Banking as Insurance • Banks as suppliers of liquidity • (What is liquidity?) Insurance problem • Demand-deposit contracts • Bank runs • The case for suspension of convertibility and deposit insurance • How markets and contracts interact 1 The Diamond and Dybvig (1983) model 1.1 • The environment A continuum of consumers with preferences u (c1 , c2 ) = u (c1 + θc2 ) • θ ∈ {0, 1} • If θ=1 is an idiosyncratic shock, realized at the consumer is late or patient, otherwise he is early or impatient • π ≡ Pr (θ = 0). By LLN, π is also the fraction of early consumers in the population • Each consumer has an endowment of • Two possible technologies: t = 1. Storage: transforms x goods at t 1 at into 1 t=0 x 1 As goods at t+1 you know, this requires abusing the law of large numbers. See Judd (1985) on why this is a problem and Uhlig (1996) on how to x it. 1 Econ 661 • Fall 2019 t = 0 into Ry > y goods at t = 2. The investment can be terminated early (liquidated) at t = 1. If z ≤ y units are liquidated, then the investment yields λz goods at t = 1 and R (y − z) goods at t = 2. Assume λ ≤ 1. Long-term investment: transforms Note: original paper has of technology is 1.2 • λ = 1, y goods at so the storage technology is redundant not the main issue. ⇒ the ex-ante choice First-best planner problem Assume (it's easy to prove) that the solution is symmetrical, that it involves early consumers consuming at t=1 and late consumers consuming at t=2 and that no long-term projects are liquidated max πu (c1 ) + (1 − π) u (c2 ) c1 ,c2 ,x,y s.t. πc1 ≤ x (1 − π) c2 ≤ Ry x+y =1 or equivalently max πu (c1 ) + (1 − π) u (c2 ) c1 ,c2 ,x,y s.t. πc1 + (1 − π) • c2 ≤1 R FOC: πu0 (c1 ) − µπ = 0 1 (1 − π) u0 (c2 ) − µ (1 − π) = 0 R so • MRS = MRT • What if types are not observable? u0 (c1 ) =R u0 (c2 ) (1) Planner can set up a mechanism: (early or late) and you get a consumption bundle in return. • The rst best allocation is incentive compatible! 2 R>1 implies c2 > c1 declare your type Econ 661 1.3 Fall 2019 Complete markets allocation • Markets for consumption at • Assume (it's easy to prove) again that in equilibrium the agent only buys positive amounts t = 1 and t = 2 contingent on realization of θ for each individual. of the following contingent claims: c1 if impatient (at price p1 ) and c2 if patient (at price p2 ) max πu (c1 ) + (1 − π) u (c2 ) c1 ,c2 s.t. p1 c1 + p2 c2 ≤ 1 with FOC: • 1 − π p1 u0 (c1 ) = 0 u (c2 ) π p2 t = 0 goods into π1 units of the contingent units of the contingent claim c2 if patient . Competition By using the LLN, rms can transform one unit of R claim c1 if impatient, or into 1−π implies p1 = π 1−π p2 = R • Therefore u0 (c1 ) =R u0 (c2 ) and we recover the rst best allocation. • (There's nothing special about this, it just illustrates the Second Welfare Theorem) • Anything other than this which arises in the model must be a result of some form of market incompleteness 1.4 Incomplete markets • Suppose there are no insurance markets • The only market is at t = 1, where agents can trade equivalently, ongoing projects) • Let the price of t=2 goods at t=1 be p. 3 t=1 goods against t=2 goods (or, Econ 661 • Fall 2019 The consumer's problem is max πu (c1 ) + (1 − π) u (c2 ) c1 ,c2 ,x,y s.t. c1 ≤ x + pRy x c2 ≤ Ry + p x+y =1 • In any equilibrium where consumers invest in both technologies, it must be that p= • If p> 1 R 1 , then it is always preferable to invest in the long-term technology at R t=1 all early consumers will be trying to sell at and nobody would buy 1 , then it is always preferable to invest in storage at t = 0, but then all late consumers R 1 cannot be the equilibrium price. would be