World-Scale Patterns of Labor-Capital Conflict: Labor Unrest, Long Waves, and Cycles of World Hegemony Author(s): Beverly J. Silver Source: Review (Fernand Braudel Center) , Winter, 1995, Vol. 18, No. 1, Labor Unrest in the World-Economy, 1870–1990 (Winter, 1995), pp. 155-192 Published by: Research Foundation of State University of New York for and on behalf of the Fernand Braudel Center Stable URL: https://www.jstor.org/stable/40241328 JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org. Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at https://about.jstor.org/terms Fernand Braudel Center and are collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Review (Fernand Braudel Center) This content downloaded from 86.26.150.31 on Wed, 12 Apr 2023 17:35:19 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms WorldScale Patterns of Labor-Capital Conflict Labor Unrest, Long Waves, and Cycles of World Hegemony Beverly J. Silver central conclusion to be drawn from the country studies in this special issue of Review is that the World Labor Research Working Group (WLG) Database can be used as a reliable tool for identifying waves of labor unrest- and in particular waves that represent turning-points in labor-capital relations. These waves of labor unrest are, in turn, a central process underlying world-scale social change, setting into motion phases of intensive global political, economic, and social restructuring.1 This essay explores the world-scale patterning of labor unrest which emerges from the WLG Database. In addition, the database is used to assess the plausibility of theories that link labor-capital conflict to three processes of world-scale social change: (1) long waves (Kondratieff cycles), (2) cycles of world hegemony (world war and peace), and (3) the core-periphery relocation of production processes. 1 The WLG Database on Labor Unrest was constructed from reports of labor unrest culled from the indexes of the New York Times and the Times (London) from 1870 through 1990. For a detailed discussion of the construction of the WLG Database see Silver, this issue. For the country reliability studies referred to above see Part II of this special issue. REVIEW, XVIII, 1, WINTER 1995, 155-92 155 This content downloaded from 86.26.150.31 on Wed, 12 Apr 2023 17:35:19 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 156 Beverly J. Silver I. LONG WAVES AND LABOR UNREST2 The wave of labor unrest that spread throughout western Europe in the late 1960's, and the more or less simultaneous end of the long postwar boom, led to a revival of interest in both Kondratieff cycles and labor-capital conflict, as well as the emergence of theories which postulated a causal link between these two process- es. Screpanti (1984; 1987), for example, argues that periods of economic expansion ("A-phases") increase workers' power and dissatisfaction culminating in an explosion of militancy toward the end of the "A-phase." These "major proletarian insurgencies," in turn, dampen capitalists' willingness to invest, provoking an economic downturn (or "B-phase"). The downturn undermines workers' power and militancy, thus recreating the conditions for another expansionary A-phase. While their theoretical reasoning about the causal mechanisms are different, Mandel (1980), Gronin (1980), and Screpanti (1984) have all hypothesized a pro-cyclical relationship between long waves and labor unrest. Starting from relatively low levels, they expect class struggle to rise during the economic expansion (A-phase), and escalate sharply at the end of the A-phase. Cronin and Screpanti are most explicit in their prediction that major explosions of labor militancy occur at the transition from the A to the B phase. During the economic contraction (B-phase), levels of class struggle may remain quite high, and repeated outbursts of unrest may occur. For Mandel, in particular, "intensified class struggle . . . generally characterizes most of the depressive long wave" (1980: 48). Nevertheless, they all expect the overall trend in the B-phase to be downward, and the transition to the new A-phase to be characterized by an atmosphere of relatively low levels of unrest. In order to assess the plausibility of the hypothesis of an overlapping cycle of long waves and labor militancy, an index of labor unrest "intensity" was constructed from the WLG Database in such a way as to be analogous to Screpanti's (1987) strike intensity index.3 The patterns of labor unrest intensity were then studied: 2 This section summarizes results published in an earlier article (Silver, 1992a). More extensive arguments and evidence are contained therein. 3 The number of mentions of labor unrest worldwide was multiplied by the number of countries in which labor unrest is reported per year. The product is a single index This content downloaded from 86.26.150.31 on Wed, 12 Apr 2023 17:35:19 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms WORLD-SCALE PATTERNS OF LABOR-CAPITAL CONFLICT 157 (1) growth rates of each A- and B-phase were compare of major world-scale explosions of worker militancy w Table 1 reproduces the results of the calculation rates. Given the pro-cyclical hypothesis, we would positive growth rates in A-phases and negative gro phases (Cronin, Mandel, Screpanti). Furthermore, w not to find any major explosions of labor militancy in of the B-phases or early years of the A-phases; ra expect to find these explosions clustered around t from A- to B-phases. The evidence (as summarized in Table 1) does support for the proposition that there is a close c tween labor unrest and long waves. While some ca is still plausible, the number of anomalies is simply Table 1 Long Waves and World-Scale Class Struggle Index of Intensity Growth Rates (%) Non- World Core Core 1872-1893 B 8 7 12 1893-1917 A 9 8 9 a 1917-1940 B -5 -6 -4 1940-1968 A 2 0 4 1968-1985 B 0-5 4 Source: WLG Database. (a) above dotted line, index based on the New York Times only; below line, based on both newspaper sources. that simultaneously reflects the level and geographical extent of worker militancy. For a detailed discussion of the methods used and their appropriateness for the task at hand, see Silver (1992a). 4 To qualify as a "great explosion" year, class-struggle intensity had to be at least double the average of the preceding five years for two or more consecutive years. This criterion had to be met for the world-scale index and for the indices of core and non- core countries taken separately for at least one year in each set. The intention was to identify "great explosions" that are truly general in geographic terms and not corespecific or regionally-specific phenomena. This content downloaded from 86.26.150.31 on Wed, 12 Apr 2023 17:35:19 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 158 Beverly J. Silver With regards to grow strong positive annua century B-phase (1872- core for the postwar positive annual growth current B-phase. With explosions" of world-sc 20, 1946-48): (1) one set period from an A- to a latter part of that A-p beginning of an A-phas of the late-nineteenth We could dating try other scheme5 in stat orde labor militancy and lo However, one look at graphed attempt series are over time (see would be misg the two world after each of the two w waves and labor unrest ship between world lab II. LABOR UNREST AND WORLD WARS Figure 1 charts a time series which gives the total number mentions of labor unrest per year in the WLG Database as reco ed from the Indexes of the New York Times and the Times (Londo Figure 2 charts a series which gives the percentage of countries the world experiencing waves of labor unrest in any given ye (Waves of labor unrest are defined as years in which the number o mentions of labor unrest in a given country are (1) more than higher than the average of the previous five years and (2) high than the overall average of the series for that country.) Both F 5 The dating for A- and B-phases used in Table 1 are taken from Goldstein (19 67) who argues that they reflect the "strong consensus" among long-wave