11/4/2015 Professor Milton Friedman Interview Professor Milton Friedman Interviewed by Radio Australia 17 July 1998 listen education glossary transcript Professor Milton Friedman received the 1976 Nobel Prize for Economic Science. He has been a senior research fellow at the Hoover Institution, Stanford, California, since 1977 and is Paul Snowden Russell Distinguished Service Professor Emeritus of Economics at the University of Chicago. Radio Australia: Professor Friedman, may I first ask you what you think was the main impact of the Keynesian orthodoxy on public policy which, basically since the Great Depression, tended to influence economic policy makers around the world? Professor Friedman: It certainly did, although the effect was primarily, I'd say, after World War II. Keynes's book, after all, came out in 1936 and only three years elapsed after that before the world was at war. So the main effect was after the war and the effect was very extensive, there's no question about that, and it still exists. The effect was to encourage politicians to do what politicians love to do: spend money and not raise taxes. The Keynesian theory; not as Keynes himself necessarily presented it, but as it was interpreted in the intellectual community, the media and the political community; said that if you have high unemployment, the way to solve that is to cut taxes, increase government spending and create a government deficit. The government could have created the deficit entirely by cutting taxes and not increasing spending, but if you're sitting in the House of Commons in London or in your counterpart in Canberra or in Washington, obviously the thing you'd like to do is increase spending. So the major effect of the Keynesian orthodoxy in the post war period was to encourage an expansion in government spending as a fraction of income and to contribute to the inflation of the 1970s, not because of the spending, but because of the loose monetary policies that went along with it. http://www.abc.net.au/money/vault/extras/extra5.htm 1/12 11/4/2015 Professor Milton Friedman Interview RA: Well, why do you think that Keynesian economics has gone out of favour when, as you've said, it tended to be the major theoretical paradigm in the post war period? Professor Friedman: It went out of fashion to some extent, but I think it's much too strong a statement to say that it's out of fashion. It is no longer accepted in the academic community in its original, more rigid form. But in terms of the effect on policy, it's still very strong. For example, Washington is currently advising Japan to get out of its trouble (and Japan is in deep trouble). What is Washington's advice? Fiscal stimulus; spend more; cut tax. It's bad advice. Japan has introduced fiscal stimulus five times in the past seven or eight years and each time it's been a failure and that's not a surprise. Fiscal stimulus is not stimulating in and of itself, in my opinion. I think the Keynesian view is wrong on that issue. Fiscal stimulus has generally been accompanied by monetary expansion and then monetary expansion has been stimulating. However, in the Japanese experiments of the last five or seven years, fiscal stimulus has been accompanied by a restrictive monetary policy rather than an expansive monetary policy and the result has been that you've had continued recession or depression. If the Keynesian orthodoxy were out of fashion, Washington would be giving Japan very different advice. It would be saying to Japan: 'Well, maybe it's a good idea for you to cut taxes in order to increase incentives, but there is no need for the government to increase spending, that's a bad thing to do. What you should do is encourage a more expansive monetary policy.' So I think it's much too strong to say that Keynesian orthodoxy is out of fashion. RA: Well, quite clearly, Professor Friedman, you do believe still that monetarism is relevant for the economic conditions and the challenges that are facing us today. Could you perhaps expand on that and explain to a lot of our listeners who have no training in economics what the basic tenets of monetarism are and why they are still relevant http://www.abc.net.au/money/vault/extras/extra5.htm 2/12 11/4/2015 Professor Milton Friedman Interview today? Professor Friedman: I would be very glad to do that. In the first place, the reason Keynesian orthodoxy came so much into favour was because of a widespread misinterpretation of the Great Depression. The contraction from 1929 to 1933 in the United States and on to 1936 in France ‐ and different dates in different countries around the world ‐ was without question the most severe economic difficulty that the United States had ever experienced. It was widely interpreted as showing that monetary policy couldn't work. It was interpreted that way, of course, because all of the central bankers kept saying that they were following easy money policies and that the economy was declining in spite of, and not because of their actions. But when Anna Schwartz and I examined the history of that period in detail, we found that the situation was very different. In the United States from 1929 to 1933, the quantity of money declined by a third. Similarly in Britain, it declined till 1931, when Britain went off the gold standard. In France, the reason the contraction kept on until 1936 was because France insisted on staying on the gold standard and kept the money supply declining. To go back to the United States, at all times from 1929 and 1933, the Federal Reserve had the power and ability to have prevented the decline in the quantity of money and to have increased the quantity of money at any desired