Macroeconomic Theory and Policy: Lecture 1 (Ch.1) University of Toronto Fall - Lecture 1 1 / 32 Course Organization In the Fall term, lecture will be held on Tuesday and tutorial will be held every Monday In the Winter term, the lecture will be on Monday and the tutorial will be held every Tuesday Office hour: I My office hour: Right after lecture I TA’s office hour: see announcement I Additional office hour will be available before the mid-term and exam Email: eco202y1y.c@course.utoronto.ca Piazza: TA and I will answer questions on Piazza University of Toronto Fall - Lecture 1 2 / 32 Grade Structure Group assignment I Four take home group assignments, each worth 2.5% (total 10%) I They will be post and be submitted on Crowdmark I Once started, you have 3 hours to submit I Up to four students a group Weekly Quizzes I Post and be submitted on Quercus after each lecture I Best 20 quizzes, each worth 0.5% (total 10%) I Due every Thursday after each lecture Writing Assignment I Two writing assignments , each worth 5% (total 10%) University of Toronto Fall - Lecture 1 3 / 32 Grade Structure Test: worth 15% each I Mid-term 1: Oct 23 (Monday) I Mid-term 2: Fall term exam period, schedule by the university I Mid-term 3: Feb 26 (Monday) Exam: worth 25% I It will be comprehensive I Winter term exam period, schedule by the university Please check the outline for more information University of Toronto Fall - Lecture 1 4 / 32 Textbook We are going to follow the textbook for the majority of the course Textbook: Macroeconomics, by Charles I. Jones, 5th edition University of Toronto Fall - Lecture 1 5 / 32 What are You Going to Learn (ch. 1) What are the important macroeconomics questions to be considered foundations of macroeconomic models and modeling the three-part structure of the text: I The long run I The short run I Issues for the future University of Toronto Fall - Lecture 1 6 / 32 Important Macroeconomic Questions to Consider Why is today’s average North American I more than 10 times richer than 100 years ago? I 50 times richer than the average Ethiopian? What could be the cause of high income inequality across the world and even within a single country? I Is it equitable that such a small percentage of people control such a large percent of the world’s wealth? Why has the unemployment rate in Europe been almost twice as high as it has been in the United States? University of Toronto Fall - Lecture 1 7 / 32 Important Macroeconomic Questions to Consider Do we understand and know the causes of the global financial crisis in 2007-2008 I Was it greedy banks lending money, irresponsible homeowners living beyond their means, or government institutions such as Freddie Mac and Fannie Mae? What are the causes of the recent rise in prices? What role do stock markets play in the economy? How did the 2008 Affordable Care Act impact the price of healthcare, economic growth, and government expenditures? some of these “macroeconomic” questions may overlap with research in other disciplines University of Toronto Fall - Lecture 1 8 / 32 GDP Per Capita GDP Per Capita represents the average income per individual in a country GDP per Capita is much higher in developed countries (Western Europe and Western Offshoots - North America + Australia, New Zealand) compared to the rest Meanwhile, Asia, Eastern Europe and Middle East experience an uptick in recent years É University of Toronto Fall - Lecture 1 9 / 32 Economic Growth Economists develop mathematical models to study these phenomena I For example, why do some countries grow faster than others? I To answer this question, we will use the Solow growth model and a model of endogenous growth I We are going explore these in the first half of the course University of Toronto Fall - Lecture 1 10 / 32 Inflation Rate in Certain Developed Countries The inflation rate is the percentage change in the price level – often measured using CPI University of Toronto Fall - Lecture 1 11 / 32 News on Inflation News on Inflation appear almost every weeks University of Toronto Fall - Lecture 1 12 / 32 What are the costs of inflation to society? rise to price Unexpected and symmetric inflation wagesincrease equal I Wages are simply the price of labor I Therefore, purchasing power of workers is unaffected, in this case, no one is worse off Unexpected and asymmetric inflation I Suppose wages increase less than the prices for goods and services I In this case, workers are worse off and relative price distortions emerge I Unexpected and uneven inflation is generally costly to society In a hypothetical scenario where wages