scholars. T-phase dating is taken from Screpanti (1984: 521). This content downloaded from 86.26.150.31 on Wed, 12 Apr 2023 17:35:19 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms WORLD-SCALE PATTERNS OF LABOR-CAPITAL CONFLICT 159 ures 1 and 2 show the series with a three-year mov The two post-world war waves of labor militancy in both series. The years 1919-20 are the peak yea for the number of mentions of labor unrest with a total of 2,085 and 1,827 mentions, respectively. The next highest peak is 1946-47 with 1,469 and 1,555 mentions, respectively. Likewise, the two post-world war waves of labor militancy are also the peak years in the series for the percentage of countries experiencing waves of labor unrest. However, the order of magnitude is reversed. The year 1946 is the overall peak of the series with 58% of the countries in the series experiencing waves of labor unrest. The year 1919 is second with 42% of the countries experiencing waves of labor unrest. The next two highest years are 1947 (with 38%) and 1920 (with 36%). Thus, although the number of mentions of labor unrest was higher for 1919-20, the geographical extent of the 1946-47 explosion (the number of countries affected) was greater. The world war effect is double-edged. Not only do the peak years of both series correspond to the immediate aftermaths of the wars, but the troughs of the series occur during the wars themselves. Thus (focusing only on 1906-90, the years for which the series is based on both newspaper sources) the trough in the number of mentions of labor unrest is 1915 with 169 mentions, followed by 1940 with 209 mentions, and 1942 with 215 mentions. Likewise, the overall trough in the series for the percentage of countries experiencing waves of labor unrest is 1942 (1%), followed by 1915 (3%), and 1939 (4%). Labor unrest waves by no means disappeared for the entire span of the world wars. For example, our data shows labor unrest waves in the middle of the First World War (particularly in Germa- ny and Russia in 1917-18 as well as elsewhere in Europe) and in the middle of the Second World War in the United States (1941, 1943), in Canada (1943), the United Kingdom (1943), as well as in some African and Asian colonies such as Zambia (1940-41) and Singapore (1940). Nevertheless, the overall effect of world wars 6 Appendix 1 at the end of this essay details the procedures used to construct these series as well as the tables and figures. This content downloaded from 86.26.150.31 on Wed, 12 Apr 2023 17:35:19 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 160 Beverly J. l-H This content downloaded from 86.26.150.31 on Wed, 12 Apr 2023 17:35:19 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Silver WORLD-SCALE PATTERNS OF LABOR-CAPITAL CONFLICT 161 CM s D O E This content downloaded from 86.26.150.31 on Wed, 12 Apr 2023 17:35:19 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 162 Beverly J. Silver (while they are being fo militancy in the worldThe WLG data thus se ferred science to as "one literature national . conflict" be read as support this hypothesis: of . . t th (198 for a 1) that involvement national level and th 2) that involvement i national 3) that level social ernments 1980: The An to and incr conflict involve t 297-98). rest of this assessment section of hyp horizon of the analysis diate aftermath. This will be undertaken in Section III, below. Hypothesis #i: War and Social Cohesion Our finding that overt conflict declined significantly during the early years of both world wars is in line with hypothesis #1. It also parallels the findings of other studies such as Hibbs (1978) and Tilly (1989). In a long-run analysis of strike activity in eleven west- ern European and North American countries, Hibbs found that industrial conflict "declined markedly" during the First and Second 7 This decline cannot be construed as an artifact of newspaper bias; that is, of labor unrest reports getting squeezed out of the newspapers by war news. In the first place, where we know from other sources that labor unrest wa"s widespread during the war years, we have found that our newspaper sources have also reported it (e.g., in the United States in the early years of the Second World War or the widespread militancy in Germany and Russia in the middle of the First World War.) Moreover, there is no reason to think that waves of labor militancy would be seen as less important news than battlefield and diplomatic reports as industrial workers had become critical cogs in the war machine (supplying the soldiers at the front) by the late-nineteenth century (cf. McNeill, 1982: Ch. 7 &: 8). 8 However, Stohl lamented (1980) that this nexus has been neither theoretically elaborated nor empirically grounded. This content downloaded from 86.26.150.31 on Wed, 12 Apr 2023 17:35:19 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms WORLD-SCALE PATTERNS OF LABOR-CAPITAL CONFLICT 163 World Wars. Hibbs attributes this decline, in part, t tions against wartime strikes." But he places even sis on a combination of consent and cooptation: . . . more important was the voluntary commitme in virtually all combatant countries to give maxim to the war effort. (Such pledges were usually ac government protection against attacks by capi lished labour organizations.) War-time strikes in tries were sporadic, usually unauthorized by u and very short-lived (Hibbs, 1978: 157). Tilly also attributes the decline in strike activity of wars to government compacts with manageme labor in support of the war effort. But he places on the coercive roots of the decline in militanc general tendency for the repressive capacities of increase during wartime. Tilly explains downturns as the combined result of (1) the increased repre governments, (2) the transfer of workers to govern war industries and (3) the transfer of organized w tary service and their replacement by less organiz 441-42). Attempts to ensure the cooperation of work effort through combinations of repression and co recognition by governments of the important r industrial armies had come to play in determining an age of industrialized warfare (cf. McNeill, These efforts appear to have extended well beyon batant countries. Thus, while Hibbs' and Tilly's st to western European and North American coun Database indicates that the decline in militancy d wars was far more general. The roots of this dec same for both metropolitan and colonial countrie time of the Second World War, colonial and semi had become tightly integrated into the resource sup imperial powers. Coercion played the main role in But coercion was proving to be insufficient give power of certain strategically-located colonial lab Britain's decision to introduce trade unions and arbitration mechanisms throughout its Empire du This content downloaded from 86.26.150.31 on Wed, 12 Apr 2023 17:35:19 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 164 Beverly J. Silver World War as labor unr tive of both the disrup move toward supplemen Great Britain's effort have had a serious restr Indeed, the cause(s) of t open to debate: through calls the generally their citizens are th to unity ag increased c during war who were promised rec and file militancy; or b tors? Whatever wars drew to a close. forces were a Hypothesis #2: War and Social Conflict The second hypothesis- that is, of a causal link between war and explosions of social conflict (especially revolutions)- is widespread in the social science literature (e.g., Laquer, 1968; Hibbs, 1978; Skocpol, 1979; Tilly, 1978). Skocpol, for example, argues that "defeats in war or threats of invasion and struggles over colonial con- trols . . . have directly contributed to virtually all outbreaks of revolutionary crises" (1979: 23). In some ways, contemporary studies in political sociology echo Lenin's contention that imperialist wars intensify all the contradictions of capitalism, and thus are "the eve of the social revolution of the proletariat" (1916: 175). Our finding that major world-scale explosions of labor unrest occurred after the world wars is in line