TO HOST OR NOT? AN ANALYSIS OF THE ECONOMIC IMPACT OF HOSTING THE OLYMPICS. Senior Thesis in Economics: Collins Kalyebi, 2020 ABSTRACT: Mega sporting events like the Olympics tend to attract a large pool of participants that compete with the hope of winning the bid to host the games. Participants tend to prioritize different interests, though what seems more apparent, for all of them, is their appetite for an economic windfall that is often associated with hosting the games. Olympics have cost over USD 8.9 billion on average in the past decade and considering this staggering amount, hosting the games could be the most financially risky mega project any city could want to take on. In this paper, I focus on five hosts (USA, Canada, Japan, France, and South Korea) to build on the findings of past research to further explore the economic worthiness of hosting the Olympic games. Impact assessment will be done through GDP per capita, Unemployment rate and Export growth rate. Results from the analysis show that host nations tend to see economic gains, irrespective of the high costs involved. INTRODUCTION The Olympics is by far one of the largest mega-sporting events the world has yet to see with one of the highest attendances and the largest budgets in terms of host expenditures. The modern Olympic games started in 1896 and happen every four years, attracting a large pool of participants, who compete at different levels, and supporters from almost every country in the world. Host cities are announced seven years prior to the games to allow enough preparation time as a lot of infrastructure development may be needed to see off the games. On average, over two hundred nations compete in the Olympic games and over four billion viewers are estimated worldwide. Hosting the Olympic games is therefore prestigious, as it allows host countries and cities to gain a platform on the international scene. Before the competitions however and before the host cities are announced, countries have to face off in a rigorous and quite competitive bidding process. The bidding process usually attracts a large pool of countries that compete with hope to host the games and hopefully reap from the international exposure that comes with it. The number of countries that participate in the bidding process took a sharp rise after a successful and profitable execution of the 1984 games in Los Angeles, but recent statistics show that cities are now turning away the opportunity to host the prestigious games. This shift is associated with the rise in expectations from host countries and the high costs involved. This on the other hand means less or no profits for the host cities and often huge debts left behind after the games. The parties that say hosting the Olympic games is of economic benefit to the host countries often argue that the games are a platform for international exposure which boosts tourism, drives growth of local economies, increases the country’s global trade performance, and creates a sense of national pride for the hosts. Host cities often see an increase in foreign visitors who mostly come to support the games. On the international scene, winning the bid to host the games could also reflect a favorable economic environment, which attracts investors and cities often end up with new infrastructure developments that could otherwise not have come sooner. But many economists argue that these benefits are quite minimal given the high costs incurred by host cities in preparation for the games and do not justify hosting the games as a good investment under most circumstances. The high costs of setting up Olympic venues, putting up transport infrastructure and housing facilities for the visitors usually outweigh the revenues generated from the games and quite often cities are left with huge debt. Staging of the Olympic games in the earlier stages was manageable to the host cities given the smaller number of participants and the fact that most bidding cities were from already developed countries and didn't need a lot of new infrastructure developments to host the games. These cities therefore had the financial muscle that was needed to finance all the activities and for most of the early hosts, it wasn't much about the financial gains, rather more about the Olympic pride and their political positioning at the world stage. Past the 1970s though, the number of competitive games at the Olympics was increased and this drove up participation to almost double the original numbers. This also drove up the costs of hosting the games and the rise in expectations from the hosts continues to push up the price tag. The average cost for the Olympic games that have been staged over the past decade is estimated at USD 8.9 billion. And this is exclusive of costs incurred in preparation for the bidding process, which are in millions of dollars. This is partly covered by the International