CHAPTER 7 The Cost of Production Prepared by: Fernando & Yvonn Quijano © 2008 Prentice Hall Business Publishing • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e. CHAPTER 7 OUTLINE 7.1 Measuring Cost: Which Costs Matter? 7.2 Cost in the Short Run Chapter 7 The Cost of Production 7.3 Cost in the Long Run 7.4 Long-Run versus Short-Run Cost Curves 7.5 Production with Two Outputs—Economies of Scope 7.6 Dynamic Changes in Costs—The Learning Curve 7.7 Estimating and Predicting Cost © 2008 Prentice Hall Business Publishing • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e. 2 of 49 Costs: Explicit vs. Implicit • Explicit costs require an outlay of money, e.g., paying wages to workers. Chapter 7 The Cost of Production • Implicit costs do not require a cash outlay, e.g., the opportunity cost of the owner’s time. • Both matter for firms’ decisions. © 2008 Prentice Hall Business Publishing • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e. 3 of 49 7.1 MEASURING COST: WHICH COSTS MATTER? Economic Cost versus Accounting Cost ● accounting cost: Actual expenses Chapter 7 The Cost of Production ● economic cost: Costs to a firm of utilizing economic resources in production, including opportunity cost. Opportunity Cost ● opportunity cost Cost associated with opportunities that are forgone when a firm’s resources are not put to their best alternative use. © 2008 Prentice Hall Business Publishing • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e. 4 of 49 EXAMPLE A man has a piece of land in his backyard. Decided to start a mango farm and work on it himself. Cost of saplings, fertilizers etc : Rs 200/week Price of mangoes (P) : Rs 100/Kg; He produces (Q) 10Kg/week His profit : Rs 1000-Rs 200 = Rs 800 Chapter 7 The Cost of Production Accounting profit He has an alternative to earn money: Work at the nearby McDonald’s for Rs 500/week and Rent out the land for Rs 500/week If he considers his foregone income for growing mangoes, his profit: Rs 1000 – Rs 200 – Rs 500 – Rs 500 = - Rs200 Economic Profit © 2008 Prentice Hall Business Publishing • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e. 5 of 49 Explicit vs. Implicit Costs: An Example You need $100,000 to start your business. The interest rate is 5%. • Case 1: borrow $100,000 Chapter 7 The Cost of Production – explicit cost = $5000 interest on loan • Case 2: use $40,000 of your savings, borrow the other $60,000 – explicit cost = $3000 (5%) interest on the loan – implicit cost = $2000 (5%) foregone interest you could have earned on your $40,000. In both cases, total (exp + imp) costs are $5000. © 2008 Prentice Hall Business Publishing • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e. 6 of 49 Economic Profit vs. Accounting Profit • Accounting profit = total revenue minus total explicit costs Chapter 7 The Cost of Production • Economic profit = total revenue minus total costs (including explicit and implicit costs) • Accounting profit ignores implicit costs, so it’s higher than economic profit. © 2008 Prentice Hall Business Publishing • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e. 7 of 49 7.1 MEASURING COST: WHICH COSTS MATTER? Sunk Costs ● sunk cost Expenditure that has been made and cannot be recovered. Chapter 7 The Cost of Production Because a sunk cost cannot be recovered, it should not influence the firm’s decisions. For example, consider the purchase of specialized equipment for a plant. Suppose the equipment can be used to do only what it was originally designed for and cannot be converted for alternative use. The expenditure on this equipment is a sunk cost. Because it has no alternative use, its opportunity cost is zero. Thus it should not be included as part of the firm’s economic costs. © 2008 Prentice Hall Business Publishing • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e. 8 of 49 7.1 MEASURING COST: WHICH COSTS MATTER? Fixed Costs and Variable Costs Chapter 7 The Cost of Production ● total cost (TC or C) Total economic cost of production, consisting of fixed and variable costs. ● fixed cost (FC) Cost that does not vary with the level of output and that can be eliminated only by shutting down. ● variable cost (VC) as output varies. Cost that varies © 2008 Prentice Hall Business Publishing • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e. 9 of 49 7.1 MEASURING COST: WHICH COSTS MATTER? Fixed Costs and Variable Costs How do we know which costs are fixed and which are variable? Chapter 7 The Cost of Production Over a very short time horizon—say, a few months—most costs are fixed. Over such a short period, a firm is usually obligated to pay for contracted shipments of materials. Over a very long