UNIVERSITY OF UEH SCHOOL OF ECONOMY, LAW AND STATE MANAGEMENT ECONOMICS FINAL PROJECT DEPARTMENT OF URBAN ECONOMICS Topic: Revisiting the effects of housing transfer taxes Lectuer: Lê Thành Nhân Class code : 22C1ECO50113811 Group 5’s members: Nguyễn Anh Thư 31211025549 Nguyễn Thị Ngọc Huệ 31211026513 Nguyễn Hoàng Phúc 31211021324 Trần Thị Ngọc Bích 31211027018 Nguyễn Nhất Hoàng 31211023293 Revisiting the effects of housing transfer taxes Housing transfer taxes are important in many countries despite evidence of substantial welfare costs. We assume that welfare costs are larger than previously thought because previous studies have ignored spillovers between treatment and control groups. We analyze the effect of a transfer tax on household mobility using a quasi test arising from a tax reform. The housing transfer tax has an impact not only on household mobility and the allocation of housing units to households, but also on the distribution of labor to workers. The paper's key finding is that transfer taxes have a large detrimental influence on mobility. A study by the team of authors Essi Eerola, Oskari Harjunen, Teemu Lyytikäinen, Tuukka Saarimaa in 2021 examined the impact of a housing transfer tax on household mobility, set in Finland as typical examples. According to the findings of the study, the reform reduces the migration rate of homeowners living in apartments in the model by 7.2%. An assessment of the reform's impact would underestimate the reform's negative impact on the mobility of homeowners living in apartments by 22%. Impact of housing transfer tax The author claims that even though house transfer taxes are frequently seen as an ineffective kind of taxation, they are nonetheless crucial economically in many nations. The introduction of that transfer tax diminishes the possibility of a transaction that benefits both parties since it widens the gap between the price paid for the residence and the price obtained by the seller. Additionally, the household's relocation family is impacted by transfer taxes since they relate to housing transactions and the distribution of employment among workers in nations like the UK and the US where most households own a property. Application of property transfer tax in Finland All residential purchases in Finland, whether for brand-new homes or renovated older ones, are subject to a housing transfer tax. The transfer tax is the buyer's responsibility, and only after the tax authorities have received the transfer tax payment does the buyer acquire legal ownership of the property. Under 40-year-old first-time buyers are exempt from taxation. Not all transactions are subject to the same tax rate in the United States, like many other nations. The kind of housing unit determines the tax rate under the Finnish system. The tax rates on properties, such as single-family homes, are currently 2% for units in a housing cooperative and 4% for. This essentially reduces the tax base. In the case of real estate, the ownership arrangement is simpler: the system and, often, the entire plot of land beneath the structure are directly owned by one person. The researchers refer to these housing units as homes because every property is a single-family home. The authors of the study took advantage of a tax adjustment that raised the transfer tax burden on flats while leaving housing taxes constant. The transfer tax rate for homes is 4% till February 2013 and 1.6% for apartments. The major objectives of the reform were to raise tax revenue and harmonize the tax treatment of houses and apartments. The size of housing cooperative loans had grown before the reform, particularly for newly constructed dwellings, according to the government's proposed law, thus weakening the tax base. The reform is anticipated to increase annual tax income from the 580 million euros (0.3% of GDP) collected in 2012 to approximately 80 million euros. Increases in tax rates and shares that result from the growth of the tax base are anticipated to account for more than 50% of this increase. December 5, 2012, saw the official announcement of the reform. Data and research design The data are Statistical from Finland and cover the entire population of Finland from 2005 to 2016. The data contains registration information about households including where they reside at the end of the year, regardless of the household. owner or tenant. Exploit the change of tax reform (incremental). In Finland, a housing transfer tax is applied to all housing transactions, both new construction, and resale. First-time buyers under the age of 40 are exempted. Based on 2 units which are houses and apartments. The measure of mobility is based on the location and characteristics of the home unit. A household will move out if at least one of the following occurs (between the end of years t-1 and t): postcode, type of housing unit (owned apartment, owned house rented unit), and the number of rooms. Table 1 reports summary statistics for the homeowner households in our data. Table 2 we decompose the annual mobility rates according to housing type before and after the tax reform. Compare the mobility of households after the tax increase and vice versa in Finland, where taxes have been increased on apartments. As taxes are increased on apartment transactions, this results in lower mobility among homeowners living in apartments. When home taxes are not increased, we can construct the opposite using homeowners living in homes as a control group. The data will be convenient to use the DID method. The parameter for the interaction term, 𝛿3 explains the term under 3 assumptions: + The assumption is about the general trend, i.e., without the countermeasures, the likelihood of movement will develop similarly. + The second assumption is that no other reform or event coincides with the transfer tax reform and affects the treatment and different control groups. + The third is that the mobility of households in the control group is not affected by the mobility decisions of households in the treatment group. This assumption is not true if the two segmented housing markets are interconnected. After presenting the baseline DID results, construct a housing market model and calibrate it to replicate the mobility rates between the housing market segments in our data and the DID processing efficiency. There are 2 issues to be concerned about, the first is the skewness of the estimate to zero and the reduction in mobility because households move out in January and February (tax announced in October and taking place in March next year). The second problem is that households planning to move out will move before the end of 2012 leading to bias. Solve these 2 problems by checking for certainty. Results Their