rate. So in our opinion, the Great Depression was not a sign of the failure of monetary policy or a result of the failure of the market system as was widely interpreted. It was instead a consequence of a very serious government failure, in particular a failure in the monetary authorities to do what they'd initially been set up to do. When the Federal Reserve Act was passed in 1913, its major purpose was to prevent 'banking panics' as they were called, temporary crises that had occurred in the United States in 1907 and during earlier periods. What it did was to preside over the worst banking panic in the history of the United States. Not only did the quantity of money go down by a third, but about a third of the banks failed and in the Spring of 1933, the Federal Reserve System, which had been set up to prevent banking panics, closed its doors itself and stopped operating. That's a disgraceful performance and was the reason why, on the one hand, the role of monetary policy was denigrated for a while, but on the other hand, why the demonstration that monetary policy had played a major negative role in producing the Great Depression promoted a revival of interest in monetary policy. http://www.abc.net.au/money/vault/extras/extra5.htm 3/12 11/4/2015 Professor Milton Friedman Interview RA: Professor Friedman, can I just take you up on this point about the central banks, or at least some central banks? Some of them don't seem to believe that they can target the money supply through the money base to control the inflation rate and instead seem to have primarily targeted interest rates. Do you think that has occurred, at least in some central banks around the world and what are its implications for monetary policy? Professor Friedman: That is a question not of basic principle, but of technique. When they so‐called 'target the interest rate', what they're doing is controlling the money supply via the interest rate. The interest rate is only an intermediary instrument. There's only one thing that all of the central banks control and that is the base, their own liability, and they can control that in various ways. They can control it directly by open market operations, buying and selling government securities or other assets, for example, buying and selling gold, or they can control it indirectly by altering the rate at which banks lend to one another. The central banks cannot control interest rates. That's a mistake. They can control a particular rate, such as the Federal Funds rate, if they want to, but they can't control interest rates. If central banks could control interest rates, you never would have had interest rates at 10‐15% in the late 1970s. If they could control interest rates, would Brazil now be having interest rates in the 20‐30% range? What central banks can control is a base and one way they can control the base is via manipulating a particular interest rate, such as a Federal Funds rate, the overnight rate at which banks lend to one another. But they use that control to control what happens to the quantity of money. There is no disagreement. No central banker today would disagree with the proposition that inflation is primarily a monetary phenomenon. Not one of them will disagree that every inflation has been accompanied by a rapid increase in the quantity of money and every deflation by a decline in the quantity of money. I believe that this argument about interest rates versus the base really takes you off the main track. RA: http://www.abc.net.au/money/vault/extras/extra5.htm 4/12 11/4/2015 Professor Milton Friedman Interview Thank you very much. I think people will be very interested to hear your comments there. Can we move to something else which perhaps isn't getting a very good press among ordinary members of the community and that's the floating exchange rates? A lot of citizens ‐ not to mention a lot of politicians ‐ around the world, particularly in Malaysia, have expressed concerns about the apparent uncertainties that come with floating exchange rates. As we've seen, that's been exacerbated in the recent Asian financial crisis. In your view can any case be made for a return to the fixed exchange rate regime? Professor Friedman: Which fixed exchange rate regime do you want to return to? Do you want to return to the gold standard of the 19th Century? Do you want to return to the pseudo‐fixed exchange rate of Bretton Woods? What fixed exchange rate do you want to return to? RA: Well, could you perhaps explain how the system of fixed exchange rates worked as it was before we saw the floating of the exchange rate? Professor Friedman: Yes, there's really a great confusion about the meaning of fixed exchange rates, as my comments have just illustrated. There are, in fact, three fundamental ways in which a country can order its exchange rates. It can have a truly fixed exchange rate, which means that it eliminates its central bank, and adopts a policy such as pegging its currency to gold. It will buy and sell gold at a fixed rate or it can establish a currency board, as Hong Kong has done in your part of the world. Hong Kong does not have a central bank; it has fixed its exchange rate to the US dollar. In effect, it says, we will let the Federal Reserve make our monetary policy. Hong Kong is, as it were, a designated thirteenth Federal Reserve district. The United States has a fixed exchange rate between the different states. California uses the same dollar as New York. Australia has a fixed exchange rate between its different states. Both New South Wales and Victoria use the Australian dollar. Now, in the same way, Panama uses the US dollar, although it calls it by a different