Uploaded by Antonio.Campello.15

Economics Portfolio 44 marks out of 45 marks

advertisement
Commentary 1
Title of the article: LED Streetlights Bring Cost Savings, and Headaches,
To Colorado Cities
Source of the article: Colorado Public Radio online site
http://www.cpr.org/news/story/led­streetlights­bring­cost­savings­and­heada
ches­to­colorado­citi es (Accessed 20 February 2017)
Date the article was published: 15 September 2016
Date the commentary was written: 17 March 2017
Word count of the commentary: 792 words
Unit of the syllabus to which the article relates: Microeconomics
Key concept being used: Efficiency
Article
LED Streetlights Bring Cost Savings, And Headaches, To Colorado Cities
The city of Denver is in the midst of a nearly $2 million project to replace lighting poles, fixtures and bulbs
on the 13-block 16th Street Mall.
On their way out: High-pressure sodium lights that have an orange hue. On their way in: White LEDs.
“These street lights are about 30 years old. It was time for an upgrade,” said Denver Public Works
spokeswoman Heather Burke. “Technology changes. It was time to change with it,”
Denver planned for years before converting the iconic 1970s-era light fixtures along the 16th Street Mall
sidewalks to LED lights. They meet new guidelines issued this June by the American Medical Association
(AMA).
Across the country, more than 10 percent of outdoor lighting is powered by LEDs. Because the energy
savings can be as much as 50 percent, many cities want to make the change. But there are also health
implications to consider; LED lights that appear too blue can suppress melatonin production, which can
lead to increased diabetes and depression.
The newer LED lights cost the same, provide the same cost savings and last as long as older versions, so
“there’s absolutely no reason to put in bad lighting,” said Dr. Mario Motta, who serves on the AMA’s
Council on Science and Public Health. “You can put in good lighting.”
Smarter Technology
In June, the AMA issued three core guidelines for cities. It suggested using lights that are 3000 degrees
Kelvin or below, referring to the color temperature of lights, where lower numbers appear warmer. Most
older versions of LED streetlights installed before 2016 were 4000 Kelvin or above.
The AMA also advised cities to properly shield LEDs to reduce glare, and to make lights dimmable.
Professional groups including the Illuminating Engineering Society criticized the guidelines as too
specific. The U.S. Department of Energy pointed out that blue light is not unique to LEDs.
Lighting designer Nancy Clanton of the Boulder-based firm Clanton & Associates said the technology that
comes with LEDs can offer cities new options.
Clanton has helped design LED streetlights for a number of cities including San Diego and Anchorage. In
San Jose, she worked to install smarter technology that allows the city to dim street lights.
"Right before the bars close, they increase the lighting level so that everyone knows it’s time to go home,
and then they decrease it back down again,” she said.
This dimming technology will be installed in Colorado Department of Transportation lights in the coming
years. Dimming is also possible on new lights Clanton’s firm helped design for the 16th Street Mall.
Denver Public Works spokeswoman Heather Burke said the poles and globe lights will look the same to
most. But there’s one noticeable change. Designers have restored a halo of lights that has been dark for
years; lost when Denver planners switched light bulb types decades ago.
"The twinkle rings, you can see that ring up there. On the old lights they were inoperable for a long time.
So those are restored now. And it’s going to create a brighter more inviting light for folks,” she said.
The AMA guidelines were a challenge for cities that had already invested time and money converting to
LEDs. Some cities like Lake Worth, Florida, changed course and opted for warmer LED streetlights.
For Ouray, on the Western Slope, which installed LEDs in 2009, the AMA guidelines released this year
were just another bump in a long road adjusting to the new technology.
City Administrator Patrick Rondinelli said Ouray was the first in the state to make the move. A huge
selling point was preserving darker night skies.
“In Ouray we’re very fortunate. We can actually still see the Milky Way. You get to Denver, you can’t see
that anymore,” he said.
But since 2009, Ouray has noticed a few hiccups as an early adopter of LED technology. LEDs cast a more
narrow light pattern compared to other lights. After installation, suddenly large sections of neighborhood
blocks went dark. Only the intersections -- where the LED street lights were placed -- appeared lit.