willing to pay 1 for t = 2 goods, so p < R • If • Therefore the consumer's problem reduces to p< max πu (c1 ) + (1 − π) u (c2 ) c1 ,c2 s.t. c1 ≤ 1 c2 ≤ R • The allocation c1 = 1 c2 = R does not in general coincide with the complete markets allocation • t = 0, but then Allocations coincide for the special case of log preferences: General optimality condition: Special case of log so the allocation c1 = 1, c2 = R u0 (c1 ) =R u0 (c2 ) c2 =R c1 satises optimality 4 Econ 661 • Fall 2019 Assume that the consumer is more risk averse than log, i.e. u00 (c) c − 0 u (c) | {z } > 1 ∀c coecient of relative risk aversion • Then cF1 B > 1 and cF2 B < R. 0 Proof: 0 Z R Ru (R) = u (1) + 1 = u0 (1) + Z ∂cu0 (c) dc ∂c R [cu00 (c) + u0 (c)] dc 1 00 Z R cu (c) 0 0 u (c) = u (1) + + 1 dc u0 (c) 1 < u0 (1) 1.5 A bank • Consumers get together and create a bank • They each deposit their endowment with the bank, which invests the rst best amount in each technology • The bank sets up the following contract: each consumer can ask for wait until t=2 cF1 B at t = 1, or can and get a pro-rata share of whatever is left. • Demand deposit • The bank commits to satisfying sequential service: satisfy consumer's withdrawals in the order in which they arrive (which, assume, is random) • If the stored goods are not enough to satisfy a consumer who demands payment, then the bank must liquidate the long-term investment until that, too, runs out. • Consumers then play a game, where the actions are withdraw or wait (or you could allow for partial withdrawal, it doesn't matter) • Let fj be the number of depositors who arrived in line before consumer j withdraw and f be the total number of consumers that will eventually ask to withdraw 5 and asked to Econ 661 • Fall 2019 The payos for an impatient consumer are: Withdraw c F B if 0 otherwise 1 • Wait cF1 B fj < xF B + λy F B The payos for a patient consumer are: 2 Withdraw c F B if 0 otherwise 1 • 0 Wait cF1 B fj < xF B + λy F B n o 1 FB B 1−πcF 1 −(f −π) λ c1 max R ,0 1−f Derivation: If The rst best allocation has invested in the long-term technology. consumers who f consumers withdraw, this requires f cF1 B goods at t=1 πcF1 B invested in storage and 1 − πcF1 B FB Therefore (f − π) c1v of the t = 1 goods from withdraw have to come from liquidating long-term projects • This requires liquidating Each produces These will be split among the R 1 λ goods at (f − π) cF1 B t = 2, for a total of 1−f 1−πcF1 B −(f − π) λ1 cF1 B R 1 − πcF1 B − (f − π) λ1 cF1 B projects, so only remain depositors who did not withdraw The symmetric straegy prole withdraw i impatient is a Nash equilibrium, with payos equal to the rst best allocation. Impatient consumers don't want to deviate because they don't care about future consumption • Patient consumers don't want to deviate because cF2 B > cF1 B The symmetric strategy prole withdraw no matter what is also a Nash equilibrium Given that cF1 B > 1 ≥ xF B + λy F B , if everyone tries to withdraw the money will run out Therefore anyone who waits will obtain zero This justies withdrawing This equilibrium produces a very bad allocation! 