Olympics Committee, though the largest portion of the bill remains allocated to the hosts, who often foot that bill through public sector funding (taxes) or through loans. Cities have to prove that they have the needed infrastructure and the financial muscle before they are allowed into the final stages, which include a secret ballot vote by the IOC to decide the winner. The final vote is politically influenced but the financial ability of the city is approved only after a careful examination by the IOC. The examination takes a multiplier effect approach, using the estimated direct expenditures to then estimate indirect expenditures associated with the games. The weakness of this approach is the fact that it relies on estimates which are likely to be inaccurate. The excitement that comes along with being a potential host often forces cities to underestimate their costs as a way of increasing their chances since doing so elevates them to a better financial standing. As a result, cities experience cost overruns 100% of the time with an average real overrun of 156% (Flyvbjerg and Stewart, 2016). When considering the bid, different cities and countries tend to prioritize different interests, though what seems more apparent, for all of them, is their appetite for an economic windfall that is often associated with hosting the games. It’s no doubt that there is a substantial inflow of money from foreign visitors who come to watch the games and from the selling of broadcasting rights, but that's usually not enough to cover for the costs incurred. Los Angeles, who were the only city to bid for the 1984 summer games, turned out to be the only city to profit from hosting the games. This was evidently due to the fact that their sole bid put them at an advantage to negotiate favorable terms with the International Olympics committee. They also relied on using existing facilities which together coupled with the growth in broadcasting revenue, allowed them a clause of up to $215 million operating surplus. Revenues from hosting the Olympic games are gained through tickets, sponsorships, television rights, and licensing. There has been a fairly steady positive growth in revenue generated from the games over time, but it still lags way behind the rising costs and because of that, host countries find themselves recovering just a small fraction of their total expenditures, which also explains why host cities often end up in debt. In 2012, London’s summer Olympics generated over $5.2 billion in revenue, which is far less when compared to over $18 billion in the incurred costs. Even worse, this revenue is not just for the host cities. A large portion of revenue generated from broadcasting rights remains with the International Olympics committee. The most notable city to have fallen in the trap was Montreal, which ran into billions of dollars in cost overruns and ended up with an estimated 1.5 billion in debt. It took nearly 30yrs to get it all cleared. It is therefore imperative that a clear economic impact analysis is done and taken into consideration before making the decision to take part in the bidding. Unfortunately, for the general public and the policy makers who are usually very excited for the party to come, they often pay less attention to the financial risks involved with hosting the games. This excitement often results in cities underestimating the costs of hosting the games and on the other hand, overestimating the potential economic benefits of being the host. And as a result, host cities run into negative fiscal shocks which alter economic performance and trap locals in the financial burden resulting from hosting the games. This paper assesses the cause of excitement from countries offering themselves as hosts while weighing into the costs of hosting the games. It examines variance in the host country’s GDP% growth, as a result of changes in the host country’s exports, unemployment rates, and government expenditure, between the years the country hosted the games and when it didn't. It focuses on the USA, Canada, France, Japan and South Korea for the periods between 1969 and 2017. LITERATURE REVIEW The Oxford Olympics Study 2016: Cost and Cost Overrun at the Games: In this paper, Bent Flyvbjerg and Allison Stewart of the University of Oxford carried out a study to weigh in on the costs involved, the cost overruns incurred and the cost risks of hosting the Olympic games. This research was done with the aim of informing and inspiring development of more reliable budgets for the games by bringing forward the cost overruns from more than a third of the games between 1960 and 2016 that seemed to be unknown to most people. The paper also aimed to test the effectiveness of the Olympic Game Knowledge Management Program (OGKMP), established to transfer skills from former host cities to new ones, in reducing cost risk from previous games while benchmarking cost