COMPENSATING WAGE DIFFERENTIALS Abdulpatta,Fiona Mallorca,Mary Gail Marondo,Maria Caila Olmilla,Claudine Talon, Maria Christina INTRODUCTION: COMPENSATING WAGE DIFFERENTIALS The model of competitive labor markets implies that as long as workers or firms can freely enter and exit the marketplace, there will be a single wage in the economy if all jobs are alike and all workers are alike. The labor market is not characterized by a single wage: workers differ and jobs differ Adam Smith proposed the idea that job characteristics influence labor market equilibrium Compensating wage differentials arise to compensate workers for nonwage characteristics of the job Workers have different preferences and firms have different working conditions Workers’ & Firms’ Choice with RISKY JOB EXAMPLE: Employer X: NT.$100 per hour, clean, safe work conditions Employer Y: NT.$100 per hour, dirty, noisy factory Most workers would undoubtedly choose employer X. If employer Y decides not to alter working conditions, it must pay wage above NT.$100 to be competitive in the labor market. The extra wage it must pay attract workers is called a compensating wage differential because the higher wage is paid to compensate workers for the undesirable working conditions. After the wage rise of firm Y, if both firms could obtain the quantity and quality of works they wanted, the wage differential would be an equilibrium differential, in the sense that there be no forces causing the differential to change. The Compensating Wage Differential Serves Two Purposes: 1. It serves a social need by giving people an incentive to voluntarily do dirty, dangerous, or unpleasant work or a financial penalty on employers offering unfavorable working conditions. 2. At an individual level, it serves as a reward to workers who accept unpleasant jobs by paying them more than comparable workers in more pleasant jobs. Those who opt for more pleasant conditions have to buy them by accepting lower pay. The Compensating Wage Differential Theory is Based on Three Assumptions Utility Maximization Workers seek to maximize their utility, not their income. Compensating wage differentials will only arise if some people do not choose the highest-paying job offered, preferring instead a lower-paying but more pleasant job. Workers Mobility Worker Information Workers are aware of the job characteristics of potential importance to them. Workers have a range of job offers from which to choose. It is the act of choosing safe jobs over dangerous ones that forces employers offering dangerous work to raise wages. Determining the Market Compensating Differentials The supply curve slopes up because as the wage gap between the risky job and the safe job increases, more and more workers are willing to work in the risky job. The demand curve slopes down because fewer firms will offer risky working conditions if risky firms have to offer high wages to attract workers. The market compensation differential equates supply and demand and gives the bribe required to attract the last worker hired by risky firms. FIGURE 4-5 Indifference Curve for Three types of Workers Figure 5-4 illustrates the indifference curves for three different workers, A, B, and C (with associated utilities U A , U B , and U C ). The slope of each indifference curve tells us how much the wage would have to increase if the particular worker were to voluntarily switch to a slightly riskier job. The slope of an indifference scurve, therefore, is the reservation price that the worker attaches to moving to a slightly riskier job. ISOPROFIT CURVE An isoprofit curve Figure 5-5 gives all the risk-wage combinations that yield the same profits. Because it is costly to produce safety,a firm offering risk level p* can make the workplace safer only if it reduces wages (while keeping profits constant), so that the isoprofit curve is upward sloping. Higher isoprofit curves yield lower profit. ISOPROFIT IMPORTANT PROPERTIES 1. Isoprofit curves are upward sloping because it costs money to produce safety. 2. Wage-risk combinations that lie on a higher isoprofit curve yield lower profits. 3. Isoprofit curves are concave. 5-3 Policy Application: How Much Is a Life Worth? Many studies estimate the hedonic function relating wages and the probability of injury on the job. These studies estimate the wage differences that exist across jobs that offer different probabilities of risk, after adjusting for other factors that might affect wage differentials such as the skills of the worker, the location of the job, and so on. Calculating Value of life Suppose that firms X and Y each employs 1,000 workers. Because firm Y’s probability of fatal injury exceeds that of X by .001 point, an additional worker is likely to die in firm Y during any given year. Workers in firm Y willingly accept this additional risk because each gets a compensating differential of $7,600. Policy Application: Safety and Health Regulations Since the enactment of the