24mm This textbook contains: • Accessible analysis, theory and diagrams, combining intuitive understanding and sophisticated analysis • A choice of learning routes with different levels of difficulty and mathematics • Real-world economic reasoning, not dry theory • Online animations that illustrate macroeconomic fluctuations and shocks • Continuous focus on South Africa as an open economy in an African and global context shaped by China, Trump’s trade wars and Brexit • Theoretical and policy analysis of unemployment, inflation, low growth and inclusive growth, and the NDP • Analytical case studies of the global financial crisis, quantitative easing, the Euro crisis and the Eskom crisis • First-hand, updated insights into how South African policy institutions, processes and instruments work • Relevant South African data sources, with useful data tips • An integration of the structural social and economic realities (notably inequality and poverty) of South Africa • Incorporation of broader considerations, such as sustainable development. Macroeconomics The answers are given in How to think and reason in Macroeconomics – A South African text, a university textbook with excellent feedback from students, lecturers and practitioners. This fifth edition with updated context and case studies combines practical information with solid economic theory plus a discussion of South African economic issues, processes, institutions and data. It enables the reader to analyse macroeconomic events and policies in a globalised and development context, and understand the different perspectives in policy and political-economic debates. How to think and reason in How does the South African economy work? Why do macroeconomic variables change? So what if they do? What happens next? How do economic processes and policy institutions really work? How can we reduce unemployment and maintain low inflation? What about poverty and inequality? The book covers the main topics for a second-year or MBA course in Macroeconomics or a third-year course on Macroeconomic Policy. Any manager or practising economist will also find this a lifelong handy reference source on how the economy works. FIFTH EDITION Philippe Burger is Professor of Economics, Vice Dean of the Faculty of Economics and Management Sciences and Pro Vice-Chancellor: Poverty, Inequality and Economic Development at the University of the Free State. He is a past President of the Economic Society of South Africa (ESSA) and was a member of the South African Statistics Council. He is a National Research Foundation rated researcher and has been a research consultant to the OECD and visiting scholar at the IMF. He is the 2002 recipient of the Founder’s Medal of ESSA for the best PhD thesis at a SA university and was associate editor of the South African Journal of Economics. He is the author of Getting it right: A new economy for South Africa (2018). www.juta.co.za Macroeconomics A SOUTH AFRICAN TEXT Frederick C v N Fourie Frederick C v N Fourie Philippe Burger ABOUT THE AUTHORS Frederick Fourie has a PhD in Economics from Harvard University, has been Professor of Economics at the University of the Free State since 1982, was appointed Distinguished Professor in 1996, and served as Vice-Chancellor there from 2003–2008. In the 1990s he was founding head of the Unit for Fiscal Analysis at the National Treasury and a member of the first Competition Tribunal. From 2012-2018 he was Research Co-ordinator of the Research Project on Employment, Income Distribution and Inclusive Growth (REDI3x3), based at the University of Cape Town. He is founding editor of the online policy forum Econ3x3 and editor and co-author of The South African informal sector: Creating jobs, reducing poverty (2018). How to think and reason in Philippe Burger FIFTH EDITION How to think and reason in Macroeconomics How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 1 2019/12/17 09:14 How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 2 2019/12/17 09:14 How to think and reason in Macroeconomics Frederick C v N Fourie Philippe Burger How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 3 2019/12/17 09:14 How to think and reason in Macroeconomics First published 1997 Second edition 2001 Third edition 2009 Fourth edition 2015 Fifth edition 2019 Juta and Company (Pty) Ltd First floor, Sunclare Building, 21 Dreyer Street, Claremont 7708 PO Box 14373, Lansdowne 7779, Cape Town, South Africa www.juta.co.za © 2019 Frederick C v N Fourie, Phillippe Burger and Juta and Company (Pty) Ltd ISBN 978 1 48513 047 5 (Print) ISBN 978 1 48513 048 2 (WebPDF) All rights reserved. No part of this publication may be reproduced or transmitted in any form or by any means, electronic or mechanical, including photocopying, recording, or any information storage or retrieval system, without prior permission in writing from the publisher. Subject to any applicable licensing terms and conditions in the case of electronically supplied publications, a person may engage in fair dealing with a copy of this publication for his or her personal or private use, or his or her research or private study. See section 12(1)(a) of the Copyright Act 98 of 1978. Project manager: Seshni Kazadi Editor: Lilané Putter Joubert Proofreader: Lilané Putter Joubert Cover designer: Drag and Drop Typesetter: Wouter Reinders Indexer: Frederick Fourie Typeset in 11 on 13 pt Photina MT Std The author and the publisher believe on the strength of due diligence exercised that this work does not contain any material that is the subject of copyright held by another person. In the alternative, they believe that any protected preexisting material that may be comprised in it has been used with appropriate authority or has been used in circumstances that make such use permissible under the law. How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 4 2019/12/17 09:14 Table of contents Preface��������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������� ix 0. Introduction and orientation: macroeconomics in the South African context�������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������� 1 Part I How does the economy work? 1. Why macroeconomics? An introduction to the issues 1.1 1.2 1.3 1.4 1.5 1.6 1.7 1.8 1.9 2. The basic model I: consumers, producers and government 2.1 2.2 2.3 3. What is macroeconomics?������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������9 How can learning to think and reason in macroeconomics help me?����������������������10 Main macroeconomic problems and policy objectives��������������������������������������������11 The development objective���������������������������������������������������������������������������������������25 Intermediate objectives���������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������30 Conflict between the standard objectives – priorities and trade-offs�����������������������30 Priority choices of the South African government����������������������������������������������������������31 Main perspectives in the economic debate in South Africa�������������������������������������33 Analytical questions and exercises���������������������������������������������������������������������������41 The basic framework�������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������46 The real (or goods) sector ����������������������������������������������������������������������������������������50 Analytical questions and exercises���������������������������������������������������������������������������74 The basic model II: financial institutions, money and interest rates 3.1 The monetary sector and interest rates��������������������������������������������������������������������76 3.2 Linkages between the monetary and the real sectors����������������������������������������������98 3.3 The IS-LM model as a powerful diagrammatical aid���������������������������������������������� 109 3.4Real-world application: The 2007–08 financial crisis – varying investor behaviour and impotent monetary policy�������������������������������������������������������������� 134 3.5 Analytical questions and exercises������������������������������������������������������������������������ 138 4. The basic model III: the foreign sector 4.1 4.2 4.3 4.4 4.5 Background – why trade internationally?��������������������������������������������������������������� 141 Imports, exports and capital flows������������������������������������������������������������������������� 142 The balance of payments and exchange rates������������������������������������������������������ 156 The BoP adjustment process��������������������������������������������������������������������������������� 171 The complete model – the BoP, the exchange rate and the domestic economy��� 172 Table of contents How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 5 v 2019/12/17 09:14 4.6 4.7 4.8 4.9 5. Conflict between internal and external considerations������������������������������������������ 186 The IS-LM-BP model for an open economy����������������������������������������������������������� 188 Real-world application – the Euro crisis and the impact of confidence on international capital flows��������������������������������������������������������������������������������� 204 Analytical questions and exercises������������������������������������������������������������������������ 210 Understanding sectoral coherence and constraints: how to use macroeconomic identities 5.1 From equilibrium conditions to identities��������������������������������������������������������������� 214 5.2 The interpretation of identities – uses and abuses������������������������������������������������ 216 5.3 Expenditure, production and current account deficits������������������������������������������ 219 5.4 The sectoral balance identities������������������������������������������������������������������������������ 219 5.5 The financing of gross capital formation���������������������������������������������������������������� 225 5.6 The SNA at a glance – relationships between subaccounts���������������������������������� 228 5.7 Using the sectoral balance identities for decision making������������������������������������ 232 5.8 Analytical questions and exercises������������������������������������������������������������������������ 234 Addendum 5.1: National accounting definitions and conventions – a student’s guide�������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������� 235 6. A model for an inflationary economy: aggregate demand and supply 6.1 Essentials of the AD-AS model������������������������������������������������������������������������������ 241 6.2 Aggregate demand (AD)����������������������������������������������������������������������������������������� 243 6.3 Aggregate supply (AS)�������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������� 249 6.4 Aggregate supply (ASLR, ASSR) and aggregate demand (AD) together������������������� 272 6.5 Real-world application – the Eskom crisis, GDP and prices���������������������������������� 294 6.6 Analytical questions and exercises������������������������������������������������������������������������ 299 Addendum 6.1: Labour market changes following demand stimulation������������������������� 300 Addendum 6.2: Labour market details following a domestic supply shock�������������������� 301 Addendum 6.3: A complete example of IS-LM-BP and AD-AS for an increase in the repo rate������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������� 302 Addendum 6.4: A complete example of IS-LM-BP and AD-AS for an increase in the price of imported inputs (e.g. oil)����������������������������������������������������������������� 303 7. Extending the model: inflation and policy reactions 7.1 7.2 7.3 8. vi Adjusting the model – inflation-augmented AD and AS curves����������������������������� 306 Managing inflation – policy options and the monetary reaction (MR) function����� 320 Analytical questions and exercises������������������������������������������������������������������������ 327 Macroeconomics in the very long run: growth theory 8.1 8.2 8.3 8.4 The importance of growth�������������������������������������������������������������������������������������� 329 Why growth theory?����������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������� 330 From intuition to formal analysis – from AD-AS to the Solow growth model��������� 332 Rearranging the model – towards income per capita�������������������������������������������� 336 8.5 Sources of sustained growth in – first conclusions�������������������������������������������� 338 8.6 8.7 Is any capital–labour ratio possible? The idea of balanced growth����������������������� 340 Expanding the model – the expanded balanced growth condition����������������������� 344 Y N Table of contents How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 6 2019/12/17 09:14 8.8 Using the model – changes in the balanced growth path due to changing parameters��������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������� 348 8.9 Convergence between low-and-middle-income and high-income countries?������ 354 8.10 Human capital – the previously missing element��������������������������������������������������� 355 8.11 Summary and conclusions������������������������������������������������������������������������������������� 358 8.12 A last word on growth (for now …) ������������������������������������������������������������������������ 361 8.13 Analytical questions and exercises������������������������������������������������������������������������ 362 Addendum 8.1: The Cobb-Douglas production function������������������������������������������������� 363 Addendum 8.2: An illustration of balanced growth – the course of ratios between key variables����������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������� 365 Part II Macroeconomic policy, unemployment, inflation and growth in an open economy 9. Monetary policy: the role of the Reserve Bank 9.1 9.2 9.3 9.4 9.5 9.6 9.7 9.8 9.9 10. Definition and main instruments���������������������������������������������������������������������������� 371 Monetary policy design – four important choices�������������������������������������������������� 376 Inflation targeting in South Africa��������������������������������������������������������������������������� 380 The practice of monetary policy����������������������������������������������������������������������������� 383 Public debt management – the interface between financial markets and fiscal and monetary policy������������������������������������������������������������������������������������� 386 Exchange rate policy and the problems of monetary policy in an open economy�������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������� 389 Real-world application – quantitative easing and ‘creative monetary policy’ in the USA��������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������� 392 Monetary policy and the ownership of the Reserve Bank������������������������������������� 394 Analytical questions and exercises������������������������������������������������������������������������ 394 Fiscal policy: the role of government 10.1 State, government and public sector��������������������������������������������������������������������� 397 10.2 Definition and instruments of fiscal policy������������������������������������������������������������� 397 10.3 The choice of overarching policy objectives���������������������������������������������������������� 402 10.4 Constraints on fiscal policy choices���������������������������������������������������������������������� 405 10.5 The decision on the main fiscal aggregates����������������������������������������������������������� 411 10.6 Public debt and public debt management������������������������������������������������������������� 431 10.7 Fiscal discipline and fiscal norms�������������������������������������������������������������������������� 436 10.8 Fiscal policy and development – broader criteria�������������������������������������������������� 451 10.9 Analytical questions and exercises������������������������������������������������������������������������ 452 Addendum 10.1: Measuring aggregate government expenditure����������������������������������� 454 Addendum 10.2: Measuring government revenue and the deficit����������������������������������� 459 11. Policy problems: coordination, lags and schools of thought 11.1 Monetary vs. fiscal policy?������������������������������������������������������������������������������������� 461 11.2 Policy problems������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������ 464 11.3 The larger problem – different schools of thought������������������������������������������������� 467 Table of contents How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 7 vii 2019/12/17 09:14 12. Inflation, unemployment and low growth: causes and remedies 12.1 12.2 12.3 12.4 12.5 12.6 12.7 Inflation������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������� 481 Unemployment������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������� 501 Low economic growth�������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������� 528 Inclusive growth and development������������������������������������������������������������������������ 553 Policy design in practice – the National Development Plan����������������������������������� 558 A final thought – the structural dimension of macroeconomic problems�������������� 564 Analytical questions and exercises������������������������������������������������������������������������ 565 Index��������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������������� 568 viii Table of contents How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 8 2019/12/17 09:14 Preface How to think and reason in macroeconomics – a South African text. Why the complicated title? First, this textbook purposefully and methodically teaches the reader how to think and reason about economic behaviour, real-life processes and change in macroeconomics – not merely how to manipulate a set of theoretical equations or shift a few curves around. (After all, the economy does not have curves.) Secondly, the text continually situates the analysis and comprehension of economic processes in the South African context. Thus the reader will learn extensively about: ❐ relevant data and data sources to underpin understanding; ❐ economic institutions that shape economic processes, including policy institutions and the political-economic landscape; ❐ policies that could be used (but also misused) in the pursuit of macroeconomic objectives such as high employment, low inflation and steady growth; as well as ❐ broader considerations such as human development and inclusive growth – with South Africa being an (upper-) middle-income country relative to peer countries in Africa and elsewhere, as well as high-income countries. But what does this really entail? Combining intuitive understanding and sophisticated analysis Modern macroeconomics, especially in advanced and postgraduate courses, typically aims to equip students with the ability to manipulate complex mathematical models of the economy. Yet one finds graduates with a first or advanced degree in economics who still do not have the ability to analyse and converse about the basic operation and dynamics of the economy, for example in response to cyclical or policy effects, or international economic shocks. Economics graduates often have very limited knowledge of the institutions, processes and data – and often feel they have to ‘unlearn’ or disregard prior ‘academic’ studies when they start work as practising economists in the private or public sectors. Our point of departure is that theoretical insights and refinements should always be rooted in a thorough intuitive understanding of economic behaviour, processes, data and institutions. Without a solid intuitive understanding, technical wizardry and theoretical sophistication have limited value in practice. ❐ Therefore, in this text, topics typically evolve from a thorough intuitive understanding through increasing levels of theoretical sophistication up to the theoretical rigour found in standard intermediate macroeconomics texts. Preface How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 9 ix 2019/12/17 09:14 In addition, without the ability to situate theoretical insights in the real-life institutional context, theory becomes almost sterile. The practices of institutions such as the central bank or national treasury, or ratings agencies and labour unions, often have as large a bearing on economic processes and outcomes as the behaviour of individuals or businesses. Also, it is important to have a sense of economic magnitudes: to know when a statistic or number, mentioned by some commentator or churned out by an analyst, sounds plausible … or just could not be right. ❐ In this book, pertinent institutional and historical information as well as data tables, graphs and tips continually reinforce the link between theory (abstraction) and reality. This also provides a confidence-building experience to students who could easily have a sense of alienation if confronted with economic theory only. So what? Let’s reason To contribute to active learning and a higher knowledge retention rate, the text has been written in an interactive style. Expositions are interspersed with questions and stimulating data, or a fascinating institutional backdrop. Students are encouraged to ask questions about the operation of the economy: Why do things happen? How does the process actually occur? How do the institutions operate? So what? What happens next? Why does it matter? Such a habit of thinking and asking questions makes the acquired insights ‘active’ and ready for application. In the same way, the policy chapters do not provide recipes to ‘solve’ macroeconomics. They demonstrate how intelligent economic analysis can help one to think more effectively and make fewer policy mistakes. All of this will help to impart to users of the book (both students and practitioners) an enduring and satisfying understanding of – and the ability to think and reason about – macroeconomics in South Africa. Exhaustive experience with this approach to lecturing macroeconomics has shown that students retain significantly more knowledge and insights, even years afterwards, than with conventional mostly theoretical analysis. They also feel confident in discussing both theory and its practical aspects – and to think on their feet. Learning routes – a choice of difficulty level A distinguishing characteristic of the book is that the reader can choose to read and engage with the subject matter, and especially the theory, at different levels of difficulty. Thus it affords access at different levels of complexity, progressively providing deeper insights and higher analytical capabilities. These levels are: ❐ a mainly intuitive route, or level, using chain-reaction arguments in which a sequence of changes in variables unfold, accompanied by relatively simple theory, basic equations and basic diagrams; then moving on to ❐ a more theoretical level, where the sequence of changes is depicted and analysed with more complex equations and diagrammatical aids such as the IS-LM-BP model and the AD-AS or AD'-PC curves (see below); then, if desired, ❐ a more advanced level, using mathematical derivations and analysis presented in a parallel series of ‘maths boxes’; these show the relevant mathematical derivations and manipulations alongside the intuitive, chain-reaction and diagrammatical analyses – to fully deepen understanding. x Preface How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 10 2019/12/17 09:14 Learning how macroeconomic changes unfold: from chain reactions to time-paths and animations A key objective is for the reader or student to develop a ‘feel’ for the economy: how macroeconomic changes in fact are dynamic processes that unfold and evolve, rather than being jumps from one static equilibrium to the next – which is not how people experience the economy. The first tool is the extensive use of chain reactions in analysing economic behaviour. Based on the basic theories of consumption, investment, etc., the reader learns to construct sequences of likely effects as disturbances spread from one variable to another and one sector to another. This creates a real sense of how things unfold over the business cycle or in response to an external shock or a policy intervention. Building on this, novel time-path diagrams demonstrate the possible course of several variables unfolding over time, affording a strong real-world feel to examples of the consequences of macroeconomic disturbances or policy steps. A related feature is the explicit clarification of the short, medium and long run. This develops the reader’s understanding of the time dimension of disturbances and various adjustment processes in the money market, balance of payments and aggregate supply. The culmination of this is a new online learning aid, animations of key diagrams, ideal for the video generation. These are vastly effective in giving readers a sense of dynamics and changes in the economy. The analysis is not limited to comparing equilibrium points, but can be seen as ‘live’ dynamic shifts of curves that move a point of intersection on the way to a new equilibrium. These analytical visuals are paired with the time-path diagrams, showing the corresponding course of the variables over time live – movies of the economy changing and adapting to cycles, shocks and policies. Enthusiastic feedback from lecturers and students indicates that the animations add significantly to one’s understanding of macroeconomic forces and dynamics. These animations are available online free of charge to students for use on laptops, tablets and cell phones and can be accessed on the following websites: ❐ www.ufs.ac.za/macroecon ❐ https://jutapassmasters.co.za/learning/search.php?search=how+to+think PowerPoint slides of all the diagrams in the book, with hyperlinks to the animations, are available to lecturers. The slides provide a seamless transition from static diagrams to animations in the lecture room (providing wi-fi is available). These slides can be downloaded at: ❐ https://jutapassmasters.co.za/learning/search.php?search=how+to+think Major features in terms of content As an integral part of a distinctive approach to teaching macroeconomics and situating it in the South African context, the book differentiates itself also with regard to content. Chapter 0 contains some detail on this. Here we only note a few. Preface How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 11 xi 2019/12/17 09:14 An open-economy approach throughout An important characteristic of this book is the explicit incorporation of the fact that South Africa has a very open economy, strongly subject to international economic forces. Whereas many textbooks consider the macroeconomic implications of international trade and capital flows only in the final chapters, if at all, here they are incorporated throughout the text, starting in the first chapters. Chapter 4 sets out these intricacies in depth and provides a level of analysis not often accessible to readers of macroeconomics textbooks. This should make the reader very comfortable with discussions of, for example, the balance of payments, exchange rates, the gold price and the impact of events in South Africa’s main trade partners on the local economy. The emerging-market, middle-income and African context The book illuminates the development context of the South Africa economy. From the first chapter it situates the standard macroeconomic issues and policy objectives in the circumstance of South Africa as a middle-income country and emerging-market economy in Africa. A brief overview of the definition, measurement and analysis of human development is presented, also with reference to the Sustainable Development Goals (SDGs). Attention is given to development aspects by means of informative boxes and explicit discussions of, for instance, the link between economic growth and human and institutional development, as well as HIV and Aids (see chapters 8 and 12). The first chapter also includes perspectives on the political-economic elements of race, class, capitalism and apartheid that continue to shape the economic policy and development debate in South Africa. Unemployment – and structural unemployment There is thorough coverage of the labour market and unemployment, particularly recognising the role of labour-market features such as segmentation and entry barriers, as well as the informal sector. This neatly complements a key feature of the book, i.e. the analysis of structural unemployment – something economists and policymakers need to engage with seriously. Structural unemployment is included in the theory, data and policy discussion in several chapters. In the theoretical model the treatment of unemployment and a long-run equilibrium output level is couched in a way that explicitly accommodates the existence of structural unemployment and a structural rate of unemployment (SRU) – while retaining easy comparability with texts and theory from abroad. (Such texts usually have very little to say about structural unemployment in low- and middle-income countries.) The final chapter provides a thorough analysis of the causes of voluntary and involuntary unemployment – and structural unemployment in particular. This includes possible links to the development trajectory, demography, health and education status, technology and capital intensity, sectoral factors, labour unions and labour mobility, social welfare, migrant labour, etc. This informs a critical discussion of possible policy interventions, including the limitations of conventional macroeconomic policy instruments to address this problem. Supply-side analysis quite exhaustive In standard textbook presentations of the AD-AS model, the aggregate supply side often gets only cursory treatment. This book presents a more exhaustive treatment of the xii Preface How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 12 2019/12/17 09:14 aggregate supply side (in chapter 6) to match the depth of the derivation of the aggregate demand side. The short- and long-run aggregate supply (AS) curves are derived from behaviour in the labour market, using price-setting and wage-setting relationships in a context that recognises imperfect competition and institutional rigidities in product and labour markets. Differences between expected and actual prices explain the difference between the short-run and long-run AS curves as well as related supply adjustment processes towards a long-run, or structural, equilibrium. This well-grounded derivation of the AS curve enables a much better analysis of supply shocks, revealing new nuances and complexities, also in the policy context. Inflation integrated from the start Another distinctive feature is having an intensive and integrated treatment of inflation and the inflationary context. While a variable price level is only formally introduced in the AD-AS model in chapter 6 and inflation in chapter 7, the distinction between nominal and real variables is present in the first theory chapters. This enables the investment function to be stated as a function of the real rate of interest, and the money demand function as a function of the nominal interest rate. Secondly, in chapter 7, a theoretical framework is provided that prepares the reader to analyse macroeconomic shocks and adjustments in a setting where inflation is a permanent phenomenon. It combines an inflationaugmented AD curve with inflation-augmented AS curves – the short- and long-run Phillips (or PC) curves. Also included is a discussion of monetary reaction (MR) functions, typically associated with inflation-targeting policy regimes. The final chapter then deals exhaustively with the measurement, causes and remedies of inflation in South Africa. Economic growth theory – in a way everyone can understand In many macroeconomics courses, growth theory is often disregarded, or otherwise experienced by students as murky and somewhat disconnected from macroeconomic models that focus on the business cycle, unemployment and inflation. The treatment in this book is a natural extension of the theory of aggregate supply in a time frame stretching from the short and medium run to the long run and very long run. This presentation of growth theory (chapter 8) provides a novel, intuitive and insightful grasp of the idea of balanced growth paths. The exposition starts from a simple Solow model, but soon broadens to include aspects such as social and economic institutions, thus also linking growth theory to human capital and human development. Here the animations are particularly useful in grasping the technicalities of one of the more challenging topics in macroeconomics. The section in the final chapter on the measurement, causes and remedies of low growth in South Africa also considers aspects particularly relevant to many African countries, e.g. human capital, income inequality, institutions, political barriers, culture, trust, ethnicity, social division and geography. The relationship between economic growth and the environment is also discussed. A window on the real worlds of monetary and fiscal policy making The text conveys a solid feel for the real world of policy making: the difficult choices policymakers face and the constraints they have to deal with. In addition, the institutional dimension is incorporated throughout, revealing the actual policy-making processes in the National Treasury and the Reserve Bank. For example, in addition to analyses of the Preface How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 13 xiii 2019/12/17 09:14 role and impact of monetary policy steps, chapter 9 explains the key choices in the design of monetary policy (objectives, instruments, targets, including inflation targeting), as well as the practice of monetary policy, i.e. monetary monitoring combined with basic monetary policy making such as the determination of the repo rate by the Monetary Policy Committee (MPC). The chapter on fiscal policy is especially rich in this regard, distinguishing this book from most others. The role and financing of government are central to the intense debates on service delivery, public sector wages, government expenditure on health or higher education (or Eskom bail-outs), VAT and income tax, the budget deficit and growing public debt (and the hazard of ratings downgrades). Chapter 10 provides essential insights and methods of analysis. It draws extensively on the practical experience of the authors in either working in or advising the National Treasury, putting across an authentic sense of how decisions are made in the budget process amidst complex constraints. Also shown is how to make sense of public finance numbers and use fiscal yardsticks. Using the national accounting identities as a tool to understand sectoral coherence and constraints The national accounts can be a dry subject area, dominated by definitions and accounting conventions. But one can engage with the topic without doing accounting. Indeed, chapter 5 provides a unique treatment of the national accounting identities: as powerful tools to bolster logical-intuitive reasoning and analyses of macroeconomic change. It becomes a tool to understand the accounting-type coherence between sectors of the economy – the numbers must add up, must balance – as well as underlying constraints on macroeconomic change and adjustments. Along the way the reader will acquire a working understanding of the System of National Accounts and important South African data sources. Extensive case studies and real-world applications In addition to real-world examples throughout the book, there are several major case studies with full diagrammatical analysis and animations. These include the 2007–08 international financial crisis, quantitative easing and ‘creative monetary policy’ in the USA, the Euro-zone public-debt crisis, as well as the ongoing Eskom crisis in South Africa and its impact on gross domestic product (GDP) growth and inflation. Changes in the fifth edition The focus on the South African context, including its status as an upper-middle-income country in the Southern Africa Development Community (SADC) and Africa, already was present in the earlier editions. In this edition the quest to integrate the appropriate context into the analysis has been sharpened and made more explicit, also in data boxes, applications, examples and exercises. All policy sections have been freshly updated to incorporate the newest policy approaches as well as institutional changes in South Africa. Major policy initiatives, such as the National Development Plan (which appears to be back on the table under president Ramaphosa), are thoroughly discussed. Also noted are controversies relating to the mandate and ownership of the Reserve Bank, frequent changes in Ministers of Finance, the public debt issue, as well as the impact of recent political dynamics. The book retains its unique, institution-rich treatment of the complex role of government in macroeconomic relationships, events, policies and official South African data. xiv Preface How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 14 2019/12/17 09:14 Other updates include the implications of major changes in South Africa’s international trade patterns, as well as recent international shocks such as Brexit and US president Donald Trump’s trade war with China. On the development front it includes sections on the SDGs and the Inclusive Development Index, developed by the World Economic Forum, to complement the section on the United Nations Development Programme’s (UNDP) Inclusiveness Index, which measures inclusive growth. All data tables and graphs have been updated and new internet sources provided. Numerous new analytical exercises and questions at the end of chapters engage with recent developments in South Africa and internationally. These include Brexit, China’s prominence and the possibility of South Africa having to request assistance – a bail-out – from the International Monetary Fund (IMF). August 2019 Preface How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 15 xv 2019/12/17 09:14 How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 16 2019/12/17 09:14 Introduction and orientation: macroeconomics in the South African context 0 The objective of this book is to teach you to think and reason about macroeconomic events as well as policy issues such as the balance of payments, inflation, unemployment and economic growth in the South African context. The book strives to teach an active way of thinking in the particular setting of South Africa as an upper-middle-income (or ‘developing’1) country and emerging-market economy – not dry, static theory with no real-world, historical or institutional context, or situated in a European, British or American context. Consequently, the subject matter is presented in a particular style that makes it something between a textbook and a workbook, encouraging you to participate actively in developing macroeconomic thinking skills – it is a think-and-work textbook. ‘Activity boxes’ challenge the reader to find information or formulate a viewpoint on an issue, while other boxes highlight interesting facts and events in the South African economy (including its institutions and its international economic relations with the Americas, Europe, Asia and Africa). To give you a real sense of cycles and other changes in the economy, we provide – on the internet – animations of key diagrams. Thus the analysis of shocks and policy impacts is not limited to comparative statics (comparing static equilibrium points) but can be seen as dynamic shifts of curves that move a point of intersection on a path to a new equilibrium. These movies also show how the expected paths of variables unfold over time. Theory becomes live action that embeds a much more intimate understanding of macroeconomic change and processes. The animations are available free of charge on the following websites: ❐ www.ufs.ac.za/macroecon ❐ https://jutapassmasters.co.za/learning/search.php?search=how+to+think 1 A categorisation of countries using the terms ‘developing’ and ‘developed’ – to distinguish poorer and richer countries – has been the standard internationally. However, we approve of a recent policy change by the World Bank to stop using them. The two terms group countries that are very dissimilar, do not recognise that development challenges and poverty exist also in the richest countries and that all countries always are developing; the terms also suggest a patronising attitude. The World Bank distinguishes four groups, based on Gross National Income (GNI) per capita: low-income countries, lower-middle-income and upper-middle-income countries, and then high-income countries. South Africa is an upper-middle-income country. [At the moment (2019) the United Nations still uses these terms (said to be ‘for convenience’), while the International Monetary Fund (IMF) distinguishes between ‘advanced economies’ and all others as ‘emerging market and developing economies’.] Chapter 0: Introduction and orientation: macroeconomics in the South African context How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 1 1 2019/12/17 09:14 Part I presents the basic theoretical framework. Chapter 1 sets the scene. After a brief introduction to macroeconomics as a field and its usefulness to you as a citizen and other role-players in society, the main macroeconomic problems and issues are described. These also constitute the main macroeconomic policy objectives, as practised by policymakers in the fields of, notably, fiscal and monetary policy – within the broader development context of a middle-income country such as South Africa (within SADC and sub-Saharan Africa). Unemployment, one of the most severe economic problems in South Africa, receives prominent attention. A brief overview of the definition, measurement and analysis of human development is presented, showing South Africa’s human development status relative to relevant other countries. The chapter also provides a backdrop to understanding the macroeconomic policy debate in South Africa. This includes a rudimentary outline of the main schools of thought in economics – from Marxism to the two major mainstream approaches – as well as an introduction to political-economic views (from the left to the right) on race, class, capitalism and apartheid that continue to impact the macroeconomic policy debate in South Africa. This political-economic background traverses the period from colonial times, the Glen Grey Act of 1894 and the Natives Land Act of 1913 to the 1948 election victory of the National Party, the Freedom Charter of 1955, the ANC’s armed struggle and the 1994 democratic election and beyond. The text covers the main topics and components at the level of a second-year course in macroeconomics or a third-year course in macroeconomic policy. While it generally assumes prior knowledge of the basic Keynesian model at an introductory economics level, this is not absolutely essential. In the first theory chapter (chapter 2), on the real sector, the fundamental topics are reviewed, notably the role of expenditure – consumption, investment, government expenditure, exports and imports – in determining the level of output and real income in an economy. (The role of the supply side of the economy is introduced in chapter 6.) Crucial intuitive insights and analytical abilities are developed, notably the construction of logical sequences of events, i.e. the use of chain reasoning. This ability will aid you considerably in thinking and reasoning about real-world economic events and policy in South Africa and elsewhere, especially disturbances and resulting short-run fluctuations (i.e. the business cycle), as well as the role of the National Treasury and the national budget. Chapter 3 explains the operation of the monetary sector of the economy in a way that marries theoretical analysis and the everyday operation of money and capital markets in South Africa. After studying this chapter, you should feel comfortable with discussions of financial institutions, financial markets, interest rates and the Reserve Bank in the financial news media, and understand the linkages between the financial world and real economic activities (consumption, investment, production, employment, exports, imports and so forth). You will be able to construct more complex chain reactions that link the monetary and real sectors. Together, the first two theory chapters provide you with most of the analytical insights usually found in the so-called IS-LM model, which is a powerful diagrammatic aid and is standard fare in intermediate macroeconomics textbooks. After an intuitive introduction to the model and its uses, the more formal aspects of the theory are explained in an accessible way. The presentation of the IS-LM model and its mathematics illustrates an important characteristic of the book. It enables you to read and understand the theory at different levels, as follows. 2 Chapter 0: Introduction and orientation How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 2 2019/12/17 09:14 (a) A strongly intuitive understanding with the help of chain-reaction arguments and relatively simple diagrams, enabling you to develop an intuitive and real-world approach to economic reasoning. This promotes a thorough understanding of economic processes rather than mechanics – a major benefit. (b) A more theoretical level with the help of more complex diagrammatical aids such as the IS-LM model; or (c) The complete package of intermediate-level models coupled with and aided by mathematical derivations and analysis in ‘maths boxes’. The chapter ends with an extensive case study relating to the 2007–08 financial crisis, which impacted the entire world economy. It is demonstrated how the two-sector ISLM model can be used to explain the course of events in the USA – the housing bubble, quantitative easing and so forth – and how it pushed South Africa into a major recession. The South African economy is an open economy, strongly subject to international economic forces. A special characteristic of this book is the strong and explicit focus on the open economy. Whereas many textbooks consider the macroeconomic implications of international trade and capital flows only in the final chapters, here they are incorporated throughout the text, starting in chapters 2 and 3. Chapter 4 sets out these intricacies in depth and provides a level of analysis not often accessible to students in macroeconomics textbooks. This should make you very comfortable with discussions of, for example, the South African balance of payments, exchange rates and the gold price. Chain reactions here also include external elements and disturbances originating in other countries, including the balance of payments adjustment process (which could be different for South Africa than for high-income economies). Also included is the growing role, in South African imports and exports, of China and other Asian as well as African and SADC countries – though economic conditions in the USA and Europe continue to influence the South African economy intensely. ❐ You will encounter all the results of the IS-LM-BP model. After an intuitive introduction to the model and its uses, the more formal aspects of the theory are explained in an accessible way. ❐ Again, you can choose the extent to which you want to engage with the formal model. (As noted before, there are many benefits to mastering the full model.) This chapter also ends with an extensive real-world application: it explains the Euro crisis that started in 2010 following a debt crisis in Greece and other countries, the subsequent attempts of Germany to address this Eurozone problem, international repercussions and so forth. It provides a fascinating demonstrating of the usefulness of the IS-LM-BP model in analysing such a complex chain of events, including the impact on South Africa.. Macroeconomics in the real world is intimately involved with numbers. Understanding and interpreting macroeconomics statistics are essential skills for any economist, business person or modern citizen. Throughout the text you will encounter relevant quantitative information on the South African economy. Much of this is to be found in ‘data tip’ boxes, and in some cases you are prompted to find or calculate certain numbers yourself. You will also be alerted to the many dangers inherent in analysing economic data. The approach taken is in line with the view of the great British economist Joan Robinson on the purpose of studying economics: The purpose of studying economics is not to acquire a set of ready-made answers to economic questions, but to learn how to avoid being deceived by economists. Chapter 0: Introduction and orientation How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 3 3 2019/12/17 09:14 The insights into data provided here, as well as the thinking skills you will acquire throughout the book, should enable you to evaluate economic arguments and data interpretation in the news media with a critical eye. Tables and graphs depicting the course of important macroeconomic variables in South Africa during the last three decades can be found in most of the chapters, and information regarding the measurement of data in a specific area of analysis in chapters 5 and 10. A further dimension of economic numbers is that, in terms of the measured values of the variables, they must and will remain within an encompassing set of constraints. These are rooted in an accounting-type coherence between different sectors – the numbers must add up, must balance. This coherence is captured in special equations, called identities, involving key variables. These identities are derived from the national accounts, which have an important role in ‘keeping the books’ of a country. The national accounts can be a dry subject area, dominated by definitions and accounting conventions. But here we do not do accounting at all. Indeed, chapter 5 provides a unique treatment. You will see how these national accounting identities constitute a powerful additional tool of analysis for the economist – a tool to understand the coherence between sectors of the economy as well as underlying constraints on macroeconomic change and adjustments. Along the way you will acquire a working understanding of the System of National Accounts and important South African data sources. At the same time you will be alerted to the misuse, by some ‘experts’, of the national accounting relationships. Though inflation appears to be less of a problem in South Africa and internationally now, compared to earlier decades, it remains a key factor, and always-present risk, in macroeconomics. In chapter 6 you will acquire the ability to understand, from a macroeconomic point of view, the forces acting on the average price level (in an open economy). This knowledge is the foundation for the in-depth discussion of inflation in chapters 7 and 12. Chapter 6 shows how the analysis of expenditure, or the aggregate demand (AD) side of the economy – found in chapters 2 to 4 – must be supplemented with an analysis of aggregate supply (AS) if the simultaneous determination of real income and the average price level is to be understood. The theory of aggregate supply is rooted in economic behaviour in the labour market, where the demand of firms for labour is related to their price-setting behaviour in product markets, and where unions play an important role in setting wages, as is the case in South Africa. At the same time, the presence of structural unemployment, especially in the South African context, is highlighted. An important element of aggregate supply theory is the existence of both a long-run and a short-run aggregate supply (AS) curve. This leads to important conclusions on mediumrun adjustments on the supply side following short-run disturbances (whether on the demand or the supply side). The Eskom capacity crisis and its impact on the South African economy is the subject of the case study in this chapter. The power of the AD-AS model in analysing the short- and long-run effects of such a bottleneck on GDP growth and the price level (and inflation) is demonstrated clearly. Chapter 7 adapts the AD-AS model, which is designed to explain changes in the average price level, to a model that explains inflation as such, i.e. sustained increases in the price level over the years. The adapted AD-PC model has the AS curve renamed as the Phillips curve (PC-curve). The model strengthens your ability to analyse short-run cycles and disturbances in the context of an economy where inflation is a permanent phenomenon. The attention thus shifts to explaining increases or decreases in the rate of inflation rather than in just the price level. Important lessons for policymakers are derived. The chapter 4 Chapter 0: Introduction and orientation How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 4 2019/12/17 09:14 also provides an analysis of typical anti-inflation policy by central banks, and the kind of policy reactions one can expect if the Reserve Bank adopts an approach of steering the economy towards a targeted inflation rate or interval (which indeed is the case). Chapter 8 takes the analysis of the supply side (or production side) further by focusing on the very long run, where economic growth (or the lack of it) is the prime concern. While short-run fluctuations are very important for the well-being of people in a country, their long-run welfare and standard of living depend much more on the long-run economic growth trend – specifically, whether it is sufficient to increase income per person (or, per capita income). Economic growth theory tries to explain the factors that determine either low or high rates of growth in output (and thus income per capita). The concept of a ‘balanced growth path’ is important in this context. The role of capital goods and technology is highlighted, as is the crucial role of human skills, human development and ‘human capital’. You will also see how important the development of social and economic institutions is to economic growth and development. Chapter 8 also completes part I of the book, which comprises the basic macroeconomic model for an open, inflationary and growing economy, as applied to South Africa. Part II deals with macroeconomic policy and institutions, such as the South African Reserve Bank and the National Treasury while focusing on the problems of inflation, unemployment and low economic growth. If you wish to skip the policy and institutional discussion, you can go directly to chapter 12 – the analysis of inflation, unemployment and low growth. You should be able to follow most of it, although you will be less equipped to understand fully the policy debates on these three problems. Chapters 9 and 10 focus on macroeconomic policy, i.e. monetary policy (including exchange rate policy) and fiscal policy. The standard analytical insights with regard to policy are developed, using the logical-intuitive method encountered earlier. In addition, you will get a feel for the real world of policy making: the difficult choices policymakers face and the constraints they have to deal with. The institutional dimension – which may often be more decisive than formal economic knowledge – is incorporated throughout the discussion, revealing the actual policy-making processes in the National Treasury and the Reserve Bank. The chapter on fiscal policy is especially rich in this regard, and is something that distinguishes this book from most other textbooks that are available. In the current South African debate, the role of government as revealed in the annual budget is a key and often divisive issue. It dominates many an economic argument – consider the intense debates on service delivery, government expenditure on health or higher education or housing, taxation, the budget deficit or public debt. It is therefore one area that you should be able to analyse with some comfort. Chapter 10 is designed to give you the necessary insights and methods of analysis. It pays particular attention to helping you evaluate the fiscal state of the economy, using various fiscal yardsticks. It draws extensively on the practical experience of the authors in the fiscal policy field in South Africa. ❐ This is one area where Joan Robinson’s adage (on page 3) is most pertinent. It is also one of the most exciting areas of macroeconomics, as the frenzy surrounding budget day reveals. Throughout the text you will be aware of the fact that economics is a science within which major differences of opinion exist. These are often related to deep-seated philosophical differences on the functioning of a market economy – consider the debate on capitalism versus socialism, which is still very much alive behind the scenes in South Africa, despite appearances to the contrary. Chapter 0: Introduction and orientation How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 5 5 2019/12/17 09:14 In capitalism, man exploits man. In socialism, it’s exactly the other way around. Anonymous The debate on the budget (chapter 10) clearly illustrates these philosophical differences. As background, chapter 1 has set out three main protagonists: Marxist thought, and then the two major mainstream macroeconomic protagonists, i.e. the Keynesians/New Keynesians and the Monetarists/New Classicals. You will not be able really to understand the high emotions surrounding macroeconomic issues if you do not understand the basic differences between the latter two mainstream schools of thought, with the Marxist school of thought always present. This is especially true of the policy debate, where the different views also present the policymaker with serious problems. Whom should the policymaker believe? Chapter 11 explains the main differences and policy problems in this regard. (You will also encounter some other practical problems in executing policy, e.g. policy lags.) After all the analysis and discussions of chapters 1 to 11, the scene is set for the final chapter: an in-depth analysis of the three major macroeconomic problems of inflation, unemployment and low economic growth. The Monetarist/New Classical and New Keynesian views are analysed and compared. It becomes apparent that conventional macroeconomic analysis is not sufficient fully to understand the causes or to design appropriate policy remedies. The severity of these problems appears to derive from more fundamental, structural dimensions of a market economy, especially in a middle-income country such as South Africa. This is especially true with regard to unemployment and the prevalence of structural unemployment, which requires remedies other than macroeconomic policy measures. Examples include: skills and education policy, competition policy, employmentintensive industrial policy, the strengthening of the informal sector, and land reform. Consequently, this last chapter also broadens your understanding to include elements outside conventional macroeconomics, such as human capital, income inequality, institutions, culture, trust and social division, geography and the environment. After all, economic life does not exist in a vacuum – it is part of the larger social fabric, and it has to be analysed as such. The chapter ends with a discussion of inclusive development and inclusive growth, concepts in the South African debate that integrate several concerns: about growth, about unemployment, about poverty and inequality as well as human development. This is followed by a real-world policy application: an explanation and critical analysis of the National Development Plan, which may shape macroeconomic and other important policies for the next 10 years and beyond, depending on whether and how it is implemented. So, there it is. Now read – and enjoy thinking and reasoning about macroeconomic events and policy in complex South Africa! Legend for icons ! ✍ Take note box Activity box π Maths box Animation available The data tip box is self-explanatory. 6 Chapter 0: Introduction and orientation How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 6 2019/12/17 09:14 Part I How does the economy work? A basic model for an open, inflationary economy How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 7 2019/12/17 09:14 How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 8 2019/12/17 09:14 Why macroeconomics? An introduction to the issues 1 After reading this chapter, you should be able to: explain what macroeconomics entails and why it is useful to you and others; interpret the main concerns that typically are the focus of macroeconomics; identify and explain the standard objectives of macroeconomic policy; analyse and assess the complexities involved in defining and pursuing these objectives in a country such as South Africa, including the potential for conflict between objectives; and ■ integrate macroeconomic objectives in a broader development context, and evaluate the relative importance of macroeconomic goals in the broader social context in South Africa. ■ ■ ■ ■ It goes without saying that the state, health and course of a country’s economy matter a great deal. The material welfare of every household and individual in South Africa, as in other countries, depends decisively on the state of affairs in the economy, now and in the future. It is important to understand whether times are good or bad, so that people can comprehend what is happening to them and can deal with it to their benefit, or so that policymakers can take corrective action to try to moderate the turn of events, if required. To do this, one must gain an understanding of how things work. 1.1 What is macroeconomics? The economy comprises millions of individuals, workers and families, and thousands of businesses, as well as labour unions and other organisations, all engaged in millions of activities and transactions. For many purposes this is too much to make sense of in its disaggregated multiplicity. What macroeconomics does is to simplify that multiplicity into a broad, aggregate grasp on the cumulative and summary impact of all those millions of actions. (Other branches of economics, e.g. microeconomics or labour economics, consider the detail of small chunks of the economy or specific dimensions of economic behaviour.) So macroeconomics is about understanding the course and ‘behaviour’ of the economy as a whole – not just for the fun of it, but because the behaviour of that ‘whole’ influences the lives and welfare of the millions of individuals and families that make up the economy. These influences flow from macroeconomic phenomena such as the business cycle (upswings, downswings, recessions and depressions), unemployment, inflation and economic growth. In addition, they form the basis for macroeconomic policy steps by a government that is trying to improve the lives of citizens by ameliorating negative experiences (such as economic instability, high inflation, high unemployment and poverty) and enhancing positive processes such as economic growth, employment and development. 1.1 What is macroeconomics? How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 9 9 2019/12/17 09:14 1.2 How can learning to think and reason in macroeconomics help me? An individual, a household or a firm cannot control the macroeconomic ebbs and flows of a country, or the actions of policymakers. But one can understand these things better, learn better to anticipate events or policy steps using best available information, and prepare better to weather the storms or to exploit opportunities due to economic disturbances and changes. At the very least one can feel less bewildered about the waves and storms, the ups and downs of living in a country that is inevitably part of a global economy beset by a multitude of forces and dynamics. More specifically, politicians, civil servants, business people, labour unions, farmers, mineworkers, families and individuals need to understand the waves and storms that surround and threaten their efforts to make a dignified and decent livelihood. For instance, an understanding of macroeconomics will be relevant to the following: ❐ An individual afraid of losing her job due to a recession – a recession that can originate locally, or in economic events far away in the USA or Japan (such as the ‘subprime’ financial crisis of 2007–08 or the subsequent Eurozone crisis). ❐ Individuals hoping to get a job due to new factories being erected by private companies, or roads being constructed through public works programmes. ❐ Retired people afraid of having their savings and pensions eroded by inflation. What will the interest rate on bonds do? What will the stock market do? ❐ Young people concerned about their future income and wealth prospects or being unable to find jobs despite economic growth, or families concerned about the impact of their mortgage interest rate on their monthly budget. ❐ Businesses involved in strategic and annual planning of output and entrepreneurial initiatives and not wanting to be caught unawares – or clueless – by interest rate changes, exchange rate fluctuations, a slump or upsurge in sales for which they did not prepare. This is the essence of understanding the business cycle: having some ability to comprehend the state of the cycle and roughly anticipate prospects for the coming year or two. ❐ Businesses and farmers facing the danger, in good times, of investing and expanding as if the good times will never end, likewise the danger, in bad times, of cutting back and not investing as if the bad times will never end. ❐ Farmers planning major export initiatives for their product, but who are concerned about possible changes in the exchange rate or in sales prospects abroad. ❐ Farmers or factories concerned about the effect of the international oil price on their input costs (diesel, etc.). ❐ Voters contemplating which political party’s economic policy is the best – whether it is budgetary policy, interest rate policy, exchange rate policy, anti-inflation policy, growth and development policy (such as the National Development Plan), environmental policy or other policies. ❐ Labour unions needing to understand the state of the business cycle to gauge their bargaining power in wage negotiations, whether (and how) to incorporate some expectation of future inflation into their negotiations (including the expected impact of likely policy steps on inflation expectations), and also how excessive wage claims can impact on the pursuit of other important national goals such as the containment of inflation. ❐ NGO or government officials and politicians caring about equity and social justice, or at least the social consequences of economic shocks and policies. 10 Chapter 1: Why macroeconomics? An introduction to the issues How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 10 2019/12/17 09:14 ❐ Anybody who wants to understand why poverty and unemployment remain high despite economic stimulation and growth, and why so much economic inequality exists amidst more than a decade of successful global and domestic economic growth (since the mid-1990s up to 2008). Whoever you are, at the very least you need to have a minimum level of macroeconomic literacy: understanding the news, understanding economists, understanding public debate on economic policy (the Treasury and the budget, the Reserve Bank and the repo rate); understanding news reports on national and international economic events – unemployment rates, interest rates, the inflation rate, the exchange rate, the gold price, the oil price, US interest rates, China’s economic growth, Europe’s debt crisis and struggles with Brexit, the implications of economic growth or natural disasters in SADC and subSaharan Africa, the effects of climate change on the economy, and so forth. The macroeconomic dimensions noted above can be summarised as comprising the following: ❐ The short- to medium-run pattern and trend, notably the business cycle and fluctuations in aggregate expenditure (or demand), output and employment, and ways possibly to stabilise them through fiscal or monetary policy (i.e. government budgets, spending and taxation and the deficit, as well as Reserve Bank steps such as a change in the repo rate); ❐ Ongoing medium-term phenomena such as inflation and adjustments of the productive capacity (or supply side) of the economy, some of them occurring in reaction to shortterm shocks or policy steps; and ❐ Long-run growth and employment trends and ways to influence them. All of these occur within the broader context of structural and institutional dimensions related to the development challenges of a post-colonial, post-apartheid, middle-income country with deep-seated problems of structural unemployment, poverty and inequality; development backlogs, skills deficiencies and skills mismatches in the modern economy; low rates of labour absorption by industry, segmented labour markets and barriers to entry faced by job seekers; the economic marginalisation of poor people, as well as healthrelated issues such as HIV and Aids – and of course the wider issue of sustainability with regard to the environment and climate change. In these different contexts, we will also encounter – and come to understand – some of the puzzles and dilemmas facing the policymaker, and effectively also the voter-citizen. These include apparent trade-offs and difficult choices between desirable goals such as reducing unemployment and reducing inflation. Or indications that certain policy steps that may be good for the economy in the short run may be bad for the economy in the long run, or vice versa. What appears to be good for economic growth may be bad for the environment and climate change – or may make no real difference to the situation of the unemployed. 1.3 Main macroeconomic problems and policy objectives The main problems and issues of concern in macroeconomics are best identified by considering the main objectives of macroeconomic policy. People often think of macroeconomic policy as synonymous with stabilisation policy. While the latter is an important aspect, macroeconomic policy is concerned with much more than the business cycle. The standard objectives of macroeconomic policy usually include the following: 1. Economic growth and increasing employment (i.e. reducing unemployment) 2. Stability of output and employment levels 3. Stable and low inflation 1.3 Main macroeconomic problems and policy objectives How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 11 11 2019/12/17 09:14 4. Balance of payments 5. Distributional and equity objectives and the reduction of inequality 6. Economic development and poverty reduction. These constitute the main dimensions by which the overall health of an economy is measured. A thorough diagnosis of the state of the economy as a whole will have to deal with these aspects in one way or another. Traditional macroeconomic textbooks, notably those of American or British origins, normally will only list the first four or five of these objectives in their assessment of the macroeconomic performance of a country. However, for South Africa as an upper-middleincome country and emerging-market economy, macroeconomic events and discussions of policy objectives can never be severed from the encompassing concerns of economic and human development as well as deep-rooted poverty and inequality. For any student in a low- or middle-income country, it is essential to understand the linkages and broader context of these issues. Section 1.5 gives some background on economic and human development issues and objectives. We will also encounter development issues in the chapters on long-term economic growth (chapters 8 and 12). 1.3.1 Economic growth and increasing employment The pursuit of high economic growth is the objective that usually is accepted as the most obvious one – often to such an extent that little critical thought is given to the issue. The basic belief behind such general acceptance is that economic growth will lead to an improvement in the living standards of the entire population. (As we will see below, the matter is not so simple.) Economic growth is defined as a sustained increase, over time, in the level of aggregate production, i.e. gross domestic product or GDP. (A complementary definition considers the trend in per capita GDP, i.e. in average GDP per person.) The focus on the trend in the level of GDP is used in this definition to indicate that cyclical deviations from the underlying trend in aggregate output are not of concern here. Economic growth is a long-run policy consideration. ❐ This clearly distinguishes it from short-run or stabilisation objectives that are concerned with cyclical fluctuations around the long-run trend of real GDP (i.e. the business cycle). ❐ This also means that the focus is on the behaviour of the full-capacity level of output (GDP) over time (amidst upswings and downswings). ❐ In other words, the long-run growth path is the ‘base line’ or trend line around which cyclical fluctuations occur. It indicates, and determines, the long-term rate of increase (or decrease) in the average material standard of living of a population. In the long run it is much more important for the wealth and welfare of people than fluctuations in GDP. The simplest measure of aggregate economic growth is the annual growth rate of real GDP, i.e. the percentage increase in real GDP from one year to the next. The per capita GDP growth rate is the percentage increase in real per capita GDP from one year to the next. This way of measuring growth unfortunately does not exclude the cyclical component of the behaviour of GDP – it mixes cyclical increases and decreases in GDP with the long-run trend. To see the long-run pattern, one has to smooth the annual growth rates by taking averages over longer periods, as shown in table 1.1. (See chapter 12 for more details on the definition and calculation of the GDP growth rate.) 12 Chapter 1: Why macroeconomics? An introduction to the issues How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 12 2019/12/17 09:14 The data in table 1.1 and figure 1.1 clearly show how dramatically the South African growth performance declined since the mid-1970s (among cyclical increases and decreases in growth) – with the 1980s and early 1990s being the worst. It is apparent how economic growth has recovered after the change in government in 1994. Table 1.1 Average economic growth rates in South Africa Real GDP growth However, the period after 2008 again marks a period of sustained decline in the GDP growth rate, with especially the period 2014–18 becoming quite disastrous. Per capita real GDP growth 1971–1975 3.68 1.22 1976–1980 3.10 0.72 1981–1985 1.42 –0.90 1986–1990 1.68 –0.48 1991–1995 0.88 –1.22 1996–2000 2.80 0.66 2001–2005 3.84 1.98 2006–2010 3.14 1.80 2011–2015 2.20 0.96 2016–2018 0.87 –0.53 Source: South African Reserve Bank (www.resbank.co.za). Figure 1.1 Real GDP growth rate and moving average trendline 1960–2018 10 8 Percentage 6 4 2 0 2018 2016 2014 2012 2010 2008 2006 2004 2002 2000 1998 1996 1994 1992 1990 1988 1986 1984 1982 1980 1976 1974 1970 1972 1968 1964 1966 1960 1962 –4 1978 –2 Source: South African Reserve Bank (www.resbank.co.za). Does economic growth improve living standards? Per capita growth An important perspective on the real GDP growth rate is provided by the population growth rate. Only if the real economic growth rate exceeds the population growth rate will there be an increase in real GDP per capita, i.e. GDP per person. ❐ Up to 1990 the South African population growth rate averaged approximately 2.5% per annum. Since 1991 the rate of natural increase has fallen steeply to approximately 1.2% in 2017. ❐ Real economic growth was insufficient to compensate for the population growth for more than a decade after 1980, but in the period after 1993, GDP per person increased almost continuously, except for brief declines in 1998 and 2008–9 (see figure 1.2). However, since 2014 per capita GDP has declined (negative growth). 1.3 Main macroeconomic problems and policy objectives How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 13 13 2019/12/17 09:14 The extent to which sustained growth in GDP contributes to people’s living standards also depends on the composition of the output. For example, if increased military expenditure and production are primarily responsible for the GDP growth, it does not have the same effect on living standards as when the source of growth is expenditure on, and the production of, basic household goods, housing and medical services. Figure 1.2 Real GDP per capita (2010 base year) 1960–2018 62 000 57 000 52 000 47 000 R million 42 000 37 000 32 000 27 000 22 000 17 000 2018 2016 2014 2012 2010 2008 2006 2004 2002 2000 1998 1996 1994 1992 1990 1988 1986 1984 1982 1980 1978 1976 1974 1972 1970 1968 1966 1964 1962 1960 12 000 Source: South African Reserve Bank (www.resbank.co.za). ! Even if per capita GDP increases numerically – if there is a positive per capita growth rate, as was the case in much of the 1960s and 70s and the first two decades after 1993 – it need not be the case that all (or even the majority) of the population are better off. This depends on the way in which the benefits of economic growth are distributed among the population, i.e. the extent to which people share in the growth. This is the issue encapsulated in the inequality objective (listed previously as number 5 and discussed in section 1.3.5). Unfortunately, it regularly happens that the benefits of growth largely flow to a relatively small group of already well-off people and do not ‘trickle down’ to benefit the poor – the poor are not sufficiently part of expanding economic activities. This phenomenon is likely to have been a contributing factor in the political tension and mobilisation in South Africa in the 1960s and 70s as well as the dramatic rise in township protests since 2009. Of course, it is much worse if per capita GDP starts to decline, as has occurred from 2014 onwards. GDP growth and employment growth Assuming a direct link between GDP growth and employment, and thus unemployment, is not necessarily correct in reality. For example, increases in production capacity and output due to the substitution of capital (i.e. machines) for labour – through the use of more capital- and technology-intensive methods of production – can cause high growth accompanied by stagnating or even declining employment. In South Africa this is visible in the declining employment-intensity of output. Economic growth with low labour intensity appears to be typical. 14 Chapter 1: Why macroeconomics? An introduction to the issues How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 14 2019/12/17 09:14 Figure 1.3 Indices showing trend in real GDP and formal-sector employment since 1985 (1985=100) 250 200 Real GDP Index 150 Formal-sector employment 100 2017 2015 2013 2011 2009 2007 2005 2003 2001 1999 1997 1995 1993 1991 1989 1987 0 1985 50 Source: South African Reserve Bank employment series, derived from Statistics SA’s Quarterly Employment Series (QES) and its predecessors; GDP: South African Reserve Bank. In general employment tends to grow much more slowly than GDP. Figure 1.3 shows the absolute levels of real GDP and total formal-sector employment since 1985, while figure 1.4 shows the growth rates of real GDP and total formal-sector employment.1 ❐ From 1985 to 2018, real GDP has more than doubled, while total formal-sector employment has increased by only 30% (figure 1.3). ❐ Or, as figure 1.4 shows, from 1985 to 2018 the formal-sector employment growth rate has persistently been significantly below the GDP growth rate. The average growth rate for GDP over the entire period was 2.2% per year and that for formal-sector employment 0.8%. Figure 1.4 Real GDP growth and formal-sector employment growth rates since 1985 6 Real GDP growth 5 4 Percentage 3 2 1 0 –1 –2 Formal-sector employment growth 2017 2015 2013 2011 2009 2007 2005 2003 2001 1999 1997 1995 1993 1991 1989 1987 –4 1985 –3 Source: South African Reserve Bank employment series, derived from Statistics SA’s Quarterly Employment Series (QES) and its predecessors; GDP: South African Reserve Bank. 1 One should be careful with employment data and related calculations of coefficients. The Quarterly Employment Series (QES) – which is based on formal-sector enterprises and government – and the more comprehensive Quarterly Labour Force Survey (QLFS) produce somewhat different results, while the latter has been available for a shorter historical period. See the Data Tip box in section 12.2.1, chapter 12. (Figures 1.3 and 1.4 with approximations of longer-term trends, dating back to 1960, can be found in the fourth edition of this book.) 1.3 Main macroeconomic problems and policy objectives How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 15 15 2019/12/17 09:14 Another way to look at this, is to consider the macroeconomic ‘employment coefficient’. It expresses the employment growth rate relative to (i.e. as a ratio of) the real GDP growth rate. ❐ For the formal sector alone, the average employment coefficient for 1960–2018 has been estimated to be 0.52. This confirms a broad pattern from as far back as 1946. For total employment, data for the period since 2001 suggest an employment coefficient that is somewhat higher. ❐ Note that these values do not indicate ‘jobless growth’, which occurs when the employment coefficient is negative. In South Africa this only occurred in an exceptional few years after the political transition of the mid-1990s and in the major recession of 2008-09. These numbers mean that formal-sector employment growth in South Africa tends to occur only at roughly half the rate of GDP growth. If this is coupled with a growing population and a growing labour force (a characteristic since 1994), this is likely to lead to increasing unemployment – unless very high GDP growth rates are attained. Growth in GDP therefore does not necessarily lead to a corresponding long-run increase in formalDoes the informal sector create employment? According to the Quarterly Labour Force Survey, formal-sector employment plus employment in agriculture and private households reached approximately 13.3 million in 2018 (employment in agriculture was 0.85 million and in private households 1.3 million.) However, about 3 million people work in the informal sector, of which an estimated 1.4 million are employers plus their paid employees in enterprises, while 1.4 million work as owner-operators in their own oneperson enterprises. These workers are also affected by macroeconomic cycles and policies, but macroeconomists and media reports often ignore this part of the economy. That is a weakness in macroeconomic theory and policy thinking. The informal sector is an important current and potential source of employment. (See section 12.2 for more on the informal sector and employment.) sector employment. Formal-sector growth alone is unlikely to absorb enough workers to significantly reduce unemployment. Unemployment Unemployment is one of the most important measures of macroeconomic performance. It also is the most sensitive variable politically. It is discussed in depth in chapter 12. Unemployment occurs when a person who is in the labour force, i.e. who is economically active, does not have a job. Children, students and the elderly, for example, are not regarded as part of the labour force, and thus are not counted as being unemployed. The unemployment rate is calculated by expressing the total number of unemployed persons as a percentage of the total labour force. In practice there are two definitions (see section 12.2 for a more detailed discussion): ❐ In terms of the strict definition, a person must be actively searching for a job to be counted as unemployed. This is how the official un­em­ploy­ment rate in South Africa is defined. It is also called the narrow unemployment rate. Table 1.2 and figure 1.5 show the official unemployment rate in South Africa since 2000. It has been fluctuating around 25% since 2000, but climbing steadily since 2016. ❐ In terms of the expanded definition, persons who are not actively searching for work but who want to work and are willing to work – most of whom are so-called 16 Chapter 1: Why macroeconomics? An introduction to the issues How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 16 2019/12/17 09:14 discouraged workers – are also included. It is also called the broad unemployment rate. This rate is much higher than the narrow unemployment rate. In South Africa it has been approximately 8–10% higher than the narrow rate and has been fluctuating around 34% since 2000, increasing to 38% in 2019. Figure 1.5 shows the persistent gap between the two unemployment rates. Table 1.2 Unemployment rates in South Africa Narrow While the strict rate is the official rate of unemployment in South Africa (in line with international statistical agencies), researchers often prefer to use the broad rate in the analysis of unemployment. They argue that, given the country’s development and structural challenges, the more than three million discouraged and other non-searching unemployed must be recognised as part of the employment/unemployment problem – that these marginalised workers cannot simply be ruled out of consideration in policy analysis as being ‘not economically active’. Broad 2000 23.30 30.00 2001 26.20 34.50 2002 26.60 34.70 2003 24.80 34.70 2004 23.00 33.70 2005 23.50 32.80 2006 22.10 30.90 2007 21.00 31.40 2008 22.80 29.50 2009 24.50 33.80 2010 25.40 36.10 2011 25.00 35.50 2012 25.20 35.60 2013 24.50 34.90 2014 25.40 35.80 2015 25.50 34.40 2016 27.10 36.60 The long-run level of the rate of unemployment 2017 27.70 36.80 depends partially on the long-run growth 2018 27.50 37.70 performance of GDP, but mostly on structural Source: Statistics SA. characteristics of the labour market and the economy. These do not change easily; indeed, a high level of ‘structural’ unemployment is an ingrained characteristic of the South African economy (see section 12.2.3 for a thorough discussion). Figure 1.5 Unemployment rates since 2000 40 35 Broad rate of unemployment 30 Percentage 25 Narrow rate of unemployment 20 15 10 2018 2017 2016 2015 2014 2013 2012 2011 2010 2009 2008 2007 2006 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 0 2000 5 Source: Statistics SA, QLFS data. 1.3 Main macroeconomic problems and policy objectives How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 17 17 2019/12/17 09:14 The sustainability of economic growth The unqualified pursuit of high economic growth is increasingly questioned in the light of the considerable costs of economic growth. These include the increasing pollution of the environment (air, water, etc.), the accumulation of waste material (including dangerous substances such as nuclear waste) and noise pollution. In recent years, the apparent impact on climate change has become very prominent. In addition, there are the disadvantages of a modern, industrialised urban life (traffic congestion, noise, job stress in the rat race, and so forth). The fundamental question is whether this kind of growth necessarily brings about a real improvement in people’s quality of life. Another crucial qualification is the impact of unqualified economic growth on the depletion of natural resources. Concern exists worldwide that the world may be facing serious shortages of essential natural resources within decades. One of the most important resources – also in South Africa – is fresh water. Another is natural energy resources, some of which may be exhausted or under stress relatively early in this century. All of these factors impose important constraints on the sustainable rate of growth as well as on the kind of growth that can and should be pursued. The fact that, in addition, economic growth does not necessarily reach all sectors of the population, stresses the importance of not pursuing more and more growth in an unqualified fashion. While an increase in the general level of economic activity surely is important, especially in a country with development problems and a growing population, it would be short-sighted to ignore the inherent dangers in a single-minded growth-at-all-costs approach. (See the discussion of development in section 1.4 and also chapter 12, section 12.3.6.) 1.3.2 Stability of output and employment In contrast to a concern with the long-run level and growth of GDP and employment, this objective relates to cyclical fluctuations in general economic activity, as measured by changes in GDP (or the GDP growth rate) as well as total employment. Fluctuations in the rate of unemployment generally are linked to the business cycle, i.e. fluctuations in GDP. In most Western countries the pursuit or attainment of high (or even ‘full’) employment is regarded as a responsibility of the government. This can be traced back to the Great Depression of the early 1930s, the first major and sustained cyclical downturn that struck the USA and the world (including South Africa) after the First World War. This led to the acceptance by US President Franklin D Roosevelt of full employment as an official government objective and responsibility. While there has been some rethinking of this position in the West in the last couple of decades, few governments can dissociate themselves from the problems of unemployment, since it is an important political factor in most democratic elections. In low- or middle-income countries with significant poverty, such as South Africa, unemployment has a particular relevance from the point of view of both government and labour unions. During cyclical downturns in the economy the plight of those losing their jobs while already being members of poor households becomes acute. 18 Chapter 1: Why macroeconomics? An introduction to the issues How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 18 2019/12/17 09:14 Usually, and especially in simple theoretical models of the economy, it is assumed that there is a close correlation between the level of employment and the level of real GDP. Following this, the basic policy assumption also is that cyclical fluctuations in GDP will cause corresponding changes in total employment. ❐ The standard objective of stabilisation policy, therefore, is to moderate cyclical fluctuations in GDP and thus simultaneously moderate fluctuations in employment.2 While the link between GDP and employment is weak in the context of long-run growth (figure 1.3), in the short-run or cyclical context a clearer correspondence between GDP fluctuations and employment fluctuations is apparent – see figure 1.4. Nevertheless, the data in figure 1.4 show that sometimes the direction and often the magnitude of changes in the two variables differ noticeably. One must realise that cyclical movements in production do not necessarily cause corresponding changes in employment. In an upswing in production a corresponding proportional increase in employment will not occur if the extra output is produced using machines and capital goods which have surplus capacity, or with current employees initially working below capacity. Likewise, in a downswing, employment can fall less than production if labour unions use their power to prevent retrenchments; on the other hand, it could also fall more if employers shift the burden of falling sales and profits disproportionately onto labour. (In practice both of these effects may be operational at the same time.) ❐ Therefore, policy steps – such as monetary and fiscal policies – aimed at short-run levels of GDP are not automatically appropriate or sufficient for achieving the employment stability objective. The important point is that one can distinguish two components of unemployment: a cyclical component and a long-run or structural component. Macroeconomic policy can influence GDP in the short run, bearing in mind that steps to moderate fluctuations in GDP (or to promote GDP growth) will not automatically be effective to deal with cyclical unemployment. However, this is even less the case with regard to long-run, or structural, unemployment, which is largely outside the reach of standard macroeconomic policy remedies. It is rooted in complex aspects of labour markets, spatial patterns, economic marginalisation, underdevelopment and so forth. This means that, given that employment is a legitimate objective of public policy, the different kinds and components of unemployment require a combination of different kinds of policy steps, many of them not macroeconomic in nature. Therefore, the design of macroeconomic policies geared towards (un)employment must fully take account of the labour-economic and other intricacies of unemployment. The macroeconomic debate on unemployment of 25% cannot proceed as if it is primarily a low-growth problem or a downswing-in-GDP problem. The problem of unemployment is further complicated by the fact that it is also an integral part of the broader problems of poverty and underdevelopment. This forces one to consider a much wider set of perspectives, causes and policy options (see section 1.4 and also chapter 12, section 12.2). 1.3.3 Stable and low inflation The control of inflation is accepted as a very important macroeconomic policy objective in most countries. It is discussed in depth in chapters 7 and 12. Table 1.3 displays the five2 As we will see later, ‘full’ employment does not actually mean 0% unemployment. It allows for frictional unemployment and seasonal unemployment (see the box in chapter 6, section 6.3.2). 1.3 Main macroeconomic problems and policy objectives How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 19 19 2019/12/17 09:14 year averages for inflation in South Africa since the 1960s. Notice the steep increase in the inflation rate in the 1970s, an increase that was reversed only in the late 1990s – with relatively low rates then sustained into the 2010s. Table 1.3 The rate of inflation in South Africa 1961–1965 2.1% 1966–1970 3.4% 1971–1975 9.4% Inflation is defined as a sustained increase in the general or average price level. One-off or intermittent increases in the average price level do not constitute inflation. Likewise, increases in the prices of individual products or services are not inflation, but rather a change in relative prices. The average price level is measured by different price indices, the consumer price index (CPI) being the most important. 1976–1980 12.1% 1981–1985 14.0% 1986–1990 15.4% 1991–1995 11.3% 1996–2000 6.7% 2001–2005 5.1% 2006–2010 6.9% Inflation is measured as the rate of increase of the average price level during a specified period, normally one year. More specifically, the inflation rate is the percentage change in the CPI during the chosen period. 2011–2015 5.4% 2016–2018 5.5% Source: South African Reserve Bank (www.resbank.co.za). The formulation and pursuit of this policy objective is no simple matter. For example, one must distinguish between the prevention of higher (or increasing) inflation and the actual reduction of the inflation rate. That the latter is automatically preferred to the former is not accepted by all. ❐ Also bear in mind that, specifically when inflation is a policy objective, the existence of various trade-offs will be of utmost importance. The most prominent (and controversial) of these is the trade-off between inflation and unemployment (see chapters 7 and 12). Another important link between inflation and other policy objectives derives from the impact of high domestic inflation on the international competitiveness of a country, and the subsequent impact on the current account of the balance of payments (objective 4). If the South African inflation rate is persistently higher than that of its main trading partners, this will impair exports and encourage import expenditure. This may continually place the current account of the balance of payments under pressure (see the analysis in chapter 4). Inflation also can have important redistributional impacts (objective 5): ❐ People with debt (borrowers) benefit from inflation, since the real value of the debt decreases gradually due to inflation. Homeowners with mortgage bonds are a good example of such a group. By the same token, inflation harms lenders, since it reduces the real purchasing power of debt repayments. ❐ Inflation harms any person with a constant or slow-growing income source. Pensioners and people dependent on interest income are important examples. ❐ In a progressive income tax system, bracket creep harms income taxpayers: adjustments to wages and salaries to keep abreast of inflation push people into higher tax brackets, where they have to pay higher marginal and average tax rates – even though their income has not increased in real terms. The state is the beneficiary of this redistribution (unless it takes active steps to prevent bracket creep by regularly adjusting tax brackets so that they remain constant in real terms). 20 Chapter 1: Why macroeconomics? An introduction to the issues How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 20 2019/12/17 09:15 ❐ People who (have to) spend the largest portion of their monthly income – especially on consumer goods such as food and clothing – may experience a higher inflation rate than people who spend only a relatively small portion of their income (and save or invest much of it). This means that low-income households may experience a higher inflation rate than high-income households. 1.3.4 Balance of payments (BoP) While the balance of payments does not directly affect the welfare or living standards of people, it is an important policy consideration, notably in an economy as open as South Africa’s. This objective should not be understood to mean that the BoP should always be in equilibrium. As discussed in chapter 4, a BoP deficit or surplus need not be a problem – as long as it does not persist indefinitely – and may even be desirable at times. What one can say is that in the very long run the BoP must be in equilibrium. That means that the average BoP position over a very long period should be that of equilibrium (BoP = 0). One reason why the BoP position is important is that it determines the foreign reserves of the country, i.e. the stock of foreign currency. The foreign reserves are important, inter alia, to finance imports (notably of essential inputs), to repay foreign debt, and to support the currency in foreign exchange markets should it come under pressure (see chapter 4). Another reason for keeping an eye on the BoP is that the BoP position can have important effects on the real economy (via money supply and exchange rate adjustments). It has an important influence on other objectives of policy (e.g. GDP, growth, employment and inflation). The BoP also influences the pursuit of these other objectives: policy steps to attain growth and employment objectives often cause an undesirable impact on the BoP – and especially on the current account.3 ❐ Therefore, the BoP position is often an objective of policy in the sense that it is a constraint on the extent to which other objectives can be pursued. As a consequence, situations often arise where the BoP situation has to be corrected before other objectives can be pursued. In similar fashion, the individual components of the BoP, e.g. the current account or the financial account, can also become important policy considerations at times, requiring corresponding policy steps. In particular, a current account deficit cannot be endured indefinitely. The financial account surplus necessary to finance it can be achieved and sustained only with high interest rates (and sufficient foreign confidence in the domestic economy) to attract foreign investment or loans. High interest rates are likely to discourage the investment that is necessary for growth and for repaying the foreign debt. A persistent current account deficit also makes a country vulnerable to capital outflow problems. This has been the case with South Africa since 1994, when the current account turned negative. 3 Chapter 4 demonstrates that the different channels of the BoP adjustment process can drastically affect the effectiveness of, for example, monetary policy. 1.3 Main macroeconomic problems and policy objectives How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 21 21 2019/12/17 09:15 1.3.5 Distributional and equity objectives and the reduction of inequality The equity of the distribution of income and wealth between individual members of the population is an important consideration when evaluating just how optimal the overall results of the economic institutions, processes and interactions in a country are. The issue is whether each individual or household in society earns or possesses a sufficient, fair or equitable share of the national income and wealth. Equity or equality? Equity does not mean that everyone should have an equal share (or quantity) of income or wealth. This is not what it is all about. Equity is about fairness and justice, which are complex concepts. Equity cannot and should not be reduced to a one-dimensional measure such as equality in the quantity of income or wealth of persons or households. It is a characteristic of market economies (and other types of economies, let it be said) that normal economic processes often lead to a very unequal distribution of income and wealth. As a result, government has to include the equitable distribution of wealth in its range of objectives. However, the way and extent to which this objective must be pursued is very controversial. No consensus exists on what constitutes a fair and equitable distribution of income and wealth. In particular, there is little agreement between those who have much and those who have little. Yet, often it is not too difficult to recognise something as unfair – even though it may be difficult to specify accurately what would constitute fairness, let alone how to attain such a condition. How does one measure the inequality of the distribution of income? One important measure of inequality is the Gini coefficient, which is derived from the Lorenz curve. When there is absolute equality, the Gini value is zero; a value closer to 1 indicates greater inequality. Most countries lie between 0.3 (highly equal) and 0.7 (highly unequal). High-income countries usually have Gini values around 0.40, while middle- and low-income countries have values between 0.50 and 0.60. For South Africa the Gini value for income was estimated at 0.68 in 1991 – one of the highest in the world. Estimates from Statistics SA show the Gini coefficient for income at 0.70 in 2000, rising to 0.72 in 2006 and thereafter declining gradually to 0.70 in 2009 and 0.68 in 2015. This slight downward movement is supported by similar estimates based on the National Income Dynamics Study (NIDS). Income inequality in South Africa is stubbornly high and persistent, despite significant progress in reducing poverty and deprivation levels. Although inequality in South Africa has a significant racial pattern, there is also significant inequality within each population group. The 2015 Gini coefficient for blacks was 0.65 – more unequal than that for whites, which was at 0.51. For more information on income inequality in South Africa, visit the website of Statistics SA at www.statssa.gov.za. In South Africa the distribution of personal income is exceptionally unequal compared to other countries – even some Third World countries. South Africa has the ominous reputation of having the highest degrees of income and expenditure inequality in the world. ❐ According to the 2005/6 Income and Expenditure Survey of Statistics SA, the richest 10% of the population as a group received 51% of total income, while the poorest 50% of the population received less than 10% of total income in the country. The Living Conditions Survey of Statistics SA shows that by 2014/15 the income share of the richest 10% had declined to 41%, while especially those in the middle gained. 22 Chapter 1: Why macroeconomics? An introduction to the issues How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 22 2019/12/17 09:15 ❐ Another way of putting this is to say that 10% of the population receives roughly 40% of all income, while the remaining 90% receives 60% of all income. The political and policy relevance of this inequality cannot be underestimated. ❐ Recent studies of the middle class confirm the presence of high inequality. Because there are so many poor people, those with the occupations, lifestyle and stable income to put them in ‘the middle class’, are not in the middle of the income distribution at all! Who falls in the middle class? Households with a per capita income of only R3 800 up to R12 750 per month in 2019 money terms. But the data show they are in the top 20% to 25% of households (which include the elite – the top 4%), thus up to 80% of households have a lower standard of living. The share of the middle class has grown slowly since 1993, but there has been a major demographic transformation, with Africans constituting two-thirds of the middle class by 2017. The large disparities between the incomes of individuals/households in South Africa and the existence of extensive poverty alongside great wealth have exerted tremendous pressure on the government to address this issue. This state of affairs has serious political implications and threatens the legitimacy and acceptability of the entire public order – even after the political transformation has run its course. This threat stems, in particular, from the fact that the skew distribution of income seems to correspond largely with racial divisions. ❐ Unfortunately, the traditional macroeconomic policy debate, especially in the private sector, often disregards (or studiously avoids) the distributional objective. It is true that the South African government has been giving increasing attention to the inequity of economic conditions. However, narrower macroeconomic issues do tend to dominate the policy discussion in Pretoria – especially when a factor such as the BoP becomes problematic and begins to dominate all policy thinking. Even ‘normal’ macroeconomic policy steps necessarily have distributional effects: ❐ How much government spends and on what it spends, the kinds of taxes levied, and the level of interest rates – to mention a few examples – do not affect all individuals to the same extent: some benefit, others are harmed. ❐ Macroeconomic policy steps also affect the welfare levels in different regions of the country, and the relationships between agriculture and other sectors, between small and large business enterprises, between homeowners, investors and pensioners, and so forth. This means that the equity dimension or objective should be kept in mind at all times, even when contemplating ‘pure’ macroeconomic policy steps. Likewise, inequality can have important effects on growth and employment (objective 1). Recent international research from the International Monetary Fund (IMF)4 indicates that a high degree of inequality can be detrimental to economic growth. Inequality undermines progress in health and education, inhibits full economic participation, narrows the consumer market and the tax base, and creates deep tensions that undermine social consensus and investor confidence. Their results show that longer growth spells are robustly associated with lower inequality in the distribution of income, especially in lowand middle-income countries. Carefully designed redistributive policies can thus promote the duration of high growth spells. The contrary, more traditional view is that policies to reduce inequality (e.g. via taxes and government expenditure) can inhibit economic growth by discouraging business investment. 4 Berg A, Ostry JD, Tsangarides CG and Yakhshilikov Y (2018). Redistribution, inequality and growth: new evidence, Journal of Economic Growth. 1.3 Main macroeconomic problems and policy objectives How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 23 23 2019/12/17 09:15 Redistribution versus growth? The relationship between economic growth and redistribution has deadlocked the public debate in an unfruitful squabble since 1990. This often constituted the form in which the economic dimension of the transition to a new political dispensation was discussed. Different political-economic constituencies favoured different relationships between these two objectives. In its crudest form, the debate displayed a split between two opposing viewpoints: Growth through redistribution or Redistribution through growth. The latter viewpoint was favoured by the business sector and the pre-1994 policy establishment. Their argument is that economic growth should be pursued first, in order to enlarge the economic ‘cake’. The increased availability of income and wealth – the benefits of growth – will spread or filter down to all the people in the country, including the poor, thereby establishing a more equitable distribution of income. In addition, the growing economic cake will increasingly make it possible to channel more resources to the satisfaction of basic needs (education, housing and health). Direct steps to attain speedier redistribution – higher taxes to finance higher government spending on public services, for example – will be counterproductive since they will simply retard economic growth. As a consequence, there would be a shrinking pool of income and wealth to redistribute, and the goose that laid the golden eggs would be strangled. (What would happen is that ‘poverty would be redistributed’.) This viewpoint can be discerned in the proposals of the business sector. The first viewpoint was held by representatives of those who were excluded from power in the previous political dispensation. They argue that the business argument has only one objective: the protection of the privileges of the rich and of the status quo of income and economic power distribution – and, moreover, that the trickling down of benefits to the poor is a myth. The goose that lays the golden eggs is not under threat at all. They argue further that direct government intervention should be used to restructure the pattern of income and economic power. Increased government expenditure to build the capacity of the poor and empower them will unleash their potential and lead the country to a new phase of economic prosperity for all. Social expenditure on housing, schools and hospitals will also provide an economic injection and new domestic economic opportunities – for all. ❐ This viewpoint was present in the initial policy documents of the ANC, as well as, for example, in the proposals of Cosatu (the Congress of South African Trade Unions) and labour unions such as Numsa. Different and subtler variants of these two viewpoints have developed in the past two decades. In the Reconstruction and Development Programme (RDP) of the ANC, elements of both viewpoints are present. The redistribution sentiment remains strong, though – perhaps not in its original crude form, but rather with a strong focus on economic empowerment and capacity building. In pursuing this the government is accorded a significant responsibility, with certain sections of the ANC pushing for a strong planning role for the state. In 1996 the government introduced the Growth, Employment and Redistribution (GEAR) programme. For the most part, GEAR is a macroeconomic stabilisation policy aimed at setting the scene for a higher economic growth rate and higher employment. A key component is tight fiscal policy and the reduction of the budget deficit. GEAR to a large extent considers a prudent fiscal policy as a prerequisite for growth, with growth then generating the revenue that will help to finance more development. Therefore, GEAR leans over to the redistribution through growth viewpoint. In 2006 the government introduced the Accelerated and Shared Growth Initiative for South Africa (ASGISA). With its emphasis more on microeconomic policy aspects, ASGISA, more than GEAR, recognises that, within the constraints of the budget, some human development can and must take place without waiting for growth. ⇒ 24 Chapter 1: Why macroeconomics? An introduction to the issues How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 24 2019/12/17 09:15 ⇒ After 2009 two key policy frameworks were adopted. These are the New Growth Path (NGP) of 2010 and the National Development Plan (NDP) of 2012. The NGP focuses on growth via labour-intensive manufacturing. The NDP is a comprehensive development plan that covers almost all areas of society, e.g. demography, education, health, social protection, human settlements, spatial legacies, infrastructure, agriculture and the rural economy, the economy and employment – and a ‘capable and developmental state’. Whereas GEAR, ASGISA and the NGP focused largely on economic growth, the NDP has a broader concern with human capabilities, the inclusivity of growth and the reduction of unemployment and poverty – also by tackling structural problems. Job creation and the reduction of inequality (and poverty) are explicit objectives of the NDP. Nevertheless, the NDP has been heavily criticised by Cosatu as being too free-market oriented, protecting the rich and not being concerned with the plight of poor workers – especially in its chapter on the economy. ❐ The concept of inclusive growth has the potential to defuse the apparent tension between growth and redistribution. If properly understood, it combines the increased participation of poor and marginalised people in growing economic processes – i.e. via employment – with increased sharing in the benefits of growth via equitable earnings, social expenditure and human capacity-building (see section 12.4 in chapter 12). This implies that the nature of production and employment processes, and thus the nature of growth itself, needs to be adapted to attain both objectives simultaneously. ❐ Unfortunately, this concept is prone to distortion. For example, many people in the private sector appear to restrict the concept of inclusivity to benefit-sharing – and then in the restricted sense of receiving social grants and social services – after growth has occurred. This would require no change to current economic practices and simply recasts the old tension between growth and redistribution in new terminology. 1.4 The development objective One possible way out of the sterile, polarised debate on redistribution versus growth may be found in the concept of development. 1.4.1 What is development? Development is not a particular outcome or event. Development can be understood as a decisive, comprehensive and integrated process that expands the range of choices that people have and improves their standards of living. It therefore entails much, much more than an increase in income or GDP or employment, as explained in the UN’s Human Development Report 1990: Human development is a process of enlarging people’s choices. The most critical ones are to lead a long and healthy life, to be educated and to enjoy a decent standard of living … It is sometimes suggested that income is a good proxy for all other human choices since access to income permits exercise of every other option. This is only partly true for a variety of reasons: ❐ Income is a means, not an end. Well-being of a society depends on the uses to which income is put, not on the level of income itself. ❐ Country experience demonstrates several cases of high levels of human development at modest income levels and poor levels of human development at fairly high income levels. ❐ Present income of a country may offer little guidance as to its future growth prospects… ❐ Multiplying human problems in many industrial, rich countries show that high income levels, by themselves, are no guarantee of human progress. The simple truth is that there is no automatic link between income growth and human progress. United Nations Human Development Report 1990 (1990: 10) 1.4 The development objective How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 25 25 2019/12/17 09:15 It is not the redistribution or the growth of income as such that is important. What is critical is the development of people, their potential, their abilities to experience a selfreliant and humane existence, and to use their increasing power of disposal over economic means or resources to satisfy their needs. Real development can therefore deliver both economic growth and the economic empowerment of the poor. ❐ This results in economic growth and redistribution through development. Development therefore has the potential to dissolve the tension between growth and social considerations. What is the difference between economic growth and development? This question can provoke a never-ending debate. The most important insight is that development entails (and requires) much more than an increase in the total value of production (GDP) or income, or even in per capita income. GDP growth is necessary but not sufficient for human development. While increased household income or purchasing power is a crucial element in eliminating poverty, alone it is insufficient to achieve development. The single-minded pursuit of economic growth, narrowly defined, without taking the other dimensions of human and social development into consideration, cannot but produce distorted or unbalanced ‘development’ in a country. Human development can be absent in a society despite fast growth in GDP or per capita incomes unless certain other steps are taken and other endogenous social and economic processes are activated and empowered. ❐ This has been demonstrated by the failed efforts of the high-income countries, in previous decades, to solve the poverty and development problems of the low- and middle-income countries through large capital projects to achieve economic growth. (Also see chapter 12, sections 12.3 and 12.4.) 1.4.2 How does one measure development? Development is a complex process, as is the measurement of development. Through the years different approaches to development have produced different measures. These have evolved from crude measures that considered only per capita income to sophisticated indicators that measure several dimensions of basic need satisfaction and of capacity building and empowerment. Besides measures of income or purchasing power, they include several ‘social’ indicators of aspects such as education (level of schooling, literacy), life expectancy, nutrition levels, health (e.g. infant mortality rates) and housing (persons per room, running water per household, sanitation, etc.). Such information can also be summarised in composite development indicators. The best known of these indicators is the Human Development Index (HDI), which was developed by the United Nations Development Programme. It provides, in a single number, a composite measure of the level of development in a country, and of progress with development efforts. The HDI is constructed from three indicators of the basic dimensions of human development: ❐ ability to lead a long and healthy life (i.e. life expectancy, which implicitly includes factors such as nutrition, health and shelter); ❐ ability to acquire knowledge (measured by years of schooling, which implicitly includes adult literacy and school enrolment); and ❐ ability to acquire a decent standard of living (measured by income in terms of purchasing-power-adjusted real gross national income (GNI) per capita). 26 Chapter 1: Why macroeconomics? An introduction to the issues How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 26 2019/12/17 09:15 1.4.3 The development picture – South Africa and other countries For South Africa, the development picture as compared with four groups of countries is shown in table 1.4. The data show that South Africa compares quite well with other middle- and lower-income countries in terms of per capita income levels, but relatively poorly in terms of life expectancy – and also with regard to the overall development index, the HDI. A country such as Vietnam, for example, has an income level only half of that of South Africa, but its HDI is similar since its life expectancy is much higher (76.5 years in 2017 in contrast to 63.4 years for South Africa). Table 1.4 Development indicators Rank Country Very high human development HDI 1990 2000 2010 2015 2017 Change in HDI rank Life expectancy (years) Mean years of schooling GNI per capita (2011 PPP US$) 2012–2017 2017 2017 2017 1 Norway 0.85 0.92 0.94 0.95 0.95 – 82.3 12.6 68 012 4 Ireland 0.76 0.86 0.91 0.93 0.94 +13 81.6 12.5 53 754 5 Germany 0.80 0.87 0.92 0.93 0.94 –1 81.2 14.1 46 136 12 Canada 0.85 0.87 0.90 0.92 0.93 – 82.5 13.3 43 433 13 USA 0.86 0.89 0.91 0.92 0.92 –5 79.5 13.4 54 941 19 Japan 0.82 0.86 0.89 0.91 0.91 +1 83.9 12.8 30 660 31 Greece 0.75 0.80 0.86 0.87 0.87 –1 81.4 10.8 24 648 37 Qatar 0.75 0.81 0.83 0.85 0.86 –1 78.3 9.8 116 818 49 Russia 0.73 0.72 0.78 0.81 0.82 +3 71.2 12.0 24 233 High human development 79 Brazil 0.61 0.07 0.73 0.76 0.76 +7 75.7 7.8 13 755 86 China 0.50 0.59 0.71 0.74 0.75 +7 76.4 7.8 15 270 101 Botswana 0.59 0.57 0.66 0.71 0.72 +8 67.6 9.3 15 534 Medium human development 113 South Africa 0.62 0.63 0.65 0.69 0.70 +6 63.4 10.1 11 923 115 Egypt 0.55 0.61 0.66 0.69 0.69 – 71.7 7.2 10 355 129 Namibia 0.58 0.56 0.59 0.64 0.65 – 64.9 6.8 9 387 130 India 0.43 0.49 0.58 0.63 0.64 +2 68.8 6.4 6 353 142 Kenya 0.47 0.45 0.54 0.58 0.59 +3 67.3 6.5 2 961 144 Zambia 0.40 0.43 0.54 0.58 0.59 –3 62.3 7.0 3 557 Low human development 154 Tanzania 0.37 0.40 0.49 0.53 0.54 +3 66.3 5.8 2 655 156 Zimbabwe 0.49 0.44 0.47 0.53 0.54 +2 61.7 8.1 1 683 157 Nigeria – – 0.49 0.53 0.53 –2 53.9 6.2 5 231 159 Lesotho 0.50 0.47 0.49 0.51 0.52 –1 54.6 6.3 3 255 180 Mozambique 0.21 0.30 0.40 0.43 0.44 +1 58.9 3.5 1 093 Source: United Nations Development Programme: Human Development Indicators – Statistical Update 2018. PPP US$ is a special income measure designed to solve the exchange-rate problem in international comparisons of income. 1.4 The development objective How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 27 27 2019/12/17 09:15 ❐ The spectre of Aids had a marked downward effect on life expectancy in South Africa and other African countries after 1995: this affected their HDI values negatively. ❐ Life expectancy in South Africa fell from 62.2 years in 1992 to 53.3 in 2012. That was a quite disturbing decline. However, it was turned around after that, following the government’s eventual policy decision to provide antiretroviral medicine, as well as a marked improvement in the efficacy of such medicine. ✍ Income and development Study table 1.4. Why do you think the relationship between GDP per capita and the HDI values as well as the relationship between GDP per capita and the components of the HDI values are not perfect? What does this signify regarding the link between economic growth and development? (Also see box in chapter 12, section 12.3.4.) ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ In 2017, Norway had the highest HDI in the world and the Niger the lowest. Qatar had the highest per capita income in 2017, but it was ranked only number 37 given that some other high-income countries performed better in terms of life expectancy and education enrolment. (However, the first 20 countries all have very similar HDI values ranging from 0.91 to 0.95.) For 2017, South Africa ranked number 113 in a list of 189 countries. With the exception of Papua New Guinea, the Solomon Islands, Yemen and Haiti, all countries below number 150 are African countries. This demonstrates the enormous developmental backlog still faced by Africa. 1.4.4 What does macroeconomic policy have to do with development? The tension between growth and redistribution is often transmitted to the analysis of the relationship between growth and development. A major reason for this is that people reason as if development and redistribution are synonymous. Proponents of the redistribution-through-growth approach then proceed to evaluate development-oriented steps of government in the same way as they would evaluate redistribution efforts, i.e. as a threat to growth and other macroeconomic objectives. ❐ This is a mistake. Development is something quite different from redistribution – although good development, which addresses poverty successfully, should produce improved income distribution patterns as well as economic growth. Obviously it is true that the development efforts of a government often have significant budgetary and fiscal implications. They usually entail government expenditure that has to be financed. Government expenditure also has macroeconomic implications, as analysed in the following chapters. Overambitious development-oriented government expenditure can cause undesirable macroeconomic consequences – through an increasing tax burden, an excessive budget deficit, crowding-out, inflation or excessive stimulation of the economy. Therefore unwise development policy can threaten macroeconomic objectives. On the other hand, a country can achieve good macroeconomic performance in the sense of a high growth rate of real GDP, but in a way that does not address the problems of severe poverty and underdevelopment. In particular, excessively conservative fiscal policy 28 Chapter 1: Why macroeconomics? An introduction to the issues How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 28 2019/12/17 09:15 can seriously impair government development activities if funds for these purposes are cut back. (See the discussion of fiscal policy in chapter 10.) Unwise macroeconomic policy, therefore, can threaten development objectives. The Sustainable Development Goals (SDGs) for 2030 The SDGs constitute an internationally adopted blueprint to achieve a better and more sustainable future for all by 2030. It is a collection of 17 goals for global development, set by the United Nations General Assembly in 2015. These include: no poverty; zero hunger; good health and well-being; quality education; gender equality; clean water and sanitation; affordable and clean energy; decent work and economic growth; infrastructure, new industries and technologies; reduced inequality; sustainable cities and communities; responsible consumption and production; climate action; life on land and below water; and peace, justice and strong institutions. A total of 195 governments, including South Africa, have committed to translating the goals and associated targets into national legislation and plans of action, to establish budgets and monitor progress using appropriate indicators. Though non-enforceable, implementation to tackle all the challenges started worldwide in 2016. For more information on the SDG project, see: https://www.un.org/sustainabledevelopment Development problems will not disappear conveniently unless steps are taken to initiate development processes. Macroeconomic performance as conventionally measured in itself is not sufficient. Therefore, the important thing is to pursue an appropriate balance between macroeconomic objectives and development objectives. ❐ Achieving such a balance requires that macroeconomic objectives should not be regarded as of absolute and sole importance. Their relative importance is to be found in the fact that, if macroeconomic considerations do not receive sufficient attention in the pursuit of development objectives, the economy can experience serious problems, e.g. BoP crises, a drastic depreciation of the currency, runaway inflation, a disastrous public debt burden and so forth. Correcting such severe macroeconomic errors will require incisive structural adjustments which can impair development work seriously, and for many years. ❐ By taking macroeconomic considerations seriously, a government can create room for good development efforts. Healthy macroeconomic policy makes the pursuit of other objectives possible. Therefore, macroeconomic objectives should be recognised, in this wider context, as important constraints on development policy. Yet this last point still does not mean that macroeconomic objectives should be seen as being of absolute importance. What is necessary is a balance between the macroeconomic and other objectives. This means that the discussion on macroeconomic policy must be broadened expressly to include the development dimensions. Development objectives should not be regarded as something separate from or opposite to macroeconomics, or as something that can be addressed afterwards. Ideally, a development orientation should guide and characterise all policy. For example, proper development-oriented fiscal (and monetary) policy would also use development indicators and objectives in the design and monitoring of policy. In the final instance, development policy – which empowers people and unleashes their economic and social capacity – can be an important instrument in boosting productivity, 1.4 The development objective How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 29 29 2019/12/17 09:15 output and employment – the basic macroeconomic indicators. Good development policy will also serve macroeconomic objectives. Real development can deliver both economic growth and the economic empowerment of the poor. In such a case, any choice between growth and development is a false choice. At the same time, the debate on development policy should, at all times, expressly take the importance of macroeconomic constraints into account. Development objectives cannot be pursued uncompromisingly either, especially not if via government expenditure programmes. It is clear that macroeconomic policy is (or should be) much concerned with development. However, in practice, the pursuit of development objectives also concerns microeconomic and public management aspects, as well as budget practices, which takes the discussion far beyond the normal macroeconomic frame of reference. This is one reason why macroeconomists so readily disregard development aspects. 