instantly and perfectly adjusted to changes in prices (symmetric in ation), individuals might not experience the typical negative e ects of in ation on their real purchasing power. However, it's important to note that such a scenario is quite unrealistic, as wage adjustments are in uenced by various factors, including negotiation dynamics, market imperfections, and contractual agreements. In the real world, in ation can still a ect people even if wages adjust somewhat symmetrically to price changes. For example, there can be lags in wage adjustments, leading to temporary reductions in purchasing power. Additionally, not all wages and salaries may adjust at the same rate, so some individuals or groups could be disproportionately impacted by in ation. Moreover, other economic factors, such as interest rates, asset prices, and consumer expectations, can also be in uenced by in ation, a ecting people's overall nancial well-being. Therefore, while symmetric wage adjustments would mitigate some of the negative e ects of in ation, it wouldn't necessarily eliminate all its impacts on individuals and the economy. University of Toronto Fall - Lecture 1 13 / 32 What are the costs of inflation to society? Deflation I Deflation increases the real value of outstanding debt, this is harmful to borrowers and restricts access to credit F I Firm also earn less in dollar term but might hold same amount of debt Consumer form an expectation that the price would keep falling Sticky prices I Sticky prices are related to the asymmetric (uneven) inflation I If some prices do not adjust as quickly as others, there are resulting distortions and inefficiencies I Distortions are bad—see end of the lecture—Pareto efficiency and free markets I Sticky prices cause inflation to be costly University of Toronto Fall - Lecture 1 14 / 32 The Unemployment Rate in the United States, Europe, and Japan Unemployment rate are highly correlated with the business cycle Before 1980, unemployment rates in Europe were actually lower than in the United States, while Japan has remained low over this time frame University of Toronto Fall - Lecture 1 15 / 32 How Macroeconomics Studies Key Questions Macroeconomists have a general approach to study questions of interest: Document the facts I In recent years, more macroeconomists rely more and more on micro-data Develop a model I Models simplify the complicated real world into its most relevant elements F The goal of a model is not to perfectly replicate every single detail/feature of markets or behavior I A model is useful if it has good predictive power I Economic models often involve systems of multiple equations Compare predictions of the model with original facts Use the model to make other predictions that will eventually be tested University of Toronto Fall - Lecture 1 16 / 32 Parts of an Economic Model Parameter: An input that is fixed over time, except when the model builder changes it for an experiment I Minimum we assume not to change; can be changed by the model builder as an experiment. Exogenous variable: An input that can change over time, but determined ahead of time by the model builder I Exogenous = “outside of the model” I Can change over time but determined outside of the model. Endogenous variable: An outcome of the model—something that is explained by the model I Endogenous = “within the model” I Determined by factors plugged into our model. University of Toronto Fall - Lecture 1 17 / 32 Parts of an Economic Model variable exogenous For example, a linear model Y = University of Toronto 0 + 1 X1 Fall - Lecture 1 + 2 X2 18 / 32 Suppose We Have a Working Model. . . How can we use it? I Models are built using existing data, but can be used to predict events and outcomes for which we do not have data yet – set up a counterfactual “what if” situation I Change parameters and exogenous variables to see how they affect endogenous variables I Predict costs and benefits of new government policies – a change in parameter that mimic the policy I All models can make inaccurate predictions, so we should always interpret the results with caution University of Toronto Fall - Lecture 1 19 / 32 Model Example: Labor supply and demand Variables: I Ls = number of hours laborers want to work I LD = number of labor hours firms want to hire I w = wage no exogenous variables Parameter: f̄ , l̄, ā University of Toronto Fall - Lecture 1 20 / 32 Model Example: Labor supply and demand of puppy Supply Function: a Ls = f (w) = āw + l̄ = 2w + 30 Demand Function: Ld = g(w) = f̄ w = 60 ouv of lah Equilibrium: demand Ld = Ls University of Toronto