with hypothesis #2, and parallels the findings of various country and regional studies. Hibbs, for example, found that "most [western European and North American] countries experienced strike explosions towards the ends or just after the end of the World Wars" (1978: 157). He attributes these strike waves to efforts by labor "to defend its war- 9 For studies emphasizing the strategic position of export workers in Latin America and Africa and their resulting disruptive potential, see Bergquist (1986) and Brown (1988), respectively. See Brown (1988) and Burawoy (1982) on Great Britain's policy of extending trade unionization to the colonies. This content downloaded from 86.26.150.31 on Wed, 12 Apr 2023 17:35:19 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms WORLD-SCALE PATTERNS OF LABOR-CAPITAL CONFLICT 165 time organizational gains, to resolve the shop-floo had accumulated over the long period of 'discipli serve real wages in the face of war generated upwar prices" (1978: 157). Tilly argues that a "war shaken state often faces m cized industrial conflict" (1989: 442); and moreov tionary situations are often brought on by war. great revolutions, and many of its lesser ones, strains imposed by war" (1990: 186). This, he clai "the essential relationship between war and the re of the government" (1978: 211). As we saw above, Tilly attributes the decline in during the early years of the war, in part, to the sive capacity of states during wartime. However, repressive capacity is highly unstable: Although war temporarily places large coerci under the control of a government, it does not gu they will be used efficiently, or that they will under the government's firm control. Defeat an lization provide especially favorable circumstanc tion because they combine the presence of substan resources with uncertain control over their use Moreover, the aftermath of wars are characterized in which the demands made by workers and othe state increase, at the same time as the states' ability or repress those demands decreases. Demands pressed or suspended for the duration of the surface as the war ends. But at the same moment, T is "a very general pattern in which the end of w not) produces a crisis of governmental incapacity size of the problems increase (e.g., millions of dem are thrown on soft labor markets), as the capacity t through cooptation or repression decreases (e.g., d cial costs of the war and the exhaustion of militar defeated, and even sometimes, the victorious coun bination of increased demands from below and d mental capacities to either meet and/or repres mands fosters politicized (and often revolutionar labor militancy towards the ends of wars (Tilly, 1 This content downloaded from 86.26.150.31 on Wed, 12 Apr 2023 17:35:19 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 166 Beverly J. Silver Most of those who draw the link between war and social conflict focus on the main metropolitan rivals, and certainly on those directly involved in the fighting. The WLG time series, however, show that waves of labor militancy extended well beyond the main metropolitan rivals, and well beyond those directly involved in the fighting. The widespread nature of the unrest in the immediate postwar years can be seen clearly in the world maps that highlight the countries experiencing labor unrest waves after each of the world wars (Figures 3 and 4). This is consistent with Goldfrank's hypothesis that major waves of social conflict are likely to occur in the periphery and semiperiphery during periods in which core countries are preoccupied with war and/or social unrest at home- and thus when core capacities for foreign intervention are hobbled. For Goldfrank, it is not merely the direct impact of the war mobilization and demobilization that explains the clustering of waves of social unrest during and immediately following major imperialist wars. Rather, "the preoccupation of major powers with war or serious internal difficulty" provides a permissive context for challenges from subordinate groups, which would have otherwise been nipped in the bud by direct or indirect foreign intervention. Intense competition among the core powers also increases the likelihood that labor and nation- alist movements will get outside help from one rival power or another, as part of strategies designed to undermine the colonial allies of the enemy. Thus, "as one moves toward the present temporally and toward the periphery of the world-system spatially, [the world-systemic context] becomes increasingly critical" in explaining rebellions and revolutions (1979: 148-49). Similarly, Skocpol argues that "international military balances and conflicts have . . . provided the 'space' necessary for the completion and consolidation of social revolutions" by dividing the efforts or diverting the attention of foreign enemies interested in preventing revolutionary successes (1979: 23; cf. Kowalewski, 1991). A strong correlation between world wars and waves of labor unrest is clearly evident from the WLG Database. Goldstone's claim that "the broad relationship between war and revolution is virtually nil" is not supported by the evidence (1991: 15-16). Nevertheless, Stohl rightly cautions us to distinguish among different types of wars when hypothesizing about the relationship between war and social conflict: This content downloaded from 86.26.150.31 on Wed, 12 Apr 2023 17:35:19 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms WORLD-SCALE PATTERNS OF LABOR-CAPITAL CONFLICT 167 CO D O •a o I This content downloaded from 86.26.150.31 on Wed, 12 Apr 2023 17:35:19 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 168 Beverly J. Silver i v I U o This content downloaded from 86.26.150.31 on Wed, 12 Apr 2023 17:35:19 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms WORLD-SCALE PATTERNS OF LABOR-CAPITAL CONFLICT 169 As Durkheim noted eighty years ago, "while gr wars have had a strong influence on the amount both France and Germany, purely dynastic wars Crimean or Italian which have not violently mov es, have had no appreciable effect" (Durkheim 07). This suggests that we would do well, when stud impact, to consider such properties as its len casualties, domestic popularity, and social dist adversary (Stohl, 1980: 327-28). Indeed, the type of war with which we found a ship is "world war." From a world-systems perspect are just the most morbid symptom of a general crisis In the next section the hypothesis that the centra not between social conflict and "war," but rather b conflict and the alternating cycles of world hegem that have characterized the modern world-system is e process a theoretical approach that encompasses al hypotheses outlined above is elaborated. III. LABOR UNREST AND HEGEMONY/RIVALRY IN THE WORLD-SYSTEM Two contrasting patterns emerge when we divide the 80 series10 into two equal periods- roughly corresponding to th od of transition from British to U.S. hegemony (1911-50) a the period of U.S. hegemony (1951-90).11 Table 2 summariz differences. 10 The mentions of labor unrest series is based on both newspaper sources for 85 years, that is, from 1906-90. However, the wave series begins in 1911 and is only 80 years long. This is because wave-years are singled out on the basis of their size relative to the average of the previous five years. 