and cost overrun for the Rio 2016 against previous games. The study focused on 19games for which they could get all the data points. There has been prior research about the costs of the games, but there seem not to be attempts to specifically and systematically evaluate the costs. Also most of the early research tends to focus on understanding whether hosting the games is a viable investment from the perspective of cost-benefit analysis. That though often leaves a debate on what exactly should be measured when determining the costs and benefits of the games to the host country. Underlying results show that there could be different benefits, some of which can’t be weighed in financial terms and it's very likely that countries have different priorities when they chose to host such mega sports events. For example, legacy benefits or national pride that are intangible make it hard to compare the valuations across countries. Comparisons were made between the actual outturn costs with the estimated costs stated in the bid year to calculate the cost overruns. This was followed by a number of statistical tests and comparisons across time and geographies in real terms to ensure that fair comparisons are made between the hosts. Results from this research show that the average actual outturn cost for summer games is USD 5.2 billion and 15 billion for winter games, after excluding wider capital costs for general infrastructure, which are often larger than sports-related costs. Results also show that host cities experience cost overruns 100% of the time with an average real overrun of 156%, the highest of any type of megaproject. The highest cost overrun for the summer games was reported in Montreal at 720% and Lake Placid for winter games at 324%. On that note though, research shows that the OGKMP has helped reduce the cost risk for the games as cost overruns have gone down since the establishment of the program. This alone is a reflection of the risks of large cost overruns that are inherent to the Olympic games and should be a concern to countries planning to host the games, especially those with relatively smaller and fragile economies. It’s very unlikely for host countries to not go into cost overruns given the set-up of hosting the Olympics. The bidding process of the games is set to look like a show where cities are likely to overestimate their ability to host the games in order to lue those on the committee to vote for them. Cities that are often selected to host the games have never hosted such a mega event and often have to start close to zero in preparation to host the games. And those often in charge of the preparation process have no experience organizing such a project before. In all these cases, most of the cost overruns come out as unexpected or changes in project specifications. The time between the announcement of the next host and the actual year for the games is also long and different events could alter the expected expenditures on the games. For Example, the 9/11 incident that happened a year before the 2002 winter games in Salt Lake City meant that the host city had to incur extra costs to beef-up security at the games. The Olympic effect: This paper by Rose and Spiegel buries the general skepticism around the economic benefits of hosting the Olympics that usually arises from the fact that hosting the event is associated with huge cost demands and yet there are relatively fewer tangible benefits that come with it. It examines the economic impact of hosting mega-sporting events like the Olympics with a focus on the impact on trade. It uses a variety of trade models and employs the Gravity model of international trade, which expresses bilateral trade flows between a pair of countries as a function of the distance between the two countries and their economic masses, to empirically argue the assumption that hosting a mega-sporting event would provide visibility to a host country and thus stimulate global demand for its exports. Analysis is also done on countries that participated in the bidding but were not selected to host the games. The implicit assumption in comparing the trade effects of Olympic hosting and candidacy was that failed candidacies form a valid quasi-experimental counterfactual control group for Olympic hosts (Rose and Spiegel, 2010). Other factors that affect trade intensity, like distance and existence of trade agreements are also considered. Results showed that hosting a mega event has a positive impact on national exports and that countries that participate in the bidding process but never win the vote to host the games experience similar effects and on average see a general increase in their exports. Host countries are seen to register an increase of about 36% in exports, a boost that is relatively more significant compared to factors like trade agreements and the distance between the countries. The sensitivity