Uploaded by Isa Suleimanov

m reading1

advertisement
Institutions and Growth
in East Asia*
StephanHaggard
Institutions have played a central role in political economy explanations of East
Asia's growth, from the developmental state to the micro-institutions of industrial
policy. A review of these institutional explanations finds that few if any of the postulated institutional explanations involve either necessary or sufficient conditions
for rapid growth. This finding suggests two conclusions. First, there are multiple
institutional means for solving the various collective action, credibility, and informational problems that constitute barriers to growth. The search for a single institutional "taproot" of growth is likely to be a misguided exercise, and more attention
should be given to understanding the varieties of capitalism in East Asia. Second,
institutions are themselves endogenous to other political factors that appear more
consequential for growth, including particularly the nature of the relationship between the state and the private sector.
he debate about the relationship between institutions and economic growth in
Asia has its own distinctive pedigree, and as a result must be understood through
a sociology of knowledge. Japan's post-Meiji transformation and subsequent reconstruction after the Pacific War naturally attracted attention, but could initially
be dismissed as sui generis. Other developing countries, particularly in Asia, were
unlikely to replicate Japan's entry into the ranks of the advanced industrial states;
indeed, it was doubtful that Japan itself would sustain its extraordinary burst of
postwar growth.
Three developments, spread over several decades, redefined the study of Asia's
political economy. The first was the explosive growth of the newly industrializing
countries (NICs)--Korea, Taiwan, Hong Kong, and Singapore--that began in the
T
Stephan Haggard is the Lawrence and Sallye Krause Professor at the Graduate School of International Relations and Pacific Studies, University of California, San Diego. He is the author of Pathways from the Periphery: The Political Economy of Growth in the Newly Industrializing Countries
(1990) and The Political Economy of the Asian Financial Crisis (2000). He is the co-author (with
Robert Kaufman) of The Political Economy of Democratic Transitions (1995) and (with David
McKendrick and Richard Doner) From Silicon Valley to Singapore: Location and Competitive Advantage in the Hard Disk Drive Industry (2000). Also with Robert Kaufman, he is co-editor of The
Politics of Economic Adjustment (1992). He is currently working with Robert Kaufman on a project
on changing social contracts in East Asia, Latin America, and Central Europe.
Studies in Comparative International Development, Winter 2004, Vol. 38, No. 4, pp. 53-81.
54
Studies in Comparative International Development / Winter 2004
mid 1960s, followed by extraordinary episodes of high growth in Thailand, Indonesia, and Malaysia, as well. Japan was no longer alone. The second development
was Japan's apparent economic invincibility. Until the economic malaise of the
1990s set in, Japan's success in key industries from autos to electronics was taken
as evidence of the superiority of its dirigist economic model.~ The third development occurred when, after 1978, China and Vietnam pursued a reform course that
avoided the devastating collapse of output that characterized the transition in the
former Soviet Union and Eastern Europe. By comparison to all relevant groups
(other developing countries, the OECD, and other socialist economies in transition), the countries of East Asia were outliers.
The emergence of the NICs had particular significance for debates about development in general, and I focus primarily on them here. John Williamson's (1990)
famous checklist of the "Washington Consensus" could have been taken directly
from the early literature on the NICs; the list of desirable policies included stable
fiscal and monetary policy; low inflation; exploitation of comparative advantage
through trade, exchange rate, and foreign investment policies; flexible labor markets; and market-friendly--if not exactly laissez-faire--governments.
At least in North America, the counter-revolution against these views can be
dated quite precisely to the appearance of Chalmers Johnson's MITI and the Japanese Miracle in 1982. Johnson emphasized the positive role of industrial policy in
Japanese growth, but his account was predominantly political rather than economic.
MITI explained how distinctive features of the political system allowed the bureaucracy to steer a course between Anglo-American minimalism (the "regulatory state")
and the problematic features of socialist planning. Johnson's work on the "developmental state"--including his own extensions of the concept to Korea and Taiwan
(Johnson 1987)--structured the debate about Japan's development for over a decade (Samuels 1987; Friedman 1988; Okimoto 1989; Calder 1993; Ramseyer and
Rosenbluth 1993; Noble 1998), influenced a large body of comparative political
economy literature on the East Asian NICs (Deyo 1987; Chu 1989; Gereffi and
Wyman 1990; Haggard 1990; Cheng 1990; Doner 1991; Evans 1995; Chan, Clark,
and Lam 1998; Woo-Cumings 1999), and presented the stylized facts of the Japanese case for comparisons within the OECD (Berger and Dore 1996; Hall and Soskice
200!).
The literature on the developmental state was complemented by a second body
of work on precisely how government interventions contributed to growth. Spearheaded by scholars outside the mainstream of North American economics, this work
began by underlining empirical anomalies: the myriad ways in which the East Asian
cases failed to conform to the neoclassical view. Alice Amsden (1989) suggested
that Korea had grown rapidly because it had gotten prices wrong, but in ways that
nurtured firm-level learning and innovation. Robert Wade (1990), an anthropologist by training, and Ha-Joon Chang (1994), who taught at Cambridge University,
outlined the central features of industrial policy in Taiwan and Korea, respectively.
A succession of excellent industry studies by sociologists, political scientists, and
students of business dissected the workings of industrial policy and institutions at
the sectoral level (for example, Rhee 1994; Evans 1995; Kuo 1995; Uriu 1996;
Noble 1998) and firm level (for example, Dote 1973; Aoki 1988; Hamilton and
Biggart 1988; Fields 1995; Fruin 1998). A handful of economists (Pack and Westphal
Haggard
55
1986; Lall 1996; Kim and Nelson 2000; Amsden 2001) emphasized the role of
technology, a topic that mainstream economists tended to avoid. And of course,
some economists from Japan (for example, Shinohara 1982; Aoki 1988; Yanagihara
and Sambommatsu 1997; Aoki, Kim, and Okuno-Fujiwara 1996) and elsewhere in
the region (for example, Jomo et al. 1997; Wong and Ng 2001) never bought into
the neoclassical consensus in the first place, and developed their own lines of thought.
Little of this work gained any recognition from the American economics profession, where a renaissance in the study of economic growth in the 1980s shifted
attention back to the macro level. Endogenous growth theory opened the door to
interpretations of the role of policy, institutions, and learning. Yet in important
empirical papers, Kim and Lau (1994) and Young (1994, 1995) argued that Asia's
growth could be explained largely by sheer capital accumulation. If productivity
did not appear to be very important for the region's development, both neoclassical
interpretations (emphasizing the role of policy in achieving allocative efficiency)
and those looking at industrial policy (and emphasizing the role of the state in
"creating" comparative advantage) were barking up the wrong tree. Either there
was no puzzle to be explained, as Krugman (1994) argued, or the puzzle was why
the region managed such rapid accumulation of physical and human capital (for
very different perspectives, see Ito and Krueger 1995; Rodrik 1995; Easterly 1995;
Young 1994, 1995).
In the 1990s, intellectual developments with respect to imperfect competition,
information economics, and institutions provided the study of government intervention with micro-foundations that made them legitimate to the economics profession. The World Bank (1993) made an important bow to institutional factors in
its much-debated Miracle report on the region's growth. That bow deepened during
the 1990s as the international financial institutions placed greater and greater emphasis
on "governance" as a central determinant of growth (World Bank 1997, 2003).
The Asian financial crisis of 1997-98 sparked another round of controversy about
East Asia's experience. The "Washington" postmortems on the crisis focused on
institutional failures such as weaknesses in financial regulation and corporate governance (for example, World Bank 1999). Not coincidentally, the post-crisis period
saw a much more skeptical literature on the nature of business-government relations (for example, Jomo and Kahn 2000; Campos 2001; Kang 2002a, 2002b) and
Asian political institutions more generally (Haggard 2000; Maclntyre 2001 a, 2003).
The crisis was interpreted very differently by a dissident group of economists
who emphasized the risks associated with financial market integration. Underlying
their critique was a broader reinterpretation of the region's history that was very
similar to what Grrard Roland (SCID 38:4, 110) calls an "evolutionary-institutionalist perspective." Led in part by a Nobel laureate (Stiglitz and Uy 1996; Stiglitz
and Yusuf 2001; Stiglitz 2002), this analysis emphasized how Asia (including China
and Vietnam) had succeeded through an extraordinarily protracted "transition" that
lasted several decades and was highly experimental in nature. These interpretations
emphasized gradualism, strong governments, a variety of coordinating institutions,
and self-conscious development of local technological capabilities.
In sum, thirty years after general interpretations of East Asia's postwar growth
first appeared, new interpretations emphasizing the role of institutions are still finding
their way into print. I structure my review of this work around three central de-
56
Studies in Comparative International Development / Winter 2004
bates: (1) the role of "big" institutions in capital accumulation and growth; (2) the
significance of industrial policy; and (3) the nature of business-government relations.
An important source of growth in East Asia is the region's very high level of
physical and human capital accumulation. A number of institutional approaches
suggest why governments might be able to elicit high levels of private investment,
including strong protection of property rights, authoritarian political systems, and
institutional innovations such as business-government counsels and "strong" bureaucracies. These theories exist in substantial tension with one another, and none
makes a convincing case for the necessity or sufficiency of any given institutional
arrangement. Plausible links can be drawn between these institutions and growth in
particular instances, but the variance across countries is high and no single institutional model of accumulation emerges clearly from the historical record.
A second big debate on institutions and growth in East Asia concerns industrial
policies for "governing the market" (Wade 1990). We have impeccable theoretical
reasons to explain why such coordination can be welfare-improving and numerous
case studies of industrial policies that appeared to work. Yet superficially similar
strategies had deleterious effects in other settings, and East Asia has its own share
of industrial policy failures. A plausible explanation for this variance is that the
institutions surrounding these policies mattered. Theory provides good reasons why
such institutions might be effficiency-enhancing, but the empirical variation is again
quite large, and some countries grew rapidly with only "thin" institutions of this
sort.
In the third and concluding section of this article, I suggest that these analytic
problems are self-induced and spring in part from the misguided effort to find a
single institutional "taproot" for the region's growth--a sin cognate to what Peter
Evans calls, in this volume, "institutional monocropping." But the problem is deeper.
The preoccupation with institutions, and the functionalism in much institutionalist
thinking (Roland, this volume), has obscured more fundamental political and social processes that are themselves determinants of institutional form and quality.
There are gains in returning to some fundamental questions about political
economy: Who rules? What are their preferences and capabilities? In this article, I
consider business-government relations in the region and how they influenced both
institutions and the growth process. Political elites in the region forged alliances
with the private sector, but simultaneously retained independent sources of political power over it. The erosion of these conditions and the growth of business power
was one factor in the onset of the Asian financial crisis of the late 1990s. Rebuilding institutions to check the private sector is a common theme in current reform
efforts, and those efforts emanate not only from "Washington" but from deep-seated
political processes in the region itself.