11 The start date for U.S. hegemony used in this essay corresponds to the beginning of the Cold War. This is consistent with the Gramscian concept of hegemony used in this study (Arrighi, 1990a; Silver & Slater, 1993) whereby hegemony implies more than economic and military dominance (cf. Wallerstein, 1984; Chase-Dunn, 1989: 166-98). While the U.S. was the dominant world power in 1945, hegemony was achieved through the Cold War. It is important to note, however, that while some of the details change, the main findings remain the same whether a 1945 or 1950 start date is usedthat is, there is a downward trend in labor unrest for the core and for the world as a whole during the period of hegemony. This content downloaded from 86.26.150.31 on Wed, 12 Apr 2023 17:35:19 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 170 Beverly J. Silver Table 2 Patterns of World Labor Unrest (World-Level Series) Rivalry Hegemony 1911-50 1951-90 Average Annual % of Countries with Waves of Labor Unrest 16 18 Average Annual "Mentions" of Labor Unrest 775 772 "Explosiveness": Standard Deviation of Wave Series 11 6 "Explosiveness": Standard Deviation of Mentions Series 425 194 Explosion Years in Either Wave 1919-20 NONE Series or Mention Series 1946-47 High Deviations from the Mean 1919-20 1955 in Either Series 1937 1956 1946-50 1959 Source: WLG Database. Labor unrest in the rivalry period is far more "explosive" tha labor unrest in the hegemony period, as indicated by the far great- er variance in both the wave and mention series for 1911-50 (standard deviation equals 11 and 425, respectively) than for 90 (standard deviation equals 6 and 194, respectively.) Al "explosions" of labor unrest (defined as years in which the se equal to twice its mean) occur during the rivalry period. Mor eight out of the eleven "high deviations from the mean" (ye which the series is greater than the mean plus the standard tion) are concentrated in the rivalry period. The less explosive nature of world-scale labor unrest in hegemony period does not mean that there was less labor u As can be seen from Table 2, the average annual number of tions of labor unrest in the two periods were virtually identica versus 772), while the average annual percentage of coun experiencing waves of labor unrest was slightly higher in the h mony period (18%) than the rivalry period (16%). The differe This content downloaded from 86.26.150.31 on Wed, 12 Apr 2023 17:35:19 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms WORLD-SCALE PATTERNS OF LABOR-CAPITAL CONFLICT 171 that during the rivalry period labor unrest tended particular years, giving rise to simultaneous, worldwi to the capitalist world-system. This tendency for nat labor unrest to cluster in time disappears in the hege Rivalry and Explosive Labor Unrest In large part this divergent pattern is due to the r wars in first dampening, and then provoking simult scale outbreaks of social conflict (in line with hypoth discussed above). The absence of world wars in th period has made labor unrest less explosive. The world wars, however, do not explain fully the between the rivalry and hegemony periods. We also n hypothesis 3 into the picture: that is, that social co national level encourages governments to involve th interstate wars. Escalating social conflict increases th wars and wars promote escalating social conflict. Indeed, the time series of labor unrest charted in F 2 clearly illustrate the tendency for labor unrest (1 prior to the outbreak of world wars, (2) to be tem pressed during the wars, and (3) to explode as the wa tendencies can also be seen from Table 3, which disag world-level indicators of labor unrest into three gr semiperiphery, and periphery.12 Focusing on the ri only: the only labor unrest "explosions" for the wor are the post-world war peaks (1919-20 and 1946-4 1919-20 and 1946-50 are "high deviations from the m world labor unrest time series. But so is 1937. Moreov several additional "explosions" or "high deviations" in semiperiphery during the immediate prewar years. Fo addition to the post-world war peaks, these are 191 and 1937. And for the semiperiphery, these are 1 1936, and 1938.13 12 Arrighi and Drangel's (1986) classification of countries as organ semiperiphery, and organic periphery is used. See Appendix B for th and their classification. 13 A different pattern, however, is visible for the periphery: there is no explosion following the First World War (although 1920-21 qualify as high deviations from the This content downloaded from 86.26.150.31 on Wed, 12 Apr 2023 17:35:19 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 172 Beverly J. Silver Table 3 Table 3(a)- Average Annual % of Countries Experiencing Waves of Labor Unrest World Core Semiperiphery Periphery Rivalry. 16 23 18 14 1911-50 Hegemony: 1951-90 18 15 20 20 Table 3(b)- Average Annual "Mentions" of Labor Unrest World Core Semiperiphery Periphery Rivalry: 775 467 153 60 1911-50 Hegemony: 772 1951-90 340 165 82 Table 3(c)- "Explosiveness": Standard Deviation of Wave Series World Core Semiperiphery Periphery Rivalry: 11 19 14 13 1911-50 Hegemony: 1951-90 6 11 11 10 Table 3(d)- "Explosiveness": Standard Deviation of Mentions Series World Core Semiperiphery Periphery Rivalry 425 289 102 58 1911-50 Hegemony. 1951-90 194 130 58 40 Table 3(e)- "Explosion" Years in Either Wave Series or Mention Series World Core Semiperiphery Periphery Rivalry: 1919-20 1912 1913 1925 1911-50 1946-47 1918-20 1919-20 1927-29 1932,1937 1936,1946 1946,1949 1946-47 1950 Hegemony None None 1951,1959 1953-56 1951-90 1965 1959,1962 1981 Table 3(f)- High Deviations World Core Semiperiphery Periphery Rivalry 1919-20 1912,1918-20 1913-14,1919-20 1920-21 1911-50 1937 1932,1936-37 1922,1932,1936 ' 1925,1927-29 1946-50 1946-49 1938,1946-47,1950 1946,1949 Hegemony 1955-56 1955 1951,1959,1965-66 1953-56,1958-59 1951-90 1959 1973,1976,1986 1962,1974,1980-81, 1988-89 1985-86,1989 Source: WLG Database. This content downloaded from 86.26.150.31 on Wed, 12 Apr 2023 17:35:19 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms WORLD-SCALE PATTERNS OF LABOR-CAPITAL CONFLICT 173 Since the world wars originated in the core and se the explosions of labor unrest in the immediate pre-vto in the core and semiperiphery- 1912-14 and 1936-38to hypothesis 3. In other words, the patterning of l the core and semiperiphery simultaneously supports all hypotheses outlined by Stohl. First, when multiple coun ence explosions of social conflict at the national level and capitalists seek solutions to internal tensions th that increase the likelihood of world war. Secondly, the world war leads to an initial decline in labor militanc increased repression or increased social cohesion). Thi the end of world wars, labor militancy is re-ignite widespread, simultaneous explosions of conflict that, er, constitute a challenge to the capitalist world-system Hegemony and Conflict Containment If a vicious circle of social and interstate conflict characterizes the rivalry period, the hegemony period can be characterized as a virtuous circle- at least for the core. But how is the vicious circle broken? Historically, a partial pre-condition for the emergence of a new hegemony has been the concentration of economic and military power in a single state (Wallerstein, 1984; Chase-Dunn, 1989: 166-98). However, this has not been sufficient. The new hegemon must also be in a position to bring social conflict under control (Arrighi, 1990a). Historically, this has been achieved through a combination of (1) repression, (2) "consent" through reforms and cooptation, and (3) the weakening of the challenging groups' bargaining power "behind their backs"- that is, through transformations in the labor process and the geographical relocation of capital (Silver, 1992b; Silver 8c Slater, 1993). During the rivalry period, all three of these mechanisms tended to be weak and ineffective. States swung sharply between harsh repression and total collapse (cf. Tilly, 1978 and "Hypothesis #2: War and Conflict" above). Corporatist solutions at the national level tended to crumble under the fiscal pressure of acute interstate mean). Explosion years for the periphery are concentrated in the middle and late 1920's (1925, 1927-29) and in the aftermath of the Second World War (1946, 1949). This content downloaded from 86.26.150.31 on Wed, 12 Apr 2023 17:35:19 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 174 Beverly J. Silver competition and- along trous involvements in the rivalry period, th strained national by the risks an business, and b and multilateral trade closed off, the only ch malfunctioning of thes (repression, cooptatio produced major explos By the end of the Se might was mobilized concentra at the global l create effective mecha communist parties and classes were coopted vi norms. At the firm leve al level it