analysis that followed the results also showed that this enhancement in trade tends to be permanent and that hosting winter games had a relatively weaker effect on exports. Winter games are however seen to be dwarfed by the summer games mainly because they have specific geographic requirements that limit potential hosts. Based on these observations, the paper concludes that the effect of hosting mega-sporting events is attributable to the signal a country sends when bidding to host the games rather than the act of actually hosting the game. The question that remains though is that, if countries don’t actually have to host to see this impact on trade, why then do countries still compete fiercely for the right to host the games? Some of that could be explained by factors like, national pride, boost in tourism and long-term infrastructure developments, that may not have been considered in this paper. A Ticket to the Olympics: An Assessment of the “Olympic effect” on Tourism (Laura Costanzo, 2010): This paper examines the magnitude of the Olympic effect on tourism in the host country. It uses primarily OLS regressions to empirically examine whether hosting the Olympics boosts tourism, and if so, to what magnitude is the effect and whether there is a significant difference between the tourism generated by the summer and the winter Olympic games. It uses the White’s heteroskedasticity correction with clustering on countries to take into account the possibility of within-country correlation in the errors. The travel variables used are also modified to take into account the possible naturally occurring time trends that may cause continual increases in tourism. And dummy variables are employed to specify the year and country. These dummy variables are used to explain the variations that may be as a result of outside factors that vary by country and year. The research focused on 112 countries all with 2006 populations of three million people or more, while excluding those with ten or more missing values of the travel variable (REAL_TRAVEL_ML), which represents total expenditures (in millions) on all goods and services obtained from a country’s economy by travelers within that country during a stay of 12months or less. This research is also extended to cities that placed unsuccessful bids. The decision to look at countries with unsuccessful bids assesses the assumption that placing a bid usually shows the openness and readiness of the country to take position on a world stage. And even though these countries do not win the bid to host the games, they still get international attention by simply participating in the bidding process, which may with time drive interest from international visitors and boost the total tourism. Results from this research show significant increases in tourism for the host countries. Surprisingly though, similar increases are observed for countries with unsuccessful bids. On the other hand, summer games are shown to have more global attention and therefore larger impacts on tourism compared to winter games. Results also show that the visible increases in tourism for the host countries and the unsuccessful bids are greatly dependent and influenced by the country profile and year factors. Beyond these variables, most of the significant results and positive associations were found to be byproducts of natural occurring time trends, which cause sectors like tourism to increase over time. In other words, this research showed that there are other external and internal factors that weigh heavily on tourism trends which also means that making a close to accurate quantification of the Olympic effect on tourism is to some extent impractical. DATA/ METHODOLOGY Theoretical expectations are that by hosting such mega events, countries should see a significant growth in their economy. A positive relationship between economic performance and hosting the games is therefore expected. Hosting the games comes with economic opportunity that drive exports of the host country, attract foreign visitors and investors, and create employment for the locals. This growth in economic activity usually translates into a boost in the country’s GDP per capita (GDPpc). Results that show a positive impact of the Olympics on the economy of the host country would also be in support of the results obtained by past researchers like Rose and Spiegel (2009) who found that hosting the games positively drives the host country’s internal and external economic activities. The original intention of this research paper was to use a model similar to the one used by Rose and Spiegel (2009) where I track economic performance of the countries in question 8yrs before the games and 8yrs after the games. Other variables like number of tourist arrivals, population, and Exports were to also take a similar trend for fair comparison. But I later ran into data problems and realized that for