time horizon—say, ten years—nearly all costs are variable. Workers and managers can be laid off (or employment can be reduced by attrition), and much of the machinery can be sold off or not replaced as it becomes obsolete and is scrapped. © 2008 Prentice Hall Business Publishing • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e. 10 of 49 7.1 MEASURING COST: WHICH COSTS MATTER? Fixed versus Sunk Costs Sunk costs are costs that have been incurred and cannot be recovered. Chapter 7 The Cost of Production An example is the cost of R&D to a pharmaceutical company to develop and test a new drug and then, if the drug has been proven to be safe and effective, the cost of marketing it. Whether the drug is a success or a failure, these costs cannot be recovered and thus are sunk. © 2008 Prentice Hall Business Publishing • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e. 11 of 49 7.1 MEASURING COST: WHICH COSTS MATTER? It is important to understand the characteristics of production costs and to be able to identify which costs are fixed, which are variable, and which are sunk. Chapter 7 The Cost of Production Good examples include the personal computer industry (where most costs are variable), the computer software industry (where most costs are sunk), and the pizzeria business (where most costs are fixed). Because computers are very similar, competition is intense, and profitability depends on the ability to keep costs down. Most important are the variable cost of components and labor. A software firm will spend a large amount of money to develop a new application. The company can try to recoup its investment by selling as many copies of the program as possible. For the pizzeria, sunk costs are fairly low because equipment can be resold if the pizzeria goes out of business. Variable costs are low—mainly the ingredients for pizza and perhaps wages for a couple of workers to help produce, serve, and deliver pizzas. © 2008 Prentice Hall Business Publishing • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e. 12 of 49 Recap: MPL = Slope of Prod Function Q Chapter 7 The Cost of Production (no. of (bushels MPL workers) of wheat) 0 0 1 1000 2 1800 3 2400 4 2800 5 3000 1000 800 600 400 200 MPL 3,000 Quantity of output L equals the slope of the 2,500 production function. 2,000 Notice that MPL diminishes 1,500 as L increases. 1,000 This explains why the 500 production function gets flatter 0 as L 0increases. 1 2 3 4 5 No. of workers © 2008 Prentice Hall Business Publishing • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e. 13 of 49 Recap: Why MPL Is Important • When Farmer Jack hires an extra worker, Chapter 7 The Cost of Production – his costs rise by the wage he pays the worker – his output rises by MPL • Comparing them helps Jack decide whether he should hire the worker. © 2008 Prentice Hall Business Publishing • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e. 14 of 49 EXAMPLE 1: Farmer Jack’s Costs • Farmer Jack must pay $1000 per month for the land, regardless of how much wheat he grows. Chapter 7 The Cost of Production • The market wage for a farm worker is $2000 per month. • So Farmer Jack’s costs are related to how much wheat he produces…. © 2008 Prentice Hall Business Publishing • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e. 15 of 49 EXAMPLE 1: Farmer Jack’s Costs L Q Chapter 7 The Cost of Production (no. of (bushels workers) of wheat) Cost of land Cost of labor Total Cost 0 0 $1,000 $0 $1,000 1 1000 $1,000 $2,000 $3,000 2 1800 $1,000 $4,000 $5,000 3 2400 $1,000 $6,000 $7,000 4 2800 $1,000 $8,000 $9,000 5 3000 $1,000 $10,000 $11,000 © 2008 Prentice Hall Business Publishing • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e. 16 of 49 7.1 MEASURING COST: WHICH COSTS MATTER? Marginal and Average Cost Marginal Cost (MC) Chapter 7 The Cost of Production ● marginal cost (MC) Increase in cost resulting from the production of one extra unit of output. Because fixed cost does not change as the firm’s level of output changes, marginal cost is equal to the increase in variable cost or the increase in total cost that results from an extra unit of output. We can therefore write marginal cost as © 2008 Prentice Hall Business Publishing • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e. 17 of 49 7.1 MEASURING COST: WHICH COSTS MATTER? Marginal and Average Cost Marginal Cost (MC) TABLE 7.1 Chapter 7 The Cost of Production Rate of Output (Units per Year) A Firm’s Costs Fixed Cost (Dollars per Year) Variable Cost (Dollars per Year) Total Cost (Dollars per Year) Marginal Cost (Dollars per Unit) Average Fixed Cost (Dollars per Unit) Average Variable Cost (Dollars per Unit) Average Total Cost (Dollars per Unit) (FC) (1) (VC) (2) (TC) (3) (MC) (4) (AFC) (5) (AVC) (6) (ATC) (7) 0 50 0 50 -- -- -- 1 50 50 100 50 50 50 100 2 50 78 128 28 25 39 64 3 50 98 148 20 16.7 32.7 49.3 4 50 112 162 14 12.5 28 40.5 5 50 130 180 18 10 26 36 6 50 150 200 20 8.3 25 33.3 7 50 175 225 25 7.1 25 32.1 8 50 204 254 29 6.3 25.5 31.8 9 50 242 292 38 5.6 26.9 32.4 10 50 300 350 58 5 30 35 11 50 385 435 85 4.5 35 39.5 © 2008 Prentice Hall Business Publishing • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e. -- 18 of 49 7.1 MEASURING COST: WHICH COSTS MATTER? Marginal and Average Cost Average Total Cost (ATC) Chapter 7 The Cost of Production ● average total cost (ATC) Firm’s total cost divided by its level of output. ● average fixed cost (AFC) Fixed cost divided by the level of output. ● average variable cost (AVC) Variable cost divided by the level of output. © 2008 Prentice Hall Business Publishing • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e. 19 of 49 You try… Calculating costs Fill in the blank spaces of this table. Q VC Chapter 7 The Cost of Production 0 1 10 2 30 TC AFC AVC ATC $50 n/a n/a n/a $10 $60.00 80 3 16.67 4 100 5 150 6 210 150 20 12.50 36.67 8.33 $10 30 37.50 30 260 MC 35 43.33 © 2008 Prentice Hall Business Publishing • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e. © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use. 60 20 of 49 You try.. Answers Chapter 7 The Cost of Production Use AFC == FC ///Q ATC AVC TC VC Q Q= between First,relationship deduce FC $50 andMC useand FC TC + VC = TC. Q VC TC AFC AVC ATC 0 $0 $50 n/a n/a n/a 1 10 60 $50.00 $10 $60.00 2 30 80 25.00 15 40.00 3 60 110 16.67 20 36.67 4 100 150 12.50 25 37.50 5 150 200 10.00 30 40.00 6 210 260 8.33 35 43.33 © 2008 Prentice Hall Business Publishing • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e. © 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part, except for use as permitted in a license distributed with a certain product or service or otherwise on a password-protected website for classroom use. MC $10 20 30 40 50 60 21 of 49 As Q rises: $200 Initially, falling AFC pulls ATC down. $175 Eventually, rising AVC pulls ATC up. Efficient scale: The quantity that minimizes ATC. $150 Costs Chapter 7 The Cost of Production EXAMPLE 2: Why ATC Is Usually U-Shaped $125 $100 $75 $50 $25 $0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Q © 2008 Prentice Hall Business Publishing • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e. 22 of 49 EXAMPLE 2: ATC and MC When MC < ATC, ATC is falling. $175 $150 Costs Chapter 7 The Cost of Production When MC > ATC, ATC is rising. The MC curve crosses the ATC curve at the ATC curve’s minimum. ATC MC $200 $125 $100 $75 $50 $25 $0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Q © 2008 Prentice Hall Business Publishing • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e. 23 of 49 Chapter 7 The Cost of Production Costs in the Short Run & Long Run • Short run: Some inputs are fixed (e.g., factories, land). The costs of these inputs are FC. • Long run: All inputs are variable (e.g., firms can build more factories, or sell existing ones). • In the long run, ATC at any Q is cost per unit using the most efficient mix of inputs for that Q (e.g., the factory size with the lowest ATC). Diminishing Marginal Returns and Marginal Cost Diminishing marginal returns means that the marginal product of labor declines as the quantity of labor employed increases. As a result, when there are diminishing marginal returns, marginal cost will increase as output increases. © 2008 Prentice Hall Business Publishing • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e. 24 of 49 7.2 COST IN THE SHORT RUN The Shapes of the Cost Curves Figure 7.1 Chapter 7 The Cost of Production Cost Curves for a Firm In (a) total cost TC is the vertical sum of fixed cost FC and variable cost VC. In (b) average total cost ATC is the sum of average variable cost AVC and average fixed cost AFC. Marginal cost MC crosses the average variable cost and average total cost curves at their minimum points. © 2008 Prentice Hall Business Publishing • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e. 25 of 49 7.2 COST IN THE SHORT RUN The Shapes of the Cost Curves Chapter 7 The Cost of Production The Average-Marginal Relationship Consider the line drawn from origin to point A in (a). The slope of the line measures average variable cost (a total cost of $175 divided by an output of 7, or a cost per unit of $25). Because the slope of the VC curve is the marginal cost , the tangent to the VC curve at A is the marginal cost of production when output is 7. At A, this marginal cost