1.5 Intermediate objectives While the list in section 1.3 contains the main objectives of macroeconomic policy, there is also a set of secondary or intermediate macroeconomic objectives. These are important because they have crucial implications for the other, main objectives – and are sometimes important in their own right. Most notable among these is the rate of interest. Whichever way it moves, it affects certain groups of people positively and others negatively – homeowners, investors, borrowers, lenders, farmers, pensioners, etc. These differential effects, and their consequences, can make the interest rate an important policy objective at times. Likewise, the exchange rate can harm or benefit people, which can also make it an important objective at times. In this sense, interest rate and exchange rate levels are also important in any diagnosis of the economic situation, so they will usually be included in such an exercise. A last factor sometimes proposed as a policy objective is a balanced budget. However, this is not generally accepted, mainly because an intentional budget deficit can be an important Keynesian policy instrument. In more sophisticated fiscal analyses, the preference is for other fiscal norms (criteria) that are derived from specially defined budget balance concepts, e.g. the primary deficit (see chapter 10). 1.6 Conflict between the standard objectives – priorities and trade-offs While it may be simple to understand each objective in relative isolation, the problem in practice is to pursue or realise all these objectives simultaneously. The fundamental problem is that, given the way the economy works, several of the objectives are usually in conflict with each other. The pursuit of one of them frequently has a negative impact on another. This conflict often occurs in the form of a trade-off, where progress with one objective is possible only at the expense of another. In such a situation the government is forced to choose, i.e. it has to give priority to certain objectives over others. This choice is often the source of serious political differences. The choices, and the disputes, are also strongly determined by the relative influence and popularity of alternative economic schools of thought (such as Keynesianism and Monetarism/New Classicism, as well as Marxism) in policy-making circles. The most well-known trade-offs are those between (a) employment and the BoP, and (b) employment and price stability. These are fully discussed in chapters 6, 7 and 12. 30 Chapter 1: Why macroeconomics? An introduction to the issues How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 30 2019/12/17 09:15 Chapter 4 will demonstrate how conflict can arise between BoP and unemployment considerations. Stimulating the economy to relieve unemployment stimulates imports and thus causes a deterioration in the current account (and the BoP). Cooling down the economy to alleviate a current account deficit, on the other hand, is likely to aggravate unemployment. Increasing interest rates to improve the financial account discourages investments – which harms the growth and employment objectives. Moreover, if unemployment and a BoP deficit occur simultaneously, the dilemma is particularly acute: the economy suffers from two serious problems, but policymakers can alleviate one only to the detriment of the other. The conventional solution for this policy dilemma is to fight unemployment with expansionary fiscal policy, while simultaneously using restrictive monetary policy to increase interest rates sufficiently to rectify the BoP position (by attracting strong capital inflows). Theoretically, the correct combination of these two steps can lead to the simultaneous achievement of both objectives. In South Africa prior to 1994, the low sensitivity of foreign capital to domestic interest rates inhibited the effectiveness of this policy package – especially since political conditions also discouraged capital inflow. After 1994 it has become much less of a problem. However, this problem might return if South Africa loses all three sovereign investor-grade credit ratings (i.e. the sovereign credit ratings issued by Moody’s, S&P and Fitch rating agencies). On a deeper level, trade-offs have to be faced when contemplating economic growth and unemployment together with economic development and poverty reduction. Whereas it is often assumed that higher economic growth will lead to lower unemployment and progress with economic development, things are not so straightforward. As we will see when we discuss the concept of structural unemployment (see box in chapter 6, section 6.3.2), certain kinds of growth can leave structural unemployment unreduced (compare the concept of jobless growth). Depending on the way it occurs, economic growth can also be accompanied by increasing inequality among citizens of a country, can make a limited impact on the level of human development, or can harm the environment. On the other hand, making economic growth truly inclusive could generate an important convergence between economic growth, on the one hand, and development, employment creation and poverty reduction on the other (see ‘Redistribution versus growth’ above). 1.7 Priority choices of the South African government The South African government is also forced to choose between various policy objectives. Throughout the years the South African government also did not award the same priority to all its objectives: ❐ In the first half of the 1970s, economic growth had the highest priority. However, these also were the last years of the so-called macroeconomic ‘golden age’ that started in the 1960s in South Africa. The 1973 OPEC oil crisis introduced the period of high inflation all over the world; price stability became a major policy concern. After the 1976 Soweto student uprising, when international economic pressure on South Africa (e.g. trade sanctions) began, the BoP demanded increasing attention. ❐ A rather low priority was given to growth and employment in the period 1981–85. South Africa registered rather good economic growth in 1981 following the boom in the gold price. However, the large inflow of foreign reserves in 1981 caused a significant spike in the inflation rate. Therefore, the government and the Reserve Bank came to associate growth with unwanted inflation. This led to an under-emphasis of growth. ❐ Much changed in 1986. That year’s budget speech was unique in that it expressly gave the highest priority to the economic conditions for social reform – i.e. the distribution, 1.7 Priority choices of the South African government How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 31 31 2019/12/17 09:15 ❐ ❐ ❐ ❐ ❐ ❐ ❐ 32 equity and development objectives, in conjunction with the employment objective. This was a first for a Minister of Finance (then Barend du Plessis). The political protests of those years (perhaps partly due to the previous neglect of the employment and development objectives?) are likely to have been a major factor in this policy shift. The financial sanctions imposed on South Africa put tremendous pressure on the BoP though, pushing economic growth to the back burner. The early 1990s represent a period of major political transition. Economic growth received a higher priority, but, due to political uncertainty (resulting in low investment) as well as the international recession, actual growth was at its lowest level since 1960. During the 1990s the Reserve Bank under governor Chris Stals was very successful in reducing inflation to below 10%. After the first democratic election in 1994, the new government came to power with the Reconstruction and Development Programme (RDP) as its mandate. The RDP emphasised human development, but acknowledged the need for economic growth. It also acknowledged the budgetary constraints that government faced. This year marked a significant shift in government policy towards emphasising development and social spending. In 1996 the government announced the Growth, Employment and Redistribution (GEAR) strategy. GEAR was mainly a macroeconomic stabilisation policy that reflected the basic principles of the so-called Washington consensus. (It is called thus because it reflects the central ideas propounded by the IMF and the World Bank – both located in the US capital Washington DC.) These principles include an emphasis on growth, fiscal prudence and avoiding government dissaving (typically requiring cutting government expenditure and deficits), monetary prudence (to get low inflation) and privatisation. With the GEAR emphasis on a 6% growth target, many people – but most notably the trade unions – accused government of neglecting employment, redistribution and social spending. Although government succeeded in reducing the budget deficit and public debt, it was less successful in stimulating investment and economic growth. After 1999, when Tito Mboweni became governor, the Reserve Bank was able to use conservative monetary policy to focus on maintaining an inflation rate of 6% on average – though at times inflation exceeded 10% due to exchange rate or oil price shocks. With a prudent macroeconomic (i.e. fiscal and monetary) policy in place at the turn of the century, and the subsequent room created in the budget, the government turned to the more microeconomic and redistributive aspects of policy. Since 2000 a permanent expansion of the social welfare system was introduced. Whereas only 5.8 million people received a type of social grant in 2003, by 2018 about 17.5 million people received a social grant. The largest increase occurred in child support grants. In 2003 there were 2.6 million child grants and in 2018 about 12.2 million. Approximately 45% of households received some type of government grant in 2018. In 2006, government introduced the Accelerated and Shared Growth Initiative South Africa (ASGISA). ASGISA was a rather loose collection of initiatives to address the binding constraints on growth. It included elements of industrial policy, small business development and infrastructure investment. However, it never really got off the ground. Government’s New Growth Path (NGP) of 2010 prioritised employment creation and ‘decent’ jobs through investment in massive infrastructure projects (also in rural areas), reindustrialisation, minerals beneficiation, small business development and public works programmes – while it also intended to produce equitable and inclusive growth and decent jobs (via labour rights). With the focus on ‘jobs drivers’, little was said of social objectives or changing the situation of marginalised people. The NGP was soon superseded by the more encompassing National Development Plan (NDP) of 2012. Chapter 1: Why macroeconomics? An introduction to the issues How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 32 2019/12/17 09:15 ❐ The NDP, which was formally adopted by government, presented plans with 2030 as the end goal. While it thoroughly addressed many dimensions of society, at its core the NDP prioritised ‘faster and more inclusive growth: an economy that will create more jobs’. For GDP growth it mainly proposed increasing exports, linked to a growing service sector and small business development for employment growth. Extensive infrastructure expenditure was intended to stimulate growth while public works programmes would create millions of temporary public-sector jobs in the interim years. Social expenditure and social protection would be increased to eliminate poverty and reduce inequality, while also transforming human settlements and the rural economy. (In the period up to 2018 the implementation of the NDP was slow or absent, though.) ❐ The Minister of Finance up to May 2014, Pravin Gordhan, adopted economic growth as the key to tackling unemployment and poverty, declaring that a growth rate of 7% will be required for a generation to reduce unemployment. Since the rate of inflation had been below 6% for several years, it was not a high priority and the Reserve Bank (with new governor Gill Marcus and subsequently Lesetja Kganyago) had a low profile. ❐ This policy approach largely continued up to early 2019 (amidst a high rotation of Ministers of Finance, including Nene, Van Rooyen (literally for a weekend), Gordhan, Gigaba and Mboweni). At the same time, decisions with huge fiscal implications, such as the abrupt announcement of free higher education, as well as repeated financial bail-outs of state-owned enterprises (SOEs) such as Eskom, South African Airways (SAA) and the SA Broadcasting Corporation (SABC), forced to the fore government debt and the government’s ability to borrow money internationally (i.e. South Africa’s sovereign credit rating). ❐ At this stage the NDP objectives had largely faded away, or was not being implemented at all. However, in June 2019 President Cyril Ramaphosa recommitted the government to the implementation of the goals of the NDP. 1.8 Main perspectives in the economic debate in South Africa Any person reading the overview of policy choices and priorities of the South African government since the 1970s will be struck by the strong undertone of opposing economic and political philosophies. Moreover, when one considers the economic policy history, embedded as it is in South Africa’s peculiar political history, one realises that it cannot be separated from at least two debates: one on economic philosophy, the other political-economic. 1.8.1 Economic schools of thought – Classicism, Marxism and Keynesianism Since early in the last century, South African policymakers have always been influenced by the broader international debate between economic schools of thought (or ideologies). This is discussed in depth in chapter 11 (section 11.3). At this stage it is necessary, though, to note the broad outlines of the course of mainstream economics since its inception. It has shaped, and still shapes, our everyday lives. A very simple, rudimentary outline This will be a very simple, even crude outline. Its very simplicity implies a high risk of hiding important nuances. Nevertheless, such a simple outline has an important role: to set out the very broad parameters of the main streams, or traditions, of thought in economics and about economic policy. Once these are understood, the refinements of various economists and schools of thought can be better understood and positioned within the large scope of things. The biggest divide exists between the following two broad streams: 1.8 Main perspectives in the economic debate in South Africa How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 33 33 2019/12/17 09:15 A. Mainstream economic thought, which accepts and works within the basic capitalist or mixed-economy model. B. Marxist thought, which is fundamentally critical of the capitalist model and seeks radically alternative ways of organising economic activity. Some of the political alternatives proposed include socialism and communism (but few proponents would approve any of the forms observed in former communist states). Marxist thought is based on a deep criticism of the way the interaction of private property, private enterprise and the free market has lead to a high inequality of economic power, political power and economic welfare among people and nations – while acknowledging that no system has produced economic growth and wealth (in the aggregate) like the capitalist system. The state and politicians are seen as often being in cahoots with the capitalists: the ‘capitalist state’ is no antidote for the market. ❐ While little formal economic theory (parallel to standard microeconomic or macroeconomic theory, say) has been forthcoming from Marxist circles, Marx is one of those historical and philosophical figures that one cannot ignore or avoid. Think of a fundamental economic issue, and Marx has been there (i.e. he probably has said something profound – whether right or wrong – about it and it probably has influenced thinking about the issue). Marxist thought tackles issues at a different angle and level, and rarely fails to provoke an intellectual reaction from the reader. ❐ Several loosely affiliated strands, ‘radical’ or ‘alternative’ in varying degrees, can be identified. These include neo-Marxism, post-Keynesianism, Institutionalism and Evolutionary Economics. * * * Mainstream economic thought and related theories are based on the principles of private property, private enterprise and a significant role for the market, as well as at least a minimum role for government in the economy. Within the mainstream, the latter element – the role of the state vis-à-vis the market – has been responsible for an important, major divide between two broad sub-streams. Mainstream Group 1 – the free market and minimalist state group: This group believes, in the core, in markets as the optimal organisational mechanism for social and economic activity, and in the smooth and efficient functioning of mar­kets in determining equilibrium prices, quantities and incomes. As a corollary, the role of the state should be kept to a minimum – which comprises the provi­sion of a public legal order and the en­forcement of private property rights and contracts. Anything more than a mini­malist state will be counterproductive and cause more problems than benefits. Government failure is a real risk. 34 Mainstream Group 2 – the mixed economy group: This group believes, in the core, that markets are very important but that they face and harbour intrinsic de­ficiencies that constrain their ability to work smoothly and efficiently, thus leading to distorted outcomes – market failures – in terms of prices, quantities and incomes. The only agent that can step in to rectify these distorted outcomes, is the state (i.e. government), which can and must support, oversee, regulate and complement the activities of the market and private enterprise. (Within this group, a variety of sub-views exist regarding the proper mix of ‘state and market’, as well as the best design of government in­terventions and activities in the economy.) Chapter 1: Why macroeconomics? An introduction to the issues How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 34 2019/12/17 09:15 From broad approaches to two seminal models (1) The Classical model and its articles of faith Mainstream Group 1 first entered the ring in the middle 1700s, with the works of Adam Smith, founder of so-called Classical economic thought, and John Locke, the English philosopher. Both were exponents of Classical liberalism, the philosophy built on the fundamental belief that individual freedom and liberty are the highest good. The state is fundamentally distrusted. No artificial restrictions are to be placed on individuals, least of all by a state. If only individuals could be left alone to pursue their own interests in complete freedom, a situation of harmony and equilibrium would prevail in society – a ‘natural order’ would emerge ‘as if arranged by an Invisible Hand’. ❐ Adam Smith’s most famous work on economics was An inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations (1776). Its central thesis is that resources for the production of wealth are best employed under conditions of governmental non-interference or laissez faire. The intellectual heirs of Adam Smith, in particular the neo-classical economists, refined this view into the well-known atomistic model of ‘perfect’ competition. In this model the unrestricted interaction of demand and supply theoretically leads to an efficient, optimal equilibrium – as long as the state keeps its hands off. This theoretical model clearly corresponds closely to the general Classical view. The main thrust of the Classical approach to macroeconomics is the proposition that, given unfettered markets, the economy will always tend towards a stable equilibrium at full employment. The economy is inherently stable. Recessions and periods of unemployment are only temporary and due to external disturbances; the economy will automatically Marxist thought – a reaction to Classical views? Living in London during the Industrial Revolution, Karl Marx (1818–1883) was highly critical of the way industrialists exploited workers, including women and children, for the benefit of a few, wealthy capitalists. In an era when Classical views were accepted wisdom, there was little oversight or regulation of markets by government. Marx developed a radical critique of the capitalist process of production. His classic book Das Kapital (1867) highlighted fundamental characteristics, forces and contradictions in the way a capitalist economy functions. These characteristics laid the foundation for large inequalities and inequities between workers and the owners of business enterprises, i.e. the capitalists. The resultant class conflict, he predicted, would continually place the market system under stress, leading to a series of crises. He foresaw a cycle of growth, followed by collapse, followed by growth, etc. In the process, the capitalist class would become richer and the working class poorer. In the end, he predicted, the capitalist system would be destroyed by its intrinsic tensions and crises. (It was to be replaced by socialism, an interim phase on the way to a classless, stateless society.) Footnote: The reader might find it interesting that Karl Marx’s sister Louise was married to a Dutch gentleman called Johann Carel Juta. They moved to South Africa in 1853 and settled in Cape Town, where he built a publishing company now known as Juta & Company – the publisher of this book. Mr Juta knew Marx well and encouraged him to write articles for a Cape Town newspaper, De Zuid-Afrikaan. 1.8 Main perspectives in the economic debate in South Africa How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 35 35 2019/12/17 09:15 return to the full employment equilibrium promptly. As a result, unemployment is not a real problem. No remedial steps are necessary, least of all from government. Protracted periods of unemployment and recession cannot occur. The Classical model of the economy was in vogue up to 1930. (2) The Keynesian model and its articles of faith Mainstream Group 2 emerged in the 1930s. While the Classical and the neo-classical models constituted the dominant economic paradigm up to the end of the third decade of the 20th century, the Great Depression of 1929–33 all but killed the Classical proposition that unemployment at most is a temporary aberration (disequilibrium) that will disappear spontaneously. The Depression was triggered by the US stock market crash of 1929. It quickly spread to the rest of the Western world. In the USA, hundreds of banks collapsed, bankruptcies abounded, and employment rose to more than 10 million, which at the time represented a 25% unemployment rate (with similar rates in countries such as the UK). This lasted until at least 1933. South Africa also experienced the Depression, with severe unemployment and poverty being aggravated by the great drought of 1933. From 1933 to 1938, US President Franklin D Roosevelt introduced the New Deal, a set of economic policies intended to counter the effects of the Great Depression via large government infrastructural projects and fiscal stimulation. This was not dissimilar to the policies suggested by the British (Cambridge) economist John Maynard Keynes (1883–1946). Keynes, one of the most influential people of the 20th century, published his General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money in 1936. From the late 1920s he already proposed similar policies for the UK. The demise of the Classical model coincided with the rise of Keynesian theory. The crux of the Keynesian approach is the acceptance of the inherent instability of the economy and the intrinsic imperfections and flaws of markets. Keynesian macroeconomic theory demonstrated that the economy can stabilise (stagnate) at an equilibrium with unemployment (see chapter 2). This was a radical deviation from Classical thought. Moreover, Keynesianism prescribed deliberate government action in the form of a fiscal stimulus as a remedy. In general, it favoured active anti-cyclical fiscal policy, and deficit spending if necessary, to remedy the flawed dynamics of the unfettered market. The positive economic impact of wartime government expenditure on the US economy, and of the Marshall Plan in Europe, boosted this view. Keynesian macroeconomics – later refined to include the attempted fine-tuning of the business cycle to minimise cyclical instability – became the dominant policy approach of most Western governments until the mid-1970s. The end of the business cycle was proclaimed (prematurely, as it turned out). Ideologies, legacies and disciples With both these large ideologies having been founded, and each having had a period of dominance in economic teaching and research as well as policymaking, the stage was set for a prolonged battle of ideas. The unfolding of this process involved various comebacks, revisions and refinements. It was interspersed with – and triggered by – definitive occurrences in the real world. One example was the sudden high inflation of the late 1970s, which could not be explained by existing Keynesian theory, and of which the timing and diagnosis fitted the analytical 36 Chapter 1: Why macroeconomics? An introduction to the issues How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 36 2019/12/17 09:15 paradigm of the Classical proponents like a glove. University of Chicago economists such as Milton Friedman had been working hard, from the 1950s, at rehabilitating Classical liberal economic thought. A first ‘reborn Classical’ approach, which came to be known as Monetarism, became very popular in the high-inflation 1970s – following a decade of intense policy debates with Keynesians (see chapter 11, sections 11.3.2 and 11.3.5). A central tenet was that policy to fight unemployment is impotent in the long run and will only lead to permanently higher inflation. This was followed by the birth of the so-called New Classical School. This was a younger and more extreme mutation in the Classical-Monetarist lineage (sometimes also called Monetarism mark II; see section 11.3.3). It claimed that not only is policy impotent in the long run (Friedman’s view), but also that it is impotent in the short run. The concept of rational expectations, introduced by Robert Lucas (also from the University of Chicago), is central to this approach. Just as the advent of Keynesian economics in the 1930s did not mean the end of the Classical tradition, so the resurgence of the Classical tradition in the form of Monetarism and New Classical economics did not mean the end of the Keynesian approach. (That is the nature of ideologies: they do not wither and die easily.) From the late 1980s, Keynesian economists such as Mankiw and Blanchard addressed the weaknesses of the older Keynesian approach – inter alia that it failed to explain the high inflation of the 1970s. Their approach became known as New Keynesian economics. While incorporating rational expectations into their models, they showed that various wage and price rigidities can explain why an economy experiences unemployment and instability in the short and medium run – a central tenet of original Keynesianism (see chapter 6). Nevertheless, at the turn of the century, New Classical economists appeared to think that they had won the intellectual battle. The world was in an unprecedented era of economic growth and prosperity, coinciding with an era of shrinking government involvement – often in the form of financial and economic deregulation – in major Western economies. Keynesian theory started to disappear from macroeconomic courses, first at postgraduate level, and then from undergraduate textbooks. Then the real world intervened – again. In late 2007, the subprime crisis struck in the USA and quickly spread to other countries, leading to the greatest financial and economic crisis in the world economy since the infamous Great Depression of the 1930s. Analysts quickly pointed fingers to the legacy of Thatcher, Reagan and others: by making deregulation and unfettered markets the centrepiece of policy in major high-income economies, they opened the door for excessive risk-taking in financial markets – on a huge scale. Governments had to respond quickly to prevent a worldwide economic meltdown. After bailing out several banks and financial institutions, the government of US President Barack Obama launched a government spending programme, notably on infrastructure, of unprecedented scale. Several newspapers proclaimed – with a certain sense of irony – that this marked a return, in the USA at least, to Keynesianism on a huge scale. (It was complemented by a huge programme of monetary stimulation, until October 2014, called ‘quantitative easing’, run by the US Federal Reserve – see the case study in section 3.4.) Similar policy shifts occurred in Europe: although anti-Keynesian ideas did seem to have some purchase there previously, the experience of the harm caused by fiscal austerity changed many policy minds. 1.8 Main perspectives in the economic debate in South Africa How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 37 37 2019/12/17 09:15 In the USA president Donald Trump enacted large tax cuts and market deregulation in 2017–18. While these were seen as ‘freeing-up business’ steps that resembled the ‘supply-side’ policy approach of former president Reagan, Trump’s introduction of protectionist international trade tariffs constitutes the opposite of free-market ideology. Increased government spending on the military and on infrastructure ‘to get the economy working again’ also suggests a Keynesian approach. On the whole, though, his mix of policies appeared to be driven by political opportunism or populism, rather than any coherent Keynesian (or non-Keynesian) policy framework or economic ideology. South Africa – always a microcosm? While most of this ideological battle occurred in the USA and the UK, and also in Europe, countries such as South Africa have always been affected by the broader currents. Through the use of foreign textbooks, studying abroad in the USA, UK and Europe, and through international academic journals, conferences and communication, these debates spilled over to South Africa quite rapidly. Elements of how this unfolded in South African policy circles are discussed above (section 1.7) and in chapter 10 (on fiscal policy). Views representing both main schools of thought are to be found among South African universities and economists. 1.8.2 Political-economic perspectives – race, class, capitalism and apartheid A broader South African context is provided by the debate on the constitutional, political and social framework of the country – going from a colonial and later apartheid past to a fully democratic, post-1994 present. That political history had a parallel economic philosophy and policy history. The interaction between politics and economics in South African history is a complex and contested topic. Several theories exist on whether race-based legislation and policies have inhibited economic development, or may have served the interests of business and especially mining. There are too many to summarise here. Nevertheless, there are many indications of an intricate symbiosis (or mutual dependence) between, first, the way the capitalist economy and business sector was organised and managed since before 1900, and, second, the development of various manifestations of racial supremacy, racial exploitation, migrant labour, separate development and apartheid. In short: persons and institutions who wielded political power and economic power were often in agreement – since at least 1894, when the Glen Grey Act was promulgated – about the need to use race-based measures and subjugation of especially black workers to further the economic and political interests of a selected group of people. The interesting thing to note is the contrasting role played by socialist/communist thinking during the 20th century. During the mineworker strike of 1922, communist sympathies and class consciousness among white workers were strong, as they were united against (English) capitalists. During the 1930s and 1940s, there was a strong block of support amongst the (at the time very poor) white Afrikaner community for socialist views of the state and the economy, favouring state interventions and redress to benefit the poor (white) class. Market-based philosophies were seen as the other side of the coin of British imperialism and dominance by British capital. Hence, during the Second World War, some support developed for the philosophy of National Socialism, then strongly propounded in Nazi Germany. (This philosophy combined socialist ideals with nationalist ideals regarding the self-determination of the German people.) 38 Chapter 1: Why macroeconomics? An introduction to the issues How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 38 2019/12/17 09:15 After the war, despite increasing involvement in the international economy, the National Party government remained sceptical of classical-liberal economic thinking. This might have been partly due to the association of the latter philosophy with growing criticism, from overseas, against the system of apartheid and ‘separate development’. Also, the state was seen to be, and was used as, an important instrument to strengthen the economy, often for the disproportionate benefit of whites. After 1948 and the election victory of the National Party, apartheid rapidly changed from a tacit understanding amongst the powerful to an explicit, formalised and legalised social regulation system. Government policymakers distrusted the ‘market’ and (English-dominated) business sector, and the state was a major actor in steering the economy within the context of the capitalistapartheid economy. In the Freedom Charter, adopted at Kliptown in 1955 following the ANC defiance campaign, principles for a future South Africa were set out. Many of the economic clauses refer to basic economic freedoms: to work, to be paid equitably, to own land, to be educated. What raised the ire of the economic and political establishment at the time were clauses that sounded just too socialist for comfort or raised fears of expropriation, such as: The People Shall Share in the Country’s Wealth! The national wealth of our country … shall be restored to the people The mineral wealth beneath the soil, the Banks and monopoly industry shall be transferred to the ownership of the people as a whole All other industry and trade shall be controlled to assist the wellbeing of the people The Land Shall be Shared Among Those Who Work It! There Shall be Work and Security! The Doors of Learning and Culture Shall be Opened! Education shall be free, compulsory, universal and equal for all children There Shall be Houses, Security and Comfort! These yearnings of oppressed people did not find much sympathy in (white) establishment circles, whether political or economic. The 1960s were an era of high economic growth based largely on high gold export earnings. To whites there appeared to be little reason to change political or economic policies. In the ANC the struggle was transformed into an armed struggle (in 1961). Only in the mid-1970s did voices in influential Afrikaner circles start to argue for the ‘free market philosophy’ (notably economists such as Jan Lombard and Nic Wiehahn). By this time, the National Party government increasingly associated socialism with the communist threat. In addition, the latter had a very immediate presence in the form of support from the USSR and China for liberation movements, the armed struggle and the border war. Moreover, movements such as the ANC, Azapo and the PAC propounded various socialist solutions for the South African economy and state. Thus, government sympathies started to shift towards the free market ideology, a move encouraged by good relations with the conservative UK government of Margaret Thatcher. In the early 1980s, the National Party government and the business sector openly moved closer together around the free market theme. Labour market liberalisations led to a new era for labour unions. By the late 1980s, the first meetings (in Europe) between domestic economists/ businessmen and ANC economists-in-exile revealed a large gap between, respectively, free market capitalist proponents and pro-state, socialist proponents – with a few outsiders arguing for a Third Way, but without much success. In the years that followed, intense lobbying and debate took place behind the scenes. After the 1994 election, the new ANCdominated government took a surprisingly conciliatory line with regard to key elements 1.8 Main perspectives in the economic debate in South Africa How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 39 39 2019/12/17 09:15 of the economy, notably property rights and private ownership of the economy (after propounding nationalisation for many years), central bank independence, monetary and fiscal discipline, a firm anti-inflationary stance, international trade liberalisation and so forth. It had already adopted many elements of the Washington consensus, as noted above. The adoption of the RDP (1994) and the GEAR (1996) policies followed, harbouring elements of both (a) a state-directed approach to development and redress, and (b) a market-based, business-oriented approach to economic policy. This was an evolving form of social democracy, one could say. But it was a highly contested one, squeezed between players such as, on the one hand, the more socialist Cosatu and the SACP, and, on the other, the ANC government, often supported by the business sector (by now with a growing black and black empowerment component). At the time of the 2009 election, the role of the SACP and Cosatu in the so-called tripartite alliance appeared to be gaining influence in ANC economic thinking. However, in the following years the SACP fully submitted to the ANC approach without protest. Then, in the run-up to the 2014 election, significant internal divisions developed in Cosatu, particularly with respect to the economic policy component of the National Development Plan (NDP). Numsa, Cosatu’s largest affiliate, together with a number of smaller Cosatu affiliates, distanced themselves from the NDP and withdrew their support of the ANC in the 2014 national election. These unions also broke away from Cosatu and formed the SA Federation of Trade Unions (SAFTU). In 2018 Numsa established a Socialist Revolutionary Workers Party (SRWP) as a ‘Marxist-Leninist political party fighting to overthrow the brutal capitalist system’ – but it did not receive many votes. Other political breakaways from the ANC were the Economic Freedom Fighters (EFF) as well as new, non-Cosatu labour formations such as the Association of Mineworkers and Construction Union (AMCU) (opposing ‘democratic capitalism’ and ANC policies) and SAFTU (with its proclaimed ‘revolutionary and socialist orientation’). These signalled a growing split in groupings on the left of the political spectrum – between those with stronger class-based and socialist (or democratic socialist) views and those with stronger social democratic views. Alongside this big debate, parties such as the Democratic Alliance continued to represent the more business- and market-oriented part of the political-economic spectrum (liberaldemocratic albeit with a social conscience) – but with signs of a growing social-democratic component since 2015. These broad political divisions would continue to shape the South African debate, also on economic policy, in the years to follow. ❐ By developing a political party spectrum that is differentiated mainly on the basis of economic policy – notably the role of government in the economy – South Africa would join large parts of the world where economic ideology and policy are the main dividing factors among political parties in elections. Left, right or centre – or what? Sorting out the left and the right in South Africa is not easy. Unlike other countries, we have always had a left-to-right on politics and another one on economics. And the two have not necessarily corresponded. ❐ The political left-to-right has always been along race-and-culture views, politics and policies. ❐ The economic left-to-right, as in other countries, is along views on market vis-à-vis state. 40 ⇒ Chapter 1: Why macroeconomics? An introduction to the issues How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 40 2019/12/17 09:15 ⇒ Politically left and right – a race-based spectrum Political conservatives, in terms of race-based paradigms, are the political right or far-right. In the old South Africa, the National Party considered themselves moderate/centre, with the Conservative Party (later the Freedom Front) on the right wing, the Democratic Party (later the Democratic Alliance) viewed as ‘left’, and the ANC and PAC far out off the cliff on the radical left. From the viewpoint of the ANC and PAC, the DP was centrist at best; the rest were varying degrees of right and far-right. The ANC and its affiliates have always been proudly left. While racial attitudes and politics still feature resiliently at grassroots level, South African political parties today are increasingly differentiated according to their view on the economy rather than on race and identity, as follows: Economically left and right – a market-state spectrum The basic positions can be defined as follows: ❐ Economic conservatives = free marketeers = economically on the right wing (several variants of ‘classical liberals’ and libertarians: US Republican Party; UK Conservative Party; South Africa: elements of the DA). ❐ Economic liberals = mixed economy moderates = economically centrist (several variants: US: ‘bleeding heart’ liberals = Democratic Party; UK New Labour Party; European Social Democratic Parties; South Africa: post-1994 Mandela-Mbeki ANC; centrist wing of the current ANC; elements of the DA). ❐ Economic radicals = critical of market economies, neo-Marxist = economically leftist (Old UK Labour Party; European Democratic Socialist Parties; European Communist Parties; South Africa: pre-1994 ANC; left wing of post-1994 and current ANC, SACP and elements of Cosatu; Saftu; Numsa and SRWP; EFF; AMCU). 1.9 Analytical questions and exercises 1. Discuss economic growth and price stability as objectives of macroeconomic policy. Refer to all possible complementarities and/or trade-offs that might exist between these two objectives, and also discuss the most current trends in the indicators that are associated with these objectives. 2. The clearest indicator of South Africa’s worsening position globally has been the sustained fall in the rand since 2011, frequently due to foreign investors selling SA bonds and equity. In the first six months of 2019 alone, foreign investors withdrew about R70 billion from South African bond and equity markets. What could this imply for the pursuit of economic growth and development? Also explain how the macroeconomic goals of balance of payments stability and price stability are affected. (In Chapter 4 you will encounter a detailed analysis of the international context.) 3. Discuss price stability as an objective of macroeconomic policy in South Africa. In your discussion, clearly define what is meant by the objective, and indicate how inflation affects low-income households and pensioners, as well as borrowers and investors respectively. Provide most recent values of suitable indicators of the situation. 4. ‘To solve South Africa’s unemployment problem, there is only one solution: the economic growth rate needs to be increased.’ Critically discuss this statement with reference to employment trends and various types of unemployment. (In Chapter 12 you will learn much more about employment and unemployment.) 1.9 Main perspectives in the economic debate in South Africa How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 41 41 2019/12/17 09:15 5. Discuss economic growth and the redistribution of income as objectives of macroeconomic policy. In your discussion, clearly define what is meant by each objective, and indicate any complementarities and/or trade-offs between these two objectives. Provide most recent values of suitable indicators to measure these objectives in South Africa. 6. Explain the possible effect of a higher inflation rate on interest rates and related impacts on low-income groups and pensioners earning fixed interest income. 7. During the first two quarters of 2018 South Africa experienced consecutive negative quarterly economic growth rates for the first time in many years – following steady declines in the GDP growth rate since 2011. Can such a decline have any significant effects on the country’s economic development? Discuss with reference to the relationship between economic growth and economic development. 42 Chapter 1: Why macroeconomics? An introduction to the issues How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 42 2019/12/17 09:15 The basic model I: consumers, producers and government 2 After reading this chapter, you should be able to: ■ construct a basic model of production and income determination; ■ use the model to explain why and how total income in the economy tends to fluctuate over the course of the ‘business cycle’; ■ compare and explain the behaviour of the main components of expenditure in an open economy, i.e. consumption, investment, government expenditure, imports and exports; ■ compose chain reactions (or ‘chain reasoning’) to analyse the way changes in economic variables (taxation, interest rates and so forth) or external disturbances work dynamically through the economy; and ■ use graphical aids to support and critically evaluate your economic reasoning. Unemployment, inflation, interest rates, exchange rates, the balance of payments, the gold price, the budget, public debt, taxation, Reserve Bank policy – these issues are what macroeconomics is all about. They deeply affect all our lives, whether as student, household consumer, investor, business manager, employee, labour union member or government official. News coverage and political-economic debates show the importance of macroeconomic events and issues in these times, with the added complication of concurrent development challenges. As noted in chapters 0 and 1, the objective of this book is to enable you to think and reason about actual macroeconomic events and policy. It does so by systematically building a comprehensive framework of analysis (i.e. a theory or model of the macroeconomy) that you can use to analyse events – in conjunction with a thorough intuitive grasp of the issues and a concrete feel for South African economic processes, institutions and data. As a first step towards understanding the operation of the economy, we consider, in this chapter, the simple Keynesian theory of income determination. This theory was designed originally to explain recessions and periods of unemployment. It emphasises the nature and causes of short-run fluctuations in real domestic income and employment. ❐ The short run is a period usually thought to be up to three years. In later chapters (chapters 6 and 7) we will also encounter adjustments, notably on the supply side of the economy, that occur in the so-called medium term. This can be thought of as lasting another three to seven years. The typical average for both processes, allowing for some overlap, is approximately four to seven years. Short- and medium-term changes and adjustments are frequently discussed in the context of business cycles with references to ‘booms’ and ‘busts’, ‘upswings’ and ‘downswings’. Both the short- and medium-term periods can be distinguished from the very long term, with a time horizon measured in decades, which is the topic of economic growth (chapter 8). Chapter 2: The basic model I: consumers, producers and government How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 43 43 2019/12/17 09:15 The simple model focuses on the so-called real sector (or goods sector) of the economy, where real economic activities such as production, consumption, saving, investment, imports and exports occur. The theory can, therefore, help us understand the short-run course of the South African economy, especially the course of gross domestic product (GDP). ❐ You would have encountered this theory in an introductory economics course. This chapter will, therefore, review this material in a summary fashion. Still, important intuitive insights and new analytical abilities will be developed. While the interest rate plays a major role in this chapter, its full explanation is left to chapter 3, where the monetary sector – the world of financial institutions, money and interest rates – is added to the framework. Chapter 4 considers matters such as the balance of payments and exchange rates (the foreign sector). The price level, which is essential for an analysis of inflation, is a prominent variable in more modern versions of Keynesian theory. However, for explanatory reasons, this is brought into the analysis only in chapter 6. (Inflation gets a thorough treatment in chapters 7 and 12.) ❐ In the simple Keynesian model we assume, for the time being, that the average price level P remains constant. While obviously unrealistic, it does not affect the initial results of the analysis materially. And it is helpful to make things clear at the start. We will relax this assumption in chapter 6. At the end of this book the model will be fully developed and quite sophisticated. ❐ Nevertheless, throughout the book we will define all concepts and relationships in such a way that the place of the average price level P (and the inflation rate π where appropriate) is evident. Allowing for changes in the average price level P, and for inflation, brings us to the use of the term ‘real’ in another context. ❐ This is the difference between so-called nominal values of economic variables (e.g. nominal GDP) and real values of variables (e.g. real GDP). For example, nominal GDP is the value of total output measured in terms of the current prices of goods and services. The presence of inflation can inflate the measured value of a nominal variable artificially. In real values this artificial inflation has been removed to reveal the true, underlying change in a variable. Thus real GDP is the value of total output expressed in the prices of a base year, e.g. 2010. It is also called GDP at constant prices. The significance of this distinction will become clear as we proceed. Inflation and the distinction between real and nominal Working with variables and data in an inflationary context requires an acute awareness of the difference between nominal and real values. It must be taken into account in the way values are measured. The following are useful formulae: Real values (e.g. GDP) = Nominal value (of GDP, say) deflated with a price index, i.e. divided by a suitable price index Real GDP growth rate = Nominal growth rate – inflation rate [approximately] Real interest rate [approximately] = Nominal interest rate – inflation rate One must also ask whether certain economic behaviours reflect a reaction to a nominal value or to a real value of a variable. For example, real investment reacts to real interest rates, but money demand reacts to nominal interest rates (see sections 2.2.2 and 3.1.2). 44 Chapter 2: The basic model I: consumers, producers and government How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 44 2019/12/17 09:15 ❐ Except where explicitly indicated otherwise, we will be concerned with real values of GDP, income, consumption, investment, interest rates and so forth – without always adding the adjective ‘real’. In this chapter we focus on the determination of total production and real income in the short run. This is measured in terms of real GDP. Changes in real GDP are reflected in the business cycle (short-run fluctuations – i.e. upswings and downswings – in the economy). Table 2.1 provides pertinent information on the business cycle in South Africa. Table 2.1 Business cycle upswings and downswings in South Africa since 1968 ✍ Upswings Downswings Jan 1968 – Dec 1970 Jan 1971 – Aug 1972 Sept 1972 – Aug 1974 Sept 1974 – Dec 1977 Jan 1978 – Aug 1974 Sept 1981 – March 1983 April 1983 – June 1984 July 1984 – March 1986 April 1986 – Feb 1989 March 1989 – May 1993 June 1993 – Nov 1996 Dec 1996 – Aug 1999 Sept 1999 – Nov 2007 Dec 2007 – Aug 2009 Sept 2009 – Nov 2013 Dec 2013 – Note the variability in the duration of both upswings and downswings, the average duration of each being approximately 30 months, so that a full cycle takes approximately 5 years on average. The recession of 51 months from March 1989 to May 1993 and the almost decade-long upswing after September 1999 have been the longest since the second World War. (See graphs in section 1.3.1.) * The official turning points are determined by the Reserve Bank after a statistical analysis of approximately 230 time series as well as consideration of economic events in the vicinity of a possible turning point. The data requirements cause a long time lag in the official announcement of a turning point date. Source: Key Information. Reserve Bank Quarterly Bulletin. Approximately how many trillion rand was the GDP of South Africa last year? _____________________________________________________________________________________ What is the definition of GDP? _____________________________________________________________________________________ What is the difference between nominal and real GDP? Why is this difference important? _____________________________________________________________________________________ What was the approximate growth rate in South Africa since 2010? How does it compare with previous decades? How does one measure the growth rate? _____________________________________________________________________________________ (Consult the formulae, tables and graphs in chapter 5 and chapter 1, section 1.3.) DATA TIP Macroeconomic data: which source? The main source of macroeconomic data in South Africa is the Quarterly Bulletin of the South African Reserve Bank. It is available from the Bank or from libraries, or at www.resbank.co.za For employment and unemployment data, the main source is the Quarterly Labour Force Survey (QLFS), published by Statistics South Africa. It is available at www.statssa.gov.za Tables and graphs depicting the course of the main macroeconomic variables in South Africa can be found throughout this book. Chapter 2: The basic model I: consumers, producers and government How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 45 45 2019/12/17 09:15 2.1 The basic framework The crux of the original Keynesian approach is that the explanation of changes in production and income, particularly in the short run, is to be found in fluctuations in total expenditure in the economy. Thus, in the short run, total expenditure in the economy is at the centre of the action. If that can be explained, the decisions that lead to (or are reflected in) the macroeconomic state of the economy can be understood. Therefore, the basic Keynesian model is an expenditureor demand-determined model. (Later versions of the model also take the supply side into consideration – see chapters 6 and 7.) The significance of expenditure is that it induces and determines production decisions. In the simple model, we more or less assume that the production (or supply) side of the economy – the decisions of producers to produce – will respond without difficulty or delay to changes in total expenditure. (This assumption will be relaxed in chapter 6 to make the model more realistic.) Each level of production implies a corresponding level of real domestic income. Depending on the methods of production chosen by producers, this is likely to have some effect on employment. The idea of an income-expenditure circular flow is very useful to illustrate the Keynesian approach (see figure 2.3). It shows the circular flow of expenditure and income between two key groups of role-players in a simple economy: households (consumers) and firms (producers). ❐ In a more complete diagram, one will also indicate a public sector (state), a monetary sector and a foreign sector. A complete circular flow diagram can be found at the beginning of chapter 6; also compare the one at the end of this chapter. What we study on the macroeconomic level is the aggregate of activities taking place on a microeconomic level. The circular flow is a simplified representation of all transactions in the economy. To see this, consider the three transactions (or exchanges) portrayed in figure 2.1. There are three types of transaction: 1. A goods market transaction where Vusi buys vegetables from Vuyelwa’s grocery store. In exchange for the vegetables, Vuyelwa’s store receives payment in the form of money. Figure 2.1 Three types of transaction A goods market transaction Vuyelwa’s grocery store (Firm) Expenditure on goods Vegetables Vusi and his family (Household) A factor (labour) market transaction Vuyelwa’s grocery store (Firm) Labour services Wages Sylvia (Household) A factor (capital) market transaction Vuyelwa’s grocery store (Firm) 46 Capital (funds) Interest John (Household) Chapter 2: The basic model I: consumers, producers and government How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 46 2019/12/17 09:15 2. A labour market transaction where Vuyelwa’s store employs Sylvia. In exchange for her labour services, Sylvia receives a wage/salary from Vuyelwa’s grocery store. 3. A financial (or capital) market transaction where John buys shares in Vuyelwa’s grocery store, or where John extends a loan to Vuyelwa’s grocery store. In exchange for the capital funds invested in Vuyelwa’s grocery store, John receives dividends and/ or interest. The labour and financial markets both are factor markets – labour and capital are factors of production. Grouping them together, distinct from goods market transactions, and aggregating all such transactions in the economy, one can represent the two types of transaction between all firms and all households as follows: Figure 2.2 All transactions together Total expenditure Goods Firms Households Factors of production Factor payments (income) If we focus only on the flows of income and expenditure between firms and households (and thus disregard the flows of factors and goods), the circular flow in the entire economy can be represented as shown in figure 2.3: Figure 2.3 A basic circular flow Expenditure flow (Payments for goods) FIRMS (Producers) HOUSEHOLDS (Consumers) Income flow (Factor payments) Our main concern now is the aggregate amount of real income that ends up in the pockets of households and individuals in the bottom half of the circle. The volume of real income flowing in the bottom half of the circular ‘tube’ depends on the volume of expenditure in the top half. If the flow of total expenditure increases, for example, it is likely to induce decisions to increase production to meet the increased expenditure. This implies a corresponding adjusted level of sales and real income Y. The same is true for decreases in 2.1 The basic framework How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 47 47 2019/12/17 09:15 expenditure, which initially lead to unsold products and stock increases, to be followed by a drop in production, income and employment (i.e. a recession). This reasoning provides us with the first and basic chain reaction: changes in expenditure cause adjustments in production and real income. When production has adjusted fully to a change in total expenditure, a situation of macroeconomic equilibrium occurs. In such a situation, neither expenditure nor production has any further reason to change, and therefore income stabilises on a certain level. All demand/expenditure is satisfied, and all production is sold. At such an equilibrium, the following condition is satisfied: Total expenditure = Total production In Keynesian theory, both short-run fluctuations and trends in real domestic income Y are interpreted as changes in this equilibrium, or at least as movements towards a new equilibrium point. Therefore, it is an equilibrium approach. Changes in the equilibrium level of income are caused and explained by changes in total expenditure. ❐ Accordingly, a low level of income and employment – a recession – is caused by a too low level of aggregate expenditure, i.e. a demand deficiency. Figure 2.4 The business cycle: fluctuations in real GDP relative to its long-term trend 3 600 3 100 Acute recession Strong upswing R billion 2 600 2 100 Severe recession 1 600 Mild recession 2018/04 2017/03 2016/02 2015/01 2013/04 2012/03 2011/02 2010/01 2008/04 2007/03 2006/02 2005/01 2003/04 2002/03 2001/02 2000/01 1998/04 1997/03 1996/02 1995/01 1993/04 1992/03 1991/02 1990/01 1988/04 1987/03 1986/02 1985/01 1983/04 1982/03 1980/01 600 1981/02 1 100 Source: South African Reserve Bank (www.resbank.co.za). Figure 2.4 shows cyclical fluctuations in real GDP around the long-term real GDP trend (or potential GDP) of South Africa since 1980. Note the significant fluctuations from 1980 to 1993 and in 2008–09 and the smaller fluctuations around a strong upward trend in between. A slowdown (or mild recession) occurs when the GDP data line becomes less steep, even though it may still be increasing. A proper recession occurs when the data line drops below previous levels of GDP. The ‘technical definition’ of a recession is two (or more) successive quarters of negative growth in GDP. A generic definition of a recession is: a significant decline in economic activity spread across the economy, lasting more than a few months, normally visible in real GDP, real income, employment, industrial production, and wholesale and retail sales. 48 Chapter 2: The basic model I: consumers, producers and government How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 48 2019/12/17 09:15 Is a macroeconomic equilibrium a good thing? Not necessarily, even though the concept of ‘equilibrium’, especially in the natural sciences but also in everyday language, has a positive connotation (balance, harmony, etc). One of the main contributions of Keynes was to show that an equilibrium does not necessarily occur at full employment and, especially, that an economy can attain equilibrium and stabilise (stagnate) at levels of high unemployment for considerable periods of time. In this way, he sought to explain the Great Depression of 1929–33. ❐ This view contrasts strongly with the Classical or pre-Keynesian view that, given unfettered markets, the economy will always tend towards a stable equilibrium with full employment. Times of unemployment are temporary aberrations at most, in the Classical view. ❐ Today this view, or variations of it, can be found in the New Classical or Monetarist approaches, for example (see chapter 11, section 11.3.4 as well as chapter 12, section 12.2.2). A more complete chain reaction would run as follows: Suppose total expenditure increases. At existing production levels, production is less than the new level of expenditure. This will be apparent in a decrease in the stocks of producers, which is a sign and inducement for producers to adjust their production levels to the new expenditure levels. When (and if) they decide to do so, total production will increase (as measured in terms of real GDP) and so will employment. The real income from the increased sales flows to the different factors of production – managers, workers, land owners, shareholders, other input suppliers, etc. – and real domestic income Y increases correspondingly. This increase is bound to continue until production is equal to the new, higher level of total expenditure – i.e. until a new and higher equilibrium level of real income Y is reached. An economic upswing occurs. In brief: Total expenditure increases ⇒ stocks are depleted ⇒ increased production is induced ⇒ real GDP and real income Y increase The role of stock adjustments is central in this chain reaction. The entire Keynesian approach centres on this fundamental chain reaction. It enables one to identify the likely causes of short-run fluctuations in real income Y, or the likely consequences of fluctuations in expenditure. ❐ We will see in this chapter and others that there are different types of real expenditure (e.g. consumption and investment) and that changes in these will cause changes in total expenditure. Once total expenditure changes, the rest of the chain reaction remains the same. In this way, one can gain insight into the causes of upswings or downswings in the economy, or increases or decreases in the real economic growth rate. The rest of the theory consists of a refined focus on real expenditure. It focuses on two aspects: (a) To understand and explain trends and fluctuations in expenditure as such, and (b) To relate and translate all other disturbances and shocks in the economy – changes in interest rates, the money supply, taxation, VAT, the gold price, the exchange rate, the balance of payments (BoP), etc. – into one or another impact on (a component of) expenditure. If this has been derived, the likely impact on production and real income Y follows more or less automatically. 2.1 The basic framework How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 49 49 2019/12/17 09:15 The income–expenditure diagram or ‘45° diagram’ shown in figure 2.5, is the basic graphical aid of the simple Keynesian approach. This shows the real sector (or goods sector) of the economy, and illustrates the interaction between total expenditure E and total production to determine the equilibrium level of real income Y. The graphical indication of this level is where the total expenditure line intersects the 45° line. Only at that level of Y (i.e. Y0) will total production (measured horizontally) be equal to total expenditure (measured vertically). Any other Y level is a disequilibrium level, since production can be seen to be either higher or lower than expenditure. Figure 2.5 Equilibrium income determination E 45° line Aggregate expenditure Y0 Income Y In other words, only at Y0 is the condition for macroeconomic equilibrium satisfied: Total expenditure = Total production. Any disturbance of, or fluctuation in, total expenditure is graphically reflected in vertical shifts in the total expenditure line, with a corresponding change in the equilibrium level of real income Y. ! Does an economy have curves? : The usefulness of a graphical aid for sensible economic thinking and reasoning – our main purposes – must be understood carefully. Its use is that it can serve: ❐ as a guide or ‘road map’ to indicate where an economic chain of logic (‘chain reasoning’) must end up, or ❐ as an ‘afterwards test’ to check whether one’s thinking on the expected chain of consequences of a disturbance has been correct. Therefore, graphical manipulations and economic reasoning must occur in parallel. One should always be able to use both of these methods. The graphical illustration as such has no economic meaning. It is not an explanation of an economic event to say that this or that line or curve or equilibrium point has shifted. An economy does not have curves, and curves cannot explain economic events. Graphical depictions have meaning only if used to support and supplement economic thinking and reasoning. The latter – the economic explanation of the dynamic path between two equilibrium points – is ultimately what matters. 2.2 The real (or goods) sector The basic thrust of the Keynesian approach is to understand, explain and anticipate the behaviour of total expenditure. This is done by dividing total expenditure into different components of expenditure. Each of these components can then be analysed using the chain reaction set out above. The main components or types of expenditure are consumption expenditure C, capital formation (or investment) I, government expenditure G, and net exports, i.e. exports X less imports M. 50 Chapter 2: The basic model I: consumers, producers and government How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 50 2019/12/17 09:15 Therefore: Total expenditure = C + I + G + (X – M) In the explanation of macroeconomic events, these types of expenditure are distinguished because they are determined and explained by different factors, and flow from the decisions of different agents with different motives and ways of decision making. For example, real consumption expenditure patterns are determined by other factors compared to real investment behaviour, while decisions on government expenditure are something quite different. Different decision-makers with different concerns are at work in each case. Therefore one has to distinguish between them and analyse their actions separately to understand events (i.e. if one wants to develop a theory of expenditure and income). Expenditure components: which data? DATA TIP The main source of data on the components of aggregate expenditure is the Quarterly Bulletin of the Reserve Bank, in particular the national account section. ❐ The table ‘Expenditure on gross domestic product’ summarises the main expenditure items of the real sector. Subsequent tables give detailed information on individual components, e.g. consumption and capital formation (investment). The data are presented in various formats and also disaggregated in various ways. ❐ The national accounts are explained in chapter 5, section 5.6 which shows the relation between the different accounts and tables. Chapter 5 also contains many figures with pertinent data on expenditure components. The graph in figure 2.6 shows the behaviour of the main domestic expenditure components for South Africa since 1960: consumption expenditure by households, gross fixed business capital formation, and total expenditure by general government (all in real terms, constant 2010 prices). Observe the relative magnitudes of these categories of expenditure and Figure 2.6 The components of aggregate expenditure (in real terms – 2010 prices) 2 000 1 800 Household consumption 1 600 1 400 R billion 1 200 1 000 800 600 Government expenditure 400 2017/04 2016/01 2014/02 2012/03 2010/04 2009/01 2007/02 2005/03 2002/01 2000/02 1998/03 1996/04 1995/01 1993/02 1991/03 1989/04 1988/01 1986/02 1984/03 1982/04 1981/01 1979/02 1977/03 1975/04 1974/01 1972/02 1970/03 1968/04 1967/01 1965/02 1963/03 1961/04 1960/01 0 2003/04 Business capital formation 200 Source: South African Reserve Bank (www.resbank.co.za). 2.2 The real (or goods) sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 51 51 2019/12/17 09:15 how they behave in relation to the upswings and downswings in real GDP. Note that both household consumption and the fixed capital formation cycle broadly correspond with the GDP cycle, although clearly more complex causalities are at work. Traditionally, consumption and investment constitute the core of the theory, with other components added on. 2.2.1 Real consumption Real consumption C pertains to expenditure by households on consumable items and services such as clothing, food, sport, movies, transport, medical services, books, pencils, computers, fridges, lawnmowers and vehicles. Expenditure on imported items is included in total real consumption expenditure. ❐ Total consumption expenditure is usually a very stable component of aggregate expenditure. ❐ The national accounts for South Africa, discussed in more detail in chapter 5, section 5.6 (and for which data tables can be obtained from www.resbank.co.za), distinguish between ‘consumption expenditure by households’ and ‘consumption expenditure by general government’. This section deals with ‘consumption expenditure by households’, usually denoted by C, while a later section deals with ‘consumption expenditure by general government’, usually denoted by, or as part of, G. When discussing ‘consumption’ in this book, ‘consumption expenditure by households’ is meant. On what does consumption depend? If one wishes to explain consumption expenditure, one usually thinks of the purchases by individuals or consumers. Business enterprises also buy consumable items. In most economic reasoning we will usually think mainly in terms of individuals or households. Real consumption C depends on (or, is a function of) real disposable income YD, wealth, the average price level, expectations, habits, etc. C = f(real disposable income YD; wealth; expectations; habits; demographic factors, etc.) This means that the decisions to spend income on consumption goods largely are determined (or caused) by these factors. Some of these factors have a positive impact on consumption expenditure, others a negative impact. ❐ Of all these factors, the most important is the level of real disposable income YD. Disposable income is the part of income Y that remains after taxation T has been paid or subtracted (YD = Y – T). ❐ If real disposable income increases, individuals and households are likely to increase their consumption spending. Decreasing real disposable income will depress total consumption. Therefore, there is a positive relationship between real disposable income and consumption. ❐ The part of disposable income that is not spent on consumption is saved. Therefore saving also depends on disposable income. ❐ The essence of the relationship between real consumption and real disposable income can be found in the marginal propensity to consume (MPC). ❐ A tax increase will decrease disposable or after-tax income, which should discourage consumption spending. Here one finds a negative or inverse relationship between taxes and consumption. 52 Chapter 2: The basic model I: consumers, producers and government How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 52 2019/12/17 09:15 ✍ One can distinguish between durable, semi-durable and non-durable consumption, as well as services. Can you mention examples of each? _______________________________________________________________________________________ _______________________________________________________________________________________ _______________________________________________________________________________________ Visit www.resbank.co.za and download the annual data series, both at constant and current prices, for total, durable, semi-durable and non-durable consumption, as well as services for the period 1990 until the latest year available. Place these on a couple of graphs and describe what you see. What is the difference between the constant and current prices? _______________________________________________________________________________________ _______________________________________________________________________________________ Which percentage of gross domestic expenditure (GDE) does consumption C represent in South Africa (approximately)? _______________________________________________________________________________________ ✍ Define the marginal propensity to consume (MPC). How is it related to the marginal propensity to save (MPS)? _____________________________________________________________________________________ _____________________________________________________________________________________ ❐ If levels of wealth increase, people are better off, which encourages consumption spending. It is reasonable to expect a positive relationship between wealth and consumption. A prominent example is the positive effect of rising stock market prices on wealth and thus on consumption. ❐ If the average price level increases, the real value of assets will decrease. This decreases the wealth of people and discourages consumption. In this way, the average price level can have a negative impact on consumption. The consumption function The relationship between real consumption and real income, i.e. the consumption function, can be expressed in mathematical terms as: C = a + bY + . . . ...... (2.1) This function can be depicted graphically on the income-expenditure diagram, as in figure 2.7. The consumption line shows, for each level of Y (real income), the corre­spond­ing level of C (real consumption expenditure in the country), e.g. Y0 and C0 in the figure. It depicts the overall behaviour of consumers and largely explains the level of consumption in terms of real income. The positive slope indicates the positive relationship between real consumption and real income: as income Y increases, an increase in consumption C is induced. When income decreases, consumption should decrease. The induced change in consumption expenditure is less than the change in income, therefore 0<b<1. 2.2 The real (or goods) sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 53 53 2019/12/17 09:15 ❐ The slope of the consumption function is directly related to the marginal propensity to consume. (How?) ❐ Graphically, any change in consumption due to a change in Y is indicated by a movement on or along the C line. ❐ A change in one of the other factors that determines consumption implies, graphically, a shift of the C line. If wealth levels increase, for example, the C line is shifted upwards. If taxation is increased, the C line is shifted down. For simplicity, these factors are captured by changes in the intercept a in the consumption equation. Figure 2.7 Keynesian consumption function C C = a + bY C0 a Y Income Y 0 The intercept term, a, thus represents autonomous consumption, i.e. the portion of consumption that is not sensitive to income levels and would occur irrespective of the level of income. It can be interpreted, for instance, as a minimum existence level of consumption. More complex relationships between consumption and income The above consumption function is known as the ‘Keynesian consumption function’, as John Maynard Keynes was one of the first major economists to define the relationship set out above between income and consumption. After Keynes, a number of economists have suggested more complex relationships between income and consumption. For instance, in his Relative Income Theory, James Duesenberry has argued that consumption is not so much determined by the absolute level of income but also by the income of the individual or households relative to that of friends or neighbours, or relative to higher levels of their own income in an earlier period. The latter implies that households are reluctant to scale down consumption if income decreases after a period with higher levels of consumption. Duesenberry’s Relative Income Theory was an early attempt to refine Keynes’s consumption theory. However, the best-known consumption theories following Keynes are the Permanent Income Hypothesis of Milton Friedman and the Life-cycle Hypothesis of Franco Modigliani. Permanent income: Friedman argues that a household’s consumption depends not so much on the cur­rent income of a household at a cer­tain time but rather on the level of income that this household expects to earn normally. ❐ What a household considers as normal depends on what it expects to earn in future. This level of normal income is called its ‘per­manent income’ and is distin­guished from unexpected, ‘tran­sitory income’ – usually measured as the difference between its ac­tual and permanent income. ❐ When actual income decreases to below its normal or permanent level, households will borrow or use savings to sustain consump­tion levels. When actual income increases above the normal or permanent level, households will rather save than consume more. This implies an element of stabil­ity in consumption patterns, since the consumption expenditure of households will not react much to temporary or transitory increases or decreases in income. 54 Chapter 2: The basic model I: consumers, producers and government How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 54 2019/12/17 09:15 Consumption smoothing and life-cycle income The Keynesian consumption function is altered to become: Y (1 + r) Ct = 1 (Yt + ∑t + i t + i i + At ) N T where Ct is current consumption (in period t), Yt is current wage income (in period t), Yt + i is expected future income in period t + i, r is the discount rate used to arrive at the present value Yt + i of the future income, ∑ , At is the present value of wealth (e.g. bonds, shares or property), (1 + r) i N is the amount of years that the individual expects to work and T is the amount of years that the individual expects to live. ❐ Essentially this equation states that individuals sum all their current and expected future income, add their existing wealth, and then divide it over the amount of years that they expect to live, so as to establish what amount they can consume per period. ❐ From this equation it can be seen that a R1 change in Yt will cause consumption to only Y change by the rand amount __ Tt ❐ If consumption in a particular period does not match income, individuals can borrow money at the prevailing interest rate. This introduces a role for the interest rate into the consumption function. In addition, a higher interest rate will decrease the value of wealth (i.e. bond and share prices, even house prices), which in turn will cause a decrease in consumption. Life-cycle income: According to this theory, households and individuals plan their expenditure given an expected pattern of income over their entire life­time. Young people, who have rela­tively low earnings, will borrow to support higher levels of consumption – in expectation of higher earnings later in their careers, when the debt can be repaid. This later period in their ca­reers, with its higher earnings, is also used to save for old age, when income is likely to fall below consumption. This also means that con­sumption does not only depend on in­come but also on assets (wealth). All this means that consumption is likely to be relatively stable over the life cycle, and will in any case vary less than in­come – a phenomenon called con­sumption smoothing. Therefore, this argument implies an element of stability in this component of expenditure. The permanent income and life-cycle hypotheses both require an al­teration of the Keynesian consumption function. They imply that consumption becomes a function of income over a longer time horizon. More specifically, a house­hold’s consumption depends not so much on current income but on the expected future income stream of the household, plus its wealth. Thus con­sumption will be averaged, or smoothed, across periods and will be less volatile than income when income varies across periods. ❐ Note that consumption in these al­ ternative theories does not include durable consump­tion. The latter is considered as investment from which households derive a benefit (called an im­puted income). The total amount spent on buying a car or a washing machine, for example, is not included in the consumption of the period in which it was purchased. Rather, the benefit (consumption) is spread over the life span of the asset. (This means that the annual depre­ciation of the asset must be counted as part of consumption.) 2.2 The real (or goods) sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 55 55 2019/12/17 09:15 The distribution of income: It is likely that poor, middle-income and rich households have different marginal pro­pensities to consume. Poor house­holds usually have a higher MPC – they have little choice but to consume most of their income. A redistribution of income from highincome to low-income households can, therefore, cause an increase in total consumption. Poor households are also often con­strained in their ability to borrow. Thus, poor households might not be able to smooth their consumption over time and they are, therefore, much more ex­posed to the effects of income fluctua­tions. These alternative theories are important if one wants to understand empirical patterns in income and consumption in depth. For understanding most macro­economic chain reactions, they are of lesser importance, though, and it is suf­ficient to work with the simple Keynesian consumption function most of the time (although there are a couple of notable exceptions). 2.2.2 Real investment (capital formation) Real investment I is the purchase of production or capital goods, for example factories or machinery – real assets on which a return is expected from the sales of production. (Expenditure on imported capital goods, e.g. machinery, is included in total investment.) ❐ Typically, real investment is a very unstable element in the economy. It is one of the main sources of instability in a market economy. ❐ In the national accounts, investment is called ‘capital formation’. These two terms are synonymous and are used interchangeably in this book. ❐ Study the behaviour of investment (business capital formation) in figure 2.6 to get a feel for its relative size and its movement over time and over the business cycle. ✍ What is the difference between financial investment and real investment? Financial investment is the purchase of financial assets, whereas real investment (capital formation) is the purchase of real assets. The term ‘capital formation’ clearly indicates this. Financial investment, however, is a form of saving. What is the role of the interest rate in the case of financial investment, e.g. in deciding to invest in a savings account or certificate, or another financial asset? ___________________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________________ Is a purchase of shares real investment (capital formation) or financial investment? Does it depend on whether the shares are in a new project or existing shares? Are share issues usually for specific investment projects or for a general addition to operational capital? Does an investor usually know this? Does it matter? ___________________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________________ 56 Chapter 2: The basic model I: consumers, producers and government How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 56 2019/12/17 09:15 More specifically, what is of concern here is fixed investment: gross fixed capital formation comprises the following components: residential buildings, non-residential buildings, construction, transport equipment, machinery and other equipment. The other (non-fixed) part of gross investment is change in inventories (or inventory investment). This is merely a change in the unplanned and unsold inventory of produced goods due to an imbalance between total production and total expenditure. It is not investment in the true sense of the word. The value of change in inventories can also be negative, i.e. when stocks are depleted in times when production is lower than sales. Both these categories of real investment can also be divided according to the type of institution involved – investment by private business enterprises IP, by public corporations IPC and by general government IG. Net capital formation differs from gross capital formation due to ‘consumption of fixed capital’, which, in an accounting sense, can be understood as ‘allowance for depreciation’. Consumption of fixed capital is supposed to measure that part of gross investment funds that is used for the replacement of, for example, machinery. Net capital formation indicates the net addition to the total capital stock. In practice, it is not actual replacement that is measured, but an estimate of the wear and tear or depreciation of assets over their normal life span. The question is which types of investment to include. In macroeconomic reasoning, one is usually concerned with explaining the investment activities of private business enterprises. This is because general government investment IG, which is done by government departments, is driven and explained by a very different set of factors, mostly social and political. However, the behaviour of government business enterprises or ‘public corporations’ is not that dissimilar from that of private firms in so far as they have to avoid losses and must be active in capital markets. Also, investment by public corporations IPC is not included in the concept of total government expenditure G, which we will encounter in section 2.2.5, and thus not in the national budget either (the topic of chapter 10). To ensure alignment with the latter, we will include investment by public corporations in our definition of aggregate investment as comprising private and public business fixed investment: I = IP + IPC DATA TIP (Of course, some investment, e.g. in houses – i.e. residential investment – is done by households. However, residential investment is relatively stable. In any case, it is not seen as a driving force in economic growth or the business cycle in the way business investment is. Hence the focus here is on understanding and explaining (private and public) business fixed investment (capital formation). In the national accounts and in published investment figures in for example the Quarterly Bulletin of the Reserve Bank, gross capital formation comprises investment by all three groups: private firms IP, public corporations IPC and government IG. One must therefore be very careful when using investment figures for macroeconomic analysis: one must select the non-government components of gross investment (capital formation). 2.2 The real (or goods) sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 57 57 2019/12/17 09:15 ✍ Approximately what percentage of gross domestic expenditure (GDE) does business investment constitute in South Africa? ______________________________________________________________________________________ Which factors determine business real investment? The decisions of private and public business enterprises to invest largely depend on, and are strongly influenced by, the following factors and variables: Investment = f (real interest rates; expectations; business confidence; regulations, etc.) Real investment and the real interest rate have an inverse or Sensitivity vs. elasticity negative relationship: an increase This book refers to parameters in equations such in the real interest rate is likely as b and h as indicators of sensitivity. As slope to discourage capital formation, parameters, they denote the absolute change in one while a decreased real interest variable due to an absolute change in the other, such ∆x rate is likely to stimulate capital as ∆y formation. This is so because the Some macroeconomics textbooks incorrectly call real interest rate is the opportuthese parameters elasticities. An elasticity measures nity cost of capital formation. the percentage change in one variable due to a ❐ The meaning of the term the %∆x percentage change in the other: %∆y real interest rate was noted One would only be able to call these parameters in the introduction, and is elasticities if, instead of the actual values of explained in detail in the box say, consumption and income, one uses natural on the following page. Basically logarithms of both the left- and right-hand variables. it is the after-inflation rate of interest. It is very important to distinguish it from the nominal interest rate. Real investment behaviour is sensitive to the real interest rate. What is the meaning of the last statement? The real interest rate represents the return that one could have earned by buying and holding bonds, and which one now forfeits by investing in a real asset. Therefore it amounts to a cost item. Given expected rates of return on planned investment projects, an increase in the interest rate (opportunity cost) will make some projects, that were projected to be marginally profitable before, unviable propositions. As a consequence, some projects will not be undertaken, i.e. real investment is likely to decline. ❐ Note that it is not the real interest rate as such that is of importance, but the comparison of the real interest rate with the expected real rate of return on the planned investment project. More formally, we can represent a very simple relationship between business investment I and the real interest rate r as follows: I = Ia hr …… (2.2) In this equation Ia is autonomous investment, i.e. the level that investment will be if the interest rate is 0%. It can be understood to capture all the other elements listed in the general formulation of the investment relationship above. 58 Chapter 2: The basic model I: consumers, producers and government How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 58 2019/12/17 09:15 Nominal and real interest rates – making sense in an inflationary context Everyday experience in an inflationary environment can lead to confusion with measurements. This is particularly true of interest rates. If there is inflation a distinction should be made between nominal and real interest rates. ❐ Nominal interest rates are the rates usually mentioned when the bank charges a customer, say, the ‘prime rate’, or ‘prime-plus-one’, or when the Reserve Bank announces a change in the repo rate. ❐ Real interest rates are the effective interest rates after the eroding effect of inflation has been removed. A lender lending, for example, R1 000 to a borrower for a year would want a large enough amount of money back after that year, first to provide a real return on the loan, and second to compensate for the reduced buying power of every rand due to inflation. The real interest rate does the former. The nominal rate is higher because it must also include compensation for inflation. What then is the relationship between the nominal interest rate, the real interest rate and inflation, and how does one calculate the real rate? There is a simple formula for this: 1 + i = (1 + r)(1 + π) where i is the nominal interest rate, r is the real interest rate and π is the inflation rate. The nominal rate thus comprises the following elements: i = r + π + rπ Since the last term of this equation, rπ, usually is negligibly small, one can approximate the nominal interest rate as: Numerical examples Suppose the real rate is 4% and inflation is 10%. Then the nominal interest rate is: Correct formula: i = 0.04 0.1 (0.04)(0.1) = 0.144 (or 14.4%) Approximate formula: i≈r+π i ≈ 0.04 0.1 = 0.14 (or 14%) The approximate formula for the real interest rate is: r≈i–π while the precise formula is: r = _____ 11 ++ πi – 1 The approximation can only be used when inflation and the real interest rate are fairly low. The minus in the equation indicates that the relationship between I and r is inverse, i.e. when the real interest rate increases, investment will decrease. The parameter h indicates the sensitivity of investment to changes in the real interest rate r. A larger h indicates that in­vestment is relatively more sensitive to a change in the real interest rate. Graphically, the investment–interest-rate relationship can be depicted as in figure 2.8. Note that, uncommonly, the dependent variable I is on the horizontal axis, and the independent variable r on the vertical axis. Thus the intercept term of the investment function is on the horizontal axis. The inverse economic relationship between real invest­ment I and the real interest rate r is reflected graphically in a negative slope. Changes in the interest rate will influence and determine the level of in­vestment. Graphically, this amounts to a movement along the investment curve or function. 2.2 The real (or goods) sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 59 59 2019/12/17 09:15 ✍ This negative relationship is true whether one borrows funds for capital formation or whether one uses one’s own funds. Why? ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ Is there a positive or a negative relationship between financial investment and interest rates? Why? ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ ❐ The intercept will change – and the line will shift right or left – if one of the factors contained in Ia (e.g. business confidence) changes. Note that business investment (capital formation) in South Africa often does not react strongly to changes in real interest rates. Figure 2.8 The investment function Factors such as tax incentives and depreciation allowances, or decentrali­sation incentives, are r often more important, if not decisive, in the determination of in­vestment in South Africa. r0 ❐ Graphically, changes in these factors will shift the invest­ment curve, since they will be reflected in a change in Ia. (Why?) r In addition, the degree of business confidence in the long-term prospects of the economy is of critical importance, since investment is a long-term decision and commitment. This is of particular relevance in the post-1994 period, when the expectations of both domestic and foreign investors regarding the future of the South African economy – and the economic policies of the government – have been and are likely to continue being more decisive than interest rates in determining investment patterns. ❐ Changes in confidence and expectations will shift the curve in the diagram. ❐ The potent influence of expectations and psychological factors is one reason why investment can fluctuate wildly at times. ❐ A factor that often influences expectations is the exchange rate. (How? Why?) In the income–expenditure diagram (the 45° diagram, which does not have the interest rate on one of its axes), investment is depicted as a horizontal line at the level of investment determined in the diagram (see figure 2.9). In 60 1 l0 l1 la l Figure 2.9 Investment in the 45° diagram l 45° Line I1 l0 Income Y Chapter 2: The basic model I: consumers, producers and government How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 60 2019/12/17 09:15 this way we are provided with a channel for interest rates to influence total expenditure in the 45° diagram. Any change in the level of real investment, due to either an interest rate change or some other relevant factor, implies a parallel shift of the I line in the 45° diagram. 2.2.3 Macroeconomic equilibrium: the basic idea The basic concept of equilibrium between total expenditure and total production, and the corresponding graphical analysis of equilibrium in the 45° diagram, was explained above. If one assumes, for a moment, that consumption and investment are the only kinds of expenditure in the economy, together they constitute total expenditure. Graphically, the C line and the I line can be added vertically to form the total expenditure line. Together with the 45° line, the equilibrium level of real income Y is determined. Investment as such is graphically depicted in the second diagram we encountered. The two diagrams can be placed alongside each other as in figure 2.10: Figure 2.10 Basic macroeconomic equilibrium r E r0 C + I0 C l0 l0 Investment l l Y0 lncome Y At the equilibrium Total expenditure = Total production or, for this simple case with only consumption and investment expenditure, C + I = Total production Since production must be identical to income – all revenue from production sold must flow to some production factor in the form of income – one can also describe the equilibrium as the point where: C+I = Y Inserting the illustrative equations used above, this statement can be refined to: ...... (2.3) Y = a + bY + Ia – hr This statement describes the equilibrium for this simple, illustrative case. (See section 2.2.6 for the general case.) ❐ But it is more than that. It is an equilibrium condition – it constitutes the requirement or prerequisite for equilibrium in the real sector. 2.2 The real (or goods) sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 61 61 2019/12/17 09:15 2.2.4 Changes in the equilibrium: multipliers The basic tools to analyse changes in the economy are available to us now. Although the model still is very simple, one can already construct much more comprehensive macroeconomic chain reactions. For example: Suppose real interest rates fall. (The next chapter will explain why that can happen.) This decreases the opportunity cost of investment. More planned investment projects become potentially profitable and viable. Therefore, investment is encouraged. If investment does increase, total expenditure and sales increase. This will cause a decline in inventories, which is a sign and an incentive for producers to decide to increase production. When (and if) they do increase production to match the higher level of expenditure, GDP and real income will increase. The economy experiences an upswing. In brief: r ⇒ I ⇒ total expenditure ⇒ production ⇒ Y Having gone through the logic of the economic chain reaction, one can now use the diagram to test whether the above reasoning was correct. One does that by indicating the chain of events on the two diagrams as in figure 2.11: Figure 2.11 Changes in the macroeconomic equilibrium r E r0 C + I1 r1 C + I0 l1 l1 l0 l0 l1 Investment l l0 Y0 Y1 lncome Y Was the chain of reasoning above correct or incorrect? ! 62 It is critically important not to go about these chain reactions or sequences of events in a mechanical fashion. The various parts and actors in the economy do not fit together like gears in a machine. People make choices and decisions – wise or unwise, responsible or irresponsible. Each transition between steps is uncertain and subject to delays. An expected change will not necessarily occur, or will not occur immediately or when expected. One reaction may be weak, another strong. At most one should speak of incentives, encouragements or discouragements. It is best to think of each reaction being likely (at most). (Perhaps one should indicate this by placing a small question mark above each horizontal arrow in the chain reactions.) Chapter 2: The basic model I: consumers, producers and government How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 62 2019/12/17 09:15 ✍ ✍ Repeat the example above for an increase in interest rates. Also show this in a diagram. If someone were to state that a reduction in interest rates will stimulate the economy and that this therefore amounts to good news, (a) would you agree with that persons, and (b) would you know exactly why he or she is right or wrong? Are lower interest rates beneficial for all people in the economy? Why or why not? ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ (Some more considerations are encountered in chapter 3.) The expenditure multiplier The core of the idea of the multiplier is that any change in real expenditure ∆Exp – i.e. any injection of expenditure into, or withdrawal of expenditure from, the circular flow – will eventually lead to a change in equilibrium real income ∆Y significantly larger than the original injection (or withdrawal). The size of the multiplier K is the ratio between the eventual, cumulative change in Y (i.e. ∆Y) and the original change in expenditure that caused it, i.e. ∆Y ∆Exp KE = _____ It can be seen on the 45° diagram in figure 2.12. The value of the multiplier shows the extent to which an expenditure injection (or withdrawal) is amplified or multiplied. The multiplier effect can be explained by refer­ ence to the existence of a multiplier process. The crux of the multiplier process is that a number of rounds of respending follow an initial injection of expenditure. Each amount that is spent is received by somebody else, and becomes that person’s income. Of this, a certain percentage will be respent (depending on the marginal propensity to consume). This yet again becomes another person’s income, who spends part of it, and so forth – until the process peters out. The cumulative Figure 2.12 The multiplier effect E Aggregate expenditure E Y lncome Y 2.2 The real (or goods) sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 63 63 2019/12/17 09:15 change in income, i.e. the sum of each of these individual increases in income – will therefore be much higher than the initial increase (injection) of expenditure and income. That is, the initial injection is multiplied or amplified. How large this cumulative sum of all the respending is will depend on the portion of spending that is returned to the circular flow in each round, i.e. the percentage respent – or, the percentage that does not leak from the income–expenditure stream. The larger the leakage from the domestic expenditure flow in each round – e.g. in the form of savings, taxation, or spending on imports – the smaller will be the cumulative total, and therefore the smaller will be the value of the multiplier. In this way, one can see that the value of the expenditure multiplier will be inversely related to the percentage leakage in each round. It can be mathematically shown that 1 marginal KE = __________________ leakage rate Thus the value of the multiplier depends on factors such as the marginal propensity to save (MPS), the marginal propensity to import and the marginal income tax rate – all related to forms of leakages from the expenditure–income flow. We can illustrate this in our simple model with only consumption and investment. A multiplier can be derived from the equilibrium condition stated above: Y = C+I After substitution of the consumption and investment functions, it becomes: Y = a + bY + Ia – hr ( 1 ) 1 – b (a + Ia – hr) = ____ ...... (2.4) 1 where 1 – b is the multiplier KE and (1 – b) is the marginal leakage rate given for the above equations of C and I. This formula for KE is not generally correct. It recognises only one form of leakage: (1 – b) is the marginal propensity to save or MPS. It is especially wrong for an open economy with a significant degree of imports and with taxes. ❐ Remember that at this stage our model is still a simplified one that excludes government and the foreign sector. These restrictions will be relaxed later. ❐ Calculations of the value of the multiplier with this formula produce unrealistically large values. Nevertheless, the formula in terms of the marginal leakage rate can be applied generally, if one incorporates such leakage rates as the marginal propensity to save, the marginal propensity to import, and the marginal income tax rate. The exact mathematical formula for KE will in each case depend on exactly how each function in the macroeconomic model is formulated mathematically (see maths box in section 2.2.6). ❐ Find out for yourself why the value of the multiplier depends on the size of MPC by investigating how the multiplier process and the value of KE change if MPC increases or decreases. Also experiment with some of the other leakages. ❐ In practice, the value of the multiplier is between 1 and 2. The multiplier effect is valid for any injection (or withdrawal) of expenditure, i.e. any vertical shift in the total expenditure line due to changes in government spending, taxation, exports and so forth. 64 Chapter 2: The basic model I: consumers, producers and government How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 64 2019/12/17 09:15 2.2.5 Real government expenditure and taxation Government expenditure concerns the purchase of goods and services by the general government. This may vary from pencils to roads to policing services to army tanks. A large portion of real government spending goes towards the payment of wages and salaries of public servants. DATA TIP While the terms ‘government’ and ‘the state’ are used indiscriminately in everyday speech, here one should be more specific. General government comprises the central government, provincial governments, as well as local governments (municipalities). It does not include public corporations. Warning: Where data and measurement are concerned, the government sector is one of the most complex (and confusing) areas of economics. Published data, even in tables in the same publication, are often difficult to reconcile or they may even be contradictory. This is due to reasons such as the following: ❐ Different definitions of ‘government’ or ‘public sector’ and the inclusion or exclusion of different public institutions (universities, public corporations, etc.); ❐ Different data systems, e.g. the System of National Accounts (SNA) as against the Government Finance Statistics (GFS), each with its own interpretations, objectives, bases, rules and conventions; ❐ Different institutions that process data for different purposes, e.g. the Reserve Bank as opposed to the National Treasury, which publishes its own budget figures in a particular way. For macroeconomic analysis, national accounts measures are best. You should, however, always be very careful. (Even in the public debate, government data and concepts are often used incorrectly.) ❐ Whenever you want to analyse the budget in some detail, national accounts data are not suitable. See the analysis that is supplied annually in the Budget Review, published by the National Treasury. ❐ Always be very careful to ascertain where you work with nominal data or real data. See chapter 10, section 10.1 and addendum 10.1. See also Mohr (2019) Economic Indicators, Van Schaik, chapter 10. We define total government expenditure G as the sum of general government consumption expenditure and general government investment. ❐ Note that many textbooks define G as government consumption expenditure only. One reason for this is that it corresponds to the practice in the national accounts, the main source of macroeconomic data, as well as in the national accounting identities (see chapter 5). ❐ For the sake of consistency throughout this book, we will indicate government consumption expenditure with the symbol GC. The graph in figure 2.13 shows the two main components of total government expenditure, i.e. government consumption expenditure GC as well as investment (capital formation) by general government IG in South Africa since 1960. 2.2 The real (or goods) sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 65 65 2019/12/17 09:15 G and government investment DATA TIP In national accounts data only consumption expenditure by the general government is indicated separately. Government investment is included in the gross capital formation (investment) figure. ❐ Capital formation tables show a breakdown of investment between general government, government enterprises and public corporations. Total government expenditure G must thus be calculated as the sum of general government consumption expenditure and fixed capital formation by general government. See chapter 10, section 10.5.1 and addendum 10.1. Also see Mohr (2019) Economic Indicators. ✍ What percentage, approximately, of gross domestic expenditure (GDE) does total government expenditure constitute? ______________________________________________________________________________________ What percentage, approximately, of gross domestic expenditure (GDE) does general government consumption expenditure constitute? ______________________________________________________________________________________ What portion, approximately, of that is spent on wages and salaries? ______________________________________________________________________________________ Figure 2.13 Components of government expenditure as % of GDP 30 25 Total government expenditure Percentage 20 Government consumption 15 10 5 Government capital formation 2018 2016 2014 2012 2010 2008 2006 2004 2002 2000 1998 1996 1994 1992 1990 1988 1986 1984 1982 1980 1978 1976 1974 1972 1970 1968 1966 1964 1962 1960 0 Source: South African Reserve Bank (www.resbank.co.za). Note the peak in government consumption expenditure in the late 1980s and early 1990s, as well as the decline under the new policy regime after 1994. For government capital formation, the noticeable thing is the significant decline since the mid 1970s – a decline that has not been reversed, despite a small and transient uptick in 2006–08. 66 Chapter 2: The basic model I: consumers, producers and government How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 66 2019/12/17 09:15 In macroeconomic reasoning we often ignore most of the institutional and definition problems and broadly treat the general government in terms of total government expenditure G and total taxation T. While this does not correspond one hundred percent with budget figures and practices, for the purpose of macroeconomic analysis it is close enough. Government expenditure and taxation are the main elements of so-called fiscal policy. Government borrowing to finance budget deficits is a third important element of fiscal policy (see chapter 10 for a detailed discussion of fiscal policy). These are primarily the administrative responsibility of the National Treasury, i.e. the government department that handles the ‘purse’ of central government. However, in the final instance, it is the decisions of the national government, more specifically the national Cabinet, that determine fiscal policy and the national budget. In macroeconomic reasoning, one usually regards government expenditure and taxation decisions as exogenous or autonomous, i.e. as political decisions under full control of the government. These decisions are taken ‘outside’ the economy (therefore exogenous). Real government expenditure G is a direct component of total real expenditure and influences it directly and fully. ❐ In the 45° diagram, as shown in figure 2.14, G (just like I) is shown as a horizontal line, at the level of real government expenditure. It is then simply added, vertically, to the C and I lines to get the total expenditure line. ❐ Also note that, whereas the equilibrium condition is Y = C + I in the absence of government, with government it becomes Y = C + I + G. Figure 2.14 Macroeconomic equilibrium with government expenditure r E r0 C + I0 + G0 C + I0 C G0 G0 l0 l0 l0 Investment l Y0 lncome Y Any increase in G has the same direct impact as any other direct increase in expenditure. Graphically the expenditure line is shifted upwards by the exact amount of such an increase. ❐ The expenditure multiplier KE also applies to changes in G: the eventual change in Y exceeds the initial change in G by a factor equal to the multiplier. 2.2 The real (or goods) sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 67 67 2019/12/17 09:15 Taxation has an indirect effect on equilibrium income, i.e. via its impact on disposable income and, in that way, on consumption. The consumption function must be adapted to show the introduction of tax: C = a + b(1 t)Y ...... (2.5) where t is the tax rate on income. Thus (1 – t)Y is after-tax or disposable income. Note that we simplify by assuming that all individuals pay the same tax rate, which is usually not the case. We also ignore other types of taxes. Although this simplification can be relaxed (e.g. to consider also a progressive tax rate system where individuals with higher income pay a higher average tax rate), we maintain it to demonstrate the underlying impact of an income tax on consumption. ❐ Graphically, the consumption function is shifted up or down as a result of tax changes. ❐ Since there is now an additional leakage from the expenditure due to the payment of tax, the expenditure multiplier will differ from the no-tax case. Whereas the expenditure 1 multiplier was equal to 1 – b , with tax (and government expenditure G) we now have: Y = C+I+G which becomes: Y = a + b(1 – t)Y + Ia – hr + G ( 1 ) (a + Ia – hr + G). = 1 – b(1 – t) ...... (2.6) The marginal leakage rate is larger when there is an income tax in the model. Thus the expenditure multiplier is smaller. ❐ If the tax rate t is higher, (1 – t) will be smaller; this increases the denominator of the multiplier, and decreases the value of the multiplier. (Can you see that? The larger is t, 1 the smaller is b(1 – t), the larger is 1 – b(1 – t), and thus the smaller is 1 – b(1 – t) , which is the expenditure multiplier.) The tax multiplier Since a tax increase is partly financed by the individual or households who consume less and save less – the impact of the higher tax falls only partly on consumption – consumption will decrease by less (and the C line will shift by less) than any increase in total taxation. However, that (reduced) decrease in expenditure will experience the normal multiplier process. ❐ Therefore, the tax multiplier KT is smaller than the expenditure multiplier by a factor equal to the marginal propensity to consume MPC: KT = MPC × KE ❐ This means that a Rl million increase in government expenditure, for example, will not have the same impact on equilibrium income Y as a Rl million reduction in total taxation. The former has a larger impact. ❐ A balanced increase in the budget – equal increases in government expenditure and taxation – will therefore have a positive net impact on Y. (This is the ‘balanced budget multiplier’ result. See whether you can establish this by considering an increase in G of R1 000 that is financed by an increase in T of R1 000.) 68 Chapter 2: The basic model I: consumers, producers and government How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 68 2019/12/17 09:15 ✍ Tax reduction ⇒ _______________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ Graphically: Does your economic reasoning tally with your graphical results? How would the graphical analysis change if the tax reduction was specified as a cut in the average tax rate? (See remark 4 below.) ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ Remarks 1. An increase in G and a reduction in T are both examples of expansionary fiscal policy (and vice versa for restrictive policy). 2. In any discussion of the consequences of a change in government expenditure G, one should analytically handle them in isolation, i.e. one should not automatically assume that taxation T will be increased to finance the higher level of spending. Likewise, a tax change should not be taken automatically to imply a corresponding change in expenditure. If G and T both do happen to change, analyse first the one and then the other to finally derive the net impact. 3. In practice, a large portion of taxation is in the form of income taxation. This implies that the tax revenue of government is a function of total income: if income Y increases during an upswing, income tax revenue of the Treasury will also increase, even in the absence of an increase in the tax rate. 4. The graphical analysis of a change in taxation is complicated by the difference between types of taxation. Only for a very simple kind of tax (a ‘lump sum’ tax where everybody pays the same amount of tax irrespective of income levels) will a tax change be depicted, in the 45° diagram, as a parallel shift of the consumption line. In real life, the most important type of tax is income tax, where the total amount of tax paid varies with the level of income. If it is a proportional tax (the example we use here for simplicity), the percentage of tax deducted from income remains constant, e.g. 25% means T = 0.25Y. Thus, the average tax rate remains unchanged 2.2 The real (or goods) sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 69 69 2019/12/17 09:15 as income increases. If it is a Automatic stabilisers progressive tax, the percent­ age of tax deducted increases Since income tax payments increase when the as income increases; the economy is in an upswing phase, total taxation T average tax rate will increase increases in the process. This has a constraining effect on total expenditure, which will hold back as income increases. In both the upswing. This effect automatically tempers the cases the total amount of upswing. Similarly, in a downswing phase, income tax T paid will be more at tax payments will automatically decrease, which higher levels of GDP than stimulates expenditure and restrains the severity of at lower levels of GDP. In the downswing. In this way, income tax serves as an both cases, a decrease in ‘automatic stabiliser’ of the business cycle. the average income tax ❐ This also implies that income tax is yet another rate does not produce a factor that effectively decreases the value of the parallel upward shift in the expenditure multiplier. consumption function, but rather rotates the C line up­ wards (anticlockwise) from its intercept with the vertical axis: the slope of the C line increases, without any change in the intercept. Doing the same activity as on the previous page for the case of a reduction in income tax will thus have a different graphic result from the simple tax reduction case. (In the latter case, there would be a parallel upward shift of the C line.) Note, however, that the resultant change in equilibrium income Y will be in the same direction for both cases. 2.2.6 Real exports and imports (introductory) The South African economy is ‘open’: a large part of total production is exported, and a large part of total expenditure is spent on the purchase of imported items. Therefore international trade affects the pattern of expenditure and production decisively. It is therefore essential to understand fully the macroeconomic effect of foreign trade transactions. ✍ How ‘open’ is the South African economy? What percentage of South African GDP is exported annually? _____________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________ What percentage of South Africa’s gross domestic expenditure (GDE) is spent on imported items, i.e. effectively ends up in the pockets of foreign producers? ______________________________________________________________________________ The graph in figure 2.15 shows South African imports and exports in real terms since 1985 (at constant 2010 prices). Real exports and imports are elements of ‘expenditure on gross domestic product’. The gap between the two shows net exports, which is an indication of, but not equal to, the state (deficit or surplus) of the current account of the balance of payments (see chapter 4). A close correlation between import fluctuations and GDP fluctuations can be observed, e.g. during the long upswing since 2000. Also note the significant increase in both exports and imports, in real terms, since the early 1990s, indicating a significant increase in external trade. 70 Chapter 2: The basic model I: consumers, producers and government How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 70 2019/12/17 09:15 Figure 2.15 Exports and imports (in real terms – 2010 prices) 1 200 1 000 800 Real imports of goods and services R billion 600 Real exports of goods and services 400 200 Real exports minus real imports 0 2018/01 2016/03 2015/01 2013/03 2012/01 2010/03 2009/01 2007/03 2006/01 2004/03 2003/01 2001/03 2000/01 1998/03 1997/01 1995/03 1994/01 1992/03 1991/01 1989/03 1988/01 1986/03 1985/01 –200 Source: South African Reserve Bank (www.resbank.co.za). Chapter 4 discusses these issues in detail. Here it suffices merely to add net exports (X – M) as a component of total expenditure. To arrive at the total demand that South African producers experience, one must: ❐ add spending in foreign countries on South African goods to domestic expenditure, and ❐ deduct local spending on imported goods, since this spending merely flows to producers in other countries. Gross domestic expenditure is the sum of consumption, business investment and government expenditure, i.e. GDE = C + I + G However, this is not equivalent to the total spending that is effectively felt by domestic producers. The latter magnitude – the total demand for domestic production – is indicated by the term expenditure on gross domestic product = C + I + G + (X – M). ❐ In published expenditure data, one also finds a ‘residual’ term. This is an unexplained error term that is necessary to balance the different totals. Therefore: Total expenditure E = C + I + G + (X M) 2.2 The real (or goods) sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 71 71 2019/12/17 09:15 For this, the complete open economy case, macroeconomic equilibrium will be at that level of real income Y where Total expenditure Total production or C I G (X M) Total production Since production is identical to income, one can equivalently write the equilibrium condition as: C I G + (X M) Y ...... (2.7) Graphically, one merely adds net exports to the total expenditure line. Any increase in net exports is treated like any other expenditure injection (and is subject to the same multiplier process): (X M) ⇒ Total expenditure ⇒ induces production ⇒ GDP ⇒ Y π The expenditure multiplier with exports and imports While exports and imports are considered in detail only in chapter 4, it is useful to show now how equation 2.6 can be expanded to include exports and imports. This then gives the complete real sector expenditure multiplier. If X is taken as exogenous, and the import function as M = ma + mY where m is the marginal propensity to import (see chapter 4, section 4.2.1), then Y = C + I + G + (X – M) …… (2.7) becomes equation (2.8): Y = a b(1 – t) Y + Ia – hr + G + X – ma – mY ( 1 ) 1 – b(1 – t) (a + Ia – hr + G + X – ma ) = +m ...... (2.8) The import propensity thus adds a marginal leakage rate, which decreases the size of KE. ✍ Complete the following diagram to depict the sequence above: E lncome Y 72 Chapter 2: The basic model I: consumers, producers and government How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 72 2019/12/17 09:15 If one considers the two graphs derived in this chapter, it appears that there is still one unexplained variable, i.e. the real interest rate (r). What determines the level of real interest rates? The explanation of interest rate changes can be found in the operation of the so-called money and capital markets – or the monetary sector of the economy. This is the subject of the next chapter. The monetary sector is not a separate part of the economy at all. However, for purposes of analysis, it is useful to distinguish (but not separate) this component or subsector of the economy from the real sector. A more complete circular flow In section 2.1 the income–expenditure circular flow was developed as an intuitive way to grasp the basic Keynesian reasoning. The concept of chain reasoning was developed from this basic idea. At this stage, a more complete depiction of a circular flow can serve to summarise the main components encountered so far: Exports Imports EXPENDITURE Consumption + +G ) I + C X–M ( Investment Government expenditure Saving FIRMS (Producers) Disposable income HOUSEHOLDS (Consumers) Corporate taxes GOVERNMENT Personal income tax REAL INCOME This is an enhanced version of the simple circular flow of figure 2.3. Given the basic counter-clockwise flow of expenditure and income between households and firms, it highlights the different components of expenditure (consumption, investment, government expenditure and net exports). Government has been added as a major actor. Various leakages such as saving, import spending and taxes are shown, as are injections such as investment, export earnings and government expenditure. An increase or decrease in any of these will either diminish or boost the stream of aggregate expenditure. The resultant impact on the flow of real income to households can then be deduced quite readily. 2.2 The real (or goods) sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 73 73 2019/12/17 09:15 In the following chapters we will progressively fill in the blank spaces in this circular flow, depicting additional elements of a modern, open economy. At the same time, the circular flow diagram will serve to remind you of exactly where the topics in a particular chapter fit into the broader economic picture. The circular flow will be completed at the beginning of chapter 6. 2.3 Analytical questions and exercises 1. Suppose autonomous consumption increases. Explain, using the appropriate diagram, what the impact will be on equilibrium income and expenditure. 2. From 2006 to 2008, as part of responses to the international financial crisis, interest rates were increased from 11% to 15%. What will be the expected impact of an increase in interest rates on investment and/or consumption, and finally on income? Explain using the appropriate chain reactions and diagrams. 3. If South Africa develops an increased taste/need for imported products and/or production inputs, will it lead to higher or lower national income? Explain using (a) the relevant formula, and (b) the appropriate diagram. 4. How can the government increase output using: (a) government expenditure, and (b) taxation? Explain, using a relevant diagram. (The budget implications of such steps will be encountered in chapter 12.) 