countries that have recently hosted the games, Brazil, China, and South Korea, it wouldn’t be possible to get consolidated data for the 8yrs after the games. Other variables like the number of tourist arrivals also had data that only dated back to 1995, and it would be hard to recover unbiased data for the earlier years given there is no other database with reliable data for those years. To consolidate for all these challenges, I decided to use panel data format and focused on the USA, Canada, Japan, France and South Korea as the host countries. For these countries, I recorded their past data between 1969 and 2017 and that could allow me to get a reasonable sample size for reliable results. To quantify the economic impact of hosting the Olympic games, I used the World Bank and the Federal Reserve Database (FRED) to trace annual data for GDPpc, Unemployment rates, and Exports for countries that have hosted the Olympic games at least twice during the period between 1969 and 2017. The World Bank and FRED are reliable sources, given their consistency in tracking development indicators like GDP, Unemployment rates and the major trade indicators for different countries. For the analysis, I use the Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) regression method. The choice of OLS as the empirical method is based on its simplicity and its ability to minimize variance in addition to a number of other useful characteristics that come with OLS estimates. The formulated multivariate regression equation uses GDPpc as the dependent variable and Exports, Unemployment rates for the host countries as independent variables. I also added dummy variables to the regression model to allow for a fair comparison and minimize specification errors. The first dummy variable was to determine which year the country hosted the Olympic games. ‘1’ is used to denote the year the country hosted the games and ‘0’ otherwise. For the second dummy variable ‘1’ is used to denote summer Olympics and ‘0’ otherwise. I also added a dummy to determine if the games were winter games and used ‘1’ to signal yes and ‘0’ otherwise. GDPpc = ꞵo + ꞵ1(EXP) + ꞵ2(UNP) + ꞵ3(SUM) + ꞵ4(WIN) + ꞵ5(HY) + ε RESULTS AND ANALYSIS I initially did the analysis using the data as collected but noticed huge standard deviations within the data sets. I decided to log the data as a remedy for the huge standard deviations and then followed up with other diagnostic tests. Diagnostic tests: To ensure the quality of my data, I performed a series of diagnostic tests. The first test was to check for multicollinearity. Collinearity occurs when two or more variables in the regression equation are closely related, which results in a lower and less reliable t-statistic of the independent variable. I used the ‘corr’ function in STATA to get the numerical comparison of the collinearity between the variables and then used scatter diagrams to visualize it. The scatter graphs output reflected different levels of collinearity between the variables with the most significant being between the logged GDPpc and the logged exports. Logged GDPpc and logged unemployment rates on the other hand show a quite minimal collinearity which in this case didn’t call for attention. Similar to that was the displayed relationship between the logged exports and the logged unemployment rates. I decided to do nothing in an attempt to correct for the significant collinearity between the logged GDPpc and the logged exports. I believe exports are a good measure of trade for a country and in this I couldn’t find a better way to track trade than through the exchange of goods and services between countries. On the same note, I noticed that in whatever case, improvements of trade positively correlate with GDPpc and that’s because generally, improvements in trade increase GDP. Secondly, I ran the Heteroskedasticity test. Heteroskedasticity basically arises when the variance of the error term differs across observations. For this I plotted potential residuals against the potential fitted values and from the reflected graphs there seemed to be no signs of heteroskedasticity. GDPpc Results: The results from the stated regression model show some expected findings. Countries that host the games are seen to have a relative boost in GDPpc with improvements in trade driven by relative growth in exports and reductions in unemployment. The host year variable is also seen to have significant impact. There is no surprise that the coefficient for unemployment is negative. It proves that over the period of hosting the games, unemployment rates will be lower. This can be due to the increase in project activities, including construction, and increase in service activities like tourism which as a result boost demand in the respective sectors and help reduce unemployment. Similarly, attempting to host the games is reflection of a good and stable economy. This often attracts outside investments and signals readiness for trade with other nations. This explains the positive relation of the games with exports as countries that host the games find themselves involved in more trade with their near and sometimes far neighbors. PRACTICAL APPLICATIONS Hosting the olympic games would be any cities dream. It not only fun for the citizens but also gives a chance to countries who want to show case their cities and, in the process, attract tourists, investment and trade in general. Following the results of this research, cities that host the games benefit in most cases irrespective of the high costs, but the risk of making losses and ending up in debt remains high and therefore any cities that are thinking of bidding to host the games would need to clearly assess, not only their financial ability to fund the games, but also their ability to recover in any case of such major losses that may hurt the economy. Cases where countries have made large losses arent very rare. We have seen it happen in Brazil (Rio) , Greece (Athens) , Canada (Montreal) and other places. Its unlikely that the IOC or any country planning on bidding for the games will take a look at my paper, but in any case, I would give the following recommendations. To the IOC, I would argue that priority should be given to cities/countries that have hosted the games before or have a reasonable infrastructure already in place to be used in the process. Infrastructure developments are the major reasons for the high costs of hosting the games, and for cities/countries that have never hosted the games, they would have to start from zero. On the other hand, countries that have experience of hosting the games, are not only aware of any unexpected costs involved, they also don’t have to build everything from scratch. This makes a very big difference both in terms of the final costs of hosting the games and in the quality of cost estimations at the beginning of the bidding process. To any city/country planning to take the first bid, I would recommend that rigorous, costs-benefit assessments are made, and structures put in place to cater for recovery in case of an economic turn down as a result of taking on the host responsibility. Cities usually fall short of this, and their cost-benefit estimates are all but driven by excitement. Its definitely exciting to win the bid to host the games but paying clear attention to the numbers can help save the host from the tuff economic times that usually follow the games. It’s also hard to clearly forecast the economic position of the city/country given the seven-year lag that lies between being announced and finally hosting the games. A lot of things can change in seven years so it’s always important that a plan-B, usually reserve funds, is put in place to support the city/country when economic conditions following the Olympic games turn out unfavorable. LIMITATIONS There are several limitations with this research. First is with the data and country specifications. I limited my research to the period between 1969 and 2017 and to only five countries (USA, Japan, Canada, France and South Korea). Data specifications were a result of the fact that most data only dates back to 1960 and for countries like South Korea, it only goes back to 1969. Few countries have hosted the games between this time and for most of, it was only once and in the early years which means the economic significance of hosting the games may have faded out with little impact to their current economic performance. Countries like German and Russia also had incomplete data given the fact that during the early days German was still dived into West and East German and Russia was still part of the Soviet Union. Second is the fact that the research uses country data instead of data from the specific host cities. The data from the specific cities isn’t available and the variance between country data and city data could be significant to alter the results. The impact of the games on the specific city is also likely to be drastically different. On the same note, its almost impossible to control for other factors that may affect the used independent variables. For example, there are many other factors that may affect unemployment rates and exports. That being said, there might be changes in these variables that are not connected to the Olympics. The model also misses some of the important variables that are likely to be impacted by the Olympic games. One of these factors is tourism, which I believe is one of the major income drivers for Olympic hosting cities. Other benefits like Olympic legacy cannot be quantified which also limits the impact coverage. Including data from tourism for example and finding a way to quantify some of these other benefits would provide a wider coverage of the economic impact of the games. CONCLUSIONS The main objective of this research was to assess the economic impact of hosting the Olympic games and whether it is a worthy investment any city. Broader studies have been done on the topic, but for this research I chose to specifically focus on five countries, that had hosted two or more games between the period of 1969 and 2017 and for which I could get the data. The data was collected mainly from the World Bank database and FRED and qualitative analysis focused on GDP per capita growth as the dependent variable and Unemployment rate, Exports as the independent variables. Dummy variables for the host year, summer games and winter games were also added to allow for further specifications in the model. The results from the model show that hosting the Olympic games ends up being beneficial to the host nations anyway. This was evident with a clear cut in unemployment and positive change in exports for the host nations. That being said however, its important that countries planning to participate in the bid to host the games should always make a clear analysis to ensure that the expected benefit is obtained. Otherwise, negative economic impacts as seen after the games in Rio, Athens and Montreal are still possible and the ever-raising costs pose very high risks to the host nations. REFERENCES Andranovich, G., Burbank, M. J., & Heying, C. H. (2001). Olympic Cities: Lessons Learned from MegaEvent Politics. Journal of Urban Affairs, 23(2), 113. https://doi.org/10.1111/0735-2166.00079 Baade, R. A., & Matheson, V. A. (2016). Going for the Gold: The Economics of the Olympics†. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 30(2), 201–218. https://doi.org/10.1257/jep.30.2.201 Barros, C. P., Ibrahım ́ o, M., & Szymanski, S. (2002). Transatlantic sport the comparative economics of North American and European sports. Cheltenham, UK: E. Elgar. Bista, R. (2017). Revisiting the Olympic Effect. Review of International Economics, 25(2), 279–291. https://doi.org/10.1111/roie.12266 CHEN, Y., QU, L., & SPAANS, M. (2013). Framing the Long-Term Impact of Mega-Event Strategies on the Development of Olympic Host Cities. Planning Practice & Research, 28(3), 340–359. https://doi.org/10.1080/02697459.2013.750072 Costanzo, L.L. (2010). A Ticket to the Olympics: An Assessment of the "Olympic Effect" on Tourism. Flyvbjerg, Bent & Stewart, Allison & Budzier, Alexander. (2016). The Oxford Olympics Study 2016: Cost and Cost Overrun at the Games. Saïd Business School Working Papers. 10.2139/ssrn.2804554. Fourie, J. (2017). Should South Africa host mega-events?: Evidence has shown that the costs of putting on events such as the FIFA World Cup or Olympics outweigh the benefits. So why are countries still so eager to host them? Finweek, 6. McBride, J. (2018, January 19). The Economics of Hosting the Olympic Games. Retrieved January 2, 2019, from https://www.cfr.org/backgrounder/economics-hosting-olympic-games McCoy, T. L. (2016). Why Brazil’s post-Olympic hangover will hit so hard. Finweek, 12–13. Pagels, J. (2016). Olympic Ruins. Reason, 48(4), 44–49. Rose, A., & Spiegel, M. (2011). THE OLYMPIC EFFECT. The Economic Journal, 121(553), 652-677. Retrieved March 11, 2020, from www.jstor.org/stable/41236997 Streicher, T., Schmidt, S. L., Schreyer, D., & Torgler, B. (2017). Is it the economy, stupid? The role of social versus economic factors in people’s support for hosting the Olympic Games: evidence from 12 democratic countries. Applied Economics Letters, 24(3), 170–174. https://doi.org/10.1080/13504851.2016.1173175 APENDIX Data Summaries . summarize logGDPpp logGNI logUNP logEXP, detail logGDPpp 1% 5% 10% 25% Percentiles -2.662654 -.6979884 -.299105 .4927489 50% .9911544 75% 90% 95% 99% 1.486814 1.944531 2.226467 2.4497 Smallest -5.613308 -2.814983 -2.662654 -2.197561 Largest 2.430517 2.4497 2.483065 2.55061 Test Results Obs Sum of Wgt. 213 213 Mean Std. Dev. .871639 1.007735 Variance Skewness Kurtosis 1.015531 -1.926738 11.43107 1% 5% 10% 25% 50% 1.235558 75% 90% 95% 99% 1.683438 2.083657 2.309248 2.620401 Smallest -6.453255 -4.932073 -2.346158 -1.930224 Largest 2.60842 2.620401 2.663687 2.685165 Number of obs Number of groups R-sq: Obs per group: within = 0.2173 between = 0.5743 overall = 0.3366 corr(u_i, X) Coef. 224 224 logUNP logEXP HY WIN SUM _cons -.5873478 .3128542 .6192715 -.5694409 0 1.332658 Mean Std. Dev. 1.115312 1.026011 sigma_u sigma_e rho 0 .60282651 0 Variance Skewness Kurtosis 1.052698 -3.135799 20.73256 Obs Sum of Wgt. = = 193 5 min = avg = max = 35 38.6 43 = = 95.39 0.0000 Wald chi2(4) Prob > chi2 = 0 (assumed) logGDPpp logGNI Percentiles -2.346158 -.4845657 .1126374 .7918599 Random-effects GLS regression Group variable: ID Std. Err. z .0918735 .0558901 .3384484 .4732347 (omitted) .2044768 P>|z| [95% Conf. Interval] -6.39 5.60 1.83 -1.20 0.000 0.000 0.067 0.229 -.7674166 .2033117 -.0440752 -1.496964 -.407279 .4223968 1.282618 .3580821 6.52 0.000 .9318912 1.733425 (fraction of variance due to u_i) logUNP 1% 5% 10% 25% Percentiles .1823216 .7241612 .9066443 1.280934 50% 1.686399 75% 90% 95% 99% 2.04122 2.294654 2.373603 2.515032 Smallest .0953102 .0953102 .1823216 .2623643 Largest 2.491137 2.515032 2.530995 2.533141 Heteroskedasticity Testing Obs Sum of Wgt. 245 245 Mean Std. Dev. 1.636323 .5352312 Variance Skewness Kurtosis .2864724 -.4915654 2.656246 Percentiles -.8194209 .1289541 .5742862 1.380181 50% 2.010246 75% 90% 95% 99% . 2.428042 2.807168 3.11906 3.662041 Smallest -2.292272 -.9298691 -.8194209 -.7484584 Largest 3.597511 3.662041 3.758078 3.926374 Iteration Iteration Iteration Iteration 0: 1: 2: 3: log log log log likelihood likelihood likelihood likelihood = = = = -197.79922 -193.64875 -193.64744 -193.64744 Heteroskedastic linear regression ML estimation Log likelihood = -193.6474 logEXP 1% 5% 10% 25% Fitting full model: Obs Sum of Wgt. 214 214 Mean Std. Dev. 1.823786 .9218406 Variance Skewness Kurtosis .8497902 -.8696173 4.656308 Number of obs = 193 Wald chi2(4) Prob > chi2 = = 97.93 0.0000 logGDPpp Coef. logGDPpp logUNP logEXP HY WIN SUM _cons -.5873478 .3128542 .6192715 -.5694409 0 1.332658 .0906757 .0551614 .3340356 .4670645 (omitted) .2018107 -6.48 5.67 1.85 -1.22 0.000 0.000 0.064 0.223 -.7650688 .2047399 -.0354262 -1.484871 -.4096268 .4209685 1.273969 .3459887 6.60 0.000 .9371166 1.7282 lnsigma2 _cons -.8311678 .1017973 -8.16 0.000 -1.030687 -.6316488 Std. Err. z P>|z| [95% Conf. Interval] Hausman test Correcting for Heteroskedasticity Random-effects GLS regression Group variable: ID Number of obs Number of groups R-sq: Obs per group: within = 0.2173 between = 0.5743 overall = 0.3366 corr(u_i, X) = = 193 5 min = avg = max = 35 38.6 43 = = 415.26 0.0000 Wald chi2(4) Prob > chi2 = 0 (assumed) (Std. Err. adjusted for 5 clusters in ID) logGDPpp Coef. logUNP logEXP HY WIN SUM _cons -.5873478 .3128542 .6192715 -.5694409 0 1.332658 sigma_u sigma_e rho 0 .60282651 0 Robust Std. Err. .162082 .1084466 .1409918 .1465003 (omitted) .2204621 z P>|z| -3.62 2.88 4.39 -3.89 0.000 0.004 0.000 0.000 -.9050227 .1003028 .3429327 -.8565762 -.2696729 .5254056 .8956103 -.2823057 6.04 0.000 .9005607 1.764756 R-sq: Obs per group: within = 0.2173 between = 0.5743 overall = 0.3366 Coef. sigma_u sigma_e rho 0 .60282651 0 = = 193 5 min = avg = max = 35 38.6 43 = = 95.39 0.0000 Wald chi2(4) Prob > chi2 = 0 (assumed) .3128542 -.5873478 .6192715 -.5694409 0 1.332658 .3128542 -.5873478 .6192715 -.5694409 Std. Err. .0558901 .0918735 .3384484 .4732347 (omitted) .2044768 z P>|z| [95% Conf. Interval] 5.60 -6.39 1.83 -1.20 0.000 0.000 0.067 0.229 .2033117 -.7674166 -.0440752 -1.496964 .4223968 -.407279 1.282618 .3580821 6.52 0.000 .9318912 1.733425 (fraction of variance due to u_i) Robust test using GNI Random-effects GLS regression Group variable: ID Number of obs Number of groups R-sq: Obs per group: within = 0.1132 between = 0.3631 overall = 0.1638 = = 202 5 min = avg = max = 37 40.4 43 = = 718.17 0.0000 Wald chi2(4) Prob > chi2 = 0 (assumed) (Std. Err. adjusted for 5 clusters in ID) logGNI Coef. lohEXP logUNP HY WIN SUM _cons .2884059 -.4671568 .6412316 -.4632444 0 1.381396 sigma_u sigma_e rho 0 .87840652 0 -.0817278 -.0683149 -.1022321 .1870456 . .0907301 . . b = consistent under Ho and Ha; obtained from xtreg B = inconsistent under Ha, efficient under Ho; obtained from xtreg Test: Ho: difference in coefficients not systematic chi2(4) = (b-B)'[(V_b-V_B)^(-1)](b-B) = -22.15 chi2<0 ==> model fitted on these data fails to meet the asymptotic assumptions of the Hausman test; see suest for a generalized test Fixed-effects (within) regression Group variable: ID Number of obs Number of groups R-sq: Obs per group: within = 0.2251 between = 0.5108 overall = 0.3280 corr(u_i, Xb) logGDPpp Coef. lohEXP logUNP HY WIN SUM _cons .2311264 -.6556626 .5170393 -.3823953 0 1.596732 sigma_u sigma_e rho .34251619 .60282651 .24404651 Robust Std. Err. .1064356 .1497153 .1692795 .1441249 (omitted) .29563 z P>|z| [95% Conf. Interval] 2.71 -3.12 3.79 -3.21 0.007 0.002 0.000 0.001 .079796 -.7605935 .3094499 -.7457239 .4970157 -.1737202 .9730133 -.1807648 4.67 0.000 .8019722 1.960821 (fraction of variance due to u_i) = = 193 5 min = avg = max = 35 38.6 43 = = 13.36 0.0000 F(4,184) Prob > F = 0.0501 Std. Err. .0527676 .1291228 .3081788 .4320976 (omitted) .2420268 t P>|t| [95% Conf. Interval] 4.38 -5.08 1.68 -0.88 0.000 0.000 0.095 0.377 .1270192 -.9104142 -.090979 -1.234898 .3352337 -.4009111 1.125058 .4701076 6.60 0.000 1.119227 2.074236 (fraction of variance due to u_i) F test that all u_i=0: F(4, 184) = 11.83 corr(u_i, X) sqrt(diag(V_b-V_B)) S.E. Fixed effects Number of obs Number of groups lohEXP logUNP HY WIN SUM _cons .2311264 -.6556626 .5170393 -.3823953 (b-B) Difference (fraction of variance due to u_i) Random-effects GLS regression Group variable: ID logGDPpp lohEXP logUNP HY WIN [95% Conf. Interval] Random effects corr(u_i, X) Coefficients (b) (B) fe re Prob > F = 0.0000