Regimes of Accumulation: "Big" Institutions, Investment, and Policy Reform
In a simple accounting sense, economic growth can result from productive inputs-capital and labor--or from greater efficiency in their use. Early growth accounting
suggested that virtually all of Asia's growth could be explained by sheer accumulation. This view is still contested, but physical and human capital accumulation in
Asia was clearly extraordinary. 2 Three closely related theories link institutions to
Haggard
57
FIGURE 1
Institutional Models of Capital Accumulation
Property Rights I
Strong property rights-)investment-~growth
Property Rights II
Political stability-If,certainty over property
rights'-) investment-]~growth
Regime Type I
Authoritarian regime-~direct mobilization of resources
and pro-investment policies'ql, investment'~l'growth
Regime Type IIa
Authoritarian regime-~stable macroeconomic
policy") investment-l~growth
Regime Type lib
Authoritarian regime-~policy reforms that improve
allocative efficiency-')investment and increased
product ivity"~ growth
Credible
commitments I:
Representative
institutions
Business-government networks and/or counsels limit
predation and solve credible commitment
problems-,) investment'-~growth
Credible
commitments II:
Delegative
institutions
Delegation and "Weberian" bureaucracies limit predation,
solve credible commitment problems, and improve the
quality o f policy-~ investment-If,growth
investment; respectively, they emphasize property rights, regime type, and institutional solutions to credible commitment problems. The basic arguments and the
variants I explore here are outlined in Figure 1.
The first, owed to North (1990) and others, emphasizes clear definition and protection of property rights, and needs little elaboration. Strong property rights provide incentives to invest, overcome problems that arise in private contracting, and
constitute a check on the predatory behavior of the state (Besley 1995). The proxies
for property rights protection are far from perfect, and most cross-national empirical studies have relied on subjective evaluations by investors rather than objective
indicators of legal rules? Nonetheless, in the last decade some cross-national empirical work has found that strong property rights are positively related to growth
(Knack and Keefer 1995; Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson 2001). East Asia does
relatively well on some, but not all, of these measures. Campos and Nugent (1999),
for example, compare East Asia favorably to Latin America. Rodrik (1997) argues
that differences in growth within Asia are associated with measures of institutional
quality as well, with protection of property rights only one element of the composite measure used.
A literature on political instability and growth can also be given a property rights
58
Studies in Comparative International Development / Winter 2004
interpretation (for example, Barro 1991, 1996; Alesina and Perotti 1996; Feng 1997).
Not surprisingly, political uncertainty--whether measured by the incidence of political violence or government turnover--is associated with lower growth in a cross
section of countries. Insecurity of property rights may be one reason for this result.
Casual empiricism suggests that the growth miracles in East Asia occurred during
relatively long periods of political dominance by conservative parties or elites that
might have mitigated property rights concerns--the Liberal Democratic Party (LDP),
Kuomintang (KMT), and People's Action Party (PAP) in Japan, Taiwan, and
Singapore, respectively; Park Chung Hee, Soeharto, and Mahathir in Korea, Indonesia, and Malaysia; the British colonial administration in Hong Kong; and a surprisingly stable alliance of king, military, and bureaucracy in Thailand. The Chinese
Communist Party fits this model over the last two decades, as well.
Despite these findings, Asia presents some fairly obvious anomalies--at least if
we consider property rights to ultimately rest on the rule of law and other constraints on state power. I have already noted the biggest anomaly of all: in China, a
communist party dictatorship with weak legal and judicial institutions has nonetheless enjoyed unprecedented capital inflows, investment, and growth for two decades. However, most of the other East Asian miracles were authoritarian systems
in which executives enjoyed substantial discretion. If property rights were secure,
such security did not rest on formal legal and institutional constraints on state power.
Informal institutions or some other mechanism must have been at work.
A second and more contested theory for rapid capital accumulation and growth
argues that authoritarian regimes were a crucial element of the story. Two implicit
political models run through the developmental state literature, including my own
writing (1990). The first begins with the trade-off between investment and consumption. Growth requires capital accumulation, which in turn demands that resources be diverted from consumption to investment.4 Voters (or the poor or labor,
depending on the precise specification) are likely to oppose such a reallocation: If
we take the problematic assumption of myopia at face value, limiting the political
voice of "pro-consumption" groups could increase aggregate investment.
The second authoritarian model focuses on the general policy environment. Economic performance depends heavily on the conduct of macroeconomic policy, including stable and appropriate real exchange rates and fiscal and monetary policies
that limit high and variable inflation (for example, Fischer 1993). Growth also depends on allocative efficiency,6 an important barrier to which is policy-induced
distortions of various sorts. Trade policy in the region, for example, was far from
liberal, but when compared with other developing countries, incentives to export
were stronger.
How did Asian governments get macroeconomic policy and incentives "right?"
The policy status quo in many developing countries is characterized by high and
erratic inflation, overvalued exchange rates, and a welter of interventions tied to
rent-seeking groups of various sorts. The political economy problem is one of transition. Dictators can overcome collective action problems inside and outside the
government, override rent-seeking pressures, and thus push the economy onto a
more efficient growth path.
The controversy surrounding the effects of regime type has resurfaced in recent
years because of the widespread transition to democratic rule, as occurred in the
Haggard
59
Philippines (1986); Korea (1987); Taiwan and Thailand (gradually, beginning in
the mid 1980s); and Indonesia (1998). If the authoritarian hypothesis is correct, the
transition to democracy should imply more consumption, less investment, less coherent economic policy, and correspondingly slower growth.
With the exception of Indonesia, none of the Asian countries that democratized
experienced an immediate or dramatic slowdown in growth, 7 and some--most
notably the Philippines--performed better than they had under authoritarian rule.
However, a number of studies appearing in the wake of the financial crisis of 1997
to 1998 argued that democracy complicated the policy-making process. Moon and
Mo (1999) state the case most forcefully; they argue that democratization in Korea
compounded problems of moral hazard before the financial crisis and undermined
the coherence of economic policy making once the crisis broke. Others are more
cautious, arguing that it was not democracy per se but particular democratic institutions that have adverse consequences. In an important book on the financial crisis,
MacIntyre (2003) argues that both authoritarian and democratic systems with a
high number of veto players are more prone to policy failures and crisis. Cheng
(2003) provides an even broader catalogue of institutional weaknesses in Asia's
new democracies, from excessive legislative powers on the part of presidents, to
features of the electoral system (such as the non-concurrency of elections and term
limits), to the weakness of party systems. At least in theory, all of these could have
adverse consequences for economic policy making and thus for growth.
For many years, the political science discipline wrestled with the link between
regime type and growth, with inconclusive results. Adam Przeworski and his colleagues (2000) have made substantial progress toward resolving the debate. In a
sophisticated set of tests covering a very large sample of countries over the 1950-90 period, Przeworski et al. report the following:
9 Controlling for income and a number of other variables, regime type has no effect on
investment, the growth rate of the capital stock, or overall income growth.
9 Dividing the sample into wealthy and poor countries (above and below $3000 per
capita income), there is no evidence that regime type affects growth in poor countries.
9 There is no significant difference in the aggregate economic performance of wealthy
dictatorships and wealthy democracies, but the nature of growth differs. Wealthy
democracies exhibit somewhat slower growth in the capital stock and much slower
growth in the labor force, but use labor more productively, pay higher wages, and
show higher productivity growth.
9 The standard deviation of growth in the sample of dictatorships is much larger than
in the democracies (6.08 vs. 3.87, controlling for a number of potentially confounding factors), suggesting that dictatorships include both high-growth "miracles" and
low-growth "debacles."
9 Dictatorships that experience high growth for some period---even an extended period-revert to the mean or even experience disastrous growth collapses; Nigeria,
Iraq, Romania, and Ecuador provide examples.
If any other region were under consideration, the debate could end with the observation that no convincing empirical evidence exists that authoritarian regimes
outperform democratic ones. However, a high proportion of all growth miracles in
the developing world are concentrated in East Asia, and all of the countries except
60
Studies in Comparative International Development / Winter 2004
Japan were under authoritarian regimes during their inflection onto a high growth
path. Moreover, if we discount a few non-trivial anomalies (the Marcos period in
the Philippines; the disastrous collapse of the Soeharto regime in Indonesia; the
even more horrifying history of Pol Pot's Cambodia), authoritarian regimes in Asia
did not show the tendency visible in other high-growth authoritarian cases toward a
marked slowdown in growth over time. Thus, while regime type may not matter for
growth in a cross section of countries, the Przeworski et al. findings offer little
insight into why East Asian dictatorships cluster at the high-accumulation, highgrowth tail of the authoritarian distribution.
This statement of the problem brings us to a third approach that stresses the
resolution of credible commitment problems. Note that the property rights and authoritarian models are in significant theoretical tension. The "na'fve" property rights
approach outlined above simply assumes that rights are credibly defined and enforced. Yet authoritarian regimes lack credible checks on executive discretion and
should therefore suffer from credibility problems in protecting property rights. 8
One possible explanation for East Asia's success is that authoritarian regimes inherited, evolved, or consciously devised institutions that allowed them to signal
their commitment to property rights and a stable policy environment conducive to
long-run growth.
Some historical context suggests the plausibility of this approach. All of the
high-growth Asian countries began their postwar histories in extraordinarily inauspicious circumstances; indeed, it is hard to imagine a part of the world where the
immediate postwar future looked so bleak. Japan had been completely defeated in
war. South Korea was subjected to a relatively hostile American occupation, riven
by near-civil war, and then engulfed in a devastating conflict with North Korea.
The Communists defeated the KMT on the mainland, forcing them to relocate to
Taiwan. China experienced revolution, and then the equally disruptive Great Leap
and Cultural Revolution, both of which had spillovers for Hong Kong. The Philippines, Indonesia, Singapore, and Malaysia went through domestic political uncertainties associated with independence that were arguably no worse than those faced
elsewhere, but Indonesia subsequently experienced devastating loss of life in 1965
as the Sukarno regime collapsed in indiscriminate slaughter. Singapore faced isolation following the collapse of its union with Malaya and the subsequent withdrawal
of the British military. Thailand's geographic position left it exposed to uncertainties associated with the wars in Vietnam, Cambodia, and Laos.
In sum, political leaderships in all of these countries faced the problem of how to
mobilize resources under political circumstances that were highly uncertain. 9 The
solution was to provide assurances to the private sector--in effect, to separate economic, civil, and political liberties (Chan 2002). Grabowski (1994, 1997) and Huff,
Dewit, and Oughton (2001) have modeled relations between a developmental state
and the private sector as a simple game in which the government signals its credibility to the private sector by complementary investments that elicit private investment. These models do not consider institutions centrally, ~~ but the idea that
institutions can help solve credible commitment problems is by now highly familiar (North and Weingast 1989; Cox and McCubbins 2000).