5. Suppose a simple economy with only consumption, investment and government. Further suppose Income (Y) 5 R1000, the marginal propensity to consume (b) 5 0.8, autonomous consumption (a) 5 R100, Investment (I) 5 R80, Government consumption (G) 5 R100 and the tax rate (t) 5 0.1. a. Calculate the size of the expenditure multiplier. b. Calculate the size of the tax multiplier. c. Suppose investment (I) increases by R100, calculate the new income level following the increase in investment. Also use the appropriate diagram to explain the effect of the increase in investment on income. d. Suppose the tax rate on income (t) increases from 0.1 to 0.15, what will be the value of equilibrium income following the increase in the tax rate? Also use the appropriate diagram to explain the effect of the increase in the tax rate on income. 6. It appears that, in the period after 2010, private corporations had large amounts of savings (cash), but were not inclined to use that to invest in new ventures, factories, etc. (compare figure 2.6 and the period from 1999 to 2008). Looking at the determinants of private investment, which factor(s) do you think could explain that behaviour? 7. At President Ramaphosa’s Jobs Summit in August 2018, large private-sector companies announced investment plans amounting to billions of rands. If these plans were to be implemented, what would be the expected impact on the economy? Construct a simple chain reaction and diagram. 8. Nine months after the 2018 Jobs Summit, in the second quarter of 2019, unemployment had risen from 27% to 29%. How does that square with your analysis? Can you explain what happened? 9. Download the Excel file containing Quarterly Labour Force Trends from the latest QLFS page of Statistics SA. Use the data to describe what has happened since 2008 to the number of people who are (a) employed, (b) unemployed according to the official definition of unemployment, and (c) unemployed when including discouraged job-seekers. Is it possible for the number of employed people to increase while the unemployment rate also increases? Explain. (You may want to consult chapter 12, section 12.2.1 in this regard.) 74 Chapter 2: The basic model I: consumers, producers and government How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 74 2019/12/17 09:15 The basic model II: financial institutions, money and interest rates 3 After reading this chapter, you should be able to: ■ explain the everyday, practical operation of financial markets; ■ explain the way interest rates are determined by money supply and demand; ■ explain movements in nominal and real interest rates and compare the different roles of nominal and real interest rates in economic behaviour; ■ compose chain reactions that show how monetary disturbances impact on interest rates and the real economy, and vice versa, and evaluate these with appropriate graphical aids; and ■ assess the role of monetary policy and the Reserve Bank in the determination of real income. (Monetary policy is discussed in detail in chapter 9.) In the discussion of changes and fluctuations in expenditure in the real (or goods) sector of the economy in chapter 2, the real interest rate featured as an important variable. However, the theory and logic in that chapter left the interest rate dangling and its behaviour unexplained. To fill this gap, we turn to an analysis of the monetary sector of the economy: the world of money and interest rates. The monetary sector comprises various financial institutions such as commercial banks, merchant banks and the Reserve Bank (SARB), as well as the financial markets, which is where nominal and real interest rates are determined. Financial institutions and markets are integral parts of the economy. Real activities such as consumption invariably imply financial transactions which involve bank accounts and, often, bank credit to consumers. Commercial credit is essential for business activities. Investment and saving imply flows of funds that are channelled via financial institutions. The same is true for international financial flows deriving from foreign trade or foreign investment. ❐ The monetary sector can be seen to handle the ‘oil’ (money, credit and financial transactions) necessary for the smooth functioning of the ‘wheels’ of real activities (production, employment, consumption, investment, etc.) in the real sector. Its importance largely derives from this facilitating role. Real sector changes have monetary impacts, and monetary disturbances can have real impacts. One must be able to analyse these interactions to understand the short-run and medium-run cyclical behaviour of the economy (as well as the long-term issue of economic growth). This chapter integrates the analysis of the monetary sector – and especially interest rates – into your understanding of the real sector and short-run fluctuations in expenditure. Chapter 3: The basic model II: financial institutions, money and interest rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 75 75 2019/12/17 09:15 The location of this topic in the circular flow diagram (compare p. 73) FINANCIAL INSTITUTIONS Supply of credit Interest rates Savings Monetary policy Demand for credit FIRMS dit cre rcial e m m Co RESERVE BANK Government C ons borrowing um er c (deficit) redi HOUSEHOLDS t GOVERNMENT ✍ How high are interest rates in South Africa currently? Can you indicate the current level of a particular interest rate? ______________________________________________________________________________________ DATA TIP Monetary sector data: which source? The main source of monetary data is the Quarterly Bulletin of the Reserve Bank, which provides an extensive set of banking, financial and monetary data. For macroeconomic analysis, the following tables in the sections ‘Money and banking’ and ‘Capital market’ are most relevant: ❐ ‘Monetary aggregates’: money stock figures. ❐ ‘Money market and related interest rates’: short-term interest rates, such as the BA rate and the prime rate. ❐ ‘Capital market and related interest rates’: long-term interest rates. On the internet, consult the Quarterly Bulletin at: www.resbank.co.za. Also see Mohr (2019) Economic Indicators, chapter 9. 3.1 The monetary sector and interest rates Interest rates are analysed at two levels: first, in terms of the practical, everyday operation of money markets and, second, more formally in terms of the behavioural relationships that lie behind and explain this everyday operation – the supply of money MS and the demand for money MD. In doing this, the distinction between nominal and real interest rates must be kept in mind. (See the box in chapter 2, section 2.2.2 on the calculation of nominal and real interest rates.) ❐ Nominal interest rates are the rates usually mentioned when the bank charges a customer, say, the ‘prime rate’, or the rate earned on a savings account, or when the Reserve Bank announces a change in the repo rate. 76 Chapter 3: The basic model II: financial institutions, money and interest rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 76 2019/12/17 09:15 ❐ Real interest rates are the interest rates earned in effect after the eroding effect of inflation has been removed from the nominal value. An approximate formula for the real interest rate is: r i – π. ❐ So, if the inflation rate is 7%, and the nominal interest rate is 12%, the real interest rate is (approximately) 5%. 3.1.1 The practical determination of nominal interest rates in the money market Although one is used to thinking of nominal interest rates in the context of, for example, savings accounts or, especially, interest rates on loans or on an overdraft, the main interest rates are those determined in the money market. Other interest rates usually depend largely on what happens in the money market. Where are the money and capital markets? The financial market is arbitrarily divided into the money market and the capital market: ❐ The money market handles instruments/assets with a term or ‘maturity’ of up to one year (‘short term’). Associated with these are short-term interest rates. ❐ Transactions in financial instruments with a term of more than one year (‘long term’) occur in the capital market, which is organised in exactly the same fashion as the money markets. In this market one finds long-term interest rates. The money and capital markets do not exist in a physical location or building. They are constituted by a large number of financial institutions, such as commercial and investment banks, pension funds and long-term insurers that are continually in contact with each other via telephone, video and computer links. These institutions have ‘dealer rooms’ where dealers handle large amounts of money, buying and selling in the money market. Buying and selling transactions occur on behalf of clients who either have surplus funds to invest in money and capital market assets (‘instruments’), or who require funds on credit/loan for a certain period. Each transaction establishes a price and a nominal interest rate. These materialise, as you watch, on computer screens, as the transactions occur (followed by electronic book entries). When a lot is happening in the market and many opportunities to make profit from buying and selling present themselves, the adrenalin flows fast, the dealers’ voices are hoarse from shouting, and their eyes red from staring at video and computer screens. (One must remember that, even with very small price or interest differentials, significant profit can be made, given the large amounts that are involved.) Very often dealers do not last long; the stress is too great. On the other hand, dealers experience tremendous excitement, and some almost become addicted to it, like one can become addicted to gambling. ❐ Visit the dealer room of a bank to see for yourself how nominal interest rates materialise on computer screens before your eyes. Money market dealers trade, on behalf of clients, in short-term financial instruments or ‘financial paper’. The purpose of the trade is to connect lenders (financial investors) and borrowers; in other words, the money market channels funds. The financial paper is merely the proof of a claim (like an IOU). Most of these claims exist for a relatively short period, normally three months (90 days) at most. Various kinds of money market paper exist, each with its own nominal interest rate. Each transaction determines a price for the paper at that moment, which implies a certain nominal interest rate for that transaction (and type of paper or asset). 3.1 The monetary sector and interest rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 77 77 2019/12/17 09:15 For the main types of money market paper this occurs as follows: (1) Treasury bills (TBs) Treasury bills are one type of debt instrument issued by the Treasury/government when it borrows from the private sector during the course of the year to finance the budget deficit. This occurs regularly, usually every Friday. A TB is issued as proof of the loan, and it entitles the holder/lender to receive a specified amount (the nominal or face value, e.g. R100 000) typically after 91 or 182 days. (The Treasury has also issued 273-day TBs.) Alternatively, one can say that the lender is a financial investor who buys the TB at a certain price. The interest that the lender/investor receives for the loan to the government (i.e. for the financial investment in TBs) derives from the fact that she pays less than the R100 000 for the TB, e.g. R97 000. This discount depends on the interest that the government is willing to pay, or that it has to pay in order to sell the TBs. ❐ The discount implies that, when the investor claims the full R100 000 after three months, she has earned a certain percentage nominal rate of return or nominal rate of interest – in this case, the ‘91-day TB rate’. For this example, the TB rate would amount to: ( )( ) 3 000 365 97 000 91 × 100 = 12.45%. ❐ Note: The higher the price the lender has to pay, the lower the nominal interest rate, and vice versa. If the price of TB went down to R96 000, the rate of return would be: ( )( ) 4 000 365 96 000 91 × 100 = 16.71%. ❐ Since TBs are issued/sold on tender, the initial or issue rate is also called the ‘tender TB rate’. ❐ Issues of TBs occur in the so-called primary market. What are government bonds (or stock)? Government bonds are similar to treasury bills. Both are debt instruments issued by the National Treasury to finance the budget deficit. However bonds have a longer term (or ‘maturity’) attached to them. Treasury bills typically have terms of 3, 5, 10, 15 or 20 years. Bonds with terms up to 3 years are called ‘short-term’ bonds. (Government stock is a synonym for government bonds.) However, the holder of a bill does not necessarily have to wait the full three months to get the money back. If the money is needed earlier, the bill can be sold to somebody else (in the so-called secondary market). Depending on market conditions at that stage – the supply and demand of TBs – the seller will get a particular price for his TB (still below the face value). ❐ For instance, suppose that after holding a TB for 30 days, a financial investor decides to sell his TB. Note that the buyer, should she decide to hold it till maturity, A free market? will hold it for 61 days. If the seller sells it for R98 200, say, then the Although these transactions occur in the corresponding nominal interest rate money market, where supply and demand are of decisive importance, this trade does not on the TB will be: ( ) 1 800 365 98 200 ) ( 61 × 100 = 10.97%. ❐ Thus, trade and prices in the secondary market determine corresponding nominal TB interest rates. In this way the 78 occur in a completely free market. The Reserve Bank continually monitors the market and steers it in the direction it desires by intervening in the market in various ways (see the discussion of the money supply that follows). Chapter 3: The basic model II: financial institutions, money and interest rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 78 2019/12/17 09:15 TB rate is determined daily, depending on the buying and selling (demand and supply) of TBs. For example, if investors have surplus funds and are eager to invest in TBs, the demand for financial paper is high and the price increases accordingly, leading to a decrease in the nominal interest rate. A shortage of funds in the money market, on the other hand, means a relatively high supply of financial paper by holders who would rather have cash, which is likely to translate into a decrease in price and upward pressure on the nominal interest rate. A similar story can be told for other types of money market paper. (2) Negotiable certificates of deposit (NCDs) Negotiable certificates of deposit arise when short-term financial investments are made at banks. NCDs usually are issued/sold by banks as a way of getting hold of cash when they experience a liquidity/cash shortage. An NCD is the certificate that is issued as proof of (or in exchange for) the investment. This type of instrument is in high demand by investors, and usually carries a relatively high nominal interest rate. An active secondary market in NCDs also exists. As is the case with TBs, the NCD can be sold to a third person (or ‘third party’) if the investor needs his money before the expiry date. The price the investor obtains in this instance will always be lower than the nominal value or redemption value; the difference determines the nominal interest rate.1 (3) Banker’s acceptances (BAs) Banker’s acceptances are surely the most important short-term money market instrument, and the BA rate – mentioned daily in the news – is one of the best indicators of short-term nominal interest rate trends. A BA is a bill of exchange (a credit instrument) that is guaranteed by a bank. It usually comes into existence in the context of production credit, for example when a producer requires credit to buy inputs. Instead of buying on account, she pays the seller with a bill of exchange that is payable, for instance, three months later. To get the In layman’s terms, one can describe a BA seller to accept the bill, the producer asks as a ‘post-dated, bank-guaranteed cash her bank to guarantee the bill (by signing cheque’. While this is not 100% correct on the back, thereby ‘accepting’ it). Such a technically – a BA is an instrument of credit; banker’s acceptance constitutes a claim on a cheque is not – this does give one a rough the bank, entitling the holder to receive a idea. As is the case with a post-dated cheque, certain amount from the bank at a certain the BA gives the holder the right to receive date in the future. The initial recipient of a certain amount in future. As with a cash cheque, it is payable to whoever holds it – in the BA can now sell it in the secondary fact, a BA is transferable and can be sold – market; the price – once again, lower than and it is guaranteed by a bank. the face value – results in a corresponding nominal BA rate. Although these financial instruments come into existence for different reasons and are issued by different institutions, they (and other financial assets, such as government bonds) all share the following characteristics: 1 This is as if my savings book shows a certain amount or balance that can be drawn only at a future date. If I want to sell this savings book to somebody else before that date, he or she will surely only be willing to pay me an amount less than the balance shown. 3.1 The monetary sector and interest rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 79 79 2019/12/17 09:15 ❐ There is an inverse relationship between the price and the nominal interest rate. ❐ The price, and thus the nominal rate of interest, is determined by the buying and selling of the paper, i.e. by the demand for and supply of such instruments. Even if one understands the money market and how nominal interest rates are determined every day, one may still not understand why interest rates change. Why does the demand for financial instruments sometimes increase and sometimes decrease? What determines the supply of instruments in the market? To understand this, we have to look beyond (or behind) the visible trade in financial instruments. ❐ The supply of and demand for financial instruments can be understood in terms of the underlying supply of and demand for cash or money. ❐ Therefore, one must understand the role of money in the economy. 3.1.2 More formally – the supply of and demand for money Briefly, the process that occurs is the following: ❐ If people or institutions hold more money (e.g. cash) than they really want in their portfolio – i.e. there is a surplus of money holdings (which also means the supply of money exceeds the demand for money) – they are likely to buy financial paper (as a short-term financial investment). An increased demand for such paper is likely to cause an increase in the price, and a decrease in the nominal interest rate. ❐ If there is a shortage of money (which also means that the demand for money exceeds the supply) – i.e. people want to improve their cash position – they tend to sell financial paper. The increased supply of paper on the market causes a decrease in price, and the nominal interest rate increases. In other words, nominal interest rates depend on the trade in money market instruments, and this trade is determined by the supply of and the demand for money. If one understands fluctuations in these demand and supply relationships, one will be able to understand nominal (and real) interest rates. ! Money or income? When one speaks of ‘money’ in macroeconomics it is important to distinguish it from the everyday usage of the term. The latter usage – as in ‘Do you have enough money to buy a car?’ – actually concerns income or wealth rather than money. The decision to buy something or not depends on whether you have earned or saved enough income with which to buy it. In macroeconomics, the term ‘money’ very specifically refers to that which is used as a medium of exchange or as a means of payment to facilitate buying and selling transactions. Everyday examples of money are cash (coins and banknotes) and money in a cheque account. In the decision to buy a vehicle, the amount of money in this specific sense plays no decisive role. If, however, you decide that you do have enough income to buy the car, you must decide whether you will use money for the transaction. If you wish to use money, you must convert the income into money form for that purpose. If you do not wish to use money, you may be able to exchange something else of value, e.g. sheep, for the car. It still is a valid transaction. Obviously, most transactions in a modern economy are concluded (and, indeed, expedited immensely) with the aid of money as the medium of exchange or payment. However, that does not invalidate the formal and very important analytical distinction between money and income. 80 Chapter 3: The basic model II: financial institutions, money and interest rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 80 2019/12/17 09:15 The demand for money (MD) The aggregate demand for money in the economy depends mainly on the amount of money people require for transactions. Therefore, the total money value, or nominal value, of transactions (in a year, say) in the country is decisive. This in turn depends on the total volume of goods that is to be exchanged, i.e. the total volume of goods produced, as measured by real GDP (or Y). ❐ This means that, if Y increases (the economy is in an upswing and economic activity increases), the demand for money typically increases. As more goods are produced and exchanged, more money is required to conclude these transactions.2 There is a direct or positive relationship between Y and MD. ❐ This suggests that there is an endogenous or built-in effect of the business cycle on the demand for money, and hence on interest rates. Data show that interest rates typically start to increase about halfway into an upswing phase, and again start to drop in the latter part of the downswing phase. In addition to the volume of (real) production, the nominal value of transactions also depends on the average price level P [Nominal GDP = P × Y]. Accordingly, an increase in the average price level (as experienced when inflation occurs) also increases the demand for money. There is a positive relationship between P and MD.3 A final important factor determining the demand for money is the nominal interest rate i. The demand for money depends on the amount of money people want to hold at one time (instead of going to the bank to get money for each transaction). Holding money is not free of cost, however, since one forfeits interest: the interest rate is the opportunity cost of holding money/cash. The higher the nominal rate of interest, the less willing people will be to hold significant amounts of money/cash. That is, a higher nominal rate of interest will decrease the demand for money; a lower rate is likely to increase the demand for money. There is an inverse or negative relationship between i and MD. Therefore the (nominal) money demand relationship is as follows: MD = f(i; Y; P) The signs below the equation indicate the kind of relationship between the left-hand variable (MD) and the corresponding right-hand variable: indicates a direct or positive relationship; indicates an inverse or negative relationship. Since we prefer to work in real terms when studying economic relationships and behaviour, it is preferable to state the money demand relationship in real terms. We will also do so with money supply MS later on. It will also prepare the ground for later chapters when we explicitly introduce the price level and inflation into the model. 2 3 Producers typically also require additional production credit if they want to increase production; since credit creation also leads to money creation, an increase in production also leads to an increased money supply. Although a higher price level increases the transactions demand for money, it may cause the demand for money held for precautionary reasons (i.e. holding money in ready form to deal with unexpected (good and bad) events and opportunities) to decrease. This reduction becomes more likely when a higher level of inflation is not a transitory event, but a more enduring feature of the economy. When money is held it loses real value due to inflation. As a result, people and institutions may wish to reduce their money holdings so as to minimise this inflationary loss. 3.1 The monetary sector and interest rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 81 81 2019/12/17 09:15 Money demand, investment and their opportunity costs In chapter 2, when analysing investment behaviour, we argued that the opportunity cost of investment is the real interest rate. Here, when analysing the demand for money, we argue that the opportunity cost of holding money is the nominal interest rate. Why the difference? When deciding to make a real investment in capital goods, the relevant best alternative is buying a bond with a certain nominal and real yield (interest rate): i = r + π, so there is a real interest rate r plus compensation for inflation. Funds invested in a capital good will grow for two reasons: the value of the capital good should rise with inflation and there should be a real return from using the capital to produce and sell goods. If inflation is 10%, a machine bought now for R100 should have a value of R110 a year from now. On top of that it can yield a real return (after allowing for depreciation) for the investor. A bond bought for R100 now will yield inflation (e.g. 10%) plus a real interest rate (e.g. 5%). The nominal yield will be R15 (a nominal interest rate of 15%). In both cases there is compensation for inflation plus a real return. The increase in the price or value of the capital good and the nominal interest rate on the bond both indemnify the real/ financial investor against inflation. All that is relevant in deciding whether to buy the capital good is to compare its expected real return with the real interest rate on bonds. ❐ So the opportunity cost of buying a capital good (i.e. investment) is the real interest rate. When holding money in the form of cash, there is no compensation for inflation and no real return. A R100 note now is still a R100 note a year from now – and its buying power will have been eroded by inflation. By not putting that money in a bond, one loses the entire nominal interest (= R15) that one could have earned. ❐ Therefore, the opportunity cost of holding money is the nominal interest rate. Formally, the demand for money can be divided into three types: ❐ Transactions demand: the need for money to use in ‘active’ form in transactions. This depends largely on the value of transactions, i.e. nominal Y. ❐ Precautionary demand: holding money in ‘ready’ form, since one cannot at all times foresee all transactions. This depends on income Y and the interest rate (opportunity cost), as well as expectations (pessimistic or optimistic). In times of pessimism, people may want to hold more cash as a precautionary step. ❐ Speculative demand: money comprises part of a person’s asset portfolio, together with other financial assets such as bonds. If a person expects the prices of other assets to increase, he will hold less cash and rather buy other assets, hoping to profit from the expected price increase. On the other hand, if a decrease in asset prices is expected, a person is likely to exchange part of her assets (wealth) for cash/money. What does this decision have to do with interest rates? Recall that the higher the price of financial assets such as bonds or BAs, the lower the rate of return (interest rate). If interest rates are low, it is not unreasonable to expect that they may increase at some time in the future (implying that the prices of bonds may decrease). It may then be wise to rather sell one’s bonds and hold more cash/money in ‘passive’ form. This means that a low rate of interest creates the incentive for a greater demand for money (from a speculative point of view). Speculative demand, therefore, is largely determined by interest rates. For most macroeconomic reasoning, it is sufficient to use only the transactions and precautionary motives, with Y and the interest rate as main determinants. For the sake of convenience, these can be combined into one line of reasoning, as was done above. 82 Chapter 3: The basic model II: financial institutions, money and interest rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 82 2019/12/17 09:15 ❐ Under the standard macroeconomic convention, real sector symbols such as C, I and Y always indicate real values. Strangely enough, in the monetary sector the convention is that MS and MD are nominal variables. ❐ To convert them to real values, the convention is to write them as a fraction, i.e. divide M MP and them by the price level P, i.e. P . ❐ We will also work increasingly with the real interest rate r. S D The above relationship can be rewritten for the real demand for money: MD P = f(i; Y) We can then express the real money demand mathematically as: MD P = kY – li ...... (3.1) In this equation MP indicates the real amount of money required in the economy for transactions; the parameter k indicates how responsive real money demand is to changes in real income, and l indicates how responsive real money demand is to changes in the nominal interest rate i. P does not appear as a variable on the right-hand side because its effect is captured on the left-hand side. D M Note that the P in the above equation is the demand for real money. The concept of real money can be understood as follows. We demand money mainly to conduct transactions (i.e. to buy goods and services). If the average price level increases by a certain percentage (e.g. when there is inflation), we will require proportionally more nominal money so that in real terms we will have the same amount of money to conduct our transactions of goods and services. D Graphically, the real money demand relationship can be depicted as in figure 3.1. Changes in the rate of interest result in a move along the curve. Changes in Y and P shift the real money demand curve. (How?) Figure 3.1 Real money demand i MD P Real quantity of money The money supply (MS) The nominal stock of money is the amount that the monetary system (i.e. the central banks plus all other financial institutions) is supplying at a particular moment, under the watchful eye (if not control) of the central bank. Thus, when economists talk about the money supply, they usually talk about the stock of money. (In standard economic theory, it is assumed that the central bank is able to control the level of money supplied by the monetary system.) The nominal stock of money can be defined as the total amount of money that is present in the economy at a particular moment. However, there are different definitions of what constitutes money. In published official data in South Africa, there are four different definitions of the stock of money or the money supply: 3.1 The monetary sector and interest rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 83 83 2019/12/17 09:15 M1A =Sum of coins and banknotes in circulation, plus cheque and transmission deposits of the domestic private sector at monetary institutions. M1 =M1A plus other demand deposits held by the domestic private sector at monetary institutions. M2 =M1 plus other short-term deposits and all medium-term deposits at monetary institutions (including savings deposits). M3 = M2 plus all long-term deposits held by the domestic private sector. You will note that the definition gets broader and broader, progressively including assets that are more difficult to convert to, or use as a means of payment. M1 comprises the immediately ‘liquid’ instruments. The graph in figure 3.2 shows the value of coins and notes, M1, M2 and M3. Note how small a proportion coins and notes are of M3 – usually less than 5%. Notice the continual and strong growth in all these aggregates over time amidst up- and downswings in the economy. Figure 3.2 The money supply (coins and notes, M1, M2 and M3) 4 000 M3 3 500 3 000 M2 R billion 2 500 2 000 M1 1 500 1 000 500 Coins and notes Jan-17 Oct-14 Jul-12 Apr-10 Jan-08 Oct-05 Jul-03 Apr-01 Jan-99 Oct-96 Jul-94 Apr-92 Jan-90 0 Source: South African Reserve Bank (www.resbank.co.za). ✍ How large is the money stock in SA currently? Coins and notes = R ...................... billion M1A = R ....................... billion M1 = R ....................... billion M2 = R ....................... billion M3 = R ....................... billion Since the 1980s the Reserve Bank has preferred to use M3 as the most important money supply indicator. However, there is no general agreement on which definition is best. One should choose an appropriate measure depending upon what one wants to analyse. 84 Chapter 3: The basic model II: financial institutions, money and interest rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 84 2019/12/17 09:15 ✍ Who creates money in the economy? The government? The Reserve Bank? How is it created? ____________________________________________________________________________________ ____________________________________________________________________________________ ____________________________________________________________________________________ What determines the money supply relationship in the economy? This relationship reflects the money creation process that occurs mainly via (a) lending by the commercial banking system (in reaction to a demand for credit from within the economy), but is also influenced by (b) the deliberate actions of the Reserve Bank as part of monetary policy. ❐ One can use the balance sheets of banks and the Reserve Bank to better understand the money supply and credit creation process (see next subsection). The nominal quantity of money available at any moment is the result of the credit creation process and interaction between individuals, firms and banks, and between banks and the Reserve Bank. ❐ Money creation does not occur via the printing of notes but, rather, via the extension of credit (loans) by banks. ❐ Banks lend money that has been deposited by clients, e.g. in cheque accounts, to other persons. This can be a direct loan, such as a mortgage to buy a house, or the provision of an overdraft. When this facility is used by the borrower to pay for something, the money typically flows to the bank account of the supplier of the goods or service; that person or institution’s bank can then, in turn, put out a portion of this deposit on loan, and so on. Each time this occurs there is an addition to both the total amount of credit extended and the total amount of bank deposits in the country; and each creation of a deposit is equivalent to money creation. ❐ There are a number of rounds of lending and relending, with deposits being created and recreated all the time. Gradually this process peters out. The cumulative result of this process of relending is the total money stock or supply of money. In this way, an initial ‘injection’ of a deposit is multiplied, with an eventual effect on the money stock much greater than the initial injection – it is a credit multiplier process that takes place. ❐ The extent of the money creation process, i.e. the value of the credit multiplier, depends on how much is relent in each round. A ceiling is placed on this by the legally prescribed minimum cash reserve that banks have to hold, implying a forced ‘leakage’ from the process in each round. Each commercial bank is legally compelled (by the Reserve Bank) to hold a specified minimum percentage of all deposits at the bank in the form of cash. Only the remainder may be put out on loan. In 2009 this reserve requirement was at 2.5% of deposits. ❐ The higher this percentage leakage, the smaller the portion that can be lent in each round. Therefore the maximum scope of the money creation process is inversely proportional to the minimum reserve requirement (the leakage rate). 1 ❐ This means that the value of the credit multiplier is R , where R = reserve requirement (e.g. 0.025, meaning 2.5% of deposits). The logic of this is the same as with the expenditure multiplier outlined in chapter 2: the more that is held back (or that leaks from the process) in each round, the smaller the cumulative effect of the money creation process. The credit multiplier can be quite large – it is 40 in the South African case. 3.1 The monetary sector and interest rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 85 85 2019/12/17 09:15 It is important to note that the reasoning here concerns the maximum scope of the money creation process. Banks can choose voluntarily to hold higher-than-required reserves or so-called excess reserves (see the balance sheet subsection that follows). The holding of excess reserves restrains the money and credit creation process. Because banks hold an additional percentage of deposits, the effective value of the credit multiplier will decrease. ❐ For example, should banks choose to hold excess reserves equal to 1% of deposits, while 1 the required reserve requirement is 2.5%, the effective multiplier will be 0.025 + 0.01 = 1 28.6. Compare this to the value of 0.025 = 40 if no excess reserves are held. The formula of the credit multiplier thus indicates a maximum value. ❐ Excess reserves result in an element of uncertainty regarding the extent of any change in the money stock; they also imply that changes in the money supply do not occur mechanically. ❐ The proportion of excess reserves that banks hold is very sensitive to the nominal interest rate they can charge on loans. When the prime rate increases, for instance, the opportunity cost of holding excess reserves increases – the bank has an incentive to reduce excess reserves and lend a larger proportion of the deposits that it holds. ✍ What is the value of the credit multiplier if the cash reserve requirement is 2.5% and banks hold 2% excess reserves on average? __________________________________________________________________________________ The role of the Reserve Bank in the money supply process Three factors that determine the supply of money have been identified so far: injections of money into and withdrawals from the banking system, banks voluntarily holding excess reserves, and changes in the minimum reserve requirement. The last factor is under the control of the Reserve Bank. Though it has not been used much in recent years, it is an instrument to control the money supply – it is an instrument of monetary policy. The Reserve Bank can and does use two other instruments of monetary policy to influence the money supply: (1) The repo rate (or ‘repurchase’ rate): This rate – which is not to be confused with the prime overdraft rate – is the nominal interest rate (i.e. the price) that commercial banks have to pay when they borrow from the Reserve Bank (have a look at the balance sheet of the SARB further on). Banks do this when they run low on cash reserves or borrow with the intent to support their credit creation activities. The former is where the Reserve Bank functions as ‘lender of last resort’, providing ‘accommodation’ to commercial banks. ❐ Increases in the repo rate discourage commercial banks from borrowing from the Reserve Bank and, accordingly, restrain their ability to create credit/money. ❐ The opposite occurs when the Reserve Bank decreases the repo rate. When the repo rate decreases banks are encouraged to borrow more from the Reserve Bank. As banks then start lending out the money that they borrowed from the Bank, the credit multiplier starts to operate. The loans reflect in the bank balances (deposits) of firms and households in various banks. With a multiplier value of, for example, 86 Chapter 3: The basic model II: financial institutions, money and interest rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 86 2019/12/17 09:15 40, the cumulative effect can be huge. In this way changes in the repo rate have a significant impact on the money supply via loans and deposits.4 The repo rate is formally announced by the governor of the SARB after the regularly scheduled meetings of the Monetary Policy Committee (MPC). ❐ Practically it is made effective via a weekly tender process in which banks express their need for accommodation (funds). Depending on the total liquidity needs of banks, the rate is set (in line with the MPC decision) by adjusting the amount of funds the SARB is willing to provide to banks.5 Bank profit originates from the difference between the nominal interest rate that banks pay on their liabilities (loans from the SARB and private deposits) and the nominal interest rate that they earn on their loans and advances to households and firms. Thus the repo rate at which the banks borrow (the ‘wholesale price of credit’) will determine the rate that banks will charge (the ‘retail’ price) on the loans that they extend. This explains why, when the repo rate increases, the prime overdraft rate charged by banks immediately follows suit. ❐ The margin between the repo rate and the prime overdraft rate typically is 3.5%. The graph in figure 3.3 shows the consistently parallel way these two rates have moved over time, and how their cyclical movement relates to the business cycle. (The repo rate’s predecessor prior to 1997 was known as the bank rate.) Figure 3.3 The repo (bank) rate and the prime overdraft rate 25 Prime rate Nominal interest rates (%) 20 15 10 Bank rate/Repo rate 5 2017 2015 2013 2011 2009 2007 2005 2003 2001 1999 1997 1995 1993 1991 1989 1987 1985 1983 1981 0 Source: South African Reserve Bank (www.resbank.co.za) and Quantec. 4 5 This process will commence with an increase in the ‘loans extended to bank’ on the asset side of the SARB. Simultaneously, the excess reserves that banks hold with the SARB (appearing on the liability side of the SARB balance sheet) will also increase. As banks then start lending out the money that they borrowed from the SARB, the ‘loans and advances’ on the asset side and the ‘deposits’ on the liability side of the bank balance sheet start to increase. Because of the higher levels of deposits and thus the increase in the amount of cash reserves required, the excess reserves of banks will decrease and be converted into required reserves. Should the repo rate remain constant, it does not mean that the amount of credit extended and deposits created in the economy will necessarily remain unchanged (indeed, it usually does not remain unchanged). When the level of economic activity increases, one could also expect that there will be increases in the demand for bank loans and in the demand for deposits held for transactional purposes. Thus, banks may borrow more reserves from the SARB to finance an increase in their loan book even when the repo rate remains unchanged (which, in effect, means that the SARB accommodates the additional demand by allowing the money supply to increase at the prevailing repo and interest rate level). Given a cash reserve requirement of 2.5% and thus a credit multiplier of 40, relative to their total deposits, banks will not need to borrow that much from the SARB. 3.1 The monetary sector and interest rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 87 87 2019/12/17 09:15 Unlike cash reserve requirements (discussed earlier) and open market operations (discussed later), the repo rate conveys a direct price signal to the financial markets as to the Reserve Bank view regarding the direction into which the interest rate should be moving. Cash reserve requirements and open market operations can also influence the nominal interest rate level in the economy, but the effect is more indirect. Because of the clarity of its signal, the repo rate is the most important monetary policy instrument that the SARB uses to conduct monetary policy and to convey its policy stance to the financial markets. This is the case not only in South Africa but in most countries with a monetary policy system pursuing a clear goal (usually low inflation). (2) Open market operations (OMOs): This refers to the Reserve Bank’s buying and selling of treasury bills or short-term government bonds in order to influence the supply of money in the economy. Selling of bonds withdraws money from circulation and decreases the money supply; buying bonds brings money into circulation and increases the money supply. (Remember that government bonds are originally issued by the Treasury in the primary market to finance the budget deficit.6 Open market transactions thus occur in the secondary market, with the role of the Reserve Bank being that of dominant market participant able to influence the market significantly.) ❐ See sections 3.4 and 9.7 for an explanation of ‘quantitative easing’, a practice introduced in the USA in 2008. It is similar to open market operations but involves the sale, by a central bank, of long-term government bonds as well as other, privatesector financial assests such as MBSs (Mortgage-Backed Securities). Summary: determinants of the money supply Household, firm and bank actions: 1. Injections of money (deposits, inflows) into and withdrawals (outflows) from the domestic banking system. This includes international in- or outflows of funds due to a surplus or deficit on the balance of payments (see chapter 4). 2. Banks voluntarily holding excess reserves or reducing their excess reserves. 3. Banks borrowing more reserves from the SARB to finance an expansion of their loan book (see footnote 4). Reserve Bank actions: 4. Changes in the official minimum reserve requirement by the Reserve Bank, which affects the size of the credit multiplier. 5. Open market operations by the Reserve Bank, which either injects or withdraws money from circulation. 6. Changes in the repo rate instituted by the Reserve Bank. ✍ What is the prime rate? How high is it at the moment? ____________________________________________________________________________________ ____________________________________________________________________________________ 6 88 The matter is complicated by the fact that even primary issues of bonds used to be handled by the Reserve Bank in its capacity as agent of the Treasury. However, see chapter 9, section 9.5 for current arrangements. Chapter 3: The basic model II: financial institutions, money and interest rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 88 2019/12/17 09:15 A bank balance sheet approach To gain a better understanding of how a change in credit leads to a change in the money supply and what role the central bank (i.e. the Reserve Bank) plays in the process, we can examine the balance sheets of the central bank and the commercial banks. ❐ We will see linkages between key, corresponding items in the Reserve Bank and commercial bank balance sheets. ❐ In the commercial bank balance sheet we will see the link between deposits (liability side) and the loans (asset side) so enabled. Figure 3.4 Balance sheets – SA Reserve Bank and commercial banks SOUTH AFRICAN RESERVE BANK BALANCE SHEET COMMERCIAL BANK BALANCE SHEET Assets Liabilities Assets Liabilities Gold and foreign reserves Liquidity provided Utilisation of cash reserves Loans granted to banks (repurchase agreements) Advances and investments Advances Banks Other Investments Government stock (bonds) Other Notes and coins Deposits Central government Banks and mutual banks Required reserve balances and excess reserves Other Capital and liabilities other than notes, coins and deposits Central bank money and gold Banknotes and coins Gold coin and bullion Deposits with the SARB Deposits* Other assets Loans and advances Mortgage advances Overdrafts and loans Instalment debtors, leases Foreign currency loans Other Investments (bonds, shares) Fixed assets Other liabilities to the public Loans received from SARB (repurchase agreements) Other Foreign loans Other loans and advances Other liabilities to the public Capital and other liabilities Other assets *Including cash, cheque and transmission accounts, short-, medium- and long-term savings. The asset side of the balance sheet of the South African Reserve Bank comprises, among others, gold and foreign reserves as well as loans granted to banks. ❐ The gold and foreign reserves include the dollars, euros, yen and pounds etc. held by the SARB. ❐ The loans to banks comprise the repurchase agreements into which the SARB enters with banks, i.e. when banks borrow from the SARB at the ‘repo rate’. ❐ Government bonds that the SARB buys in OMOs appear on the asset side of the balance sheet of the SARB under ‘government stock’ (under ‘investments’; see below). The liability side of the SARB balance sheet includes: ❐ Notes and coins circulating in the economy. Just as a treasury bill is an IOU whereby government promises to pay you the face value of the bill, so a R100 note is an IOU issued by the SARB whereby they promise to pay you R100 if you offer them your IOU (bank note). (Until the 1990s banknotes had such a promise written on them). ❐ Deposits made by government (the SARB acts as banker to government) and commercial banks. The latter includes the required reserves that they need to hold, as well as additional (excess) reserve deposits at the SARB. 3.1 The monetary sector and interest rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 89 89 2019/12/17 09:15 The asset side of the balance sheet of commercial banks includes: ❐ The deposits that they hold at the SARB (the required reserves as well as the excess reserves), and ❐ Loans and advances that the banks extend to firms and households. These include mortgage advances, overdrafts and loans, instalment credit and leases. (The asset side of banks may also include investments in bonds and shares as well as some fixed assets.) The liability side of the balance sheet of commercial banks includes: ❐ Private deposits (i.e. if you deposit money at the bank, the bank owes you the money). ❐ Loans that the banks receive from the SARB in the form of repurchase agree­ments, and on which they pay the repo rate. (Banks may also borrow from other banks, and from foreign banks and institutions.) These two liability-side items are the main elements that enable banks to extend loans to households and firms, i.e. to create credit (which then is reflected on the asset side of their balance sheets). This is the heart of the money creation process. ❐ If ‘deposits’ increase on the liability side of commercial bank balance sheets, their conversion into loans to households and firms will be visible in the amount of ‘loans and advances’ on the asset side. ❐ Observe the mechanism through which changes in the repo rate will affect the liability side of the balance sheets of commercial banks, and thus the basis of their credit extension to the private sector, i.e. their money creation. If a repo rate change encourages banks to borrow from the Reserve Bank, it will reflect first as an increase in ‘loans received from SARB’ on their liability side, but when it is used to extend loans to households and firms, it will reflect similarly as an increase in ‘loans and advances’ on the asset side of their balance sheets. ❐ Likewise, changes in the required reserves (held at the SARB) will impact on the latitude of commercial banks to extend loans, from deposits, to households and firms. ❐ The asset side reveals how voluntary excess deposits (excess reserves) at the SARB will reduce the scope for loans that can be extended by commercial banks. Note how: ❐ Loans from the Reserve Bank to banks are symmetrically reflected as assets for the Reserve Bank and liabilities for commercial banks. ❐ Required and excess reserves are symmetrically reflected as assets for commercial banks and liabilities for the Reserve Bank. It is also possible to compile a consolidated balance sheet for the whole monetary sector (defined to include, inter alia, the Reserve Bank, commercial banks, the Land Bank, the Post Bank and the Corporation for Public Deposits). The components of the nominal M3 money supply and the loans that the monetary sector extends then appear as assets and liabilities on the sector balance sheet. Thus an increase in M3 can be traced back, for instance, to an increase in the extension of credit to the private sector, which in turn can be broken down into increases in mortgage loans or overdraft facilities, and so forth. Indeed, most of the increase in M3 can be traced back to changes in the different types of credit extended to the private sector. One can thus gain insight into money supply conditions and dynamics by studying the consolidated balance sheets of the monetary sector together with those of the commercial banks and the Reserve Bank. These balance sheets are published regularly in the Quarterly Bulletin of the Reserve Bank. 90 Chapter 3: The basic model II: financial institutions, money and interest rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 90 2019/12/17 09:15 The bank sector balance sheet in numbers The numbers referring to the above discussed balance sheet can be found in the Quarterly Bulletin of the South African Reserve Bank. The graphs in figures 3.5 and 3.6 present some of the salient features of the data. Whereas deposits constitute M3 and thus the liability Figure 3.5 M3 and its counterparts 4 000 Total credit extended to the private sector 3 000 M3 R billion 2 000 1 000 Foreign assets Net credit extended to government 0 –1 000 Jul-18 Jan-17 Jul-15 Jan-14 Jul-12 Jan-11 Jul-09 Jan-08 Jul-06 Jan-05 Jul-03 Jan-02 Jul-00 Jan-99 Jul-97 Jan-96 Jul-94 Jan-93 Jan-90 –2 000 Jul-91 Net other assets and liabilities Source: South African Reserve Bank (www.resbank.co.za). Figure 3.6 Private credit extension and its main components 4 000 Total credit extended to private sector 3 500 3 000 R billion 2 500 2 000 Other loans and advances Mortgage advances 1 500 1 000 500 Jul-18 Jan-17 Jul-15 Jan-14 Jul-12 Jan-11 Jul-09 Jan-08 Jul-06 Jan-05 Jul-03 Jan-02 Jul-00 Jan-99 Jul-97 Jan-96 Jul-94 Jan-93 Jul-91 Jan-90 0 Instalment sale credit Leasing finance Source: South African Reserve Bank (www.resbank.co.za). 3.1 The monetary sector and interest rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 91 91 2019/12/17 09:15 side of the banking sector, ‘loans and advances’ constitute the asset-side counterparts to M3. In figure 3.5, the graph shows M3 and these counterparts. The lines represent the counterparts to M3 and add up to the value of M3, itself represented by the shaded area. One of the main components of loans and advances is credit extension to the private sector. The graph in figure 3.6 shows its main components, of which the category of mortgages is the largest. The money supply function The instruments of monetary policy are the main determinants of the supply of money. The nominal money supply MS is mainly a function of exogenous policy factors under the control of the monetary authorities. In simple theory this is as far as one would go. It implies a vertical money supply curve that is shifted left or right by curtailments or expansions of the nominal money supply as a consequence of monetary policy steps. A first refinement that we need to make is to convert the money supply function, and the diagram, from dealing with the nominal money supply MS to the real money supply, indicated as MP . This parallels the formulation of the money demand function in real terms above. We will also increasingly use the real interest rate r in our analysis. M ❐ Henceforth, when we use the term ‘money supply’, we mean the real money supply P . S S A further possible refinement would be to include the practice that banks frequently hold excess reserves. This means that the effective money supply is lower than it would have been without excess reserves, i.e. when only the exogenous policy factors play a role. Why would a bank hold excess reserves, and how does that affect the money supply function? ❐ In a period of uncertainty excess reserves provide security. ❐ Excess reserves also provide a ‘buffer’ to protect a bank against unexpected, large withdrawals of cash by its clients. Especially when the repo rate is high, a bank will want to ensure that it is not forced to go to the Reserve Bank for assistance (accommodation). Holding excess reserves is not without cost, however. If a bank holds excess reserves, it forfeits the interest it could have earned by putting the funds out as loans: the interest rate is the opportunity cost of holding excess reserves. High interest rates are likely to discourage the holding of excess reserves and encourage maximum lending. Lower interest rates can induce banks not to lend to the fullest extent. This suggests the possibility of a positive relationship between the interest rate and credit/ money creation. Graphically, this is represented as a money supply curve with a positive slope. The steepness of the curve (the value of the slope) will depend on the interest responsiveness of the money supply. (How?) This positive relationship can be valid only up to the point where banks are fully loaned up. Then money creation in the banking system reaches a ceiling. Exactly where this ceiling is will depend on the exogenous policy factors analysed above – most importantly, the size of the cash reserve requirement. Graphically, this means that the money supply curve becomes vertical at this point. The money supply can therefore be depicted in two ways, as shown in figure 3.7. M For most macroeconomic chain reactions, it is sufficient to use the simple, vertical P curve. One should, however, always keep the role of excess reserves in mind, as it can be decisive in some lines of reasoning. S 92 Chapter 3: The basic model II: financial institutions, money and interest rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 92 2019/12/17 09:15 Figure 3.7 Two depictions of the real money supply i Simple form: MS P Refined form: i M P S Real quantity of money Real quantity of money Is the money supply exogenous or endogenous? ❐ If a portion of the money supply curve is interest responsive (i.e. non-vertical graphically), then the money supply is partially endogenous (i.e. dependent on factors within the economy) and reacts spontaneously to changes in the economy. ❐ If policymakers respond to problems such as unemployment by allowing the money supply to grow, then this money supply growth is (partially) an endogenous result or symptom of events in the economy. In both cases the control of the Reserve Bank over the money supply is not complete, nor independent. If only the exogenous policy instruments determine the money supply, then it is exogenous and Reserve Bank control is complete. That is the case with a vertical money supply curve (graphically). Supply and demand interaction: equilibrium in the monetary sector? Graphically (see figure 3.8), it is simple to indicate that the equilibrium between the Figure 3.8 Money market equilibrium supply of and demand for money is deter-S i MD M and mined by the intersection of the MP P P curves which determines an equilibrium interest rate as well as an equilibrium quantity of money. S Mathematically the equilibrium in the money market can be expressed as: MS i0 MD P = P M and because P = kY – li, the money market equilibrium condition can be rewritten as: D MS P = kY li …… (3.2) MD P Real quantity of money 3.1 The monetary sector and interest rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 93 93 2019/12/17 09:15 Any shift in either or both of the curves will lead to a new interest rate level. An increase in the money demand (e.g. due to an increase in Y) will lead to a rate increase. Likewise, an expansion of the money supply should result in downward pressure on the rate of interest. Figure 3.9 Money market changes i MS P However, such a mere diagrammatical or i1 mathematical statement is not sufficient – one must analyse and understand the economics i0 behind these diagrammatical stories. The demand for money must be linked to the demand for financial assets and to money MP M P market instruments in particular. Changes in or MP , and changes in the equilibrium interest Real quantity of money rate and quantity (see figure 3.9), can then be understood and interpreted in terms of the trade in financial instruments. D D S For example, suppose (due to some change in the economy) the real demand for money were M to increase ( P shifts right graphically). The following chain of events would occur in the money market: D At the initial interest rate level i0 there will be an excess demand for money. This implies that the public requires more money (not income) for transactions than they currently have in their portfolios. One way to get hold of money is to sell some of their financial instruments/assets. The sale of financial paper implies an increased supply of, for example, BAs on the money market. This causes downward pressure on the prices of BAs, which is equivalent to upward pressure on the BA rate. The interest rate moves to i1. ✍ A similar story can be told for an increase in the money supply (MS ). Complete this chain reaction in the space below: ______________________________________ Graphical test: ______________________________________ ______________________________________ ______________________________________ ______________________________________ ______________________________________ ______________________________________ ______________________________________ ______________________________________ ______________________________________ ______________________________________ ______________________________________ ______________________________________ 94 Chapter 3: The basic model II: financial institutions, money and interest rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 94 2019/12/17 09:15 M These events explain, practically, why the increase in P leads to an increase in the nominal rate of interest, as shown in the diagram. It thus explains the path between the two equilibrium points. M ❐ At both equilibrium points: P = kY – li. D S Remarks 1. In practice, quite a number of different short-term rates of interest exist (compare the interest rate information in the Quarterly Bulletin of the Reserve Bank). In addition, there are long-term rates of interest, for example on 20-year Eskom stock or long-term government stock. Therefore, the single rate of interest shown in the diagram must thus be understood as being representative of the interest rate spectrum. ✍ How many interest rates? See how many different rates you can find in the Quarterly Bulletin or in financial weeklies or the financial pages of newspapers. Can you classify them into groups? ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ 2. The relationship between short-term and long-term interest rates is called the ‘term structure of interest rates’ or the ‘yield curve’. It is standard practice to use the interest rates on government bonds when constructing the yield curve. 7 The relative height of short-term as against long-term interest rates – the slope of the yield curve – and their expected relation in future is of great interest to financial investors and portfolio managers who must decide between investment in shortor long-term assets. ❐ Usually, when the short-term interest rates are lower than the long-term interest rates (i.e. there is a positive yield curve), it indicates that there is an expectation in financial markets that interest rates are likely to increase in future. ❐ If short-term interest rates are higher than long-term interest rates (a negative yield curve), the expectation is for interest rates to decrease in future. ❐ Close to the peak of a business cycle, when money market conditions become tight because of the high demand for short-term credit), the yield curve tends to become negative – short-term rates become higher than long-term rates. A negative yield curve also means interest rates are relatively high. Hence, there is an expectation that they will decrease in future. When the economy is close to the trough of the business cycle (i.e. in recession), money market conditions are not tight, so there is not much upward pressure on short-term interest rates. The yield curve will be positive. This implies that interest rates are relatively low. Hence, interest rates are expected to increase in future. 7 When one compares short-term and long-term interest rates, one should ensure that they are issued by the same institution. This will ensure that the risk premium included in both the short-term and the long-term interest rate are the same and that the only difference between the short-term and long-term interest rate is the time to their maturity. Government is one of few institutions to issue both short-term and long-term bonds. 3.1 The monetary sector and interest rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 95 95 2019/12/17 09:15 For portfolio managers, it is very important to know what the interest rate is expected to do in the future, because, as you may recall from above, there is an inverse relationship between the interest rate and the price of a financial asset (or ‘security’). ✍ Which are higher – short-term rates or long-term rates? Find examples of short-term rates and long-term rates for a few years and compare the levels, also on a graph. Is there any pattern? ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ (Hint: Is there any link to the business cycle? Compare graphs comparing the yield curve to the economic growth rate.) 3. Note that neither the government nor the Reserve Bank sets interest rates in the sense of a legal prescription or decree. The Reserve Bank influences, manages or controls interest rates via the money market by influencing the money supply and changing the repo rate. The Bank indeed has many potent ways to influence the course of interest rates decisively (these are discussed in depth in chapter 9), but they still do not amount to ‘interest rate fixing’. 4. In the analysis above, we saw how open market operations Monetary policy and the demand side of the monetary sector (OMOs) can change the supply of money in the market, In practice, the repo rate, which constitutes a cost thereafter leading to a change factor for banks, has an immediate effect on the in the rate of interest. In praclending rates of banks. tice, the sale of, for example, ❐ This can influence the demand for credit (graphically, a move along the MD curve), which government stock in OMOs can result in a new equilibrium money stock and usually has an immediate efinterest rate. fect on interest rates, since ❐ This is discussed in the analysis of the practice of each transaction carries a monetary policy in chapter 9. certain price and thus a corresponding rate of interest. If the Reserve Bank experiences difficulties in selling stock, it has to reduce the price sufficiently to attract buyers, i.e. the rate of interest must be increased sufficiently. To keep one’s economic reasoning on track, it might be safer, though, to understand the effect of open market transactions as first affecting the money supply, which in turn causes a change in the rate of interest. 5. The Quarterly Bulletin of the SARB contains information about the weekly money market accommodation that the SARB provides to banks in the form of, mainly, repo transactions. The accommodation means that banks are continuously experiencing a shortage of funds that they are unable to fill by borrowing in the market (by borrowing from other banks in the so-called ‘interbank market’). Thus they need to borrow from the SARB. News media sometimes refer to this when they report on the ‘money market shortage’. 96 Chapter 3: The basic model II: financial institutions, money and interest rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 96 2019/12/17 09:15 Why always a shortage? In practice the Reserve Bank prefers the money market always to show a modest shortage. Why? A shortage means that banks are forced to go to the Reserve Bank for accommodation. This in turn means that the repo rate is continually activated as a cost factor for banks, which makes it an effective policy instrument for the Bank (see chapter 9). ❐ The Reserve Bank maintains the necessary shortage by using either open market operations or changes in the minimum reserve requirement to manipulate the supply side of the market. ❐ Only when the shortage becomes unusually large can one really expect upward pressure on interest rates. ❐ In early 2014 the average shortage (amount of accommodation) ranged between R20 billion and R40 billion. (Is this relatively large or small? What percentage of the money stock does this constitute? Compare the money supply figures above.) ✍ 1. Commentators may state that an increase in interest rates is a symptom of prosperity and good times. Why? ___________________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________________ This effect on interest rates typically occurs in the later stages of an upswing – as the economic upswing gains momentum, credit bottlenecks start to develop, creating upward pressure on interest rates. (It is as if the economy heats up and runs a temperature.) 2. If you have to explain why interest rates have declined, what are all the possible causes (including policy steps)? Make a list. (Hint: Distinguish between demand-side and supplyside causes, and between endogenous and policy-related causes.) ___________________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________________ ___________________________________________________________________________________ Built-in cycles? The restraining feedback effect may imply some kind of cyclical tendency in the economy. The automatic increase in interest rates at the end of an upswing, which dampens expenditure, may perhaps initiate the start of a downswing phase. Likewise, decreasing interest rates at the end of a recession may be the beginning of forces that may initiate the next upswing. In practice, this factor alone cannot explain the cyclical movement in the economy (also see section 3.2.2). In chapter 4 other factors are identified that may constitute inherent or endogenous cyclical forces. 3.1 The monetary sector and interest rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 97 97 2019/12/17 09:15 3.2 Linkages between the monetary and the real sectors At this point we can combine the elements of the model encountered so far: the monetary sector and the real sector. Together the two sectors constitute a coherent model of the economy (temporarily excluding the external sector variables and the price level). Different chain reactions can now be linked together to explain most macroeconomic changes in these two sectors. The three diagrams involved can be juxtaposed to illustrate the linkages between the two sectors. The first important linkage is from the monetary sector (or money market) to the real sector (or goods market). Working with both nominal and real interest rates in one set of diagrams Before we demonstrate that, we need to find a way to link the money market diagram – which has the nominal interest rate i on its vertical axis – with the real investment diagram, which has the real interest rate r on its vertical axis. The two diagrams in figure 3.10 show how the money market diagram can be converted into one with the real interest rate on its vertical axis. Given an inflation rate π, for every nominal interest rate level i there is an equivalent real interest rate r. So, if a nominal rate i0 is determined in the money market, in effect a real rate r0 is also determined (given the inflation rate). Note how the vertical displacement of the two diagrams is equal to the inflation rate π, as required by the expression r = i – π, or i = r + π. (See the box in chapter 2, section 2.2.2, for a discussion of this expression.) Figure 3.10 The money market with nominal and real interest rates The money market with a nominal interest rate i The money market with a real interest rate r MS P MS P r0 i0 i0 r0 MD M P D P Real quantity of money Real quantity of money From now on we will use the right-hand version of the money market diagram, with the real interest rate r on the vertical axis (while keeping in mind that actual money market behaviour – the buying and selling of financial instruments, and real money demand and supply – is based on the nominal interest rate). 98 Chapter 3: The basic model II: financial institutions, money and interest rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 98 2019/12/17 09:15 ❐ If the inflation rate is zero, the two diagrams become identical. Since in this chapter we are still assuming, for the sake of exposition, that the price level P is constant, the new diagram does not affect our analysis at all. But it does mean that our diagrammatical apparatus is equipped to deal with the inflationary context when that becomes necessary (e.g. in chapter 6). 3.2.1 The Keynesian transmission mechanism in the short run The first important linkage is from the monetary sector (or money market) to the real sector (or goods market). Changes in the monetary sector cause changes in the rate of interest that, via the impact on investment (capital formation), influence aggregate expenditure and consequently real GDP. This sequence is particularly important in the analysis of the consequences of monetary policy steps. A more complete example follows. Suppose the repo rate is increased by the Reserve Bank. This discourages the lending and money creation capacity of banks. The money supply contracts. This is likely to cause excess demand in the money market. Sales of money market instruments (to increase money holdings) cause downward pressure on their prices, and thus upward pressure on nominal interest rates (towards a new money market equilibrium). In effect this increases real interest rates with the same amount. The higher real interest rates discourage investment. (Why?) The likely decrease in investment expenditure I decreases aggregate expenditure (C + I + G + X – M). Accumulating stocks discourage production. If and when production decreases, real GDP and thus real income Y decrease. The level of economic activity declines and the economy experiences a downswing or cooling down period. In brief: Repo rate ⇒ MS ⇒ upward pressure on r ⇒ I discouraged; if I ⇒ total expenditure decreases ⇒ production discouraged ⇒ real GDP and Y decline. Figure 3.11 Effect of an increase in the repo rate E r r MS P C + I0 + C + I1 + M P D Real quantity of money G+X– M G+X– M I0 I1 I I Y The left-hand diagram in figure 3.11 shows what happens in the money market, and with the interest rate, when the money supply changes due to the repo rate change. The middle diagram shows what happens to investment due to the change in interest rate. The righthand diagram shows what happens to total expenditure E and consequently to the level of production (GDP) or income Y. 3.2 Linkages between the monetary and the real sectors How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 99 99 2019/12/17 09:15 In this theory or view of the macroeconomy, therefore, the connection between monetary disturbances and the real sector occurs via the interest rate-investment link. (Note that the middle diagram has a monetary variable on the vertical axis and a real variable on the horizontal axis.) This is the so-called Keynesian transmission mechanism: the transmission from monetary to real variables occurs primarily via interest rates. (The Classical or Monetarist view differs from this. It is discussed in chapter 11.) ✍ 1. Suppose the reserve requirement is increased ⇒ _____________________________________________________________________________________ _____________________________________________________________________________________ Diagram: 2. Suppose the Reserve Bank sells government stock in open market transactions ⇒ _____________________________________________________________________________________ _____________________________________________________________________________________ Diagram: To summarise: 1. The implications of money market conditions or events are not limited to the monetary sector of the economy. They are also transmitted to the real sector. In this transmission, the link between the real rate of interest and investment is decisive. 2. The main significance of monetary disturbances and events is the consequences they have for real GDP and employment. 100 Chapter 3: The basic model II: financial institutions, money and interest rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 100 2019/12/17 09:15 3. The direct causes of, for example, a downswing in the economy can be found in reductions in one or more of the components of aggregate expenditure (e.g. G or X), but may actually lie further back in money market conditions. The reverse is true for an upswing. Remember that these rather long chain reactions do not come about in a mechanical fashion. Each step depends on human decision making; uncertainties abound, and delays or weak reactions often occur. This can significantly influence the speed and extent of the real impact of a monetary disturbance or policy step. And even though we are working with short-run changes, these chain reactions can take a year or two to complete. How strong is the real impact of a change in the money supply? One specific important factor in these events is the interest rate responsiveness of the MP = kY – li. We have seen that interest rate demand for money MD – the parameter l in changes are of critical importance in understanding the real impact of a monetary policy step in the form of a money supply change: the larger the interest rate change, the larger the real impact (via investment). However, what determines the extent to which the interest rate will increase or decrease? D Reconsider the chain reaction in the case of a restrictive monetary policy step such as an increase in the cash reserve requirement. ❐ What happens in the money market is that the initial decline in the money supply results in an excess demand situation. This is what causes the upward pressure on the nominal (and thus real) interest rate. ❐ How far will the interest rate increase? It depends on the extent that the rate needs to increase in order to dampen or ‘choke’ the excessive money demand sufficiently to attain balance with the new, reduced supply of money. ❐ Put differently, the interest rate increase must encourage people and institutions to hold less money/cash and to rather buy financial assets. How far it needs to increase before demand has been curtailed sufficiently depends on the sensitivity of people and institutions to the interest rate. If a small interest rate increase is sufficient to curtail all the excess demand, money market equilibrium will be reached promptly. The interest rate will increase only minimally and the impact on the real economy will be relatively mild. ❐ In other words, if money demand reacts strongly and sensitively to nominal interest rate changes (if the demand for money is highly interest rate responsive, i.e. a large value M of l in P = kY – li) the real impact of a monetary policy step such as an increase in the money supply on the interest rate will be relatively weak. (In extreme cases monetary policy can be entirely impotent; in practice this is a rare event, limited to periods when confidence in the economy is extremely low. The Great Depression in the USA and many other countries was one such event and the 2008–09 financial crisis was another.) ❐ Conversely, if money demand is relatively insensitive to nominal interest rate changes M (i.e. a small value of l in P = kY – li) interest rates will change quite a lot during the chain reaction and a relatively larger real impact can be expected. In such a situation monetary policy is relatively powerful. ❐ The diagrams in figure 3.12 illustrate the impact of a money supply contraction on the real interest rate for the contrasting cases of money demand with high and low interest rate responsiveness (left-hand and right-hand side diagrams respectively). D D 3.2 Linkages between the monetary and the real sectors How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 101 101 2019/12/17 09:15 ❐ The left-hand diagram below shows the impact of a money supply contraction on the equilibrium real interest rate for a money demand relationship with a relatively high interest rate responsiveness. The right-hand diagram shows a much larger change in the equilibrium real interest rate for a similar contraction in money supply if the money demand has a relatively low interest rate responsiveness. Figure 3.12 The impact of the interest rate responsiveness of money demand r r MS P MS P r1 r1 r0 D MP r0 MD P Real quantity of money Real quantity of money In addition to factors that determine the extent of the real interest rate change, the rest of the impact of the monetary policy step will depend on: ❐ How strongly investment reacts to a real interest rate change. A high interest responsiveness of investment (a high sensitivity to the rate of interest, indicated by a large h in I = Ia – hr) will strengthen the impact; and ❐ How strongly any change in investment expenditure impacts on production and income. This depends on the extent of the multiplier process. Therefore, all the determinants of the value of the expenditure multiplier KE – various leakage rates – are potentially relevant. The table summarises the potency and impact of a money supply change. Potency of monetary policy Interest responsiveness of money demand: Interest responsiveness of investment: Expenditure multiplier: High Lower Low Higher High Higher Low Lower Large Higher Small Lower The interest rate as a cost factor Although an interest rate increase due to restrictive monetary policy, for example, has been analysed primarily as a factor influencing expenditure or demand, interest rates can also be an important cost consideration for a business enterprise. Thus interest rate changes can also affect the production or supply side of the economy. 102 Chapter 3: The basic model II: financial institutions, money and interest rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 102 2019/12/17 09:15 Note that these conclusions about potency apply specifically to monetary policy steps in the form of money supply changes. If a monetary policy step is defined in terms of interest rate changes, a very different result emerges. We will return to this issue in section 3.3.8. 3.2.2 Secondary effects and ‘crowding out’ There is a second linkage between the two sectors. This one operates in the opposite direction, i.e. from the real to the monetary sector: any change in real income Y has an effect on the monetary sector (via real money demand). This effect attains prominence with regard to the expected consequences of increases in government expenditure (although it is present for any change in total expenditure, even those originating in monetary disturbances). It can be illustrated by means of an example: Suppose government tries to stimulate the economy by increasing government expenditure G. The subsequent chain reaction exhibits two distinct effects: Primary effect: G ⇒ total expenditure increases ⇒ production encouraged ⇒ real GDP and Y increase. Secondary effect: As and while GDP increases, so does the volume of goods to be traded ⇒ total value of transactions increases ⇒ transactions demand for money increases, i.e. money demand increases (graphically, MP shifts right); this puts upward pressure on (nominal and real) interest rates (why?); increasing real interest rates, in turn, start to discourage private investment (why?) ⇒ as investment declines, the rise in total expenditure is held back ⇒ production growth is held back ⇒ real GDP and Y growth are held back. D Graphically, this secondary effect and the net effect of an increase in government expenditure can be represented as shown in figure 3.13. Figure 3.13 Net effect of an increase in government expenditure E r Shift in money demand due to initial increase in real income r C + I + G1 Secondary effect ∆I Primary effect C+I+ G0 + X – M • Net effect on income I MD P Real quantity of money +X–M ∆I I Y Note that the secondary, feedback effect via the money market runs counter to the initial increase in Y. Income is pushed up but then starts experiencing a force in the opposite direction. However, the secondary impact on Y, being a side-effect, is weaker than the primary impact. 3.2 Linkages between the monetary and the real sectors How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 103 103 2019/12/17 09:15 ❐ The net impact on Y will still be in the direction of the primary effect (in the example above there would still be a positive impact on real income Y). ❐ In practice the two effects are not separated in time. It is not an increase in Y followed by a distinct, smaller decline. It is not a two-step process. As the primary effect gathers speed, the secondary effect simultaneously becomes operational. This effectively starts to put a brake on the growth in real income and progressively restrains the net change in Y. (We will see this even better when we use the IS-LM diagram in section 3.3.6.) ❐ Thus, in reality, there will probably be no zigzag or cyclical movement in the level of real income Y. What happens is that, in the later stages of the expansion, the increase in income starts to lose momentum due to the braking effect of the secondary interest rate increase. ❐ However, the rate of increase or growth rate of Y, i.e. the percentage change in Y per quarter or per annum, will go through a cycle: it will increase initially, but decline when the secondary, restraining effect takes effect. The point is that monetary feedback effects may noticeably reduce the income-boosting effect of an increase in government expenditure. The growth in real income is gradually restrained or choked by the rising interest rate. This secondary counter-effect is valid for any stimulation of GDP and applies to changes in exports X and the autonomous components of consumption (the a-term) and investment (the Ia term). It also applies to changes in investment due to monetary policy pressure on the real interest rate and changes in consumption due to income tax changes (affecting disposable real income (1 – t)Y). A term less often heard is the ‘crowding-in’ effect of government expenditure. What does this indicate? It indicates the stimulation of private investment that may result from government investment in, for example, infrastructure. This is due to the opportunities that the stimulation of the economy creates for private economic activity in general, or specifically for the private sector to supply inputs to government projects. These backward and forward linkages with government investment can serve to create more room for private investment, hence the idea of crowding in. In the macroeconomic debate, the secondary effect really came to prominence with regard to the use of government expenditure to stimulate the economy (fiscal expansion). The expected advantages of increases in government expenditure may be partially offset by the real sector impact of the upward movement in interest rates. ❐ Since private investment is depressed by the higher interest rates that result from the increase in government expenditure, the process has been called the ‘crowding out’ of private investment by government expenditure. How strong is crowding out? On what does it depend? The strength of the crowding-out effect is one of the major disputes in the debate on the potency of fiscal policy. Four factors are relevant. Three of these were encountered in the discussion of the potency of monetary policy above and are restated only briefly: ❐ The extent of the crowding-out effect depends first on the income responsiveness of the M demand for money – i.e. the k in P = kY – li. Recall that the secondary effect is initiated by an increase in the transactions demand for money due to an increase in production and income. In the diagram MP shifts to the right. If this reaction is strong – k is relatively large so that money demand is very income responsive (and shifts a lot) – the secondary effect D D 104 Chapter 3: The basic model II: financial institutions, money and interest rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 104 2019/12/17 09:15 will be larger and crowding out will be stronger. If money demand has a low income responsiveness, i.e. k is relatively small, crowding out will be weaker. ❐ A second factor is the interest responsiveness of the demand In practice, the initial state of the money market is also relevant in this process. A market with for money – i.e. the parameter M surplus liquidity will easily absorb the extra demand = kY – li. The increase in l in P without significant upward pressure on interest money demand causes excess rates emerging. However, if the process starts with a demand in the money market. significant money market shortage – a tight market – If money demand has a high the upward reaction of interest rates definitely comes interest rate responsiveness into play. – i.e. l is relatively large – the real interest rate will increase M relatively little before reaching a new equilibrium. The P curve will be relatively flat. A relatively small negative impact on investment and income follows. Crowding out is relatively weak in this case. If money demand is interest unresponsive, i.e. l is relatively small, crowding out will be relatively stronger. (Why?) ❐ A third factor is the interest responsiveness of private investment – the h in I = Ia – hr. A high responsiveness will increase the secondary effect on expenditure and income. ❐ The fourth factor is the size of the expenditure multiplier KE, which determines the ultimate impact on Y of any change in investment. As before, all the leakage rates are relevant. D D The table summarises the potency and impact of fiscal expansion via increased government expenditure. In reality, the strength of the crowding-out effect is an empi­ rical question. It depends on the factual conditions and behavioural patterns in a par­ticu­ lar country at a particular time. (For example, in chapter 2 it was mentioned that investment in South Africa appears to be relatively insensitive with regard to changes in the interest rate.) ✍ Potency of fiscal policy Income responsiveness of money demand: Interest responsiveness of money demand: Interest responsiveness of investment: Expenditure multiplier: High Lower Low Higher High Higher Low Lower High Lower Low Higher Large Higher Small Lower How does the existence of monetary feedback effects affect the size of the expenditure multiplier? _____________________________________________________________________________________ _____________________________________________________________________________________ _____________________________________________________________________________________ _____________________________________________________________________________________ The value of the expenditure multiplier KE mentioned above is still overoptimistic, since the secondary effect – which reduces the change in Y – is not taken into account. 3.2 Linkages between the monetary and the real sectors How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 105 105 2019/12/17 09:15 Which factors determine the income responsiveness of the demand for money? It depends on the behaviour patterns of economic participants (buyers, sellers, producers, consumers, workers), as well as institutional factors. For example: ❐ The increasing use of credit cards implies that the direct need for cash reacts less quickly to increases in transaction volumes. ❐ The accessibility of the money market for firms wishing to expand their activities is also important. The more easily they can obtain credit via the issue of banker’s acceptances, for example, the smaller their need for trade credit from commercial banks. This implies that their demand for money (bank credit in particular) increases relatively slightly. ❐ Workers who receive weekly wages need to hold smaller precautionary balances, whereas monthly wages create a need to hold more money, either in cash or on deposit at a bank. Whatever the factors that determine the income responsiveness of money demand, they are not likely to change rapidly. In general, these elasticities are relatively stable, at least in the short and medium term. Different countries can also have very different elasticities, depending on factors such as the level of development and the nature of their economic and financial institutions. 3.2.3 Financing the budget deficit Although the budget deficit as an element of fiscal policy is analysed in depth in chapter 10, it is desirable to analyse some interactions of the deficit with the rest of the economy at this stage. The financing of the budget deficit by the Treasury constitutes a critically important form of interaction between the real and the monetary sectors. It also provides further insight into the concept of crowding out. In the case of a budget deficit – when total tax revenue falls short of total government expenditure – the shortfall must be financed in some way or another. Since borrowing is the main form of deficit financing, the deficit is often called the ‘deficit before borrowing’. There are three main methods of financing a budget deficit: domestic borrowing from the private non-bank sector, borrowing from the Reserve Bank, and foreign loans. Our concern here is the different macroeconomic consequences of the three options. (1) Domestic borrowing from the private non-bank sector This is the most general and traditional method of deficit financing: the government gets financing by selling government bonds and TBs in the financial markets to large corporations (such as pension funds and life insurers). Treasury bills are usually Crowding out mark II? sold weekly as part of a running Since a deficit-induced increase in interest rates borrowing process. can also discourage private investment, a form of ❐ We can interpret government crowding out may also exist in this case. However, borrowing as a component this is not a secondary or indirect monetary effect, of the demand for credit. De(which we can denote as ‘crowding out mark I’). pending on financial market Rather, it concerns the direct financial market effect of conditions and behaviour, an government borrowing. One should thus distinguish increase in borrowing is likely this ‘direct’ form of crowding out – crowding out mark II – from the indirect one analysed above – to cause upward pressure on ‘crowding out mark I’. interest rates, which is likely to 106 Chapter 3: The basic model II: financial institutions, money and interest rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 106 2019/12/17 09:15 discourage private investment and is likely eventually to have a contractionary effect on aggregate expenditure and production. ❐ The standard method of financing is restrictive. If the amount of borrowing is extensive and places substantial demands on the money market, the contractionary effect on domestic real income can be significant. ✍ What determines the extent of the impact of government borrowing on interest rates? Can you explain? _____________________________________________________________________________________ _____________________________________________________________________________________ _____________________________________________________________________________________ _____________________________________________________________________________________ _____________________________________________________________________________________ (Hint: Consider monetary responsiveness.) The impact on the actual money market There is no rule of thumb regarding the size of the deficit that can be financed without putting inordinate pressure on financial markets (i.e. on interest rates). It depends on economic and market conditions at a particular time. In times of monetary tightness (limited liquidity in the market), a relatively stronger interest reaction can be expected. In an economic downturn, which usually brings about a low demand for money and credit, a large deficit can be financed domestically without noticeable upward pressure on interest rates. Actually, the important question is whether the deficit that is announced in the budget speech in Parliament comes as a surprise for money and capital market participants. Usually the markets discount the expected deficit before the national budget is presented – the expected impact is already largely reflected in the interest rate situation before the budget. If the budgeted deficit is as expected, there should be no further impact on interest rates. If the budget deficit is, say, unexpectedly large, interest rates may increase noticeably soon after the budget speech. ❐ The impact of the budget deficit on interest rates is particularly important in understanding interest rate patterns in the USA, as well as changes in the dollar exchange rate. As we will see in chapter 4, US interest rates can be of great importance for the South African economy. (2) Borrowing from the Reserve Bank An alternative is for the government to borrow from the Reserve Bank. This can be effected by selling TBs or government bonds to the Reserve Bank. The payment that the government receives for the bills constitutes the loan. ❐ Since such transactions constitute an inflow of money from ‘outside’ the economy, they lead to an injection of money into the system. The resultant money supply expansion is likely to cause downward pressure on interest rates. Therefore this method of deficit 3.2 Linkages between the monetary and the real sectors How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 107 107 2019/12/17 09:15 financing is expansionary. Because of the credit multiplier, the ultimate increase in the money supply will in all likelihood be much larger than the initial injection into the money supply resulting from the government financing its deficit with ‘new money’. This method is also called financing of the deficit via money creation. In the media one often notices the expression ‘financing the deficit with the printing press’, as if the government finances the deficit by printing money. This is merely a manner of speaking, and does not indicate what usually really happens. Remember that the government in South Africa does not control the printing or issue of money – only the Reserve Bank is mandated to do so. Also, actual paper notes and coins are not the issue where the money supply is concerned – recall that notes and coins constitute only a fraction of the total M3 money supply. Since such monetary expansion is commonly regarded as inflationary (see chapters 7 and 12) and has indeed in reality led to inflationary and even hyperinflationary episodes – Zimbabwe being a case in point – this is not a popular or approved form of deficit financing. In practice, governments will only use it in extraordinary circumstances (see chapter 10). ❐ In contrast, domestic borrowing from the private sector is described as a ‘noninflationary method of deficit financing’. (3) Foreign loans In this case, the Treasury goes offshore to foreign money and capital markets and sells (or ‘floats’) bond issues there. The inflow of the borrowed funds from outside implies a monetary injection, which increases the money supply. The macroeconomic effect is expansionary. ❐ The so-called ‘Yankee’ and ‘Samurai’ bonds that the South African Treasury issued are two examples. The ‘Yankee’ bond is a dollar-denominated bond, while the ‘Samurai’ bond is a yen-denominated bond. Which option? The choice that government makes between these options will clearly depend on general economic as well as money market conditions (among other things). ❐ In some situations, government (the Treasury) may expressly want to use an expansionary method of financing; at other times definitely not. The likely extent of any crowding out that may occur surely is relevant, as are the private investment level and prospects. ❐ A further consideration with regard to both domestic and foreign loans is the extent of annual interest payments, which indeed can become an important expenditure item, eventually claiming a significant part of the expenditure budget. ❐ As foreign loans are usually denominated in what is called a ‘hard currency’ (i.e. either dollars, pounds, euros or yen), foreign loans have the additional disadvantage that foreign exchange is required when they are to be repaid or when interest is paid on them. ❐ This also means that the government faces exchange rate risk. If the exchange rate changes before the due date, the size of the loan in rand terms can balloon (or shrink, depending on the case). For example, should the rand depreciate from $1 = R12 to $1 = R18, it means that for every $1 that the South African government borrowed, it now effectively owes the lender (maybe a US bank) R6 more in rand terms. This is a 50% increase in the foreign indebtedness of the government purely due to a depreciation of the rand, i.e. without it actually having borrowed more. 108 Chapter 3: The basic model II: financial institutions, money and interest rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 108 2019/12/17 09:15 These considerations are closely linked to the problems of fiscal policy and public debt management. They are part of a more comprehensive set of considerations and arguments that are relevant in the policy context, and which are analysed further in chapter 10. ❐ Remember that domestic borrowing from the non-bank private sector is the primary and predominant method of financing. The deficit and the balance of payments (BoP) Although the international aspects of macroeconomics are analysed in chapter 4, it is desirable to note certain linkages at this stage: ❐ Foreign loans imply an inflow of foreign capital. Therefore they constitute a link between the budget deficit and the balance of payments deficit or surplus. (How?) ❐ Such a link also results when the budget deficit is financed with domestic loans. The upward pressure that this places on interest rates can attract foreign capital, which strengthens the capital account, and thus the balance of payments. (This is of particular importance in the USA, but also has important implications for South Africa; see below.) Crowding out mark III? We have encountered two possible forms of crowding out. Chapter 4 will show that the financing of a budget deficit via borrowing also can lead to the crowding out of exports – a possible third form of crowding out linked to the budget deficit or to government expenditure. (Once again, this has been a major issue in the USA.) 3.3 The IS-LM model as a powerful diagrammatical aid The diagrammatical exposition encountered so far is straightforward. All the main components in the chain reactions are individually visible. Each diagram represents a recognisable component or sector in the overall picture and shows specific economic behavioural relationships such as consumption or investment. The three diagrams alongside one another show how disturbances are transmitted from the monetary to the real sectors via the interest–investment diagram. It also allows for secondary or feedback effects from the real to the monetary sectors. Thus, a complete diagrammatical framework has been developed. A sequence of economic events can be followed clearly through the diagrams. However, working with three diagrams is cumbersome and imprecise. 3.3.1 Essentials of the IS-LM model The IS-LM model is an alternative way of depicting these relationships diagrammatically (see figure 3.14). It is a diagram that summarises these three diagrams into one, somewhat complex, diagram. It is a more abstract diagram in that it derives ‘equilibrium curves’ from the various behavioural relationships. These curves do not permit the direct type of behavioural interpretation possible in the diagrams encountered so far, e.g. a consumption function that directly shows consumption behaviour. The IS-LM curves are indirect, derived curves. 3.3 The IS-LM model as a powerful diagrammatical aid How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 109 109 2019/12/17 09:15 On the other hand, the IS-LM diagram provides a concise and powerful graphical (and mathematical) tool for analysing macroeconomic changes. Still, it does not add much economic reasoning or content to the analysis. Mostly, it is a diagrammatic tool. The IS-LM model integrates the real and the monetary sectors and shows their interrelatedness and interaction in one diagram. It offers a one-diagram summary of the traditional three diagrams in the simple two-sector Keynesian 45° diagram model. The model depicts the key macroeconomic relationships in a diagram with real income Y and the real interest rate r on the two axes. As the name indicates, the IS-LM model comprises two curves: the IS curve and the LM curve. The IS curve is a summary curve that depicts the real sector – i.e. the two diagrams shown in chapter 2, containing the interest rate, investment, consumption, government expenditure, net exports and aggregate expenditure – in a single diagram. ❐ The IS curve shows combinations of the real interest rate r and real income Y that are consistent with equilibrium in the real sector. ❐ It is a series of potential equilibrium points, from the point of view of relationships and behaviour in the real sector. It has a negative slope. The LM curve is a summary curve that depicts the monetary sector – i.e. the demand for money and the supply of money – on the same axes as the IS curve. ❐ The LM curve shows combinations of the real interest rate r and real income Y that are consistent with equilibrium in the money market. ❐ It is a series of potential equilibrium points, from the point of view of relationships and behaviour in the monetary sector. It has a positive slope. Figure 3.14 The IS-LM model r r1 r0 LM curve • • Overall macroeconomic equilibrium Y1 and r1: simultaneous equilibrium in real and monetary sectors IS curve Y Y0 Y1 The intersection of the two curves indicates an overall macroeconomic equilibrium – simultaneous equilib­rium in the real sector and monetary sector (money market). The intersection is the only point among the two sets of potential equilibrium points denoted by the two curves that produces equilibrium in both sectors. The IS-LM diagram can be used to show the impact of macroeconomic disturbances on the equilibrium levels of real income and real interest. Macroeconomic shocks translate into a shift in either the IS or the LM curves, or both, resulting in a new intersection point. This indicates a change in the equilibrium values of r and Y. For instance, an increase in aggregate expenditure will shift the IS curve right, leading to both a higher real interest rate and a higher level of real income. The equilibrium point changes from (r0; Y0) to (r1; Y1). 110 Chapter 3: The basic model II: financial institutions, money and interest rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 110 2019/12/17 09:15 Which is which? How does one remember which curve is the IS and which the LM? Try the following association: ❐ IS: Investment, Savings and other real sector variables. ❐ LM: Liquidity, Money and other monetary sector variables.8 3.3.2 Deriving the IS curve As noted above, the IS curve shows combinations of the interest rate i and real income Y that are consistent with equilibrium in the real sector. The IS curve is derived directly from the 45° diagram and the accompanying interest–investment diagram. The derivation is shown in the set of diagrams in figure 3.15. The starting point for this derivation is an equilibrium position in the 45° diagram. This shows a level of Y, which depends on a level of aggregate expenditure – notably a level of investment I0 – which is consistent with a particular interest rate r0. From this it follows that those levels – e.g. Y0 and r0 – represent a particular pairing of Y and r that is consistent with the condition for equilibrium in the real sector, i.e. that aggregate expenditure equals aggregate production. This pair can be plotted as a point on the income–interest (Y-r) pair of axes. If the interest rate were at another level, say r1, it would imply a different level of investment I and of aggregate expenditure, and hence of equilibrium real income – therefore, another equilibrium pairing, say of r1 and Y1 on the Y-r axes.9 A line connecting these (and other such) points is the IS curve. It has a negative slope. In general, each equilibrium level of Y has a specific, corresponding interest rate r as its counterpart. Stated differently, each point of equilibrium in the real sector has two sides: a specific level of Y and a corresponding level of r. ❐ In this way one can derive, from the interest-investment diagram and the 45° diagram, many such pairings of Y and r that satisfy the conditions for equilibrium in the real sector. ❐ If these (r; Y) pairs are plotted on a dia­gram with these two variables on the axes, the result is the IS curve. Note that the IS curve is a set of points where equilibrium in the real sector may occur – where the conditions for equilibrium in the real sector are satisfied. Along the IS curve, the real sector would be in equilibrium. Thus an important interpretation of the IS curve is as a series of potential equilibrium values of Y and r, given the way economic actors in the real (or goods) sector – investors, consumers, the government – behave. When economic shocks and fluctuations have run their course and a new equilibrium has been attained in the real sector, it will always be one of the points on the IS curve. 8 9 Formally, the IS label comes from the real sector equilibrium condition I = S, which is an alternative way of stating Y = C + I + G + (X – M). The LM label derives from the money market equilibrium condition restated as L = M, where L denotes money demand MD and M the money supply MS. Put differently: any equilibrium level of income other than Y0 would entail a level of the interest rate that differs from i0 (otherwise there would not be an equilibrium in the real sector). 3.3 The IS-LM model as a powerful diagrammatical aid How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 111 111 2019/12/17 09:15 Figure 3.15 Deriving the IS curve r Equilibrium pair (r0;Y0 ) Equilibrium pair (r1;Y1 ) E r0 C r1 +G + I1 +X –M C +G + I0 +X –M I1 I0 I0 I1 Y0 Investment I Y1 r Different interest rates reappear on vertical axis of new diagram Values of Y in 45° diagram reappear on horizontal axis of IS diagram Income Y Corresponding pairs of Y and r denote points that form the IS curve r0 (r0;Y0 ) r1 (r1;Y1) IS curve Y0 Y1 Income Y ❐ Note that, at a point lower down (to the right) on the IS curve, investment I will always be at a higher level than at any point higher up on the IS curve. (If this is not clear to you, scrutinise the derivation diagrams of the IS curve again, focusing on the level of investment I associated with each of the two points on the IS curve: I1 is associated with point Y1 and r1 on the IS curve.) ❐ The IS curve alone cannot be used to analyse sequences of events in the economy. It summarises only one part of the economy, i.e. relationships and changes in the real sector. The addition of the LM curve is necessary to incorporate monetary effects and to complete the model. ❐ Diagrammatically: to determine the actual equilibrium point and value of Y, a specific point among the series of potential equilibrium points on the IS curve must be selected. ❐ This will depend on the LM curve (see section 3.3.4). 112 Chapter 3: The basic model II: financial institutions, money and interest rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 112 2019/12/17 09:15 The IS curve as a summary curve Economic changes involving r and Y can be summarised in terms of the IS curve. Consider a simple change in the interest rate. It would lead to a different equilibrium level of income Y. While this can be depicted using the two diagrams shown in the first part of this chapter, the IS curve is a handy, concise summary curve that depicts the string of equilibrium points among which the real economy can settle following such a change in r. Given a particular change in r, the resultant change in equilibrium Y is shown by the IS curve (excluding monetary effects). π A formula for the IS curve Since the IS curve represents (r; Y) points that satisfy the equilibrium conditions for the real sector (or goods market), we already have derived its equation in chapter 2 (see equation 2.6): ( ) 1 1 – b (1 – t) (a + Ia + G – hr) Y = …… (3.3 = 2.6) = KE(a + Ia + G) – KEhr If this equation is solved for r, one can see that the slope parameter of the IS curve is K1h and its 1 E __ intercept h (a + Ia + G): 1 1 K h Y…… (3.4) r= h (a + Ia + G) – E If exports and imports are included, we have, from chapter 2 (equation 2.8): ( 1 ) 1 – b(1 – t) + m (a + Ia – hr + G + X – ma ) Y = …... (3.5) = KE(a Ia G X ma hr) as a formula for the open-economy IS curve. 3.3.3 Properties of the IS curve The slope of the IS curve The well-known sequence following a decline in the real interest rate also indicates the slope of the IS curve. Since a lower interest rate will be associated with a higher equilibrium income level (other factors being the same), the IS curve has a negative slope, as indicated in the diagram. Moving along the IS curve, shifting the IS curve The sequence starting with an interest rate change illustrates an important characteristic of the IS curve. ❐ If the interest rate changes, the change in Y from one equilibrium to the next is depicted as a move along the IS curve from one point to another. (Compare the first diagram in figure 3.15.) A shift in the IS curve would occur if, for some reason, a higher or lower equilibrium level of Y occurs without the interest rate r having changed. Formal rule for shifting vs. moving along a curve The shifting of the two curves is the most important aspect of the IS-LM model for rudimentary analysis and reasoning about economic events. It is essential to master this part of the theory. ❐ A curve shifts if a relevant variable not on one of the axes of the diagram changes. ❐ If one of the variables on the axes changes, there is a move along the curve. 3.3 The IS-LM model as a powerful diagrammatical aid How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 113 113 2019/12/17 09:15 The primary reason for such a shift is an exogenous change in expenditure. If exogenous expenditure is higher, e.g. due to a higher level of government expenditure, it would imply a higher equilibrium level of Y being paired with the initial level of r. Since this change does not involve the interest rate, the initial interest rate would now be paired with a different, higher level of real income Y (to the right in the horizontal dimension). The whole set of potential equilibrium points – the points (r; Y) that satisfy the conditions for equilibrium in the goods market – would lie on a different plane. ❐ Diagrammatically, this translates into a Figure 3.16 Shifting the IS curve shift of the IS curve, horizontally, to the r right (see figure 3.16). When we analyse disturbances in an IS-LM diagram this means that changes New real sector equilibrium Y1 at in any factor other than the interest rate, unchanged r0 which impact on aggregate expenditure and hence on real income Y, will shift the IS curve. These include exogenous changes in consumption, investment, government r0 expenditure, taxation (which affects consumption), exports or imports. Entire IS curve ❐ Any exogenous change in expenditure shifts to the right that boosts Y would shift the IS curve to Y0 Y1 Y the right. ❐ Any exogenous change in expenditure that decreases Y would shift the IS curve to the left. (See the examples in section 3.2.2.) How far will the IS curve shift? The extent of the shift in the IS curve following an exogenous change in expenditure depends on the resultant change in equilibrium Y. Obviously this depends on the magnitude of the change in expenditure. A small increase in G, for example, would shift the IS curve less than a large change would. In addition, it would depend on the relationship between the change in G and the eventual change in Y that results. This depends, simply, on the size of the expenditure multiplier KE: ❐ If the multiplier is small, IS shifts relatively little (for a given change in G). ❐ If the multiplier is large, IS shifts relatively much (for a given change in G). To be specific, the IS curve will shift horizontally a distance equal to ∆Expenditure × KE How steep is the IS curve? For more sophisticated analysis the factors determining the steepness of the IS curve are important. The clue to the steepness of the IS curve lies in the reasoning behind the slope of the curve. The slope of the IS curve will depend on the magnitude of the change in real income Y, given a certain initial change in the interest rate r. A smaller change in Y would result in a relatively steep IS curve; a relatively large change in Y gives rise to a relatively flat IS curve. Diagrammatically, this can be represented as in figure 3.17. 114 Chapter 3: The basic model II: financial institutions, money and interest rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 114 2019/12/17 09:15 The more important question is: which economic factors or characteristics determine the slope of the IS curve? Reconsider the example of a drop in interest rates in chapter 2, section 2.2.4: r ⇒ I ⇒ total expenditure ⇒ production ⇒ Y How much will Y change? Two factors determine the extent of the change in Y: Figure 3.17 The slope of the IS curve r IS steeper Slope of IS curve depends on how 1. The first is the reaction much Y changes in response to a change in the interest rate of investment to the interest rate change. (r0;Y0 ) r0 The extent of the reaction depends on the r1 sensitivity of investors to the interest rate, i.e. IS flatter the interest responsiveness of investment – the size of h in I = Ia – hr (or in the formula for Y Y0 Y1 Y2 IS, see equation 3.5 in the maths box above). If this sensitivity/responsiveness is high, a given interest rate change will elicit a strong investment reaction and the eventual change in Y will be K1h ). A low relatively large. This would make the IS curve relatively flat (its slope being interest responsiveness of investment would make the IS curve relatively steeper. 2. The second factor is the reaction of total production to the change in aggregate expenditure. This reaction involves the multiplier process (see section 3.2.1). If the multiplier KE is large, the change in I in the first step will be amplified considerably and the eventual, cumulative change in Y would be large. A large multiplier KE would therefore make the IS curve flatter (its slope being K1h ). A smaller multiplier would make the IS curve steeper. (Remember that the size of the multiplier depends on various marginal leakage rates. See Note that the multiplier affects both the slope of the IS the examples below.) E E curve and the extent to which the IS curve would shift following an exogenous change in expenditure. In the diagram above, therefore, the slope of the ‘flatter’ IS curve reflects either a high interest responsiveness of investment or a large multiplier, or both. The ‘steep’ IS curve reflects either a low interest responsiveness of investment or a small multiplier, or both. Examples Effect on slope of IS curve Investors not very sensitive to interest rates (h) → High interest responsiveness of investment (h) → Large multiplier KE→ Small multiplier KE→ High propensity to consume b → High propensity to save (1 – b) → High propensity to import m→ Cut in income tax rates t→ Steeper Flatter Flatter Steeper Flatter Steeper Steeper Flatter 3.3 The IS-LM model as a powerful diagrammatical aid How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 115 115 2019/12/17 09:15 Points off the IS curve Since the IS curve is a collection of combinations of Y and r that are consistent with real sector equilibrium, any point off the IS is a disequilibrium point in the real sector. At such a point the interest rate is too high or too low to be compatible with the level of real income. Alternatively, the income level Y is too low or too high to be compatible with that interest rate (and the resultant investment level). For such a pairing of Y and r, aggregate expenditure would not be equal to aggregate output, so there would not be real sector equilibrium. 3.3.4 Deriving the LM curve In this section we add the second element in the IS-LM model, i.e. the LM curve. Following that, we can use both curves to analyse economic events and changes. Whereas the IS curve summarises economic relationships and equilibria in the real sector of the economy, the LM curve summarises relationships and equilibria in the monetary sector. More specifically, the LM curve summarises the money market derived in the first sections of this chapter. It differs from that depiction of the monetary sector in that it makes explicit the link between monetary relationships and real income Y. As noted above, the LM curve shows combinations of the real interest rate r and real income Y that are consistent with equilibrium in the money market. The LM curve is derived directly from the money market diagram, in conjunction with the 45° diagram (see section 3.2.1). The essential linkage between the money market and real income lies in the real demand for money relationship (now written in converted form with the real interest rate r). Recall that: MD P = f(i; Y) = kY – li But with i = r π: MD P = f(r; π; Y) = kY lπ lr The key element to notice is the presence of Y on the right-hand side. It indicates that the specific position of the real money demand curve in the money market diagram depends on the prevailing level of real income Y. If Y is relatively high, the money demand curve would be in a position relatively far to the right. If Y is relatively low, the money demand curve would be in a position less to the right. ❐ In general, for each level of Y the money demand curve would be in a different position (other things being the same). Notice the presence of inflation on the right-hand side. It was mentioned in section 3.1.2 that a higher price level causes the nominal demand for money to increase. This effect M , the real demand for money. However, the of P was handled by working in terms of P above equation indicates that inflation (continually increasing P) has an impact on the real demand for money. The relationship is negative. As shown in section 3.1.2, holding money means that one is not compensated for the loss of value due to inflation. Therefore, one would prefer to hold less money when inflation is present. An increase in the inflation rate will decrease one’s real money demand. D 116 Chapter 3: The basic model II: financial institutions, money and interest rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 116 2019/12/17 09:15 ❐ In general, for each level of π the money demand curve would be in a different position (other things being the same). Money demand and money supply together determine the equilibrium interest rate in the M M , each different money moneymarket. For a given real money supply P P curve would imply a different equilibrium real interest rate. ❐ For a given money supply (and inflation rate), therefore, each level of Y would imply a different position for money demand and a different equilibrium interest rate r. Thus there is a relationship between Y and the equilibrium interest rate r in the money market. The LM curve depicts this relationship. S D Figure 3.18 Deriving the LM curve r For income at the higher level of Y monetary demands is at a higher level. Hence a higher r is necessary for money market equilibrium r Corresponding pairs of Y and r denote points that form the LM curve LM curve M S r1 r0 (r1;Y1) r1 MD for income at Y1 r0 (r0;Y0 ) MD for income at Y0 Quantity of money Y0 Y1 Y To derive this in the diagram (see figure 3.18), do the following: ❐ The starting point for this derivation is an equilibrium in the money market (left-hand diagram). For a given money supply (and inflation rate), this shows an equilibrium interest rate that is compatible with the prevailing position of money demand, which in turn depends on the prevailing level of Y. Hence that combination of r and Y – e.g. r0 and Y0 – is consistent with money market equilibrium. This pair can be plotted as a point on the income–interest (Y-r) pair of axes. ❐ Suppose Y is at a different, higher level. This would imply a higher level of money demand, or a position more to the right. The equilibrium interest rate would be higher, resulting in a second equilibrium pairing of, say r1 and Y1 on the income–interest (Y-r) axes. A line connecting these (and other such) points is the LM curve. It has a positive slope. In general, each equilibrium level of the interest rate r has a specific, corresponding income level Y as its counterpart. Stated differently, each point of equilibrium in the monetary sector has two sides: a specific level of r and a corresponding level of Y. ❐ In this way one can derive, from the money market diagram and the 45° diagram, many such pairings of Y and r that satisfy the conditions for equilibrium in the money market (monetary sector). ❐ If these (r; Y) pairs are plotted on a diagram with these two variables on the axes, the result is the LM curve. 3.3 The IS-LM model as a powerful diagrammatical aid How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 117 117 2019/12/17 09:15 Note that the LM curve is a set of points where equilibrium in the monetary sector may occur – where the conditions for equilibrium in the money market are satisfied. Along the LM curve the money market is in equilibrium. Thus an important interpre­tation of the LM curve is the following: the LM curve shows a series of potential equilibrium values of Y and r, given the way economic actors in the monetary sector behave. When economic shocks and fluctuations have run their course and a new equilibrium has been attained in the monetary sector, it will always be one of the points on the LM curve. π A formula for the LM curve Since the LM curve represents (r; Y) points that satisfy the equilibrium conditions for the money market, we already have derived its equation above (see equation 3.2). In real interest format it is: MS MD P = P = kY – lπ lr If solved to get the interest rate on the left-hand side, it becomes: k ( 1 MS ) r = l Y – l P + lπ …… (3.6) ( ) S 1l MP + lπ . Thus the slope of the LM curve is kl and its intercept is The LM curve as a summary curve Whereas the money market diagram can be used to analyse the relationship between the money market and real income, the LM curve is a handy, concise summary curve that depicts the string of points along which the money market can settle following a change in real income Y. Given a particular change in Y, the resultant change in equilibrium r – via a shift of the real money demand curve – is shown by the LM curve (for a given real money M supply P and inflation π). S 3.3.5 Properties of the LM curve The slope of the LM curve Since a higher level of Y is associated with a higher equilibrium interest rate (for a given money supply), the LM curve has a positive slope, as indicated in figure 3.19. Moving along the LM curve, shifting the LM curve If Y changes, the change in r from one equilibrium to the next is depicted as a move along the LM curve. A shift in the LM curve would occur if the equilibrium interest rate were to change for a reason other than a change in Y. Three main factors can shift the LM curve: changes in the price level P, an exogenous MP . In increase in the real demand for money MP , and a change in the real money supply each case the set of points that satisfy the conditions for money market equilibrium, i.e. the LM curve, moves. D 1. 118 S At a higher price level, there would be a higher transactions demand for money, implying a higher interest rate is necessary to yield money market equilibrium Chapter 3: The basic model II: financial institutions, money and interest rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 118 2019/12/17 09:15 (at the prevailing level of Y). The initial level of Y would then be paired with a different, higher level of r. ❐ Diagrammatically, this is shown as a horizontal, leftward shift of the LM curve. 2. At a higher level of real demand for money (linked to an exogenous factor, e.g. pessimistic expectations) there would be a higher precautionary demand for money, implying a higher equilibrium interest rate (at the prevailing level of Y). The initial level of Y would now be paired with a different, higher level of r. ❐ Diagrammatically, this is shown as a leftward shift of the LM curve. 