2 These payos are accurate for the case where f ≥ π, which will be true in equilibrium because all impatient consumers withdraw. To be fully correct you have to take into account that if f < π you need to use storage between t = 1 and t = 2 6 Econ 661 • Fall 2019 Note on strategic complementarity: Best response is a step function of UW ithdraw − UW ait f is not globally increasing in f Goldstein and Pauzner (2005) show how to solve for a unique equilibrium if one assumes incomplete information as in Morris and Shin (1998) 1.6 Suspension of convertibility • One variant of the contract can rule out the bad equilibrium • The contract states that you can withdraw cF1 B at t = 1 as long as less than π other consumers have withdrawn before you. After that, you are forced to wait • Now the payos for an impatient consumer are: Withdraw c F B if 0 otherwise 1 • fj < π Wait 0 3 and the payos for a patient consumer are: Withdraw c F B if 0 otherwise 1 fj < π Wait cF2 B • So now waiting is dominant for patient consumers, and runs will not take place. • There won't be suspension of convertibility in equilibrium • Problem: you need to know 1.7 • π exactly in order to use these contracts! Remarks Liquidity transformation as a form of insurance, not provided by narrow banking (Wallace 1996) • We'll come back to the idea of narrow banking later on. What is the reason for the sequential-service constraint? What does it mean? 3 Again, you would need to take into account what happens if f < π 7 Econ 661 Fall 2019 Wallace (1988) camping trip economy. Minnesota approach to microfoundations Also Green and Lin (2003), Ennis and Keister (2009) • Why have a bank rather than a direct mechanism? • Deposit insurance as a way to undo the sequential service constraint • 2 Can work even with stochastic Taxation can be conditioned on aggregate withdrawals π Chicken models and the why doesn't the government just do everything argument. The Jacklin (1987) critique • Jacklin (1987) makes three related points: 1. Under the Diamond and Dybvig (1983) assumptions, you don't really need a bank, equity is good enough 2. The Diamond and Dybvig (1983) assumptions are very special. Under more general preferences: (a) You can do more with an bank than with equity (b) A bank may or may not be able to achieve the rst best 3. If there is a market, a bank that is useful cannot survive 2.1 Who needs a bank? • Suppose instead of a bank consumers set up a rm • The rm invests the rst-best amount and issues shares. Each consumer gets one share • It declares (and commits to) the following dividend policy: a dividend of paid at • t=1 and a dividend of Consumers can trade shares in the rm at dividends) at a price of • d2 = (1 − π) cF2 B will be paid at p t = 1 goods per share. Supply of shares (impatient consumers sell): S=π 8 d1 = πcF1 B will be t=2 (they trade ex-dividend - after paying Econ 661 • Fall 2019 Demand for shares (patient consumers perhaps buy): D= • (1−π)d1 if 0 otherwise p p < d2 Market clearing: (1 − π) d1 p (1 − π) d1 = (1 − π) cF1 B p= π π= • This is sometimes known as cash-in-the-market pricing Buyers are at a corner solution. They would want to buy more but have no more money. Consumption attained by early consumers c1 = d1 + p = cF1 B • Consumption attained by late consumers d1 c2 = d 2 1 + p FB = (1 − π) c2 1+ πcF1 B (1 − π) cF1 B = cF2 B • 2.2 • No need for demand deposits, no risk of bank runs! General preferences Diamond and Dybvig (1983) assume a very special form of preferences. Consider the more general formulation: ( u (c1 , c2 , θ) = where uE and uL uE (c1 , c2 ) uL (c1 , c2 ) with prob are smooth functions Original version is uE = u (c1 ), uL = u (c1 + c2 ) 9 θ 1−θ with prob Econ 661 Fall 2019 To keep the spirit of the original model, you may assume that uL1 (c1 , c2 ) uE 1 (c1 , c2 ) > uE uL2 (c1 , c2 ) 2 (c1 , c2 ) so that early and late are still meaningful terms, but the argument doesn't depend on this. • Planner problem: max E L L cE 1 ,c2 ,c1 ,c2 E L cL1 , cL2 θuE cE 1 , c2 + (1 − θ) u s.t. E c2 cL2 E L θ c1 + + (1 − θ) c1 + R R • Before we assumed (it was obvious) that the planner went to a corner, so he was only choosing two