name. Hong Kong says that 7.8 Hong Kong dollars equals one US dollar and they use the US dollar, fundamentally, as their currency. The reason they do it through a currency board instead of through direct http://www.abc.net.au/money/vault/extras/extra5.htm 5/12 11/4/2015 Professor Milton Friedman Interview dollarisation, is very clear. In the first place, it enables them to get what economists call 'seigniorage.' When the Federal Reserve Board issues dollars, essentially it's borrowing money at a zero interest rate. People who hold those dollars are, in effect, lending resources to the US government and therefore the US government is benefiting by the interest that could be earned on those funds. That's what's called 'seigniorage,' in fact, it's called 'seigniorage' because it refers to the benefit the seignior or the lord got from issuing money or from stamping his picture on coins. If Hong Kong were literally to use the US dollar and not print any of its own [money], the US would get the seigniorage from the currency that was printed. By establishing a currency board in which they say 7.8 Hong Kong dollars equals one US dollar and conducting the currency board so that for every 7.8 Hong Kong dollars in existence in Hong Kong it holds at least one US dollar, it can invest those US dollars in government bonds and other assets and earn interest on them and so Hong Kong gets the seigniorage instead of the United States. That's why you have a currency board instead of straight dollarisation. But that is a truly fixed exchange rate. The second way of arranging the exchange system is the way that Thailand, Korea and so on adopted before the crash last year. [This involved] a pegged exchange rate in which they said, 'we are going to instruct the central bank to act in such a way as to keep the local currency exchanging for the US dollar at a fixed rate'. Now they didn't have to peg to the US dollar, they could have pegged to the Yen and indeed they would have been much better off if they had done so. They could also have pegged to the German Mark. Indeed, some countries have pegged to a combination of currencies, through a mixture of the Mark and the dollar, for example. That's a fundamentally different arrangement, because it involves keeping a Central Bank and it's an arrangement that's a recipe for trouble. This is what happened in East Asia. The Central Bank followed internal monetary policies that were not consistent with keeping the exchange rate at the designated peg and sooner or later there was a collapse. Whenever you have a pegged exchange rate system like that, it has a tendency to let small problems accumulate into big ones and then to create a crisis. This is true, I may say, not only among small countries like Thailand or Korea. Several times in the 1950s and 1960s, Great Britain had similar exchange crises arising from exactly the same thing. It was trying to peg its currency, at http://www.abc.net.au/money/vault/extras/extra5.htm 6/12 11/4/2015 Professor Milton Friedman Interview that time under Bretton Woods, to the US dollar, and its Central Bank was behaving in a way that was not consistent with that. So, lo and behold, you had an exchange crisis and a devaluation. The same thing happened in 1992 and 1993, when you had the crisis in the European common market and when Britain and Italy both broke away because their pegged exchange rates were not consistent with what their central banks were doing. The third method of having an exchange rate system is to have a floating exchange rate. Now, a floating exchange rate is one in which the government does not intervene in the exchange rate market but allows the market to set its own values. [Here you find] one very interesting historical phenomenon. No nation that has had a floating exchange rate has ever had external currency crisis in international finance. Why is it that the East Asian crisis hasn't affected New Zealand, close neighbour to Australia? It hasn't affected New Zealand, because New Zealand has a truly floating exchange rate. Has it affected Australia? I don't know the details about Australia. But Australia has a quasi‐floating exchange rate and that has insulated it. RA: So, in short, do you think that some people are perhaps drawing the wrong lessons from the Asian economic troubles? Professor Friedman: They are drawing the wrong lessons. The lesson for Asia is; if you have a central bank, have a floating exchange rate; if you want to have a fixed exchange rate, abolish your central bank and adopt a currency board instead. Either extreme; a fixed exchange rate through a currency board, but no central bank, or a central bank plus truly floating exchange rates; either of those is a tenable arrangement. But a pegged exchange rate with a central bank is a recipe for trouble. RA: Perhaps could we move to another common perception or misconception about the price of the dollar? Many ordinary people seem to think that it's the screen jockeys, as I think they've become known, who hang on the news from around the world. It's those (some people would say economically illiterate) screen jockeys who determine exchange rates at the moment. Could you perhaps explain, as http://www.abc.net.au/money/vault/extras/extra5.htm 7/12 11/4/2015 Professor Milton Friedman Interview an economist, who actually does the determining of the exchange rates in this flexible rate regime? Professor Friedman: Well, in a day‐to‐day term, the speculators, whom you are describing, can have some influence. But let me ask a very simple question: You are a speculator. How can you make money and how can you lose money? You can only make money if you buy a