of $25 is equal to the average variable cost of $25 because average variable cost is minimized at this output. © 2008 Prentice Hall Business Publishing • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e. 26 of 49 Example: LRATC with 3 factory sizes Chapter 7 The Cost of Production Firm can choose from three factory Avg Total sizes: S, M, L. Cost Each size has its own SRATC curve. ATCS ATCM The firm can change to a different factory size in the long run, but not in the short run. © 2008 Prentice Hall Business Publishing • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e. ATCL Q 27 of 49 A Typical LRATC Curve Chapter 7 The Cost of Production In the real world, factories come in many sizes, each with its own SRATC curve. ATC LRATC So a typical LRATC curve looks like this: Q © 2008 Prentice Hall Business Publishing • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e. 28 of 49 7.4 LONG-RUN VERSUS SHORT-RUN COST CURVES Long-Run Average Cost Figure 7.8 Chapter 7 The Cost of Production Long-Run Average and Marginal Cost When a firm is producing at an output at which the longrun average cost LAC is falling, the long-run marginal cost LMC is less than LAC. Conversely, when LAC is increasing, LMC is greater than LAC. The two curves intersect at A, where the LAC curve achieves its minimum. © 2008 Prentice Hall Business Publishing • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e. 29 of 49 7.4 LONG-RUN VERSUS SHORT-RUN COST CURVES Long-Run Average Cost Chapter 7 The Cost of Production ● long-run average cost curve (LAC) Curve relating average cost of production to output when all inputs, including capital, are variable. ● short-run average cost curve (SAC) Curve relating average cost of production to output when level of capital is fixed. ● long-run marginal cost curve (LMC) Curve showing the change in long-run total cost as output is increased incrementally by 1 unit. © 2008 Prentice Hall Business Publishing • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e. 30 of 49 How ATC Changes as the Scale of Production Changes Chapter 7 The Cost of Production Economies of scale: ATC falls as Q increases. ATC LRATC Constant returns to scale: ATC stays the same as Q increases. Diseconomies of scale: ATC rises as Q increases. © 2008 Prentice Hall Business Publishing • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e. Q 31 of 49 7.4 LONG-RUN VERSUS SHORT-RUN COST CURVES Economies and Diseconomies of Scale As output increases, the firm’s average cost of producing that output is likely to decline, at least to a point. This can happen for the following reasons: Chapter 7 The Cost of Production 1. If the firm operates on a larger scale, workers can specialize in the activities at which they are most productive. 2. Scale can provide flexibility. By varying the combination of inputs utilized to produce the firm’s output, managers can organize the production process more effectively. 3. The firm may be able to acquire some production inputs at lower cost because it is buying them in large quantities and can therefore negotiate better prices. The mix of inputs might change with the scale of the firm’s operation if managers take advantage of lower-cost inputs. © 2008 Prentice Hall Business Publishing • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e. 32 of 49 7.4 LONG-RUN VERSUS SHORT-RUN COST CURVES Economies and Diseconomies of Scale At some point, however, it is likely that the average cost of production will begin to increase with output. There are three reasons for this shift: Chapter 7 The Cost of Production 1. At least in the short run, factory space and machinery may make it more difficult for workers to do their jobs effectively. 2. Managing a larger firm may become more complex and inefficient as the number of tasks increases. 3. The advantages of buying in bulk may have disappeared once certain quantities are reached. At some point, available supplies of key inputs may be limited, pushing their costs up. © 2008 Prentice Hall Business Publishing • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e. 33 of 49 7.4 LONG-RUN VERSUS SHORT-RUN COST CURVES Economies and Diseconomies of Scale Chapter 7 The Cost of Production ● economies of scale Situation in which output can be doubled for less than a doubling of cost. ● diseconomies of scale Situation in which a doubling of output requires more than a doubling of cost. Increasing Returns to Scale: Output more than doubles when the quantities of all inputs are doubled. Economies of Scale: A doubling of output requires less than a doubling of cost. © 2008 Prentice Hall Business Publishing • Microeconomics • Pindyck/Rubinfeld, 7e. 34 of 49