numbers • First order conditions: L uE 1 (·) = u1 (·) L uE 2 (·) = u2 (·) uE 1 =R E u2 • May or may not be incentive compatible • Edgeworth box illustration: 10 Econ 661 Fall 2019 early consumer c2 late consumer c1 11 Diamond & Dybvig Allocation Econ 661 Fall 2019 early consumer mirror image c2 late consumer interior allocation c1 12 Econ 661 Fall 2019 early consumer c2 late consumer mirror image c1 • General deposit contracts: give the depositor the following options at Bundle E E : cE 1 , c2 Bundle L: cL1 , cL2 cE1 , cE2 , cL1 , cL2 t=1 or are any four numbers. Original version, assuming corner solution, constrains this to Contracts that make sense are those that respect resouce constraints and incentive cE 2 = 0 and compatibility (They might be vulnerable to runs, but we don't worry about this here) 13 cL1 = 0 Econ 661 • Fall 2019 If social optimum is incentive compatible, implementable via deposits Proof: trivial Otherwise, social optimum not implementable and need to think about incentive-constrained or second-best optimum • What can you do with equity contracts? Notice the following about the FB allocation in the original model The price of shares is p = (1 − π) cF1 B Shares pay a dividend of d2 = (1 − π) cF2 B Eectively, the price of t=2 godds at t=1 q= is: cF B p = 1F B d2 c2 Patient households have MRS of Both types go to a corner; neither equates price to MRS. The FOCs for the planner in 1; impatient household have and MRS of ∞. the smooth case DO NOT hold • The consumption bundles of each type cost the same at the equilibrium prices This NOT a general property In general, equity contracts can implement the rst best if and only if two allocations cost the same at the equilibrium price • 2.3 More restrictive conditions that for implementation via deposits In general case, deposits are useful relative to equity Free riding and trading restrictions • Go back to original model • Suppose that, after a bank/rm is set up, at trade t=2 goods against t=1 t = 1 a market opens where consumers can goods • What is the price? • The bank/rm oers consumers either cF1 B at 14 t=1 or cF2 B at t=2 Econ 661 • Therefore the price of • • Fall 2019 t=2 goods in terms of t=1 goods must be B cF 1 . F B c2 q= Otherwise, either withdrawing or not-withdrawing is dominant Consider a free-riding strategy: Don't join the bank/rm Invest in the long term technology If you are impatient, sell your long term project at If you are patient, hold on to your project and consume at t=1 t=2 This delivers c1 = Rq = R cF1 B > cF1 B cF2 B c2 = R > cF2 B so the bank\rm would unravel! • The same issue would arise in the equity implementation of the planner's allocation • In general, opening a market of any kind at t = 1 means that you cannot attain with deposits any more than you can attain with equity. • Pecuniary externality: Investing in the bank rather than in long-term projects increases rate between periods 1 and 2) by making t=1 q (lowers the interest goods more abundant This is good for insurance purposes (it makes up for the missing insurance market) Without restrictions, individuals do not internalize the externality so they invest in long-term projects rather than in the bank • Restrictions on trading are needed to sustain these insurance-like arrangements. Are they reasonable? • This relates to the microfoundations of the sequential service constraint In the camping economy of Wallace (1988) a 15 t=1 market is impossible Econ 661 3 Fall 2019 The Holmström and Tirole (1998) Model 3.1 Environment • Three periods: • Consumers 0, 1, 2 Utility u = c0 + c1 + c2 • Large endowments at each of the three periods