3. At a higher level of the real money supply, and at the prevailing level of Y, a new and lower level of the interest rate would be necessary to attain equilibrium in the money market. The initial level of Y would now be paired with a different, lower interest rate r. ❐ Diagrammatically, this is shown as a rightward shift of the LM curve. When we analyse disturbances in an IS-LM diagram, this means: ❐ If the money supply is increased, it will shift the LM curve right. If the money supply contracts, it will shift the LM curve left. ❐ If the price level increases, the LM curve shifts left. If the price level decreases, the LM curve shifts right. ❐ If money demand increases for an exogenous reason, the LM curve shifts left. If it decreases for some reason, the LM curve shifts right. The case of a change in the real money supply is very important, especially in analysing the effects of monetary policy in the IS-LM diagram. How far will the LM curve shift? In the case of an expansion in the real money supply, the LM curve will shift right M 1 (horizontally) by a distance equal to the change in P multiplied by k . S How steep is the LM curve? The clue to the steepness of the LM curve lies in the reasoning behind the slope of the curve. The slope of the LM curve will depend on the magnitude of the change in equilibrium interest necessary to re-establish equilibrium in the money market, following a particular change in real income Y. A smaller change in r would imply a relatively flat LM curve; a relatively large change in r implies a relatively steep LM curve. Diagrammatically, this can be represented as shown in figure 3.19. The economic factors or characteristics that determine the slope of the LM curve are important. Reconsider the example of an increase in real income Y, the resulting increase in money demand, and the eventual increase in the equilibrium interest rate. How much will r change? Two factors or sensitivities are relevant: M 1. The income responsiveness of the demand for money (which is k in the P equation; also see the LM equation (3.6) in the maths box). This determines the extent to which monetary demand increases following a given increase in real income Y. ❐ If k, the income responsiveness of money demand, is high, money demand MP will increase (shift in the money market diagram) relatively a lot following an increase in Y, and the interest rate will have to be raised relatively a lot higher to restore equilibrium in the money market. This would make the LM curve relatively steep (its slope being kl ). D D 3.3 The IS-LM model as a powerful diagrammatical aid How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 119 119 2019/12/17 09:15 Figure 3.19 The slope of the LM curve r Slope of LM curve depends on how much r has to increase to re-establish money market equilibrium for a higher level of Y LM curve steeper r2 LM curve flatter r1 r0 (r0; Y0) Y0 Y Y1 ❐ If monetary demand is relatively unresponsive to changes in Y, meaning k is small, the LM curve will be relatively flat. MP equation; 2. The interest rate responsiveness of the demand for money (which is l in the also see the LM equation (3.6) in the maths box). Following a given increase in real money demand (a shift to the right in the money market diagram due to a higher Y), this responsiveness determines by how much the interest rate would have to increase to choke off the excess demand for money in the money market (for the existing real money supply). ❐ If the demand for money reacts strongly to interest rate changes – the interest responsiveness of money demand l is high – a relatively small interest rate increase would be sufficient to restore money market equilibrium. As a result, the LM curve k would be relatively flat (its slope l will be smaller). ❐ If the interest responsiveness of money demand is low, a relatively large interest rate increase would be necessary to restore money market equilibrium. Consequently, the LM curve would be relatively steep. D LM a mirror-image of the money demand curve? In terms of the effect of interest responsiveness the slope of the LM curve is the same as that of the money demand curve. MD curve and a ❐ A high interest responsiveness of money demand implies a relatively flat P relatively flat LM curve. MD curve and a ❐ A low interest responsiveness of money demand implies a relatively steep P relatively steep LM curve. 120 Chapter 3: The basic model II: financial institutions, money and interest rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 120 2019/12/17 09:15 To summarise: Effect on slope of LM curve → Flatter Low income responsiveness of money demand k High income responsiveness of money demand k → Steeper → Steeper Low interest responsiveness of money demand l → Flatter High interest responsiveness of money demand l Points off the LM curve Since the LM curve is a collection of pairs of Y and r that are consistent with money market equilibrium, any point off the LM is a disequilibrium point in the money market. At such a point, the interest rate is too high or too low to be compatible with the level of real income (and resultant level of money demand). For such a pairing of Y and r, aggregate monetary demand would not equal the money supply and there would not be equilibrium in the money market (or monetary sector). 3.3.6 IS and LM together – simultaneous equilibrium in the real and monetary sectors Section 3.3.1 intuitively described the use of the IS and LM curves to determine an overall equilibrium. Shifts in either curve would lead to a new equilibrium level of GDP and the interest rate. Graphically, this new equilibrium was to be found at the intersection point of the two curves. Why is equilibrium at the intersection? It was noted that the intersection between the two curves is the only point among the two sets of potential equilibrium points (denoted by the two curves) that produces equilibrium in both sectors. This statement needs to be formalised. The question is why the economy would be at, or would gravitate to, the point of intersection or simultaneous equilibrium. The reason is that at any point other than the intersection, forces would exist that would push the economy towards the intersection. Consider a point such as 1 (see figure 3.20), which is on the IS curve but not on the LM curve. Being a point on the IS curve, there would be equilibrium in the real sector (goods market), i.e. between total expenditure and total production. However, that particular pairing of the interest rate r1 and income Y1 would not Figure 3.20 Equilibrium in the IS-LM model produce equilibrium in the monetary r sector: any point off the LM curve is one of money market disequilibrium. LM curve In this case, for that particular interest r2 2 rate and income level, the resultant r1 1 money demand would be relatively depressed and would be lower than the r0 available money supply: there would 0 be an excess supply of money. Money market participants would hold more cash than desired at that interest rate. They would then tend to buy money IS curve market instruments (e.g. BAs), which Y1 Y0 Y2 Income Y would tend to push up the price of these 3.3 The IS-LM model as a powerful diagrammatical aid How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 121 121 2019/12/17 09:15 Simultaneous equilibrium in the goods and money markets π We have the formula for the IS curve: Y = KE(a + Ia + G – hr)……(3.3) and the formula for the LM curve: ( k 1 MS ) r= l Y – l P + lπ ……(3.6) Substituting (3.6) into (3.3) produces: ( [ ( )]) k 1 M Y = KE a + Ia + G – h l Y – l P + lπ S Solving for Y and simplifying produces: ( MS Y = 1 (a + Ia + G) + 2 P + lπ ) ……(3.7) where K 1 = KE hk 1 + El ……(3.7.1) K Eh 2 = l KEhk Equation 3.7 shows how the equilibrium level of real income Y depends on expenditure elements as well as real money supply – as captured in the IS and LM curves respectively. Note that 1, the expenditure multiplier that incorporates secondary effects, is very different from, and smaller than, KE, which is the expenditure multiplier in the model without a monetary sector (chapter 2). This demonstrates the constraining impact of the secondary effect in the money market on changes in Y. The equilibrium level of the real interest rate can be solved from (3.7) to produce: (M S ) r = 1 (a Ia G) 2 P + lπ ……(3.8) where kKE 1 = l K hk E 2 = l + K1 hk E ……(3.8.1) The equilibrium level of r likewise depends on expenditure elements and the real money supply. We will return to equation (3.7) in chapter 6 when we derive the aggregate demand (AD) curve. instruments and push down interest rates. As this happens, investment will increase and GDP will increase. In the diagram this would push the economy down along the IS curve towards the intersection. This process will continue until the intersection at point 0 is reached, because only then would there be no disequilibrium in the monetary sector, and thus no forces for change. A similar argument applies to a point such as 2, which is on the LM curve but not on the IS curve. While the money market would be in equilibrium, the real sector would not be. While there would be output (production) at the level of Y2, the interest rate r2 at point 2 would be too high for a goods market equilibrium to exist. The interest rate at point 2 is such that investment spending and durable consumption spending would be relatively low – too low to buy up all the production. There would be an excess supply of goods 122 Chapter 3: The basic model II: financial institutions, money and interest rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 122 2019/12/17 09:15 and inventories would increase. This would induce producers to cut back on production, moving the economy towards Y0. As this happens the interest rate would fall to r0. The process of cutting back will continue until GDP and aggregate expenditure is on par, which would only be when the economy has moved down the LM curve to meet the IS curve, i.e. at the intersection point 0. The point of intersection is the only point where both the real and the monetary sectors are in equilibrium, implying the absence of excess supply or excess demand in the goods or money markets that could induce a change in output, expenditure, interest rates or money market behaviour. If any disturbance changes conditions, the economy will not be at a simultaneous equilibrium any more. Graphically the disturbance will be seen in a shift in one or both of the IS and LM curves, implying a new intersection point. With the initial values of Y and r the economy would not be at the new intersection point and would be in disequilibrium. This will put into motion the kind of forces described above, moving the economy towards a new simultaneous equilibrium and point of rest at the new intersection point. The particular pairing of r and Y would persist until a new disturbance occurs. Analysing disturbances: shifting curves To use the model, one must be able to translate economic disturbances or policy steps into shifts in the curves: ❐ Shifts in the IS curve: any exogenous change in expenditure – in C, I, G or (X – M) – that boosts expenditure and thus Y would shift the IS curve towards the right. Any exogenous decrease in expenditure shifts the IS curve towards the left. – If G is increased, the IS curve shifts to the right. – If G declines, the IS curve would shift to the left. – If exports fall, the IS curve would shift to the left. – If taxes are reduced, this would lead to an exogenous boost in consumption, and the IS curve would shift to the right. – If restrictions are placed on imports, an exogenous drop in imports would result, (X – M) would increase, and the IS curve would shift to the right. – If investment falls due to a drop in investor confidence (i.e. at the prevailing interest rate level), it would shift the IS curve to the left. ❐ Shifts in the LM curve: the primary reason for a shift in the LM curve is an exogenous or policy change in the money supply (see also discussion below). – If the money supply expands, the LM curve shifts right. – If the money supply contracts, the LM curve shifts left. ! The IS-LM model, in particular, is a case where it is crucial to remember that a purely diagrammatical analysis – ‘that this or that curve has shifted’ – is no explanation of economic events. It only provides a way of checking your economic reasoning. ❐ Therefore, always use the diagram in conjunction with the appropriate economic chain reasoning. Use the three-diagram set outlined in chapters 2 and 3 where necessary. Examples 1. Suppose there is an increase in government expenditure. This would shift the IS curve to the right. As the diagram indicates, the equilibrium will change. The new 3.3 The IS-LM model as a powerful diagrammatical aid How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 123 123 2019/12/17 09:15 equilibrium shows a higher level of real income Y1, coupled with a higher interest rate r1. Figure 3.21 Fiscal expansion in the IS-LM model r LM curve In the context of the 45° diagram (see section 3.2.2), this would be depicted as an upward shift of the G r1 line and the aggregate expenditure 2 r0 line in the 45° diagram. The subse1 quent upswing in Y would increase monetary demand, depicted as a rightward shift of the MP curve in the money market diagram. The resulting increase in the interest rate would be transmitted to the real Y0 Y1 Y2 sector via reduced investment, implying a secondary, constraining effect on the economic expansion. New macroeconomic equilibrium point: Y1 and r1 D IS curve Income Y The IS-LM diagram in figure 3.21 summarises the simultaneity of these processes. In response to the increase in aggregate expenditure, income starts increasing. This is the primary effect. On the diagram this implies a force trying to move Y horizontally to the right (arrow 1). If nothing else were to change, Y would increase to Y2 (which would be the full multiplier effect as if there was no monetary sector; see equation 2.6 in chapter 2). However, as soon as Y starts increasing, the secondary, money-market effect kicks in. Money demand starts to increase, which causes the interest rate to start rising. The rising interest rate, in turn, causes investment to decrease. This partially offsets the expenditure boost due to the initial increase in government expenditure. This implies a force on Y in the direction of arrow 2. The net effect of these two forces is the bold blue arrow. Income never gets to Y2. Income only increases from Y0 to Y1 and the interest rate has increased from r0 to r1. ❐ We see that as the IS curve shifts, the equilibrium point moves along the LM curve. In terms of the chain reaction, the increase in government expenditure has the following effects: G ⇒ total expenditure ⇒ production ⇒ Y Primary effect M While Y ⇒ P ⇒ r ⇒ I ⇒ total expenditure ⇒ production ⇒ Y Interest rate change + Investment change and expenditure offset = Concurrent secondary effect D The economics behind the move from the initial to the new equilibrium point in the IS-LM diagram therefore is the entire sequence of events following an increase in G: the primary effect on Y (expansionary impact on real sector) plus the concurrent secondary effect on r and I (upward pressure on the interest rate in the monetary sector). ❐ This example compellingly illustrates ‘crowding out’, explained in section 3.2.2. 124 Chapter 3: The basic model II: financial institutions, money and interest rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 124 2019/12/17 09:15 Moving up the ramp This example shows the impact of the secondary or feedback effect via the monetary sector very graphically. It also provides a telling (if rather mechanical) analogy. Imagine the equilibrium point being pushed to the right by the forces generated by an increase in expenditure. However, the equilibrium point cannot move ahead in a horizontal direction. As it moves to the right, it is forced up a ‘ramp’ formed by the LM curve: the equilibrium point not only moves to the right, it also has to go up the slope of the LM curve. The ‘ramp’ exists due to the upward pressure on interest rates generated by the economic expansion. The eventual ‘horizontal’ change in Y is less than it would have been in the absence of a ramp (a secondary effect). Going up the slope saps the energy of the expansion. Which path to the new equilibrium? The path from one equilibrium to a next need not be exactly along the LM curve, as drawn in figure 3.21. The path of adjustment of the economy will depend on the speed of adjustment in each sector or market. r ❐ If the interest rate adjusts quickly LM curve relative to the goods market, the economy will loop, for instance, from points 1 to 2, and then again New macroeconomic 3 from 2 to 3 (black dotted arrows). equilibrium point ❐ If the money market adjusts 2 more slowly, a bigger loop from point 1 to 3 can materialise (blue dotted arrow). 1 ❐ To simplify the graphics, we will normally just indicate the net IS curve effect, i.e. a move along the LM curve from point 1 to point 3. Y 2. Suppose the money supply expands due to an expansionary monetary policy step such as a cut in the repo rate, which encourages more credit creation by banks. This would shift the LM curve to the right. As the diagram indicates, the equilibrium would change to one with a higher level of real income Y1 coupled with a lower interest rate r1. In the context of the 45° diagram, this would be depicted as a rightward shift of the M vertical P curve. This would decrease the interest rate. As intended, this will stimulate investment and, in turn, output and income Y (see section 3.2.1). However, this is not the end of the story – there will be a secondary money market effect. The upswing in Y will increase monetary demand – a rightward shift of the MP curve – resulting in upward pressure on the interest rate which will, by discouraging investment, imply a constraining effect on the economic expansion. S D The IS-LM diagram in figure 3.22 again captures the complex simultaneity of these processes. In response to the increase in real money supply, the real interest rate 3.3 The IS-LM model as a powerful diagrammatical aid How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 125 125 2019/12/17 09:15 starts to drop. This is the primary effect. In the diagram this implies a force trying to move r vertically downwards (arrow 1). If nothing else were to change, r would decrease to r2 to re-establish money market equilibrium on the new LM curve. Figure 3.22 Monetary expansion r LM curve r0 r1 New macroeconomic equilibrium point: Y1 and r1 1 r2 However, as soon as r starts 2 decreasing, investment is IS curve stimulated, as is production and real income. This causes the secondary, money-market Y0 Y1 Y effect to be activated. The demand for money starts to increase, causing upward pressure on the (still falling) interest rate. This implies a force on r and Y in the direction of arrow 2. The net effect of these two forces is the bold blue arrow. The interest rate never drops as far as r2. Income increases from Y0 to Y1 and the interest rate has decreased from r0 to r1. Investment has increased. ❐ Therefore, we see that as the LM curve shifts, the equilibrium point moves along the IS curve. While the main effect may be on the money market (the interest rate change), the transmission mechanism ensures that it also impacts on the real sector (real income Y). This diagram therefore illustrates the Keynesian transmission mechanism in the case of an expansionary monetary policy step. In both cases, the IS-LM mechanics serve as a concise rendition of the many economic relationships in the real and monetary sectors of the economy, including the interaction and feedback effects between them. In this sense, the IS-LM model integrates the real and monetary sectors. Which path to the new equilibrium? As before, the actual path from the initial equilibrium to the new one need not be exactly along the IS curve. The path of adjustment will depend on the speed of adjustment in each sector. ❐ If the interest rate drops quickly relative to the growth in investment and income in the goods market, a big loop from point 1 to 3 can materialise (blue dotted arrow). ❐ If investment reacts rapidly when interest rates start to drop, the economy will have smaller loops, for instance, from points 1 to 2, and then again from 2 to 3 (black dotted arrows). ❐ We will normally just indicate the net effect along the IS curve from point 1 to point 3. 126 r LM curve 1 2 3 IS curve Y Chapter 3: The basic model II: financial institutions, money and interest rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 126 2019/12/17 09:15 ✍ Suppose taxes are increased ⇒ _______________________________________________________________________________________ _______________________________________________________________________________________ IS-LM diagram: Suppose the cash reserve requirement is increased ⇒ _______________________________________________________________________________________ _______________________________________________________________________________________ IS-LM diagram: Suppose exports increase ⇒ _______________________________________________________________________________________ _______________________________________________________________________________________ IS-LM diagram: 3.3 The IS-LM model as a powerful diagrammatical aid How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 127 127 2019/12/17 09:15 The IS-LM is therefore a quick tool for checking one’s economic reasoning, indicating the basic direction of changes in Y and r. At the same time, however, one loses much of the diagrammatic richness of the traditional three-diagram model. Hence it is wise to open the IS-LM ‘black box’ and take out these three diagrams frequently as a way of making absolutely sure that your economic reasoning is correct. In a way, the very conciseness of the IS-LM model increases one’s chances of making a mistake. Of course, while one should never use the three diagrams without giving serious attention to the relevant economic chain reasoning, this is even truer in the case of the IS-LM model. The use of the latter model can easily degenerate into pure mechanical manipulation. Do not fall into this trap. 3.3.7 Different slopes and policy effectiveness The preceding discussion and examples illustrate the basic application of the IS-LM mechanics for disturbances originating in either the monetary or the real sector of the economy. An interesting dimension of the IS-LM mechanics is the effect of steeper or flatter curves on the magnitude of the resultant changes in Y and r. These results have an important implication for the effectiveness of policy. Thus we now reconsider the discussion in section 3.2 regarding the potency of (a) monetary policy and (b) fiscal policy. Various responsiveness parameters and multipliers were shown to be relevant. A few examples suffice to illustrate the basic points. How potent is monetary policy in affecting real income? Section 3.2.1 concluded that the potency and impact of a monetary policy step in the form of a money supply increase will depend on: ❐ the interest responsiveness of money demand l; ❐ the interest responsiveness of investment h, and ❐ the size of the expenditure multiplier KE. However, these factors also determine the slopes of the IS and LM curves (sections 3.3.3 and 3.3.5). This information can now be combined with the diagrammatical analysis to answer a question such as the following: what is the effect on real income Y of a one unit change in the money supply, given different slopes for the LM curve? ❐ For a similar but somewhat surprising analysis regarding the potency of an interest rate step, see section 3.3.8. Therefore, consider the impact of a given monetary policy stimulus in the form of a one unit real money supply increase. It will shift the LM curve to the right by a distance of MP . 10 Equilibrium Y will increase, combined with a decline in the real interest rate r. 1k S The diagram in figure 3.23 illustrates the influence of the slope of the LM curve on the change in real income Y (for the same horizontal shift of the LM curve): ❐ If the LM curve is relatively steep, the change in Y is relatively large – monetary policy is more potent. ❐ If the LM curve is flat, the change in real income Y is smaller – monetary policy is less potent. 10 Can you see why this is the value? Consider the formula for the LM curve (equation 3.6), but solve this formula for Y on the left-hand side. 128 Chapter 3: The basic model II: financial institutions, money and interest rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 128 2019/12/17 09:15 Figure 3.23 Monetary stimulus – influence of LM curve slope r For a similar horizontal shift a flatter LM produces a smaller change in both Y and r r LM shifts to the right LM shifts to the right r0 r1 r0 r1 IS curve Y0 Y1 IS curve Y Y0 Y1 Y The economic reason for the latter case lies in the interest responsiveness (parameter l) of the demand for money. If this responsiveness is low – the MP curve is relatively steep, as is the LM curve – the interest rate will drop much before money market equilibrium is restored (and all the additional money has been absorbed in portfolios). D The ‘liquidity trap’ An extreme case is that of a completely horizontal LM curve. In such a case, a monetary stimulus would have no effect whatsoever on income or the interest rate. All extra liquidity would be absorbed (‘trapped’) in portfolios without any impact on interest rates – there is an infinite demand for money (a horizontal MD curve). If this situation were to occur, monetary policy would be entirely impotent. In the 1940s and 1950s, some economists believed that this condition prevailed at low interest rates. Although for many years thought to be a theoretical oddity, the liquidity trap drew new attention first in the late 1990s in Japan when the Bank of Japan decreased its lending rate to banks to zero per cent, while still failing to stimulate lending. In 2008 the liquidity trap again drew attention when, in the face of the subprime crisis in the USA, banks were unwilling to lend to each other as they did not know the extent to which the balance sheets of borrowing banks were contaminated by bad assets. Effectively this meant that the interbank market came to a virtual standstill with interbank rates increasing significantly. In an effort to reignite lending, the major central banks reduced lending rates to banks significantly, some even providing guarantees for the interbank lending activities. For a time these steps were not altogether successful, meaning that central banks were unable to spur lending even at much reduced central bank lending rates. This event appeared to reaffirm the relevance of the liquidity trap theory. However, its relevance seems to be limited to periods characterised by crises of confidence. Under normal conditions the liquidity trap theory is not applicable. The 2007–08 financial crisis in the USA has shown that monetary policy impotence can also spring from behaviour that is reflected in a very steep IS curve, rather than a very flat LM curve. (See section 3.4.) The opposite extreme of the liquidity trap theory is the case of a vertical LM curve. Any monetary stimulus would have a maximum impact on real income. Therefore, monetary policy would be very potent in stimulating the economy. The vertical LM curve is called the Classical case, mainly because it seems to suggest a preference for monetary policy rather than fiscal policy. 3.3 The IS-LM model as a powerful diagrammatical aid How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 129 129 2019/12/17 09:15 The diagram in figure 3.24 illus­ trates the influence of the slope of the IS curve on the outcome (for the same horizontal shift of the LM curve): ❐ If the IS curve is flat, the change in real income is large – monetary policy is very potent. ❐ If the IS curve is relatively steep, the change in Y is smaller – monetary policy is less potent. Figure 3.24 Monetary stimulus – influence of IS curve slope r LM0 LM1 r0 If IS curve is flatter, change in Y is larger and change in r smaller IS curve ‘flat’ The economic reasons for the IS curve ‘steep’ latter case are as follows: ❐ If the interest responsiveness Y0 Y of investment (h in the invest­ ment equation) is high, invest­ ment will react strongly to the policy-induced drop in interest rates. ❐ If the expenditure multiplier KE is large, the increase in investment has a strong multiplier effect on real income Y. To summarise, the impact on real income of a monetary policy stimulus in the form of an increase in the money supply is larger if: ❐ the LM curve is relatively steep, and/or ❐ the IS curve is relatively flat. Similarly, such monetary policy is less potent in affecting real income if the IS curve is relatively steep and/or if the LM curve is relatively flat. (Similar types of conclusion can be made regarding the impact of monetary stimulation on the real interest rate.) These policy examples illustrate that the magnitude of changes in the interest rate or real income can differ greatly depending on the relative slopes of the two curves. However, this is a purely mechanical illustration. The question is: why or when would curves be steep or flat? Which factors determine the slope, and what is the economic interpretation of slopes? To answer these questions, we have to turn to more formal IS-LM theory. How potent is fiscal policy in affecting real income? Or, how strong is crowding out? Section 3.2.2 concluded that the potency and impact of fiscal expansion via increased government expenditure will depend on: ❐ the income responsiveness of money demand k; ❐ the interest responsiveness of money demand l; ❐ the interest responsiveness of investment h, and ❐ the size of the multiplier KE. Once again, these factors also determine the slopes of the IS and LM curves, as shown in sections 3.3.3 and 3.3.5. Combining the information about these discussions with the diagrammatical analysis, one can answer a question such as: what is the effect on real income Y of a one unit change in government expenditure (or in taxation), given different slopes for the IS curve? 130 Chapter 3: The basic model II: financial institutions, money and interest rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 130 2019/12/17 09:15 Therefore, consider an expansionary fiscal policy step, e.g. an increase of one unit (e.g. R1 m) in government expenditure. It would shift the IS curve horizontally to the right. Equilibrium Y will increase, combined with an increase in the real interest rate r. Figure 3.25 Fiscal stimulus – influence of LM curve slope r If LM curve is steeper change in Y is smaller and change in r larger: stronger secondary effect (crowding out) LM curve ‘steep’ LM curve ‘flat’ The diagram in figure 3.25 illustrates the influence of a flat or a steep LM curve on the change in Y: r0 ❐ If the LM curve is relatively steep, the change in Y is relatively small – fiscal policy is less potent. Crowding out IS1 IS0 is relatively strong (i.e. the ‘ramp’ is more steep). Y0 Y ❐ If the LM curve is relatively flat, the change in Y is relatively large – fiscal policy is more potent. Crowding out is relatively weak (i.e. the ‘ramp’ is less steep). The economic reasons for the latter case are as follows: ❐ If the income responsiveness of money demand (k in the money demand equation) is low, there will be a relatively small increase in the transactions demand for money when Y increases), and/or ❐ If the interest responsiveness l of money demand is high, a relatively small change in r will be sufficient to re-establish money market equilibrium. The Classical case again If the LM curve were vertical, fiscal expansion (e.g. an increase in G) would have no effect on real income. Fiscal policy would be totally impotent. Crowding out would be complete, and any increase in G would be exactly offset by an equal reduction in private spending (investment). If the LM curve were horizontal – the liquidity trap case – fiscal expansion would be enormously potent in stimulating real income. There would be absolutely no upward pressure on interest rates, and no crowding out whatsoever. Again, while these issues were part of the policy debate decades ago, today they merely serve to illustrate extreme theoretical cases (and to test your understanding of the theory). In reality, the IS and LM slopes lie between these two extremes (although they may differ widely from country to country). The pair of diagrams in figure 3.26 illustrates the influence of the slope of the IS curve on the outcome (for the same horizontal shift of the IS curve): ❐ If the IS curve is relatively flat, the change in real income Y is smaller – fiscal policy is less potent. ❐ If the IS curve is relatively steep, the change in Y is relatively large – fiscal policy is more potent. The latter result occurs since: ❐ The interest responsiveness h of investment is low – this reduces the restraining effect of the secondary interest rate increase on investment. 3.3 The IS-LM model as a powerful diagrammatical aid How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 131 131 2019/12/17 09:15 ❐ The expenditure multiplier KE is small – in the secondary phase this limits the restraining impact of the investment reduction on Y. However, the role of the multiplier is complex. It also affects the magnitude of the shift in this IS curve: a larger multiplier implies a bigger shift, the impact of which may outweigh the contrary effect that occurs via the slope of the IS curve. Figure 3.26 Fiscal stimulus – influence of IS curve slope r For a similar horizontal shift, a steeper IS produces a larger change in both Y and r r LM curve r1 LM curve r1 r0 r0 IS shifts to the right Y0 Y1 IS shifts to the right Y Y0 Y1 Y In summary, the impact of a given fiscal policy stimulus on real income is larger if: ❐ the LM curve is relatively flat (i.e. the ‘ramp’ is less steep, implying limited crowding out), and/or ❐ the IS curve is relatively steep. Conversely, fiscal policy is less potent if the IS curve is relatively flat and/or the LM curve is relatively steep. A similar analysis can be made regarding the impact on the interest rate following a fiscal policy step. 3.3.8 The potency of monetary policy when the interest rate is targeted The above discussion contrasts the result of a steep LM (with money demand not being interest sensitive), with a flat LM (with money demand being interest sensitive). The discussion compares the potency, under contrasting behavioural sensitivities, of monetary policy for equivalent increases in the money supply. ❐ In the money market diagram (see figure 3.8), this comparison relates to equivalent M horizontal dimensions of shifts (e.g. rightward) of the P line (measured by its position on the horizontal axis). ❐ In the IS-LM diagram, it relates to equivalent horizontal shifts of the LM curve (see figure 3.23). S The focus on such ‘money supply steps’ was very relevant up to the 1970s and 1980s and even the 1990s when many countries, including South Africa (from 1986 to 1997) had money supply targets. 132 Chapter 3: The basic model II: financial institutions, money and interest rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 132 2019/12/17 09:15 However, these days the focus of many central banks is to engineer desired interest rate changes. The question then is not the potency of a given ‘money supply step’, but what the potency of a given ‘interest rate step’ will be. Figure 3.27 Monetary expansion r LM0 Thus one must compare the potency (for contrasting behavioural sensitivities) of monetary policy for equivalent changes in the interest rate. ❐ In the IS-LM diagram, this is indicated by equivalent downward displacements of the LM curve (see figure 3.28). Thus it relates to equivalent vertical dimensions of right- or leftward shifts of the LM curve. (This is measured by the change in its intercept on the vertical axis.) LM1 Horizontal dimension of rightward shift of LM curve Income Y Vertical dimension of rightward shift of LM curve When the focus is on the comparative effectiveness of a given interest ratebased change, the outcome regarding the potency of monetary policy changes dramatically. ❐ The potency result becomes the opposite of that for equivalent money supply-based changes. In figure 3.28, the diagrams contrast the impact on Y, for different LM slopes, of equivalent interest rate-based steps. (This will usually be effected by equivalent changes in the repo rate, e.g. a decrease.) This interest rate step is shown as identical vertical drops in the LM curve. To someone accustomed to equivalent horizontal shifts of the LM curve this may look completely wrong. But it is not – and it is an important point for graphical analysis. Figure 3.28 Interest rate-based monetary expansion – influence of LM curve slope on change in real income r Equal vertical displacements of the LM curve r LM1 r0 LM2 r1 LM1 r0 r1 IS IS Y0 Y1 LM2 Y Y0 Y1 Y For equivalent vertical shifts in LM, a flat LM curve – which reflects a more interestsensitive money demand – will result in a larger increase in income compared to the case where the LM is steeper. Compare the changes from Y0 to Y1 in the two cases. 3.3 The IS-LM model as a powerful diagrammatical aid How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 133 133 2019/12/17 09:15 ❐ A flat LM curve makes such a monetary policy step more potent in changing Y. ❐ A steep LM curve would make an equivalent monetary policy step less potent in changing Y. This is the opposite of the conventional result, which was derived based on equivalent changes in the money supply. Note that this potency result also applies when measuring potency in terms of changing the market interest rate (the intersection of IS and LM). Compare the changes from r0 to r1 in the two cases. ❐ A flat LM curve makes such a monetary policy step more potent in changing Y. ❐ A steep LM curve would make an equivalent monetary policy step less potent in changing Y. Central bank behaviour that targets the interest rate can be described by a so-called monetary policy reaction function (see chapter 7). Interest rate-based changes are usually engineered by a change in the repo rate, but they can also be achieved through a money supply change: central banks change the money supply and/or the repo rate with whatever amount necessary to bring about the desired change. 3.4 Real-world application: The 2007–08 financial crisis – varying investor behaviour and impotent monetary policy In trying to analyse real-world economic events, an important point to bear in mind is that the values of the parameters in the behavioural equations such as h, the sensitivity of investment to changes in the real interest rate, or b, the propensity to consume, are not cast in stone. The same goes for the autonomous components of consumption and investment (the constant terms a and Ia in their respective equations). These parameters describe, or capture, human behaviour, expectations and sensitivities – and human behaviour can change. Changes in the behaviour of people would, therefore, change these parameters. Graphically, that would shift the IS and LM curves and/or change their slopes. This shows that such changing behaviour can affect the impact and potency of policy. A policy that was potent five years ago may become less potent now. An excellent example is how the 2007–08 financial crisis and its multi-year aftermath played out in the USA. It also illustrates the huge impact that problems in the financial system can have on the real economy and real people. In the words of Timothy Geithner, US Treasury Secretary during the Great Recession: I learned something valuable ... which is how fragile financial systems are, how connected they are to the economy, how hard it is to separate trauma in a financial system from trauma in the economy, how hard it is to protect the average person from financial panics. Time magazine, 26 May 2014, p. 48. In simplified terms the following occurred. The run-up: the dot-com bubble and expansionary monetary policy The financial crisis had a long run-up. Its roots can be found in the reaction of US monetary policy authorities to the bursting of the so-called dot-com bubble in 2000. During 1997–2000 share prices on the New York Stock Exchange and the NASDAQ stock market increased dramatically. Especially the share prices of internet-related companies 134 Chapter 3: The basic model II: financial institutions, money and interest rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 134 2019/12/17 09:15 rose far above their intrinsic value due to speculative trading and inflated expectations – a stock price ‘bubble’ developed. When the bubble burst and share prices fell, the NASDAQ index fell from 5047 in 2000 to 1114 in 2002, losing 78% of its value. The resulting fall in wealth caused a drop in consumer expenditure and hence a recession in the USA. To counter this shock, the US Federal Reserve or ‘Fed’ (the US central bank) lowered the Fed Funds rate (the policy rate in the USA) to push market interest rates down. The lower interest rates succeeded in restoring investment and economic growth. However, the lower interest rates also led to the next asset bubble, this time in the housing market. The housing bubble and the crisis in the financial system The housing bubble occurred because US banks, in reaction to the lower interest rates, simultaneously (and somewhat recklessly) lowered their requirements for approving mortgage loans. This quickly grew a market for so-called subprime borrowers (i.e. borrowers whose balance sheets are not strong enough to be ‘prime borrowers’). The risk of a subprime borrower not being able to repay a mortgage loan is significantly higher than that of a prime borrower. Banks subsequently repackaged these risky subprime mortgages together with prime mortgages and sold these mixed-risk packages to other financial institutions as low risk, prime securities. (Such a package is called a Mortgage-Backed Security, or MBS, and the repackaging is called securitisation.) Inexplicably, ratings agencies rated these packages as top-drawer AAA investments; thus, financial institutions were keen to invest in them. By 2007–08 many financial institutions experienced problems when large numbers of subprime borrowers defaulted on their mortgages. Institutions saw their balance sheets weaken to the point that Lehman Brothers went bankrupt in 2008 while most other large US investment banks only survived because the US government and Federal Reserve, as an emergency measure, extended very large loans to them at low interest rates. Despite these measures, the financial stress experienced by these institutions marked the start of the worldwide financial crisis. Because so many banks and other financial institutions were affected by MBS holdings, widespread uncertainty and a lack of trust in the banking and financial system developed. Financial institutions became unwilling to extend loans. Households and businesses found it difficult to borrow, and consumer and business expenditure dropped. Households and businesses also preferred to reduce their debt before investing. Likewise, the uncertainty reduced the willingness of potential investors to invest. As a result, the US economy entered a recession. The monetary policy reaction: ‘quantitative easing’ (QE)11 The Fed responded by implementing three waves of quantitative easing from November 2008 to October 2014. In effect the Fed started buying up huge volumes of government bonds as well as MBSs from financial institutions, thereby injecting trillions of dollars of money into the financial system. (See section 9.7 for more detail on the nature of this monetary policy step, which is almost similar to open market transactions.) This monetary 11 In 2008 the US government also implemented the Troubled Asset Relief Program (TARP), in terms of which the Treasury spent $350 billion to buy MBSs and other financial assets (and later also equity) from troubled financial institutions such as AIG and Citigroup. The aim of the program was to stabilise these institutions by strengthening their balance sheets. It amounts to an injection of $350 billion into US financial markets, and thus TARP is analytically more or less equivalent to QE, as shown in figure 3.29. Hence we do not show TARP separately. 3.4 Real-world application: The 2007–08 financial crisis How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 135 135 2019/12/17 09:15 expansion drove the nominal Fed Funds rate down to 0.25%. With inflation very low, the real interest rate came close to 0%. To its surprise the Fed found that investment did not respond and remained flat. The US recession (which infected the rest of the world) continued for several years. The question is why QE was so ineffective, if macroeconomic theory tells us that moneysupply expansion, by reducing interest rates, would stimulate investment and consumption expenditure, and thereby boost GDP growth. For the first round of monetary stimulus (after the dot-com collapse) the theory appeared to be correct. So what happened with QE? Understanding the crisis in the IS-LM model: varying slopes and policy impotency The IS/LM model can be used to understand why the US Federal Reserve failed in its efforts to stimulate economic activity. The reason is the variable, even fickle, nature of investment behaviour in particular, which manifested during the financial crisis. The IS/LM model in figure 3.29 applies to the USA. Suppose that, prior to the financial crisis, there is equilibrium in both the money market and the goods market at point 0, where LM0 intersects with IS0. The real interest rate equals r0 and output equals Y0. Figure 3.29 The financial crisis and quantitative easing in the USA IS shifts left and rotates clockwise; a reverse rotation occurs later on r IS1 LM shifts left initially, then right again in the QE phase, and left if QE is phased out IS0 IS2 LM1 LM0 0 r0 r1 r4 1 4 r3 3 r2 2 Y1 Y2 Y0 ;Y3 Y4 Y LM2 0 = Initial equilibrium Y0 r0 1 = New equilibrium Y1 r1 after LM shifts left and IS shifts and rotates clockwise. Recession. 2 = Post-QE equilibrium Y2 r2 after QE monetary stimulus: interest rates collapse, but expenditure is unresponsive. Monetary policy impotent. Still recession. 3 = Equilibrium Y3 r3 after fiscal expansion (IS shifts right to IS2). Recession over. 0 = Final equilibrium Y0 r0 if confidence returns and fiscal stimulus withdrawn (IS rotates and moves back to IS0) and QE is reversed (LM shifts left to LM 0). 4 = Equilibrium Y4 r4 occurs if QE is not phased out. Risk of further bubbles. The impact of the financial crisis When the financial crisis broke out, two things happened. First, financial institutions became unwilling to extend and roll over loans. As the quantity of loans extended shrank, their balance sheets shrank and thus the money supply shrank. In figure 3.29 this is shown by a leftward shift of the LM curve from LM0 to LM1. Secondly, households cut back their autonomous consumption a and companies cut back their autonomous investment Ia. With investors also uncertain about the future, 136 Chapter 3: The basic model II: financial institutions, money and interest rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 136 2019/12/17 09:15 companies cut back autonomous investment even further. These cutbacks would reflect in a leftward shift of the IS curve. But that is not all. The diagram also shows the slope of the IS curve becoming steeper. Recall that its slope reflects the sensitivity of investment to changes in the interest rate, h, as well as the marginal propensity to consume, b. When uncertainty increases, investors become less sensitive to interest rate changes: h falls and the IS curve becomes steeper. Likewise, when households’ marginal propensity to consume out of income is reduced (when they decide to rather repay debt), b falls – which also causes IS to become steeper. Therefore, with the drop in autonomous consumption and investment as well as h and b, the IS curve shifts and rotates – it changes from IS0 to IS1. Given these moves of the IS and LM curves, a new equilibrium would settle at point 1, with the interest rate at r1 and real output much lower at Y1. The failed policy response: QE and thereafter To counter this contraction in output, the US Federal Reserve massively expanded the money supply in three waves of quantitative easing. These steps are shown as a shift of the LM curve from LM1 to LM2, intersecting IS1 at a new equilibrium point 2. At this point the real interest rate r2 is close to 0%. However, despite the huge drop in the interest rate, the steepness of IS1 implies that the output level only increases minimally from Y1 to Y2 – still far below the pre-crisis level Y0. Being stuck at Y2 while the interest rate level has collapsed to r2 shows how monetary policy became impotent due to the changing behaviour of economic agents. Due to fear and uncertainty they all but stopped responding to a drop in the rate of interest. And, since nominal interest rates cannot go below 0%, monetary policy could not stimulate the economy to grow beyond Y2. The only alternative for the US government was to use expansionary fiscal policy, running much larger budget deficits. The fiscal stimulus was supposed to shift the IS curve from IS1 to IS2, resulting in the interest rate increasing to r3 and output to Y3, i.e. back to the initial output level Y0 – but with a much-reduced rate of interest (equilibrium point 3). (At the time of writing this fiscal policy had not been entirely successful in stimulating the US economy – implying that the IS curve was still lying somewhere between IS1 and IS2.) The aftermath: back to normal? Once confidence returns to the US economy fiscal stimulus can be withdrawn. While the latter will shift the IS from IS2 towards IS1, the return of confidence will shift and rotate the IS curve back from IS1 to IS0. Reversing the quantitative easing will shift the LM curve leftward from LM2 back towards LM0 – possibly reaching equilibrium close to equilibrium point 0 where it all started. Were the quantitative easing not to be reversed, an equilibrium would occur at point 4. While output Y4 would be much higher than the pre-crisis level, the real interest rate r4 would be much lower. This could create a renewed risk of a bubble and excessive borrowing. To push the interest rate up to a less risky level (such as r0), the quantitative easing would need to be reversed, at least partially, to get LM to a position such as LM0. (To suppress any tendency towards excessive borrowing it might even be necessary to push the interest rate noticeably higher than r0. Graphically this means shifting LM even further left.) 3.4 Real-world application: The 2007–08 financial crisis How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 137 137 2019/12/17 09:15 International repercussions: how did the financial crisis affect South Africa? Due to limitations of space, the knock-on effects of the financial crisis on South Africa cannot be analysed here. It suffices to say that the main effects stem from a decline in GDP in the USA (initially, and later also in Europe) and hence in their imports from other countries, including South Africa. The analysis of the impact of these changes on GDP and interest rates in the IS-LM diagram is left to the reader as an exercise. But that is not the whole story. The financial crisis also led to foreign investor nervousness in the USA, Europe and Asia. This can spill over into a wariness to invest in emerging markets, which could have an impact on capital inflows into South Africa. To understand these, one has to study the international dimensions of the macroeconomy – the topic of the next chapter. * * * This completes the discussion of the IS-LM model. It will be encountered again in chapter 4, where it will be analysed in the context of an open economy and expanded on by the addition of a third curve, the BP (or balance of payments) curve. This curve will give information regarding the external balance of the economy, and augments the discussion on the internal balance (as shown by the IS-LM equilibrium). 3.5 Analytical questions and exercises 1. Suppose exports increase, what will be the effect on income and the interest rate if the income responsiveness of money demand is low compared to when the income responsiveness of money demand is high? 2. Suppose government expenditure increases, what will be the effect on income and the interest rate if the income responsiveness of money demand is high compared to when the income responsiveness of money demand is low? 3. Suppose tax rates increase, what will be the effect on income and the interest rate if the interest rate responsiveness of investment is low compared to when the interest rate responsiveness of investment is high? 4. Suppose autonomous investment increases, what will be the effect on income and the interest rate if the interest rate responsiveness of investment is high compared to when the interest rate responsiveness of investment is low? 5. Use chain reactions and the IS-LM model to explain and illustrate the impact of an increase in the repo rate on national income and the interest rate. 6. Use chain reactions and the IS-LM model to explain and illustrate the impact of a decrease in the cash reserve requirement on national income and the interest rate. 7. Use chain reactions and the IS-LM model to explain and illustrate the impact of a decrease in taxes on national income and the interest rate. 8. In question 6 of chapter 2, the puzzling lack of private investment after 2010 was noted. Consider your response again, now also noting the level of interest rates in the period after 2008 compared to earlier periods. Would you change your explanation, or perhaps add to it? Can interest rate levels explain the observed lacklustre investment behaviour? Analyse and discuss. 9. Use chain reactions and the IS-LM model to explain and illustrate the impact of the increase in the gold price on national income and the interest rate. 10. Use chain reactions and the IS-LM model to explain and illustrate the impact of a stimulating fiscal policy on national income and the interest rate. 138 Chapter 3: The basic model II: financial institutions, money and interest rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 138 2019/12/17 09:15 The basic model III: the foreign sector 4 After reading this chapter, you should be able to: ■ explain the behaviour of international trade in goods and services (i.e. imports and exports), and foreign investment and lending (international capital flows); ■ appraise the role and importance of the balance of payments, the current account, the financial account and foreign reserves; ■ assess and explain movements in exchange rates, including the practical, everyday determination of these rates in foreign exchange markets; ■ assess the external implications of domestic economic disturbances and fluctuations; ■ compose chain reactions that show how external disturbances impact on domestic financial markets as well as the real economy, and evaluate these with graphical aids; ■ analyse the role of the balance of payments adjustment mechanism in creating cyclical forces; and ■ unravel key linkages between foreign interest rates, the gold price, the rand and the dollar. While the South African economy is relatively strong in the African context, in the world context it is small. Owing to the openness of the South African economy, it is extremely vulnerable to external shocks, and foreign factors often dominate the economic news. Therefore a sound understanding of the linkages between the national economy and foreign economic relations is essential if we are to grasp events in the South African economy. The ‘closed’ model of the economy, as introduced in the previous chapters, must therefore be amended. This chapter presents the main elements of a Keynesian macroeconomic model (or theory) for an open economy. ✍ What percentage of GDP is exported? Which are the most important products that local producers export from South Africa? Which countries are our main trading partners? ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ What percentage of GDE is spent on imported products? Which are the most important products imported by South Africans? From which countries mainly? ______________________________________________________________________________________ See Mohr (2019) Economic Indicators, sections 7.2 and 7.3. Chapter 4: The basic model III: the foreign sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 139 139 2019/12/17 09:15 The location of this topic in the circular flow diagram (compare pp. 73, 76) International capital flows Ex FOREIGN COUNTRIES po rts Ex ch a rat nge e Im po FINANCIAL INSTITUTIONS rts Disposable income FIRMS HOUSEHOLDS GOVERNMENT Some preliminary definitions The balance of payments (BoP) is an accounting record of a country’s involvement in international trade (exports and imports) and international capital flows. The former category of transactions is indicated on the current account of the balance of payments and the latter on the financial account. The most important international ‘price’ is the exchange rate. This denotes the international exchange value (or external value) of, for example, the South African rand against another currency such as the US dollar, e.g. $1 = R10.00 or £1 = R17.00. (The latter represents the indirect way of quoting the exchange rate. The direct way would be the other way around, i.e. R1 = $0.10 or R1 = £0.06.) Another relevant variable is the price ratio between average price levels in the home P P country, e.g. South Africa, and those in the rest of the world: SA Foreign The exchange rate and the price ratio can be combined into one concept, the real effective exchange rate, denoted by ( the Greek letter theta). (The term ‘effective’ indicates an average exchange rate; see section 4.3.2 on exchange rate definitions.) It is defined as:1 1 PSA P Foreign Foreign SA = Average exchange rate P = Average exchange rate in direct form P 1 140 Note that in many USA and UK textbooks the direct way of expressing the exchange rate is used, also in these formulas. In general one should always be very careful when working with formulas containing an exchange rate. Chapter 4: The basic model III: the foreign sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 140 2019/12/17 09:15 ✍ What are the latest figures for the balance on the current account, the financial account and the BoP? ______________________________________________________________________________________ What is the current exchange rate of the rand against the US dollar, the British pound, the Euro and the Japanese yen? DATA TIP ______________________________________________________________________________________ Warning: Data on foreign economic transactions are almost as complex as data on the government sector (also see chapter 2). ❐ Different institutions, e.g. the SA Reserve Bank and the SA Revenue Service (Customs and Excise division), gather and publish data for different purposes and in various ways. ❐ At least three sets of data are available: national accounts data, balance of payments data and trade statistics. They may use different terms or may include different elements or have different frequencies, or may be only in nominal or real terms. ❐ Before June 1999, data on imports and exports in balance of payments tables in the Quarterly Bulletin of the Reserve Bank differed from data in the national accounts tables. However, in the revised data system used since June 1999 these figures are exactly the same, removing the ambiguities in Reserve Bank foreign sector data. The two sets of tables do use different terms for elements such as labour income flows, though. ❐ The foreign trade statistics of the SA Revenue Service (Customs and Excise division) pertain to trade in goods only (including gold). They are published monthly. For macroeconomic and expenditure analysis, it is usually sufficient to use national accounts data on imports and exports. If one wishes to analyse the current account of the balance of payments or capital flows, though, the balance of payments table is more comprehensive. (See other explanatory boxes that follow.) Exchange rate data can be found in the section on ‘International economic relations’ in the Quarterly Bulletin. This section also contains a table ‘Gold and other foreign reserves’. Data on the balance of payments and exchange rates can be found on the Reserve Bank website (www.resbank.co.za), while data on trade statistics can be found on the website of the South African Revenue Service (www.sars.co.za) under ‘Customs and Excise’. International comparisons of economic data are difficult and can easily lead to absurd conclusions. Be careful, especially as far as exchange rate conversions of variables such as GDP, wage levels or petrol prices are concerned. Comparisons of rates of change (GDP growth rate, inflation rate) and ratios (tax ratio, import ratio) are less risky, although still subject to differences in definition and calculation. (An interesting website is 'World in Figures' of the Economist magazine at https://worldinfigures.com or www.economist.com. Also see Mohr (2019) Economic Indicators, chapter 7.) 4.1 Background – why trade internationally? One way to study international economic relations is to attempt to understand why countries engage in international trade and to explain the pattern of imports and exports. (For example, why does South Africa import clothes pegs – surely they can be manufactured locally?) Such questions are explored in courses on international 4.1 Background – why trade internationally? How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 141 141 2019/12/17 09:15 economics. In macroeconomics these questions are not considered further. Consequently, we shall analyse only total import and export levels, ignoring the microeconomic details of trade patterns. Who are South Africa’s main trading partners? South Africa's trade with regions and top 10 partners: shares in 2018 and 1994 Import share 2018 1994 Export share 2018 1994 Asia 45.4% 27.8% Asia 31.3% 26.8% European Union 28.5% 46.0% Africa 26.5% 13.5% Africa 11.9% 3.4% European Union 23.5% 31.4% NAFTA* 7.0% 12.9% SADC 22.8% 11.2% SADC 6.5% 2.5% NAFTA* 7.3% 11.1% China 18.3% 1.8% China 9.2% 0.8% Germany 9.9% 16.6% Germany 7.5% 6.4% USA 5.9% 11.4% USA 6.7% 10.1% Saudi Arabia 5.8% 0.1% United Kingdom 5.0% 9.5% India 4.1% 0.6% Japan 4.8% 8.5% Nigeria 4.1% 0.0% India 4.7% 0.8% United Kingdom 3.5% 12.0% Botswana 4.3% 0.0% Thailand 3.1% 0.8% Namibia 3.8% 0.0% Japan 3.1% 10.0% Mozambique 3.4% 2.6% Italy 2.7% 4.0% Netherlands 3.3% Total imports (R) 1.24 trillion 81.8 billion Total exports (R) 1.15 trillion 3.3% 65.1 billion Source: Department of Trade and Industry (www.thedti.gov.za). Note the persistence of some large countries such as the USA, UK, Germany and Japan – but also the new dominance of China and growing role of India, Saudi Arabia and Nigeria. The shares of the Asian bloc, Africa and SADC have grown since 1994, while that of the European Union and North America have shrunk. (NAFTA = USA, Canada and Mexico) 4.2 Imports, exports and capital flows As indicated in chapter 1, imports and exports are important for the macroeconomy since they impact directly on total expenditure. ❐ Exports X imply an injection of expenditure (by foreigners) into the domestic expenditure flow, and imports M imply a leakage from the expenditure flow to the rest of the world. ❐ Net exports (X – M) – i.e. the net injection – constitute a direct component of total expenditure = C + I + G + (X – M). Therefore it is essential to understand the behaviour of X and M as well as their consequences for the state of the economy. International payments relating to imports and exports are recorded in the current account of the balance of payments (BoP). The gap between real exports and imports is net exports. It differs from the current account because the current account also includes factor payments (e.g. dividends, wages) paid across borders. A close correlation between import fluctuations and GDP fluctuations can be observed. 142 Chapter 4: The basic model III: the foreign sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 142 2019/12/17 09:15 Figure 4.1 Exports and imports (in real terms – 2010 prices) 1 200 1 000 800 Real imports of goods and services R billion 600 Real exports of goods and services 400 200 Real exports minus real imports 0 2018/01 2016/03 2015/01 2013/03 2012/01 2010/03 2009/01 2007/03 2006/01 2004/03 2003/01 2001/03 2000/01 1998/03 1997/01 1995/03 1994/01 1992/03 1991/01 1989/03 1988/01 1986/03 1985/01 –200 Source: South African Reserve Bank (www.resbank.co.za). The graph in figure 4.1 depicts the movements in real imports and exports as well as net exports since 1980. What is notable from the graph is that for long stretches of time real imports were less than real exports. This was the case in the period 1985 to 1994. Since 2003, imports have exceeded exports by a substantial margin, leaving net exports negative. Also note that, since the early 1990s, both real imports and real exports have increased significantly. Which products comprise the main elements of South African imports and exports? The main export categories (2018) are precious metals and gems (18%), iron and other ores (13%), vehicles (11%), mineral fuels (11%), iron, steel and aluminium (9%) and machinery and equipment (8%). The main import categories are machinery and equipment (22%), mineral fuels including oil (18%) and vehicles (8%), and also plastic products, pharmaceuticals, technical and medical apparatus, and chemical products. Capital and intermediate goods represent a large portion of imports. Therefore the causal link between changes in total production and imports is likely to be strong (see below). 4.2.1 Imports (M) Imports concern the purchase of foreign products (both consumer goods and capital goods). The major share of South African imports comprises machinery and capital items; oil is also an important item. Expenditure on imports by all participants is included: households, business enterprises, the government sector, government corporations, etc. 4.2 Imports, exports and capital flows How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 143 143 2019/12/17 09:15 Which factors determine imports? PSA M = f(YDSA; P ; rand; ...) Foreign + + + A part of import expenditure involves the purchase of imported consumer goods. Therefore, like consumption C, it depends positively on disposable income YD and thus on total income Y. Furthermore, a very large portion of import expenditure is on production inputs (machinery and intermediate inputs, often high-tech items). Since increases in output require more inputs, the demand for imported inputs is strongly influenced by total production Y (see previous box). In both cases, total income is a crucial determinant. This suggests the concept of marginal import propensity. (Can you define it?) One can then write a simple import function as: M = ma + mY + ... ...... (4.1) where m is the marginal import propensity. If national income Y increases, imports will increase. An upswing (or downswing) in the economy frequently causes an increase (or decrease) in imports. This means that imports behave pro-cyclically: imports increase and decrease concurrently with the business cycle. ✍ General tax increases will affect import expenditure positively/negatively (choose one alternative). Why? ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ Rising imports can be a symptom of (too) good times. Why? ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ Restrictive policy often causes imports to decline. Why? ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ A second factor influencing the decision to import is the price of imported goods relative to the price of locally produced goods. (In the case of essential items that are not produced in South Africa, such as oil or high-tech machinery, one may have less freedom of choice; thus, a lower price sensitivity is likely.) ❐ The relevant variable is the price ratio, defined above. The expected relationship is positive, since a higher price ratio (e.g. due to increasing South African prices) is likely to encourage imports (and discourage exports, see section 4.2.2). The exchange rate is a third important factor determining imports. This follows from the fact that the exchange rate determines the price of an imported product in South African rands. For example: if the external value of the rand is $1 = R10.50 and an imported video recorder costs $300, the price in rand is R3 150. Rands have to be exchanged for dollars to buy the machine; therefore the rate of exchange determines the effective rand price of the imported item. 144 Chapter 4: The basic model III: the foreign sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 144 2019/12/17 09:15 ✍ How does South Africa’s inflation rate compare with those of our main trade partners? Is this likely to encourage or discourage imports? What about exports? (Explain your answer.) ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ A higher price ratio will make local producers less/more (choose one alternative) competitive relative to foreign producers (import competitors). If the external value of the rand increases – e.g. when the rand strengthens from $1 = R10.50 to $1 = R10.00 – imports are encouraged because the rand price of imports effectively de­ clines. The international purchas­ ing power of the South African rand has increased. Therefore the likely relationship between M and the rand is positive. ❐ Be very careful here. If you think in terms of the actual number 10.50 or 10.00, the relationship is negative: a stronger rand means the exchange rate number decreases – which leads to an increase in imports M. Terms of trade is a concept similar to the price ratio. It is published in the Quarterly Bulletin of the Reserve Bank and is calculated as the export price index divided by an import price index, expressed as an index. A weakening of the terms of trade means that South African export prices have decreased relative to the prices of imported products: the country earns less from exports, compared to what it needs to pay for imports. See Mohr (2019) Economic Indicators, section 7.4. Each international transaction actually comprises a double transaction: the necessary foreign exchange or currency is bought first, and then the item is bought with that foreign currency. It also means that the demand for foreign currency is a derived demand, i.e. it is derived from the demand for the products that importers want to buy. The price ratio and the exchange rate jointly determine the real effective exchange rate , defined above. The real effective exchange rate can be thought to impact on m, the marginal propensity to import. If increases – due to an increase in the external value of the rand, or an increase in the price ratio – m will increase, and vice versa. The argument is that changes in will affect a country’s willingness to import goods from abroad – i.e. the portion of every extra R1 of income that will be spent on imported goods and services. So we can write the marginal propensity to import as being dependent on the value of , i.e. m(). ❐ In thinking and reasoning about open economy chain reactions it will often be better to work in terms of the constituent elements of , i.e. the exchange rate and the price P ratio P . One must be able to work in both formats. SA Foreign Other factors that can influence imports are trade policy (import taxes, import tariffs or quotas, etc.), trade sanctions or boycotts. 4.2 Imports, exports and capital flows How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 145 145 2019/12/17 09:15 ✍ Depreciation or devaluation? If the rand weakens, i.e. its external value decreases, it is said that the rand ‘depreciates’. (The opposite is an ‘appreciation’.) What does devaluation mean? And revaluation? If you do not know, read section 4.3.2. A more complete import function thus would be: M = ma + m()Y ...... (4.2) In this form, the real effective exchange rate Figure 4.2 The import function – and thus the price ratio and the exchange E rate – are built into the import propensity parameter. (While we will not always write m as m() in diagrams and mathematical expressions, its presence must always be remembered.) M 5 ma 1 mY ❐ An increase in – due to a strengthening m a rand and/or a higher price ratio – will encourage imports, i.e. the import propensity m will be higher. ❐ The import function can be depicted in the 45° income–expenditure diagram as a positively sloped line/curve, as in figure 4.2. Income Y If Y increases, the ensuing increase in M will be apparent as a move along the M curve. ❐ An increase in implies a steeper import curve. If any of the elements of the real effective exchange rate – the price ratio or the exchange rate – changes, the import function will rotate. ❐ Trade policy steps such as an import tax, tariff or quota or trade sanctions will shift the import curve up or down. 4.2.2 Exports (X) Insufficient domestic production of exports can Since South African exports are occur if there are not enough South African goods actually imports by other countries to meet export demand. However, at this stage we from South Africa, the explanation assume that there are no supply-side restrictions. of exports is relatively simple. (This will change in chapter 6.) However, as a rule, Accordingly, South African exports aggregate supply bottlenecks very rarely constitute are determined by factors similar a real constraint on export levels – except in the to those concerning imports. It is case of agricultural products, where a drought can important to realise, though, that have a disastrous effect on exports. It is quite simple the export decision is primarily taken to analyse the expected effects of a drought (or a in another country, i.e. a South miners’ strike) on export performance, and hence on African producer’s supply of export aggregate economic performance. goods occurs on demand from foreigners. It specifically does not depend on domestic income or production (GDP) to any significant extent. 146 Chapter 4: The basic model III: the foreign sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 146 2019/12/17 09:15 Which factors determine exports? Exports depend not only on foreign income levels (YForeign or Yf ), but also on the price ratio (terms of trade) and the exchange rate. Thus: PSA P ; rand; ...) X = f(YForeign; Foreign The expected signs (+ or –) of the variables follow from arguments similar to those with regard to imports. Exports will have a negative relationship with the price ratio – relatively higher domestic prices will discourage exports. And they will have a negative relationship with the value of the rand – a weaker rand will make exports cheaper for foreigners. Similar to our handling of the import function above, the real effective exchange rate can also be brought into the slope parameter of an export function: X = va + v()Yf + … ...... (4.3) The parameter v is not interpreted as a marginal propensity, but as an indication of the home country’s share of world trade. A higher value of v will reflect a higher share of world trade, if Yf represents world income. An increase in – due to a stronger rand or a higher price ratio – will discourage exports (imports by foreign countries from South Africa), and thus reduce our share of world trade v. Graphically, in the 45° diagram, the X curve is simply a horizontal line (see figure 4.3). ❐ A change in foreign income levels (e.g. upswings or downswings in the economies of major trading partners) will shift the export curve up or down correspondingly. ❐ A change in the trade share v (due to a change in the real effective exchange rate ) will also shift the export curve. ✍ What is the impact of relatively high domestic inflation on South African exports? ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ What does the expression ‘we are pricing ourselves out of world markets’ mean? ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ Net exports Putting both the X and the M curves on the 45° diagram enables us also to observe net exports. Net exports is the numerical difference between imports and exports, i.e. (X – M). Plotting that difference against income gives us the net exports (X – M) curve. As shown in figure 4.3, net exports (X – M) is a line with a negative slope. Observing the difference between the X and M curves relative to income shows why trade deficits (when the imports of goods exceeds the export of goods) are more prone to occur at higher levels of income than lower levels of income. 4.2 Imports, exports and capital flows How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 147 147 2019/12/17 09:15 Figure 4.4 A change in net exports Figure 4.3 Exports and net exports E E C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 M)0 Imports M Exports X Net exports (X 2 M) C 1 I 1 G 1 (X 2 M)1 (X 2 M) Y Y Income Y Any change in one or more of the factors that determine X and/or M will imply a change in (X – M), which – as a direct component of total expenditure – will cause a change in the real economy (with the usual multiplier effect, as in figure 4.4). For example: Suppose the rand appreciates ⇒ effective price of imports declines (and the effective price of SA exports for foreigners increases) ⇒ imports are encouraged and exports discouraged ⇒ (X – M) declines ⇒ total expenditure declines ⇒ production discouraged ⇒ GDP and Y decline. ✍ Foreign inflation declines ⇒ ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ Upswing in the USA ⇒ ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ What is the difference between ‘Expenditure on Gross Domestic Product’ and ‘Gross Domestic Expenditure’ in the national accounts? Why is this difference important? ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ If you do not know, read addendum 5.1 (chapter 5). Remarks 1. Conceptually (X – M) also can be called the trade balance. If X exceeds M there is a trade surplus; if import payments exceed export earnings, there is a trade deficit. However, the trade balance includes only imports and exports of goods. Services are excluded. Therefore the trade balance is also called the goods balance. 148 Chapter 4: The basic model III: the foreign sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 148 2019/12/17 09:15 2. If trade in services – payments and receipts for services such as international tourism, transport, financial and insurance services – is included, one gets ‘net exports’. ❐ In our macroeconomic reasoning and chain reactions this is how we interpret (X – M). 3. Net exports still exclude inflows and outflows of income payments, i.e. compensation of employees as well as returns on investment (dividends and interest earned abroad). Income payments thus reflect trade in factors of production – labour and capital. Also excluded are international transfers. ❐ These excluded items are denoted as ‘invisible trade’. What is the difference between the trade balance, net exports and the current account in actual data? The numerical difference between net exports and the current account can be quite large, but also quite variable between quarters and years. The table below shows net exports and the current account in 2018. The two balances differ markedly. It shows how ‘invisible trade’ can affect the current account significantly, often negatively. For example, in 2018, the net figure for income receipts and payments was R97 billion – R251 billion = –R154 billion and for exports (R1 176 + R72 + R210) billion – (R1 223 – R218) billion = –R17 billion. Income payments always exceed income receipts by far. Thus the net income outflows aggravated the negative payments balance before transfers. DATA TIP Note that in the Quarterly Bulletin BoP data are recorded only in nominal terms, whereas the Bulletin’s national accounts (SNA) data are published in both nominal and real terms. The table below is in nominal terms. Note that, if income receipts and payments are excluded from the balance of payments column, the export and import totals are the same as in the national accounts column. A trade balance (or goods balance) can also be calculated. However, trade balance figures are also published by the South African Revenue Service (Customs and Excise Division) on a monthly basis. These say little about macroeconomic trends, since they fluctuate a lot between months. Second, annual totals also differ from SNA and balance of payments numbers. For macroeconomic analysis, it is best to use the SNA data. National accounts 2018 R million Balance of payments 2018 R million Exports of goods and services 1 457 641 Merchandise exports Exports of goods 1 247 226 Net gold exports 71 678 210 415 Service receipts 210 415 Less: Imports of goods and services –1 440 883 Income receipts 96 507 Imports of goods –1 222 944 Less: Merchandise imports –1 222 944 –217 939 Less: Payment for services –217 939 Less: Income payments –250 552 Exports of services Imports of services Exports minus Imports 16 748 Current transfers (net receipts (+)) Balance on current account 1 175 547 –35 674 –172 962 Source: South African Reserve Bank (www.resbank.co.za). 4.2 Imports, exports and capital flows How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 149 149 2019/12/17 09:15 4. The current account is the broadest measure: it includes net exports and net income payments, as well as net current transfers. A positive net inflow of payments for goods and services implies that the current account is in surplus (and vice versa). 5. A current account deficit means that a country is importing more goods, services and factors than it exports: total expenditure buys up all domestic production and more. It is a sign, therefore, that a country is ‘living beyond its means’. Consequently, one solution is to curb total expenditure. ✍ An economic upswing is likely to strengthen/weaken the current account. (Choose one option and explain why.) _____________________________________________________________________________________ _____________________________________________________________________________________ _____________________________________________________________________________________ _____________________________________________________________________________________ _____________________________________________________________________________________ It is often stated that the government cannot stimulate the economy before the current account is ‘ready’ for it. What does this mean? _____________________________________________________________________________________ _____________________________________________________________________________________ _____________________________________________________________________________________ _____________________________________________________________________________________ _____________________________________________________________________________________ (Hint: If there is a current account deficit, any stimulation is bound to lead to what?) 6. The extent to which the current account will deteriorate when Y increases will depend on the marginal propensity to import. A high propensity will cause imports to react strongly to any increase in GDP, causing the current account to deteriorate significantly. This can be important if a country is inclined to experience current account problems. In South Africa, the import propensity is relatively high, especially since any meaningful expansion of production is dependent on imported inputs. South African consumer expenditure patterns also contribute to a high marginal propensity to import. This has important macroeconomic implications (see section 4.5.3). 7. A depreciating rand should stimulate exports and curb imports. The current account balance is bound to improve after such a depreciation. The appreciation of the currency is likely to weaken the current account balance. 8. Any positive or negative change in net exports (X – M) has a multiplier effect on income (via the expenditure multiplier KE). 150 Chapter 4: The basic model III: the foreign sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 150 2019/12/17 09:15 The peculiar J curve In practice it often happens that, following a currency depreciation, the current account first deteriorates and then improves. On a graph with the current account on the vertical axis and time on the horizontal axis, this produces a curve with a J shape. Why does this happen? Import and export contracts usually are valid for a relatively long Time of period of time. In addition, many import contracts are denominated depreciation Current account in foreign currency such as the dollar. Therefore, if the rand depreciates suddenly, existing contract volumes will continue to be imported and exported for some time. Given a weaker rand, 0 payments for the contracted volume of imports will require more Time rands (since the prices of imports are denominated in foreign currency). This implies an increase in the outflow of payments for imports. Export prices are mostly denominated in rands; hence total receipts for exports will remain constant for some time. The net effect is that the current account deteriorates initially. Only after some time will contracts adjust to the new external value of the rand, causing export volumes to increase and import volumes to decrease. This means that the volume effect on the current account starts to dominate the price effect. Only then will the current account show an improvement. The diagrammatic result: a J curve. The Marshall-Lerner condition The typical existence of a J curve implies that the net effect of a depreciation of the currency is that the current account (X – M) improves (albeit with some delay). As noted, this is because the effect on the current account of the change in the volume of imports and exports is stronger than the contrary effect of the change in the price of imports and exports (in rands). If this is indeed the case, the socalled Marshall-Lerner condition is satisfied. (The condition is satisfied if the sum of the exchangerate elasticities of imports and exports exceeds 1.) If imports and exports have very low elasticity to exchange rate changes – implying such small changes in the volume of imports and exports that the current account will deterioriate following a currency depreciation – this condition is not satisfied. In reality, the Marshall-Lerner condition is satisfied in most cases. So we will continue to assume that a currency depreciation leads to an improvement in (X – M). Volumes vs. values The J curve and Marshall-Lerner condition illustrate an important issue with regard to imports and exports: one should be extremely careful in analysing volumes versus values. Changes in the exchange rate influence the rand value of a particular import or export volume dramatically. They can even cause rand values to increase while volumes decline, and vice versa. In open-economy macroeconomic analysis, both volumes and rand values are important: ❐ For BoP analysis, the rand values are decisive. ❐ For expenditure and production analysis, it is actually the volumes that are important, since they indicate the real quantities being imported or exported, or the real expenditure involved. However, national accounts data do not really reflect real quantities. Real figures are derived simply by deflating rand values with an estimated price index. The exchange rate effect is not removed from the data. Therefore patterns in real import and export data (national accounts) will not correspond exactly to patterns in import and export volumes. 4.2 Imports, exports and capital flows How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 151 151 2019/12/17 09:15 ✍ The degree of openness of the economy will influence the size of the multiplier. How and why? (Hint: Consider the import propensity.) ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ 9. The normal secondary effects (monetary feedback effects) will also follow from any stimulation of income due to changes in (net) exports. As production and income are stimulated, interest rates are pushed up by an increased demand for money. This increasingly acts as a brake on the upswing, thereby restraining the expected upswing in the economy. 10. One factor that complicates the analysis of the likely consequences of an export surge is that efforts at export promotion often lead to a subsequent increase in imports. This is due to the necessary importation of production inputs. In this sense, South African exports are often import-stimulating. (Normally one would exclude this effect from the analysis.) 4.2.3 Capital flows Capital inflows are all inflows of foreign funds for the purpose of fixed investment (in fixed assets), as well as financial investment (for the purchase of financial assets). Capital inflows include foreign loans by either the private sector or the public sector (e.g. for infrastructural projects or for financing a budget deficit). The flow of capital into and out of the country is recorded in the financial account of the BoP. Direct and portfolio investment can be distinguished, also in published data. The former pertains to setting up new companies or foreign subsidiaries, or acquiring shares in companies with the objective of gaining a meaningful say in management, as well as investment in real estate. The latter pertains, for example, to purchases or shares or bonds with the objective of financial returns on the investment, rather than having a say in management, i.e. there is no longer-term commitment. It also includes the acquisition of long-term debt and money market instruments. In figure 4.5, the graph shows quarterly capital movements for the period 1980 to 2018, as recorded in the financial account of the balance of payments. Three distinct periods can be observed. In the period between 1985 and 1994, capital movements were rather small. Real investment, financial investment and the financial account The important macroeconomic distinction between real investment (capital formation) and financial investment was explained in chapter 2. In the financial account of the BoP, these matters are handled differently, which can be confusing. The financial account combines flows of funds for the sale and purchase of all kinds of assets: residential homes, commercial buildings, factories, land, companies, shares, government and other stock, even deposits with financial institutions; it also records loans and loan repayments. However, it does distinguish between direct investment, portfolio investment and other investment. Compare the balance of payments table in section 4.3.1. See also Mohr (2019) Economic Indicators, 131–2. 152 Chapter 4: The basic model III: the foreign sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 152 2019/12/17 09:15 Figure 4.5 International capital flows – the financial account 100 80 Financial account R billion 60 40 20 2018/01 2016/03 2015/01 2013/03 2012/01 2010/03 2009/01 2007/03 2006/01 2004/03 2003/01 2001/03 2000/01 1998/03 1997/01 1995/03 1994/01 1992/03 1991/01 1989/03 1988/01 1985/01 –20 1986/03 0 Source: South African Reserve Bank (www.resbank.co.za). This was mainly due to the international isolation of, and financial sanctions against, South Africa in the period prior to 1994. Since 1994, capital movements increased significantly. However, notice that capital flows were still rather modest and stable between 1994 and 2003. In the third period, after 2003, capital inflows into South Africa increased dramatically (albeit with quite some volatility) – and from 2015 with even more volatility. Also see figure 4.6. Which factors determine capital inflows? Capital flows across international borders because capital owners are seeking the highest possible real rates of return on investments (whether real or financial investments). Therefore the main factors that determine the inflow of capital into a country are relative interest rates (on financial investments), relative rates of return (on real investment), the exchange rate,2 and economic and political expectations. Accordingly: rSA K-inflow = f ( rForeign ; relative SA rates of return; rand; expectations) ? Optimism about expected real returns on real investment (i.e. economic growth possibilities) should attract foreign investors. Furthermore, local interest rates that increase relative to foreign rates should induce inflows of foreign capital (and strengthen the financial account). The main effect of the exchange rate is that it determines the effective cost, for a foreign investor, of the purchase of an asset. A relatively weak rand reduces the prices of South African assets for foreign investors and encourages foreign investment. This implies an inverse relationship between the value of the rand and capital inflows. On the other hand, a weak rand reduces the effective value of dividends to a foreigner – a discouraging factor. Normally this effect is small, however, and the inverse relationship mentioned above is likely to predominate. 2 Until 1995, South Africa had a special exchange rate for capital flows – the so-called financial rand. 4.2 Imports, exports and capital flows How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 153 153 2019/12/17 09:15 Interest rates and risk premiums in emerging markets Changes in the interest rate, rather than differences between the levels of interest rates in countries, are what matters here. Interest rates in South Africa always tend to be higher than in countries such as the USA or UK. Yet there is no perpetual flow of capital into South Africa. But South Africa will experience capital outflows when the domestic interest rate level decreases even though domestic rates still are higher than in other economies. When searching for investment options across potential target countries, international investors do not simply decide on the basis of nominal interest rates (or nominal rates of return) in different countries. They take a broader view. First, they will take note that high nominal interest rates usually reflect high inflation in a target country. This implies some risks. An inflation rate that is relatively high is likely to lead to currency depreciation over the duration of the investment. This will reduce the buying power, in the investor’s home country, of the nominal return earned in the target country. Moreover, such depreciation will decrease the value, in home currency, of the capital when it is repatriated eventually. (The longer the term of the investment, the higher is this risk.) For this reason, investors will often compare real rates of interest: r ≈ i – π. Second, investors are sensitive to risks relating to economic and political instability. An investor investing in, say, a low- or middle-income country or ‘emerging market’, will want some premium built into the return or interest rate to compensate for the higher risk compared to a ‘safe’ investment in the USA or Germany, for instance. Everything else being equal (including inflation rates), the typical investor will at least require a real interest rate that is higher by the amount of the risk premium. Thus: Required real interest rate in risky country = Real interest rate in safe countries + risk premium The safe country rate will depend on international capital market conditions, but will not vary much. The premium will depend on each individual target country. ❐ The risk premium for South Africa, compared to the USA or other OECD countries, may be in the order of 3%. This can increase dramatically if events occur that signal political uncertainty and risk. ❐ In a stable situation, the gap between South African nominal rates and average OECD nominal rates is an approximate indication of the combined exchange rate and political risk premiums in the eyes of international investors. Political uncertainty, disturbances and unrest can be potent factors. Such factors have quite frequently affected South Africa’s external economic relations negatively, with the Sharpeville incident of 1961 and the Soweto uprising of 1976 as notable examples. Political instability continues to bedevil many low- and middle-income countries in Africa and elsewhere (see chapter 12, section 12.3.4). The perceived high risk of investment in South Africa required a substantial risk premium in order to induce foreign investors to consider investment here. This was the case, for instance, in the 1980s and early 1990s when foreign investors watched the political course of events much more than interest rate or rate of return differentials. Thus, international capital flows to South Africa were not very sensitive to interest rate differentials (i.e. they were interest rate inelastic). For these reasons, there was a relatively low flow of capital into South Africa, especially for direct investment. The situation improved after 1994. Although there is still a significant risk premium, capital flows are more sensitive to interest rate changes and rate of return differentials. 154 Chapter 4: The basic model III: the foreign sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 154 2019/12/17 09:15 This does not mean that politics does not play a role. Rather, the more legitimate and more stable post-1994 political environment has reduced political uncertainty and the risk premium. However, since 2009 the risk premium has increased again, mostly because of weak economic conditions, but also increased political risk. Elections and changes of party and national leadership, or contentious policy views expressed by presidents or party officials, regularly cause heightened political concern. Since South Africa is part of the so-called emerging markets, foreign investors will continue to pay more attention to its politics than those of democratically mature economies such as the USA, UK and Japan. Therefore, in contrast to South Africa, there is high international mobility of capital into the USA. In particular, there is a tremendous international sensitivity to American interest rates. A small rate increase in the USA can cause a tremendous inflow of foreign capital into the USA. ❐ This illustrates the fact that one should be careful in applying macroeconomic reasoning to different countries. ❐ The US example is crucial in understanding movements in the gold price, the dollar and the rand. (See section 4.5.3.) Foreign loans by the private sector normally derive from investment plans. The same is true for large infrastructural projects of the state or of quasi-state institutions (e.g. Eskom, Telkom and Transnet). Foreign borrowing towards the financing of a budget deficit depends on the borrowing requirement of the government, the cost and conditions of such loans compared to domestic loans, and the debt-management policy of the state (discussed in chapters 9 and 10). How do foreign capital flows affect the economy? The analysis of the short-term macroeconomic impact of foreign capital inflows is quite complex. To understand this, one must clearly distinguish between possible real and monetary effects. Not being a direct component of aggregate expenditure, an inflow of foreign capital (e.g. a foreign loan) as such has no direct impact on aggregate spending, and hence no direct or immediate effect on real income. (The repayment of foreign loans is simply an outflow, or a negative inflow, of capital, requiring an analogous analysis.) To see this, one must distinguish analytically the inflow of funds from their actual use. If the funds are used to purchase existing shares, there is no new real investment, and hence no direct real impact. However, even if the funds are used to finance new real investment, one should rather analyse the effects of the investment expenditure separately – with the foreign capital simply the method of financing, having no real expenditure effect in itself. Foreign capital inflows as such therefore have no direct real effect on the economy. But surely the inflow of funds must have a monetary impact? This is true – with the crucial qualification that the effect of the financial account cannot be determined and analysed on its own. Further on we shall see that the financial account, together with the current account – i.e. It is important to note that in the long run the inflow of foreign capital is important in the sense that it boosts the domestic pool of funds available to finance investment. In this way it is important for long-term real economic growth (see chapter 12, section 12.3). the whole balance of payments – has important 4.2 Imports, exports and capital flows How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 155 155 2019/12/17 09:15 implications for monetary conditions. But one cannot analyse the monetary impact of the financial account separately – the net balance of the two accounts is what matters here. To understand this, we first have to consider the exchange rate and the balance of payments, and the complex two-way interaction between these two. At this stage it is sufficient to note that a net inflow of funds will expand the domestic money supply. A net outflow will contract the domestic money supply. In the following section, the entire network of interrelationships will be traced and explained. The final and comprehensive picture will materialise. 4.3 The balance of payments and exchange rates 4.3.1 The balance of payments (BoP) In accounting terms, the balance of payments (BoP) is the sum of the balances on the current and financial accounts: BoP = Current account balance + Financial account balance The graph in figure 4.6 shows historical patterns for annual data on these two elements for South Africa. Note how, before 1994, the current account was managed (via the management of GDP growth) to counter financial account imbalances. Specifically, note the major turnarounds in 1984–85 and again in 1993–94. After 1994, a shortage of international capital ceased to be a problem, and even more so after 2003. This inflow enabled the economy to carry a large deficit on the current account – the by-product of high economic growth – without any problem. However, in 2007 and 2008, questions were increasingly being asked about the sustain­ ability of the current account deficit when it reached levels of 7% and 8% of GDP (compared to the 3% international rule of thumb that is often cited in the press). Figure 4.6 The current account and the financial account 300 270 240 Financial account 210 180 150 120 R billion 90 60 30 0 –30 –60 –90 –120 Current account –150 –180 –210 2018 2017 2016 2015 2014 2013 2012 2011 2010 2009 2008 2007 2006 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 1993 1992 1991 1990 1989 1988 1987 1986 1985 –240 Source: South African Reserve Bank (www.resbank.co.za). 156 Chapter 4: The basic model III: the foreign sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 156 2019/12/17 09:15 The unease reached new heights since 2013, when the relatively large current account deficit, combined with weak GDP growth prospects and a relatively large budget deficit, caused the South African economy to be seen as rather fragile. The balance of payments table The composition and terms of the balance of payments table in the Quarterly Bulletin of the Reserve Bank is somewhat confusing. The components of the current account were discussed above. The table below adds the financial account figures to the current account figures shown on p. 149. Balance of payments 2018 (R billion) Current Account: Merchandise exports 1 175 547 Net gold exports 71 678 Service receipts 210 415 Income receipts 96 507 Less: Merchandise imports –1 222 944 Less: Payment of services –217 939 Less: Income payments –250 552 Current transfers (net receipts (+)) –35 674 Balance on current account –172 962 DATA TIP Capital transfer account (net receipts (+)) 236 Financial Account: Net direct investment 10 360 Net portfolio investment 33 224 Net financal derivatives 7 209 Net other investment 102 595 Reserve assets (increase (–)/decrease (+)) –11 337 Balance on the financial account with change in reserves included 142 051 Balance on the financial account (change in reserves excluded) 153 388 Unrecorded transactions 30 675 Balance of Payments with change in reserves included Balance of Payments (change in reserves exluded, unrecorded transactions included) – 11 337 Source: South African Reserve Bank (www.resbank.co.za). ❐ ❐ ❐ ❐ The capital transfer account item is relatively insignificant in economic analysis. ‘Other investment’ mainly includes trade credits, and is typically quite large. Unrecorded transactions denote a capital flow error term, and can be significant. In the published table in the Quarterly Bulletin the actual number for the ‘Balance of payments’ is not shown. Due to accounting conventions, its value is shown in the financial account just above the ‘balance on the financial account’ as ‘Reserve assets (increase (–)/decrease (+))’. In the tables above and in chapter 5, section 5.6, we have labelled it ‘Balance of payments (excl. change in reserves, incl. unrecorded transactions)’. Being equal to the change in reserves, it also equals the sum of the balances on: the current account, the capital transfer account (very small), the financial account (change in reserves excluded), and unrecorded transactions. 4.3 The balance of payments and exchange rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 157 157 2019/12/17 09:15 What causes an imbalance in the balance of payments (BoP)? The BoP position depends on all the factors that determine the international flow of goods and capital: domestic and foreign income levels, interest rates and rates of return, price levels and exchange rates, as well as expectations, perceptions of risk and so forth. A change in one or more of these factors – as in the many chain reactions we have encountered – normally also leads to a concurrent change in imports and exports (and thus the current account) or capital inflows (the financial account). From these follow a net impact on the BoP – which is always in the thick of things, as we will see. We will consider three illustrative examples and elaborate on them throughout this chapter, as well as in chapter 6 (when introducing inflation): 1. A change in the money supply or repo rate (i.e. a disturbance in the money market/ monetary sector). The primary and secondary effects that usually follow a monetary policy step, e.g. an increase in the repo rate, were explained in chapter 3 (section 3.3.6). To summarise: The net effect of an increase in the repo rate is an increase in interest rates and a decrease in real income (through several concurrent processes, the details of which are not relevant now). ❐ The higher interest rates are likely to attract an inflow of foreign capital, which affects the financial account of the balance of payments: a financial account surplus will develop. ❐ The drop in income is likely to lead to a fall in imports, which affect the current account of the BoP: a current account surplus will develop. Together these two effects will determine the BoP position, in this case unambiguously a surplus. 2. A change in aggregate expenditure (i.e. a disturbance in the domestic goods market). The primary and secondary effects of an increase in government expenditure were explained in chapter 3 (sections 3.3.2 and 3.3.6). To summarise The net effect of an increase in government expenditure is an increase in real income accompanied by an increase in interest rates. ❐ The higher interest rates are likely to attract an inflow of foreign capital, which strengthens the financial (or capital) account of the balance of payments. ❐ The upswing in income is likely to lead to a rise in imports, which negatively affect the current account of the BoP. The net impact of the two opposing effects will determine the ultimate BoP position. 3. A change in exports (i.e. a disturbance in the foreign sector), for example due to an economic upswing in the USA. (See chapter 2, section 2.2.6; section 4.5.3 in chapter 4 contains a complete chain reaction.) In brief: The net effect of an increase in exports is an increase in real income accompanied by an increase in interest rates. ❐ Increasing exports are directly reflected in an improved current account. ❐ Increased export earnings imply an expenditure injection in the economy, which causes income Y to increase (see chapter 2, section 2.2.6). ❐ The upswing in income is likely to lead to a rise in imports (why?), which is a negative impact on the current account. ❐ The increase in Y is likely to lead, via increased money demand, to higher interest rates. These are likely to attract foreign capital, which strengthens the financial (or capital) account. 158 Chapter 4: The basic model III: the foreign sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 158 2019/12/17 09:15 The net impact of these effects will determine the ultimate BoP position. It is likely to be in a surplus. ✍ What is the effect of the following on the BoP? Suppose South Africa’s inflation is higher than foreign inflation ⇒ ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ Suppose South Africa’s interest rates are higher than foreign interest rates ⇒ ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ Suppose South Africa has to repay foreign debt ⇒ ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ Suppose the repo rate is reduced ⇒ ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ What are the consequences of a BoP disequilibrium? A surplus on the balance of payments (BoP > 0) implies a net inflow of payments (for whatever purpose). A deficit (BoP < 0) implies a net outflow of funds, i.e. outflows exceed inflows (in a given period). The BoP has a direct impact on three key variables: 1. the foreign reserves; 2. the money supply (monetary liquidity); and 3. the exchange rate. (1) Impact on foreign reserves Since foreign payments to South Africans initially occur in the form of foreign currency, a surplus on the BoP causes the amount of foreign currency – or ‘foreign reserves’ – in the country to increase. Likewise, a deficit will cause the foreign reserves to decline, while a BoP equilibrium will leave reserves unaffected. In this way the state of the foreign reserves is a good indicator of the BoP situation. The graph in figure 4.7 shows the balance of payments together with the foreign reserves since 1985. The balance of payments is a net figure, reflecting the current and financial accounts. These are nominal values, hence the apparent increase in the magnitude of the figures. Note how the stock of gold and foreign reserves increased since 1996, with temporary dips in 2002–03, 2009–10 and 2016–17. The graph indicates that the BoP in South Africa has improved significantly even though the current account of the balance of payments has registered a significant and growing deficit. However, 2008, 2013 and 2018 were difficult years. 4.3 The balance of payments and exchange rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 159 159 2019/12/17 09:15 Figure 4.7 The balance of payments and foreign reserves 780 720 660 Gross gold and foreign reserves 600 540 480 R billion 420 360 300 240 180 120 Balance of payments 60 0 2018 2017 2016 2015 2014 2013 2012 2011 2010 2009 2008 2007 2006 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 1993 1992 1991 1990 1989 1988 1987 1985 –120 1986 –60 Source: South African Reserve Bank (www.resbank.co.za). DATA TIP Net and gross foreign reserves Technically, foreign reserves also are affected by a number of other international monetary flows. In published BoP data, the following are distinguished: ❐ Change in net gold and other foreign reserves, and ❐ Change in gross gold and other foreign reserves. The differences between these two depend on changes in three factors: (1) the net monetisation/demonetisation of gold, (2) SDR allocations and calculations (SDR: Standard Drawing Rights at the IMF) and (3) liabilities related to reserves.3 If one wants to evaluate changes in foreign reserves as such, the gross figure is the relevant one. However, the net figure is closest to the macroeconomic concept of ‘the balance of payments’. Foreign reserves are critically important since they are essential in paying for imports. A country cannot sustain a BoP deficit for an indeterminate period of time: eventually there will be insufficient foreign currency reserves to pay for imports – especially essential imports such as oil. ❐ A rule of thumb in this regard is that a country should have sufficient reserves to cover three months’ imports. ❐ The following table from the Reserve Bank shows the performance of the SA economy in this regard. During the 1990s the average number of months of imports covered by foreign reserves was quite low. However, in the 2000s the foreign reserve position improved. As table 4.1 indicates, the foreign reserve position improved from less than two months of imports in 2003 to averaging 4.6 months of imports from 2009 onwards. Still, that is not a huge buffer. 3 160 This concerns foreign loans by the Reserve Bank and the government from foreign banks and governments, but for specialised purposes other than trade or capital flow. Therefore it falls outside the ambit of the BoP as conventionally understood, and does not necessarily have any effect on the macroeconomy. Chapter 4: The basic model III: the foreign sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 160 2019/12/17 09:15 Foreign reserves and the ‘man in the street’ The level of foreign reserves may be one of the most important considerations in Reserve Bank interest rate policy (in conjunction with other policy goals such as inflation; see chapter 9). As soon as foreign reserves reach relatively low levels, the Reserve Bank may consider pushing up interest rates (e.g. via a repo rate increase) in order to restrain expenditure and therefore imports, and perhaps to attract foreign capital. Therefore, if either the current or the financial account shows a deteriorating trend, and depending on the state of the other account, one can expect that interest rates may be increased. Obviously such a step affects the economy and, for example, homeowners, negatively. Therefore the level of foreign reserves is of great importance for everyone. ❐ On the other hand, low reserves normally are symptomatic of a period of BoP deficits. This might cause the rand to depreciate, which is negative for import prices and thus for inflation. Shoring up reserves with a repo rate increase will also serve the inflation objective. Foreign reserves also are essential if the Reserve Bank Table 4.1 Foreign reserves wants to support the rand in foreign exchange markets Imports of goods and services covered as part of its exchange rate policy (see section 4.3.2). by reserves (average number of months) If there is a continuous current account deficit, the financial account should be in surplus to compensate. As long as capital inflows occur continually, a country can sustain a current account d eficit without running into foreign reserve problems. However, if there is a sustained capital outflow, current account deficits cannot be tolerated for very long. (2) Impact on the money supply An important consequence of a BoP deficit or surplus, referred to above, is that it influences the nominal money supply MS. A net inflow of payments (even if in foreign currency initially) leads to an increase in the domestic money supply, as follows: 2003 1.8 2005 2.8 2007 3.0 2009 4.6 2011 4.3 2013 4.3 2015 4.9 2016 5.4 2017 4.9 2018 4.7 Source: South African Reserve Bank, balance of payments tables (www.resbank.co.za). Suppose a foreigner wishes to buy an item from a South African producer. She first buys rands from the Reserve Bank (via her bank), then uses these to pay the export company. When the funds are deposited in the company’s bank account, the total amount of deposits in the country (i.e. M3) increases. Alternatively, if the export company is paid in dollars or other foreign currency, this company has to exchange the foreign currency for rands (that come from the Reserve Bank, via her bank), which it then deposits in its account. The impact on the nominal (and real) money supply is identical: the deposit is a monetary injection, which will be followed by the normal credit multiplier process. In the aggregate there is an increase in domestic monetary liquidity (nominal and real). Therefore: BoP > 0 ⇒ increase in nominal (and real) MS BoP < 0 ⇒ decrease in nominal (and real) MS 4.3 The balance of payments and exchange rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 161 161 2019/12/17 09:15 This impact on the money supply will occur as long as there is a BoP disequilibrium. As soon as a deficit or surplus is eliminated, there will be no further impact on the money supply from this source. There are ways for the Reserve Bank to counter the impact of such an inflow of foreign currency on the nominal money supply. Such a step is called the sterilisation of the foreign currency inflow. A sterilisation entails that the Reserve Bank conducts an open market operation where it sells bonds on the domestic capital market equal in value to the rand value of the foreign reserve inflow. The BoP constraint Until 1976 it was usually the case that South Africa experienced significant capital inflows. As a result, the country could afford to run large current account deficits. But 1976 was a turning point. (What happened in that year?) The subsequent loss of foreign confidence in South Africa’s political-economic future – and again in 1985 – drastically changed this situation. A huge and increasing withdrawal of foreign capital occurred, causing a continuous and large deficit on the financial account. Hence the current account had to be kept in surplus to earn enough foreign exchange to finance the financial account deficit. This meant that imports had to be curtailed at all costs. In turn this implied that the authorities could not allow the economy to experience too strong an upswing. (Can you explain why not?) Therefore, restrictive policy had to be used to protect the BoP. Especially in the period between 1985 and 1994, South Africa was in the ironic position that only weak to moderate upswings could be allowed; anything better would have caused BoP difficulties. ❐ This analysis shows just how effective financial sanctions – and not the trade sanctions introduced earlier – were in applying pressure on the former South African government to change the political system. ❐ Note that in this way the balance of payments position can create a significant constraint on the economic growth rate that can be sustained. This is what is indicated by the term ‘the balance of payments constraint’. (3) Impact on the exchange rate The last important effect of the BoP on the economy concerns the exchange rate. We must first understand exchange rates before this effect can be explained. 4.3.2 Exchange rates What is the exchange rate? As mentioned at the beginning of this chapter, the exchange rate is the price of one currency in terms of another, e.g. $1 = R10.00 or £1 = R17.00. This is also called the nominal exchange rate. The exchange rate of the rand against the dollar, say, determines the ‘outside’ or external value of the rand, i.e. for a foreign resident who wants to buy rands, or for a South African wishing to buy foreign currencies with rands. The exchange rate therefore determines the foreign or international purchasing power of the rand. The external value of the rand is something completely different from the internal value or domestic purchasing power of the rand, which is a reflection of the domestic impact of the 162 Chapter 4: The basic model III: the foreign sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 162 2019/12/17 09:15 ! The way rand–dollar exchange rates are usually written (i.e. $1 = R10.00) may be somewhat confusing. If the rand depreciates (weakens) against the dollar, the numerical value of the rate of change actually increases: the exchange rate increases. Why does a change in the exchange rate from $1 = 10.50 to $1 = R10.20 represent a strengthening of the rand? Think of the dollar as an item that you buy, just like a can of cola. If the price of cola decreases, from R10.50 to R10.20, you can buy more cola per rand, i.e. in terms of buying cola the purchasing power of the rand has increased. The same applies to buying a dollar. If the price of a dollar decreases from R10.50 to R10.20, then the purchasing power of the rand in terms of the dollar has increased. The rand has strengthened. The exchange rate between the rand and some other currencies, such as the Japanese yen, is expressed the other way around, for example, R1 = ¥10.00. To prevent confusion and incorrect macroeconomic reasoning, it is safer not to think in terms of increases or decreases of the exchange rate, but rather of increases or decreases in the value of the rand (except when a formula requires the exchange rate as such). inflation rate. (This is true even though there may be important links between these two concepts of purchasing power.) If the rand strengthens (the external value of the rand increases), one would say that the rand has appreciated. Depreciation is the opposite – the rand weakens. ❐ One should therefore use the terms ‘appreciation’ and ‘depreciation’ with care. Only a currency (the rand or the dollar) can depreciate or appreciate, not the exchange rate. ❐ The terms ‘devaluation’ and ‘revaluation’ have a similar but different meaning. This is explained later. In practice, there is no such thing as the exchange rate, but a whole spectrum of rates. An exchange rate exists between each pair of currencies in the world, i.e. the rate at which one can be exchanged for the other. The dollar–rand exchange rate is merely the most prominent one, seen as representative of the value of the rand against other currencies. The euro–rand exchange rate is also very important. Special exchange rates The real exchange rate is an adjusted exchange rate that takes differences between countries’ price levels (and thus inflation rates) into account. The real exchange rate is calculated as follows using the normal (nominal) exchange rate in its indirect manner of quotation, i.e. $1 = R10.00. (The real exchange rate is expressed in the direct form.) 1 PSA P Real exchange rate = Exchange rate × Foreign The effective exchange rate expresses the value of the rand relative to a ‘basket’ of important foreign currencies, namely those of the main trading partners of the country. It is a kind of weighted average exchange rate. As such, its value is less sensitive to currency disturbances in a single country, for example the USA. It is expressed as an index. By combining these two operations, a real effective exchange rate, indicated with the symbol , can be calculated (also as an index): PSA Real effective exchange rate () = Effective exchange rate × P Foreign 4.3 The balance of payments and exchange rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 163 163 2019/12/17 09:15 Note that by convention the Reserve Bank publishes both these exchange rates in the direct way (see the introduction to this chapter). Thus a decrease in the external value of the rand is represented by a decrease in the numerical value of the exchange rate. Often it is safer to reason in terms of nominal rates rather than real rates, and to handle the price ratio as a separate variable, as is done in this chapter. Doing so makes the analysis more transparent and easier to follow. Figure 4.8 Nominal effective and real effective exchange rates 350 300 250 Index 200 Nominal effective exchange rate of the rand 150 100 2018/07 2017/01 2015/07 2014/01 2012/07 2011/01 2009/07 2008/01 2006/07 2005/01 2003/07 2000/07 1999/01 1997/07 1996/01 1994/07 1993/01 1991/07 1990/01 0 2002/01 Real effective exchange rate of the rand 50 Source: South African Reserve Bank (www.resbank.co.za). Figure 4.8 depicts both the real and the nominal effective exchange rates. The real effective exchange rate in South Africa is much more stable than the nominal effective exchange rate (though it has had a dip in 2001–02). The nominal effective exchange rate displays a downward trend, especially prior to 2001, which is an indication of the impact of inflation. After 2006 and especially from 2011 to 2016 there is a discernible downward trend. Buying and selling rates for currencies Most often the media report only one exchange rate for, say, the rand/dollar. Currency dealers such as banks and ‘bureaux de change’ (smaller scale currency dealers in cities or at international airports) quote two rates, often seen in two columns on electronic boards. The ‘We buy’ column is the exchange rate at which the dealer is willing to buy a foreign currency, while the ‘We sell’ column is the rate at which a foreign currency is sold. As with any other commodity or product, a currency dealer wants a profit. ❐ For instance, a currency dealer will buy dollars from you at R10.5112 (it is always quoted to four places after the decimal point), while they will sell to you at R10.7353. The R0.2241 difference is the profit margin of the dealer. ❐ Exchange rates in the media may be the middle rate between the buy and sell rates, or alternatively they may quote the sell rate. Therefore, always ensure that you know which one is quoted. ❐ Rates quoted and published by the SARB are middle rates, calculated as weighted average daily rates of banks at approximately 10:30. ❐ The difference between the buy and sell rates is called the spread. 