That’s a problem when you have bears walking down side streets.
“As our law enforcement are trying to chase bears around and get them out of the community, they have a
hard time seeing a lot of that,” said Rondinelli.
Rondinelli said he doesn’t know what to make of the recent AMA guidelines. Overall, citizen feedback has
been positive and cost savings have helped the city’s bottom line.
“We’ve had some lessons learned along the way. But there’s no regrets,” he said.
Since LED technology changes so quickly, there may actually be a benefit in moving slowly.
If a proposed budget item is passed, Fort Collins will swap about one-third of its streetlights to LEDs in
2017 and 2018.
Fort Collins Engineering Manager Kraig Bader said the city hopes to install 3000 and 4000 Kelvin lights
with varying brightness depending on how large and busy streets are. It plans to study the results before
converting the rest of the city’s lights.
“In essence we’re going slow to go fast later on,” he said.
(Colorado Public Radio, Sep 15, 2016)
http://www.cpr.org/news/story/led­streetlights­bring­cost­savings­and­headaches­to­colorado­citi
es
Commentary
Many problems are associated with the economic evaluation and provision of public goods.
How should communities proceed with the installation of LED streetlights in order to ensure
that there is allocative efficiency, with the social surplus being maximized where marginal
social cost=marginal social benefit (MSC=MSB)?
Streetlights are public goods because they are non-rivalrous and non-excludable. This
causes complications when attempting to analyze their advantages (Figure 1).
Figure 1: Cost/benefit model for sodium and LED streetlights
The MSC1 curve represents the supply curve of sodium streetlights. The marginal private
benefit (MPB), or demand curve for streetlights, does not intersect with the MSC curve because
streetlights are public goods. This signifies that the free rider problem is occurringΝΎ no-one (or,
in reality, very few people) will buy the good because they are all waiting for someone else to
buy it. However, the city government ought to pay for these goods, as the MSB of streetlights is
high. Before the implementation of LEDs, the optimum or efficient output was Q1 where the
MSB curve intersects the MSC1 curve.
Although the article mentions that LEDs “cost the same”, the MSC2 curve for LED streetlights is
below the MSC1 curve. This is because private costs are lower, and “energy savings can be as
much as 50 percent”, signifying that the costs of using the lights, for many years after
implementation, will decrease significantly.
Therefore, the MSC curve will drop. Simultaneously, the efficient quantity of LED streetlights
the city ought to acquire will increase from Q1 to Q2. From the diagram, it can be seen that the
city can reduce the costs spent on streetlights and at the same time obtain more. The extra
lights can be stored until some need to be replaced, implying that costs in the budget for
future purchases of the replacement of lights can also be saved.
However, the disadvantages of LED are associated health problems, namely an external
cost of consumption (Figure 2).
Figure 2: Negative Consumption Externality of LED streetlights
Because streetlights are public goods, the D (MPB) curve has been shown to be almost
irrelevant to the model. Instead, the externality (“health implications” of “increased diabetes and
depression”) is shown by the downwards shift of the MSB1 curve to MSB2. The marginal
external cost notated in the diagram supposedly measures the per unit negative impact of
individual health problems on society.
The diagram shows that the efficient quantity of LEDs is not QP (initially predicted quantity), but
QA (actual quantity). It also implies that in order to dissuade cities from implementing harmful
LED lights, the efficient “price” of the LED lights at QA will not be cost/benefit2, where
MSB2=MSC, but instead at cost/benefit3.
This diagram supports Fort Collins’ argument for changing only part of the city’s streetlights to
LED lighting. It illustrates that because of the negative externality, LED lighting, while
apparently more “cost-efficient”, has problems. However, the negative externality is probably
not so large that LED lighting should be completely eliminated from the city government’s
options. It makes sense for Fort Collins to “swap one third of its streetlights to LEDs”.
Furthermore, Fort Collins mentioned that they hope to “install 3000 and 4000 Kelvin lights with
varying brightness” and “study the results” before making further decisions about whether they
will replace the rest of the city’s lights. This exemplifies how communities may use economic
models to assess the advantages and disadvantages of public goods, with the aim of
improving the well-being of their citizens and reaching allocative efficiency.