Entrepreneurs Utility u = c0 + c1 + c2 Endowment Can carry out a project of scale Output is realized at Pr (y) = pH A or at pL t=0 t=2 I and can be yI or 0 depending on entrepreneur's eort Lack of eort gives utility At B t = 1 the project needs an extra amount of money ρI in order to continue (e.g. some machines broke down). This is the assumption then adopted by Lorenzoni (2008). ρ ∼ F (ρ) You can call If the entrepreneur does not invest ρ a liquidity shock ρ then the project terminates and pays private benet of shirking also goes away if the project is terminated • Assumption: Z Z max {pH y − ρ, 0} dF (ρ) − 1 > 0 > • max {pL y + B − ρ, 0} dF (ρ) − 1 Timing: 1. Investment takes place 2. ρ is realized 3. Either ρ is reinvested or the project is terminated 16 0. The Econ 661 Fall 2019 4. Entrepreneur chooses eort 5. Output is realized • The fact the eort is chosen after the reinvestment decision is really important. It means that even at that stage there is a limit to how much the entrepreneur can pledge to consumers 3.2 • Second-best allocation Contracts between entrepreneur and consumers specify: The size of the investment When the project will be terminated I (equivalently the loan amount λ (ρ) ∈ {0, 1} I − A) (later we allow for fractional liqui- dation) The dividends paid to each party de , dc if the project succeeds, possibly depending on the size of the liquidity shock • Solve Z max I pH de (ρ) λ (ρ) dF (ρ) Z s.t. I [pH dc (ρ) − ρ] λ (ρ) dF (ρ) ≥ I − A I,de (ρ),dc (ρ),λ(ρ) de (ρ) ∆p ≥ B dc (ρ) + de (ρ) = y • Note that the implicit assumption is that the consumer agrees to pay for both the gap in the entrepreneur's initial funds and the liquidity shock (in those cases where they agree that the shock will be met) • Since entrepreneurs gets surplus, objective is equivalent to just maximizing surplus Z I • It's immediate (from linearity) that the optimum will be given by a cuto shock is met i • [pH y − ρ] λ (ρ) dF (ρ) − 1 ρ < ρ̂ and the project is terminated otherwise Dene ρ 1 = pH y • ρ1 is the expected value of the project (per unit of investment) 17 ρ̂ such that the Econ 661 Fall 2019 • In the rst-best allocation, the cuto would be • Dene ρ0 = pH • ρ0 ρ1 B y− ∆p is the maximum divident the entrepreneur can promise the consumers while still satisfying the IR constraint • Why is this a useful thing to compute? At If they don't meet the liquidity shock, both parties lose everything The entrepreneur can credibly promise t = 1, than ρ0 the parties will always nd some way to meet the liquidity shock if it is less suade them to put up ρ0 ρ0 to the consumers, so he will be able to per- in order not to lose everything • Moral hazard model is just one way to justiy nonpledgeability • What matters for the rest of the analysis is just the values of • (At MIT people knew this model in its various incarnations as the ρ0 -ρ1 model ') • Holmström and Tirole (2011) is a book-length version of this paper, where ρ0 and ρ1 ρ0 and ρ1 are taken as primitives of the model • Write the program as ρ̂ Z max I I,ρ̂ Z s.t. I [ρ1 − ρ] dF (ρ) − 1 0 ρ̂ [ρ0 − ρ] dF (ρ) ≥ I − A 0 • Assume that Z ρ0 [ρ0 − ρ] dF (ρ) < 1 0 Economically, this means that maximum pledgeable income after meeting liquidity shocks is not enough to pay for invesment Otherwise investment would go to The entrepreneur will need to put in his own money to be able to invest at all ∞ 18 Econ 661 • Fall 2019 Let Z m (ρ̂) ≡ ρ̂ [ρ1 − ρ] dF (ρ) − 1 0 k (ρ̂) ≡ • m (ρ̂) • k (ρ̂) 1 1− R ρ̂ 0 1 = [ρ0 − ρ] dF (ρ) 1+ 0 ρdF (ρ) − ρ0 F (ρ̂) is the marginal net social return on investment. It is maximized at ρ̂ = ρ1 is the equity multiplier. It measures how much investment can take place for each unit of the entrepreneur's wealth. It is maximized at • R ρ̂ ρ̂ = ρ0 The problem reduces to max U (ρ̂) = m (ρ̂) k (ρ̂) A ρ̂ R ρ̂ [ρ1 − ρ] dF (ρ) − 1 0 = A R ρ̂ 1 + 0 ρdF (ρ) − ρ0 F (ρ̂) = ρ1 − R ρ̂ 0 • R ρ̂ 0 ρdF (ρ)+1 F (ρ̂) ρdF (ρ)+1 F (ρ̂) ρ∗ = arg min ρ̂ • (2) − ρ0 Therefore the optimal cutof solves R ρ̂ • A 0 ρdF (ρ) + 1 F (ρ̂) Interpretation: minimize the cost per unit of investment that reaches period Numerator: Total cost Denominator: Number of projects that reach What is the tradeo ? 