Macroeconomics and the Global Economic Environment International Trade and Financial Flows Professor Tim Landvoigt TRADE IN THE DATA 2 1/1/2020 1/1/2018 1/1/2016 1/1/2014 1/1/2012 1/1/2010 1/1/2008 1/1/2006 1/1/2004 1/1/2002 1/1/2000 1/1/1998 1/1/1996 1/1/1994 1/1/1992 1/1/1990 1/1/1988 1/1/1986 1/1/1984 1/1/1982 1/1/1980 1/1/1978 1/1/1976 1/1/1974 1/1/1972 1/1/1970 Global Trade as % of World GDP 65 60 55 50 45 40 35 30 25 20 Source: World Bank, OECD 3 Exports and Imports for U.S. 4 Index of Openness (imports plus exports as percent of GDP) 120 100 80 1990 60 2000 40 2010 20 2015 0 5 WHY DO COUNTRIES TRADE? 6 Why does anyone trade? • Two important theories for the benefits / motives for trade 1. Specialization – Is at the heart of any modern economy. Without specialization, TFP would be abysmal – Much trade between developed economies is in intermediate, not final, goods – Intra-industry trade as extreme form of specialization in widgets and gadgets 2. Variety – Why does Germany import Korean cars and Korea import German cars? – Clearly, this is not specialization, but taste for variety of the modern consumer • Important lesson: international trade is really no different from trade within a country. 7 Specialization and comparative advantage • Trade allows us (countries) to specialize in what we are good at. – What does Lionel Messi do when he plays professional soccer? – He trades in his amazing abilities on the pitch for money. Then he uses the money to buy food, clothes, cars, mansions, yachts, … – Without trade, Lionel would live “off the grid” on a farm, make his own food, build his own cars, perform his own dental surgery, … • Specialization brings gains from trade even if someone (a country) is better at everything because it allows us (countries) to focus resources on what we are relatively good at. – This is the notion of comparative advantage. – Allows most efficient use of resources. • International trade – by increasing overall production – can be viewed as a better technology to combine capital and labor into output. 8 Comparative advantage – an example • Two regions – North and South – produce apples and computers. – Note: North is better at producing both goods; i.e. it has an absolute advantage. • Each region prefers to spend half of its income on apples and half if its income on computers. 9 Outcome under no trade (“Autarky”) • Suppose that each worker supplies one unit of labor so that the wage π€π€ is the worker’s income. • Workers want to spend half the income on apples and half on computers. We have: Let’s normalize the price of apples to 1. So the price of computers, p, denotes the cost of a computer in numbers of apples. 10 • Computers are relatively cheap in the North – i.e. the North has a comparative advantage in producing computers. Similarly, South has comparative advantage in apples. • If there was free trade, this would represent an arbitrage opportunity. 11 How to compute free trade solution? 1. Figure out comparative advantage – North has comp.adv. in computers, because computers cheaper there 2. Compute each region’s output under full specialization – South only makes apples, North only makes computers 3. Calculate wage in each country and world market prices of both goods – There is no money in the model, so one good functions as numeraire – let’s use apples 4. Compute how much of each good a worker in each region consumes • Details are in appendix slides and chapter 19.4 in Jones textbook • Spreadsheet with example on Canvas that allows you to play around with numbers 12 Autarky: 80 Autarky: 1 • By specializing, global supply of apples and computers increases and both regions are better off. • Trade occurs even though the North has an absolute advantage in both apples and computer production. 13 Is international trade a good thing? • Gains from trade – Specialization and comparative advantage – Trade, in addition, often brings new technologies • Costs from trade – Relatively unskilled workers in high-productivity countries may lose their jobs and retraining / relocation is difficult and costly – Specialization can lock low-productivity countries into poverty trap • Big issue: how to share gains from trade. 