Formulas You may detach this page, but turn it in with your exam. Second derivative test Let r > 0 and assume that all second order derivatives of the function f (x, y) are continuous at all points (x, y) that are within a distance r of (a, b). Assume that fx (a, b) = fy (a, b) = 0. Define D(x, y) = fxx (x, y)fyy (x, y) − [fxy (x, y)]2 If D(a, b) > 0 and fxx (a, b) > 0, then f (x, y) has a local minimum at (a, b). If D(a, b) > 0 and fxx (a, b) < 0, then f (x, y) has a local maximum at (a, b). If D(a, b) < 0, then f (x, y) has a saddle point at (a, b). If D(a, b) = 0, then we need more information to classify the critical point. The Simpson’s rule approximation is Z b ∆x f (x) dx ≈ [f (x0 ) + 4f (x1 ) + 2f (x2 ) + · · · + 2f (xn−2 ) + 4f (xn−1 ) + f (xn )] 3 a where n is even, ∆x = b−a n , and xi = a + i∆x. Assume that |f (4) (x)|≤ L for all a ≤ x ≤ b. Then the total error introduced by Z b L (b − a)5 f (x) dx is not greater than Simpson’s rule when approximating . 180 n4 a First-order linear differential equation Let a and b be constants. The differentiable dy function y(x) obeys the differential equation = a(y − b) if and only if dx ax y(x) = (y(0) − b) e + b. Selected Taylor series ex = sin(x) = cos(x) = 1 = 1−x ln(1 + x) = arctan x = ∞ X xn n=0 ∞ X n! (−1)n n=0 ∞ X (−1)n n=0 ∞ X (−1)n (−1)n n=0 1 2 1 x + x3 + · · · 2! 3! for all −∞ < x < ∞ 1 1 1 x2n+1 = x − x3 + x5 − · · · (2n + 1)! 3! 5! for all −∞ < x < ∞ 1 x2n (2n)! for all −∞ < x < ∞ xn n=0 ∞ X n=0 ∞ X =1+x+ =1− 1 2 1 x + x4 − · · · 2! 4! = 1 + x + x2 + x3 + · · · for all −1 < x < 1 xn+1 n+1 =x− x2 x3 x4 + − + ··· 2 3 4 for all −1 < x ≤ 1 x2n+1 2n + 1 =x− x3 x5 + − ··· 3 5 for all −1 ≤ x ≤ 1 Definitions You may detach this page, but turn it in with your exam. Marshallian and Hicksian Demand Let x be a quantity of good X, let y be a quantity of good Y , and let u(x, y) be the utility function of these two goods. Let px resp. py be the unit prices for good X resp. Y . The function xm (px , py , I) giving the optimal consumption of X to maximize u(x, y) subject to the budget constraint px x+py y = I is called the Marshallian demand function. Let U be the minimum level of utility required by the consumer. The Hicksian demand function xh (px , py , U ) gives the value of x that minimizes the cost function f (x, y) = px x + py y subject to the constraint u(x, y) ≥ U . Surplus Consider a supply curve S(q) and a demand curve D(q) with intersection point (qe , pe ). The consumer surplus is the area from q = 0 to q = qe under D(q) and above the line p = pe . The producer surplus is the area from q = 0 to qe over S(q) and under the line p = pe . The total surplus is the sum of consumer and producer surplus. Marginal and Total Cost and Revenue Let TC(q) be the total cost of producing q units of a particular good. TC(q) is the sum of the fixed cost, TC(0), and variable costs, TC(q)−TC(0). The marginal cost of production is d [TC(q)]. MC(q) = dq Let TR(q) be the total revenue collected from q units of output, with d TR(0) = 0. The marginal revenue is MR(q) = [TR(q)] and the unit dq TR(q) price is P(q) = q Expected Value, Variance, and Standard Deviation The expected value of P a discrete random variable X with sample space S is E(X) = x · P r(X = x). S P Its variance is V ar(X) = (x − E(X))2 · P r(X = x) = E(X 2 ) − [E(X)]2 . S The expected value of a continuous random variable X with PDF f (x) is R∞ R∞ E(X) = x · f (x) dx. Its variance is V ar(X) = (x − E(X))2 · f (x) dx = −∞ −∞ E(X 2 ) − [E(X)]2 . The standard deviation of a random variable X is σ(X) = p V ar(X). The Taylor Series for the function f (x) around the centre a is the power series ∞ (n) P f (a) (x − a)n . n! n=0