19 t=2 (3) 2 Econ 661 • Fall 2019 FOC: ∗ ∗ ∗ ∗ ρ f (ρ ) F (ρ ) − f (ρ ) R ρ∗ 0 ρdF (ρ) + 1 =0 [F (ρ∗ )]2 R ρ∗ ∗ ρf (ρ) dρ + 1 F (ρ∗ ) R ρ∗ ρ∗ F (ρ∗ ) − 0 F (ρ) dρ + 1 = F (ρ∗ ) 0 ρ = Z ρ∗ F (ρ) dρ = 1 (4) ρ1 − ρ∗ A ρ∗ − ρ0 (5) 0 • Therefore: U= (This follows from integration by parts in equation (4): ∗ Z ∗ ρ F (ρ ) − ρ∗ ρf (ρ) dρ = 1 0 ρ∗ = 1+ R ρ∗ ρf (ρ) dρ F (ρ∗ ) 0 and replacing in (2) • 3.3 • What happens if there is a mean-preserving spread in Lower Higher utility Why? F (ρ)? ρ∗ Implementation Pure loan doesn't work: Lend At Lenders are willing to be diluted by the new lenders who provide I −A t = 1, at t=0 in exchange for some promise at entrepreneur needs t=2 ρ ρ because otherwise they will lose everything (They will of course require compensation ex-ante for this possibility) New lenders could be the same people as old lenders or dierent ones 20 Econ 661 Fall 2019 At So whenever t = 1, the most that the entrepreneur can pledge to new lenders is ρ ∈ (ρ0 , ρ∗ ), ρ0 the second-best-optimal thing to do would be to continue the project, but we will need to terminate it! • Initial loan plus line of credit Lend (For simplicity, suppose that at I −A t = 1. at t=0 and grant an irrevocable line of credit for ρ ρ∗ I is observable, or that the entrepreneur cannot consume Otherwise you have to worry about entrepreneurs claiming they've had a bad liquidity shock and running away with they money) In exchange for this, the entrepreneur promises Notice that the consumers need to be able to commit to the line of credit For at • ρ ∈ (ρ0 , ρ∗ ), the extra money they put up at t = 1 is less than what they will recover t = 2, so they are making an expected loss! That's the point of a line of credit! Material adverse change clauses Would the parties want to renegotiate? To lower credit line? To higher credit line? Large initial loan plus liquid assets Lend Contractually limit investment to exactly ρI I − A + ρ∗ I I and agree that the entrepreneur will keep in liquid assets (Requires that such liquid assets exist!) When the liquidity shock comes, the entrepreneur meets it with the liquid assets The entrepreneur promises Notice that the entrepreneur would in general not want to choose the right combination ρ0 I + (ρ∗ − ρ) I of investment/liquid assets at • to the lender. ∗ • ρ0 I t = 0. to the consumers The investment level has to be enforceable Contrast this to the Diamond and Dybvig (1983) version of liquidity shocks Why not rely on the market at D&D: there is no market H&T: the market will say no t = 1? What if consumers cannot commit (and there is no storage technology)? 