meant expan safety nets (Aglietta, at the global level it me and finance to the Key employment (Schurma policy sponsored by th 1970's implied a recogn commodities," and trol protectin required destructiveness Ruggie, This, these is protective but capital Plan of and a only measu steadily and self Mjoset, however, slowly of 1982; more unde transfor military Keyne wave of U.S. corporate and 1960's (Hymer, 197 with the European co lenge," fostered the techniques backbone of the of in western the militan twentieth This content downloaded from 86.26.150.31 on Wed, 12 Apr 2023 17:35:19 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms cent WORLD-SCALE PATTERNS OF LABOR-CAPITAL CONFLICT 175 production (Hobsbawm, 1984:169; Arrighi & Silver same time, this geographical relocation of investme undermined the bargaining power of those worke the backbone of the U.S. labor movement in the 1930's and 1940's- the semiskilled mass production workers (Edwards Goldfield, 1987; Moody, 1988; Arrighi 8c Silver, 1984). The result of these processes of repression, cooptation, tion, and restructuring was a transition from a period of inten conflict to a period of relative social peace in the core. The in sociology literature of the 1950's and 1960's referred to thi tion as "the withering away of the strike" (Ross & Hartman This "withering" can be seen in the steep decline in labor unre the WLG time series registers for the core from the 1950's on (see Figure 5). The average annual number of labor unrest m in the core declines from 467 in the rivalry period to 340 hegemony period; and the average annual percentage of c experiencing waves of labor unrest declines from 23% to 15 p Moreover, while seven years qualified as labor unrest explo the core during the rivalry period, no explosions of labor unr place during the hegemony phase (see Table 3). Finally, it is striking to note that the last high deviation fr mean in labor unrest for the core takes place in 1955- th before the reestablishment of currency convertibility in w Europe and the consequent inauguration of a major wave o sion of foreign direct investment by U.S. multinational c tions. Although the timing may be a coincidence, it is co with our claim that the relocation of production from the States and the expansion of mass production/mass consum industries in western Europe are central processes underlying cline of labor militancy in the core in the period of U.S. hege With the generalization of mass production techniques th out western Europe, and the drying-up of rural industrial armies, a "resurgence of class conflict" took place in the la and early 1970's (Grouch & Pizzorno, 1978). This "resurgen visible in Figure 5 as a slight upturn on a strong downward The power and vitality of these movements were quickly c (and their victories largely overturned) as a result of intense rate and state restructuring efforts. The automation of pr (aggressively pursued in Italy), the relocation of capital t peripheral locations (aggressively pursued in Germany This content downloaded from 86.26.150.31 on Wed, 12 Apr 2023 17:35:19 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 176 Beverly reversal of J. Silver Keynesian econ United Kingdom) rapid mass production worke Baglioni, 1989; Hyman, 1987). And in the United had begun decades earlier Organizations (CIO) str collapse of the mass pro under the combined imp (Goldfield, 1987; Moody, labor unrest in the core had virtually disappeared The clear contrast between labor unrest in the core for the hegemony and rivalry periods cannot be seen in the periphery semiperiphery. To be sure, there is a decline in explosiveness both the semiperiphery and the periphery (see Table 3). But th is an increase in the average annual percentage of countries exp encing waves of labor unrest in both the semiperiphery (from to 20%) and the periphery (from 14% to 20%). Likewise, there i increase in the average annual mentions of labor unrest, from to 165 in the semiperiphery and from 60 to 82 in the periph Moreover, while the number of years that qualified as high de tions from the mean for the core dropped from eleven to one fro the rivalry period to the hegemony period, it increased in periphery (from eight years to thirteen years) and decreased o slightly in the semiperiphery (eleven years versus nine years sum, while all indicators show a decline in labor unrest in the core with the transition to hegemony, the indicators for the semip phery and periphery all show increases or no significant chang The underlying nature of these divergent zonal patterns b comes clearer if we break up the hegemony period into four t year segments (see Table 4). The mean intensity of labor unres the core declines each decade in relation to the previous decad But in both the semiperiphery and periphery labor unrest intensi shows an initial decline, followed by an increase. For the se periphery, the decline in labor unrest intensity occurs in the 1960 the rise takes place in the 1970's and 1980's. In the periphery decline lasts for two decades, the 1960's and 1970's, before ris again in the 1980's. This content downloaded from 86.26.150.31 on Wed, 12 Apr 2023 17:35:19 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms WORLD-SCALE PATTERNS OF LABOR-CAPITAL CONFLICT 177 i This content downloaded from 86.26.150.31 on Wed, 12 Apr 2023 17:35:19 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 178 Beverly J. to D O E This content downloaded from 86.26.150.31 on Wed, 12 Apr 2023 17:35:19 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Silver WORLD-SCALE PATTERNS OF LABOR-CAPITAL CONFLICT 179 W 04 P O fa This content downloaded from 86.26.150.31 on Wed, 12 Apr 2023 17:35:19 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 180 Beverly J. Silver Table 4 Patterns of Labor Unrest During the Period of U.S. Hegemony Table 4(a)-Mean Labor Unrest Intensity (1911-90=100) (Intensity Index=Mentions Index Multiplied by Waves Index) World Core Semiperiphery Periphery 1951-60 143 76 123 192 1961-70 87 68 80 91 1971-80 87 65 94 79 1981-90 58 19 Table 103 120 4(b)- (Number of High Devia Years Qua World Core Semiperiphery Periphery 1951-60 3 1 2 6 1961-70 1971-80 0 0 0 0 2 2 1 1 1981-90 0 0 3 5 Source: WLG Database. An examination of the number of high deviations from the mean for the mentions and waves series reinforces the general picture of an initial decline followed by a resurgence of labo unrest for the periphery and semiperiphery (see Table 4b). In the core, one year (1955) qualifies as a high deviation from the mean for the entire hegemony period. In the semiperiphery, two years qualify in each of the first three decades of the hegemony period while three years qualify in the 1980's. The pattern of decline an rise is clearest for the periphery: six years qualify as high deviations from the mean in the 1950's, while only one year qualifies for eac of the following two decades. In the 1980's, a strong resurgence takes place, with five years qualifying as high deviations from th mean. The initial declines in the periphery and sem partly be attributed to the successes of nationa ments and communist revolutions, and the subse This content downloaded from 86.26.150.31 on Wed, 12 Apr 2023 17:35:19 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms WORLD-SCALE PATTERNS OF LABOR-CAPITAL CONFLICT 181 tion of both. In the semiperiphery, and especially labor unrest rose in the late 1940's and 1950's, as escalated together with national liberation strug Asia and Africa (see Figure 7). But the U.S./UN-s nization process succeeded in channeling the nation into paths that could be absorbed by a reformed system. The new states were incorporated into the w project as subordinate members through the promise mination" and "development." Once nationalist m trolled state power, workers' struggles inevitably los former support from other classes in society and we repressed. Likewise, the extension of communist rul European semiperiphery and China initially dampe through a combination of cooptation, repression, ing-poorer (peripheral and