Occupational Safety and Health Act of 1970, the federal government in the United States has played a major role in setting safety standards at the workplace. The legislation created the Occupational Safety and Health Administration (OSHA), whose job is to protect the health and safety of the American labor force. In the past 20 years, OSHA has set workplace standards that mandate the maximum amount of cotton dust in the air in textile plants, the amount of asbestos in the air in work settings, and a host of other restrictions on the job environment. These regulatory activities raise a number of important questions. Are workers better off as a result of these regulations? How do the safety standards alter the nature of the labor market equilibrium that generates compensating wage differentials? And, finally, do these government mandates actually reduce the probability of injury on the job? Figure 5.7 Impact of OSHA Regulation on Wage, Profits and Utility Impact of Regulations When Workers Are Unaware of the Risks We have seen that mandated safety standards reduce both the utility of affected workers and the profitability of affected firms. In view of this result, it is worth asking why governments bother to regulate safety standards at all. One argument used to justify the government mandates is that workers are unaware of the true risks associated with particular jobs. Construction workers in the 1950s and 1960s, for instance, did not know that continued exposure to asbestos fibers would eventually create serious health problems. It is worth pointing out, however, that neither firms nor government bureaucrats had that information, and, hence, it is doubtful that the problem could have been handled properly at the time. Compensating Differentials and Job Amenities ●the model clearly applies to many other job characteristics, such as whether the job involves repetitive and monotonous work, whether the job is located in an amenable physical setting (southern California versus northern Alaska), whether the job involves strenuous physical work, and so on. ● The key implication of the theory is easily summarized: As long as all persons in the population agree on whether a particular job characteristic is a “good” or a “bad,” good job characteristics are associated with low wage rates and bad job characteristics are associated with high wage rates. ●For example, white teachers in schools that have a predominantly black student population receive a compensating differential Why Do Compensating Differentials Often Go the “Wrong” Way/ ●the “correct” direction of the wage differential typically reflects our own preferences and biases! We are obviously reasonable people, so jobs we find disagreeable should pay more ●the estimates of the compensating wage differentials associated with particular job characteristics are valid only if all the other factors that influence a worker’s wages are held constant. ●It turns out that the correlation between the change in a worker’s wage and the change in her package of job amenities is much more consistent with the compensating differentials model. Compensating Differentials and Layoffs A key justification for the unemployment insurance (UI) system is that workers need to be protected from the vagaries of the competitive labor market. ● In 2004, unemployed workers in the United States collected over $34 billion in unemployment compensation. ● Adam Smith first noted two centuries ago, the “constancy or inconstancy of employment” will generate compensating wage differentials. FIGURE 5-9 Layoffs and Compensating Differentials At point P, a person maximizes utility by working ho hours at a wage of wo dollars. An alternative job offers the worker a seasonal schedule, where she gets the same wage but works only h, hours. The worker is worse off in the seasonal job (her utility declines from U, to U'utils). If the seasonal job is to attract any workers, the job must raise the wage to w₁ so that workers will be indifferent between the two jobs. Health Insurance and the Labor Market • In the United States, employers provide health insurance coverage as a fringe benefit to a large fraction of the workforce • A number of recent studies have applied the compensating differentials framework to evaluate the relation between wages and the availability of employer-provided insurance. • The worker’s indifference curve relating wages and health insurance would then have the usual downward-sloping convex shape. • These data trace out the isoprofit curve, and thus indicate the trade-off implied by the compensating differential model. • Most studies that attempt to calculate this trade-off do not find a negative correlation, instead they usually find a positive correlation. • In recent years, the method of instrumental variables has been used to rid the data of the ability. • Suppose we consider the relation between wages and health insurance coverage in a sample of married women. End………