Two types of institutions arise repeatedly in efforts to explain why East Asia's
authoritarian governments were distinctive. I call them "partially representative"
Haggard
61
and "delegative" institutions. The World Bank (1993), Campos and Root (1996),
and Root (1996) develop the argument that "deliberation councils" linking business and government played an important role in resolving credibility problems
associated with authoritarian rule and building trust between the public and private
sectors. Evans (1995), Maxfield and Schneider (1997), Weiss (1998), and Moon
and Prasad (1999) cast the argument in more general terms, claiming that a complex of both formal and informal networks between the public and private sectors
played a similar function. In Evans' (1995) felicitous phrase, the East Asian state
was characterized by "embedded autonomy": strong political and bureaucratic institutions that simultaneously maintained dense ties with the private sector.
How did it work? These councils and networks operate at different levels in the
political system (from the bureau to the chief executive), can include representatives of formal business associations as well as individual firms, and may consider
functional (e.g., export promotion, wage-setting), industry-specific, or even firmspecific issues. They are "partially" representative because, unlike corporatist arrangements and policy networks in Europe, labor and other social groups were
under-represented or represented only through controlled organizations. Formal
councils and informal networks provide opportunities for private sector actors to
relay information to politicians and bureaucrats and allow politicians and bureaucrats to signal their intentions and commitment and thus to build trust (Maxfield
and Schneider 1997 provide an overview; see also Evans, this volume, on the role
of deliberation). H Unlike informal networks--such councils limited private sector
opportunism. The relative inclusiveness of participation and the establishment of
clear and transparent "rules of the game" with respect to particular policy areas
limited the ability of individual firms to secure particularistic rents. Such councils
had a similarly restraining effect on the predatory tendencies of the government.
Root (1996: 12) explains by reference to an implicit model of costly signaling:
Tying the fortunes of many groups to the continued use of the cooperative decisionmaking structures raises the cost of altering the system ex post. Once councils permeate
an economy, a government that unilaterally imposes its will on an industry or sector will
risk undermining the value of councils for other groups, thus subverting the entire system of cooperative decision-making. Government, then, is unlikely to abide only by
those decisions it prefers, overturning those it opposes . . . . By institutionalizing deliberative councils, government reduces its discretionary power but gains the confidence of
business in the stability of agreed upon policies.
Business-government networks exist almost everywhere, and are difficult to map;
nor is it easy to distinguish "good" networks from "bad" ones e x a n t e . How prevalent were these business councils and what role did they play in contributing to a
favorable policy environment?
The existence and operation of such councils is thoroughly documented for Japan (Okimoto 1989; Schwartz 2001; Schaede 2001). The early Korean experience
of export-promotion meetings chaired personally by Park Chung Hee is also a frequently used example (Rhee, Ross-Larson, and Pursell 1984). Yet as we move beyond these two Northeast Asian cases, the evidence thins. The World Bank's M i r a c l e
report demonstrates the problem of drawing wider conclusions. With the exception
62
Studies in Comparative International Development / Winter 2004
of Japan, the World Bank (1993: 184) deems public-private consultation "most
explicit" in Singapore, where private citizens serve as directors on statutory boards
and as members of ad hoc government advisory councils, and the government solicits the opinion of private industry groups. Yet such practices are hardly distinctive, and the report neglects to mention that the local private sector in Singapore is
politically and economically the weakest in the region. Many of the statutory boards
on which private citizens serve oversee activities that directly usurp the private
sector, including activities which members of the private sector have repeatedly
(and unsuccessfully) argued should be ceded to them.
Thailand offers another example. The country developed a coordinating council
mechanism in the early Prem years, and the most prominent study of it underlines
its purpose in securing private sector support (Laothamatas 1992). But the experiment was short-lived and does not appear to fit the model of a government preoccupied with stimulating private investment. Rather, Prem was preoccupied with
securing private sector support for the political changes he sought to introduce. In
Malaysia, such institutions did not appear until 1991, when Mahathir's "Look East"
campaign sought to emulate the Northeast Asian NICs. Yet in a succession of outstanding studies, Gomez (1991; Jomo and Gomez 1997) has detailed how this period was the high point of corruption, cronyism, and the interpenetration of
government, state, and party. The Malaysian Business Council served important
informational functions but had no decisional authority, and Mahathir maintained
other political channels to the private sector. Moreover, this council does not appear to fit the model of a government trying to reassure a skeptical private sector.
Investment was robust and the political objective was primarily to buttress the Malay
private sector vis-g~-vis the Chinese. As the World Bank admits (1993:184-5), "formal mechanisms for business-government interface are almost entirely lacking in
T a i w a n . . . a n d . . . Indonesia lacks the formal coordinating links of other high-performing Asian economies." In his 1994 study of business-government relations in
Asia, Maclntyre (1994) finally stated the claim more generally: the Southeast Asian
countries simply do not fit models of business-government relations derived from
the Northeast Asian cases. 12
But even those paradigmatic cases require closer scrutiny. In Korea, the most
important case (outside of Japan) for the significance of such councils, institutionalized consultation between the government and the private sector was transformed
during the heavy industry and chemical industry drive of the 1970s into more particularistic relationships between the executive and the largest groups (Rhee 1994).
As Evans (1995: 53) admits, "embeddedness under Park was a much more 'top
down' affair than the Japanese prototype, lacking the well-developed intermediary
associations and focused on a small number of very large firms." Business-government relations became acrimonious during the Chun Doo Hwan years (1980-87;
Haggard and Moon 1990) and substantially more particularistic and corrupt, as
well (Kang 2002a, 2002b; Schopf 2001).
In sum, partially representative institutions performed useful functions in some
cases for some periods of time, but to the extent that dictatorial regimes faced credible commitment problems, representative institutions did not appear to be a necessary condition for solving them. Authoritarian governments established their
credentials with private actors through other commitment technologies: industrial
Haggard
63
policies, subsidies, rents, corruption, particularistic ties, and simple "repeat play."
Through non-predatory behavior and restraint, sustained over time, governments
signaled that the property rights of favored groups were assured. Institutions were
not necessarily important, and to the extent that they were, they rested on more
fundamental political coalitions and exchange relationships.
By "delegative institutions," I mean bureaucratic agencies that are granted broad
developmental mandates and insulated in various ways from political interference.
Internally, such agencies are run on meritocratic principles with strong internal
systems of both rewards (such as competitive pay and long-term career tracks) and
controls (sanctions for corruption) designed to ensure the alignment of individual
incentives with broader organizational goals. Delegation is necessarily imperfect
in all political systems. In democracies, legislators can take back what they have
granted, although at some cost; in dictatorships, such delegation is even more easily reversed. Similarly, the Weberian bureaucracy is clearly an ideal type. Yet these
real-world imperfections do not negate the positive effects that delegation and bureaucratic reform can have in signaling government intentions to private actors,
increasing the decisiveness of decision making, and simply improving the quality
of policy formulation and implementation.
Cross-national evidence of the effects of bureaucracy is scarce because of the
difficulty of measuring its quality with any precision. In a highly innovative study,
Evans and Rauch (2000) found that the "Weberianness" of the bureaucracy was in
fact associated with growth in a cross section of thirty-five developing countries.
Case-study work finds that economic reforms in the region were typically accompanied by major bureaucratic reorganizations that concentrated economic decisionmaking authority in one or several lead agencies, strengthened the role of technocrats
in formulating policy, and reformed internal bureaucratic routines (Haggard 1990).
Reform of the bureaucracy did not typically reach the entire administrative apparatus. Pockets of bureaucratic efficiency coexisted with ministries that dispensed "pork"
and political favors (Kang 2002a, 2002b). Nonetheless, all of the high-growth Asian
countries had strong "delegative" institutions: core economic ministries and/or specialized agencies with important policy-making powers that were run on meritocratic
principles and had strong internal rules and norms.
Despite the tight theoretical and empirical fit between delegation, bureaucratic
reform, and economic take-off, the underlying causal connections are very far from
clear. Indeed, in recent years an acrimonious debate has emerged on the importance
of the bureaucracy in the policy-making process in Asia. Japan has been the battleground of this fight, with Johnson's MITI and the Japanese Miracle once again at
the center of the debate. Johnson claimed that bureaucrats and politicians in Japan
operated under a tacit division of labor, in which politicians reigned but bureaucrats actually ruled and pursued their own developmental objectives even when
they clashed with those of politicians. This view was never the dominant one within
Japanese studies (e.g., Krauss and Murimatsu 1984), but the challenge was given a
new theoretical edge in the 1990s by political scientists working with a principalagent framework. Ramseyer and Rosenbluth (1993) argued forcefully that bureaucrats in Japan were little more than agents of politicians who ultimately dictated the
course of policy. Noble (1998) showed that the consultative structure of MITI and
its particular interventions were closely tied to the electoral strategy of the LDP.
64
Studies in Comparative lnternalional Development / Winter 2004
Look closely enough, and the core principal-agent relationships could always be
found, with politicians and their electoral incentives in command.
It is even more misleading to think that bureaucrats enjoyed independence in the
authoritarian regimes. Rather, bureaucracies are rightly interpreted as instruments
of authoritarian rulers, reformed not to ensure their independence but to assure
their loyalty to the leadership. Nunberg's (2002) biting critique of East Asia's institutional "conceit" notes that although initial recruitment in the region tended to be
meritocratic, seniority often drove advancement, and performance was judged by
rule compliance "appropriate for carrying out directives handed down from the
commanding heights of government" (Nunberg 2002: 5).
I began this section by arguing that rapid growth in East Asia was attributable in
the first instance to extraordinary levels of sheer capital accumulation. Strong property rights constitute one "big" institutional theory that might explain why East
Asia did well in this regard. Conservative governments in the region did signal
their commitment to the development of the private sector, but not through limitedgovernment institutions such as the rule of law and independent courts. Arguments
about regime type do not fare well, either; as a general proposition, there is no
connection between regime type and growth, although we are left with the puzzle
that most of Asia's high-growth economies were authoritarian. Partially representative institutions catering to business might have contributed to the credibility of
East Asia's dictatorships. But such institutions were neither ubiquitous nor necessarily salutary in their effects, as I will show. Bureaucratic reform signaled government commitment, resolved collective action problems within governments, and
simply improved the quality of policy. However, it is highly unsatisfying to invoke
partially representative and delegative institutions as prime movers when they are
so obviously endogenous to some deeper political process.
Institutions Writ Small: The Industrial Policy Debate
Before turning to what those processes might be, it is useful to descend from the
macro to the micro levels and review the debate about industrial policy in Asia. The
first question concerns the underlying theoretical rationale for such policies, which
I define as selective interventions designed to influence the allocation of resources
among different activities. The second question is an empirical one: did such policies matter? Finally, and of most interest to us here, did the institutions associated
with such policies influence their effectiveness and efficiency? Did governance
matter?
Theoretically, selective intervention can be welfare-enhancing only under restrictive conditions--namely, that it addresses well-defined problems of market
imperfection and externalities. Although these arguments take a wide variety of
forms, their underlying structure is similar in emphasizing coordination problems
that private actors cannot resolve efficiently through private contracting (Chang
1994; Noland and Pack 2003: 16--8). Institutions feature prominently in the discussion of these policies because they address just such coordination problems.