semiperipheral) version es at work on the core side of the Cold War.14 Whereas the downward trend of labor unrest accelerated in the core in the 1970's and 1980's, a reversal of that trend occurred in the periphery and semiperiphery. The upturn in labor unrest in the semiperiphery and periphery can be interpreted as "the other side of the coin" of the continuing downward trend in the core. The geographical relocation of capital- as a mechanism for evading and undermining the bargaining power of labor- has played an important role in containing overt militancy in the core. The (threatened and actual) elimination of jobs in mass production industry has become an increasingly potent weapon on the side of capital since the early 1970's. Relocation, however, has proved to be a doubleedged sword: labor movements in areas from which capital emigrates are undermined, but new working classes are created (and over time strengthened) in the sites to which capital migrates (Arrighi 8c Silver, 1984; Silver, 1992b; 1993). To be sure, many workers in the periphery and semiperiphery are incorporated into the world-scale division of labor in ways that leave them little effective bargaining power vis-à-vis either their employers or the state- e.g., young women drawn into labor-inten- 14 On the deradicalization of workers' movements in post-revolutionary states through repression and cooptation see, among others, Post (1988) on Vietnam; Beinin and Lockman (1987: 14-18) on Egypt and more generally. See also Selden (this issue) on China. This content downloaded from 86.26.150.31 on Wed, 12 Apr 2023 17:35:19 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 182 Beverly sive J. export turnover Silver productio rates "Primitive and high Taylorizat labor-intensive industr basic electronics. In the core (through foreign d and reproduces a wage power (Nash & Fernand However, significant g periphery, have been dr sive mass production tec ed to particular semiper cheap and docile worke Korea). The subsequen investment contribute miracles" in the 1970's intensive mass produ "economic miracles" als with significant disrup waves of struggle that cles of the 1970's and 1 Keck, 1989; Moreira Al Southall, 1985; Obrery, in the 1970's to South K berg, 1993). These wa upturn registered by t since the 1970's (see Ta One of the responses movements has been a production (from Brazi more peripheral sites (Silver, 1993). If past exp geographical relocation sites of disinvestment movements too soon to in the new expect f maj 15 For an analogous interpret notably the Polish "economic (1992b: Ch. 2). This content downloaded from 86.26.150.31 on Wed, 12 Apr 2023 17:35:19 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms WORLD-SCALE PATTERNS OF LABOR-CAPITAL CONFLICT 183 upturn in the WLG's labor unrest indicator for t the 1980's is consistent with our hypothesis that s the epicenters of labor unrest follow successive sh of production. Moreover, recent reports of mount in China (Tyler, 1994)- a new favorite site of in further evidence in support of this hypothesis. The Crisis of U.S. Hegemony and the Future of Wor The upturn in labor unrest outside the core coincides with an incipient crisis of U.S. hegem the conceptual framework developed here, th tween the time-space patterning of world-labor un world-hegemony may not be accidental. Duri 1960's- the decades of solid U.S. hegemony- lab worldwide. Cooptation through rising wages an central mechanism of conflict containment in the core; while less expensive forms of cooptation via developmentalism, nationalism, and populism obtained in the semiperiphery and periphery. But, with the sharp intensification of inter-capitalist competition in the 1970's, as western Europe and Japan caught up with the U.S. economic lead, old conflict-containment strategies have ceased to function. Cooptation has become too expensive and has been replaced, in the core, by geographical relocation, restructuring, and union-busting. Likewise, in the periphery and semiperiphery (in- cluding eastern Europe and the former U.S.S.R.), International Monetary Fund-imposed structural adjustment plans have overturned many populist social contracts. To date, the new conflict- containment strategies have succeeded in virtually eliminating overt expressions of labor unrest in the core. But, in the periphery and semiperiphery, the result has been escalating conflict. The map of labor unrest waves for 1986-90 (see Figure 8) shows widespread conflict in the East and South. The core (with the exception of Scandinavia) remains untouched. As we have argued above, these divergent trends in core and semiperiphery/periphery can be interpreted as two sides of the same coin. Indeed, it could be argued that the "success" of the conflict-containment mechanisms in the core is premised on the ability of the core to "externalize" or "export" contradictions to the periphery and semiperiphery. Whether there are limits to this This content downloaded from 86.26.150.31 on Wed, 12 Apr 2023 17:35:19 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 184 Beverly J. oo D O S This content downloaded from 86.26.150.31 on Wed, 12 Apr 2023 17:35:19 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Silver WORLD-SCALE PATTERNS OF LABOR-CAPITAL CONFLICT 185 "externalization" process, and how/when they w complex questions that lie beyond the bounds o wise, the related question of whether we can exp experience of the past cycle in which waves of lab deepening crisis of hegemony were intertwined open. REFERENCES Aglietta, Michel (1979). A Theory of Capitalist Regulation: The U.S. Experience. London: New Arrighi, Giovanni (1990a). "The Three Hegemonies of Historical Capitalism," Review, Sum., 365-408. Arrighi, Giovanni (1990b). "Marxist-Century, American-Century: The Making and Remaking of the World Labor Movement," New Left Review, No. 179, Jan.-Feb., 29-63. Arrighi, Giovanni 8c Drangel, Jessica (1986). "The Stratification of the World-Economy: An Exploration of the Semiperipheral Zone," Review, X, 1, Sum., 9-74. Arrighi, Giovanni & Silver, Beverly J. (1984). "Labor Movements and Capital Migration: The US and Western Europe in World-Historical Perspective," in C. Bergquist, éd., Labor in the Capitalist World-Economy. Beverly Hills: Sage, 183-216. Atkinson, Rob (1987). "Trade Unions, Industrial Change and the Effects of Recession in West Germany and the United Kingdom," in W. Brierley, éd., Trade Unions and the Economic Crisis in the 1980s. Gower: Aldershot, 3-26. Baglioni, Guido (1989). "Industrial Relations in Europe in the 1980s," Labour and Society, XIV, 3, July, 233-49. Beinin, Joel & Lockman, Zachary (1987). Workers on the Nile: Nationalism, Communism, Islam, and the Egyptian Working Class, 1882-1954. Princeton: Princeton Univ. Press. Bergquist, Charles (1986). Labor in Latin America: Comparative Essays on Chile, Argentina, Venezuela and Colombia. Stanford: Stanford Univ. Press. Brown, Carolyn (1988). "The Dialectics of Colonial Labour Control: Class Struggles in the Nigerian Coal Industry, 1914-1949,"/ouraa/ of Asian and African Studies, XXIII, 1-2, Jan.Apr., 105-23. Burawoy, Michael (1982). "The Hidden Abode of Underdevelopment: Labor Process and the State in Zambia," Politics and Society, XI, 42, 123-66. Carr, Edward H. (1945). Nationalism and After. London: Macmillan. Chase-Dunn, Christopher (1989). Global Formation: Structures of the World-Economy. Cambridge, MA: Basil Blackwell. Cronin, James (1980). "Stages, Cycles and Insurgencies: The Economics of Unrest, in I. K. Hopkins 8c I. Wallerstein, eds., Processes of the World-System. Beverly Hills: Sage, 101-18. Crouch, Colin 8c Pizzorno, Alessandro, eds. (1978). The Resurgence of Class Conflict in Western Europe Since 1968, 2 vols. New York: Holmes & Meier. Deyo, Frederic C. (1989). Beneath the Miracle: Labor Subordination in the New East Asian Industrial ism. Berkeley: Univ. of California Press. Durkheim, Emile (1951). Suicide: A Study of Sociology. New York: The Free Press. Edwards, Richard (1979). Contested Terrain: The Transformation of the Workplace in the Twentieth