Public policy influence on renewable energy investments – a longitudinal study across OECD countries This version: June 2014 Friedemann Polzin*1,2, Michael Migendt1, Florian A. Täube1 & Paschen von Flotow2 Abstract: This paper examines the impact of public policy measures on renewable energy (RE) diffusion through corresponding investments in electricity-generating capacity made by institutional investors (i.e. investment/pension funds, banks and insurance companies). Capacity investment data is gathered from Bloomberg New Energy Finance (BNEF) and policy indicators from the IEA/IRENA Policy and Measures Database. The authors observe the influence of different policy measures on a sample of OECD countries during an 12-year period (2000-2011) to suggest an effective policy mix which could tackle existing path dependencies and failures in the market for clean energy. The results call for technology-specific policies which take into account actual market conditions and the position in the technology life cycle. To improve the environment for institutional investments, advisable policy instruments include economic/fiscal incentives such as feed-in tariffs (FIT) with grants and subsidies being less effective. Additionally market-based instruments such as greenhouse gas emission trading systems for mature technologies should be included. These policy measures directly impact the risk and return structure of RE projects. Supplementing these with regulatory measures such as codes and standards (e.g. RPS), and long term strategic planning could further strengthen the environment for RE investments. Keywords: renewable energy, public policy mix, institutional investors, longitudinal analysis JEL codes: G28, O33, O38, Q42, Q48 *Corresponding author: polzin@sbi21.de 1 EBS Business School, Strascheg Institute for Innovation and Entrepreneurship (SIIE), Rheingaustr. 1, 65375 Oestrich-Winkel, Germany 2 Sustainable Business Institute (SBI), Burgstr. 4, 65375 Oestrich-Winkel, Germany 1 Electroniccopy copy available available at: Electronic at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 1 Introduction Climate change has been aggravating in recent years as CO2 emissions continue to grow in developed and developing countries alike (IPCC, 2014). OECD countries have a larger responsibility to address these issues, as they accounted for almost 50% of the global carbon emissions in 2010, most of which were linked to the energy sector (BNEF, 2013; Müller et al., 2011; OECD, 2013) While developed countries bear a historically larger responsibility to address climate change issues, it is now clear that transitioning towards a low-carbon society will involve decoupling economic growth and prosperity from growing CO2 emissions, respectively encouraging “green growth”. One possibility is to increase the share of energy (especially electrical energy) generated by renewable energy (RE) sources (Foxon and Pearson, 2007; Jefferson, 2008) Investments in clean energy1 companies, projects and infrastructure have been growing in the last decade and total up to a relevant amount. Remarkable investment markets have been created based on RE technologies (Figure 1). Yet the volumes are still relatively small when compared to investments in conventional fossil fuel-based power (BNEF, 2013). Figure 1 here This is partially due to the challenge which the diffusion of RE technology presents (Friebe et al., 2014, 2013; Veugelers, 2011). Market failures occur related to inherent characteristics of the energy sector (designed for fossil fuels-based power plants) on the one hand, as well as the particular nature of RE technologies on the other (Helm, 2002). Long payback periods and illiquid assets coupled with high regulatory dependencies and corresponding uncertainties often make RE unattractive or even unsuitable for investors. While this holds true even for mature technologies and conventional power plants, REs still face some technological uncertainty (Kenney and Hargadon, 2012). To mitigate market failures and compensate for technological and economic weaknesses, policy makers were historically confronted with a variety of options to stimulate diffusion and “green growth” while de-linking it from CO2 emissions. This article attempts to uncover the effects of different policies to support clean energy applications in the future. It adds to recent academic and political discussions about the choice among feed-in tariffs (FITs) and 1 Throughout this paper, we will use renewable energy (RE) and clean energy interchangeably. 2 Electroniccopy copy available available at: Electronic at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 alternative mechanisms as well as the corresponding overall effectiveness and efficiency of these policy instruments (Carley, 2009; Lesser and Su, 2008; Mathews et al., 2010). Building on previous work on RE investor behavior (Bergek et al., 2013; Wüstenhagen and Menichetti, 2012), it investigates the influence of public policies on subsequent RE investments by institutional investors across OECD countries over a time period of 12 years (2000-2011). The overarching research question therefore is: Which policies have proven (most) conducive to investments in renewable energy assets? The remainder of this paper is structured as follows: Section two briefly describes the conceptual motivation. Section three introduces the analytical method and data used. Section four depicts the results while section five presents the discussion, conclusion, limitations and next steps in the research process. 2 Conceptual background 2.1. Clean energy innovation and diffusion RE technologies are a prime example of issues associated with commercialization and diffusion of innovations. Innovative technologies face difficulties from the moment they are introduced to markets, as their potential and quality cannot be evaluated ex-ante (Arrow, 1962; Jaffe et al., 2005). These difficulties lead to market or system failures which provide grounds for policy intervention (Dodgson et al., 2011; Martin and Scott, 2000). In addition, other externalities, such as path-dependencies and external costs (i.e. for CO2 emissions), occur. Path dependencies are particularly high in heavily regulated sectors such as energy, and need special attention from the responsible policy makers (Brown, 2001; Mowery et al., 2010; Sandén and Azar, 2005). Hence, a multitude of short-term instruments need to be found for long-term climate targets, which according to Sandén and Azar (2005) range from R&D support to technology-specific subsidies and niche market creation. Historically, mitigation policies that target the early stage (i.e. generation phase) have been deployed (CárdenasRodríguez et al., 2013; Veugelers, 2012, 2011). In later stages (i.e. diffusion phase) the distinct features of RE are subject to severe market failures due to high path dependency in fossil fuels (Müller et al., 2011; Popp et al., 2011). Here, policy support is limited so other regulatory measures to stimulate markets need to be established, even though diffusion and application of RE technologies is socially and politically desirable (Jefferson, 2008). In addition, the highly regulated environment for 3 Electroniccopy copy available available at: Electronic at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 diffusion of mature RE might require new forms of regulation compared to the commercialization of RE in order to overcome market failures and dissolve path dependencies. Literature on energy policy has analyzed these relationships in a number of different ways, generating evidence for policy makers to support their decisions (Jacobsson et al., 2009). Fundamental questions such as influence of price or quantity-based mechanisms have been addressed (Menanteau et al., 2003). Scholars argue that in the sense of carbon and energy market liberalization, preference should be given to market-based instruments as first best solutions, e.g. carbon cap and trading systems (Helm, 2002; Rogge and Hoffmann, 2010; Rogge et al., 2011; Smith and Swierzbinski, 2007). However in the absence of global carbon markets and their inability to address incubation efforts (e.g. rapid development) and costefficiency, second-best policy instruments need to be considered (Jacobsson et al., 2009). Within the range of policy choices, evidence points towards the superiority of FIT (Butler and Neuhoff, 2008; Couture and Gagnon, 2010; Jenner et al., 2013; Lesser and Su, 2008) over quota and obligation schemes (Butler and Neuhoff, 2008), renewable portfolio standards (RPS) (Delmas and Montes-Sancho, 2011; Carley, 2009) and tax-based incentives (Cansino et al., 2010; Quirion, 2010). One solution to address the problems encountered so far, apparently, is a ‘policy mix’ consisting of complementary instruments. However, there is no scholarly consensus on what the optimal policy mix could look like (Foxon and Pearson, 2007) or on which criteria should be applied to determine it (Carley, 2009). Relatedly, the question arises, if there is one optimal policy mix or several ones, contingent on different other factors? 2.2. Investor perspective on RE and public policy In an attempt to answer these questions, scholars investigated the implications for private sector investment of policy instrument usage (Bergek et al., 2013; Delmas and MontesSancho, 2011; Masini and Menichetti, 2012; Wüstenhagen and Menichetti, 2012), given that private finance mobilization is regarded a core component of strategies to foster development of clean technologies and their complementary infrastructure (Mathews et al., 2010; Mowery et al., 2010). Mathews et al. (2010, p. 3263) note that “the issue of public vs. private financing is not yet adequately explored”, but add that there is consensus among policy makers that the transition to a low carbon economy will not happen without the involvement of private institutional investors. Investments by institutional investors are typically hindered by a number of factors; high upfront costs, risks and uncertainty regarding long-term viability of the technology, long 4 Electroniccopy copy available available at: Electronic at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 payback periods, high regulatory and infrastructural dependency as well as public acceptance (Cárdenas-Rodríguez et al., 2013; Haley and Schuler, 2011; Kenney and Hargadon, 2012; Müller et al., 2011). These factors directly influence the risk/return profile of an RE investment, which is a major determinant for institutional investors. To mitigate the economic barriers, de Río and Bleda (2012) underline the superiority of feedin tariffs to spur deployment and technological diversity and lower risks associated with RE technologies. They argue that a variety of policies, consisting of technology-specific and technology-neutral measures (“systemic package” – knowledge generation and diffusion) is needed to not only enhance deployment of mature technologies but also the subsequent creation of new technologies. Bergek et al. (2013) consider the evaluation criteria used by the heterogeneous group of RE investors, such as (overall or portfolio) cost, perceived (market) uncertainty and political risk. They argue that purely economic analyses (i.e. focusing on risk and return) fall short of capturing the wide range of factors influencing the decisions and processes for investing into RE technologies, with one being the reaction to different policy instruments. CárdenasRodríguez et al. (2013) distinguish between instruments that directly depend on public budgets (e.g. tax incentives or grants and subsidies), support measures oriented towards mitigating the externalities (regulations) and price-based systems (FIT). The ultimate requirement for a sustainable RE policy is a reduction of capital costs to create a level playing field with fossil fuel-based technologies which have been heavily subsidized in the past (Szabó and Jäger-Waldau, 2008). Thus a monitoring of these costs is crucial. Szabó & Jäger-Waldau (2008) suggest a more competitive financial environment could actually reduce the costs of capital for RE projects, given that capital markets function efficiently. Decreasing support to encourage technological improvements as well as tradability of RE certificates might further spur the deployment of renewables. Above all policy instruments that influence the risk and return structure of RE projects impact investor behavior (CárdenasRodríguez et al., 2013). In addition, investment decisions can be related to policy instruments that do not directly impact the risk and return structure of RE projects. For example, the perception of investment opportunities and preference for short term or long-term incentives, also influence the decision to invest (Masini and Menichetti, 2012). In this respect, Wüstenhagen & Menichetti (2012, p. 9) specifically call for investigating the role of policy on the perception of institutional investors: “[…] how can policy build on this knowledge to devise more effective 5 Electroniccopy copy available available at: Electronic at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 regulatory frameworks in an evolutionary and boundedly rational world? What is, for example, the relative importance of ‘‘symbolic’’ policies compared to the actual monetary value of incentives?” Thus policy measures that do not directly impact the risk and return structure of RE projects but influence investor behavior indirectly need to be considered as well. In sum, the literature has been searching for an integral overview of sustainable energy to spur RE diffusion by private investments. In order to contribute to this debate, our research aims at uncovering the effectiveness of different policy instruments to induce private finance in RE assets. 3 Methods and data 3.1. Research design Investigating the diffusion of a particular technology and corresponding investments requires a longitudinal research design (Angrist and Pischke, 2008; Hair, 2010). Major works in the field of energy policy have been of a qualitative nature, presenting in-depth evidence from case studies in a small number of countries. On the other hand, energy economists apply sophisticated econometric methods, mostly panel data regressions (e.g. Cárdenas-Rodríguez et al., 2013; Jenner et al., 2013 for FIT; Johnstone et al., 2010; Popp et al., 2011). Most quantitative studies have been carried out in the EU (e.g. Marques and Fuinhas, 2012a) with a few comparing OECD or BRIC countries (Cárdenas-Rodríguez et al., 2013; Johnstone et al., 2010; Popp et al., 2011). To provide more generalizable results we cover a variety of countries, thus conducting a panel regression. We use the time period from 2000 to 2011 to explain the influence of policy instruments on the diffusion of clean energy technologies. This time frame is chosen because it covers substantial developments in the worldwide renewable energy sector. Globally the wind sector grew from 18 GW installed capacity in 2000 to 238 GW installed capacity in 2011, while the solar sector grew from 1.5 GW installed capacity in 2000 to 67 GW installed capacity in 2011 (IEA, 2014). As policy instruments do not exhibit an immediate effect on technology application, we add a lag procedure (Wooldridge et al., 2009). Our descriptive analysis of the data reveals a strong relationship between the use of RE policy and investments in RE projects by institutional investors. Initial case studies of Italy and the UK show, on one hand, the high dependency of investments on regulation and on the other hand, a time-dependent phenomenon, i.e. investments lagging behind policy measures. Figure 2&3 here 6 Electroniccopy copy available available at: Electronic at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 Italy has favorable conditions for solar energy generation. Thus it is one of the earlier adopters of solar energy and has built up a sizable amount of capacity. This growth is supported by a policy mix targeted at the solar sector. The first policies targeting the solar sector were established in the year 2000. The “Renewable Electricity support - PV Roofs Programme” classified as a regulatory instrument and promoted the installation of solar PV, thereby liberalizing electricity production from small solar PV installations. According to the decree from the Ministry of Environment, the sale price of excess power to the grid was set equal to the purchase price from the grid, independent of time and season. The next bigger step in supporting the market was the “Feed-In Premium for photovoltaic systems” established in the year 2005. This financial incentive, which is still in force today (albeit after several alterations), initiated the rapid expansion of solar investments in the year 2006 and following. This FIT policy included a set of tariffs, valid for a period of 20 years. Electricity producers got a fixed price premium in addition to the price of the electricity sold. Further policies introduced in 2007 and 2008 spurred the investments into solar even further. The United Kingdom has similar positive natural conditions for the wind sector. The first measure implemented to foster wind energy was the “Offshore Wind Capital Grants Scheme”, set up in 2002. This grants scheme was implemented to stimulate early deployment of offshore wind through direct support, and the grants could cover up to 40% of the eligible project costs. The “Energy Act of 2004”, a regulatory instrument, awarded licenses for wind farm sites in designated Renewable Energy Zones. The “Climate Change and Sustainable Energy Act” of 2006 further enriched the regulatory landscape by reporting on greenhouse gas emissions and actions taken to reduce them. In 2010, a “Feed-in Tariffs for Renewable Electricity” was added, which mandated additional payments for renewable energy fed into the grid or consumed on-site. This FIT varies according to technology and project size and covers 20 years of electricity production. We observe a growing trend of more policies over the years. These policies are lagged by investments until a sudden drop of active policies as well as investments in 2010 and further decreasing investments in 2011. This drop is also likely related to the financial crisis from 2008 and later. 3.2. Data Data was collected from two independent data sources. Investments in RE capacity have been drawn from Bloomberg New Energy Finance (BNEF), which possesses one of the most comprehensive databases in the field of clean technology financing (Cárdenas-Rodríguez et 7 Electroniccopy copy available available at: Electronic at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 al., 2013). It contains information on installed electricity generating capacity, date, transaction type, financing type, equity and debt during the years 2003-2012. The database includes 5840 Solar Investments, 9643 Wind Investments and 2889 Biomass & Waste Investments. These three RE subsectors account for 72% of the RE investments and with 74 GW installed for 75% of all capacity additions in the period, have therefore been selected for further analysis. Policy indicators were drawn from the IEA/IRENA Policy and Measures Database with other data sources2 consulted to check the robustness of the descriptions3. These indicators have been used by scholars to analyze the evolution and clustering (Nicolli and Vona, 2012; Vona et al., 2012) as well as the impacts of aggregated policy instruments in Europe (CárdenasRodríguez et al., 2013; Marques and Fuinhas, 2012a, 2012b). A priori we included all indicators ‘Economic Instruments’, ‘Information and Education’, ‘Policy Support’, ‘Regulatory Instruments’, ‘Research, Development and Deployment (RD&D)’ as well as ‘Voluntary Approaches’. The aggregation procedures resulted in 7835 policy data points resulting from 957 distinct policy measures (see appendix for a detailed description of the indicators). This allows comparing the experience of many countries and decomposing the effect of distinct factors econometrically (Cárdenas-Rodríguez et al., 2013). We structured the data according to sectors (i.e. Multiple RE sources, Wind, Solar, Biomass) and applied additional data processing: First, we limited the timeframe for IEA policy measures to 2000-2011. BNEF investment data is available from 2003. This approach permitted us to include the lag structure (i.e. investments lagging behind policy measures). We further decided not to include the year 2012, as data quality did not meet the standards of previous years. This is due to the fact that BNEF staff continuously updates investments even for the previous year. We removed cases with missing values and included only completed deals. Second, regarding the selection of cases (i.e. countries), our interest in the influence of policy measures meant the exclusion of countries with less than three consecutive years of investor activities (DV). The case-selection is carried out for each sector we analyze (see section 3.3. for the procedure and the Table A.1 appendix for a list of excluded countries). The selection of policy instruments to be included in the model is described in section 3.3.2. 2 3 REN21, DSIRE, OpenEI, Clean Energy Sources The timeframe here included the years 1990 to 2012. 8 Electroniccopy copy available available at: Electronic at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 3.3. Model We investigate the influence of different policy measures on subsequent investments into RE capacity by institutional investors. The components of this model are explained in Figure 4. The model set up permits, depending on the sector, to estimate from 176-435 parameters (i.e. coefficients for the different policy instruments). The included variables are log-transformed to correct for the skewed distribution of both dependent and independent variables (Hair, 2010). Figure 4 here 3.3.1. Dependent variable The dependent variable for the overall model is measured as aggregated installed capacity (in MW) in a certain country and year in a specific subsector (e.g. solar, wind, biomass). We use capacity indicators since they represent the most accurate proxy for the deployment of a technology (Popp et al., 2011). This variable is constructed by aggregating the newly installed electricity generating capacity of all projects financed by institutional investors per year and country. 3.3.2. Independent variables The main independent variables are constructed using distinct policies (regulatory instruments, grants, …) which are active per country per year. These are measured by the number of active instances regulating the RE sector (Johnstone et al., 2010; Marques and Fuinhas, 2012a). We can further distinguish between technology specific instruments (e.g. specific targets for certain energy source) and instruments that apply to all types of renewable energy (e.g. German FIT). The scheme is taken from the IEA Policies and Measures database 4 and included in the appendix. This database provides relevant information on characteristics (Title, country, year (started and ended), Policy Status (e.g. in force, ended, superseded), policy type (see policy scheme), policy target (e.g. subsector such as solar, wind, etc.), geographical scope (Supranational, national, regional), policy sector (e.g. electricity, multi-sectoral, framework policy), size of plant targeted (Large, small or both) and funding (partially, depending on instrument)). We selected distinct policies based on previous studies. The selected instruments include (Table 1): 4 http://www.iea.org/policiesandmeasures 9 Electroniccopy copy available available at: Electronic at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 Table 1: Policy Scheme (adapted from IEA Policies and Measures) here 3.3.3. Controls To account for technological progress, economies of scale as well as the fact that the installed capacity gains momentum (leading to variance from the previous years), we include year and country dummy variables. To rule out alternative explanation for RE investments we included a number of control variables in the regressions. Technology advancement: Economies of scale are picked up by time dummy variable and therefore not included among the control variables. Economic indicators: Further economic indicators that might drive capacity additions including GDP (c_GDP) Energy system: To account for differences in energy use and consumption we include energy dependency (CO2 intensity – Metric Tons of Carbon Dioxide per thousand year 2005 U.S. dollars GDP) as well as electricity consumption in the regression. (c_CI, c_TEC) Investor behavior: To account for factors influencing investor behavior, we include interest rates (c_LIR) as well as share prices (c_SP) of local indices as these might render an investment into RE vs. non-RE more or less attractive. 3.3.4. Lag structure To account for the time-dependent influence of policy measures on investor behavior, we include a lag structure in the analysis (Angrist and Pischke, 2008; Wooldridge et al., 2009). On the one hand, it is possible that investors anticipate the regulation and already have their projects ready when it is passed, as the regulatory process is mostly open. On the other, there are factors delaying the investment process such as the time needed to build the wind farm or solar park and to gain access to the grid (Jenner et al., 2013). 3.4. Analysis The evaluation of the outcomes of RE policies has differed in the last 25 years. Konidaris & Mavrakis (2007) construct a multi-method evaluation tool, highlighting cost effectiveness and (economic) efficiency (Finon and Perez, 2007; Foxon and Pearson, 2007) as the main criteria for measuring the impact of climate change-mitigating policies. Still, questions arise over the quantification of support mechanisms (Sukumar et al., 2010). Determining the influence of policy measures on investments in RE capacity proves to be a complex task. A priori, we expect spatial as well as temporal effects. We anticipate the 10 Electroniccopy copy available available at: Electronic at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 number of countries and the number of policies and measures to be reinforced over time. Assuming that a set of countries (e.g. EU countries) is exposed to common policy guidance on RE, we expect contemporaneous correlations. Academic literature describes some drivers for RE use, which are included in the model (see section 3.3.2). To fulfill all the demands on a model, the best fitting econometric approach is to use a panel data approach, which is flexible enough to work under the complex conditions of RE deployment (Marques and Fuinhas, 2012a). We estimate Random Effects, and Panel Corrected Standard Error (PCSE) models. We perform our panel data estimation upon complex error compositions. Heteroskedasticity, panel autocorrelation, and contemporaneous correlation phenomena are addressed through fitting approaches (Reed and Ye, 2011). Thus we circumvent inefficiency in coefficient estimation and biasedness in the estimation of standard errors. We do not focus on random effects estimators (REE) as they do not address serial correlation and contemporaneous correlation, however we include the estimates for reasons of robustness, as suggested by Marques and Fuinhas (2012a, 2012b). We use the following procedure: 1. We observe the quality and nature of the data; 2. We test the presence of heteroskedasticity, panel autocorrelation, and contemporaneous correlation; 3. If deviation from the classical assumptions is noticeable, we apply the PCSE estimator, which is a suitable solution with the presence of panel-level heteroskedasticity and contemporaneous correlation of observations among panels; 4. We compare the results with those derived from the REE to check the robustness (Marques and Fuinhas, 2012a). 3.4.1. Panel data analysis Table 2 presents results from the estimations and confirms that especially the policy data is heteroskedastic (i.e. has a common variance) and that panel autocorrelation and contemporaneous correlation is present. Table 2: Specification tests here 3.4.2. Panel data regressions As public policy effects differ across RE subsectors (e.g. solar, wind, biomass) we carried out the analysis sector by sector and also aggregated the data (Multiple RE sources) to analyze effects that are similar across sectors. Thereby we can also distinguish policy instruments between the sectors as well as policies that apply to all sectors. 11 Electroniccopy copy available available at: Electronic at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 Additional analyses have been performed using aggregated independent policy measures following the IEA policy scheme (Table 1) and the corresponding categories (e.g. Economic Instruments - Direct investment, Economic Instruments – Fiscal/financial incentives etc.) Panel data estimation without lag procedure (I) ∑ Panel data estimation with lag procedure (II-IV) ∑ is the aggregated installed capacity financed by institutional investors per country j per year k. is a vector of i explanatory variables representing policy measures based on the IEA scheme (per country per year). consists of a number of control variables. For the analyses of time-dependent phenomenon we include lags “l” of one to three years in the regressions. The PCSE estimator allows the error term allows the use of first-order autoregressive process for to be correlated over the countries, over time and allows to be heteroskedastic (Cameron and Trivedi, 2009; Marques and Fuinhas, 2012a). 4 Results 4.1. Descriptive statistics Following the initial analysis of selected countries (see chapter 3.1) we further aggregated investments in capacity of multiple RE and policy measures taken over time to gain an overview about the relationship between the dependent and independent variable. Figure 5 provides the relationship between the two. One dot represents one country. It becomes apparent that some countries have neither attracted any investments nor instituted policy measures whereas other countries have implemented an above average number of policy measures with regard to attracted investments. This confirms our assumptions that some policy measures are more effective than others in attracting RE projects. Figure 5 here Furthermore the correlation among explanatory variables has been subject to analysis. The simultaneous use of several drivers leads to the hypothesis of collinearity among explanatory variables. Table A.2 and Table A.3 (in the appendix) show the summary statistics and the 12 Electroniccopy copy available available at: Electronic at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 correlation coefficients for our analysis. The analysis suggests the absence of collinearity among variables. 4.2. Panel-Regression We estimated all models separately using the PCSE and the random effects estimator. We conducted the analysis for Multiple RE data and distinct sectors. Analyses have been performed structuring the policy measures according to the IEA policy scheme (Table 1). The estimation results are displayed in order of the categories and different policy structures. 4.2.1. Multiple RE sources The results of our complete policy variable analysis using Multiple RE are presented in Table 3. Findings confirm that six of the variables show a significant influence on capacity additions in all energy sectors combined. PCSE shows positive, highly significant contributions by Feed-in tariffs/premiums and GHG allowances, which directly impact the risk and return structure of RE projects and thus provide an incentive for investors. Grants and subsidies temporally reduce the cost of finance for a project, and directly depend on a public budget. Interestingly, the presence of a GHG trading system has a stronger effect on RE capacity then an FIT or grants and subsidies. Feed-in tariffs have been implemented in a range of countries, starting with Germany and Austria in 2000, while GHG emission trading systems have been introduced in the Australia, UK, Italy and Norway since 1991. In addition, supportive instruments such as a clear long term energy strategy (Strategic planning), as well as regulatory instruments (Codes and standards),especially RPS, for the use of RE sources prove to be effective. The PCSE and random effects estimators display consistent results, however when adding further restrictions such as robust standard errors or autocorrelation assumptions, some policy instruments become insignificant (e.g. Codes and standards and Strategic planning). This might be due to the fact that statistical noise is more pronounced in the cross-sectoral data. Table 3: Results for Multiple RE here 4.2.2. Solar The results of our complete policy variable analysis using solar energy data are presented in Table 4. Findings confirm that seven of the policy variables show a significant influence on capacity additions in all energy sectors combined. PCSE estimator shows positive contributions with high significance of Feed-in tariffs/premiums as a policy instrument that 13 Electroniccopy copy available available at: Electronic at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 guarantees a certain return of investment of time. FIT for solar technologies have been particularly successful in countries such as Germany and Italy. As a supporting instrument, investors favor a long term framework with a clear vision (Strategic planning). Essentially all countries in our study had policy measures containing a strategic component, however only a few incorporated it in many policy initiatives. On the other hand we found two instruments which prove to be ineffective. GHG emissions allowances show a negative impact on the capacity financed by institutional investors, which might be due to the lack in maturity and the low amount of certificates generated per capital invested compared to other sectors, such as wind. Green certificates that permit trading the obligatory RE capacity in a national scheme do not incentivize institutional investors, as these depend on the total quantity in the market which might vary (especially in sunny periods). Without the assumption of auto-correlation other instruments are significant as well. These results are mostly consistent across estimators (PCSE and REE). Table 4: Results for Solar here 4.2.3. Wind The results of the complete policy variable analysis using Wind energy data are presented in Table 5. Findings confirm that three policy variables show a significant influence on capacity additions in all energy sectors combined. The PCSE estimator shows the positive contributions of Feed-in tariffs/premiums, as a measure that directly impacts the risk and return structure of wind projects. Interestingly the presence of GHG emissions allowances have a stronger impact on the capacity financed by institutional investors than FIT, as investors prefer market-based systems which are less dependent on policy changes. GHG emissions allowances have been introduced in the US, UK and Italy. Institutionalization of markets in the form of Codes and standards is further conducive to RE capacity additions for mature technologies. These RPS have mainly been deployed throughout North America and in parts of Europe. The random effects estimator confirm these findings. Table 5: Results for Wind here 4.2.4. Biomass The complete policy variable analysis using Biomass energy data is presented in Table 6. Findings confirm that five policy variables show a significant influence on capacity additions in all energy sectors combined. Positive contributions with high significance include Funds to sub-national governments (direct investments with federal money with regional, local or 14 Electroniccopy copy available available at: Electronic at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 municipal level entities as intermediaries or targets) as biomass markets tend to be regionally dispersed. Grants and subsidies prove to be effective as short term measures to alleviate finance constraints. The presence of a GHG emissions trading system as a market based system did also spur the investments in biomass plants. This might be due to the fact that these plants generate a constant flow of certificate an exhibit base-load characteristics. Institutional creation such as the forming an energy agency, further accelerates the capacity additions in the biomass sector. Infrastructure investments do not increase the capacity installed in the biomass sector which might be due to the fact that bioenergy can be used locally. Here both estimators display consistent results as well. Table 6: Results for Biomass here Finally, the disaggregated results (i.e. individual policy instruments) were cross-checked with aggregated results (categories of policy instruments) for the entire analysis. An overview is given in figure 6. Figure 6 here 5 Discussion RE technologies are subject to market insufficiencies and system failures. Therefore scholars have been discussing the policy mix for an effective support for RE technologies (Foxon and Pearson, 2007; Jacobsson et al., 2009). This discussion was transformed by questions concerning energy system transformation (Jefferson, 2008). Theoretically, market based solutions (such as emissions trading systems) would be preferable. However, due to the absence of such functioning global markets for carbon emissions, second best solutions have been implemented across countries with mixed effects. Research found that FITs proved particularly successful in countries such as Germany with some exceptions in other countries (e.g. Spain) (Büsgen and Dürrschmidt, 2009; Couture and Gagnon, 2010; Jenner et al., 2013). Other policies such as quotas, renewable portfolio standards and tax based measures have been applied as well, revealing mixed evidence (Butler and Neuhoff, 2008; Cansino et al., 2010; Carley, 2009; Quirion, 2010). In sum, single policies have been subject to analysis on a country or industry level. A second stream of literature deals with investor behavior regarding RE technologies, as investors provide funds for large scale deployment (Bergek et al., 2013). This perspective has not been adequately explored (Mathews et al., 2010). Evidence by Río and Bleda (2012) underlines the superiority of FITs to spur deployment and to lower risks associated with RE technologies, however the authors argue that a variety of policies, consisting of specific and 15 Electroniccopy copy available available at: Electronic at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 technology-neutral measures provide fertile ground for RE technology deployment. Calls for future research explicitly state the need for an advanced (quantitative) analysis of the influence of policy measures on investor decision making (Wüstenhagen and Menichetti, 2012) With our analysis we contribute to both realms of literature, providing an integral picture of RE policies and their influence on RE capacity investments by institutional investors. The analysis is conducted on a sectoral basis to allow differentiated policy recommendations. In the following discussion, we highlight significant effective and ineffective policy measures. First, the three RE subsectors have been aggregated to allow for an overall policy analysis. The results highlight the robust positive influence of tradable permit systems as a market based instrument and the less pronounced positive influence of fiscal incentives such as FIT as well as grants and subsidies on subsequent capacity investments. Regulatory mechanisms such as codes and standards (especially RPS) also attract institutional investors. These findings confirm earlier work by Jenner et al. (2013) who highlight FIT as effective measures to increase the overall capacity of RE. We also provide new insights in the discussion about RPS schemes. Looking at US states, Carley (2009) found a positive effect, whereas Delmas and Montes-Sancho (2011) did not find a significant positive contribution of RPS to RE investments. Adding to this literature we underline positive effects of GHG allowance system. Finally, policy support mechanisms such as strategic planning prove to be effective. These results confirm conceptual and empirical works by Wüstenhagen & Menichetti (2012) and Lüthi & Prässler (2011), which hold clear strategic long-term economic instruments to be conducive to RE investments. While the multiple RE analysis includes different technologies at different stages in their life cycle, it only allows for a rough overview on policy instruments. Therefore, in a second step, we conduct an individual sectoral analysis for solar, wind and biomass. A detailed analysis of the solar sector confirms the strong role of FITs for market development (Couture and Gagnon, 2010; Jenner et al., 2013). This instrument is a strong signal to investors as it addresses the capital market restrictions by adjusting the risk/return structure (Cárdenas-Rodríguez et al., 2013). We add empirical support for the strong role which a long-term policy commitment (strategic planning) plays in an effective policy mix (Bergek et al., 2013). The German “Energiewende” provides a successful example of this type of policy measure. 16 Electroniccopy copy available available at: Electronic at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 Solar energy technologies, being less mature and more diverse than wind, are more heavily dependent on regulation, although grid parity is almost reached. These developments are reflected in our results regarding the policy mix. Market based incentives (such as GHG emission trading systems) prove to be ineffective in this case. A possible explanation lies in the fact, that solar technologies require stronger signals towards investors due to their relative novelty compared to wind technologies. Furthermore, green certificates are a second ineffective policy instrument due to limited implementation, insufficient mobilization of funds and high regulatory uncertainty, all of which make them unattractive for institutional investors. In addition, quota-based systems tend to be opaque as they involve over-the-counter transactions for certificates (Cárdenas-Rodríguez et al., 2013). Wind sector results add empirical evidence to the debate revolving around FITs and tradable permits (Butler and Neuhoff, 2008; Cansino et al., 2010). Our results show a stronger influence of tradable permits as market based system than FITs for wind. Regulatory measures such as codes and standards (e.g. RPS) have also proven to be effective, perhaps because the wind sector shows elements of a developed market. The cost-effectiveness of this technology is proven so it can compete with fossil fuel-based electricity generation in certain environments. Our analysis of the biomass sector, however, yields inconclusive results. On one hand, grants and subsidies as direct economic instruments prove to be effective, however these are only short-term policy measures. Long term market based instruments (GHG emission trading system) complement these and prove to have positive effect as well. On the other, indirect measures such as “funds to subnational governments” and institutional creation seem to be effective as well. According to our results, infrastructure investments to provide grid access and strategic planning to develop a long-term energy supply based on bioenergy are ineffective for channeling investor’s money into biomass technologies. Reasons for deviating results in the biomass energy sector lie in the different structure which can be characterized by a strong regional focus and usually the small scale of power plants (Upreti, 2004). This might attract a different set of investors that focus less on overall market conditions. 6 Conclusions Our research calls for technology specific policies, taking into account the actual market conditions and the position in the technology life cycle to design a supportive and effective policy mix. We thus provide empirical support for policy implications by the IEA. “Policy needs to take into account the overall maturity of the technology and the state of its market on 17 Electroniccopy copy available available at: Electronic at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 a global scale” (Müller et al., 2011, p. 31). To foster investments by institutional investors during the diffusion phase the policy mix needs to contain elements of economic/fiscal incentives (such as FITs) as well as market based incentives such as GHG emission trading system which directly impact the risk/return structure of RE projects. Grants and subsidies are helpful in the R&D and commercialization phase yet prove to be less effective in the later stages as they depend on public/fiscal budgets. Regulatory instruments such as codes and standards (especially RPS) accelerate the diffusion of RE technologies. Our results further indicate support for policy measures such as strategic planning which provide investors with the necessary prospects and goals concerning the different technologies to adjust their investment strategy. With our research, we firstly extend work on effectiveness of renewables policy (Marques and Fuinhas, 2012a; Marques et al., 2010) and secondly provide empirical evidence for investor influences (Masini and Menichetti, 2012; Wüstenhagen and Menichetti, 2012). Our results also have implications for strategies of transitioning towards a clean energy system (Huberty and Zysman, 2010; Jefferson, 2008), which is not possible without the integration of institutional investors (Mowery et al., 2010). In this respect we indirectly complement research on how to heal market failures (Mowery et al 2010, Dodgson et al 2011). Our results reveal policy implications based on patterns for a suitable policy mix. Policy makers interested in improving their country’s transition towards RE should implement measures for attracting institutional investors, as the capital required for large-scale RE projects by far surpasses the available funds of utility companies as well as the public budgets. Institutional investors’ capital played an important role in the development of the RE sector, and establishing a favorable environment for them, including specific policies, should increase capacity additions in the future. A policy mix which contains the following elements proved to be suitable for institutional investors: Above all, our results strongly suggest the establishment of a reliable framework with a clear vision and long-term policy objectives regarding the RE capacities to be installed in the future as well as complementary transitions in the energy sector. Ex-post changes to the remuneration of existing projects should be avoided. However, as technological progress continues, the measures taken need to be adjusted, taking the market and technological conditions (i.e. life cycle) into account. Within this framework, monetary/fiscal and economic incentives are the most relevant policy measures for investors. These directly impact the risk/return profile of RE projects and thus 18 Electroniccopy copy available available at: Electronic at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 their attractiveness. Investors are positive about long term reliable support mechanisms that cannot be revoked and provide a highly predictable revenue stream. Feed-in tariffs thus provide the more reliant and long-term signal than grants which depend on public budgets however these funds, directly influencing the direct and early project cash flows, are also seen favorable. According to our results, market based incentives (such as GHG emission trading systems) can also have strong influence on investments by institutional investors. These measures support the need of investors for a highly reliable environment, best accompanied by a diminished risk exposure. However, for an emission trading system to become an effective anchor for institutional investors, the technology should have reached maturity, ruling out technological difficulties. Supportive regulatory measures such as codes and standards (especially RPS) further accelerate the diffusion process of RE technologies by further reducing technological and regulatory risk associated with investments in RE projects. Thus we recommend the streamlining and strengthening of legislation and a transparent setting of renewable energy targets There are a number of limitations regarding study design and modeling. The use of dummy variables for the policy measures does not allow for statements concerning policy implementation or policy uncertainty (Bergek et al., 2013; Lüthi and Wüstenhagen, 2012; Müller et al., 2011). Unlike e.g. Jenner et al. (2013) we thus cannot reflect on the design features of the policy instruments. Amending our fine grained policy analysis, future studies could look at the influence of these and other policies on general capacity additions, including non-institutional investments (such as households and utilities). Geographically our research could be extended to the BRICS and/or less developed countries (LDC) which might alter the results due to an different institutional setting (Friebe et al., 2014, 2013). It would be interesting to close the link between early stage and later stage financing along the finance value chain for RE technologies, thus analyzing venture capital and private equity investments in the early and later stages which might lead asset finance investments. Finally, with our analysis we also open up a discussion about the effectiveness and efficiency of certain policy instruments for a low-carbon carbon economy. Thus policy makers might want to consider both options for a relevant policy mix, depending on the stage of the 19 Electroniccopy copy available available at: Electronic at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 technology. Future research has to further clarify social costs for alternative policy instruments, such as FIT and GHG emission trading systems (see also Müller et al. (2011). 7 Acknowledgements The authors are grateful for the time and support of Martin Kenney and Donald Patton (University of California, Davis) and Alex Coad and Paul Nightingale (SPRU – University of Sussex). In addition the discussion at the ZEW Energy Conference 2014 helped us in further refining our arguments. We would like to thank the Federal Ministry of Education and Research (BMBF), Germany, for their financial support as part of the research project ‘‘Climate Change, Financial Markets and Innovation (CFI)’’. 20 Electroniccopy copy available available at: Electronic at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 8 References Angrist, J.D., Pischke, J.-S., 2008. Mostly Harmless Econometrics: An Empiricist’s Companion. Princeton University Press. Arrow, K.J., 1962. Economic Welfare and The Allocation of Resources for Invention, in: Nelson, R.R. (Ed.), The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity, Princeton University Press and NBER. Bergek, A., Mignon, I., Sundberg, G., 2013. Who invests in renewable electricity production? Empirical evidence and suggestions for further research. Energy Policy 56, 568–581. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2013.01.038 BNEF, 2013. Bloomberg New Energy Finance (BNEF). Bloomberg. Brown, M.A., 2001. Market failures and barriers as a basis for clean energy policies. Energy Policy 29, 1197–1207. doi:10.1016/S0301-4215(01)00067-2 Büsgen, U., Dürrschmidt, W., 2009. The expansion of electricity generation from renewable energies in Germany: A review based on the Renewable Energy Sources Act Progress Report 2007 and the new German feed-in legislation. Energy Policy 37, 2536–2545. Butler, L., Neuhoff, K., 2008. Comparison of feed-in tariff, quota and auction mechanisms to support wind power development. Renewable Energy 33, 1854–1867. Cameron, A.C., Trivedi, P.K., 2009. Microeconometrics using stata. Stata Press College Station, TX. Cansino, J.M., Pablo-Romero, M. del P., Román, R., Yñiguez, R., 2010. Tax incentives to promote green electricity: An overview of EU-27 countries. Energy Policy 38, 6000– 6008. Cárdenas-Rodríguez, M., Johnstone, N., Haščič, I., Silva, J., Ferey, A., 2013. Inducing private finance for renewable energy projects: Evidence from micro-data. OECD Environment Working Papers. Carley, S., 2009. State renewable energy electricity policies: An empirical evaluation of effectiveness. Energy Policy 37, 3071–3081. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2009.03.062 Couture, T., Gagnon, Y., 2010. An analysis of feed-in tariff remuneration models: Implications for renewable energy investment. Energy Policy 38, 955–965. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2009.10.047 Del Río, P., Bleda, M., 2012. Comparing the innovation effects of support schemes for renewable electricity technologies: A function of innovation approach. Energy Policy 50, 272–282. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2012.07.014 Delmas, M.A., Montes-Sancho, M.J., 2011. U.S. state policies for renewable energy: Context and effectiveness. Energy Policy 39, 2273–2288. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2011.01.034 Dodgson, M., Hughes, A., Foster, J., Metcalfe, S., 2011. Systems thinking, market failure, and the development of innovation policy: The case of Australia. Research Policy 40, 1145–1156. doi:10.1016/j.respol.2011.05.015 Finon, D., Perez, Y., 2007. The social efficiency of instruments of promotion of renewable energies: A transaction-cost perspective. Ecological Economics 62, 77–92. Foxon, T.J., Pearson, P.J.G., 2007. Towards improved policy processes for promoting innovation in renewable electricity technologies in the UK. Energy Policy 35, 1539– 1550. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2006.04.009 Friebe, C.A., Flotow, P. von, Täube, F.A., 2013. Exploring the link between products and services in low-income markets—Evidence from solar home systems. Energy Policy 52, 760–769. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2012.10.038 Friebe, C.A., von Flotow, P., Täube, F.A., 2014. Exploring technology diffusion in emerging markets – the role of public policy for wind energy. Energy Policy 70, 217–226. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2014.03.016 21 Electroniccopy copy available available at: Electronic at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 Hair, J., 2010. Multivariate data analysis : a global perspective., 7th ed. /. ed. Pearson Education, Upper Saddle River N.J., London. Haley, U.C.V., Schuler, D.A., 2011. Government Policy and Firm Strategy in the Solar Photovoltaic Industry. California Management Review 54, 17–38. doi:10.1525/cmr.2011.54.1.17 Helm, D., 2002. Energy policy: security of supply, sustainability and competition. Energy Policy 30, 173–184. Huberty, M., Zysman, J., 2010. An energy system transformation: Framing research choices for the climate challenge. Research Policy 39, 1027–1029. doi:10.1016/j.respol.2010.05.010 IEA, 2014. IEA FAQ Renewable Energy [WWW Document]. URL http://www.iea.org/aboutus/faqs/renewableenergy/ IPCC, 2014. Climate Change 2014: Mitigation of climate change - IPCC Working Group III Contribution to AR5. Int, Berlin. Jacobsson, S., Bergek, A., Finon, D., Lauber, V., Mitchell, C., Toke, D., Verbruggen, A., 2009. EU renewable energy support policy: Faith or facts? Energy Policy 37, 2143– 2146. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2009.02.043 Jaffe, A.B., Newell, R.G., Stavins, R.N., 2005. A tale of two market failures: Technology and environmental policy. Ecological Economics, Technological Change and the Environment Technological Change 54, 164–174. doi:10.1016/j.ecolecon.2004.12.027 Jefferson, M., 2008. Accelerating the transition to sustainable energy systems. Energy Policy 36, 4116–4125. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2008.06.020 Jenner, S., Groba, F., Indvik, J., 2013. Assessing the strength and effectiveness of renewable electricity feed-in tariffs in European Union countries. Energy Policy 52, 385–401. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2012.09.046 Johnstone, N., Haščič, I., Popp, D., 2010. Renewable Energy Policies and Technological Innovation: Evidence Based on Patent Counts. Environ Resource Econ 45, 133–155. doi:10.1007/s10640-009-9309-1 Kenney, M., Hargadon, A., 2012. Misguided Policy? California Management Review 54, 118–139. doi:10.1525/cmr.2012.54.2.118 Konidari, P., Mavrakis, D., 2007. A multi-criteria evaluation method for climate change mitigation policy instruments. Energy Policy 35, 6235–6257. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2007.07.007 Lesser, J., Su, X., 2008. Design of an economically efficient feed-in tariff structure for renewable energy development. Energy Policy 36, 981–990. Lüthi, S., Prässler, T., 2011. Analyzing policy support instruments and regulatory risk factors for wind energy deployment—A developers’ perspective. Energy Policy 39, 4876– 4892. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2011.06.029 Lüthi, S., Wüstenhagen, R., 2012. The price of policy risk — Empirical insights from choice experiments with European photovoltaic project developers. Energy Economics 34, 1001–1011. doi:10.1016/j.eneco.2011.08.007 Marques, A.C., Fuinhas, J.A., 2011. Do energy efficiency measures promote the use of renewable sources? Environmental Science & Policy 14, 471–481. doi:10.1016/j.envsci.2011.02.001 Marques, A.C., Fuinhas, J.A., 2012a. Are public policies towards renewables successful? Evidence from European countries. Renewable Energy 44, 109–118. doi:10.1016/j.renene.2012.01.007 Marques, A.C., Fuinhas, J.A., 2012b. Is renewable energy effective in promoting growth? Energy Policy 46, 434–442. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2012.04.006 Marques, A.C., Fuinhas, J.A., Pires Manso, J.R., 2010. Motivations driving renewable energy in European countries: A panel data approach. Energy Policy 38, 6877–6885. 22 Electroniccopy copy available available at: Electronic at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 Martin, S., Scott, J.T., 2000. The nature of innovation market failure and the design of public support for private innovation. Research Policy 29, 437–447. doi:16/S00487333(99)00084-0 Masini, A., Menichetti, E., 2012. The impact of behavioural factors in the renewable energy investment decision making process: Conceptual framework and empirical findings. Energy Policy 40, 28–38. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2010.06.062 Mathews, J.A., Kidney, S., Mallon, K., Hughes, M., 2010. Mobilizing private finance to drive an energy industrial revolution. Energy Policy 38, 3263–3265. Menanteau, P., Finon, D., Lamy, M.-L., 2003. Prices versus quantities: choosing policies for promoting the development of renewable energy. Energy Policy 31, 799–812. Mowery, D.C., Nelson, R.R., Martin, B.R., 2010. Technology policy and global warming: Why new policy models are needed (or why putting new wine in old bottles won’t work). Research Policy 39, 1011–1023. Müller, S., Brown, A., Ölz, S., 2011. Renewable energy: policy considerations for deploying renewables. International Energy Agency. Nicolli, F., Vona, F., 2012. The Evolution of Renewable Energy Policy in OECD Countries: Aggregate Indicators and Determinants (SSRN Scholarly Paper No. ID 2123094). Social Science Research Network, Rochester, NY. OECD, 2013. OECD factbook: economic, environmental and social statistics. OECD. Popp, D., Hascic, I., Medhi, N., 2011. Technology and the diffusion of renewable energy. Energy Economics 33, 648–662. doi:10.1016/j.eneco.2010.08.007 Quirion, P., 2010. Complying with the Kyoto Protocol under uncertainty: Taxes or tradable permits? Energy Policy 38, 5166–5173. Reed, W.R., Ye, H., 2011. Which panel data estimator should I use? Applied Economics 43, 985–1000. doi:10.1080/00036840802600087 Rogge, K.S., Hoffmann, V.H., 2010. The impact of the EU ETS on the sectoral innovation system for power generation technologies - Findings for Germany. Energy Policy 38, 7639–7652. Rogge, K.S., Schneider, M., Hoffmann, V.H., 2011. The innovation impact of the EU Emission Trading System — Findings of company case studies in the German power sector. Ecological Economics 70, 513–523. Sandén, B.A., Azar, C., 2005. Near-term technology policies for long-term climate targets— economy wide versus technology specific approaches. Energy Policy 33, 1557–1576. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2004.01.012 Smith, S., Swierzbinski, J., 2007. Assessing the performance of the UK Emissions Trading Scheme. Environmental and Resource Economics 37. Sukumar, S.., Shankar, M., Olama, M., Hadley, S., Protopopescu, V., Malinchik, S., Ives, B., 2010. Quantifying state-policy incentives for the renewable energy investor. Energy Conversion Congress and Exposition (ECCE), 2010 IEEE 386–391. Szabó, S., Jäger-Waldau, A., 2008. More competition: Threat or chance for financing renewable electricity? Energy Policy 36, 1436–1447. Upreti, B.R., 2004. Conflict over biomass energy development in the United Kingdom: some observations and lessons from England and Wales. Energy Policy 32, 785–800. doi:10.1016/S0301-4215(02)00342-7 Veugelers, R., 2011. Europe’s clean technology investment challenge (Policy Contributions No. 561). Bruegel. Veugelers, R., 2012. Which policy instruments to induce clean innovating? Research Policy 41, 1770–1778. doi:10.1016/j.respol.2012.06.012 Vona, F., Nicolli, F., Nesta, L., 2012. Determinants of Renewable Energy Innovation: environmental policies vs. market regulation. Documents de Travail de l’OFCE 5. 23 Electroniccopy copy available available at: Electronic at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 Wooldridge, J.M., Calhoun, J.W., Jung, B., Greber, S., Montgomery, R., 2009. Introductory Econometrics, 4th ed. South-Western Cengage Learning, Mason, OH. Wüstenhagen, R., Menichetti, E., 2012. Strategic choices for renewable energy investment: Conceptual framework and opportunities for further research. Energy Policy 40, 1–10. doi:10.1016/j.enpol.2011.06.050 9 24 Electroniccopy copy available available at: Electronic at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 10 Appendices 10.1. Definitions Information and education: Policies and measures designed to increase knowledge, awareness and training among relevant stakeholders or the general public. This can include general information campaigns, targeted training programs for professionals and labeling schemes that provide the purchaser with information on a product’s energy usage or emissions performance. Economic instruments: Policies and measures that stimulate certain activities, behaviors or investments using financial supports and price signals to influence the market. These include fiscal and financial policy instruments such as taxes, tax relief, grants or subsidies, feed-in tariffs for renewable energy, and loans for the purchase or installation of certain goods and services. They also include direct public funding and procurement rules, and market mechanisms such as tradable permits. Policy development and reform: Refers to steps in the ongoing process of developing, supporting and implementing policies. This includes strategic plans that guide policy development and the creation of specific bodies to support policy Research, Development &Deployment (RD&D): Policies and measures aimed at supporting technological advancement, through direct government investment, or facilitation of investment, in technology research, development, demonstration and deployment activities. Regulatory instruments: Covers a wide range of instruments with which a government imposes targets, obligations and standards on actors requiring them to undertake specific measures and/or report on specific information. Examples include energy performance standards for appliances, equipment, and buildings; requirement for companies to manage energy consumption, produce or purchase a certain amount of renewable energy or deliver energy efficiency to customers; mandatory energy audits of industrial facilities; requirements to monitor and report