21 Econ 661 Fall 2019 No commitment ∗ 3.4 • ⇒ no credit line Similar issue in Lorenzoni (2008) No storage Liquid assets cannot be claims on consumers, because consumers cannot commit They cannot be stored goods because goods are not storable Firms can acquire claims on other rms ⇒ what are the liquid assets? Do we have enough of them? Idiosyncratic ρ shocks Paper argues that intermediary is necessary: direct stakes in rms are not enough. This is actually wrong (problem set) • Similar issue in D&D: actually, equity can be enough! The total amount of resources needed at t=1 to implement the second best allocation is ρ∗ Z D=I ρdF (ρ) 0 • An intermediary is set up at • The intermediary obtains • (There are many rms and the law of large numbers applies: there is no aggregate risk) • The intermediary also oers a credit line to rms for an amount of • In exchange, the intermediary gets a claim to t=0 I −A from investors in exchange for shares and lends it to rms ρ0 I at t=2 ρ∗ I from each rm (but the rm of course will not pay if the project is terminated) • The intermediary can commit to the credit line, but this doesn't solve the problem, because the intermediary does not have an endowment at t = 1: it must persuade consumers to give up some endowment. • At • It can sell its claims on • Is this enough? t=0 the intermediary has to nd t=2 D to honour the credit lines. ouptut to consumers, obtaining up to ∗ F (ρ∗ ) ρ0 I . ρ∗ Z F (ρ ) ρ0 I − I ρdF (ρ) = I − A > 0 0 so yes, by selling its claims on rms to consumers the intermediary can satisfy the credit line and have some left over, which it will then use to repay the original investment 22 I −A Econ 661 Fall 2019 • There is enough inside liquidity to implement the second-best allocation • Liquidity here is used to mean something like credible promises of goods at a specic date 3.5 Aggregate ρ shocks • Now suppose that all rms have the same • Now whenever ρ shock ρ ∈ (ρ0 , ρ∗ ) the value of the intermediary's portfolio (assuming that the second best allocation is implemented) will be ρ0 I • But in order to face the liquidity shock it needs to raise ρI > ρ0 I which is not possible even by selling all its holdings to consumers • Therefore this doesn't work • The economy does not generate sucient inside liquidity 3.6 Government bonds • Suppose that, although consumers can't commit, the government can commit for them! • i.e. the government can issue debt and credibly promise to tax consumers in order to pay back its debt • Now government debt plays the role of a storage technology! • Outside liquidity • We can go back to implementing the second-best allocation • Is this a chicken model? 3.7 Liquidity premium on bonds • Suppose that shocks are aggregate / there is just one rm • There is a limited supply of government bonds, so that in equilibrium they trade at a price q>1 • (i.e. you pay q at t=0 to get 1 at t = 1) How does that change the optimal decision of rms? 23 Econ 661 • Fall 2019 Invest Meet liquidity shock until some cuto In order to do so, hold (because you can always raise I (ρ̂ − ρ0 ) I ρ0 ρ̂ government bonds at t=1 by diluting the original investors) Program is: Z ρ̂ [ρ1 − ρ] dF (ρ) − 1 − (q − 1) (ρ̂ − ρ0 ) Z ρ̂ ρdF (ρ) + (q − 1) (ρ̂ − ρ0 ) I s.t. F (ρ̂) ρ0 I ≥ I − A + I max I I,de ,dc ,λ(ρ) 0 0 • Now 1 k (ρ̂, q) = R ρ̂ 1 + 0 ρdF (ρ) − ρ0 F (ρ̂) + (q − 1) (ρ̂ − ρ0 ) Z ρ̂ m (ρ̂, q) = [ρ1 − ρ] dF (ρ) − 1 − (q − 1) (ρ̂ − ρ0 ) 0 • And, again, the problem can be rewritten as max k (ρ̂, q) m (ρ̂, q) A ρ̂ • As before, the optimal cuto will satisfy ∗ ρ = arg min 3.8 1+ R ρ̂ 0 ρdF (ρ) + (q − 1) (ρ̂ − ρ0 ) F (ρ̂) The Jacklin (1987) critique rears its ugly head • Suppose all rms are doing the optimal policy of holding bonds • A single rms can deviate and choose to buy shares in other rms instead of bonds • (The expected return on shares is • What is the value of shares at 1> t=1 1 , so they are better than bonds in that sense) q when ρ ∈ (ρ0 , ρ∗ )? (ρ∗ − ρ) I (i.e. the value of excess bonds that are not needed because the shock is only 24 ρ) Econ 661 • Fall 2019 By buying enough shares in other rms the rm can implement the q = 1-second-best allocation • And investors will be willing to lend it enough money to buy these shares at they are pledgeable and have a return of 3.9 • t=0 because 1 Partial liquidation Is a simple cuto still the correct solution of the problem? termination. We buy z Suppose we could do partial bonds and use these to either partially or fully meet the liquidity shock Z [ρ1 − ρ0 ] λ (ρ, z) dF (ρ) max I Z s.t. I 0 • I,,λ(ρ,z),z ∞ ∞ 0 [ρ0 − ρ] λ (ρ, z) dF (ρ) ≥ I − A + I (q − 1) z z λ (ρ, z) ≤ min 1, ρ − ρ0 Notice here we express the objective as the entrepreneur's surplus rather than total surplus. Because IR binds, this is equivalent. The paper switches back and forth in order to be harder to follow. • Let • The entrepreneur will choose the maximum possible continuation (i.e. δ be the multiplier on the investor's IR constraint. n o z λ (ρ, z) ≤ min 1, ρ−ρ ) 0 i ρ1 − ρ0 + δ [ρ0 − ρ] > 0 ⇔ρ< • The choice of z is governed by Z ρ̄ ρ0+z • ρ1 − ρ0 (1 − δ) ≡ ρ̄ δ ∂λ (ρ, z) · [ρ1 − ρ0 + δ (ρ0 − ρ)] dF (ρ) − δ (q − 1) = 0 ∂z q > 1 implies that partial liquidation will indeed be used! ∂λ(ρ,z) use partial liquidation, we would have = 0 a.s., which ∂z (6) Note that (if we had enough bonds to not is not optimal according to (6) 25 Econ 661 3.10 • Fall 2019 The demand for liquidity Go back to the case without partial liquidation (the same holds in the case with partial liquidation) • We had that ∗ ρ = arg min 1+ R ρ̂ 0 ρ̂ ρdF (ρ) + (q − 1) (ρ̂ − ρ0 ) F (ρ̂) • Demand for bonds will be decreasing in • At some • At • Shape of demand curve for bonds • Evidence from Krishnamurthy and Vissing-Jorgensen (2012) q=1 q max q liquidity will be so expensive that projects will just be infeasible consumers become willing to buy government bonds. 26 Econ 661 Fall 2019 References Diamond, D. W. and Dybvig, P. H.: 1983, Bank runs, deposit insurance, and liquidity, Political Economy 91(3), 401419. Journal of Ennis, H. M. and Keister, T.: 2009, Run equilibria in the green-lin model of nancial intermediation, Journal of Economic Theory 144(5), 1996 2020. Goldstein, I. and Pauzner, A.: 2005, Demand-deposit contracts and the probability of bank runs, The Journal of Finance 60(3), 12931327. Green, E. J. and Lin, P.: 2003, Implementing ecient allocations in a model of nancial intermediation, Journal of Economic Theory 109, 123. Holmström, B. and Tirole, J.: 1998, Private and public supply of liquidity, Economy 106(1), 140. Holmström, B. and Tirole, J.: 2011, Journal of Political Inside and Outside Liquidity, Vol. 1 of MIT Press Books, The MIT Press. Jacklin, C. J.: 1987, Demand deposits, trading restrictions, and risk sharing, N. Wallace (eds), Contractual arrangements for intertemporal trade, in E. C. Prescott and University of Minnesota Press, pp. 2647. Judd, K. L.: 1985, The law of large numbers with a continuum of iid random variables, of Economic Theory 35(1), 1925. Journal Krishnamurthy, A. and Vissing-Jorgensen, A.: 2012, The aggregate demand for treasury debt, Journal of Political Economy 120(2), 233267. Lorenzoni, G.: 2008, Inecient credit booms, Review of Economic Studies 75(3), 809833. Morris, S. and Shin, H. S.: 1998, Unique equilibrium in a model of self-fullling currency attacks, American Economic Review 88(3), 587597. Uhlig, H.: 1996, A law of large numbers for large economies, Economic Theory 8(1), 4150. Wallace, N.: 1988, Another attempt to explain an illiquid banking: the diamond-dybvig model with sequential service taken seriously, 12, 316. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review Wallace, N.: 1996, Narrow banking meets the diamond-dybvig model, Minneapolis Quarterly Review 20(1), 313. 27 Federal Reserve Bank of