14 Who are the winners and losers of globalization? • Winners – Consumers – as trade increases overall productivity, consumers can afford more goods and services with a given income. – Workers in industries in which the country has a comparative advantage. – Workers in regions of the country benefitting from trade. • Losers – Workers in industries in which the country does not have a comparative advantage. – Workers in regions of the country not benefitting from trade. • These effects are not particular to globalization but apply to increased automation as well. 15 Manufacturing Employment and Globalization 16 Manufacturing Employment and Globalization • Manufacturing employment declined by about 6 million from 2000 to 2010. – Between 10 and 35% of this decline is estimated to be due to increased import competition after China’s accession to WTO in 2000. – This estimate does not take into account positive employment effects of the U.S. having access to cheaper manufacturing goods. • At the same time, manufacturing output increased substantially, due to a large increase in labor productivity – Manufacturing sector mostly shed low-productivity / low-skill jobs. – High-skill / high productivity jobs have become more productive due to better technology and imports of cheaper intermediates. ⇒ The manufacturing sector as a whole is not a loser of globalization but lower-skill workers are; and much of the employment losses are not directly due to globalization but increased automation. 17 Trade for Variety • Not all trade is well characterized by comparative advantage • Recall my initial example: South Korea imports some German cars and Germany imports South Korean cars • Lots of trade especially between advanced countries best understood as consumers’ desire to have a large set of product choices • Little downside to this kind of trade 18 NATIONAL INCOME ACCOUNTING WITH NET EXPORTS 19 Savings, investment and net exports • National income accounting revisited Y = C + I + G + (X − M ) (ππ − πΆπΆ − πΊπΊ) + (ππ − ππ) = πΌπΌ Domestic savings πΊπΊ Foreign savings NX = ( X − M ) = S − I Net exports= Trade balance Net capital outflow • If a country saves more than it invests domestically, its citizens invest some of their savings abroad • Then simple accounting implies the country is a net exporter • Let’s take a look at the data and the official statistics 20 Current Account and Financial Account • Current Account (CA) measures – Trade in goods and services: exports (+) and imports (-) – Direct factor payments • corporate profits, dividends • salaries, other labor compensation • Financial Account (FA) measures – Acquisition (+) of foreign financial assets by U.S. based entities – Incurrence (-) of financial liabilities of U.S. based entities with foreign creditor • Accounting identity: CA = FA – Recall our simplified model: NX = S - I 21 International trade transactions settlement • Trade implies payments • Example: U.S. car dealership imports car from abroad. Price of car is $50k • Consider two scenarios: 1. Transaction settled in kind: car dealer not only imports foreign cars, but also exports U.S. cars. Pays for import of foreign car through equivalent-value export of domestic car. Import and export offset each other, no net impact on CA or FA. 2. Transaction settled in dollars: foreign car manufacturer maintains U.S. dollar account at U.S. bank. Gains 50k dollars, a liability of the U.S. bank. CA declines by 50k, and FA declines 50k. • By the way, if you are not a U.S. resident, then I am exporting educational services to you right now 22 Financial Transactions • Financial Account Loss (FAL) occurs when a foreign entity gains ownership of U.S. assets or a U.S. entity loses ownership of foreign asset. Examples: – A foreigner buys U.S. stocks ο¨ foreigner gains U.S. asset – An American tourists spends foreign currency while on vacation ο¨ U.S. entity loses foreign asset (NOTE: when you vacation abroad