Four lines of theory and research provide a sense of both the argument and the
historical experience of the region; those that emphasize coordination problems in
the real sector, capital market failures, technology, and agglomeration economies.
Haggard
65
These four lines of thought also follow an admittedly imperfect historical sequence,
from the dictates of early industrialization, to the demands of a more open and
technologically demanding phase of economic growth.
A number of recent studies have revived "big-push" models of growth that emphasize coordination problems in the industrial sector, particularly in its early stages
of growth (Chang 1994; Rodrik 1995; Matsuyama 1996). In these models, efficient
investment can be deterred by small market size and the absence of complementary
suppliers or customers. Current market prices will not adequately convey information about future growth, and countries thus forego investments that would lower
production costs through larger plant size. Big-push-like investments by the government and subsidies, protection, and other incentives to private firms can overcome these collective action problems, but only if explicitly coordinated; such
coordination is where institutions come in. Okazaki (1996), for example, details
how MITI's Council for Industrial Rationalization resolved pricing problems between the coal, steel, and downstream industries. Similar efforts have been well
documented in Korea's heavy-industry drive of the 1970s, although the breakdown
of coordination ultimately resulted in substantial surplus capacity (Rhee 1994; Stern
et al. 1995). The coordination rationale for intervention can also be seen in less
obvious cases than the heavy intermediates such as steel and petrochemicals. For
example, Gold (1981) and Kuo (1995) document the Taiwanese government's role
in coordinating complementary investments in different segments of the textile industry, such as between the spinning and weaving segments, and Doner (1991)
examines coordination problems between assemblers and suppliers in the automobile industry in Southeast Asia.
A second theoretical rationale for intervention centers on failures in capital markets. Hellman, Murdock, and Stiglitz (1996) have offered a neatly integrated theoretical framework of systems of "financial restraint" motivated directly by the East
Asian experience. In the model, controls on deposit rates and limitations on entry
create rents for financial intermediaries ("franchise value"). These rents provide
incentives for banks to expand their deposit base, thereby contributing to financial
deepening, and to undertake socially profitable projects that banks would not otherwise finance due to problems of adverse selection and moral hazard. Controls on
lending rates create rents for firms in the real sector, as well. These rents do not
necessarily imply inefficiencies if banks are capable of monitoring firms, and if
firms have incentives to increase their equity stake in a given project. In addition to
general controls on deposit and lending rates, more direct government intervention
in channeling credit to particular high-return sectors may still be justified by the
divergence of private and social returns due to market failures. Government-directed finance was particularly important in the Korean case (Woo 1991) but is
visible in particular sectors and projects elsewhere in the region, as well (Haggard,
Lee, and Maxfield 1993; Jomo et al. 1997).
Again, government and private institutions each play a coordinating function in
such a system. Governments must be able to coordinate with banks--which have
superior information on potential borrowers--and among them on grounds similar
to those outlined with respect to big-push strategies (Hellman, Murdock, and Stiglitz
1996: 185-99). In an intriguing application of principal-agent and transactionscosts models motivated by the Korean case, Lee (1992) argues that hierarchical
66
Studies in Comparative International Development / Winter 2004
forms of financial coordination (a "quasi-internal organization") economize on communication costs, reduce opportunism, resolve small-number bargaining indeterminacies, and permits auditing of outcomes.
A third rationale for industrial policy centers on technology and has produced its
own quite distinctive literature. The NICs succeeded largely through processes of
imitation, yet even the success of imitative policy is subject to a variety of market
failures (Amsden 2001: Chapter 3); firms lack full information on technological
alternatives, function with imperfect information on the technologies they do acquire, and are subject to variable, unpredictable, and highly path-dependent learning processes (Lall 2000). Actual innovation is even more difficult. Rationales for
government intervention include incomplete appropriability that leads to
underinvestment in R and D, coordination problems such as standards setting, and
above all, the externalities that arise from R and D activities.
The firm is the ultimate locus of innovation, but some countries produce a larger
number of innovative firms than do others. It is therefore highly plausible that "national systems of innovation"--including sector-specific policies--influence technological trajectories and thus patterns of international specialization and trade (for
an application to Asia, see Lundvall 1992; Tyson 1993; Zysman 1996; and Kim and
Nelson 2000). Numerous policies and institutions may matter, from the supply of
high-quality education to strategic technology alliances among firms. Nonetheless,
selective interventions may also be appropriate, including protection, restrictions
on licensing and royalties, and government support for research consortia (Lall
1996). Again, institutions play a role in providing public goods and coordinating
both with and among private sector actors; the government-run research institute
and subsidies in support of R and D consortia are the paradigmatic examples. All
governments in the region (including Hong Kong) have had some form of sectorspecific technology policies. A sizable literature on the electronics industry has
documented how countries in the region supported this high-growth sector (for
example, Ernst and O'Connor 1992; Hobday 1997; L. Kim 1997; Matthews and
Cho 2000).
A fourth body of work on location gained prominence with Paul Krugman's
(1991) simple observation that the dynamism and growth of "national" economies
is driven by the dynamism and growth of particular regions and cities. This is no
less true in Asia than elsewhere, and research on regional and urban clusters in the
region has itself become a growth industry (Yusuf 2003: Chapter 6). The externalities associated with such agglomeration include both the concentration and diversity of skills in the labor market; the advantages of a wide range of suppliers of
specialized inputs and services; lowered transactions costs associated with proximity; and informal exchanges that occur outside of market relations, such as the transfer
of business information, that generate knowledge and technology spillovers. Some
clusters emerge through the activities of dominant firms, and generic policies such
as good urban planning are adequate to foster them. However, both the R and D and
production activities in such clusters are often quite specialized, and as a result the
"public" goods they require are highly specific to the activity in question. For example, innovative clusters often arise around strong universities and thrive on
complementarities between university-based research, specialized graduates, and
the R and D and personnel needs of related firms; the rise of Route 128 in Boston
Haggard
67
and the emergence of Silicon Valley in California are examples in the United States
(Saxenian 1994), but Singapore provides examples, as well (McKendrick, Doner,
and Haggard 2000). Specialized training provides another example of a localized
coordination problem. Governments and public-private partnerships can overcome
well-known collective action problems that can arise when firms invest heavily in
worker training, but are subject to poaching. Government training programs, such
as those implemented in Singapore, and quasi-public entities such as the Penang
Skills Development Centre in Malaysia, are models of collective efforts to solve
such coordination dilemmas in the labor market.
So much for the theory. Does any of it matter? A surprisingly common research
design is to pick a successful (or unsuccessful) industry, demonstrate that policy
support existed, and conclude that the case for the significance of industrial policy
is made (or rejected). Even some of the most widely cited studies in the field, including studies by Wade (1990) and Evans (1995), are guilty of this post hoc ergo
propter hoc reasoning. Stern et al. (1995) summarize:
A policy may succeed at one level but, by introducing other economic distortions, may
undermine developments elsewhere. Or the seeming success of the policy may have
come about through exogenous factors, leading to the erroneous observation that the
policy created the apparent economic success. And finally, a policy may appear to have
been implemented when, in fact, the implementation was neither effective in practice
nor so dramatically different from what might have occurred if the policy had not been
enunciated.
The ideal way to resolve the issue is to examine industry-level data gathered
from a range of sectors (or regions) within a given country to determine if those
that received policy support surpassed others on some metric, such as total factor
productivity (TFP), export growth, or profitability. Smith (1995), Rodrik (1996),
and Noland and Pack (2003) provide overviews of these efforts, and the findings
are generally not encouraging for industrial policy advocates. The amounts of measurable support are relatively small; protection and other instruments are often targeted to the "wrong" sectors (in Japan, for example, toward non-competitive,
resource-based sectors; Beason and Weinstein 1995); and policy does not appear to
be correlated strongly, or even positively, with measures of success such as TFP
growth. Even if such a correlation existed, the effects on overall growth (as opposed to sectoral outcomes) would probably be slight. Success in any given sector
does not demonstrate that aggregate social welfare was enhanced, and may reflect
the diversion of resources away from equally if not more profitable activity.
Of course, such studies cannot capture the full range of informal policies or
institutional arrangements that might have affected industry performance. Most
importantly, these policies could have played an important function in the political
economy by signaling government commitment to private sector profitability and
growth. Nonetheless, the controversy has reached an unproductive standoff between the "anecdotal" evidence that makes a plausible case for industrial policy in
particular sectors, and the "systematic" evidence that is more skeptical, but necessarily omits significant institutional detail.
This standoff is not easily resolved, but we can shift the terrain back to the un-
68
Studies in Comparative International Development / Winter 2004
derlying conditions that make it more likely that any given intervention will be
welfare-enhancing. Recall that critics of industrial policy cannot cast their arguments in general theoretical terms: market failures provide a justification for selective intervention. As a result, critics of industrial policy revert to the following
syllogism about government failure:
1) Even if an intervention may be warranted in theory, politicians, bureaucrats, interest
groups, and individual firms can bias all of the selective interventions outlined above
in inefficient and even resource-destroying ways;
2) East Asia was unique in its ability to limit government failure;
3) Any efforts to replicate that experience in other settings is likely to fail;
4) The safest way to avoid inefficient rent-seeking is to limit the distribution of rents in
the first place.
Rather than constituting a general critique of industrial policy, this line of argument
simply admits our ignorance about the political and institutional conditions that
generate or limit government failures. These conditions must be discussed in greater
detail.
The logical place to start is with the specific political tasks which coordinating
institutions must perform. Most obviously, the decision-making process must be
organized in a way that generates growth-promoting policies. This apparently anodyne observation is no less significant for neoclassical interpretations of the region's
growth than it is for "heterodox" ones; in both cases, we need a theory of efficient
government. ' 3
First, if rents are extended for any of the purposes outlined above, they must be
conditional. Governments must define the objectives of the rent in terms of some
discernible market failure or externality, monitor rent recipients, and credibly commit to withdraw rents for non-compliance or non-performance (Amsden 2001, 8;
Aoki, Murdock, and Okuno-Fujiwara 1996). |4 A related observation is that the ability
to impose market discipline and competition on firms is a crucial component of any
credible industrial policy. 15 If governments cannot credibly signal their willingness
to revert to a market equilibrium, or some other punishment strategy for non-compliance, then firms will exploit the government.
Institutions mitigate these problems by limiting rent-seeking that wastes resources,
either in the rent-seeking process or in the subsequent introduction of distortions.
Beginning with the state itself, Schleifer and Vishney (1993) provide an influential
model of corruption that outlines a rationale for centralization (see Kang 2002a,
2002b; and Maclntyre 2001 b for applications to Asia). Rent-seekers demand a range
of complementary government-supplied goods. If the state is highly decentralized,
different branches of government, ministries, or bureaus pursue their own interests,
pushing the cost of government-supplied goods to a suboptimal level and introducing uncertainty over property rights in those rents. Political centralization does not
eliminate corruption, but bounds it by solving these collective action problems,
pricing rents at an "appropriate" level, and providing security of property rights,
which stimulates investment.
The Shleifer and Vishney model conceptualizes the state in a highly stylized
way as a collection of administrative agencies that control rents, but their findings
parallel other work on constitutional design, electoral rules, and party systems. For
Haggard
69
example, Hicken (2001) shows how a fragmented party system, coalition cabinets,
weak party labels, and candidate-centered electoral strategies produced strong incentives for Thai politicians to channel benefits to narrow constituencies. Conversely, centralization of authority (for example, through strong executive powers
or parties) operates as a control mechanism and has been used to explain the difference between the Thai experience following the financial crisis and Korea under
Kim Dae Jung (Haggard 2000: Chapter 2).
Somewhat similar arguments have been made about the internal coherence of
the bureaucracy. In the previous section, I emphasized the role that bureaucratic
reform played in signaling commitment and improving the overall quality of policy.
But meritocratic recruitment and promotion, adequate compensation, and career
paths with clear rewards at the top are important for controlling rent-seeking, as
well (Rose-Ackerman 1997). Evans (1995) and Evans and Rauch (2000) suggest
that the internal coherence of the bureaucracy is the key factor allowing
"embeddedness" to occur without degenerating into inefficient rent-seeking. The
case-study work on industrial policy repeatedly returns to the significance of independent bureaucratic capabilities and information as a condition for effective governance.
Within the literature on the "micro-institutions" that link government to the private sector, there is less consensus regarding the effects of institutional design on
the efficiency of policy. Networks linking individual politicians and bureaucrats
who control rents paid to individual firms (or family members) are prone to quite
obvious inefficiencies. Particularistic, patron-client relations may have played an
important role in assuring business clients at crucial historical junctures, but such
networks are almost certain to lack transparency or incentives to monitor corporate
behavior. Studies of corruption in the Philippines (Hutchcroft 1998), Indonesia
(Maclntyre 2001b), and Malaysia (Gomez 1991; Jomo and Gomez 1997) typically
underline the costs of particularistic networks (see Khan 2000b for a comparative
perspective).
At the other extreme are arguments for broad, "encompassing" representation
through peak or sector-wide private sector organizations. 16 In addition to resolving
the credibility and information problems outlined above, breadth of representation
can incorporate checks on both the state and the private sector. On the one hand,
broadly-organized business sectors act as a check on government through what
Kang (2002a, 2002b) calls "mutual hostage-taking." Where states are centralized
(in the Shleifer and Vishney sense) and private sectors are well-organized, neither
is in a position to exploit the other. Wide representation of the private sector can
also check particular sectors or firms because one firm's rent is another's cost (Doner
1991; Kuo 1995; Campos and Root 1996: Chapter 4). t7
Noble (1998) and Doner and Ramsay (1997, 2000) show how fragile such resuits can be. Their more fine-grained institutional analysis shows that the nature of
the coordination problem will determine what institutional arrangements are optimal. Noble's comparative work on industrial policy in Japan and Taiwan, for example, shows how "encompassing" arrangements can easily degenerate into
collusion, and that such arrangements are kept efficient not through enforcement of
coordination, but through defection by a competitive fringe. The idea that governments must be able to effectively structure competition for rents is also one of the
70
Studies in Comparative International Development / Winter 2004
more interesting analytic contributions of the World Bank (1993) Miracle report.
Governments in Japan and Korea established competition for rents that were noncompulsory and open, but rent-distribution was dependent on fulfilling performance
criteria such as exports, investment, or cost-reductions. Analyses of such "performance-indexed rewards" imply an altogether different institutional relationship
between the government and the private sector than those analyses focusing on the
advantages of "encompassing" arrangements.
If the common theme of the previous section on capital accumulation was the
importance of checking the state, the discussion of industrial policy underlines the
importance of checking private rent-seeking (see Khan 2000a, 2000b). Strong theoretical justifications exist for selective intervention and various forms of coordination, but institutions affect whether these policies will be efficient. Some degree of
centralization in the allocation of rents, appropriate incentives within the bureaucracy, and limits on particularistic business-government networks seem plausible
institutional requirements for a coherent industrial policy---or any policy, for that
matter. But findings about the organization of any particular policy effort appear to
be highly sensitive to the particular coordination problem at hand. In cases where
defection carries high costs, such as in the coordination of training efforts, encompassing organizations with the capacity to sanction are the most efficient institutional form. Yet in other instances, more open and competitive institutional
arrangements will be more effective over the long run; R and D consortia provide
an example. At this point, we still know far too little about government and market
institutions at this level of analysis, but we also know too little about the
complementarity among these "small" institutions and the larger political order. I
conclude by returning to this question.
Business-Government Relations and the Varieties of Capitalism in East Asia
An enduring problem with the institutionalist approach to Asia's growth is its functionalist form: the tendency to address the capacity of the state hut not its motivations is characteristic of the approach. East Asian states may have been "strong,"
but ultimately we want to know why they embraced relatively efficient, outwardoriented, growth-promoting policies. More generally, we need to be wary of the
functionalist view of institutions that is so central to much economic reasoning (see
Roland, this volume, for a similar critique). Institutions do produce gains from
coordination and exchange, but there is typically more than one way to structure
them to achieve those ends. As Knight (1992: 28) argues, "if we want to explain the
development and maintenance of social institutions in terms of the relevant actors'
preferences, we will need to specify what rational actors want the substantive content of such rules to be in the context of diverse distributional forms."
The institutionalist literature on East Asia is not unaware of this problem, and
typically pursues one of four escape routes. The first is ideology. State officials
developed, inherited, or imported ideas about how to achieve economic growth,
and used their control over material and organizational resources to implement them.
Johnson's account of MITI relies on ideological considerations to a substantial degree, and Vogel (1991) and others have emphasized the spread of Japanese ideas
about development throughout the region (see also Haggard 1990).
Haggard
71
A second option is to argue that political elites in East Asia were constrained by
international pressures of various sorts. Bruce Cumings (1984) and Meredith WooCumings (1991, 1996, 1999b) have been the most consistent advocates of this view.
They describe how first a Japanese imperial system and then an American-dominated regional order influenced the emergence and subsequent behavior of state
structures. Japanese colonialism had a profound effect on Korea and Taiwan, and
the United States strengthened right-wing authoritarian governments throughout
the region in the postwar period, creating various networks of influence over economic policy. Resource constraints (Haggard 1990) and security threats (Kang 2002a,
29-40) have also been invoked as external pressures that limited the predatory tendency of the state and pushed governments toward greater efficiency.
Third, the outward-oriented, mixed-economy strategies of the region might be
interpreted in terms of the material interests of the government itself. Rent-seeking
and predatory-state models assume that the interests of political elites are necessarily in conflict with economic efficiency, but this cannot be correct; a number of
growth-promoting reforms benefit the government directly, by increasing the supply of foreign exchange and taxes or deepening financial intermediation, for example. Many "market-oriented" reforms in the region were not motivated by
efficiency, but by efforts on the part of state elites to extract resources.
A fourth option is to return to state-society relations. A central critique of the
developmental state approach from its inception was its excessive focus on institutions and relative neglect of social actors, and business interests in particular (Doner
1991; Maclntyre 1994; Evans 1995; Fields 1995; Moon and Prasad 1997; E. M.
Kim 1997; Chan, Clark, and Lain 1998). All governments in the region reached
explicit or implicit political agreements with segments of the private sector; these
agreements or coalitions served as the political foundation for rapid growth (Campos and Root 1996: Chapter 4). The absence or repression of the left and the weakness of labor no doubt shaped these bargains (Deyo 1989), as did the relatively
equitable distribution of the gains from growth (Campos and Root 1996). But governments in the region typically had independent sources of political and/or organizational power that allowed them to check the private sector. ~8
When we look more closely at how this balancing act worked, we find--again-not a single model of business-government relations, but significant variations. First,
political institutions differed in the extent to which they provided opportunities for
business groups or firms to gain access to, and control over, the policy agenda,
through elections or corporatist arrangements, for example. Second, the political
power of business varied across the region in its organizational coherence, ability
to mobilize support from other sections of the population, and ability to withdraw
economic support from the government (the exit option). I have developed this
argument at greater length elsewhere (Haggard 1999; 2000: Chapter 1), and will
confine myself here to some comparative examples from the early period of high
growth and some observations on the debate surrounding the origins of the Asian
financial crisis.
The Korea-Taiwan comparison provides a sense of the argument (see Cheng
1990 in particular). On relocating to Taiwan following the civil war on the mainland, the KMT had few ties with indigenous elites; the party initially relied on a
military and a bureaucracy composed overwhelmingly of mainlanders. The
72
Studies in Comparative International Development / Winter 2004
government's independence was buttressed by military and police power, the absence of open political competition, a relatively large state-owned enterprise sector, and control over commercial banks. State-corporatist business organizations
provided nominal channels of representation for the private sector, and we are continually learning more about the range of relationships that existed between parts of
the bureaucracy and the Taiwanese private sector as early as the 1950s. But from a
comparative perspective, local business had little formal or informal representation
in the tightly-organized dominant party system and, at least initially, few independent organizational capabilities, either.
In Korea, by contrast, the American occupation imposed nominally democratic
institutions on Korea. However abused, these institutions forced Rhee, and later
Park, to woo private-sector support. The collusive relations between Rhee, the Liberal Party, and the private sector explain the extent of corruption and rent-seeking
during that period, as well as the growth of a well-organized and highly concentrated big-business sector. Riding a tide of popular revulsion toward both Rhee and
the inefficiencies of the short-lived Second Republic, Park Chung Hee's military
dictatorship gained substantial leverage over these rent-seeking groups, both politically and through its seizure of control over the banking system. Yet the military
junta in Korea was ultimately more dependent on the private sector than was the
case in Taiwan. The state-owned enterprise sector was small, the military lacked a
coherent party apparatus for mobilizing support along one-party lines, and American pressure again contributed to the reinstitution of electoral politics that required
financial resources.
Outstanding comparative analyses by Cheng (1990, 1993), Fields (1995), and
Noble (1998) have shown that these political arrangements had profound consequences for the conduct of economic policy and structure. In Taiwan, the stateowned enterprise sector remained larger for longer. Although the Taiwanese private
sector was allowed to flourish, the KMT always feared industrial concentration and
private control over the "commanding heights" of the economy, particularly the
financial sector. The result was a growth trajectory that relied on smaller firms to a
much greater degree than did that seen in Korea, where the government's partnership with business and aggressive industrial policies produced highly diversified
corporate conglomerates. In sum, industrial organization and financial and corporate structure in both countries were directly influenced by the politics of businessgovernment relations.
Comparative analyses along similar lines have been used to understand the differences between the industrial policies of Japan and Taiwan (Noble 1998); between Hong Kong's laissez-faire and the more statistic approach to growth in
Singapore (Chiu, Ho, and Liu 1997); and between the "developmental states" of
Northeast Asia and their Southeast Asian counterparts (MacIntyre 1994; Jomo et
al. 1997). Yet with the important exception of the Philippines (where problems of
capture, rent-seeking, and corruption were apparent quite early in the postwar period), political elites enjoyed a degree of political, organizational, and economic
independence from private sector actors in the early phases of the region's growth,
and this key political fact was reflected in institutional arrangements. Governments
sought cooperation from the private sector on a selective basis, but could use alternative sources of political support (for example, from the rural sector in Korea,
Haggard
73
Taiwan, Thailand, and Indonesia; from the popular sector in the 1950s in Singapore;
from indigenous ethnic majorities in Malaysia and Indonesia) as well as the organizational resources of the state itself to limit business access, force coordination on
private sector actors, and impose conditions on access to rents. In sum, institutional
arrangements, however crucial, were embedded in more fundamental relationships
between political elites and the private sector.
These "business-government risk partnerships," as Wonhyuk Lim (2003) calls
them, were not without their risks from the beginning. Yet what is striking is the
steady rise of the political power of business over time, and the relative decline in
both the willingness and capacity of governments to check it. The rise of the private
sector is not surprising given the extraordinary economic transformation of the
region, but several factors buttressed it. First, the levels of both industrial concentration and the concentration of private ownership in the region are quite high, as a
direct result of government policies that explicitly or implicitly encouraged the
expansion of diversified business groups. Economic concentration implies that private actors can bring substantial resources to bear on the political process and can
blackmail the government, shifting risk back onto the public sector. Political developments in the region also tended to enhance business power. In the authoritarian
systems, corrupt business-government relations became more entrenched over time
as the empires of cronies expanded and even colonized sections of the state; the
Philippines under Marcos and the development of cronyism in Malaysia and particularly Indonesia over the 1990s are examples. But democracies were not altogether immune from these processes either; in Thailand, Korea, the Philippines,
Taiwan, and to some extent Malaysia, competitive politics provided new opportunities for the private sector to exercise influence, as it did throughout the postwar
period in Japan.
A brief consideration of the political economy of the financial crisis that swept
the region in the late 1990s provides a fitting conclusion (see Pempel 1999; Haggard 2000; Maclntyre 2003). Again, the sociology of knowledge is as revealing as
the substance of the conflicting analyses that emerged in the crisis' wake. An initial
emphasis on political economy factors and crony capitalism was quickly drowned
out by attention to the risks of deregulation, the irrationalities of international capital markets, and the various errors of the IMF---in short, anything but domestic
politics (see Radelet and Sachs 1998; Wade and Veneroso 1998; Stiglitz 2002).
This analysis shifted considerations of moral hazard at the national level toward
relations between governments, foreign lenders, and the international financial institutions. These incentive and moral-hazard problems had to do either with governments' willingness to offer implicit guarantees to foreign lenders (the "left" view)
or the IMF's willingness to offer implicit guarantees toforeign investors through
bailouts expost (the "right" view).
Yet the decision to liberalize the capital account, the choice of a fixed exchange
rate, the decision to bail out connected firms, and the weakness of regulation as
governments moved toward deeper financial market integration, were endogenous
to some political process in which private sector actors had very large stakes. The
weakness of institutions for regulating and overseeing the private sector, and the
financial sector in particular, was not simply an accident of history, a sin of omission on the road to liberalization. These weaknesses were consistent with the evo-
74
Studies in Comparative International Development / Winter 2004
lution of political economies in which business influence over regulatory institutions and processes limited the ability of those institutions to check the socialization of risk and moral hazard.
Not surprisingly, the current agenda of reform in the region mirrors these considerations to a substantial degree. At the most general level, the push for greater
transparency and for more democratic and competitive politics can be interpreted
as a backlash against closed political systems that shielded collusive business-government relations. The victory of Corazon Aquino over the cronyism of the Marcos
regime was an early example of this trend, but we see parallel developments in the
election of the Democrat Party in Thailand (1997) and of Kim Dae Jung (1997) and
Roh Moo-hyun (2002) in Korea, in the reform movement around Anwar in Malaysia, and in the social mobilization that led to the collapse of the Soeharto regime; all
exemplify these reform politics.
The substance of economic policy reform also shows a push not simply toward
liberalization of markets--the so-called Washington agenda--but the pressing need
to reassert regulatory oversight of business. Examples include reform of laws on
campaign contributions, corruption, corporate governance, and, perhaps above all,
the financial sector, where the socialization of losses in the wake of the crisis was
staggering in its dimensions. The countries in the region are unlikely to converge
on a single institutional model for solving these problems, but the push for regulation will be a central feature of the region's political economy for years to come.
Conclusion
Institutions have been at the center of the study of East Asia's political economy for
decades, and that focus has yielded a rich body of theoretical and empirical work
on the relationship between institutions and growth. If one central lesson emerges,
it is that we have hit the point of diminishing marginal returns in the quest for a
unifying "model" of East Asia's growth. Countries in Asia solved the problems that
institutionalists highlight--guaranteeing property rights, making credible commitments, pursuing efficient policy making, and limiting rent-seeking and corruption-in a wide variety of ways. This fact supports Roland's advocacy (in this volume) of
an experimental approach to policy reform and institutional design; Asia proves
that a variety of institutional arrangements can contribute to high growth. Understanding the diversity of institutional arrangements, however, requires analytic strategy that differs somewhat from focusing on the functions that institutions might
perform, and calls on us to dig beneath institutional arrangements to reveal the
political relationships that create and support them.
Notes
*
I am indebted to Tun-Jen Cheng, Rick Doner, Cheng-Tian Kuo, Greg Noble, and Andrew
Maclntyre,not only for commentsbut for extendeddiscussion of these issues over the years.
1. Probablythe most widelyread of these accountswas Ezra Vogel's(1979) Japan as Number One,
which was sober by comparisonwith some of its more alarmistcounterparts.
2. I focus here primarily on physical capital accumulation;surprisinglylittle attention has been
Haggard
3.
4.
5.
6.
7.
8.
9.
10.
11.
12.
13.
t4.
15.
16.
17.
18.
75
given to the political economy of education and human capital formation. See Birdsall, Ross,
and Sabot (1995).
The bias of greatest concern is that subjective evaluations do not adequately separate success
from institutionalquality but suggest that if a country has high growth, then the institutions must
be good.
As Johnson (1999, 52) puts it, while denying any necessary connection, "authoritarianism can
sometimes inadvertently solve the main political problem of economic development using market forces--namely, how to mobilize the overwhelming majority of the population to work and
sacrifice for development projects."
An important strand of the literature on East Asian growth looks at the labor-repressive nature of
industrial relations in the region; I return to it briefly below.
Actually, this issue is tricky. As Noland and Pack (2003, 16) point out, most theoretical models
are static and thus the effects of policy should be expressed in terms of improving welfare rather
than accelerating growth. But as they point out, the terms "welfare-enhancing" and "growthaccelerating" are often used synonymously.
Haggard and Kaufman (1995) outline a political model in which new democratic governments
have few incentives to deviate from the policies of their authoritarian predecessors so long as
those policies were successful.
Mancur Olson (1993) tries to wriggle out of this conundrum by arguing that long-lived, "stationary" autocrats have an "encompassing" interest in the growth of their domains. But Olson offers
us no clues on how to distinguish good and bad autocrats e x a n t e ; we only know that dictators
have long time horizons and "encompassing" views of their domains e x p o s t .
One solution was for the state to undertake this role itself, and in some countries it did; stateownership of industry even played an important role in the more open countries in the region,
such as Singapore (Lim 1983).
Not coincidentally, Huff, Dewit, and Oughton (2001) argue that democratic governments facing
electoral constraints find it difficult to stick to such a strategy.
In some instances, most notably Japan, such councils are delegated effective decision-making
and implementation authority.
For a contrasting view, see Jomo et al. (1998), which recognizes the differences between Northeast and Southeast Asia but nonetheless makes the case for the significance of industrial policy
in Southeast Asia.
These costs include both the distortions that can arise from the granting of the rent, and the
resources that are eaten up trying to secure it.
An important corollary of this requirement, emphasized by Lee (1992) in connection with directed credit and stated more generally by Chang (1994, 83), is that states must have the capability to prevent the diversion of resources into unproductive venues.
The economic advantages of an export-oriented growth strategy have been a staple of the literature on the region for some time, but exports also provided clear information to the government
and economized on direct monitoring of firm performance (World Bank 1993, 97-99).
On labor, for example, see Lange 1984. On the governance of particular industries, see
HoUingsworth, Schmitter, and Streeck 1994.
Kuo (1995) provides a test along these lines by looking at three industries (textiles, plywood, and
electronics) in two countries (Taiwan and the Philippines) and isolates four institutional arrangements. He argues that performance in sectors organized on corporatist lines with wide industry
representation outperform those with "clientelist" business-governmentties as well as sectors in
which the state attempts independent action or simply leaves outcomes to the market,
Evans (1995) and Kang (2002a, 2002b) make this point in criticizing the developmental state
literature, but autonomy from business was central to the whole concept of a developmental state
from the beginning. However, see the work of Johnson (1999, 56--60), who now argues that the
public-private distinction is misleading in the Asian context.
76
Studies in Comparative International Development / Winter 2004
References
Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson, and James A. Robinson. 2001. "The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation." American Economic Review 91 (December 2001): 1369-140l.
Alesina, Alberto and Roberto Perotti. 1996. "Income Distribution, Political Instability, and Investment." European Economic Review 40 (1996): 1203-28.
Amsden, Alice H. 1989. Asia's Next Giant: South Korea and Late Industrialization, New York: Oxford University Press.
- - .
2001. The Rise of the 'The Rest': Challenges to the West from Late-Industrializing Economies. New York: Oxford University Press.
Anek, Laothamatas. 1992. Business Associations and the New Political Economy of Thailand: From
Bureaucratic Polity to Liberal Corporatism. Boulder: Westview Press.
Akyuz, Yilmaz. 1999. EastAsian Development: New Perspectives. London: Frank Cass & Co. Ltd.
Aoki, Masahiko. 1988. Information, Incentives and Bargaining in the Japanese Economy. New York:
Cambridge University Press.
Aoki, Masahiko, Hyung-Ki Kim, and Masahiro Okuno-Fujiwara. 1996. The Role of Government in
East Asian Economic Development: Comparative Institutional Analysis. New York: Oxford
University Press.
Aoki, Masahiko, Kevin Murdock, and Masahiro Okuno-Fujiwara. 1996. "Beyond The East Asian
Miracle: Introducing the Market-Enhancing View." In The Role of Government in East Asian
Economic Development." Comparative lnstitutionalAnalysis. Aoki, Hyung-Ki Kim, and Masahiro
Okuno-Fujiwara, eds. New York: Oxford University Press.
Barro, Robert. 1991. "Economic Growth in a Cross-Section of Countries," Quarterly Journal of Economics (May): 407-43.
.1996. "Democracy and Growth." Journal of Economic Growth 1, 1 (March): 1-28.
Beason, Richard and David E. Weinstein. 1995. "Growth, Economies of Scale, and Targeting in Japan
(1955-1990)." Review of Economics and Statistics 78, 2: 286--95.
Berger, Suzanne and Ronatd Dote. 1996. National Diversity and Global Capitalism. Ithaca: Cornell
University Press.
Besley, Tim. 1995. "Property Rights and Investment Incentives: Theory and Evidence from Ghana."
Journal of Political Economy, 103, 5: 903-37.
Birdsall, Nancy and Frederick Jaspersen. 1997. Pathways to Growth: Comparing East Asia and Latin
America. Washington, D.C.: The Johns Hopkins University Press.
Birdsall, Nancy, D. Ross and R.H. Sabot. 1995. "Inequality and Growth Reconsidered: Lessons from
East Asia." World Bank Economic Review (September).
Calder, Kent E. 1993. Strategic Capitalism: Private Business and Public Purpose in Japanese Industrial Finance. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton Academic Press.
Campos, Edgardo J. 2001. Corruption: The Boom and Bust of East Asia. Manila, Philippines: Ateneo
De Manila University Press.
Campos, Edgardo J. and Hilton L. Root. 1996. The Key to the Asian Miracle: Making Shared Growth
Credible. Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution.
Campos, Nauro and Jeffrey B. Nugent. 1999. "Development Performance and the institutions of
Governance: Evidence from East Asia and Latin America." Worm Development 27, 3: 439-52.
Chan, Steve, Cal Clark, and Danny Lam. 1998, Beyond the Developmental State: EastAsia's Political
Economies Reconsidered. London and New York: St. Martin's Press, Inc.
Chan, Sylvia. 2002. Liberalism, Democracy and Development. New York: Cambridge University
Press.
Chang, Ha-Joon, 1994. The Political Economy of Industrial Policy. London and Basingstoke: Macmillan
Cheng, Tun-jen. 1990. "Political Regimes and Development Strategies: South Korea and Taiwan." In
Manufacturing Miracles: Patterns of Development in Latin America and East Asia. Gary Gereffi
and Donald Wyman, eds. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
9 1993. "Guarding the Commanding Heights: The State as Banker in Taiwan." In The Politics
of Finance in Developing Countries. Stephan Haggard, Chung Lee, and Sylvia Maxfield, eds.
Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
Haggard
77
Chiu, Stephen W. K., K. C. Ho, and Tai-Lok Lui. 1997. City-States in the Global Economy. Boulder:
Westview Press.
Chu, Yun-han. 1989. "State Structure and Economic Adjustment of the East Asian Newly Industrializing Countries." International Organization 43, 4: 647-72.
Cox, Gary and Mathew McCubbins. 2000. "The Institutional Determinants of Economic Policy Outcomes" In Presidents, Parliaments and Policy. Stephan Haggard and Mathew McCubbins, eds.
New York: Cambridge University Press.
Cumings, Bruce. 1984. "The Origins and Development of the Northeast Asian Political Economy."
International Organization 38, 1: 1-40.
Deyo, Fred. 1987. The Political Economy of the New Asian Industrialism. Ithaca: Cornell University
Press.
Doner, Richard F. 1991. Driving a Bargain: Automobile Industrialization and Japanese Firms in
Southeast Asia. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.
Doner, Richard E and Ansil Ramsay. 1997. "Competitive Clientelism and Economic Governance:
The Case of Thailand." In Business and the State in Developing Countries. Sylvia Maxfield and
Ben Ross Schneider, eds. New York: Coruell University Press.
Doner, Richard E and Ansil Ramsay. 2000. "Rent-Seeking and Economic Development in Thailand."
In Rents, Rent-seeking and Economic Development: Theory and Evidence in Asia. Mushtaq I4.
Khan and K.S. Jomo, eds. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Dore, Ronald. 1986. Flexible Rigidities: Industrial Policy and Structural Adjustment in the Japanese
Economy 1970-80. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.
--.
1987. Taking Japan Seriously: A Confucian Perspective on Leading Economic Issues. Stanford,
California: Stanford University Press.
Easterly, William. 1995. "Explaining Miracles: Growth Regressions Meet the Gang of Four." In Growth
Theories in Light of the East Asian Experience. Takatashi Ito and Anne O. Krueger, eds. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Ernst, Dieter and David O'Connor. 1992. Competing in the Electronics Industry: The Experience of
the Newly Industrializing Economies. Paris: OECD Development Centre.
Evans, Peter. I995. Embedded Autonomy: States and Industrial Transformation. Princeton: Princeton
University Press.
Evans, Peter and James Rauch. 2000. "Bureaucratic Structure and Bureaucratic Performance in Less
Developed Countries." Journal of Public Economics 75 (January): 49-71.
Feng, Yi. 1997. "Democracy, Political Stability and Economic Growth." British Journal of Political
Science. 27, 3: 391--418.
Fields, Karl. 1995. Enterprise and the State in Korea and Taiwan. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
Friedman, David. 1988. The Misunderstood Miracle: Industrial Development and Political Change
in Japan. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
Fruin, Mark. W. 2000. Networks, Markets, and the Pacific Rim. New York: Oxford University Press.
Gereffi, Gary and Donald L.Wyman. 1990. Manufacturing Miracles: Paths oflndustrialization in
Latin America and East Asia. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press.
Gold, Thomas B. 1981. Dependent Development in Taiwan. Ph.D. dissertation, Harvard University.
--.
1986. State and Society in the Taiwan Miracle. New York: M.E. Sharpe.
Gomez, E.T. 1991. Money Politics in the Barisan Nasional. Kuala Lumpur: Forum.
Grabowski, R. 1994. "The Successful Developmental State: Where Does it Come From?" World
Development 22: 413-22.
--.
1997. "Developmental States and Developmental Entrepreneurial Groups: Asian Experiences." Journal of Asian Business 13: 25-45.
Haggard, Stephan. 1990. Pathways from the Periphery: the Politics of Growth in the Newly Industrializing Countries. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
--.
1999. "Business, Politics and Policy in East and Southeast Asia?' in Henry Rowen, ed. Behind East Asian Growth: The Political and Social Foundations of Prosperity. London: Routledge.
--.
2000. The Political Economy of the Asian Financial Crisis. Washington: Institute for International Economics.
Haggard, Stephan and Robert Kaufman. 1995. The Political Economy of Democratic Transitions.
Princeton: Princeton University Press.
Haggard, Stephan, Chung H. Lee, and Sylvia Maxfield. 1993. The Politics of Finance in Developing
Countries. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
78
Studies in Comparative International Development / Winter 2004
Haggard, Stephan and Chung-in Moon. 1990. "Institutions and Economic Policy: Theory and a Korean Case Study." World Politics 42, 2.
Hall, Peter and David Soskice. 2001. Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage. New York: Oxford University Press.
Hamilton, Gary. 1991. Business Networks and Economic Development in East and Southeast Asia.
Hong Kong: University of Hong Kong.
Hamilton, Gary and Nicole Woolsey Biggart. 1988. "Market, Culture and Authority." American Journal of Sociology 94 (Supplement July): $52-94.
Hamilton-Hart, Natasha. 2002. Asian States, Asian Bankers: Central Banking in Southeast Asia. Ithaca
and London: Cornell University Press.
Hellman, Thomas, Kevin Murdock, and Joseph Stiglitz. 1996. "Financial Restraint: Toward a New
Paradigm" In Masahiko Aoki, Hyung-Ki Kim and Masahiro Okuno-Fujiwara, eds. The Role of
Government in East Asian Economic Development: Comparative lnstitutional Analysis. Masahiko
Aoki, Hyung-Ki Kim and Masahiro Okuno-Fujiwara, eds. New York: Oxford University Press.
Hobday, Michael. 1997. Innovation in East Asia: The Challenge to Japan. Cheltenham: Elgar.
Horowitz, Shale and Uk Heo. 2001. The Political Economy oflnternational Financial Crises. Oxford: Rowman and Littlefield.
Hicken, Allen. 2001. "Governance and Growth in Thailand." In Corruption: The Boom and Bust of
East Asia. Edgardo J. Campos, ed. Manila, Philippines: Ateneo De Manila University Press.
Huff, W. G., G. Dewit, and C. Oughton. 2001. "Credibility and Reputation Building in the Developmental State: A Model with East Asian Applications." World Development 29, 4:711-724.
Hutchcroft, Paul. 1998. Booty Capitalism: The Politics of Banking in the Philippines. Ithaca: Cornell
University Press.
Ito, Takatashi and Anne O. Krueger. 1995. Growth Theories in Light of the East Asian Experience.
Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Johnson, Chalmers. 1982. MITI and the Japanese Miracle: The Growth of lndustrial Policy, 19251975. Stanford, California: Stanford University Press.
. 1987. "Political Institutions and Economic Performance: The Government-Business Relationship in Japan, South Korea and Taiwan." In The Political Economy of the New Asian Industrialism. Fred Deyo, ed. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
. 1999. "The Developmental State: Odyssey of a Concept." In The Developmental State.
Meredith Woo-Cumings, ed. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
Jomo, K.S. 1998. Tigers in Trouble: Financial Liberalization and Crises in East Asia. London: Zed
Books.
__
et. al. 1997. Southeast Asia's Misunderstood Miracle: Industrial Policy and Economic Development in Thailand, Malaysia and Indonesia. Boulder: Westview Press.
Kang, David. 2002a. Crony Capitalism: Corruption and Development in South Korea and the Philippines. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press. 56, 1 (winter: 177-208
.. 2002b. "Bad Loans to Good Friends: Money Politics and the Developmental State in Korea."
International Organization. 56, 1 (Winter): 177-208.
Khan, Mushtaq H. 2000a. "Rents, Efficiency and Growth." In Rents, Rent-seeking and Economic
Development: Theory and Evidence in Asia. Mushtaq H. Khan and K.S. Jomo, eds. New York:
Cambridge University Press.
9. 2000b, "Rent-seeking as Process." In Rents, Rent-seeking and Economic Development." Theory
and Evidence in Asia. Mushtaq H. Khan and K.S. Jomo, eds. New York: Cambridge University
Press.
Khan, Mushtaq H. and K.S. Jomo, eds. 2000. Rents, Rent-seeking and Economic Development: Theory
and Evidence in Asia. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Kim, Linsu. 1997. Imitation to Innovation: The Dynamics of Korea's Technological Learning. Boston: Harvard Business School Press.
Kim, Linsu and Nelson, Richard R. 2000. Technology, Learning, & Innovation: Experiences of Newly
Industrializing Economies. Cambridge and New York: Cambridge University Press.
Kim, Eun Mee. 1997. Big Business, Strong State: Collusion and Conflict in South Korean Development 1960-1990. New York: SUNY Press.
Kim, Jong-il and Lawrence Lau. 1994. "The Sources of Economic Growth of the East Asian Newly
Industrializing Countries." Journal of the Japanese and International Economies 8: 235-71.
Haggard
79
Knack, Steven and Philip Keefer. 1995. "Institutions and Economic Performance: Cross-Country
Tests Using Alternative Measures." Economics and Politics 7, 3: 207-27.
Knight, Jack. 1992. Institutions and Social Conflict. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Krauss, Ellis and Michio Muramatsu. 1984. "Bureaucrats and Politicians in Policymaking: the Case
of Japan." American Political Science Review 78, 1 (March): 126--48.
Krugman, Paul. 1991. Geography and Trade. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Kuo, Cheng-Tian. 1995. Global Competitiveness and Industrial Growth in Taiwan and the Philippines. Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press.
Lall, Sanjaya. 1996. Learning from the Asian 17gers: Studies in Technology and Industrial Policy.
New York: St. Martin's Press, Inc.
~ .
2000. "Technological Change and Industrialization in the Asian Newly Industrializing Economies: Achievements and Challenges." In Technology, Learning and Innovation: Experience of
Newly Industrializing. Linsu Kim and Richard R. Nelson, eds. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Lira, Wonhyuk. 2003. "The Emergence of the Chaebol and the Origins of the Chaebol Problem." In
Economic Crisis and Corporate Restructuring in Korea. Stephan Haggard, Wonhyuk Lim and
Euysung Kim, eds. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Lundvall, 13. A. 1992. National Innovation Systems: A Comparative Analysis. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
MacIntyre, Andrew. 1994. Business and Government in Industrializing Asia. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
~ .
2001a. "Institutions and Investors: The Politics of the Economic Crisis in Southeast Asia,"
International Organization, 55, 1 (Winter): 81-122.
.200lb. "Investment, Property Rights and Corruption in Indonesia," in J. Edgardo Campos,
ed.: Corruption: the Boom and Bust of East Asia. Manila: Ateneo University Press.
9 2003. The Power of Institutions: Political Architecture and Governance. Ithaca: Cornell
University Press.
Matthews, J. A. and D. Cho. 2000. Tiger Technology: The Creation of a Semiconductor Industry in
EastAsia. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Matsuyama, Kiminori. 1996. "Economic Development as Coordination Problems." In The Rote of
Government in East Asian Economic Development: Comparative lnstitutional Analysis. Masahiko
Aoki, Hyung-Ki Kim and Masahiro Okuno-Fujiwara, eds. New York: Oxford University Press.
Maxfield, Sylvia and Ben Ross Schneider. 1997. Business and the State in Developing Countries.
New York: Cornell University Press.
McKendrick, David, Richard Doner, and Stephan Haggard. 2000. From Silicon Valley to Singapore:
Location and Competitive Advantage in the Hard Disk Drive Industry. Stanford: Stanford University Press.
Moon, Chung-in and Jongryn Mo. 1999. Democratization and Globalization in South Korea9 Seoul:
Yonsei University Press.
Moon, Chung-in and Rashemi Prasad. 1998. "Networks, Policies, Institutions." In Beyond the Developmental State: East Asia's Political Economies Reconsidered. Steve Chan, Cal Clark, and
Danny Lam, eds. London and New York: St. Martin's Press, Inc.
Noland, Marcus and Howard Pack. 2003. Industrial Policy in an Era of Globalization. Washington:
Institute for International Economics.
Noble, Gregory. 1998. Collective Action in East Asia: How Ruling Parties Shape Industrial Policy.
Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
North, Douglass C. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance. New York:
Cambridge University Press.
North, Douglass C. and Barry Weingast. 1989. "Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of
Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth Century England." Journal of Economic
History 44, 4: 803-32.
Nunberg, Barbara. 2002. "Civil Service Quality after the Crisis: A View of Five Asian Cases." Asian
Journal of Political Science 10, 2 (December): 1-21.
Okazaki, Tetsuji. 1996. "The Government-Firm Relationship in Postwar Japanese Economic Recovery: Resolving the Coordination Failure by Coordination in Industrial Rationalization." In The
Role of Government in East Asian Economic Development: Comparative Institutional Analysis.
80
Studies in Comparative International Development / Winter 2004
Masahiko Aoki, Hyung-Ki Kim, and Masahiro Okuno-Fujiwara, eds. New York: Oxford University Press.
Okimoto, Daniel I. 1989. Between MITI and the Market: Japanese Industrial Policy for High Technology. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press.
Olson, Mancur. 1993. "Dictatorship, Democracy and Development." American Political Science Review 87, 3 (September): 567-76.
Pack, Howard and Larry E. Westphal. 1986. "Industrial Strategy and Technological Change: Theory
vs. Reality." Journal of Development Economics 22:87-128
Pempel, T.J., ed. 1999. The Politics of the Asian Financial Crisis. Ithaca: Col-nell University Press.
Przeworski, Adam, Michael E. Alvarez, Jose Antonio Cheibub, and Fernando Lemongi. 2000. Democracy and Development: Political Institutions and Well-Being in the World, 1950-1990. New
York: Cambridge University Press.
Ramseyer, Frances McCall and J. Mark Rosenbluth. 1993. Japan's PoliticalMarketplace. Cambridge:
Harvard University Press.
Rhee, Jong-Chan. 1994. The State and Industry. in South Korea: The Limits of the Authoritarian State.
New York: Routledge.
Robsion, Richard, Mark Beeson, Kanishka Jayasuriya, and Hyuk-Rae Kim. 2000. Politics and Markets in the Wake of the Asian Crisis. London: Routledge.
Rodrik, Dani. 1995. "Getting Interventions Right: How South Korea and Taiwan Grew Rich." Economic Policy 20 (April).
--.
1997. "TPFG Controversies, Institutions, and Economic Performance in East Asia." National Bureau of Economic Research Paper No. 5914. Cambridge: National Bureau of Economic Research.
Roland, Gerard. 2002. "Synthesizing Lessons from Transition." Unpublished manuscript, University
of California, Berkeley.
Rose-Ackerman, Susan. 1997. "The Political Economy of Corruption." In Corruption and the Global
Economy. Kimberly Ann Elliot, ed. Washington, D.C.: Institute for International Economics.
Rhee, Jong-Chan. 1994. The State and lndustry in South Korea: The Limits of the Authoritarian State.
London and New York: Routledge.
Rhee, Yung Whee, Bruce Clifford Ross-Larson, and Garry Pursell. 1984. Korea's Competitive Edge:
Managing Entry into World Markets. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.
Root, Hilton L. 1996. Small Countries, Big Lessons: Governance and the rise of East Asia. New York:
Oxford University Press.
Samuels, Richard J. 1987. The Business of The Japanese State: Energy Markets in Comparative and
Historical Perspective. Ithaca, New York: Cornell University Press.
Saxenian, Anna Lee. 1994. Regional Advantage: Culture and Competition in Silicon Valley and Route
128. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
Schaede, Ulrike. 2001. Cooperative Capitalism: Self-regulation, Trade Associations, and the AntiMonopoly Law in Japan. New York: Oxford University Press.
Schein, Edgar C. 1996. Strategic Pragmatism: The Culture of Singapore's Economic Development
Board. Cambridge: MIT Press.
Schopf, James C. 2001. "An Explanation for the End of Political Bank Robbery in the Republic of
Korea." Asian Survey. 41, 5 (September/October): 693-715.
Schwartz, Frank. 2001. Advice and Consent: The Politics of Consultation in Japan. New York: Cambridge University Press.
Shinohara, Miyohei. 1982. Industrial Growth, Trade, and Dynamic Patterns in the Japanese Economy.
Tokyo: Tokyo University Press.
Schleifer, Andrei and Robert W. Vishney. 1993. "Corruption." Quarterly Journal of Economics. 108,
3: 599--617.
Stern, Joseph J., Ji-Hong Kim, Dwight Perkins, and Jung-ho Yoo. 1995. Industrialization and the
State: The Korean Heavy and Chemical Industry Drive. Cambridge: Harvard Institute for International Development.
Stiglitz, Joseph. 2002. Globalization and Its Discontents. New York: W. W. Norton.
Stiglitz, Joseph and Marylou Uy. 1996. "Financial Markets, Public Policy, and the East Asian Miracle."
The World Bank Research Observer 11, 2: 249-76.
Haggard
81
Stiglitz, Joseph E. and Shahid Yusuf. 2001. Rethinking the East Asian Miracle. New York: Oxford
University Press and the World Bank.
Tyson, Laura D'Andrea. 1993. Who's Bashing Whom? Trade Conflict in High TechnologyIndustries9
Washington, D.C.: Institute for International Economics9
Uriu, Robert M. Troubled Industries: Confronting Economic Change in Japan. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
Vogel, Ezra. 1979. Japan as Number One. New York: HarperCollins.
Wade, Robert. 19909 Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East
Asian Industrialization. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press.
Weiss, Linda. 1998. The Myth of the Powerless State. Ithaca, New York: Cornel] University Press9
Williamson, John. 1990. Latin American Adjustment: How Much has Happened? Washington, D.C.:
The Institute for International Economics.
Wong, Poh-Kam and Chee-Yuen Ng. 2001. Industrial Policy, Innovation & Economic Growth: The
Experience of Japan and the Asian NIEs. Singapore: Singapore University Press.
Woo, Jung-en. 1991. Race to the Swift: State and Finance in Korea Industrialization. New York:
Columbia University Press.
Woo-Cummings, Meredith. 1999. The Developmental State. New York: Cornell University Press9
World Bank, 19939 The East Asian Miracle: Economic Growth and Public Policy9World Ba~k Policy
Research Report. New York: Oxford University Press.
World Bank. 1993. The East Asian Miracle: Economic Growth and Public Policy. New York: Oxford
University Press for the World Bank.
91997. World Development Report 1997: The State in a Changing World. New York: Oxford
University Press for the World Bank.
--..
1998. EastAsia: Road to Recovery. Washington, D.C.: The World Bank.
92003. WorldDevelopmentReport 2003: Sustainable Development in a Dynamic World: Transforming Institutions, Growth and Quality of Life. New York: Oxford University Press for the
World Bank.
Yanagihara, Torn and Susumu Sambommatsu. 1997. EastAsian Development Experience Economic
System Approach and Its Applicability. Tokyo: Institute of Developing Economies.
Young, Alwyn. 19949 "Lessons from the East Asian N1CS: A Contrarian View." European Economic
Review 38: 964-73.
91995. "The Tyranny of Numbers: Confronting the Statistical Realities of the East Asian
Growth Experience." Quarterly Journal of Economics 110:641-80.
Yusuf, Shahid. 2003. Innovative EastAsia: the Future of Growth. Washington, D.C.: The World Bank.
Zysman, John9 1996. "Nations, Institutions, and Technological Development." International Journal
of Technology Management 12, 5-6:651-78.
Download