Century. New York: Basic. Goldfield, Michael (1987). The Decline of Organized Labor in the United States. Chicago: Univ. of Chicago Press. Goldfrank, Walter (1979). "Theories of Revolution and Revolution Without Theory: The Case of Mexico," Theory and Society, VII, 2, Mar., 135-65. This content downloaded from 86.26.150.31 on Wed, 12 Apr 2023 17:35:19 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 186 Beverly Goldstein, Univ. Press. J. Joshua Silver S. (1988). Long Goldstone, Jack (1991). Revolution and Rebellion in the Early Modern World. Berkeley: Univ. of California Press. Gordon, David; Edwards, Richard 8c Reich, Michael (1982). Segmented Work, Divided Workers: The Historical Transformation of Labor in the United States. Cambridge: Cambridge Univ. Press. Hart-Landsberg, Martin (1993). The Rush to Development: Economic Change and Political Struggle in South Korea. New York: Monthly Review Press. Hibbs, Douglas (1978). "On the Political Economy of Long-Run Trends in Strike Activity," British fournal of Political Science, VIII, part 2, Apr., 153-75. Hobsbawm, Eric (1984). "The 'New Unionism' in Perspective," in Workers: Worlds of Labor. New York: Pantheon, 152-75. Humphrey, John (1982). Capitalist Control and Workers' Struggle in the Brazilian Auto Industry. Princeton: Princeton Univ. Press. Humphrey, John (1987). "Economic Crisis and Stability of Employment in the Brazilian Motor Industry," in W. Brierley, éd., Trade Unions and the Economic Crisis of the 1980s. Gower: Aldershot, 119-31. Hyman, Richard (1989). "The Sickness of British Trade Unionism: Is There a Cure?," in The Political Economy of Industrial Relations: Theory and Practice in a Cold Climate. London: Macmillan, 166-87. Hymer, Stephen (1972). "The Multinational Corporation and the Law of Uneven Development," in J. N. Bhagwati, éd., Economics and World Order. London: Macmillan, 113-40. Keck, Margaret E. (1989). "The New Unionism in the Brazilian Transition," in A. Stepan, éd., Democratizing Brazil Problems of Transition and Consolidation. New York: Oxford Univ. Press, 252-96. Kowalewski, David (1991). "Core Intervention and Periphery Revolution, 1821-1985," American fournal of Sociology, XCVII, l.July, 70-95. Laquer, Walter (1968). "Revolution," International Encyclopedia of the Social Sciences, XIII, 501-07. Lenin, Vladimir I. (1971). "Imperialism, the Highest State of Capitalism," in V. I Lenin Selected Works. New York: International Publishers, (orig. 1916), 169-263. Lipietz, Alain (1987). Mirages and Miracles: The Crises of Global Fordism. London: Verso. Mandel, Ernest (1980). Long Waves of Capitalist Development: The Marxist Interpretation. Cambridge: Cambridge Univ. Press. Marée, Johann (1985). "The Emergence, Struggles and Achievements of Black Trade Unions in South Africa from 1973 to 1984," Labour, Capital and Society, XVII, 2, Nov., 278-303. McNeill, William (1982). The Pursuit of Power: Technology, Armed Forces and Society Since A. D. 1000. Chicago: Univ. of Chicago Press. Mjoset, Lars (1990). "The Turn of Two Centuries: A Comparison of British and US Hegemonies," in D. P. Rapkin, éd., World Leadership and Hegemony. Boulder: Lynne Reiner, 21-47. Moody, Kim (1988). An Injury to All: The Decline of American Unionism. London: Verso. Moreira Alves, Maria Helena (1989). "Trade Unions in Brazil: A Search for Autonomy and Organization," in E. Epstein, éd., Labor Autonomy and the State in Latin America. Boston: Unwin Hvman. 39-72. Nash, June 8c Fernandez-Kelly, Maria Patricia, eds. (1983). Women, Men and the International Division of Labor. Albany, NY: State Univ. of New York. Obrery, Ingrid (1989). "Cosatu Congress: Unity in Diversity," Work in Progress, No. 60, Aug./Sep., 34-39. Ogle, George E. (1990). South Korea: Dissent Within the Economic Miracle. London: Zed. Polanyi, Karl (1957). The Great Transformation: The Political and Economic Origins of Our Times. Boston: Beacon Press (orig. 1944). Post, Ken (1988). "The Working Class in North Viet. Nam and the Launching of the Building of Socialism," fournal of Asian and African Studies, XIII, 1-2, Jan. -Apr., 141-55. Regini, Mario (1986). "Political Bargaining in Western Europe During the Economic Crisis of the 1980s," in O. Jacobi et al., eds., Economic Crisis, Trade Unions and the State. London: Croom Helm, 61-76. This content downloaded from 86.26.150.31 on Wed, 12 Apr 2023 17:35:19 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms WORLD-SCALE PATTERNS OF LABOR-CAPITAL CONFLICT 187 Rollier, Matteo (1986). "Changes in Industrial Relations at Fiat/' in O. Jac Kastendick & M. Rcgini, eds., Technological Change, Rationalisation and Ind London: Croom Helm, 116-33. Ross, Arthur M. & Hartman, Paul T. (1960). Changing Patterns of Industrial Conflict. New York: Wilev. Ruggie, John C. (1982). "International Regimes, Transactions, and Change: Embedded Liberalism and the Postwar Economic Order," International Organization, XXXVI, 2, Spr., 379-415. Schurmann, Franz (1974). The Logic of World Power. New York: Pantheon. Screpanti, Ernesto (1984). "Long Economic Cycles and Recurring Proletarian Insurgencies, Review, VII, 3, Win., 509-48. Screpanti, Ernesto (1987). "Long Cycles of Strike Activity: An Empirical Investigation," British Journal of Industrial Relations, XXV, 1, Mar., 99-124. Seidman, Gay W. (1994). Manufacturing Militance: Workers' Movements in Brazil and South Africa, 1970-1985. Berkeley: Univ. of California Press. Silver, Beverly J. (1990). "The Contradictions of Semiperipheral Success: The Case of Israel," in W. G. Martin, éd., Semiperipheral States in the World-Economy. New York: Greenwood Press, 161-81. Silver, Beverly J. (1992a). "Class Struggle and Kondratieff Waves, 1870 to the present," in A. Kleinknecht, E. Mandel & I. Wallcrstein, eds., New Findings in Long Wave Research. New York: St Martin's Press, 279-96. Silver, Beverly J. (1992b). "Labor Unrest and Capital Accumulation on a World Scale," Ph.D. diss., SUNY-Binghamton. Ann Arbor: UMI. Silver, Beverly J. (1993). "Labor Unrest and the Successive Geographical Relocation of the World Automobile Industry, 1930's to the Present." Program in Comparative and International Development Working Papers Series #11. Baltimore, MD: Dept. of Sociology, Johns Hopkins Univ. Silver, Beverly J. & Slater, Eric (1993). "Social Cohesion and Conflict," working paper no. 104., unpubl., Fernand Braudel Center, Binghamton Univ. Skocpol, Theda (1979). States and Social Revolutions: A Comparative Analysis oj trance, Kussia ana China. Cambridge: Cambridge Univ. Press. Smith, W. Rand (1987). Crisis in the French Labour Movement. London: Macmillan. Southall, Roger (1985). "Monopoly Capitalism and Industrial Unionism in the South African Automobile Industry," Labour, Capital and Society, XVIII, 2, Nov., 304-42. Stohl, Michael (1980). "The Nexus of Civil and International Conflict," in Ted Robert Gurr, éd., Handbook of Political Conflict: Theory and Research. New York: The Free Press, 297-330. Tilly, Charles (1978). From Mobilization to Revolution. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley. Tilly, Charles (1989). "Introduction: The Effects of Short-Term Variation," in L. Haimson & C. Tilly, eds., Strikes, Wars, and Revolutions in International Perspective. Cambridge: Cambridge Univ. Press, 443-48. Tilly, Charles (1990). Coercion, Capital and European States. Oxford: Basil Blackwell. Wallerstein, Immanuel (1984). "The Three Instances of Hegemony in the History ot the Capitalist World-Economy," in I. Wallerstein, éd., The Politics of the World-Economy. Cambridge: Cambridge Univ. Press, 37-46. Ward, Kathryn, ed. (1990). Women Workers and Global Restructuring. Ithaca, NY: ILR Press. This content downloaded from 86.26.150.31 on Wed, 12 Apr 2023 17:35:19 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 188 Beverly J. Silver Appendix 1 Construction of Labor Unrest Indicators Most of the figures and tables in this essay are based on time series derived from the World Labor Research Working Group (WLG) Database, which itself was created by recording all mentions of labor unrest from the indexes of the New York Times (from 18701990) and the Times (London) (from 1906-90). For a detailed discussion of the construction of this database see Silver, this issue. Figure 1 charts the "maximum mentions" series for the world. This world-level time series includes all countries for which there were at least 85 mentions of labor unrest from 1906-90 in either of the two newspaper sources (i.e., a minimum average of one mention per year). Seventy-five countries met this minimum threshold (see Appendix B, this issue). For each of these countries a "maxi- mum" time series of labor unrest mentions was created for the years 1906-90. This was done by comparing the number of me tions for each year from the two newspaper sources and takin whichever number was larger for each year. The 75 country-lev maximum mentions series were then aggregated into a single world level "maximum mentions" series. (The time series of labor unr mentions from 1870-1905 is composed of the mentions collect from the New York Times Index only and is therefore not stric comparable with the series after 1906.) Figures 5, 6, and 7 chart the "maximum mentions" series fo the organic core, organic semiperiphery, and organic peripher respectively. Each of these aggregate series was created by summin the maximum mentions series for the applicable countries. Arri and DrangeFs (1986) classification was used to group countries zone. Only countries that qualified as "organic" members of ea zone were included in the zonal aggregates (i.e., only countries t remained in one zone throughout the 50-year period covered i Arrighi and Drangel's study [1986]). Non-organic members that m the 85-mention threshold (e.g., countries such as Japan or Italy tha moved from the semiperiphery to the core over the period of o study) are included in the world-level series but not the zonal serie Appendix B of this special issue shows the categorization of cou tries by world-economic zone. Figure 2 charts a "wave" series derived from the "maximum mentions" series. Wave-years were calculated for each of the 7 This content downloaded from 86.26.150.31 on Wed, 12 Apr 2023 17:35:19 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms WORLD-SCALE PATTERNS OF LABOR-CAPITAL CONFLICT 189 countries that met the minimum mentions threshold. Two criteria had to be met to qualify as a wave-year: the number of mentions in the maximum mentions series had to be (1) at least 50% higher than the average of the previous five years and (2) higher than the overall average of the series for that country. For each year the number of countries experiencing waves of labor unrest was summed. A series which gives the percentage of countries experiencing waves of labor unrest in any given year was created from the resulting series by dividing the latter by the total number of coun- tries in the series. Up until 1950 the denominator was 72; from 1950-71 it was 74 (with the addition of Pakistan and East Germany); from 1972-90 it was 75 (reflecting the addition of Bangladesh). Appendix B of this special issue specifies the 75 countries included in the series. The country wave series discussed above were used to create the world maps indicating countries experiencing labor unrest waves in various key periods (Figures 3, 4, and 8). Wave-years were also calculated for the organic core, organic semiperiphery, and organic periphery. The procedure was analogous to that used for the world-level calculation. The Arrighi and Drangel (1986) classification scheme was used. These series were then used in Table 3 (see below). For Table 2, the "maximum mentions" and the "waves" worldlevel time series each were divided into two equal time periods: 1911-50 and 1951-90. Table 2 shows the mean level of mentions and waves for each period. For both series the standard deviation was calculated for each period (as an indicator of relative explosiveness). Finally, two criteria were used to single out exceptional years of world-level labor unrest. Explosion years were defined as years in which the number of mentions/ waves was equal to twice the mean of the mentions/waves series. High deviations from the mean were years in which the number of mentions/ waves was greater than the mean number of mentions/waves plus the standard deviation for the mentions/waves series. Table 3 uses the same indicators as Table 2. The difference is that the results are presented for the organic core, organic semiperiphery, and the organic periphery aggregates, as well as the world-level aggregate. Table 1 is based on an earlier elaboration of the WLG data. The procedures used are discussed briefly in the text of this essay, and more fully in Silver (1992a). This content downloaded from 86.26.150.31 on Wed, 12 Apr 2023 17:35:19 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 190 Beverly J. Silver Appendix 2 Labor Unrest "Maximum Mentions Series," 1906-90 Index: 1906-90=100 Year World Core Semiperiphery Periphery Index Index Index Index 1906 43 47 69 1907 69 70 94 44 1908 47 59 35 41 1909 61 1910 82 1911 99 1912 103 120 137 108 1913 104 1914 1916 42 1917 1918 98 12 48 38 132 3 30 181 54 34 10 96 243 31 1 25 111 36 22 27 61 159 93 63 1915 21 0 0 10 58 122 0 12 1919 276 376 213 158 1920 242 262 254 201 1921 126 123 144 195 1922 128 118 203 170 1923 89 1924 1925 118 77 103 76 95 43 74 122 49 43 285 1926 74 99 23 149 1927 67 67 32 250 1928 86 84 51 303 1929 81 83 57 251 1930 89 89 118 105 1931 81 76 129 1932 86 83 157 1933 1934 76 70 127 1935 1936 145 166 1938 105 95 1940 1942 1943 1944 1945 1946 1947 I 28 64 83 86 195 206 I 50 159 77 56 75 20 38 53 33 77 124 181 249 16 25 128 58 37 96 34 100 28 62 233 248 1941 87 67 171 40 13 143 65 1937 1939 38 94 96 68 47 36 44 31 21 31 32 140 | This content downloaded from 86.26.150.31 on Wed, 12 Apr 2023 17:35:19 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 9 27 222 WORLD-SCALE PATTERNS OF LABOR-CAPITAL CONFLICT 191 Appendix 2 Labor Unrest "Maximum Mentions Series," 1906-90 Index: 1906-90=100 Year World Core Semipcriphery Periphery Index 1948 155 1949 1950 Index 166 133 1951 189 202 135 138 1952 Index 86 48 62 66 137 122 117 97 Index 112 201 61 62 145 1953 120 98 42 213 1954 108 99 87 198 1955 151 171 244 1956 158 132 210 1957 1958 122 104 115 119 97 118 158 201 1959 133 1960 112 76 101 114 1961 95 156 109 95 95 105 189 81 69 1962 139 113 127 228 1963 128 125 77 176 1964 104 80 85 164 1965 105 87 111 149 1966 124 126 120 148 1967 75 71 88 100 1968 107 145 54 83 1969 94 82 67 96 1970 90 88 74 53 1971 88 91 59 61 1972 86 83 81 65 1973 100 100 162 33 1974 120 113 120 155 1975 92 76 137 64 1976 93 68 204 38 1977 102 90 105 127 1978 107 96 90 111 1979 75 79 63 90 1980 127 78 123 90 1981 143 74 80 124 1982 74 50 78 75 1983 62 35 104 49 1984 92 90 87 95 1985 69 41 118 112 1986 I 79 I 48 I This content downloaded from 86.26.150.31 on Wed, 12 Apr 2023 17:35:19 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms 192 Beverly J. Silver Appendix 2 Labor Unrest "Maximum Mentions Series," 1906-90 Index: 1906-90=100 Year World Core Scmipcriphcry Periphery Index Index Index Index 1987 69 29 148 81 1988 68 23 126 78 1989 1990 I 81 46 I 25 19 Note: 165 202 I (1) The m based on "mentions'* of labor unrest found in the indexes of the New York Times and the Times (London). For an explanation of the procedures used to construct the maximum mentions series, see Appendix 1 of this article. (2) Seventy-five countries met the minimum threshold of 85 mentions of labor unrest during the years 1906-90, and were thus included in the world index. The world index is the sum of the maximum mentions series for those countries. (Sec Appendix B of this special issue for the listing of countries included.) (3) Only those countries which were classified by Arrighi and Drangel (1986) as organic core, organic semiperiphery, or organic periphery were included in the zonal indexes. (See Appendix B of this special issue for the classification of countries.) Source: WLG Database. This content downloaded from 86.26.150.31 on Wed, 12 Apr 2023 17:35:19 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms