 0.0046 (0.0109) and -0.0366 (0.0301) for the non, moderate and heavy drinker earnings equations respectively. 44 The test statistics have a chi-squared distribution with 1 degree of freedom, and the critical value at the 1 per cent level of significance is 6.635 and at the 10 per cent level is 2.706. 94 ECONOMIC RECORD supporting the exclusion of the smoked at age 18 dummy variable from the earnings equations.45 The validity of the instrument measuring drinking patterns in the individual’s local area was also tested. Assuming that the smoked at age 18 variable is a valid instrument, the earnings equations were estimated with the proportion of the local population who abstained and who drank heavily included as explanatory variables.46 The DWH test statistics for the null hypothesis that these variables are validly excluded from the earnings equations were 0.575, 3.471 and 1.676 for the non-, moderate and heavy drinking earnings equations, respectively. These test statistics were well below the chisquared critical values at conventional levels of significance47 supporting the validity of these instruments. Alternative instruments for identifying the drinking status choice equation were also examined. The NHS89 records whether an individual had private health insurance, which may also proxy an individual’s attitude toward risk. The likelihood ratio test failed to reject the hypothesis that the coefficients on the private health insurance variable in the drinking status choice equations were jointly equal to zero. Conse- 45 The selection model and earnings equations were also estimated with the inclusion of an indicator variable for current smoking status. With this specification the validity of the smoked at age 18 variable as an instrument for drinking behaviour status was supported by DWH specification tests, and the same pattern of wage differentials by drinker type (as discussed in the text) was evident. Therefore it may be concluded that the smoked at age 18 dummy variable is not capturing current smoking status. The models which include a dummy variable indicating current smoking status are not presented in the main set of results due to the potential endogeneity of this variable. 46 The point estimates for the two variables were individually statistically insignificant in all the wage equations except for the estimated coefficient on the proportion of abstainers in the local area in the wage equation for moderate drinkers. In that model, the point estimate (and standard error) for the proportion of abstainers in the local area was )0.653 (0.511), which has a P-value of 0.100. 47 The test statistics have a chi-squared distribution with two degrees of freedom, and the critical value at the 1 per cent level of significance is 9.210 and at the 10 per cent level is 4.605. MARCH quently, this variable is not used because it is at best a weak instrument.48 The NHS89 contains detailed information on additional health risk behaviours such as whether the respondent is under/overweight and whether the respondent exercised regularly. Inclusion of these variables in the drinking status choice model magnified the estimated selection effects found in Table 3 and increased the estimated moderate drinking earnings premium. However, because these measures are contemporaneous with earnings, they are not included in the preferred specification since they are potentially correlated with the error term in the earnings equations. The models were also estimated using alternative definitions of drinking status. Following Kenkel and Ribar (1994), a lower threshold for heavy drinking at six drinks on any one day during the reference week was considered. This led to a reclassification of 572 observations from the moderate to heavy drinking category. The model estimates and earnings differentials were very similar to those reported in Tables 3 and 4. The NHMRC (1992) definition of drinker types was also used. The NHMRC categories for medium and high risk drinking require frequent intense drinking. This led to a substantial reclassification of the sample, with 84 per cent classified as low risk drinkers, 10 per cent as medium risk and 6 per cent as high risk drinkers. The sample means indicate that low risk drinkers earn 1.5 per cent less, and high risk drinkers 11.5 per cent less, than medium risk drinkers. After controlling for individual and job characteristics and self selection of drinking status, the unconditional earnings differentials indicate a statistically insignificant earnings premium for low risk relative to medium risk drinking of 10 per cent, and an insignificant earnings penalty of 2 per cent for high risk relative to medium risk drinking. These findings may be reconciled with the results in Tables 3 and 4. The NHMRC low risk drinker group approximates the combined non-drinker-moderate drinker groups used above, and the NHMRC demarcation between medium and high risk drinking splits the heavy drinker group in two 48 In addition, this is a contemporaneous variable that is highly correlated with current earnings: see Cameron and Trivedi (1991) and Barrett and Conlon (2000). 2002 ALCOHOL CONSUMPTION AND EARNINGS based on the average intensity of drinking. The results using the NHMRC classification are then consistent with a 10–12 per cent earnings penalty for ‘harmful’ or ‘hazardous’ drinking. A distinctive feature of the NHS89 is the detailed information on job attributes, which were found to be important determinants of earnings. To gauge the consequences of not controlling for these characteristics, the selection model and earnings equations were re-estimated excluding the industry, occupation and public sector dummy variables. The selection effects were still well identified, however, the coefficients on the educational attainment variables in the moderate and, to a lesser extent, heavy drinking earnings equations were substantially larger. This result is due to the correlation between educational attainment and occupational status. Therefore, the large differences in the returns to education by drinking status reported by Hamilton and Hamilton (1997) may be overstated due to the omission of controls for job attributes, particularly occupation. V Conclusion This paper examined the effect of alcohol consumption on individual earnings. Treating drinking status as exogenous, and entering separate dummy variables indicating abstention and heavy drinking into a standard earnings equation, indicated that earnings increased with greater levels of alcohol consumption. However, allowing for the endogeneity of drinking status due to the effects of income and unobservables on alcohol consumption levels revealed a significant positive earnings premium for moderate drinking and a substantial penalty for heavy drinking. These effects of alcohol on earnings were masked in the raw data by worker selfselection of drinking status. Estimates of the selectivity corrected earnings functions were consistent with the health-productivity-earnings nexus suggested by the medical literature on the effects of alcohol consumption patterns. There are several directions in which it may be fruitful to extend this research. The present analysis has focussed on the earnings effects of drinking among a sample of full-time male workers. Alcohol consumption may have consequences for individuals’ labour supply which could be important in assessing the private and social costs of different drinking patterns. It would also be useful to analyse the effects of drinking behaviour on the earnings of women. 95 Furthermore, the results of this analysis suggest that it may be interesting to explore the consequences of health risk behaviours more generally, in addition to the consumption of legal and illicit drugs, for labour market outcomes. REFERENCES Australian Statistician (1991), 1989–90 National Health Survey Users’ Guide, Australian Bureau of Statistics, Canberra, Catalogue No. 4363.0. Barrett, G.F. and R. Conlon (2000), ‘Adverse selection and the demand for health insurance in Australia: 1989-1995’, Mimeo, University of New South Wales. Baum-Baicker, C. (1985a), ‘The health benefits of moderate alcohol consumption: a review of the literature’, Drug and Alcohol Dependence 15, 207–27. Baum-Baicker, C. (1985b), ‘The psychological benefits of moderate alcohol consumption: a review of the literature’, Drug and Alcohol Dependence 15, 305–22. Berger, M.C. and J.P. Leigh (1988), ‘The effect of alcohol use on wages’, Applied Economics 20, 1343– 51. Cameron, C. and P. Trivedi (1991), ‘The role of income and health risk in the choice of health insurance’, Journal of Public Economics 