However, there are also many limitations to the models above. The models are all static, and do
not reflect development of LEDsΝΎ an example of rapidly improving, new and clean technology.
Research has probably been conducted in order to reduce harmful blue light, and costs of the
lights have also been reduced. As the article suggests, the cities have probably taken measures
to reduce negative impacts, such as warmer lights, shielding and dimming.
Additionally, more variables should be considered. For instance, the article mentions positive
externalities of consumption of LEDs due to the ability to preserve darker night skies. There are
also problems associated with LED light patterns being narrow and therefore posing danger of
bear attacks. The city must consider different aspects because LEDs are public goods which
need to benefit citizens, not only the city budget.
Finally, all the curves and points on the models are qualitativeΝΎ although they reflect directional
shifts, it is impossible to determine the monetary cost of negative and positive externalities.
Therefore, applying corrections based on these static models will be unrealistic.
In conclusion, analysis shows that installation of LEDs in some streetlights will save costs while
minimizing negative externalities. However, in order to ensure that allocative efficiency is
improved, the city government should closely monitor effects on society and citizens’ feedback
to make decisions based on reality rather than just on the abstract models.
Commentary 2
Title of the article: The country with the world’s most progressive taxes has
the world’s highest income inequality
Source of the article: Washington Post
https://www.washingtonpost.com/news/wonk/wp/2017/07/16/what-american-lib
erals-could-learnfrom-south-africa/?utm_term=.5738f496ae30 (Accessed 10
October 2017)
Date the article was published: 16 July 2017
Date the commentary was written: 10 November 2017
Word count of the commentary: 781words
Unit of the syllabus to which the article relates: Macroeconomics
Key concept being used: Equity
Article
The Washington Post
The country with the world’s most progressive taxes has the world’s highest
income inequality
By Max Ehrenfreund July 16
South Africa has the world's most progressive tax system, according to a new report. South
Africa is also, by another measure, the world's most unequal country -- making it a cautionary
example for U.S. liberals about the limited power of taxation to remedy inequality.
Yes, taxing the rich more and the poor less can have benefits, but many experts argue inequality
is more meaningfully addressed by spending on public programs that provide for people's basic
needs while giving them an opportunity to get ahead.
In particular, that requires ensuring people have access to education, training, transportation
and health care. And funding those enterprises requires more than just soaking the rich. In
northern European countries -- where economists have found that people who are born poor are
more likely to make it into the middle class -- governments also rely on broad taxes that force
the middle class to pay more as well.
"The basic story is taxes do not change the income distribution," said Graham Glenday, a tax
scholar at Duke University who was born in Cape Town, South Africa and plans to retire there.
"Changing the income distribution is much more of a dynamic thing that comes about if poor
people can actually move up," he said. "That obviously takes, sometimes, generations."
The new report, published Sunday by Oxfam, ranks 152 countries on how well their economic
policies are designed to address inequality. South Africa ranks first on taxation. The rich pay
steeper rates, the corporate tax is hard to shirk and a national value-added tax includes
exemptions for food and other staples that are major expenses for the poor.
"It’s quite an efficient system that tries, to the extent that’s possible, to really, kind of, balance
the equation," said Sipho Mthathi, the director of Oxfam South Africa. "It is one of the most
efficient tax systems in the world."
But despite ranking first in tax redistribution, South Africa ranks slides to 21st in the overall
measure of addressing inequality, just ahead of the United States at 23rd. A poor score on the
labor market -- South Africa does not have a minimum wage, for example -- brings down the
country's general ranking.
The other countries in the top 25 are all developed nations, almost all of them in Europe.
Sweden ranks first, followed by Belgium, Denmark and Norway.
There are many methods of measuring inequality, but among the most common is the Gini
coefficient -- a measure of the share of income that would have to be redistributed to achieve
perfect equality. Based on the Gini coefficient, South Africa is the most unequal country in the
world among those for which data are available, according to the World Bank.
As of 2011, the most recent year for which data are available from the bank, the coefficient
was 0.63 in South Africa. Data from the Organization for Economic Cooperation and
Development (OECD) show that inequality has increased in South Africa since 2000, when the
Gini coefficient was 0.58.
The coefficient for the United States was just 0.41 as of 2013, but that figure is still relatively
high for a rich country.
It is difficult to compare economic policies across countries. Different approaches may work
better for some countries than others, and the data is not always available in the same form.
Any
ranking necessarily involves a degree of subjective judgment.
For instance, Oxfam did not rank countries' systems of taxation according to a strict measure of
fiscal progressivity, that is, the distribution of the burden on people of different levels of
income. (The northern European and Scandinavian tax systems also perform well in the report,
despite the relatively high taxes paid by the middle class in those countries.)
Instead, the authors of the report considered several factors. South Africa performed well on all
of them.
The South African government consistently collects between 27 percent and 29 percent of the
country's gross domestic product in revenue, Glenday said. He added that those numbers are
comparable to those for the United States -- where general government revenue totaled 33.5
percent of GDP in 2015, according to the OECD.
That is despite the fact that the United States is a much richer country, where taxpayers can
afford to pay much more. In the United States, GDP per person is more than 10 times that of
South Africa.
Indeed, Americans pay only 68 percent to 71 percent of the maximum amount of taxes that the
government could theoretically collect, according to researchers at the International Monetary
Fund. The estimates for South Africa are higher -- between 75 percent and 76 percent,
depending on how the maximum is calculated.
South Africa is able to collect so much in taxes in part because of a bureaucracy that is
unusually
effective for a developing country. While corruption is a serious problem in South Africa, the tax
authorities have a reputation for professionalism.
"They collect it very competently," Glenday said.
Hefty penalties for cheating the system discourage abuse, according to Mthathi. "It’s created a
culture where it’s not easy for people to just not follow the rules," she said.
Another factor that might make South Africa's tax system particularly progressive is that about
one fifth of tax revenue comes from taxes on corporate income. That is roughly twice the share
of U.S. taxes that is paid by corporations.
People who own corporations, whether privately or in the form of publicly traded stock, tend to
be wealthier, and most economists believe that steeper corporate taxes tend to favor the poor
and the middle class. An important exception is Kevin Hassett, President Trump's nominee to
serve as chairman of the White House's Council of Economic Advisers. Hassett has argued that
workers wind up paying a substantial share of corporate taxes in the form of reduced wages.
By Oxfam's reckoning, though, the United States would fall in the rankings from 23rd to 29th if
Trump's agenda were implemented.
Despite decades of progressive, efficient tax policy in South Africa, the country's extreme
inequality is stubbornly persistent. "It doesn’t mean that the country doesn’t have problems,"
Mthathi said.
In particular, she said, South Africa could spend the money that it collects more efficiently to
reduce poverty and create opportunity. The problem of corruption makes it more difficult for the
government to achieve those aims.
And as Glenday pointed out, South Africa's public education system is notoriously poor -- a
grave obstacle to economic development over the long term. That is arguably a legacy of the era
of apartheid, when schools for white students were much better than those for students of other
ethnicities.
Without good tax policy, South Africans might be much worse off, but that country's example
suggests that progressive taxes on their own are not a solution to inequality.
"It’s not just about collecting money, and making sure that is done is fairly and progressively,"
Mthathi said.
https://www.washingtonpost.com/news/wonk/wp/2017/07/16/what-american-liberals-could-learnfrom
-south-africa/?utm_term=.5738f496ae30
Commentary
This article illustrates the problems associated with income inequality and inequity. Contrary
to popular belief, despite having the world’s most progressive tax system in the world, South
Africa has high income inequality. What might be the implications of the Gini coefficient of
South Africa and how does progressive tax influence the income distribution?
Progressive taxes are usually designed to reduce the inequality between people by taxing
the higher income workers proportionately more than the lower income workers. As the
article mentions, it is often considered to be a “remedy to inequality”, implying that there is
more equity. However, South Africa still has a high degree of income inequality. It is
mentioned that the Gini coefficient in 2011 was 0.63. This is illustrated in the below income
π‘Žπ‘Žπ‘Žπ‘Žπ‘Žπ‘Žπ‘Žπ‘Ž (𝐴𝐴)
distribution diagram where the 𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺𝐺 𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐𝑐 = π‘Žπ‘Žπ‘Žπ‘Žπ‘Žπ‘Žπ‘Žπ‘Ž (𝐴𝐴+𝐡𝐡)
Naturally, the question will follow: Why, despite the progressive tax, does South Africa have
a wide gap in the income distribution? Inequality may depend on the productivity of
resources owned, non-competitive labor markets, stage of economic development of the
country, the type of economy, society and culture, luck, or a combination of these.
However, the flaw in this article is that it does not make it clear whether the Gini coefficient
provided is for pre-tax income or disposable income. If the Gini coefficient is for pre-tax
income, the problem is the significant difference in the wages the workers are receiving. This
means that the reasoning provided by the article is insufficient because with the pre-tax
figures, no measure of the relationship between income inequality and progressive taxes
has been provided. Perhaps, the Gini coefficient for the disposable income will actually show
that the world’s most progressive tax does indeed greatly reduce inequality.
On the other hand, if the Gini coefficient is for disposable income, it is implied that the
progressive taxes may not have as much influence on the redistribution of income as
expected, which supports the article’s viewpoint. The diagram below shows that effect on
income distribution due to government spending may be greater than the progressive taxes.
In the above model, the Lorenz curve C reflects the income distribution of South Africa
before taxes are imposed, due to other factors such as inefficient government spending.
Then the effect of the progressive taxes is shown by the less curved Lorenz curve D. It is
shown that the taxes will only slightly make the area enclosed by the curve smaller.
Therefore, the model above illustrates the possibility that progressive taxes are indeed not
very effective in remedying inequality, as the article suggests.
However, the article also states that inequality in South Africa may be due to corruption and
a lack of spending on infrastructure, educational and health facilities. While it may be true
that the tax system itself has severe penalties for cheating it, corruption could occur
afterwards. This suggests that the tax is not being used effectively to counter eventual
structural unemployment due to lack of education; the problem lies with the effective
utilization of the tax revenue and not the progressivity of the tax.
This is significant because it implies that progressive taxes, while less effective on their own,
could lead to effective supply-side policies using the tax revenues, if corruption decreases.
Measures such as increased education and training would encourage occupational mobility
and lower unit costs, shown by the movement of the short run aggregate supply
curve to the right from SRAS1 to SRAS2. This will also reduce frictional and structural
unemployment due to a more flexible labor force and increased quality and quantity of the
production of goods. Furthermore, investment in human capital is an increase in the quality
of the factors of production with higher productivity, which can be represented by a shift the
long run aggregate supply curve (LRAS1 to LRAS2) of South Africa. If used correctly,
progressive tax revenues may lead to sustained economic growth and reduced income
inequality in the future.
Limitations of the economic theory used include the fact that effects of other factors used to
promote income equality, such as transfer payments, government subsidies and intervention
in the labor markets have not been compared thoroughly in order to assess the
effectiveness of the progressive tax in improving equity.
Economists will also have to observe the effects in the long run to make viable conclusions,
as South Africa is a developing country and has the potential for higher economic growth. In
conclusion, the ambiguity in the article about the source of South Africa’s large Gini
coefficient makes the extent of the influence of progressive taxes in reducing inequality
questionable, although the tax system does appear to be less significant than that of
government expenditure in promoting equity.
Commentary 3
Title of the article: E.U. and Japan Reach Deal to Keep ‘Flag of Free Trade
Waving High’
Source of the article: The New York Times
https://www.nytimes.com/2017/12/08/business/economy/eu-japan-trade.html
(Accessed 22 January 2018)
Date the article was published: 8 December 2017
Date the commentary was written: 5 March 2018
Word count of the commentary: 800
Unit of the syllabus to which the article relates: The Global Economy
Key concept being used: Interdependence
Article
E.U. and Japan Reach Deal to Keep ‘Flag of Free
Trade Waving High’
By Prashant S. Rao and Jack Ewing Dec. 8, 2017
The European Union and Japan said on Friday that they had finalized a sweeping deal
that would create a free trade area covering more than a quarter of the world’s economy,
pushing against rising calls for protectionism in much of the West.
Leaders of both parties to the agreement trumpeted its strategic, as well as economic,
importance. That it was announced just hours after Britain and the European
Union broke a deadlock to start a new round of talks over that country’s withdrawal
from the bloc only heightened its symbolic impact.
The so-called economic partnership agreement, which would be one of the largest free
trade deals ever, “demonstrates the powerful political will of Japan and the E.U. to
continue to keep the flag of free trade waving high,” the Japanese prime minister, Shinzo
Abe, and the president of the European Union’s executive arm, Jean-Claude
Juncker, said in a joint statement.
The deal is subject to ratification by lawmakers in Europe as well as Japan, but Mr. Abe
and Mr. Juncker said that they were confident that once in place, it would “deliver
sustainable and inclusive economic growth, and spur job creation.”
“It sends a clear signal to the world that the E.U. and Japan are committed to keeping
the world economy working on the basis of free, open and fair markets with clear and
transparent rules fully respecting and enhancing our values, fighting the temptation of
protectionism,” the leaders added.
The agreement also reaffirms its parties’ commitment to the Paris climate accord, from
which the Trump administration has said it will withdraw.
Tokyo and Brussels began trade talks in 2013, and said in June that they were nearing a
deal. Japan trades less with the European Union than it does with the United States or
China. But completing a deal with the European Union became a more urgent priority
for Tokyo after President Trump’s decision in January to withdraw the United
States from another agreement, the Trans-Pacific Partnership. Japan has also pushed
to revive that deal, even without the United States.
Japan had effectively paused its talks with the European Union while it focused on the
larger Pacific Rim deal, which included 10 other nations along with the United States
and Japan. Mr. Abe has made liberalizing trade a centerpiece of his economic agenda —
a notable shift in a country that, despite its success exporting cars, electronics and other
merchandise, had long shied away from trade deals.
The change of direction on trade owes partly to the waning power of Japan’s farm lobby,
which has fought to keep tariffs on imported agricultural products high, impeding the
country’s ability to strike agreements. Japanese negotiators still focus much of their
efforts on protecting farmers, but with Japan’s rural population rapidly aging and
shrinking, governments no longer see making concessions on agriculture as politically
fatal.
The European Union and Japan have a combined annual economic output of around
$20 trillion, and together would constitute a trading area roughly the size of the one
created by the North American Free Trade Agreement. The future of Nafta, which
comprises the United States, Canada and Mexico, has also been cast into doubt by tense
renegotiations.
Still, while Japan and the European Union have expressed confidence over the
agreement they announced on Friday, political interests are still at play. National and
some regional legislatures in Europe will have a say, a process that nearly derailed a
trade deal with Canada.
The main beneficiaries from the agreement are likely to be Japanese carmakers and
European food and beverage producers.
The deal will make it easier for European producers of cheese, beef, wine and processed
meat to sell in Japan, which imposes duties of as much as 40 percent on some products.
European makers of pharmaceuticals, medical equipment and trains are also expected to
come out ahead.
The pact also presents Japanese carmakers with an opportunity to increase sales in
Europe, which has long been difficult for them. Toyota and other Japanese
manufacturers have only a 13 percent share of the auto market in the European Union,
in part because of import tariffs, compared to the United States where they account for
about 40 percent.
But Japan’s carmakers already have major manufacturing operations in Europe which
are not subject to import duties, suggesting that their meagre sales also stem from lack
of products that appeal to European tastes.
While the pact will be important for some industries, said Angel Talavera, senior
eurozone economist at Oxford Economics in Britain, its overall economic impact will be
modest.
The deal “does not materially alter the outlook for the eurozone, as Japan represents
only around 2 percent of total exports,” Mr. Talavera said in an email. “I don’t think this
is a game changer.”
Commentary
Interdependence between different sectors within one economy and between global
economies can cause clashes when trade is liberalized, especially if declining industries are
involved. The Economic Partnership Agreement (EPA), a free trade agreement (FTA)
between the European Union (EU) and Japan, symbolizes the advantages of free trade,
while also raising issues about the protection of declining industries and about flows of trade
between all economies.
An FTA reduces or eliminates trade barriers on goods from member countries, while allowing
them to erect their own trade barriers against other countries. There will be tariff reductions
on, for example, Japanese car imports into the EU and on European “cheese, beef, and
wine”, among others imports, into Japan. Before the FTA, Japan had been imposing a tariff
of up to 40%.
Before the EPA, the price of cheese was Pw+Tariff (40%) where the quantity of imports from
the EU was Q2Q3. However, when the tariff is eliminated, with price falling to Pw, the quantity
of domestically produced cheese will fall from Q2 to Q1 because some Japanese dairy
farmers will lower output or even give up farming in response to lower prices and their
revenue will decrease from Pw+Tariff x Q2 to Pw x Q1. Thus, the quantity of imports will
increase to Q1Q4. Because more efficient EU firms are producing the cheese, there will no
longer be welfare losses, represented by areas a and b. Simultaneously, there will be a
decrease in tariff revenue, which the Japanese government had been collecting, shown in
the area GOV.
A similar analysis can be made for the elimination of tariffs on Japanese car companies.
Currently, “Toyota and other Japanese manufacturers have only a 13% share of the auto
market”, suggesting that import tariffs placed on cars by the EU have been harming
Japanese exports. However, this could be due to a mismatch between the Japanese
products and the European tastes, a non-price determinant of demand. Moreover, the tariff
reduction will have no impact on the Japanese cars which are manufactured in Europe.
On the other hand, the EPA may negatively affect the farmers of Japan, a declining industry
which has been protected for many years. Due to “waning power of Japan’s farm lobby”
attributed to the aging population in rural areas, “governments no longer see making
concessions on agriculture as politically fatal”. Although political effects of the loss of tariffs
on agricultural products may no longer be large, there may be economic losses.
The lowering/elimination of tariffs on European farm products in competition with Japanese products
suggests a decrease in production of agricultural goods from QA1 to QA2, as inefficient domestic
farmers are replaced by Europeans. However, it is likely that this will only result in a much smaller
quantity increase of QM1 to QM2 in the production of manufactured goods. Farmers are likely to have
had the job for their whole lives. Thus, relatively low mobility of the “aging population”, especially in
“rural areas” can be expected.
Therefore, the EPA could cause a fall in Japan’s real GDP and as total output decreases, high
frictional and, more problematically, structural unemployment. The growth in car exports may lead to
a decline in the economic vitality of rural areas, even though car manufacturing and farming may not
seem at first to be interdependent. Similarly, infant industries (for example, wine production in
Japan) may also struggle as they do not yet have the economies of scale to compete against large
established overseas companies.
The FTA between the EU and Japan will have various other consequences. On the one hand, trade
liberalization will increase competition and incentives for firms. The consumers will be able to
choose from a wider variety of goods at lower prices, as import prices will fall. There will be a rise in
global allocative efficiency as specialization according to comparative advantage takes place
leading to trade creation.
At the same time, governments inside and outside the EPA will have to closely monitor to ensure
that imports from outside the FTA are not routed through the low-tariff economy into a high- tariff
economy. The phenomenon of trade diversion shows how all economies in the world are
interdependent, not just those within each FTA.
As indicated above, Korean cars could be imported into Europe via Japan at a lower total tariff of
3% instead of 10%, impacting both tariff revenues for each area (where government revenues from
tariffs will already be lower due to the abolition of tariffs in the EPA) and competition between firms.
However, some economists maintain that the EPA may provide little stimulation to the EU economy
because “Japan represents only around 2 percent of exports”. Maybe rather than interdependence
between the two areas, Japan is more dependent on the EU. But this could change as trade
develops in the long run.
ECONOMICS – PORTFOLIO: A
Marks and Comments
Commentary: 1
Criterion
Mark
Out of
Justification
A Diagrams
3
3
Both diagrams are relevantly labeled and usefully entitled. Switches the
horizontal axis effectively from “Quantity of streetlights” to “Quantity of
LED lights” for the second diagram. The explanations are clear and
correct.
B Terminology
2
2
Appropriate economic terminology is used precisely. Concise definition
of the crucial term “public good”, while correct understanding of the
other terms (such as external cost of consumption) is shown by the way
in which they are used.
C Application and
3
3
The use of cost-benefit analysis is well-linked to the article, being
effectively applied to a non-text-book situation. The small demand curve
analysis
on the left of the optimum implies that a few people might be willing to
pay for street lights (rather than zero consumers as implied by pure
public good theory), but that does actually seem likely in a real-world
situation.
D Key concept
3
3
The commentary recognizes that the key concept of efficiency is difficult
to measure and even more difficult to ensure, given the external costs
(of LED streetlights, which meanwhile have lower monetary costs) and
the benefits of streetlights. Nonetheless it is seen as necessary to try to
move towards it.
E Evaluation
3
3
The evaluation is balanced and comprehensive. It covers both the
points made in the article and the weaknesses of the models used in the
analysis. It is well summed up in the final paragraph.
Total:
14
14
Marks and Comments
PORTFOLIO: A
Commentary: 2
Criterion
Mark
Out of
Justification
A Diagrams
3
3
Uses two different models in three diagrams. Titles and labels are
correct and relevant. Recognises that the Lorenz curve diagram cannot
be used for any predictive purposes, but only as an illustration.
Explanations are very clear and focused.
B Terminology
2
2
Plentiful use of relevant terminology with concise and precise definitions
of a progressive tax and of the Gini coefficient. Uses the terminology of
supply-side policies, such as unemployment, capital, etc correctly,
demonstrating that their meaning is understood.
C Application and
3
3
The use of the Lorenz curve model is highly relevant to the article.
Uses the AD/AS model effectively and interestingly to analyse and
analysis
emphasise the importance of investment in infrastructure and human
capital.
D Key concept
2
3
The key concept of equity is mentioned initially and in the conclusion. It
is appropriate to both the article and the commentary. However since
both are explicitly about equality rather than equity, the link between the
two concepts needed to be more fully explained.
E Evaluation
3
3
Critical and focused evaluation with an especially pertinent point made
in the third paragraph regarding the ambiguity of the information in the
article itself. Argues effectively for the need for additional policies, rather
than simply relying on progressive taxation.
Total:
13
14
Marks and Comments
PORTFOLIO: A
Commentary: 3
Criterion
Mark
Out of
Justification
A Diagrams
3
3
Uses diagrams very effectively with explanatory titles and detailed,
relevant labels. Although the first diagram is the standard tariff diagram,
the other two are rather innovative in this context. Explanations are
clear, correct, and focused.
B Terminology
2
2
The terminology of international economics is used correctly and
precisely, distinguishing, for example, between trade creation and trade
diversion. Concise definitions of crucial terms, such as FTA, are
provided where necessary.
C Application and
3
3
the implications of statements made in the article.
analysis
D Key concept
The analysis, using economic models or theories, effectively explains
3
3
The key concept of interdependence is used both to discuss how
different sectors (farming and car manufacturing) have an impact on
each other and on how economies are interdependent globally.
E Evaluation
3
3
Evaluation is apparent at several points in the article, not just in the
concluding paragraphs. It takes a balanced approach, considering the
theoretical benefits of freer trade against the impact on Japanese
farmers and rural areas. It also discusses whether the benefits
(especially for Japanese car sales) might not be as large as suggested
by the theories.
Total:
14
14
_________________________________________________________________________________________
__
Criterion F
Mark
3
Out of
Justification
3
The three commentaries are each based on different syllabus units. Each
article is taken from a different and appropriate source and is published
less than one year before the commentary was written.
Marks from three commentaries (Out
of 42)
41
Total marks – including criterion F
(Out of 45)
44
Download