on greenhouse gas emissions or energy use. Voluntary approaches: Refers to measures that are undertaken voluntarily either by public agencies or by the private sector unilaterally, or by the two in a negotiated agreement. Unilateral commitments are when entities set themselves environmental targets and communicate successful compliance to their stakeholders. Public voluntary schemes invite companies to meet specified environmental targets established by public authorities. Negotiated agreements set environmental targets agreed between a government and a private 25 Electroniccopy copy available available at: Electronic at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 sector entity, and may require reporting information on energy use to the government, being subject to audits, and undertaking measures to reduce energy use. 10.1. Case selection Table A.1 here 10.2. Variable Selection Economic instruments/ Direct investments: We excluded the variable Procurement rules as there is no significant public market for RE technologies. Further, we excluded RD&D funding as only five policies falling into this category have been implemented. Economic instruments/ Fiscal/financial incentives: Here we excluded only user charges due to data availability. Economic instruments/ Market-based instruments: The IEA policy scheme included a white certificate scheme (focusing on energy efficiency). Although research shows that these policy measures might accelerate the diffusion of RE technologies (Marques and Fuinhas, 2011), we found no causal link to investor behavior. Information and Education: Here, Information provision, Advice/Aid in Implementation as well as performance labels and professional training and qualification have been excluded, firstly due to missing investor reference and secondly due to data availability. Regulatory Instruments: Auditing, building codes and standards as well as monitory have been removed from the list of explanatory variables as to our knowledge these might have no effect on investments in RE capacity by institutional investors. Research, Development and Deployment (RD&D): measures have been removed as these measures target individual firms, which are not our unit of analysis. Voluntary Approaches: These variables have been excluded as they target corporations, rather than investors. 10.3. Summary statistics Table A.2 & A.3here 26 Electroniccopy copy available available at: Electronic at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 Category Instruments Variable Abbreviation Literature Economic Instruments - Direct investment Funds to sub-national governments EI_DI_FSGjk (Ragwitz et al. 2008) Infrastructure investments EI_DI_IIjk (Bergek et al. 2013) Feed-in tariffs/premiums EI_FI_FIjk (Jenner et al. 2013) Grants and subsidies EI_FI_GSjk (Bergek et al. 2013) Loans EI_FI_Ljk (Bergek et al. 2013) Tax relief EI_FI_TRjk (Cansino et al. 2010; Quirion 2010) Taxes EI_FI_Tjk (Cansino et al. 2010; Quirion 2010) GHG emissions allowances EI_MI_GAjk (Rogge et al. 2011; Rogge & Hoffmann 2010) Green certificates EI_MI_GCjk (Rogge et al. 2011; Rogge & Hoffmann 2010) Institutional creation PS_ICjk (Wieczorek & Hekkert 2012) Strategic planning PS_SPjk (Lüthi & Wüstenhagen 2012) Codes and standards RI_CSjk (Carley 2009) Obligation schemes RI_OSjk (Butler & Neuhoff 2008), Other mandatory requirements RI_MRjk (Butler & Neuhoff 2008) Institutional creation PS_ICjk (Wieczorek & Hekkert 2012) Strategic planning PS_SPjk (Lüthi & Wüstenhagen 2012) Economic Instruments – Fiscal/financial incentives Economic Instruments – Market-based instruments Policy Support Regulatory Instruments Policy Support Table 7: Policy Scheme (adapted from IEA Policies and Measures) 27 copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 Electronic copy available at:Electronic https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 Random effects Fixed effects Multiple RE Solar Wind Biomass Multiple RE Solar Wind Biomass Modified Wald test - - - - 236.84*** 91.24*** 1052.72*** 141.05*** Pesaran’s test 19.550*** 5.544*** 16.264*** 8.702*** 15.020*** 4.127*** 10.148*** 4.611*** Frees’ test 2.997*** 1.029*** 2.491*** 0.900*** 2.344*** 0.216 1.872*** 0.631** Notes: The Modified Wald Test Chi2 distribution and tests the null hypothesis: , for c = 1,.,N; Pesaran and Frees’ tests test the null hypothesis of crosssection independence; Pesaran’s test is a parametric testing procedure and follows a standard normal distribution; Frees’ test uses Frees’ Q-distribution; xtcsd command was used (Hoyos & Sarafidis 2006). ***, *, denote 1 and 10% significance level, respectively. Table 2: Specification tests 28 copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 Electronic copy available at:Electronic https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 PCSE Independent variables EI_DI_FSGjk EI_DI_IIjk EI_FI_FIjk Random effects No autocorrelation AR(1) CSE AR(1) (I) (II) (III) (IV) Coeff. SD -.6516576* .39985 .1480486 .2566804 Coeff. SD Coeff. SD Coeff. SD -.8630866 .5901286 -1.12362 .7074356 -.6923118 .6345557 .2910476 .1199704 .5227986 -.013469 .3534862 .5025643 .6871031*** .2806932 .3448074** .4361374 .6460938* .3767379 .4565576 .3533344 EI_FI_GSjk .3262012 EI_FI_Ljk -.3590348 .2642972 .0480538 .3678096 -.3814668 .5468806 -.1682956 .5119435 EI_FI_TRjk .4008434** .1780084 .3064977 .3259957 EI_FI_Tjk -.8995866* .4812785 -.7008466 .5409997 -1.428411** .5878148 -.7806197 .5767547 EI_MI_GAjk 1.476** .2525002 .7721907** .3423242 .983853*** .3595374 .6290736** .3265612 .3614985 .4265634 .2877263 .3978518 .6289598 1.422642* .7595094 2.060666*** .7979844 1.366636* .793817 EI_MI_GCjk -.0147581 .3439044 .3990277 PS_ICjk -.407161 .2785661 .0366566 .4038071 -.5492414 .4767925 -.2247933 PS_SPjk .7037612* .3738054 .4092362 .4437024 1.199293*** .4226628 .5398187 .4043298 RI_CSjk .4475644*** .1712941 .1326882 .3174074 .8248669* .4792686 .2805152 .4863 .36328 .153039 .5558723 .1682016 .5317527 .461503 .474983 .4229809 .359739 .4520459 RI_OSjk .2783923 .2619837 .3480405 .4777855 RI_MRjk .5228704 .3580947 .8174922** .4244155 .7293992 .4620257 .5434511 .4384469 c_TECjk .6369263 .2235642 .5377107 .3651499 .6155304** c_CIjk -.0896215 .6683637 1.03767 .7754292 -.6598328 1.594438 -.2695809 1.262449 Control variables c_LIRjk .6704916*** c_SPjk c_GDPjk _cons Observations R2 Wald .1896642 .6700271*** .27879 .5122237** .2315727 .185451 -.7077997** .3075835 .6700027** .2868721 1.841445*** .5574079 1.547328** .6609779 1.840681*** .3614505 1.55531*** .3780566 -.0211656 .0781152 -.0409273 .0761332 -.0361108 .0843065 -.0087939 .0721356 - - -7.118729** 3.28976 -5.843901 3.640319 330 330 330 330 0.3811 0.3173 0.3632 0.3741 258.81*** 222.09*** 205.74*** 106.10*** 7.542619*** 2.787254 5.936144** 2.540102 Notes: The Wald test distribution and tests the null hypothesis of non-significance of all coefficients of explanatory variables; panel corrected standard errors are reported in brackets. ***, **, *, denote significance at 1, 5 and 10% significance levels, respectively; AR(1) - first-order autoregressive error; CSE – Conventional Standard Errors. Estimations include both country and time dummies. Table 3: Results for Multiple RE 29 Electroniccopy copy available available at: Electronic at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 PCSE Independent variables Random effects No autocorrelation AR(1) CSE AR(1) (V) (VI) (VII) (VIII) Coeff. SD Coeff. SD Coeff. SD Coeff. SD -1.430191*** .452557 -.4345027 .6578232 -1.430191*** .4693717 -.7560549 .5740057 EI_DI_IIjk .205142 .4027607 .1930198 .4221444 .205142 .5622184 -.2319487 .5570207 EI_FI_FIjk 1.183469*** .2614633 .9968022*** .2765806 1.183469*** .3108172 1.064136*** .3318779 EI_FI_GSjk .6075715*** .2286481 .153594 .2578642 .6075715** .2519058 .3574473 .296831 EI_FI_Ljk -.9083116*** .3042927 -.3219862 .3829625 -.9083116** .428827 -.5934808 .4710678 -.0101943 .2788787 .5962874 .3225234 -.0101943 .3439999 .3352309 .3777232 EI_FI_Tjk .9986014** .452132* .1905455 .4228552 .9986014* .5788794 .5929351 .6261464 EI_MI_GAjk -1.174446** .5967956* -1.207017** .521431 -1.174446 .8048623 -.7284159 .9053043 EI_MI_GCjk -2.274715*** .4114937 -1.244204** .5135853 -2.274715*** .4830896 -1.649163*** .5472138 PS_ICjk -1.513661*** .3755918 -.1851111 .3821114 -1.513661*** .4327728 -.6471036 .4550913 PS_SPjk 2.347876*** .3042435 1.099465*** .3478684 2.347876*** .3444409 1.72752*** .3965018 RI_CSjk .5437917** .2699895 -.445115 .4370589 .5437917 .3625386 .0065249 .4092227 RI_OSjk .1625115 .3058051 -.1337805 .3184731 .1625115 .4126382 .064317 .4607792 RI_MRjk .7667914** .3652028 .6711904 .4245183 .7667914 .4680079 .5862809 .4653205 c_TECjk .9454781 .7403308 .502266 .8728845 .9454781 .7233382 .19094 .7615019 c_CIjk -6.009266 2.240291*** -4.545095 2.778778 -6.009266** 2.582556 -1.444087 2.93114 c_LIRjk -.5395957 .751136 .4752815 .7520795 -.5395957 .6670382 -.1201582 .6801035 c_SPjk -.2380471 .5872644 -.0602443 .6734641 -.2380471 .4560057 -.2061717 .4829867 c_GDPjk -.8238478 .7017687 -.1409385 .7989894 -.8238478 .6983512 .1140484 .732125 _cons 21.59223 17.18385 2.75846 18.93736 21.59223 17.01726 -2.987067 17.79872 EI_DI_FSGjk EI_FI_TRjk Control variables 30 copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 Electronic copy available at:Electronic https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 Observations R2 Wald 176 176 176 176 0.4938 0.1043 0.4938 0.4668 161.69*** 46.59*** 152.19*** 70.93*** Notes: The Wald test distribution and tests the null hypothesis of non-significance of all coefficients of explanatory variables; panel corrected standard errors are reported in brackets. ***, **, *, denote significance at 1, 5 and 10% significance levels, respectively; AR(1) - first-order autoregressive error; CSE – Conventional Standard Errors. Estimations include both country and time dummies. Table 4: Results for Solar 31 copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 Electronic copy available at:Electronic https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 PCSE Independent variables Random effects No autocorrelation AR(1) CSE AR(1) (XI) (VII) (III) (IV) Coeff. SD Coeff. SD Coeff. SD Coeff. SD EI_DI_FSGjk -.3757999 .4309306 -1.115682*** .5215933 -1.117909 .7042944 -.490034 .5922703 EI_DI_IIjk .3654253 .2427625 .5124566 .3962674 .5206531 .4555222 .2274922 .4362141 EI_FI_FIjk .7034015*** .2594473 .3466685 .3705958 .6145793* .3562496 .5717061* .3242466 EI_FI_GSjk .1299914 .2458559 .3584737 .2852773 .8257291** .3584267 .4697756 .3197792 EI_FI_Ljk .3021586 .2754532 .9553349** .3801406 .6636585 .5289154 .5423989 .4828976 EI_FI_TRjk .1957176 .2003498 .0637804 .3724269 -.0227203 .4155139 .1331156 .36574 EI_FI_Tjk -.5103487 .3414624 -.2289026 .4386519 -.5030176 .5816102 -.3150329 .5275276 EI_MI_GAjk 1.5911*** .411295 1.196165** .6036883 1.460892* .8265885 1.289026* .7588826 EI_MI_GCjk -.0326347 .3549096 -.1049938 .4631245 .2383117 .5159596 .2998673 .4947087 PS_ICjk .1335157 .2622394 .079518 .4187491 .0165175 .4525562 .2484949 .4156641 PS_SPjk .1607409 .4327854 .3294506 .4911224 .6631261 .4301623 .1116961 .4089962 RI_CSjk .6264673** .1855897 .5738682* .3321465 1.031217** .4704546 .6056064 .4105352 RI_OSjk -.0883198 .3071059 .2490448 .3150301 .2585585 .4727774 .0770355 .4299847 RI_MRjk .2113357 .3181797 .2007613 .3819612 .0357223 .4277984 .1372273 .4099641 .7544588** .3608242 .8300047 .2988083 .6483789*** .2371395 Control variables c_TECjk .768095*** .223812 32 copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 Electronic copy available at:Electronic https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 c_CIjk .9649845 .6596128 1.941291** .9370116 -.3786435 c_LIRjk -.748926*** .1827553 -.662133*** .187107 -.7451924** .311754 -.7195487** .286342 c_SPjk 2.103777*** .5937315 1.579907*** .616685 1.916384*** .368951 1.635179*** .3850877 c_GDPjk -.0465362 _cons -8.327666*** 3.172761 Observations R2 Wald .0787399 -.0578715 .0769572 -.047532 -6.743841** 1.798071 .0829624 3.474884 -8.641509*** 2.79598 .6928736 -.0240795 1.354673 .0710109 -6.851058*** 2.512694 319 319 319 319 0.3977 0.2739 0.3634 0.3868 398.37*** 208.87*** 198.02*** 108.58*** Notes: The Wald test distribution and tests the null hypothesis of non-significance of all coefficients of explanatory variables; panel corrected standard errors are reported in brackets. ***, **, *, denote significance at 1, 5 and 10% significance levels, respectively; AR(1) - first-order autoregressive error; CSE – Conventional Standard Errors. Estimations include both country and time dummies. Table 5: Results for Wind 33 copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 Electronic copy available at:Electronic https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 PCSE Independent variables Random effects No autocorrelation AR(1) CSE AR(1) (XVI) (XVII) (XVIII) (XIX) Coeff. SD Coeff. SD Coeff. SD Coeff. SD EI_DI_FSGjk 1.506121*** .392019 1.219264** .5174145 1.506121*** .5247834 1.468757** .5802493 EI_DI_IIjk -1.196352** .3852509 -1.040943** .4669735 -1.196352*** .4578357 -1.214129** .4882678 EI_FI_FIjk .0855131 .3397968 .2857104 .0855131 .0383056 EI_FI_GSjk .6062906** .2448567 .5218678* .3076593 .6062906*** .2486713 .6356551** .274053 EI_FI_Ljk -.1467847 .3211142 -.0673767 .3596578 -.1467847 .3941907 -.0481403 .422529 EI_FI_TRjk .0978145 .182495 -.055498 .2731093 .0978145 .2681086 .0529121 .2944414 EI_FI_Tjk -.2000953 .293675 -.1988765 .414443 -.2000953 .3874982 -.2509206 .4246686 EI_MI_GAjk .9708445* .4696504 .9970731 .6529303 .9708445** .5348302 1.000802* .591107 EI_MI_GCjk .0611662 .3388353 .1831551 .4952602 .0611662 .1213299 .4069643 PS_ICjk .8325421** .3670397 .7382939* .4009378 .8325421** .3553792 .7920043** .3846703 PS_SPjk -.44445* .2364515 -.267019 .371566 -.44445 .3023074 -.4376296 .330444 RI_CSjk -.4141917 .374794 -.3366353 .4092963 -.4141917 .334913 -.4235416 .3691855 RI_OSjk -.012409 .2674505 -.0289097 .3806128 -.012409 .3380002 .0439453 .3685454 RI_MRjk .2794535 .2654414 .1784495 .3318189 .2794535 .3128969 .3191621 .3401591 .2354532 .2630173 .370753 .2877502 Control variables 34 copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 Electronic copy available at:Electronic https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 c_TECjk -1.969388*** .6450672 -1.69437* .6629631 -1.969388*** .5245612 -1.929471*** .5697671 c_CIjk 4.368859*** 1.560729 3.975855** 2.147203 4.368859*** 1.601548 4.250155** 1.752275 c_LIRjk -.565306** .2911711 -.5420741* .3153329 -.565306* .2952814 -.5717118* .3110166 c_SPjk .6105773 .4172689 .6457221 .4520086 .6105773* .3712451 .6356115 .3993678 c_GDPjk 2.159608*** .5804663 1.928434*** .62993 2.159608*** .5019944 2.083474*** .5420153 _cons -53.24435*** 13.25234 -48.23348*** 15.25634 -53.24435*** 11.51497 -51.45514*** 12.44432 Observations R2 Wald 220 220 220 220 0.3825 0.2365 0.3825 0.3818 169.40*** 61.50*** 123.86*** 98.50*** Notes: The Wald test distribution and tests the null hypothesis of non-significance of all coefficients of explanatory variables; panel corrected standard errors are reported in brackets. ***, **, *, denote significance at 1, 5 and 10% significance levels, respectively; AR(1) - first-order autoregressive error; CSE – Conventional Standard Errors. Estimations include both country and time dummies. Table 6: Results for Biomass 35 copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 Electronic copy available at:Electronic https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 Countries included in Multiple Countries included in Solar Countries included in Wind Countries included Biomass RE Australia Austria Belgium Canada Chile Czech Republic Denmark Estonia Finland France Germany Greece Hungary Ireland Italy Japan Korea, Rep. Mexico Netherlands New Zealand Norway Poland Portugal Slovak Republic Spain Sweden Switzerland AUS AUT BEL CAN CHL CZE DNK EST FIN FRA DEU GRC HUN IRL ITA JPN KOR MEX NLD NZL NOR POL PRT SVK ESP SWE CHE Australia Belgium Canada Czech Republic France Germany Greece Italy Japan Korea, Rep. Netherlands Portugal Slovak Republic Spain Turkey United Kingdom United States AUS BEL CAN CZE FRA DEU GRC ITA JPN KOR NLD PRT SVK ESP TUR GBR USA Australia Austria Belgium Canada Chile Czech Republic Denmark Estonia Finland France Germany Greece Hungary Ireland Italy Japan Korea, Rep. Mexico Netherlands New Zealand Norway Poland Portugal Spain Sweden Switzerland Turkey AUS AUT BEL CAN CHL CZE DNK EST FIN FRA DEU GRC HUN IRL ITA JPN KOR MEX NLD NZL NOR POL PRT ESP SWE CHE TUR Australia Austria Belgium Canada Chile Czech Republic Finland France Germany Ireland Italy Japan Mexico Netherlands Norway Poland Spain Sweden United Kingdom United States AUS AUT BEL CAN CHL CZE FIN FRA DEU IRL ITA JPN MEX NLD NOR POL ESP SWE GBR USA 36 copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 Electronic copy available at:Electronic https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 Turkey United Kingdom United States TUR GBR USA United Kingdom United States GBR USA Table A.1: Country selection 37 copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 Electronic copy available at:Electronic https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 Variable Obs. Mean Std. Dev. Min BNEF_Capacity_ALL 360 3.607634 2.814445 0 9.428982 BNEF_Capacity_Biomass 240 2.251529 2.091209 0 6.800838 BNEF_Capacity_Solar 192 1.759968 2.268786 0 8.557951 BNEF_Capacity_Wind 348 3.337217 2.806457 0 9.168638 EI_DI_FSG 360 .1603185 .3238168 0 1.386294 EI_DI_II 360 .1676961 .3603024 0 1.609438 EI_FI_FI 360 .4791029 .5231468 0 1.94591 EI_FI_GS 360 .88213 .639799 0 2.302585 EI_FI_L 360 .2467513 .3814493 0 1.609438 EI_FI_TR 360 .4044712 .5213873 0 1.791759 EI_FI_T 360 .2651274 .3723063 0 1.098612 EI_MI_GA 360 .1019019 .2921595 0 1.386294 EI_MI_GC 360 .18623 1.609438 PS_IC 360 .4748967 .4910026 0 1.94591 PS_SP 360 .8731863 .5641254 0 2.079442 RI_CS 360 .5062903 .5155385 0 2.397895 RI_OS 360 .6436002 .5068814 0 2.079442 RI_MR 360 .4636214 .5625358 0 2.302585 c_TEC 360 3.501761 1.181402 1.226126 6.960218 c_CI 360 .3411723 .1685374 .0972628 .991836 c_LIR 360 1.517852 .5975912 0 c_SP 360 4.488321 .4851809 2.895912 5.699774 c_GDP 360 26.72129 1.999405 0 .3680391 0 Max 2.818398 30.33849 Table A.2: Summary statistics 38 Electroniccopy copy available available at: Electronic at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 Variables IC EI_DI_~G EI_DI_II EI_FI_FI EI_FI_ EI_FI_T EI_MI_ EI_MI_ EI_FI_L EI_FI_T GS R GA GC PS_IC PS_SP RI_CS RI_OS RI_MR c_TEC c_CI c_ LIR c_SP IC 1.0000 EI_DI_FSG 0.1374 1.0000 EI_DI_II 0.1074 0.0576 1.0000 EI_FI_FI 0.1464 -0.1385 0.0967 1.0000 EI_FI_GS 0.2626 0.2780 0.3621 0.2118 1.0000 EI_FI_L 0.2259 0.2470 0.2334 0.1085 0.1724 1.0000 EI_FI_TR 0.3295 0.2282 0.2600 0.0871 0.2226 0.3433 1.0000 EI_FI_T 0.0924 0.1887 0.0245 -0.0096 0.0681 0.2758 0.0734 1.0000 EI_MI_GA 0.1968 0.0390 -0.0462 -0.2560 0.0054 0.2204 0.0831 0.5718 1.0000 EI_MI_GC 0.1779 -0.0904 0.0222 -0.1668 -0.0536 0.1898 0.1947 0.2310 0.2665 1.0000 PS_IC 0.1821 0.0842 0.2683 0.2234 0.3447 0.3205 -0.0057 0.1888 0.1434 -0.1353 1.0000 PS_SP 0.2919 0.2644 0.0530 -0.0299 0.2617 0.3440 -0.0084 0.3384 0.4124 0.3706 0.3970 1.0000 RI_CS 0.3240 0.3432 0.2854 0.1014 0.3798 0.2549 0.4373 0.2329 0.0516 0.2243 0.2739 0.3023 1.0000 RI_OS 0.3632 0.1689 0.0843 0.0829 0.2272 0.1701 0.3035 0.0090 0.1967 -0.0018 0.4586 0.1505 0.3443 1.0000 RI_MR 0.3292 0.3978 0.2592 -0.1101 0.0695 0.4104 0.4534 0.1751 0.0819 0.1633 0.0349 0.1478 0.4009 0.4023 1.0000 c_TEC 0.3988 0.3866 0.1253 -0.1240 0.3047 0.3059 0.3784 0.0415 0.1934 0.0639 0.1899 0.1259 0.3005 0.4479 0.5330 c_CI -0.1768 0.1746 0.0773 -0.0436 -0.1826 -0.1740 -0.1024 -0.2211 -0.1904 -0.1298 -0.1899 -0.3430 -0.1639 -0.0001 0.0142 -0.2637 1.0000 c_LIR 0.0931 0.0063 0.1709 0.0753 0.1560 0.1596 0.1495 0.2521 0.0958 0.1347 0.1591 0.1808 0.2194 0.1160 0.1065 0.0492 -0.2801 1.0000 c_SP 0.3140 0.0830 0.0051 0.2664 0.1889 0.2100 0.2005 0.1923 0.0466 0.2229 0.2611 0.3705 0.2376 0.2189 0.0982 0.0666 -0.3268 0.2384 1.0000 c_GDP 0.3748 0.1673 0.1021 0.0198 0.2299 0.2079 0.3190 0.0929 0.1550 0.1573 0.0953 0.0992 0.3081 0.3267 0.3887 0.6997 -0.3101 0.0665 0.1594 1.0000 Table A.3: Pairwise correlation coefficients (Multiple RE) 39 copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 Electronic copy available at:Electronic https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 c_ GDP 1.0000 Figure 1: Aggregated sources of finance in the cleantech sector during the last 10 years in USDm (Bloomberg New Energy Finance 2013) 40 copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 Electronic copy available at:Electronic https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 Figure 2: Solar energy investments in Italy Figure 3: Wind energy investments in UK 41 copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 Electronic copy available at:Electronic https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 Figure 4: Model 42 copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 Electronic copy available at:Electronic https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 Figure 5: Scatterplot of log(Investments in multiple RE) and log(Policy Measures) 43 copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 Electronic copy available at:Electronic https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 Figure 6: Overview of results 44 copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310 Electronic copy available at:Electronic https://ssrn.com/abstract=2423310