key conclusion is that the transfer tax seriously hampers mobility. They discover that a 0.5 percentage point increase in the transfer tax rate results in a 7.2% reduction in treatment group mobility by combining quasi-experimental analysis with a model-based analysis. A 22% downward bias in the estimate is indicated by their DID estimate of the effect, which is approximately 5.6%. Because mobility falls by 1.6% in the control group as well, there is a bias. Taking into account the spillover impact, our estimate for the reform's cost in terms of public monies is 2.3, whereas the estimate based solely on the DID estimate would be 1.3. The welfare costs of the transfer tax would be significantly underestimated if the spillover effect were to be ignored. Moreover, their findings imply that the negative effects of transfer taxes may be significantly underestimated by using conventional quasi-experimental empirical methodologies. Their extensive registration data, which includes specifics on the characteristics of households and their housing units, enables them to get a more thorough picture of the consequences of the tax change on the labor and housing markets in addition to the general effects. As examples, see Munch et al. (2006), Battu et al. (2008), and Yang 2019 for analyses of outcomes pertaining to the labor markets. However, they also discover negative effects on long-distance moves (more than 50 km), indicating that the transfer tax also has an impact on the labor market. They find that the transfer tax has a stronger impact on short-distance moves (less than 50 km). In contrast to this finding, Hilber and Lyytikäinen (2017) paper, the only one to examine mobility rather than transactions, indicates that the transfer tax has no significant impact on mobility. The literature on housing consumption over the life cycle (e.g., Ortalo-Magné and Rady, 2006; Flavin and Nakagawa, 2008; Attanasio et al., 2012; and Li et al., 2016) has identified a number of margins of housing consumption changes. In their second investigation, they look into these margins. The tax increase had the greatest impact on moves involving minor changes in dwelling unit size, as one might anticipate. Downsizing had little impact while upsizing became less common due to the asymmetrical nature of these impacts. This asymmetry is consistent with a life-cycle model where creditconstrained households gradually climb the housing ladder by making small upgrades in unit size with numerous moves and downsizing, possibly only once towards the life-end. cycle's See, for example, Ortalo-Magné and Rady (2006) and Attanasio et al. (2012). All of these findings point to the fact that Consequences of the policy and its application Property transfer taxes are important in many countries despite evidence of substantial welfare costs.We analyze the effect of the transfer tax on household mobility using a quasi test arising from tax reform. The housing transfer tax has an impact not only on household mobility and the allocation of housing units to households, but also on the distribution of labor among workers. The important finding of the paper is that the transfer tax has a large detrimental effect on mobility. According to the results of the study, the reform reduced the migration rate of homeowners living in the model apartments by 7.2%. The type of housing unit determines the tax rate according to the Finnish system. Tax rates on properties, such as single-family homes, are currently 2% for units in a housing cooperative and 4% for assets. The transfer tax rate for houses is 4% until June 2013 and 1.6% for apartments. The main goals of the reform were to increase tax revenue and harmonize tax treatment for houses and apartments. The size of housing cooperative loans had increased before the reform, especially for newly built housing, under the government's proposed law, thus weakening the tax base. The reform is expected to increase annual tax income from 580 million euros (0.3% of GDP) collected in 2012 to around 80 million euros. In the Finnish system, the tax rate depends on the type of housing unit. On March 1, 2013, the transfer tax rate for apartments was raised from 1.6% to 2% and the tax base was expanded to include loans from housing cooperatives associated with apartments. household. For example, for an apartment with a transaction price of 200,000 euros and an outstanding loan from the housing cooperative of 20,000 euros, the transfer tax liability is 3200 euros (1.6% × 200,000) before the reform.After the reform, the tax liability increased to 4400 euros (2% × (200,000 + 20,000)). First, the migration rate was clearly higher in the treatment group than in the control group over the time period. In our data, the weights are of no practical importance because the standard errors are almost identical. The time series nature of the data raises the additional problem of sequential correlation of error terms (Bertrand et al., 2004), but this is a minor concern in our context later. when controlling for the overall effects of the year. Finally, by increasing moving costs for people living in apartments, tax reform may have made it less likely for households to move into apartments. Housing transfer taxes are important in many countries despite evidence of substantial welfare costs. An assessment of the reform's impact would underestimate the mobility of homeowners living in apartments by 22%. All residential purchases in Finland are subject to a housing transfer tax. In Finland, a housing transfer tax is applied to all housing transactions, both new construction, and resale. As taxes are increased on apartment transactions, this results in lower mobility among homeowners living in apartments. We compare the mobility of households before and after the tax reform in Finland. After presenting the baseline results, construct a housing market model and calibrate it to replicate the mobility rates between the housing market segments in our data. There are 2 issues to be concerned about, the skewness of the estimate to zero and the reduction in mobility because households move out in January and February. For four years prior to the financial crisis, mobility rates are higher in the treatment group than in the control group. After the tax rate on apartments is raised from 1.5% to 2%, mobility rates for owners of apartments fall by 7.2%. Tax reform in Finland reduced the migration rate of homeowners living in model apartments by 7.2%. This summary is based on a research paper by EssiEerola, OskariHarjunen, TeemuLyy &TuukkaSaarimaa ( Volume 124, July 2021, 103367). Revisiting the effects of housing transfer taxes. https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0094119021000498?via%3Dihub