45(1), 1–28. Cook, P.J. and M.J. Moore (1999) ‘Alcohol’, National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 6905. Cook, P.J. and M.J. Moore (2000), ‘Environment and persistence in youthful drinking patterns’ in J.Gruber (ed.) Risky Behaviour Among Youth: An Economic Analysis, University of Chicago Press, Chicago. Duncan, G. and D. Leigh (1980), ‘Wage determination in the union and nonunion sectors: a sample selectivity approach’, Industrial and Labor Relations Review 34(1), 24–34. Evans, W.N. and E. Montgomery (1994), ‘Education and health: where there’s smoke there’s an instrument’, National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 4949. French, M.T. and G.A. Zarkin (1995), ‘Is moderate alcohol use related to wages? Evidence from four worksites’, Journal of Health Economics 14, 319–44. Grossman, M. (1972), The Demand for Health – A Theoretical and Empirical Investigation, National Bureau of Economic Research, New York. Gyourko, J. and J. Tracy (1988), ‘An analysis of public- and private- sector wages allowing for endogenous choices of both government and union status’, Journal of Labor Economics 6(2), 229–53. Hamilton, V. and B.H. Hamilton (1997), ‘Alcohol and earnings: does drinking yield a wage premium?’, Canadian Journal of Economics 30(1), 135–51. Hersch, J. and W.K. Viscusi (1990), ‘Cigarette smoking, seatbelt use and differences in wage-risk tradeoffs’, Journal of Human Resources 25(2), 202–27. Hilton, M.E. (1987), ‘Drinking patterns and drinking problems in 1984: results from a general population 96 ECONOMIC RECORD survey’, Alcoholism: Clinical and Experimental Research 11, 167–75. Idson, T.L. and D.J. Feaster (1990), ‘A selectivity model of employer-size wage differentials’, Journal of Labor Economics 8(1), 99–122. Jones, F.L. (1983), ‘On decomposing the wage gap: a critical comment on Blinder’s method’, Journal of Human Resources 18, 126–30. Kenkel, D.S. and D.C. Ribar (1994), ‘Alcohol consumption and young adults’ socioeconomic status, Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, Microeconomics, 119–61. Knupfer, G.K. (1984), ‘The risks of drunkenness (or, ebrietas resurecta)’, British Journal of Addiction 79, 1985–96. Last, J.M. (1998), Public Health and Human Ecology, Prentice Hall, London. Lee, L.F. (1982), Some approaches to the correction of selectivity bias, Review of Economic Studies 49, 355– 72. Lee, L.F. (1983), ‘Generalized econometric models with selectivity’, Econometrica 51(2), 507–12. Lye, J. and J. Hirschberg (1999), ‘Wages and Alcohol Consumption, Smoking, Weight Gain and Exercising: Evidence on Australian Men and Women’, University of Melbourne Department of Economics Research Paper No. 621. Manski, C.F. (1993), ‘Identification of endogenous social effects: The reflection problem’, Review of Economic Studies 60, 531–42. Mullahy, J. and J.L. Sindelar (1991), ‘Gender differences in labour market effects of alcoholism’, American Economic Review 81, 161–65. MARCH Mullahy, J. and J.L. Sindelar (1993), ‘Alcoholism, work and income’, Journal of Labor Economics 11, 494– 519. National Health and Medical Research Council (1992), Is There a Safe Level of Daily Consumption of Alcohol for Men and Women? AGPS, Canberra. Oaxaca, R. (1973), ‘Male-female wage differentials in urban labor markets’, International Economic Review 14, 693–709. Rao, C.R. (1973), Linear Statistical Inference and Its Applications, Wiley, New York, Second edition. Shaper, A.G. (1993), ‘Editorial: alcohol, the heart and health’, American Journal of Public Health 83(6), 799–801. Smith, J.P. (1999), ‘Healthy bodies and thick wallets: the dual relationship between health and economic status’, Journal of Economic Perspectives 13(2), 145– 66. Stewart, M.B. (1983), ‘On least squares estimation when the dependent variable is grouped’, Review of Economic Studies 50, 737–53. Trost, R.P. and L.F. Lee (1984), ‘Technical training and earnings: a polychotomous choice model with selectivity’, Review of Economics and Statistics 66, 151–56. White, H. (1980), ‘A heteroskedasticity-consistent covariance matrix estimator and a direct test for heteroskedasticity’, Econometrica 48(4), 817–38. Zarkin, G.A., M.T. French, T. Mroz and J.W. Bray (1998), ‘Alcohol use and wages: new results from the National Household Survey on Drug Abuse’, Journal of Health Economics 17, 53–68.