product, whatever it is ‐ maybe a currency, maybe wheat and maybe something else ‐ at a relatively low price and sell it at a higher price than you buy it at. There's no other way to make money. If you buy at a relatively low price, you're making that price higher than it otherwise would be. If you're selling at a relatively high price, you're making that price lower than it otherwise will be. If speculators make money, on the whole ‐ there are some rare theoretical exceptions ‐ but, on the whole, they make the market more stable, not less stable. However, when you have the kind of pegged exchange rate situation we were talking about, there's an invitation for speculators, because they're given a one way ride. They can't lose because the government is a counter‐party and what happens is that speculators can make money because the government is going to lose money. The government, in effect, is following a policy which is not tenable. It's following an internal monetary policy which is not consistent with the exchange rates they're trying to pay. And yet, they try to peg it. This process gives speculators a one‐way option. However, in floating exchange rate markets, speculators can only make money if they help to stabilise a market, not if they make it more unstable. Over anything but the shortest period, a month or two months or three months, the exchange rates and the flexible exchange rate system are determined by two fundamental forces: one is trade ‐ imports, exports and the comparative advantage of the country in question in respect to exports ‐ and the second is capital movements. If a country is an attractive place for foreigners to invest their funds, then that country will have a relatively high exchange rate. If it's an unattractive place, it will have a relatively low exchange rate. Those are the fundamentals that determine the exchange rate in a floating exchange rate system. Let me emphasise that there's nothing special about exchange rates. If Australia tries to peg the price of wool ‐ let's say wool is a major product of Australia ‐ and if it sets the price too high, it'll have the same effects as if the exchange rate is set at too high a rate. If it sets it too high, then there will be a surplus of people http://www.abc.net.au/money/vault/extras/extra5.htm 8/12 11/4/2015 Professor Milton Friedman Interview trying to sell wool and a shortage of people trying to buy wool. If it sets it too low, it'll be the other way around. And the government can maintain the price only if it is willing to accumulate stocks of wool in the one case or to provide wool from inventories in the other. Everything I've just said about wool applies just as well to the Thai baht. RA: Could we now look more broadly at how governments around the world are coping with the economic challenges of the last couple of decades? We've seen the floating of exchange rates, and before that, the floating of the dollar. Would you say that governments today are more receptive to the arguments and policies that you set out in your book 'Capitalism and Freedom', which I think you published back in 1962? Do you think that's the case and how do you explain that? Professor Friedman: Well, in the first place, you have to distinguish between rhetoric and practice. There's no doubt that the rhetoric comes closer to what I was talking about in 'Capitalism and Freedom', but part of the reason it does that is because practice has gone further away. I shouldn't speak about Australia because I don't know enough about it. But the United States, Great Britain, Germany, France, almost every major country I know anything about, has a bigger government, larger government spending, more intrusive government and more rules and regulations than they had in 1962 when 'Capitalism and Freedom' was published and I bemoaned at the time the fact that government was too big and too intrusive! The practice has gone the other way, but rhetoric has changed. The reason it's changed is because the public at large has learned a lesson that governments of that kind are very expensive, impose very high taxes and are very inefficient. The actual results of policies are almost always the opposite of the intended results of policies. A government which claims that it's going to cut unemployment, generally ends up having higher unemployment than one that keeps quiet about it. Governments have also been proclaiming for years that they are going to eliminate poverty and in fact, welfare systems in the United States and Britain and elsewhere have not been effective in achieving their objectives. So the public themselves have gotten rather fed up with excessively large and intrusive government. In http://www.abc.net.au/money/vault/extras/extra5.htm 9/12 11/4/2015 Professor Milton Friedman Interview Britain, Margaret Thatcher first was elected because of this widening view and helped to dramatise it. In the United States a couple of years later, Ronald Reagan was elected because the public had come to agree with his views. He had expressed the same views 20 years earlier, but he could not have been elected President 20 years earlier. Margaret Thatcher could not have been Prime Minister 20 years earlier in Britain. What's happened is that, on the one hand, governments have become bigger and more intrusive, while on the other, the public at large has experienced the adverse results of that. The result is that there is pressure on governments everywhere to become smaller and less intrusive. Moreover, when you talk about the world in the last 20 or 30 years, there have been a number of important forces that have led the rhetoric for change, the most important of