w it aage i Fall - Lecture 1 21 / 32 Model Example: Labor supply and demand Consider a case of an increase in income taxes Firm would still pays a wage of w, but worker receives only a wage of (1 t)w For any given wage, the worker gets to keep less of his wage so he supplies less 0 0 labor. In equilibrium, we move from (w ⇤ , L⇤ ) to (w ⇤ , L⇤ ) University of Toronto Fall - Lecture 1 22 / 32 Model Example: Labor supply and demand Consider a case of an increase in an input price As production costs increase for firms, their demand for labor decreases. It lead to a leftward shift in Ld 0 0 The equilibrium move from (w ⇤ , L⇤ ) to (w ⇤ , L⇤ ) University of Toronto Fall - Lecture 1 23 / 32 Theoretical and Empirical Approach They rely on each other to solidify the validity of analyses Most mainstream theoretical methods are motivated by empirical work, theoretical models typically try to explain some important feature of the data Empirical macroeconomics needs theoretical macroeconomics to establish causation I Suppose the data show that when interest rates decrease, taxes usually go down I It might be tempting to conclude that reduced interest rates lead to decreased taxes. However, this can go the other way around I Or, there is likely omitted variable bias here, which implies that a third variable is causing the changes in both interest rates and taxes I For instance, poor macroeconomic conditions probably result in the central bank decreasing interest rates and the government cutting taxes Empirical work can never establish causality with 100 percent probability. But, when it is supported by theory, a causal relationship is more convincing University of Toronto Fall - Lecture 1 24 / 32 An Overview of the Course Microeconomics also has many subfields and a lot of them are overlapped with macroeconomics University of Toronto Fall - Lecture 1 25 / 32 The Long Run Income per person in the United States: I $2,800 in 1870 I $44,000 in 2008 As seen earlier, many countries have not experienced similar increases in living standards The analysis of economic growth helps explain the long run University of Toronto Fall - Lecture 1 26 / 32 Per Capita GDP in the United States, 1870–2015 Overall growth is upward Short-run fluctuations can cause peaks and troughs It encourages us to ask, Will there ever be a long-run peak? Can we grow forever? What does the future hold? University of Toronto Fall - Lecture 1 27 / 32 The Short Run Potential output (Yp ): Measure of how per capita GDP would evolve with completely flexible prices and fully employed resources Short-run fluctuations are often defined as deviations of actual output (Y) from its potential level I When Y > Yp , this is an expansion I When Y < Yp , this is a recession In 1982, actual output was 5 percent less than potential output, which is economically important I In today’s prices, the gap was roughly $1,500 per person ($6,000 for a typical family of 4) I This recession represented a large cost in terms of lost income Recessions are costly and cause devastation in the short run but are overcome by long-run trends University of Toronto Fall - Lecture 1 28 / 32 Welfare Welfare: Variable used to determine preferable policies and rank outcomes Measuring welfare is highly subjective I More GDP (consumption) increases welfare Are there variables other than GDP that we should consider? I Leisure I Equality I Life expectancy I Environmental quality I Individual freedom Often, policymakers use increasing GDP as a benchmark for standards of living and welfare University of Toronto Fall - Lecture 1 29 / 32 Pareto Efficiency and Free Markets How do efficiency can be measure in term of welfare? Pareto efficiency is reached when you cannot make someone else better off without making another worse off maximising bothconsumerand surplus prove The fundamental theorem of welfare economics (a version of Adam Smith’s invisible hand) states if there is a competitive market for everything, then equilibrium will be Pareto efficient However, if complete and competitive markets do not exist there is no reason to believe that equilibrium will be Pareto efficient Deviations: I Market power I Externalities I Public goods I Asymmetric (imperfect) information University of Toronto 7 Market failure Fall - Lecture 1 30 / 32 Why do economists disagree? Nature of market failures (magnitude) Theory of complete and competitive markets breaks down Which Pareto efficient outcome is best? University of Toronto Fall - Lecture 1 31 / 32 Next Lecture Next lecture will cover Ch.2 University of Toronto Fall - Lecture 1 32 / 32