that counts as an “import”) • Financial Account Gain (FAG) occurs when a U.S. entity gains ownership of foreign assets or foreign entity loses ownership of U.S. asset. Examples – U.S. corporation sets up factory abroad ο¨ U.S. entity gains foreign asset – Foreign tourist spends dollars while vacationing in U.S. ο¨ foreigner loses U.S. asset (NOTE: when a foreigner vacations here that’s an “export”) 23 Currency Exchange And Other Financial Transactions • Currency exchange is neutral for financial account • Example: U.S. bank uses U.S. dollars to buy Yen from Japanese bank • Japanese bank gains U.S. dollars: FAL • U.S. bank gains Yen: FAG • These transactions perfectly cancel in Financial Account • Many other examples of purely financial transactions that balance out within Financial Account 24 Summary: Four Possibilities • Thinking about cross border transactions can be confusing • Big picture: there can be 4 types of transactions 1. Purely non-financial: export and import of equal value offset each other ο¨ no effect on CA or FA – Example: “pay” for import of car with export of equivalent-value car 2. Purely financial: FAG and FAL offset each other ο¨ no effect on CA or FA – Example: currency exchange 3. Export: receive financial asset from foreigner as payment for export ο¨ CA up, FA up – Example: export car and grant trade credit (accounts receivable) ο¨ Export + FAG 4. Import: pay for import by giving financial asset to foreigner ο¨ CA down, FA down – Example: import car and incur trade credit (accounts payable) ο¨ Import + FAL 25 Line 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 Current Account from bea.gov Current account (millions of USD) Exports of goods and services and income receipts (credits) $ Exports of goods and services $ Goods $ Secondary income: receipts and Services $ Primary income receipts remittances of earnings across border$ Investment income $ Compensation of employees $ Secondary income (current transfer) receipts /1/ $ Imports of goods and services and income payments (debits) $ Imports of goods and services $ Goods $ Services $ Primary income payments $ Investment income $ Compensation of employees $ Secondary income (current transfer) payments /1/ $ 2021 3,780,154.00 2,556,638.00 1,761,364.00 795,273.00 1,052,080.00 1,045,181.00 6,899.00 171,436.00 4,626,508.00 3,401,685.00 2,851,660.00 550,025.00 912,587.00 895,030.00 17,557.00 312,236.00 26 When confused about the terminology, remind yourself of this definition 19 Financial account (millions of USD) Net U.S. acquisition of financial assets excluding financial derivatives (net increase in assets / financial outflow (+)) $ 1,278,599.00 20 Direct investment assets $ 421,749.00 21 Portfolio investment assets $ 719,095.00 22 Other investment assets $ 23,763.00 $ 113,993.00 $ 1,977,294.00 23 24 Reserve assets Net U.S. incurrence of liabilities excluding financial derivatives (net increase in liabilities / financial inflow (+)) 25 Direct investment liabilities $ 448,325.00 26 Portfolio investment liabilities $ 676,112.00 27 Other investment liabilities $ 852,857.00 $ (41,902.00) 28 Financial derivatives other than reserves, net transactions /2/ 27 How CA and FA net out … or not Statistical discrepancy 29 Statistical discrepancy /3/ Balances 30 31 Balance on current account (line 1 less line 9) /4/ Balance on goods and services (line 2 less line 10) If we had properly recorded all transactions, these would be equal, but some slippage in reality “Trade deficit” $ 108,231.00 $ (846,354.00) $ (845,047.00) 32 Balance on goods (line 3 less line 11) $ (1,090,296.00) 33 Balance on services (line 4 less line 12) $ 245,248.00 34 Balance on primary income (line 5 less line 13) $ 139,493.00 35 Balance on secondary income (line 8 less line 16) $ (140,800.00) Balance on capital account (line 17 less line 18) /4/ $ Net lending (+) or net borrowing (-) from current- and capital-account transactions (line 30 plus line 36) /5/ $ Net lending (+) or net borrowing (-) from financial-account transactions (line 19 less line 24 plus line 28) /5/ $ “Net borrowing” (2,474.00) 36 37 38 (848,828.00) (740,597.00) 28 US Net Debt Position Relative to GDP The large trade deficits of recent decades have made the U.S. a net debtor to the rest of the world. The net debt exceeded 70 percent of GDP in 2021. 