which was the collapse of the Soviet Union and the tearing down of the Berlin Wall. That was a major event and altered the public and intellectual conception. Up until that point, there was widespread belief in the intellectual community that collectivism, central planning and central direction was a viable, possible way to organise a modern economy. The collapse of the Soviet Union and in particular, the discovery that places like East Germany, which had been thought to be fairly efficient, were much worse than they'd ever been estimated to be, shattered that belief. The Soviet experience was much worse than experts in the West had thought. That discovery had a tremendous impact both on the intellectual community and on the public at large. I think that is the most important single factor explaining why the rhetoric is so very different than it was earlier. The fascinating thing to me is that the past 20 or 30 years have been very good years around the world on the whole. We're talking about very severe crises in East Asia, but remember, those crises, with the possible exception of Indonesia, only reduced by a small amount the gains that had been made in the previous ten years. After all, those countries all had very rapid real growth. The same thing has happened in Singapore, Hong Kong, Taiwan and New Zealand. China has been transformed in the past 20 years. So that if you look at it from a broad point of view, the developments over the past 20 years have been very positive and have been all produced not by government policy, but by the forces of private enterprise, foreign investment, foreign technology and opening up of trade. An increase in trade and the revolution in technology ‐ those have been the forces that have created the rapid advances of the past 20 years for much of the http://www.abc.net.au/money/vault/extras/extra5.htm 10/12 11/4/2015 Professor Milton Friedman Interview world. Now there are some exceptions. Russia is obviously a basket case. But aside from Russia ‐ well, maybe North Korea is another example ‐ it's hard to find any place in the world which is worse off now than it was 30 years ago. RA: Thank you very much. Before we sign off, could I just take the opportunity to ask you what you think the prospects are for the attempts in Europe to create a common currency area? Are you optimistic about their success? Professor Friedman: : I think it's a big gamble and I'm not optimistic. Unfortunately, the Common Market does not have the features that are required for a common currency area. A common currency area is a very good thing under some circumstances, but not necessarily under others. The United States is a common currency area. Australia is also a common currency area. The characteristics that make Australia and the United States favourable for a common currency are that the populations all speak the same language or some approximation to it; there's free movement of people from one part of the country to the other part, so there's considerable mobility; and there's a good deal of flexibility in prices and to some extent in wages. Finally, there's a central government which is large relative to the local state governments so that if some special circumstances affect one part of the country adversely, there will be flows of funds from the centre which will tend to offset that. If you look at the situation in the Common Market, it has none of those features. You have countries with people all of whom speak different languages. There's very little mobility of people from one part of the Common Market to another. The local governments are very large compared to the central government in Brussels. Prices and wages are subject to all sorts of restrictions and control. The exchange rates between different currencies provided a mechanism for adjusting to shocks and economic events which affected different countries differently. In establishing the common currency area, the Euro, the separate countries are essentially throwing away this adjustment mechanism. What will substitute for it? Perhaps they will be lucky. It may be that events, http://www.abc.net.au/money/vault/extras/extra5.htm 11/12 11/4/2015 Professor Milton Friedman Interview as they turn out in the next 10 or 20 years, will be common to all the countries; there will be no shocks, no economic developments that affect the different parts of the Euro area asymmetrically. In that case, they'll get along fine and perhaps the separate countries will gradually loosen up their arrangements, get rid of some of their restrictions and open up so that they're more adaptable, more flexible. On the other hand, the more likely possibility is that there will be asymmetric shocks hitting the different countries. That will mean that the only adjustment mechanism they have to meet that with is fiscal and unemployment: pressure on wages, pressure on prices. They have no way out. With a currency board, there is always the ultimate alternative that you can break the currency board. Hong Kong can dismantle its currency board tomorrow if it wants to. It doesn't want to and I don't think it will. But it could. But with the Euro, there is no escape mechanism. Suppose things go badly and Italy is in trouble, how does Italy get out of the Euro system? It no longer has a lira after whatever it is ‐ 2000 or 2001 ‐ so it's a very big gamble. I wish the Euro area well; it will be in the self‐interest of Australia and the United States that the Euro area be successful. But I'm very much concerned that there's a lot of uncertainty in prospect. RA: Thank you very much Professor Friedman. http://www.abc.net.au/money/vault/extras/extra5.htm 12/12