164 Chapter 4: The basic model III: the foreign sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 164 2019/12/17 09:15 Where and by whom are exchange rates determined? As with interest rates, exchange rates are not fixed or set by law or decree by some or other authority or governmental body – and specifically not by the Reserve Bank. Exchange rates are determined, on a daily basis, in the so-called foreign exchange (‘forex’) market. (Foreign exchange = currencies of other countries.) Where is the forex market? The forex market, like the money market (see chapter 3), is not a building or a place. A large number of forex dealers – primarily at banks and the Reserve Bank – are continually in contact with each other by electronic means. Currencies – rand, dollar, euro, pound, etc. – are bought and sold on behalf of clients of the banks wishing to conclude international transactions. Using computers, video monitors and telephones, they make and receive offers, and as deals are struck and ‘prices’ agreed upon, exchange rates are determined minute by minute. As in the money market, dealers experience tremendous excitement, especially when things are happening in forex markets, or if rumours appear about possible important events all over the world. Speculators can make huge profits (or losses!) from small differentials or movements in rates. Enormous amounts of funds flow (electronically) across borders due to these transactions. Obviously, foreign exchange markets are internationally oriented, and international capital is extremely mobile. Instant electronic communication and transactions make distance and international borders irrelevant. Since the important forex markets are scattered around the globe – New York, London, Zurich, Hong Kong, Tokyo – forex trade goes on 24 hours a day. Mostly, foreign exchange markets work as simply as a vegetable market: fundamentally, the (external) value of the rand is determined by the demand for, and supply of, rand in forex markets at a particular time. The same is true for any other currency. ❐ If the demand for a currency (e.g. the rand) increases, there is upward pressure on its external value, and it is likely to appreciate (e.g. the rand–dollar exchange rate will change from $1 = R10.00 to $1 = R9.80). If the supply of What are ‘spot’ and ‘forward’ exchange rates? rands increases, there will be The ‘spot exchange rate’ is the conventional rate downward pressure on the that is determined daily for immediate (on the ‘spot’) rand, and depreciation occurs. trade in foreign currencies. ❐ The supply and demand for However, importers and exporters often wish rands can be depicted in a to protect themselves against future changes in diagram similar to that for exchange rates. To reduce uncertainty with regard any microeconomic market; to planned future transactions, they then conclude a straightforward analysis of agreements for foreign exchange transactions to shifts in either the demand occur on some date in the future: the price and or the supply curves can prequantity are agreed upon today for a transaction in dict the expected results of the future. The agreed-upon exchange rate is the changing market conditions. ‘forward exchange rate’. Guesses, expectations and (In fact, the foreign exchange risks regarding the future course of exchange rates market is one of the few realare decisive in these cases. life markets whose operation 4.3 The balance of payments and exchange rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 165 165 2019/12/17 09:15 and relatively smooth adjustment to equilibrium approximate the theoretical model of a ‘perfectly competitive’ or atomistic market.) The basic reason why currencies are bought and sold is to make international transactions possible. Importers must first exchange their rands for yen, for example, before they can pay for a Japanese import. Likewise, a foreign importer must exchange his means of payment, e.g. dollars, for South African rands: the importer must first buy the South African rands, and then use them to purchase the South African product (the double transaction). In the first instance, therefore, exchange rates are determined by the activities of importers, exporters, foreign investors, foreign borrowers, etc. ❐ Of course, policy intervention by the relevant authority (the Reserve Bank in the South African case) can also play a significant role. This is explained below. Which factors determine exchange rate movements? The inflow and outflow of funds – either for import and export payments or for capital flows – determines the intensity and extent of forex buying and selling transactions, i.e. the demand and supply for foreign exchange. ❐ Each outflow of funds from the country implies a demand for foreign exchange – which is mirrored by an exactly equivalent supply of rands. ❐ Each inflow of funds into South Africa implies a demand for rands (i.e. a supply of foreign currency). ❐ If the inflow exceeds the outflow of funds, there is an excess demand for rands. That should translate into upward pressure on the external value of the rand. ❐ Likewise, a net outflow of funds leads to an excess supply of rands on forex markets, and downward pressure on the rand. At this juncture, the decisive importance of the BoP is unmistakable. A BoP surplus (= net inflow of funds indicated by rising foreign reserves) implies an excess demand for rands, and hence upward pressure on the value of the rand, with appreciation the likely outcome. In brief: BoP > 0 ⇒ excess demand for rands ⇒ upward pressure on the rand ⇒ rand appreciates A BoP deficit (= a net outflow of funds and falling reserves) causes downward pressure on the rand. As long as there is a BoP deficit or surplus, pressure exists on the rand to depreciate or appreciate. Only when (and if) a BoP deficit or surplus is eradicated would pressure on the rand to adjust disappear. ❐ Exchange rates often undergo smaller day-to-day fluctuations due to minor influences on markets: single large transactions, rumours of transactions or policy events (in South Africa or elsewhere), speculative transactions and so forth. However, the BoP position remains as the underlying determinant of the direction of change of the exchange rate. Remember that the value of the rand against the dollar can change simply because the dollar, as such, has strengthened or weakened on international markets, often due to factors in the US economic scene unrelated to the rand or South African economic conditions. In such a case it is preferable to analyse the value of the rand by comparing it with other currencies, or with a group of other currencies. ❐ This is why (and when) the effective exchange rate is particularly useful, being more stable and less subject to distortion by foreign country-specific shocks. The previous analysis focused on short- and medium-term movements in the external value of the rand. That excludes an important question: which factors determine the longterm tendency in the exchange rate? 166 Chapter 4: The basic model III: the foreign sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 166 2019/12/17 09:15 In principle, the analysis of the decisive role of the BoP is valid for the longer term, ignoring smaller disturbances. Sustained BoP deficits would lead to sustained downward pressure on the currency (depreciation), while sustained BoP surpluses would augur well for sustained currency appreciation. (Sustained current account or financial account tendencies, in turn, explain basic tendencies in the BoP.) However, the question is: which underlying factors determine or cause sustained BoP tendencies? Important determinants are discussed below. Inflation differentials In some of the examples above it was demonstrated that, if South African inflation is higher than that in other countries (especially its main trading partners), it would discourage exports and encourage imports. The current account would deteriorate, which would weaken the BoP (assuming that the financial account is unaffected), eventually leading to downward pressure on the external value of the rand. ❐ Therefore, a sustained gap between the inflation rates of South Africa and its trading partners will cause a long-term, gradual depreciation of the rand. ❐ In practical terms, one can state the argument as follows: the only way in which South African exporters can remain competitive in world markets while South Africa is experiencing higher domestic inflation than the rest of the world is if the rand persistently and gradually depreciates to compensate. Such depreciation will prevent the effective price for the foreign buyer of the South African product from increasing all the time due to South African inflation. ❐ One may therefore expect an annual rate of depreciation over the long term that is roughly equivalent to the difference between the average trading partner inflation rate and the South African inflation rate. This is one of the most important underlying explanations of long-term tendencies in exchange rates. The theory of purchasing power parity (PPP) This is a more formal and more theoretical version of this rule of thumb. It is a typical equilibrium approach, and it posits that exchange rates will tend towards an equilibrium P situation where the exchange rate is precisely equal to the price ratio ( ). The exchange rate P would change precisely proportionate to changes in the price ratio. While in the short run it never works like this in practice, inter alia because factors other than prices also play a role, there is an important element of truth in this theory when viewed over the longer run. Domestic Foreign International competitiveness or non-competitiveness This is another important factor determining trade patterns and therefore the current account. Competitiveness depends on factors such as productivity, input cost tendencies, labour force skills, innovative management and marketing, technological developments, natural resource development, human development and so on. Political-economic expectations and perceptions These are important long-term factors, especially on the financial account side. If a country is regarded as safe, stable and prosperous (e.g. Switzerland), it can experience 4.3 The balance of payments and exchange rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 167 167 2019/12/17 09:15 significant capital inflows over an extended period of time. This can cause a sustained appreciation of the currency (depending, of course, on the current account position). The opposite holds for when a country is considered unsafe and unstable. In the South African case, perceptions about safety and stability are potentially some of the most important negative factors in the future (as they have been during the past couple of decades). What are fixed and floating exchange rates? Exchange rate policy Exchange rates that are determined by the interaction of demand and supply in a fully free and smoothly functioning foreign exchange system are called floating exchange rates. However, this would be an extreme, pure case. Even if the foreign exchange market operates smoothly, the behaviour of the exchange rate can be influenced significantly by dominant sellers or buyers of, for example, rands. One such dominant buyer is the Reserve Bank, which has the responsibility of keeping a watchful eye over the exchange rate. This is the objective of exchange rate policy, and part of the responsibilities of the Reserve Bank. By taking part, on a relatively large scale, in purchases or sales of rands in the foreign exchange market, the Reserve Bank can influence the ‘price’ of the rand. This is the system that exists in South Africa and in the majority of countries in the world (albeit in different forms and with different degrees of central bank action). It works in the following way: ❐ If the Reserve Bank wishes to prevent the rand from depreciating (too much), it can enter the market and purchase a substantial amount of rands – using foreign currencies as payment – thereby supporting the value of the rand and preventing a further decline. ❐ The opposite occurs if the Reserve Bank sells large quantities of rands, e.g. by buying dollars. In this way it can put downward pressure on the value of the rand, thereby preventing it from appreciating. The need for such a step occurs less frequently, except to smooth erratic jumps. Supporting the rand requires dollars or other currencies to pay for the rands that the Bank is purchasing. Therefore the rand can be supported only as long as the Reserve Bank has sufficient foreign currency reserves to purchase rands. Because reserves are being used up as long as support is given, at some point reserves must start reaching critically low levels. This is one reason why a country’s foreign reserves are so important and are constantly monitored by policymakers. ❐ In addition to its own foreign reserves, a central bank might also have foreign credit lines (i.e. loan facilities) on which it can draw at times to obtain foreign reserves (these loans have to be repaid, of course). The Bank cannot, therefore, prevent currency depreciation indefinitely. It can at most prevent unwanted short-term dips, or try to smooth the behaviour of the exchange rate if transient erratic movements occur, for instance, due to market rumours or speculative trading. ❐ Therefore the moderation of exchange rate volatility, rather than the sustained prevention of depreciation (or appreciation), is the main aim of exchange rate policy. When the Reserve Bank participates (or ‘intervenes’) in the forex market in this way, the exchange rate is not freely floating in the true sense of the word. It is then appropriate to speak of a system of ‘dirty floating’. 168 Chapter 4: The basic model III: the foreign sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 168 2019/12/17 09:15 The Reserve Bank: always there to support the rand? The limited ability of the Reserve Bank to prevent a depreciation of the rand was clearly demonstrated in 1998 when the Asian crisis caused significant downward pressure on the rand. The Reserve Bank attempted to stabilise the value of the rand by selling its foreign reserves. It even borrowed foreign reserves to then sell in support of the rand. However, these attempts failed to prevent the depreciation of the rand. The Reserve Bank ended up with what was known as a net open forward position (also known as the international liquidity position of the Reserve Bank), that increased from negative $12.7 billion in April 1998 to negative $23.2 billion in September 1998. After the events of 1998 the Bank decided against such practices. When the rand again came under pressure in 2001, the Bank did not intervene in the forex market. The rand depreciated significantly (as it might have done even had the Reserve Bank intervened). However, after a couple of months foreign investors realised that the rand was significantly undervalued, and its earlier depreciation was reversed. In January 2019 the international liquidity position of the Reserve Bank was positive $44 billion. Note: While it is true that the Reserve Bank does not formally fix the exchange rate in this system, it is as true that its participation or intervention in the market always constitutes a form of policy influence (‘control’) of the exchange rate. The exchange rate is not determined by market forces alone. However, any intervention cannot continue indefinitely – ultimately, market forces will be decisive. A system of fixed exchange rates occurs when this intervention of the Reserve Bank is so absolutely dominant that it effectively pegs the exchange rate at a particular level (even if it is technically free to move). This system can be illustrated as follows: ❐ Suppose the Reserve Bank wants to prevent the rand from going above, for example, $1 = R10.00. All it has to do is to be willing to flood the market with rands at that rate (price) – i.e. supply any amount of rands at that price, no matter how large the demand for rands. Then no foreigner would have to pay more than $0.10 for a rand. Whatever the demand for rands, no upward pressure on the rand can occur. In effect, the rand is fixed or ‘pegged’ at that rate. ❐ Likewise, if the Reserve Bank wants to prevent the rand from depreciating below $1 = R10.00, all it has to do is purchase all rands offered to the market at that price. If it is willing to buy whatever quantity is supplied, no downward pressure on the rand can develop, and its value cannot fall below that level. In effect, the exchange rate is fixed. ❐ If there is downward pressure on the rand due to substantial selling of rands, and if the foreign reserves are insufficient to finance further purchases of rands, the Bank will not be able to counter the downward pressure on the rand. All it can do then is to allow the rand to fall to a new ‘floor price’. This is what is meant by the term devaluation: an explicit policy decision to go to a lower floor price for the rand. (Thus devaluation is the fixed exchange rate equivalent of depreciation.) Conversely, a policy decision to peg the rate at a higher level is called revaluation. ❐ Note that even fixed exchange rates are not fixed by law. Fixed exchange rates are similar to any system of floor prices and price ceilings. From 1946 to 1971 most Western countries had a system of fixed exchange rates – the outcome of the so-called Bretton Woods Agreement. After 1971, various countries experimented with freely floating exchange rates and systems of controlled, or dirty, floating. 4.3 The balance of payments and exchange rates How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 169 169 2019/12/17 09:15 4.3.3 The BoP and exchange rates: a restatement and summary The basic linkages between internal economic variables and different external sector variables are complex but fascinating, and can be summarised as follows. ❐ The exchange rate is determined by the net inflow or outflow of funds. Thus the BoP position is a decisive factor. In turn the BoP position is determined (caused) by changes in exports and imports (current account) and in capital inflows (financial account). ❐ The current account (X – M) influences total expenditure (C I G X M) – and thus also production GDP and Y – directly. ❐ The financial account on its own has no direct short-term effect on expenditure (see section 4.2.2). ❐ In other words, the real sector is influenced, in the first instance, by the current account, since it affects expenditure directly. ❐ The monetary sector is influenced by the current account and financial accounts together, i.e. by the BoP, and not by the financial account alone. (Of course, this effect on the monetary sector will subsequently impact on the real sector.) The current and financial accounts together, i.e. the BoP position, have two important consequences: (a) the money supply is influenced, and (b) the exchange rate is influenced. Normally one can expect the efOne should therefore take care not to argue the fect on the money supply to occur seemingly obvious, i.e. that the monetary sector is first. The effect on the exchange influenced by the financial account (as the expected rate is likely to become apparent parallel argument for the influence of the current somewhat later. Though the effect account on the real sector). It is incorrect reasoning. of the balance of payments on the exchange rate is direct (through the interaction of the supply and demand for currency), the effect very often is strengthened and even triggered when news about the size of the current account deficit (or surplus) is published and discussed in the media and financial circles. These changes in the money supply and in the exchange rate will then have further effects on the economy (see below for complete chain reactions). The main consequences of exchange rate movements are changes in exports and imports, i.e. in the current account; however, capital inflows can also be affected. ❐ All this means that the exchange rate has an effect on the BoP. Therefore: ❐ There is an important interaction and two-way causation between the exchange rate and the BoP (and its components). ❐ In addition, both the exchange rate and the BoP have important links with the rest of the economy. At the same time, the real and monetary sectors of the economy also are in continuous two-way interaction, as analysed in chapter 3. How everything fits together will soon be demonstrated. First we must consider the so-called BoP adjustment The exchange rate also affects the rand price of process, which is an important part imported inputs, which can influence production costs and inflation. This is analysed in chapter 6. of the whole picture. 170 Chapter 4: The basic model III: the foreign sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 170 2019/12/17 09:15 4.4 ! The BoP adjustment process Important note to instructors and students Most textbooks explain the BoP adjustment process under either of two extreme exchange rate regimes: either fixed rates or fully flexible rates. While it simplifies the analysis, it limits the analysis to theoretically extreme cases. Most countries have a system of dirty floating exchange rates, hence the BoP adjustment process will exhibit elements of both pure systems. The analysis in this book integrates these elements into one chain of events, distinguishing between an initial and a later, concluding effect. The same approach is followed in the analysis in terms of the IS-LM and IS-LM-BP models in sections 4.7 and 4.8. The crux of the idea of a BoP adjustment process is that a BoP disequilibrium activates forces that tend to eliminate the disequilibrium. These forces operate via the abovementioned effects of the BoP on the money supply and the exchange rate. Suppose there is a BoP surplus (BoP > 0). One can then expect the following two adjustment effects: 1. Initial BoP effect: via the money supply (while the exchange rate is still relatively passive or rigid). 2. Concluding BoP effect: via the exchange rate (when it starts to adjust). Both of these effects will operate as long as there is a BoP disequilibrium (BoP 0). On the whole, what happens is the following complex chain reaction. This constitutes the BoP adjustment process: M BoP > 0 ⇒ (i) inflow of foreign exchange ⇒ P ⇒ i ⇒ I ⇒ total expenditure ⇒ Y ⇒ M ⇒ current account S ⇒ (ii) inflow of foreign exchange ⇒ excess demand for rands ⇒ rand ⇒ X and M ⇒ current account Both effects will cause the current account to deteriorate. Hence they will reduce the BoP surplus. Both these adjustment effects will continue as long as BoP 0, and hence continues to push the BoP towards equilibrium. When and if BoP equilibrium is reached, the process stops. In practice, the process will seldom reach equilibrium so smoothly. Moreover, it rarely happens that the adjustment process proceeds uninterrupted to the end. New disturbances may interfere. What is important is the basic direction of the adjustment effects via the money supply and the exchange rate. The BoP adjustment is not the end of the story either. The deterioration of the current account will, in turn, have a cooling-down effect on expenditure and GDP, with the accompanying secondary downward pressure on interest rates (see section 4.5). 4.4 The BoP adjustment process How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 171 171 2019/12/17 09:15 ✍ Suppose BoP < 0 ⇒ ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ ! 4.5 Remember that, as with other chain reactions, there continues to be much uncertainty, especially regarding the speed and smoothness of the adjustment process. At each step people have to take decisions and make choices. Nothing adjusts automatically or mechanically. Ultimately, everything that occurs is the result of the (responsible or irresponsible) decisions of human beings. The complete model – the BoP, the exchange rate and the domestic economy Our model has been developed sufficiently to analyse the expected consequences of any internal or external disturbance (as reflected in changes in foreign trade or in capital flows). It is illustrated with the same three examples introduced in section 4.3.1 – although with the direction of change reversed – followed by an exposition of a general method. At the same time we will consider the impact of the exchange rate and BoP adjustment on the effectiveness of fiscal and monetary policy steps – a recurring theme in all chapters thus far. Each of these examples now includes three secondary effects, a concept first introduced in chapter 3 and its IS-LM analysis (e.g. sections 3.2.2 and 3.3.6). ❐ As mentioned before, in practice the primary and secondary effects are not neatly separated in time as distinct steps that follow one another ­– say, as if an increase in Y is followed by a distinct increase in money demand. The secondary effects concurrently become operational as the primary effect gathers speed. Different secondary effects may, though, have different dynamics and time spans. Nevertheless, their typical effect is to either curb or turn around initial changes in key macroeconomic variables such as real income Y and the real interest rate r. ❐ In the open economy there are more secondary effects – three – than in the closed economy, where there is one only. As we will see, the secondary effects flowing from the balance of payments are likely to commence a while later, but will still unfold parallel and concurrent to ongoing changes in main variables. 172 Chapter 4: The basic model III: the foreign sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 172 2019/12/17 09:15 4.5.1 Monetary policy steps – consequences and effectiveness Example 1: the internal and external effects of a cut in the repo rate Primary effect: (1) Lower repo rate ⇒ banks pay less for Reserve Bank accommodation ⇒ banks encourage credit creation ⇒ money supply expands ⇒ excess supply of money ⇒ increase in acquistion of money market paper ⇒ prices of money market paper rise ⇒ decrease in nominal (and real) interest rates ⇒ capital formation I encouraged ⇒ aggregate demand increases ⇒ production encouraged ⇒ Y increases (= upswing in the economy). As Y increases ⇒ imports M increase (why?) ⇒ current account (CA) deficit develops. The decrease in r causes an outflow of foreign capital, leaving the financial account (FA) in a deficit. Together these two effects imply that a balance of payments deficit develops: BoP < 0. Secondary effects: (2) Money market effect: As Y increases, it causes the demand for money to increase concurrently ⇒ upward pressure on interest rates ⇒ initial drop in interest rates gradually comes to an end ⇒ initial increase in investment is curbed ⇒ initial increase in aggregate demand arrested ⇒ increase in Y brought to an end ⇒ rise in M arrested and initial weakening of (X – M) comes to an end. ❐ The main impact of this secondary effect is that the changes in r, I, Y and M will be smaller than they would have been, had there been no such effect via money demand. While this secondary effect operates in the opposite direction from the primary effect, it is a weaker force. The secondary effect does not cancel the primary effect, it only reduces it. The net effect of the primary and secondary effects leaves Y higher, r lower and both the current and financial accounts in deficit. There is a BoP deficit (BoP < 0). Further secondary effects due to BoP < 0: (3) Initial BoP effect (foreign reserves adjustment): The BoP deficit causes (i) an outflow of foreign exchange ⇒ money supply decreases ⇒ upward pressure on interest rates (which causes the outflow of foreign capital to decrease or reverse and the financial account deficit to decrease); the increase in the interest rate discourages real investment I ⇒ aggregate demand/expenditure decreases, causing Y to decrease; as Y decreases it dampens imports ⇒ (X – M) increases ⇒ prevailing current account deficit is reduced; the turnaround in the real interest rate will also start to encourage or reverse capital outflows; thus the financial account is likely to start improving. On both fronts, the BoP deficit is being reduced. The contraction in Y implies that the initial upswing has turned around (for now …). (4) Concluding BoP effect (exchange rate adjustment): The initial BoP deficit also leads to (ii) an excess supply of rand (excess demand for foreign exchange) ⇒ downward pressure on the rand ⇒ stimulation of exports and discouragement of imports ⇒ (X – M) increases ⇒ current account deficit is reduced, and so is the remaining BoP deficit. The BoP tends towards equilibrium. The process will continue as long as BoP ≠ 0 and until BoP = 0. 4.5 The complete model – the BoP, the exchange rate and the domestic economy How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 173 173 2019/12/17 09:15 This cumulative increase in (X – M) due to these two BoP effects again boosts aggregate expenditure, which reverses the short decline in Y – the economic upswing resumes (Y expands again). It is likely that the foreign reserves effect (phase 3 above) will come about sooner than the exchange rate effect (phase 4). Summary of changes It is interesting to note the changes that occur in the main macroeconomic variables, i.e. income Y, interest rate, rand, BoP and exchange rate. In particular, consider the beha­ In this way the BoP adjustment process may cause viour of income Y. Following an a cyclical movement in Y, or will at least have a initial upswing in income (held restraining effect in the later phases of an upswing back somewhat by the secondary, (or downswing). Thus one finds signs of inherent money market effect), the BoP sources of cyclical movements in production and adjustment activates monetary income in the BoP adjustment process. In practice, forces in the opposite direction this factor in itself is not sufficient to explain the larger – via foreign reserves – which cyclical movements in the economy. However, it does reverse the upswing and pushes contribute to cyclical forces and fluctuations. Y into the early phases of a downswing. However, before long the exchange rate adjustment again places upward pressure on income – the downswing Figure 4.9 Illustrative time path of key variables due to a decrease in the repo rate may be short lived, and an upswing period may recur. Thus the net effect of all these processes on Y is likely to be positive. Interest rates first decrease, only to experience repeated upward pressure in later stages. The net effect should be a rate decline. The rand depreciates during the latter stages of the BoP adjustment phase (phase 4). This depreciation is the main cause of the final upswing towards the end – mainly because the depreciation stimulates exports and discourages imports, thereby boosting aggregate expenditure. The balance of payments goes into deficit, which is then reversed. The current and financial accounts change as side-effects of the primary and secondary effects. ❐ This is in contrast to example 3 that follows (the case of an export stimulus), where the primary effect (i.e. initial disturbance) will directly and immediately influence the current account. The diagram in figure 4.9 is a stylised illus­ tration of the course of these main variables 174 r Time Y Time Rand Time BoP BoP adjustment phase Demand expansion op to 3 years Chapter 4: The basic model III: the foreign sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 174 2019/12/17 09:15 over time during the primary and three secondary effects. Study it carefully and see whether it conforms to your understanding of the whole chain reaction. ❐ Of course, in reality time paths never are so smooth, and shocks and disturbances occur simultaneously. Our purpose here is to isolate the basic directional effects encountered by an open economy following an initial stimulus. The effectiveness of monetary policy Note that the basic impact of the monetary policy step on real income is countered by the foreign reserve, or money supply, effect of the BoP. This effect can take place because, and as long as, the exchange rate is rigid or slow to adjust. Subsequently, however, the flexible exchange rate effect does the opposite and boosts the potency of monetary policy. For practical monetary policy, it is important to ascertain which of these effects will dominate in practice. Monetary stimulation in a situation with fixed or very rigid exchange rates has been called ‘sending the money supply overseas’. Example 1 illustrates how, for a decrease in the repo rate, a BoP deficit develops as a result of the monetary stimulation. That implies an outflow of funds/money, which contracts the money supply. That means that the initial monetary stimulus is counteracted or even nullified by the BoP effect. When the exchange rate starts to adjust, it speeds up the elimination of the BoP deficit, which will counter the monetary contraction effect somewhat. In a fully free and quick-adjusting floating exchange rate system, the exchange rate will adjust so rapidly that the BoP deficit does not even get the opportunity to emerge. Then there would be no opportunity or reasons for the money supply outflow to take place. The monetary policy impact will be 100%. However, if the exchange rate adjusts very slowly or not at all, the money supply effect has ample opportunity to manifest itself, implying a considerable outflow of money. Then one can indeed say that the money supply is simply being ‘sent overseas’, with little domestic monetary impact of the monetary policy step. This produces the important policy conclusion that rigid exchange rates undermine the potency of monetary policy, while a quick-adjusting exchange rate enhances the effectiveness of monetary policy. ❐ In the extreme case of a fixed exchange rate regime, and if capital is perfectly mobile, the outflow of capital following monetary stimulation would completely offset the initial stimulation. The rigid exchange rate effect is dominant, and monetary policy would be entirely ineffective. ❐ In the other extreme of an instantly adjusting floating exchange rate, monetary policy would be maximally effective: any monetary stimulus is boosted since falling interest rates weaken the domestic currency, which stimulates net exports (X – M). The flexible exchange rate effect dominates. 4.5 The complete model – the BoP, the exchange rate and the domestic economy How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 175 175 2019/12/17 09:15 4.5.2 Fiscal policy steps – consequences and effectiveness Example 2: the internal and external effects of a cutback in government expenditure Primary effect: (1) Reduction in government expenditure ⇒ aggregate expenditure decreases ⇒ negative impact on domestic production ⇒ real income Y decreases. As Y decreases ⇒ imports M decrease ⇒ a current account surplus develops. Secondary effects: (2) Money market effect: As Y decreases, it causes a concurrent decrease in the demand for money ⇒ downward pressure on interest rates ⇒ encouragement of real investment I ⇒ increase in aggregate demand, partially countering the impact of the initial reduction in government expenditure ⇒ curbs the fall in Y ⇒ decline in M curtailed and initial strengthening of (X – M) comes to an end. The net effect of the primary effect and the secondary, money market effect leaves Y lower, r lower and (X – M) > 0, i.e. a current account (CA) surplus. The decrease in r causes an outflow of foreign capital, causing a deficit on the financial account (FA). The net effect on the BoP is uncertain: depending on the relative size of the CA and FA positions, the BoP = CA + FA could be in balance, in a surplus or in a deficit. Since the state of the BoP is decisive for the further BoP adjustment effects, we must make some assumptions here. If foreign investors consider the economy well-integrated into the global economy, international capital flows will be relatively sensitive to domestic interest rate changes. Therefore, should interest rates decrease as a result of the secondary effect, there will be a relatively large outflow of foreign capital. Thus, one might expect the deficit on the FA to exceed the surplus on the CA, in which case BoP < 0. We assume this case to apply to South Africa at the moment. ❐ If capital flows were not that sensitive to domestic real interest changes, the deficit on the FA would have been smaller than the surplus on the CA – implying a BoP surplus. Thus we have further secondary effects due to BoP < 0: (3) Initial BoP effect (foreign reserves adjustment): The BoP deficit causes (i) an outflow of foreign exchange ⇒ contraction in money supply ⇒ upward pressure on interest rates (which causes the outflow of foreign capital to decrease or reverse and the FA deficit to decrease); the increase in the interest rate also discourages real investment I ⇒ aggregate demand/expenditure decreases, causing Y to decrease; as Y decreases it dampens imports ⇒ (X – M) increases ⇒ prevailing CA surplus is reduced; however, the turnaround in the real interest rate will also start to reverse capital outflows; thus the FA deficit is likely to start being reversed. Assuming a stronger FA effect, the net effect would be that the BoP deficit is being reduced. The decrease in Y implies that the initial downswing has been followed by a continuation of the downswing that exacerbates the decline in Y. (4) Concluding BoP effect (exchange rate adjustment): The initial BoP deficit also leads to (ii) an excess supply of rand (excess demand for foreign exchange) ⇒ downward pressure on the rand ⇒ stimulation of exports and discouragement of imports ⇒ increase in (X – M) ⇒ current account surplus increases again. This helps to eliminate the 176 Chapter 4: The basic model III: the foreign sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 176 2019/12/17 09:15 remaining BoP deficit – the BoP tends towards equilibrium. The process will continue as long as BoP ≠ 0 and until BoP = 0. Note how, towards the end, the depreciation of the rand is responsible, via an induced increase in (X – M), for a stimulation of aggregate expenditure. This reverses the twophase contraction of Y – a small recovery begins when Y increases. Summary of changes Following an initial contraction of real income Y (held back somewhat by the secondary, money market effect), the BoP adjustment activates monetary forces in the same direction – via foreign reserves – which exacerbates the decline in Y into a deeper recession. Only after the exchange rate adjustment occurs do we see the first signs of recovery. Real income would have gone through a business cycle trough – which is no surprise, given the contractionary fiscal step that initiated everything. Only at the end is there a small recovery. Interest rates first decrease, but in the BoP adjustment stages they experience upward pressure twice. The net effect should still be a rate decrease, though. The rand depreciates during the latter stages of the BoP adjustment phase (phase 4). This depreciation is the main cause of the final recovery down towards the end – the depreciation stimulates exports and discourages imports, thereby boosting aggre­ gate expenditure. Figure 4.10 Illustrative time path of key variables due to a government expenditure cutback r Time Y Time Rand Time BoP BoP adjustment phase The balance of payments goes into deficit, Demand contraction which is then reversed. The current and up to 3 years financial accounts play complex roles in this process, since they often move in contradictory directions. The effectiveness of fiscal policy The basic impact of a fiscal policy step – whether contractionary or expansionary – on real income is strengthened by the money supply effect of the balance of payments. The flexible exchange rate effect – depreciation or appreciation – works in the opposite direction. This produces the important conclusion, as regards South Africa, that a rigid or fixed exchange rate strengthens the potency of fiscal policy, while a quick-adjusting exchange rate undermines its effectiveness. 4.5 The complete model – the BoP, the exchange rate and the domestic economy How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 177 177 2019/12/17 09:15 4.5.3 External disturbances Example 3: the effect of an economic downswing in the USA on the SA economy Primary effect: (1) Lower YUSA ⇒ US imports MUSA decrease ⇒ decreased imports from abroad, including South Africa ⇒ XSA decreases ⇒ (X – M) decreases, i.e. cur­ rent account goes into defi­ cit ⇒ aggregate expenditure decreases ⇒ production dis­ couraged ⇒ Y declines. (2) As Y decreases, a concurrent decrease in imports M de­ velops ⇒ positive impact on (X – M), i.e. current account (CA) improves a bit. The importance of diagrammatical aids These examples demonstrate that it can become quite bewildering to sort out the complexities of open-economy chain reactions. This is why it is so important to master, and use, appropriate diagrammatical aids to guide and check our chainreaction thinking. From the initial 45o model we developed the IS-LM in chapter 3, which offers a concise and powerful ‘roadmap’ to analyse chain reactions. Later in this chapter it is expanded by including the BP curve, which enables us to bring the state of the balance of payments, and the BoP adjustment process, into the graphical analysis. The net effect on the current account will still be a substantial deterioration. Secondary effects: (3) Money market effect: As real income Y declines, the real demand for money decreases ⇒ downward pressure on real interest rates, which, in turn, causes investment to increase ⇒ upward pressure on aggregate demand ⇒ initial decrease in aggregate demand countered ⇒ production encouraged ⇒ decrease in Y curbed, downswing comes to an end; drop in M arrested and deterioration in CA comes to an end; CA in deficit. The decrease in interest rates should lead to an outflow of foreign capital, which hurts the financial account (FA) – the FA will be in a deficit. The net effect of the primary effect and the secondary effect leaves Y lower, r lower and the current and financial accounts in deficit. Thus the BoP will have a deficit. Thus we have further secondary effects due to BoP < 0: (4) Initial BoP effect (foreign reserves adjustment): The BoP deficit causes (i) an outflow of foreign exchange ⇒ money supply decreases ⇒ upward pressure on interest rates (which causes the outflow of foreign capital to decrease); higher rates discourage real investment I ⇒ aggregate demand/expenditure decreases, causing Y to decrease further; as Y decreases it dampens imports ⇒ (X – M) increases ⇒ prevailing CA deficit is reduced. The rise in interest rates will encourage capital inflows, so the existing FA deficit will shrink. (5) Concluding BoP effect (exchange rate adjustment): The initial BoP deficit also leads to (ii) an excess supply of rands (excess demand for foreign exchange) ⇒ downward pressure on the rand ⇒ stimulation of exports and discouragement of imports ⇒ increases (X – M) ⇒ CA deficit is reduced. This depreciation-induced increase in (X – M) boosts aggregate expenditure, which turns around the sustained downswing. Y will increase, also pulling up interest rates. 178 Chapter 4: The basic model III: the foreign sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 178 2019/12/17 09:15 The financial account will improve further, and so will the remaining BoP deficit. The BoP tends towards equilibrium. The process will continue as long as BoP ≠ 0 and until BoP = 0. Summary of changes Figure 4.11 Illustrative time path of key variables due In contrast to example 1 (internal monetary to a decrease in exports disturbance), where the current account changed mainly as part of the BoP r adjustment phase, in this case the initial disturbance directly and immediately affects the current account. As a result, the current account pattern is somewhat intricate: Time ❐ The current account deteriorates initially, due to the direct role of exports. Y As income decreases due to the export decline, imports are likely to start declining. This will restrain the current account deterioration. On balance the Time current account will still deteriorate. Later, when the balance of payment Rand adjustment process comes into play, the current account improves due to changes in income and the exchange rate. Time ❐ The financial account is hurt by the secondary, money market impact on BoP interest rates and goes into deficit, but later improves during the BoP adjustment processes. BoP adjustment phase ❐ Income declines due to the export shock and then again due to the initial BoP Demand contraction adjustment effect, but then recovers due up to 3 years to the depreciation of the rand. ❐ The real interest rate first drops, but increases in the BoP adjustment phases. ❐ The rand depreciates in the later stages of the BoP adjustment process, when it is the main cause of the final recovery at the end. Theoretically the BoP surplus should be eliminated at the end, since the BoP adjustment process should continue until BoP = 0. In practice, the process rarely gets to equilibrium so effortlessly. Nevertheless, the basic nature and direction of the adjustment process is unchanged. The export shock example appears similar to the fiscal contraction example. Note the following differences, though: ❐ In the fiscal contraction example, a CA surplus develops, but it is overshadowed by a FA deficit, hence a (small) BoP deficit develops. In the export example, a substantial CA deficit develops immediately, on top of which a FA deficit develops, so that the BoP deteriorates much quicker and goes into a much larger deficit. ❐ The BoP adjustment process is much longer in the export example. ❐ The rise of r during the BoP adjustment is larger in the export example, due to the larger BoP deficit and its effects on the money supply. 4.5 The complete model – the BoP, the exchange rate and the domestic economy How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 179 179 2019/12/17 09:15 ❐ The downswing in Y is likely to last longer than in the fiscal example. In all these examples the change in the exchange rate is, simultaneously, a symptom of one condition, but also the cause or source of a new phase. More specifically, one can say that a depreciating rand is a symptom of a BoP deficit, but also the seed of the BoP recovery process. Note that a rigid exchange rate heightens the domestic effects – whether negative or positive – of a change in exports, while a quickly adjusting exchange rate puts a damper on export-led economic fluctuations. (This parallels the conclusion about the positive impact of a slowly adjusting exchange rate on the effectiveness of fiscal policy, but in this case it makes export-led downswings worse.) Remark All these examples are still incomplete, since the effect on the price level is omitted. This will be rectified in chapter 6. 4.5.4 Analysing internal and external disturbances – a general method What follows is a general method to analyse the complete, expected consequences of any internal or external disturbance, as reflected in a change in foreign trade or capital inflows. Internal disturbances 1. Derive the primary effect of (i.e. initial impact on) internal variables such as expenditure components, aggregate expenditure and thus Y. Also derive the endogenous effect on the current account. 2. Following the primary effect, derive the concurrent secondary internal effect and its endogenous impact on the current account. Derive the net effect on Y. 3. Summarise the effects of steps 1 and 2 on both the current account and the financial account (itself the result of the interest rate change occurring in steps 1 and 2). 4. Show the initial BoP adjustment process (rigid exchange rate or foreign reserves effect). 5. Show the concluding BoP adjustment process (flexible exchange rate effect). Finally, note the impacts of steps 4 and 5 on expenditure and Y (as well as other relevant variables). Summarise the movements and net effect on different variables. External disturbances 1. Derive the initial exogenous impact on the current or financial account, and the ensuing effect on internal variables such as aggregate expenditure and thus Y. Also identify any concurrent endogenous effect on the current account (and/or financial account) that is likely to accompany these changes. In this way determine the net, combined effect on the BoP. 2. Following the primary effect, derive the concurrent secondary internal effect and its endogenous impact on the current account. Derive the net effect on Y. 3. Summarise the effects of steps 1 and 2 on both the current account and the financial account (itself the result of the interest rate change occurring in steps 1 and 2). 4. Show the initial BoP adjustment process (rigid exchange rate or money supply effect). 5. Show the concluding BoP adjustment process (flexible exchange rate effect). 180 Chapter 4: The basic model III: the foreign sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 180 2019/12/17 09:15 Finally, note the impacts of steps 4 and 5 on expenditure and Y (as well as other relevant variables). Summarise the movements and net effect on different variables. At each juncture, take the time to ask why something happens, and what the expected consequences of that occurrence are likely to be as one moves along the chain reaction. ✍ Complete the following: Suppose taxation is decreased ⇒ _____________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ Suppose the rand depreciates strongly ⇒ _____________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ 4.5.5 Chain reactions in reverse – the likely causes of events We can use our knowledge of the linkages and interactions between internal and external variables to uncover the likely causes of observed changes in economic variables. That is, we return to possible chain reactions, searching for the likely source of changes. For example, what are the likely causes of the following occurrences? (a) A depreciation of the rand Answer: An excess supply of rands on the foreign exchange market, which is likely to be a reflection of a net outflow of payments via the current and/or financial accounts (i.e. a BoP deficit). Of course, the likely causes of the latter can also be, for example, a withdrawal of capital (investment) by foreigners. (b) Increasing interest rates Answer: The immediate cause is either an increase in money demand or a decrease in the money supply, or both. The cause of the former is likely to be an economic upswing 4.5 The complete model – the BoP, the exchange rate and the domestic economy How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 181 181 2019/12/17 09:15 (increase in Y), i.e. some stimulus on the economy, or a large budget deficit that is financed via domestic borrowing. A money supply contraction can follow from either: ❐ internal causes, the main candidates being one or several restrictive monetary policy steps; or ❐ an external factor that has resulted in a BoP deficit (which implies a leakage of money from the domestic economy). (c) A depreciating rand and increasing interest rates occurring together Answer: (Complete by eliminating some of the possible causes identified in (a) and (b). ______________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________ (d) A current account deterioration Answer: (Complete) ______________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________ The budget deficit and the BoP It is important to note certain important linkages between the budget deficit and the BoP: ❐ Foreign loans to finance a budget deficit imply an inflow of foreign capital. This links the budget deficit and the BoP (which may be in deficit or surplus). ❐ Such a linkage also emerges where a budget deficit is financed via domestic borrowing. The upward pressure that it may put on interest rates can attract foreign capital, which will strengthen the financial account, and thus the BoP. The crowding out of exports by a budget deficit With the exception of the late 1990s and early 2000s, the last linkage has been a major issue in the USA since the 1980s. It is argued that a budget deficit financed by domestic borrowing pushes up interest rates. Given the high sensitivity of international capital to US interest rates, this causes a significant inflow of capital. The subsequent demand for dollars causes the dollar to appreciate. In turn, this discourages foreign purchases of US goods (as reflected in a current account deficit). Therefore, US exports are restricted – or ‘crowded out’ – by the budget deficit. This association between the budget deficit and the current account deficit is known as the ‘twin deficit phenomenon’. ❐ This effect can only occur in a country with high international capital mobility, and can only occur in a system of floating (or controlled floating) exchange rates. ❐ This effect decreases the fiscal multiplier, because the restriction of exports counteracts any fiscal stimulation. ✍ 182 The world financial crisis of October 2007–08: open economy aspects We introduced this case study in section 3.4 – reread that section. Now try to deduce what the accompanying open-economy changes would be for the US economy due to the various changes in the US rate of interest and GDP indicated by the analysis and diagram. Secondly, what would be the expected effects on South African exports, imports or capital flows – and hence on internal variables such as GDP? Chapter 4: The basic model III: the foreign sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 182 2019/12/17 09:15 (e) A financial account improvement Answer: Possible causes include high interest rates relative to the rest of the world, new foreign confidence in the growth potential of the South African economy and/or foreign optimism about the political stability in South Africa. (f) A shrinking balance of payments deficit Answer: (Complete.) ______________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________ 4.5.6 Thirteen open economy puzzles 1. Is a weak rand relative to, for example, the dollar a good thing or a bad thing? And a strong rand? ______________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________ 2. Is a balance of payments surplus good and a deficit bad? Sustained BoP surpluses are not necessarily desirable. Sustained surpluses imply that the foreign reserves of a country are increasing all the time. If foreign reserves are in excess of what is required to finance any foreseeable BoP deficit, it amounts to an unnecessary hoarding of wealth that is not being used to improve living standards in the country. It would be better to use it to import goods that can improve the standard of living of the inhabitants of the country. BoP deficits are a problem when the foreign reserves are near exhaustion and the financing of the deficit becomes a problem (i.e. the country does not have sufficient foreign currency reserves to pay for imports). Sustained deficits or continuously deteriorating deficits especially are a source of anxiety. On the other hand, temporary or short-term deficits need not be a cause for concern. 3. Why does government have to wait for a considerable current account surplus to be present before it can institute measures to stimulate the economy? ______________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________ 4. Is a sustained current account surplus (or current account deficit) a good (or bad) thing? A current account deficit need not be a problem if it is accompanied by sufficient capital inflows (a financial account surplus). However, if a country experiences shortfalls in capital inflows (as South Africa has at times), a sustained current account deficit can cause very serious BoP and foreign reserve problems. Whether a current account deficit is a problem also depends on the phase of the business cycle at a particular moment. A current account deficit at the beginning of 4.5 The complete model – the BoP, the exchange rate and the domestic economy How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 183 183 2019/12/17 09:15 an upswing phase is particularly undesirable since any growth in economic activity will stimulate imports, exacerbate the deficit and put the foreign reserves under pressure. However, at the end of an upswing phase a current account deficit is less of a problem, being a natural side-effect of the upswing (why?) that is likely to disappear during the subsequent downswing (why?). ! For a country with high international capital mobility – meaning that changes in interest rates would elicit a strong capital flow reaction – current account deficits might be less of a problem. Together with the deteriorating current account that accompanies an upswing, one would usually also find upward movement in interest rates (as a secondary effect). If the increase in the interest rate elicits a strong inflow of foreign capital, it can improve the financial account to such an extent that any current account deficit is easily financed, without pressure on foreign reserves. In such a situation, the current account side-effect of an upswing presents no problem at all. ❐ The correct economic reasoning will, therefore, depend on the country concerned and its particular economic characteristics. 5. What is the likely effect of high South African inflation (relative to its main trading partners) on the external value of the rand? ______________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________ 6. How is it possible that gold and platinum mines can show low profits in a period when the international gold and platinum prices are high (and vice versa)? ______________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________ Questions 7 to 11 should be tackled as a group. They are intended to challenge the reader to put together a number of causal relationships in the international arena. Individually they are not complex, but when combined they constitute a powerful set of linkages which are essential to understanding some of the most important interrelationships and transfer of shocks between South Africa and the global economy. 7. High American interest rates and a strong dollar often occur simultaneously. Why would that be? (Is the same true for South African interest rates and the rand?) ______________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________ 184 Chapter 4: The basic model III: the foreign sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 184 2019/12/17 09:15 8. A strengthening of the US dollar on foreign exchange markets often occurs in concert with a drop in the gold price. Can you think of a possible explanation or linkage? (Can there be a similar link between the oil price and the US dollar?) ______________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________ 9. Therefore, it often happens that, when the gold price increases, the rand simultaneously appreciates (and vice versa). Why would this be? (Can there be a similar link between the oil price and the rand?) ______________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________ 10. Therefore: what is a possible four-way linkage between US interest rates, the dollar, the rand and the gold price? How does the oil price link up with this foursome? ______________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________ 11. Finally: can you derive an important linkage between the American budget deficit, the dollar, the rand and the gold price? ______________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________ 12. What is the link between the American budget deficit, the American current account deficit, and the American financial account surplus? (Hint: See the preceding discussion about the ‘twin deficit phenomenon’ and the crowding out of exports.) ______________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________ 4.5 The complete model – the BoP, the exchange rate and the domestic economy How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 185 185 2019/12/17 09:15 13. What is a link between the American budget deficit, the American current account deficit, the Chinese current account surplus and the value of the US dollar relative to the Chinese yuan? ______________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________ 4.6 Conflict between internal and external considerations The previous discussion demonstrates the existence of important linkages between internal economic variables (e.g. interest rates, GDP, unemployment, the budget deficit) and external variables (e.g. the exchange rate, the BoP). It is important to note that desirable changes in internal variables do not necessarily augur well for external variables – and vice versa. For example, whereas high interest rates may be ‘good’ for the financial account and foreign reserves, they are detrimental to investment (and homeowners, due to high bond rates). An important tension exists between the BoP and unemployment considerations. This conflict manifests itself in South Africa during the course of each business cycle. During an upswing, unemployment decreases, but the current account deteriorates. During a downswing, the external position improves, while unemployment deteriorates. This tension is less severe if capital flows are relatively sensitive to interest rate changes. Rising interest rates associated with the secondary effect of an economic upswing will stimulate capital inflows and cause a financial account surplus that may match or even exceed the current account deficit. Thus capital inflows provide more than enough cover for the outflow of payments on the current account. ❐ However, the Reserve Bank might still be concerned about the sustainability of such capital inflows – particularly when these flows mostly comprise easily reversible portfolio flows (e.g. financial investments on the JSE and not foreign direct investment). Therefore, the central bank might still wish to reduce the deficit on the current account and thereby reduce the risk of a sudden reversal on the financial account for the economy. ✍ If there is low capital mobility, the combination of a BoP deficit and an overheated economy is not a policy problem. Why would this be? On the other hand, a BoP surplus combined with unemployment is not a problem irrespective of capital mobility. Why? ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ The tension between a deteriorating current account and a decrease in unemployment creates a policy dilemma: stimulation of the economy to alleviate unemployment hurts the 186 Chapter 4: The basic model III: the foreign sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 186 2019/12/17 09:15 current account, with concomitant pressure on foreign reserves. One way to address the current account deficit is to use policy to constrict income Y. However, that will increase unemployment. In the South African context this unavoidable tension creates a severe predicament for policymakers and politicians. Although inflation – one of the most important dimensions of internal equilibrium – is discussed in later chapters, it is necessary to note two open-economy linkages concerning inflation: ❐ To the extent that aggregate expenditure is affected by current account, BoP and exchange rate changes, aggregate demand in the economy is influenced. This implies a potential influence on the average price level and, therefore, inflation. ❐ Since the exchange rate directly influences the cost of imported inputs, it has critical implications for cost-push and supply-side inflation. All these linkages simultaneously bring a larger number of objectives or considerations into play, and make the evaluation of any particular internal–external situation that much more difficult. The ideal may be to attain all internal as well as external objectives. As we shall see, however, the relationships and causal linkages between economic variables often make the simultaneous achievement of important policy goals impossible. Situations that require a complex ‘trade-off ’ – where one objective can be pursued only at the cost of another – develop quite often. The preceding remarks on inflation highlight an important aspect: this discussion of openeconomy macroeconomic aspects still is incomplete since the price level and inflation have not been incorporated. Likewise, any discussion of inflation that excludes external considerations is, equally, incomplete. Therefore, we shall return to the foreign sector in chapter 6, when the price level is introduced into the model. Trade policy In such difficult situations, the standard fiscal and monetary policy package is not sufficient, and other policy instruments have to be considered. The instruments of trade policy, e.g. tariff or import quotas, are important examples in the open economy. ❐ A tariff is a tax on imported items that increases the effective price of those imported goods. This discourages imports. Quotas are quantitative restrictions on the quantities of goods that may be imported. ❐ Tariffs and quotas are important since they may be used to restrict imports directly – in contrast to the indirect restraining of imports by contracting total expenditure. ❐ A government can also pay a subsidy to local producers, allowing them to reduce their price to below the price of the imported goods. The European Union is very often accused by low- and middle-income countries that are dependent on agricultural exports of protecting European farmers with such subsidies. Governments of these countries have been debating this issue (as well as other trade issues) for years in the so-called Doha rounds, without reaching a final deal. (Doha is a city in Qatar where the first round of negotiation took place.) ❐ The desirability of implementing tariffs and quotas has been hotly debated in policy circles with little indication that consensus will be reached in the foreseeable future. The way these instruments affect the situation differs from normal fiscal or monetary policy steps. One side-effect of a direct measure such as tariffs is that it switches domestic expenditure from imports to domestic production (while aggregate expenditure remains unchanged). In the domestic economy this implies an expansion of total demand (which 4.6 Conflict between internal and external considerations How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 187 187 2019/12/17 09:15 may be desirable or undesirable at that stage). Since such a stimulation of demand may be unwanted for other reasons (e.g. inflation), policymakers must keep this expenditureswitching effect in mind. It may be necessary to add other policy steps to absorb the extra expenditure and limit the expansionary effect. ❐ Direct import-restricting steps are called a policy of ‘expenditure switching’. ❐ The indirect restraint of imports via a contraction of total expenditure is called a policy of ‘expenditure reduction’. ✍ What is the WTO? Why is it important for South Africa in these times? How does it affect our economic prospects? ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ What have been the main stumbling blocks in reaching a deal in the Doha rounds? ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ ______________________________________________________________________________________ 4.7 The IS-LM-BP model for an open economy In chapter 3 the IS-LM diagram was introduced and explained as a diagram that summarises the basic economic relationships in the monetary and real sectors. In principle, the IS and LM curves are not different in the open economy, although one should take note of certain open-economy aspects. In this section we add a new curve, the BP curve (or BoP curve). We show how this model can be used to add important open-economy insights, in particular a refined analysis regarding the BoP position and the ensuing BoP adjustment process. ! 188 Remember the warning, in chapter 2, that the IS-LM model – and therefore also the extended IS-LM-BP model – is a mechanical tool that encourages purely mechanical manipulation of curves. While it is very instructive and powerful, one should always use such diagrammatic manipulation only as a support system for economic logic and reasoning. Chapter 4: The basic model III: the foreign sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 188 2019/12/17 09:15 4.7.1 The IS curve in the open economy For the open-economy IS curve, aggregate expenditure must be defined to include net exports (X – M). Actually this is how the IS curve was defined and derived in chapter 3.4 Hence we do not have to add anything to that analysis. However, it is useful to highlight certain open-economy aspects of the IS curve. Changes in exports or imports caused by factors other than Y or r – e.g. changes in exchange rates or foreign economic conditions – would shift the IS curve. Examples 1. An upswing in the USA that is How far would IS shift? likely to increase US imports is The size of the expenditure multiplier affects the likely to boost South African distance that the IS curve would shift following an exports (including those to exogenous change in expenditure (chapter 3, section the USA) and thus aggregate 3.3.3). The higher the import propensity, the smaller expenditure. This would be the multiplier, and thus the smaller such a shift. reflected in a rightward shift of the IS curve, and a new equilibrium value of Y and r. 2. A BoP surplus in South Africa is likely to cause upward pressure on the external value of the rand. Such appreciation is likely to encourage imports and discourage exports. The net decline in (X – M) and, therefore, aggregate expenditure would be reflected in a leftward shift of the IS curve, to produce new equilibrium values of Y and r. The slope of the IS curve You will recall from chapter 3 (section 3.3.3) that the slope of the IS curve depends, inter alia, on the multiplier. In turn, the size of the multiplier depends on various ‘marginal leakage rates’. One of these is the marginal propensity to import. ❐ If the import propensity is high, the total leakage rate would be higher, and the multiplier smaller. This would make the IS curve steeper. A low import propensity would make the IS curve flatter. The higher the import propensity, the steeper the IS curve. ❐ Hence, the IS curve for an open economy would be steeper than one for a closed economy (an economy without any imports). 4.7.2 The LM curve in the open economy The LM curve was defined and derived in chapter 3 in terms of real money demand and real money supply in the economy. That derivation allowed for foreign sector influences in the monetary sphere. It is worth highlighting some of these. The slope of the LM curve, which depends mainly on the domestic demand for money, is not markedly different in an open economy. The position of the LM curve depends decisively on the money supply. International inflows and outflows of payments strongly influence the supply side of the money market. Such flows derive mainly from the BoP position. 4 Historically, the IS-LM model was developed primarily to analyse a closed economy. Most textbooks first derive the IS curve for the closed economy, and then add open-economy elements. 4.7 The IS-LM-BP model for an open economy How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 189 189 2019/12/17 09:15 ❐ For example, a BoP surplus implies an inflow of funds, which expands domestic liquidity. In terms of our analysis, this is equivalent to the effects of an expansionary monetary policy step in the form of an increase in the real money supply. The LM curve would therefore be shifted rightward by the money supply effect of a BoP surplus. A BoP deficit, which implies a net outflow of payments/funds, would shift the LM curve leftward. These characteristics are particularly important when one analyses the BoP adjustment process in the IS-LM diagram. Simultaneous equilibrium in the goods and money markets – the open economy case mathematically π We have the formula for the open economy IS curve: Y = KE(a + Ia – hr + G + X – ma)…… (4.4 = 3.5) where the multiplier in an open economy equals: 1 1 – b(1 – t) + m KE = and the formula for the LM curve: (M ) 1 r= k Y – l P 1 l …… (4.5 = 3.6) l S where the nominal money supply in an open economy equals: MS = D + eF where D represents domestic deposits, e, the exchange rate defined as the amount of domestic currency necessary to purchase one unit of foreign currency (e.g. 10 rands per dollar) and F represents foreign reserves (e.g. dollars, yens, euros). Foreign reserves multiplied by the exchange rate are added to the domestic money supply because the Reserve Bank and other domestic institutions that bought the foreign reserves had to pay for them with domestic money, i.e. rands in the South African case. These rands are now foreign-held deposits that can be used to buy South African goods priced in rands. In essence, by adding the foreign reserves multiplied by the exchange rate to domestic deposits, we add the value of foreign-held rand deposits to domestically held rand deposits – the sum of all deposits then constituting the money supply. Substituting equation (4.5) into (4.4) produces: ( [ ( )]) k 1 M l Y – l Y = KE (a + Ia + G + X – ma) – h P 1 lπ S Solving for Y and simplifying produces: MS Y = 1(a + Ia + G + X – ma) + 2 ( P 1 lπ) ...... (4.6) where KE 1 = 1 + K hk/l E K Eh 2 = l + K hk ...... (4.6.1) E Equation 4.6 shows how the equilibrium level of real income Y depends on expenditure elements as well as the real money supply – as captured in the IS and LM curves respectively. We will return to equation 4.6 in chapter 6 when we derive the aggregate demand (AD) curve. 190 Chapter 4: The basic model III: the foreign sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 190 2019/12/17 09:15 4.7.3 The BP curve The BP curve adds precision and clarity to the analysis of the BoP position and the adjustment process in an IS-LM framework. Essentially the curve provides a way to read the BoP condition, following a disturbance, directly off the diagram. In addition, it can be used to make the analysis of the BoP adjustment process in the diagram more explicit. This is shown in figure 4.12. The BP curve is a summary curve that depicts the external sector – imports, exports, capital flows and the BoP – on the r-Y axes. Like the IS and LM curves, it is a derived curve showing equilibrium points, in this instance in the external sector. ❐ Points on the curve indicate a state of BoP equilibrium. ❐ Points above the curve indicate a BoP surplus, and points below it indicate a BoP deficit. Essentials of the model This information on the BoP surplus and deficit areas can be used to characterise the external dimension of any internal economic equilibrium indicated by the intersection of the IS and LM curves. Thus one would analyse normal shifts in IS or LM, and get to an equilibrium point such as (r0; Y0). The diagram in figure 4.12 illustrates a point where r and Y (and X and M and capital inflows) are such that there is a BoP deficit. (The position of the BP curve as such may also have been affected by the initial disturbance.) Figure 4.12 The IS-LM-BP model r BoP surplus area LM curve BP curve r0 BoP deficit area IS curve Once the BoP situation at such a point has Y0 Income Y been derived, the expected BoP adjustment processes will follow. The BP curve may also shift due to this adjustment. Nevertheless, the process will take the equilibrium to a point on the BP curve. BoP equilibrium will have been attained, together with goods market and money market equilibria. All three sectors will be in simultaneous (short-run) equilibrium. The formal derivation of the BP curve The BP curve is defined as follows: The BP curve shows all combinations of real income Y and the interest rate r that are consistent with the conditions for BoP equilibrium (i.e. in the external sector). The BP is a series of points at which the BoP would be in equilibrium, were the economy to be on the curve. Where the economy is, depends on the location of the internal economic equilibrium, and consequently on the positions of the IS and LM curves. The BP curve indicates the BoP characteristics of that equilibrium. The shape of the BP derives from linkages between the BoP and the two variables on the axes, i.e. real income and the interest rate: ❐ Real income affects imports, which affect the current account of the BoP. ❐ Interest rates affect capital inflows, which affect the financial account of the BoP. 4.7 The IS-LM-BP model for an open economy How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 191 191 2019/12/17 09:15 The BP curve is derived as follows (see figure 4.13): ❐ Consider a pairing Y0 and r0 in the diagram which is consistent with balance of payment equilibrium. For a higher level of Y, a higher level of imports would be present. To counter this negative impact on the BoP and re-establish a point of BoP equilibrium, the real interest rate would have to be higher to attract the necessary capital inflows. ❐ Thus a second pairing (Y1 and r1) with BoP equilibrium would lie above and to the right of the first point. Any number of such points can be derived. Connecting them produces the BP curve. Figure 4.13 Deriving the BP curve r r1 r0 (r1;Y1) BP curve Y1 Income Y (r0;Y0) Y0 The slope of the BP curve The BP curve has a positive slope because, starting from a point with BoP equilibrium, a higher level of Y would imply higher imports, requiring a higher interest rate to attract sufficient capital inflows to re-establish BoP equilibrium. How steep is the BP curve? The steepness of the BP curve depends on how much the interest rate has to increase, given a certain increase in real income, to re-establish BoP equilibrium. Hence the relative steepness or flatness of the BP curve will depend on the following factors: (1) The income responsiveness of imports. If imports react strongly to a higher level of real income – the income responsiveness of imports is high – the interest rate would have to be significantly higher to attract sufficient capital to counter the outflow of payments on the current account. This would make the BP curve relatively steeper. A low income responsiveness of imports, on the other hand, would serve to make the BP curve relatively flatter. (2) The responsiveness of foreign capital flows to domestic real interest rates. If foreign capital inflows react strongly to higher domestic real interest rates, only a moderate increase in interest rates would be sufficient to counter the current account deterioration following a given increase in income. Therefore the BP curve would be relatively flatter. If foreign capital is less sensitive to domestic interest rates, the BP curve would be relatively steep. ❐ In everyday terms, this sensitivity can be understood in terms of capital mobility: low capital mobility to and from a country implies a fairly steep BP curve, and high capital mobility a fairly flat BP curve. ❐ Countries often differ much with regard to the degree of capital mobility. The income responsiveness of imports appears to be less decisive (although not irrelevant). For a country such as the USA, very high capital mobility would dominate import responsiveness effects. That is why its BP curve is very flat. For a country such as South Africa prior to 1994 or countries such as Zimbabwe and Lesotho, a high import propensity as well as relatively low capital mobility work together to produce a fairly steep BP curve. After 1994, and especially after 2000, South African capital mobility has increased markedly. 192 Chapter 4: The basic model III: the foreign sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 192 2019/12/17 09:15 Important: the slope of the BP curve relative to the LM curve The relative slope of the BP curve decisively affects even a simple diagrammatical analysis. What is crucial is the slope of the BP curve relative to the slope of the LM curve: ❐ If capital mobility is low, the BP curve must be drawn steeper than the LM curve. This was the case in South Africa prior to 1994. ❐ If capital mobility is relatively high, the BP curve would be flatter than the LM curve. This would be the case in the USA, or South Africa in the 2000s. Since the slope of BP (relative to LM) depends on international capital mobility – which is so vulnerable to international perceptions, political expectations and risk assessment of the group of so-called emerging markets – for South Africa it can easily become steeper than the LM curve again. For many low- or middle-income countries it would be steeper in any case. In some cases, the relative slopes do not make a large difference to the outcome (e.g. a monetary stimulation). However, in other cases (e.g. a fiscal stimulation), they do make a crucial difference. ❐ Where relevant we will present both scenarios: a relatively steep BP and a relatively flat BP, so that the reader can handle any situation. Points off the BP curve Points off the BP curve indicate pairings of Y and r that do not imply BoP equilibrium. The level of imports or the level of capital inflows would be incorrect, given the level of exports. The current account and the financial account would therefore not add up to zero. ❐ At points in the area above the BP curve there is a BoP surplus. The interest rate is too high for equilibrium, attracting more capital than required to match the current account position. ❐ At points in the area below the BP curve there is a BoP deficit. The interest rate is too low for equilibrium, causing insufficient capital inflows to match the current account position. Shifting the BP curve Shifts in the BP curve are caused by any change (other than Y and r) that affects either the current account or the financial account: ❐ If the disturbance improves the BoP position, the BP curve shifts to the right. ❐ If the disturbance weakens the BoP position, the BP curve shifts to the left. Three main factors shift the BP curve – an exogenous change in exports, an exogenous change in capital flows and the exchange rate: ❐ An increase in exports or capital inflows would shift the BP curve to the right. A drop in exports or capital flows would shift the curve to the left. ❐ An appreciation of the rand, which stimulates imports and inhibits exports and capital inflows, would shift the BP curve to the left. Depreciation would shift it to the right. 4.7.4 Using the IS-LM-BP model – the basics The usefulness of the BP curve can best be seen if one distinguishes three phases – in two groups – when analysing economic events: (1) The disturbance phase, when the basic internal effect takes hold, with an accompanying BoP situation developing. (2) & (3) The BoP adjustment phases, when the money supply and the exchange rate effects of a BoP surplus or deficit take hold. 4.7 The IS-LM-BP model for an open economy How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 193 193 2019/12/17 09:15 (1) The disturbance phase: the BP curve as an indicator of the BoP position The first purpose of the BP curve is to indicate the BoP position that accompanies a particular IS-LM intersection following an economic disturbance. ❐ The IS-LM intersection shows a pairing of Y and r consistent with both real sector and monetary sector equilibrium – i.e. internal economic equilibrium.5 ❐ The BP curve gives additional information about such an internal equilibrium, i.e. the accompanying BoP position. It therefore shows the external dimensions of the internal equilibrium determined by the IS-LM curves. Internal disturbances For internal disturbances such as our two policy examples the addition of the BP curve shows the accompanying BoP position. (The diagrams below correspond to the first phases of the chain reactions of these examples.) Figure 4.14 Monetary stimulus r Internal real or monetary disturbances shift the IS and LM curves as usual. The BP r0 curve is not affected by these disturbances r1 as such. It remains static, serving mainly as a reference point from which to evaluate the BoP dimension of the new IS-LM intersection point (internal equilibrium). ❐ If the IS-LM intersection point is below the BP curve, it indicates that the BoP is in deficit (see figure 4.14). ❐ A position above the BP curve indicates a BoP surplus as a by-product of the internal disturbance. LM0 LM1 BP BoP in deficit IS Y0 Y1 Y In the case of a monetary stimulus, a BoP deficit develops – irrespective of the relative slopes of the BP and LM curves. (Check for yourself whether this statement is correct.) For a fiscal stimulus, the relative slopes make a marked difference. This is illustrated in figure 4.15. When cross-border capital flows are very interest-sensitive (and thus the BP is flatter), a BoP surplus develops. Lower capital mobility implies that a BoP deficit develops. (Why? See the examples.) External disturbances For external disturbances, the analysis is a bit more complicated. The BP curve itself is shifted by external sector shocks or disturbances. Hence one cannot manipulate only the IS or LM curves – possible shifts in the BP must also be shown. This is the case, in particular, for exogenous changes in exports or changes in imports induced by the exchange rate. Shifts in the BP curve are caused by any change (other than Y and r) that affects either the current account or the financial account: 5 194 Once again, this may be a full employment or an unemployment equilibrium. Chapter 4: The basic model III: the foreign sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 194 2019/12/17 09:15 Figure 4.15 Fiscal stimulus with differing relative slopes Fiscal stimulus: BP flatter than LM r Fiscal stimulus: BP steeper than LM r LM BP BoP in surplus r1 BP r0 IS0 Y0 Y1 r1 BoP in deficit r0 IS1 IS1 IS0 Y ❐ If the disturbance improves the BoP position, the BP curve shifts to the right. For example, an increase in exports would shift the BP curve to the right. A drop in exports would shift the curve to the left. ❐ If the disturbance weakens the BoP position, the BP curve shifts to the left. An appreciation of the rand, which stimulates imports and inhibits exports, would shift the BP curve to the left. Depreciation would shift it to the right. LM Y0 Y Y1 Figure 4.16 An increase in exports – IS and BP shift r r1 LM BoP in surplus r0 BP0 BP1 To analyse an external disturbance, the graphical impact on the IS or LM curves as IS0 IS1 well as on the BP curve must be shown (see Y Y0 Y1 figure 4.16). ❐ In the disturbance phase, the increase in exports shifts the BP curve to the right (in addition to the rightward shift of the IS curve). ❐ In the case of a BP that is steeper than LM, the BP curve must be shifted far enough so that the new IS-LM intersection is above the BP curve, to indicate the BoP surplus that surely must come about (starting out from BoP equilibrium). ! In the IS-LM-BP model, the equilibrium values of Y and r – the state of the domestic economy – are always indicated by the intersection of IS and LM. In this sense, the IS and LM curves are dominant. The BP curve shows only the external dimension of that equilibrium. However, as shown below, a certain BoP condition can lead to further changes in either the IS or LM positions, and hence to a new internal equilibrium with new external characteristics. However, even then the IS and LM curves always denote the equilibrium levels of Y and r. 4.7 The IS-LM-BP model for an open economy How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 195 195 2019/12/17 09:15 (2) & (3) The two BoP adjustment phases: the role of the BP curve in the adjustments A second, and more complicated, purpose of the BP curve is to indicate impacts on the domestic economy that may flow from the external dimension of an internal equilibrium. The essence of such impacts was encountered in the discussion of the BoP adjustment process. The following are key elements of the BoP adjustment process in terms of all three curves (starting from an internal equilibrium with a BoP deficit or surplus): (a) The initial, money supply effect – or rigid exchange rate effect – which shifts the LM curve. (b) The concluding, flexible exchange rate effect, which shifts both the IS and the BP curves (in the same direction). (c) Whereas the sensitivity of capital flows Figure 4.17 BoP adjustment from a surplus to interest rate changes may determine r whether the BoP develops a surplus or LM a deficit (compare the two possible out1 BoP in comes of a fiscal stimulus above), it does surplus not affect the direction in which the LM, 2 BP or IS curves will shift due to a surplus BP 3 or a deficit on the BoP. In the case of a BoP surplus (see figure 4.17): (a) Rigid exchange rate effect: LM shifts right (due to inflow of funds) in the initial End: internal phase of BoP adjustment. This moves the and external IS equilibrium from point 1 to point 2. equilibrium (b) Flexible exchange rate effect: both IS and BP shift to the left (due to currency appreciation) in the concluding BoP adjustment phase. This moves the Figure 4.18 BoP adjustment from a deficit equilibrium from point 2 to point 3 in r the diagram. In the case of a BoP deficit (see figure 4.18): (a) Rigid exchange rate effect: LM shifts left (due to an outflow of payments/funds) in the initial BoP adjustment phase. This moves the equilibrium from point 1 to point 2. (b) Flexible exchange rate effect: both IS and BP shift to the right (due to currency depreciation) in the concluding BoP adjustment phase. This moves the equilibrium from point 2 to point 3. ✍ 196 3 BP 2 Y End: internal and external equilibrium Start: BoP in deficit 1 LM IS Y The above BoP adjustment diagrams have been drawn for a BP that is flatter than the LM. Repeat the exercise for a BP that is steeper than the LM and show that LM, IS and BP move in the same direction as in the diagrams above. Chapter 4: The basic model III: the foreign sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 196 2019/12/17 09:15 Fixed and perfectly flexible exchange rates ❐ If the exchange rate is fixed (not just rigid), only the rigid exchange rate effect and shifts will occur. ❐ If the exchange rate is perfectly flexible and adjusts instantaneously, only the flexible exchange rate effect and shifts will occur. As noted earlier, most textbooks explain the BoP adjustment process in terms of either of the extreme exchange rate regimes. While it simplifies the analysis considerably, these are theoretically extreme cases unlikely to be of much practical use. In reality, most countries have a system of dirty floating exchange rates. Thus both effects are typically present, although not necessarily at the same time and with the same strength. Unfortunately, reality is quite messy in this regard – and, of necessity, so must our analysis be. These shifts in the IS, LM and BP curves can be spliced onto the tail end of any disturbance of the IS-LM curves that produces a BoP deficit or surplus. Then they actually show the effect of the BoP adjustment process very clearly. ❐ Theoretically, the BoP adjustment processes, and hence the shifts, would continue until BoP = 0. That is, the shifts would be such that at the end the IS-LM intersection point would also be on the BP curve. There would be simultaneous internal and external balance (equilibrium). (Of course, this excludes the labour market: unemployment can still be present at such a simultaneous, short-run equilibrium.) 4.7.5 Using the model for an open economy – disturbances and policy effectiveness In section 4.5 the consequences of three types of disturbance were analysed: a monetary policy step, a fiscal policy step, and a change in exports. Chain reactions became quite complex, indicating the need for diagrammatical support. We now revisit those examples in terms of the IS-LM-BP model for an open economy, but with the direction of change reversed. Figure 4.19 shows the complete set of IS-LM-BP graphics for a particular disturbance followed by the complete BoP adjustment process. Because so much is compressed into one diagram, it is very crowded and complicated and should be studied carefully. Also consult the simpler diagrams (the 45° diagram and supplementary diagrams) in chapters 2 and 3, and remember the economic chain reasoning behind the curves, repeated below. Ultimately that is what matters. Example 1: the internal and external effects of an increase in the repo rate Primary effect: (1) [The process starts at point 0 on the IS-LM-BP diagram.] Higher repo rate ⇒ banks pay more for Reserve Bank accommodation ⇒ banks discourage credit creation ⇒ money supply contracts ⇒ excess demand for money ⇒ increase in sales of money market paper ⇒ prices of money market paper fall ⇒ increase in nominal (and real) interest rates ⇒ capital formation I discouraged ⇒ aggregate demand decreases ⇒ production discouraged ⇒ Y decreases (= downswing in the economy). 4.7 The IS-LM-BP model for an open economy How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 197 197 2019/12/17 09:15 As Y declines, imports M decrease (why?) ⇒ current account (CA) surplus develops. The increase in r causes an inflow of foreign capital, leaving the financial account (FA) in a surplus. Secondary effects: (2) Money market effect: As Y decreases, it causes the demand for money to decrease concurrently ⇒ downward pressure on interest rates ⇒ initial rise in interest rates gradually comes to an end ⇒ initial fall in investment is curbed ⇒ initial fall in aggregate demand arrested ⇒ fall in Y brought to an end ⇒ drop in M arrested and initial strengthening of (X – M) comes to an end. ❐ The main impact of this secondary effect is that the changes in r, I, Y and M will be smaller than what they would have been had there been no such effect via money demand. While this secondary effect operates in the opposite direction from the primary effect, it is a weaker force. The secondary effect does not cancel the primary effect, it only reduces it. The net effect of the primary and secondary effects leaves Y lower, r higher and both the current and financial accounts in surplus. There is a BoP surplus (BoP > 0). [The economy is at point 1 on the diagram. The increase in the repo rate causes the LM curve to move from LM0 to LM1 and the economy is now at point 1 on the diagram. This point lies above the BP curve and thus indicates the presence of a surplus in the BoP. This corresponds with our economic reasoning thus far.] Further secondary effects due to BoP > 0: (3) Initial BoP effect (foreign reserves adjustment): The BoP surplus causes (i) an inflow of foreign exchange ⇒ MS increases ⇒ downward pressure on interest rates (which causes the inflow of foreign capital to decrease or reverse and the FA surplus to decrease) ⇒ the decrease in the interest rate encourages real investment I ⇒ aggregate demand/ expenditure increases, causing Y to increase; as Y increases it stimulates imports ⇒ (X – M) decreases ⇒ prevailing CA surplus is reduced; the turnaround in the real Figure 4.19 Increase in repo rate r LM1 r1 r3 1 3 LM2 LM0 BP1 2 BP0 0 r0 IS1 Y1 Y3 198 LM shifts left initially, and right again in the initial BoP adjustment phase Y0 IS0 Y 0 5 Initial equilibrium Y0r0 with BoP equilibrium 1 5 New equilibrium Y1r1 with BoP surplus (point is above BP0 curve) 2 5 Temporary equilibrium Y2r2 after initial BoP adjustment phase (foreign reserves effect). Still BoP surplus 3 5 Final equilibrium Y3r3 after concluding BoP adjustment phase (flexible exchange rate effect). Both internal and external equilibrium. IS and BP shift left due to the concluding BoP adjustment phase Chapter 4: The basic model III: the foreign sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 198 2019/12/17 09:15 interest rate will also start to discourage or reverse capital inflows; thus the FA is likely to start deteriorating. On both fronts the BoP surplus is being reduced. The increase in Y implies that the initial downswing has turned around (at least for now … ). [The economy is at point 2 on the diagram.] (4) Concluding BoP effect (exchange rate adjustment): The initial BoP surplus (now already slightly reduced) also leads to (ii) an excess demand for rands (excess supply of foreign exchange) ⇒ upward pressure on the rand ⇒ stimulation of imports and discouragement of exports ⇒ decreases (X – M) ⇒ CA surplus is reduced, and so is the remaining BoP surplus. The BoP tends towards equilibrium. The process will continue as long as BoP ≠ 0 and until BoP = 0. This cumulative decrease in (X – M) due to these two BoP effects again reduces aggregate expenditure, which reverses the short recovery of Y – a further economic downswing occurs (Y declines again). [The economy ends up at point 3 on the IS-LM-BP diagram.] It appears likely that the foreign reserves effect (phase 3 above) will come about sooner than the exchange rate effect (phase 4). Summary of changes Note the changes that occur in the main macro­ economic variables, i.e. income Y, interest rate, rand, BoP and exchange rate. As far as r and Y are concerned their cyclical movements can be checked against their up-and-down changes on the axes of the IS-LM-BP diagram. The time-path diagram (figure 4.20) illustrates the stylised course of these main variables over time during the primary and three secondary effects of the example above. ❐ As noted before, in reality time paths are never so smooth, and multiple shocks and disturbances occur on top of one another. Our purpose here is to isolate the basic directional effects encountered by an open economy following an initial stimulus. Policy effectiveness again This analysis confirms the conclusions regarding policy effectiveness: the effectiveness of monetary policy is undermined by a rigid or slowly adjusting exchange rate (which allows the money supply effect time to take hold), and enhanced by a quickly adjusting exchange rate. ❐ If the exchange rate is completely flexible and adjusts rapidly, the downward shift of Figure 4.20 Illustrative time path of key variables – increase in the repo rate r Time Y Time Rand BoP Time BoP adjustment phase Demand contraction up to 3 years 4.7 The IS-LM-BP model for an open economy How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 199 199 2019/12/17 09:15 the LM curve – the money supply or rigid exchange rate effect – would not occur at all. All that remains is the flexible exchange rate effect, which boosts the effectiveness of monetary policy. ❐ If the exchange rate is fixed, the IS curve would not adjust at all, and the downward shift in the LM curve would be decisive and substantial. Indeed, this shift in the LM curve would cancel the initial, policy-induced upward shift in the LM curve. Monetary policy would have no net impact on real income. Example 2: the internal and external effects of an increase in government expenditure Primary effect: (1) [The process starts at point 0 on the IS-LM-BP diagram (see figure 4.21).] Increase in government expenditure ⇒ aggregate expenditure increases ⇒ positive impact on domestic production ⇒ real income Y increases. As Y increases ⇒ imports M increase ⇒ a current account (CA) deficit develops. Secondary effects: (2) Money market effect: As Y increases, it causes a concurrent increase in the demand for money ⇒ upward pressure on interest rates ⇒ discouragement of real investment ⇒ decrease in aggregate demand, partially countering the impact of the initial increase in government expenditure ⇒ curbs the upturn in Y ⇒ growth in M curtailed and initial weakening of (X – M) comes to an end. The net effect of the primary effect and the secondary, money market effect leaves Y higher, r higher and (X – M) < 0, i.e. a CA deficit. The increase in r causes an inflow of foreign capital, causing a surplus in the financial account (FA). The net effect on the BoP is uncertain: depending on the relative size of the CA and FA positions, the BoP = CA + FA could be in balance, in a surplus or in a deficit. As we did in section 4.5.2, we assume international capital flows to be relatively sensitive to domestic interest rate changes. Therefore, should interest rates increase as a result of the secondary effect, there will be a relatively large inflow of foreign capital. Thus, one might expect the surplus on the FA to exceed the deficit on the CA, in which case BoP > 0. ❐ If capital flows were not that sensitive to domestic real interest changes, the surplus on the FA would have been smaller than the deficit on the CA – implying a balance of payments deficit. (We leave this case to the reader as an exercise.) [The economy is at point 1 on the diagram.] Thus we have further secondary effects due to BoP > 0: (3) Initial BoP effect (foreign reserves adjustment): The BoP surplus causes (i) an inflow of foreign exchange ⇒ expansion of money supply ⇒ downward pressure on interest rates (which causes the inflow of foreign capital to decrease or reverse and the FA surplus to decrease); the decrease in the interest rate also encourages real investment I ⇒ aggregate demand/expenditure increases, causing Y to increase; as Y increases it swells imports ⇒ (X – M) decreases ⇒ prevailing CA deficit is reduced; however, the turnaround in the real interest rate will also start to reverse capital inflows; thus the FA surplus is likely to start being reversed. Assuming a stronger FA effect, the net effect would be that the BoP surplus is being reduced. 200 Chapter 4: The basic model III: the foreign sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 200 2019/12/17 09:15 Figure 4.21 Increase in government expenditure r LM shifts right initially in the first BoP adjustment phase LM0 BP shifts left in the concluding BoP adjustment phase LM1 3 r3 r0 BP1 1 r1 2 BP0 0 IS2 IS0 Y0 IS1 IS shifts right initially, then left in the concluding BoP adjustment phase Y Y3 0 5 Initial equilibrium Y0r0 with BoP equilibrium 1 5 New equilibrium Y1r1 with BoP surplus (point is above BP0 curve) 2 5 Temporary equilibrium Y2r2 after first BoP adjustment phase. Still BoP surplus 3 5 Final equilibrium Y3r3 after entire BoP adjustment process. Simultaneous internal and external equilibrium The increase in Y implies that the initial upswing has been followed by another upswing. [The economy is at point 2 on the diagram.] (4) Concluding BoP effect (exchange rate adjust­ ment): The initial BoP surplus also leads to (ii) an excess demand of rands (excess supply of foreign exchange) ⇒ upward pressure on the rand ⇒ stimulation of imports and discouragement of exports ⇒ decrease in (X – M) ⇒ current account deficit increases again. This helps to eliminate the remaining BoP surplus – the BoP tends towards equilibrium. The process will continue as long as BoP ≠ 0 and until BoP = 0. Note how, towards the end, the appreciation of the rand is responsible, via an induced decrease in (X – M), for a contraction of aggregate expenditure. This partially reverses the two-phase expansion of Y. [The economy ends up at point 3 on the IS-LM-BP diagram.] Summary of changes The time-path diagram (see figure 4.22) illustrates the stylised course of these main variables over time during the primary and three secondary effects of the example above. Figure 4.22 Illustrative time path of key variables – increase in government expenditure r Time Y Time Rand BoP Time BoP adjustment phase Demand expansion up to 3 years 4.7 The IS-LM-BP model for an open economy How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 201 201 2019/12/17 09:15 Example 3: the probable effect of an economic upswing in the USA on the South African economy Primary effect: (1) [The process starts at point 0 on the IS-LM-BP diagram (see figure 4.23).] Higher YUSA ⇒ US imports MUSA increase ⇒ increased imports from abroad, including South Africa ⇒ XSA increases ⇒ (X – M) increases, i.e. current account (CA) goes into surplus ⇒ aggregate expenditure increases ⇒ production encouraged ⇒ Y increases. (2) As Y increases, a concurrent increase in imports M develops ⇒ negative impact on (X – M), i.e. current account deteriorates a bit. The net effect on the current account will still be a substantial improvement. Secondary effects: (3) Money market effect: As real income Y increases, the real demand for money increases ⇒ upward pressure on real interest rates, which, in turn, causes investment to decrease ⇒ downward pressure on aggregate demand ⇒ initial increase in aggregate demand countered ⇒ production discouraged ⇒ increase in Y curbed, upswing comes to an end; increase in M arrested and improvement in CA comes to an end; CA in surplus. The increase in interest rate should attract an inflow of foreign capital, which improves the financial account (FA) – the FA will be in a surplus. The net effect of the primary effect and the secondary effect leaves Y higher, r higher and the current and financial accounts in surplus. Thus the BoP will have a surplus. [The economy is at point 1 on the diagram.] Thus we have further secondary effects due to BoP > 0: (4) Initial BoP effect (foreign reserves adjustment): The BoP surplus causes (i) an inflow of foreign exchange ⇒ money supply increases ⇒ downward pressure on interest rates (which causes the inflow of foreign capital to decrease) ⇒ encourages real investment I ⇒ aggregate demand/expenditure increases, causing Y to increase further; as Figure 4.23 Increase in exports r LM shifts right in the initial BoP adjustment phase LM0 BP shifts right initially, then left in the concluding BoP adjustment phase LM1 1 r1 r3 r0 0 3 2 IS0 Y0 202 Y1 Y3 BP0 IS2 BP2 BP1 IS1 Y 0 5 Initial equilibrium Y0r0 with BoP equilibrium 1 5 New equilibrium Y1r1 with BoP surplus (point is above BP0 curve) 2 5 Temporary equilibrium Y2r2 after first BoP adjustment phase. Still BoP surplus 3 5 Final equilibrium Y3r3 after entire BoP adjustment process. Simultaneous internal and external equilibrium IS shifts right initially, then left in the concluding BoP adjustment phase Chapter 4: The basic model III: the foreign sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 202 2019/12/17 09:15 Y increases it stimulates imports ⇒ (X – M) decreases ⇒ prevailing CA surplus is reduced. The drop in interest rates will discourage capital inflows, so the existing FA surplus will shrink. [The economy is at point 2 on the diagram.] (5) Concluding BoP effect (exchange rate adjustment): The initial BoP surplus also leads to (ii) an excess demand for rands (excess supply of foreign exchange) ⇒ upward pressure on the rand ⇒ stimulation of imports and discouragement of exports ⇒ decreases (X – M) ⇒ CA surplus is reduced. This appreciation-induced decrease in (X – M) contracts aggregate expenditure, which turns around the sustained upswing. Y will decrease, also dragging interest rates down further. The FA will shrink further, and so will the remaining BoP surplus. The BoP tends towards equilibrium. The process will continue as long as BoP ≠ 0 and until BoP = 0. [The economy ends up at point 3 on the IS-LM-BP diagram.] Summary of changes Figure 4.24 shows that, in contrast to example 1 above (internal monetary disturbance), where the current account changed mainly as part of the BoP adjustment phase, in this case the initial disturbance directly and immediately affects the current account. The export stimulation example appears similar to the fiscal stimulation example. Note the following differences, though: ❐ In the fiscal expansion example, a CA deficit develops, but it is overshadowed by a FA surplus, hence a (small) BoP surplus develops. In the export example, a substantial CA surplus develops immediately, on top of which a FA surplus develops, so that the BoP improves much quicker and goes into a much larger surplus. ❐ The BoP adjustment process is much longer in the export example. ❐ The decline of r during the BoP adjustment is larger in the export example, due to the larger BoP surplus and its effects on the money supply. ❐ The upswing in Y is likely to last longer than in the fiscal example. Note that a rigid exchange rate enhances the beneficial domestic effects of exports, while a quickly adjusting exchange rate puts a brake on the export-led economic upswing. This parallels the conclusion about the positive impact of a slowly adjusting exchange rate on the effectiveness of fiscal policy. Figure 4.24 Illustrative time path of key variables – increase in exports r Time Y Time Rand BoP Time BoP adjustment phase Demand contraction up to 3 years 4.7 The IS-LM-BP model for an open economy How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 203 203 2019/12/17 09:15 Conclusion Theoretically, the BoP surplus should be eliminated at the end, since the BoP adjustment process should continue until BoP = 0. In practice, the process rarely gets to equilibrium so effortlessly. Nevertheless, the basic nature and direction of the adjustment process is unchanged. However, this neat outcome is a theoretical result. In practice it rarely happens that the adjustment process proceeds to the end – it is likely to be interrupted by new economic disturbances. What is important is the basic direction of the adjustment effects via the money supply and the exchange rate. Internal equilibrium and unemployment? Remember that internal equilibrium need not be accompanied by full employment. This is the central theme of the Keynesian approach. Even if the BoP adjustment process pushes the economy towards a point of simultaneous internal and external equilibrium, there could still be substantial unemployment. These issues are discussed in chapter 6. Finally, as noted earlier, all these examples are incomplete since the effect on the price level still is absent. This will be rectified in chapter 6. Important: While these diagrams are quite powerful, they have intrinsic limitations. In diagrams such as these one can indicate only the direction and the approximate magnitude of shifts in the curves – and hence the resultant changes in Y and r. Depending on how far each curve shifts, and on the different slopes of the curves, the net impact on Y and r can vary. ❐ The diagrams are not intended to produce accurate ‘forecasts’ of changes in Y and r, and any attempt to do so goes beyond the limits of diagrammatical analysis. ❐ To get more specific forecasts, one has to use much more sophisticated mathematical analysis and empirical econometric estimates of the various parameters and multipliers. ❐ Even then there will always be imprecision and substantial uncertainty. As noted earlier in this book, the economy is not a machine, and changes do not happen mechanically. Therefore the quantitative results of sequences of events cannot be forecast with mechanical precision. ✍ The world financial crisis of 2007–08 – using the IS-LM-BP model We introduced this case study in section 3.4 and earlier in this chapter. Now is the time to redo that analysis using the IS-LM-BP model, and apply that to both the USA and South Africa. 4.8 Real-world application – the Euro crisis and the impact of confidence on international capital flows The European Union is a monetary union comprising (in 2014) 28 European countries. Since 1 January 2002, 18 of these countries have used a single currency called the Euro (€), therefore no foreign exchange transactions are necessary (or possible) between these countries. (The 18 countries are Austria, Belgium, Cyprus, Estonia, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Ireland, Italy, Latvia, Luxembourg, Malta, the Netherlands, Portugal, Slovakia, Slovenia and Spain.) 204 Chapter 4: The basic model III: the foreign sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 204 2019/12/17 09:15 The Euro is managed by the European Central Bank (ECB). The single currency also means that none of the 18 countries using the Euro can pursue an independent, nationally-managed monetary policy: any policy-induced change in domestic interest rates will be reversed by capital flows (see ‘sending the money supply overseas’ in section 4.5.1). However, each country’s government retains control over its own fiscal policy. The Euro crisis: a brief overview The Euro crisis started in 2010, peaked between 2010 and 2012 and was mostly resolved by 2014 (although Greece received assistance until 2018). It appears to have resulted from a failure to harmonise fiscal policy (especially budget deficits), which – as we shall see below – is necessary for a monetary union to be a success. A serious lack of fiscal discipline tends to lead to a loss of confidence and, in turn, destabilising flows of funds among countries. The protagonists in this crisis are Germany, on the one hand, and Portugal, Italy, Greece and Spain (also called the PIGS countries, an acronym based on their initials) on the other. Germany started the 2000s with a large budget deficit and relatively high labour cost. To address these problems, it implemented what today is called an austerity policy – a policy of fiscal and general economic contraction, intended to drive down the budget deficit (and labour cost). The PIGS countries did the opposite – presumably to obtain or sustain political support for their governments. Fiscal expansions in the PIGS countries increased GDP growth and led to current account deficits, which in turn required high levels of capital inflows from financial investors outside their countries to finance these deficits. The scale of fiscal expansions was such that the governments of Greece and Italy in particular ran large budget deficits, driving up their public debt/GDP ratios to well above 100% (in the case of Greece to 130%). In Greece some creative public-sector accounting also hid the actual size of the deficits and public debt for a number of years. Unaware of the real nature of the deficits, German banks had gladly financed much of the Greek public debt, contributing much to the capital inflows. However, in 2010 the full extent of the debt problems facing the PIGS countries became clear. Foreign investors lost confidence in the government bonds issued by these countries and many withdrew their funds. As a result, governments such as those of Greece and Italy had to offer much higher interest rates to attract foreign capital. In many cases they were not fully successful in attracting investors. The IMF (in partnership with the ECB) had to extend and facilitate very large loans to assist Greece in particular. The country’s fiscal predicament worsened and the spectre of default on Greek government bonds arose. Although all the PIGS countries were supposed to arrest their fast-increasing public debt/GDP ratios by implementing cutbacks in government expenditure and deficits, they were at first reluctant to do so. In the case of Greece the situation became dire. Default on government bonds was in the air. To avoid such a crisis, the IMF and ECB facilitated negotiations with foreign banks that led to ‘write-downs’ of existing Greek debt. These meant that foreign creditors would agree to extending a new loan of, say, 70c (€0.70) to fully replace every €1 of an old loan. In effect the creditor would lose 30c for each €1 of the loan – thus ‘taking a haircut’ rather than risking total default on the loan. 4.8 Real-world application – the Euro crisis How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 205 205 2019/12/17 09:15 The impact on the Greek economy was huge. Banks took a hit and general economic confidence evaporated; the crisis intensified. After several months of dithering, the Greek government was forced – also as part of the ongoing international write-down deal – to implement large cutbacks in government expenditure to get the deficit under control and reduce public debt levels. These cutbacks meant, for example, that Greek civil servants were forced to accept salary reductions, leading to street protests in Athens and other Greek cities – and a deep political crisis. In contrast, confidence in the German economy increased significantly as many investors saw it as a paragon of good economic management and good financial investment opportunities. Using the IS-LM-BP framework to explain the Euro crisis With some adjustments, example 2 in section 4.7.5 above can be used to explain the Euro crisis. In example 2 an exchange rate adjustment occurs after a fiscal stimulus as the second component of the BoP adjustment process; this helps to take the economy back to equilibrium. In contrast, since a single currency is used by all eighteen Euro countries, an exchange rate adjustment is not possible. The situation among these countries is similar to having a fixed exchange rate. In a fixed exchange rate system, there can be no exchange rate adjustment process – only a foreign reserves adjustment. However, in a single currency system the foreign reserves adjustment of the BoP has a peculiarity. Since no exchange of domestic currencies is necessary to buy or sell goods or government bonds, foreign reserves are not involved in transactions between Eurozone countries. Thus, any buying of Greek bonds by a Eurozone-based financial investor would see Euros flow directly into the seller’s Greek bank account. Thus it has a direct impact on the Greek money supply – not via a foreign exchange transaction, as is normally the case. This implies that the normal BoP adjustment via foreign reserves reduces to a direct money supply adjustment. The end result is the same, but it is much more direct and rapid. Figure 4.25a is an IS-LM-BP model for Greece (or any other PIGS country), while figure 4.25b is an IS-LM-BP model for Germany. Analysing events in Greece The analysis starts at equilibrium point 0 where IS0, LM0 and BP0 intersect, with output for Greece at Y0 and the interest rate at r0. The Greek government then enters a period of fiscal expansion that would eventually lead to the crisis. Graphically the fiscal stimulus is portrayed by the IS curve shifting right from IS0 to IS1. Output expands and an internal equilibrium is reached at point 1, with the interest rate higher at r1. This point 1 is above the BP0 curve, indicating that the balance of payments (BoP) has gone into a surplus: although the primary effect of the fiscal stimulus causes a current account (CA) deficit, international capital flows are relatively sensitive to an increase in the interest rate; this leads to an inflow on the financial account (a FA surplus) which exceeds the deficit on the CA. As a result there is a net surplus on the BoP – exactly as in example 2. ❐ These inflows mostly comprised financial investments by German banks that were buying Greek government bonds. (For simplicity we ignore inflows from outside the Euro zone.) 206 Chapter 4: The basic model III: the foreign sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 206 2019/12/17 09:15 Figure 4.25a Fiscal stimulus and the confidence crisis in the Greek economy IS shifts right in initial fiscal stimulus and left in later fiscal contraction r IS0 r1 r3 IS1 LM shifts right in the first BoP adjustment, then left in second BoP adjustment BP1 LM0 LM1 1 3 BP0 r2 r0 LM2 2 0 BP shifts up and rotates anticlockwise Y3 Y0 Y1 Y2 Y 0 = Initial equilibrium Y0 r0 1 = New equilibrium Y1 r1 after IS shifts right (due to fiscal stimulus). BoP surplus. 2 = Equilibrium Y2 r2 after BoP adjustment (equivalent to monetary expansion). Confidence crisis occurs – BoP shifts up and rotates anticlockwise. Capital outflow and BoP deficit develops. 3 = Equilibrium Y3 r3 after BoP adjustment as well as fiscal contraction. Major recession. 0 = Possible final equilibrium Y0 r0 if confidence returns and capital inflows resume. BP rotates and moves back to BP0. BoP surplus develops, followed by BoP adjustment (equivalent to monetary expansion): LM shifts back to LM0. As explained above, the BoP surplus implies an inflow of Euros into Greece that causes a direct increase in the Greek money supply (the ‘initial’ BoP adjustment effect). As a result, the LM curve shifts right from LM0 to LM1. A new internal and external equilibrium is established at point 2, with the interest rate dropping to r2 and output increasing to Y2 – again, exactly as in example 2. Note that, since the Euro regime implies that the exchange rate cannot adjust, there will be no ‘concluding’ BoP effect via an exchange rate adjustment. However, the Greek story does not end at point 2. There is a confidence problem that is not apparent from the IS-LM-BP diagram. The Greek government ran large budget deficits and sold the government bonds to foreign investors. As the stimulus continued for a number of years, the Greek public debt/GDP ratio increased sharply, reaching 130%. The Greek government was supposed to cut back on its expenditure, but they refused. In 2010 this led to a crisis of confidence. Wary foreign investors started demanding much higher interest rates on Greek government bonds. Graphically, this investor reluctance (or: increased risk aversion) means that the BP curve shifts up. The Greek government found it almost impossible to finance its budget deficit and had to offer very high interest rates on their government bonds to attract investors. However, even these rates were not enough. Investors started withdrawing their funds in large amounts, causing major capital outflows. Simultaneously, investors’ behaviour regarding risk-taking changed. Foreign capital inflows became much less sensitive to Greek interest rates than prior to the crisis. This lower interestrate sensitivity of foreign financial investors makes the BP curve much steeper. 4.8 Real-world application – the Euro crisis How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 207 207 2019/12/17 09:15 These two effects mean that, in figure 4.25a, the BP shifts and rotates from BP0 to BP1. This is critical: whereas BP0 is flatter than the LM curves, the new BP1 is steeper than the LM curves. This changes the whole situation. Point 2 now lies well below BP1, reflecting that a large BoP deficit has developed. This is largely due to the large outflow of Euros from Greece (a deficit on the FA) that, together with the CA situation, implies a BoP deficit. Now the BoP adjustment process kicks in, in the form of a contraction in the money supply, moving the LM curve from LM1 towards LM2. The internal equilibrium starts moving up the IS1 curve. At about this time, given the severity of the crisis and international pressure, the Greek government was eventually forced to implement a severe austerity package, cutting government expenditure sharply. In the diagram, the IS curve is forced from IS1 back to IS0. The combined shifts of LM and IS culminate in a new internal and external equilibrium being established at point 3 (roughly along the path indicated by the dashed blue arrow). The new equilibrium interest rate is at r3 and output at Y3. Graphically one can see that this new equilibrium at point 3 results from the new position and, especially, new slope of the BP1 curve. Note that Y3 is much lower than Y2 or even Y0. This indicates the huge price that Greece eventually had to pay – in terms of a deep recession and a large drop in employment – for previous years of excess and unwillingness to cut budget deficits and manage public debt timeously. Should Greece maintain a prudent fiscal policy for a number of years and the Greek public debt/GDP ratio decline to sustainable and manageable levels, confidence in the Greek economy may return and foreign capital inflows might resume. In the diagram the BP curve will shift and rotate back to BP0; point 3 will then come to lie above BP0 due to a BoP surplus having developed. The subsequent inflow of funds (which constitute the BoP adjustment process) will increase the Greek money supply. The LM curve will shift back from LM2 to LM0, with equilibrium returning to a point such as point 0 – implying a recovery of GDP and employment. Greece will have recovered from the crisis. Analysing changes in Germany In Germany almost the opposite happened to what happened in Greece. In the early 2000s the German government ran a large budget deficit. In figure 4.25b this is indicated as equilibrium point 0. The German government subsequently decided to rein in the budget deficit by cutting government expenditure. Graphically this shifts the IS curve left from IS0 to IS1. At the new internal equilibrium (point 1), coupled with a decline in income to Y1, there is a deficit on the balance of payments. (This is the primary effect: the decline in income reduces imports, creating a surplus on the CA of the BoP. However, the drop in the interest rate towards point 1 causes a capital outflow, causing a deficit on the FA that exceeds the CA surplus. Hence, at point 1 the German BoP is in a deficit.) Note: The outflow of Euros from Germany and the inflow of Euros into the PIGS countries were largely two sides of the same coin. Euros flowing out of Germany often willingly found their way to countries such as Greece and Italy. 208 Chapter 4: The basic model III: the foreign sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 208 2019/12/17 09:15 Figure 4.25b Fiscal austerity and the German economy LM shifts right in the first BoP adjustment, then left in second BoP adjustment r IS0 IS1 LM1 LM0 LM2 BP0 0 r0 r2 r1 r3 2 BP1 1 3 Y2 Y1 Y3 Y0 Y 0 = Initial equilibrium Y0 r0 1 = New equilibrium Y1 r1 after IS shifts left (due to fiscal contraction). Major recession. BoP deficit. 2 = Equilibrium Y2 r2 after BoP adjustment (equivalent to monetary contraction). Recession worsens. Greek crisis causes investors to have stronger confidence in Germany. BoP shifts down. Capital inflow and BoP surplus develops. 3 = Equilibrium Y3 r3 after BoP adjustment. Upswing, but ends well below starting point Yo. The outflow of funds due to the BoP deficit reduced the money supply in Germany. This shifts the LM left from LM0 towards LM1, with a new internal and external equilibrium likely to be established at point 2. The BoP deficit shrinks, moving towards BoP = 0. (This is the initial BoP effect, operating through direct changes in the money supply – with no exchange rate effect occurring.) However, now something changes. Simultaneous to the loss of confidence in Greece and the other PIGS countries, confidence in Germany increased. Investors became willing to accept lower interest rates on German bonds. As a result the BP curve moves downwards. The BP curve moves from BP0 to BP1. With the BP curve moving to BP1, point 2 now lies above BP1, reflecting that a surplus has developed on the BoP due to the capital inflow (FA surplus). ❐ If an increase in investors’ sensitivity to German interest rates also occurs, the BP curve would become flatter. (This is not shown in the diagram.) In the German case the change in slope does not change the basic result – the BP is flatter than the LM curve in any case. As a result, a BoP adjustment occurs for a second time. The LM curve shifts from LM1 to LM2. A final equilibrium is reached at point 3, with output (GDP) higher at Y3 and the interest rate having declined to r3. This indicates that, after having gone through an austerity phase, Germany eventually benefited from the subsequent increase in international investor confidence in the German government and economy. Of course, the German people also paid a heavy price – a dramatic drop in GDP and employment – but in their case it was early in the process. Still, their final equilibrium GDP is much below the starting point. 4.8 Real-world application – the Euro crisis How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 209 209 2019/12/17 09:15 Implications: the need for harmonised fiscal discipline in the Euro zone The PIGS crisis demonstrates that the behaviour of foreign investors depends greatly on the confidence that they have in an economy or government, notably its fiscal policies. Furthermore, a loss of international confidence can have severe implications for a national economy. In the context of the Euro zone, such a national crisis can affect other member states badly and threaten the sustainability of the Euro single currency area as such. Therefore, such a single currency model, which already implies coordinated/unified monetary policy, needs measures to keep budget deficits and public debt in line with each other. Following the PIGS crisis, Euro zone members have signed a compact (the Treaty on Stability, Coordination, and Governance in the Economic and Monetary Union) to try to ensure fiscal discipline amongst member states. The goal is to get national governments to maintain structurally balanced budgets – i.e. the budget balance excluding cyclical effects on expenditure and revenue should not be in a deficit – and to eventually reduce all national debt levels to below 60%. The compact, pushed by Germany, requires member countries to introduce laws strictly limiting their structural government budget deficits to less than 0.5% of GDP (or a more lenient 1% if their debt/GDP ratio is significantly below 60%). The compact also foresees that the European Commission would have the power to review the national budgets of member states to avoid repeating past excesses. Such supra-national control over fiscal policy is essential for the Euro single-currency area to function efficiently and without disruptive confidence crises. The question is whether voters in the different countries – who are at very different stages of economic development and levels of wealth – would be willing to accept their government budgets being prescribed by an external body (in effect, the all but dominant Germany). (See chapter 10 for more on fiscal policy issues as well as the definition and application of the concept of a structural budget balance.) International repercussions: how does the Euro crisis affect South Africa? Due to limitations of space the knock-on effects of the Euro crisis on other countries, such as South Africa, cannot be analysed here. It suffices to say that the main effects stem from a decline in GDP in Europe, and hence in their imports from other countries, including South Africa. At the same time, foreign investor nervousness may spill over into a wariness to invest in emerging markets, which could have an impact on capital inflows into South Africa. The analysis of the impact of these changes on GDP, interest rates and the exchange rate in the IS-LM-BP diagram for South Africa is left to the reader as an exercise. 4.9 Analytical questions and exercises 1. Explain fully why international investors include a risk premium in their decision to invest in South Africa. In your discussion you must clearly indicate what is meant by the risk premium. 2. Use chain reactions and diagrams to explain and illustrate the internal and external impact of an increase in economic growth in the European Union on the level of national income, the interest rate and the exchange rate of South Africa. Assume that the degree of international capital mobility is low for South Africa, that the European and Chinese propensity to import is high and that the exchange rate is floating. Clearly show the balance of payments adjustment process. 210 Chapter 4: The basic model III: the foreign sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 210 2019/12/17 09:15 3. In 2018–19, US President Trump initiated a ‘trade war’ with China, introducing high tariffs on Chinese goods imported into the USA. This resulted in lower growth being forecast for China. (a) How important is China as a trade partner for South Africa? (b) Analyse and explain what would be the likely effect on the South African economy. Assume that the degree of international capital mobility is low for South Africa, that the Chinese propensity to import is high and that the exchange rate is floating. Clearly show the balance of payments adjustment process. 4. Suppose the cash reserve requirement is increased. Use the Keynesian transmission mechanism’s chain reactions to show the primary, secondary and net effects on total expenditure, total income and the interest rate. Indicate clearly the balance of payments adjustment process. Assume a floating exchange rate and the capital flows are not interest rate sensitive. 5. The violence, shootings and deaths at the Marikana platinum mine in August 2012 triggered a sell-off of domestic bonds by foreign investors. (a) Use the Keynesian transmission mechanism’s chain reactions to show the effect of this event on South Africa’s income level, interest rate and exchange rate. Clearly indicate the balance of payments adjustment process. Assume a floating exchange rate and capital flows that are interest rate sensitive. (b) How would the outcomes have differed if capital flows were not sensitive to interest rates? 6. In March 2019 the Minister of Finance’s budget speech indicated that the budget deficit will increase markedly in 2019/20, partly due to bail-outs of Eskom. Use the Keynesian transmission mechanism’s chain reactions to show the effect on South Africa’s income level, interest rate and exchange rate. Indicate clearly the balance of payments adjustment process. Assume a floating exchange rate and capital flows that are interest rate sensitive. 7. Suppose the rating agency Moody’s reduces South Africa’s rating as a country, which means that, compared to previous years, South Africa is considered a higher investment risk. South Africa depends on the inflow of portfolio investments. Use the Keynesian transmission mechanism’s chain reactions to show the likely effect on the inflow of portfolio investments due to a lower rating by Moody’s. Then show how the changed inflow of portfolio investments affects South Africa’s income level, interest rate and exchange rate. Indicate clearly the balance of payments adjustment process. Assume a floating exchange rate. (Hint: Assume that prior to the rating adjustment the slope of the BP curve was flatter than the slope of the LM curve, while after the adjustment the BP curve is the steeper of the two curves – i.e. the BP curve swivels anticlockwise due to the ratings decrease. Thus, assume that the interest-rate sensitivity of capital flows decreases.) 8. The Business Confidence Index decreased markedly in 2018–2019. Use the Keynesian transmission mechanism’s chain reactions and appropriate diagrams to explain and show the likely impact of lower levels of business confidence on South Africa’s income level, interest rate and exchange rate. Indicate clearly the balance of payments adjustment process. First, assume a fixed exchange rate and that capital flows are not interest rate sensitive. Then assume a floating exchange rate and capital flows that are interest-rate sensitive. 9. Growth has been sluggish since 2013, and especially bad in the first quarter of 2019. In July 2019 the Reserve Bank reduced the repo rate by 0.25%. Describe the likely impact on economic behaviour and macroeconomic outcomes in a chain reaction and with the IS-LM-BP model, if capital inflows are sensitive to changes in the interest rate and the exchange rate is allowed to float freely. 4.9 Analytical questions and exercises How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 211 211 2019/12/17 09:15 10. Use chain reactions and the IS-LM-BP model to explain and illustrate the internal and external impact of a decrease in taxes on national income and the interest rate. Assume the degree of international capital mobility is low and the exchange rate is fixed. Assume further that both the real and monetary sectors are highly responsive to interest rates. 11. Use chain reactions and the IS-LM-BP model to explain and illustrate the internal and external impact of a major increase in the gold and platinum prices on national income and the interest rate. Assume the degree of international capital mobility is high and the exchange rate is floating. 12. Use chain reactions and the IS-LM-BP model to explain and illustrate the internal and external impact a stimulating fiscal policy will have on national income and the interest rate. Assume the degree of international capital mobility is low and the exchange rate is floating. 13. Explain (by using a chain reaction) the relationship between a budget deficit in the USA, a strengthening US dollar, a weaker rand and South Africa’s export and imports. 14. ‘Foreign investors are becoming risk-averse and selling their shares on the JSE, due to uncertainty in the South African mining and political sectors.’ Explain the relationship between the foreign investors selling their shares on the JSE, the effect on the financial account and the implications for the balance of payments. 15. Explain the ‘twin deficit’ phenomenon by referring to the budget deficit and the components of the balance of payments. 16. When a country develops an extraordinarily large current account or balance of payments deficit, it may be forced ‘to get an IMF bail-out’. Consult internet sources (including factsheets at https://www.imf.org/en/about) to answer the following questions: a. What is the role and purpose of the IMF in assisting countries in such a case? b.What kind of ‘assistance’ could it provide for a middle-income country such as South Africa in the situation described above? (What specific instruments can the IMF make available?) c.What is typical IMF ‘conditionality’ in the case of such IMF assistance? d.Analyse the likely impact on a country such as South Africa of implementing IMF conditions (use suitable diagrams). 17. In the run-up to Brexit, the British pound lost a lot of value in international currency markets. Discuss the likely effect of this on different sectors of the British economy and on the economy as a whole. 18. In the United Kingdom, 2019 was the year of the prospect of leaving the European Union (EU), of which it had been a member since 1973. At the time of writing (August 2019), it appeared that the ‘divorce’ could happen without an agreement on future trade between the UK and the EU – i.e. a ‘no-deal Brexit’. The governor of the Bank of England (the central bank) warned that such an exit would likely cause the UK economy to shrink (have negative growth) in 2020. a. Explain, with diagrams, why this could happen, taking domestic and international aspects into account (and making appropriate assumptions about capital mobility in the UK and EU). b. What could be the effect on South Africa and why? Analyse and explain, given that South Africa has a floating exchange rate and that capital flows are interest rate sensitive. c. What did eventually happen with Brexit and what was the impact on the UK economy in the first couple of years? (Consult the internet.) Analyse and explain how these outcomes differed, or not, from the prediction of the Bank of England. 212 Chapter 4: The basic model III: the foreign sector How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 212 2019/12/17 09:15 Understanding sectoral coherence and constraints: how to use macroeconomic identities 5 After reading this chapter, you should be able to: ■ analyse and interpret the different macroeconomic identities that are derived from the national accounts; ■ use the identities as an analytical tool to understand the coherence between sectors and evaluate the functioning of an economy; ■ integrate the constraints implied by these identities into macroeconomic analysis; ■ recognise the misuse of the national accounts relationships to derive invalid conclusions regarding cause-and-effect relationships; and ■ explain the basic structure of the System of National Accounts (SNA) and the relationships between the different subaccounts. In chapters 2 to 4 most of the main macroeconomic variables were encountered. These reflect different types of economic behaviour such as consumption, savings and investment, by different economic actors such as households (consumers), domestic and foreign business enterprises, and the government. These behaviours (and variables) influence each other or are collectively influenced by domestic or international events. The assembly and analysis of chain reactions have revealed how shocks or policy measures impact behaviour throughout the economy, as reflected in changes in the magnitude of macroeconomic variables. Various graphs have shown South African macroeconomic data that reflect the course of these variables over time. The South African Reserve Bank publishes much of these data regularly. The theory in the previous chapters provides a framework for making sense of observed patterns of economic behaviour – and understanding the likely linkages between variables. It uses such linkages to explain channels through which disturbances or policy steps are transmitted through the economy, moving the economy from one state to another. (The theory explains these transitions as moves from one equilibrium point to another.) A further dimension of all these interactions and transitions is that, in terms of the measured values of the variables, they must, and will, at all times remain within an encompassing set of constraints. These are rooted in an accounting-type coherence between different sectors – the numbers must add up, must balance. For example, a change in the measured balance (surplus or deficit) in one sector – for example, a current account deficit in the external sector – must and will be reflected in the measured balance (surplus or deficit) in another sector for that year or quarter – either the government-sector budget balance or the country’s savings-investment balance, or both. Such crosscutting coherence between sectors (or groups of economic activity) is valuable to unravel interrelated changes in the data on key macroeconomic components. The coherence is captured in several identities involving C, I, G, X and M and so forth. These Chapter 5: Understanding sectoral coherence and constraints: how to use macroeconomic identities How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 213 213 2019/12/17 09:15 identities are derived from the national accounts. The System of National Accounts (SNA) has an important role in ‘keeping the books’ of a country. ❐ Fortunately, here we do not have to do accounting at all. But, we will see how these national accounting identities constitute a powerful additional tool of analysis for the economist. The System of National Accounts (or SNA) is the primary data system in macroeconomics. It was developed by the United Nations to promote and standardise systematic economic measurement. The system prescribes the correct methods to collect, measure and process the data. ❐ It offers a complete set of definitions of macroeconomic variables such as consumption, investment, imports and exports – the well-known variables of macroeconomic theory. The definitions are crucial once one starts working with published data. ❐ It offers an accounting framework for all the numbers to ensure a consistent set of data. Section 5.6 offers a bird’s eye view. The SNA is illustrated using the classification of the numbers as in the Quarterly Bulletin of the Reserve Bank. It is, therefore, a handy reference section. (You can answer many of the questions in boxes in previous chapters using these data.) It also is an introduction to the complexities of the data tables and the need to take utmost care when working with such data. The Addendum offers a ‘student’s guide’ to the national accounts. The analytical use of the identities is discussed in sections 5.1 to 5.5, while section 5.7 analyses how the sectoral balance identities can be used in decision making. Section 5.6 shows the interaction and links between different subaccounts, how the identities actually operate, and the way economic changes are reflected in the real numbers. 5.1 From equilibrium conditions to identities In all the chain reactions, the importance of unplanned changes in inventories were highlighted. If planned expenditure is less than aggregate production, inventories will increase. If planned expenditure exceeds aggregate production, inventories will be used up. So what is the actual position in a non-equilibrium situation? While the economy is moving towards the equilibrium level of income, there is an imbalance between aggregate planned expenditure and production – which is reflected in either an increase or a decrease in inventories (involuntary inventory investment). Aggregate planned expenditure > production ⇒ Change in inventories is negative (inventories decrease) i.e. C + IT + GC + (X – M) > Y ⇒ Inventory investment figure is negative OR C + IT + GC + (X – M) < Y ⇒ Inventory investment figure is positive where IT is total fixed investment and GC is government consumption expenditure (see the shaded box below on the definition of these symbols). Both these inequalities can be changed into equalities by adding inventory investment II to the left-hand side of the expression: C + IT + GC + (X – M) + II = Y OR C + I* + GC + (X – M) Y OR C + (IT + II ) + GC + (X – M) = Y ...... (5.1) where I* denotes investment redefined to include unplanned inventory investment: I* = IT + II. Thus I* constitutes gross domestic investment (fixed and non-fixed). 214 Chapter 5: Understanding sectoral coherence and constraints: how to use macroeconomic identities How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 214 2019/12/17 09:15 Important: G and GC, I and IT In chapter 2 (section 2.2.5) we defined G, total general government expenditure, as follows: G = government consumption expenditure plus government investment = GC + IG. However, as noted in section 2.2.5, published national accounts data do not do this, since IG is not a part of ‘G’ in the national accounts. That is why we have adopted the practice, throughout this book, of using the symbol GC to denote government consumption. In chapter 2 we adopted the practice of defining I as business real fixed investment: I = IP + IPC, where the former is investment by private firms and the latter is investment by public corporations. However, in the national accounts, government fixed investment IG is included in the concept of total fixed investment: ❐ To avoid confusion, we introduce the symbol IT to denote total fixed investment in this allinclusive sense: IT = I + IG = IP + IPC + IG. It should also be noted that the definition of GC as used in the sectoral balance identities in section 5.4 (and in the ‘Production, distribution and accumulation accounts’ in the Reserve Bank Quarterly Bulletin) is slightly broader and more comprehensive than general government consumption in other contexts. ❐ The more comprehensive concept – called general government current expenditure – also includes interest payments, subsidies and transfers to households and the rest of the world. These items can be quite large (see table 10.1 in chapter 10). ❐ They are not included in the narrower definition of GC because interest on government debt, though being current expenditure, does not represent consumption. It is a factor payment. Subsidies represent a negative tax, while transfers represent a redistribution of income. ❐ Government current expenditure is relevant when calculating saving by general government (see section 5.4). The equality in equation 5.1 has the special attribute that it is always true, regardless of whether the economy is in macroeconomic equilibrium or not. This follows from the fact that the amount of any gap (excess or shortfall) between aggregate planned expenditure and aggregate production (which then causes unplanned inventory investment) is automatically included in the gross investment figure.1 This establishes and continuously maintains the numerical equality between the left-hand and right-hand sides of the equation. An expression such as equation 5.1, which is always true by definition, is called an identity. This characteristic is indicated by using the ‘’ symbol rather than the normal ‘=’ symbol. ❐ This particular identity is called the national income identity. ! The national income identity closely resembles the equilibrium condition for macroeconomic equilibrium (see chapter 2, section 2.2.6). However, they are completely different kinds of expression, as are their interpretations. ❐ The identity is always true, while the equilibrium condition is true only on the infrequent occasion when the economy actually is in macroeconomic equilibrium. ❐ The major substantial difference lies in the way in which the investment term is put together to include any excess or shortfall – which then actually creates the identity. ❐ When using either of these in macroeconomic analysis, these differences must be kept in mind at all times. 1 In the case of equilibrium, planned expenditure and production will be equal, with unplanned inventory investment being zero. 5.1 From equilibrium conditions to identities How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 215 215 2019/12/17 09:15 Figure 5.1 Nominal domestic expenditure and production 6 000 GDP 5 000 4 000 C R billion 3 000 2 000 GC 1 000 I* 0 X-M 2018/01 2016/03 2015/01 2013/03 2012/01 2010/03 2009/01 2007/03 2006/01 2004/03 2003/01 2001/03 2000/01 1998/03 1997/01 1995/03 1994/01 1992/03 1991/01 1989/03 1988/01 1986/03 1985/01 –1 000 Source: South African Reserve Bank (www.resbank.co.za). A more complete version of the national income identity, which corresponds to published tables, also shows ‘net current transfers received from the rest of the world’ TR: C + I* + GC + (X + TR – M) Y + TR ...... (5.1a) The graph in figure 5.1 shows the course of the variables in the national income identity since 1985 (R million in nominal terms).2 At all times, despite all kinds of fluctuation, these variables conform to the national income identity. How to interpret these changes is discussed next. 5.2 The interpretation of identities – uses and abuses The national income identity can be interpreted in several important ways. With some simple mathematical manipulation it can also be converted into different formats, which provide yet more insights. Broadly speaking, the meaning of these identities is that they indicate certain accounting constraints on macroeconomic variables – as defined and measured in the system of national accounts. All changes in variables that occur in the course of a macroeconomic chain reaction must and always will ‘obey’ these identities. This follows from the basic accounting coherence built into the system of national accounts. As with the accounting practice of a private business, the numbers must add up, must balance (with shortfalls or surpluses added in). 2 216 The data are taken from the table ‘National income and production account of South Africa’ in the Quarterly Bulletin of the Reserve Bank. It would be worth your while to scrutinise this table. Chapter 5: Understanding sectoral coherence and constraints: how to use macroeconomic identities How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 216 2019/12/17 09:15 While the linkages between variables produce important insights, unfortunately it can say absolutely nothing about causes, consequences or chain reactions. ❐ Hence it reveals nothing of the causality between economic variables and events. It merely constitutes the accounting outlines within which economic chain reactions can run their course. (Indeed, an incalculable number of permutations are possible within these constraints.) Example: the South African economy, 1985–2018 The graph in figure 5.2 shows the main variables from the national income identity from 1985. It differs from figure 5.1 in that all data are in real terms. The components of aggregate expenditure show a number of important trends: ❐ Real GDP increased every year from 1993 to 2018 (following ‘negative growth’ between 1989 and 1992) with the exception of the steep recession of 2008–09. ❐ During 2008–09 gross capital formation by (private and public) businesses slumped notably, whereafter it recovered before losing steam again since 2014. ❐ After being relatively stable for more than a decade, government consumption expenditure increased markedly after 1999, before slowing down from 2010 onwards. ❐ Net exports (in real terms) grew gradually up to 2001, whereafter it declined steadily and developed a persistent deficit since 2011. ❐ Household consumption expenditure increased steadily, but was stable as a ratio of GDP (similarly showing a large dip during 2008–09). The data patterns in figure 5.2 are open to various interpretations. ❐ For example, in the period of stagnation between 1988 and 1992, it could appear that the increase in GC was the cause of the decline in investment I – i.e. excessive government consumption expenditure GC was crowding out private economic activities in general – and private investment in particular. Figure 5.2 Real domestic expenditure and production (2010 prices) 3 500 GDP 3 000 2 500 R billion 2 000 C 1 500 1 000 GC I* 500 X-M 0 2018/01 2016/03 2015/01 2013/03 2012/01 2010/03 2009/01 2007/03 2006/01 2004/03 2003/01 2001/03 2000/01 1998/03 1997/01 1995/03 1994/01 1992/03 1991/01 1989/03 1988/01 1986/03 1985/01 –500 Source: South African Reserve Bank (www.resbank.co.za). 5.2 The interpretation of identities – uses and abuses How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 217 217 2019/12/17 09:15 ❐ To take another example, it might be argued that the sharp decline and eventual deficits in net exports from 2001 are the result of increasing imports that, in turn, flow from the sharp increase in private consumption. Is it valid to derive such conclusions about cause and effect from the identity? It is not, since an identity can give no indication of causality. Even if the explanation were correct, it would still be scientifically invalid to deduce it from the identity. It is unwarranted because a number of other explanations are possible for the same pattern. Consider the two examples again: ❐ The decline in investment between 1988 and 1992 could just as easily have been due to political-economic uncertainty and a lack of investor confidence (as occurred since 2014). And the increase in GC after 1988 may have prevented the downswing from being much more serious than it would have been, had GC not increased – rather than being a cause of the recession. ❐ Regarding the decline in net exports, it is equally possible to argue that, due to promising returns on investment, foreign investors invested significantly in South Africa in the high-growth period after 2003. This significant inflow of funds would have increased the external demand for rands, and the rand would have appreciated, which would have discouraged exports Two versions of the identities and encouraged imports. Is this view of the sequence of events more correct? The answer remains that one cannot deduce anything about causes and consequences merely by inspecting the identity. Either of the two explanations – or another one – may be correct. The identity cannot help one in this regard at all. The danger of the identities lies in their simplicity, in how ‘obvious’ apparently related changes look. The actual relation­s­hips and cause-and-effect relations in economic reality usually are more complicated. To understand the latter, one has to use logical analysis, theoretical frameworks and empirical research. ❐ The identities do not describe behaviour. Rather, they record a numerical balance in the outcomes of several behavioural variables in a specific, accounting way. Economic theory, such as the theory and chain reactions contained in chapters 2 to 4, describe behaviour and can be used to explain how change in one variable may lead to changes in other variables. 218 The national accounting identities can be expressed in terms of either GDP or GNDI (i.e. gross national disposable income). The major difference between GDP and GNDI is net ‘primary’ income from the rest of the world (payments to migrant labour from other countries, and so forth), as well as current transfers. Each version is characterised by the way exports and imports are defined and measured: ❐ If GDP is used, (X – M) is net exports, and only includes foreign trade in goods and services. ❐ If GNDI is used, net primary income receipts and current transfers are included in (X – M). (Also see the data tip in chapter 4, section 4.2.1.) It is immaterial which option is chosen. They are equivalent, since the same element is added to both sides of the definition. One reason to work with GNDI is that it allows a direct link-up with the current account data in the balance of payments table (which always includes international income flows). It also provides a direct link-up with the important table called ‘The financing of gross capital formation’ (see section 5.5). ❐ Hence the data and diagrams that follow are shown in terms of gross national disposable income. This means that the expression (X + TR – M) encountered in the equations is identical to the current account. ❐ Since balance of payments data are only published in nominal terms (i.e. in current prices), the rest of this chapter will mostly work in nominal terms. Chapter 5: Understanding sectoral coherence and constraints: how to use macroeconomic identities How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 218 2019/12/17 09:15 Nevertheless, the identities provide important insights into the way components and sectors of the macroeconomy cohere. In addition, they give some indication of the quantitative range of possible macroeconomic changes as well as constraints on such changes. As long as one is very careful not to use them incorrectly, identities can be valuable (see section 5.7). 5.3 Expenditure, production and current account deficits One can rewrite the complete, open economy national income identity as (X + TR – M) Y + TR – (C + I* + GC)...... (5.2) This form of the identity has a very powerful interpretation. It shows that the extent to which aggregate domestic expenditure3 (GDE = C + I* + GC) exceeds aggregate national disposable income GNDI is directly and identically reflected in net exports, and therefore in the current account (X + TR – M). Leaving aside the complication of net international transfers TR, one can state the following: ❐ A current account surplus means that GDE is less than gross national disposable income or GNDI. ❐ A current account deficit means that GDE exceeds gross national disposable income or GNDI. OR ❐ If GDE is less than gross national disposable income or GNDI, it implies a current account surplus. ❐ If GDE exceeds gross national disposable income or GNDI, it implies a current account deficit. Therefore an external disequilibrium (current account deficit or surplus) always has an internal macroeconomic counterpart (production is < or > expenditure). Therefore, the removal of a current account disequilibrium must always include the restoration of internal balance between expenditure and production (income). Likewise, restoring internal equilibrium between expenditure and production (income) always will and must reflect in the establishment of external (current account) equilibrium. 5.4 The sectoral balance identities For these identities, we redefine some government sector variables slightly. Let T = current revenue of government, i.e. taxes and other current revenue, and let GC = current expenditure of government, i.e. government consumption expenditure and other current expenditure (interest payments, subsidies and transfers to households and the rest of the world; see the data tip in section 5.1). If one adds and immediately subtracts T on the right-hand side of equation 5.2, it produces: (X + TR – M) (Y + TR – T) – (C + I*+ GC – T) ...... (5.3) 3 Take note of the difference between gross domestic expenditure (GDE), expenditure on gross domestic product, and aggregate demand. This is explained in the addendum to this chapter. 5.4 The sectoral balance identities How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 219 219 2019/12/17 09:15 Moving terms around produces: (Y + TR – T) C + I* + (GC – T) + (X + TR – M) ...... (5.4) Since Y + TR – T is the disposable income (YD) of residents, the following can be derived with some substitution of terms: YD C + I* + (GC – T) + (X + TR – M) ...... (5.5) Furthermore, saving is that part of disposable income that is not spent on consumption: S = YD – C, hence YD = S + C. Substituting this in equation 5.5, while collecting terms, produces: (S – I*) + (T – GC) (X + TR – M) ...... (5.6) This form of the identity is called the sectoral balance identity. It is extremely important, and can be interpreted in various ways. It shows a fundamental linkage between key balances in the private sector (households and business enterprises), the government sector and the foreign sector. Each element (or balance) indicates the relationship between inflows and outflows of a particular sector: DATA TIP S – I* = The excess of the total private saving (saving of households and businesses) over capital formation by both the businesses and government.4 We will call this the private saving balance.5 ❐ Remember that government capital formation is included in I*. While this is not entirely correct in terms of macroeconomic reasoning, convention is followed here so that the form of the identities matches published South African data tables. ❐ Should the consumption of fixed capital (also known as provision for depreciation) be included in both S and I*, the term S – I* will represent the gross private saving balance. Otherwise it is net private saving. ❐ Keep in mind that unplanned inventory investment is included in the investment term I* in all these identities. This element can be negative or positive. 4 5 220 Data for the components of total private saving S can be found in the following tables in the Quarterly Bulletin: ❐ Production, distribution and accumulation accounts of South Africa ❐ Current income and saving. The relevant data are also summarised in the table ‘Financing of gross capital formation’. The latter table also shows the gross figure for I*, of which more details can be found in the expenditure and capital formation tables. This element shows the overall (gross and net) investment–saving balance. Investments and loans between firms or between households and firms do not affect the (gross and net) balance, since these are internal to this component. This terminology is not quite correct, given our comprehensive definition of I* to include government investment IG. Most textbooks, indeed, show the identities with I as private sector investment, and government investment as a part of G. Then (S – I) is the private sector balance proper, and (T – G) is the overall fiscal deficit (not only the current deficit, as in South Africa). However, it does not change the analysis fundamentally – except that government saving or dissaving is not highlighted so explicitly. The South African debate may have been distorted somewhat by the fact that the data and the identities highlight government dissaving rather than the overall fiscal deficit. Chapter 5: Understanding sectoral coherence and constraints: how to use macroeconomic identities How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 220 2019/12/17 09:15 T – GC = The current government deficit or surplus (current income less current expenditure, i.e. gross and net government saving). This term is often negative, indicating general government ‘dissaving’. ❐ This is not the overall, conventional budget balance. Government capital expenditure (and revenue) is not included. It only shows current expenditure and revenue. ❐ Remember that in these sectoral identities GC is current government expenditure, which comprises more than government consumption expenditure (previously also indicated with the letter GC). The current expenditure of general government comprises government consumption expenditure plus interest on public debt, subsidies and transfers to households and the rest of the world. ❐ If one chooses to define current expenditure to include consumption of fixed capital by government, T – GC represents gross saving by government. Otherwise it is net saving by government. ❐ Remember that on the revenue side T includes, in addition to the tax revenue of the general government, revenue from property, as well as transfers received from households, business enterprises and the rest of the world. ❐ This element concerns the general government (national government plus provincial governments plus local governments). The budget presented annually by the Minister of Finance mostly concerns the national government. DATA TIP X + TR – M = The external surplus or deficit, i.e. the current account of the BoP. (Net current transfers from the rest of the world, and net primary income from the rest of the world, are included.) Detailed data on (T – GC) can be found in the Quarterly Bulletin table ‘Production, distribution and accumulation accounts for South Africa (General Government)’. It also is summarised in the table ‘Financing of gross capital formation’. The (X + TR – M) data can be found in the ‘Balance of payments’ table in the Quarterly Bulletin. Table 5.1 shows the sectoral balances for the South African economy for 2018 (in nominal terms). Consider the first line of the table first. The observed values reflect the outcomes, in a particular year, of numerous intertwined macroeconomic chain reactions, due inter alia to external disturbances, inherent instability and policy steps. Amidst all the changes, the figures remain within the constraints of the identity. The numbers always add up; always balance (given the SNA definitions). While the identity allows an innumerable number of combinations of values of economic variables such as C, I*, GC, X, M and T, there are limits within which these values must stay (or add up). Table 5.1 also demonstrates that the sectoral balances can be calculated either on a gross saving (first line) or net saving (third line) basis, the latter being gross saving minus the ‘consumption of fixed capital’ (i.e. the provision for depreciation). (Recall that for gross saving by government GC includes consumption of fixed capital, otherwise known as provision for depreciation.) ❐ The first three columns show the gross and net private saving of businesses (financialand non-financial corporations) and households. This is denoted by S. ❐ Column four shows the gross and net saving by government, denoted by the current deficit (T – GC). 5.4 The sectoral balance identities How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 221 221 2019/12/17 09:15 Table 5.1 The sectoral balances for 2018 (R million, current prices) Households Non–fin corp Financial corp (T – Gc) S Gross saving/ investment Consumption of fixed capital Net saving/ investment General govt Domestic economy S + (T – Gc) I* (S – I*) 67 099 518 640 116 818 –1 124 701 433 874 396 –171 839 –70 138 –491 447 –21 141 –93 761 –676 487 –676 487 93 761 –3 039 27 193 95 677 –94 885 24 946 197 909 –78 078 Foreign sector (S – I*) + (T – Gc) = (X + TR – M) –172 963 –172 963 –172 963 –172 963 Source: South African Reserve Bank (www.resbank.co.za). ❐ These add up to net or gross domestic saving (S + T – GC), with the difference between gross and net saving again being the consumption of fixed capital. ❐ Subtracting I* from S yields (S – I*), the private saving balance, while subtracting I* from [S + (T – GC)] yields excess domestic saving = (S – I*) + (T – GC), which equals the current account (X + TR – M). Figure 5.4 shows these basic elements for the South African economy since 1995 (in nominal terms). Note the change with regard to the current account position after 2002, and how it is linked to corresponding changes in the other variables. The identity shows, at each point in time, a ‘snapshot’ of the limits, at a particular moment, within which the values of variables must stay at all times. By switching terms around, the sectoral balance identity (equation 5.6) can be written in different forms, each of which provides different interpretations and insights. 5.4.1 Interpretation 1 – external imbalances (X + TR – M) (S – I*) + (T – GC) [S + (T – GC)] – I* ...... (5.6a) Together, the two terms on the right-hand side amount to the overall domestic saving– investment position: ❐ (T – GC) plus S is gross domestic saving (by government and businesses – i.e. private firms and government corporations – and households). ❐ I* is gross capital formation (by government and businesses, with inventory investment included). The left-hand side is the current account of the BoP – the external (im)balance. In this form of the identity one can deduce that, if there is an external, current account surplus (net inflow of funds), the funds have to be, and are being, absorbed somewhere: either the domestic private sector must save more than it invests, or the government sector must collect taxes in excess of its current expenditure – or both. That is, any external imbalance must be matched by corresponding internal sectoral imbalances. ❐ Still, there can and should be no explicit or implicit suggestion of causality in this interpretation. That is the function of theory and ‘chain reasoning’. 222 Chapter 5: Understanding sectoral coherence and constraints: how to use macroeconomic identities How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 222 2019/12/17 09:15 Conversely, if the government sector shows a current fiscal deficit (T < GC) and domestic investment is in excess of domestic saving (S < I*) – in both cases more is spent than the funds that are available – it will be matched by an external imbalance (current account deficit) of corresponding size. ❐ This parallels the conclusion in section 5.3: a trade or current account deficit means that domestic expenditure is in excess of available domestic production. And, once again, these deficits or imbalances can have their origins/causes in any of the sectoral balances, or in variables elsewhere in the economy. In South Africa it was the case, until 1993, that T < GC (government dissaving) while S > I* (private saving surplus). The positive (S – I*) figure exceeded the negative (T – GC) figure in absolute terms, implying a net positive figure. Therefore it was matched by a current account surplus in each year. (See section 5.5 for a further interpretation of this situation.) ❐ After 1994 this situation reversed: (S – I*) was still positive, but in absolute terms it was less than (T – GC). Hence the domestic saving–investment [(S + (T – GC)) – I*] situation was matched by a parallel deficit on the current account. The relationship over time between the different elements of the identity is shown in figure 5.3. The consumption of capital is included in saving and investment, so we are dealing with gross saving concepts. The graph clearly shows how, when the gap between gross domestic saving and gross domestic investment increased after 2002, the current account deficit widened correspondingly. Figure 5.3 Gross domestic saving and the current account 1 000 (S – I*) + (T – GC) I* 800 600 R billion S + (T – GC) 400 200 0 X + TR – M –200 2018 2017 2016 2015 2014 2013 2012 2011 2010 2009 2008 2007 2006 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 –400 Source: South African Reserve Bank (www.resbank.co.za). 5.4 The sectoral balance identities How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 223 223 2019/12/17 09:15 5.4.2 Interpretation 2 – saving and investment imbalances (S I*) (GC T) (X TR M) ...... (5.6b) A domestic imbalance between saving and investment (i.e. between inflows and outflows) is mirrored in either the current government balance or the external balance. If the private sector as a whole saves more than is being invested domestically, the resultant surplus funds are being absorbed somewhere: either as loans to the government (to finance a current government deficit (GC – T) or loans to the external sector (to foreign countries that need the funds to finance their trade deficit with South Africa) or other forms of capital outflow. Of course, both can occur simultaneously. In South Africa, capital outflows absorbed the greater part of these surplus funds for many years (in addition to those being absorbed by the fiscal deficit). Indeed, the capital outflows were the major reason why a current account surplus had to be maintained – sufficient foreign exchange reserves had to be generated from trade to finance the capital outflows. (Capital flows cannot be seen explicitly in this identity. Section 5.5 shows a form of the identity in which they are explicit.) The relationship between the different elements of the identity is shown in figure 5.4 (again with consumption of capital included). It clearly shows how, when the gap between gross domestic saving and gross domestic investment increased after 2002, the current account deficit widened correspondingly. ❐ In 1994, and thereafter, the situation changed significantly, bringing about a positive inflow of capital from other countries. For the first time in more than a decade, South Africa could afford a current account deficit – the capital inflows brought sufficient foreign reserves to finance the growing current account deficit (X + TR – M) (see figure 5.4 and table 5.2). ❐ This current account deficit was largely reflected in an increasing negative gross private saving–investment gap (S – I*), while gr­oss saving by government (T – GC) turned Figure 5.4 Gross private saving, government saving and the current account 1 200 1 000 I* 800 S R billion 600 T 400 GC 200 0 X + TR – M –200 2018 2017 2016 2015 2014 2013 2012 2011 2010 2009 2008 2007 2006 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 –400 Source: South African Reserve Bank (www.resbank.co.za). 224 Chapter 5: Understanding sectoral coherence and constraints: how to use macroeconomic identities How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 224 2019/12/17 09:15 positive in 2004. This means that government eliminated gross dissaving in 2004 (in national accounting terms). ❐ However, what is not shown on this graph is that net saving by government (i.e. gross saving minus the consumption of fixed capital) only turned positive for 2006 and 2007. Since net saving is the relevant concept when analysing dissaving by government, this is an important aspect to remember (see chapter 10, section 10.7.3 for data on net saving). 5.4.3 Interpretation 3 – current fiscal deficits (T – GC) (I* – S) + (X + TR – M) ...... (5.6c) If government has a current fiscal deficit, it must borrow from a sector that has surplus funds: either the domestic private sector (households and/or business enterprises) that saves in excess of total domestic investment, or the foreign sector, which has earned net surplus funds from trade with South Africa – or both. ❐ Should the current account happen to be in equilibrium, the current fiscal deficit can be reflected in only one place: an internal imbalance between I* and S. ❐ Likewise, if government finances show a current balance, then the domestic S-I imbalance must precisely match the external sector (current account) imbalance. In South Africa, capital outflows occurred for a long period between the early 1980s and 1994; therefore a current account surplus had to be maintained. Domestic expenditure had to be kept below total production. In other words, the domestic private saving– investment balance had to generate sufficient surplus funds to finance both the current fiscal deficit and the capital outflows. ❐ Increased political stability following the political change in 1994 put a stop to the drainage of domestic saving to other countries. This left more room for gross fixed capital formation, which could – for the first time in a decade – be allowed to exceed domestic saving. Despite the richness of the insights that can be derived from the different forms of the sectoral balance identity, they still do not reveal any causal relationships. All three of the balances are determined simultaneously by the entire complex of macroeconomic relationships, processes and reactions. 5.5 The financing of gross capital formation Table 5.2, reproduced from the Quarterly Bulletin of the Reserve Bank, provides very useful additional insights in the constraints implied by the sectoral balance identities. It is closely related to equation 5.6a, i.e. interpretation 1 of the identity. The top four lines yield: S + (T – GC) = gross domestic saving. The last line is: I* = gross capital formation. Lines 7 and 8 may be more difficult to understand. They derive from the following identity for the external sector (BoP): Change in gold and other foreign reserves = BoP + change in liabilities related to reserves = Current account + financial account + change in liabilities related to reserves = Current account + ‘net capital inflow from the rest of the world’. 5.5 The financing of gross capital formation How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 225 225 2019/12/17 09:15 Table 5.2 Financing of gross capital formation (R millions, current prices) 2013 2014 2015 2016 –48 311 –45 553 –19 930 –23 214 5 595 –3 038 171 749 184 126 165 602 167 545 193 360 122 870 3. Saving by general governmenta –62 083 –76 770 –45 941 –52 164 –80 809 –94 884 4. Consumption of fixed capital 482 989 525 308 560 416 617 969 638 782 676 486 5. Gross savingsc 544 344 587 111 660 147 710 136 756 928 701 434 6. Foreign investment 204 841 192 966 187 006 125 102 118 234 172 962 7. Net capital inflow from the rest of the world 209 468 208 100 172 991 164 624 143 759 184 299 8. Change in gold and other foreign reserves –4 627 –15 134 14 015 –39 522 –25 525 –11 337 749 185 780 077 847 153 835 238 875 162 874 396 1. Saving by households a 2. Corporate savingsa 9. Gross capital formation b d 2017 2018 a. After consumption of fixed capital and after inventory valuation adjustment. b. At replacement value. (This term used to be called ‘provision for depreciation’.) c. After inventory valuation adjustment. d. Increase –; decrease +. Source: SARB. The change in liabilities related to reserves usually occurs due to short-term foreign loans by the national government or the Reserve Bank from foreign banks and governments. Thus it is a form of capital inflow, but for very specific reasons unrelated to international trade and investment. It allows for changes in reserves for reasons other than normal BoP transactions. Moving terms around in this last equation produces: Current account (CA) = Change in gold and other foreign reserves + net capital inflow from the rest of the world This expression is particularly useful since it shows how changes in the current account will be matched by changes in capital flows and especially foreign reserves: ❐ A current account deficit, for example, must be financed by either capital inflow or the use of foreign reserves (or both). Hence a current account deficit will cause and require an equivalent change in the sum of the latter two sources of financing. ❐ Conversely, a current account surplus must be reflected in an addition to reserves or an outflow of capital (or both). The portion of the net current account inflow that does not go into reserves must have flown out of the country. Hence, the sum of lines 7 and 8 indicates the current account position. The current account position is indicated in line 6, where it is called foreign investment. This may sound strange, but it reflects the fact that a current account deficit needs to be financed, and matched, by capital inflows. (Note that in this table a positive sign indicates a current account deficit.) It can now be seen that the structure of the table simply reflects the sectoral balance identity in a somewhat different form: [S + (T – GC)] – CA I* Therefore, table 5.2 provides an extension of the set of identities above in that it makes explicit the linkages between (a) the current account (CA) and (b) capital flows and changes in foreign reserves. 226 Chapter 5: Understanding sectoral coherence and constraints: how to use macroeconomic identities How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 226 2019/12/17 09:15 Interpretation 1 above therefore can be restated as follows: if gross domestic saving exceeds gross domestic investment, it must be matched by a current account surplus – which must, in turn, be matched by either a capital outflow or an increase in foreign reserves (or both). This was the case in South Africa after 1986. Only in 1994 did things turn around, showing current account deficits from 1995 onwards. Another interpretation, which clearly illustrates the South African economic crisis of the decade 1983–93, is as follows: ❐ If there is a continual capital outflow (net capital inflow is negative), and if reserves are insufficient to finance this outflow fully, then the current account has to be kept in a surplus. ❐ Given the sectoral links revealed by the identities, this can be achieved only by getting gross capital formation (domestic investment) to a level lower than gross domestic saving – and keeping it there. ❐ If the level of domestic saving is high, there is no problem. However, if total saving already is relatively low, it implies a low ceiling below which investment must be squeezed. Hence investment cannot be allowed to be ‘high’ (relative to domestic saving). Such a ‘saving ceiling’ makes the problem of capital outflows much worse. ❐ If the contribution of the general government to domestic saving is negative (i.e. government dissaving, a current fiscal deficit) – as had progressively been the case in South Africa – it becomes increasingly difficult to generate enough net domestic saving (from the only remaining source, private households and businesses). The pressure to put a lid on investment (and expenditure in general) escalates. ❐ In other words, in such a situation a current fiscal deficit – which need not necessarily be a problem in a general fiscal context6 – suddenly constitutes a major problem, placing severe pressure on the fiscus. This analysis reveals the severe ‘straitjacket’ that substantial capital outflows imply for a country such as South Africa – given the intrinsic constraints, as revealed by the different identities. In such a situation significant economic growth is not allowed, because: ❐ Private consumption C may not be stimulated, since that may depress personal saving. ❐ Government consumption expenditure GC may not be used for stimulation, since that would increase government dissaving. ❐ Tax cuts may not be used to stimulate growth, since that also increases government dissaving. ❐ Capital formation may not be stimulated, since it has to be kept far enough below total saving to generate a large enough current account surplus (to finance the capital outflow). ❐ GDP may not increase, since it will stimulate imports, aggravating the problem of sustaining a current account surplus. The turnaround of this situation after 1994 signalled a great relief for South Africa from the stranglehold, shown in the identities, which prevailed before that. With capital inflows occurring again, government dissaving suddenly is less of a problem (and something that can now be evaluated in fiscal terms rather than in the ‘financing of investment’ context; see chapter 10). Although the relief after 1994 has been quite significant (aided by capital inflows and government dissaving that decreased significantly), the low saving rate still creates problems 6 This is discussed in chapter 10. 5.5 The financing of gross capital formation How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 227 227 2019/12/17 09:15 for the economy. More specifically, I* exceeds S by a substantial margin because of the low rate of domestic saving, particularly by households (see table 5.1). 5.6 The SNA at a glance – relationships between subaccounts7 The composite SNA table on the If you have trouble understanding the concepts and following pages shows the basic variables in the tables, consult the addendum to this structure and coherence of the chapter, which provides a simple explanation of the national accounts at a glance. main definitions. Study it carefully and thoroughly. Nine different accounts are shown. These correspond with the SNA tables in the Quarterly Bulletin of the Reserve Bank (which also provide a more detailed breakdown of the tables.) The SNA accounts organise macroeconomic data in terms of: ❐ the main domestic economic activities (production, income, expenditure and saving); ❐ the main domestic sectors (incorporated business enterprises, general government, and the household or personal sector), and ❐ the external sector, which is represented in a separate account (no. 5), and indirectly in the expenditure account (no. 3). Account name SARB table BLOCK A Account 1 Account 2 Account 3 Production Income Expenditure Gross value added by kind of economic activity National income and production accounts Expenditure on gross domestic product Account 4 Saving and investment Account 5 External account Financing of gross domestic capital formation; Gross and net capital formation by type of organisation Balance of payments In this table X and M are defined to include income payments to, and receipts from, the rest of the world (as is the practice in the balance of payments table)8 BLOCK B BLOCK C Accounts 6–9 Net sectoral saving Production, distribution and accumulation (One table for each sector, the sectors being financial corporations, non-financial corporations, general government and households) For all three sectors, capital expenditure – i.e. investment – is not shown here. All the investment components feature indirectly in account 4, where together they constitute gross capital formation I* (= GCF or GDI). 7 8 228 This section can be omitted without loss of continuity. Formally, the special capital flows are called Changes in liabilities related to reserves. These are short-term foreign loans by the Reserve Bank and the government from foreign banks and governments. SDR allocations and valuation adjustments are excluded from the Change in gross reserves item, since these fall outside the conventional macroeconomic framework. Chapter 5: Understanding sectoral coherence and constraints: how to use macroeconomic identities How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 228 2019/12/17 09:15 Block A illustrates the three methods of calculating aggregate output noted above, and the intrinsic equivalence of the three methods: ❐ Account 1 shows how total production is made up from production (value added) in three sectors: the primary sector (agriculture, mining, etc.), the secondary sector (manufacturing, electricity, construction) and the tertiary or services sector (wholesale and retail trade, transport and communication services, financial services, and community and social services). ❐ Account 2 calculates aggregate output from the income side of the circular flow, i.e. from the income earned by different production factors. ❐ Account 3 works from the expenditure side, using the income-expenditure identity Y = C + I* + GC + (X – M) (+ residual). More detailed tables in the Quarterly Bulletin show the breakdown of expenditure within each of the main categories, e.g. household consumption expenditure and capital formation. Block A also shows how indirect taxes and subsidies must be taken into account (compare the market price vs. basic price vs. factor cost methods). The difference between GDP and GNI is apparent, as is the equivalence of GDP and ‘Expenditure on GDP’. Block B shows the relationship between domestic saving and investment (capital formation), as well as the external account (BoP). ❐ Account 5 shows the relationship between the current account, the capital account and the BoP, as well as the foreign reserves. More specifically: – Changes in either trade or capital flows are reflected in the BoP. – Changes in the BoP are necessarily mirrored in changes in reserves. – When observing the actual data for these variables (see Quarterly Bulletin), one can see how the current account deficit in 2018 is financed by capital inflows. Since these exceeded the CA deficit (outflow of payments), the reserves showed an increase. If capital flows were less than the CA deficit, reserves would necessarily have been used to finance the current account (the change in gross reserves figure would have been negative). ❐ Account 4 is basically the ‘Financing of Gross Capital Formation’ (GCF) table discussed in section 5.5. It is placed in Block B together with the external account to illustrate the very important sectoral balance identity, discussed extensively above. In essence, any gap between gross (or net) capital formation and gross (or net) domestic saving – a saving deficiency – is reflected in a current account deficit. Excess domestic saving will be matched by a current account surplus. Block C shows the sectoral breakdown of production, distribution and accumulation. Note that these sectoral tables are incomplete in the sense that investment (capital expenditure) is not shown. Yet the tables are important in that they show how sectoral production, income and expenditure behaviour, as reflected in saving, becomes an input in account 4, where total saving is instrumental in financing total capital formation (which, in turn, is composed of sectoral capital formation). Of course, sectoral behaviour, in turn, is the endogenous result of changes occurring in other accounts – as explained in the theory of chapters 2 to 4. The SNA accounts constitute a complete and consistent system. As in business accounting, identities and equalities govern the coherence between the different accounts and subaccounts. 5.6 The SNA at a glance – relationships between subaccounts How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 229 229 2019/12/17 09:15 230 Chapter 5: Understanding sectoral coherence and constraints: how to use macroeconomic identities How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 230 2019/12/17 09:15 Total capital flows (marked with *) match the difference between saving and capital formation – and thus also equals the current account. C Saving by households Total corporate saving S Total private saving (T – GC)1 Saving by genl government (S + T – GC )1 Total savings I* – Total capital formation (S – I* + T – G ) SAVING–INVESTMENT BALANCE 4. Saving and investment Net –3.0 122.9 119.9 –94.9 25.0 –197.9 5. External account Merchandise exports Net gold exports Service receipts Income receipts – Merchandise imports – Payment for services – Income payments Net current transfers Capital transfer account* FINANCIAL ACCOUNT Direct investment Portfolio investment Financial derivatives Other investment [Reserve assest* (increase (–)] FINANCIAL ACCOUNT* (excluding change in reserves, including unrecorded transactions)* BALANCE OF PAYMENTS (change in reserves excluded, unrecorded transactions included) –173.0 CURRENT ACCOUNT Gross 67.1 635.5 702.6 –1.1 701.4 –874.4 4 873.49 4 857.1 1 457.6 1 440.9 2 921.0 1 037.3 886.4 –12.0 24.5 30.7 11.3 10.4 33.2 7.2 102.6 –11.3 153.4 0.2 –173.0 1 175.6 71.7 210.4 96.5 –1 222.9 –217.9 –250.6 –35.7 (‘Change in reserves’) (X + TR – M)3 Difference between GDE and GNDI equals the balance on the current account –154.1 4 719.9 –35.7 4 684.2 Net primary income from the rest of the world GNI @ market prices Net current transfers from the rest of the world GNDI @ market prices Gross domestic expenditure (GDE) + Exports – Imports 3. Expenditure Final consumption expenditure by households Final consumption expenditure by government Gross fixed captital formation Change in inventories Residual 4 873.9 Expenditure on GDP 2 320.2 1 249.2 676.5 4 245.9 101.9 6.5 4 341.3 545.6 13.0 GDP at market prices 2. Income Compensation of employees Net operating surplus Consumption of fixed captital Gross value added at factor cost + Other taxes on production – Other subsidies on production Gross value added at basic prices + Taxes on products – Subsidies on products B) SECTORAL BALANCE IDENTITIES: (S – I*) + (T – GC) = X + TR – M Total production equals total expenditure (on the right-hand side of the table) 4 341.3 Gross value added at basic prices Y 456.9 909.2 2 975.2 1. Production Primary sector Secondary sector Tertiary sector A) NATIONAL PRODUCTION, INCOME AND EXPENDITURE: Y = C + I* + GC + (X – M ) (Please note that at the time of publication these figures were still subject to revision – so by e.g. 2022 some of the 2018 numbers will have changed after revision.) THE NATIONAL INCOME AND PRODUCTION ACCOUNTS AT A GLANCE (2018, R billion, current prices)1 C + I* + GC + X – M C + I* + GC X M I* C GC2 5.6 The SNA at a glance – relationships between subaccounts How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 231 231 2019/12/17 09:15 22.8 182.4 274.8 223.7 53.1 210.9 233.5 183.3 63.9 Net property income Gross balance of primary income Social contributions received Other current transfers received – Current taxes on income and wealth – Social benefits paid – Other current transfers paid Gross disposable income – Adj for change in net equity of households in pension reserves – Residual 93.5 Net lending (+)/Net borrowing (–) Net lending (+)/Net borrowing (–) Gross saving Capital transfers (net) – Change in assets (net) Net saving – Consumption of fixed capital Gross saving – Residual Other current transfers received – Current taxes on income and wealth – Social benefits paid – Other current transfers paid Gross disposable income Net property income Gross balance of primary income 7. Non-financial corporations Gross value added – Compensation of employees – Other taxes on production Other subsidies on production Gross operating surplus –86.5 518.6 2.2 607.3 65.1 491.5 518.6 16.2 40.4 196.3 19.0 45.6 534.8 –281.6 755.2 2 317.7 1 232.3 54.5 5.9 1 036.7 Net lending (+)/Net borrowing (–) Gross saving Capital transfers (net) – Change in assets (net) Net saving – Consumption of fixed capital Gross saving –164.0 –1.1 –17.1 145.8 –136.6 93.8 –1.1 1 037.3 88.0 1 036.1 – Other current transfers paid Gross disposable income – Final consumption expenditure 836.7 719.0 9.6 0.4 108.6 545.6 101.9 13.0 6.5 –179.1 557.5 752.4 25.3 12.1 223.1 8. General government Gross value added – Compensation of employees – Other taxes on production Other subsidies on production Gross operating surplus Taxes on products Other taxes on production – Subsidies on products – Other subsidies on production Net property income Gross balance of primary income Current taxes on income and wealth Social contributions received Other current transfers received – Social benefits paid 1) Due to rounding of numbers small discrepancies may appear in some totals. 2) GC in Block B4 is government current expenditure, where as in Block A3 it is government consumption expenditure – see section 5.4. 3) In this line X and M are defined to include income payments to, and receipts from, the rest of the world (as is the practice in the balance of payments table). 95.7 116.8 0.0 23.3 Gross saving Capital transfers (net) – Change in assets (net) 21.1 – Consumption of fixed capital Net saving 116.8 Gross saving 2.6 373.7 208.8 5.3 0.0 159.6 6. Financial corporations Gross value added – Compensation of employees – Other taxes on production Other subsidies on production Gross operating surplus C) SECTORAL PRODUCTION, DISTRIBUTION AND ACCUMULATION ACCOUNTS –15.9 67.1 15.1 98.0 –3.0 70.1 67.1 63.9 5.7 2 988.1 2 921.0 434.0 251.0 502.9 281.1 195.9 2 929.9 286.1 3 224.8 813.2 160.1 32.5 0.2 620.8 2 317.9 Sectoral saving produces total saving Net lending (+)/Net borrowing (–) Gross saving Capital transfers (net) – Change in assets (net) Net saving – Consumption of fixed capital Gross saving Social benefits received Other current transfers received – Current taxes on income and wealth – Social benefits paid – Other current transfers paid Gross disposable income + Adj for change in net equity of households in pension reserves – Residual Total household resources – Final consumption expenditure Net property income Gross balance of primary income 9. Households Gross value added – Compensation of employees – Other taxes on production Other subsidies on production Gross operating surplus Compensation of employees Items that appear in more than one place must match. For example: ❐ Government consumption expenditure and household consumption in sector subaccounts 8 and 9 also appear in the expenditure account 3, in the familiar C + I + GC + (X – M) context. ❐ Direct taxes of financial and non-financial corporations and households (accounts 6, 7 and 9) add up to the direct tax receipts of general government in account 8. ❐ Indirect taxes and subsidies, in account 2, match the indirect tax revenue received and subsidies paid by general government in account 8. ❐ Gross capital formation in account 3 matches that in account 4. ❐ The different sectors’ saving, derived in accounts 6 to 9, reappear as components of domestic saving in account 4. ❐ The X and M figures in account 5 match those in the C + I + GC + (X – M) table (account 3). Identities must always be true. A change in one place will and must be reflected in other accounts (without saying anything about the direction of causality, as explained above). The system must balance in an accounting sense. ❐ Any discrepancy between total domestic expenditure GDE and total production GNDI (in account 3) will be reflected in a current account deficit (in account 5) – a sign of domestic overspending. (This imbalance could have originated either internally or externally, e.g. a drop in exports.) ❐ Because of the coherence between the accounts, this will necessarily have its mirror image in a discrepancy between gross domestic saving GDS and gross capital formation GCF (account 4). ❐ Any gap between GCF and gross domestic saving GDS – a domestic saving deficiency – is reflected in the current account, but likewise requires financing by foreign capital inflows or the use of reserves to finance that part of the investment not financed by domestic saving. Or, equivalently, the current account deficit must be financed; thus it will reflect in the financial account of the BoP and/or the reserves. (Excess domestic saving is mirrored by capital outflows or reserves increasing, matched by a current account surplus.) Changes in the economy, as discussed in the various chain reactions in chapters 2 to 4, will be reflected in the national accounts. For example: ❐ If the economy experiences a recession, production, income and expenditure on GDP will all be at a lower level. The external account is likely to show changes, at least in imports. In accounts 1 to 3 some or all components will have to be different (depending on how, why and where exactly in the economy the recession started and spread through the economy). Of necessity, some or all sectoral activities will also reflect this (without revealing which of the changes were causes and which were effects in the various chain reactions). All the elements in the sectoral balance identity are likely to have different values – while the identity will remain true at all times (it will always balance). 5.7 Using the sectoral balance identities for decision making It has been stated repeatedly that all the identities do not show any causal relationships between sectors and variables. All the sectoral balances are simultaneously determined by macroeconomic processes and reactions. So, what is the use of the identities for decision making and analysis (over and above the insights already gained above)? 232 Chapter 5: Understanding sectoral coherence and constraints: how to use macroeconomic identities How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 232 2019/12/17 09:15 Anticipating the possible causes of disturbances or policy steps If one of the elements, e.g. in the sectoral balances, is disturbed by a policy step or some other event, it will lead – via the normal economic channels and chain reactions – to a new situation that will be reflected ex post in the identities and balances in an accounting sense. If government is contemplating a change to (GC – T) with policy, the identity tells it beforehand that changes in one or both of the other sectoral balances will result (via the normal chain reactions indicated in chapters 2 to 4). However, since both sectoral balances can be affected, and to different extents, this knowledge is of limited value only. Also, GC and T may be affected by changes in the economy. On the basis of the identities alone, one cannot even predict where the largest impact will be – unless one has other information on the likely behaviour of sectoral variables (e.g. policy variables under the control of policy authorities). ❐ Acceptable predictions require estimates of the different elasticities, sensitivities and time lags involved in economic relationships. Empirical estimates of these can be made using techniques such as regression analysis or econometric model building, based on economic theory. These may then be used to generate quantitative estimates of changes in economic variables following a disturbance. Following such a disturbance or policy step, and with the prior knowledge of the origin of a sequence of changes, one can follow the reflection of this sequence in the national accounts, and interpret the accounting changes in that context. (One should bear in mind that other events may also have impacted the sequence of events as they took their course. An economy is continually subject to multiple influences.) ❐ Such an analysis of causes and effects does not flow from the identities themselves, but from prior knowledge and theoretical insights in economic relationships and causality. The identities can therefore be useful instruments, in conjunction with others, in better anticipating and understanding the future course of events. Diagnostic analysis or problem solving? Where the cause of a sequence of events is not known, the identities are of less use. If one were only to observe, ex post facto, changes in the sector balances, it would not be possible to make a deduction regarding the sequence of events or the cause-and-effect relations that might have been occurring. Observed changes in the balances cannot indicate where changes originated; cannot indicate ‘guilty’ or ‘not guilty’ sectors or variables. Where the identities can be an aid is in checking whether a possible explanation of an event or problem or the use of economic theory is consistent with the identities. By checking whether proposed explanations are consistent with the constraints revealed by the identities, invalid explanations can be disqualified and the potential validity of others ascertained. However, it would not be possible to designate a ‘winner’. But is it not possible to identify likely problem areas, or a sector where one should start to solve certain macroeconomic problems? To some extent this may be possible – first, the identities do indicate sectors or balances where the economy is experiencing pressure or tightness, and, second, one knows how the sectors are linked and has a good (theoretical) idea of how chain reactions spread through the economy. It may therefore be possible to target certain areas for remedial action. 5.7 Using the sectoral balance identities for decision making How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 233 233 2019/12/17 09:15 ❐ This still does not mean that the targeted sector has been identified as ‘guilty’. An undesirable balance in one or more sectors may have been caused by a disturbance or policy step elsewhere in the economy. ❐ Without theoretical insights and reasoning, any identification of problem areas is a very dangerous, mechanical exercise that bases decisions on a ‘black box’. And so we come to a general and crucial insight regarding the national accounting identities: they are very useful, but can easily be used improperly. 5.8 Analytical questions and exercises 1. Suppose that the government is running a budget surplus. Use the relevant sectoral balance identity to indicate how this surplus could have originated. 2. Suppose that domestic investment exceeds domestic saving. Use the relevant sectoral balance identity to indicate how this saving shortfall could have originated. 3. In 2019 several huge amounts (up to R70 billion) were given to Eskom by the National Treasury as bail-outs to keep it running and to service its debt. At the same time, said the Treasury, ‘growth is not coming through and tax revenues are not there: we are in trouble’. Discuss the sectoral balance identity, the budget identity and fixed budgetary commitments as constraints on the fiscal policy choices that the National Treasury faces. 4. Consider the current account position in South Africa at the moment and use the relevant sectoral balance identity to indicate how this position can be absorbed in the economy. 5. The current account recorded a deficit of R173 billion in 2018. Use the relevant sectoral balance identity to show how this external imbalance could be absorbed in the economy. 234 Chapter 5: Understanding sectoral coherence and constraints: how to use macroeconomic identities How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 234 2019/12/17 09:15 Addendum 5.1: National accounting definitions and conventions – a student’s guide The intricacies of national accounting match those of accounting for a private business enterprise. As the name indicates, the System of National Accounts is an accounting framework for the national economy. It is a complete accounting system, organised in a number of separate accounts that are linked together and which must balance. The most important accounts and concepts, for macroeconomic purposes, concern expenditure, saving, production and income. All these take both the domestic economy and external linkages into account.9 An important element of the SNA, and of the linkages, is the definitions of variables. These definitions, which can be quite complicated, are governed by a number of national accounting conventions. For the purposes of basic macroeconomic analysis, the following distinctions are most important. 1. Measurement at ‘market prices’, ‘basic prices’ and ‘factor cost’, as in GDP at market prices, GDP at basic prices and GDP at factor cost This distinction relates to the way in which GDP is actually calculated, and the different sets of prices used. Three sets are used in the national accounts: market prices, basic prices and factor cost. The first refers to a calculation looking at the market value or prices of the goods and services produced, the second considers the effective price received by a seller, and the third considers the income earned by production factors in the process (i.e. the cost of the factors of production such as labour, capital and land). Conceptually, these three appear to be the same. However, in practice, the presence of different types of indirect taxes and subsidies implies wedges between market price, effective (or basic) price and factor income (or factor cost). Therefore the SNA distinguishes between (a) taxes ‘on products’, e.g. VAT or import duties payable on products as such, and (b) other taxes and subsidies ‘on production’; the latter relate to taxes payable in the production process, e.g. payroll taxes or licence fees. For example, the presence of VAT means that the market price of bread is higher than the price effectively received by the seller of bread. The indirect tax VAT must be subtracted from the market price figure to get the ‘basic price’ value of the bread. However, the presence of a payroll tax, for example, means that this basic price still is higher than the income those involved in producing the bread (production factors such as labour, capital and land) will really receive as gross income (i.e. before paying income tax). When this type of indirect tax is deducted, one gets the value of production ‘at factor cost’. Similar arguments apply to subsidies on products or production. Therefore the total value of the production of bread calculated on the basis of market prices will not equal the total value of bread production calculated on the basis of basic prices or the income earned by bread producers. The difference is made up by the net tax/ subsidy figure. 9 See the relevant section in Mohr (2019) Economic Indicators for a more complete explanation. Addendum 5.1: National accounting definitions and conventions: a student’s guide How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 235 235 2019/12/17 09:15 The same principle applies to calculations of aggregate production in a country. Therefore: GDP at market prices — taxes on products subsidies on products GDP (also known as Gross value added) at basic prices AND THEN GDP at basic prices — taxes on production subsidies on production GDP (also known as Gross value added) at factor cost If GDP at market prices > GDP at factor cost, all the indirect taxes together (on products and production) exceed total subsidies. In South Africa this is consistently the case, especially with indirect taxes such as VAT and the fuel levy having become such important elements in the national budget. In 2018, for example, GDP at market prices was R4 874 billion while GDP at factor cost was R4 246 billion. GDP at basic prices was somewhere in the middle of these two, at R4 341 billion. What is ‘value added’? Conceptually, value added simply is the total value of production. Gross value added and gross domestic product (GDP) are therefore exactly the same concepts. In the national accounts, whenever measurement of total value of production is made at either factor cost or basic prices, the convention is to use the term gross value added rather than GDP. However, this is only a terminological convention. It is perfectly proper to think of GDP at factor cost or GDP at basic prices (compare the SNA table in section 5.6). Therefore: GDP at market prices — taxes on products subsidies on products Gross value added (or GDP) at basic prices AND THEN Gross value added (or GDP) at basic prices — taxes on production subsidies on production Gross value added (or GDP) at factor cost 2. Domestic vs. national measures, e.g. as in gross domestic product (GDP) and gross national income (GNI) This relates to the geographic as against the citizenship basis of calculations: ❐ ‘Domestic’ refers to the gross production within the geographic borders of the country, irrespective of whether South African citizens or foreigners (including migrant labour) undertook the activity. ❐ ‘National’ refers to aggregate production by South African citizens, irrespective of where in the world they do that. The production of foreigners within the country must be subtracted, and the production of South African citizens working in other countries added. The net figure is called ‘net primary income payments to the rest of the world’, and constitutes the difference between GDP and GNI. GDP at market prices — net income payments GNI at market prices 236 Chapter 5: Understanding sectoral coherence and constraints: how to use macroeconomic identities How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 236 2019/12/17 09:15 If GDP > GNI ⇒ Net primary income payments to the rest of the world are positive ⇒ Foreign workers and companies in South Africa produce and earn more here than South African residents and companies earn in other countries. In South Africa, GDP is consistently higher than GNI. This is mainly due to large numbers of migrant labourers from neighbouring countries, and large numbers of foreign companies doing business here. In 2018, GDP was R4 874 billion while GNI was R4 684 billion (both at market prices). What is gross national income (GNI)? Gross national income (GNI) is exactly equivalent to gross national product (GNP). GNP is a well-established term in macroeconomics. However, the new System of National Accounts prefers GNI. Both are proper whenever GDP is being adjusted for net primary income flows across national borders (compare the SNA table in section 5.6). GDP at market prices — primary income from the rest of the world primary income to the rest of the world = GNI at market prices The equivalence of production, income and expenditure The equivalence of aggregate expenditure, aggregate production and aggregate income is a most fundamental principle in the national accounts. There are also three corresponding methods to calculate the total value of aggregate output in an economy. 1. Via production: calculate the aggregate value added, in the production of goods and services, by private enterprises, government and households. 2. Via income: calculate the aggregate income, before taxes, of all the factors of production (= remuneration of employees plus operating surpluses of producing units). 3. Via expenditure: calculate the aggregate final expenditure on goods and services, i.e. C + l* + GC + (X – M), where investment includes unplanned inventory investment. In principle these should be equivalent. In macroeconomic theory, notably in explaining the circular flow of expenditure and income, one of the basic insights is that the value of aggregate production must equal the value of income received by the factors of production. Therefore the terms ‘product’ and ‘income’ are treated as synonyms. In national accounts data there is one complication, introduced by indirect taxes and subsidies (see above). This affects the distinction between product and income. Hence indirect taxes and subsidies must be factored into the equation (see 1 above). 3. Gross domestic expenditure (GDE) or expenditure on gross domestic product? It is crucial to understand the difference between these similar-sounding terms. Gross domestic expenditure (GDE) at market prices is the value of aggregate spending on final goods and services by households, business entities and the government in the country in a particular year or quarter. Both fixed capital formation and inventory investment are included. GDE includes spending on imported goods (but excludes exports, i.e. spending by Addendum 5.1: National accounting definitions and conventions: a student’s guide How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 237 237 2019/12/17 09:15 foreigners on South African goods and services). Note that the residual term is included in published estimates of GDE.10 GDE C I* GC ( residual) This is to be used when speaking of ‘total expenditure’ taking place in the country (despite the fact that some of the expenditure will end up in the pockets of foreign producers). An example is the relationship between the demand for money and total expenditure (total transactions) in the country. Expenditure on gross domestic product indicates the aggregate expenditure felt by domestic producers. Expenditure leakages to other countries (imports) are subtracted from GDE, and injections from other countries (exports) added. By definition, expenditure on gross domestic product is identical to GDP (at market prices). This reflects the expenditure method of calculating the value of gross output: Expenditure on GDP C I* GC X M ( residual) GDP Therefore this variable offers another way to read GDP from the SARB tables. If one wishes to measure aggregate demand, in the sense of comparing it with aggregate supply, only planned expenditure must be included. Inventory investment therefore must be excluded in this case11 and the appropriate compilation is: Aggregate demand C I GC X M ( residual) This is to be used when comparing ‘aggregate demand’ with present levels of domestic production GDP. 10 See Mohr (2019) for an explanation of the residual term. 11 Of course, some inventory investment may be planned. Unfortunately there is no way of identifying the planned portion. 238 Chapter 5: Understanding sectoral coherence and constraints: how to use macroeconomic identities How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 238 2019/12/17 09:15 A model for an inflationary economy: aggregate demand and supply 6 After reading this chapter, you should be able to: ■ use the aggregate demand (AD) and aggregate supply (AS) model to explain both fluctuations in real GDP and changes in the average price level; ■ explain how the interaction between wage-setting and price-setting relationships determines both a short-run and a long-run aggregate supply relationship; ■ analyse and assess the importance of the short-run supply adjustment process towards a long-run, structural equilibrium and a long-run AS curve; ■ assess the importance of structural unemployment in determining the position and nature of this long-run equilibrium, especially in a low- or middle-income country; and ■ compose complex chain reactions for an open economy which include effects on the price level together with real GDP, and evaluate these chain reactions with appropriate graphical aids. As mentioned at the beginning of chapter 2, the original and relatively simple Keynesian model paid scant attention to the average price level and inflation – the price level was assumed to remain constant. The focus was on real income and unemployment. The reason for this is that Keynesian theory (and macroeconomic theory as such) was developed in response to high and sustained unemployment during the Great Depression. While there were periods of inflation after that, they were never serious (at least until the early 1970s). Therefore the basic Keynesian theory paid only limited attention to the question of inflation, and only in a very circumscribed way. Below the full employment level of Y the model shows unemployment, but no upward pressure on prices. If expenditure is so high that the point of equilibrium is pushed beyond the full employment level of Y – on the 45° diagram, the equilibrium is to the right of the full employment level of Y – then there is no unemployment, but upward pressure on prices (inflation). Therefore, in the simple Keynesian model there can be either unemployment or inflation – respectively explained by deficient or excessive aggregate expenditure – but not both. The stagflation experience of the 1970s, with high or rising inflation occurring simultan­ eously with high or rising unemployment, placed a serious question mark over the tradit­ ional Keynesian theory. As a result, it was adapted in order to try to find an explanation for the phenomenon of stagflation. Our objective in this chapter is to incorporate the average price level P into the various interlinking relationships analysed so far. This is the purpose of the aggregate demand (AD) and aggregate supply (AS) framework. The derivation of the AD curve is the culmination of the expenditure theory of chapters 2 to 4, also utilising the IS-LM model. As a parallel to this, the aggregate supply (AS) Chapter 6: A model for an inflationary economy: aggregate demand and supply How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 239 239 2019/12/17 09:15 relationship will be developed in some depth by focusing on the labour market behaviour of workers and businesses (firms) together with the aggregate production function. Both a short-run and a long-run AS relationship will be identified. AD and AS through their interaction determine the aggregate level of output and the average price level. (Inflation will be discussed in depth in chapters 7 and 12.) A complete circular flow (compare pp. 73; 76; 140) The circular flow diagram has been progressively completed in the chapters so far. With the concepts of aggregate supply and demand now introduced, as well as the average price level as an explicit variable, a complete circular flow diagram can now be presented. Study it carefully. ❐ The price level is indicated in the lower left-hand corner of the diagram. It is shown as a leakage, in the sense that an increase in the price level implies a leakage (or dilution) of real income: the larger a price increase, the less the quantity of real income left. International capital flows FOREIGN COUNTRIES Ex po rts Ex ch a rat nge e EXPENDITURE Aggregate demand for goods and services Government expenditure Investment FINANCIAL INSTITUTIONS Supply of credit Interest rates cre rcial Comme C or po ra Changes in average price level te t a xes, VAT dit po rts s Saving Monetary Demand for credit FIRMS (Producers) Aggregate supply of goods and services Im Consumption policy Disposable income RESERVE BANK HOUSEHOLDS (Consumers) Government C on sum borrowing er c redit (deficit) GOVERNMENT (Budget and fiscal policy) VA T + G I + M) + C (X – et Personal incom , ax REAL INCOME Remarks 1. In chapters 2 and 3 you were introduced to the distinction between nominal and real values. This distinction becomes particularly important the moment the price level is recognised and used as a variable. Expenditure and income aggregates (and data) can 240 Chapter 6: A model for an inflationary economy: aggregate demand and supply How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 240 2019/12/17 09:15 2. 3. 4. 5. be expressed in terms of their present monetary value, i.e. at current prices. Then we speak of nominal GDP, C, I, Y, etc. If these aggregates are adjusted to eliminate the effect of inflation, then we are working with real GDP, C and so forth, i.e. at constant prices. One way to eliminate the effect of inflation is to divide nominal values by a suitable price index (this is known as ‘deflating’). Another method is to express all amounts in terms of a base year, for example 2010 rands. As far as interest rates are concerned, the rate normally quoted by banks is the nominal rate i. The real interest rate r can be calculated (approximately) by subtracting the rate of inflation from the nominal rate of interest (see the introduction to chapter 2 on the relationship between real and nominal values, as well as chapter 2, section 2.2.2 for details on the calculation of the real interest rate). The difference between real and nominal values is extremely important and must be borne in mind at all times, otherwise incorrect conclusions and arguments may follow. This distinction is especially important when working with published data. Normally the symbols (Y, C, etc.) indicate real values. The only exception is the money M supply, where the real money supply is denoted by P . The real money supply will be a very important variable in this analysis. S DATA TIP Real and nominal data and price indices 6.1 ❐ The national accounts section in the Quarterly Bulletin shows all expenditure components, income and product (GDP) in both real and nominal terms. ❐ Price indices (CPI, PPI) can be found in the section ‘General economic indicators’, while inflation rates are shown in the section ‘Key information’. ❐ Real interest rates and real money supply data are not published by the Reserve Bank. ❐ Balance of payments data also are only available in nominal terms. Essentials of the AD-AS model You will recall that the traditional Keynesian model was a demand-determined model (see chapter 2). It focused on explaining short-run fluctuations in real domestic income Y and employment by considering fluctuations in aggregate expenditure (or aggregate demand). ❐ Recall that we defined the short-run as a period of usually up to three years. In section 6.3.3 we will encounter adjustments on the supply side of the economy that occur in the so-called medium term. This can be thought of as lasting a further three to seven years. The average for both processes, allowing for some overlap, typically is approximately four to seven years. Short- and medium-term changes and adjustments are frequently discussed in the context of business cycles with reference to ‘booms’ and ‘busts’, ‘upswings’ and ‘downswings’. ❐ Both the short- and medium-term periods can be distinguished from the very long run, with a time horizon measured in decades, which is the topic of economic growth (chapter 8). Throughout the unfolding exposition of the Keynesian model – both for the closed and the open economy – it was assumed that the supply side of the economy would respond effortlessly to any change in demand. Also, the price level was assumed to be constant. We must now relax these two assumptions. 6.1 Essentials of the AD-AS model How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 241 241 2019/12/17 09:15 The AD-AS model is a powerful analytical tool to focus on the price level, while retaining the important focus on real income Y. The basic purpose of the aggregate demand-and-supply model is to recast the analysis of the real and monetary sectors (encountered in chapters 2 to 4) in one diagram that explicitly isolates the average price level P as a variable on one axis. Real income Y appears on the other axis (see figure 6.1). The AD-AS model therefore summarises the traditional theory in one diagram. However, it also expands that theory to incorporate the systematic explanation of the behaviour of firms and workers on the production, or supply, side of the economy. The supply and demand sides of the economy together then determine the average price level P. In this way, the AD-AS model overcomes two of the major weaknesses of the traditional Keynesian model in an inflationary context. In essence, the entire analysis of the traditional ‘demand-side’ model – the 45° diagram threesome as well as the IS-LM and IS-LM-BP diagrams – is collapsed into one curve, the aggregate demand (AD) curve. The AD curve has a negative slope, as shown in figure 6.1. Figure 6.1 Simultaneous determination of real income and the price level P ASLR ASSR Short-run equilibrium after demand stimulation 1 The aggregate supply (AS) curve is P1 then added to represent the supply side 0 P0 (or producer side) of the economy and allows for disturbances and chain re­ actions to originate on the supply side, AD0 or for supply-side factors to modify the anticipated consequences of demandY1 YS side occurrences. To explain short-run fluctuations we will use the short-run AS or ASSR curve. It has a positive slope, as shown in the diagram in figure 6.1. AD1 Y Together the ASSR and AD curves simultaneously determine the short-run equilibrium levels of real income Y and the average price level P. This equilibrium is at the intersection of the two curves (see figure 6.1). ❐ Any disturbance will shift one or both of the curves, leading to a new intersection and a new equilibrium level of Y and P. ❐ For instance, diagrammatically, an increase in government expenditure will be reflected in a rightward shift of the AD curve. The diagram shows the result to be both an increase in Y (i.e. real GDP) and an increase in the average price level P: the equilibrium moves from point 0 to point 1. In this way the model provides a diagrammatical explanation of short-run changes in the price level together with short-run changes in the level of real GDP. ❐ However, the model also shows a new category of change: adjustments on the supply side of the economy that occur over a somewhat longer time span, which we call the medium term. ❐ To understand these supply adjustments, we will develop a second AS curve, i.e. the so-called long-run AS curve, or ASLR. In the medium term the long-run AS relationship has a strong influence: the short-run equilibrium will be pulled towards the ASLR curve through adjustments of the ASSR curve. 242 Chapter 6: A model for an inflationary economy: aggregate demand and supply How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 242 2019/12/17 09:15 All this will become clear in this chapter. The derivation of the AD and both AS curves is explained below. As always, we will stress that the economic chain reactions and reasoning are more important than the diagrammatical analysis. However, given the complexity of these curves, substantial energy will go into explaining the derivation and properties of the curves. This is followed by an extensive demonstration of the use of these curves to support reasoning about economic events and policy. 6.2 Aggregate demand (AD) 6.2.1 What is the aggregate demand relationship? How is it derived? One definition of the aggregate demand relationship is simply that it shows, for each price level, the aggregate quantity of goods and services demanded in the economy. While this is a useful interpretation, it is not entirely correct. This is apparent from the way the aggregate demand relationship is derived directly from the Keynesian expenditure model and the 45° diagram, as described below (and in figure 6.2). You will recall that a particular 45° diagram is drawn for a given, constant price level, and shows a particular equilibrium level of real income. Suppose that initially the economy is at equilibrium income level Y0, with the associated price level being P0. This can be depicted as point 0 in the P-Y plane. Figure 6.2 Deriving the AD curve from the 45° diagram E Equilibrium points for different price levels (C + I + G + X – M)P0 (C + I + G + X – M)P1 Y P Points on the aggregate demand curve Suppose the price is at a higher level P1. For several reasons (ex­ 1 plained in section 6.2.3) a higher P1 0 average price level implies a lower P 0 level of aggregate expendi­ ture AD (C + I + G + X – M). Allowing for the secondary, money market effect of a Y Y1 Y0 change in expenditure and in­come (see chapter 3, section 3.2.2), the net ef­fect would be that the aggregate expenditure line now lies below the initial line, and the equilibrium level of real income would also be lower at Y1 (showing the net effect on Y). This produces point 1 in the P-Y plane. ❐ A similar analysis follows for a lower price level. ❐ Connecting these and other such points yields the AD curve. 6.2 Aggregate demand (AD) How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 243 243 2019/12/17 09:15 The aggregate demand curve there­ fore shows, for various average price levels, the corresponding equilibrium level of expen­diture/income – under the assumption that supply would re­spond automatically to meet changes in expenditure. Formally, the AD curve can be defined as follows: The AD curve shows all combinations of real income Y and the average price level P at which there would be simultaneous equilibrium in the real and monetary sectors. Another important way of under­ Essentially, each point on the AD curve is a little ‘black standing the aggregate demand box’ containing a 45° diagram with its own price level curve is to see it as a collection of and levels of expenditure and hence equilibrium real points of potential equilibrium, each income Y. A different level of Y implies a different 45° at a different price level, under the diagram with a different equilibrium Y – and therefore a assumption that no supply-side different point on the AD curve. constraints are present. ❐ In the discussion that follows we will show that supply considerations actually limit the choice between these po­ tential equilibrium points. (This interpretation will become clearer once the aggregate supply curve has been discussed.) 6.2.2 What determines the slope of the aggregate demand curve? As noted above, the expected slope of the AD curve is negative. Several reasons can be given why an increase in P can be expected to lead to a decrease in aggregate expenditure, i.e. why a negative relationship can be expected to exist between aggregate demand and the average price level P. 1. The interest rate effect: An increase in the average price level P contracts the real money supply MP ; this forces interest rates upwards, which is likely to depress expenditure.1 2. The wealth effect: A higher average price level diminishes the real value of assets; people become less affluent and expenditure is discouraged. 3. The foreign trade effect: A higher domestic price level discourages export expenditure (and encourages imports), so that aggregate expenditure decreases. 4. The tax effect: When personal income increases in periods of increases in the average price level (i.e. inflation), taxpayers are pushed into higher personal income tax brackets (so-called bracket creep). This curbs disposable income and thus expenditure.2 S The real income effect is often cited as an additional factor: a higher average price level lowers the real value (real purchasing power) of people’s income and thus their capacity to spend. There is no agreement on the validity of this argument. It is Recall the formal rule for shifting vs. moving along applicable only if the ‘price level’ a curve. A curve shifts if a relevant variable not on is understood not to include the one of the axes of the diagram changes. If one of the price of labour and other factors of variables on the axes changes, there is a move along production, i.e. only prices of final the curve. goods and services are included 1 2 244 Equivalently, one can consider the money market in nominal terms. In this case, an increase in the average price level increases the nominal value of transactions. This increases the nominal demand for money. For a given nominal money supply, an increase in the price level is likely to put upward pressure on interest rates. See chapter 3, section 3.2. This is true only in countries where progressive income tax systems are used, which is the case in most Western countries. See chapter 10. Chapter 6: A model for an inflationary economy: aggregate demand and supply How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 244 2019/12/17 09:15 (as is done in the calculation of the consumer price index). It may be safer not to use this argument. Figure 6.3 Deriving the AD curve from the IS-LM diagram r Graphically, any change in P, or any change in expenditure that is exclusively brought about by a change in P, leads to a movement along the AD curve. Usually such a change in P is the endogenous result of a shift in the AD or AS curves. 6.2.3 LMP1 LMP0 1 0 Deriving the AD curve from the IS-LM model The derivation of the AD curve can also be shown in the context of the IS-LM model. This has the benefit that it clearly shows the secondary, money market effects associated with changes in the IS-LM diagram. Equilibrium points for different price levels IS Y P Recall that the LM curve is always drawn Points on the aggregate for a particular (constant) price level. demand curve Either of two arguments can be used to show the impact of a different price level 1 on the internal economic equilibrium P1 0 shown by the intersection of the IS and P0 LM curves. The first is couched in real terms, the second in nominal terms: AD 1. A higher price level implies a lower Y0 Y1 M , which shifts real money supply P the LM curve left; or 2. A higher price level implies a higher nominal value of transactions. This increases the nominal (transactions) demand for money MD, for a given nominal money supply. This shifts the LM curve to the left (see figure 6.3). S Suppose that initially the economy is at equilibrium income level Y0, with the associate price level P0. This can be depicted as point 0 on the P-Y axes. Suppose the price level is at a higher level P1. This implies a lower real money supply M P . Expressed diagram­matically, this is a leftward shift of the LM curve from the initial LM curve. The result is a different equilibrium with a higher interest rate and a lower level of real income Y1. This produces point 1 in the P-Y plane. ❐ Connecting these and other such points yields the AD curve. S 1 This derivation can be supple­mented with an analysis of the wealth, foreign trade and tax ef­fects of a higher price level. These reduce expenditure, and are reflected in a shift to the left of the IS curve, in addition to the leftward shift of the LM curve already shown in the dia­gram. The combined effect would be a (larger) decline in the equilibrium level of real in­ come Y. The addition of the IS curve to the analysis therefore confirms the diagrammatic conclusion regarding the slope of the AD curve. (The IS effect is not shown in the diagram.) 6.2 Aggregate demand (AD) How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 245 245 2019/12/17 09:15 6.2.4 How steep is the AD curve? The steepness of the AD curve can best be understood by considering the first reason for its negative slope in section 6.2.2, i.e. the fact that an increase in the average price level P decreases the real money supply MP . Since this is analytically equivalent to a contractionary monetary policy step, the analysis in chapter 3 (section 3.2.1) relating to the factors affecting the potency of monetary policy is relevant here. These were the interest sensitivity of money demand, the interest sensitivity of investment (capital formation), and the size of the expenditure multiplier. S The reasoning can be applied as follows: ❐ If the interest sensitivity of money demand is low, monetary contraction will have a large impact on the real economy. In the derivation of the AD curve, for a given M increase in P (and thus a decrease in P ), Y will decline a lot. Hence the AD curve will be relatively flat. ❐ If the interest sensitivity of investment is high, monetary contraction will have a large impact on the real economy. Therefore, for a given change in P (and thus in MP ), Y will decline a lot. As a result, the AD curve will be relatively flat. ❐ If the expenditure multiplier is large, the drop in invest­ment (capital formation) caused by monetary contrac­tion (via interest rate in­creases) will have a large impact on the M real economy. For a given change in P (and thus in P ) therefore, Y will decline a lot. Conse­quently, the AD curve will be relatively flat. S S S Conversely, the AD curve will be steep if one or more of the following is true: ❐ the interest sensitivity of money demand is high; ❐ the interest sensitivity of investment is low; or ❐ the expenditure multiplier is small. π Deriving the AD relationship mathematically Recall from chapter 3 that when we substituted the LM relationship into the IS relationship, we found an equation for the level of real income Y at which both the goods and money markets will be in equilibrium. Chapter 4 then added the foreign sector. More formally we had: (M ) P + l Y 1(a Ia G X – ma) 2 __ S where: K 1 + K Ehk/l 1 ________ E ...... (4.6) ......(4.6.1) KEh 2 ______ l + KEhk It now transpires that this equation for the equilibrium level of Y is nothing but the equation for the AD curve, given the equations in our model as derived in the last several chapters – where P now is a variable (having been treated as constant in the equations of chapters 3 and 4). It shows an inverse relationship between P and Y, hence the negatively sloping AD curve. A higher price level P implies a smaller real money supply and therefore a smaller level of Y. ❐ The slope parameter 2 contains several responsiveness parameters and multipliers (k, l, h, KE). ❐ The position of AD depends on several autonomous expenditure components (a, Ia, X and ma) and exogenously determined policy variables (G and MS). 246 Chapter 6: A model for an inflationary economy: aggregate demand and supply How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 246 2019/12/17 09:15 In a more complete and more complex analysis, it can also be demonstrated that the AD curve will be flatter if the income sensitivity of the demand for money is lower. Another factor flows from the open economy context. If exports and imports are very sensitive to domestic price level changes, the AD curve will be relatively flat. This implies that the AD curve will be flatter for an economy that is relatively more open. 6.2.5 Which factors shift the AD curve? How far does AD shift? Figure 6.4 Shifts of AD originate in IS-LM changes r r1 r3 r0 LM1 1 LM2 LM0 BP1 3 2 BP0 0 IS1 Y1 Y3 Y2 Y0 IS0 Y P Any factor other than P (or Changes in Y (due to shifts of IS and Y) which affects aggregate LM) translate into expenditure will lead to a equivalent horizontal shift in the AD curve. shifts of AD, at every price level. ❐ Any stimulating factor would increase aggregate demand (and vice versa for a contractionary factor). In the diagram, P0 any non-price stimulation of expenditure would cause the AD curve to shift to the right. Factors that contract expenditure would shift the AD curve Y to the left. ❐ All the internal factors (real and monetary) and external factors that influ­ence ag­ gregate ex­penditure also influ­ence aggregate de­mand. These include monetary and fiscal policy measures, ex­pectations, external shocks, interest rates, exchange rates, etc. Changes in any of these factors would therefore shift the AD curve. ❐ The three illustrative examples analysed in chapter 4 (section 4.5) are all relevant here. Both expansionary fiscal policy and ex­pansionary monetary policy would be re­flected in the diagram as a rightward shift of the AD curve. Con­tractionary policy would shift the AD curve left. A surge in exports would shift the AD curve right. ❐ More specifically, any change in the equilib­rium level of Y (due to real, monetary or external disturbances or adjustments) – ex­cept due to a change in the average price level P – will shift the AD curve by exactly the same amount. The diagram in figure 6.4 copies the IS-LM-BP dynamics of an increase in the repo rate from chapter 4, section 4.7.5. 6.2 Aggregate demand (AD) How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 247 247 2019/12/17 09:15 The fluctuating short-run equilibrium values of Y (on the horizontal axis of the IS-LMBP diagram) show the different phases and impacts of the repo change (from point 0 to point 1, which include the money market secondary effect) plus the two secondary BoP adjustment effects (from point 1 to 2 and again to 3), on the equilibrium value of Y – all in an exclusively demand-side model. Note the typical pattern generated by the two BoP effects following a BoP surplus: first the LM and AD curves shift right (money supply effect), then the IS, BP and AD curves shift left (exchange rate effect). ❐ The AD curve shifts right then left. The final, net effect of the two BoP effects on the position of the AD curve often appears to be relatively minor. For a BoP deficit a contrasting typical pattern is generated. First the LM and AD curves shift left (money supply effect), then the IS, BP and AD curves shift right (exchange rate effect). ❐ The AD curve shifts left then right. When this result is transferred to the P-Y axes, it reflects as corresponding horizontal shifts in the AD curve – still under the assumption of a constant average price level P. The net shift in AD is indicated by the blue curve. When the aggregate supply curves are added to the AD curve in section 6.3, we will see changes in Y resulting. These will impact on the final, net change in equilibrium real income Y (together with Y). Policy potency The analysis of policy potency can also be transferred to explain the magnitude of any shift in the AD curve: ❐ If fiscal policy is very potent, the AD curve will shift relatively far if an expansionary fiscal step occurs. ❐ Likewise, if monetary policy is potent, the AD curve will shift relatively far when mon­ etary expansion occurs. Again, the analysis in chapter 3 (section 3.3.7) can be applied. It identified underlying characteristics of an economy that determine the potency of fiscal and monetary policy steps. These were the interest sensitivity of money demand, the income sensitivity of money demand, the interest sensitivity of investment, and the size of the expenditure multiplier. Any of these that make fiscal or monetary policy potent would lead to the AD curve shifting further (for a given real or monetary expansion). For example, any of the following will cause the AD curve to shift relatively far if fiscal expansion occurs: ❐ a high interest sensitivity of money demand; ❐ a low income sensitivity of money demand; ❐ a high interest sensitivity of investment, or ❐ a large expenditure multiplier. Similar results can be derived for the magnitude of the shift in AD due to monetary expansion. 248 Chapter 6: A model for an inflationary economy: aggregate demand and supply How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 248 2019/12/17 09:15 6.3 Aggregate supply (AS) The explicit introduction of an aggregate supply relationship is aimed at correcting a previous simplifying assumption, namely that supply (or production) automatically and effortlessly reacts to all fluctuations in expenditure. Problems on the supply side often prevent, hamper or modify the anticipated impact of changes in expenditure on Y. Also, macroeconomic disturbances and problems can originate on the supply side. ❐ The supply side of the macroeconomy implies a constraint on the role of expenditure (i.e. demand) in determining the equilibrium level of real income Y, and allows for independent supply-side factors to impact on the economy. ❐ Therefore, before the expected consequences of changes in expenditure can be spelt out, one must consider the quantity of aggregate production which producers in the economy (a) are prepared to, and (b) are able to deliver, given supply-related circumstances and behaviour. These considerations are represented by the aggregate supply (AS) curve, which can be defined formally as follows: The AS curve shows, for each price level P, the aggregate level of real output Y that producers are willing or able to supply. As will be explained below, the AS curve can be interpreted as a set of attainable combinations of P and Y, given supply-side conditions. Which factors determine aggregate supply? The main factors that determine, in the aggregate, the ability and/or willingness of firms to produce output are the following: ❐ size of the labour force (and thus also population growth); ❐ productivity of labour; ❐ labour skills levels (and thus education and training); ❐ cost of labour (wages); ❐ availability of raw materials; ❐ cost of raw materials; ❐ availability of capital goods (and thus investment); ❐ cost of capital goods; ❐ technology (which increases the productivity of labour and capital goods); ❐ cost of financial capital, i.e. interest rates; ❐ exchange rates (which affect the cost of imported inputs), and ❐ actual and expected prices. Some of these factors impact on supply in the short run (i.e. in the cyclical context), while others only take effect in the medium to very long run (i.e. the economic growth context). The long run and the short run Although this general definition of aggregate supply is true in general, the discussion of aggregate supply needs to distinguish between aggregate supply in the short run and in the long run. The difference is defined by the introduction of expected prices (and expected real wages). In particular (a) that there could be, at times, a difference between expected prices and actual prices, but (b) over time such a difference should disappear – it will not be sustained in the long run. In other words, expected prices will be assumed to equal actual prices in the long run, but in the short run there can and often will be a deviation. 6.3 Aggregate supply (AS) How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 249 249 2019/12/17 09:15 In fact, this is how we will define long run and short run for purposes of the AS curve: ❐ The long run is when, following some disturbance, sufficient time has elapsed for any mistaken price expectation to have corrected itself so that the expected average price level P e is the same as the actual average price level: P = P e. ❐ The short run is when this has not yet happened: the expected average price level is not equal to the actual average price level: P ≠ P e. This distinction will be critical in un­derstanding aggregate sup­ply behaviour, as the discussion below will show: ❐ Aggregate supply in the long run indicates combinations of P and Y where the actual av­erage price and wage equal the expected average price and wage. ❐ When, due to some economic factor or disturbance, the actual average price and real wage deviate from the expected average price and real wage, other combina­tions and levels of P and Y can and will occur. This is aggregate supply in the short run. (Note that, for ease of exposition, we will from here on just talk of ‘prices’ and ‘wages’ to indicate the ‘average price level’ and the ‘average wage level’.) How long is the short run? And the long run? It is risky to specify hard time frames for such indications of time periods, since economic behaviour and macroeconomic reactions vary across time and countries. Nevertheless, it is helpful to adopt some approximations, as follows: 1. The short run is normally assumed to cover a period of up to three years. 2. The period necessary for price expectations to adjust fully so that the ‘long-run’ position is reached is normally assumed to be a further period of between three and seven years. Both the long-run and short-run aggregate supply curves show levels of output that producers are willing to supply. The difference between the relationships is that in the short run producers can and probably will supply more (or less) than the long-run level of The typical average for both processes, allowing for output. They will do so if actual some overlap, is approximately four to seven years. prices and wages for a certain period allow for higher (or lower) profits, since such higher (or lower) profits create an incentive to supply more (or less). However, as will also be shown below, these devia­tions are likely to persist only for a limited period of time (which could be several years), since expectations will catch up – and aggre­gate supply will eventually return to the long-run level. As will be seen in section 6.3.3, explanations of the reasons for actual prices to deviate from expected prices – i.e. reasons why expectations turn out to be mistaken – are central to understanding the short-run aggregate supply pattern in the economy. Imperfectly anticipated economic events, disturbances and shocks can be seen to translate into sometimes prolonged deviations between actual and expected prices. Aggregate supply will accordingly deviate substantively from the long-run level of output The maths of aggregate supply for considerable periods of time – The derivation of the aggregate supply relationships depending, as we will see, also on and curves requires more mathematics than was the the state of aggregate demand at case with aggregate demand. In the exposition that the time (see section 6.4). follows, basic equations will be shown in the text, ❐ We will also see that even but more advanced equations and derivations will be the long-run level of output shown in maths boxes. as such can also vary due to 250 Chapter 6: A model for an inflationary economy: aggregate demand and supply How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 250 2019/12/17 09:15 economic factors, implying that the graphical posi­tion of the ‘long-run’ aggregate supply curve is not stationary or permanent (even before we consider the impact of economic growth, which is considered in chapter 8). Preview The core of the theory of aggregate supply can be summarised as follows: ❐ At the beginning of a period, firms decide/plan what amount they will supply at the price level that they expect. Workers do the same in terms of the amount of labour services that they are contracted to supply to the firm in exchange for the wage rate that they expect. Should their price and wage expectations turn out to be correct, all parties will supply what they wanted to supply, and hence no party desires to adjust its supply of goods or labour services in that period. ❐ If, however, actual prices in the period exceed expected prices, real wages (and real wage costs of the firm) will in effect fall short of expected real wages and costs. Because the lower real wage costs increase profits, firms are willing and keen to supply more goods, and will do so. However, once wage negotiations occur at the beginning of the next period, real wages can and are likely to adjust, thereby eradicating some or all of the increase in profit and hence causing the firm partially or fully to reverse the increase in the supply of goods. (Analogous but reverse changes occur when actual prices fall short of expected prices.) ❐ Thus, the changes in supply that result from actual prices falling short of, or exceeding, expected prices are only short-run, temporary changes – arising from ‘temporary mistaken expectations’ regarding prices (and thus real wages). ❐ In the longer run, after expected prices and wages have had time to catch up with actual prices and wages, output will eventually return to the level where actual prices and wages equal expected prices and wages. Expectations are assumed to be self-correcting in the long run and thus there are no mistaken expectations in the end. ❐ This level of output to which supply tends to return in the long run – amidst short-run fluctuations and deviations – will be called the long-run level of output, or long-run supply. It is denoted graphically as the long-run aggregate supply curve (ASLR ). ❐ The pattern of output resulting when supply diverges from the long-run output level is the short-run aggregate supply curve (ASSR ). 6.3.1 Deriving aggregate supply – the labour market What determines the level of output that producers are willing to supply, either in the ‘short run’ or in the ‘long run’? The answer lies in the link between profit, output prices and input prices. Producers of goods pursue profit, i.e. they want the difference between the price per unit and the cost per unit that they produce to be sufficiently large, or even as large as possible. Thus, how much producers supply will depend on the relationship between the prices that they can charge and their cost of production, and how these vary over time. The price-setting (PS) relationship A more formal way to state the link between prices and cost is to consider the price-setting (PS) and wage-setting (WS) relationships. The PS relationship indicates how producers set their prices, taking wages (labour cost) as the most important cost. The PS relationship assumes that prices are set as a mark-up over wage cost, i.e. a producer determines her wage cost and then adds a mark-up (margin) to set the price of the goods. The mark-up includes 6.3 Aggregate supply (AS) How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 251 251 2019/12/17 09:15 provision for profits but also for the cost of other (non-labour) inputs and also taxes. Changes in non-labour costs and taxes would thus impact on the size of the mark-up. ❐ One could alternatively define the mark-up as a pure profit mark-up (i.e. to exclude taxes and the cost of other inputs) over all costs (i.e. expenditure on all inputs as well as taxes). However, this would complicate the discussion below without adding additional insight. Labour cost (i.e. wage cost) is chosen as the base for the mark-up because it is usually the largest running expenditure item of firms. ❐ Note that the PS relationship assumes that producers are price setters and not price takers in goods markets. That is, goods markets are assumed to be not completely competitive, so that sellers have market power to set prices. Formally, the PS relationship can be stated as: W P = (1 μ) ____ Q(N) ...... (6.1) where P is the price level, μ is the mark-up (denoted as a fraction) over labour cost, W is the nominal wage level and Q is an indicator of labour productivity (which can be measured W as the volume of output that a worker produces on average). Thus, __ Q is a measure of the labour cost per unit of output. Q is written as a function of N since the marginal productivity of labour declines as employment N increases (see the discussion of the total production function below). ❐ Equation 6.1 can represent the behaviour of a single business or that of all firms in the economy together. It is in the latter, aggregate sense that we will use it in this book. Thus the mark-up, for instance, will be interpreted as the average mark-up in the entire economy. Equation 6.1 can be interpreted as follows. (A graphical representation of the PS relation­ ship will be shown later.) ❐ A higher nominal wage W implies a higher cost per unit produced, and should lead to a higher price P being set. ❐ Higher labour productivity Q implies a lower cost per unit produced – and should cause the price P that a producer will charge to be lower. Because, in general, the marginal productivity of labour decreases as a firm employs additional labour, Q (which can be defined as the average product per worker) will be lower at higher levels of employment N. (Labour productivity also depends on factors such as the managerial skills of the producer and the skills and capacity of the workers, as well as the capital goods, technology and enabling economic institutions available to workers.) ❐ The mark-up is likely to be higher if producers have more market power. If a producer is a monopolist, or if a group of producers band together in a cartel, they have more market power compared to producers in a competitive market. ❐ The mark-up is likely to be higher if non-labour input costs (including the cost of raw material, energy, the depreciation of capital and so forth) are higher. ❐ The mark-up is also likely to be higher if taxes such as corporate taxes and VAT are higher. However, this leaves unanswered what determines the wage. For that, we need to consider wage-setting behaviour in the economy in the aggregate. The wage-setting (WS) relationship The wage-setting (WS) relationship indicates how, on an aggregate level, nominal wages are set – or contracted – by workers or worker organisations in their interaction with 252 Chapter 6: A model for an inflationary economy: aggregate demand and supply How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 252 2019/12/17 09:15 employers/firms. It is assumed that wages are not set in a competitive labour market, but in a typical modern labour market characterised by collective bargaining, labour unions, monopolistic and monopsonistic behaviour, minimum wage legislation and so forth. Such contracts typically determine wages and other employment conditions for one to three years. ❐ This is quite important, because it can cause fixed nominal wage contracts to be based on an expected price level (and expected cost of living) that becomes outdated if and when the actual price level changes unexpectedly due to an economic disturbance. Unexpected price movements have major implications for the production decisions and thus supply behaviour of firms, as will be shown in the discussion that follows. Several factors are relevant to understanding wage-setting behaviour: ❐ The expected price level P e , which is an indicator of the expected cost of living in the upcoming contract period, is a key determinant of wage-setting behaviour. If increases in the cost of living are anticipated, workers will want a higher nominal wage to compensate for the higher price level P (and in effect leave their future real wage unchanged). ❐ General labour market conditions in terms of the rate of unemployment U are also relevant. This is a reflection of the aggregate level of employment N relative to the labour force LF. Lower levels of employment (which imply higher rates of unemployment U) are likely to cause downward pressure on wages. Lower rates of unemployment are likely to cause upward pressure on wages. ❐ A third causal factor comprises the various institutional aspects of labour markets, mostly pertaining to the level and nature of unionisation, government labour institu­ tions and legislation, unemployment and other benefits, and so forth. Formally, the WS relationship can be formulated as: W = P e f(N; Z) ...... (6.2) where W is the nominal wage and P e is the expected price level, N is the employment level and Z captures institutional factors in the labour market (to be discussed later). ❐ The employment level N and the unemployment rate U are inversely related, as follows. The unemployment rate U is defined as the difference between the total labour force LF and N, the number of the employed, expressed as a fraction of the labour force: (LF – N) U = LF . Equation 6.2 indicates that, for a given expected price level, a higher employment level N causes a higher nominal wage W: ❐ For a given labour force, a higher level of employment N will mean a lower rate of unemployment. A higher level of employment will reduce rivalry among the unemployed (i.e. workers become more scarce and their bargaining power is strengthened), and thus put upward pressure on the wage level. Therefore, higher levels of employment are associated with higher levels of the nominal wage W. There is a positive relationship between N and W. ❐ Conversely, the higher the unemployment rate U, the lower is the employment level and thus the number of people employed. More of the unemployed are competing for the number of available job vacancies and their bargaining power is weaker. This will put downward pressure on wages. Again, there is a positive relationship between N and W. ❐ If the labour force LF as such grows, this will also put downward pressure on wages. 6.3 Aggregate supply (AS) How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 253 253 2019/12/17 09:15 As far as the institutional factors in the labour market (indicated by Z) are concerned, one can note the following: 1. Labour unions: In many labour markets there are labour unions that negotiate on behalf of all or a substantial proportion of the workers. Such workers do not compete with each other in their negotiations with employers. Rather, they band together (like a cartel) to negotiate through their labour union. Such a labour union may then exploit their market power and strong bargaining position to act as a monopolistic seller of labour services. This is likely to cause the wage to be higher than it would be in the absence of the unions (i.e. in a more competitive labour market). ❐ Of course, although employers may have to pay the higher wages, they may decide to employ fewer workers. 2. Employer organisations: Employers in an industry can band together in an industry association or employer’s organisation to be the sole buyer of labour services. (A sole buyer is called a monopsonist.) The market power and strong bargaining position of employers may result in workers being paid a lower wage than it would have been in a more competitive market. If there are organised unions it implies bargaining between two powerful organisations. 3. Efficiency wages: Efficiency wages are wages that are higher than the wages that would otherwise be paid in a competitive labour market. Employers may choose to pay such a premium in order to elicit higher levels of efficiency and productivity from workers. Although this increases the unit cost of labour, the higher output per worker implies that fewer workers are required. 4. Unemployment and other benefits: Many governments pay unemployment benefits and other benefits such as disability grants. These could serve as a disincentive to seek employment, since the unemployed will not accept employment at a wage below the monthly unemployment benefit they could receive from government. Thus the benefit implies a floor below which the wage cannot go. Higher unemployment benefits imply a higher wage floor (and that more people may choose to remain unemployed or outside the labour force). ❐ Social security and income grants may have similar disincentive effects. In addition, both employees and employers may have to contribute to the fiscus or to social security funds to finance these benefits, thereby increasing the effective cost per worker. 5. Minimum wage legislation: Labour legislation may stipulate a minimum wage, some­ times for specific sectors. This wage may be higher than the wage rate would have been in the absence of the labour legislation, thereby increasing the effective cost per worker. It could also reduce the number of people employed by employers. Generally, the nominal wage W will be set higher the larger the effect of unionisation, the smaller the effect of employer organisations, the more prevalent the payment of efficiency wages, the higher the level of unemployment benefits, and the higher the minimum wage. While the combined effect of these institutional factors can be quite complex, they all impact – together with the unemployment situation and the expected price level – on the nominal wage that will be set for those employed. Diagrammatical depictions of the price-setting and wage-setting relationships To show these two relationships on one diagram requires some manipulation of the equations (without changing their real meaning). Equation 6.2 can be rearranged as 254 Chapter 6: A model for an inflationary economy: aggregate demand and supply How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 254 2019/12/17 09:15 W e equation 6.3, which shows the expected real wage, P (because P is the ‘expected’ price level) as a function of employment N and the institutional factors Z: e W __ P = f(N; Z) e ...... (6.3) [Indirect WS relationship] Figure 6.5 is a diagrammatical representa­ Figure 6.5 The wage-setting and labour supply curves tion of equation 6.3, with the expected real W WS wage on the y-axis and employment on P the x-axis. Given the positive relationship between N and W discussed above, the WS curve will have a positive slope. ❐ It must be understood that wage negotiations and wage setting occur LS once a nominal wage in terms of a nominal wage, not the has been set implied real wage. However, whether or not workers explicitly factor in their cost of living or expected changes in the cost of living, in effect an expected real wage is being set – and an actual real wage N will be determined as P is established by price setting in the future. ❐ WS as written in equation 6.3 can be viewed as analogous to a labour supply relationship, but one must remember that the context of the WS relationship is one of wage setting through collective bargaining by workers and unions and not ‘competitive’ or ‘atomistic’ labour markets that clear, as usually assumed in labour supply theory. ❐ In addition, since wages are not determined by supply and demand continually and recurrently, once the nominal wage has been contractually set, the WS relationship becomes dormant until the next round of wage bargaining. The wage-setting relationship thus is ‘active’ only at the time of bargaining and wage setting, since it captures the underlying desired wage-and-work pattern of workers. ❐ The set nominal wage W becomes the price of employable labour for the duration of the contract period, e.g. one to three years. ❐ This implies that the post-bargain­ing labour supply curve (LS) effectively is horizontal at the level of the contracted implied real wage. (We will return to the LS curve when we analyse the labour market and aggregate supply in the short run in section 6.3.3 below.) Earlier we noted that the volume of output supplied by producers depends on the relationship between the prices that they can charge and their cost of production, especially labour costs. To see how price setting relates to wage setting, we need to relate equations 6.1 and 6.3. We rewrite equation 6.1 so that its left-hand variable is similar to the left-hand side of equation 6.3: W 1 __ 1 + μ Q(N) P = ____ ...... (6.4) [Indirect PS relationship] Although equation 6.4 has the real wage on its left-hand side, it is just an indirect form of the price-setting (PS) relationship – it still captures price-setting behaviour by firms. For a specific nominal wage W there is a price P derived as a mark-up over the nominal wage W cost W (see equation 6.1). Every W implies a matching P and thus a real wage P that firms in effect are willing to pay as a function of labour productivity Q and the mark-up μ. ❐ Thus, PS as written in equation 6.4 can be viewed as analogous to a demand for labour relationship, but always remembering that the PS relationship reflects pricesetting behaviour of firms in non-competitive market structures (rather than atomistic, 6.3 Aggregate supply (AS) How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 255 255 2019/12/17 09:15 competitive product markets where firms are price takers, as is usually assumed in labour demand theory).3 W Figure 6.6 The price-setting curve Equation 6.4 shows that the real wage P that firms in effect are willing to pay (given W P their chosen price-setting behaviour) will be lower, the higher the mark-up and the lower average labour productivity Q. Because the marginal productivity of labour de­ creases as a factory employs additional labour, Q is inversely related to the levels of employment N. Thus higher levels of employment N will be associated with lower levels of the implied W real wage P that firms are willing to pay (i.e. as implied by the prices P set by firms). PS When depicting the price-set­ting relationship diagrammatically as a set of combinations of the real wage and employ­ment, as is done in figure 6.6, the PS curve will have a negative slope. N Note that the faster the marginal product of labour de­clines, the faster Q (the average product of labour) in equation 6.1 will decline and the steeper the PS curve will be. If the mar­ginal productivity of labour does not decline as output grows, Q will remain constant and the PS curve will be horizontal, its position (i.e. how high above the horizontal axis it is drawn) depending on the nominal wage W and the mark-up. Equilibrium and the determination of wage and employment levels Having derived both the PS and WS curves, we can now put them on the same diagram, which is done in figure 6.7. It then seems simple to say that, graphically, the equilibrium W levels of the real wage P and employment N are determined by the intersection of the PS and WS curves. Equilibrium implies that the real wage implicitly desired by workers during nominal wage setting must be equal to the real wage that firms are willing to pay (implied by the price setting of firms). The equilibrium can be derived by setting PS = WS using equations 6.3 and 6.4. This produces the following: W W __ __ P = P e ...... (6.5) This equation is not very revealing, though. At this stage it becomes necessary to dis­ tinguish between the labour market situation and the resultant aggregate supply in the long run and in the short run. 3 256 Figure 6.7 Equilibrium in the labour market W P WS W0 P 0 PS N0 N It can be shown that the WS curve lies above the competitive market labour supply curve, and the PS curve below the competitive market labour demand curve. The PS-WS equilibrium level of N will be below that of a competitive market model. Chapter 6: A model for an inflationary economy: aggregate demand and supply How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 256 2019/12/17 09:15 6.3.2 The labour market and aggregate supply in the long run (ASLR) Having defined the long run as a state when sufficient time has elapsed for any mistaken price expectation to have corrected itself so that expected prices are the same as actual prices, we assume now that P = P e. From equations 6.3 and 6.4: W W __ P = __ P e or 1 ______ (1 + μ) Q(N) = f(N; Z) The equilibrium can be under­ stood as follows. Recall that A formula for the PS-WS equilibrium equilibrium implies that the real Instead of equation 6.5 one can insert wage, implic­itly desired by work­ equation 6.2 into equation 6.1: ers during wage setting, must be P e · (1 + μ) · f(N; Z) equal to the willingly-paid real ...... (6.6) P = _____________ Q wage im­plied by the price set­ This equation describes the equilibrium between PS ting of firms. Because workers and WS (for a given nominal wage W). We will return in effect set their labour supply to it below. on the basis of their expect­ed real wage, when the actual real wage equals the expected real wage (as is as­sumed now), workers sup­ply the amount of labour services that they want to supply in exchange for the real wage that they expected. Likewise, firms supply their chosen output level at their preferred price level, given the nominal wage previously contracted with workers. ❐ Therefore, excluding mistakes in price and wage expectations for the moment, no party will desire to adjust its supply of goods or of labour services. Therefore, the actual real wage will equal the expected real wage and both employers and workers will be satisfied with their position. There can be said to be an equilibrium. π As long as the underlying fac­ tors that determine the position A formula for the long-run equilibrium of the price-setting and wageWith P = P e equation 6.6 becomes: setting relationships remain P (1 μ) f(N; Z) unchanged (and as long as the P = _____________ Q actual price equals the expected or (1 μ) f(N; Z) price), labour supply and em­ ...... (6.7) 1 = ___________ Q ployment – and thus output If a formula is specified for f(N,Z) the equation can be – will remain at the levels de­ solved for N, the long-run equilibrium level of output, fined by the equilibrium of the as a function of Q, μ and Z. price-setting and wage-setting ❐ An important insight is that the long-run equilibrium relationships. Graphically, the level of output is independent of the price level P. We location of this equilibrium is will return to equation 6.7. where PS intersects WS. ❐ The concept and existence of a long-run equilibrium in the labour market does not imply that there is full employment, nor that there is no invol­ untary unemployment, at the long-run equilibrium. This is explained further in the box on employment concepts below. π Note that many of the factors underlying the price-setting and wage-setting relationships, and thus the positions of the PS and WS curves, are of a structural nature and, therefore, usually change very slowly over time. Labour market institutional factors such as unions or labour legislation or unemployment benefits do not frequently change materially. Product market structure and the power of firms to set mark-ups and prices also change slowly. 6.3 Aggregate supply (AS) How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 257 257 2019/12/17 09:15 Thus, the equilibrium defined by the intersection of PS and WS can be defined as a longrun equilibrium whose location is largely determined by structural characteristics of the economy. This equilibrium can also be denoted as a structural equilibrium (in contrast to a cyclical equilibrium). The employment level of the structural equilibrium can be indicated as NS and the corresponding output level as YS. Nevertheless, the position of the long-run or structural equilibrium is not permanent or invariable, and shifts in the PS and WS curves can occur should any of the factors that determine the position of these curves change (also see section 6.4). Some of these shifts can occur less frequently or slower than others (see below). A shift of the PS curve: Equation 6.4 shows that an increase in the mark-up μ will cause the W price level to increase which, in turn, will cause the real wage P that producers in effect are willing to pay at any employ­ment level (i.e. at a given nomi­nal wage) to de­crease. As figure 6.8 demonstrates, the PS curve will Figure 6.8 A shift in the PS curve shift down­wards and a new ‘long-run’ or W struc­tural equilibrium will be estab­lished at a P WS lower real wage and a lower level of employ­ ment NS1. (Similar reasoning applies to a decrease in the mark-up.) W P ❐ An increase in taxes and non-labour input costs may cause the mark-up to increase, W P leading to a new ‘long-run’ equilibrium PS0 at a lower real wage and a lower level of employment NS. Supply shocks such as an oil price shock are important examples of such negative impacts on the structural PS1 equilib­rium level of employment (as seen NS1 NS0 N in a downward shift in the PS curve due to a compensatory increase in the mark-up). ❐ An increase in economic concentration and the degree of product market power in the economy may thus cause the mark-up to increase; hence real wages and the structural equilibrium employment level NS will be at lower levels. While the mark-up in the first instance needs to be large enough to cover the costs of non-labour inputs and taxes, the extent to which a producer can pass on an increase in input costs to its clients depends on its market power. ❐ An increase in import competition can also affect the structural equilibrium. If high levels of economic concentration or monopolism characterise a relatively closed economy, opening up the economy to foreign competition means that domestic businesses may lose market power. The loss of market power may cause them to reduce their mark-up and thus their prices, leading to the structural equilibrium being at a higher real wage and employment level NS. 0 0 0 1 Likewise an increase, for example, in labour productivity implies a decrease in labour cost per unit of output, enabling firms to reduce the price level P at every level of employment. This amounts to an increase in the implied real wage at every level of employment. PS shifts up. The structural equilibrium level of employment NS will be at a higher point. In contrast, a drop in worker productivity will shift the PS curve down; the structural equilibrium level of employment NS will be at a lower point. 258 Chapter 6: A model for an inflationary economy: aggregate demand and supply How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 258 2019/12/17 09:15 ❐ Labour productivity, in turn, depends for example on the capital goods available to workers, levels of technology and the skills levels of workers. An increase in capital stock K (due to private sector or government real investment), or an improvement in technology, or improved skill levels would all shift the PS curve up and yield a higher structural equilibrium level of employment NS. (This is a longer-term effect, especially relevant in the context of economic growth; see chapter 12.) A shift of the WS curve: The WS curve will shift if any of the institutional factors that affect its position change. The power of labour unions and employer organisations, the payment of efficiency wages, and unemployment and other benefits may all influence the nominal (and implied real) wage level that workers are willing to work for. ❐ When union power or the unemployment Figure 6.9 A shift in the WS curve benefits that government pays increase, WS1 there will be upward pressure on the real W P expected wage that work­ers are willing to work for. There will also be upward WS0 pressure on the expected real wage if businesses be­come willing to pay a higher ( W )1 P effi­ciency premium to workers, or if the W ( ability of employer organisa­tions to depress P )0 wages diminishes. In the diagram this will shift the WS curve vertically upwards, as in figure 6.9. This change will cause the equilibrium real wage to be at a higher PS level, while the long-run (or structural) equilibrium level of employment NS will be NS1 NS0 N at a lower level than before. ❐ Note that structural market character­ istics that constrain competition either Staggered contracts? between firms in the goods market or between workers in the labour market In reality it is not the case that all contracts tend to lower the long-run equilibrium are si­multaneously revised every year (or every three years). Such negotiations level of employment NS. It is important to note that the existence of labour contracts that fix nominal wages for a period of one to three years implies that the WS curve can shift only at the time of new wage bargaining. (Recall that the WS curve is activated only at the time of wage bargaining; once the nominal wage is set the curve becomes dormant until the next round of wage bargaining.) ❐ This means the WS curve is institution­ ally rigid. Thus changes in the location of the long-run equilibrium due to changes in the under­lying determinants of the wage-setting rela­tionship will be slow. occur in any month throughout the year, for the next year or more. Cer­tain months may see a higher frequency of contract renegotiations than others, so the spread of renego­tiations is not even. ❐ Nevertheless, staggered contracts mean that instead of jumping every year with a big amount, the LS (and WS) moves every month with a fraction of where it needs to go. ❐ In the analysis, however, we will assume one move per period and not, say, 12 small moves spread across a period. 6.3 Aggregate supply (AS) How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 259 259 2019/12/17 09:15 ❐ Recall that this also im­plies that the effective labour supply curve post-bargaining – indi­cated as LS – is hori­z ontal. We will return to this when we consider the labour market and aggregate supply in the short run (section 6.3.3). If the labour force (LF) increases due to an increase in the labour force participation rate or through normal population growth, the additional workers will put downward pressure on wages, creating an incentive for producers to employ more workers. WS shifts down and the equilibrium output level YS would be at a higher level. Structural unemployment, the ‘natural’ unemployment rate and types of unemployment Earlier in this chapter the long-run equilibrium was also denoted as a structural equilibrium with a corresponding structural unemployment rate (SRU). It is important to realise that, at this ‘long run’ or structural employment level, there may still be substantial involuntary unemployment. Employment may still be below what would amount to genuine ‘full’ employment. Types of unemployment Four different types of unemployment can be distinguished: 1. Seasonal unemployment occurs due to seasonal patterns of increased or decreased activity in certain sectors of the economy, for instance the building industry or the agricultural sector. This is not of great importance and is often ignored from a macroeconomic perspective. 2. Frictional (or search) unemployment – which is always present – exists because there is always a certain number of people who are in the process of searching for new jobs or busy changing jobs or careers. The extent of this type of unemployment is relatively limited and it is not really a macroeconomic problem. 3. Cyclical unemployment exists because of short-run cyclical downswings in the level of macroeconomic activity Y: as the level of Y fluctuates, so employment fluctuates. Usually this kind of unemployment is the main focus of macroeconomic theory and policy. We will return to this below when combining aggregate demand AD and aggregate supply AS. 4. Structural unemployment is especially important in the South African context. It refers to a form of unemployment that occurs regardless of the cyclical state of the economy. This type of unemployment can be of substantial proportions and is the most problematic, being very difficult to address with normal macroeconomic policy instruments (see section 12.2.3 in chapter 12 for further analysis). ❐ Structural unemployment is involuntary unemployment and arises, first, from the nature, location and pattern of employment opportunities (i.e. the demand side of the labour market). The types of product that are selected for production and the production technology that is used to determine what kinds of, and how much, labour can be employed. Technology largely determines the employment intensity of the production process; most new production technologies are labour-saving. Another factor is mismatches between the (increasing) skills requirements of jobs and the skills of workers. ❐ On the supply side of the labour market, many job seekers face a variety of constraints and entry barriers with regard to entering labour markets. These include weak education backgrounds, low skill levels, limited information on job opportunities, long distances from urban labour markets, being marginalised, disempowered and trapped in poverty. ❐ Entry barriers are related to market segmentation. The South African labour market is not a single market – in effect it comprises several submarkets. Labour mobility between these market segments is often limited. An example is the informal and formal sectors – small numbers of workers succeed in entering the formal sector from the informal sectors. Entry barriers also apply to (especially informal) small, labourintensive businesses wishing to enter markets that are dominated by large corporations. ❐ More generally, structural unemployment can be ascribed to structural rigidities, entry barriers, distortions and imperfections in markets and in the manner in which the economy is organised. Institutional factors and economic power relations play an important role. ❐ Given a certain pattern of production and employment, the labour market can absorb only a portion of the labour force. The rest is excluded from the operation (and advantages) of the market. 260 ⇒ Chapter 6: A model for an inflationary economy: aggregate demand and supply How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 260 2019/12/17 09:15 ⇒ The existence of structural employment effectively implies an intrinsic ceiling on employment in the normal labour market, given the structure of the economy at a certain stage. Despite being considerably below full employment in South Africa, this level of employment is the maximum that the normal interaction of producers and other decision-makers can deliver in input and labour markets, amidst short-run or cyclical fluctuations. ❐ The structurally unemployed thus remain without jobs ‘in the long run’, being more or less excluded from the labour market proper. ❐ Cyclical fluctuations in production and employment occur around this level of employment and production, denoted as YS . Upswings can push the economy above YS for considerable periods of time, but not permanently. In downswings, real income Y will fall below YS. The structural rate of unemployment (SRU) is the level of unemployment corresponding to YS. The levels of genuinely full employment (FE) and structural equilibrium employment (at YS ) can be indicated graphically in terms of real GDP or Y as in the following diagram – where FE only allows for those that are frictionally unemployed. At YS , which reflects the intersection of PS and WS, there is equilibrium employment in the labour market. But the important point is that it is accompanied by structural unemployment – without any downward (or upward) pressure on wages in the market. Labour markets are ‘saturated’ at YS. ❐ Below YS there is cyclical unemployment in the labour P ASLR market, leading to downward pressure on wages. ❐ Above YS cyclical ‘over’-employment occurs, which is Area of cyclical Area of likely to imply upward pressure on wages. The latter unemployment cyclical ‘over’may happen amidst and despite the existence of employment Downward substantial structural unemploy­ment. Such upward (or downward) pressure on wages and input prices in short-run positions above or below YS is important when the short-run supply curve ASSR is considered in relation to YS (section 6.3.3). ❐ One must also remember that the position of ASLR and YS can vary over time. Full employment and the natural rate of unemployment (NRU) pressure on wages Structural unemployment ever present Structural equilibrium Upward pressure on wages Structural unemployment still present YS YFE Y In much economic literature, the long-run unemployment rate is called the natural unemployment rate (NRU). The use of the word ‘natural’ derives from the idea that NRU is a level of unemploy­ment created by the natural forces of supply and demand in the labour market. It usually also im­plies the NRU corresponds to a situation of ‘full’ employment in which there is no involuntary unem­ployment. Those who are unemployed would be voluntarily so, choosing not to be part of the labour force at that moment. The only unemployment would be frictional or seasonal. Our analysis of the labour market, and the derivation of the PS and WS curves, explicitly incorpo­rated non-competitive labour and product markets, characterised by market power, price and wage setting, monopolies, monopsonies and so forth. This was done to recognise the reality of labour and product markets in most countries, including South Africa. The NRU approach usually assumes competitive market structures where the forces of supply and demand can freely interact, clear the market, and produce competitive equilibria with, for labour markets, no involuntary unemployment. This approach excludes recognition that structural factors in the economy can preclude the ‘natural’ or automatic attainment of full employment and can cause workers to be involuntarily unemployed for long periods, despite being willing and eager to work. ❐ Some theoreticians who adopt the NRU approach would argue that the economy returns to long-run equilibrium so quickly and efficiently that even cyclical unemployment can be ignored macroeconomically. ⇒ 6.3 Aggregate supply (AS) How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 261 261 2019/12/17 09:15 ⇒ To use the term ‘full employment’, as some textbooks do, to characterise equilibrium in the labour market, is clearly misleading as well, since it suggest the absence of an unemployment problem – which is not true at the long-run equilibrium at all. At the latter equilibrium the full extent of structural unemployment is still present. Thus it is more suitable to use the term structural rate of unemployment (SRU) to reflect the true nature of the long-run (or structural) equilibrium in the labour market. In any case, in a country such as South Africa where the official unemployment rate is close to 25% (and the unemployment rate according to the expanded definition close to 35%), calling the long-term unemployment rate natural is a bit misplaced. Relating PS, WS and total production The aggregate output produced by the number of workers employed in the ‘long-run’ equilibrium – graphically indicated by the intersection of the price-setting and wagesetting relationships – represents the total amount of goods that producers in the economy can supply in the ‘long run’ (i.e. amidst short-run fluctuations and mistaken expectations). This level of output represents the long-run aggregate supply of the economy (where longrun has the very specific meaning defined in the preceding discussion). The relationship between the level of employment and the level of aggregate output can be depicted by the total production function for the economy. Total production is a function of the quantity of labour employed N, capital K and technology A. A basic production function would look as follows: Y = f(N; K; A) A more sophisticated production function would also include human capital as well as social and economic institutions. We will do this when we consider economic growth in chapter 8. The total production function – the TP curve in figure 6.10 – shows, for a given amount of capital (i.e. keeping capital K constant), the relationship between the level of employment N (on the x-axis) and the level of aggregate output Y (on the y-axis). Since the employment of more workers will lead to an increase in output, the TP curve has a positive slope. If capital usage increases, the TP curve rotates upwards: compared to the original TP curve, the same number of workers can now produce more output. Figure 6.10 The total production curve Changes in the usage of new technology will Y TP also rotate the TP curve correspondingly. ❐ In a very simple case the production function can be assumed to be linear, e.g. Y = N Y2 (meaning that if one additional unit of labour Y1 is employed, one additional unit of output will be produced). While ac­ceptable for some Y0 simple mathematical manipulations (see box below), this would be too unrealistic. ❐ Note in the diagram (figure 6.10) that, although TP has a positive slope, the slope becomes flatter at higher levels of employment: creases as employment increases, output in­ N 10 11 12 flects the but at a decreasing rate. This re­ 262 Chapter 6: A model for an inflationary economy: aggregate demand and supply How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 262 2019/12/17 09:15 decreasing marginal produc­tivity of labour (an economic phenome­non which also explained the negative slope of the PS curve). As em­ployment increases, every extra worker added will produce less additional output than the previous worker added. ❐ This is illustrated in figure 6.10 where the additional output (from Y1 to Y2) produced by the 12th worker is less than the additional output (from Y0 to Y1) produced by the 11th worker. ❐ Because the effect of decreasing marginal productivity of labour becomes more pronounced as output reaches higher levels, at some point the TP curve flattens out and reaches a maximum. It means that even if more workers are employed, aggregate output will not increase (for a given capital stock). Deriving long-run aggregate supply ASLR At the beginning of this section we stated that aggregate supply in the long run, as defined, indicates combinations of P and Y in a situation where actual prices and wages equal expected prices and wages. To determine graphically what total level of output firms will supply in the long run, the long-run equilibrium level of employment NS established by the PS and WS relationships (bottom, left-hand panel of figure 6.11) is extended to the top left-hand panel of figure 6.11. The level of output that corresponds, on the TP curve, to that long-run level of employment, Figure 6.11 Deriving the ASLR curve Y Y TP 45° line YS NS N YS P W P WS W0 P Y ASLR P0 0 PS NS N YS 6.3 Aggregate supply (AS) How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 263 Y 263 2019/12/17 09:15 is the level of output YS that producers in the aggregate are able and willing to supply ‘in the long run’. π The formula for ASLR The formula for the ASLR relationship can be derived from equation 6.8, which describes the long-run equilibrium intersection of PS and WS: This output level YS can also be shown on the P-Y plane, which is the bottom right-hand panel of figure 6.11. Note that in this panel total output Y is measured on the horizontal axis. (This switch of axis is made possible by the mirror graph with its 45° line in the top right-hand panel of figure 6.11.) (1 + μ) f(N; Z) 1 = ___________ Q ...... (6.8) To translate this equilibrium level of employment N into aggregate output (for a given capital stock), we need the production function. To simplify matters, assume for the moment that the production function is a simple linear function Y = N. Then equation 6.8 becomes: (1 + μ) f(Y; Z) 1 = ___________ Q ..... (6.9) The bottom, right-hand panel of This equation describes the ASLR curve. If an equation figure 6.11 finally shows ‘longis specified for f(N, Z) and for the production function Y = f(N, K, A), the ASLR equation can be solved for Y run’ aggregate supply ASLR. so that Y is expressed as a function of Q, μ, Z factors, ❐ Note that graphically ASLR N, K and A factors. is a vertical line, indicating ❐ Since P does not appear in this equation, ASLR is a that output in the ‘long run’ vertical line in the P-Y plane. is inde­pendent of the price level P. ❐ This might seem surpris­ing, given the role that the price level plays in the PS and WS relation­ships. However, since the long-run PS-WS equilib­rium is defined in real terms, changes in the price level do not af­fect the equilibrium. (Also see the graphical inter­pretation of equa­tion 6.8 in the box.) Shifts in the ASLR curve As noted before, the position of the ASLR curve is not constant or permanent. Changes in the ‘structural’ and other factors identified above that underlie the position of the PS and WS curves will influence the position of the ASLR curve. ❐ The diagrammatical position of ASLR, like the ‘long-run’ or structural level of aggregate output, is variable over time. ❐ Any factor that reduces the equilibrium level of output in the PS-WS diagram will be reflected as a leftward shift of the ASLR curve, and conversely for a rightward shift. (Also see the AD-AS discussion in section 6.4.1.) ❐ Changes from the price-setting side can change the position of the ASLR curve at any time, while changes from the wage-setting side occur only at wage bargaining time (i.e. the reason for the rigidity of the WS curve). Example: changes from the price-setting side and PS A change in labour productivity Q, e.g. an increase in labour productivity, firstly causes the PS curve in figure 6.12 to shift upwards from PS0 to PS1. A new equilibrium is estab­ WS0. It is a characteristic of the new equilibrium that lished at the intersection of PS1 and W W P ). Likewise, its real wage would be higher (at P ) than that of the initial equilibrium (i.e. its long-run employment level would be at the higher level of NS1 compared to NS0 initially. Secondly, the increased labour productivity rotates the TP curve upwards from TP0 to TP1. 1 0 264 0 0 Chapter 6: A model for an inflationary economy: aggregate demand and supply How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 264 2019/12/17 09:15 Figure 6.12 Shifts in the ASLR curve TP1 Y 45° line Y TP0 YS1 YS0 NS0 NS1 N YS0 YS1 Y P W P ASLR0 ASLR1 WS0 W1 P P0 0 W 0 P PS1 0 PS0 NS0 NS1 N YS0 YS1 Y Transferring this to the P-Y plane shows that ASLR shifts to the right from ASLR0 to ASLR1. Thus the new structural equilibrium output level would be at YS1, which is higher than the initial YS0. ❐ An increase in the capital stock K (due to private sector or government real investment), or an improvement in technology (due to investment in research and development), or improved skills levels (e.g. due to better education and training) would all improve labour productivity over time. This yields a higher structural equilibrium level of employment NS. Graphically, ASLR would shift to the right. (Bear in mind that some of the changes can take some time to effect.) Changes in the mark-up: As deduced earlier, an increase in the mark-up will shift the PS W curve downwards – the higher price level will decrease the real wage P at every level of employment – which results in a drop in the structural employment level. ASLR shifts to the left, i.e. the structural equilibrium output YS would be at a lower level. (Note: In this case TP does not rotate or shift.) ❐ This is an important case, since it is also the avenue through which changes in nonlabour input costs will impact on the structural equilibrium and on the position of ASLR. A supply shock such as a large change in the oil price will push the structural equilibrium point left, i.e. to a point with a lower output level YS than before the shock. Graphically, ASLR will shift to the left. ❐ Increases in monopoly power that increase the mark-up will shift ASLR to the left. 6.3 Aggregate supply (AS) How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 265 265 2019/12/17 09:15 Example: changes from the wage-setting side and WS Increases in union power or the unemployment benefits that government pays will put upward pressure on the real expected wage that workers are willing to work for. Graphically, the WS curve shifts vertically upwards, reducing the long-run or structural equilibrium level of employment NS and thus output YS . This means ASLR shifts to the left. A similar shift in ASLR will result if firms become willing to pay a higher efficiency wage premium to workers, or if the ability of employer organisations to depress wages diminishes. However, due to the rigidity of the WS curve for the duration of labour contract periods, these shifts – or ‘jumps’, rather – can only occur infrequently. If the labour force increases through normal population growth or due to an increase in the labour force participation rate, the additional workers will put downward pressure on wages (when wages are renegotiated), creating an incentive for producers to employ more workers. WS will then shift down and the equilibrium output level YS will be at progressively higher levels. ❐ A scourge such as HIV/Aids can dramatically reduce the life expectancy of the popula­ tion and decrease population growth or even shrink the labour force over time. This would inhibit any rightward shift of YS to higher levels of equilibrium output. Long-term economic growth and investment In most countries the level of technology continuously improves in the long run, while the population and thus the labour force also continually expand; capital stock also grows due to investment (capital formation). Such continual improvements in productive capacity will be discussed in section 6.4.4, as well as in chapter 8 on long-term economic growth. A continually growing labour force and capital stock, as well as continually improving technology, implies that the ASLR curve will steadily shift to the right. Such improvements in the factors of production depend to a large extent on real investment. One can distinguish between (a) private sector real investment in, for example, factories and new machinery and equipment, and (b) government real investment (capital formation) in infrastructure, education and training facilities, health facilities, etc. (To the private sector in this context can also be added public corporations and government enterprises; see chapter 2.) Another important form of investment is investment in research and development (R&D), which produces new technology. Government expenditure and shifts of ASLR When analysing the macroeconomic impact of government spending G, one must distinguish between government consumption expenditure GC and government capital formation IG. GC impacts primarily on AD, while IG impacts on both AD (in the short run) and ASLR (in the medium to long run). It can even be argued (see chapter 8, section 8.10), that a significant portion of GC goes towards the provision of education and health services, which build human capacity and thus human capital – a key element in generating economic growth and economic development. In an HIV- and Aids-affected society, health spending can be particularly important. Thus GC partially could also impact on ASLR in the medium to long run – an important point regarding the relationship between macroeconomic and development policy. 6.3.3 The labour market and aggregate supply in the short run (ASSR ) An important element of understanding the determination of the price and output levels, and notably cyclical fluctuations and changes in these variables, is the behaviour of aggregate supply in the short run. This section demonstrates that, in the short run, producers can willingly deviate from the long-run output level. 266 Chapter 6: A model for an inflationary economy: aggregate demand and supply How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 266 2019/12/17 09:15 Deriving the short-run aggregate supply curve ASSR Like the ASLR curve, the ASSR curve shows, for each price level P, the aggregate level of real output that producers are willing or able to supply. The difference between the relationships is that in the short run producers can and probably will supply more (or less) than the long-run equilibrium level of output if actual prices and wages for a certain period allow for higher (or lower) profits, since such higher (or lower) profits create an incentive to supply more (or less). Such opportunities occur when the actual prices (and thus actual real wages), set by producers, deviate from expected prices (and thus expected real wages) due to some economic factor or disturbance. ❐ The corresponding deviations in output from YS yield aggregate supply in the short run. Recall that, in the long-run equilibrium, the actual price P equals the expected price P e, W W and the actual real wage P equals the expected real wage P . But how will producers and workers behave when the labour market is not in this long-run equilibrium, i.e. when P W W P ? Figure 6.13, and specifically the PS does not equal Pe, and P therefore does not equal curve, together with the LS curve, help to answer that question. e e Figure 6.13 Deriving the ASSR curve Y 45° line Y TP Y1 YS NS N1 N P W P WS when nominal wage was set at W0 W0 P 0 P Y1 ASLR Y ASSR P1 LS0 W0 YS P0 LS1 1 PS NS N1 N YS Y1 6.3 Aggregate supply (AS) How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 267 Y 267 2019/12/17 09:15 W0 In figure 6.13 the actual wage and expected real wage are initially equal at P , with W0 having been set contractually through the interaction of WS and PS behaviour. Employment is at the long-run equilibrium level NS, long-run output is at YS, and actual price P equals the expected price P e at P0. 0 W0 At a price that is higher than P e (= P0), say P1, the actual real wage will be lower at P . The ‘post-bargaining’ labour supply curve will in effect shift down from LS0 to LS1. At the lower real wage, employers will, on the PS curve, be willing to employ more workers N1 and produce higher output Y1. On the price-output schedule (bottom right-hand panel of figure 6.13), the combination of price P1 and output Y1 lies to the right and above the longrun equilibrium combination of P0 and YS. Firms will be willing to employ more workers to produce more because, at the contracted wage of W0, a higher price implies a higher mark-up, and thus higher profit. 1 Likewise (not shown in the dia­gram), at a price lower than P e (= P0), say P2, employment will be N2. N2 workers will produce output Y2. The combination of price P2 and output Y2 can again be plotted on the price-output schedule, which indicates that this combination lies to the left and below the equilibrium combination of P0 and YS. This exercise can be re­peated for any price be­low or above the price that equals the expected price. If the co­ordinates are then connected, the resulting curve is the short-run AS curve. It is derived in the bottom right-hand panel of fig­ure 6.13. It shows, for each price level, the level of output Y that produc­ers are willing to supply in the ‘short run’ – if, when and as long as the price level deviates from the expected price level, i.e. as long as the price expec­tation is incorrect or is lagging be­hind due to rigidity. The ASSR curve shows the pattern of supply be­hav­iour that results when firms willingly deviate from the long-run level of output as a result of profit opportu­nities due to unan­ ticipated increases in the price level coupled with wages being con­tractu­ally fixed for a pe­riod – wages are rigid for a period of time. (A corresponding explanation applies to un­ anticipated declines of the price level.) Any ASSR curve is thus drawn for a given nominal wage and expected price. What is the probable slope and shape of the ASSR curve? The slope of the ASSR curve is positive: an increase in output is caused by an opportunity for producers, the price setters, to increase the price level above its ‘long-run’ position (at which point it equalled the expected price Figure 6.14 The shape of the ASSR curve level), and to increase output to realise new P profit opportunities. Likewise, a drop in the price level leads to a drop in output. The shape of the ASSR curve is explained graphically by the shape of the TP curve in figure 6.14. The shape of the ASSR curve is a perfect mirror image of the curvature of the total production (TP) curve. Both reflect the decreasing marginal productivity of labour. As production is increased, the average out­ put per worker decreases, while the nominal wage remains the same (by contract). Thus the labour cost per unit of output (i.e. the total 268 Bottleneck area ASSR Y Chapter 6: A model for an inflationary economy: aggregate demand and supply How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 268 2019/12/17 09:15 π The formula for ASSR The formula for the ASSR relationship can be derived by inserting equation 6.2 into equation 6.1, and inserting a production function. Assuming for simplicity, as earlier, that Y = N, this produces the following illustrative equation for ASSR: P e (1 + μ) f(Y; Z) P = _____________ Q ...... (6.10) Thus aggregate supply in the short run is positively related to the output level Y, the expected price level P e and the mark-up μ; for Z it depends on each factor. Via the production function, it is also related to capital stock K and the use of other inputs and technology A. Aggregate supply in the short run is inversely related to labour productivity Q. But P ≠ P e is a condition for its existence in the first place. The intercept of the ASSR curve on the vertical ASLR curve is at the level of Pe. The ASSR curve will shift up or down if there are changes in the expected price level Pe. The ASSR curve will shift right or left (in lock-step with the ASLR curve) if there are changes in the mark-up μ (which includes non-labour input costs and taxes), labour productivity Q, a Z factor, or in capital stock K, the use of other inputs and technology A, or the labour force LF. Remember that the equation above is the same one that we used to derive the long-run AS curve, except that now P ≠ P e and thus they are not eliminated from the equation. If it is assumed that P = P e, i.e. that we are in the long run, this equation reduces to the equation for the ASLR curve (see box in section 6.3.2). wage bill divided by the units of output) increases as more workers are added. Producers will be willing to produce more only if the price per unit of output, i.e. the price level P, increases (and increases by an increasing amount – i.e. the rate at which it increases is itself increasing). Graphically, ASSR curves become steeper at higher levels of output. ❐ If the production function is assumed to be linear, ASSR will also be linear. The total production function will ulti­mately flatten out, as noted above, as mar­ginal productivity converges towards zero. Correspondingly, ASSR ultimately becomes vertical. Even if prices increase and more workers are employed, output can and will not increase beyond this level. ❐ The area on the short-run supply curve when it becomes very steep, just before it reaches its vertical point, is called the bottleneck area. It reflects the increasing dif­ ficulty and even futility of trying to increase output by adding additional labour to a production process that operates with a fixed amount of capital (machinery, etc.) in the short run. The economy is reaching short-run full capacity (i.e. unless additional capital is added). ❐ This vertical portion of ASSR is not on the ASLR curve, nor is it on the YFE line indicated in the box on page 261. It is somewhere in the middle, between them. What shifts the ASSR curve? Analysing shifts in the ASSR curve is relatively complicated. The ASSR curve can shift either on its own or in lock-step (or in tandem) together with the vertical ASLR curve when the latter shifts. 6.3 Aggregate supply (AS) How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 269 269 2019/12/17 09:15 ❐ When the ASSR curve shifts on its own, its intercept on the vertical ASLR line changes: it shifts up or down. In the diagram, for example, the intercept on the vertical ASLR1 line changes from P0 to P1 (the blue arrows in figure 6.15). ❐ When ASSR shifts in lock-step with ASLR the intercept on the vertical ASLR line does not change – it remains at P0 in the diagram – and it shifts right or left (the black arrows in the diagram). Figure 6.15 Two types of shift in the ASSR curve P ASLR1 ASLR0 Vertical shift of ASSR alone: intercept on ASLR changes ASSR2 ASSR1 ASSR0 P1 P0 Lock-step horizontal shift of both ASSR and ASLR An increase in the expected price Y P e will shift the ASSR curve up – it changes the inter­ cept of the ASSR curve on ASLR. In economic terms, this upward shift is a reflection of a higher nominal wage being contracted (during a new round of negotiations) to match the increase in the expected price level. (This is discussed again in the next section.) ❐ This shift thus only occurs if and when such negotia­tions occur. ❐ This is the only case when the ASSR curve shifts on its own. The other shifts in the ASSR curve are lock-step changes that occur when Changes in the nominal wage ASLR shifts due to its underlying In the text it is stated that ‘any ASSR curve is causal factors. Both of these curves drawn for a given nominal wage’. What does this thus shift left or right for the same mean for shifts in the ASSR curve? The nominal distance due to the same factors. wage is the vehicle through which the expected Thus the ASSR curve will shift right or price manifests itself. left – together (in lock-step) with the ❐ If it changes due to a change in P e it implies a ASLR curve – if there are changes in vertical shift of the ASSR curve. the mark-up μ (which includes non❐ If it changes for a reason unrelated to labour input costs and taxes), labour expected price, e.g. the exercise of labour union power, it is analysed as a change in productivity Q, a Z factor, or in capital that particular causal factor, which implies a stock K, the use of other inputs and lock-step shift of ASSR together with ASLR. In technology A, or the la­bour force LF. such cases, an increase in the nominal wage ❐ For example, an in­crease in labour has the same effect as an increase in the pro­ductivity shifts ASSR and ASLR to price of a non-labour input, e.g. oil. the right in lock-step. ❐ Supply shocks, e.g. a large oil price in­crease, will shift the ASSR curve to the left in lock-step with the ASLR curve. As discussed earlier, except for changes in the average price (cost) of non-labour inputs, most of these shifts in ASSR (and ASLR) are likely to occur relatively infrequently. They are more of a medium- or long-run nature. This is especially true of those that originate in the wage-setting context, whose WS curve is rigid. Adapting expectations and the adaptive nature of the ASSR curve Shifts in the ASSR curve due to a change in the expected price level Pe explain an important pattern that usually follows a disturbance that places the economy at a point off the long270 Chapter 6: A model for an inflationary economy: aggregate demand and supply How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 270 2019/12/17 09:15 run or structural equilibrium, i.e. a point off the ASLR curve. (As noted in section 6.1, such a point can occur due to a change/shift in the aggregate demand (AD) relationship; see section 6.4.1 for further analysis.) The key point of this section is that any equilibrium point on ASSR curve that is off the ASLR curve is unlikely to be sustained for an indefinite period. An adjustment process will kick in that will push the equilibrium back, over time, to the structural equilibrium output level YS (i.e. to the ASLR curve). Adjustments in the expected price level P e are central to this process. Recall that the short-run supply relationship – and the ASSR curve – was explained by periods when the price level diverged from the expected price level. For example, firms will willingly increase output beyond the structural equilibrium level of output YS – along the ASSR curve – as a result of profit opportunities due to unanticipated increases in the price level (coupled with wages being contractually rigid for a period of, for example, one to three years). However, after some time, people’s expectations will catch up with reality – a discrepancy between the actual price level and the expected price level cannot be maintained in the longer run. For example, if the actual price level has been higher than the expected price level at the time of contracting, expectations will gradually adjust and the expected price will move towards the actual price. Once wage renegotiations occur, real wages will probably adjust to reflect this, causing an increase in labour costs and thereby eroding any opportunistic profit opportunity and any incentive to produce more than the structural output level YS. Output will decline. ❐ Theoretically the process should continue until P = P e and end when output has returned to the long-run, structural equilibrium level YS. Exactly how, and in how many phases, the economy moves back to the long-run level will become clear when we combine aggregate demand and aggregate supply in the next section. ❐ Every output level above or below the long-run output level (and thus every point on ASSR) is the result of mistaken price expectations or ‘price surprises’ (due to some kind of economic disturbance). At every point on ASSR (except the price at ASLR) the actual price either exceeds or falls short of the price expected at the time of contracting. Since this is unlikely to be sustained over time, levels of output above or below the long-run level of output cannot be sustained indefinitely. ❐ The only aggregate supply level that is sustainable in the long run – in the sense of being free of expectations-driven pressure to change – is the level where P = P e, which is also the output level YS corresponding to the ASLR curve. Only when P = P e will workers have no reason to want to renegotiate their contracted wage to reflect a changed price level and cost of living (assuming that the factors underlying the price-setting and wage-setting relationships remain unchanged). The fact that points along the ASSR curve are ‘temporary’ or ‘short-run’ in a specific technical sense does not render them unimportant at all. The corresponding fluctuations in aggregate output are the essence of the business cycle and one of the main ‘problems’ of macroeconomic analysis and policy. In reality, economic disturbances and related dynamics (for instance, balance of payments or interest rate adjustments) push the economy off the long-run ASLR curve most of the time. ❐ Moreover, because changes in price expectations have to be reflected in renegotiated labour contracts before having an impact on labour costs and the position of the ASSR curve, the shift in ASSR occurs relatively slowly. As we will see, it is also not completed in one step, because the renegotiated wages usually do not catch up in one round. 6.3 Aggregate supply (AS) How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 271 271 2019/12/17 09:15 6.4 Aggregate supply (ASLR, ASSR) and aggregate demand (AD) together 6.4.1 Macroeconomic equilibrium in the ‘short’ and ‘long’ run As noted in the brief overview in section 6.1, and using the analogy of standard micro­ economic theory, the essence of the AD-AS model of explaining, graphically, the state of the economy is twofold: ❐ First, the actual, ‘month-to-month’, Figure 6.16 AD-AS equilibrium short-run equilibrium levels of out­ P ASLR put and real income Y and the price level P are determined by the inter­ ASSR section of the AD and ASSR curves. ❐ Second, the presence of a structural Structural equilibrium equilibrium with its output level YS (and price level PS) and a vertical PS Short-run ‘long-run’ or structural ASLR curve P1 equilibrium exerts a ‘gravita­tional pull’ so that, if the actual, short-run equilibrium output level of the econ­omy is not AD at YS, the intersection of the AD and ASSR curves will over time move YS Y1 YFE towards ASLR through a dynamic Y justments in process involving ad­ price expectations. Following this process, the intersec­tion of the AD and ASSR is likely to end up exactly on the ASLR curve (see examples below). The long-run or structural equilib­rium point – which can be thought of as exerting the gravitational pull – is thus at the intersection of the AD and ASLR curves. The economic interpretation of the longThe full-employment level of output YFE is run point of equilibrium is somewhat indicated on the horizontal axis throughout different from how it is understood in the rest of this chapter to serve as a micro­ economics. We saw above that reminder that the long-run, or structural, the AD curve is a collection of potential equilibrium level of output YS is not a fullequilibrium points – each for a different employment level and still leaves structural price level. However, all these points unemployment untouched. of equilibrium are not attainable at all times, because producers are not necessarily willing or able to produce the quantity of output that is demanded at certain price levels. (Remember that the points on the AD curve are derived using the assumption that production readily responds to expenditure.) The points that can be attained are indicated by the ASSR curve. ❐ In this sense, the short-run aggregate supply curve is a kind of ‘production possibility frontier’ – points on (and to the left of) the curve are attainable, but points to the right are not. ❐ The point of intersection is the short-run equilibrium point with the highest attainable level of income Y, given supply and demand conditions. This leads to the conclusion that the actual, short-run level of real income Y and the price level P are simultaneously determined by the interaction between aggregate demand and short-run aggregate supply, graphically illustrated by their intersection, e.g. Y1 and P1 in 272 Chapter 6: A model for an inflationary economy: aggregate demand and supply How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 272 2019/12/17 09:15 figure 6.16. Shifts of the The AD-AS equilibrium mathematically short-run supply curve would change the set Having derived an equation for the AD curve in of attainable points of section 6.2 of this chapter: equilibrium. In the same S Y = 1(a + Ia + G + X – ma) + 2 __ MP + lπ …… (4.6) way, shifts of the de­ mand curve change the and an equation for the ASSR curve in section 6.3.3 above point of equilibrium. (based on equilibrium in the labour market): P e (1 ) f(Y; Z) ❐ Given the way AD …… (6.10) P = ______________ Q was constructed from these two relations simultaneously determine the equilibrium the goods and money level of Y and P ‘in the short run’. They can be solved to obtain markets (i.e. the real equilibrium values of Y and P. and monetary sectors ❐ For the long-run equilibrium, one simply substitutes P for and the IS and LM P e in the equations. curves), any point on the AD represents equilibrium in the goods and money markets. ❐ Likewise, given the way ASSR was constructed from the labour market (and the interaction of the PS and the post-bargaining LS curves), the labour market is in an interim, between-bargaining equilibrium. ❐ Thus all three of these markets or sectors are simultaneously in equilibrium at the intersection point of AD and ASSR. Both pairs LS-PS and IS-LM intersect at the same equilibrium output level. ❐ Note that in a longer-term sense there is no labour market equilibrium, since we are not at the intersection of WS and PS. Thus workers are not working for the real wage at which they would have wanted to work at wage-setting and -bargaining time (which is on the WS curve). π ( ) There is no reason why the AD-ASSR equilib­rium should be on the ASLR curve, i.e. why equilibrium output should be at the long-run, structural level YS. De­pending on the position of the AD curve (and thus values of investment, consumption, exports, imports, gov­ernment expenditure, taxes and mone­tary aggregates) and the position of the ASSR curve (and thus the expected price level Pe and other supply-side factors) the equil­ibrium of P and Y can be anywhere on the P-Y plane. (At all but one of these, P will not equal P e.) ❐ Whether the economy can remain at such a point indefinitely is another matter, as ar­ gued above. It is analysed again below. A number of typical patterns are often found in P and Y. One can distinguish patterns originating in demand-side changes/disturbances, or in supply-side changes/disturbances. Combinations can also occur. In each case, the initial effect of the disturbance is followed by an adjustment back towards the long-run level of YS. 6.4.2 Demand-side disturbances leading to points off the ASLR curve Demand expansion followed by supply adjustment Suppose that aggregate demand increases (AD shifts to the right in figure 6.17), starting from an equilibrium income level at YS with the price level at P0 and with P e = P0. ❐ Such a change can be caused by expenditure-stimulating events such as an increase in government expenditure, a tax cut, an exogenous in­crease in exports, a drop in imports 6.4 Aggregate supply (ASLR, ASSR) and aggregate demand (AD) together How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 273 273 2019/12/17 09:15 due to a de­precia­tion of the rand or, on the monetary side, a decrease in the repo rate (see complete examples and chain reac­tions below). Figure 6.17 Initial impact of demand expansion P ASLR ASSR0 The increased demand alerts firms to Short-run new possibilities to increase output, P2 equilibrium after demand which can be sold at a price premium P1 stimulation – remembering that they are price setters. Moreover, increased output P0 also requires a higher price because AD1 AD0 of increased costs. As employment increases to produce the higher output demanded, the marginal product of labour decreases; at the existing YS Y1 Y YFE nom-inal wage rate the unit cost of production increases. Producers will be willing to employ these additional workers only if there is a higher price level (which will allow the real wage rate to fall and producers to recover the higher unit cost of production). This places upward pressure on the price level: the price level increases from P0 to P1 in the diagram. At the given nominal wage, the higher price level creates new profit opportunities, which induce businesses to increase aggregate production. Thus, the price increase leads to an increase in output and income Y along the ASSR curve. Short-run equilibrium output and income increase from the long-run level YS to Y1. The economy experiences a short-run or cyclical upswing. ❐ Graphically, this is a shift in the AD curve from an equilibrium point on the YS line to the right, with the new intersection of AD with ASSR being to the right of YS. ❐ In the product and money markets, changes indicated by a rightward shift in IS and/ or LM would have occurred, depending on whether a real or a monetary change was behind the shift in AD. (See section 6.2.5 and examples 1 and 2 further on.) ❐ In the labour market a downward shift of the LS curve occurs, as shown in figure 6.13 in section 6.3.3. Equilibrium occurs at the intersection of the PS and LS curves. (Details of changes in the PS and LS curves are shown in the graphical examples in addendum 6.1.) W ❐ Workers experience a drop in living standards due to a drop in their real wage P since P has increased. However, there is nothing they can do about it until the next round of wage negotiations. But at the initially contracted nominal wage W0 (based on P e = P0) there are more employment opportunities available than before. So at least there is an increase in employment along the horizontal labour supply curve LS1, as in figure 6.13. ❐ The structural equilibrium, meanwhile, has relocated to the intersection of AD1 with the long-run supply curve ASLR at point (YS; P2). ❐ This kind of expansion typically takes one to three years to play out through changes in interest rates, prices, expenditure decisions, production decisions, etc. At the new short-run equilibrium, output is above the structural equilibrium employment level YS and the actual price (at P1) is higher than the initial expected price (P e0 = P0). As noted above, such a position cannot be sustained indefinitely, since adapting expectations would start to impact on the labour market. Workers are likely to realise that the average price level P has been increasing. Their price expectation P e would adjust towards the actual price P1. In due course, labour contracts are likely to adjust to the higher average price level P1. As a result, nominal wages start to increase. 274 Chapter 6: A model for an inflationary economy: aggregate demand and supply How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 274 2019/12/17 09:15 ❐ Graphically, as shown in figure 6.18, this is indicated by the ASSR curve starting to shift up, say to position ASSR1, which intercepts ASLR where the new expected price level P e1 = P1. Figure 6.18 Demand expansion followed by supply adjustment P ASLR ASSR2 ASSR1 ASSR0 Equilibrium after supply adjustments P2 The increase in the nominal wage P1 increases production costs, which P0 constrains the ability of producers to produce. Aggregate output contracts. The equilibrium moves up and to the left. There is new upward pressure on the average price level, accompanied by a drop in total production and income Y – we have an increasing price level combined with an economic contraction. Equilibrium after demand stimulation AD0 YS Y1 AD1 YFE Y The new output level is still above YS. And, the new price level is yet again above the recently adjusted expected price level P e1, leading to further changes in the expected price and resultant wage contract adjustments when the next round of negotiations comes around. These processes where ASSR shifts up are likely to continue as long as Y is above YS. The process pushes Y towards YS and ends when the equilibrium level of Y stabilises on YS and the price level (as well as the expected price level P e) is at P2. In the diagram above (figure 6.18), this is when ASSR and AD intersect on the YS line. The neutrality of money? The economy has reached the When the demand stimulation is due to an expansion long-run, structural equilibrium in the money supply, this example demonstrates point (YS; P2). what is meant by the term ‘neutrality of money’. ❐ We see here the ‘upward Since the long-run effect of the monetary expansion elbow’, the typical pattern of on output is eventually zero, it has no long-term the ASSR adjustment process benefit regarding output or employment. The price following stimulation of aggre­ level P will eventually increase exactly in proportion to the increase in the money supply M – the only gate demand AD that pushed Y long-run change. above YS. ❐ This does not mean that monetary policy cannot ❐ Remember that the move of the be used to counter a recession. But output equilibrium point up along the cannot be sustained beyond YS indefinitely by AD curve is founded in corresmoney supply growth. ponding changes in the IS and ❐ The neutrality result depends on the ASLR curve LM curves. Similarly, changes being stationary. If the drop in interest rates due on the supply side are founded to the money supply expansion stimulates real in changes in the WS, LS and investment, it will shift ASLR to the right, producing PS curves. a long-term real positive impact on YS (see the ❐ Since the ASSR adjustment pro­ combination patterns below). cess requires successive rounds The neutrality of money was an important issue in the of wage renegotiations, the debate between Keynesians and Monetarists on the adjustment process can take use of monetary policy to stimulate economic growth several years to complete. The (see chapter 11). entire process of stimulation 6.4 Aggregate supply (ASLR, ASSR) and aggregate demand (AD) together How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 275 275 2019/12/17 09:15 followed by supply adjustment can easily take five years or more, allowing for some overlap and concurrency. What if policymakers try to keep the economy at Y1, above the long-run, structural equilibrium level of Y? They would again and again have to counter the supply adjustment process and accompanying contraction by further expansionary policy to push the economy towards Y1 again. Supply adjustment would occur yet again, requiring yet further expansionary policy. And so on, and so on. The result would be continual increases in the price level. As people start to expect these policy reactions, price expectations would adjust much quicker and be incorporated into wage contracts proactively. ASSR would start adjusting upwards much quicker, requiring stronger and stronger expansionary policy. In the end, P would increase faster and faster – i.e. we would get inflation (more specifically, increasing inflation). The output level Y1 simply cannot be sustained indefinitely with a given capital stock, labour force and technology. (We will examine this result better in the next chapter when the model is expanded to deal with an inflationary environment.) Demand contraction followed by supply adjustment For a decrease in aggregate de­mand Figure 6.19 A demand contraction sequence AD (figure 6.19), a similar pattern P ASLR ASSR0 emerges. In this case Y drops ASSR1 below YS. The adjustment proc­ess ASSR2 entails a down­ward adjust­ment in the average price level P, this being Equilibrium after demand decrease part of the process of moving back P0 towards YS. P1 Equilibrium after ❐ Such a change can be caused supply adjustments PS by a decrease in government penditure (e.g. to reduce a ex­ large budget deficit), or a drop in ex­ports due to a re­cession AD1 AD0 in the economies of our major trading partners. YFE Y1 YS Y ❐ The details of the economic analysis are similar to that of the expansion example above, but in the opposite direction. Such an example is presented below. Remember that the move of the equilibrium point down along the AD curve is founded in corresponding changes in the IS and LM (and BP) curves. Similarly, changes on the supply side are founded upon changes in the WS, LS and PS curves. ❐ As shown in figure 6.19 this is the ‘downward elbow’, the typical pattern of the ASSR adjustment process after a decline in AD which decreases Y to a level below YS. The adjustment returns the economy to YS. ❐ This adjustment can take many, many years, notably since actual prices and nominal wages have to adjust downwards – not an easy thing in any economy. Key perspectives on the complete chain reactions Any of the open-economy chain reactions which in previous chapters led to changes in aggregate expenditure, now lead to a change in Y as well as in P. The change in P can also have a feedback effect on the components of expenditure (e.g. investment, imports 276 Chapter 6: A model for an inflationary economy: aggregate demand and supply How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 276 2019/12/17 09:15 and exports). Depending on the position of the equilibrium relative to YS, there could then also be a supply adjustment process. ❐ Thus any chain reaction leading to an equilibrium income level above or below YS is unlikely to stop there. The ASSR adjustment process will lead to further changes in Y and P (and other variables). ❐ As mentioned in chapters 3 and 4, in practice the primary and secondary effects are not neatly separated in time as distinct steps that follow one another – say, as if an increase in Y is followed by a distinct increase in money demand. The secondary effects concurrently become operational as the primary effect gathers speed. Different secondary effects may, though, have different dynamics and time spans. The secondary effects flowing from the balance of payments are likely to commence a while later than the money market secondary effect, but will still unfold parallel and concurrent to ongoing changes in main variables. ❐ We must now also distinguish between short-run and medium-run secondary effects. The secondary effects in the money market, and thereafter the two BoP adjustment effects, pertain to the short run, i.e. a period of up to three years following the initial stimulus. (Note that these effects were all demand-side adjustments.) The supply-side adjustment process, which we add now, takes place in the medium term, and can take several years, typically from three to seven years. ❐ The supply adjustment (a medium-run secondary effect) similarly is not neatly separated in time from the short-run primary and secondary effects of a change in demand, as the above theory might suggest. There is likely to be overlap, with the supply adjustment process starting and gathering speed already in the later stages of the short-term effects. Such concurrency implies that, on average, an entire macroeconomic chain reaction can take from four to seven years to complete. Time path diagrams will demonstrate this in the discussion that follows. ❐ These only are indicative time frames. In reality, an economy never changes in neat, mechanical fashion – as noted several times before. Moreover, long before this particular complete chain reaction has played itself out, other shocks will occur on top of it and start new stimulus-plus-adjustment processes. ❐ Like others, the supply adjustment process – the theoretically predicted move to the long-run structural equilibrium – is unlikely to occur quite as quickly or smoothly as the preceding discussion may suggest. Nevertheless, the existence of such adjustment forces is clear. ❐ During the supply adjustment process, there will also be concurrent impacts on demandside elements such as the interest rate and balance of payments components. However, in this phase their role becomes of minor importance. In the medium term, if any of the other adjustments causes price or quantity changes contrary to the price and quantity changes brought about by the supply-adjustment process, the latter will dominate – the ‘gravitational pull’ of ASLR is persistent and will be as long as the economy is not at ASLR. Thus expected price will continue to adjust to actual prices until they are equal. The first two examples in chapter 4, section 4.7.5 will now be spelt out fully, while the third is left to the reader as an activity. Additions are in italics. The IS-LM-BP dynamics in those examples explain shifts of the AD curve. These shifts of the AD curve constitute the first part of the complete chain reactions that follow. This will then be followed by a description of the economic events that constitute the adjustment of the ASSR curve towards the longrun, structural equilibrium level of real income, i.e. a point of rest on ASLR. 6.4 Aggregate supply (ASLR, ASSR) and aggregate demand (AD) together How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 277 277 2019/12/17 09:15 Example 1: The short- and medium-run internal and external effects of an increase in the repo rate Primary effect (demand side) (1) [The process starts at point 0 on the AD-AS diagram (figure 6.20).] Higher repo rate ⇒ money supply contracts ⇒ increase in interest rates ⇒ aggregate demand decreases ⇒ downward pressure on prices and production ⇒ Y decreases (= downswing in the economy) and P starts to decline. As Y and P decline, imports decrease ⇒ current account (CA) surplus develops; increase in r ⇒ capital inflows ⇒ financial account (FA) goes into surplus. Short-run secondary effects (demand side): (2) Money market effect: As Y decreases, it causes the demand for money to decrease concurrently ⇒ downward pressure on interest rates ⇒ initial fall in Y arrested ⇒ drop in M arrested, initial strengthening of (X – M) starting to end. The net effect of the primary and money Figure 6.20 AD-AS and an increase in the repo rate market secondary effects is that aggregate AD0 AD1 AD3 AD2 demand and output falls, but that this fall P ASLR ASSR0 is restrained by (a) a concurrent drop D in M , which holds back (but does not ASSR1 reverse) the repo-initiated rise in r and the consequent drop in I and Y. Moreover, (b) 0 P 3 2 the simultaneous decline in the average price P0 3 level P implies upward pressure on MP . This 1 acts as a further restraining force on the P4 4 increase in r and the decline in I and Y (and M). ❐ Note that, now that P is not assumed to be constant any more, P changes and has feedback effects on compo­ Y1 Y3 Y2 YS Y YFE nents of expenditure (investment and imports). ❐ If (a) didn’t happen, it would mean that the IS curve is flat. AD would shift left further. If (b) didn’t happen, it would mean that the ASSR curve is flat. The decline in Y would be larger. S The net effect of the primary and money market secondary effect can be depicted on the P-Y plane, using the AD-AS framework. The demand/expenditure contraction causes the AD curve to shift left. The first horizontal shift from AD0 to AD1 captures the combined primary and money market secondary effects. ❐ The intersection of the shifting AD curve and the (stationary) ASSR curve determines the short-run equilibrium of P and Y. The short-run equilibrium moves along ASSR0 from point 0 to point 1. ❐ This move along the ASSR curve captures the restraining effect of the declining P on aggregate expenditure. [The economy is at point 1 on the diagram.] The net effect of the primary and money market secondary effects leaves Y and P lower, r higher and both the current and financial accounts in surplus. There is a BoP surplus (BoP > 0). 278 Chapter 6: A model for an inflationary economy: aggregate demand and supply How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 278 2019/12/17 09:15 Further secondary effects due to BoP > 0: (3) Initial BoP effect (foreign reserves adjustment): BoP surplus ⇒ inflow of foreign exchange ⇒ MS increases and downward pressure on interest rates (which decreases the inflow of foreign capital and the FA surplus) ⇒ aggregate demand increases, causing Y and P to increase; as Y and P increase it stimulates imports ⇒ prevailing current account surplus is reduced; the turnaround in the real interest rate starts to discourage or reverse capital inflows. The BoP surplus is being reduced. The increase in Y implies that the initial downswing has turned around (at least for now …). The decline in P is also reversed slightly. In the diagram, AD shifts a bit to the right to AD2 (or, the initial leftward shift is restrained – depending on the speed of the MS effect, which is assumed to happen quicker than the exchange rate effect). [The economy is at point 2 on the diagram.] (4) Concluding BoP effect (exchange rate adjustment): The initial BoP surplus (now already slightly reduced) also leads to appreciation of the rand ⇒ current account surplus is reduced, and so is the remaining BoP surplus. The process will continue until BoP = 0. This cumulative decrease in (X – M) again reduces aggregate expenditure, which reverses the short recovery of Y and P – a further economic downswing occurs (Y and P decline again). Note the typical AD pattern generated by the two BoP effects following a BoP surplus: first the AD curve shifts right (money supply effect), then the AD curve shifts left (exchange rate effect). ❐ The AD curve shifts right then left. ❐ The net effect of the two BoP effects on the position of the AD curve and on equilibrium Y appears to be relatively minor. Nevertheless, Y went through a noticeable up-down cycle in the process. See chapter 4, section 4.7.4 for the initial analysis of these BoP-related shifts. Addendum 6.3 provides a complete illustration of the IS-LM-BP changes that underlie the movements of and along the AD curve in this example. In the diagram, AD shifts a bit left again to AD3. The short-run equilibrium moves to point (P3;Y3). [The economy is at point 3 on the diagram.] Depending on the timing of the BoP effects, there can be either a zig-zag in Y and P or one will only notice the net effect, i.e. the net shift of AD from AD0 to AD3 and the net move of the equilibrium along ASSR from point 0 to point 3 (blue arrow). Y declines from YS to Y3 and P from P0 to P3. ❐ Working with the net shift of AD simplifies AD-AS analysis. We will do so in the rest of this and the next example. The net effect of the primary and money market and BoP secondary effects leaves Y and P lower, r higher and the BoP = 0. More specifically, and crucial for the supply adjustment that will follow: real income Y is below YS, the structural equilibrium level of Y, and the actual price level P is below the expected price level P e, since at this moment P e = P0. That is: Y < YS and P < P e These will lead to further economic adjustment processes. 6.4 Aggregate supply (ASLR, ASSR) and aggregate demand (AD) together How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 279 279 2019/12/17 09:15 Medium-run secondary effects (supply side): (5) Supply adjustment: Y < YS and P < P e ⇒ downward pressure on expected prices. These should lead to reduced wages in the next rounds of labour negotiations. As these come into effect they reduce production costs and boost the ability of firms to produce ⇒ reduction in price level P and increase in sales and production Y. After several such (annual) rounds of wage negotiation, the output level will gradually approach YS and the price level P declines until a point on ASLR is reached and P = P e. In figure 6.20 this is reflected as a downward move of the ASSR until it intersects AD3 at a point that is on ASLR (which is where P = P e). The short-run equilibrium moves along the AD3 curve from point 3 to point 4. Y increases from Y3 to YS and P declines from P3 to P4. M The decline in P also increases the real money supply P , which puts downward pressure on interest rates and increases aggregate demand (along the IS and AD curves). Thus the FA should also go into deficit. The (cost- and interest-rate induced) increase in income Y also leads to an increase in imports, so that the current account CA should go into deficit. A BoP deficit develops. S The normal BoP adjust­ment processes will play out (during which r should increase some­ what and the rand should depreciate; the impact of a declining P on X and M will assist these proc­esses). All these will then take the BoP back to a position of balance – perhaps caus­ing minor fluctuations in Y on its path along AD3 towards its final resting point at YS. These processes continue until the short- Figure 6.21 Illustrative time path of key variables – run equilibrium is at YS and BoP = 0, i.e. increase in the repo rate with both internal (real, monetary and labour market) and external equilibrium. [This is at point 4 in the diagram.] Summary of final, net effects 1. The price level ends up significantly lower than at its starting level. The contractionary monetary policy step followed by the AS adjustment has unequivocally reduced the average price level. 2. Real income is back where it started, af­ ter a deep cyclical down­swing, with the recovery – punctuated by a dip on the way – lasting several years. 3. Cyclical unemployment increases for several years, but decreases during the AS adjustment phase. 4. The balance of payments goes through two cycles of surplus and deficit, but ends up in balance. 5. The real interest rate goes through a strong upward phase initially, but declines during the BoP as well as AS adjustment phases. It will probably end up roughly where it started. 280 r Time Y Time P Time Rand BoP Demand contraction phase up to 3 years Time Supply adjustment phase 3–7 years Overall (with overlap): 4–7 years Chapter 6: A model for an inflationary economy: aggregate demand and supply How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 280 2019/12/17 09:15 6. The external value of the rand increases during the second BoP effect of the demand contraction phase, and will likewise decline again at the end of the supply adjustment phase. Example 2: the short- and medium-run internal and external consequences of an increase in government expenditure Primary effect and short-run, demand-side secondary effects: The net impact of higher government expenditure, via its primary and money market secondary effects, can be summarised as follows. (See chapter 4, section 4.7.5 for detailed steps.) [The process starts at point 0 on the AD-AS diagram (figure 6.22).] (1) & (2): Aggregate demand and output Y as well as P rises (as does M), but this increase is restrained by (a) a concurrent rise in interest rates, which dampens expenditure, as M well as (b) the simultaneous increase in the average price level P, which contracts P . This acts as a further restraining force on the increase in Y (and M). S This phase leaves Y and P higher, r higher and the CA < 0. The increase in r leaves the FA > 0. Assuming mobile international capital flows, the net effect will be a BoP > 0. As a result, further secondary effects follow. These continue until BoP = 0. (3) The initial, money supply effect of the BoP reduces interest rates, which stimulates expenditure, Y and P to increase. This reduces the current account deficit, while the FA surplus is also reduced by the drop in interest rates. The initial upswing in Y has been followed by another upswing. (4) The concluding, exchange rate effect of the BoP leads to an appreciation of the rand ⇒ current account deficit increases again. This helps to eliminate the remaining BoP surplus. The appreciation of the rand is responsible for a contraction of aggregate expenditure and Y towards the end. In the diagram the entire set of demand-side primary and secondary effects is summarised in the net rightward shift of AD from AD0 to AD1. (If shown in detail, the AD curve will display the typical right-then-left shift pattern, associated with phases 3 and 4 for a BoP surplus, before reaching the AD1 position.) Figure 6.22 AD-AS and an increase in government expenditure The short-run equilibrium has moved from (P0; YS) to point (P1; Y1). AD1 [The economy is at point 1 on the diagram.] P ASSR2 ASSR1 ASLR ASSR0 P2 P1 P0 Equilibrium after supply adjustments 2 1 0 Equilibrium after all demand-side secondary effects AD0 YS Y1 YFE Y The net effect of the primary, money market and BoP secondary effects leaves Y and P higher, r higher and the BoP = 0. More specifically, and crucial for the supply adjustment that will follow: Y > YS and P > P e 6.4 Aggregate supply (ASLR, ASSR) and aggregate demand (AD) together How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 281 281 2019/12/17 09:15 since at this point in the process P e = P0. These will now lead to further economic adjustment processes. Medium-run secondary effect: (5) Supply adjustment: Y > YS and P > P e ⇒ upward pressure on expected prices. These should lead to increased wages in the next rounds of labour negotiations. As these come into effect they increase production costs and restrict the ability of firms to produce ⇒ increase in price level P coupled with a decrease in sales and production Y. This process will repeat itself. After several such (annual) rounds of wage negotiation, the output level will continue to decline and gradually approach YS. In the diagram, the short-run AS curve shifts upwards to, say, position ASSR1. It shows a downswing in Y together with an increase in the average price level P – not a happy combination for a country. Further such adjustments are portrayed as a continual upward move of the ASSR until it intersects the AD and the ASLR, i.e. at point 2. M The increase in P also decreases the real money supply P , which puts upward pressure on interest rates and dampens demand (moving up along the AD curve). Thus the FA should also go into surplus. The (cost- and interest-rate induced) decrease in income Y also leads to a decrease in imports, so that the CA should go into surplus. A BoP surplus develops. S The normal BoP adjust­ment processes will play out (during which r should decrease some­ what and the rand should appreciate; the Figure 6.23 Illustrative time path of key variables – impact of an increasing P on X and M will increase in government expenditure assist these proc­esses). All these will then take the BoP back to a position of balance – perhaps caus­ing minor fluctuations in Y on r its path along AD3 towards its final resting point at YS. These processes continue until the shortrun equilibrium reaches YS and BoP = 0, i.e. with both internal (real, monetary and labour market) and external equilibrium. [The economy ends up at point 2 on the AD-AS diagram.] Summary of final, net effects 1. The price level ends up significantly higher than at its starting level, follow­ ing interrupted years of increase. The expansionary fiscal policy step followed by the AS adjustment has unequivo­ cally increased the average price level. 2. Real income goes through a substantial cyclical up­swing, followed by a down­ swing lasting several years (the whole process lasting perhaps four to seven years on average). In the end, output and income are back where they started, and YS below YFE. 282 Time Y Time P Time Rand BoP Time Demand contraction phase up to 3 years Supply adjustment phase 3–7 years Overall (with overlap): 4–7 years Chapter 6: A model for an inflationary economy: aggregate demand and supply How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 282 2019/12/17 09:15 3. Unemployment decreases below long-run levels for several years, but increases again during the downswing of the AS adjustment phase. It ends up at the same level as when the process started – the structural rate of unemployment (and still below full employment). 4. The balance of payments goes through two successive cycles of surplus, and ends up in balance. 5. The real interest rate goes through two cycles of increase followed by a weaker decline – one each in both the expansion and contraction phases. It should end up higher compared to where it started. 6. The rand appreciates during the second BoP effect of the demand contraction phase, and does so again at the end of the supply adjustment phase. At the end, the rand is much stronger than it was initially. ✍ 6.4.3 The two examples of the impact of monetary and fiscal policy changes built on the IS-LM-BP analysis of chapter 4. Sections 4.5.3 and 4.7.5 in chapter 4 also presented a third demandside example, i.e. an increase in exports (an external disturbance). Complete that example by incorporating price and supply behaviour. Draw an appropriate AD-AS diagram. Supply-side disturbances leading to points off the ASLR curve The analysis of a supply-side disturbance is complex since it affects both the long-run and the short-run aggregate supply relationships (and curves). A decrease in aggregate supply – a so-called supply shock – causes both ASSR and ASLR to shift to the left in tandem, and results in a decrease in Y (a downswing), which is accompanied by an increase in P (see figure 6.24). ❐ Such a change can be caused by output-restricting or cost-raising events such as a drought, or increases in the cost of non-labour inputs, e.g. an increase in the oil price, the price of electricity or an increase in the price of imported inputs due to a depreciation of the rand, for instance. ❐ On the wage-setting side, such a change can result from an increase in union power that is used to secure higher nominal wages during a wage bargain­ing round, or an increase in the legislatively determined minimum wage. The whole process plays out in two phases. Since the long-run supply curve also shifts to the left, the structural equilibrium point relocates to the point (YS2; P2). Simulta­ne­ously, 6.4 Aggregate supply (ASLR, ASSR) and aggregate demand (AD) together How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 283 283 2019/12/17 09:15 the ASSR curve shifts left an Figure 6.24 Supply shock followed by supply adjustment equal distance. The short-run ASLR1 ASSR2 P equilibrium point slides up and ASSR1 to the left along the AD curve. ASSR0 Because of the slide along the Phase 1: AD curve, this new short-run Supply shock P2 shifts both equilibrium is not on ASLR – ASSR and ASLR P 1 output would be at Y1, which is left P0 to the right of YS2. Thus it is not Phase 2: a long-run or sustainable equi­ AD Supply librium because the expected adjustment process shifts price level P e still is at P0, while ASSR up the actual price is already high­ e er than that; thus P ≠ P . The YS2 Y1 YS0 Y YFE normal ASSR supply adjustment process in such a situation will be activated – the second phase of the process. Thus ASSR starts shifting up through an upwardly adjusting expected price P e and a renegotiated nominal wage W, as described in the case of a demand-led expansion above. The short-run equilibrium moves further up and to the left along AD through an upwardly shifting ASSR. This process depresses Y further, combined with a further increase in the price level P. It should continue until the short-run equilibrium reaches ASLR1 at actual price level P2 and income level YS2. ❐ Recall that the second phase in the diagram, where the ASSR curve shifts due to the supply-adjustment process, will be relatively slow (i.e. not instantaneous – it may take approximately three to seven years). This is because it requires the next round of wage setting/bargaining to take place. Only then can the supply adjustment process start, to be followed by yet further rounds of wage setting to complete the adjustment process. ❐ It could thus be several years before the new structural equilibrium point on ASLR1 is reached. A prolonged economic contraction is likely. ❐ Remember that the move of the equilibrium point down along the AD curve is founded in corresponding changes in the IS and LM curves. Similarly, changes on the supply side are founded in changes in the WS, LS and PS curves. (Details of changes in the PS and LS curves are shown in the graphical example in addendum 6.2; also compare addendum 6.4.) ❐ Note that in this case the situation regarding both key variables, income and prices, worsens (and does so in both phases). In the case of demand-side disturbances, the position regarding one variable would worsen while the other would improve ‘in exchange’ (see the preceding graphical examples). A negative supply shock is quite disagreeable for society. Example 3: the short- and medium-run internal and external impacts of an increase in the price of imported inputs (e.g. oil) Primary effect and short-run, demand-side secondary effects: Two simultaneous impacts: (1) Demand-side impact: Higher imported input prices ⇒ if price elasticity of the demand for the product is low (as is the case with oil) ⇒ M increases ⇒ (X – M) decreases ⇒ total domestic expenditure decreases (and the CA into deficit) and output Y as well 284 Chapter 6: A model for an inflationary economy: aggregate demand and supply How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 284 2019/12/17 09:15 as P decreases. As Y decreases, interest rates decline as a sec­ ondary money-market effect, causing an outflow of foreign capital (FA into deficit). ❐ The development of a large initial current account deficit is an important characteristic of this case (in contrast to a domestic supply shock). In the diagram (figure 6.25), AD shifts leftward from AD0 to AD1. A new (P; Y) short-run equilibrium results. Figure 6.25 AD, ASSR, ASLR and an increase in the oil price P ASSR2 AD0 AD1 ASSR1 3 P3 2 P2 P0 P1 0 1 ASLR1 YS1 Y2 Y1 ASLR0 YS0 ASSR0 Supply shock shifts both ASSR and ASLR left. Then supply adjustment process shifts ASSR up Rise in import bill decreases domestic expenditure YFE Y [The economy has moved from point 0 to point 1 on the AS-AD diagram.] (2) Supply-side impact: Higher imported input prices (e.g. oil and petrol) ⇒ increase in costs of production, constrains ability of firms to produce at current price levels ⇒ upward pressure on the average price level P; this simultaneously decreases the real money M supply P , which increases the interest rate and causes investment and thus aggregate expenditure to decline ⇒ output Y starts declining. Thus P starts to increase while Y declines (and thus also M). S Without an IS-LM-BP diagram, one cannot deduce the net effect on the interest rate. It would have increased in phase 2 above, but may still be below the starting point. (Addendum 6.4 contains a complete example that shows the IS-LM-BP curves as well.) While the FA will have recovered, it is still likely to be in a deficit or a small surplus. The CA should have improved somewhat due to the decline in Y (and thus M). Nevertheless, the magnitude of the initial CA deterioration should still dominate, given the relative size of the oil bill (and bearing in mind that the increase in P would curb any CA improvement). Thus we can assume that the BoP is still in deficit when the economy reaches point 2. Graphically, there is a leftward shift of (a) ASSR from ASSR0 to ASSR1 and (b) ASLR from ASLR0 to ASLR1 (see section 6.3.3 if this is not clear). This shows the following things: (a) Through the interaction between ASSR1 and AD1 a temporary equilibrium (P2; Y2) is reached on the AD-AS diagram. (b) The structural equilibrium level of output YS has shifted to a lower level YS1. (c) The average price level P is higher than at the starting point: P2 > P0. [The economy is in the vicinity of point 2 in the diagram.] The expected price level that is embodied in wage contracts is still at its initial level: P e = P0. And Y is lower than before the supply shock occurred. Yet, because YS has shifted to a lower level, we have: Y > YS and P > P e But first there is a BoP deficit that will have short-run effects: (3) Initial BoP effect (foreign reserves adjustment): The BoP deficit and outflow of foreign ex­ change ⇒ money supply decreases ⇒ upward pressure on interest rates ⇒ aggregate demand and expenditure decreases. 6.4 Aggregate supply (ASLR, ASSR) and aggregate demand (AD) together How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 285 285 2019/12/17 09:15 (4) Concluding BoP effect (exchange rate ad­justment): The initial BoP deficit also leads to a depreciation of the rand ⇒ discourage­ment of imports and stimulation of exports ⇒ aggregate expen­diture stimulated. These two effects will return the BoP to a position of balance. Within the AD-AS model it suffices to note the typical AD patterns generated by the two BoP effects following a BoP deficit. First the AD curve shifts left (due to the money supply effect), then the AD curve shifts right (due to the exchange rate effect). ❐ The AD curve zig-zags left then right. Y would decline a bit, then rise again. P would de­cline a bit, then rise again. ❐ The net effect of the two BoP effects on the position of the AD curve and on equilibrium Y and P appears to be rela­tively minor. They are less relevant in the medium-term context of this ex­ample. ❐ Whatever the magni­tude of the two BoP effects, we draw the curve AD1 to show the net effect after both BoP adjustment processes. [The internal equilibrium of the economy has moved to point 2 in the diagram.] After the BoP adjustment effects, at short-run equilibrium point 2, we still have: Y > YS1 and P > P e = P0 The economy still operates at an output level that exceeds the structural, long-run equilibrium, and there is a discrepancy between the expected price level (in wage contracts) and the actual price level. This is not a stable, sustainable equilibrium. A medium-run supply adjustment process must follow. Medium-run secondary effect: (1) Supply adjustment: Because Y > YS and P > P e ⇒ upward pressure on expected prices. These should lead to increased wages in the next rounds of labour negotiations. As these come into effect they increase production costs ⇒ an increase in price level P and a decrease in sales and production Y. Gradually the output level will approach YS. Graphically this is portrayed by an upward shift of ASSR until it intersects the AD curve and ASLR. The increase in P also decreases the real money supply MP , which puts upward pressure on interest rates and dampens demand. S The internal equilibrium moves along the IS and AD curves towards point 3. With interest rates increasing again, now clearly above the starting levels, the FA should go into surplus. The further, cost- and interest-rate induced decrease in income Y (from point 2 to 3) also leads to a decrease in imports, so that the current account should go into surplus. A BoP surplus develops. The normal BoP adjust­ment processes will play out (during which r should decrease some­what and the rand should appreciate; the impact of an increasing P on X and M will assist these proc­esses). All these will then take the BoP back to a position of balance – perhaps caus­ing minor fluctuations in Y on its path towards its final resting point at YS. 286 Chapter 6: A model for an inflationary economy: aggregate demand and supply How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 286 2019/12/17 09:15 Graphically, AD is likely to shift right then left, so we retain AD1 as the likely net position of aggregate demand. These processes continue until the equilibrium is at YS and BoP = 0, i.e. with both internal (real, monetary and labour market) and external equilibrium. This is point 3 on the AD-AS diagram. [The final equilibrium of the economy is at point 3.] Summary of final, net effects: 1. The large initial in­crease in the import bill implies a substitution of imported goods for do­mestic goods. This re­duces domestic expen­ diture, putting down­ ward pressure on prices initially. Yet the price level soon starts to in­crease due to the cost shock. The contraction­ ary effect of the outflow of reserves temporarily brakes the upward mo­ mentum of P, before it resumes a sustained in­crease. 2. Real income (and together with it employ­ ment) decreases significantly. Except for a brief upturn due to the first exchange rate effect of the BoP, it decreases to a new, lower long-run equilibrium level. ✍ Figure 6.26 Illustrative time path of key variables – increase in the oil price r Time Y Time P Time Rand BoP Contraction due to supply shock phase up to 3 years Time Supply adjustment phase 3–7 years Overall (with overlap): 4–7 years Example 3 above analyses the impact of a change in the oil price – a supply-side disturbance (or shock) in the external sector. Supply-side disturbances can also originate within the domestic economy. Examples include unexpected, large changes in labour cost or the price of important other inputs such as electricity. Redo the analysis of example 3 for an internal cost disturbance such as a sudden increase in the price of electricity. Illustrate this on an AD-AS diagram. (Also see the case study in section 6.5.) 6.4 Aggregate supply (ASLR, ASSR) and aggregate demand (AD) together How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 287 287 2019/12/17 09:15 3. The balance of payments first deteriorates due to the increase in the oil import bill. However, later, as part of the medium-run AS effect, it goes into a surplus before adjusting to final equilibrium. 4. The real interest rate first decreases, before it increases significantly. Much later, as part of the last BoP adjustments within the medium-run AS adjustment, it decreases slightly – but still ends up higher than before the shock. 5. The rand first depreciates, before it appreciates later, as part of the BoP-adjustment dimensions of the medium-run AS adjustment. 6.4.4 Combination patterns A supply shock followed by policy stimulation Combinations of patterns can also be found. A pattern that oc­curs frequently is a ‘left-hand upward zig-zag’ due to a supply shock (ASSR and ASLR shift to the left) followed by expansion­ary fiscal or monetary policy (AD shifts to the right) to counteract the contraction. This is shown in figure 6.27. As shown in figure 6.24, the initial shock, followed by a supply adjust­ment, takes the economy to a new equilibrium at YS2 with the price level at P2. Note that the long-run aggre­ gate supply curve has Figure 6.27 Supply shock followed by accommodation moved left to ASLR1 due to the P initial shock. The expan­sionary ASLR1 ASLR0 ASSR3 demand policy then pushes ASSR2 ASSR1 the economy to a point to the ASSR0 right which again is off ASLR1 (combined with an increase in P4 the price level to P3, say). A new Adjustment P3 round of supply adjustment – process then P2 shifts ASSR up which increases the price level again yet again (eventually to P4) P 0 AD1 Policy together with a reversal of the AD0 stimulation policy-led expansion to YS2 – is shifts AD right likely. ❐ The reason for the frequent YS2 YS0 YFE Y occurrence of the latter zigzag pattern is that, as indi­ Understanding the structural equilibrium level cated earlier, a supply shock leaves the economy with twin The level of structural employment, i.e. YS, can problems: more unemploy­ now unambiguously be understood as the level ment plus an increas­ing price around which cyclical disturbances, fluctuations and level. Political pressure and/or adjustments in Y occur (see box on unemployment socio-economic considerations on page 260). It is the output level (together with its price level PS ) from which the ‘gravitational pull’ that often persuade a govern­ment we have been speaking about is exerted. In other to adopt unemploy­ment as the words, YS is the cyclically neutral level of income (and first priority of policy, and to employment). stimulate aggregate expendi­ ture. Nevertheless, its own position is not permanent, since ❐ This is called the ‘accomit can also be shifted around due to economic factors and forces. modation’ of the supply shock. 288 Chapter 6: A model for an inflationary economy: aggregate demand and supply How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 288 2019/12/17 09:15 The problem with such accommo­da­tion is that, in exchange for what turns out to be only temporary higher GDP and employ­ment, the country has to endure a further increase in the price level – followed by yet another downswing-plus-price-increase phase due to the fact that the long-run structural equilibrium has relocated to a lower level. (This policy dilemma is discussed again in chapter 12, section 12.1.) Government or business investment leading to supply expansion It was noted above that real Figure 6.28 Supply expansion due to investment investment expenditure, either P ASLR0 ASLR1 by government, public corpora­ Equilibrium tions and government entities after supply or the private sector, has two growth and ASSR2 supply creases aggregate effects. It in­ adjustment ASSR0 demand in the short run (and ASSR1 P2 Equilibrium thus shifts the AD curve to the P1 after demand right); and it boosts produc­ stimulation P0 tive capacity in the medium to long run. As shown in the AD1 AD0 diagram (figure 6.28) it thus gether shifts the ASLR curve to­ with the ASSR curve to the right. YS Y2 Y1 Y YFE Thus there is a com­ bination of a positive supply shock and a de­mand stimulation. Depending on the speed and magni­tude of the relative shifts of the AD and AS curves, the new short-run equilibrium may be on, to the left of, or to the right of the new ASLR1 curve (shown in figure 6.28). If it is off the ASLR curve, it may be followed by supply-adjustment processes until the short-run equilibrium set­tles on the new, augmented ASLR1 2 at point (P2; Y2). ❐ It is important to note that – compared to a standard non-investment aggregate demand stimulation (see example 2 above) – the price level increases by less and that there is a net increase in the long-run, structural equilibrium output to Y2. ❐ This will be important when discussing the determinants of economic growth, which is graphically equivalent to a steadily outward shifting ASLR curve and a steadily increasing structural equilibrium output YS. ❐ This example also relates to the discussion of the Phillips curve in chapter 7 and the pros and cons of government expenditure to stimulate growth in chapter 10. ❐ Expenditure on new technology and human capital would have similar effects to those shown above. ❐ This example also alerts one to the importance of supply-directed policies of a structural nature – rather than anti-cyclical demand policy – to effect outward shifts in the longrun output level and thus achieve sustained reductions in structural unemployment. 6.4 Aggregate supply (ASLR, ASSR) and aggregate demand (AD) together How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 289 289 2019/12/17 09:15 YS and the rate of unemployment in a growing economy The preceeding diagrams show how the long-run, structural equilibrium level of real income YS shifts right or left over time due to different economic factors. A YS that continually shifts to the right implies steady economic growth. It is important to understand how that relates to the rate of unemployment. An increase in the structural equilibrium level of output implies higher levels of employment N. However, the rate of unemployment U will depend on what has been happening with the labour force (LF) (as well as technology and labour intensity/productivity) over time. Recall that: (LF – N) LF U = _______ A growing YS and growing employment N does not necessarily imply that the rate of unemployment is declining over time. With a growing population and labour force, a growing YS is necessary to absorb new entrants into the labour market to prevent the unemployment rate from rising. However, the absorption of labour also depends on the extent to which the growth in YS is due to productivity-enhancing technological progress. ❐ If YS grows steadily at the same rate as the labour force, but a major cause of this growth is productivity-enhancing technological progress, the long-run or structural rate of unemployment (SRU) could actually increase. A YS that grows at the same rate as the labour force would produce an unchanging long-run or structural unemployment rate (SRU) only if technology is not augmenting labour productivity. ❐ If YS grows at a rate higher than the growth in the labour force, but this relatively higher rate is not primarily due to improved technology (i.e. higher labour productivity), it would mean that the output growth is the result of increased employment or labour absorption. Thus the long-run or structural rate of unemployment (SRU) would decline. ❐ The structural dimensions of unemployment imply that changes in YS on their own are not sufficient. For more on this, see section 12.2 in chapter 12. ✍ The world financial crisis of 2007–08: aggregate supply and price level effects We introduced this case study at the end of chapter 3 and followed up in chapter 4. Recall the context briefly. The world economy was shattered by the so-called subprime credit crisis in the USA that came to a head in September–October 2008. It led to the failure of several banks in the USA (and other countries), and a serious credit shortage ensued. Economic confidence disappeared, durable consumer expenditure and residential (and other) investment dropped. The US economy hit a recession, and many businesses, e.g. the Big Three motor companies in the USA, faced serious financial ruin. (These recessionary conditions spread to the UK, Europe and Japan, for example.) In reaction to this, the US government increased government expenditure (including national infrastructure investment) to restore confidence, create jobs and rebuild the economy, and fend off the threat of deflation. The Federal Reserve also backed up the banking sector, reduced the bank rate to stimulate credit creation and introduced several rounds of quantitative easing. Now analyse these fiscal and monetary policy steps with the additional analytical tools and insights acquired in this chapter. Focus especially on the aggregate demand and aggregate supply effects, and thus the joint impact on GDP as well as the average price level. 290 ⇒ Chapter 6: A model for an inflationary economy: aggregate demand and supply How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 290 2019/12/17 09:15 ⇒ ✍ Hint: First consider the initial shock in the AD-AS model and then the policy response. Also consider whether any supply adjustment processes take place or can be expected to take place. Second, go back and try to analyse the underlying developments in the real and monetary sectors (or use the IS-LM-BP diagram). Third, try to analyse events in the labour market (the WS-PS framework). What are probable or possible explanations for: ❐ increasing prices? ____________________________________________________________________________________ ____________________________________________________________________________________ ____________________________________________________________________________________ ____________________________________________________________________________________ ❐ decreasing prices? ____________________________________________________________________________________ ____________________________________________________________________________________ ____________________________________________________________________________________ ____________________________________________________________________________________ ❐ increasing prices combined with an upswing? ____________________________________________________________________________________ ____________________________________________________________________________________ ____________________________________________________________________________________ ____________________________________________________________________________________ ❐ increasing prices combined with a downswing? ____________________________________________________________________________________ ____________________________________________________________________________________ ____________________________________________________________________________________ ____________________________________________________________________________________ ❐ increasing prices with a constant level of Y? ____________________________________________________________________________________ ____________________________________________________________________________________ ____________________________________________________________________________________ ____________________________________________________________________________________ 6.4.5 Can this theory explain the course of the South African economy? The Keynesian framework developed in these chapters can be used to try to explain different observed patterns in the macroeconomy. While this largely constitutes ‘enlightened guesswork’ in hindsight, one can attempt to explain the course of the average price level P and real GDP Y in the South African economy over the last decades. 6.4 Aggregate supply (ASLR, ASSR) and aggregate demand (AD) together How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 291 291 2019/12/17 09:15 Figure 6.29 Output fluctuations and the price level in South Africa 2018 2009 2008 2003 Average price level (log scale) 1997 1993 1989 1986 1981 1977 1974 –5 –4 –3 –2 –1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 Real GDP (% deviation from long-run AS) Source: South African Reserve Bank (www.resbank.co.za), and authors’ own calculations. Consider the graph in figure 6.29 representing data on the South African economy since 1970. The graph plots the (log of the) CPI index against the deviation of output from its long-run trend. Thus it is comparable to the AD-AS framework with P and Y on the axes. The graph period includes the major recession that followed the substantial increase in oil prices by the OPEC oil cartel in 1973. It also shows the recession after 1981 and 1989. The economy reached a trough in 1993, whereafter output increased and exceeded trend output. However, also note that, after the Asian crisis in 1998 and the rather severe depreciation of the rand in 2001, output fell slightly below the trend. After the latter deterioration it improved for several years, reaching a peak in 2007–08. However, in 2009 the economy experienced a deep recession following the fall-out from the global financial crisis. At the time of writing (2019), the South African economy was stuck in a long period of very low economic growth. The question is: can shifts in AD and AS, and related adjustment processes that result in changes in the equilibrium level of Y and P, map out a path that approximates the behaviour of the real South African economy? Or, can the latter path be explained by finding appropriate shifts in AD and AS that can be traced back to actual policy steps or other disturbances? 292 Chapter 6: A model for an inflationary economy: aggregate demand and supply How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 292 2019/12/17 09:15 We will not provide such a comprehensive explanation now. It is left to the reader. What one can and must do is to identify periods such as the following: (1) demand pull; (2) cost push; (3) cost push followed by accommodation (stimulation); (4) demand stimulation followed by supply adjustment towards long-run supply; and (5) simultaneous demand pull and cost push. Can you identify such periods in the graph? Once that is done, one can search – among the determinants of AD and AS – for those potential determinants that were active at specific points in time. Doing so would identify the likely causes of the changes in AD and AS, and thus of Y and P. This would constitute a probable explanation of the course of the South African economy during the past two decades. 6.4.6 A comprehensive explanation of the consequences of economic disturbances The entire modern Keynesian macroeconomic theoretical model is now almost complete. This is apparent from the complete circular flow diagram earlier in this chapter. We have considered the role of, and linkages between, all the major macroeconomic variables. We have considered their behaviour and complex interrelationships in the short and the medium term. The likely causes or consequences of changes in these variables can be indicated with a reasonable degree of certainty. The model can be used to predict, albeit only roughly, the expected consequences of any real or monetary, internal or external disturbance, including adjustment towards the long-run supply curve. Graphically, the model has been set out in a series of diagrams (see figure 6.30). It started with the 45° model and its link to the monetary sector. This was then summarised in the IS-LM model, or the IS-LM-BP model in the open-economy context. Finally, we derived the AD-AS model, which summarised the initial three-diagram model and the IS-LM dynamics in the AD curve, and added two AS curves. Together, these diagrams enable one to trace the consequence of a real, monetary, internal or external disturbance through the (open) economy. We can see how it impacts on interest rates and exchange rates and several real and monetary economic variables along the way, often initiating complex adjustment processes – until it ends with a final impact on the price level and output/income. Note that in many cases the supply-adjustment process will appear to be inoperative. This is because of the length of time it takes – from three to seven years – and the frequent occurrence of new disturbances or policy steps that override the adjustment. Truth or theory? Remember that this is still only a theory of the way the economy works. While it is sophisticated, and the product of the work of highly regarded theorists and economic scientists, including Nobel Prize winners, it should never be regarded as the absolute Truth (with a capital T). No theory or science can ever be that. Human knowledge and insight are and always will be limited, should be regarded as provisional, and should be used unpretentiously and in full awareness of their fallibility. Therefore one often focuses on the initial impact on the AD-AS diagram, largely leaving the sup­ ply adjustment process out of consideration – especially in cases where the BoP adjustment process is of greater importance. Nevertheless, one should always be aware of the underlying forces of the AS adjustment process. 6.4 Aggregate supply (ASLR, ASSR) and aggregate demand (AD) together How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 293 293 2019/12/17 09:15 Figure 6.30 The whole model – monetary and real sectors, aggregate demand and aggregate supply Monetary sector Real sector Transmission mechanism r r M P S E ASLR P ASSR C+I+Gc+X–M MD P Money AD I I Y Y Feedback mechanism NOTE •Monetary changes are transmitted to the real sector via the interest-investment link (a left-to-right causality). • Real sector changes include aggregate income (Y) as well as the average price level (P). •Changes in the real sector (Y, P) have secondary, feedback effects on the monetary sector via the demand for money (a right to left, indirect causality). •The first impact of monetary policy is in the monetary sector, while the first impact of fiscal policy is in the real sector. This model enables one to consider and analyse specific problem areas of macroeconomics. The first of these is macroeconomic policy; the second, the problems of inflation, un­em­ ploy­ment and low growth. These will be discussed in chapters 9 to 12. However, the above model, though rather extensive, still needs one bit of upgrading to represent a complete model for the modern era: it needs to be adapted for a world where inflation is a permanent feature. Whereas this chapter introduced the aggregate price level and changes in the price level, the next chapter extends the model to situate it in a world where price increases are not one-off occurrences, but a permanent feature. 6.5 Real-world application – the Eskom crisis, GDP and prices Section 6.4.4 describes how investment by government and the private sector expands the long-run capacity of the economy. Graphically this expansion was represented by a rightward shift of both the long-run and short-run AS curves. In the period after 2008, South Africa had a striking experience of this kind – although it was in the reverse direction and a bad experience! The run-up: Eskom shocks the country with blackouts (or ‘load shedding’) State-owned electricity producer Eskom, which declared its fourth power emergency of the 2013/14 summer maintenance season on Thursday morning, began implementing load shedding from 9:00, causing shops to shut, disrupting cellular networks and raising fresh concerns about the constraint being placed on South Africa’s already poor growth outlook by the country’s electricity shortages. Mining Weekly, 6 March 2014 294 Chapter 6: A model for an inflationary economy: aggregate demand and supply How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 294 2019/12/17 09:15 In 2007 Eskom suddenly announced that, with electricity reserves running lower than 8% in some areas, they would need to implement a blackout schedule – euphemistically called ‘load shedding’ – from 2008 onward to prevent crashing the entire national electricity grid. They also announced that, following years of underfunding by the government, they faced a huge longer-term generation capacity problem and would need to build several new power stations – but that it could take several years (and cost billions of rands). To ‘solve’ the problem in the interim, Eskom put pressure on mines, aluminium smelters and large factories to cut back on their electricity usage. To achieve the desired 10% reduction in electricity consumption, many had to cut back on production. Retail and other businesses suffered losses and many had to buy diesel generators to carry them through blackout periods. Planned – and often unplanned – maintenance on ageing power stations and other equipment contributed to a bad period for the economy with regard to a vital input. The disruptions had a very negative effect on business confidence and appear to have discouraged foreign direct investment in South Africa. The year 2008 alone is estimated to have cost the economy R50 billion in lost production. In 2012, Eskom once again warned that rolling blackouts may happen. This pattern continued on and off until the time of writing (2019), despite the fact that Kusile and Medupi, two coal power stations being built in Mpumalanga and Limpopo respectively, were supposed to be on stream by 2017. (The fact that the construction of these power stations had again fallen behind schedule and suffered from construction faults that prevented them from operating at full capacity, further increased business and consumer anxiety.) Moreover, to help fund its capital expenses, Eskom started to increase electricity tariffs significantly. Having had average annual price increases of just above 5% since 2000, from 2008 tariffs were increased by, on average, 27% per year for four years. After that it was restricted by Nersa (the official regulator) to 16% and then 8% per year. By 2019 electricity tariffs had increased by more than 300% within ten years. By 2019 Eskom also accumulated debt of almost half a trillion rand, equal to almost 10% of GDP, imposing a heavy interest burden on the company and necessitating continual government bail-outs. On a macroeconomic level, as shown in the diagrams in chapter 1, the period under discussion is characterised by upward pressure on the average price level since 2010 (i.e. several increases in the inflation rate) plus a decline in the GDP growth rate since 2011. While many factors have probably contributed to this course of events – e.g. increases in the dollar price of oil from 2009 to 2014, coupled with a decline in the real effective exchange rate of the rand since early 2011 – the Eskom problems appear to have had a noticeable impact on both the GDP rate of growth and the rate of inflation. At the very least Eskom is a substantial part of the explanation of events. Understanding the slowdown in GDP growth and upward pressure on the average price level since 2008 The AD-AS model can be used to get a clear analytical grasp of how this could have occurred. There are two blows stemming from Eskom: 1. A bottleneck in electricity output (i.e. in the flow of electricity), which repeatedly causes cost increases in production processes (lost production, damage to machinery, workers and machines being unproductive during blackouts, switch-on costs of factories after blackouts, having to install diesel generators and so forth), as well as major increases in electricity tariffs. 6.5 Real-world application – the Eskom crisis, GDP and prices How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 295 295 2019/12/17 09:15 2. A backlog in Eskom’s long-term electricity generation capacity. This delays and discourages private investment in productive capacity (factories, mines, infrastructure, etc.), thereby constraining the growth in the country’s overall capital stock and productive capacity in the medium to long run. (If Eskom’s construction of expensive new power stations is delayed, that in itself would constitute an additional reduction in real investment.) Both of these are considered in the following discussion in the context of a situation with a steadily growing GDP. This enables us to see the medium- to long-term effects of the two Eskom-related problems. Figure 6.32 shows their combined impact on output Y and the price level P over several years. ❐ The bottom diagram shows a base run with steadily growing output and income levels due to steadily growing aggregate demand and aggregate supply – i.e. a steadily increasing structural equilibrium output YS resulting from a steadily outward-shifting AD together with ASLR (with ASST tagging along). The equilibrium price level P remains constant. ❐ The top diagram shows how the course of equilibrium Y and P is affected by Eskom’s output and capacity constraints: Y expands less per year and the price level P increases. The top path in figure 6.32 is a combination of the following: ❐ a supply, or cost, shock (see figure 6.24), and ❐ the supply (and demand) effects of a decline in investment (compare figure 6.28). This path will be explained by first analysing changes in a single year and then inserting that analysis into a longer-term, steady-growth situation. Unpacking the Eskom effects for a single year As a first step, figure 6.31 zooms in on an interval between two points in time, i.e. the year 0 (when the Eskom problems start, approximately 2008) and year 1, when the impact is felt. Nevertheless, we keep the context of a steadily outward-shifting AD and ASLR in mind. In figure 6.31 we start in year 0 at point 0 where AD0 and ASLR0 intersect. In the absence of any Eskom problems, AD and ASLR would have shifted to AD1* and ASLR1* and generated equilibrium point a with income at Y1* and the price level constant at P0. However, the supply shock of load shedding (which causes cost increases and production cutbacks) and higher tariffs implies that the expansion of aggregate supply is being constrained. There is a negative supply shock on both long-term and short-term aggregate supply: ASLR and ASSR shift left (in tandem) relative to where they would have been in the absence of the shock. Secondly, the discouragement of investment has two effects. First, it holds back aggregate demand (AD) growth – AD only shifts to AD1 (indicated by the dotted blue arrow) and not all the way to AD1*. Secondly, and importantly, it causes a negative impact on the growth of the capital stock and the expansion of productive capacity. This causes a negative impact on the expansion of aggregate supply (ASLR). The combined negative supply-side effects imply that the long-term aggregate supply curve actually shifts only from ASLR0 to ASLR1 (as indicated by the solid blue arrow). (In other words, compared to where it would have been without the Eskom supply shock, ASLR ends up in a more leftward position – it has ‘shifted’ left in relative terms, as has ASSR). Combined with a constrained AD shifting rightwards only to AD1 it means that the economy would converge on point b. 296 Chapter 6: A model for an inflationary economy: aggregate demand and supply How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 296 2019/12/17 09:15 Figure 6.31 The impact of Eskom bottlenecks on GDP growth and prices: decomposing the changes of a single year ASLR0 ASLR1 ASLR1* P Equilibrium after supply constriction, the drop in investment (demand) and the ASSR adjustment ASSR1 ASSR0 ASSR1* P1 P0 1 b a 0 Equilibrium after supply constriction and a drop in investment – but before ASSR adjustment Equilibrium if no Eskom problems AD0 YS0 Y1 AD1 Y1* AD1* Y However, since this point is not on the vertical ASLR1, it would not be an equilibrium point. Price expectations will come into play and cause ASSR to adjust, shifting ASSR upwards to ASSR1 and taking the economy to an equilibrium at point 1, with income at Y1 and the price level having increased to P1. The net effect is that the increase in equilibrium income (from YS0 to Y1) in that year ends up being smaller than it would have been, were it not for the Eskom problems – and the price level P ends up being higher. The economy has moved from point 0 to point 1 (see the curved blue arrow) instead of point a. Repeated Eskom problems leading to ongoing growth and inflation problems Since these Eskom problems have recurred in the subsequent years, this pattern has repeated itself several times. Figure 6.32 shows the cumulative effect of a series of years such as that of figure 6.31 (without showing the smaller annual adjustments) compared to a base run where no Eskom problems occur. Key to this sequence is that, following the Eskom shocks in year 0, from year 1 onward the net annual rightward shifts of ASLR and AD are smaller than before. The result is a series of smaller annual steps in Y (i.e. a drop in the GDP growth rate) and continued upward movements in the average price level P (i.e. a higher rate of inflation). 6.5 Real-world application – the Eskom crisis, GDP and prices How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 297 297 2019/12/17 09:15 Growth is being choked, coupled with upward pressure on prices, on a path indicated by the curved row of equilibrium dots (upper half of figure 6.32). If the cost shocks come to an end, the increases in P should level off within a few years, for example by year 7 or 8 (i.e. the rate of inflation will decline again). ❐ Note that, for example by year 8 (i.e. 2016/7 in reality), Y would be much lower than in the base run – i.e. much lower than it would have been, had the Eskom shocks and backlogs not occurred. The Eskom problems would have had a large, permanent impact on the level of GDP. ❐ If Eskom’s capacity problem remains, growth of GDP would continue steadily from there on, but at the lower rate. ❐ If Eskom resolves the problem, the rate of growth could return to higher levels. ❐ If new problems recur, a pattern of still slower growth and a yet further increasing price level would repeat itself. While the diagram is only a stylised depiction of the post-2008 experience with Eskom, it provides a powerful analysis and explanation of the performance of the South African economy in this period – even though it is not the only explanation. Figure 6.32 The impact of Eskom bottlenecks on GDP growth and prices (medium- to long-term effects) P AD-2 AD-1 ASLR-2 ASLR-1 ASLR1 ASLR0 ASLR2 AD0 AD1 AD2 ASSR-2 AS AS SR0 SR-1 ASSR2 P8 P4 P0 ? Y-2 P Y0 Y1 Y2 Y3 Y-1 ASLR-2 ASLR-1 Y8 Y ASLR1 ASLR2 ASLR0 AD-2 AD-1 AD0 AD1 AD2 In years 1 and 2 the annual shift of ASLR to the right gets smaller. Thus the annual increase in YS declines. Growth is being choked, coupled with upward pressure on costs and prices. • By year 8, Y is much lower than in the base run (below). • Growth in Y will continue at the lower rate until Eskom solves the capacity problem. ASSR-2 ASSR-1 AS ASSR1 AS SR2 SR0 In this base run, the annual increase in YS is constant. Growth is steady and there is no upward pressure on costs and prices. • By year 8, Y is much higher than in the Eskom-constrained run. P1 Y-2 298 Y-1 Y0 Y1 Y2 Y3 Y8 Y Chapter 6: A model for an inflationary economy: aggregate demand and supply How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 298 2019/12/17 09:15 6.6 Analytical questions and exercises 1. It is often argued that the introduction of the Labour Relations Act has restricted the ability of businesses to lay off employees, making it more difficult for firms to reduce their labour costs in order to stay profitable. Use the price-setting (PS) and wagesetting (WS) relations to explain and illustrate how such a restriction can impact the long-run (or structural) rate of unemployment. 2. Suppose the productivity of South African workers increases due to better skills development. Use the price-setting (PS) and wage-setting (WS) relations to explain and illustrate the impact of higher productivity on the long-run rate of unemployment. 3. Use the AS-AD model to explain and illustrate the short-run and long-run impact, on the aggregate price level and the level of national income, of the overall change in the repo rate since 2007. 4. Turmoil in the Middle East, especially tension between the USA and Iran, has raised the spectre of major increases in the price of oil again (following such a period in 2008–09). Use the AS-AD model to explain and illustrate the expected impact on the economy of an oil-dependent country such as South Africa. 5. US President Trump signed large cuts in corporate tax into law in December 2017. He has also put pressure on the US Federal Reserve to reduce interest rates further. Use the AS-AD model to explain and illustrate the expected short-run and long-run impact on the aggregate price level and the level of national income of South Africa due to these policy steps in the USA. 6. ‘The flight from risk, by investors, has led to the depreciation of emerging countries’ currencies. South Africa’s rand depreciated due to the sale of shares and bonds by foreigners – almost R70 billion in the first six months of 2019. The weak rand is likely to result in an increase in the petrol price.’ Use the price-setting (PS) and wage-setting (WS) relations to explain and also illustrate, in a diagram, the impact of an increase in the petrol price. Clearly indicate the impact on the long-run rate of unemployment and the aggregate price level. Also indicate diagrammatically how this will shift the ASLR curve. 7. Suppose the annual rise in the consumer price index (CPI) increases to well outside the 3–6% official range targeted by the Reserve Bank, with direct implications for decisions on the repo rate. There would be good reasons for the Bank to apply a restrictive policy. Use the AS-AD model to explain and illustrate the short-run and long-run impact on the aggregate price level and the level of national income if the Reserve Bank implemented such a restrictive monetary policy. 8. Use the price-setting (PS) and wage-setting (WS) relations to explain and illustrate the impact of more stringent labour laws on the South African economy. Clearly indicate the expected impact on the unemployment rate. Also indicate diagrammatically how this will shift the ASLR curve. 9. In 2014 the government introduced a youth wage subsidy, also known as the Employment Tax Incentive Act (ETI), to encourage companies to employ more young employees. Use the price-setting (PS) and wage-setting (WS) relations to explain and illustrate the likely impact of the implementation of such a subsidy. Clearly indicate the expected impact on employment and the unemployment rate. Also indicate diagrammatically how this will shift the ASLR curve. What is the evidence regarding the success of this subsidy in increasing youth employment? (Consult the internet as necessary.) 6.6 Analytical questions and exercises How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 299 299 2019/12/17 09:15 Addendum 6.1: Labour market changes following demand stimulation This is an extension of the example of demand stimulation followed by aggregate supply adjustment in section 6.4.2. It should be read together with that text, plus the following to explain events in the labour market. ❐ In the expansion phase, the LS curveWshifts down to LS1. WS remains stationary because P e has not changed. The real wage drops to P because of the increase in actual price to P1; employment increases to N1. ❐ As the ASSR adjustment starts, Pe and the renegotiated nominal wage increases (to W1) to match W up with price P1. However, the actual price has already risen above P1 to P2. The new real wage P is still lower than the starting real wage. But the real wage has recovered some of the ground lost due to the demand stimulus and unanticipated price level increase. Employment drops due to the adjustment of ASSR, but not yet as far back as its starting value NS. LS would have shifted back to LS2, reflecting effective labour supply at fixed nominal wage W1 for the duration of the renegotiated labour contract. ❐ Since the equilibrium is not yet on ASLR the adjustment continues. In the end, when ASLR is reached, the nominal wage will be at W3 to match up with the final price level P3. The final expected price P e will equal the final actual price P3, but obviously at a higher level than initially. W W The real wage would have recovered all the way so that P = P . Employment drops yet further, back to its starting level at NS, the structural equilibrium level of employment. 0 1 1 2 3 3 Y 0 0 Y TP 45° line Y1 YS NS N1 W W P 3 = P 0 3 N P W P YS ASLR WS P3 0;2 LS0;3 0 LS2 W1 P 2 W0 P 1 1 LS1 2 ASSR2 ASSR1 1 0 AD1 PS NS 300 N1 Y ASSR0 P2 P1 P0 Y1 AD0 N YS Y1 Y Chapter 6: A model for an inflationary economy: aggregate demand and supply How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 300 2019/12/17 09:15 Addendum 6.2: Labour market details following a domestic supply shock This is an extension of the example of domestic supply shock followed by aggregate supply adjustment in section 6.4.3. It should be read together with that text, plus the following to explain what happens in the labour market. ❐ As the supply shock occurs, the PS curve shifts down due to an increase in the mark-up to compensate for the increased non-labour input costs. Because the price level P increases (to W P1) to reflect the higher input costs, the LS curve shifts down to LS1. The real wage drops to P because of the increase in actual price to P1 while the initially contracted nominal wage W0 is still in place. The new short-run equilibrium is at employment level N1, reflecting a drop in employment due to the supply shock as such. ❐ As the ASSR adjustment starts, P e and the renegotiated nominal wage increases (to W1) to match W up with price P1. However, the actual price has already risen above P1 to P2. The new real wage P W is still lower than the starting real wage P . But the real wage has recovered some of the ground lost due to the supply shock and unanticipated price level increase. Employment drops further below N1 due to the ASSR adjustment, but it is not yet at the long-run level NS. LS would have shifted back to LS2, reflecting effective labour supply at fixed nominal wage W1 for the duration of the renegotiated labour contract. ❐ Since the equilibrium is not yet on ASLR the adjustment continues. In the end, when ASLR is reached, the nominal wage will be at W3 to match up with the final price level P3. The final expected price P e will equal the final actual price P3, but obviously at a higher level than initially. Through the Wincreases in the levels at which W is set and P is set, the real wage would have W recovered to P which is lower than P . Employment drops yet further, back to the new, postshock structural equilibrium level at N2. 0 1 1 2 0 0 3 0 3 0 TP Y N2 N1 N0 45° line Y N YS2 Y W P PS0 ASLR1 Y1 YS0 ASLR0 W0 LS0 P 0 W3 P3 W1 LS3 P P3 P2 P1 P0 Phase 1: Supply shock shifts both ASSR and ASLR left LS2 2 W0 P AD LS1 1 NS N1 N0 N ASSR2 ASSR1 AS SR0 WS PS1 Y YS2 Y1 YS0 Phase 2: Supply adjustment process shifts ASSR up Y Addendum 6.2: Labour market details following a domestic supply shock How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 301 301 2019/12/17 09:15 Addendum 6.3: A complete example of IS-LM-BP and AD-AS for an increase in the repo rate The case of a repo rate increase has been explained several times. ❐ In chapter 4 (section 4.7.5) the IS-LM-BP analysis was shown, still under the as­ sumption of a constant price level P, to produce equilib­ rium values of r and Y. ❐ In section 6.2.5 the diagram of section 4.7.5 was used to show how the AD curve would shift in line with the change in the IS-LM equilib­ rium point. ❐ Section 6.4.2 finally showed that same, shifting AD curve together with AS curves, generating changing equi­ librium values of P and Y. The direct correspondence be­ tween changes in the IS-LM-BP model and the AD-AS model are shown alongside in one set of diagrams. ❐ Note how the short-run equilib­rium points 1 to 3 in the IS-LM-BP diagram have their exact counterparts in the AD-AS dia­gram. ❐ Thus one can see, together with the changes in Y and P, what happens to the real interest rate r as well as the balance of payments (BoP). r LM1 LM2 LM3 LM0 LM4 1 r1 BP1 2 r3 r0 BP0 BP2 0 3 4 IS1 IS0 IS2 Y P AD1 AD3 AD2 AD0 ASLR ASSR0 ASSR1 P0 P3 2 1 0 3 P4 4 Y1 Y3 Y2 One important thing to notice is that the shifts of the LM curve are NOT the same as the original shifts in section 4.7.5 or in 6.2.5. Y0 YFE Y This is because the move of the equilibrium along the ASSR curve – from point 0 to 1 and back to 2 and 3 – implies changes in the price level P. This impacts correspond­ingly on the real money supply MP , which affects the position of the LM curve. ❐ The leftward shift from LM0 to LM1 is re­strained by the decrease of P from P0 to P1. Thus LM1 shows the net shift in LM. Likewise, the shift from LM1 to LM2 is restrained by the increase of P to P2. LM2 shows the net shift in LM. ❐ The LM shifts to position LM3 when P declines from P2 to P3. (Points 2 and 3 are not on the same LM curve.) S MS P , which shifts the LM curve right. Due to a When P declines from point 3 to point 4, it increases BoP deficit that develops, the BP and IS curves will also shift to the right. This takes the economy to point 4 on both diagrams. 302 Chapter 6: A model for an inflationary economy: aggregate demand and supply How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 302 2019/12/17 09:15 Addendum 6.4: A complete example of IS-LM-BP and AD-AS for an increase in the price of imported inputs (e.g. oil) The analysis of an oil price increase was provided in section 6.4.3. The purpose here is to show the corres­ ponding changes in the ISLM-BP diagram, notably its power in showing the rather complex behaviour of the BoP and its con­ stituent components, the CA and FA. Thus we con­ centrate on the graphical analysis – which is quite complex and requires care­ ful scrutiny. r LM4 LM5 LM3 LM2 LM0 LM1 BP1&3 r5 r7 r0 r2 r1 5 7 BP2 6 4 3 BP0 0 2 1 IS0 IS2 IS1&3 From point 0 to point 1: P AD3&5 ASSR2 AD The decrease in domestic AD1&4 0 AD2 expenditure causes the IS and BP curves to shift left from IS0 to IS1 and BP0 to 7 BP1, while the LM curve P7 momentarily shifts right to LM1 due to the decline in 2 M P4 P (and increase in P ). The P0 4 1 0 3 IS-LM intersection moves P1 left, and AD shifts the same horizontal distance left from AD0 to AD1. The equilibrium moves from ASLR1 ASLR0 point 0 to point 1 on both the IS-LM-BP and ADYS1 Y3 Y4 Y1 YS0 AS diagrams. This point is below the BP1 curve, indicating that a BoP deficit has developed (CA and FA in deficit). Y ASSR1 ASSR0 S YFE Y From point 1 to point 2: As supply contracts, Y decreases while P increases; thus MP decreases. LM starts shifting left. Given the slopes of IS and LM, the net effect on the interest rate from the starting point is still negative: r2 < r0. While the FA should recover, it is still likely in a deficit. CA should have improved due to the decline in Y, but the magnitude of the initial CA deficit still dominates, given size of oil bill (and bearing in mind that the increase in P would curb any CA improvement). The BoP is still in deficit. S There has been a leftward shift of (a) ASSR from ASSR0 to ASSR1 and (b) ASLR from ASLR0 to ASLR1. This shows the following things: Addendum 6.4: A complete example for an increase in the price of oil How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 303 303 2019/12/17 09:15 (a) Through the interaction between ASSR1 and AD1 a temporary equilibrium (P2; Y2) is reached at point 2 on the AD-AS diagram. (b) The structural equilibrium level of output YS has shifted to a lower level. (c) The average price level P is higher than at the starting point: P2 > P0. From point 2 to points 3 and 4: Initial BoP effect (foreign reserves adjustment): Graphically, the net decrease in the money supply will reflect as a shift in LM to the left from LM2 to LM3 (partly restrained by a decrease in P from P2 to P3). Internal equilibrium moves to point 3. AD shifts left to AD2. Concluding BoP effect (exchange rate adjustment): IS and BP move to the right from IS1 to IS2 and BP1 to BP2. An internal and external short-run equilibrium will be reached at point 4. In the AS-AD diagram, AD will shift to the right from AD2 to AD3 with the equilibrium also reaching point 4. At short-run equilibrium point 4, we still have: Y > YS and P > P e A medium-run supply adjustment process follows. From point 4 to point 5 (only shown on IS-LM-BP diagram): Supply adjustment: Graphically, ASSR shifts upward until it intersects the AD curve and ASLR. M The increase in P de­creases P and LM shifts left to LM4. The equilibrium moves up along IS and AD towards points 5 and 7 respec­tively. With r now above starting levels, FA moves into a surplus. The cost- and interest-rate induced de­crease in income Y from point 4 to 5 also de­creases M, so CA moves into surplus. BoP surplus de­velops. S From point 5 to point 6 (only shown on IS-LM-BP diagram) and 7: Normal BoP adjust­ment processes, during which r decreases and the rand appreciates; (impact of in­creasing P on X and M will assist BoP proc­esses). BoP back to po­sition of balance. The money supply effect will see LM and AD shift right to LM5 and AD4 (al­most at the position of AD1). After that IS, BP and AD will shift left to IS3 (almost at the posi­tion of IS1), BP3 (almost at the position of BP1) and AD5 (almost back at the position of AD3). On the IS-LM-BP dia­gram the equilibrium moves from 5 to 6 to 7. (For visual ease, we draw these closely posi­tioned lines superimposed.) On the AD-AS diagram only the net effect is shown. While all the shifts are not shown, the typical right-then-left shift of AD will be present in the BoP adjustment phases of the final stages of the ASSR adjustment. AD3 as shown must thus be understood as the final position of AD. P and Y ends at (P7; YS1), following perhaps minor fluctuations in Y on its path towards its final resting point on ASLR. The process ends at point 7 where there is both internal (real, monetary and labour market) and external (BoP) equilibrium. 304 Chapter 6: A model for an inflationary economy: aggregate demand and supply How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 304 2019/12/17 09:15 Extending the model: inflation and policy reactions 7 After reading this chapter, you should be able to: ■ demonstrate how an adapted AD-AS framework can be used to show how the rate of inflation is determined together with real GDP, i.e. to analyse economic fluctuations in an inflationary environment; ■ use the Phillips (or PC) curve to assess and analyse possible short-run and long-run relationships between inflation and GDP; ■ evaluate the relevance of the Phillips-curve debate for anti-inflation policy, and assess arguments on whether policies can or cannot be used to manage inflation; and ■ analyse and compare typical central bank policy reactions to steer the inflation rate to a target value, including the costs and benefits of a radical, as opposed to a gradualist, approach to reducing inflation. The previous chapter showed various cases of demand and supply disturbances impacting on the average price level and output. Such disturbances tend to be followed by supply adjustment processes that eventually return the economy to a long-run or structural equilibrium level of output and a new, stable price level. In some of these cases, the price level adjusts downwards before reaching the stability of the structural equilibrium. Both a stable price level and a downward-moving price level may seem strange, given that in most economies inflation is a more or less permanent phenomenon Do you want to know more about inflation? – the average price level is always More information on and discussions of inflation increasing, even in recessionary in South Africa and other countries, including the times or when the central bank or probable causes of inflation, can be found in chapter government is pursuing a contrac12, section 12.1. tionary policy. Does this make the model irrelevant? The answer is no, but it requires a slight adjustment to the model to set it in an inAS by a different name? The Phillips curve flationary context. An inflationary context means an economic envi­ ron­ ment where it has be­come normal for prices and wages to increase year by year and where, indeed, prices and wages are expected to increase continually. An essential part of analysing the inflationary context, and policy in that context, is a name that will crop up in all textbooks: the Phillips curve. For reasons that are explained below, the aggre­gate supply curves in this context are frequently called Phillips curves, and indicated as PCSR and PCLR in diagrams. We will also do so in the discussion that follows. Chapter 7: Extending the model: inflation and policy reactions 305 How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 305 2019/12/17 09:15 Defining inflation Inflation is defined as a sustained increase in the average price level. One-off or intermittent increases in the average price level do not constitute inflation. The inflation rate, usually denoted by the symbol π, is the rate of increase of the average price level during a specific period, normally one year. More specifically, the inflation rate is the percentage increase in the price level during the chosen period: Pt – Pt–1 π = P 100 t–1 Statistically, it is measured using price indices such as the consumer price index (CPI). Various ways of measuring the inflation rate exist in practice. This, and other aspects of inflation, including historical data for South Africa, is discussed in chapter 12. Improvements in quality One complexity in measuring changes in the price level is that prices often increase due to improvements in goods, i.e. higher quality. Or nominal prices remain roughly the same despite significant increases in quality, e.g. cell phones or PCs since the 1990s. Separating quality changes from pure price changes is very difficult. Some economists have argued that, as a rule of thumb, a 2% inflation rate merely reflects the increase in the price level that results from the general improvement in quality of all goods. Thus an inflation rate of approximately 2% would be normal and, actually, negligible. The rate of inflation may vary, but inflation is always there. ❐ Note that this regular increase in the price level may not be high, and might be as low as 2% per annum in some countries. No central bank would be overly concerned with an inflation rate of 2%. In some countries Figure 7.1 AD-AS and a continually increasing a higher rate of inflation is considered price level normal, and the central bank may be ASLR P happy with a rate between 3% and 6% (e.g. South Africa; see chapters 9 and 12). 7.1 7.1.1 Adjusting the model – inflationaugmented AD and AS curves P4 A state of steady inflation P3 Consider an economy with a steady rate of inflation at x%, and assume that it is steady at the structural equilibrium output level YS. This means that the price level P increases by x% every year, while the economy remains on ASLR. If we illus­trate this ‘steady inflation state’ graphi­cally on the P-Y plane, using the AD-AS curves, it would show a repeatedly up­ward-moving AD-AS cross, pushing the equilibrium point up repeatedly along the vertical ASLR line (see figure 7.1). The price level in­creases from P0 to P1 to P2 and so forth without end. This process would soon push the AD-AS curves off the page! 306 ASSR2 ASSR1 P2 ASSR0 P1 AD2 P0 AD1 AD0 YS Y Chapter 7: Extending the model: inflation and policy reactions How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 306 2019/12/17 09:15 To prevent this, we can redefine the ver­tical axis: instead of the price level, we plot the rate of change (%∆) in the price level (i.e. inflation, denoted as π) on the y-axis. Output Y appears on the x-axis, as in the normal AD-AS framework. This is shown in the diagram in figure 7.2. ❐ The thus redefined aggregate demand and aggregate supply relationships can be termed inflation-augmented or quasi-AD and quasi-ASSR curves, in­dicated as AD and ASSR. A quasi-ASLR curve can also be plotted (it will remain vertical). ❐ Alternatively, the supply curves can be indicated as PCSR or PCLR, as noted above. The main characteristic of AD and ASSR is that, in a state of steady inflation, they remain sta­tionary in the new π-Y plane – while AD-AS would soon drop off the top edge of the page in the P-Y plane. As we will see below, disturbances would once again lead to short-run equilibrium points off the ASLR curve, followed by supply-side adjustments. But we will see impacts on the inflation rate π rather than on the price level P. Figure 7.2 A state of steady inflation π ASLR (or PCLR ) ASSR (or PCSR ) π Steady inflation structural equilibrium AD Note the following important points regarding the steady inflation case: Y YS ❐ At every equilib­rium point in both diagrams (figures 7.1 and 7.2), the ex­pected price equals the actual price. Thus ∆P e = ∆P and thus also %∆P e = %∆P. The latter means that the expected rate of inflation is equal to the actual rate of in­flation (in the steady state described): πe = π. The short-run equilib­rium of AD and ASSR is on ASLR all the time. ❐ In the labour market, the nominal wage would increase every year by exactly the same rate as the price level P, i.e. its percentage rate of increase would equal the inflation rate π. Thus the real wage remains constant. PS and WS would remain stationary. Producers and workers expected inflation to be at π and inflation is at π. No one is surprised by the normal price level increase. When wages are negotiated at the beginning of the contract period, nominal wages are adjusted in anticipation of the expected normal inflation in that period. The same is true for the prices set by firms. ❐ Likewise, the steady AD curve means that aggregate expenditure, comprising the components of expenditure C, I, G and (X – M), remains constant in real terms (as does The causes of inflation? We are not analysing the causes of inflation now. That will be done in chapter 12, section 12.1. We merely create the analytical tools to enable us to analyse economic fluctua­tions, shocks in supply and demand, and policy steps in an environment where there always is inflation. Thus we sim­ply work in terms of the inflation rate π rather than the price level P. What will be required in due course is an economic explanation of how and why the AD and ASSR curves started shifting up and how and why this shift came to be perpetuated as a permanent phenomenon. 7.1 Adjusting the model – inflation-augmented AD and AS curves How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 307 307 2019/12/17 09:15 the real money supply MP ). In other words, the nominal value of aggregate expenditure increases by the same percentage π in every year (as does the nominal money supply MS). S 7.1.2 Disturbances in the π-Y plane Disturbances due to demand or supply shocks can now be analysed in parallel fashion to the original analysis in the AS-AD diagram. However, some results are particularly forceful in the new diagram with π on the vertical axis. Disturbances and shocks will register as unexpected shifts in the ASSR and AD that take place over and above the expected, continual shifts shown in figure 7.1 or, equivalently, in figure 7.2. Figure 7.3 Higher expenditure growth in the P-Y plane P ASLR ASSR2 ASSR1 P2 e P2 AD2 ASSR0 P1 A demand expansion example P0 Suppose expected inflation is steady at AD1 π e = 4% and has been so for some time. ❐ In the P-Y plane (figure 7.3), both ASSR and AD will have been shifting AD0 upwards steadily by 4%. Suppose they YS Y1 Y have now reached the point of shifting from AD0 to AD1 and ASSR0 to ASSR1. The price level increases the normal 4% from P0 to P1. Output is steady at YS. ❐ In the π-Y plane (figure 7.4), both AD and ASSR (i.e. PCSR – the short-run Phillips curve) will be stationary and intersect at π0 = 4%. Expected inflation also is at π e = 4%. Output is steady at YS. However, suppose in the next period nominal government expenditure or investment (due to an interest rate decrease, for instance) increases more than normal and causes aggregate expenditure growth to go up to, for example, 6%. ❐ In the P-Y plane this will cause AD to Figure 7.4 Higher expenditure growth in the π-Y plane shift upwards and to the right (to AD2) π ASLR (or PCLR ) faster than ASSR (since the expected e price P2 is now lagging behind). This involves shifting in excess of its ASSR0;1 (or PCSR ) ‘normal’ (and expected) upward shift Equilibrium of 4%. Therefore, a larger increase after demand in the price level will occur (from P1 π stimulation 1 to P2), in excess of the normal 4%, π 0 together with an increase in output AD2 beyond long-run output (output will AD0;1 climb to Y1). ❐ In the π-Y plane, the AD curve shifts up and to the right, while PCSR YS Y1 308 Y Chapter 7: Extending the model: inflation and policy reactions How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 308 2019/12/17 09:15 (i.e. ASSR) remains stationary since its intercept with PCLR (i.e. ASLR ) is at π0 (and the expected inflation rate π e = π0). The short-run equilib­rium shifts along the ASSR curve to the right of ASLR, registering an increase in the out­put level to Y1. The inflation rate rises to π1. Similar but opposite shifts in AD would occur for a decrease in the growth rate of expenditure to below the expected inflation rate. It would cause a decrease in the out­put level to below YS, and the inflation rate would drop to a value below π0. ❐ If AD shifts so far down that the short-run equilibrium inflation level is below zero, it means that the economy is in negative inflation or deflation territory, i.e. prices decline year after year. 7.1.3 The AS-adjustment process in the π-Y plane with AD and PCSR As we know by now, points off the ASLR curve (i.e. PCLR) will not be sustained indefinitely due to intrinsic economic dynamics. The expected aggregate supply adjustment process also occurs in the inflationary context, and thus in the AD-AS model. Demand expansion or contraction Let us take up the example of demand Figure 7.5 Complete effect of higher growth in expenditure stimulation shown above. Once π PCSR2 PCLR inflation has increased from π0 to π1 (figure 7.5), inflation expectations PCSR1 are sure to adjust upwards and there PCSR0 Equilibrium will be upward pressure on nominal π 2 after supply wages. Once wages are renegotiated adjustments π upwards, this will shift the ASSR, 1 Equilibrium now renamed the short-run Phillips π after demand 0 curve (PCSR), to shift upwards from stimulation PCSR0 to PCSR1. Prices, real wages AD1 and employ­ment will adjust (as in AD0 the AD-AS model), and inflation will increase together with a decrease in Y YS Y1 output. The actual inflation rate will, however, yet again be higher than the expected inflation rate (which would now be at π e = π 1). Thus, during a next cycle of wage negotiations, another upward adjustment of wages is sure to follow, shifting PCSR up again. And so on and so on (just like the process in the AD-AS model). ❐ The process is likely to continue until the short-run equilibrium settles on PCLR, the long-run supply curve, at the structural equi­librium level of output YS and with the infla­tion rate at π2. ❐ As the economy is back at a structural equilib­rium point, π2 is now also the new expected inflation rate πe. From now on, workers and firms will expect prices to increase annually at rate π2 and not π0. There has been a lasting in­crease in the inflation rate (and the expected inflation rate). ❐ Using the illustrative numbers of expenditure growth of the example above, the annual inflation rate will have increased from 4% to 6%. ❐ As noted in the AD-AS con­text, the whole process of ex­pansion followed by supply adjustment (in this case a con­ traction combined with an in­ crease in inflation, 7.1 Adjusting the model – inflation-augmented AD and AS curves How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 309 309 2019/12/17 09:15 i.e. stagflation) could take between four and seven years, requiring suc­cessive rounds of wage rene­gotiations. What is stagflation? The short-run Phillips curve associates higher output and employment with higher inflation. This is typically when inflation is what is called an ‘excess demand phenomenon’, i.e. when the aggregate quantity demanded exceeds long-run levels of output. This corresponds to the expansion phase in the example above. Nevertheless, even though the government or the central bank was able to stimulate output (and employment) in the short run for a number of years, in the long run In contrast, stagflation occurs when higher inflation output is likely to return to YS (and occurs together with economic stagnation. Typically, employment will correspondingly stagflation occurs after a supply shock or supply decline again over time). The adjustment that shifts the ASSR (or PCSR) upwards short-run, and thus temporary, and to the left. The adjustment phase in the example gain in output and employment above is an illustration, although a pure supply shock came at the cost of a permanently would be a better one. higher inflation rate. ❐ The main implication for policy is that a sustained stimulation of aggregate demand growth will eventually only translate, after all the short-term supply adjustments, into a higher rate of inflation (even though this may take several years). The structural equilibrium level of output will not change. ❐ This does not mean that monetary or fiscal policy cannot be used to counter a recession, i.e. from a point below the structural equilibrium output level YS. But output cannot be pushed beyond YS for a significant period of time without paying an inflation penalty later. ❐ Of course, if the increased demand expenditure led to a permanent boost of the productive capacity of the economy (e.g. through infrastructure investment), the new YS would indeed be higher than before, and any inflation rate increase would be moderated. The more realistic policy lesson thus is less severe than the one stated in the previous paragraph, as long as the focus of any increased expenditure is the creation of new productive capacity (see section 7.1.6). One-off vs. sustained demand changes If the higher nominal growth rate (e.g. at 6%) of aggregate expenditure is sustained year after year, the AD curve will remain in its higher position at AD1, followed by the supply adjustment as shown. However, if the increased growth rate of aggregate expenditure is one-off, so that it returns to the normal 4% in the next year, the AD curve will shift down again to its original position. The conclusion of the one-off demand stimulation will be back at the starting point. Output will have declined back to YS after the brief upswing. Inflation will have increased briefly, but it will be back at π0 (say 4%, as in the numerical example). There is no permanent increase in the inflation rate. Yet there may still be some social costs to this process. As long as inflation expectations are slow to adjust and be reflected in wage contracts – which is not unlikely in practice – the PCSR curve will remain stationary and the return to the original equilibrium will be straightforward. The AD curve will simply shift down again to its original position before any supply adjustment starts taking place. If, however, inflation expectations and 310 Chapter 7: Extending the model: inflation and policy reactions How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 310 2019/12/17 09:15 renegotiated nominal wages go up rapidly, the PCSR curve will indeed shift up noticeably. The drop in the AD curve will then generate a more roundabout route for the shortrun equilibrium point, involving a drop in output below YS before settling back, through supply adjustment, at YS. (This phase shares elements of the case of a decrease in demand; compare chapter 6, section 6.4.2. The details are left to the reader as an exercise.) ✍ Do the complete graphical analysis for a one-off increase in the growth rate of expenditure, allowing for rapidly adjusting inflation expectations and wage contracts. Supply shocks in the AD-PCSR model A supply shock in the con­text of a steady inflation state will provide the fol­lowing, as shown in figure 7.6. The sup­ply shock will shift both PCSR and PCLR an equal distance to the left. The rate of inflation increases from π0 to π1, and output con­tracts from YS0 to Y1. (Compare the supply shock analysis in the AD-AS model in chapter 6, sections 6.4.3 and 6.4.4.) As higher inflation expectations are built into new rounds of wage negotiations, the PCSR curve will start shifting up as part of the supply adjustment process. The inflation rate increases further, eventually to π2, while output drops further to YS2, reaching the new structural equilibrium output level. The equilibrium point ends up on the relocated PCLR line, the long-run supply curve. The net result of a contraction in output Figure 7.6 A supply shock in the π-Y plane and employment combined with an PCLR1 PCLR0 π increase in the inflation rate is classic PCSR2 π3 stagflation. ❐ The structural rate of unemployPCSR0 ment SRU would have increased – Equilibrium more involuntary unemployment after supply would be present. Involuntary π2 shock unemployment, whether cyclical π1 π0 or structural, can be understood AD2 as the difference between actual AD0 unemployment and what it would have been with market clearing in labour and product markets. Y YS2 Y1 YS0 If policymakers come under political pressure to counter the contraction in output and employment, they may try to stimulate demand (to AD2) to reverse these effects. They will be successful, but only for a while, and at the price of still higher inflation. As we saw above, any short-run equilibrium point to the right of the PCLR line (which has now been relocated) is not sustainable without higher inflation. The supply adjustment process will eventually push output back to the relocated PCLR line, with yet another increase in the inflation rate to π3. There appears to be no way to avoid the permanent contractionary effect of a supply shock on output and employment, and neither can the permanent upward effect of a supply shock on inflation be avoided. 7.1 Adjusting the model – inflation-augmented AD and AS curves How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 311 311 2019/12/17 09:15 7.1.4 A permanent increase in output above YS? The augmented Phillips curve policy lesson The main implication for policy thus far has been that a sustained stimulation of aggregate demand growth will eventually only translate, after all the short-term supply adjustments, into a higher rate of inflation. Output will contract to the structural equilibrium level YS after the initial upswing to Y1. Our next conclusion is very important in the context of the ‘augmented’ Phillips curve debate (see below). It is the following: should the government or the central bank wish to increase output to Y1 and keep it there permanently, it will only be possible through repeated increases in the growth rate of aggregate demand, which will translate into a continually increasing inflation rate. Thus, not only will the average price level increase from period to period, it will increase at an increasing rate. Figure 7.7 Continually increasing inflation π PCLR PCSR4 PCSR3 PCSR2 PCSR1 π3 PCSR0 π2 AD4 π1 π0 AD2 Consider the process following an increase in the aggregate expenditure growth rate from, for example, 4% to 6% with the aim of increasing output to Y1. AD3 AD1 YS Y1 AD0 Y In year 1, the expansionary policy shifts the AD curve from AD0 to AD1, causing output to increase from YS to Y1. The short-run equilibrium inflation rate in­creases to π1 (e.g. 5%). In year 2, nominal wage increases will be renegotiated to match the new inflation rate of π1 = 5%. This would shift the short-run Phillips curve upward from PCSR0 to PCSR1 (whose intercept with PCLR is at π1). Output would start to contract along AD1 – unless the sup­ply adjustment is countered by pushing AD up fur­ther to AD2 by increasing the growth rate of expendi­ture further. This would keep output at Y1, but the in­flation rate would increase to π2 = 6%, say. In year 3, supply adjustment would again kick in via re­negotiated nominal wage increases to match the new, higher inflation rate of π2 = 6%. If output is to be kept at Y1, government will need to counter the effect of higher wage increases and the upward shift of PCSR1 to PCSR2 (whose intercept with PCLR is at π2). It will need to stimulate aggregate expenditure growth again, this time shifting AD2 to AD3. Though output will then remain at Y1, inflation will increase yet again to π3 = 7%, say. And so on and so on. The picture of a ‘vicious cycle’ is clear. Keeping output at Y1 requires repeated increases in the growth rate of aggregate demand. Inflation will increase continually year after year. In short, output can only be kept at Y1 at the price of a continually increasing inflation rate. This is not just a higher inflation rate – it is an increasing rate. This is clearly not a sustainable policy as no country can live with an ever-increasing inflation rate. It would also not be possible to increase expenditure growth indefinitely. ❐ In other words, the only output level where inflation is not increasing in the long run is when the economy is at the structural equilibrium level of output YS. ❐ A contrasting result can be derived for keeping output levels below YS, in which case the inflation rate would continually decline. The only output level where inflation would not be declining in the long run is at the structural equilibrium level of output YS. 312 Chapter 7: Extending the model: inflation and policy reactions How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 312 2019/12/17 09:15 The first bullet in the previous paragraph is the narrow augmented Phillips curve policy result. As before, we must qualify this conclusion, since it assumes a permanently stationary structural equilibrium output level YS (as in figure 7.7). Any positive impact of the growing expenditure on productive capacity (i.e. on capital stock, technology, labour skills and so forth) will shift the PCLR line to the right. This may significantly moderate the harshness of the process previously described, since the inflation rate will increase less or not at all, depending on the growth in YS. ❐ Thus one must rather say that the output level Y1 simply cannot be sustained indefinitely with a given, unchanged capital stock, labour force, labour force skills and technology. ❐ More generally: even when YS is understood to be growing over time (inter alia due to appropriate policies), output can only be sustained at a level above YS at the price of a continually increasing inflation rate. Alternatively, it can be expressed in terms of inflation and unemployment (rather than output). Being at YS (be it stationary or growing) implies that the economy is at the structural rate of unemployment (SRU). Thus the general augmented Phillips curve result can be restated in terms of inflation and unemployment as follows: unemployment can be sustained permanently below the SRU only at the price of a continually increasing inflation rate. ❐ This also reminds us of a point made in chapter 6: structural unemployment cannot be reduced through standard macroeconomic or demand-management policies. It requires structural policies. Therefore, over time (and amidst cyclical disturbances), actual output growth must match the growth of the structural equilibrium level of output YS. The economy cannot be pushed continually to grow beyond its long-term potential output growth (as determined by the growth of its productive capacity). Such a strategy would only lead to increasing inflation without the benefit of a sustained positive impact on output and employment. Thus, a ‘tolerable’ amount of higher inflation cannot be exchanged for output growth beyond YS (i.e. unemployment lower than the SRU). There would be increasing inflation, not just higher inflation. ❐ Thus, in the long run there is no trade-off between inflation and unemployment (or ‘excess output’). The vertical PCLR line (whether stationary or growing) illustrates the absence of a trade-off in the long run. ❐ In the short run, by contrast, there is a trade-off, but between unemployment (or ‘excess output’) and rising inflation. The sloping PCSR curve provides the parameters for this policy trade-off. If policy stimulation beyond YS occurs only for a very limited period (i.e. a short enough time before expectations and wages can adjust much) the inflation rate may not rise by much. But there may always be a price to be paid. Using this trade-off to reduce unemployment below the SRU for a few years, say, is likely to lead, at the very least, to higher inflation and is likely to lead to increasing inflation. However, if in the same period PCLR is growing concurrently due to expanding productive capacity, the inflation penalty may be small. Such are the complex considerations that policymakers have to weigh in thinking about policy options. Reducing the inflation rate may also be a policy goal (from a high-inflation equilibrium point on PCLR, say). Doing this through contractionary policy that reduces the growth rate of aggregate expenditure will indeed lead to a lower rate of inflation. Graphically, AD 7.1 Adjusting the model – inflation-augmented AD and AS curves How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 313 313 2019/12/17 09:15 would shift left/down, producing a new equilibrium point with a lower rate of inflation. However, as demonstrated with the ‘downward elbow’ case in chapter 6 (section 6.4.2), it will imply a relatively long period of higher unemployment. Graphically, this is when the equilibrium point initially slides down along the PCSR curve – the short-term trade-off at work again – followed by expansionary supply adjustment back to PCLR. ❐ As we will see in section 7.2, policy authorities such as a central bank (the monetary policy authority) also have the option of fine-tuning or steering the process so that a different, more preferable path is followed towards the final equilibrium, notably in the supply adjustment phase. 7.1.5 The short-run and long-run Phillips curves (PCSR and PCLR) – history and insight As noted above, in economic literature the inflation-augmented AS or quasi-AS (denoted ASSR) curve has come to be denoted as the short-run Phillips curve (denoted PCSR). This was the final (and somewhat ironic) outcome of a long and roundabout theoretical and policy discourse since the first proposition of the Phillips curve in 1958. The curve was named thus after AWH Phillips, who plotted a curve in 1958 on the basis of an observed pattern in empirical data of the UK economy. It suggested an inverse correlation between the rate of unemployment and the rate of wage increases for the period 1861 to 1957. In its popular form, the Phillips curve refers to an inverse correlation between the rate of unemployment and the (price) inflation rate. In many countries it was found that, over long periods, observations of these two variables tended to show the stable pattern shown in the diagram (figure 7.8). Figure 7.8 The original Phillips curve Inflation rate (%) The general proposition was that a stable relationship exists between inflation and unemployment. In the 1960s this was interpreted as a menu of policy options – combinations of unemployment and inflation – from which policymakers could choose at will. They could choose Unemployment rate (%) low unemployment, but paired with high inflation. Or, they could choose to have low inflation as long as they were willing to accept high unemployment in the country. At the time, it was understood that the choice to have and keep an economy in such a position could be a lasting one. This is the idea of a trade-off between inflation and unemployment. Given a particular selection from the menu, the necessary policy stimulation or contraction could then be used to push the economy to the desired equilibrium (point on the curve). In contrast to the economists and policymakers who wanted to exploit the supposed tradeoff between inflation and unemployment, Friedman and Phelps argued already in the 1960s that the trade-off between inflation and unemployment only exists in the short run. They agreed that in the short run it is possible for government or the central bank to stimulate the economy, an action that will result in higher inflation as well as higher output and 314 Chapter 7: Extending the model: inflation and policy reactions How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 314 2019/12/17 09:15 How many Phillips curves? One must be aware of possibly three forms of the short-run Phillips curve. 1. The original version depicted the Phillips curve as a relationship between nominal wage inflation πW and unemployment U. This is the diagram on the left-hand side below. 2. The later, popular version depicts a relationship between price inflation π and unemployment U. This is the centre diagram below. 3. The most recent version, in the form of the quasi-ASSR or PCSR curve, depicts a relationship between price inflation π and aggregate output Y. Graphically, the three versions capture the same relationship in almost equivalent ways: π πw PCoriginal U employment. However, they also argued that in the long run output returns to its long-run level, leaving the economy only with higher inflation. Changing inflation expectations was key to this process. Thus, according to Friedman and Phelps, in the long run the Phillips curve is vertical: whatever the rate of inflation, output will return to its long-run level. π PCSR PCpopular U Y Figure 7.9 A disintegrating Phillips curve? Inflation rate (%) Observations in the 1970s Their warnings at first were left un­heeded, inter alia because it was part of the ideological struggle between Mone­tarists and Keynesians Unemployment rate (%) (see box below). However, during the 1970s data points started to appear on the diagram that suggested a positive correlation between unemployment and inflation, or at least the absence of any correlation or pattern. This was the arrival of stagflation (a combination of high inflation and eco­nomic stagnation) on the world stage. This experience seemed to suggest that the Phillips curve had broken down. These experiences induced the development of the modern Keynesian AD-AS framework with the average price level as an explicit variable. It transpired that the expanded Keynesian theory of aggregate demand and supply could indeed provide a solid explanation for the original Phillips relationship as well as the ‘aberrant’ observations of the 1970s. Shifts in the aggregate demand curve produce an equilibrium that shifts up and down the short-run aggregate supply curve – i.e. a series of equilibria on the ASSR curve. The price 7.1 Adjusting the model – inflation-augmented AD and AS curves How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 315 315 2019/12/17 09:15 level and unemployment move in opposite directions – an inverse relationship between inflation and unemployment. This is precisely the original Phillips pattern, which can be seen to be a reflection of the short-run equilibrium sliding along the ASSR curve. The Phillips curve simply is a mirror-image of the short-run supply curve ASSR. Figure 7.10 A shifting Phillips curve Inflation rate (%) Second, the observations of the 1970s indicated not a disin­ te­grating curve but a shifting Phillips curve. Theore­tically Unemployment rate (%) this is explained by shifts in the short-run AS curve. For example, shifts of ASSR due to supply shocks or inflationary expectations pro­duce episodes of price in­creases coupled with a drop in real income (i.e. stagflation). For that particular period it generates a positive correla­tion between inflation and un­employment. The data points of the 1970s thus lie on dif­ferent, parallel Phillips curves. This implies that the Phillips curve is not dead. When and if the short-run supply curve shifts, the trade-off shifts to another plane. From a policy point of view, a usable trade-off relationship still exists. However, this is in a more complex context of a shifting supply relationship which implies that inflation will increase if output is above the long-run level, even if for a limited period. The trade-off menu is very different from what it was before (see illustrative Phillips curve data below). Today the Phillips curve is an essential part of the analytical apparatus and vocabulary of macroeconomic policy analysis. After a period of rather obscure existence, it has returned to centre stage of the policy, and especially monetary policy, debate. The empirical data pattern that Phillips observed generally is accepted as a manifestation of economic relationships captured by the ASSR relationship relative to the ASLR curve. ❐ For many decades, the data reflected a more or less stationary ASSR relationship with small variations around it. This was the era before inflation had become embedded in price expectations. Whatever inflation existed was largely ignored in price and wage setting. ❐ Since the 1970s, the data reflected a shifting ASSR due to various supply shocks, starting with the oil price shock of 1973 and followed by the impact of increasingly ingrained inflationary expectations. High inflation could not be ignored, and people wizened up to the phenomenon of inflation. Inflation expectations came to be embedded in price and wage setting. ❐ This means that the quasi-ASSR curve is identical to the original Phillips curve (in its shifting form). This is why we adopted the practice of denoting it as PCSR in this chapter. Modern AD-AS theory also shows that in the long run – after the ASSR adjustment process has run its course – output returns to the vertical ASLR curve. After any disturbances, 316 Chapter 7: Extending the model: inflation and policy reactions How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 316 2019/12/17 09:15 shocks and cycles have played out, perhaps over several years, the only long-run impact is on the inflation rate. In the long run there is no trade-off curve. ❐ This result is especially clear in the inflation-augmented AD-PC version of the theory. ❐ This means that the ASLR curve is identical to the long-run Phillips curve of Friedman and Phelps. This is why we adopted the practice of denoting it as PCLR in this chapter. ❐ The theory put forward by Friedman and Phelps is known as the expectations-augmented Phillips curve theory. Their use of the theory of expectations injected an important long-run dimension into the analysis of the original Phillips curve and the aggregate supply relationship. The fact that the modern expecta­ tions-augmented Phillips curve tradeoff means that inflation will increase when output is above YS means that higher output (i.e. lower unemployment, below SRU) will be associated with an increase (posi­tive change) in the inflation rate π. Likewise, higher unemployment (above SRU) will be associated with a decline (negative change) in the inflation rate. Figure 7.11 The expectations-augmented Phillips curve 6 4 Typical data points generated by ‘new’ expectationsaugmented Phillips relationship 2 0 Unemployment –2 This implies an inverse, or negative, correlation between unemployment –4 SRU and changes in the inflation rate (i.e. ∆π and not the inflation rate π, as was the case with the original Phillips relationship) (figure 7.11). Thus it appears that the post-1970s era of (a) lively and energetic inflation expectations and thus (b) shifting the expectations-augmented Phillips curves has generated a new inverse relationship that differs significantly from the original Phillips relationship. ❐ The implied trade-off for an expansionary policy stance is thus between lower unemployment and rising inflation. ❐ If this theory is correct, it should also be displayed in real-world economic data. In the case of the USA, this is indeed the case. 7.1.6 Summary: some Phillips curve lessons for policymakers Starting from a position of long-run equilibrium on the PCLR line and with unemployment at SRU: 1. A short and one-off demand stimulation, reversed after one period, is unlikely to cause higher inflation. There will be a short upswing followed by a downswing back to the starting level. Not much gain, not much pain. 2. An increase in the rate of expenditure growth that is sustained at the higher rate will eventually lead to higher inflation. There will be an initial upswing in output, but a downswing back to the original output level will follow (even though it may take several years). 3. A continual, repeated increase in expenditure growth rates to keep output at a higher level will lead to increasing inflation. The higher level of output is not sustainable for long. 7.1 Adjusting the model – inflation-augmented AD and AS curves How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 317 317 2019/12/17 09:15 4. A permanent reduction in the rate of unemployment below the structural rate of unemployment (via expenditure growth) can be obtained only at the cost of a continually increasing inflation rate (not just a higher level of inflation). A ‘tolerable’ amount of higher inflation cannot be exchanged for unemployment permanently lower than the SRU. 5. Trying to counter the negative impact of a supply shock on output and employment by stimulating demand will only lead eventually to further increases in inflation. The pain of a supply shock cannot be avoided. Is there a Phillips curve relationship in South Africa? There is some debate on whether or not there is a Phillips curve relationship in South Africa. Some of the evidence indicates that there is either no relationship between the output gap and inflation or, if there is, the impact of the output gap on inflation is not that large. A small impact is an indication of a rather flat PCSR. As such, one might be under the impression that output can be stimulated beyond its long-run equilibrium value without putting too much upward pressure on inflation. However, that would be a mistake, because research also indicates that inflationary expectations in South Africa adjust fairly quickly, wiping out any output gain in a rather short span of time and leaving the economy with a permanent increase in inflation. ❐ This means that the South African Phillips curve may be relatively flat, but that it is quite mobile and shifts up very quickly following inflationary stimulation. The quick adjustment of expectations – and mobility of the PC curve – also provides benefits, though. It means that if the economy is hit by a transitory external supply or demand shock that causes a sudden, unexpected increase in the inflation rate, monetary policy can return inflation to lower levels fairly quickly. (By fairly quickly is meant a period from 24 to 36 months – around the lower end of the three-to-seven year interval mentioned earlier. This is the minimum time it appears to take for interest rate changes to change the behaviour of private economic agents via impacts on their balance sheets and income statements.) ❐ Examples include a sudden weakening of the rand as in 2001, or an unexpected increase in the oil price as in 2007–08. In both cases, the inflation rate decreased fairly quickly after 2002 and 2008 following periods of significant inflationary pressure due to a supply shock. 6. If expenditure-raising policy is carefully designed so that it expands the productive capacity of the economy effectively, the inflation penalty of expansionary policy will be less severe or even negligible. Such policy can include government investment, or expenditure on skills development, or incentivised taxes. 7. However, government should be very careful with more broad-range fiscal or monetary policy steps such as general tax reductions or interest rate reductions. While such broad-range steps may also stimulate investment and thus productive capacity, they will in all likelihood lead to a significant expansion of consumption expenditure. Unless the economy is below YS, this will put upward pressure on inflation. Hence, if they are not to be inflationary, expenditure-raising policy steps must be very carefully designed to focus on stimulating the supply side and not so much the demand side. More generally: 8. If output falls below the structural equilibrium level due to a demand shock or cyclical downturn, a countercyclical stimulation of expenditure (demand) to get the economy back to the structural equilibrium output level (but not further) is appropriate. 318 Chapter 7: Extending the model: inflation and policy reactions How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 318 2019/12/17 09:15 The mathematics of the Phillips curve π The augmented Phillips curve is typically written in one of two forms: either with reference to output level Y and the structural equilibrium YS, or with reference to the unemployment rate U and the SRU, or US: e = t + (Yt – YS ) + x where > 0...... (7.1) or e = t + (Ut – US) + x where < 0...... (7.2) Both equations state that inflation in period t, πt, will equal expected inflation π et plus the unanticipated change in the inflation rate brought about by policy or an autonomous shock that pushes output away from YS, or unemployment away from US. In addition, both equations include x, which represents supply shocks such as increases in import prices, wages, and other inputs such as oil. and are slope parameters when π is graphed relative to (Y – YS), while is a parameter measuring the response of π to a change in x. ❐ Graphically, this implies that the intercept of the augmented Phillips curve with the vertical YS line (thus with PCLR) is at the level of πe. (This mirrors the intercept result that we derived for the short-run supply curve in chapter 6, section 6.3.3.) ❐ These are linear curves for illustrative purposes. More complex mathematical functions would provide the curvature associated with the short aggregate supply curve ASSR and PCSR which reflect the curvature of the production function (compare chapter 6). ❐ (Yt – YS) is the so-called output gap, i.e. the gap between actual and long-run output. Such a gap typically emerges from changes in either aggregate expenditure or aggregate supply and, through that, actual output Y. One reason for such changes would be policy steps. ❐ These equations do not actually model economic behaviour, as was done by the supply relationships in chapter 6. They show a simple mathematical approximation of an observed pattern in economic data using the concept of an output gap. (A behavioural equation can be derived from appropriate aggregate supply equations.) (For the link between the two versions of the Phillips curve, i.e. equations 7.1 and 7.2, see the box on Okun’s Law in section 12.2.2.) This can be either monetary or fiscal policy, although normally monetary policy may be more appropriate as countercyclical medication (but see section 12.3.3). A weaker exchange rate (weaker rand) will also help by stimulating net exports. 9. Do not try to push the economy faster than the expansion of its productive capacity. Spend policy energy and resources on boosting human and physical capital, technology and so forth. That is: pursue complementarity between macroeconomic policy and development policy. 10. It is inappropriate, ineffective and, indeed, counterproductive to try to use macroeconomic demand stimulation (e.g. a weaker exchange rate, or a low interest rate strategy to boost consumer demand) to address the underlying problems of long-run, structural unemployment. Structural unemployment must be recognised for what it is and addressed with appropriate structural policies. Rather use special targeted policy measures in product and labour markets to reduce structural unemployment (see chapter 12, section 12.2). The Phillips curve discussion has taken us towards the analysis of policy options, trade-offs and constraints. An interesting issue is whether this theory can help us understand the behaviour of policymakers (or can guide policymakers in their decisions). An important case study is the modelling of monetary policy, or central bank policy behaviour. 7.1 Adjusting the model – inflation-augmented AD and AS curves How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 319 319 2019/12/17 09:15 7.2 Managing inflation – policy options and the monetary reaction (MR) function We have seen that higher or increasing inflation can result from several sources, mainly (a) excessive expenditure growth plus (b) the supply adjustment process following such excessive growth, or (c) a supply shock (exacerbated by its supply adjustment process) or (d) accommodating policy to counter the supply shock. These were depicted graphically in section 7.1.3 above. The question is what policymakers are set to do if, for any of these reasons, the inflation rate is at an unacceptably high level. How can it be reduced? How can we analyse the options using our model and diagrams? 7.2.1 Basic effects of anti-inflationary policy The basic answer is simple. It was Figure 7.12 Demand contraction to reduce inflation illustrated in our examples of the π PCSR0 PCLR ‘downward elbow’ in chapter 6 PCSR1 (section 6.4.2). Let us start from a high inflation equilibrium point PCSR2 on PCLR with inflation at π2 (figure π2 Equilibrium 7.12). A reduction in the growth rate π3 after demand of nominal aggregate expenditure decrease below the current rate (which will π4 AD1 equal the rate of inflation in the AD2 Equilibrium equilibrium) will cool the economy after supply down, reduce production and push adjustment output below the long-run, structural level YS to point (π3; Y3). The inflation Y YS Y3 rate will drop to π3. Since the latter is below the expected inflation rate (which still is equal to π2), expectations will adjust downwards and be reflected in the next round of wage negotia­tions. Lower nominal wages will reduce costs and output will start to expand. In this, the supply ad­justment phase, the short-run equilibrium will slide along the new AD2 curve, through several rounds of wage renegotiations, until it reaches PCLR. At this new equilibrium the final inflation rate will be still lower at π4, while output will be back at YS. An inflation reduction would have been achieved, but at the cost of a fairly long period of lower output and higher unemployment. (Output and income will experience a cyclical downswing followed by a recovery.) ❐ By appropriately choosing the position of the new AD2 curve, the policymaker can steer the economy towards a desired, target inflation rate such as π4 (assuming rather precise demand control abilities; see below). If the unacceptably high infla­tion rate was the result of pre­ceding excessive demand growth (plus supply adjust­ment), the equilibrium would have followed an anticlockwise diamond-shaped (or roughly cir­cular) route (figure 7.13). There would be four segments as AD moved to the right (segment 1) and moved left again later (segment 3). The PCSR curve would have shifted up (seg­ment 2) and down later (segment 4). ❐ The inflation rate and the output level would have fluctuated accordingly. ❐ The final, target inflation rate (indicated as π4 in the diagram) need not be the same 320 Chapter 7: Extending the model: inflation and policy reactions How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 320 2019/12/17 09:15 as the initial inflation rate π0, as was shown in this illustration. It could be either higher or lower. That would dictate the appropriate position of the final AD curve. 7.2.2 Steering the process – more activist policy strategies Figure 7.13 Demand contraction to counter demand inflation π PCSR1 PCLR PCSR0;2 π2 π3 3 4 π0;4 2 1 Equilibrium after demand increase plus supply adjustment AD1 Initial equilibrium AD0;2 AND equilibrium after demand decrease plus supply adjustment Policy authorities may want to intervene to change the route of the short-run equilibY3 YS Y1 Y rium. Remember that the only thing that they can affect with demand policy (fiscal or monetary), is to effect and affect the downward shift of the AD curve. They can manage the timing, speed and magnitude of this shift. ❐ In reality, policy authorities do not have the information and mechanisms to control aggregate demand as readily and accurately as may be suggested by these theoretical manipulations. As noted several times in this book, the economy does not behave mechanically. In addition, there are problems concerning policy control, including policy lags. These are discussed in chapter 11. Different paths, different options Consider the second example above, i.e. of excessive demand growth (figure 7.13). Let us regard its graphical depiction as a baseline path (represented by the solid blue arrow curve in figure 7.14). If this path is not acceptable, policymakers could act pre-emptively and start contracting expenditure before the first supply adjustment process gets very far and before inflation reaches its peak on PCLR. Figure 7.14 Different policy paths to counter demand inflation π πT PCLR Baseline path to eradicate excess demand inflation More graduated anti-inflation policy path This would create a flatter circular route YS Y back to the target inflation rate (represented by the dashed arrow curve). Inflation would not rise as much, and output would have to dip less below YS. The preemptive and more moderated path seems to be less costly in terms of both inflation and unemployment. The first example above (figure 7.12) is particularly important for understanding typical monetary policy management. It starts from a high-inflation point on the PCLR line, due to ei­ther supply shocks or excess demand growth or both. Again, different paths are pos­sible. Consider the basic graphical depiction in figure 7.12 as the baseline path. (In figure 7.15 it is shown as the bold blue arrow curve.) 7.2 Managing inflation – policy options and the monetary reaction (MR) function How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 321 321 2019/12/17 09:15 The contraction in aggregate expendi­ture Figure 7.15 Different policy paths to reduce inflation can be managed so that the AD curve π gregate shifts down slower, giving the ag­ PCSR PCLR supply and wage adjustment process more time to kick in. This would produce a less roundabout route to the target equilibrium More gradualist anti-inflation point (and tar­get inflation rate) (represented policy path by the finely dashed arrow curve to the More reactionist right of the baseline arrow curve). The anti-inflation drop in output that is necessary to squeeze policy path πT the unwanted inflation out of the system is less in this case. However, the process will take longer since the successive downward adjustments in expectations and thus in YS Y nominal wages will be in smaller steps. It is a more gradualist process. ❐ This strategy implies that the minimisation of the contraction carries relatively more weight than the speedy reduction of inflation. If, by contrast, the reduction of inflation is top priority, demand can be pushed down more quickly and further to force a quick drop in the inflation rate. The supply adjustment process combined with some demand revitalisation can then be used to steer the equilibrium point to the target inflation rate. This will produce the third path shown in the diagram (represented by the dashed arrow curve to the left of the baseline arrow curve). Output and employment will fall a great deal, but inflation will be squeezed out much more quickly. This is a more severe, reactionist approach. The strategy chosen by the policy authorities will depend on their preferences regarding the urgency of lower inflation as against the unavoidable temporary drop in output and employment (the core elements in the Phillips curve trade-off, essentially). The monetary reaction function One way to think about different strategies is in terms of a so-called policy reaction function. This concept has been developed in recent years, primarily in the context of monetary policy and central bank actions. So let us confine our attention to the monetary reaction (MR) function. However, it can clearly be applied to other kinds of policy as well. Chapter 3 introduced the basic analysis of monetary policy. It demonstrated how the central bank can manage the money supply process to set the interest rate at a desired level to pursue a chosen policy goal. What was not explained is how the desired interest rate level will be determined. The MR function describes how a central bank decides what should be its policy strategy, normally via interest rate setting, to steer the economy to a target equilibrium point. As chapter 9 will discuss in more detail, the SARB has had an official policy of inflation targeting since 2000. For most of the time, the SARB wanted to contain the inflation rate within a target range of 3% to 6%. Its main policy lever to achieve this was management of the repo rate in reaction to the actual and anticipated inflation rate. An undesired increase in the inflation rate is typically met by an increase in the repo rate to dampen demand. 322 Chapter 7: Extending the model: inflation and policy reactions How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 322 2019/12/17 09:15 ❐ The idea of a reaction function is not restricted to an inflation targeting regime. It can apply to different monetary policy regimes (inflation targeting or others) and via either interest rate setting or money supply manipulation (both most often via the repo rate). The MR function is a way to describe the likely reaction of the central bank should the inflation rate increase above the target value or target range. It can be interpreted as the imposition of an enforced path for the journey of the short-run equilibrium point towards its target. The reaction function, MR, of the central bank can be plotted in the Phillips curve space, as in figure 7.16. The MR curve intersects the long-run Phillips curve at the target inflation rate πT. Figure 7.16 The MR curve π PCLR πT MR curve The MR line shows the desired path of the short-run equi­librium point (π; Y) on its way YS Y towards the target equilib­ rium point (with the target inflation rate πT) on the PCLR line. Thus it is a series of desired levels of Y for inflation rates that still are above (or below) the target inflation rate. Should the inflation rate exceed the target, the central bank would try to push the economy to the MR line. Thereafter, the central bank will manage further demand contractions (or expan­sions, as necessary) alongside the supply adjustment proc­ess to steer the equilibrium along the MR line towards the targeted level of inflation πT (together with its matching output level YS). ❐ The MR curve has a negative slope, indicating the extent to which the central bank needs to keep output below its long-run, structural equilibrium level to put downward pressure on inflation. As noted above, the central bank has a spectrum of options in terms of how gradually or rapidly it wants to guide inflation back to its target level. It can adopt a gradualist approach or a stronger, reactionist approach. ❐ Graphically, the differences in approach are reflected in differ- Figure 7.17 A gradualist MR curve ent MR slopes. π PCSR0 ❐ The difference between these PCLR approaches will be evident in the PCSR1 extent to which the central bank PCSR2 chooses to increase interest rates π0 Path forced by MR via a repo rate increase. The gradualist MR curve is illustrated in the diagram in figure 7.17. It shows how the fall in output is moderated by decreasing aggregate demand gradually, in stepwise fashion, until it reaches AD2, allowing the supply adjust­ ment process to kick in and take the function – stepwise decrease in AD curve πT AD2 Baseline path AD0 MR curve YS Y1 7.2 Managing inflation – policy options and the monetary reaction (MR) function How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 323 323 2019/12/17 09:15 The Taylor ‘rule’ The most well-known monetary reaction function is known as the Taylor rule. In 1993 Taylor presented the following equation as a simple model and description of monetary policy behaviour in the USA: i = rLR + π + h(π – πT) + g(Y –YS ) where i is the nominal short-term interest rate, rLR is the long-term or ‘normal’ real interest rate, π is the actual inflation rate, πT is the inflation target, and (Y – YS) is the output gap (i.e. the percentage gap between actual output Y and long-term output YS ). ❐ The real interest rate is given by r = i – π. (It should not be confused with the long-term interest rate rLR.) The rule means that two ‘gap-elements’ exert an influence on the central bank to change the real interest rate. (They do so by changing the short-term nominal interest rate i as shown by the formula.) ❐ Inflation gap: If and while inflation is above the target value, there is pressure to increase the real interest rate above the ‘normal’ value. [Consider the term h(π – πT).] ❐ Output gap: If and while output is above the long-run level YS , there is pressure to increase the real interest rate above the ‘normal’ value. [Consider the term g(Y – YS).] ❐ If both inflation and output are below the target values, there is twofold pressure to reduce the real (and nominal) interest rate. ❐ If inflation is above the target value, but output is below YS, there are opposing forces: the inflation gap-related pressure to increase the real interest rate will be moderated by the output gap-related pressure to reduce rates. A central bank that behaves like this will in effect steer the economy along one of the reaction paths shown in the diagrams above. Interest rate setting will change during the route to reflect the changing influence of the two evolving gaps along the path. As a description of interest rate policy, the Taylor rule highlights that a central bank fights inflation not so much by increasing the nominal interest rate, but by increasing the real interest rate – it is when interest cost in real terms increases that people cut back their expenditure and borrowing. Note that the inflation target is not necessarily an officially announced target. It could also be the implicit, unannounced target that the central bank pursues. The parameters h and g indicate the importance that the central bank attaches to fighting inflation versus keeping output and employment as close as possible to its long-run, structural value. ❐ For the USA, Taylor found that setting h = 0.5 and g = 0.5 provides a good description of monetary policy behaviour. A higher value of h implies that the central bank attaches more importance to fighting inflation. ❐ For instance, suppose rLR = 2% and that h = 0.2. If inflation is at 6% while its target value is 4%, h(π – πT) will amount to 0.2(6% – 4%) = 0.4%. Assuming for a moment that (Y – YS) = 0, the short-term nominal interest rate will be set at 8.4%. Thus the real interest rate r equals 2.4% = 8.4% minus 6%. ❐ However, if h = 0.5, h(π – πT) will amount to 1%, which translates into a short-term nominal interest rate of 9%. The real interest rate r equals 3% = 9% minus 6%. ❐ A higher value of h thus implies a more stringent interest rate policy when inflation is above the target value: the central bank attaches more weight to inflation than unemployment. Similarly, the value of g shows how much emphasis the central bank places on getting output and employment back to their long-run, structural values. ❐ A larger g will imply relatively greater output gap-related pressure to change the interest rate. The parameters h and g should always exceed zero. A value below zero would imply that the central bank perversely lowers interest rates when faced by higher inflation or an economic upswing, or vice versa. 324 Chapter 7: Extending the model: inflation and policy reactions How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 324 2019/12/17 09:15 econ­omy towards the long-run equilibrium output level. The fall in output (which is less than in the basic example in figure 7.12) is indicated as the ‘baseline path’. As noted, this path will take longer than the baseline example to reach the tar­get level of inflation πT. Unemployment will increase less, but those unemployed will remain un­employed for longer. ❐ An MR curve that is relatively steep indicates a political or policy prefer­ence that favours the protection of employment over infla­tion, even though the inflation reduction is the agreed end goal. ❐ Interest rates will be pushed up less in this case. The reactionist approach is illustrated in the next diagram (figure 7.18). The path from π0 to πT is very different from that seen in the gradualist approach. Demand is con­tracted further than AD2. The drop in short-run equilibrium output (and employ­ment) is severe, so much so that demand has to be re­vitalised in the later stages, otherwise it would be overkill and the infla­tion rate would end up below πT. However, the rate of inflation de­ clines much more quickly than in the baseline example, and obvi­ously also more quickly than in the gradualist case. The recovery of output and employment may not be so quick, though. ❐ An MR curve that is rela­tively flat indicates a politi­cal or policy preference that favours low inflation over low unem­ployment, with a more or less single-minded focus on the reduction of inflation. Figure 7.18 A reactionist MR curve ❐ The necessary increase in interest π rates will be much larger in this case. PCLR PCSR0 An extreme example of the reactionist PCSR1 approach is the so-called cold-turkey approach. It aims to eradicate excessive inflation in one decisive move and in π0 Baseline path one period by increasing the repo rate drastically. ❐ Graphically, the cold-turkey approach πT AD0 is indicated by a horizontal MR funcMR curve Path forced by MR AD2 tion, indicating an uncompromising function – severe initial anti-inflationary stance by the cendecrease in AD curve, then gradual recovery tral bank. ❐ The cold-turkey approach has the YS Y1 benefit that inflation returns to its low level within one period. However, the drastic increase in unemployment that it entails may render it politically difficult to implement. Few, if any, central banks follow a coldturkey approach (because the turkey may end up dead ...?). How should the interest rate be set by the central bank? The appropriate interest rate path in each case can be determined if one considers the IS-LM diagram corresponding to this AD-PC diagram. ❐ In some textbooks, you will find a so-called IS-PC-MR three-equation model. This is like figure 7.18, but it is trimmed to show only the essential curves from the point of view of a central bank that sets/controls/pegs interest rates through open-market operations and so forth. Typically, they will not show the AD curve, preferring to analyse demand with the IS curve. The preferred equilibrium path is deduced from PC and MR only. Then, on the accompanying IS-LM plane, they will not show the LM curve, and focus 7.2 Managing inflation – policy options and the monetary reaction (MR) function How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 325 325 2019/12/17 09:15 only on deriving, from the IS Which policy objective? curve, the target interest rate to produce the desired fall in At the moment most central banks consider price output. stability to be their main objective. This is a broad ❐ This ‘underplaying’ of the LM current consensus in central bank and monetary policy circles. The South African Reserve Bank curve is not purely innocuous. (SARB) is no exception. It reflects a particular way of ❐ Usually, price stability does not mean zero thinking about what central inflation, but rather an inflation rate low and banks should do, underpinned stable enough so that people cease to take by the growing influence of a inflation into account in their economic decisions. particular doctrine – in United In other eras (and countries), objectives such as States economic policy circles, employment creation have had similar prominence. for example – that monetary In the USA the Federal Reserve has to consider both policymakers should interfere inflation and economic growth. In South Africa, an as little as possible in markets, influential labour federation such as Cosatu feels that that markets clear efficiently, the Reserve Bank should consider employment and and so forth. poverty alleviation as policy objectives, or at least ❐ A more generally useful model that inflation should not be the only consideration that can aid understanding of of monetary policy. See chapter 12 for a fuller different countries and eras discussion of these issues. keeps the LM intact, since it can be used to analyse several approaches to monetary policy. ❐ In any case, the world financial crisis of 2007–08, and the political reactions to it, reminds one that different eras may also make different approaches appropriate. One’s analytical apparatus should not be constrained by a single approach that is currently in vogue. ✍ Analysing the world financial crisis of October 2007–08: inflation effects We have considered this case study several times since chapter 3. You should have gained many insights into a complex situation. The analysis culminated in chapter 6, using the AD-AS model. The last step is to take your analysis of chapter 6 and transfer it to the AD-PC model. What additional insights does this model add, relative to the AD-AS model? 7.2.3 Conclusion This concludes the exposition of the expanded AD-AS theory, in the form of the AD-PC model, to be used to analyse macroeconomic behaviour, fluctuations, shocks and policy in an inflationary context. ❐ Nevertheless, it appears that most of the analytical conclusions from the AD-AS chapter regarding shocks and disturbances and their graphical reflection in diagrams, can be transferred, with a few modifications, to the inflation context. Therefore, insights from the standard AD-AS model remain relevant, in most respects, for the inflationary context. 326 Chapter 7: Extending the model: inflation and policy reactions How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 326 2019/12/17 09:15 In terms of the time frame concerned, we have now dealt, first, with short-term fluctuations due to demand and supply shocks. These can be thought to occur over a time horizon of up to approximately three years. We have also considered medium-term adjustments of the supply side of the econ­omy towards the ‘long run’ (sic) or structural equilibrium level of output and employment. Such adjustments can involve a period of a further three to seven years approximately (within which short-term disturbances and fluctuations can recur, of course). The average for both short- and medium-run processes, allowing for some overlap, is typically approximately four to seven years. Now is the time to consider the context of output and employment in the very long run, with a time horizon measured in decades – the topic of economic growth. 7.3 Analytical questions and exercises 1. There was a steady reduction in the repo rate of the Reserve Bank between 2007 and 2013. Use the expectations-augmented Phillips curve to analyse (explain and illustrate) the short-run and long-run impact of this reduction on the inflation rate, as well as on the unemployment rate. 2. Use the expectations-augmented Phillips curve to analyse (explain and illustrate) the short-run and long-run impact of negative supply shocks on the inflation rate, as well as on the unemployment rate. 3. Following from the previous question, suppose the government wants to restore the output level that existed prior to the occurrence of the shock, explain the effect such steps will have on the inflation rate. 4. ‘Manufacturers will appeal to the National Energy Regulator of SA (NERSA) for relief on Eskom's planned, steep electricity tariff increases, which they say will force many companies out of business.’ Use the expectations-augmented Phillips curve to analyse (explain and illustrate) the short-run and long-run impact of an increase in Eskom's electricity tariffs on the inflation rate, as well as the unemployment rate. 5. During 2016 South Africa experienced the highest inflation rate in seven years. What can policymakers do to reduce inflation? Which policy institution(s) is (are) best geared to do that? Use the AS-AD model to illustrate and explain your answer. 6. Suppose the inflation rate is 12% and the Reserve Bank wants to reduce it to 6%, explain the difference between the options that the Reserve Bank has in terms of the speed by which it reduces the inflation rate and factors that may slow down such a reduction. 7. In 2019 pressure increased to expand the mandate of the South African Reserve Bank so that it does not only target inflation, but also economic growth. Use the AS-AD model to discuss the merit of targeting growth and inflation. Can the South African Reserve Bank ensure a higher economic growth rate in the longer term? Discuss. (You can also consult chapter 9 in this regard.) 7.3 Analytical questions and exercises How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 327 327 2019/12/17 09:15 How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 328 2019/12/17 09:15 Macroeconomics in the very long run: growth theory 8 After reading this chapter, you should be able to: ■ understand how the analysis of aggregate supply, and the production function in particular, provides the key to explaining economic growth; ■ analyse and evaluate how the concept of balanced growth helps to explain the long-run growth path of economies; ■ analyse the main sources of sustained growth in per capita GDP, and compare how changes in economic behaviour and structure can impact on per capita growth; ■ evaluate the potent roles of technology, institutions and human capital in economic growth; ■ evaluate how policy measures can and cannot be used to increase the long-term growth prospects and performance of an economy; and ■ appreciate the importance of a wider social and human development context in understanding and promoting economic growth. The foregoing chapters of this book have dealt with short-term fluctuations due to demand and supply shocks (e.g. a time horizon of up to three years) and also medium-term adjustments of the supply side of the econ­omy (a further three to seven years) towards the ‘long-run’ or structural equilibrium level of output and employment. We have also ex­ panded our analysis of changes in the price level P to include the ‘con­tinually increasing’ context of P and thus inflation. Now is the time to consider the context of continually growing output Y in the very long run, with a time horizon measured in decades. That brings us to the topic of economic growth and theories of economic growth. 8.1 The importance of growth While short- and medium-term fluc­tuations of an economy are cru­cial for the inhabitants of a country, the long-term economic health of an economy is a very important topic. Within the broader context of devel­opment and poverty alleviation in a country such as South Africa, increasing the standard of living of people in the long term is a major political objective. The struggle in South Af­rica to reach a targeted 6% GDP growth rate calls for a better understanding of the determinants of growth. Table 1.1 in chapter 1 shows average economic growth rates for South Africa since the 1960s. Economic growth was strong up to the mid-1970s, with economic growth rates peaking at 6% per annum in the 1960s. However, in the mid-1970s, eco­nomic growth in South Africa weakened significantly, with per capita growth turning negative in the period 8.1 The importance of growth How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 329 329 2019/12/17 09:15 1981 to 1993. Since then the economic growth rate, both in aggre­gate and per capita terms, has im­proved significantly. Measuring economic growth The simplest measure of economic growth is the annual growth rate of real GDP, i.e. the percentage increase in real GDP from one year to the next. GDP – GDP t t–1 Real GDP growth rate = × 100 GDP t–1 or Yt – Yt–1 × 100 Y t–1 It can also be measured in terms of per capita GDP (i.e. aver­age GDP per person). The formula is the same except that aggregate GDP is replaced by real per capita GDP. When studying long-term trends in economic growth, the focus of attention is per capita GDP. Warning: economic growth theory is not about ‘economic growth’… 1. Popular discussions by economists, business people and politicians about economic growth usually proceed in terms of the growth rate of GDP, not GDP per capita. Only rarely will they relate the GDP growth rate to the popula­tion growth rate. 2. The annual change in GDP comprises both a short-run or cyclical component and a long-run or trend (i.e. growth) component. However, this distinction is very often not made when either cyclical or growth trend issues are discussed. Thus, when the business cycle is discussed (for instance in the media), the growth rate is used indiscriminately by commentators who forget that part of the growth rate represents trend or long-term growth. Strictly speaking, the cyclical component should be removed from the actual growth rate to obtain the trend or long-term growth rate. (Also see chapter 12, section 12.3.1.) These averages, and particularly the dramatic drop in per capita GDP growth rates after 1981, clearly show the importance of long-term growth relative to the business cycle, which involves short-run fluctuations. ❐ Graphs in chapter 12, section 12.3.2 show per capita GDP together with the long-term trend in per capita GDP for South Africa and the USA. Deviations from the growth path indicate the business cycle. It appears that, over the very long run, deviations from the long-term growth path are dwarfed by the long-term trends of the macroeconomy. 8.2 Why growth theory? While the harsh reality of recessions and depressions when people lose their jobs cannot be denied, sustained economic growth can play a powerful role in lifting aggregate, as well as per capita, production and income in a country. In terms of the AD-AS framework, sustained growth in GDP implies that the structural equilibrium output level continually shifts to the right at a sustained rate of growth. The ASLR (or PCLR) curve obviously moves in tandem. Note that in growth theory the focus is exclusively on the supply side of the economy. This is a pattern: the theoretical analysis of short-run fluctuations focuses on expenditure and demand, with some attention to the supply side; the analysis of me­dium-term adjustments focuses largely on supply with some atten­tion to the demand side. Very long-term analysis focuses exclusively on the supply side, since it is all about the expansion of productive 330 Chapter 8: Macroeconomics in the very long run: growth theory How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 330 2019/12/17 09:15 potential in the very long term, and the ad­justment of the economy towards that potential growth path. In our analysis of the aggregate supply curve, we encountered the aggregate production function (TP), which captures the way aggregate output Y depends on the quantities of labour N, capital K and technology A that are employed in the multitude of production processes in an economy. Does economic growth help everyone? A major argument for economic growth is that the economic pie must grow if the slices that people get are to get bigger. Better living standards require economic growth. However, per capita GDP is an average. Despite an increase in per capita GDP, some people may not be better off. Or, the living standards of some people may increase much faster than those of others. It depends on how the growing income flows to different households and individuals are apportioned. ❐ South Africa has one of the highest degrees of income inequality in the world (see chapter 1, section 1.3.5 and chapter 12, section 12.3.2). For a more rounded analysis, we expand this function somewhat in this chapter. First, the A factor is expanded to include the role of progress with regard to social and economic institutions and practices that impact on the productive potential of an economy. These can be legal (e.g. property rights, constitutional framework, company law frame­work, labour law, competition law and policy, etc.), managerial (management techniques, style of doing business, work ethic, motivational make-up, etc.) or organisational (new ways of organisation and management) and so forth. These aspects do not change the analysis of earlier chapters materially, but we embed a much richer analysis of social development over time in that variable. This will appear to be quite important (also Why does demand not matter for growth? see chapter 12, section 12.3.4.) Second, we add another variable H. This represents so-called human capital. In its narrowest sense, human capital can be defined as the skills of individuals that allow them be more efficient. Such skills are accumulated over a lifetime, notably through schooling and postschool training and education. Expenditure in education that increases the amount or years of schooling of individuals can be seen as an investment in human capital, i.e. the ability of people to be productive. Other forms of knowledge, such as workplace experience, on the job training, life skills, etc., improve labour efficiency as well. A broader interpretation would also allow for the development of human Short-run and medium-run fluctuations are largely explained by shocks and disturbances that initially cause output (supply) and expenditure (demand) to diverge from each other. The adjustment in economic behaviour that brings output and expenditure back into bal­ance takes the economy to a new equilibrium point. Moving equilibrium points are the substance of the business cycle and medium-term patterns in output and employment. In the very long run, our interest is the long-run trend in ag­gregate income. Thus we intentionally ignore short-term and medium-term deviations from the trend. To exclude that ele­ment, we regard expenditure and output as being in equilibrium in the long run. This means we can only focus on the behaviour of output (and thus income) in the long run, since expenditure will behave concurrently. Obviously the economy will not be on the long-run growth path at all times, as we will see, and will regularly be busy, over time, adjusting back to the long-run trend. Nevertheless, to see this we first need the long-run trend. 8.2 Why growth theory? How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 331 331 2019/12/17 09:15 ability/capacity due to reasons other than education, e.g. improved health care. This additional variable is included in our expanded production function, allowing one to analyse the impact of changes in all these variables on aggregate supply. (See section 8.10 for a fuller discussion.) It seems rather obvious that economic growth depends on things like labour, capital, skills, technology and social and economic institutions. And it seems quite straightforward to deduce how changes in the components of N, K, A or H will impact positively or negatively on aggregate productive potential and actual output. For example, an increase in the skills levels of the workforce will improve output and increase aggregate supply. If this happens continually, aggregate output will grow continually. To be a bit sarcastic: what else is new in growth theory? Three aspects deserve attention: ❐ First, not all factors of production can necessarily contribute to economic growth in the long term in the same way or with the same forcefulness. Some are more potent than others (in a specific sense to be explained) and some are more constrained than others. ❐ Second, not all long-term growth paths are equally accessible for an economy. Some growth paths can suffer from imbalances and run into constraints. But at least there are some economic forces at work that help an economy to get to the balanced growth path. ❐ Third, policymakers (and voters/citizens) can improve the conditions and prospects for balanced growth if they are well informed and can implement a few appropriate changes in economic behaviour and parameters in a country. This chapter mainly presents the Solow growth model, named after Robert Solow, the American economist who developed this theory (for which he received the Nobel Prize in Economics in 1987). However, the chapter also highlights issues that the standard model does not cover but that need to be considered when thinking about growth (and policies to support growth) in a low- or middle income country. Thus, we try to fashion a bit of a bridge between growth theory and development theory, without going into the detail of the latter. (In chapter 12, section 12.3, we will see that this bridge may be very important.) 8.3 From intuition to formal analysis – from AD-AS to the Solow growth model Consider the production function and TP curve in chapter 6 (section 6.3.2), and let us add the variable H on the right hand side: Y = f(N; K; H; A) ...... (8.1) where N = Labour usage (employment) in production; K = Physical capital stock in productive use; H = Human capital stock (the skills levels of workers); and A = An index of technological and institutional progress. We will pay limited attention to H for a while, to simplify the initial analysis. However, it is quite an important variable, particularly in a low- and middle-income countries, where skills deficiencies often hamper productivity and economic growth. We will also see that the role of human capital H in economic growth is thought to be very similar to that of physical capital K, but that some kinds of human capital play a role similar to that of technology. 332 Chapter 8: Macroeconomics in the very long run: growth theory How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 332 2019/12/17 09:15 So the analysis of both physical capital K and labour efficiency A can be largely replicated, with some adjustments, for the analysis of H (see section 8.10). So, for the moment we proceed with the simpler production function: What about natural resources as a source of growth? Countries rich in natural resources such as oil reserves or mineral deposits (e.g. gold, platinum, iron ore) clearly have a major economic advantage. How would you accommodate that in the production function and growth model? ❐ See the box in section 8.5. Y = f(K; N; A) ...... (8.1a) This is the form used originally by Solow. Constant returns to scale are assumed, as well as diminishing marginal returns to both labour and capital. (a) The former means that if each of the factors of production is increased by a given percentage, e.g. 10%, total output will also increase by 10%. (b) The latter means that if only one production factor, e.g. labour, is repeatedly increased by a particular percentage, e.g. 10%, while the other factors remain constant, total production Y will successively increase not by the same percentage (10%), but by a shrinking percentage, e.g. 8%, and then 7%, and then 6%, and so forth. Each successive increment in the production factor is met by a shrinking increment in output. Eventually, if theoretically, this growth in output will approach zero. ❐ Graphically diminishing marginal returns are seen in a curved TP function that gradually flattens out as the variable on the horizontal axis increases (given that the other factors remain constant). Figure 8.1 shows diminishing marginal returns to labour. Factor A is very different in this The maths of production functions – the regard. Non-diminishing marginal Cobb-Douglas function returns are assumed with regard This is one of the most popular production to A. Technological and institufunctions in economics. Despite its simplicity, it tional progress is thought to be can be used to generate a variety of production unconstrained by diminishing relations that approximate real-world situations marginal returns in the long run. quite well. It looks as follows: New technological or institutional 1– innovations and refinements that Yt = AtKt Nt where 0 < < 1 add proportionally (or more) to The parameters and 1– represent the share output growth always appear to of capital K and labour N in income Y. For more be possible. This characteristic of details, see addendum 8.1. A, as against the others, will prove to be very important in the analysis and conclusions that follow. ❐ The absence of diminishing marginal returns means that there are either constant marginal returns for that factor, or increasing marginal returns. ❐ For illustrative purposes we will assume, in the rest of this chapter, that A is subject to constant marginal returns (as against the other option, i.e. increasing marginal returns). So we assume that an increase (i.e. growth) in A always leads to the same proportional increase (i.e. growth) in Y: if A increases by 5% it will cause a 5% increase in Y. π Graphically, sustained increases in Y must come from either of two sources (or both): a sustained move along TP due to increasing N, or a sustained upward shift/rotation of TP due to increased K or improved technology and social and economic institutions A. 8.3 From intuition to formal analysis – from AD-AS to the Solow growth model How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 333 333 2019/12/17 09:15 Figure 8.1 TP and growth in long-run real income due to changing K or A Y TP1 TP0 Y Y1 Y1 YS YS NS0 NS1 YS0 N __ W P 45° line P YS1 Y ASSR WS PS NS0 NS1 N YS Y1 Y 1. Changes in K and A will increase labour productivity; thus TP rotates up and, in the PS-WS diagram, PS shifts up – see figure 8.1. ❐ New technology lifts but also extends/elongates the TP curve to the right – there is a new technical relationship, so that the flattening area (diminishing marginal returns area) is shifted out to the right. ❐ Increasing K produces purely a proportional upward shift/rotation in TP, and the hazard of diminishing marginal returns to labour setting in is not forestalled. There is no change in the technical relationships inherent in TP. 2. Changes in the labour force (LF) will shift WS in the WS-PS diagram, but TP will not rotate. That is, there is a move along a stationary TP, and no change in the technical relationships inherent in TP. 3. For a similar change in the employment level N, the resultant change in YS (and ASLR) will be larger when it is combined with changes in A and K (that shift/rotate TP). What one sees here is that sustained increases in Y (i.e. GDP), and thus economic growth in the very long run, will depend positively on investment (capital formation: infrastructure, machinery and equipment, etc.), labour force growth, and progress in 334 Chapter 8: Macroeconomics in the very long run: growth theory How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 334 2019/12/17 09:15 terms of new technology and the development of social and economic institutions and processes. (Growth of human capital can be added to this list to be more complete; see section 8.10.) However, growth in Y is not without constraints and limitations. ❐ Regarding N (as a proxy for the labour force LF): First, it is constrained by natural limits on the population growth rate. Moreover, increasing employment N is subject to diminishing returns, so increasing N out of line with K is less productive in the long run. ❐ Regarding K: Capital expansion is subject to diminishing returns (if it is increased out of line with N), which means that the rotation of TP will be stifled more and more. Second, capital formation (investment) has to be financed from aggregate saving – which depends, in turn, on Y (and the saving rate). Also, the capital stock does not necessarily remain constant. A fraction of the capital stock is depleted annually – i.e. there is depreciation – due to wear and tear, or machinery becoming obsolete and having to be replaced regularly through investment. ❐ Regarding A: With growth due to improving technology and institutions not being subject to diminishing returns, a given percentage growth in technology and institutions (as measured by growth in A) leads to the same percentage growth in Y. The amplifying impact of technology and institutions on labour efficiency means that by improving technology and institutions one can overcome the ultimately choking effects, on output growth, of diminishing re­turns to labour. ❐ This is seen in the way TP is rotated and elongated by improving technology and institutions without the rotation being stifled by diminishing marginal returns: a given improvement in A leads to an equi-proportional improvement in Y. Note, with reference to figure 8.2, that in the initial graphical depiction of the pro­duction function shown in figure 8.1 we have chosen to place employment N on the horizontal axis. Thus, changes in K, which is not on either of the axes, will shift the TP curve. The same applies to changes in A. By contrast, changes in N result in moves along the TP curve. Figure 8.2 The impact of technology and institutions on TP Y TP1 TP0 Y1 Y0 One can, alternatively, choose to show TP with the capital stock K on the horizontal axis as in figure 8.2. Changes in A would still shift/rotate the TP curve, as from TP0 to TP1. A change in K now is seen as a move along a particular curve, e.g. TP0, as indicated. Changes in N will shift the TP curve. Nevertheless, in terms K0 K1 K of analysis, the diagram will produce results iden­tical to those for figure 8.1 and its version of TP. The resultant changes in Y will, as before, re­flect as a shift of the vertical ASLR line. ❐ As before, the curvature shows diminishing marginal returns, in this case diminishing marginal returns to capital. From now on we will only work with the TP diagram and dispense with the ASLR diagram. We know that any vertical change in Y in the TP diagram is equiva­lent, in the AD-AS plane, to a right­ward shift of ASLR and an increase in YS. ❐ For reasons that will immediately become clear, our further development of the TP relationship will build on figure 8.2, with K on the horizontal axis. 8.3 From intuition to formal analysis – from AD-AS to the Solow growth model How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 335 335 2019/12/17 09:15 8.4 Rearranging the model – towards income per capita A major limitation of the analysis above is that it works in terms of the growth of aggregate output and income Y (i.e. GDP). What is important for growth theory, but actually for the population of a country, is GDP growth relative to population growth. This would determine what is happening with GDP (or Y) per capita, which indicates what is happening with the material living standards of individuals in the population. Thus we have to evaluate and analyse growth in Y relative to the population growth rate n. Changes in (if not levels of) the latter ratio can be approximated by changes in NY , i.e. output per worker or income per worker. Although not precisely equivalent, for the purposes of this chapter we shall use the terms Y N , output per worker, income per worker, and income (or GDP) per capita interchangeably. 8.4.1 Recasting the production function Thus it becomes convenient to recast our analysis with NY as the key variable. This can be done by rewriting the production function TP in so-called intense form with NY as the dependent variable, and thus the variable on the vertical axis of the TP diagram. ❐ This also has the benefit of avoiding a situation where a shifting and rotating TP will rapidly disappear off the top of the page (similar to when we studied the AD-AS model in an inflationary context). Thus the standard production function Y = f(K; N; A) can be rewritten in the following form, which we will still indicate as TP: Y (K ) __ __ N = f N ; A where ...... (8.2) NY = output–labour ratio, i.e. output per worker (also: average labour productivity); K N = capital­­­–labour ratio, i.e. capital stock per worker; A = an index of labour efficiency. Since A in the first production function above is an index of technological and institutional progress (and something that broadly speaking is available to everybody), it need not be divided by N. One could also simply think, in this form of the production function, of A as a measure, or an index, of labour efficiency due to improved technology, social and economic institutions and practices. This is the approach we adopt in this chapter. ❐ The growth rate of A (which is denoted as a) thus indicates the growth rate of labour efficiency due to technological progress and social and economic institutional development. Note: K ❐ Increasing N is called capital deepening. Its opposite is capital widening. ❐ Another relevant ratio is KY , the capital–output ratio, which is called the capital intensity of an economy. From this function we can derive a model that explains fairly robustly how sustained increases in NY – and thus economic growth that increases the standard of living over time (in the very long run) – will depend on: 336 Chapter 8: Macroeconomics in the very long run: growth theory How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 336 2019/12/17 09:15 (a) saving and investment (i.e. capital formation and accumulation, which improves capital intensity); (b) labour force growth; (c) progress in terms of new technology and the development of social and economic institutions and processes (which improves labour efficiency); and also (d) improvements in human capital – which we will not analyse for the moment (see section 8.10). NK on the This function enables us to generate a diagram with NY on the vertical axis and horizontal axis (see figure 8.3). ❐ The benefit of this diagram is that any movement of the economy to a point on TP that shows an increase in NY implies that Y has not only grown, but has grown more than the labour force or population growth in that period. Economic growth in the sense of a K Working in terms of ratios such as NY and is sustained annual increase in GDP N Y somewhat confusing at first, so be careful when per capita, as approximated by N thinking about changes in variables. We will in the Solow model, implies (and initially present the analysis in some detail to aid requires) a sustained increase in understanding. Addendum 8.2 provides a helpful the NY ratio on the vertical axis. illustrative numerical example. It is worth studying A higher value of NY is beneficial it carefully. for the population, but it does not constitute growth (just as an increase in the price level does not constitute inflation). Economic growth is about NY over time. sustained, recurring annual increases in NY - NK plane has the same general shape as in the Y-K plane, for the same The TP curve in the reason: diminishing marginal returns. It will thus also flatten out at higher levels of NK . 8.4.2 Moving along TP, shifting TP As noted above, increasing one factor of production while keeping the others constant will increase out­put Y, but at a decreasing rate. This has complex implications for the change in NY , as follows: K ❐ If K is increased (for constant N), NK increases to N . Graphically, there is a move to the right along TP0. Output Y will increase due to the ad­ditional capital and NY will increase Figure 8.3 Changes in TP Y ). Since it involves diminishing re(to N TP2 Y/N turns to capital (graphically, the move is along the curvature of TP0), NY increases Y2 /N0 proportionally less than the increase TP0 Y1/N0 in NK (and K increases proportionally less than Y). Y0 /N0 ❐ If only N is increased (for constant K), there is a move to the left along TP0 (not Y shown). N will de­cline. ❐ Note that the variable N (or LF) has Y an unexpected effect on N . Increasing employment N increases output Y, yes, but since the growth in Y is subject K0 /N0 K1/N0 K/N to diminishing marginal returns, the 1 0 1 0 8.4 Rearranging the model – towards income per capita How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 337 337 2019/12/17 09:15 higher value of N implies that output per worker (or per capita income) decreases. Put differently, because the unchanging capital stock must be spread over more workers, dimin­ishing marginal returns set in, and Y does not expand proportionally to match the increase in N. Output per worker actually declines. NY remains constant though, as If both K and N are increased and in the same proportion, K does N (of course). ❐ Flowing from our assumption, for the production function, of constant returns to scale for in-tandem increases in N and K, total output Y will increase in proportion to the change in N and K. This means output per worker NY will remain constant. The economy remains at the same point on the TP curve. Once again, an improvement in technology or in social and economic institutions gives strikingly different results. Improvements that improve labour efficiency A will increase NK being required. output Y as well as output per worker NY without any change in K or N or Graphically, such an increase in A will rotate the TP curve and lengthen it up and towards Y . the right (from TP0 to TP2, say). Income per worker increases to N 2 0 8.5 Y Sources of sustained growth in – first conclusions N Economic growth in the sense of a sustained increase in GDP per capita, or rather NY , graphically implies (and requires) a sustained increase in the NY ratio on the vertical axis. An important question is the sources for such growth, and whether all apparent sources of growth can deliver such an outcome – or whether they can deliver it in the same way or with the same potency. We can examine this by repeating the analysis above in a ‘continually growing’ context: deducing how and whether each factor can deliver the required sustained increase in NY . Growing labour force and employment Sustained growth in the labour force and employment can cause growth in aggregate output and income Y, but income will grow slower than N and in such a way (being choked increasingly by diminishing marginal returns) that it actually leads to a decline in NY or per capita income. The average material standard of living of people will decline. NY . ❐ So N alone cannot produce sustained growth in Y or Growing capital stock Growth in the capital stock K (with constant N) will lead to growth in aggregate output Y (output per worker) will and income Y. Since the labour force remains constant, N increase/grow, suggesting that income per capita grows correspondingly. Graphically, the production point moves to the right along the TP curve. This demonstrates the unhappy truth that the growth in NY is constrained and ultimately capped by the slope of the TP curve, which reflects diminishing marginal returns to capital for increasing capital–labour ratios. NY can grow, but it cannot grow indefinitely. In fact, it will increase from one level to a higher one, and will then remain there. (Its growth rate will be positive only during this transition.) Y ❐ Thus, sustained growth in K alone cannot produce sustained growth in N . ❐ In addition, as we will see be­low, the move along TP is con­strained by being dependent on capital formation (investment) that has to be financed from savings (which comes out of GDP, i.e. Y). Forces will be at work to guide the NK ratio to a stable rest point. 338 Chapter 8: Macroeconomics in the very long run: growth theory How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 338 2019/12/17 09:15 Expanding human capital Although we will only discuss human capital H later, it is worth noting here that the impact of NY and growing human capital on per capita income is an important part of our eventual analysis. As we have noted, the impact of human capital on NY is thought to be similar to that of either physical capital K or labour efficiency A. (See the analysis in section 8.10.) What about natural resources as a source of growth? Countries rich in natural resources such as oil reserves or mineral deposits (e.g. gold, platinum, iron ore) clearly have a major economic advantage. The question is how to accommodate that in the production function and growth model. The basic answer is that natural resources form the resource base upon which K, N and A are applied in order to produce output Y. They do not have a separate effect on output, which depends on the utilisation of K, N and A. Therefore: ❐ In a growth model, their main impact is on the level of GDP (or the level of the GDP growth path). ❐ Since the extraction of such resources involves huge capital expenditure, there is also a capital effect – but also only on the level of GDP. ❐ However, natural resources do not determine the Y growth rate of Y (or N ). ❐ The infusion of new technology into mineral extraction and mining will, however, affect the growth rate of GDP. Growing labour and capital together Synchronised sustained growth in the labour force and the cap-ital stock will increase aggregate output in the same proportion (in terms of the assumption of constant return K to scale). N remains constant. This means, however, that output per worker, NY , remains constant in the long term. This is explained by the fact that the benefit of the growth in Y, caused by the growth in K, is partly negated by the growth in N, which reduces the per capita benefit. ❐ Thus, sustained growth in N and K together can also not produce sustained growth in NY . Technological and social institutions/labour efficiency Growth in labour efficiency due to progress in technology and/or social and economic institutions will improve the productive performance of an economy and increase Y. Moreover, since decreasing marginal returns to one of the main factors K and N are not NY due to policy growth in A will always remain equal to the growth involved, growth in rate of A, unlike the case with capital and labour growth. Graphically, TP can rotate and be elongated upwards and to the right over time without constraint. ❐ This produces one of the most important results of the Solow growth model: sustained growth NY , i.e. per capita GDP, can only be produced by sustained growth in labour efficiency resulting in from sustained progress in technology and institutions. (But also see section 8.10.) Historically, this factor, much more than capital accumulation, is understood to explain the most important eras of sustained growth in living standard in the USA and other countries, e.g. the post World War II period up to the middle 1970s. Y 8.5 Sources of sustained growth in N – first conclusions How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 339 339 2019/12/17 09:15 8.6 Is any capital–labour ratio possible? The idea of balanced growth A second set of results from the Solow growth model relates to the following key question for society and government: can a society choose to be at any point on a given TP curve? Can it move, or be pushed, as far right on the TP curve as it wishes? Preview: key points of this section 1. The only economic growth path that can be maintained for a very long period is one where a balance between output and the various factors of production is maintained. 2. Any other course will be subject to economic forces that gradually push the economy towards the balanced growth path. 8.6.1 The concept of balanced growth Assume for the moment that there is no growth in A, i.e. labour efficiency remains constant. This will enable us to focus on NY and NK . We will relax this assumption in section 8.7. The first question amounts to asking whether or not there is an optimal value of K relative to N, i.e. an optimal value of the NK ratio (the capital–labour or capital per worker ratio). Solow’s approach was the typical economist’s approach: he asked whether the course of the economy (the growth path and growth rate of Y) is unconstrained and unbounded, or whether there are either constraints or forces that push it towards rest values or, in favoured economic parlance, equilibrium values. An important result of Solow’s model is that there are indeed such rest points or balance points. ❐ In Solow’s model these are captured in the concept of balanced growth points, or steadystate growth points. One can thus study economic growth by analysing the pattern and behaviour of ‘stable points’ over time and analysing how the economy moves towards such stable points over time if it is not at such a point. We can now give our first definition of the concept of balanced growth. This is in terms of balanced growth in aggregate GDP (or Y). It will prepare the way for a more general definition, in section 8.7 below, in terms of balanced growth in per capita GDP. Balanced growth (in aggregate Y) is defined as a growing-economy situation in which the K Y ratios N and N remain constant. Y is growing in line with N, and K is growing in line with N. No variable is getting out of line with regard to any of the others. But there is sustained growth in aggregate output Y (equal to the growth rate in N and K). This means that both output and capital stock expand precisely in line with population growth. K ❐ In such a balanced growth situation, Y (capital intensity) remains constant. ❐ The striking thing about a balanced growth situation is that, when the economy is in such a state of growth, all these ratios remain constant while the many different variables in the economy change, vary and grow over time. ❐ Note that this particular definition is for balanced growth in aggregate Y, i.e. it is only for a situation where the aggregate growth (in Y) is such that there is no per capita Y growth (in N ). As we will see later, this is a situation where the factor A has no growth. For the more or less normal situation where A has positive growth, the definition will have to be broadened (section 8.7). 340 Chapter 8: Macroeconomics in the very long run: growth theory How_to_think_BOOK_2019.indb 340 2019/12/17 09:15 Defining such a point of balanced aggregate growth is not very interesting in itself. But Solow’s next conclusions are very interesting. (a) For a given set of conditions and parameters, there is only one balanced growth point. (b) Any point on TP off the balanced growth point cannot be kept going in the very long run. There are ‘gravitational’ forces at work, in the very long run, that pull the economy towards the balanced growth point. Let’s consider these in turn. 8.6.2 Conditions for a balanced growth point – a first version To pin down the concept of balanced growth, the question is: ar