29 Is a persistent trade deficit a problem? • As with any borrowing, the net debt has to repaid at some point and it implies interest payments. • Warren Buffet (2005) “As time passes, and as claims against us grow, we own less and less of what we produce. …Should we continue to run current account deficits comparable to those now prevailing,…our U.S. ‘family’ will be delivering [a substantial fraction of] its annual output to the rest of the world simply as a tribute for the overindulgences of the past.” • Yet, so far, net income on foreign assets has been positive! – How can that be? • Under what circumstances does a negative net foreign asset position become a problem? 30 Back to our simplified model • National income accounting revisited ππ = πΆπΆ + πΌπΌ + πΊπΊ + ππ − ππ (ππ − πΆπΆ − πΊπΊ) + (ππ − ππ) = πΌπΌ Domestic savings πΊπΊ Foreign savings Current Account = Trade Surplus Financial Account = Net Lending ππ − ππ = ππ − πΌπΌ 31 PRACTICE QUESTIONS 32 Q1 Labor Force Fish Production per Person Chip Production per Person West 100 200 kilos 100 kilos East 400 60 kilos 20 kilos Which of the following statements is true? A. The West has an absolute advantage in the production of both fish and chips and has a comparative advantage in the production of chips. B. The East has an absolute advantage in the production of both fish and chips and has a comparative advantage in the production of fish. C. The West has an absolute advantage in the production of chips and the East has an absolute advantage in the production of fish. D. The East has a comparative advantage in chip production and the West has a comparative advantage in the production of fish. 33 Q2 If a U.S. firm buys machines from a Japanese firm and the Japanese firm uses the dollars it gets to buy French stocks, the U.S. current account ________ and the Japanese financial account ________. A. Falls; falls B. Rises; rises C. Falls; rises D. Rises; falls 34 APPENDIX 35 Autarky Solution • Steps for North (same for South): 1. Quote all numbers in units of apples (price of apple normalized to 1) 2. Wage equal to number of apples a worker can produce: π€π€ππ = 160 apples (wage = MPL !) 160 = 10 apples (why?) 3. Price of computer ππππ = 16 4. Consumption of apples ππππ,π΄π΄ = π€π€ππ 2 5. Consumption of computers ππππ,πΆπΆ = = 80 π€π€ππ /ππππ 2 =8 36 Free Trade Solution (1/4) • First determine comparative advantage: what is the ratio of apples/computers that can be produced? • North: 10, South: 50 → South has comparative advantage for apples • That means that North must have comparative advantage for computers! (note: by definition, it is impossible to have the comparative advantage for both goods) 37 Free Trade Solution (2/4) • World production: π΄π΄ = 400 × 100 = 40,000, πΆπΆ = 100 × 16 = 1,600 • Key step: what is the world price of computers? • World price of computers: ππ = 40,000 1,600 = 25 apples • Can verify that at this price world markets clear • Intuition see next slide 38 Free Trade Solution (3/4) • World price of computers: ππ = 40,000 1,600 = 25 apples • Wage equal to revenue per worker (=MPL): • π€π€ππ = 25 ππππππππππππ ππππππππππππππππ × 16 ππππππππππππππππππ = 400 apples • π€π€ππ = 100 apples • Why do markets clear? At price of 25, North workers can trade in half of their production of computers for apples, and apple market exactly clears • If price of computers was >25, there would “too much income” relative to supply of apples: excess demand, apple price rises (=computer price drops) 39 Free Trade Solution (4/4) • Consumption North • ππππ,π΄π΄ = • ππππ,πΆπΆ = • South: • ππππ,π΄π΄ = • ππππ,πΆπΆ = π€π€ππ 2 π€π€ππ 2 ππ π€π€ππ 2 π€π€ππ 2 ππ = = = = 400 = 200 2 400 =8 2×25 100 = 50 2 100 =2 2×25 Does the world market for both goods clear? • Computers: 8 x 100 + 2 x 400 = 1,600 • Apples: 200 x 100 + 50 x 400 = 40,000 40