Case studies illustrate how the principles of economics are applied using contemporary, relevant examples STUDY HACK #18 Explaining the work to friends and family helps you understand and remember what you’ve learnt. Ash, student, Sydney STONECASH ∙ GANS ∙ KING ∙ BYFORD ∙ IVANOVSKI ∙ MANKIW Boost your understanding of the concepts in each chapter with recent news articles that connect economic ideas to current affairs 8TH EDITION Introduces you to the essentials of macroeconomics, helping you to learn important tools for economic analysis — PRINCIPLES OF — Give yourself the advantage — own this subject! This book has the essentials you need! Macroeconomics BE UNSTOPPABLE — PRINCIPLES OF — Macroeconomics ROBIN STONECASH JOSHUA GANS STEPHEN KING MARTIN BYFORD KRIS IVANOVSKI N. GREGORY MANKIW ISBN 978-0170445658 9 7 8 01 7 0 4 4 5 6 5 8 8TH ASIA-PACIFIC EDITION Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 — PRINCIPLES OF — Macroeconomics ROBIN STONECASH JOSHUA GANS STEPHEN KING MARTIN BYFORD KRIS IVANOVSKI N. GREGORY MANKIW 8TH ASIA-PACIFIC EDITION Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 00_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_FM_txt.indd 1 25/08/20 9:45 PM To Belanna, Ariel & Annika Jacqueline & Rebecca Catherine & Nicholas ii Copyright 2021 Cengage Part 1 Firm behaviour and the organisations of Learning. industry All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 00_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_FM_txt.indd 2 25/08/20 9:45 PM — PRINCIPLES OF — Macroeconomics ROBIN STONECASH JOSHUA GANS STEPHEN KING MARTIN BYFORD KRIS IVANOVSKI N. GREGORY MANKIW 8TH ASIA-PACIFIC EDITION Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 00_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_FM_txt.indd 3 25/08/20 9:45 PM Principles of Macroeconomics 8th Edition Robin Stonecash Joshua Gans Stephen King Martin Byford Kris Ivanovski N. Gregory Mankiw Head of content management: Dorothy Chiu Content manager: Rachael Pictor Content developer: Eleanor Yeoell, Rhiannon Bowen Project editor: Raymond Williams Text designer: James Steer Cover designer: Watershed Art (Leigh Ashforth) Editor: Greg Alford Permissions/Photo researcher: Debbie Gallagher Proofreader: Sylvia Marson Indexer: Max McMaster, Master Indexing Cover: pika111 Typeset by MPS Limited Any URLs contained in this publication were checked for currency during the production process. Note, however, that the publisher cannot vouch for the ongoing currency of URLs. Seventh edition published 2018 Adapted from Principles of Macroeconomics, 9th edition, by N. Gregory Mankiw, published by Cengage © 2021 © 2021 Cengage Learning Australia Pty Limited Copyright Notice This Work is copyright. No part of this Work may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, or transmitted in any form or by any means without prior written permission of the Publisher. Except as permitted under the Copyright Act 1968, for example any fair dealing for the purposes of private study, research, criticism or review, subject to certain limitations. These limitations include: Restricting the copying to a maximum of one chapter or 10% of this book, whichever is greater; providing an appropriate notice and warning with the copies of the Work disseminated; taking all reasonable steps to limit access to these copies to people authorised to receive these copies; ensuring you hold the appropriate Licences issued by the Copyright Agency Limited (“CAL”), supply a remuneration notice to CAL and pay any required fees. For details of CAL licences and remuneration notices please contact CAL at Level 11, 66 Goulburn Street, Sydney NSW 2000, Tel: (02) 9394 7600, Fax: (02) 9394 7601 Email: info@copyright.com.au Website: www.copyright.com.au For product information and technology assistance, in Australia call 1300 790 853; in New Zealand call 0800 449 725 For permission to use material from this text or product, please email aust.permissions@cengage.com National Library of Australia Cataloguing-in-Publication Data ISBN: 9780170445658 A catalogue record for this book is available from the National Library of Australia Cengage Learning Australia Level 7, 80 Dorcas Street South Melbourne, Victoria Australia 3205 Cengage Learning New Zealand Unit 4B Rosedale Office Park 331 Rosedale Road, Albany, North Shore 0632, NZ For learning solutions, visit cengage.com.au Printed in Singapore by 1010 Printing International Limited. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 24 23 22 21 20 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 00_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_FM_txt.indd 4 25/08/20 9:45 PM BRIEF CONTENTS Preface to this edition xv Preface to the original edition xviii To the students xix About the authors xx Acknowledgements xxii Part I Introduction 3 Chapter 1 Chapter 2 Chapter 3 Ten principles of economics 4 Thinking like an economist 22 Interdependence and the gains from trade 49 Part 2 Supply and demand: How markets work 65 Chapter 4 The market forces of supply and demand 66 Part 3The data of macroeconomics 93 Chapter 5 Chapter 6 Measuring a nation’s income 94 Measuring the cost of living 115 Part 4 The real economy in the long run 135 Chapter 7 Chapter 8 Chapter 9 Production and growth 136 Saving, investment and the financial system 167 The natural rate of unemployment 195 Part 5 Money and prices in the long run 223 Chapter 10 Chapter 11 The monetary system 224 Inf lation: Its causes and costs 249 Part 6The macroeconomics of open economies 277 Chapter 12 Chapter 13 Open-economy macroeconomics: Basic concepts 278 A macroeconomic theory of the open economy 303 Part 7Short-run economic f luctuations 327 Chapter 14 Chapter 15 Chapter 16 Chapter 17 Aggregate demand and aggregate supply 328 The influence of monetary and fiscal policy on aggregate demand 355 The short-run trade-off between inf lation and unemployment 380 Contemporary macroeconomics topics 403 Part 8 Final thoughts 437 Chapter 18 Five debates over macroeconomic policy 438 Glossary 452 Suggestions for reading 456 Index 458 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 00_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_FM_txt.indd 5 25/08/20 9:45 PM CONTENTS Preface to this edition xv Preface to the original edition xviii To the students xix About the authors xx Acknowledgements xxii Part I Introduction 3 Chapter 1 Ten principles of economics 4 Introduction 5 How people make decisions 5 Principle 1: People face trade-offs 5 Principle 2: The cost of something is what you give up to get it 6 Principle 3: Rational people think at the margin 7 Principle 4: People respond to incentives 8 How people interact 10 Principle 5: Trade can make everyone better off 11 Principle 6: Markets are usually a good way to organise economic activity 12 Principle 7: Governments can sometimes improve market outcomes 14 How the economy as a whole works 15 Principle 8: A country’s standard of living depends on its ability to produce goods and services 15 Principle 9: Prices rise when the government prints too much money 16 Principle 10: Society faces a short-run trade-off between inflation and unemployment 17 Study tools 19 Chapter 2 Thinking like an economist 22 Introduction 23 The economist as scientist 23 The scientific method: Observation, theory and more observation 23 The role of assumptions 24 Economic models 25 Our first model: The circular-flow diagram 25 Our second model: The production possibilities frontier 27 Microeconomics and macroeconomics 30 The economist as adviser 30 Positive versus normative analysis 31 Economists in government 31 Why economists’ advice is not always followed 32 Economists in business 33 Why economists disagree 33 Differences in scientific judgements 33 Differences in values 34 What Australian economists think 34 Study tools 36 Appendix: Graphing – a brief review 39 Chapter 3 Interdependence and the gains from trade 49 Introduction 50 A parable for the modern economy 50 Production possibilities 51 Specialisation and trade 52 Comparative advantage: The driving force of specialisation 54 Absolute advantage 54 Opportunity cost and comparative advantage 54 Comparative advantage and trade 55 The price of trade 56 Applications of comparative advantage 57 Should Serena Williams mow her own lawn? 57 Should Australia trade with other countries? 58 Study tools 61 Part 2 S upply and demand: How markets work 65 Chapter 4 The market forces of supply and demand 66 Introduction 67 Markets and competition 67 What is a market? 67 What is competition? 67 Demand 68 The demand curve: The relationship between price and quantity demanded 68 Market demand versus individual demand 70 Shifts in the demand curve 71 Supply 75 The supply curve: The relationship between price and quantity supplied 76 Market supply versus individual supply 76 Shifts in the supply curve 77 Supply and demand together 80 Equilibrium 80 Three steps for analysing changes in equilibrium 82 Study tools 88 Part 3 T he data of macroeconomics 93 Chapter 5 Measuring a nation’s income 94 Introduction 95 The economy’s income and expenditure 95 The measurement of gross domestic product 97 ‘GDP is the market value …’ 97 ‘… of all …’ 97 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 00_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_FM_txt.indd 6 25/08/20 9:45 PM ‘… final …’ 98 ‘… goods and services …’ 98 ‘… produced …’ 98 ‘… within a country …’ 98 ‘… in a given period of time’ 99 The components of GDP 99 Alternative measures of income 101 Real versus nominal GDP 102 A numerical example 103 The GDP deflator 104 GDP and economic wellbeing 106 So why do we look at GDP at all? 106 International differences in GDP and the quality of life 108 Study tools 112 Chapter 6 Measuring the cost of living 115 Introduction 116 The consumer price index 116 How the consumer price index is calculated 117 Problems in measuring the cost of living 120 The GDP deflator versus the consumer price index 124 Correcting economic variables for the effects of inflation 126 Dollar figures from different times 126 Indexation 127 Real and nominal interest rates 127 Study tools 131 Part 4 T he real economy in the long run 135 Chapter 7 Production and growth 136 Introduction 137 Economic growth around the world 138 Productivity: Its role and determinants 141 Why is productivity so important? 141 How is labour productivity determined? 142 The production function 146 Economic growth and public policy 147 The importance of saving and investment 147 Diminishing returns to physical capital and the catch-up effect 148 Investment from abroad 150 Education 151 Health and nutrition 152 Property rights, markets, trust and political stability 153 Free trade 154 Discouraging excessive population growth 158 Research and development 160 Study tools 164 Chapter 8 Saving, investment and the financial system 167 Introduction 168 Financial institutions in the Australian economy 168 Financial markets 169 Financial intermediaries 173 Summing up 174 Saving and investment in the national income accounts 176 Some important identities 177 The meaning of saving and investment 178 The market for loanable funds 179 Supply of and demand for loanable funds 180 How government policies can affect saving and investment 182 Policy 1: Taxes and saving 182 Policy 2: Taxes and investment 184 Policy 3: Government budgets – surplus or deficit? 185 Study tools 192 Chapter 9 The natural rate of unemployment 195 Introduction 196 Identifying unemployment 197 How is unemployment measured? 197 Is unemployment measured correctly? 201 How long are the unemployed without work? 203 Why is there unemployment? 203 Classical unemployment 204 Minimum-wage laws 204 Unions and collective bargaining 206 The theory of efficiency wages 208 Frictional unemployment 212 The inevitability of frictional unemployment 212 Public policy and job search 213 Unemployment benefits 213 Structural unemployment 214 Study tools 218 Part 5 M oney and prices in the long run 223 Chapter 10 The monetary system 224 Introduction 225 The meaning of money 225 The functions of money 226 Kinds of money 226 Money in the Australian economy 228 The Reserve Bank of Australia 231 Organisation of the RBA 232 Changes in the RBA’s role 233 Banks and the money supply 236 The simple case of 100 per cent reserve banking 236 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 00_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_FM_txt.indd 7 25/08/20 9:45 PM Money creation with fractional-reserve banking 237 The money multiplier 238 Bank capital, leverage and the Global Financial Crisis of 2008 239 Monetary policy in Australia today 241 Problems in controlling the money supply 243 Study tools 246 Chapter 11 Inf lation: Its causes and costs 249 Introduction 250 The causes of inf lation 251 The level of prices and the value of money 251 Money supply, money demand and monetary equilibrium 251 The effects of a monetary injection 253 A brief look at the adjustment process 255 The classical dichotomy and monetary neutrality 256 Velocity and the quantity equation 257 The inf lation tax 259 The Fisher effect 260 The costs of inflation 263 A fall in purchasing power? The inflation fallacy 264 Shoeleather costs 264 Menu costs 265 Relative-price variability and the misallocation of resources 266 Inflation-induced tax distortions 266 Confusion and inconvenience 267 A special cost of unexpected inflation: Arbitrary redistributions of wealth 267 Study tools 273 Part 6 T he macroeconomics of open economies 277 Chapter 12 Open-economy macroeconomics: Basic concepts 278 Introduction 279 The international flows of goods and capital 279 The flow of goods: Exports, imports and net exports 279 The flow of financial resources: Net foreign investment 285 The equality of the current account and the capital and financial accounts 287 Saving, investment and their relationship to the international flows 288 The prices for international transactions: Real and nominal exchange rates 291 Nominal exchange rates 291 Real exchange rates 292 A first theory of exchange-rate determination: Purchasingpower parity 293 The basic logic of purchasing-power parity 293 Implications of purchasing-power parity 294 Limitations of purchasing-power parity 298 Study tools 300 Chapter 13 A macroeconomic theory of the open economy 303 Introduction 304 Supply of and demand for loanable funds and foreign-currency exchange 304 The market for loanable funds 305 The market for foreign-currency exchange 306 Net foreign investment: The link between the two markets 308 Simultaneous equilibrium in two markets 310 Government budget deficits 312 Trade policy 316 Political instability and capital flight 319 Study tools 323 Part 7 S hort-run economic f luctuations 327 Chapter 14 Aggregate demand and aggregate supply 328 Introduction 329 Three key facts about economic f luctuations 329 Fact 1: Economic fluctuations are irregular and unpredictable 329 Fact 2: Most macroeconomic quantities fluctuate together 331 Fact 3: As output falls, unemployment rises 331 Explaining short-run economic fluctuations 333 How the short run differs from the long run 334 The basic model of economic fluctuations 334 The aggregate-demand curve 335 The aggregate-supply curve 338 Two causes of recession 344 The effects of a shift in aggregate demand 344 The effects of a shift in aggregate supply 347 Study tools 351 Chapter 15 The influence of monetary and fiscal policy on aggregate demand 355 Introduction 356 How monetary policy influences aggregate demand 356 The downward slope of the aggregate-demand curve 359 The theory of liquidity preference 360 How fiscal policy influences aggregate demand 363 Changes in government purchases 363 The multiplier effect 363 The crowding out effect 364 Changes in taxes 366 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 00_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_FM_txt.indd 8 25/08/20 9:45 PM Using policy to stabilise the economy 368 The case for active stabilisation policy 368 The case against active stabilisation policy 371 Automatic stabilisers 372 The economy in the long run and the short run 373 Study tools 376 Chapter 16 The short-run trade-off between inf lation and unemployment 380 Introduction 381 The Phillips curve 381 Origins of the Phillips curve 381 Aggregate demand, aggregate supply and the Phillips curve 382 Shifts in the Phillips curve: The role of expectations 384 The long-run Phillips curve 384 Expectations and the short-run Phillips curve 386 Shifts in the Phillips curve: The role of supply shocks 391 The cost of reducing inflation 393 The sacrifice ratio 394 Rational expectations and the possibility of costless disinf lation 395 The Accord approach 396 A low-inflation era 398 Study tools 400 Chapter 17 Contemporary macroeconomics topics 403 Introduction 404 What does globalisation mean? 404 Overview of the main elements of financial crises 410 The causes of the GFC 411 Rising household debt 412 Opaque mortgage securitisation 413 Ill-designed government policies 415 Loose monetary policy 416 Global economic trends and imbalances 416 The European debt contagion 417 Policy responses to the GFC 419 What kind of shocks caused the GFC? 419 The self-correction of the GFC shocks: The theory 420 Macroeconomic policy response to the GFC shocks: The theory 421 Macroeconomic policy responses to the GFC shocks: The reality 422 Lessons from the GFC 427 Slow wages growth 428 Study tools 433 Part 8 Final thoughts 437 Chapter 18 Five debates over macroeconomic policy 438 Introduction 439 That monetary and fiscal policymakers should try to stabilise the economy 439 Pro: Policymakers should try to stabilise the economy 439 Con: Policymakers should not try to stabilise the economy 440 That monetary policy should be made by rule rather than by discretion 440 Pro: Monetary policy should be made by rule 441 Con: Monetary policy should not be made by rule 441 That the central bank should aim for zero inflation 442 Pro: The central bank should aim for zero inflation 442 Con: The central bank should not aim for zero inflation 443 That the government should balance its budget 444 Pro: The government should balance its budget 444 Con: The government should not balance its budget 445 That the tax laws should be reformed to encourage saving 447 Pro: The tax laws should be reformed to encourage saving 447 Con: The tax laws should not be reformed to encourage saving 448 Study tools 450 Glossary 452 Suggestions for reading 456 Index 458 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 00_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_FM_txt.indd 9 25/08/20 9:45 PM Guide to the text As you read this text you will find a number of features in every chapter to enhance your study of macroeconomics and help you understand how the theory is applied in the real world. PART OPENING FEATURES The chapter list outlines the chapters contained in each part for easy reference. The macroeconomics of open economies PART SIX Chapter 12 Open-economy macroeconomics: Basic concepts Chapter 13 A macroeconomic theory of the open economy CHAPTER OPENING FEATURES Identify the key concepts that the chapter will cover with the learning objectives at the start of each chapter. 7 Production and growth The term productivity refers to the quantity of goods and services that a worker can produce for each hour of work. In the case of Crusoe’s economy, it is easy to see that productivity is the key determinant of living standards and that growth in productivity is the key determinant of improvements in living standards. The more fish Crusoe can catch Learning per hour,objectives the more he can eat at dinner. If Crusoe finds a better place to catch fish or a smarter way of doing his productivity rises. in productivity makes Crusoe better After reading thisso,chapter, you should be This able increase to: off – he could eat the extra fish, or he around could spend less time fishing and devote more time to LO7.1 understand economic growth the world other activities hethe enjoys. LO7.2 understand role of productivity and its determinants LO7.3The examine growth public policy. key roleeconomic of productivity in and determining living standards is as true for nations as it is for stranded sailors. Recall that an economy’s gross domestic product (GDP) measures three things at once – the total production, the total income earned in the economy and the total expenditure on the economy’s goods and services. The reason GDP can measure these three things simultaneously is that, for the economy as a whole, they must be equal. Put simply, workers and owners of capital get paid their income for what they produce and use this income to purchase the goods and services produced in the economy. The implication is that Australians are more prosperous than Nigerians mainly because Australian workers are more productive than Nigerian workers. The Chinese have enjoyed more rapid growth in living standards than Venezualans primarily because Chinese workers have experienced more rapidly growing productivity. Indeed, one of the Ten Principles of Economics in chapter 1 is that a country’s standard of living depends on its ability to produce goods and services. The above discussion implies that in order to understand the large differences in living standards across countries or over time, we must focus on the production of goods and services. But seeing the link between prosperity and productivity is only the first step. It leads naturally to the next question: Why are some economies so much better at producing goods and services than others? 136 FEATURES WITHIN CHAPTERS Definitions or explanations of important key terms are located in the margin for quick reference. A full list of key terms are also available in the glossary, which can be found at the back of the book. How is labour productivity determined? Although productivity is uniquely important in determining Robinson Crusoe’s standard of living, many factors determine Crusoe’s productivity. Crusoe will catch more fish, for instance, if he has more fishing rods, if he has been trained in the best fishing techniques, if his island has a plentiful fish supply or if he has figured out the best places and times on his island to fish. Each of these determinants of Crusoe’s productivity – which we can call physical capital, human capital, natural resources and technological knowledge – has a counterpart in more complex and realistic economies. Let’s consider each of these factors in turn. Physical capital physical capital the stock of equipment and structures that are used to produce goods and services Workers are more productive if they have tools with which to work. The stock of equipment and structures that are used to produce goods and services is called physical capital, or just capital. For example, when woodworkers make furniture, they use saws, lathes and drill presses. More tools allow work to be done more quickly and more accurately. That is, a worker with only basic hand tools can make less furniture each week than a worker with sophisticated and specialised woodworking equipment. As you may recall from chapter 2, the inputs used to produce goods and services are called the factors of production. An important feature of physical capital is that, unlike labour, it is a produced factor of production. That is, capital is an input into the production process that in the past was an output from the production process. The woodworker uses a lathe to make the leg of a table. Earlier, the lathe itself was the output of a firm that manufactures lathes. The lathe manufacturer in turn used other equipment to make its product. Thus, capital is a factor of production used to produce all kinds of goods and services, including more capital. 142 Part 4 The real economy in the long run Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 00_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_FM_txt.indd 10 25/08/20 9:45 PM processes. Similarly, labour relates to the quantity of workers in terms of the number of hours they supply, while human capital expresses the quality and intellectual capacity of people with regard to economic activities. To use a relevant metaphor, technological knowledge is the quality of society’s textbooks, whereas human capital is the zeal and ingenuity with which individuals write these textbooks and learn from them. Based on the above discussion, it will probably not surprise you that labour productivity depends on physical capital and human capital, as well as technological knowledge. You will, however, soon see that physical capital only has a temporary effect: Ongoing increases in the number of machines per worker cannot permanently sustain economic growth. This is in contrast to human capital and technological knowledge, both of which improve the quality of the production inputs rather than just adding more inputs. FEATURES WITHIN CHAPTERS Analyse practical applications of concepts through the case studies and test your understanding with the associated questions. CASE STUDY Are natural resources or global warming limits to growth? The world’s population is far larger today than it used to be (in 1800 it was around one billion, one-seventh of what it is now), and most people are enjoying a much higher standard of living. A perennial debate concerns whether this growth in population and living standards can continue in the future. Many commentators have argued that natural resources provide a limit to how much the world’s economies can grow. At first, this argument might seem hard to ignore. If the world has only a fixed supply of non-renewable natural resources, how can population, production and living standards continue to grow over time? Eventually, won’t supplies of oil and minerals start to run out? When these shortages start to occur, they stop economic and, saving perhaps, even force living Although thewon’t accounting identity S = I growth shows that and investment are equal for standards to fall? the economy as a whole, this does not have to be true for every individual household or In the early 1970s, a group of researchers at the Massachusetts Institute of firm. Mary’s saving can be greater than her investment, and she can deposit the excess in Technology (MIT) in the US were commissioned to undertake analysis of whether a bank. Jerry’s saving can be less than his investment and he can borrow the shortfall from this would in fact happen. They published a book called The Limits to Growth. They a bank. Banks andbyother make individual differences concluded that aboutfinancial 2020, weinstitutions would reach peakthese production – that we would between not be saving and investment possible byoutput allowing person’s to finance another person’s able to continue to increase our of one goods as we saving would run out of key inputs of investment. non-renewable resources. The researchers were criticised – their computer modelling made simplistic assumptions, they didn’t consider technological advances and so on. It appears that they weren’t entirely accurate about their predictions … and yet … We are experiencing changes to our climate that may force us to limit our production to prevent catastrophic changes to our environment. Having discussed someare of less the concerned important about financial institutions in our economy and their Most economists running out of resources as the source What Australian role, are ready to buildprogress a model of financial markets. Our purpose in doingmany so is to explain of we limits. Technological has led to discoveries that have replaced noneconomists think with how financialresources markets coordinate the economy’s saving investment. The model also renewable renewables or that allow us toand recycle the non-renewables. gives uscompare a tool with we can analyse various economic and government If we thewhich economy today with the economy of thedevelopments past, we see various ways debate. Of the economists surveyed, There are a number of government in which the use of natural resources has improved. Modern cars, particularly hybrids, policies that saving and investment. 84.9 per cent agree with the statement: policies thatinfluence are generally opposed by require litres of petrol per kilometre. houses have insulation and To keepfewer things we65.2 assume that the New economy onlybetter one financial ‘Prior to has approval of any majormarket, public called economists. For simple, example, per cent require less to heat and cool them. Recycling allowstosome non-renewable the forenergy loanable . All this market deposit savings and all infrastructure project, antheir independent ofmarket economists would likefunds to see an savers end go to resources to be reused. Solar panels on houses and the use of batteries to store borrowers go toduty this market tosales get their loans. Inand this market there is onestudy interest rate,be which expert cost–benefit should to the stamp on home (stamp energy generated during the day are now fairly common. conducted and released publicly.’ Only arereturn state taxes payable youof borrowing. is duties both the on saving andwhen the cost Half a century ago, some people were concerned about the excessive use of tin and per cent of respondents disagree. buy orassumption sell an asset), 19.2 per cent of 8.5 The of awhile single financial market is, of course, not realistic. We have seen that copper. At the time, these were crucial commodities – tin was used to make many food respondents disagree. As experts, the role the economy has many types of financial institutionsSource: and instruments. But, as we discussed ESA Policy Opinion of Australian containers, and copper was used to make telephone wire. Some peopleSurvey advocated Economists 2011,the http://esacentral.org.au/ economists public policy formation inof chapter 2, recycling theinart inand building an of economic model is world mandatory rationing tin and copper so simplifying that supplies would bein order to publications/useful -links/2011-policy-opinion-survey is to analyse proposals andhere, inform public explain it. For purposes we can however, ignore theplastic diversity of financial institutions available for our future generations. Today, has replaced tin as a materialand assume that the economy has a single financial market. for making many food containers, and phone calls often travel over fibre-optic cables, which made from sand. Technological progress once-crucial natural oppose Why are do policies such as stamp duties persist if has the made experts overwhelmingly resources less necessary. them? The reason may be that economists have not yet convinced the general public that But are all these technological efforts enough to continued economic growth? these policies are undesirable. One of the purposes ofpermit this book is to help you understand One way to answer this question is to look at the prices of natural resources. In a market LO8.3 The market for loanable funds Gain insights into recent policy issues using data from Economics Society of Australia with the What Australian economists think boxes. Useful macroeconomic facts can be found in FYI boxes. They will provide you with additional information and material to support key concepts within each chapter. market for loanable funds a (virtual) place where those who supply and demand funds interact FYI the economist’s view of these and other subjects and, perhaps, to persuade you that it is the Question: If you put $100 in a bank right one. value Present 144 account (that pays interest) today, how Imagine that someone offered to give much money will you have in N years? today or $100 in 10 years. That is, what will be the future value of Which would you choose? This is an easy this $100? question. Getting $100 today is clearlyinnovation.Answer just before you do arguably discourages As Boldrin state:the ‘Insofar as : Let’sand useLevine r to denote Give two reasonsyou whycan twoalways economic advisers to the federal government might disagree better, because deposit interest rate them expressed decimal form (so innovators have unique ideas, it may make sense to reward with in monopolies to make about a question of policy. the money in a bank, still have it in 10 interest rate of 5 per cent means r= sure we get advantage of their unusual talentsan … As it happens, simultaneous discoveries years and earn interest along the way. The 0.05). If interest is paid eachexcessive year, andpatent tend to be the rule rather than the exception’. Third and most importantly, lesson: Money today is more valuable than if this interest paid remains in the bank protection inhibits a key driver of prosperity, namely learning from others. As the authors the same amount of money in the future. to earn more interest (a processhave argue:Now ‘Imitation is aa harder great thing. It is among theaccount most powerful technologies humans consider question: called compounding, which you learnt ever developed’. Imagine $100 The first that two someone chapters offered of this you book have introduced youearlier to the ideas and methods about in an chapter), the $100 will of today or $200 in 10 years. Which would you economics. We are now ready to get to work. Inbecome the next(1chapter, we after start1learning inrmore + r) × $100 year, (1 + )× choose? To the answer this question, you need detail about principles of economic behaviour (1 +and r) ×economic $100 afterpolicy. 2 years, (1 + r) × (1 + r) × some wayproceed to compare sums of book, money from (1asked + r) × $100 after yearsofand sointellectual on. After As you through this you will be to draw on3many your different points of time. Economists do this N N years, (1 +John r) ×Maynard $100. skills. It may be helpful to keep in mind some advice fromthe the$100 greatbecomes economist with present value. The important Why aisconcept researchcalled and development (R&D) for long-run economic For example, if the interestgrowth? rate is 5 per Keynes: present value of any future sum of money cent, then the value of the $100 in 10 years’ The studythat of economics not seem to require any specialised gifts of an is the amount today would bedoes needed, 10 time will be (1.05) × $100, which is $163. unusually highto order. Is it not … a very easy subject compared with the higher at current interest rates, produce that Now suppose you are going Using experiments to evaluate aid andQuestion ignite: prosperity philosophy or pure science? An easy subject, at which very few future sum. branches To learn of how to use the to be paid $200 in N years. What is the excel! The paradox finds itseffective explanation, in that the master-economist To figureofout what policies are low-income nations, economists concept present value, let’s work through inperhaps, present value of this future payment? must possess a rare combination of gifts. He must be mathematician, historian, are increasingly turning to randomised controlled experiments used in a couple of simple problems. Part 4 The real economy in the long run you $100 CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING Conclusion: Let’s get going CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING Expand your knowledge of economics related to contemporary events In the news. These boxes provide news articles about economics in the real world. IN THE NEWS statesman, philosopher – in some degree. He must understand symbols and speak medical trials. in words. He must contemplate the particular in terms of the general, and touch abstract and in the same flight of thought. must study the So heHe and a bunch ofpresent his colleagues What it takes toconcrete lift families 179 Because ofin differences in GDP growth rates,ofthe countries by with income the light of the past for the purposes the ranking future. Noof part of man’s or thechanges had a radical idea: Test nature aid same out of poverty Chapter 8 Saving, investment and the financial system his institutions must entirely outside his regard. He must be purposeful and substantially over time. Japan islie a country that has risen relative to others between 1950is, and method doctors use to test drugs (that by Michaeleen Doucleff disinterested a simultaneous as aloof and incorruptible as an artist, randomized control trials). 1990 and 2015 has fallen sinceinthen. The risemood; of China and other South East Asianyetcountries still 15 May sometimes as near the earth as a politician. The idea is quiteand simple. Give some continues. Two countries that have fallen behind are New Zealand Argentina. In 1950, Eighteen years ago, Dean Karlan was a aid with but others nothing. New Zealand was one of thepractice, richest countries infamilies the world, average incomeThen nearly as This is abright-eyed tall order. But with fresh, graduate studentyou in will become more and more accustomed to thinking follow both groups, and seeincome if the in New high as the United and well above the United Kingdom. Today, average like an economist. economics at theStates Massachusetts Institute actually made aIndifference in the had Zealand is well below average income what in the USaid and in Australia. 1950, Venezuela of Technology. He wanted to answer long run. almost fourlike times the income of its South American neighbour, Brazil. Today, Venezuela’s seemed a simple question: Karlan, who’s now a professor at average income only justKarlan over half ‘Does globalisaid work?’ says.that of Brazil’s. Australia’s story is somewhere in Yale University, says many people were He was reading a bunch of studies had the highest per capita income in the world, but between these two. In 1900, Australia skeptical. ‘I have many conversations with on the topic. But none of them actually by 1970 it had fallen to around seventh in the rankings. By 1991, Australia was longer in say, ‘You wantmaking. to dono what? Today, you can find economists involved in manypeople areas ofwho government decision answered thehad question. ‘We weremost tearing the topEconomists 10 and behind European countries intorelative terms. Since havefallen a valuable role to play western in government because they understand Whyprecisely would you want do that?’ Chapter 2 our Australia’s hair outdecisions reading thesetrade-offs, paperseconomic because that all involve and because they are skilled in evaluating thosefamilies trade-since then, relatively strong growth (we have had nosome recession One issue is that go 1992) it was frustrating,’ he says. ‘[We] never really offs.Australia’s Economists are also ablerise, to useattacking another of the Principles of Economics – people has seen ranking theTen top 10 again. home empty-handed, withrespond no aid. So felt like the papers were really satisfactory.’ to incentives – to identify possible unintended consequences of policy proposals. We saw an the idea seems unethical. Butthat Karlan These data show that the world’s richest countries have no guarantee they will example of this in the that ‘babyno bonus’ study in Chapter 1, and unintended consequences of One problem was onecase was disagrees. whole point of this is to in stay the richest and thatisthe world’s poorest countries are ‘The not doomed forever to remain well-meaning policies a theme that we actually testing global aid programs —will return to often throughout this book. hecountries says. ‘Ifthe we findahead out poverty. But what explains these changes over help time?more Why dothe some zoom In Australia, economists skilled in macroeconomics work people,’ in Treasury and methodically — to see if they really andwe what in five years Department of Finance to provide advice on taxation andworks fiscal policy, andtake indoesn’t, the while others lag behind? These are precisely thewhat questions that upReserve next. 35 Thinking like an economist Bank studying monetary and financial issues. Economists skilled in microeconomics haven’t the scientific workbeen in the taking Productivity Commissionmethod advising the government on microeconomic reform, around So Karlan and collaborators to problems poverty,’Competition he says. and Consumer Commission advising on issues related and at theof Australian the world, including those at the Abdul Take, for instance, a charity thatingives to competition policy. Economists all areas of government are supported by their Latif Jameel Poverty Action Lab at MIT colleagues at The the Australian Bureaucheck of Statistics, a family a cow. charity might on who construct the statistical information and the nonprofit Innovations for that is used in alater wide variety of government the family a year and say, ‘Wow! The decision making and economic research. Poverty Action, decided totake out the What has been the approximate annual growth rate of real GDP per person intry Australia Political seek the inputwith of economists in developing the policies that they to family is doingparties so much better this with oneofinof the toughest and elections. China over theall,past half century? Before reading the rest the chapter, canproblems you After economic ‘credibility’ is often a idea prominent issue election campaigns. cow. Cows must be the reason.’ out there: helping families getbetween out of suggest any possible explanations for the differences in economic growth rates Politicians, of all parties, rely on the economists in the Parliamentary Budget Office to provide But maybe itcostings wasn’t the cow that non-partisan theirperiod? proposed policies, andextreme independent analysis of economic and poverty. Australia and China overofthis improved theissues. family’s life. Maybe it had a budgetary An anti-poverty program in bumper crop that of year or property values The influence economists on policy goes beyondBangladesh, their role as advisers and policymakers; called BRAC, looked like and writings can affect policy indirectly. Economist John Maynard Keynes wenttheir up research in the neighborhood. it was successful. It seemed to help offered thisreally observation: Researchers weren’t doing those nearly 400 000 families who were experiments, Karlan The ideassays. of economists and political philosophers, both when they are right and living off less than $1.25 each day. Test your progress through each section by answering the Check your understanding questions as you progress through the chapter. CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING LO7.2 Productivity: Its role and determinants when they are wrong, are more powerful than is commonly understood. Indeed, Explaining the large variation in living standards around the world is, in one sense, very the world is ruled by little else. Practical men, who believe themselves to be quitethe exempt from intellectualcan influences, are usually the slaves of single some defunct easy. As we will see, explanation be summarised in a word – productivity. But, Madmen in authority, who hear voices in the air, are distilling their in another sense, economist. the international variation is deeply puzzling. To explain why incomes are frenzy from some academic scribbler of a few years back. so much higher in some countries than in others, we must look at the many (economic as Chapter 7 These words were written in 1935, but they remain true today. Indeed, the ‘academic well as non-economic) factors that determine a nation’s productivity. ICONS The Key figure icon highlights content relating to a key figure in economics. scribbler’ now influencing public policy is often Keynes himself. 161 Production and growth economists’ so advice is not always followed Why isWhy productivity important? KEY FIGURES Economists who advise the government know that their growth recommendations are not always Let’s begin our study of productivity and economic by developing a simple model heeded. Frustrating as this can be, it is easy to understand. The process by which economic based policy loosely on Daniel Defoe’s famous novel, Robinson Crusoe. Robinson Crusoe, as you is actually made differs in many ways from the idealised policy process assumed in may recall, is a sailor stranded on a desert island. Because Crusoe lives alone, he catches his economics textbooks. text, whenever we economic policy, we often on oneof Crusoe’s own fish,Throughout grows histhis own vegetables anddiscuss makes his own clothes. We focus can think question: is the bestand policy for the government to pursue? We act as if policy were set activities – hisWhat production consumption of fish, vegetables and clothing – as being a by a benevolent queen. Once the queen determines the ‘right’ policy, she has no difficulty simple economy. By examining Crusoe’s economy, we can learn some lessons that also apply putting her ideas into action. to more complex and realistic economies. In the real world, determining the right policy is only part of a leader’s job, sometimes What determines Crusoe’s standard living? answer is obvious. Crusoe is good the easiest part. After the prime ministerofhears fromThe her economic advisers whatIfpolicy they deem she turns to otherand advisers for clothes, related input. The well. prime Ifminister’s at catching fish, best, growing vegetables making he lives he is bad at doing communications advisers will tell her how best to explain the proposed policy to the public, these things, he lives poorly. Because Crusoe gets to consume only what he produces, his and they will try to anticipate any misunderstandings that might make the challenge more living difficult. standard ispress tied advisers to his productive Her will tell her ability. how the news media will report on her proposal and what opinions will likely be expressed on the nation’s editorial pages. Her legislative advisers will tell her how parliament will view the proposal, what amendments members of the Senate will suggest, and the likelihood that the two houses of parliament will pass some 141 32 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Chapter WCN 02-200-202 7 Production and growth Part 1 Introduction 00_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_FM_txt.indd 11 25/08/20 9:45 PM END-OF-CHAPTER FEATURES At the end of each chapter you will find several tools to help you to review, practise and extend your knowledge of the key learning objectives. STUDY STUDY STUDY TOOLS TOOLS TOOLS Review your understanding of the key chapter topics with the Summary. Quickly navigate to Key concepts introduced in the chapter with this list of key terms. Summary LO5.1 Because every transaction has a buyer and a seller, the total expenditure in the economy must equal the total income in the economy. LO5.2 Gross domestic product (GDP) measures an economy’s total expenditure on newly LO5.1 Because every transaction has a buyer and a seller, the total expenditure in the produced goods and services and the total income earned from the production of economy must equal the total income in the economy. these goods and services. More precisely, GDP is the market value of all final goods and LO5.2 Gross domestic product (GDP) measures an economy’s total expenditure on newly LO5.1 Because every transaction a buyer a seller, total expenditure in the services produced within a has country in aand given periodthe of time. produced goods and services and the total income earned from the production of must among equal the total income in of the economy. – consumption, investment, LO5.3 economy GDP is divided four components expenditure these goods and services. More precisely, GDP is the market value of all final goods and LO5.2 Gross domestic productand (GDP) an economy’sincludes total expenditure government purchases netmeasures exports. Consumption spending on newly goods and services produced within a country in a given period of time. produced and services andexception the total of income earned the production of services bygoods households, with the purchases of from new housing. Investment LO5.3 GDP is divided among four components of expenditure – consumption, investment, these goods and services. precisely, is the market value of all finalpurchases goods and includes spending on new More equipment andGDP structures, including households’ government purchases and net exports. Consumption includes spending on goods and services produced within a country in a given period of time. of new housing. Government purchases include spending on goods and services by services by households, with the exception of purchases of new housing. Investment LO5.3 GDP divided components expenditure consumption, investment, local,isstate andamong federalfour governments. Netofexports equal –the value of goods and services includes spending on new equipment and structures, including households’ purchases government purchases and and sold net exports. Consumption spending onand goods and produced domestically abroad (exports) minusincludes the value of goods services of new housing. Government purchases include spending on goods and services by services byabroad households, with the exception of purchases of new housing. Investment produced and sold domestically (imports). local, state and federal governments. Net exports equal the value of goods and services new equipment and structures, including households’ purchases LO5.4 includes Nominal spending GDP useson current prices to value the economy’s production of goods and produced domestically and sold abroad (exports) minus the value of goods and services of new housing. Government purchases include spending onthe goods and services by services. Real GDP uses constant base-year prices to value economy’s production produced abroad and sold domestically (imports). local, stateand andservices. federal governments. Net –exports equalfrom the the value of goods and services of goods The GDP deflator calculated ratio of nominal to real LO5.4 Nominal GDP uses current prices to value the economy’s production of goods and produced domestically andofsold abroad (exports) minus the value of goods and services GDP – measures the level prices in the economy. services. Real GDP uses constant base-year prices to value the economy’s production abroad and sold domestically (imports). LO5.5 produced GDP is a good measure of economic wellbeing because higher incomes mean people of goods and services. The GDP deflator – calculated from the ratio of nominal to real LO5.4 Nominal GDP of uses prices toto value economy’s of goods and can buy more thecurrent things that add theirthe wellbeing. But production it is not a perfect measure GDP – measures the level of prices in the economy. services. RealFor GDP uses constant base-year pricesoftoleisure value the of wellbeing. example, GDP excludes the value andeconomy’s the value ofproduction a clean LO5.5 GDP is a good measure of economic wellbeing because higher incomes mean people of goods and as services. deflator – calculated ratio of inequality nominal to environment, well asThe the GDP negative impact of greater from levelsthe of income orreal can buy more of the things that add to their wellbeing. But it is not a perfect measure GDP crime.– measures the level of prices in the economy. of wellbeing. For example, GDP excludes the value of leisure and the value of a clean LO5.5 GDP is a good measure of economic wellbeing because higher incomes mean people environment, as well as the negative impact of greater levels of income inequality or can buy more of the things that add to their wellbeing. But it is not a perfect measure crime. of wellbeing. For example, GDP excludes the value of leisure and the value of a clean environment, of greater levels investment, p. 100of income inequality or consumption, p. 100as well as the negative impact crime. p. 104 net exports, p. 100 GDP deflator, Summary Summary Key concepts Key concepts government p. 100 consumption,purchases, p. 100 gross domestic (GDP), p. 97 GDP deflator, p.product 104 gross national product (GNP), government purchases, p. 100p. 98 consumption, p. 100 gross domestic product (GDP), p. 97 GDP deflator, p. 104 gross national product (GNP), p. 98 government purchases, p. 100 gross domestic product (GDP), p. 97 Questions review gross national for product (GNP), p. 98 Key concepts Practice questions Practice questions nominal GDP, 103 investment, p.p. 100 real GDP, p. 103 net exports, p. 100 value added, nominal GDP,p. p.101 103 investment, p. 100 real GDP, p. 103 net exports, p. 100 value added, p. 101 nominal GDP, p. 103 real GDP, p. 103 value added, p. 101 1 Explain why an economy’s income must equal its expenditure. Questions for review 2 Which contributes more to GDP – the production of a tonne of wheat or the production of a tonne of coal? Why? 1 Explain why an economy’s income must equal its expenditure. 3 A farmer sells milk to a cheesemaker for $2. The cheesemaker uses the milk to make 2 Which contributes more to GDP – the production of a tonne of wheat or the production of Questions for review cheese, which is sold for $6. What is the contribution to GDP? a tonne of coal? Why? 1 economy’s income equal its expenditure. 4 Explain Over thewhy lastan three years, Kane paidmust $5000 buying new parts to restore his vintage car. 3 A farmer sells milk to a cheesemaker for $2. The cheesemaker uses the milk to make 2 Which contributes more to GDP –for the production a tonne of wheat the production of Today he sells the car at auction $20 000. Howof does this sale affector current GDP? cheese, which is sold for $6. What is the contribution to GDP? tonne of coal? Why? 5 a List the four components of GDP. Give an example of each. 4 Over the last three years, Kane paid $5000 buying new parts to restore his vintage car. 3 sells milkthe to economy a cheesemaker for $2. cheesemaker to make 6 A Infarmer the year 2020, produces 200The serves of fish anduses chipsthe formilk $9.50 each. In the Today he sells the car at auction for $20 000. How does this sale affect current GDP? cheese, which sold for produces $6. What is theserves contribution to GDP? year 2021, the is economy 250 of fish and chips for $12.75 each. Calculate 5 List the four components of GDP. Give an example of each. 4 Over theGDP, last three years, Kane buying newyear. parts(Use to restore vintage car. By nominal real GDP and the paid GDP$5000 deflator for each 2020 ashis the base year.) 6 In the year 2020, the economy produces 200 serves of fish and chips for $9.50 each. In the Today he sells thedoes car at auction for $20 000. How does GDP?Why is what percentage each of these three statistics rise this fromsale oneaffect year current to the next? year 2021, the economy produces 250 serves of fish and chips for $12.75 each. Calculate 5 List the fourfor components ofhave GDP.aGive example it desirable a country to largeanGDP? Give of aneach. example of something that would nominal GDP, real GDP and the GDP deflator for each year. (Use 2020 as the base year.) By 6 In theGDP yearand 2020, produces 200 serves of fish and chips for $9.50 each. In the raise yetthe be economy undesirable. what percentage does each of these three statistics rise from one year to the next? Why is year 2021, the economy produces 250 serves of fish and chips for $12.75 each. Calculate it desirable for a country to have a large GDP? Give an example of something that would nominal GDP, real GDP and the GDP deflator for each year. (Use 2020 as the base year.) By raise GDP and yet be undesirable. what percentage does each of these three statistics rise from one year to the next? Why is it desirable for a country to have a large GDP? Give an example of something that would raise GDP and yet be undesirable. Practice questions Test your knowledge and consolidate your learning through Apply and revise and Practice questions, containing multiple choice questions and problems and applications. Multiple choice 112 1 GDP includes: a Consumption, Investment, Government Transfers, Exports Part 3 The data of macroeconomics b 112 Consumption, Multiple choice Private Investment, Government Investment, Exports and Imports c Consumption, Private and Government Investment, Government Expenditure and Net GDPExports includes: a Consumption, Investment, Government Transfers, Exports d Revenue and Imports b the Consumption, Investment, Government and Imports If nominal GDPPrivate of HobbitLand in 2020 is $2 350Investment, 000 and theExports GDP deflator in 2020 is Part 3 The data of macroeconomics 103 c Consumption, Private Government and Net and the base year forand the Government GDP deflatorInvestment, is 2016, what is real GDP Expenditure in 2020: Exports a $2 281 553 d $2 Consumption, Investment, Government Revenue and Imports b 420 500 2 cIf the $2nominal 350 000GDP of HobbitLand in 2020 is $2 350 000 and the GDP deflator in 2020 is 103$1 and the base year for the GDP deflator is 2016, what is real GDP in 2020: d 807 692 a $2 281 553 3 Which of the following should not be included in GDP: b Your $2 420 500 a purchase of a new pair of pants. c Qantas’ $2 350 000 b purchase of a new ticketing kiosk. $1bank’s 807 692 cd A purchase of an existing building for a new office. 3 d Which the following be included in GDP: TheofRoyal Australianshould Navy’snot purchase of a new patrol boat. a Your purchase of a new pair of pants. 4 According to the information in Table 5.4, Australia has a higher life expectancy and b Qantas’ a new ticketing higher meanpurchase years of of schooling and yet kiosk. Norway is ranked as number 1 on the Human c A bank’s purchase of Australia an existing building 2. forWhich a newof office. Development Index and is number the following must be true? d Australia’s The Royal Australian Navy’s of a new patrol boat. a schooling isn’t as purchase good as Norway’s. 4 b According to real the information in Table 5.4, Australia has a higher life expectancy and Norway’s GDP per person is higher. mean years of schooling and yet Norway is ranked as number 1 on the Human chigher Australia’s distribution of income is worse. Development Indextreat and Australia is number 2.as Which of the following must be true? d Norway doesn’t its old people as well Australia does. Australia’s schooling isn’t as good as Norway’s. 5 a If Australia is experiencing rising inflation, then b Norway’s real is GDP per person is higher. a nominal GDP growing faster than real GDP. cb Australia’s distribution of income is worse. nominal GDP is growing faster than the GDP deflator. d treatfaster its oldthan people as well as Australia does. c Norway real GDPdoesn’t is growing nominal GDP. 5 If is is experiencing rising inflation, then d Australia real GDP growing faster than the GDP deflator. a nominal GDP is growing faster than real GDP. b nominal GDP is growing faster than the GDP deflator. c real GDP is growing faster than nominal GDP. real GDP is growing faster thanwould the GDP deflator. 1 d What components of GDP (if any) each of the following transactions affect? Explain. 1 Part 3 The data of macroeconomics 112 2 Problems and applications a A family buys a new LED TV. b Aunt Maria buys a new iPad. Problems and applications c Kia sells a Rio from its inventory. 1 2 3 2 3 4 5 4 5 What components GDP (ifticket. any) would each of the following transactions affect? Explain. d You buy a movieoftheatre a The A family buys a new LED South TV. e government of New Wales creates a new light rail system in Sydney. Aunt parents Maria buys iPad. fb Your buyaanew bottle of South Australian wine. c Ford Kia sells a Rio from its shuts inventory. g Motor Company down its factory in Campbellfield, Victoria. d You buy a movie theatre ticket. The ‘government purchases’ component of GDP does not include spending on transfer e The government New South Walesabout creates new light rail system in Sydney. payments like welfareofbenefits. Thinking thea definition of GDP, explain why transfer fpayments Your parents buy a bottle of South Australian wine. are excluded. g Ford Motor Company shutspurchases down its factory Campbellfield, Victoria. Why do you think households’ of newin housing are included in the investment The ‘government purchases’ component of GDP does not include component of GDP rather than the consumption component? Canspending you thinkon oftransfer a reason payments like welfare benefits. Thinking about the definition of GDP, in explain why transfer that households’ purchases of refrigerators should also be included investment rather payments are excluded. than in consumption? To what other consumption goods might this logic apply? Why dochapter you think households’ purchases of new housing are included in the investment As the states, GDP does not include the value of volunteer work. Do you think GDP component of GDP than theWould consumption component? Can you think a reason should include suchrather transactions? this make GDP a better measure of of economic that households’ purchases of refrigerators should also be included in investment rather wellbeing? than in To what other consumption goods might logicthink apply? Look onconsumption? the ABS website to find the base year for real GDP. Whythis do you the ABS As the chapter states, does not include the value of volunteer work. Do you think GDP updates the base yearGDP periodically? should include such transactions? Would this make GDP a better measure of economic wellbeing? Look on the ABS website to find the base year for real GDP. Why do you think the ABS updates the base year periodically? 113 Chapter 5 Measuring a nation’s income 113 Chapter 5 Measuring a nation’s income Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 00_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_FM_txt.indd 12 25/08/20 9:45 PM Guide to the online resources FOR THE INSTRUCTOR Cengage is pleased to provide you with a selection of resources that will help you prepare your lectures and assessments. These teaching tools are accessible via cengage.com.au/instructors for Australia or cengage.co.nz/instructors for New Zealand. MINDTAP Premium online teaching and learning tools are available on the MindTap platform - the personalised eLearning solution. MindTap is a flexible and easy-to-use platform that helps build student confidence and gives you a clear picture of their progress. We partner with you to ease the transition to digital – we’re with you every step of the way. The Cengage Mobile App puts your course directly into students’ hands with course materials available on their smartphone or tablet. Students can read on the go, complete practice quizzes or participate in interactive real-time activities. MindTap for Principles of Economics is full of innovative resources to support critical thinking, and help your students move from memorisation to mastery! Includes: • Principles of Economics eBook • Concept clips • Graphing workshops • Video problem walkthroughs • Video lessons • Study guide • Aplia problem sets • Aplia news analysis • Adaptive test preparation • Practice quizzes • MobLab games and experiments MindTap is a premium purchasable eLearning tool. Contact your Cengage learning consultant to find out how MindTap can transform your course. INSTRUCTOR’S MANUAL The Instructor’s manual includes: • • • • • Learning objectives Key point summaries Chapter outline Check your understanding questions Questions for review and practice questions Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 00_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_FM_txt.indd 13 25/08/20 9:45 PM COGNERO TEST BANK This bank of questions has been developed in conjunction with the text for creating quizzes, tests and exams for your students. Deliver these through your LMS and in your classroom. POWERPOINT™ PRESENTATIONS Use the chapter-by-chapter PowerPoint slides to enhance your lecture presentations and handouts by reinforcing the key principles of your subject. ARTWORK FROM THE TEXT Add the digital files of graphs, tables, pictures and flow charts into your course management system, use them in student handouts, or copy them into your lecture presentations. FOR THE STUDENT MINDTAP MindTap is the next-level online learning tool that helps you get better grades! MindTap gives you the resources you need to study – all in one place and available when you need them. In the MindTap Reader, you can make notes, highlight text and even find a definition directly from the page. If your instructor has chosen MindTap for your subject this semester, log in to MindTap to: • Get better grades • Save time and get organised • Connect with your instructor and peers • Study when and where you want, online and mobile • Complete assessment tasks as set by your instructor When your instructor creates a course using MindTap, they will let you know your course link so you can access the content. Please purchase MindTap only when directed by your instructor. Course length is set by your instructor. Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 00_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_FM_txt.indd 14 25/08/20 9:45 PM PREFACE TO THIS EDITION Studying economics should invigorate and enthral. It should challenge students’ preconceptions and provide them with a powerful, coherent framework for analysing the world they live in. Yet, all too often, economics textbooks are dry and confusing. Rather than highlighting the important foundations of economic analysis, these books focus on the ‘ifs’ and ‘buts’. The motto underlying this book is that it is ‘the rule, not the exception’ that is important. Our aim is to show the power of economic tools and the importance of economic ideas for people’s prosperity and wellbeing. This book has been designed particularly for students in Australia. However, we are keenly aware of the diverse mix of students studying this subject. When choosing examples and applications, we have kept an international focus. Whether the issue is the international capital flows in Indonesia or inflation targeting in Australia, examples have been chosen for their relevance and to highlight that the same economic questions are being asked in many countries. The specific context in which economics is applied may vary but the lessons and insights offered by the economic way of thinking are universal. To boil economics down to its essentials, we had to consider what is truly important for students to learn in their first course in economics. As a result, this book differs from others not only in its length but also in its orientation. It is tempting for professional economists writing a textbook to take the economist’s point of view and to emphasise those topics that fascinate them and other economists. We have done our best to avoid that temptation. We have tried to put ourselves in the position of students seeing economics for the first time. Our goal is to emphasise the material that students should and do find interesting about the study of the economy. One result is that more of this book is devoted to applications and policy, and less is devoted to formal economic theory, than is the case with many other books written for the principles course. For example, after students learn about the demand for and supply of loanable funds in chapter 8, they immediately apply these tools to answer important macroeconomic questions facing the Australian economy, such as: How do changes in government tax policy affect the nation’s ability to invest in new capital equipment? These principles are extended to the open economy in chapter 13, where students learn about the demand for and supply of foreign exchange and immediately apply the new tools to explain capital flight from Indonesia during the Asian economic crisis. Throughout this book we have tried to return to applications and policy questions as often as possible. Most chapters include case studies illustrating how the principles of economics are applied. In addition, ‘In the news’ boxes offer excerpts from newspaper articles showing how economic ideas shed light on the current issues facing society. It is our hope that after students finish their first course in economics, they will think about news stories from a new perspective and with greater insight. To write a brief and student-friendly book, we had to consider new ways to organise the material. This book includes all the topics that are central to a first course in economics, but the topics are not always arranged in the traditional order. What follows is a whirlwind tour of this text. This tour will, we hope, give instructors some sense of how the pieces fit together. Chapter 1, ‘Ten principles of economics’, introduces students to the economist’s view of the world. It previews some of the big ideas that recur throughout economics, such as opportunity cost, marginal decision making, the role of incentives, the gains from trade and the efficiency of market allocations. Throughout the book, we refer regularly to the Ten Principles from Economics in xv Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 00_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_FM_txt.indd 15 Preface to this edition 25/08/20 9:45 PM chapter 1 to remind students that these principles are the foundation for most economic analysis. A key icon in the margin calls attention to these references. Chapter 2, ‘Thinking like an economist’, examines how economists approach their field of study. It discusses the role of assumptions in developing a theory and introduces the concept of an economic model. It also discusses the role of economists in making policy. The appendix to this chapter offers a brief refresher course on how graphs are used and how they can be abused. Chapter 3, ‘Interdependence and the gains from trade’, presents the theory of comparative advantage. This theory explains why individuals trade with their neighbours, and why nations trade with other nations. Much of economics is about the coordination of economic activity through market forces. As a starting point for this analysis, students see in this chapter why economic interdependence can benefit everyone. This is done using a familiar example of trade in household chores among flatmates. The next chapter introduces the basic tools of supply and demand. Chapter 4, ‘The market forces of supply and demand’, develops the supply curve, the demand curve, the notion of market equilibrium, elasticity and its applications to different markets, and uses the tools of supply, demand and government to examine price controls, such as rent control and the award wage system, and tax incidence. Beginning in chapter 5, the book turns to the topics of macroeconomics. The coverage starts with the issues of measurement. Chapter 5, ‘Measuring a nation’s income’, discusses the meaning of gross domestic product and related statistics from the national income accounts. Chapter 6, ‘Measuring the cost of living’, discusses the measurement and use of the consumer price index, and considers other measures of inflation. The next three chapters describe the behaviour of the real economy in the long run over which wages and prices are flexible. Chapter 7, ‘Production and growth’, examines the determinants of the large variation in living standards over time and across countries. Chapter 8, ‘Saving, investment and the financial system’, discusses the types of financial institutions in our economy and examines the role of these institutions in allocating resources. Chapter 9, ‘The natural rate of unemployment’, considers the long-run determinants of the unemployment rate, including minimum-wage laws, the market power of unions, the role of efficiency wages and the efficacy of job search. Having described the long-run behaviour of the real economy, the book then turns to the longrun behaviour of money and prices. Chapter 10, ‘The monetary system’, introduces the economist’s concept of money and the role of the central bank in influencing the amount of money in the economy. Chapter 11, ‘Inflation: Its causes and costs’, develops the link between money growth and inflation and discusses the social costs of inflation. The next two chapters present the macroeconomics of open economies. Chapter 12, ‘Openeconomy macroeconomics: Basic concepts’, explains the relationship among saving, investment and the trade balance, the distinction between the nominal and real exchange rate, and the theory of purchasing-power parity. Chapter 13, ‘A macroeconomic theory of the open economy’, presents a classical model of the international flow of goods and capital. The model sheds light on various issues, including the link between budget deficits and trade deficits and the macroeconomic effects of trade policies. Because instructors differ in how much they emphasise this material, these chapters were written so they could be used in different ways. Some instructors may choose to cover chapter 12 but not chapter 13; others may skip both chapters; and others may choose to defer the analysis of open-economy macroeconomics until the end of their courses. After fully developing the long-run theory of the economy in chapters 7 to 13, the book turns its attention to explaining short-run fluctuations around the long-run trend. This organisation simplifies the teaching of the theory of short-run fluctuations because, at this point in the course, students have a good grounding in many basic macroeconomic concepts. Chapter 14, ‘Aggregate demand and aggregate supply’, begins with some facts about the business cycle and then introduces the model of aggregate demand and aggregate supply. Chapter 15, ‘The influence of xvi Preface to this edition Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 00_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_FM_txt.indd 16 25/08/20 9:45 PM monetary and fiscal policy on aggregate demand’, explains how policymakers can use the tools at their disposal to shift the aggregate-demand curve. Chapter 16, ‘The short-run trade-off between inflation and unemployment’, explains why policymakers who control aggregate demand face a trade-off between inflation and unemployment. It examines why this trade-off exists in the short run, why it shifts over time, and why it does not exist in the long run. Chapter 17, ‘Contemporary macroeconomics topics’, is devoted to globalisation – how events in one national economy flow over into other countries through interconnections in financial markets. The Global Financial Crisis of 2008 is covered as an extreme example of interconnected economies. Slow wages growth in Australia is discussed, as are the causes of the GFC. The book concludes with chapter 18, ‘Five debates over macroeconomic policy’. This capstone chapter considers five controversial issues facing policymakers: the proper degree of policy activism in response to the business cycle, the choice between rules and discretion in the conduct of monetary policy, the desirability of reaching zero inflation, the importance of balancing the government’s budget, and the need for tax reform to encourage saving. For each issue, the chapter presents both sides of the debate and encourages students to make their own judgements. Robin E. Stonecash Joshua S. Gans Stephen P. King Martin C. Byford Kris Ivanovski xvii Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 00_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_FM_txt.indd 17 Preface to this edition 25/08/20 9:45 PM PREFACE TO THE ORIGINAL EDITION During my twenty-year career as a student, the course that excited me most was the two-semester sequence on the principles of economics I took during my freshman year in college. It is no exaggeration to say that it changed my life. I had grown up in a family that often discussed politics over the dinner table. The pros and cons of various solutions to society’s problems generated fervent debate. But, in school, I had been drawn to the sciences. Whereas politics seemed vague, rambling and subjective, science was analytic, systematic and objective. While political debate continued without end, science made progress. My freshman course on the principles of economics opened my eyes to a new way of thinking. Economics combines the virtues of politics and science. It is, truly, a social science. Its subject matter is society – how people choose to lead their lives and how they interact with one another. But it approaches its subject with the dispassion of a science. By bringing the methods of science to the questions of politics, economics tries to make progress on the fundamental challenges that all societies face. I was drawn to write this book in the hope that I could convey some of the excitement about economics that I felt as a student in my first economics course. Economics is a subject in which a little knowledge goes a long way. (The same cannot be said, for instance, of the study of physics or the Japanese language.) Economists have a unique way of viewing the world, much of which can be taught in one or two semesters. My goal in this book is to transmit this way of thinking to the widest possible audience and to convince readers that it illuminates much about the world around them. I am a firm believer that everyone should study the fundamental ideas that economics has to offer. One of the purposes of general education is to make people more informed about the world in order to make them better citizens. The study of economics, as much as any discipline, serves this goal. Writing an economics textbook is, therefore, a great honour and a great responsibility. It is one way that economists can help promote better government and a more prosperous future. As the great economist Paul Samuelson put it, ‘I don’t care who writes a nation’s laws, or crafts its advanced treaties, if I can write its economics textbooks.’ N. Gregory Mankiw July 2000 xviii Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Preface to the original edition 00_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_FM_txt.indd 18 25/08/20 9:45 PM TO THE STUDENTS ‘Economics is a study of mankind in the ordinary business of life.’ So wrote Alfred Marshall, the great nineteenth-century economist, in his textbook Principles of Economics. Although we have learned much about the economy since Marshall’s time, this definition of economics is as true today as it was in 1890, when the first edition of his text was published. Why should you, as a student in the twenty-first century, embark on the study of economics? There are three main reasons. The first reason to study economics is that it will help you understand the world in which you live. There are many questions about the economy that might spark your curiosity. Why are houses more expensive in Sydney than in Perth? Why do airlines charge less for a return ticket if the traveller stays over a Saturday night? Why are some people paid so much to play tennis? Why are living standards so meagre in many African countries? Why do some countries have high rates of inflation while others have stable prices? Why are jobs easy to find in some years and hard to find in others? These are just a few of the questions that a course in economics will help you answer. The second reason to study economics is that it will make you a more astute participant in the economy. As you go about your life, you make many economic decisions. While you are a student, you decide how many years you will continue with your studies. Once you take a job, you decide how much of your income to spend, how much to save and how to invest your savings. Someday you may find yourself running a small business or a large corporation, and you will decide what prices to charge for your products. The insights developed in the coming chapters will give you a new perspective on how best to make these decisions. Studying economics will not by itself make you rich, but it will give you some tools that may help in that endeavour. The third reason to study economics is that it will give you a better understanding of the potential and limits of economic policy. As a voter, you help choose the policies that guide the allocation of society’s resources. When deciding which policies to support, you may find yourself asking various questions about economics. What are the burdens associated with alternative forms of taxation? What are the effects of free trade with other countries? What is the best way to protect the environment? How does a government budget deficit affect the economy? These and similar questions are always on the minds of policymakers whether they work for a local council or the prime minister’s office. Thus, the principles of economics can be applied in many of life’s situations. Whether the future finds you reading the newspaper, running a business or running a country, you will be glad that you studied economics. Robin E. Stonecash Joshua S. Gans Stephen P. King Martin C. Byford Kris Ivanovski N. Gregory Mankiw xix Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 00_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_FM_txt.indd 19 To the students 25/08/20 9:45 PM ABOUT THE AUTHORS Robin Stonecash is Director of Executive Education and the Global EMBA at the University of Sydney’s Business School. She was previously Director of Executive Education at the Business School at the University of Technology, Sydney, and Director of Stonecash Associates, a boutique consulting firm. She studied economics at Swarthmore College, the University of Wisconsin and the University of New South Wales. She has taught a variety of courses in microeconomics, macroeconomics and international trade to undergraduates and graduates. She currently consults on strategy and negotiation as well as teaching economics, strategy and negotiation to MBA and executive students. Professor Stonecash’s research interests currently focus on agribusiness in Australia and New Zealand and the impact of leadership programs on leadership effectiveness. Her work has been published in several journals, including Economic Record, Prometheus and Public Performance and Management Review. Professor Stonecash has also done several studies on the efficiency gains from outsourcing. She has consulted widely for private companies and government organisations such as AusAID and the Departments of Ageing and Disability and Community Services. Professor Stonecash lives in Sydney with her husband, Mark. Joshua Gans holds the Jeffrey S. Skoll Chair in Technical Innovation and Entrepreneurship and is a Professor of Strategic Management at the Rotman School of Management, University of Toronto. He studied economics at the University of Queensland and Stanford University. He currently teaches digital economics and entrepreneurship to MBA students. Professor Gans’ research ranges over many fields of economics, including economic growth, game theory, regulation and the economics of technological change and innovation. His work has been published in academic journals including the American Economic Review, Journal of Economic Perspectives, Journal of Political Economy and the Rand Journal of Economics. Joshua also has written the popular books Parentonomics, Information Wants to be Shared, The Disruption Dilemma, Prediction Machines, Innovation + Equality and Economics in the Age of COVID-19. Currently, he is department editor at Management Science. He has also undertaken consulting activities (through his consulting firm, CoRE Research), advising governments and private firms on the impact of microeconomic reform and competition policy in Australia. In 2007, he was awarded the Economic Society of Australia’s Young Economist Award for the Australian economist under 40 who has made the most significant contribution to economic knowledge. In 2008, he was elected as a Fellow of the Academy of Social Sciences Australia. Professor Gans lives in Toronto with his partner, Natalie Lippey, and children, Belanna, Ariel and Annika. Stephen King is a Commissioner with Australia’s Productivity Commission and an adjunct Professor of Economics at Monash University. He has previously been Dean of Business and Economics at Monash University, a member of the Economic Regulation Authority of Western Australia, a member of the National Competition Council and a Commissioner at the Australian Competition and Consumer Commission. After starting (and stopping) studying Forestry and Botany, Stephen completed an economics degree at xx About the authors Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 00_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_FM_txt.indd 20 25/08/20 9:45 PM the Australian National University. He completed his PhD at Harvard University in 1991. Stephen has taught a variety of courses, including teaching introductory economics for 11 years at Harvard University, Monash University and the University of Melbourne. Professor King has researched and published in a wide range of areas, including law and economics, game theory, corporate finance, privatisation and tax policy. From 2012 to 2016, he had a regular column in The Conversation and he has a YouTube channel where you can view companion videos for introductory economics. Stephen regularly provides advice to government, private firms and the Courts on a range of issues relating to regulation and competition policy. He is a Lay Member of the High Court of New Zealand and a Fellow of the Academy of Social Sciences in Australia. Professor King lives in Melbourne with his wife, Mary. Their two children, Jacqui and Rebecca, have grown up, graduated, and run away from home. Martin Byford is Senior Lecturer of Economics at RMIT University. Prior to joining RMIT, he was Assistant Professor of Economics at the University of Colorado at Boulder. Martin discovered economics during the final year of a combined Arts and Civil Engineering degree. Realising that he had made a terrible error in his choice of vocation, Martin went back to university to study economics. He completed a PhD at the University of Melbourne in 2007. Martin has taught introductory microeconomics at RMIT campuses in Australia and Singapore. Dr Byford’s research is primarily in the fields of industrial organisation and microeconomic theory. He has published in academic journals including the Journal of Economic Theory, International Journal of Industrial Organization and Journal of Economics and Management Strategy. Martin also contributes to economic policy debates on a diverse range of topics, including the design of the banking system and labour market reform. Dr Byford lives in Melbourne with his wife, Siobhan, and their son, Robert. Kris Ivanovski is a Scholarly Teaching Fellow within the Department of Economics at Monash University. He has a demonstrated history of working in the higher education industry and is skilled in Policy Analysis, Stata, Economic Research, Data Analysis, and Statistical Modelling. Kris’ strong education experience includes roles at the University of Melbourne and Deakin, as well as a PhD focused in Economics from Monash University. N. Gregory Mankiw is Professor of Economics at Harvard University. As a student, he studied economics at Princeton University and MIT. As a teacher, he has taught macroeconomics, microeconomics, statistics and principles of economics. He even spent one summer long ago as a sailing instructor on Long Beach Island. Professor Mankiw is a prolific writer and a regular participant in academic and policy debates. His work has been published in scholarly journals, such as the American Economic Review, Journal of Political Economy and Quarterly Journal of Economics, and in more popular forums, such as The New York Times, The Boston Globe and The Wall Street Journal. He is also the author of the best-selling intermediate-level textbook Macroeconomics (Worth Publishers). In addition to his teaching, research and writing, Professor Mankiw is a research associate of the National Bureau of Economic Research, an adviser to the Federal Reserve Bank of Boston and the Congressional Budget Office, and a member of the ETS test development committee for the advanced placement exam in economics. Professor Mankiw lives in Wellesley, Massachusetts, with his wife and three children. xxi Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 00_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_FM_txt.indd 21 About the authors 25/08/20 9:45 PM ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS In adapting this book, we have benefited from the input of a wide range of talented people. We would like to thank all those people who helped us with this task. We wish to thank Professor Lance Fisher of the Macquarie University, Ian Macfarlane and Glenn Stevens, former and current Governors of the Reserve Bank of Australia, Trevor Stegman of the University of New South Wales and Ian Harper of the University of Melbourne for useful discussions. We would also like to thank those economists who read and commented on portions of this manuscript, including: Dr Jayanath Ananda, Central Queensland University Dr Dinusha Dharmaratna, Monash College Ratbek Dzhumashev, Monash Unversity Aunchisa Foo, University of Western Australia. Parvinder Kler, Griffith University Tommy Tang, QUT Business School Additionally, we would like to extend our thanks to the reviewers from the previous editions, whose feedback has helped guide the direction of each edition. We would also like to thank Isaac Callaway for his contribution to the text. We give special acknowledgement to Sue Hornby, formerly of the Australian Graduate School of Management, Frank Lowy Library, now head librarian for the Reserve Bank of Australia. She provided excellent research assistance. Thanks also to Pat Matthews. Finally, we would like to thank Jan Libich for his contributions to previous editions of the text. xxii Acknowledgements Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 00_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_FM_txt.indd 22 25/08/20 9:45 PM Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 00_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_FM_txt.indd 23 25/08/20 9:45 PM PART ONE Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 01_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 2 24/08/20 5:57 PM Introduction Chapter 1 Ten principles of economics Chapter 2 Thinking like an economist Chapter 3 Interdependence and the gains from trade Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 01_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 3 24/08/20 5:57 PM 1 Ten principles of economics Learning objectives After reading this chapter, you should be able to: LO1.1 recognise that people face trade-offs when they make decisions, and discuss how the nature of these trade-offs influences their behaviour LO1.2 explain why trade among people or nations can be good for everyone, and discuss why markets are a good, but not perfect, way to allocate resources LO1.3 identify the factors that drive some significant trends in the overall economy. 4 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 01_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 4 24/08/20 5:57 PM Introduction The word economy comes from the Greek word oikonomos, which means ‘one who manages a household’. At first, this origin might seem peculiar. But, in fact, households and economies have much in common. A household faces many decisions. It must decide which members of the household do which tasks and what each member receives in return: Who cooks dinner? Who does the laundry? Who gets the extra dessert at dinner? Who gets to use the car? In short, the household must allocate its scarce resources (time, dessert, petrol) among its various members, taking into account each member’s abilities, efforts and desires. Like a household, a society faces many decisions. A society must decide what jobs will be done and who will do them. It needs some people to grow food, other people to make clothing and still others to design computer software. Once society has allocated people (as well as land, buildings and machines) to various jobs, it must also allocate the output of the goods and services that they produce. It must decide who will eat caviar and who will eat potatoes. It must decide who will drive a Porsche, and who will take the bus. The management of society’s resources is important because resources are scarce. Scarcity means that society has limited resources and therefore cannot produce all the goods and services people wish to have. Just as each member of a household cannot get everything he or she wants, each individual in society cannot attain the highest standard of living to which he or she might aspire. Economics is the study of how society manages its scarce resources. In most societies, resources are allocated not by an all-powerful dictator but through the combined choices of millions of households and firms. Economists, therefore, study how people make decisions – how much they work, what they buy, how much they save and how they invest their savings. Economists also study how people interact with one another. For instance, they examine how the many buyers and sellers of a good interact to determine the price at which the good is sold and the quantity that is sold. Finally, economists analyse the forces and trends that affect the economy as a whole, including the growth in average income, the fraction of the population that cannot find work and the rate at which prices are rising. The study of economics has many facets, but it is unified by several central ideas. In the rest of this chapter, we look at Ten Principles of Economics. Don’t worry if you don’t understand them all at first or if you are not completely convinced. We explore these ideas more fully in later chapters. The 10 principles are introduced here to give you an overview of what economics is all about. scarcity the limited nature of society’s resources economics the study of how society manages its scarce resources LO1.1 How people make decisions There is no mystery about what an economy is. Whether we are talking about the economy of Sydney, of Australia or of the whole world, an economy is just a group of people interacting with one another as they go about their lives. Because the behaviour of an economy reflects the behaviour of the individuals who make up the economy, our first four principles concern individual decision making. Principle 1: People face trade-offs You may have heard the saying, ‘There’s no such thing as a free lunch’. To get something that we like, we usually have to give up something else that we also like. Making decisions requires trading off one goal against another. 5 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 1 Ten principles of economics 01_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 5 24/08/20 5:57 PM efficiency the property of society getting the most it can from its scarce resources equity the property of distributing economic prosperity uniformly among the members of society Consider Carol, a student, who must decide how to allocate her most valuable resource – her time. She can spend all her time studying economics; she can spend all of her time studying psychology; or she can divide her time between the two fields. For every hour she studies one subject, she gives up an hour she could have used studying the other. And for every hour Carol spends studying, she gives up an hour that she could have spent sleeping, bike riding, watching YouTube clips, or working at her part-time job for some extra spending money. Consider parents deciding how to spend their family income. They can buy food or clothing, or have a holiday. Or they can save some of their income for retirement or their children’s education. When they choose to spend an extra dollar on one of these goods, they have one less dollar to spend on some other good. When people are grouped into societies, they face different kinds of trade-offs. The classic trade-off is between ‘guns and butter’. The more society spends on national defence (guns) to protect our shores from foreign aggressors, the less we can spend on consumer goods (butter) to raise our standard of living. Also important in modern society is the trade-off between a clean environment and a high level of income. Laws that require firms to reduce pollution usually raise the cost of producing goods and services. Because of these higher costs, these firms end up earning smaller profits, paying lower wages, charging higher prices or some combination of these three. Thus, while pollution regulations give us a cleaner environment and the improved health that comes with it, this benefit comes at the cost of reducing the wellbeing of the regulated firms’ owners, workers and customers. Another trade-off society faces is between efficiency and equity. Efficiency means that society is getting the greatest possible benefit from its scarce resources. Equity means that those benefits are distributed uniformly among society’s members. In other words, efficiency refers to the size of the economic pie, and equity refers to how the pie is divided between individuals. When government policies are being designed, these two goals often conflict. Consider, for instance, policies aimed at achieving a more equitable distribution of economic wellbeing. Some of these policies, such as the age pension or unemployment benefits, try to help those members of society who are most in need. Others, such as the individual income tax, ask the financially successful to contribute more than others to support the government. Although these policies achieve greater equity, they reduce efficiency. When the government redistributes income from the rich to the poor, it reduces the reward for working hard; as a result, people may work less and produce fewer goods and services. In other words, as the government tries to cut the economic pie into more equitable slices, the pie itself shrinks in size. Recognising that people face trade-offs does not by itself tell us what decisions they will or should make. A student should not abandon the study of psychology just because doing so would increase the time available for the study of economics. Society should not stop protecting the environment just because environmental regulations reduce our material standard of living. The government should not ignore the disadvantaged just because helping them would distort work incentives. Nonetheless, people are likely to make good decisions only if they understand the options that they have available. Our study of economics, therefore, starts by acknowledging life’s trade-offs. Principle 2: The cost of something is what you give up to get it Because people face trade-offs, making decisions requires comparing the costs and benefits of alternative courses of action. In many cases, however, the cost of some action is not as obvious as it might first appear. 6 Part 1 Introduction Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 01_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 6 24/08/20 5:57 PM Consider the decision whether to go to university. The benefits include intellectual enrichment and a lifetime of better job opportunities. But what is the cost? To answer this question, you might be tempted to add up the money you or your parents spend on fees, books, rent and food. Yet this total does not truly represent what you give up to spend a year at university. There are two problems with this calculation. First, it includes some things that are not really costs of university education. Even if you quit university, you would need a place to sleep and food to eat. Rent and food are costs of going to university only to the extent that they may be more expensive because you are at university. Second, this calculation ignores the largest cost of going to university – your time. When you spend a year listening to lectures, reading textbooks and writing assignments, you cannot spend that time working at a job and earning money. For most students, the wages given up to attend university are the largest cost of their education. The opportunity cost of an item is the best alternative you give up to get that item. When making any decision, decision makers should take into account the opportunity costs of each possible action. In fact, they usually do. For example, some young athletes can earn millions if they forgo university and play professional sports. Their opportunity cost of university is very high. Not surprisingly, they often decide that the benefit of a university education is not worth the opportunity cost. opportunity cost the best alternative that must be given up to obtain some item Principle 3: Rational people think at the margin rational people people who systematically and purposefully do the best they can to achieve their objectives marginal change a small incremental adjustment to a plan of action Source: Shutterstock.com/rafapress Economists normally assume that people are rational. Rational people systematically and purposefully do the best they can do to achieve their objectives, given the opportunities they have. As you study economics, you will encounter firms that decide how many workers to hire and how much of their product to manufacture and sell to maximise profits. You will encounter individuals who decide how much time to spend working, and what goods and services to buy with the resulting income to achieve the highest possible level of satisfaction. Rational people know that decisions in life are rarely black and white but usually involve shades of grey. At dinnertime, you don’t ask yourself ‘Should I fast or eat like a pig?’ More likely, the question you face is ‘Should I eat that extra spoonful of mashed potatoes?’ When exams roll around, your decision is not between blowing them off and studying 24 hours a day, but whether to spend an extra hour reviewing your notes instead of posting selfies on Instagram. Economists use the term marginal change to describe a small incremental adjustment to an existing plan of action. Keep in mind that margin means ‘edge’, so marginal changes are adjustments around the edges of what you are doing. Rational people often make decisions by comparing marginal benefits and marginal cost. For example, suppose you are considering watching a movie tonight. You pay $12 a month for a streaming service that gives you unlimited access to its films and TV shows, and you typically watch eight movies a month. What cost should you take into account when deciding whether to watch another movie? You might at first think the answer is $12/8, or $1.50, which is the average cost of a movie. More relevant for your decision, however, is the marginal cost – the extra cost that you would incur by streaming another film. Here, the marginal cost is zero because you pay the same $12 for the service regardless of how many movies you watch. In other words, at the margin, streaming a movie is free. The only cost of watching a movie tonight is the time it takes away from other activities, such as working at a Many streaming services set the job or (better yet) reading this textbook. marginal cost of a movie equal to zero. 7 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 1 Ten principles of economics 01_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 7 24/08/20 5:57 PM Thinking at the margin also works for business decisions as well. Consider an airline deciding how much to charge passengers who fly standby. Suppose that flying a 200-seat plane from Brisbane to Perth costs the airline $100 000. In this case, the average cost of each seat is $100 000/200, which is $500. One might be tempted to conclude that the airline should never sell a ticket for less than $500. But the airline can often increase its profits by thinking at the margin. Imagine that a plane is about to take off with 10 empty seats and a standby passenger waiting at the gate will pay $300 for a seat. Should the airline sell the ticket? Of course it should. If the plane has empty seats, the cost of adding one more passenger is tiny. Although the average cost of flying a passenger is $500, the marginal cost is merely the cost of the sandwich and coffee that the extra passenger will consume and the small bit of jet fuel needed to carry the extra passenger’s weight. As long as the standby passenger pays more than the marginal cost, selling the ticket is profitable. Thus, a rational airline can increase profits by thinking at the margin. Marginal decision making can help explain some otherwise puzzling economic phenomena. Here is a classic question: Why is water so cheap, while diamonds are so expensive? Humans need water to survive, while diamonds are unnecessary. Yet people are willing to pay much more for a diamond than for a cup of water. The reason is that a person’s willingness to pay for a good is based on the marginal benefit that an extra unit of the good would yield. The marginal benefit, in turn, depends on how many units a person already has. Although water is essential, the marginal benefit of an extra cup is small because water is plentiful. By contrast, no one needs diamonds to survive, but because diamonds are so rare, the marginal benefit of an extra diamond is large. A rational decision maker takes an action if and only if the action’s marginal benefit exceeds its marginal cost. This principle explains why people use streaming services as much as they do, why airlines are willing to sell tickets below average cost, and why people are willing to pay more for diamonds than for water. It can take some time to get used to the logic of marginal thinking, but the study of economics will give you ample opportunity to practise. Principle 4: People respond to incentives incentive something that induces a person to act An incentive is something that induces a person to act, such as the prospect of a punishment or reward. Because rational people make decisions by comparing costs and benefits, they respond to incentives. You will see that incentives play a central role in the study of economics. One economist went so far as to suggest that the entire field could be summarised simply: ‘People respond to incentives. The rest is commentary.’ Incentives are key to analysing how markets work. For example, when the price of apples rises, people decide to eat fewer apples. At the same time, apple orchards decide to hire more workers and harvest more apples. In other words, a higher price in a market provides an incentive for buyers to consume less and an incentive for sellers to produce more. As we will see, the influence of prices on the behaviour of consumers and producers is crucial to understanding how the economy allocates scarce resources. Public policymakers should never forget about incentives. Many policies change the costs or benefits that people face and, as a result, alter their behaviour. A tax on petrol, for instance, encourages people to drive smaller, more fuel-efficient cars. That is one reason people drive smaller cars in Europe and Australia, where petrol taxes are higher, than in the United States, where petrol taxes are low. A petrol tax also encourages people to take public transportation rather than drive, to live closer to where they work, or to switch to electric cars. When policymakers fail to consider how their policies affect incentives, they often end up facing unintended consequences. For example, consider public policy towards seat belts and car safety. Today, all cars have seat belts, but this was not the case in the 1950s. In the 8 Part 1 Introduction Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 01_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 8 24/08/20 5:57 PM late 1960s, the rising death toll from motor vehicle accidents generated much public concern over car safety. State and federal governments responded with laws requiring new cars to be equipped with seat belts, and requiring drivers and passengers to wear their seat belts. How does a seat belt law affect car safety? The direct effect is obvious. When a person wears a seat belt, the likelihood of surviving a major accident rises. But that is not the end of the story. The law also affects behaviour by altering incentives. The relevant behaviour here is the speed and care with which drivers operate their cars. Driving slowly and carefully is costly because it uses the driver’s time and energy. When deciding how safely to drive, rational people compare, perhaps unconsciously, the marginal benefit from safer driving with the marginal cost. As a result, they drive more slowly and carefully when the benefit of increased safety is high. For example, when roads are wet or visibility is poor, people drive with greater care and attention than they do when conditions are clear. Consider how a seat belt law alters a driver’s cost–benefit calculation. Seat belts make accidents less costly by reducing the risk of injury or death. In other words, seat belts reduce the benefits of slow and careful driving. People respond to wearing seat belts as they would to an improvement in road conditions – by driving faster and less carefully. The result of a seat belt law, therefore, is a larger number of accidents. The decline in safe driving has a clear, adverse impact on pedestrians, who are more likely to find themselves in an accident but (unlike the drivers) don’t have seat belts to give them protection. At first, this discussion of incentives and seat belts might seem like idle speculation. Yet, in a classic 1975 study, economist Sam Peltzman argued that car safety laws in the United States have, in fact, had many of these effects. According to Peltzman’s evidence, US laws give rise to both fewer deaths per accident, and also to more accidents. He concluded that the net result was little change in the number of driver deaths and an increase in the number of pedestrian deaths. Peltzman’s analysis of car safety is an offbeat and controversial example of the general principle that people respond to incentives. When analysing any policy, we must consider not only the direct effects but also the less obvious, indirect effects that work through incentives. If the policy changes incentives, it will cause people to alter their behaviour. Choosing when the stork comes In the decade between 2004 and 2014, the Australian Government made a payment to parents for every baby born. These payments were known as the ‘baby bonus’, and ranged in value between $3000 and $5437 across the lifetime of the scheme. The story of the baby bonus has lessons for how people respond to incentives and why governments (and others) need to anticipate these responses. In May 2004, the then Treasurer, Peter Costello, announced a $3000 payment (rising to $5000 in 2008) for every child born after 1 July 2004. This meant that the parents of someone whose birthday was 30 June 2004 or earlier would receive nothing. But hold off a day or so, and they would get $3000. This created an incentive for parents to delay births, if they could. And by agreeing with their doctors to schedule planned caesareans and inductions a little later, births could be moved. The graph in Figure 1.1 shows what happened. Notice that there was a dip in births in the last week of June followed by a sharp rise on 1 July 2004. Indeed, that day had the most number of recorded births on a single day in Australian history. And if you think this might just be ‘fiddling the books’, 2 July had the seventh-highest number of births. CASE STUDY 9 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 1 Ten principles of economics 01_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 9 24/08/20 5:57 PM FIGURE 1.1 Births in Australia, June–July 2004 No. of births 900 800 700 600 500 400 June 3 June 10 June 17 June 24 July 1 July 7 July 14 July 21 July 28 Source: Joshua Gans and Andrew Leigh, ‘Born on the First of July’, Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 93, Nos 1–2, February 2009, pp. 246–63. In their paper ‘Born on the First of July’, Joshua Gans and Andrew Leigh estimated that 1167 births were shifted from June to July that year, all as a result of the baby bonus. Medical organisations raised concerns about the health consequences of maternity hospital congestion caused by this, while economists argued that the policy should have been ‘phased in’ so there were no big jumps in payments on any given day. Nonetheless, politicians have failed to heed these warnings. On 1 July 2006, the Howard government raised the baby bonus by $834. Gans and Leigh again found shifts in birth timing, but of a lower magnitude (around 700 births). Source: Joshua Gans and Andrew Leigh, ‘Born on the First of July’, Journal of Public Economics, Vol. 93, Nos 1–2, February 2009, pp. 246–63. Questions 1 The federal government ended baby bonus payments in 2014. What incentives are created by the ending of the payments? 2 How would you expect people to respond to these incentives? CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING Describe an important trade-off you recently faced. Give an example of some action that has both a monetary and non-monetary opportunity cost. Describe an incentive your parents offered you in an effort to influence your behaviour. LO1.2 How people interact The first four principles discussed how individuals make decisions. As we go about our lives, many of our decisions affect not only ourselves but other people as well. The next three principles present some key ideas about how people interact with one another. 10 Part 1 Introduction Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 01_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 10 24/08/20 5:57 PM Principle 5: Trade can make everyone better off You may have heard on the news how Australian workers compete with overseas workers for jobs, and Australian businesses compete with overseas firms for sales. In some ways, this competition is real because Australian workers and firms produce many of the same goods that are produced overseas. A company mining iron ore in the Pilbara competes for the same customers as iron ore producers in Brazil, South Africa and Peru. Banks in Victoria compete with those in Hong Kong and New York to provide financial services. Yet it is easy to be misled when thinking about competition among countries. Trade between Australia and another country is not like a sports contest, where one side wins and the other side loses. The opposite is true: trade between two countries can make each country better off. To see why, consider how trade affects your family. When a member of your family looks for a job, he or she competes against members of other families who are looking for jobs. Families also compete against one another when they go shopping, because each family wants to buy the best goods at the lowest prices. So, in a sense, each family in the economy is competing with all other families. Despite this competition, your family would not be better off isolating itself from all other families. If it did, your family would need to grow its own food, sew its own clothes and build its own home. Clearly, your family gains much from trading with others. Trade allows each person to specialise in the activities he or she does best, whether it is farming, sewing or home building. By trading with others, people can buy a greater variety of goods and services at lower cost. Like families, countries also benefit from being able to trade with one another. Trade allows countries to specialise in what they do best and to enjoy a greater variety of goods and services. The Chinese, the Japanese, the Germans and the Indonesians are as much our partners in the world economy as they are our competitors. Outsourcing your own job The principle that ‘trade can make everyone better off’ is illustrated by this case of an American software developer who outsourced his own job to China. IN THE NEWS Software developer Bob outsources own job and whiles away shifts on cat videos by Caroline Davies When a routine security check by a US-based company showed someone was repeatedly logging on to their computer system from China, it naturally sent alarm bells ringing. Hackers were suspected and telecoms experts were called in. It was only after a thorough investigation that it was revealed that the culprit was not a hacker, but ‘Bob’ (not his real name), an ‘inoffensive and quiet’ family man and the company’s top-performing programmer, who could be seen toiling at his desk day after day and staring diligently at his monitor. For Bob had come up with the idea of outsourcing his own job – to China. So, while a Chinese consulting firm got on with the job he was paid to do, on less than one-fifth of his salary, he whiled away his working day surfing Reddit, eBay and Facebook. The extraordinary story has been revealed by Andrew Valentine, senior investigator at US telecoms firm Verizon Business, on its website, securityblog.verizonbusiness.com. Verizon’s risk team was called by the unnamed critical infrastructure company last year, ‘asking for our help in understanding some anomalous activity that they were witnessing in their VPN logs’, wrote Valentine. The company had begun to allow its software developers to occasionally work from home and so had set up ‘a fairly standard VPN [virtual private network] concentrator’ to facilitate remote access. 11 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 1 Ten principles of economics 01_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 11 24/08/20 5:57 PM When its IT security department started actively monitoring logs being generated at the VPN, ‘What they found startled and surprised them: an open and active VPN connection from Shenyang, China! As in this connection was live when they discovered it,’ wrote Valentine. What was more, the developer whose credentials were being used was sitting at his desk in the office. ‘Plainly stated, the VPN logs showed him logged in from China, yet the employee is right there, sitting at his desk, staring into his monitor.’ Verizon’s investigators discovered ‘almost daily connections from Shenyang, and occasionally these connections spanned the entire workday’. The employee, whom Valentine calls Bob, was in his mid-40s, a ‘family man, inoffensive and quiet. Someone you wouldn’t look twice at in an elevator.’ But an examination of his workstation revealed hundreds of pdf invoices from a third party contractor/developer in Shenyang. ‘As it turns out, Bob had simply outsourced his own job to a Chinese consulting firm. Bob spent less than one-fifth of his six-figure salary for a Chinese firm to do his job for him.’ He had physically FedExed his security RSA ‘token’, needed to access the VPN, to China so his surrogates could log in as him. When the company checked his web-browsing history, a typical ‘work day’ for Bob was: 9am, arrive and surf Reddit for a couple of hours, watch cat videos; 11.30am, take lunch; 1pm, eBay; 2pm-ish, Facebook updates, LinkedIn; 4.40pm–end of day, update email to management; 5pm, go home. The evidence, said Valentine, even suggested he had the same scam going across multiple companies in the area. ‘All told, it looked like he earned several hundred thousand dollars a year, and only had to pay the Chinese consulting firm about fifty grand annually’. Meanwhile, his performance review showed that, for several years in a row, Bob had received excellent remarks for his codes which were ‘clean, well written and submitted in a timely fashion’. ‘Quarter after quarter, his performance review noted him as the best developer in the building,’ wrote Valentine. Bob no longer works for the company. Source: ‘Software developer Bob outsources own job and whiles away shifts on cat videos’, by Caroline Davies, The Guardian, 16 January 2013. Copyright Guardian News & Media Ltd 2020. Principle 6: Markets are usually a good way to organise economic activity market economy an economy that allocates resources through the decentralised decisions of many firms and households as they interact in markets for goods and services The collapse of communism in the Soviet Union and Eastern Europe in the late 1980s and early 1990s was one of the last century’s most transformative events. Communist countries operated on the premise that government workers were in the best position to guide economic activity. These workers, called central planners, decided what goods and services were produced, how much was produced and who produced and consumed these goods and services. The theory behind central planning was that only the government could organise economic activity in a way that promoted economic wellbeing for the country as a whole. Most countries that once had centrally planned economies have abandoned this system and instead have adopted market economies. In a market economy, the decisions of a central planner are replaced by the decisions of millions of firms and households. Firms decide whom to hire and what to make. Households decide which firms to work for and what to buy with their incomes. These firms and households interact in the marketplace, where prices and self-interest guide their decisions. 12 Part 1 Introduction Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 01_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 12 24/08/20 5:57 PM At first glance, the success of market economies is puzzling. In a market economy, no one is looking out for the economic wellbeing of society as a whole. Decisions are made by millions of self-interested households and firms. It might sound like chaos. Yet this is not the case. Market economies have proven remarkably successful in organising economic activity to promote overall prosperity. In his 1776 book An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, economist Adam Smith explained the success of market economies. He noted that households and firms interacting in markets act as if they are guided by an ‘invisible hand’ that leads them to desirable market outcomes. One of our goals in this book is to understand how this invisible hand works its magic. As you study economics, you will learn that prices are the instrument with which the invisible hand directs economic activity. In any market, buyers look at the price when deciding how much to demand, and sellers look at the price when deciding how much to supply. As a result of these decisions, prices reflect both the value of a good to society and the cost to society of making the good. Smith’s great insight was that prices adjust to guide these individual buyers and sellers to reach outcomes that, in many cases, maximise the wellbeing of society as a whole. Smith’s insight has an important corollary: When a government prevents prices from adjusting naturally to supply and demand, it impedes the invisible hand’s ability to coordinate the millions of households and firms that make up the economy. This corollary explains why taxes adversely affect the allocation of resources. Taxes distort prices and thus the decisions of households and firms. It also explains the problems caused by policies that directly control prices, such as rent control. And it explains the failure of communism. In communist countries, prices were not determined in the marketplace but were dictated by government central planners. These planners lacked the necessary information about consumers’ tastes and producers’ costs, which in a market economy is reflected in prices. Central planners failed because they tried to run the economy with one hand tied behind their backs – the invisible hand of the marketplace. FYI Adam Smith and the role of markets Adam Smith is often seen as the founder of modern economics. When his great book An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations was published in 1776, England and Europe were going through a period of major social, political and economic upheaval. The Industrial Revolution was changing the economic landscape just as the American and the French revolutions were to change the political and social landscape. Smith’s book reflects a point of view that was gaining importance at the time – that individuals are usually best left to their own devices, without the heavy hand of government directing their actions. This political philosophy provides the intellectual foundation for the market Adam Smith economy, and for a free society more generally. Why do decentralised market economies work well? Is it because people can be counted on to treat one another with love and kindness? Not at all. Here is Adam Smith’s description of how people interact in a market economy: KEY FIGURES Man has almost constant occasion for the help of his brethren, and it is in vain for him to expect it from their benevolence only. He will be more likely to prevail if he can interest their self-love in his favour, and show them that it is for their own advantage to do for him what he requires of them … Give me that which I want, and you shall have this which you 13 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 1 Ten principles of economics 01_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 13 24/08/20 5:57 PM want, is the meaning of every such offer; and it is in this manner that we obtain from one another the far greater part of those good offices which we stand in need of. It is not from the benevolence of the butcher, the brewer, or the baker that we expect our dinner, but from their regard to their own interest. We address ourselves, not to their humanity but to their self-love, and never talk to them of our own necessities but of their advantages. Nobody but a beggar chooses to depend chiefly upon the benevolence of his fellow-citizens … Every individual … neither intends to promote the public interest, nor knows how much he is promoting it … He intends only his own gain, and he is in this, as in many other cases, led by an invisible hand to promote an end which was no part of his intention. Nor is it always the worse for the society that it was no part of it. By pursuing his own interest he frequently promotes that of the society more effectually than when he really intends to promote it. Smith is saying that participants in the economy are motivated by self-interest and that the ‘invisible hand’ of the marketplace guides this self-interest into promoting general economic wellbeing. Many of Smith’s insights remain at the centre of modern economics. Our analysis in the coming chapters will allow us to express Smith’s ideas and conclusions more precisely and to analyse fully the strengths and weaknesses of a market-based economy. Principle 7: Governments can sometimes improve market outcomes property rights the ability of an individual to own and exercise control over scarce resources market failure a situation in which a market left on its own fails to allocate resources efficiently externality the uncompensated impact of one person’s actions on the wellbeing of a bystander. A positive externality makes the bystander better off. A negative externality makes the bystander worse off. market power the ability of a single economic actor (or small group of actors) to have a substantial influence on market prices If the invisible hand of the market is so great, why do we need government? One purpose of studying economics is to refine your view about the proper role and scope of government policy. One reason we need government is that the invisible hand can work its magic only if government enforces the rules and maintains the institutions that are key to a market economy. Most important, markets work only if property rights are enforced so individuals can own and control scarce resources. A farmer won’t grow food if she expects her crop to be stolen; a restaurant won’t serve meals unless it is assured that customers will pay before they leave; and a film company won’t produce movies if too many potential customers avoid paying by making illegal copies. We all rely on government-provided police and courts to enforce our rights over the things we produce – and the invisible hand depends on our ability to enforce those rights. Another reason we need government is that, although the invisible hand is powerful, it is not omnipotent. There are two broad rationales for a government to intervene in the economy and change the allocation of resources that people would choose on their own: to promote efficiency and to promote equity. That is, most policies aim either to enlarge the economic pie or to change how the pie is divided. Consider first the goal of efficiency. Although the invisible hand usually leads markets to allocate resources to maximise the size of the economic pie, this is not always the case. Economists use the term market failure to refer to a situation in which the market on its own fails to allocate resources efficiently. As we will see, one possible cause of market failure is an externality, which is the impact of one person’s actions on the wellbeing of a bystander. The classic example of an externality is pollution. When the production of a good pollutes the air and creates health problems for those who live near the factories, the market on its own may fail to take this cost into account. Another possible cause of market failure is market power, which refers to the ability of a single person or firm (or a small group of them) to unduly influence market prices. For example, suppose that everyone in town needs water but there is only one well. The owner of the well does not face the rigorous competition with which the invisible hand normally keeps self-interest in check; she may take advantage of this opportunity by restricting the output of water so she can charge a higher price. In the presence of externalities or market power, well-designed public policy can enhance economic efficiency. 14 Part 1 Introduction Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 01_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 14 24/08/20 5:57 PM Now consider the goal of equity. Even when the invisible hand is yielding efficient outcomes, it can nonetheless leave big differences in economic wellbeing. A market economy rewards people according to their ability to produce things that other people are willing to pay for. The world’s best soccer player earns more than the world’s best chess player simply because people are willing to pay more to see soccer than chess. The invisible hand does not ensure that everyone has sufficient food, decent clothing and adequate health care. Many public policies, such as the tax and social welfare systems, aim to achieve a more equitable distribution of economic wellbeing. To say that the government can improve on market outcomes at times does not mean that it always will. Public policy is made by politicians operating in a political process that is far from perfect. Sometimes policies are designed simply to reward the politically powerful. Sometimes they are made by well-intentioned leaders who are not fully informed. As you study economics, you will become a better judge of when a government policy is justifiable because it promotes efficiency or equity and when it is not. CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING Why is a country better off not isolating itself from all other countries? Why do we have markets and, according to economists, what roles should governments play in them? LO1.3 How the economy as a whole works We started by discussing how individuals make decisions and then looked at how people interact with one another. All these decisions and interactions together make up ‘the economy’. The last three principles concern the workings of the economy as a whole. Principle 8: A country’s standard of living depends on its ability to produce goods and services The differences in living standards around the world are staggering. In 2017, the average Australian had an income (in US dollars) of about $50 000. In the same year, the average South Korean earned $37 000, the average New Zealander earned $39 000 and the average Indian earned $7000. Not surprisingly, this large variation in average income is reflected in various measures of the quality of life. Citizens of high-income countries have more computers, more cars, better nutrition, better health care, and longer life expectancy than do citizens of low-income countries. Changes in living standards over time are also large. In Australia, incomes have historically grown about 2 per cent per year (after adjusting for changes in the cost of living). At this rate, average real income doubles every 35 years. What explains these large differences in living standards among countries and over time? The answer is surprisingly simple. Almost all variation in living standards is attributable to differences in countries’ productivity – that is, the amount of goods and services produced by each hour of a worker’s time. In nations where workers can produce a large quantity of goods and services per hour, most people enjoy a high standard of living; in nations where workers are less productive, most people must endure a more meagre existence. Similarly, the growth rate of a nation’s productivity determines the growth rate of its average income. The relationship between productivity and living standards is simple, but its implications are far-reaching. If productivity is the primary determinant of living standards, other productivity the quantity of goods and services produced from each hour of a worker’s time 15 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 1 Ten principles of economics 01_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 15 24/08/20 5:57 PM explanations must be less important. For example, it might be tempting to credit labour unions or award wage laws for the rise in living standards of Australian workers over the past century. Yet the real hero of Australian workers is their rising productivity. The relationship between productivity and living standards also has profound implications for public policy. When thinking about how any policy will affect living standards, the key question is how it will affect our ability to produce goods and services. To boost living standards, policymakers need to raise productivity by ensuring that workers are well educated, have the tools needed to produce goods and services and have access to the best available technology. Principle 9: Prices rise when the government prints too much money Source: © Tribune Content Agency All rights reserved. inflation an increase in the overall level of prices in the economy In January 1921, a daily newspaper in Germany cost 0.30 of a mark. Less than two years later, in November 1922, the same newspaper cost 70 000 000 marks. All other prices in the economy rose by similar amounts. This episode is one of history’s most spectacular examples of inflation, an increase in the overall level of prices in the economy. Although Australia and New Zealand have never experienced inflation even close to that in Germany in the 1920s, inflation has at times been an economic problem. During the 1970s, for instance, the overall level of prices more than doubled, and political leaders lived under the catchcry ‘Fight Inflation First!’ In contrast, in the first two decades of the twenty-first century, inflation has run at about 2.5 per cent per year; at this rate, it would take almost 30 years for prices to double. Because high inflation imposes various costs on society, keeping inflation at a reasonable rate is a goal of economic policymakers around the world. What causes inflation? In almost all cases of large or persistent inflation, the culprit is growth in the quantity of money. When a government creates large quantities of the nation’s money, the value of the money falls. In Germany in the early 1920s, when prices were on average tripling every month, the quantity of money was also tripling every month. Although less dramatic, the economic history of Australia, New Zealand and the United States points to a similar conclusion – the high inflation of the 1970s was associated with rapid growth in the quantity of money, and the return of low inflation in the 1990s was associated with slower growth in the quantity of money. 16 Part 1 Introduction Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 01_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 16 24/08/20 5:57 PM Principle 10: Society faces a short-run trade-off between inflation and unemployment While an increase in the quantity of money primarily has the effect of raising prices in the long run, in the short run the story is more complex. Most economists describe the short-run effects of money growth as follows: • Increasing the amount of money in the economy stimulates the overall level of spending and thus the demand for goods and services. • Higher demand may over time cause firms to raise their prices, but in the meantime, it also encourages them to hire more workers and produce a larger quantity of goods and services. • More hiring means lower unemployment. This line of reasoning leads to one final economy-wide trade-off: a short-run trade-off between inflation and unemployment. Although some economists still question these ideas, most accept that society faces a short-run trade-off between inflation and unemployment. This simply means that, over a period of a year or two, many economic policies push inflation and unemployment in opposite directions. Policymakers face this trade-off regardless of whether inflation and unemployment both start out at high levels (as they did in the 1980s), at low levels (as they did in the late 1990s), or someplace in between. This short-run trade-off plays a key role in the analysis of the business cycle – the irregular and largely unpredictable fluctuations in economic activity, as measured by the production of goods and services or the number of people employed. Policymakers can exploit the short-run trade-off between inflation and unemployment using various policy instruments. By changing the amount that the government spends, the amount it taxes, and the amount of money it prints, policymakers can influence the overall demand for goods and services. Changes in demand in turn influence the combination of inflation and unemployment that the economy experiences in the short run. Because these instruments of economic policy are so powerful, how policymakers should use them to control the economy, if at all, is a subject of continuing debate. business cycle fluctuations in economic activity, such as employment and production CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING What factors determine a country’s standard of living? How does printing more money affect a country’s economy in the long run and in the short run? Conclusion: The big ideas underpinning economics You now have a taste of what economics is all about. In the coming chapters, we will develop many specific insights about people, markets and economies. Mastering these insights will take some effort, but the task is not overwhelming. The field of economics is based on a few big ideas that can be applied in many different situations. 17 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 1 Ten principles of economics 01_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 17 24/08/20 5:57 PM Throughout this book, we will refer to the Ten Principles of Economics introduced in this chapter and summarised in Table 1.1. Keep these building blocks in mind: Even the most sophisticated economic analysis is founded on these 10 principles. TABLE 1.1 Ten principles of economics How people make decisions 1: People face trade-offs. 2: The cost of something is what you give up to get it. 3: Rational people think at the margin. 4: People respond to incentives. How people interact 5: Trade can make everyone better off. 6: Markets are usually a good way to organise economic activity. 7: Governments can sometimes improve market outcomes. How the economy as a whole works 8: A country’s standard of living depends on its ability to produce goods and services. 9: Prices rise when the government prints too much money. 10: S ociety faces a short-run trade-off between inflation and unemployment. 18 Part 1 Introduction Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 01_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 18 24/08/20 5:57 PM LO1.1 The fundamental lessons about individual decision making are that people face tradeoffs among alternative goals, that the cost of any action is measured in terms of forgone opportunities, that rational people make decisions by comparing marginal costs and marginal benefits, and that people change their behaviour in response to the incentives they face. LO1.2 The fundamental lessons about interactions among people are that trade can be mutually beneficial, that markets are usually a good way of coordinating trade among people, and that governments can potentially improve market outcomes if there is some market failure or if the market outcome is inequitable. LO1.3 The fundamental lessons about the economy as a whole are that productivity is the ultimate source of living standards, that money growth is the ultimate source of inflation, and that society faces a short-run trade-off between inflation and unemployment. Key concepts business cycle, p. 17 economics, p. 5 efficiency, p. 6 equity, p. 6 externality, p. 14 incentive, p. 8 inflation, p. 16 marginal change, p. 7 market economy, p. 12 market failure, p. 14 market power, p. 14 opportunity cost, p. 7 productivity, p. 15 property rights, p. 14 rational people, p. 7 scarcity, p. 5 STUDY TOOLS Summary Apply and revise 1 Give three examples of important trade-offs that you face in your life. 2What alternatives would you include when determining your opportunity cost of a dinner at a fancy restaurant? 3 Water is necessary for life. Is the marginal benefit of a glass of water large or small? 4 Why should policymakers think about incentives? 5 Why isn’t trade among countries like a game with some winners and some losers? 6 What does the ‘invisible hand’ of the marketplace do? 7 What are ‘efficiency’ and ‘equity’, and what do they have to do with government policy? 8 Why is productivity important? 9 What is inflation, and what causes it? 10 How are inflation and unemployment related in the short run? Practice questions Multiple choice 1 2 Economics is best defined as the study of a how society manages its scarce resources. b how to run a business most profitably. c how to predict inflation, unemployment and stock prices. d how the government can stop the harm from unchecked self-interest. Your opportunity cost of going to a movie is a the price of the ticket. b the price of the ticket plus the cost of any drink and popcorn you buy at the theatre. c the total cash expenditure needed to go to the movie plus the value of your time. d zero, as long as you enjoy the movie and consider it a worthwhile use of time and money. 19 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 1 Ten principles of economics 01_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 19 24/08/20 5:57 PM 3 4 5 6 A marginal change is one that a is not important for public policy. b incrementally alters an existing plan. c makes an outcome inefficient. d does not influence incentives. Adam Smith’s ‘invisible hand’ refers to a the subtle and often hidden methods that businesses use to profit at consumers’ expense. b the ability of free markets to reach desirable outcomes, despite the self-interest of market participants. c the ability of government regulation to benefit consumers, even if the consumers are unaware of the regulations. d the way in which producers or consumers in unregulated markets impose costs. Governments may intervene in a market economy in order to a protect property rights. b correct a market failure due to externalities. c achieve a more equal distribution of income. d all of the above If a nation has high and persistent inflation, the most likely explanation is a the central bank creating excessive amounts of money. b unions bargaining for excessively high wages. c the government imposing excessive levels of taxation. d firms using their monopoly power to enforce excessive price hikes. Problems and applications 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Describe some of the trade-offs faced by each of the following: a a family deciding whether to buy a new car b a politician deciding how much to increase spending on national parks c a company director deciding whether to open a new factory d a professor deciding how much to prepare for a lecture e a recent university graduate deciding whether to undertake graduate studies. You are trying to decide whether to take a holiday. Most of the costs of the holiday (airfare, hotel, forgone wages) are measured in dollars, but the benefits of the holiday are psychological. How can you compare the benefits with the costs? You were planning to spend Saturday working at your part-time job, but a friend asks you to go swimming at the beach. What is the true cost of going swimming? Now suppose that you had been planning to spend the day studying at the library. What is the cost of going swimming in this case? Explain. You win $100 in a lottery. You have a choice between spending the money now and putting it away for a year in a bank account that pays 5 per cent interest. What is the opportunity cost of spending the $100 now? The company that you manage has invested $5 million in developing a new product, but the development is not quite finished. At a recent meeting, your salespeople report that the introduction of competing products has reduced the expected sales of your new product to $3 million. If it would cost $1 million to finish development, should you go ahead and do so? What is the most that you should pay to complete development? There has been some discussion about changes to unemployment benefits that will result in payments being withdrawn after two years for those able to work. a How do these changes in the laws affect the incentives for working? b How might these changes represent a trade-off between equity and efficiency? Explain whether each of the following government activities is motivated by a concern about equity or a concern about efficiency. In the case of efficiency, discuss the type of market failure involved. a regulating fixed-line telephone prices b providing some poor people with vouchers that can be used to buy food c prohibiting smoking in public places 20 Part 1 Introduction Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 01_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 20 24/08/20 5:57 PM d breaking up Google and Facebook into smaller companies, each focused on a different product (for example, search, advertising, mobile operating systems) e imposing higher personal income tax rates on people with higher incomes f instituting laws against driving while intoxicated. 8 Discuss each of the following statements from the standpoints of equity and efficiency: a ‘Everyone in society should be guaranteed the best health care possible.’ b ‘The minimum wage should provide each worker with sufficient income to enjoy a comfortable standard of living.’ 9In what ways is your standard of living different from that of your parents or grandparents when they were your age? Why have these changes occurred? 10 Suppose Australians decided to save more of their incomes. If banks lend this money to businesses, which use the money to build new factories, how might higher saving lead to faster productivity growth? Who do you suppose benefits from higher productivity? Is society getting a free lunch? 11 Printing money to cover expenditures is sometimes referred to as an ‘inflation tax’. Who do you think is being ‘taxed’ when more money is printed? Why? 21 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 1 Ten principles of economics 01_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 21 24/08/20 5:57 PM 2 Thinking like an economist Learning objectives After reading this chapter, you should be able to: LO2.1 explain how economists apply the methods of science and use models, to shed light on the world LO2.2 differentiate between positive and normative statements, and discuss the role of economists in making policy LO2.3 explain why economists sometimes disagree with one another. 22 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 02_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 22 24/08/20 5:59 PM Introduction Every field of study has its own language and its own way of thinking. Mathematicians talk about axioms, integrals and vector spaces. Psychologists talk about ego, id and cognitive dissonance. Lawyers talk about premeditation, torts and promissory estoppel. Economics is no different. Supply, demand, elasticity, comparative advantage, consumer surplus, deadweight loss – these terms are part of the economist’s language. In the coming chapters, you will encounter many new terms and some familiar words that economists use in specialised ways. At first, this new language may seem needlessly obscure. But, as you will see, its value lies in its ability to provide you with a new and useful way of thinking about the world in which you live. The purpose of this book is to help you learn the economist’s way of thinking. Just as you cannot become a mathematician, psychologist or lawyer overnight, learning to think like an economist will take some time. Yet, with a combination of theory, case studies and examples of economics in the news, this book will give you ample opportunity to develop and practise this skill. Before delving into the substance and details of economics, it is helpful to have an overview of how economists approach the world. This chapter, therefore, discusses the field’s methodology. What is distinctive about how economists confront a question? What does it mean to think like an economist? elasticity a measure of the responsiveness of quantity demanded or quantity supplied to one of its determinants LO2.1 The economist as scientist Economists try to tackle their subject with a scientist’s objectivity. They approach the study of the economy in much the same way as a physicist approaches the study of matter and a biologist approaches the study of life: They devise theories, collect data and then analyse these data in an attempt to verify or refute their theories. To beginners, the claim that economics is a science can seem odd. After all, economists do not work with test tubes or telescopes. The essence of science, however, is the scientific method – the dispassionate development and testing of theories about how the world works. This method of inquiry is as applicable to studying a nation’s economy as it is to studying the earth’s gravity or a species’ evolution. As Albert Einstein once put it: ‘The whole of science is nothing more than a refinement of everyday thinking.’ Although Einstein’s comment is as true for social sciences – such as economics – as it is for natural sciences such as physics, most people are not accustomed to looking at society through the scientific lens. So let’s discuss some of the ways in which economists apply the logic of science to examine how an economy works. scientific method the dispassionate development and testing of theories about how the world works The scientific method: Observation, theory and more observation Isaac Newton, the seventeenth-century scientist and mathematician, is said to have become intrigued one day when he saw an apple fall from an apple tree. This observation motivated Newton to develop a theory of gravity that applies not only to an apple falling to the ground but also to any two objects in the universe. Subsequent testing of Newton’s theory has shown that it works well in many circumstances (but not all, as Einstein would later show). Because Newton’s theory has been so successful at explaining what we observe around us, it is still taught in undergraduate physics courses around the world. 23 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 2 Thinking like an economist 02_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 23 24/08/20 5:59 PM Source: PEANUTS © 1989 Peanuts Worldwide LLC. Dist. By ANDREWS MCMEEL SYNDICATION. Reprinted with permission. All rights reserved. randomised controlled trials conducting a trial where participants are separated into two groups (a treatment and a control) in order to identify the impact of a policy change This interplay between theory and observation also occurs in economics. An economist might live in a country experiencing rapid increases in prices and be moved by this observation to develop a theory of inflation. The theory might assert that high inflation arises when the government prints too much money. To test this theory, the economist could collect and analyse data on prices and money from many different countries. If growth in the quantity of money were completely unrelated to the rate of price increase, the economist would start to doubt the validity of this theory of inflation. If money growth and inflation were strongly correlated in international data, as in fact they are, the economist would gain confidence in the theory. Although economists use theory and observation like other scientists, they face an obstacle that makes their task especially challenging: In economics, conducting experiments is challenging. Physicists studying gravity can drop many objects in their laboratories to generate data to test their theories. By contrast, economists studying inflation are not allowed to manipulate a nation’s monetary policy simply to generate useful data. Economists, like astronomers and evolutionary biologists, usually have to make do with whatever data the world gives them. Nonetheless, in some important domains, economists have been able to engage in randomised controlled trials. MIT professor Amy Finkelstein led a study in Oregon that examined how the introduction of public health insurance impacted health, health care use, financial security (increasing them) and emergency room use (having no effect). It was able to do this because it set up a real-world situation where some people received public insurance while others did not. To find a substitute for laboratory experiments, economists pay close attention to the natural experiments offered by history. When a war in the Middle East interrupts the supply of crude oil, for instance, oil prices around the world skyrocket. For consumers of oil and oil products, such an event depresses living standards. For economic policymakers, it poses a difficult choice about how best to respond. But for economic scientists, the event provides an opportunity to study the effects of a key natural resource on the world’s economies, and this opportunity persists long after the wartime increase in oil prices is over. Throughout this book, therefore, we consider many historical episodes. Studying these episodes is valuable because they give us insight into the economy of the past and, more importantly, because they allow us to illustrate and evaluate economic theories of the present. The role of assumptions If you ask a physicist how long it would take for a marble to fall from the top of a 10-storey building, she will answer the question by assuming that the marble falls in a vacuum. Of course, this assumption is false. In fact, the building is surrounded by air, which exerts friction on the falling marble and slows it down. Yet the physicist will correctly point out that friction on the marble is so small that its effect would be negligible in this instance. Assuming the marble falls in a vacuum greatly simplifies the problem without substantially affecting the answer. 24 Part 1 Introduction Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 02_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 24 24/08/20 5:59 PM Economists make assumptions for the same reason. Assumptions can simplify the complex world and make it easier to understand. To study the effects of international trade, for example, we may assume that the world consists of only two countries and that each country produces only two goods. In reality, there are many countries, each of which produces thousands of different types of goods. But by considering a world with only two countries and two goods, we can focus our thinking on the essence of the problem. Once we understand international trade in this simplified imaginary world, we are in a better position to understand international trade in the more complex world in which we live. The art in scientific thinking – whether in physics, biology or economics – is deciding which assumptions to make. Suppose, for instance, that instead of dropping a marble from the top of the building, we were dropping a beach ball of the same weight. Our physicist would realise that the assumption of no friction is far less accurate in this case: Friction exerts a greater force on the beach ball because it is much larger than a marble. The assumption that gravity works in a vacuum is reasonable when studying a falling marble but not when studying a falling beach ball. Similarly, economists use different assumptions to answer different questions. Suppose that we want to study what happens to the economy when the government changes the number of dollars in circulation. An important piece of this analysis, it turns out, is how prices respond. Many prices in the economy change infrequently. The supermarket price of milk, for instance, changes only once every few years. Knowing this fact may lead us to make different assumptions when studying the effects of the policy change over different time horizons. For studying the short-run effects of the policy, we may assume that prices do not change much. We may even make the extreme assumption that all prices are completely fixed. For studying the long-run effects of the policy, however, we may assume that all prices are completely flexible. Just as a physicist uses different assumptions when studying falling marbles and falling beach balls, economists use different assumptions when studying the short-run and long-run effects of a change in the quantity of money. Economic models Secondary school biology teachers teach basic anatomy with plastic replicas of the human body. These models have all the major organs – the heart, the liver, the kidneys and so on – and allow teachers to show their students in a simple way how the important parts of the body fit together. Because these plastic models are not actual human bodies, no one would mistake the model for a real person. Despite this lack of realism – indeed, because of this lack of realism – studying these models is useful for learning how the human body works. Economists also use models to learn about the world, but instead of being made of plastic, their models mostly consist of diagrams and equations. Like a biology teacher’s plastic model, economic models omit many details to allow us to see what is truly important. Just as the biology teacher’s model does not include all of the body’s muscles and blood vessels, an economist’s model does not include every feature of the economy. As we use models to examine various economic issues throughout this book, you will see that all the models are built on assumptions. Just as a physicist begins the analysis of a falling marble by assuming away the existence of friction, economists assume away many details of the economy that are irrelevant to the question at hand. All models – in physics, biology or economics – simplify reality in order to improve our understanding of it. Our first model: The circular-flow diagram The economy consists of millions of people engaged in many activities – buying, selling, working, hiring, manufacturing and so on. To understand how the economy works, we must find some way to simplify our thinking about all these activities. In other words, we need a 25 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 2 Thinking like an economist 02_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 25 24/08/20 5:59 PM circular-flow diagram a visual model of the economy that shows how dollars flow through markets among households and firms model that explains, in general terms, how the economy is organised and how participants in the economy interact with one another. Figure 2.1 presents a visual model of the economy, called a circular-flow diagram. In this model, the economy has two types of decision makers: households and firms. Firms produce goods and services using various inputs, such as labour, land and capital (buildings and machines). These inputs are called the factors of production. Households own the factors of production and consume all the goods and services that the firms produce. FIGURE 2.1 The circular flow Revenue Goods and services sold FIRMS • Produce and sell goods and services • Hire and use factors of production Inputs for production Wages, rent and profit MARKETS FOR GOODS AND SERVICES • Firms sell • Households buy Spending Goods and services bought HOUSEHOLDS • Buy and consume goods and services • Own and sell factors of production Labour, land MARKETS and capital FOR FACTORS OF PRODUCTION • Households sell Income • Firms buy Flow of goods and services Flow of dollars This diagram is a schematic representation of the organisation of the economy. Decisions are made by households and firms. Households and firms interact in the markets for goods and services (where households are buyers and firms are sellers) and in the markets for the factors of production (where firms are buyers and households are sellers). The outer set of arrows shows the flow of dollars and the inner set of arrows shows the corresponding flow of goods and services. Households and firms interact in two types of markets. In the markets for goods and services, households are buyers and firms are sellers. In particular, households buy the output of goods and services that firms produce. In the markets for the factors of production, households are sellers and firms are buyers. In these markets, households provide firms with the inputs that the firms use to produce goods and services. The circular-flow diagram offers a simple way of organising all the transactions that occur between households and firms in the economy. The two loops in the circular-flow diagram are distinct but related. The inner loop of the diagram represents the flows of inputs and outputs. Households sell the use of their labour, land and capital to the firms in the markets for the factors of production. Firms then use these factors to produce goods and services. The outer loop of the circular-flow diagram represents the corresponding flow of dollars. Households spend money to buy goods and services from the firms. Firms use some of the revenue from these sales to pay for the factors of production, such as the wages of their workers. What is left is the profit for the firm owners, who themselves are members of households. 26 Part 1 Introduction Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 02_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 26 24/08/20 5:59 PM Let’s take a tour of the circular flow by following a dollar coin as it makes its way from person to person through the economy. Imagine that the dollar begins at a household, sitting in, say, your pocket. If you want to buy a latté, you take the dollar (along with a few other coins) to the market for coffee, which is one of the many markets for goods and services. When you buy your favourite drink at your local cafe, the dollar moves into the cafe’s cash register, becoming revenue for the firm. The dollar doesn’t stay at the cafe for long, however, because that firm spends it on inputs in the markets for factors of production. For instance, the cafe might use the dollar to pay rent to its landlord for the space it occupies or to pay the wages of its workers. In either case, the dollar enters the income of some household and, once again, is back in someone’s pocket. At that point, the story of the economy’s circular flow starts again. The circular-flow diagram is a very simple model of the economy. A more complex and realistic circular-flow model would include, for instance, the roles of government and international trade. (A portion of that dollar you gave to the cafe might be used to pay taxes or to buy coffee beans from a farmer in Ecuador.) Yet these details are not crucial for a basic understanding of how the economy is organised. Because of its simplicity, this circular-flow diagram is useful to keep in mind when thinking about how the pieces of the economy fit together. Our second model: The production possibilities frontier Most economic models, unlike the circular-flow diagram, are built using the tools of mathematics. Here we consider one of the simplest models, called the production possibilities frontier, and see how this model illustrates some basic economic ideas. Although real economies produce thousands of goods and services, let’s imagine an economy that produces only two goods – cars and computers. Together, the car industry and the computer industry use all of the economy’s factors of production. The production possibilities frontier is a graph that shows the various combinations of output – in this case, cars and computers – that the economy can possibly produce given the available factors of production and the available production technology that firms can use to turn these factors into output. Figure 2.2 is an example of a production possibilities frontier. In this economy, if all resources were used in the car industry, the economy would produce 1000 cars and no computers. If all resources were used in the computer industry, the economy would produce 3000 computers and no cars. The two end points of the production possibilities frontier represent these extreme possibilities. More likely, the economy divides its resources between the two industries, producing some cars and some computers. For example, it could produce 700 cars and 2000 computers, shown in the figure by point A. Or, by moving some of the factors of production to the computer industry from the car industry, the economy can produce 600 cars and 2200 computers, represented by point C. Because resources are scarce, not every conceivable outcome is feasible. For example, no matter how resources are allocated between the two industries, the economy cannot produce the amount of cars and computers represented by point D. Given the technology available for manufacturing cars and computers, the economy does not have the factors of production to support that level of output. With the resources it has, the economy can produce at any point on or inside the production possibilities frontier, but it cannot produce at points outside the frontier. An outcome is said to be efficient if the economy is getting all it can from the scarce resources it has available. Points on (rather than inside) the production possibilities frontier represent efficient levels of production. When the economy is producing at such a point, say point A, there is no way of producing more of one good without producing less of the other. The same holds for point C. But point B represents an inefficient outcome. For some reason, perhaps widespread unemployment, the economy is producing less than it could from the production possibilities frontier a graph that shows the various combinations of output that the economy can possibly produce given the available factors of production and the available production technology 27 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 2 Thinking like an economist 02_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 27 24/08/20 5:59 PM FIGURE 2.2 The production possibilities frontier Quantity of computers produced 3000 D C 2200 A 2000 1000 0 Production possibilities frontier B 300 600 700 1000 Quantity of cars produced The production possibilities frontier shows the combinations of output – in this case, cars and computers – that the economy can possibly produce. The economy can produce any combination on or inside the frontier. Points outside the frontier are not feasible given the economy’s resources. The slope of the production possibilities frontier measures the opportunity cost of a car in terms of computers. This opportunity cost varies, depending on how much of the two goods the economy is producing. resources it has available – it is producing only 300 cars and 1000 computers. If the source of the inefficiency is eliminated, the economy can increase its production of both goods. For example, if the economy moves from point B to point C, its production of cars increases from 300 to 600, and its production of computers increases from 1000 to 2200. One of the Ten Principles of Economics discussed in Chapter 1 is that people face tradeoffs. The production possibilities frontier shows one trade-off that society faces. Once we have reached an efficient point on the frontier, the only way of producing more of one good is to produce less of the other. When the economy moves from point C to point A, for instance, society produces 100 more cars, but at the expense of producing 200 fewer computers. This trade-off helps us to understand another of the Ten Principles of Economics: the cost of something is what you give up to get it. This is called the opportunity cost. The production possibilities frontier shows the opportunity cost of one good as measured in terms of the other good. When society moves from point C to point A, it gives up 200 computers to get 100 additional cars. That is, at point C, the opportunity cost of 100 cars is 200 computers. Put another way, the opportunity cost of each car is two computers. Notice that the opportunity cost of a car equals the slope of the production possibilities frontier. (Slope is discussed in the graphing appendix to this chapter.) The opportunity cost of a car in terms of the number of computers is not constant in this economy but depends on how many cars and computers the economy is producing. This is reflected in the shape of the production possibilities frontier. Because the production possibilities frontier in Figure 2.2 is bowed outward, the opportunity cost of a car is highest when the economy is producing many cars and few computers, where the frontier is steep. When the economy is producing few cars and many computers, the frontier is flatter, and the opportunity cost of a car is lower. 28 Part 1 Introduction Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 02_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 28 24/08/20 5:59 PM Economists believe that production possibilities frontiers often have this bowed-out shape. When the economy is using most of its resources to make computers, the production possibilities frontier is relatively flat. Workers and machines best suited to making cars, like skilled autoworkers, are being used to make computers. If some of these skilled autoworkers are moved from computer production to the car industry, the economy will not have to sacrifice much computer production in order to increase car production. Each computer the economy gives up yields a substantial increase in the number of cars. The opportunity cost of a car, in terms of computers forgone, is small. In contrast, when the economy is using most of its resources to make cars, the production possibilities frontier is quite steep. In this case, the resources best suited to making cars are already in the car industry. Producing an additional car means moving some of the best computer technicians out of the computer industry and making them autoworkers. As a result, producing an additional car will mean a substantial loss of computer output. The opportunity cost of a car is high, and the production possibilities frontier is steep. The production possibilities frontier shows the trade-off between the production of different goods at a given time, but the trade-off can change over time. For example, suppose a technological advance in the computer industry raises the number of computers that a worker can produce each week. This advance expands society’s set of opportunities. For any given number of cars, the economy can make more computers. If the economy does not produce any computers, it can still only produce 1000 cars, so one end point of the frontier stays the same. But if the economy devotes some of its resources to the computer industry, it will produce more computers from those resources. As a result, the production possibilities frontier shifts outwards, as in Figure 2.3. FIGURE 2.3 A shift in the production possibilities frontier Quantity of computers produced 4000 3000 2100 2000 0 E A 700 750 1000 Quantity of cars produced A technological advance in the computer industry shifts the production possibilities frontier outwards, increasing the number of cars and computers the economy can produce. 29 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 2 Thinking like an economist 02_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 29 24/08/20 5:59 PM This figure shows what happens when an economy grows. Society can move production from a point on the old frontier to a point on the new frontier. Which point it chooses depends on its preferences for the two goods. In this example, society moves from point A to point E, enjoying more computers (2100 instead of 2000) and more cars (750 instead of 700). The production possibilities frontier simplifies a complex economy to highlight some basic but powerful ideas: scarcity, efficiency, trade-offs, opportunity cost and economic growth. As you study economics, these ideas will recur in various forms. The production possibilities frontier offers one simple way of thinking about them. Microeconomics and macroeconomics microeconomics the study of how households and firms make decisions and how they interact in markets macroeconomics the study of economywide phenomena, including inflation, unemployment and economic growth Many subjects are studied on various levels. Consider biology, for example. Molecular biologists study the chemical compounds that make up living things. Cellular biologists study cells, which are made up of many chemical compounds and, at the same time, are themselves the building blocks of living organisms. Evolutionary biologists study the many varieties of animals and plants and how species change gradually over the centuries. Economics is also studied on various levels. We can study the decisions of individual households and firms. We can study the interaction of households and firms in markets for specific goods and services. Or we can study the operation of the economy as a whole, which is just the sum of the activities of all these decision makers in all these markets. The field of economics is traditionally divided into two broad subfields. Microeconomics is the study of how households and firms make decisions and how they interact in specific markets. Macroeconomics is the study of economy-wide phenomena. A microeconomist might study the effects of the discovery of a new gas reserve in Queensland on energy production, the impact of foreign competition on the domestic car industry or the effects of education on workers’ earnings. A macroeconomist might study the effects of borrowing by the federal government, the changes over time in the economy’s unemployment rate, or alternative policies to raise growth in national living standards. Microeconomics and macroeconomics are closely intertwined. Because changes in the overall economy arise from the decisions of millions of individuals, it is impossible to understand macroeconomic developments without considering the underlying microeconomic decisions. For example, a macroeconomist might study the effect of a cut in income tax on the overall production of goods and services. But to analyse this issue, the macroeconomist must consider how the tax cut affects households’ decisions about how much to spend on goods and services. Despite the inherent link between microeconomics and macroeconomics, the two fields are distinct. Because microeconomics and macroeconomics tackle different questions, each field has its own set of models, which are often taught in separate courses. CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING In what sense is economics like a science? Draw a production possibilities frontier for a society that produces food and clothing. Show an efficient point, an inefficient point and an infeasible point. Show the effects of a drought. Define microeconomics and macroeconomics. LO2.2 The economist as adviser Often, economists are asked to explain the causes of economic events. Why, for example, is unemployment higher for teenagers than for older workers? Sometimes economists are asked to recommend policies to improve economic outcomes. What, for instance, should 30 Part 1 Introduction Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 02_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 30 24/08/20 5:59 PM the government do to improve the economic wellbeing of teenagers? When economists are trying to explain the world, they are scientists. When they are helping to improve it, they are policy advisers. Positive versus normative analysis To help clarify the two roles that economists play, let’s examine the use of language. Because scientists and policymakers have different goals, they use language in different ways. For example, suppose that two people are discussing minimum-wage laws. Here are two statements you might hear: Polly: Minimum-wage laws cause unemployment. Norma: The government should raise the minimum wage. Ignoring for now whether you agree with these statements, notice that Polly and Norma differ in what they are trying to do. Polly is speaking like a scientist – she is making a claim about how the world works. Norma is speaking like a policymaker – she is making a claim about how she would like to change the world. In general, statements about the world are of two types. One type, such as Polly’s, is positive. Positive statements are descriptive. They make a claim about how the world is. A second type of statement, such as Norma’s, is normative. Normative statements are prescriptive. They make a claim about how the world ought to be. A key difference between positive and normative statements is how we judge their validity. We can, in principle, confirm or refute positive statements by examining evidence. An economist might evaluate Polly’s statement by analysing data on changes in minimum wages and changes in unemployment over time. In contrast, evaluating normative statements involves values as well as facts. Norma’s statement cannot be judged using data alone. Deciding what is good or bad policy is not merely a matter of science. It also involves our views on ethics, religion and political philosophy. Positive and normative statements are fundamentally different, but within a person’s set of beliefs, they are often intertwined. In particular, positive views about how the world works affect our normative views about what policies are desirable. Polly’s claim that the minimum wage causes unemployment, if true, might lead us to reject Norma’s conclusion that the government should raise the minimum wage. Yet our normative conclusions cannot come from positive analysis alone; they involve value judgements as well. As you study economics, keep in mind the distinction between positive and normative statements because it will help you stay focused on the task at hand. Much of economics is positive: It just tries to explain how the economy works. Yet those who use economics often have normative goals: They want to learn how to improve the economy. When you hear economists making normative statements, you know they are speaking not as scientists but as policy advisers. positive statements claims that attempt to describe the world as it is normative statements claims that attempt to prescribe how the world should be Economists in government Former US President Harry Truman once said that he wanted to find a one-armed economist. When he asked his economists for advice, they always answered, ‘On the one hand … On the other hand …’ Truman was right in realising that economists’ advice is not always straightforward. This tendency is rooted in one of the Ten Principles of Economics in Chapter 1 – people face trade-offs. Economists are aware that trade-offs are involved in most policy decisions. A policy might increase efficiency at the cost of equity. It might help future generations but hurt the current generation. An economist who says that all policy decisions are easy or clear-cut is an economist not to be trusted. 31 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 2 Thinking like an economist 02_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 31 24/08/20 5:59 PM Today, you can find economists involved in many areas of government decision making. Economists have a valuable role to play in government precisely because they understand that all decisions involve trade-offs, and because they are skilled in evaluating those tradeoffs. Economists are also able to use another of the Ten Principles of Economics – people respond to incentives – to identify possible unintended consequences of policy proposals. We saw an example of this in the ‘baby bonus’ case study in Chapter 1, and unintended consequences of well-meaning policies is a theme that we will return to often throughout this book. In Australia, economists skilled in macroeconomics work in the Treasury and the Department of Finance to provide advice on taxation and fiscal policy, and in the Reserve Bank studying monetary and financial issues. Economists skilled in microeconomics work in the Productivity Commission advising the government on microeconomic reform, and at the Australian Competition and Consumer Commission advising on issues related to competition policy. Economists in all areas of government are supported by their colleagues at the Australian Bureau of Statistics, who construct the statistical information that is used in a wide variety of government decision making and economic research. Political parties seek the input of economists in developing the policies that they take to elections. After all, economic ‘credibility’ is often a prominent issue in election campaigns. Politicians, of all parties, rely on the economists in the Parliamentary Budget Office to provide non-partisan costings of their proposed policies, and independent analysis of economic and budgetary issues. The influence of economists on policy goes beyond their role as advisers and policymakers; their research and writings can affect policy indirectly. Economist John Maynard Keynes offered this observation: KEY FIGURES The ideas of economists and political philosophers, both when they are right and when they are wrong, are more powerful than is commonly understood. Indeed, the world is ruled by little else. Practical men, who believe themselves to be quite exempt from intellectual influences, are usually the slaves of some defunct economist. Madmen in authority, who hear voices in the air, are distilling their frenzy from some academic scribbler of a few years back. These words were written in 1935, but they remain true today. Indeed, the ‘academic scribbler’ now influencing public policy is often Keynes himself. Why economists’ advice is not always followed Economists who advise the government know that their recommendations are not always heeded. Frustrating as this can be, it is easy to understand. The process by which economic policy is actually made differs in many ways from the idealised policy process assumed in economics textbooks. Throughout this text, whenever we discuss economic policy, we often focus on one question: What is the best policy for the government to pursue? We act as if policy were set by a benevolent queen. Once the queen determines the ‘right’ policy, she has no difficulty putting her ideas into action. In the real world, determining the right policy is only part of a leader’s job, sometimes the easiest part. After the prime minister hears from her economic advisers what policy they deem best, she turns to other advisers for related input. The prime minister’s communications advisers will tell her how best to explain the proposed policy to the public, and they will try to anticipate any misunderstandings that might make the challenge more difficult. Her press advisers will tell her how the news media will report on her proposal and what opinions will likely be expressed on the nation’s editorial pages. Her legislative advisers will tell her how parliament will view the proposal, what amendments members of the Senate will suggest, and the likelihood that the two houses of parliament will pass some 32 Part 1 Introduction Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 02_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 32 24/08/20 5:59 PM version of the prime minister’s proposal into law. Her political advisers will tell her which groups will organise to support or oppose the proposed policy, how this proposal will affect her standing among different groups in the electorate, and whether it will change support for any of the prime minister’s other policy initiatives. After weighing all this advice, the prime minister then decides how to proceed. Making economic policy in a representative democracy is a messy affair – and there are often good reasons why prime ministers (and other politicians) do not advance the policies that economists advocate. Economists offer crucial input to the policy process, but their advice is only one ingredient of a complex recipe. Economists in business Government is not the only place you will find economists. While economists have always played a role in large multinational corporations – advising on macroeconomics trends and currency movements – increasingly, economists are involved in important elements of business innovation. Google’s search results have advertisements placed above and beside them. It was an economist, Hal Varian, who designed the auction that tells Google which advertisers should have their ads placed first and how to ensure they pay for the privilege. Susan Athey became the first Chief Economist of Microsoft and led developments there in using artificial intelligence to power many of their new innovative products. Today, economists are important advisers at Facebook, Uber, Airbnb and Amazon. CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING Give an example of a positive statement and an example of a normative statement. Name three parts of government that regularly rely on advice from economists. LO2.3 Why economists disagree ‘If all the economists were laid end to end, they would not reach a conclusion.’ This quip from George Bernard Shaw is revealing. Economists as a group are often criticised for giving conflicting advice to policymakers. Former US President Ronald Reagan once joked that if the game Trivial Pursuit were designed for economists, it would have 100 questions and 3000 answers. Why do economists so often appear to give conflicting advice to policymakers? There are two basic reasons: • Economists may disagree about the validity of alternative positive theories of how the world works. • Economists may have different values and, therefore, different normative views about what policies should try to accomplish. Let’s discuss each of these reasons. Differences in scientific judgements Several centuries ago, astronomers debated whether the earth or the sun was at the centre of the heavens. More recently, climatologists have debated whether the earth is experiencing global warming and, if so, why. Science is an ongoing search for understanding about the world around us. It is not surprising that, as the search continues, scientists can disagree about the direction in which truth lies. 33 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 2 Thinking like an economist 02_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 33 24/08/20 5:59 PM Economists often disagree for the same reason. Although the field of economics sheds light on much about the world (as you will see throughout this book), there is still much to be learned. Sometimes economists disagree because they have different hunches about the validity of alternative theories. Sometimes they disagree because of different judgements about the size of the parameters that measure how economic variables are related. For example, economists debate whether the government should levy taxes based on a household’s income or its consumption (spending). In Australia, advocates of the goods and services tax (GST), introduced in 2000, believed that the change would encourage households to save more, because income that is saved would not be taxed. Higher saving, in turn, would free resources for capital accumulation, leading to more rapid growth in productivity and living standards. Those opposing the GST believed that household saving would not respond much to a change in the tax laws. These two groups of economists held different views about the tax system because they had different positive views about the responsiveness of saving to tax incentives. Differences in values Suppose that Jack and Jill both take the same amount of water from the town well. To pay for maintaining the well, the town taxes its residents. Jack has income of $150 000 and is taxed $15 000, or 10 per cent of his income. Jill has income of $40 000 and is taxed $8000, or 20 per cent of her income. Is this policy fair? If not, who pays too much and who pays too little? Does it matter that Jill’s low income is due to a medical disability? Would your opinion change if Jill’s low income resulted from her decision to pursue an acting career? Does it matter whether Jack’s high income is due to a large inheritance or to his willingness to work long hours at a dreary job? These are difficult questions about which people are likely to disagree. If the town hired two experts to study how it should tax its residents to pay for the well, it would not be surprising if they offered conflicting advice. This simple example shows why economists sometimes disagree about public policy. As we learned earlier in our discussion of normative and positive analysis, policies cannot be judged on scientific grounds alone. Economists give conflicting advice sometimes because they have different values. Perfecting the science of economics will not tell us whether Jack or Jill pays too much. What Australian economists think Because of differences in scientific judgements and differences in values, some disagreement among economists is inevitable. Yet one should not overstate the amount of disagreement. Economists agree with one another far more than is sometimes understood. In 2011, the Economic Society of Australia (ESA) surveyed the views of more than 500 Australian economists. The respondents reflect the diverse career paths available to economists, representing industry, government and university sectors. The survey highlights policy areas in which there exists a broad consensus among Australian economists, as well as those areas that remain the subject of significant disagreements. At key points throughout this book, the opinions of Australian economists are highlighted in ‘What Australian economists think’ boxes such as the one below. 34 Part 1 Introduction Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 02_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 34 24/08/20 5:59 PM What Australian economists think There are a number of government policies that are generally opposed by economists. For example, 65.2 per cent of economists would like to see an end to the stamp duty on home sales (stamp duties are state taxes payable when you buy or sell an asset), while 19.2 per cent of respondents disagree. As experts, the role of economists in public policy formation is to analyse proposals and inform public debate. Of the economists surveyed, 84.9 per cent agree with the statement: ‘Prior to approval of any major public infrastructure project, an independent and expert cost–benefit study should be conducted and released publicly.’ Only 8.5 per cent of respondents disagree. Source: ESA Policy Opinion Survey of Australian Economists 2011, http://esacentral.org.au/ publications/useful -links/2011-policy-opinion-survey Why do policies such as stamp duties persist if the experts overwhelmingly oppose them? The reason may be that economists have not yet convinced the general public that these policies are undesirable. One of the purposes of this book is to help you understand the economist’s view of these and other subjects and, perhaps, to persuade you that it is the right one. CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING Give two reasons why two economic advisers to the federal government might disagree about a question of policy. Conclusion: Let’s get going The first two chapters of this book have introduced you to the ideas and methods of economics. We are now ready to get to work. In the next chapter, we start learning in more detail about the principles of economic behaviour and economic policy. As you proceed through this book, you will be asked to draw on many of your intellectual skills. It may be helpful to keep in mind some advice from the great economist John Maynard Keynes: The study of economics does not seem to require any specialised gifts of an unusually high order. Is it not … a very easy subject compared with the higher branches of philosophy or pure science? An easy subject, at which very few excel! The paradox finds its explanation, perhaps, in that the master-economist must possess a rare combination of gifts. He must be mathematician, historian, statesman, philosopher – in some degree. He must understand symbols and speak in words. He must contemplate the particular in terms of the general, and touch abstract and concrete in the same flight of thought. He must study the present in the light of the past for the purposes of the future. No part of man’s nature or his institutions must lie entirely outside his regard. He must be purposeful and disinterested in a simultaneous mood; as aloof and incorruptible as an artist, yet sometimes as near the earth as a politician. This is a tall order. But with practice, you will become more and more accustomed to thinking like an economist. 35 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 2 Thinking like an economist 02_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 35 24/08/20 5:59 PM STUDY TOOLS Summary LO2.1 Economists try to approach their subject with a scientist’s objectivity. Like all scientists, they make appropriate assumptions and build simplified models in order to understand the world around them. The field of economics is divided into two subfields – microeconomics and macroeconomics. Microeconomists study decision making by households and firms and the interaction among households and firms in the marketplace. Macroeconomists study the forces and trends that affect the economy as a whole. LO2.2 A positive statement is an assertion about how the world is. A normative statement is an assertion about how the world ought to be. While positive statements can be judged based on facts and the scientific method, normative statements entail value judgements as well. When economists make normative statements, they are acting more as policy advisers than as scientists. LO2.3 Economists who advise policymakers offer conflicting advice either because of differences in scientific judgements or because of differences in values. At other times, economists are united in the advice they offer, but policymakers may choose to ignore the advice because of the many forces and constraints imposed on them by the political process. Key concepts circular-flow diagram, p. 26 macroeconomics, p. 30 microeconomics, p. 30 normative statements, p. 31 positive statements, p. 31 production possibilities frontier, p. 27 randomised controlled trials, p. 24 scientific method, p. 23 Apply and revise 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 In what ways is economics like a science? Why do economists make assumptions? Should an economic model describe reality exactly? Name a way that your family interacts in the markets for the factors of production and a way that it interacts in the markets for goods and services. Name one economic interaction that isn’t covered by the simplified circular-flow diagram. Draw and explain a production possibilities frontier for an economy that produces milk and cookies. What happens to this frontier if a disease kills half of the economy’s cows? Use a production possibilities frontier to describe the idea of efficiency. What are the two subfields into which economics is divided? Explain what each subfield studies. What is the difference between a positive and a normative statement? Give an example of each. Why do economists sometimes offer conflicting advice to policymakers? Practice questions Multiple choice 1 2 An economic model is a a mechanical machine that replicates the functioning of the economy. b a fully detailed, realistic description of the economy. c a simplified representation of some aspect of the economy. d a computer program that predicts the future of the economy. The circular-flow diagram illustrates that, in markets for the factors of production, a households are sellers, and firms are buyers. b households are buyers, and firms are sellers. c households and firms are both buyers. d households and firms are both sellers. 36 Part 1 Introduction Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 02_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 36 24/08/20 5:59 PM 3 4 5 6 A point inside the production possibilities frontier is a efficient, but not feasible. b feasible, but not efficient. c both efficient and feasible. d neither efficient nor feasible. An economy produces hot dogs and hamburgers. If a discovery of the remarkable health benefits of hot dogs were to change consumers’ preferences, it would a expand the production possibilities frontier. b contract the production possibilities frontier. c move the economy along the production possibilities frontier. d move the economy inside the production possibilities frontier. All of the following topics fall within the study of microeconomics except a the impact of cigarette taxes on the smoking behaviour of teenagers. b the role of Microsoft’s market power in the pricing of software. c the effectiveness of antipoverty programs in reducing homelessness. d the influence of the government budget deficit on economic growth. Which of the following is a positive, rather than a normative, statement? a Law X will reduce national income. b Law X is a good piece of legislation. c The federal parliament ought to pass law X. d The High Court should repeal law X. Problems and applications 1 2 3 4 Draw a circular-flow diagram. Identify the parts of the model that correspond to the flow of goods and services and the flow of dollars for each of the following activities: a Sam pays a shopkeeper $1 for a litre of milk. b Terry earns $16.50 per hour working at a fast-food restaurant. c Uma spends $13 to see a film. d Violet earns $10 000 from her 10 per cent ownership of Acme Industrial. Imagine a society that produces military goods and consumer goods, which we’ll call ‘guns’ and ‘butter’. a Draw a production possibilities frontier for guns and butter. Explain why it most likely has a bowed-out shape. b Show a point that is impossible for the economy to achieve. Show a point that is feasible but inefficient. c Imagine that the society has two political parties; call them the Hawks (who want a strong military) and the Doves (who want a smaller military). Show a point on your production possibilities frontier that the Hawks might choose and a point the Doves might choose. d Imagine that an aggressive neighbouring country reduces the size of its military. As a result, both the Hawks and the Doves reduce their desired production of guns by the same amount. Which party would get the bigger ‘peace dividend’, measured by the increase in butter production? Explain. The first principle of economics discussed in Chapter 1 is that people face trade-offs. Use a production possibilities frontier to illustrate society’s trade-off between a clean environment and high incomes. What do you suppose determines the shape and position of the frontier? Show what happens to the frontier if engineers develop a car engine with almost no emissions. An economy consists of three workers: Larry, Moe and Curly. Each works 10 hours a day and can produce two services: mowing lawns and washing cars. In an hour, Larry can either mow one lawn or wash one car; Moe can either mow one lawn or wash two cars; and Curly can either mow two lawns or wash one car. a Calculate how much of each service is produced under the following circumstances, which we label A, B, C and D: i All three spend all their time mowing lawns. (A) ii All three spend all their time washing cars. (B) iii All three spend half their time on each activity. (C) iv Larry spends half his time on each activity, while Moe only washes cars and Curly only mows lawns. (D) 37 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 2 Thinking like an economist 02_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 37 24/08/20 5:59 PM 5 6 7 b Graph the production possibilities frontier for this economy. Using your answers to part (a), identify points A, B, C and D on your graph. c Explain why the production possibilities frontier has the shape it does. d Are any of the allocations calculated in part (a) inefficient? Explain. Classify the following topics as relating to microeconomics or macroeconomics: a a family’s decision about how much income to save b the effect of government regulations on car emissions c the impact of higher saving on economic growth d a firm’s decision about how many workers to hire e the relationship between the inflation rate and changes in the quantity of money. Classify each of the following statements as positive or normative. Explain. a Society faces a short-term trade-off between inflation and unemployment. b A reduction in the growth rate of the money supply will reduce the rate of inflation. c The Reserve Bank should reduce the growth rate of the money supply. d Society ought to require people on social security benefits to look for jobs. e Lower tax rates encourage more work and more saving. We have seen that disagreements between economists can be divided into disagreements concerning positive statements, and disagreements concerning normative statements. a Would you expect economists to disagree less about positive statements as time goes on? Explain. b Would you expect economists to disagree less about normative statements as time goes on? Explain. c What are the implications of your answers for the way in which economists’ views of public policy evolve over time? 38 Part 1 Introduction Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 02_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 38 24/08/20 5:59 PM Appendix: Graphing – a brief review Many of the concepts that economists study can be expressed with numbers – the price of bananas, the quantity of bananas sold, the cost of growing bananas and so on. Often these economic variables are related to one another. When the price of bananas rises, people buy fewer bananas. One way of expressing the relationships among variables is with graphs. Graphs serve two purposes. First, when economists develop theories, graphs offer a visual way to express ideas that might be less clear if described with equations or words. Second, when economists analyse data, graphs provide a way of finding how variables are, in fact, related in the world. Whether we are working with theory or with data, graphs provide a lens through which a recognisable forest emerges from a multitude of trees. Numerical information can be expressed graphically in many ways, just as a thought can be expressed in words in many ways. A good writer chooses words that will make an argument clear, a description pleasing or a scene dramatic. An effective economist chooses the type of graph that best suits the purpose at hand. In this appendix we discuss how economists use graphs to study the mathematical relationships among variables. We also discuss some of the pitfalls that can arise when using graphical methods. Three common graphs are shown in Figure 2A.1. The pie chart in panel (a) shows the sources of tax revenue for the federal government. A slice of the pie represents each source’s share of the total. The bar graph in panel (b) compares how much various large corporations are worth. The height of each bar represents the dollar value of each firm. The time-series graph in panel (c) traces the Australian–US dollar exchange rate over time. The height of the line shows the number of US dollars that can be bought by one Australian dollar in each year. You have probably seen similar graphs presented in newspapers and magazines. Graphs of two variables: The coordinate system The three graphs in Figure 2A.1 are useful in showing how a variable changes over time or across individuals, but they are limited in how much they can tell us. These graphs display information only on a single variable. Economists are often concerned with the relationships between variables. Thus, they need to be able to display two variables on a single graph. The coordinate system makes this possible. Suppose you want to examine the relationship between study time and average mark. For each student in your class, you could record a pair of numbers – hours per week spent studying and average mark. These numbers could then be placed in parentheses as an ordered pair and appear as a single point on the graph. Albert, for instance, is represented by the ordered pair (25 hours per week, 75 per cent average), and his ‘Whatme-worry?’ classmate Alfred is represented by the ordered pair (five hours per week, 40 per cent average). We can graph these ordered pairs on a two-dimensional grid. The first number in each ordered pair, called the x-coordinate, tells us the horizontal location of the point. The second number, called the y-coordinate, tells us the vertical location of the point. The point with both an x-coordinate and a y-coordinate of zero is known as the origin. The two coordinates in the ordered pair tell us where the point is located in relation to the origin – x units to the right of the origin and y units above it. APPENDIX Graphs of a single variable 39 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 2 Thinking like an economist 02_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 39 24/08/20 5:59 PM FIGURE 2A.1 Types of graphs (a) Pie chart 6% 25% Income taxes Indirect taxes Non-tax revenue 69% 180 BHP Billiton ($169.3) (b) Bar graph April 2013 market capitalisation (in billions of dollars) 160 140 120 Commonwealth Bank of Australia ($109.5) 100 80 60 Telstra ($55.9) 40 Woolworths ($42.7) 20 0 Exchange rate: US$ per A$ 1.4 (c) Time-series graph 1.2 1 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0 1972 1977 1982 1987 1992 1997 2002 2007 2012 Year The pie chart in panel (a) shows the sources of revenue for the federal government. The bar graph in panel (b) compares how much various large corporations are worth. The time-series graph in panel (c) traces the Australian–US dollar exchange rate over time. Source: (a) Department of the Treasury, http://budget.gov.au/2011-12/content/fbo/html/part_1.htm, 2011–12 Final Budget Outcome; (b) Yahoo! Finance, http://au.finance.yahoo.com/; (c) Reserve Bank of Australia, www.rba.gov.au/statistics/histexchange-rates/index.html, Exchange Rate Data. 40 Part 1 Introduction Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 02_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 40 24/08/20 5:59 PM Figure 2A.2 graphs average marks against study time for Albert, Alfred and their classmates. This type of graph is called a scatter plot because it plots scattered points. Looking at this graph, we immediately notice that points further to the right also tend to be higher. Because higher study time is associated with higher marks, we say that these two variables have a positive correlation. In contrast, if we were to graph party time and marks, it is likely that we would find that higher party time is associated with lower marks, and we say that these two variables have a negative correlation. In either case, the coordinate system makes the correlation between the two variables easy to see. FIGURE 2A.2 Using the coordinate system Average mark (%) 100 95 90 85 80 75 Albert (25, 75) 70 65 60 55 50 45 Alfred (5, 40) 40 35 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 40 Study time (hours per week) 35 Average mark is measured on the vertical axis and study time on the horizontal axis. Albert, Alfred and their classmates are represented by various points. We can see from the graph that students who study more tend to get higher marks. Curves in the coordinate system Students who study more do tend to get higher marks, but other factors also influence a student’s mark. Previous preparation is an important factor, for instance, as are talent, attention from teachers, even eating a good breakfast. A scatter plot like Figure 2A.2 does not attempt to isolate the effect that study has on marks from the effects of other variables. Often, however, economists prefer looking at how one variable affects another, holding everything else constant. 41 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 2 Thinking like an economist 02_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 41 24/08/20 5:59 PM To see how this is done, let’s consider one of the most important graphs in economics: the demand curve. The demand curve traces the effect of a good’s price on the quantity of the good consumers want to buy. Table 2A.1 shows how the number of novels that Emma buys depends on her income and on the price of novels. When novels are cheap, Emma buys them in large quantities. As they become more expensive, she borrows books from the library instead of buying them or chooses to go to a film instead of reading. Similarly, at any given price, Emma buys more novels when she has a higher income. That is, when her income increases, she spends part of the additional income on novels and part on other goods. TABLE 2A.1 Novels purchased by Emma This table shows the number of novels Emma buys at various incomes and prices. For any given level of income, the data on price and quantity demanded can be graphed to produce Emma’s demand curve for novels. Income Price $20 000 $30 000 $40 000 $10 2 novels 5 novels 8 novels 9 6 9 12 8 10 13 16 7 14 17 20 6 18 21 24 5 22 25 28 Demand curve, D3 Demand curve, D1 Demand curve, D2 We now have three variables – the price of novels, income and the number of novels purchased – which is more than we can represent in two dimensions. To put the information from Table 2A.1 in graphical form, we need to hold one of the three variables constant and trace the relationship between the other two. Because the demand curve represents the relationship between price and quantity demanded, we hold Emma’s income constant and show how the number of novels she buys varies with the price of novels. Suppose that Emma’s income is $30 000 per year. If we place the number of novels Emma purchases on the x-axis and the price of novels on the y-axis, we can graphically represent the third column of Table 2A.1. When the points that represent these entries from the table – (five novels, $10), (nine novels, $9) and so on – are connected, they form a line. This line, shown in Figure 2A.3, is known as Emma’s demand curve for novels; it tells us how many novels Emma purchases at any given price, holding income constant. The demand curve is downward-sloping, indicating that the quantity of novels demanded is negatively related to the price. (Conversely, when two variables move in the same direction, the curve relating them is upward-sloping, and we say that the variables are positively related.) Now suppose that Emma’s income rises to $40 000 per year. At any given price, Emma will purchase more novels than she did at her previous level of income. Just as earlier we drew Emma’s demand curve for novels using the entries from the third column of Table 2A.1, we now draw a new demand curve using the entries from the fourth column of the table. 42 Part 1 Introduction Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 02_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 42 24/08/20 5:59 PM FIGURE 2A.3 Demand curve Price of novels $11 10 (5, $10) (9, $9) 9 (13, $8) 8 (17, $7) 7 (21, $6) 6 5 (25, $5) 4 Demand, D1 3 2 1 0 5 10 15 20 25 30 Quantity of novels purchased The line D1 shows how Emma’s purchases of novels depend on the price of novels when her income is held constant. Because the price and the quantity demanded are negatively related, the demand curve slopes downwards. This new demand curve (curve D2) is shown alongside the old one (curve D1) in Figure 2A.4; the new curve is a similar line drawn further to the right. We therefore say that Emma’s demand curve for novels shifts to the right when her income increases. Likewise, if Emma’s income were to fall to $20 000 per year, she would buy fewer novels at any given price and her demand curve would shift to the left (to curve D3). In economics, it is important to distinguish between movements along a curve and shifts of a curve. As we can see from Figure 2A.3, if Emma earns $30 000 per year and novels cost $8 each, she will purchase 13 novels per year. If the price of novels falls to $7, Emma will increase her purchases of novels to 17 per year. The demand curve, however, stays fixed in the same place. Emma still buys the same number of novels at each price, but as the price falls she moves along her demand curve from left to right. In contrast, if the price of novels remains fixed at $8 but her income rises to $40 000, Emma increases her purchases of novels from 13 to 16 per year. Because Emma buys more novels at each price, her demand curve shifts out, as shown in Figure 2A.4. There is a simple way to tell when it is necessary to shift a curve. When a variable that is not named on either axis changes, the curve shifts. Income is on neither the x-axis nor the y-axis of the graph, so when Emma’s income changes, her demand curve must shift. Any change that affects Emma’s purchasing habits besides a change in the price of novels will result in a shift in her demand curve. If, for instance, the public library closes and Emma must buy all the books she wants to read, she will demand more novels at each price and her demand curve will shift to the right. Or if the price of films falls and Emma spends 43 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 2 Thinking like an economist 02_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 43 24/08/20 5:59 PM FIGURE 2A.4 Shifting demand curves Price of novels $11 10 (13, $8) 9 (16, $8) 8 (10, $8) 7 6 5 4 3 When income decreases, the demand curve shifts to the left. D3 (income = $20 000) When income, increases, the demand curve shifts to the right. D2 (income = D1 (income = $40 000) $30 000) 2 1 0 5 10 13 15 16 20 25 30 Quantity of novels purchased The location of Emma’s demand curve for novels depends on how much income she earns. The more she earns, the more novels she will purchase at any given price, and the further to the right her demand curve will lie. Curve D1 represents Emma’s original demand curve when her income is $30 000 per year. If her income rises to $40 000 per year, her demand curve shifts to D2. If her income falls to $20 000 per year, her demand curve shifts to D3. more time at the pictures and less time reading, she will demand fewer novels at each price, and her demand curve will shift to the left. By contrast, when a variable on an axis of the graph changes, the curve does not shift. We read the change as a movement along the curve. Slope One question we might want to ask about Emma is how much her purchasing habits respond to changes in price. Look at the demand curve shown in Figure 2A.5. If this curve is very steep, Emma purchases nearly the same number of novels regardless of whether they are cheap or expensive. If this curve is much flatter, the number of novels Emma purchases is more sensitive to changes in the price. To answer questions about how much one variable responds to changes in another variable, we can use the concept of slope. The slope of a line is the ratio of the vertical distance covered to the horizontal distance covered as we move along the line. This definition is usually written out in mathematical symbols as follows: Slope = Δy Δx where the Greek letter Δ (delta) stands for the change in a variable. In other words, the slope of a line is equal to the ‘rise’ (change in y) divided by the ‘run’ (change in x). 44 Part 1 Introduction Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 02_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 44 24/08/20 5:59 PM FIGURE 2A.5 Calculating the slope of a line Price of novels $11 10 9 (13, $8) 8 7 6 8 6 2 21 13 8 (21, $6) 5 Demand, D 1 4 3 2 1 0 5 10 13 15 20 21 25 30 Quantity of novels purchased To calculate the slope of the demand curve, we can look at the changes in the x- and y-coordinates as we move from the point (21 novels, $6) to the point (13 novels, $8). The slope of the line is the ratio of the change in the y-coordinate (–2) to the change in the x-coordinate (+8), which equals –1/4. For an upward-sloping line, the slope is a positive number because the changes in y and x move in the same direction: if y increases, so does x, and if y decreases, so does x. For a fairly flat upward-sloping line, the slope is a small positive number. For a steep upward-sloping line, the slope is a large positive number. For a downward-sloping line, the slope is a negative number because the changes in y and x move in opposite directions: if y increases, x decreases, and if y decreases, x increases. For a fairly flat downward-sloping line, the slope is a small negative number. For a steep downward-sloping line, the slope is a large negative number. A horizontal line has a slope of zero because in this case the y-variable never changes. A vertical line is said to have an infinite slope because the y-variable can take any value without the x-variable changing at all. What is the slope of Emma’s demand curve for novels? First of all, because the curve slopes down, we know the slope will be negative. To calculate a numerical value for the slope, we must choose two points on the line. With Emma’s income at $30 000, she will purchase 21 novels at a price of $6 or 13 novels at a price of $8. When we apply the slope formula, we are concerned with the change between these two points; in other words, we are concerned with the difference between them, which lets us know that we will have to subtract one set of values from the other, as follows: Slope = first y-coordinate − second y-coordinate first x-coordinate − second x-coordinate = 6−8 21 − 13 = −2 8 = −1 4 45 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 2 Thinking like an economist 02_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 45 24/08/20 5:59 PM Figure 2A.5 shows graphically how this calculation works. Try calculating the slope of Emma’s demand curve using two different points. You should get exactly the same result, –1/4. One of the properties of a straight line is that it has the same slope everywhere. This is not true of other types of curves, which are steeper in some places than in others. The slope of Emma’s demand curve tells us something about how responsive her purchases are to changes in the price. A small slope (a negative number close to zero) means that Emma’s demand curve is relatively flat; in this case, she adjusts the number of novels she buys substantially in response to a price change. A larger slope (a negative number further from zero) means that Emma’s demand curve is relatively steep; in this case, she adjusts the number of novels she buys only slightly in response to a price change. Cause and effect Economists often use graphs to advance an argument about how the economy works. In other words, they use graphs to argue about how one set of events causes another set of events. With a graph like the demand curve, there is no doubt about cause and effect. Because we are varying price and holding all other variables constant, we know that changes in the price of novels cause changes in the quantity Emma demands. Remember, however, that our demand curve came from a hypothetical example. When graphing data from the real world, it is often more difficult to establish how one variable affects another. The first problem is that it is difficult to hold everything else constant when measuring how one variable affects another. If we are not able to hold variables constant, we might decide that one variable on our graph is causing changes in the other variable when those changes are actually being caused by a third omitted variable not pictured on the graph. Even if we have identified the correct two variables to look at, we might run into a second problem – reverse causality. In other words, we might decide that A causes B when in fact B causes A. The omitted-variable and reverse-causality traps require us to proceed with caution when using graphs to draw conclusions about causes and effects. Omitted variables To see how omitting a variable can lead to a deceptive graph, let’s consider an example. Imagine that the government, spurred by public concern about the large number of deaths from cancer, commissions an exhaustive study from Big Brother Statistical Services. Big Brother examines many of the items found in people’s homes to see which of them are associated with the risk of cancer. Big Brother reports a strong relationship between two variables – the number of cigarette lighters that a household owns and the probability that someone in the household will develop cancer. Figure 2A.6 shows this relationship. What should we make of this result? Big Brother advises a quick policy response. It recommends that the government discourage the ownership of cigarette lighters by taxing their sale. It also recommends that the government require warning labels: ‘Big Brother has determined that this lighter is dangerous to your health’. In judging the validity of Big Brother’s analysis, one question is paramount. Has Big Brother held constant every relevant variable except the one under consideration? If the answer is no, the results are suspect. An easy explanation for Figure 2A.6 is that people who own more cigarette lighters are more likely to smoke cigarettes and that cigarettes, not lighters, cause cancer. If Figure 2A.6 does not hold constant the amount of smoking, it does not tell us the true effect of owning a cigarette lighter. This story illustrates an important principle – when you see a graph being used to support an argument about cause and effect, it is important to ask whether the movements of an omitted variable could explain the results you see. 46 Part 1 Introduction Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 02_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 46 24/08/20 5:59 PM FIGURE 2A.6 Graph with an omitted variable Risk of cancer 0 Number of lighters in house The upward-sloping curve shows that households with more cigarette lighters are more likely to develop cancer. Yet we should not conclude that ownership of lighters causes cancer because the graph does not take into account the number of cigarettes smoked. Reverse causality Economists can also make mistakes about causality by misreading its direction. To see how this is possible, suppose the Association of Australian Anarchists commissions a study of crime in Australia and arrives at Figure 2A.7, which plots the number of violent crimes per thousand people in major cities against the number of police officers per thousand people. The Anarchists note the curve’s upward slope and argue that since police increase rather than decrease the amount of urban violence, law enforcement should be abolished. FIGURE 2A.7 Graph suggesting reverse causality Violent crimes (per 1000 people) 0 Police officers (per 1000 people) The upward-sloping curve shows that cities with a higher concentration of police are more dangerous. Yet the graph does not tell us whether police cause crime or crime-plagued cities hire more police. 47 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 2 Thinking like an economist 02_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 47 24/08/20 5:59 PM Figure 2A.7, however, does not prove the Anarchists’ point. The graph simply shows that more dangerous cities have more police officers. The explanation for this may be that more dangerous cities hire more police. In other words, rather than police causing crime, crime may cause police. We could avoid the danger of reverse causality by running a controlled experiment. In this case, we would randomly assign different numbers of police to different cities and then examine the correlation between police and crime. Without such an experiment, establishing the direction of causality is difficult at best. It might seem that we could determine the direction of causality by examining which variable moves first. If we see crime increase and then the police force expand, we reach one conclusion. If we see the police force expand and then crime increase, we reach the other conclusion. This approach, however, is also flawed: often people change their behaviour not in response to a change in their present conditions but in response to a change in their expectations about future conditions. A city that expects a major crime wave in the future, for instance, might well hire more police now. This problem is even easier to see in the case of babies and station wagons. Couples often buy a station wagon in anticipation of the birth of a child. The station wagon comes before the baby, but we would not want to conclude that the sale of station wagons causes the population to grow! There is no exhaustive set of rules that specifies when it is appropriate to draw causal conclusions from graphs. Yet just keeping in mind that cigarette lighters don’t cause cancer (omitted variable) and that station wagons don’t cause babies (reverse causality) will keep you from falling for many faulty economic arguments. 48 Part 1 Introduction Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 02_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 48 24/08/20 5:59 PM 3 Interdependence and the gains from trade Learning objectives After reading this chapter, you should be able to: LO3.1 explain how everyone can benefit when people trade with one another LO3.2 use comparative advantage to explain the gains from trade LO3.3 apply the theory of comparative advantage to everyday life and national policy. 49 49 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 03_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 49 24/08/20 5:59 PM Introduction Consider your typical day. You wake up in the morning and you pour yourself juice from oranges grown in the Riverina region of New South Wales, and coffee from beans grown in Colombia. Over breakfast, you read a BuzzFeed article written in the United States, on your phone made in China. You get dressed in clothes made from cotton grown in India, and sewn in factories in Thailand. You drive to university in a car made of parts manufactured in more than a dozen countries around the world. Then you open up your economics textbook written by authors living in Massachusetts, Toronto, the Gold Coast and Melbourne, published by a company located in Melbourne, and printed on paper made from trees grown in Tasmania. Every day you rely on many people from around the world, most of whom you have never met, to provide you with the goods and services that you enjoy. Such interdependence is possible because people trade with one another. Those people who provide you with goods and services are not acting out of generosity. Nor is some government agency directing them to satisfy your desires. Instead, people provide you and other consumers with the goods and services they produce because they get something in return. In subsequent chapters, we will examine how an economy coordinates the activities of millions of people with varying tastes and abilities. As a starting point for this analysis, in this chapter we consider the reasons for economic interdependence. One of the Ten Principles of Economics in Chapter 1 is that trade can make everyone better off. We now examine this principle more closely. What exactly do people gain when they trade with one another? Why do people choose to become interdependent? The answers to these questions are key to understanding the modern global economy. Most countries today import many of the goods and services they consume, and they export many of the goods and services they produce. The analysis in this chapter explains interdependence not only among individuals but also among nations. As we will see, the gains from trade are much the same whether you are buying a haircut from your local barber or a T-shirt made by a worker on the other side of the world. LO3.1 A parable for the modern economy To understand why people choose to depend on others for goods and services and how this choice improves their lives, let’s examine a simple economy – the economy inside a household. Imagine that there are two chores that need to be completed in the household – cooking and laundry. And there are two people living in the house – Leonard and Sheldon – each of whom likes to eat and to wear clean and neatly ironed clothes. The gains from trade are clearest if Leonard can cook but cannot do laundry, while Sheldon can do the laundry but cannot cook. In one scenario, Leonard and Sheldon could choose to have nothing to do with each other. Leonard would cook for himself and Sheldon would wash and iron his own clothes. After several months of eating cold meat and biscuits, Sheldon might decide that self-sufficiency is not all it’s cracked up to be. Leonard, whose clothing could not have a worse odour, would be likely to agree. It is easy to see that trade would allow them to enjoy greater variety – each could eat well and wear clean clothes. Although this scene shows most simply how everyone can benefit from trade, the gains would be similar if Leonard and Sheldon were each capable of doing the other task, but only at great cost. Suppose, for example, that Leonard can wash clothes, but that he is not very good at it. Similarly, suppose that Sheldon can cook, but that he can prepare only a few basic dishes. In this case, it is easy to see that Leonard and Sheldon can each benefit by specialising in what he does best and then trading with the other. The gains from trade are less obvious, however, when one person is better at producing every good. For example, suppose that Leonard is better at cooking and better at doing the 50 Part 1 Introduction Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 03_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 50 24/08/20 5:59 PM laundry than Sheldon. In this case, should Leonard remain self-sufficient? Or is there still reason for him to trade with Sheldon? To answer this question, let’s look more closely at the factors that affect such a decision. Production possibilities Suppose that Leonard and Sheldon each have 12 spare hours a week to work on household chores and can devote this time to cooking, laundry or a combination of the two. Table 3.1 shows the amount of time each person requires to produce one unit of each good – a decent meal and a basket of clean clothes. Sheldon can wash and iron a basket of clothes in four hours and cook a meal in two hours. Leonard, who is more productive in both activities, needs only half an hour to cook a meal and can wash and iron a basket of clothes in three hours. TABLE 3.1 The production opportunities of Sheldon and Leonard Hours needed to complete: Maximum quantity completed in 12 hours: 1 meal 1 basket Meals Baskets Sheldon 2 4 6 3 Leonard ½ 3 24 4 Panel (a) of Figure 3.1 illustrates the amounts of laundry and cooking that Sheldon can produce. If he spends all 12 hours of his time on doing the laundry, he cleans three baskets of clothes but does not cook. If he spends all his time cooking, he produces six meals and washes no clothes. If Sheldon spends four hours doing laundry and eight hours cooking, he cooks four meals and washes and irons one basket of clothes. The figure shows these three possible outcomes and all others in-between. FIGURE 3.1 The production possibilities frontier (a) Sheldon’s production possibilities frontier (b) Leonard’s production possibilities frontier Meals Meals 24 6 A 4 B 12 0 1 3 Laundry (baskets) 0 2 4 Laundry (baskets) Panel (a) shows the combinations of meals and laundry that Sheldon can produce. Panel (b) shows the combinations of meals and laundry that Leonard can produce. Both production possibilities frontiers are derived from Table 3.1 and the assumption that Sheldon and Leonard each work 12 hours per week on domestic chores. 51 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in3part. WCN 02-200-202and the gains from trade Chapter Interdependence 03_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 51 24/08/20 5:59 PM The graph in panel (a) is Sheldon’s production possibilities frontier. As we discussed in Chapter 2, a production possibilities frontier shows the various mixes of output that an economy can produce. It illustrates one of the Ten Principles of Economics in Chapter 1 – people face trade-offs. Here, Sheldon faces a trade-off between cooking and doing laundry. You may recall that the production possibilities frontier in Chapter 2 is drawn bowed out. In that case, the rate at which society could trade one good for the other depended on the amounts that were being produced. Here, however, Sheldon’s ‘technology’ allows him to switch between one chore and the other at a constant rate (as summarised in Table 3.1). We can see the constant rate of trade-off illustrated in the graph as Sheldon’s production possibilities frontier is a straight line. Panel (b) of Figure 3.1 shows the production possibilities frontier for Leonard. If he spends all 12 hours of his time cooking, he produces 24 meals but does no laundry. If he spends all his time on laundry, he washes four baskets but cooks no meals. If Leonard divides his time equally, spending six hours on each activity, he cooks 12 meals and washes two baskets of clothes per week. Once again, the production possibilities frontier shows all the possible outcomes. If Leonard and Sheldon choose to go it alone, rather than trade with each other, then each consumes exactly what he produces. In this case, the production possibilities frontier is also the consumption possibilities frontier. That is, without trade, Figure 3.1 shows the possible combinations of cooking and laundry that Leonard and Sheldon can each produce and then consume. Although these production possibilities frontiers are useful in showing the trade-offs that Leonard and Sheldon face, they do not tell us what they will each choose to do. To determine their choices, we need to know something about their tastes. Let’s suppose they choose the combinations identified by points A and B in Figure 3.1 – Sheldon produces and consumes four meals and washes one basket while Leonard produces and consumes 12 meals and washes two baskets of clothing. Specialisation and trade After several months of combination B, Leonard gets an idea and talks to Sheldon: Leonard: Sheldon, have I got a deal for you! I know how to improve life for both of us. I think you should stop cooking altogether and devote all your time to laundry. According to my calculations, if you spend 12 hours a week washing and ironing, you’ll get three baskets of laundry done every week. If you do one basket of laundry for me each week, and an extra basket every second week, then I’ll cook you five meals a week. In the end, you’ll be able to eat cooked meals more often and you’ll get your clothes cleaner as well. [To illustrate his point, Leonard shows Sheldon panel (a) of Figure 3.2.] Sheldon: (sounding sceptical) That seems like a good deal for me. But I don’t understand why you are offering it. If the deal is so good for me, it can’t be good for you too. Leonard: Oh, but it is! If I spend nine hours a week cooking and three hours doing laundry, I’ll make 18 meals and also have time spare to do another basket of laundry. After I give you five meals in exchange for the extra basketand-a-half that you wash and iron, I’ll be able to eat 13 meals at home and I’ll have more clean shirts, trousers and, most importantly, socks and underwear. In the end, I will be much happier than I am now. [He points out panel (b) of Figure 3.2.] 52 Part 1 Introduction Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 03_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 52 24/08/20 5:59 PM FIGURE 3.2 How trade expands the set of consumption opportunities (b) Leonard’s production possibilities frontier (a) Sheldon’s production possibilities frontier Meals Meals 24 6 A* 5 4 A Sheldon’s consumption with trade 0 1 11/2 3 B* 13 12 Sheldon’s consumption without trade B 0 Laundry (baskets) Leonard’s consumption with trade Leonard’s consumption without trade 2 21/2 4 Laundry (baskets) The proposed trade between Sheldon and Leonard offers each a combination of meals and baskets of clean clothes that would be impossible in the absence of trade. In panel (a), Sheldon gets to consume at point A* rather than point A. In panel (b), Leonard gets to consume at point B* rather than point B. Trade allows each to consume more meals and have more clean clothes. Sheldon: I don’t know … This sounds too good to be true. Leonard: It’s really not as complicated as it seems at first. Here – I’ve summarised my proposal for you in a simple table. [Leonard hands Sheldon a copy of Table 3.2.] Sheldon: (after pausing to study the table) These calculations seem correct, but I’m puzzled. How can this deal make us both better off? Leonard: We can both benefit because trade allows each of us to specialise in doing what we do best. You will spend more time doing laundry and less time cooking. I will spend more time cooking and less time washing and ironing. As a result of specialisation and trade, each of us can consume more of great meals, and wear cleaner clothes, without spending any more time on our chores. What could be better? TABLE 3.2 The gains from trade: A summary Without trade: Production and consumption Sheldon Leonard With trade: Production Trade Consumption Gains from trade 4 meals 0 meals Gets 5 meals 5 meals 1 meal 1 basket 3 baskets for 1½ baskets 1½ baskets ½ basket 12 meals 18 meals Gives 5 meals 13 meals 1 meal 2 baskets 1 basket for 1½ baskets 2½ baskets ½ basket 53 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in3part. WCN 02-200-202and the gains from trade Chapter Interdependence 03_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 53 24/08/20 5:59 PM CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING Draw an example of a production possibilities frontier for Robinson Crusoe, a shipwrecked sailor who spends his time gathering coconuts and catching fish. Does this frontier limit Crusoe’s consumption of coconuts and fish if he lives by himself? Does he face the same limits if he can trade with native residents on the island? LO3.2 Comparative advantage: The driving force of specialisation Leonard’s explanation of the gains from trade, though correct, poses a puzzle – if Leonard is better at both cooking and laundry, how can Sheldon ever specialise in doing what he does best? Sheldon doesn’t seem to do anything best. To solve this puzzle, we need to look at the principle of comparative advantage. As a first step in developing this principle, consider the following question. In our example, who does the laundry at lower cost – Sheldon or Leonard? There are two possible answers, and in these two answers lie both the solution to our puzzle and the key to understanding the gains from trade. Absolute advantage absolute advantage the ability to produce a good using fewer inputs than another producer One way to answer the question about the cost of doing the laundry is to compare the inputs required by the two housemates. Economists use the term absolute advantage when comparing the productivity of one person, firm or nation with that of another. The producer that requires a smaller quantity of inputs to produce a good is said to have an absolute advantage in producing that good. In our example, time is the only input, so we can determine absolute advantage by looking at how much time each type of production takes. Leonard has an absolute advantage both in laundry and cooking, because he requires less time than Sheldon to produce a unit of either good. Leonard needs only three hours to do a basket of laundry, whereas Sheldon needs four hours. Similarly, Leonard needs only half an hour to cook a meal whereas Sheldon needs two hours. Thus, if we measure cost in terms of the quantity of inputs used, Leonard has a lower cost of doing laundry and a lower cost of cooking. Opportunity cost and comparative advantage There is another way to look at the cost of laundry. Rather than comparing inputs required, we can compare the opportunity costs. Recall from Chapter 1 that the opportunity cost of some item is what we give up to get that item. In our example, we assumed that Sheldon and Leonard each spend 12 hours a week on household chores. Time spent doing laundry, therefore, takes away from time available for cooking. When reallocating time between the two goods, Leonard and Sheldon give up units of one good to produce units of the other good, moving along their production possibility frontiers. The opportunity cost measures the trade-off between the two goods that each faces. Let’s first consider Leonard’s opportunity cost. According to Table 3.1, doing a basket of clothes takes Leonard three hours of work. When Leonard spends that three hours doing laundry, he spends three hours less cooking. Because Leonard needs only half an hour to produce one meal, three hours of work would yield six meals. Hence, Leonard’s opportunity cost of one basket is six meals. Now consider Sheldon’s opportunity cost. Washing and ironing one basket takes him four hours. Because he needs two hours to cook a meal, four hours would yield two meals. Hence, Sheldon’s opportunity cost of doing one basket of laundry is two meals. 54 Part 1 Introduction Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 03_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 54 24/08/20 5:59 PM Table 3.3 shows the opportunity cost of cooking and laundry for Sheldon and Leonard. Notice that the opportunity cost of cooking is the inverse of the opportunity cost of laundry. Because one clean basket of laundry costs Leonard six meals, one meal costs Leonard onesixth of a basket of laundry. Similarly, because doing one basket of laundry costs Sheldon two meals, one meal costs Sheldon half a basket of laundry. TABLE 3.3 The opportunity cost of meals and baskets of clean clothes Opportunity cost of one: Meal (in terms of baskets given up) Basket (in terms of meals given up) Sheldon ½ 2 Leonard 16 6 Economists use the term comparative advantage when describing the opportunity cost of two producers. The producer who has the smaller opportunity cost of producing a good is said to have a comparative advantage in producing that good. In our example, Sheldon has a lower opportunity cost of laundry than Leonard: A basket of laundry costs Sheldon two meals, but costs Leonard six meals. Conversely, Leonard has a lower opportunity cost of cooking than Sheldon: A meal costs Leonard one-sixth of a basket of laundry, but it costs Sheldon half of a basket. Thus, Sheldon has a comparative advantage in laundry, and Leonard has a comparative advantage in cooking. Although it is possible for one person to have an absolute advantage in both goods (as Leonard does in our example), it is impossible for the same person to have a comparative advantage in both goods. Because the opportunity cost of one good is the inverse of the opportunity cost of the other, if a person’s opportunity cost of one good is relatively high, his opportunity cost of the other good must be relatively low. Comparative advantage reflects the relative opportunity cost. Unless two people have exactly the same opportunity cost, one person will have a comparative advantage in one good and the other person will have a comparative advantage in the other good. comparative advantage the ability to produce a good at a lower opportunity cost than another producer Comparative advantage and trade The gains from specialisation and trade are based not on absolute advantage but on comparative advantage. When each person specialises in producing the good in which he or she has a comparative advantage, total production in the economy rises. This increase in the size of the economic pie can be used to make everyone better off. In our example, Sheldon spends more time doing laundry and Leonard spends more time cooking meals. As a result, the total production of laundry rises from three to four baskets and the total production of cooked meals rises from 16 to 18. Leonard and Sheldon share the benefits of this increased production. We can also look at the gains from trade in terms of the price that each person pays the other. Because Leonard and Sheldon have different opportunity costs, they can both get a bargain. That is, each benefits from trade by obtaining a good at a price that is lower than his opportunity cost of that good. Consider the proposed deal from Sheldon’s viewpoint. Sheldon gets five meals in exchange for cleaning an extra one-and-a-half baskets of laundry. In other words, Sheldon buys each meal for a price of three-tenths of a basket of laundry. This price of a meal is lower than his opportunity cost of cooking, which is half a basket. Thus, Sheldon benefits from the deal because he gets to buy meals at a good price. Now consider the deal from Leonard’s viewpoint. Leonard buys a basket of laundry for a price of just over three meals. This price of laundry is lower than his opportunity cost of 55 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in3part. WCN 02-200-202and the gains from trade Chapter Interdependence 03_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 55 24/08/20 5:59 PM laundry, which is six meals. Thus, Leonard benefits because he gets to buy a laundry service at a good price. The story of Leonard and Sheldon has a simple moral, which should now be clear – trade can benefit everyone in society because it allows people to specialise in activities in which they have a comparative advantage. FYI The legacy of Adam Smith and David Ricardo Economists have long understood the principle of comparative advantage. Here is how the great economist Adam Smith put the argument: It is a maxim of every prudent master of a family, never to attempt to make at home what it will cost him more to make than to buy. The tailor does not attempt to make his own shoes, but buys them off the shoemaker. The shoemaker does not attempt to make his own clothes but employs a tailor. The farmer attempts to make neither the one nor the other, but employs those different artificers. All of them find it for their interest to employ their whole industry in a way in which they have some advantage over their neighbours, and to purchase with a part of its produce, or what is the same thing, with the price of part of it, whatever else they have occasion for. KEY FIGURES David Ricardo This quotation is from Smith’s 1776 book The Wealth of Nations, which was a landmark in the analysis of trade and economic interdependence. Smith’s book inspired David Ricardo, a millionaire stockbroker, to become an economist. In his 1817 book On the Principles of Political Economy and Taxation, Ricardo developed the principle of comparative advantage as we know it today. He considered an example with two goods (wine and cloth) and two countries (England and Portugal). He showed that both countries can gain by opening up trade and specialising based on comparative advantage. Ricardo’s theory is the starting point of modern international economics, but his defence of free trade was not a mere academic exercise. Ricardo put his economic beliefs to work as a member of the British Parliament, where he opposed the Corn Laws, which restricted grain imports. The conclusions of Adam Smith and David Ricardo on the gains from trade have held up well over time. Although economists often disagree on questions of policy, they are united in their support of free trade. Moreover, the central argument for free trade has not changed much in the past two centuries. Even though the field of economics has broadened its scope and refined its theories since the time of Smith and Ricardo, economists’ opposition to trade restrictions is still based largely on the principle of comparative advantage. The price of trade The principle of comparative advantage establishes that there are gains from specialisation and trade, but it raises a couple of related questions: What determines the price at which trade takes place? How are the gains from trade shared between the trading parties? The precise answers to these questions are beyond the scope of this chapter, but we can state one general rule: For both parties to gain from trade, the price at which they trade must lie between their opportunity costs. 56 Part 1 Introduction Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 03_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 56 24/08/20 5:59 PM In our example, Leonard and Sheldon agreed to trade at a rate of three-tenths of a basket of laundry for each meal. This price is between Leonard’s opportunity cost (one-sixth of a basket of laundry per meal) and Sheldon’s opportunity cost (half of a basket of laundry per meal). The price need not be exactly three-tenths, but it must be somewhere between onesixth and a half for both parties to gain. To see why the price has to be in this range, consider what would happen if it were not. If the price of a meal were below one-sixth of a basket of laundry, both Leonard and Sheldon would want to buy meals, because the price would be below each of their opportunity costs. Similarly, if the price of a meal were above half of a basket of laundry, both would want to sell meals, because the price would be above their opportunity costs. But this economy (Leonard and Sheldon’s household) has only two people. They cannot both be buyers of meals, nor can they both be sellers. Someone has to take the other side of the deal. A mutually advantageous trade can be struck at a price between one-sixth and a half. In this price range, Leonard wants to sell meals and buy baskets of laundry, and Sheldon wants to sell baskets of laundry and buy meals. Each party can buy a service at a price that is lower than his or her opportunity cost of that service. In the end, each person specialises in the service in which he has a comparative advantage and, as a result, is better off. CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING Robinson Crusoe can gather 10 coconuts or catch one fish per hour. His friend Friday can gather 30 coconuts or catch two fish per hour. What is Crusoe’s opportunity cost of catching one fish? What is Friday’s? Who has an absolute advantage in catching fish? Who has a comparative advantage in catching fish? LO3.3 Applications of comparative advantage The principle of comparative advantage explains interdependence and the gains from trade. Because interdependence is so prevalent in the modern world, the principle of comparative advantage has many applications. Here are two examples, one fanciful and one of great practical importance. Should Serena Williams mow her own lawn? Serena Williams is a great athlete. She is one of the best tennis players in the world and has 23 Grand Slam singles titles. Very likely, she is better at other activities, too. For example, Serena can probably mow her lawn faster than anyone else. But just because she can mow her lawn fast, does this mean she should? To answer this question, we can use the concepts of opportunity cost and comparative advantage. Let’s say that Serena can mow her lawn in two hours. In that same two hours, she could film a television commercial for sports shoes and earn $1 000 000. In contrast, Todd, who lives down the road, can mow Serena’s lawn in four hours. In that same four hours, he could work at Coles supermarket and earn $40. In this example, Serena’s opportunity cost of mowing the lawn is $1 000 000 and Todd’s opportunity cost is $40. Serena has an absolute advantage in mowing lawns because she can do the work in less time. Yet Todd has a comparative advantage in mowing lawns because he has the lower opportunity cost. The gains from trade in this example are tremendous. Rather than mowing her own lawn, Serena should make the commercial and hire Todd to mow the lawn. As long as Serena pays Todd more than $40 and less than $1 000 000, both of them are better off. 57 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in3part. WCN 02-200-202and the gains from trade Chapter Interdependence 03_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 57 24/08/20 5:59 PM Should Australia trade with other countries? Just as individuals can benefit from specialisation and trade with one another, as Leonard and Sheldon did, so can populations of people in different countries. Many of the goods that Australians enjoy are produced abroad and many of the goods produced in Australia are sold abroad. Goods produced abroad and sold domestically are called imports. Goods produced domestically and sold abroad are called exports. To see how countries can benefit from trade, suppose there are two countries, Australia and Japan, and two goods, food and cars. Imagine that the two countries produce cars equally well – an Australian worker and a Japanese worker can each produce one car per month. By contrast, because Australia has more fertile land, it is better at producing food: An Australian worker can produce 2 tonnes of food per month, whereas a Japanese worker can produce only 1 tonne of food per month. The principle of comparative advantage states that each good should be produced by the country that has the lower opportunity cost of producing that good. Because the opportunity cost of a car is 2 tonnes of food in Australia but only 1 tonne of food in Japan, Japan has a comparative advantage in producing cars. Japan should produce more cars than it wants for its own use and export some of them to Australia. Similarly, because the opportunity cost of a tonne of food is one car in Japan but only half a car in Australia, Australia has a comparative advantage in producing food. Australia should produce more food than it wants to consume and export some of it to Japan. Through specialisation and trade, both countries can have more food and more cars. To be sure, the issues involved in trade among nations are more complex than this example suggests. Most important, each country has many people, and trade may affect them in different ways. When Australia exports food and imports cars, the impact on an Australian farmer is not the same as the impact on an Australian car worker. As a result, international trade can make some individuals worse off, even as it makes the country as a whole better off. Yet this example teaches us an important lesson: Contrary to the opinions sometimes voiced by politicians and political commentators, international trade is not like war, in which some countries win and others lose. Trade allows all countries to achieve greater prosperity. imports goods and services that are produced abroad and sold domestically exports goods and services that are produced domestically and sold abroad IN THE NEWS Economics within a marriage An economist argues that you shouldn’t always unload the dishwasher just because you’re better at it than your partner. You’re dividing the chores wrong by Emily Oster No one likes doing chores. In happiness surveys, housework is ranked down there with commuting as activities that people enjoy the least. Maybe that’s why figuring out who does which chores usually prompts, at best, tense discussion in a household and, at worst, outright fighting. If everyone is good at something different, assigning chores is easy. If your partner is great at grocery shopping and you are great at the laundry, you’re set. But this isn’t always – or even usually – the case. Often one person is better at everything. (And let’s be honest, often that person is the woman.) Better at the laundry, the grocery shopping, the cleaning, the cooking. But does that mean she should have to do everything? Before my daughter was born, I both cooked and did the dishes. It wasn’t a big deal, it didn’t take too much time, and honestly I was a lot better at both than my husband. His cooking repertoire extended only to eggs and chili, and when I left him in charge of the dishwasher, I’d often find he had run it ‘full’ with one pot and eight forks. 58 Part 1 Introduction Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 03_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 58 24/08/20 5:59 PM After we had a kid, we had more to do and less time to do it in. It seemed like it was time for some reassignments. But, of course, I was still better at doing both things. Did that mean I should do them both? I could have appealed to the principle of fairness: We should each do half. I could have appealed to feminism – surveys show that women more often than not get the short end of the chore stick. In time-use data, women do about 44 minutes more housework than men (2 hours and 11 minutes versus 1 hour and 27 minutes). Men outwork women only in the areas of ‘lawn’ and ‘exterior maintenance.’ I could have suggested he do more chores to rectify this imbalance, to show our daughter, in the Free to Be You and Me style, that Mom and Dad are equal and that housework is fun if we do it together! I could have simply smashed around the pans in the dishwasher while sighing loudly in the hopes he would notice and offer to do it himself. But luckily for me and my husband, I’m an economist, so I have more effective tools than passive aggression. And some basic economic principles provided the answer. We needed to divide the chores because it is simply not efficient for the best cook and dishwasher to do all the cooking and dishwashing. The economic principle at play here is increasing marginal cost. Basically, people get worse when they are tired. When I teach my students at the University of Chicago this principle, I explain it in the context of managing their employees. Imagine you have a good employee and a not-so-good one. Should you make the good employee do literally everything? Usually, the answer is no. Why not? It’s likely that the not-so-good employee is better at 9 a.m. after a full night of sleep than the good employee is at 2 a.m. after a 17-hour workday. So you want to give at least a few tasks to your worse guy. The same principle applies in your household. Yes, you (or your spouse) might be better at everything. But anyone doing the laundry at 4 a.m. is likely to put the red towels in with the white T-shirts. Some task splitting is a good idea. How much depends on how fast people’s skills decay. To ‘optimize’ your family efficiency (every economist’s ultimate goal – and yours, too), you want to equalize effectiveness on the final task each person is doing. Your partner does the dishes, mows the lawn, and makes the grocery list. You do the cooking, laundry, shopping, cleaning, and paying the bills. This may seem imbalanced, but when you look at it, you see that by the time your partner gets to the grocery-list task, he is wearing thin and starting to nod off. It’s all he can do to figure out how much milk you need. In fact, he is just about as good at that as you are when you get around to paying the bills, even though that’s your fifth task. If you then made your partner also do the cleaning – so it was an even four and four – the house would be a disaster, since he is already exhausted by his third chore while you are still doing fine. This system may well end up meaning one person does more, but it is unlikely to result in one person doing everything. Once you’ve decided you need to divide up the chores in this way, how should you decide who does what? One option would be randomly assigning tasks; another would be having each person do some of everything. One spousal-advice website I read suggested you should divide tasks based on which ones you like the best. None of these are quite right. (In the last case, how would anyone ever end up with the job of cleaning the bathroom?) To decide who does what, we need more economics. Specifically, the principle of comparative advantage. Economists usually talk about this in the context of trade. Imagine Finland is better than Sweden at making both reindeer hats and snowshoes. But they are much, much better at the hats and only a little better at the snowshoes. The overall world production is maximized when Finland makes hats and Sweden makes snowshoes. We say that Finland has an absolute advantage in both things but a comparative advantage only in hats. This principle is part of the reason economists value free trade, but that’s for another column (and probably another author). But it’s also a guideline for how to trade tasks in your house. You want to assign each person the tasks on which 59 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in3part. WCN 02-200-202and the gains from trade Chapter Interdependence 03_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 59 24/08/20 5:59 PM Illustration by Robert Neubecker. he or she has a comparative advantage. It doesn’t matter that you have an absolute advantage in everything. If you are much, much better at the laundry and only a little better at cleaning the toilet, you should do the laundry and have your spouse get out the scrub brush. Just explain that it’s efficient! In our case, it was easy. Other than using the grill – which I freely admit is the husband domain – I’m much, much better at cooking. And I was only moderately better One person is better at every chore, at the dishes. So he got the job of cleaning including laundry, but does that mean up after meals, even though his dishwasher he or she should have to do everything? loading habits had already come under scrutiny. The good news is another economic principle I hadn’t even counted on was soon in play: learning by doing. As people do a task, they improve at it. Eighteen months into this new arrangement the dishwasher is almost a work of art: neat rows of dishes and everything carefully screened for ‘top-rack only’ status. I, meanwhile, am forbidden from getting near the dishwasher. Apparently, there is a risk that I’ll ‘ruin it.’ Source: From Slate. © 2012 The Slate Group. All rights reserved. Used under license. CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING Suppose that the world’s fastest typist happens to be trained in brain surgery. Should that person type for herself or hire a secretary? Explain. Conclusion: Trade can make everyone better off You should now understand more fully the benefits of living in an interdependent economy. When Chinese companies buy Australian iron ore, when residents of Tasmania buy a mango grown in the Northern Territory and when you spend Friday night babysitting for neighbours rather than going out, the same economic forces are at work. The principle of comparative advantage shows that trade can make everyone better off. Having seen why interdependence is desirable, you might naturally ask how it is possible. How do free societies coordinate the diverse activities of all the people involved in their economies? What ensures that goods and services will get from those who should be producing them to those who should be consuming them? In a world with only two people, such as Leonard and Sheldon, the answer is simple: These two people can directly bargain and allocate resources between themselves. In the real world with billions of people, the answer is less obvious. We take up this issue in the next chapter, where we see that free societies allocate resources through the market forces of supply and demand. 60 Part 1 Introduction Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 03_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 60 24/08/20 5:59 PM LO3.1 Each person consumes goods and services produced by many other people, both in our country and around the world. Interdependence and trade are desirable because they allow everyone to enjoy a greater quantity and variety of goods and services. LO3.2 There are two ways to compare the abilities of two people to produce a good. The person who can produce the good with the smaller quantity of inputs is said to have an absolute advantage in producing the good. The person who has the lower opportunity cost of producing the good is said to have a comparative advantage. The gains from trade are based on comparative advantage, not absolute advantage. LO3.3 Trade makes everyone better off because it allows people to specialise in those activities in which they have a comparative advantage. The principle of comparative advantage applies to countries as well as to people. Economists use the principle of comparative advantage to advocate free trade among countries. Key concepts absolute advantage, p. 54 comparative advantage, p. 55 exports, p. 58 imports, p. 58 Apply and revise 1 2 3 4 5 6 Under what conditions is the production possibilities frontier linear rather than bowed out? Explain how absolute advantage and comparative advantage differ. Give an example in which one person has an absolute advantage in doing something but another person has a comparative advantage. Is absolute advantage or comparative advantage more important for trade? Explain your answer using the example in your answer to question 3. If two parties trade based on comparative advantage and both gain, in what range must the price of the trade lie? Why do economists oppose policies that restrict trade among nations? STUDY TOOLS Summary Practice questions Multiple choice 1 2 3 In an hour, David can wash two cars or mow one lawn, while Ron can wash three cars or mow one lawn. Who has the absolute advantage in car washing, and who has the absolute advantage in lawn mowing? a David in washing, Ron in mowing b Ron in washing, David in mowing c David in washing, neither in mowing d Ron in washing, neither in mowing Once again, in an hour, David can wash two cars or mow one lawn, while Ron can wash three cars or mow one lawn. Who has the comparative advantage in car washing, and who has the comparative advantage in lawn mowing? a David in washing, Ron in mowing b Ron in washing, David in mowing c David in washing, neither in mowing d Ron in washing, neither in mowing When two individuals produce efficiently and then make a mutually beneficial trade based on comparative advantage, a they both obtain consumption outside their production possibilities frontier. b they both obtain consumption inside their production possibilities frontier. c one individual consumes inside his production possibilities frontier, while the other consumes outside his. d each individual consumes a point on his own production possibilities frontier. 61 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in3part. WCN 02-200-202and the gains from trade Chapter Interdependence 03_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 61 24/08/20 5:59 PM 4 5 6 Which goods will a nation typically import? a Those goods in which the nation has an absolute advantage. b Those goods in which the nation has a comparative advantage. c Those goods in which other nations have an absolute advantage. d Those goods in which other nations have a comparative advantage. Suppose that in Australia, producing a tonne of beef takes 10 hours of labour, while producing a shirt takes two hours of labour. In China, producing 1 tonne of beef takes 40 hours of labour, while producing a shirt takes four hours of labour. What will these nations trade? a China will export beef, while Australia will export shirts. b China will export shirts, while Australia will export beef. c Both nations will export shirts. d There are no gains from trade in this situation. Mark can cook dinner in 30 minutes and wash the laundry in 20 minutes. His roommate takes half as long to do each task. How should the roommates allocate the work? a Mark should do more of the cooking based on his comparative advantage. b Mark should do more of the washing based on his comparative advantage. c Mark should do more of the washing based on his absolute advantage. d There are no gains from trade in this situation. Problems and applications 1 2 3 4 Maria can read 20 pages of economics in an hour. She can also read 50 pages of sociology in an hour. She spends five hours per day studying. a Draw Maria’s production possibilities frontier for reading economics and sociology. b What is Maria’s opportunity cost of reading 100 pages of sociology? Australian and Japanese workers can each produce four cars per year. An Australian worker can produce 10 tonnes of grain per year, whereas a Japanese worker can produce 5 tonnes of grain per year. To keep things simple, assume that each country has 100 million workers. a For this situation, construct a table similar to Table 3.1. b Graph the production possibilities frontier of the Australian and Japanese economies. c For Australia, what is the opportunity cost of a car? Of grain? For Japan, what is the opportunity cost of a car? Of grain? Put this information in a table similar to Table 3.3. d Which country has an absolute advantage in producing cars? In producing grain? e Which country has a comparative advantage in producing cars? In producing grain? f Without trade, half of each country’s workers produce cars and half produce grain. What quantities of cars and grain does each country produce? g Starting from a position without trade, give an example in which trade makes each country better off. Monica and Rachel are flatmates. They spend most of their time working, but they leave some time for their favourite activities – making pizza and fine coffee. Monica takes five minutes to make a pot of coffee and half an hour to make a pizza. Rachel takes 15 minutes to make a pot of coffee and one hour to make a pizza. a What is each flatmate’s opportunity cost of making a pizza? Who has the absolute advantage in making pizza? Who has the comparative advantage in making pizza? b If Rachel and Monica trade foods with each other, who will trade away pizza in exchange for coffee? c The price of pizza can be expressed in terms of pots of coffee. What is the highest price at which pizza can be traded that would make both flatmates better off? What is the lowest price? Explain. Suppose that there are 10 million workers in South Korea and that each of these workers can produce either two cars or 30 bags of wheat in a year. a What is the opportunity cost of producing a car in South Korea? What is the opportunity cost of producing a bag of wheat in South Korea? Explain the relationship between the opportunity costs of the two goods. b Draw South Korea’s production possibilities frontier. If South Korea chooses to consume 10 million cars, how much wheat can it consume without trade? Label this point on the production possibilities frontier. 62 Part 1 Introduction Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 03_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 62 24/08/20 5:59 PM c 5 6 Now suppose that Thailand offers to buy 10 million cars from South Korea in exchange for 20 bags of wheat per car. If South Korea continues to consume 10 million cars, how much wheat does this deal allow South Korea to consume? Label this point on your diagram. Should South Korea accept the deal? England and Scotland both produce scones and jumpers. Suppose that an English worker can produce 50 scones per hour or one jumper per hour. Suppose that a Scottish worker can produce 40 scones per hour or two jumpers per hour. a Which country has the absolute advantage in the production of each good? Which country has the comparative advantage? b If England and Scotland decide to trade, which commodity will Scotland trade to England? Explain. c If a Scottish worker could produce only one jumper per hour, would Scotland still gain from trade? Would England still gain from trade? Explain. The following table describes the production possibilities of two cities: Maroon shirts per worker per hour Blue shirts per worker per hour Brisbane 3 3 Sydney 2 1 a 7 8 9 Without trade, what is the price of blue shirts (in terms of maroon shirts) in Brisbane? What is the price in Sydney? b Which city has an absolute advantage in the production of each colour shirt? Which city has a comparative advantage in the production of each colour shirt? c If the cities trade with each other, which colour shirt will each export? d What is the range of prices at which trade can occur? A German worker takes 400 hours to produce a car and two hours to produce a case of wine. A French worker takes 600 hours to produce a car and X hours to produce a case of wine. a For what values of X will gains from trade be possible? Explain. b For what values of X will Germany export cars and import wine? Explain. Suppose that in a year an American worker can produce 100 shirts or 20 computers and a Chinese worker can produce 100 shirts or 10 computers. a For each country, graph the production possibilities frontier. Suppose that without trade the workers in each country spend half their time producing each good. Identify this point in your graphs. b If these countries were open to trade, which country would export shirts? Give a specific numerical example and show it on your graphs. Which country would benefit from trade? Explain. c Explain at what price of computers (in terms of shirts) the two countries might trade. d Suppose that China catches up with American productivity so that a Chinese worker can produce 100 shirts or 20 computers in a year. What pattern of trade would you predict now? How does this advance in Chinese productivity affect the economic wellbeing of the two countries’ citizens? Are the following statements true or false? Explain in each case. a ‘Two countries can achieve gains from trade even if one of the countries has an absolute advantage in the production of all goods.’ b ‘Certain very talented people have a comparative advantage in everything they do.’ c ‘If a certain trade is good for one person, it can’t be good for the other one.’ d ‘If a certain trade is good for one person, it must also be good for the other one.’ 63 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in3part. WCN 02-200-202and the gains from trade Chapter Interdependence 03_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 63 24/08/20 5:59 PM PART PART TWO ONE Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 04_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 64 24/08/20 4:31 PM Supply and demand: How markets work Chapter 4 The market forces of supply and demand Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 04_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 65 24/08/20 4:31 PM 4 The market forces of supply and demand Learning objectives After reading this chapter, you should be able to: LO4.1 identify a competitive market LO4.2 explain what determines the demand for a good in a competitive market LO4.3 explain what determines the supply of a good in a competitive market LO4.4 describe how supply and demand together determine the price of a good, and how prices allocate scarce resources in market economies. 66 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 04_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 66 24/08/20 4:31 PM Introduction When a cyclone hits Queensland, the price of bananas rises in supermarkets throughout the country. During warmer months, the price of hotel rooms in a Falls Creek skiing resort falls. When a war breaks out in the Middle East, the price of petrol in Australia rises and the price of a used SUV falls. What do these events have in common? They all show the workings of supply and demand. Supply and demand are the two words that economists use most often – and for good reason. Supply and demand are the forces that make market economies work. They determine the quantity of each good produced and the price at which it is sold. If you want to know how any event or policy will affect the economy, you must think first about how it will affect supply and demand. This chapter introduces the theory of supply and demand. It considers how buyers and sellers behave and how they interact with one another. It shows how supply and demand determine prices in a market economy and how prices, in turn, allocate the economy’s scarce resources. LO4.1 Markets and competition The terms supply and demand refer to the behaviour of people as they interact with one another in competitive markets. Before discussing how buyers and sellers behave, let’s first consider more fully what we mean by the terms market and competition. What is a market? A market is a group of buyers and sellers of a particular good or service. The buyers as a group determine the demand for the product and the sellers as a group determine the supply of the product. Markets take many forms. Sometimes markets are highly organised, such as the sharemarket, or the market for agricultural commodities, like the Sydney fish market. In these markets, buyers and sellers meet at a specific time and place. Buyers come knowing how much they are willing to buy at various prices, and sellers come knowing how much they are willing to sell at various prices. An auctioneer facilitates the process by keeping order, arranging sales, and (most importantly) finding the price that matches the quantity that sellers want to sell with the quantity that buyers want to buy. More often, markets are less organised. For example, consider the market for ice-cream in a particular town. Buyers of ice-cream do not meet together at any one time or at any one place. The sellers of ice-cream are in different locations and offer somewhat different products. There is no auctioneer calling out the price of ice-cream. Each seller posts a price for an ice-cream and each buyer decides how many ice-cream cones to buy at each store. Nonetheless, these consumers and producers of ice-cream are closely connected. The icecream buyers are choosing from the various ice-cream sellers to satisfy their cravings, and the ice-cream sellers are all trying to appeal to the same ice-cream buyers to make their businesses successful. Even though it is not as organised, the group of ice-cream buyers and ice-cream sellers forms a market. market a group of buyers and sellers of a particular good or service What is competition? The market for ice-cream, like most markets in the economy, is highly competitive. Each buyer knows that there are several sellers from which to choose. Each seller is aware that their product is similar to that offered by other sellers. As a result, the price and quantity of ice-cream are not determined by any single buyer or seller. Rather, price and quantity are determined by all buyers and sellers as they interact in the marketplace. 67 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 4 The market forces of supply and demand 04_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 67 24/08/20 4:31 PM competitive market a market in which there are many buyers and many sellers so that each has a negligible impact on the market price Economists use the term competitive market to describe a market in which there are so many buyers and so many sellers that each has a negligible impact on the market price. Each seller has limited control over the price because other sellers are offering similar products. A seller has little reason to charge less than the going price, and if more is charged then buyers will make their purchases elsewhere. Similarly, no single buyer of ice-cream can influence the price of ice-cream because each buyer purchases only a small amount. In this chapter we assume that markets are perfectly competitive. To reach this highest form of competition, a market must have two characteristics: 1 The goods offered for sale are all exactly the same. 2 The buyers and sellers are so numerous that no single buyer or seller has any influence over the market price. Because buyers and sellers in a perfectly competitive market must accept the price the market determines, they are said to be price takers. At the market price, buyers can buy all they want and sellers can sell all they want. There are some markets in which the assumption of perfect competition applies perfectly. In the international wheat market, for example, there are thousands of farmers who sell wheat and billions of consumers who use wheat and wheat products. Because no single buyer or seller can influence the price of wheat, each takes the market price as given. Not all goods and services, however, are sold in perfectly competitive markets. Some markets have only one seller and this seller sets the price. Such a seller is called a monopoly. Your local water company, for instance, may be a monopoly. Residents of your town probably have only one company from which to buy tap water. Still other markets fall between the extremes of perfect competition and monopoly. Despite the diversity of market types we find in the world, assuming perfect competition is a useful simplification and, therefore, a natural place to start. Perfectly competitive markets are easier to analyse because everyone participating in them takes the price as given by market conditions. Moreover, because some degree of competition is present in most markets, many of the lessons that we learn by studying supply and demand under perfect competition apply to more complex markets as well. CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING What is a market? What are the characteristics of a perfectly competitive market? LO4.2 Demand We begin our study of markets by examining the behaviour of buyers. To focus our thinking, let’s keep in mind a particular good – ice-cream. The demand curve: The relationship between price and quantity demanded quantity demanded the amount of a good that buyers are willing and able to purchase law of demand the claim that, other things being equal, the quantity demanded of a good falls when the price of the good rises The quantity demanded of any good is the amount of the good that buyers are willing and able to purchase. As we will see, many things determine the quantity demanded of a good, but in our analysis of how markets work, one determinant plays a central role: the good’s price. If the price of ice-cream rose to $20 per scoop, you would buy less ice-cream. You might buy frozen yoghurt instead. If the price of ice-cream fell to $0.50 per scoop, you would buy more. This relationship between price and quantity demanded is true for most goods in the economy and, in fact, is so pervasive that economists call it the law of demand. Other things being equal, when the price of a good rises, the quantity demanded of the good falls, and when the price falls, the quantity demanded rises. 68 Copyright 2021 Cengage Part 2 Supply and demand: How markets work Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 04_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 68 24/08/20 4:31 PM Table 4.1 shows how many ice-creams Catherine would buy each month at different prices of ice-cream. If ice-creams are free, Catherine eats 12 ice-creams per month. At $1.00 each, Catherine buys 10 ice-creams per month. As the price rises further, she buys fewer and fewer ice-creams. When the price reaches $6.00, Catherine doesn’t buy any ice-cream at all. Table 4.1 is a demand schedule, a table that shows the relationship between the price of a good and the quantity demanded, holding constant everything else that influences how much of the good consumers want to buy. TABLE 4.1 Catherine’s demand schedule Price of an ice-cream demand schedule a table that shows the relationship between the price of a good and the quantity demanded Quantity of ice-creams demanded $0.00 12 1.00 10 2.00 8 3.00 6 4.00 4 5.00 2 6.00 0 The graph in Figure 4.1 uses the numbers from the table to illustrate the law of demand. By convention, the price of ice-cream is on the vertical axis and the quantity of ice-cream demanded is on the horizontal axis. The line relating price and quantity demanded is called the demand curve. The demand curve slopes downward because, other things being equal, a lower price means a greater quantity demanded. demand curve a graph of the relationship between the price of a good and the quantity demanded FIGURE 4.1 Catherine’s demand curve Price of an ice-cream $6.00 5.00 4.00 3.00 2.00 1.00 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 Quantity of ice-creams This demand curve, which graphs the demand schedule in Table 4.1, illustrates how the quantity demanded of the good changes as its price varies. Because a lower price increases the quantity demanded, the demand curve slopes downwards. 69 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 4 The market forces of supply and demand 04_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 69 24/08/20 4:31 PM FIGURE 4.2 Market demand as the sum of individual demands Catherine’s demand Nicholas’ demand Price of an ice-cream Price of an ice-cream $6.00 $6.00 5.00 5.00 4.00 4.00 3.00 3.00 2.00 2.00 1.00 1.00 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 Quantity of ice-creams 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 Quantity of ice-creams The market demand curve is found by adding horizontally the individual demand curves. At a price of $4, Catherine demands four ice-creams, and Nicholas demands three ice-creams. The quantity demanded in the market at this price is seven ice-creams. Market demand versus individual demand The demand curve in Figure 4.1 shows an individual’s demand for a product. To analyse how markets work, we need to determine the market demand, which is the sum of all the individual demands for a particular good or service. Table 4.2 shows the demand schedules for ice-cream of two people – Catherine and Nicholas. At any price, Catherine’s demand schedule tells us how much ice-cream she buys, and Nicholas’ demand schedule tells us how much ice-cream he buys. The market demand is the sum of the two individual demands. TABLE 4.2 Individual and market demand schedules Price of an ice-cream $0.00 1.00 Catherine Nicholas Market 12 + 7= 19 10 6 16 2.00 8 5 13 3.00 6 4 10 4.00 4 3 7 5.00 2 2 4 6.00 0 1 1 The graph in Figure 4.2 shows the demand curves that correspond to these demand schedules. Notice that we add the individual demand curves horizontally to obtain the market demand curve. That is, to find the total quantity demanded at any price, we add the individual quantities found on the horizontal axis of the individual demand curves. Because 70 Copyright 2021 Cengage Part 2 Supply and demand: How markets work Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 04_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 70 24/08/20 4:31 PM Market demand Price of an ice-cream $6.00 5.00 4.00 3.00 2.00 1.00 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 ( 4 3) Quantity of ice-creams we are interested in analysing how markets work, we will work most often with the market demand curve. The market demand curve shows how the total quantity demanded of a good varies as the price of the good varies, while all other factors that affect how much consumers want to buy are held constant. Shifts in the demand curve Because the market demand curve is drawn holding other things constant, it need not be stable over time. If something happens to alter the quantity demanded at any given price, the demand curve shifts. For example, suppose that medical researchers suddenly announce a new discovery – people who regularly eat ice-cream live longer, healthier lives. The discovery would raise the demand for ice-cream. At any given price, buyers would now want to purchase a larger quantity of ice-cream and the demand curve for ice-cream would shift. Figure 4.3 illustrates shifts in demand. Any change that increases the quantity demanded at any given price, such as our imaginary discovery by medical researchers, shifts the demand curve to the right and is called an increase in demand. Any change that reduces the quantity demanded at every price shifts the demand curve to the left and is called a decrease in demand. Changes in many variables can shift the demand curve. Let’s consider the most important. Income What would happen to your demand for ice-cream if you lost your job one summer? Most likely, it would fall. A lower income means that you have less to spend in total, so you would have to spend less on some – and probably most – goods. If the demand for a good falls when income falls, the good is called a normal good. normal good a good for which, other things being equal, an increase in income leads to an increase in quantity demanded 71 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 4 The market forces of supply and demand 04_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 71 24/08/20 4:31 PM FIGURE 4.3 Shifts in the demand curve Price of an ice-cream Increase in demand Decrease in demand Demand curve, D3 0 Demand curve, D1 Demand curve, D2 Quantity of ice-creams Any change that raises the quantity that buyers wish to purchase at a given price shifts the demand curve to the right. Any change that lowers the quantity that buyers wish to purchase at a given price shifts the demand curve to the left. inferior good a good for which, other things being equal, an increase in income leads to a decrease in quantity demanded substitutes two goods for which a decrease in the price of one good leads to a decrease in the demand for the other good complements two goods for which a decrease in the price of one good leads to an increase in the demand for the other good CASE STUDY Not all goods are normal goods. If the demand for a good rises when income falls, the good is called an inferior good. An example of an inferior good might be bus rides. As your income falls, you are less likely to buy a car or take a taxi and more likely to take the bus. Prices of related goods Suppose that the price of frozen yoghurt falls. The law of demand says that you will buy more frozen yoghurt. At the same time, you will probably buy less ice-cream. Because icecream and frozen yoghurt are both cold, sweet, creamy desserts, they satisfy similar desires. When a fall in the price of one good reduces the demand for another good, the two goods are called substitutes. Substitutes are often pairs of goods that are used in place of each other, such as hot dogs and hamburgers, butter and margarine, and cinema tickets and video streaming. Now suppose that the price of chocolate topping falls. According to the law of demand, you will buy more chocolate topping. Yet, in this case, you will likely buy more ice-cream as well, since ice-cream and topping are often used together. When a fall in the price of one good raises the demand for another good, the two goods are called complements. Complements are often pairs of goods that are used together, such as petrol and cars, computers and software, and skis and ski-lift tickets. Are smartphones and tablets substitutes or complements? The advent of mobile computing has changed the way we interact with computers and the internet. You may carry a mobile device, such as a smartphone or tablet, with you, using it to access online services, create documents or play games. But are the different types of mobile device, smartphone and tablet substitutes or complements? Let’s explore this question by considering the case of Madeleine and Alexandra, two users of these devices. Madeleine uses her tablet to take notes in class. These notes are synced to her smartphone wirelessly, via the cloud, allowing Madeleine to review her notes on her phone during her bus trip home. 72 Copyright 2021 Cengage Part 2 Supply and demand: How markets work Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 04_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 72 24/08/20 4:31 PM Source: Shutterstock.com/tatayuki. Alexandra uses both her phone and tablet to surf the internet, write emails and check Facebook. Both of these devices allow Alexandra to access these online services. For Madeleine, smartphones and tablets are complements. She gets greater functionality out of her two devices when they are used together. For Alexandra, they are substitutes. Both smartphones and tablets fulfil more or less the same function in Alexandra’s life. This case illustrates the role that an individual consumer’s behaviour plays in determining the nature of the relationship between two goods or services. Two goods can be complements for one person and substitutes for another. Because of this, when it comes to the market as a whole, we can only determine if smartphones and tablets are complements or substitutes by observing how a change in the market price of one product affects the quantity demanded of the other. How do you use your smartphone? Questions 1 Provide another example of two goods that are complements for some people, and substitutes for others. How might people consume the two goods together? 2 How might one good act as a substitute for the other? Tastes Perhaps the most obvious determinant of your demand for any good or service is your tastes. If you like ice-cream, you buy more of it. Economists normally do not try to explain people’s tastes because tastes are based on historical and psychological forces that are beyond the realm of economics. Economists do, however, examine what happens when tastes change. Expectations Your expectations about the future may affect your demand for a good or service today. If you expect to earn a higher income next month, you may choose to save less now and spend more of your current income on ice-cream. If you expect the price of ice-cream to fall tomorrow, you may be less willing to buy an ice-cream at today’s price. Number of buyers In addition to the preceding factors, which influence the behaviour of individual buyers, market demand depends on the number of these buyers. If Peter, another consumer of icecream, were to join Catherine and Nicholas, the quantity demanded in the market would be higher at every price, and market demand would increase. Summary The demand curve shows what happens to the quantity demanded of a good as its price varies, holding constant all the other variables that influence buyers. When one of these other variables changes, the quantity demanded at each price changes, and the demand curve shifts. Table 4.3 lists the variables that influence how much of a particular good consumers choose to buy. 73 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 4 The market forces of supply and demand 04_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 73 24/08/20 4:31 PM TABLE 4.3 Variables that influence buyers Variables that affect quantity demanded A change in this variable … Price Represents a movement along the demand curve Income Shifts the demand curve Prices of related goods Shifts the demand curve Tastes Shifts the demand curve Expectations Shifts the demand curve Number of buyers Shifts the demand curve If you have trouble remembering whether you need to shift or move along the demand curve, it helps to recall a lesson from the appendix to Chapter 2. A curve shifts when there is a change in a relevant variable that is not measured on either axis. Because the price is on the vertical axis, a change in price represents a movement along the demand curve. By contrast, income, the prices of related goods, tastes, expectations and the number of buyers are not measured on either axis, so a change in one of these variables shifts the demand curve. CASE STUDY Two ways to reduce the quantity of smoking demanded Because smoking can lead to various illnesses, policymakers often want to reduce the amount that people smoke. There are two ways that policy can attempt to achieve this goal. One way to reduce smoking is to shift the demand curve for cigarettes and other tobacco products. Public service announcements, mandatory health warnings on cigarette packets and the prohibition of cigarette advertising are all policies aimed at reducing the quantity of cigarettes demanded at any given price. If successful, these policies shift the demand curve for cigarettes to the left, as in panel (a) of Figure 4.4. Alternatively, policymakers can try to raise the price of cigarettes. If the government taxes the manufacture of cigarettes, for example, cigarette companies pass much of this tax on to consumers in the form of higher prices. A higher price encourages smokers to reduce the number of cigarettes they smoke. In this case, the reduced amount of smoking does not represent a shift in the demand curve. Instead, it represents a movement along the same demand curve to a point with a higher price and lower quantity, as in panel (b) of Figure 4.4. How much does the amount of smoking respond to changes in the price of cigarettes? Economists have attempted to answer this question by studying what happens when the tax on cigarettes changes. They have found that a 10 per cent increase in the price causes a 4 per cent reduction in the quantity demanded. Teenagers are found to be especially sensitive to the price of cigarettes – a 10 per cent increase in the price causes a 12 per cent drop in teenage smoking. A related question is how the price of cigarettes affects the demand for other products, such as marijuana. Opponents of cigarette taxes often argue that tobacco and marijuana are substitutes, so that high cigarette prices encourage marijuana use. By contrast, many experts on substance abuse view tobacco as a ‘gateway drug’ leading the young to experiment with other harmful substances. Most studies of the data are consistent with this view – they find that higher cigarette prices are associated with reduced use of marijuana. In other words, tobacco and marijuana appear to be complements rather than substitutes. 74 Copyright 2021 Cengage Part 2 Supply and demand: How markets work Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 04_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 74 24/08/20 4:31 PM Source: Shutterstock.com/Olaf Speier. Questions 1 Suppose that the government legalised marijuana, allowing it to be sold by licensed retailers. How would you expect legalisation of marijuana to affect demand for cigarettes? 2 Now suppose that the government also placed a tax on marijuana, raising its price. How would the tax on marijuana affect demand for cigarettes? What is the best way to stop this? FIGURE 4.4 Shifts in the demand curve versus movements along the demand curve (a) A shift in the demand curve Price of cigarettes, per packet A policy to discourage smoking shifts the demand curve to the left. A B $4.00 0 10 D2 (b) A movement along the demand curve Price of cigarettes, per packet C $8.00 A tax that raises the price of cigarettes results in a movement along the demand curve. A 4.00 D1 20 Number of cigarettes smoked per day 0 12 20 D1 Number of cigarettes smoked per day If warnings on cigarette packets convince smokers to smoke less, the demand curve for cigarettes shifts to the left. In panel (a), the demand curve shifts from D1 to D2. At a price of $4 per packet, the quantity demanded falls from 20 to 10 cigarettes per day, as reflected by the shift from point A to point B. In contrast, if a tax raises the price of cigarettes, the demand curve does not shift. Instead, we observe a movement to a different point on the demand curve. In panel (b), when the price rises from $4 to $8, the quantity demanded falls from 20 to 12 cigarettes per day, as reflected by the movement from point A to point C. CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING List the determinants of the demand for pizza. Give an example of a demand schedule for pizza, and graph the implied demand curve. Give an example of something that would shift this demand curve. Would a change in the price of pizza shift this demand curve? LO4.3 Supply We now turn to the other side of the market and examine the behaviour of sellers. Once again, to focus our thinking, let’s consider the market for ice-cream. 75 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 4 The market forces of supply and demand 04_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 75 24/08/20 4:31 PM The supply curve: The relationship between price and quantity supplied quantity supplied the amount of a good that sellers are willing and able to sell law of supply the claim that, other things being equal, the quantity supplied of a good rises when the price of the good rises supply schedule a table that shows the relationship between the price of a good and the quantity supplied supply curve a graph of the relationship between the price of a good and the quantity supplied The quantity supplied of any good or service is the amount that sellers are willing and able to sell. There are many determinants of quantity supplied, but once again price plays a special role in our analysis. When the price of ice-cream is high, selling ice-cream is quite profitable and so the quantity supplied is large. The sellers of ice-cream work long hours, buy many ice-cream machines and hire many workers. In contrast, when the price of icecream is low, selling ice-cream is less profitable, so sellers produce less ice-cream. At a low price, some sellers may even shut down, reducing their quantity supplied to zero. This relationship between price and quantity supplied is called the law of supply: Other things being equal, when the price of a good rises, the quantity supplied of the good also rises, and when the price falls, the quantity supplied falls as well. Table 4.4 shows the quantity supplied by Tony, an ice-cream seller, at various prices of ice-cream. At a price below $2.00, Tony does not supply any ice-cream at all. As the price rises, he supplies a greater and greater quantity. This is the supply schedule, a table that shows the relationship between the price of a good and the quantity supplied, holding constant everything else that influences how much of the good producers want to sell. The graph in Figure 4.5 uses the numbers from the table to illustrate the law of supply. The curve relating price and quantity supplied is called the supply curve. The supply curve slopes upwards because, other things being equal, a higher price means a greater quantity supplied. TABLE 4.4 Tony’s supply schedule FIGURE 4.5 Tony’s supply curve Price of an ice-cream ($) Quantity of ice-creams supplied $0.00 0 1.00 0 2.00 1 3.00 2 4.00 3 5.00 4 6.00 5 Price of an ice-cream $6.00 5.00 4.00 3.00 2.00 1.00 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 Quantity of ice-creams This supply curve, which graphs the supply schedule in Table 4.4, shows how the quantity supplied of the good changes as its price varies. Because a higher price increases the quantity supplied, the supply curve slopes upwards. Market supply versus individual supply Just as market demand is the sum of the demands of all buyers, market supply is the sum of the supplies of all sellers. Table 4.5 shows the supply schedules for two ice-cream producers – Tony and Sonia. At any price, Tony’s supply schedule tells us the quantity 76 Copyright 2021 Cengage Part 2 Supply and demand: How markets work Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 04_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 76 24/08/20 4:31 PM of ice-cream that Tony supplies, and Sonia’s supply schedule tells us the quantity of icecream that Sonia supplies. The market supply is the sum of the supplies from the two individuals. TABLE 4.5 Individual and market supply schedule Price of an ice-cream $0.00 Tony Sonia Market 0+ 0= 0 1.00 0 0 0 2.00 1 0 1 3.00 2 2 4 4.00 3 4 7 5.00 4 6 10 6.00 5 8 13 The graph in Figure 4.6 shows the supply curves that correspond to the supply schedules. As with demand curves, we add the individual supply curves horizontally to obtain the market supply curve. That is, to find the total quantity supplied at any price, we add the individual quantities found on the horizontal axis of the individual supply curves. The market supply curve shows how the total quantity supplied varies as the price of the good varies, holding constant all the other factors beyond price that influence producers’ decisions about how much to sell. Shifts in the supply curve Because the market supply curve is drawn holding other things constant, when one of these factors changes, the supply curve shifts. For example, suppose that the price of sugar falls. Because sugar is an input into the production of ice-cream, the lower price of sugar makes selling ice-cream more profitable. This raises the supply of ice-cream: At any given price, sellers are now willing to produce a larger quantity. Thus, the supply curve for ice-cream shifts to the right. Figure 4.7 illustrates shifts in supply. Any change that raises quantity supplied at every price, such as a fall in the price of sugar, shifts the supply curve to the right and is called an increase in supply. Similarly, any change that reduces the quantity supplied at every price shifts the supply curve to the left and is called a decrease in supply. There are many variables that can shift the supply curve. Let’s consider the most important ones. Input prices To produce their output of ice-cream, sellers use various inputs – cream, sugar, flavouring, icecream machines, the buildings in which the ice-cream is made, and the labour of workers who mix the ingredients and operate the machines. When the price of one or more of these inputs rises, producing ice-cream becomes less profitable, and sellers supply less ice-cream. If input prices rise substantially, some sellers might shut down and supply no ice-cream at all. Thus, the quantity supplied of a good is negatively related to the prices of the inputs used to make the good. Technology The technology for turning the inputs into ice-cream is yet another determinant of the quantity supplied. The invention of the mechanised ice-cream machine, for example, reduced the amount of labour necessary to make ice-cream. By reducing sellers’ costs, the advance in technology raised the quantity of ice-cream supplied. 77 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 4 The market forces of supply and demand 04_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 77 24/08/20 4:31 PM FIGURE 4.6 Market supply as the sum of individual supplies Tony’s supply Sonia’s supply Price of an ice-cream Price of an ice-cream $6.00 $6.00 5.00 5.00 4.00 4.00 3.00 3.00 2.00 2.00 1.00 1.00 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 Quantity of ice-creams 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 Quantity of ice-creams The market supply curve is found by adding horizontally the individual supply curves. At a price of $4, Tony supplies three ice-creams and Sonia supplies four ice-creams. The quantity supplied in the market at this price is seven ice-creams. Expectations The quantity of ice-cream a seller supplies today may depend on its expectations about the future. For example, if a seller expects the price of ice-cream to rise in the future, it may put some of its current production into storage and supply less to the market today. Number of sellers In addition to the preceding factors, which influence the behaviour of individual sellers, market supply depends on the number of sellers. If Tony or Sonia were to retire from the icecream business, the supply in the market would fall. Summary The supply curve shows what happens to the quantity supplied of a good when its price varies, holding constant all the other variables that influence sellers. When one of these other variables changes, the quantity supplied at each price changes, and the supply curve shifts. Table 4.6 lists the variables that affect how much of a good producers choose to sell. Once again, to remember whether you need to shift or move along the supply curve, keep in mind that a curve shifts only when there is a change in a relevant variable that is not named on either axis. The price is on the vertical axis, so a change in price represents a movement along the supply curve. By contrast, because input prices, technology, expectations and the number of sellers are not measured on either axis, a change in one of these variables shifts the supply curve. 78 Copyright 2021 Cengage Part 2 Supply and demand: How markets work Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 04_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 78 24/08/20 4:31 PM Market supply Price of an ice-cream $6.00 5.00 4.00 3.00 2.00 1.00 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 1011121314 1516 171819 ( 3 4) Quantity of ice-creams FIGURE 4.7 Shifts in the supply curve Price of an ice-cream Supply curve, S3 Decrease in supply Supply curve, S1 Supply curve, S2 Increase in supply 0 Quantity of ice-creams Any change that raises the quantity that sellers wish to produce at a given price shifts the supply curve to the right. Any change that lowers the quantity that sellers wish to produce at a given price shifts the supply curve to the left. 79 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 4 The market forces of supply and demand 04_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 79 24/08/20 4:31 PM TABLE 4.6 Variables that influence sellers Variables that affect quantity supplied A change in this variable … Price Represents a movement along the supply curve Input prices Shifts the supply curve Technology Shifts the supply curve Expectations Shifts the supply curve Number of sellers Shifts the supply curve CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING List the determinants of the supply of pizza. Give an example of a supply schedule for pizza, and graph the implied supply curve. Give an example of something that would shift this supply curve. Would a change in the price of pizza shift this supply curve? LO4.4 Supply and demand together equilibrium a situation in which supply and demand have been brought into balance Having analysed supply and demand separately, we now combine them to see how they determine the price and quantity of a good sold in a market. equilibrium price the price that balances quantity supplied and quantity demanded Figure 4.8 shows the market supply curve and market demand curve together. Notice that there is one point at which the supply and demand curves intersect. This point is called the market’s equilibrium. The price at this intersection is called the equilibrium price and Equilibrium FIGURE 4.8 The equilibrium of supply and demand Price of an ice-cream Supply $4.00 Equilibrium price Equilibrium Demand Equilibrium quantity 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 Quantity of ice-creams The equilibrium is found where the supply and demand curves intersect. At the equilibrium price, the quantity supplied equals the quantity demanded. Here the equilibrium price is $4. At this price, seven ice-creams are supplied and seven ice-creams are demanded. 80 Copyright 2021 Cengage Part 2 Supply and demand: How markets work Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 04_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 80 24/08/20 4:31 PM the quantity is called the equilibrium quantity. Here the equilibrium price is $4.00 per ice-cream, and the equilibrium quantity is seven ice-creams. The dictionary defines the word equilibrium as a situation in which various forces are in balance. This definition applies to a market’s equilibrium as well. At the equilibrium price, the quantity of the good that buyers are willing and able to buy exactly balances the quantity that sellers are willing and able to sell. The equilibrium price is sometimes called the marketclearing price because, at this price, everyone in the market has been satisfied: Buyers have bought all they want to buy, and sellers have sold all they want to sell. The actions of buyers and sellers naturally move markets towards the equilibrium of supply and demand. To see why, consider what happens when the market price is not equal to the equilibrium price. Suppose first that the market price is above the equilibrium price, as in panel (a) of Figure 4.9. At a price of $5.00 per ice-cream, the quantity of the good supplied (10 icecreams) exceeds the quantity demanded (four ice-creams). There is a surplus of the good: Producers are unable to sell all they want at the going price. A surplus is sometimes called a situation of excess supply. When there is a surplus in the ice-cream market, for instance, sellers of ice-cream find their freezers increasingly full of ice-cream they would like to sell but cannot. They respond to the excess supply by cutting their prices. Falling prices, in turn, increase the quantity demanded and decrease the quantity supplied. These changes represent movements along the supply and demand curves (not shifts in the curves). Prices continue to fall until the market reaches the equilibrium. equilibrium quantity the quantity supplied and the quantity demanded at the equilibrium price surplus a situation in which quantity supplied is greater than quantity demanded FIGURE 4.9 Markets not in equilibrium (a) Excess supply (b) Excess demand Price of an ice-cream Price of an ice-cream Surplus Supply Supply $5.00 4.00 $4.00 3.00 Shortage Demand 0 4 7 Quantity demanded 10 Quantity supplied Quantity of ice-creams 0 4 Quantity supplied 7 Demand 10 Quantity demanded Quantity of ice-creams In panel (a), there is excess supply. Because the market price of $5.00 is above the equilibrium price, the quantity supplied (10 ice-creams) exceeds the quantity demanded (four ice-creams). Suppliers try to increase sales by cutting the price of an ice-cream and this moves the price towards its equilibrium level. In panel (b), there is excess demand. Because the market price of $3.00 is below the equilibrium price, the quantity demanded (10 ice-creams) exceeds the quantity supplied (four ice-creams). Because too many buyers are chasing too few goods, suppliers can take advantage of the shortage by raising the price. Hence, in both cases, the price adjustment moves the market towards the equilibrium of supply and demand. 81 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 4 The market forces of supply and demand 04_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 81 24/08/20 4:31 PM shortage a situation in which quantity demanded is greater than quantity supplied law of supply and demand the claim that the price of any good adjusts to bring the supply and demand for that good into balance Suppose now that the market price is below the equilibrium price, as in panel (b) of Figure 4.9. In this case, the price is $3.00 per ice-cream and the quantity of the good demanded exceeds the quantity supplied. There is a shortage of the good: Consumers are unable to buy all they want at the going price. A shortage is sometimes called a situation of excess demand. When a shortage occurs in the ice-cream market, buyers have to wait in long lines for a chance to buy the few ice-creams that are available. With too many buyers chasing too few goods, sellers can respond to excess demand by raising their prices without losing sales. These price increases cause the quantity demanded to fall and the quantity supplied to rise. Once again, these changes represent movements along the supply and demand curves, and they move the market towards the equilibrium. Thus, regardless of whether the price starts off too high or too low, the activities of the many buyers and sellers automatically push the market price towards the equilibrium price. Once the market reaches its equilibrium, all buyers and sellers are satisfied and there is no upward or downward pressure on the price. How quickly equilibrium is reached varies from market to market, depending on how quickly prices adjust. In most free markets, however, surpluses and shortages are only temporary because prices eventually move towards their equilibrium levels. Indeed, this phenomenon is so pervasive that it is sometimes called the law of supply and demand – the price of any good adjusts to bring the supply and demand of that good into balance. Three steps for analysing changes in equilibrium So far we have seen how supply and demand together determine a market’s equilibrium, which in turn determines the price of the good and the amount of the good that buyers purchase and sellers produce. The equilibrium price and quantity depend on the positions of the supply and demand curves. When some event shifts one of these curves, the equilibrium in the market changes, resulting in a new price and a new quantity exchanged between buyers and sellers. When analysing how some event affects a market, we proceed in three steps. First, we decide whether the event shifts the supply curve, the demand curve or, in some cases, both curves. Second, we decide whether the curve shifts to the right or to the left. Third, we use the supply-and-demand diagram to compare the initial equilibrium with the new one, which shows how the shift affects the equilibrium price and quantity. Table 4.7 summarises these three steps. To see how this recipe is used, let’s consider various events that might affect the market for ice-cream. TABLE 4.7 A three-step program for analysing changes in equilibrium 1 Decide whether the event shifts the supply or demand curve (or perhaps both). 2 Decide in which direction the curve shifts. 3 Use the supply-and-demand diagram to see how the shift changes the equilibrium. Example: A change in market equilibrium due to a shift in demand Suppose that one summer the weather is very hot. How does this event affect the market for ice-cream? To answer this question, let’s follow our three steps. 1 The hot weather affects the demand curve by changing people’s taste for ice-cream. That is, the weather changes the amount of ice-cream that consumers want to buy at any given price. The supply curve is unchanged because the weather does not directly affect the quantity of ice-cream that firms wish to sell. 2 Because hot weather makes people want to eat more ice-cream, the demand curve shifts to the right. Figure 4.10 shows this increase in demand as the shift in the demand curve from D1 to D2. This shift indicates that the quantity of ice-cream demanded is higher at every price. 82 Copyright 2021 Cengage Part 2 Supply and demand: How markets work Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 04_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 82 24/08/20 4:31 PM FIGURE 4.10 How an increase in demand affects the equilibrium Price of an ice-cream 1. Hot weather increases the demand for ice-cream ... Supply $5.00 New equilibrium 4.00 2. ... resulting in a higher price ... Initial equilibrium D2 D1 0 7 3. ... and a higher quantity sold. 10 Quantity of ice-creams An event that raises quantity demanded at any given price shifts the demand curve to the right. The equilibrium price and the equilibrium quantity both rise. Here, an abnormally hot summer causes buyers to demand more ice-cream. The demand curve shifts from D1 to D2, which causes the equilibrium price to rise from $4.00 to $5.00 and the equilibrium quantity to rise from seven to 10 ice-creams. 3 At the old price of $4, there is now an excess demand for ice-cream and this shortage induces sellers to raise the price. As Figure 4.10 shows, the increase in demand raises the equilibrium price from $4.00 to $5.00 and the equilibrium quantity from seven to 10 ice-creams. In other words, the hot weather increases both the price of ice-cream, and the quantity of ice-cream sold. Shifts in curves versus movements along curves Notice that when hot weather drives up the price of ice-cream, the amount of ice-cream that firms supply rises, even though the supply curve remains the same. In this case, economists say there has been an increase in ‘quantity supplied’ but no change in ‘supply’. ‘Supply’ refers to the position of the supply curve, whereas the ‘quantity supplied’ refers to the amount producers wish to sell. In this example, supply does not change because the weather does not alter firms’ desire to sell at any given price. Instead, the hot weather alters consumers’ desire to buy at any given price and thereby shifts the demand curve. The increase in demand causes the equilibrium price to rise. When the price rises, the quantity supplied rises. This increase in quantity supplied is represented by the movement along the supply curve. To summarise, a shift in the supply curve is called a ‘change in supply’ and a shift in the demand curve is called a ‘change in demand’. A movement along a fixed supply curve is called a ‘change in the quantity supplied’, and a movement along a fixed demand curve is called a ‘change in the quantity demanded’. 83 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 4 The market forces of supply and demand 04_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 83 24/08/20 4:31 PM Example: A change in market equilibrium due to a shift in supply Suppose that, during another summer, a bushfire destroys several ice-cream factories. How does this event affect the market for ice-cream? Once again, to answer this question, we follow our three steps. 1 The fire affects the supply curve. By reducing the number of sellers, the fire changes the amount of ice-cream that firms produce and sell at any given price. The demand curve is unchanged because the fire does not directly change the quantity of ice-cream consumers wish to buy. 2 The supply curve shifts to the left because, at every price, the quantity of ice-cream that firms are willing and able to sell is reduced. Figure 4.11 illustrates this decrease in supply as a shift in the supply curve from S1 to S2. 3 At the old price of $4.00 there is now an excess demand for ice-cream. This shortage causes ice-cream sellers to raise the price. As Figure 4.11 shows, the shift in the supply curve raises the equilibrium price from $4.00 to $5.00 and lowers the equilibrium quantity from seven to four ice-creams. As a result of the fire, the price of ice-cream rises and the quantity of ice-cream sold falls. FIGURE 4.11 How a decrease in supply affects the equilibrium Price of an ice-cream S2 1. A bushfire reduces the supply of ice-cream ... S1 New equilibrium $5.00 Initial equilibrium 4.00 2. ... resulting in a higher price ... Demand 0 4 7 3. ... and a lower quantity sold. Quantity of ice-creams An event that reduces quantity supplied at a given price shifts the supply curve to the left. The equilibrium price rises, and the equilibrium quantity falls. Here, a bushfire causes sellers to supply less ice-cream. The supply curve shifts from S1 to S2, which causes the equilibrium price to rise from $4.00 to $5.00 and the equilibrium quantity to fall from seven to four ice-creams. Example: A change in both supply and demand Now suppose that the hot weather and the fire occur at the same time. To analyse this combination of events, we again follow our three steps. 1 We determine that both curves must shift. The hot weather affects the demand curve because it alters the amount of ice-cream that consumers want to buy at any given 84 Copyright 2021 Cengage Part 2 Supply and demand: How markets work Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 04_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 84 24/08/20 4:31 PM FIGURE 4.12 A shift in both supply and demand (b) Price rises, quantity falls Price of an ice-cream Price of an ice-cream (a) Price rises, quantity rises Large increase in demand New equilibrium S2 S1 S2 S1 New equilibrium P2 P2 P1 D2 Small decrease in supply D1 Q1 Q2 Quantity of ice-creams Large decrease in supply P1 D2 Initial equilibrium Initial equilibrium 0 Small increase in demand D1 0 Q2 Q1 Quantity of ice-creams Here we observe a simultaneous increase in demand and decrease in supply. Two outcomes are possible. In panel (a), the equilibrium price rises from P1 to P2, and the equilibrium quantity rises from Q1 to Q2. In panel (b), the equilibrium price again rises from P1 to P2, but the equilibrium quantity falls from Q1 to Q2. price. At the same time, the fire alters the supply curve because it changes the amount of ice-cream that firms want to sell at any given price. 2 The curves shift in the same directions as they did in our previous analysis – the demand curve shifts to the right and the supply curve shifts to the left. Figure 4.12 illustrates these shifts. 3 As Figure 4.12 shows, there are two possible outcomes that might result, depending on the relative size of the demand and supply shifts. In both cases, the equilibrium price rises. In panel (a), where demand increases substantially and supply falls just a little, the equilibrium quantity also rises. In contrast, in panel (b), where supply falls substantially and demand rises just a little, the equilibrium quantity falls. Thus, these events certainly raise the price of ice-cream, but their impact on the amount of ice-cream sold is ambiguous. A pandemic shifts the supply curve In this chapter we have seen three examples of how to use supply and demand curves to analyse a change in equilibrium. Whenever an event shifts the supply curve, the demand curve, or perhaps both curves, you can use these tools to predict how the event will alter the price and quantity sold in equilibrium. This article provides another example of how a pandemic that reduces supply reduces the quantity sold and raises the price. IN THE NEWS Preparing for the apocalypse Suppose people become concerned that an apocalyptic event was on the horizon. This may be a zombie or alien invasion, but it also could be another crisis such as COVID-19 – the pandemic the world experienced in 2020 when a deadly virus spread widely. Given that these events are likely associated with shortages of goods and services (that is, the anticipation that supply will be drastically reduced as production becomes difficult) what should we expect to happen? 85 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 4 The market forces of supply and demand 04_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 85 24/08/20 4:31 PM The theory of supply and demand gives you part of the answer: prices should rise. When there is a shortage (that is, demand exceeds supply at current prices), we expect the prices of goods to increase to a point where demand will again equal supply. In March 2020, when the news of COVID-19 and its seriousness hit the world’s media, there was concern that there would be shortages of some goods. This included protective goods like hand sanitiser as well as commonly used items like toilet paper. Did prices rise? Both hand sanitiser and toilet paper are durable goods. You can buy them today, store them and they will still be useful tomorrow. If you are a consumer of such goods and you expect that there will soon be a shortage, what do you do? What you do is that you buy more than you need now – that is, you hoard those goods. This means that prior to there ever being a reduction in supply, there is an increase in demand. The theory of supply and demand, therefore, predicts that a shortage will arise even before there are any disruptions in supply. For this reason, prices should rise quickly. This is what happened. The price of hand sanitiser rose by tenfold before supplies ran out for a period of time. The price of toilet paper, on the other hand, did not change very much even though there was a shortage and supply did run out. Why did toilet paper’s price not change much? The explanation lies in the fact that toilet paper is mostly sold through chain supermarkets who did not want to increase its price (even for some short-run profits) because this might harm their brand image with customers. In addition, toilet paper is used at home and at work. While supplies of toilet paper packaged for home ran short, because people were not at work for a period during COVID-19, there was an excess supply of toilet paper packaged for work. Toilet paper can be repackaged and so supply disruptions proved temporary. CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING Analyse what happens to the market for pizza if the price of tomatoes rises. Analyse what happens to the market for pizza if the price of hamburgers falls. Conclusion: How prices allocate resources This chapter has analysed supply and demand in a single market. Our discussion has centred around the market for ice-cream, but the lessons learned here apply to most other markets as well. Whenever you go to a shop to buy something, you are contributing to the demand for that item. Whenever you look for a job, you are contributing to the supply of labour services. Because supply and demand are such pervasive economic phenomena, the model of supply and demand is a powerful tool for analysis. We use this model repeatedly in the following chapters. One of the Ten Principles of Economics discussed in Chapter 1 is that markets are usually a good way to organise economic activity. Although it is still too early to judge whether market outcomes are good or bad, in this chapter we have begun to see how markets work. In any economic system, scarce resources have to be allocated among competing uses. Market economies harness the forces of supply and demand to serve that end. Supply and demand together determine the prices of the economy’s many different goods and services; prices in turn are the signals that guide the allocation of resources. For example, consider the allocation of beachfront land. Because the amount of this land is limited, not everyone can enjoy the luxury of living by the beach. Who gets this resource? The answer is: whoever is willing to pay the price. The price of beachfront land adjusts until the quantity of land demanded exactly balances the quantity supplied. Thus, in market economies, prices are the mechanism for rationing scarce resources. 86 Copyright 2021 Cengage Part 2 Supply and demand: How markets work Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 04_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 86 24/08/20 4:31 PM Similarly, prices determine who produces each good and how much is produced. For instance, consider farming. Because we need food to survive, it is crucial that some people work on farms. What determines who is a farmer and who is not? In a free society, there is no government planning agency making this decision and ensuring an adequate supply of food. Instead, the allocation of workers to farms is based on the job decisions of millions of workers. This decentralised system works well because these decisions depend on prices. The prices of food and the wages of farm workers (the price of their labour) adjust to ensure that enough people choose to be farmers. If a person had never seen a market economy in action, the whole idea might seem preposterous. Economies are large groups of people engaged in many interdependent activities. What prevents decentralised decision making from degenerating into chaos? What coordinates the actions of the millions of people with their varying abilities and desires? What ensures that what needs to get done does, in fact, get done? The answer, in a word, is prices. If market economies are guided by an invisible hand, as Adam Smith famously suggested, then the price system is the baton with which the invisible hand conducts the economic orchestra. 87 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 4 The market forces of supply and demand 04_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 87 24/08/20 4:31 PM STUDY TOOLS Summary LO4.1 Economists use the model of supply and demand to analyse competitive markets. In a competitive market, there are many buyers and sellers, each of whom has little or no influence on the market price. LO4.2 The demand curve shows how the quantity of a good demanded depends on the price. According to the law of demand, as the price of a good falls, the quantity demanded rises. Therefore, the demand curve slopes downwards. In addition to price, other determinants of the quantity demanded include income, tastes, expectations, and the prices of substitutes and complements. When one of these other factors changes, the quantity demanded at each price changes, and the demand curve shifts. LO4.3 The supply curve shows how the quantity of a good supplied depends on the price. According to the law of supply, as the price of a good rises, the quantity supplied rises. Therefore, the supply curve slopes upwards. In addition to price, other determinants of the quantity supplied include input prices, technology and expectations. When one of these other factors changes, the quantity supplied at each price changes, and the supply curve shifts. LO 4.4 In market economies, prices are the signals that guide economic decisions and thereby allocate scarce resources. The intersection of the supply and demand curves represents the market equilibrium. At the equilibrium price, the quantity demanded equals the quantity supplied. The behaviour of buyers and sellers naturally drives markets towards their equilibrium. When the market price is above the equilibrium price, there is excess supply, which causes the market price to fall. When the market price is below the equilibrium price, there is excess demand, which causes the market price to rise. Key concepts competitive market, p. 68 complements, p.72 demand curve, p. 69 demand schedule, p.69 equilibrium, p. 80 equilibrium price, p. 80 equilibrium quantity, p. 81 inferior good, p. 72 law of demand, p. 68 law of supply, p. 76 law of supply and demand, p. 82 market, p. 67 normal good, p. 71 quantity demanded, p. 68 quantity supplied, p. 76 shortage, p. 82 substitutes, p. 72 supply curve, p. 76 supply schedule, p. 76 surplus, p. 81 Apply and revise 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 What is a competitive market? Briefly describe a type of market that is not perfectly competitive. What are the demand schedule and the demand curve, and how are they related? Why does the demand curve slope downwards? Does a change in consumers’ tastes lead to a movement along the demand curve or to a shift in the demand curve? Does a change in price lead to a movement along the demand curve or to a shift in the demand curve? Explain your answers. Harry’s income declines, and as a result, he buys more carrot juice. Is carrot juice an inferior or a normal good? What happens to Harry’s demand curve for carrot juice? What are the supply schedule and the supply curve, and how are they related? Why does the supply curve slope upwards? Does a change in producers’ technology lead to a movement along the supply curve or to a shift in the supply curve? Does a change in price lead to a movement along the supply curve or to a shift in the supply curve? Explain your answers. Define the equilibrium of a market. Describe the forces that move a market towards its equilibrium. 88 Copyright 2021 Cengage Part 2 Supply and demand: How markets work Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 04_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 88 24/08/20 4:31 PM 8 9 Beer and pies are complements because they are often enjoyed together. When the price of beer rises, what happens to the supply, demand, quantity supplied, quantity demanded and the price in the market for pies? Describe the role of prices in market economies. Practice questions Multiple choice 1 2 3 4 5 6 A change in which of the following will NOT shift the demand curve for hamburgers? a the price of meat pies b the price of hamburgers c the price of hamburger buns d the income of hamburger consumers An increase in ______ will cause a movement along a given demand curve, which is called a change in ______. a supply, demand b supply, quantity demanded c demand, supply d demand, quantity supplied Movie tickets and Blu-rays are substitutes. If the price of Blu-rays increases, what happens in the market for movie tickets? a The supply curve shifts to the left. b The supply curve shifts to the right. c The demand curve shifts to the left. d The demand curve shifts to the right. The discovery of a large, new reserve of crude oil will shift the ______ curve for petrol, leading to a ______ equilibrium price. a supply, higher b supply, lower c demand, higher d demand, lower If the economy goes into a recession and incomes fall, what happens in the markets for inferior goods? a Prices and quantities both rise. b Prices and quantities both fall. c Prices rise, quantities fall. d Prices fall, quantities rise. Which of the following might lead to an increase in the equilibrium price of meat pies and a decrease in the equilibrium quantity of meat pies sold? a an increase in the price of tomato sauce, a complement to meat pies b an increase in the price of tacos, a substitute for meat pies c an increase in the price of beef, an input into meat pies d an increase in consumer incomes, as long as meat pies are a normal good Problems and applications 1 2 Explain each of the following statements using supply-and-demand diagrams. a When a cyclone hits Queensland, the price of bananas rises in supermarkets throughout the country. b On Tuesdays, cinemas discount tickets. c When a war breaks out in the Middle East, the price of petrol rises and the price of a used SUV falls. ‘An increase in the demand for notebooks raises the quantity of notebooks demanded, but not the quantity supplied.’ Is this statement true or false? Explain. 89 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 4 The market forces of supply and demand 04_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 89 24/08/20 4:31 PM 3 Consider the market for SUVs. For each of the events listed here, identify which of the determinants of demand or supply are affected. Also indicate whether demand or supply is increased or decreased. a People decide to have more children. b A strike by steelworkers raises steel prices. c Engineers develop new automated machinery for the production of SUVs. d The price of sedans rises. e A stock-market crash lowers people’s wealth. 4 Consider the markets for film-streaming services, TVs, and cinema tickets. a For each pair, identify whether they are complements or substitutes. i film-streaming services and TVs ii film-streaming services and cinema tickets iii TVs and cinema tickets b Suppose a technological advance reduces the cost of manufacturing TVs. Draw a diagram to show what happens in the market for TVs. c Draw two more diagrams to show how the change in the market for TV screens affects the markets for film-streaming services and cinema tickets. 5 Over the last 30 years, technological advances have reduced the cost of computer chips. How do you think this affected the market for computers? For computer software? For typewriters? 6 Using supply-and-demand diagrams, show the effect of the following events on the market for woollen jumpers: a An outbreak of ‘foot-and-mouth’ disease hits sheep farms in New Zealand. b The price of leather jackets falls. c Taylor Swift appears in a woollen jumper in her latest video. d New knitting machines are invented. 7 Tomato sauce is a complement (as well as a condiment) for hot dogs. If the price of hot dogs rises, what happens to the market for tomato sauce? For tomatoes? For tomato juice? For orange juice? 8 The market for pizza has the following demand and supply schedules: Price ($) Quantity demanded Quantity supplied 4 135 26 5 104 53 6 81 81 7 68 98 8 53 110 9 39 121 a Graph the demand and supply curves. What are the equilibrium price and quantity in this market? b If the actual price in this market were above the equilibrium price, what would drive the market towards the equilibrium? c If the actual price in this market were below the equilibrium price, what would drive the market towards the equilibrium? 9 Consider the following events: Scientists reveal that eating oranges decreases the risk of diabetes, and at the same time, farmers use a new fertiliser that makes orange trees produce more oranges. Illustrate and explain what effect these changes have on the equilibrium price and quantity of oranges. 10 Because macaroni and cheese are often eaten together, they are complements. a We observe that both the equilibrium price of cheese and the equilibrium quantity of macaroni have risen. What could be responsible for this pattern: a fall in the price of flour or a fall in the price of milk? Illustrate and explain your answer. b Suppose instead that the equilibrium price of cheese has risen but the equilibrium quantity of macaroni has fallen. What could be responsible for this pattern: a rise in the price of flour or a rise in the price of milk? Illustrate and explain your answer. 90 Copyright 2021 Cengage Part 2 Supply and demand: How markets work Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 04_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 90 24/08/20 4:31 PM 11 Suppose that the price of tickets at your local cinema is determined by market forces. Currently, the demand and supply schedules are as follows: Price ($) Quantity demanded Quantity supplied 4 1000 800 8 800 800 12 600 800 16 400 800 20 200 800 9 39 121 a Draw the demand and supply curves. What is unusual about this supply curve? Why might this be true? b What are the equilibrium price and quantity of tickets? c Demographers tell you that next year there will be more film-goers in the area. The additional people will have the following demand schedule: Price ($) Quantity demanded 4 400 8 300 12 200 16 100 Now add the old demand schedule and the demand schedule for the new people to calculate the new demand schedule for the entire area. What will be the new equilibrium price and quantity? 91 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 4 The market forces of supply and demand 04_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 91 24/08/20 4:31 PM PART THREE Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 05_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 92 24/08/20 4:31 PM The data of macroeconomics Chapter 5 Measuring a nation’s income Chapter 6 Measuring the cost of living Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 05_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 93 24/08/20 4:31 PM 5 Measuring a nation’s income Learning objectives After reading this chapter, you should be able to: LO5.1 consider why an economy’s total income equals its total expenditure LO5.2 learn how gross domestic product (GDP) is defined and calculated LO5.3 see the breakdown of GDP into its four major components LO5.4 learn the distinction between real GDP and nominal GDP LO5.5 consider whether GDP is a good measure of economic wellbeing. 94 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 05_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 94 24/08/20 4:31 PM Introduction When you finish university and start looking for a full-time job, your experience will, to a large extent, be shaped by prevailing economic conditions. In some years, firms throughout the economy are expanding their production of goods and services, employment is rising and jobs are easy to find. In other years, firms are cutting back on production, employment is declining and finding a good job takes a long time. Not surprisingly, any university graduate would rather enter the labour force in a year of economic expansion than in a year of economic contraction. Because the condition of the overall economy profoundly affects all of us, changes in economic conditions are widely reported by the media. Indeed, it is hard to look at a news website without seeing some newly reported statistic about the economy. The statistic might measure the total income of everyone in the economy (GDP), the rate at which average prices are rising (inflation), the percentage of the labour force that is out of work (unemployment), total spending at stores (retail sales), or the imbalance of trade between Australia and the rest of the world (the trade deficit). All these statistics are macroeconomic. Rather than telling us about a particular household or firm, they tell us something about the entire economy. As you may recall from chapter 2, economics is divided into two branches – microeconomics and macroeconomics. Microeconomics is the study of how individual households and firms make decisions and how they interact with one another in markets. Macroeconomics is the study of the economy as a whole. The goal of macroeconomics is to explain the economic changes that affect many households, firms and markets at once. Macroeconomists consider diverse questions: Why is average income high in some countries and low in others? Why do prices rise rapidly in some periods of time but are more stable in other periods? Why do production and employment expand in some years and contract in others? These diverse questions are all macroeconomic because they concern the workings of the entire economy. Because the economy as a whole is just a collection of many households and many firms interacting in many markets, microeconomics and macroeconomics are closely linked. The basic tools of supply and demand, for instance, are as central to macroeconomic analysis as they are to microeconomic analysis. Yet studying the economy in its entirety raises some new and intriguing challenges. In this chapter and the next one, we discuss some of the data that economists and policymakers use to monitor the overall economy. These data reflect the economic changes that macroeconomists try to explain. This chapter considers gross domestic product, or simply GDP, which measures the total income of a nation. GDP is the most closely watched economic statistic because it is thought to be the best single measure of a society’s economic wellbeing. LO5.1 The economy’s income and expenditure If you were to judge how a person is doing economically, you might first look at his or her income. A person with a high income can more easily afford life’s necessities and luxuries. It is no surprise that people with higher incomes enjoy higher standards of living – better housing, better health care, fancier cars, more opulent holidays and so on. The same logic applies to a nation’s overall economy. When judging whether the economy is doing well or poorly, it is natural to look at the total income that everyone in the economy is earning. That is the task of gross domestic product (GDP). GDP measures two things at once – the total income of everyone in the economy and the total expenditure on the economy’s output of goods and services. The reason that GDP can perform the trick of measuring both total income and total expenditure is that these two things are really the same. For an economy as a whole, income must equal expenditure. 95 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Chapter WCN 02-200-202 5 Measuring a nation’s income 05_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 95 24/08/20 4:31 PM Why is this true? The reason that an economy’s income is the same as its expenditure is simply that every transaction has two parties: a buyer and a seller. Every dollar of spending by some buyer is a dollar of income for some seller. Suppose, for instance, that Karen pays Doug $100 to mow her lawn. In this case, Doug is a seller of a service and Karen is a buyer. Doug earns $100 and Karen spends $100. Thus, the transaction contributes equally to the economy’s income and to its expenditure. GDP, whether measured as total income or total expenditure, rises by $100. Another way to see the equality of income and expenditure is with the circular-flow diagram in Figure 5.1. (You may recall this circular-flow diagram from chapter 2.) This diagram describes all the transactions between households and firms in a simple economy. In this economy, households buy goods and services from firms; these expenditures flow through the markets for goods and services. The firms in turn use the money they receive from sales to pay workers’ wages, landowners’ rent and firm owners’ profit; this income flows through the markets for the factors of production. In this economy, money continuously flows from households to firms and then back to households. FIGURE 5.1 The circular-flow diagram Revenue Goods and services sold FIRMS Produce and sell goods and services Hire and use factors of production Inputs for production Wages, rent and profit MARKETS FOR GOODS AND SERVICES Firms sell Households buy Spending Goods and services bought HOUSEHOLDS Buy and consume goods and services Own and sell factors of production Labour, land MARKETS and capital FOR FACTORS OF PRODUCTION Households sell Income Firms buy 5 Flow of goods and services 5 Flow of dollars Households buy goods and services from firms, and firms use their revenue from sales to pay wages to workers, rent to landowners and profit to firm owners. GDP equals the total amount spent by households in the market for goods and services. It also equals the total wages, rent and profit paid by firms in the markets for the factors of production. We can calculate GDP for this economy in one of two ways – by adding up the total expenditure by households or by adding up the total income (wages, rent and profit) paid by firms. Because all expenditure in the economy ends up as someone’s income, GDP is the same regardless of how we calculate it. 96 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 3 The data of macroeconomics 05_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 96 24/08/20 4:31 PM The real economy is, of course, more complicated than the one illustrated in Figure 5.1. In particular, households do not spend all of their income. Households pay some of their income to the government in taxes, and they save and invest some of their income for use in the future. In addition, households do not buy all goods and services produced in the economy. Some goods and services are bought by governments and some are bought by firms that plan to use them in the future to produce their own output. Yet, regardless of whether a household, government, or firm buys a good or service, the transaction has a buyer and seller. Thus, for the economy as a whole, expenditure and income are always the same. CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING What two things does gross domestic product measure? How can it measure two things at once? LO5.2 The measurement of gross domestic product Now that we have discussed the meaning of gross domestic product in general terms, let’s be more precise about how this statistic is measured. Here is a definition of GDP: • gross domestic product (GDP) is the market value of all final goods and services produced within a country in a given period of time. This definition might seem simple enough. But, in fact, many subtle issues arise when calculating an economy’s GDP. Let’s therefore consider each phrase in this definition with some care. gross domestic product (GDP) the market value of all final goods and services produced within a country in a given period of time ‘GDP is the market value …’ You have probably heard the adage, ‘You can’t compare apples and oranges’. Yet GDP does exactly that. GDP adds together many different kinds of products into a single measure of the value of economic activity. To do this, it uses market prices. Because market prices measure the amount people are willing to pay for different goods, they reflect the value of those goods. If the price of an apple is twice the price of an orange, then an apple contributes twice as much to GDP as does an orange. ‘… of all …’ GDP tries to be comprehensive. It includes all items produced in the economy and sold legally in markets. GDP measures the market value of not just apples and oranges, but also pears and grapefruit, books and films, haircuts and health care, and so on. GDP also includes the market value of the housing services provided by the economy’s stock of housing. For rental housing, this value is easy to calculate – the rent equals both the tenant’s expenditure and the landlord’s income. Yet many people own the place where they live and, therefore, do not pay rent. The government includes this owner-occupied housing in GDP by estimating its rental value. In essence, GDP is based on the assumption that the owners pay themselves this imputed rent, so the rent is included both in their expenditure and in their income. There are some products, however, that GDP excludes because measurement of them is so difficult. GDP excludes items produced and sold illicitly, like illegal drugs. It also excludes most items that are produced and consumed at home and, therefore, never enter the marketplace. Vegetables you buy at the supermarket are part of GDP; vegetables you grow in your garden are not. 97 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Chapter WCN 02-200-202 5 Measuring a nation’s income 05_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 97 24/08/20 4:31 PM These exclusions from GDP can at times lead to paradoxical results. For example, when Karen pays Doug to mow her lawn, that transaction is part of GDP. If Karen were to marry Doug, the situation would change. Even though Doug may continue to mow Karen’s lawn, the value of the mowing is now left out of GDP because Doug’s service is no longer sold in a market. Thus, when Karen and Doug marry, GDP falls (assuming, of course, that Karen no longer pays Doug to mow the lawn). ‘… final …’ When Australian Paper makes paper which Hallmark uses to make a greeting card, the paper is called an intermediate good, and the card is called a final good. GDP includes only the value of final goods. The reason is that the value of intermediate goods is already included in the prices of the final goods. Adding the market value of the paper to the market value of the card would be double counting. That is, it would (incorrectly) count the paper twice. An important exception to this principle arises when an intermediate good is produced and, rather than being used, is added to a firm’s inventory to be used or sold at a later date. In this case, the intermediate good is taken to be ‘final’ for the moment, and its value as inventory investment is added to GDP. When the inventory of the intermediate good is later used or sold, the firm’s inventory investment is negative, and GDP for the later period is reduced accordingly. ‘… goods and services …’ GDP includes tangible goods (food, clothing, cars) and intangible services (haircuts, house cleaning, doctors’ visits). When you buy a song from iTunes by your favourite band or a t-shirt with your favourite band’s name on it, you are buying a good, and the purchase price is part of GDP. When you pay to hear a concert by the same group, you are buying a service, and the ticket price is also part of GDP. ‘… produced …’ GDP includes goods and services currently produced. It does not include transactions involving items produced in the past. When Ford produces and sells a new car, the value of the car is included in GDP. When one person sells a used car to another person, the value of the used car is not included in GDP. ‘… within a country …’ gross national product (GNP) the market value of all final goods and services produced by permanent residents of a nation within a given period of time GDP measures the value of production within the geographic confines of a country. When Japanese residents work temporarily in Australia, their production is part of Australian GDP. When an Australian resident owns a factory in Malaysia, the profit from production at that factory is not part of Australian GDP, it is part of Malaysia’s GDP. Thus, items are included in a nation’s GDP if they are produced domestically, regardless of the nationality of the producer. Another statistic, called gross national product (GNP), takes a different approach to dealing with the goods and services produced by foreigners. GNP is the value of the production of a nation’s permanent residents. When Japanese residents work temporarily in Australia, their production is not part of Australian GNP, it is part of Japan’s GNP. When an Australian resident owns a factory in Malaysia, the profit from production at the factory is part of Australian GNP. Thus, income is included in a nation’s GNP if it is earned by the nation’s permanent residents (called nationals), regardless of where they earn it. Throughout this book, we follow the standard practice of using GDP to measure the value of economic activity. For most purposes, however, the distinction between GDP and 98 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 3 The data of macroeconomics 05_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 98 24/08/20 4:31 PM GNP is not very important. In Australia and most other countries, domestic residents are responsible for most domestic production, so GDP and GNP are quite close. ‘… in a given period of time’ GDP measures the value of production that takes place within a specific interval of time. Usually that interval is a year or a quarter (three months). GDP measures the economy’s flow of income and expenditure during that interval. When the government reports the GDP for a quarter, it usually presents GDP ‘at an annual rate’. This means that the figure reported for quarterly GDP is the amount of income and expenditure during the quarter multiplied by 4. The government uses this convention so that quarterly and annual figures on GDP can be compared more easily. In addition, when the government reports quarterly GDP, it presents the data after they have been modified by a statistical procedure called seasonal adjustment. The unadjusted data show clearly that the economy produces more goods and services during some times of the year than during others. (As you might guess, December’s Christmas shopping season is a high point.) When monitoring the condition of the economy, economists and policymakers often want to look beyond these regular seasonal changes. Therefore, government statisticians adjust the quarterly data to take out the seasonal cycle. The GDP data reported in the news are always seasonally adjusted. Now let’s repeat the definition of GDP: • gross domestic product (GDP) is the market value of all final goods and services produced within a country in a given period of time. It should now be apparent that GDP is a sophisticated measure of the value of economic activity. In advanced courses in macroeconomics, you will learn more of the subtleties that arise in its calculation. But even now you can see that each phrase in this definition is packed with meaning. CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING Which contributes more to GDP – the production of a tonne of wool or the production of a tonne of iron ore? Why? LO5.3 The components of GDP Spending in the economy takes many forms. At any moment, the Tan family may be having lunch at Burgers Hut; Bega Cheese may be building a new processing factory; the Royal Australian Air Force (RAAF) may be procuring new jet fighters; and Qantas may be buying an aeroplane from Airbus. GDP accounts for all of these various forms of spending on goods and services. To understand how the economy is using its scarce resources, economists are often interested in studying the composition of GDP among various types of spending. To do this, GDP (which we denote as Y) is divided into four components: consumption (C), investment (I), government purchases (G) and net exports (NX): Y = C + I + G + NX This equation is an identity – an equation that must be true by the way the variables in the equation are defined. In this case, because each dollar of expenditure included in GDP is placed into one of the four components of GDP, the total of the four components must be equal to GDP. 99 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Chapter WCN 02-200-202 5 Measuring a nation’s income 05_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 99 24/08/20 4:31 PM investment spending on new capital equipment, inventories and structures, including household purchases of new housing government purchases spending on goods and services by local, state and federal governments net exports spending on domestically produced goods by foreigners (exports) minus spending on foreign goods by domestic residents (imports) – also called the trade balance We have just seen an example of each component. Consumption is spending by households on goods and services, like the Tan’s lunch at Burgers Hut. Investment is the purchase of new capital equipment, inventories and structures, like the Bega factory. Investment also includes expenditure on new housing. (By convention, expenditure on new housing is the one form of household spending categorised as investment rather than consumption.) Government purchases include spending on goods and services by local, state and federal governments, like the RAAF’s purchase of new jet fighters. Net exports equal the purchases of domestically produced goods by foreigners (exports) minus the domestic purchases of foreign goods (imports). A domestic firm’s purchase from a producer in another country, like the Qantas purchase of a plane from Airbus, decreases net exports. The ‘net’ in ‘net exports’ refers to the fact that imports are subtracted from exports. This subtraction is made because imports of goods and services are included in other components of GDP. For example, suppose that a household buys a $50 000 car from Audi, the German car-maker. That transaction increases consumption by $50 000 because car purchases are part of consumer spending. It also reduces net exports by $50 000 because the car is an import. In other words, net exports include goods and services produced abroad (with a minus sign) because these goods and services are included in consumption, investment and government purchases (with a plus sign). Thus, when a domestic household, firm, or government buys a good or service from abroad, the purchase reduces net exports – but because it also raises consumption, investment or government purchases, it does not affect GDP. The meaning of ‘government purchases’ also requires clarification. When the government pays the salary of an Army general, that salary is part of government purchases. But what happens when the government pays a pension benefit to one of the elderly? Such government spending is called a transfer payment because it is not made in exchange for a currently produced good or service. From a macroeconomic standpoint, transfer payments are like a tax rebate. Like taxes, transfer payments alter household income, but they do not reflect the economy’s production. No new goods or services are produced in the process of the government giving a transfer payment to an individual. Because GDP is intended to measure the income from (and expenditure on) the production of goods and services, transfer payments are not counted as part of government purchases. Table 5.1 shows the composition of Australian GDP in 2018. In this year, the GDP of Australia was about $1900 billion. If we divide this number by the 2018 Australian population of just about 25 million, we find that GDP per person – the amount of expenditure for the average Australian – was $76 006. Consumption made up 56 per cent of GDP, or $42 567 per person. Investment was $14 574 per person. Government purchases were $17 981 per person. Net exports were $884 per person. This number is positive because Australians spent less on foreign goods than foreigners purchased from us. In most of the 17 years from 2000 to 2017, this number was negative – indicating that the value of our imports was greater than the value of our exports in those years. TABLE 5.1 GDP and its components This table shows total GDP for the Australian economy in 2018 and the breakdown of GDP into its four components. GDP 2018 Consumption Total (in $ billion) Per person ($) % of total 1 064 42 567 56.0 Investment 364 14 574 19.2 Government purchases 450 17 981 23.7 22 884 1.1 1 900 76 006 Net exports Total GDP Source: ABS Data, Cat. No. 5206, Table 3 consumption spending by households on goods and services, with the exception of purchases of new housing 100 100 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 3 The data of macroeconomics 05_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 100 24/08/20 4:31 PM FYI A different way to arrive at GDP If you go to the ABS website and look at the annual GDP figures (as you are asked to do in question 8 in ‘Problems and applications’ at the end of the chapter), you’ll wonder where we got the figures we’ve presented in Table 5.1. But some simple additions will get you the same results we’ve shown. The ABS presents the information in a slightly different way by showing: • final consumption expenditure – which includes both household and government consumption • total gross fixed capital formation – both business and government investment • exports less imports. So the published data lumps all consumption together, whether household or government, and all investment together, whether business or government. That’s because some government expenditure is consumption (like the purchase by a government department of paper clips) and some government expenditure is investment (like building a new bridge or road). Sometimes we’re interested in private sector spending vs public sector (so we would use the C + I + G + NX approach) and sometimes we’re interested in how much of GDP is being generated for current consumption and how much for investment in future production capabilities (when we would be happy with the approach that the ABS presents). No matter which approach we use, when we add it all up, it should be the same! Alternative measures of income When the Australian Bureau of Statistics (ABS) calculates the nation’s GDP every three months, it uses three approaches to calculate the value of national output. The first measure, GDP(E), uses the expenditure approach to calculate national income. This is the approach described in the text. The other measures are GDP(I), the income approach, and GDP(P), the production approach. Conceptually, the three measures are the same but, in practice, they can differ because of the different data sources for each measure. They also differ more in the short run. Over time, more accurate estimates of the data become available, which allow the ABS to update its calculation of GDP. The ABS also calculates various other measures of income for the economy. These other measures differ from GDP by excluding or including certain categories of income. What follows is a brief description of the other two measures of GDP (Table 5.2). The diagram in Figure 5.2 shows the relationship between other income measures. TABLE 5.2 The relationship between GDP(I) and GDP(P) Gross domestic product income approach (GDP(I)) •The sum of factor incomes, consumption of fixed capital (depreciation) and net indirect taxes. •Factor incomes include wages, salaries and supplements paid to labour and profit received by both private and public businesses. •Depreciation, which is the wear and tear on the economy’s stock of equipment and structures, like trucks rusting and lightbulbs burning out. •In the national income accounts prepared by the ABS, depreciation is called the ‘consumption of fixed capital’. Gross domestic product production approach (GDP(P)) •Taking the market value of goods and services produced by an industry and deducting the cost of goods and services used up by the industry in the productive process. •Referred to by the ABS as ‘intermediate consumption’. •This approach uses a concept called value added to calculate GDP. When a firm produces a good, it must buy inputs. In the process of production, the firm transforms the inputs into something else. The value added to the inputs is referred to as the ‘value added’. •When the ABS uses this approach to calculate GDP, the value of the inputs must be subtracted from the value of the final product to avoid double counting, because GDP is the value of final goods and services. value added the value of a firm’s output minus the value of its inputs 101 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Chapter WCN 02-200-202 5 Measuring a nation’s income 05_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 101 24/08/20 4:31 PM FIGURE 5.2 Relationships among other income measures Imports of goods and services National turnover of goods and services Gross domestic product Imports of goods and services Gross domestic product at factor cost Imports of goods and services Domestic factor incomes Imports of goods and services Imports of goods and services Imports of goods and services Net income paid overseas Net income paid overseas Net income paid overseas Net transfers to overseas Net transfers to overseas National income National disposable income Exports of goods and services Net lending to overseas Gross national expenditure Gross national expenditure Indirect taxes less subsidies Indirect taxes less subsidies Consumption of fixed capital Consumption of fixed capital Consumption of fixed capital The figure shows the relationships among various measures of expenditure, income and output. National turnover is the total of expenditure on all goods and services, including expenditure on imports. Gross domestic product subtracts imports from national turnover to get a value of goods and services produced within the domestic economy. The value of domestic production can also be obtained by adding up the incomes of domestic factors of production. The figure shows how taxes and subsidies, payments to and receipts from overseas, and borrowing and lending are accounted for in the national income accounts. Source: Constructed from ABS, Cat. No. 5216.0, 2000 Although the various measures of income differ in detail, they almost always tell the same story about economic conditions. When GDP is growing rapidly, these other measures of income are usually growing rapidly. And when GDP is falling, these other measures are usually falling as well. For monitoring fluctuations in the overall economy, it does not matter much which measure of income we use. CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING What are the four components of expenditure? Give an example of each? LO5.4 Real versus nominal GDP As we have seen, GDP measures the total spending on goods and services in all markets in the economy. If total spending rises from one year to the next, one of two things must be true: (1) the economy is producing a larger output of goods and services, or (2) goods and services are being sold at higher prices. When studying changes in the economy over time, economists want to separate these two effects. In particular, they want a measure of the total quantity of goods and services the economy is producing that is not affected by changes in the prices of those goods and services. To do this, economists use a measure called real GDP. Real GDP answers a hypothetical question: What would be the value of the goods and services produced this year if we valued these goods and services at prices that prevailed in some specific year in the past? 102 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 3 The data of macroeconomics 05_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 102 24/08/20 4:31 PM By evaluating current production using prices that are fixed at past levels, real GDP shows how the economy’s overall production of goods and services changes over time. To see more precisely how real GDP is constructed, let’s consider an example. A numerical example Table 5.3 shows some data for an economy that produces only two goods – burgers and salads. The table shows the quantities of the two goods produced and their prices in the years 2020, 2021 and 2022. TABLE 5.3 Real and nominal GDP This table shows how to calculate real GDP, nominal GDP and the GDP deflator for a hypothetical economy that produces only burgers and salads. Year 2020 Price and quantities Price of burgers $ Quantity of burgers Price of salads $ Quantity of salads 7 45 8 40 2021 9 60 10 60 2022 12 90 14 100 Year 2020 Calculating nominal GDP ($7 per burger × 45 burgers) + ($8 per salad × 40 salads) = $635 Nominal GDP ($) 635 2021 ($9 per burger × 60 burgers) + ($10 per salad × 60 salads) = $1 140 1 140 2022 ($12 per burger × 90 burgers) + ($14 per salads × 100 salads) = $2 480 2 480 Year Calculating real GDP (base year 2020) Real GDP ($) 2020 ($7 per burger × 45 burgers) + ($8 per salad × 40 salads) = $635 635 2021 ($7 per burger × 60 burgers) + ($8 per salad × 60 salads) = $900 900 2022 ($7 per burger × 90 burgers) + ($8 per salad × 100 salads) = $1 430 Year Calculating the GDP deflator 1 430 GDP deflator 2020 ($635/$635) × 100 = 100 100 2021 ($1 140/$900) × 100 = 127 127 2022 ($2 480/$1 430) × 100 = 173 173 To calculate total spending in this economy, we multiply the quantities of burgers and salads by their prices. In the year 2020, 45 burgers are sold at a price of $7 per burger, so expenditure on burgers equals $315. In the same year, 40 salads are sold for $8 per salad and so expenditure on salads is $320. Total expenditure in the economy – the sum of expenditure on burgers and expenditure on salads – is $635. This amount, the production of goods and services valued at current prices, is called nominal GDP. The table shows the calculation of nominal GDP for these three years. Total spending rises from $635 in 2020 to $1140 in 2021 and then to $2480 in 2022. Part of this rise is attributable to the increase in the quantities of burgers and salads, and part is attributable to the increase in the prices of burgers and salads. To obtain a measure of the amount produced that is not affected by changes in prices, we use real GDP, which is the production of goods and services valued at constant prices. We calculate real GDP by first choosing one year as a base year. We then use the prices of burgers and salads in the base year to calculate the value of goods and services in all of the years. In other words, the prices in the base year provide the basis for comparing quantities in different years. nominal GDP the production of goods and services valued at current prices real GDP the production of goods and services valued at constant prices 103 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Chapter WCN 02-200-202 5 Measuring a nation’s income 05_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 103 24/08/20 4:31 PM Suppose that we choose 2020 to be the base year in our example. We can then use the prices of burgers and salads in 2020 to calculate the value of goods and services produced in 2020, 2021 and 2022. Table 5.3 shows these calculations. To calculate real GDP for 2020, we use the prices of burgers and salads in 2020 (the base year) and the quantities of burgers and salads produced in 2020. (Thus, for the base year, real GDP always equals nominal GDP.) To calculate real GDP for 2021, we use the prices of burgers and salads in 2020 (the base year) and the quantities of burgers and salads produced in 2021. Similarly, to calculate real GDP for 2022, we use the prices in 2020 and the quantities in 2022. When we find that real GDP has risen from $635 in 2020 to $900 in 2021 and then to $1430 in 2022, we know that the increase is attributable to an increase in the quantities produced, because the prices are held fixed at base-year levels. To sum up – nominal GDP uses current prices to place a value on the economy’s production of goods and services; real GDP uses constant base-year prices to place a value on the economy’s production of goods and services. Because real GDP is not affected by changes in prices, changes in real GDP reflect only changes in the amounts being produced. Thus, real GDP is a measure of the economy’s production of goods and services. Our goal in calculating GDP is to gauge how well the overall economy is performing. Because real GDP measures the economy’s production of goods and services, it reflects the economy’s ability to satisfy people’s material needs and desires. Thus, real GDP is a better gauge of economic wellbeing than is nominal GDP. When economists talk about the economy’s GDP, they usually mean real rather than nominal GDP. And when they talk about growth in the economy, they measure that growth using the percentage change in real GDP from an earlier period. The GDP deflator GDP deflator a measure of the price level calculated as the ratio of nominal GDP to real GDP times 100 From nominal GDP and real GDP, we can calculate a third useful statistic – the GDP deflator. The GDP deflator measures the current level of prices relative to the level of prices in the base year. In other words, the GDP deflator tells us the rise in nominal GDP that is attributable to a rise in prices rather than a rise in the quantities produced. The GDP deflator is calculated as follows: GDP deflator = Nominal GDP Real GDP × 100 This formula shows why the GDP deflator measures the level of prices in the economy. A change in the price of some good or service, without any change in the quantity produced, affects nominal GDP but not real GDP. This price change, therefore, is reflected in the GDP deflator. The GDP deflator in our example is calculated at the bottom of Table 5.3. For the year 2020, nominal GDP is $635 and real GDP is $635, so the GDP deflator is 100. (The GDP deflator is always 100 in the base year.) For the year 2021, nominal GDP is 1140 and real GDP is $900, so the GDP deflator is 127. Because the GDP deflator rose in year 2021 from 100 to 127, we can say that the price level increased by 27 per cent. The GDP deflator is one measure that economists use to monitor the average level of prices in the economy. We examine another – the consumer price index – in the next chapter. 104 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 3 The data of macroeconomics 05_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 104 24/08/20 4:31 PM Real GDP over recent history Now that we know how real GDP is defined and measured, let’s look at what this macroeconomic variable tells us about the recent history of Australia. Figure 5.3 shows annual data on real GDP for the Australian economy since 1970. CASE STUDY FIGURE 5.3 Real GDP in Australia 2 000 000 1 800 000 1 600 000 1 400 000 $million 1 200 000 1 000 000 800 000 600 000 400 000 200 000 0 1970 Recessions 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 Year 2000 2005 Real GDP 2010 2015 This figure shows quarterly data on real GDP for the Australian economy since 1970. Recessions – periods of falling real GDP – are marked with the red vertical bars. Source: ABS Data, Cat. 5206, Table 2 The most obvious feature of these data is that real GDP grows over time. Real GDP of the Australian economy in 2015 was almost four times its level in 1970. Put differently, the output of goods and services produced in Australia has grown on average about 3 per cent per year. This continued growth in real GDP enables the typical Australian to enjoy greater economic prosperity than his or her parents and grandparents did. A second feature of the GDP data is that growth is not steady. The upward climb of real GDP is occasionally interrupted by periods of decline, called recessions. Figure 5.3 marks recessions with red vertical bars. (Not everyone agrees about when Australia has had recessions. We have used the definition of two consecutive quarters of recession here.) Recessions are associated not only with lower incomes but also with other forms of economic distress – rising unemployment, falling profits, increased bankruptcies and so on. The third thing to notice about GDP growth in Australia is that we have had an extremely long, some would say unprecedented, period of growth in GDP. For the last 25 years, we have not had a recession. Even though many other economies suffered recessions as a result of the Global Financial Crisis, Australia’s GDP dipped in only two quarters, in 2000 and 2008. This could be due to good economic management, to the stimulus package put in place by the Rudd government, to the resources boom, to 105 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Chapter WCN 02-200-202 5 Measuring a nation’s income 05_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 105 24/08/20 4:31 PM the demand for our minerals by growing economies like China and India, and to the growth in our exports of food and education. One thing is certain – it won’t last forever. Much of macroeconomics is aimed at explaining these long-run growth and short-run fluctuations in real GDP. As we will see in the coming chapters, we need different explanatory frameworks or ‘models’ for these two purposes. Because short-run fluctuations represent deviations from the long-run trend, we first examine the behaviour of the economy in the long run. In particular, chapters 7 to 13 examine how key macroeconomic variables, including real GDP, are determined in the long run. We then build on this analysis to explain short-run fluctuations in chapters 14 to 17. Source: ABS, Cat. No. 5206.0, 2018 Question Based on your understanding of real GDP, briefly list three reasons why Australia’s real GDP has almost quadrupled since 1970? CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING Define real and nominal GDP. Which is a better measure of economic wellbeing? Why? Given the GDP deflator, if nominal GDP doubles and real GDP remain constant, what has happened to the price level? LO5.5 GDP and economic wellbeing Earlier in this chapter, GDP was called the best single measure of the economic wellbeing of a society. Now that we know what GDP is, we can evaluate this claim. As we have seen, GDP measures both the economy’s total income and the economy’s total expenditure on goods and services. Thus, GDP per person tells us the income and expenditure of the average person in the economy. Because most people prefer to receive higher income and enjoy higher expenditure, GDP per person seems a natural measure of the economic wellbeing of the average individual. Yet some people dispute the validity of GDP as a measure of welfare. The Kingdom of Bhutan uses a measure called Gross National Happiness, which measures four broad areas – good governance, sustainable socio-economic development, cultural preservation, and environmental conservation. These are broken down into nine subcategories – psychological wellbeing, health, education, time use, cultural diversity and resilience, good governance, community vitality, ecological diversity and resilience, and living standards. The survey isn’t done very often because it takes around seven hours to complete. But it gives a very different picture of a nation’s wellbeing than just looking at how much output was produced. For the most part, people in Bhutan were pretty happy! In Australia, the Australian Bureau of Statistics measures GDP, and has also begun measuring whether life in Australia is getting better. Look at the chart in Figure 5.4 – by most of these measures, we’re not doing too badly, but the economy may not be as resilient as it was and we aren’t looking after the environment as well as we could. So why do we look at GDP at all? The answer is that a large GDP does in fact help us to lead enjoyable lives. GDP does not measure the health of children, but nations with larger GDP can afford better health care for their children. GDP does not measure the quality of education, but nations with larger GDP can afford better educational systems. GDP does not measure the beauty of poetry, 106 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 3 The data of macroeconomics 05_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 106 24/08/20 4:31 PM FIGURE 5.4 Measures of Australia’s Progress (MAP) Society Economy Health Opportunities Close relationships Jobs Home Prosperity Safety A resilient economy Learning and knowledge Enhancing living standards Community connections and diversity Fair outcomes A fair go International economic engagement Enriched lives Environment Governance Healthy natural environment Trust Appreciating the environment Effective governance Protecting the environment Participation Sustaining the environment Informed public debate Healthy built environments People's rights and responsibilities Working together for a healthy environment What do these symbols mean? The headline progress indicator for this theme has shown progress. The headline progress indicator for this theme has shown regress. The headline progress indicator for this theme has not changed greatly. There is a data gap for this theme as there is currently no headline progress indicator. Source: ABS, https://www.abs.gov.au/ausstats/abs@.nsf/Lookup/by%20Subject/1370.0~2013~Main%20Features~Homepage~1 107 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Chapter WCN 02-200-202 5 Measuring a nation’s income 05_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 107 24/08/20 4:31 PM but nations with larger GDP can afford to teach more of their citizens to read and to enjoy poetry. GDP does not take account of our intelligence, integrity, courage, wisdom, or devotion to country, but all of these laudable attributes are easier to foster when people are less concerned about being able to afford the material necessities of life. In short, GDP does not directly measure those things that make life worthwhile, but it does measure our ability to satisfy material needs, and these are essential ingredients of comfortable, enjoyable and worthwhile lives. GDP is not, however, a perfect measure of wellbeing. Some things that contribute to a good life are left out of GDP. One is leisure. Suppose, for instance, that everyone in the economy suddenly started working every day of the week, rather than enjoying leisure on weekends. More goods and services would be produced, and GDP would rise. Yet, despite the increase in GDP, we should not conclude that everyone would be better off. The welfare loss from reduced leisure would offset the welfare gain from producing and consuming a greater quantity of goods and services. Another item that GDP excludes is the quality of the environment. Imagine that the government eliminated all environmental regulations. Firms could then produce goods and services without considering the pollution they create, and GDP might rise. Yet it is most likely that wellbeing would fall. The deterioration in the quality of air and water would more than offset the welfare gain from greater production. Because GDP uses market prices to value goods and services, it also excludes the value of almost all activity that takes place outside of markets. Child-rearing and volunteer work, for instance, contribute to the wellbeing of those in society, but GDP does not reflect these contributions. If parents decided to spend fewer hours at their jobs in order to spend more time with their children, the economy might produce fewer goods and services, and GDP might fall, but that change would not necessarily reflect a lower quality of life. In the end, we conclude that GDP is a good measure of welfare for most – but not all – purposes. It is important to keep in mind what GDP includes as well as what it leaves out. CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING Why should policymakers care about GDP? Why should they also consider other measures of wellbeing? International differences in GDP and the quality of life One way to gauge the usefulness of GDP as a measure of economic wellbeing is to examine international data. Rich and poor countries have vastly different levels of GDP per person. If a large GDP leads to a higher standard of living, then we should observe GDP to be strongly correlated with measures of the quality of life. And, in fact, we do. The Human Development Index was developed nearly 30 years ago to examine how well countries did at providing the basic human needs. It has captured data on income per capita, life expectancy, literacy rates and years of schooling. The Human Development Report also presents four other composite indices to give a more complete picture of how countries are doing. The Inequality-adjusted HDI discounts the HDI according to the extent of inequality. The Gender Development Index compares female and male HDI values. The Gender Inequality Index highlights women’s empowerment. And the Multidimensional Poverty Index measures non-income dimensions of poverty. In the latest report on the HDI, released in 2018, the focus is the alleviation of poverty. Poverty has a big impact on the quality of life. Just one example is life expectancy. The following chart from the HDI report shows that life expectancy for people in highly 108 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 3 The data of macroeconomics 05_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 108 24/08/20 4:31 PM developed economies is nearly 20 years higher than those living in poorer countries. The second chart shows that gender inequality is also much higher in those countries that are poorer. (See Figure 5.5.) FIGURE 5.5 Life expectancy and gender inequality Life expectancy at birth, by human development group, 2017 Ver y hig h hu m an Lif d e 79 exp .5 y .8 60 e ev w Lo nt lopme eve nd a m hu nt me lop y nc ta ec rs ea people bn bn bn 2.733 2. 3 79 1 69. e M e d iu m h u m a n d ev 6 m 1.439 92 7 6 ev .0 el op nt me me nt lo p Hig h m hu an d 70 0.2 2 0.31 Gender inequality index 0.386 La tin Su bAm Sa er ha i ra Ea ca Ar n st an ab Af Eu ric As d t S S ro ou he a t i a a pe t t an es h Ca an As d r i bb th d ia e Ce Pa ean nt c ra fic lA si a Gender inequality index, by developing region, 2017 5 51 0. 31 0.5 69 0.5 Source: United Nations Development Program, Human Development Indices and Indicators 2018 Statistical Update (CC BY 3.0 IGO) 109 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Chapter WCN 02-200-202 5 Measuring a nation’s income 05_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 109 24/08/20 4:31 PM CASE STUDY Table 5.4 shows 12 countries around the world, including Australia and New Zealand, listed in order of their Human Development Index (HDI) ranking. Note that GDP and HDI rankings are not identical, though. (In the table below, we use gross national income, which is an alternative measure of GDP.) The USA has the 2nd-highest GNI ranking of those countries shown, but a relatively lower life expectancy, which lowers its overall HDI ranking. The countries with a HDI index above 112 are considered to have high human development, the countries between 113 and 151 have medium human development and below 152 are considered to have a low level of human development. TABLE 5.4 GNI, life expectancy and literacy The table shows GNI per person and two measures of the quality of life for 12 countries for 2017. Country Norway Australia USA HDI rank* 1 Real GNI per person (2011) Life expectancy (years) Mean years of schooling (%) $68 012 82.3 12.6 3 43 560 83.1 12.9 13 54 941 79.5 13.4 UK 14 39 116 81.7 12.9 New Zealand 16 33 970 82.0 12.5 Japan 19 38 986 83.9 12.8 Thailand 83 15 516 75.5 7.6 China 86 15 270 76.4 7.8 Indonesia 116 10 846 69.4 8.0 India 130 6 353 68.8 6.4 Papua New Guinea 153 3 403 65.7 4.6 Niger 189 906 60.4 2.0 *HDI ranking is based on life expectancy, education and income per capita. Source: United Nations Development Program, Human Development Indices and Indicators 2018 Statistical Update (CC BY 3.0 IGO) Questions 1 2 Why is it useful to compare the real GNI per person across different countries? Compare and contrast real GNI per person to the other measures in Table 5.4. Do you think real GNI per person a good measure of economic wellbeing based on your findings? FYI Alternative measures of an economy’s wellbeing Several economists have tried to develop alternative measures of an economy’s wellbeing. Here are a few alternative measures: • Measures of Australia’s Progress (MAP). The Australian Bureau of Statistics developed this measure to answer the question ‘Is life getting better [in Australia]?’ Economic growth brings with it increases in population which can lead to increased congestion on the roads and in our schools, strains on the environment, increases in income inequality and crime, and strains on our health system. This measure looks at four broad categories to answer the question of whether life 110 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 3 The data of macroeconomics 05_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 110 24/08/20 4:31 PM is getting better or not: society, economy, environment and government. ABS Director, Fiona Dowsley said in 2013: The latest release of MAP shows us that overall, Australia is in pretty good shape with more progress or little movement, than regress, which is a great result. Progress was found in the areas of health, learning and knowledge, jobs, living standards and participation. We have only regressed in the areas of our economy’s resilience and sustaining the environment. Source: ABS, https://www.abs.gov.au/ausstats/abs@.nsf/Lookup/by%20Subject/1370.0~2013~Main%20 Features~Homepage~1 • • Gross National Happiness. This concept was first developed by the King of Bhutan. He wanted to ensure that the culture and environment of Bhutan was not lost on its road to economic development. Other countries have adapted the concept to suit their own measure of national happiness. Social Progress Index. Michael Porter, author of Competitive Advantage, has worked on setting up the Social Progress Index. In this measure, three categories are measured: Basic Human Needs, Foundations of Wellbeing and Opportunity. Basic Human Needs include access to nutrition and basic medical care, water and sanitation, shelter and personal safety. Foundations of wellbeing include access to basic knowledge, information and communication, health and wellness and ecosystem sustainability. Opportunity includes personal rights, freedom and choice, tolerance and inclusion and access to advanced education. All of these measures say something about how well a society is doing. And those countries that score well on these measures tend to have higher GDP per capita. So GDP is not a bad measure of wellbeing. And it has one additional advantage – it can be easier to capture the data on expenditure and production in an economy. Source: © Commonwealth of Australia. Released under a Creative Commons Attribution 2.5 Australia licence. Although data on other aspects of the quality of life are less complete, they tell a similar story. Countries with low GDP per person tend to have more infants with low birthweight, higher rates of infant mortality, higher rates of maternal mortality, higher rates of child malnutrition, and less common access to safe drinking water. In countries with low GDP per person, fewer school-age children are in school, and those who are in school must learn with fewer teachers per student. These countries also tend to have fewer radios, fewer televisions, fewer telephones, fewer paved roads and fewer households with electricity. International data leave no doubt that a nation’s GDP is closely associated with its citizens’ standard of living. Conclusion This chapter has discussed how economists measure the total income of a nation. Measurement is, of course, only a starting point. Much of macroeconomics is aimed at revealing the long-run and short-run determinants of a nation’s GDP. Why, for example, is GDP higher in Australia and Japan than in India and Afghanistan? What can the governments of the poorest countries do to promote more rapid growth in GDP? Why does GDP in Australia rise rapidly in some years and fall in others? What can Australian policymakers do to reduce the severity of these fluctuations in GDP? These are the questions we will take up shortly. At this point, it is necessary to acknowledge the importance of just measuring GDP. We all get some sense of how the economy is doing as we go about our lives. But economists who study changes in the economy and policymakers who formulate economic policies need more than this vague sense – they need concrete data on which to base their judgements. Quantifying the behaviour of the economy with statistics like GDP is, therefore, the first step in developing a science of macroeconomics. 111 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Chapter WCN 02-200-202 5 Measuring a nation’s income 05_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 111 24/08/20 4:31 PM STUDY TOOLS Summary LO5.1 Because every transaction has a buyer and a seller, the total expenditure in the economy must equal the total income in the economy. LO5.2 Gross domestic product (GDP) measures an economy’s total expenditure on newly produced goods and services and the total income earned from the production of these goods and services. More precisely, GDP is the market value of all final goods and services produced within a country in a given period of time. LO5.3 GDP is divided among four components of expenditure – consumption, investment, government purchases and net exports. Consumption includes spending on goods and services by households, with the exception of purchases of new housing. Investment includes spending on new equipment and structures, including households’ purchases of new housing. Government purchases include spending on goods and services by local, state and federal governments. Net exports equal the value of goods and services produced domestically and sold abroad (exports) minus the value of goods and services produced abroad and sold domestically (imports). LO5.4 Nominal GDP uses current prices to value the economy’s production of goods and services. Real GDP uses constant base-year prices to value the economy’s production of goods and services. The GDP deflator – calculated from the ratio of nominal to real GDP – measures the level of prices in the economy. LO5.5 GDP is a good measure of economic wellbeing because higher incomes mean people can buy more of the things that add to their wellbeing. But it is not a perfect measure of wellbeing. For example, GDP excludes the value of leisure and the value of a clean environment, as well as the negative impact of greater levels of income inequality or crime. Key concepts consumption, p. 100 GDP deflator, p. 104 government purchases, p. 100 gross domestic product (GDP), p. 97 gross national product (GNP), p. 98 investment, p. 100 net exports, p. 100 nominal GDP, p. 103 real GDP, p. 103 value added, p. 101 Practice questions Questions for review 1 2 3 4 5 6 Explain why an economy’s income must equal its expenditure. Which contributes more to GDP – the production of a tonne of wheat or the production of a tonne of coal? Why? A farmer sells milk to a cheesemaker for $2. The cheesemaker uses the milk to make cheese, which is sold for $6. What is the contribution to GDP? Over the last three years, Kane paid $5000 buying new parts to restore his vintage car. Today he sells the car at auction for $20 000. How does this sale affect current GDP? List the four components of GDP. Give an example of each. In the year 2020, the economy produces 200 serves of fish and chips for $9.50 each. In the year 2021, the economy produces 250 serves of fish and chips for $12.75 each. Calculate nominal GDP, real GDP and the GDP deflator for each year. (Use 2020 as the base year.) By what percentage does each of these three statistics rise from one year to the next? Why is it desirable for a country to have a large GDP? Give an example of something that would raise GDP and yet be undesirable. 112 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 3 The data of macroeconomics 05_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 112 24/08/20 4:31 PM Multiple choice 1 2 3 4 5 GDP includes: a Consumption, Investment, Government Transfers, Exports b Consumption, Private Investment, Government Investment, Exports and Imports c Consumption, Private and Government Investment, Government Expenditure and Net Exports d Consumption, Investment, Government Revenue and Imports If the nominal GDP of HobbitLand in 2020 is $2 350 000 and the GDP deflator in 2020 is 103 and the base year for the GDP deflator is 2016, what is real GDP in 2020: a $2 281 553 b $2 420 500 c $2 350 000 d $1 807 692 Which of the following should not be included in GDP: a Your purchase of a new pair of pants. b Qantas’ purchase of a new ticketing kiosk. c A bank’s purchase of an existing building for a new office. d The Royal Australian Navy’s purchase of a new patrol boat. According to the information in Table 5.4, Australia has a higher life expectancy and higher mean years of schooling and yet Norway is ranked as number 1 on the Human Development Index and Australia is number 2. Which of the following must be true? a Australia’s schooling isn’t as good as Norway’s. b Norway’s real GDP per person is higher. c Australia’s distribution of income is worse. d Norway doesn’t treat its old people as well as Australia does. If Australia is experiencing rising inflation, then a nominal GDP is growing faster than real GDP. b nominal GDP is growing faster than the GDP deflator. c real GDP is growing faster than nominal GDP. d real GDP is growing faster than the GDP deflator. Problems and applications 1 2 3 4 5 What components of GDP (if any) would each of the following transactions affect? Explain. a A family buys a new LED TV. b Aunt Maria buys a new iPad. c Kia sells a Rio from its inventory. d You buy a movie theatre ticket. e The government of New South Wales creates a new light rail system in Sydney. f Your parents buy a bottle of South Australian wine. g Ford Motor Company shuts down its factory in Campbellfield, Victoria. The ‘government purchases’ component of GDP does not include spending on transfer payments like welfare benefits. Thinking about the definition of GDP, explain why transfer payments are excluded. Why do you think households’ purchases of new housing are included in the investment component of GDP rather than the consumption component? Can you think of a reason that households’ purchases of refrigerators should also be included in investment rather than in consumption? To what other consumption goods might this logic apply? As the chapter states, GDP does not include the value of volunteer work. Do you think GDP should include such transactions? Would this make GDP a better measure of economic wellbeing? Look on the ABS website to find the base year for real GDP. Why do you think the ABS updates the base year periodically? 113 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Chapter WCN 02-200-202 5 Measuring a nation’s income 05_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 113 24/08/20 4:31 PM 6 Consider the following data on Australian GDP: Year Nominal GDP (in millions) GDP deflator (base year 2010–11) 2018 $1 687 453 99.5 2019 1 715 321 99 a 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 What was the growth rate of nominal income between 2018 and 2019? (Note: The growth rate is the percentage change from one period to the next. The ABS calculates annual GDP on a financial year basis, from July one year to June the next. The GDP deflator is equal to 100 in the middle of the financial year.) b What was the growth rate of the GDP deflator between 2018 and 2019? c What was real income in 2018 measured in 2011 prices? d What was real income in 2019 measured in 2011 prices? e What was the growth rate of real income between 2018 and 2019? f Was the growth rate of nominal income higher or lower than the growth rate of real income? Explain. If prices rise, people’s income from selling goods increases. Why do economists prefer using real GDP as a measure of economic wellbeing rather than using nominal GDP? Revised estimates of Australian GDP are usually released by the government near the end of each month. Look it up on the ABS website at http://www.abs.gov.au. Discuss the recent changes in real and nominal GDP and in the components of GDP. If a mining company sells less coal than last year, but at a higher price per tonne, its income may have increased. Can you tell whether the mining company is better off? A classmate tells you that Japan’s GDP per person in 2017 is roughly half of what Norway’s was, but life expectancy was slightly higher. Which is a better indicator of economic wellbeing? What else would you want to look at to gain a deeper understanding of wellbeing? Goods and services that are sold in black markets, like illegal drugs, are generally not included in GDP. a Does this lead to a misleading comparison between countries, like in the second column of Table 5.4, comparing Australia and India? Explain. b Should these activities be included as a positive or negative in GDP? c According to work done by the Federal Reserve Bank of St Louis in the USA, the underground economy represents about 13% of GDP for developed economies, while for developing economies the estimate is 36% of GDP. Do you think these figures have an impact on the level of wellbeing in these economies? Why or why not? (Source: https://www.stlouisfed.org/publications/regional-economist/january-2015 /underground-economy.) Explain the limitations of GDP: a as a measure of total production in an economy b as a measure of economic wellbeing The participation of women in the Australian labour force has risen dramatically since 1965. a How do you think this rise affected GDP? b Now imagine a measure of wellbeing that includes time spent working in the home and taking leisure. How would the change in this measure of wellbeing compare with the change in GDP? c Can you think of other aspects of wellbeing that are associated with the rise in women’s labour-force participation? Would it be practical to construct a measure of wellbeing that includes these aspects? d In the last two decades, there has been an increase in the numbers of fathers staying home to look after their children. How would this affect GDP? 114 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 3 The data of macroeconomics 05_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 114 24/08/20 4:31 PM 6 Measuring the cost of living Learning objectives After reading this chapter, you should be able to: LO6.1 learn how the consumer price index (CPI) is constructed LO6.2 consider why the CPI is an imperfect measure of the cost of living LO6.3 compare the CPI and the GDP deflator as measures of the overall price level LO6.4 see how to use a price index to compare dollar amounts from different times LO6.5 learn the distinction between real and nominal interest rates. 115 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 06_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 115 24/08/20 4:31 PM Introduction In 1930, as the Australian economy was suffering through the Great Depression, famed racehorse Phar Lap earned £9429 at the Melbourne Cup. At the time, these earnings were extraordinary, even for great racehorses. The prime minister, James Scullin, received a parliamentary allowance of about £1000. When Australia switched from pounds to decimal currency in 1966, a pound was designated to be worth $2, so in dollar terms, these earnings would have been $19 000 and $2000 respectively. (See the FYI box ‘The change to decimal currency’.) Phar Lap may be more famous than Prime Minister Scullin, but neither amount seems much when compared with the winnings for the present-day Melbourne Cup. In 2018, the Melbourne Cup paid $3.6 million to the winning horse, over 150 times what Phar Lap won. And Phar Lap is still considered one of the greatest racehorses ever to have lived. At first, this fact might lead you to think that horseracing has become much more lucrative over the past seven decades. But, as everyone knows, the prices of goods and services have also risen. In 1930, an ice-cream would have cost about 2 cents and a ticket to the local movie theatre about 5 cents. Because these prices were so much lower in Phar Lap’s day than they are in ours, it is not clear whether Phar Lap’s owners enjoyed a higher or lower standard of living than today’s horse owners. (See pp. 126–7.) In the preceding chapter we looked at how economists use gross domestic product (GDP) to measure the quantity of goods and services that the economy is producing. This chapter examines how economists measure the overall cost of living. To compare Phar Lap’s earnings of $19 000 with prize money of today, we need to find some way of turning dollar figures into meaningful measures of purchasing power. That is exactly the job of a statistic called the consumer price index. After seeing how the consumer price index is constructed, we discuss how we can use such a price index to compare dollar figures from different points in time. LO6.1 The consumer price index consumer price index (CPI) a measure of the overall cost of the goods and services bought by a typical consumer The consumer price index (CPI) is used to monitor changes in the cost of living over time. When the consumer price index rises, the typical family has to spend more dollars to maintain the same standard of living. Economists use the term inflation to describe a situation in which the economy’s overall price level is rising. The inflation rate is the percentage change in the price level from the previous period. As we will see in the coming chapters, inflation is a closely watched aspect of macroeconomic performance and is a key variable guiding macroeconomic policy. This chapter provides the background for that analysis by showing how economists measure the inflation rate using the consumer price index. The consumer price index is a measure of the overall cost of the goods and services bought by a typical consumer. Each month the Australian Bureau of Statistics (ABS) calculates and reports the consumer price index. In this section, we discuss how the consumer price index is calculated and what problems arise in its measurement. We also consider how this index compares with the GDP deflator, another measure of the overall level of prices, which we examined in the last chapter. 116 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 3 The data of macroeconomics 06_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 116 24/08/20 4:31 PM FYI The change to decimal currency Imagine that, instead of the name ‘dollar’, the currency in Australia was called the ‘inflato’. That was one of the names suggested to Prime Minister Holt for the new decimal currency introduced in 1966. The ‘royal’ was the most favoured name, but others suggested were ‘austral’, ‘A.B.C.D.’, ‘aborroo’, ‘anzac’, ‘centimate’, ‘deci-cur’, ‘dollauster’, ‘kanoala’, ‘howzat’, ‘macquarie’, ‘oz’ and ‘sheepsback’. It’s hard to imagine a shopkeeper saying ‘That’ll be five sheepsbacks, please’! The day Australia changed to decimal currency was 14 February 1966. The currency used before the change was the pound (£). One pound was worth 20 shillings, and 1 shilling was worth 12 pence. The conversion rate was $2 for every pound. A shilling became 10 cents, and 1 penny was equivalent to 5/6 of a cent. This is not an exchange rate, though. It is simply the rate chosen for converting old currency to new. If you found a pound in your attic, it would still be equivalent to $2. How much that pound would buy today compared with how much it would have bought 50 years ago is another matter. What we are discussing in this chapter is what happens to the purchasing power of a unit of currency over time as a result of inflation; that is, a rise in the prices of goods and services. At the time of the conversion, people predicted that inflation would result from the change. For example, a box of matches sold for 2 pence in the old currency. At the standard conversion rate of 1 penny to 5/6 of a cent, the price in the new currency would be 1.67 cents. But because there were no units of currency smaller than a cent, this would be rounded up to 2 cents, a price increase of roughly 20 per cent. However, these increases would have occurred only for goods that were very low in price and an insignificant part of anyone’s budget, so the predicted inflationary effects did not occur. Other costs of the conversion included changing accounting machines, cash registers and electronic data processing machines to handle decimal currency. There was a government compensation scheme to help business people with the costs of the changeover. Despite concerns that conversion would be costly and inflationary, the transition to decimal currency was made with relatively little fuss. How the consumer price index is calculated When the ABS calculates the consumer price index and the inflation rate, it uses data on the prices of thousands of goods and services. To see exactly how these statistics are constructed, let’s consider a simple economy in which consumers buy only two goods – coffees and muffins. Table 6.1 shows the five steps that the ABS follows. 1 Fix the basket. The first step in calculating the consumer price index is to determine which prices are most important to the typical consumer. If the typical consumer buys more coffees than muffins, then the price of coffees is more important than the price of muffins and, therefore, should be given greater weight in measuring the cost of living. The ABS sets these weights by surveying consumers and finding the basket of goods and services that the typical consumer buys. In the example in the table, the typical consumer buys a basket of six coffees and eight muffins. 2 Find the prices. The second step in calculating the consumer price index is to find the prices of each of the goods and services in the basket for each point in time. The table shows the prices of muffins and coffees for three different years. 3 Calculate the basket’s cost. The third step is to use the data on prices to calculate the cost of the basket of goods and services at different times. The table shows this calculation for each of the three years. Notice that only the prices in this calculation change. By keeping the basket of goods the same (six coffees and eight muffins), we 117 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 6 Measuring the cost of living 06_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 117 24/08/20 4:31 PM are isolating the effects of price changes from the effect of any quantity changes that might be occurring at the same time. TABLE 6.1 Calculating the consumer price index and the inflation rate: An example This table shows how to calculate the consumer price index and the inflation rate for a hypothetical economy in which consumers buy only coffees and muffins. Step 1: Survey consumers to determine a fixed basket of goods Six coffees, eight muffins Step 2: Find the price of each good in each year Year Price of coffees $ Price of muffins $ 2020 5.00 5.00 2021 6.25 6.50 2022 7.50 7.75 Step 3: Calculate the cost of the basket of goods in each year Year 2020 2021 2022 Cost of basket ($5.00 per coffee × 6 coffees) + ($5.00 per muffin × 8 muffins) = $70.00 ($6.25 per coffee × 6 coffees) + ($6.50 per muffin × 8 muffins) = $89.50 ($7.50 per coffee × 6 coffees) + ($7.75 per muffin × 8 muffins) = $107.00 Calculations $70.00 89.50 107.00 Step 4: C hoose one year as a base year (2020) and calculate the consumer price index in each year Year Consumer price index 2020 ($70/$70) × 100 = 100 100 2021 ($89.50/$70) × 100 = 128 128 2022 ($106/$70) × 100 = 153 153 Step 5: Use the consumer price index to calculate the inflation rate from previous year inflation rate the percentage change in the price index from the preceding period 118 Year Inflation rate 2021 (128 − 100)/100 × 100 = 28% 28% 2022 (153 − 128)/128 × 100 = 20% 20% 4 Choose a base year and calculate the index. The fourth step is to designate one year as the base year, which is the benchmark with which other years are compared. To calculate the index, the price of the basket of goods and services in each year is divided by the price of the basket in the base year and this ratio is then multiplied by 100. The resulting number is the consumer price index. In the example in the table, the year 2020 is the base year. In this year, the basket of muffins and coffees costs $70.00. Therefore, the price of the basket in all years is divided by $70.00 and multiplied by 100. The consumer price index is 100 in 2020. (The index is always 100 in the base year.) The consumer price index is 128 in 2021. This means that the price of the basket in 2021 is 128 per cent of its price in the base year. Put differently, a basket of goods that costs $100 in the base year costs $128 in 2021. Similarly, the consumer price index is 153 in 2022, indicating that the price level in 2022 is 153 per cent of the price level in the base year. 5 Calculate the inflation rate. The fifth and final step is to use the consumer price index to calculate the inflation rate, which is the percentage change in the price index from the preceding period. In our example, the consumer price index rose by 28 per cent from 2020 to 2021 and by 25 per cent from 2021 to 2022. The inflation rate is said to be 28 per cent in 2021 and 20 per cent in 2022. Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 3 The data of macroeconomics 06_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 118 24/08/20 4:31 PM Although this example simplifies the real world by including only two goods, it shows how the ABS calculates the consumer price index and the inflation rate. The ABS collects and processes data on the prices of around 100 000 goods and services at least once each quarter and, by following the five steps described above, determines how quickly the cost of living for the typical consumer is rising. When the ABS makes its quarterly announcement of the inflation rate calculated from the consumer price index, you can usually find the number on any domestic news website, hear the number on the evening news, see it in the next day’s newspaper, or look it up on the ABS website. In addition to the consumer price index for the overall economy, the ABS calculates several other price indexes. It reports the index for the capital cities (Sydney, Melbourne, Perth, Adelaide, Brisbane, Hobart, Darwin and Canberra) as well as for some narrow categories of goods and services (like food, clothing and housing). It also calculates the producer price index, which measures the cost of a basket of goods and services bought by firms rather than by consumers. Because firms eventually pass on their costs to consumers in the form of higher consumer prices, changes in the producer price index are often thought to be useful in predicting changes in the consumer price index. producer price index a measure of the cost of a basket of goods and services bought by firms FYI What is in the CPI’s basket? When constructing the consumer price index, the ABS tries to include all the goods and services that the typical consumer buys. Moreover, it tries to weight these goods and services according to how much consumers buy of each item. Figure 6.1 shows the breakdown of consumer spending into the major categories of goods and services for the 16th series, last updated in 2017. (It is updated about every five years, but the ABS is looking at updating it more frequently because of substitution bias, which is discussed in the following section.) FIGURE 6.1 The basket of goods and services Education 4% Clothing & footwear 3% Communication 3% Health 6% Insurance & financial services 6% Alcohol & tobacco 7% Furnishings, household equipment & services 9% Housing 23% Food & nonalcoholic beverages 16% Transport Recreation & culture 10% 13% Housing Food & non-alcoholic beverages Recreation & culture Transport Furnishings, household equipment & services Alcohol & tobacco Insurance & financial services Health Education Clothing & footwear Communication This figure shows how the typical consumer divides his or her spending among various categories of goods and services. The ABS calls each percentage the ‘relative importance’ of the category. Source: ABS Data, Cat. No. 6470.0.55.002 119 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 6 Measuring the cost of living 06_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 119 24/08/20 4:31 PM The basics of living are the most significant categories. Housing and household contents and services make up the largest component of the typical consumer’s budget, at 32.1 per cent. Housing (23.1 per cent) includes rent, utilities, property rates and repairs and maintenance. Furnishing, household equipment and services (8.9 per cent) include furniture, large and small appliances, and household supplies like laundry soaps and garbage bags. The next largest category at 15.8 per cent is food and nonalcoholic beverages; this includes food at home (just under 10 per cent) and food away from home (just under 6 per cent). Alcoholic beverages and tobacco products are in a separate category (7.4 per cent). The next category, at 12.6 per cent, is recreation and culture. Then comes transport, at 10.5 per cent, which includes spending on cars, petrol, buses, trains and so on. Next is health, and insurance and financial services, both just under 6 per cent, then education at just above 4 per cent. Clothing and footwear (3.3 per cent) and communication (2.6 per cent ) make up the last two segments. LO6.2 Problems in measuring the cost of living The consumer price index is a measure of the aggregate price level in the economy. The goal of the index is to measure changes in the cost of living. In other words, the consumer price index can be used to gauge how much incomes must rise in order to maintain a constant standard of living. The consumer price index, however, is not a perfect measure of the cost of living. Three problems with the index are widely acknowledged but difficult to solve. The first problem is called substitution bias. When prices change from one year to the next, they do not all change proportionately – some prices rise by more than others. Consumers respond to these differing price changes by buying less of the goods whose prices have risen by large amounts and by buying more of the goods whose prices have risen less or have even fallen. That is, consumers substitute goods that have become relatively less expensive. Yet the consumer price index is calculated assuming a fixed basket of goods. By not taking into account the possibility of consumer substitution, the index overstates the increase in the cost of living from one year to the next. IN THE NEWS What happens when prices don’t go up very much? What does it tell us when prices on average are not going up very much? You’d think this is a good thing, but you might have to think again. Even though it means households pay less on average for their basic items, it also is a sign that the economy is slowing down. And that’s not such a good thing. Inflation undershoots in Australia – why it’s a concern, is the RBA running out of ammo & what it means for investors? Dr Shane Oliver, Head of Investment Strategy and Economics and Chief Economist, AMP Capital Sydney, Australia, 29 April 2019 Introduction Surprisingly weak Australian inflation has led to expectations the Reserve Bank will soon cut rates. But what’s driving low inflation? Is it really that bad? Why not just lower the inflation target? Will rate cuts help? And what does it mean for investors? Inflation surprises on the downside again Australian inflation as measured by the CPI was flat in the March quarter and up just 1.3% over the last year. Sure, the zero outcome in the quarter was partly due to a nearly 9% decline in petrol prices and they have since rebounded to some degree. And highprofile items like food, health and education are up 2.3%, 3.1% and 2.9% respectively 120 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 3 The data of macroeconomics 06_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 120 24/08/20 4:31 PM FIGURE 6.2 Australian inflation running below target range 7 GST impact 6 Underlying inflation (avg of mean & median) Annual % change 5 4 Target band 3 2 1 Headline inflation 0 –1 93 95 97 99 01 03 05 07 09 11 13 15 17 19 Source: Dr Shane Oliver/AMP Capital, ABS Data, https://www.ampcapital.com/au/en/insights-hub/articles/2019/ april/inflation-undershoots-in-australia-why-its-a-concern from a year ago. But against this, price weakness is widespread in areas like clothing, rents, household equipment & services and communications. [See Figure 6.2.] But why the focus on ‘underlying inflation’? The increase in the CPI is the best measure of changes in the cost of living. But it can be distorted in the short term by often volatile moves in some items that are due to things like world oil prices, the weather and government-administered prices that are unrelated to supply and demand pressures in the economy. So, economists and policymakers like the RBA focus on what is called underlying inflation to get a handle on underlying price pressures in the economy so as not to jump at shadows. There are various ways of measuring this ranging from excluding items like food and energy as in the US version of core inflation, to excluding items whose prices are largely government administered to statistical measures that exclude items that have volatile moves in each quarter (as with the trimmed mean and weighed median measures of inflation). Right now they all show the same thing, i.e. that underlying inflation is low, ranging between 1.2% to 1.6% year on year. The average of the trimmed mean and weighted median measures is shown in the previous chart and is averaging 1.4%. The common criticism of underlying inflation that ‘if you exclude everything there is no inflation’ is funny but irrelevant. The point is that both headline and underlying inflation are below the RBA’s 2–3% target and this has been the case for almost four years now. [See Figure 6.3.] What is driving low inflation? The weakness in inflation is evident globally. Using the US definition, core (ex food & energy) inflation is just 1.8% in the US, 0.8% in the Eurozone, 0.4% in Japan and 1.8% in China. Several factors have driven the ongoing softness in inflation including: the sub-par recovery in global demand since the GFC which has left high levels of spare capacity in product markets and underutilisation of labour; intense competition exacerbated by technological innovation (online sales, Uber, Airbnb, etc); and softish commodity prices. All of which has meant that companies lack pricing power & workers lack bargaining power. Why not just lower the inflation target? Some suggest that the RBA should just lower its inflation target. This reminds me of a similar argument back in 2007–08, when inflation had pushed above 4%, that the RBA should just raise its inflation target. Such arguments are nonsense. First, the whole point of having an inflation 121 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 6 Measuring the cost of living 06_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 121 24/08/20 4:31 PM FIGURE 6.3 Core inflation: US, Japan, Eurozone & China 3 US China Annual % change 2 1 Eurozone 0 Japan –1 –2 00 02 04 06 08 10 12 14 16 18 Source: Dr Shane Oliver/AMP Capital, Bloomberg, https://www.ampcapital.com/au/en/insights-hub/ articles/2019/april/inflation-undershoots-in-australia-why-its-a-concern target is to anchor inflation expectations. If the target is just raised or lowered each time it’s breached for a while then those expectations – which workers use to form wage demands and companies use in setting wages and prices – will simply move up or down depending on which way inflation and the target moves. And so inflationary or deflationary shocks will turn into permanent shifts up or down in inflation. Inflation targeting would just lose all credibility. Second, there are problems with allowing too-low inflation. Most central bank inflation targets are set at 2% or so because statistical measures of inflation tend to overstate actual inflation by 1–2% because statisticians have trouble actually adjusting for quality improvements and so some measured price rises often reflect quality improvements. In other words, 1.3% inflation as currently measured could mean we are actually in deflation. And there are problems with deflation. What’s wrong with falling prices (deflation) anyway? Deflation refers to persistent and generalised price falls. It occurred in the 1800s, 1930s and the last 20 years in Japan. Most people would see falling prices as good because they can buy more with their income. However, deflation can be good or bad. In the period 1870–1895 in the US, deflation occurred against a background of strong growth, reflecting rapid technological innovation. This can be called ‘good deflation’. However, falling prices are not good if they are associated with falling wages, rising unemployment, falling asset prices and rising real debt burdens. For example, in the 1930s and more recently in Japan. This is ‘bad deflation’. Given high debt levels, sustained deflation could cause big problems. Falling wages and prices would make it harder to service debts. Lower nominal growth will make high public debt levels harder to pay off. And when prices fall people put off decisions to spend and invest, which could threaten economic growth. This could risk a debt deflation spiral of falling asset prices and falling incomes leading to rising debt burdens, increasing defaults, spurring more falls in asset prices, etc. The problem for RBA credibility? The problem for the RBA is that inflation has been undershooting its forecasts and the target for several years now. The longer this persists the more the RBA will lose credibility, seeing low inflation expectations become entrenched making it harder to get inflation back to target and leaving Australia vulnerable to deflation in the next economic downturn. [See Figure 6.4.] 122 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 3 The data of macroeconomics 06_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 122 24/08/20 4:31 PM FIGURE 6.4 RBA inflation forecasts risk losing credibility 3.5 3.0 Feb 14 Annual % change Feb 12 Feb 17 Feb 15 2.5 Feb 16 Feb 13 2.0 Feb 19 Actual underlying inflation 1.5 1.0 Mar-10 Mar-12 Mar-14 Mar-16 Feb 18 Mar-18 Mar-20 Source: Dr Shane Oliver/AMP Capital, RBA, Bloomberg, https://www.ampcapital.com/au/en/insights-hub/ articles/2019/april/inflation-undershoots-in-australia-why-its-a-concern Due to the slowdown in economic growth flowing partly from the housing downturn we have been looking for two rate cuts this year since last December. We had thought that the RBA would prefer to wait till after the election is out of the way before starting to move and coming fiscal stimulus from July also supports the case to wait as does the still strong labour market. However, with underlying inflation coming in much weaker than expected the RBA [probably feels] its arguably too risky to wait until unemployment starts to trend up. And the RBA has moved in both the 2007 and 2013 election campaigns. So, while it’s a close call our base case is now for the first rate cut to occur at the RBA’s May meeting. Failing that, then in June. Source: Dr Shane Oliver/AMP Capital, ABS Data, https://www.ampcapital.com/au/en/insights -hub/articles/2019/april/inflation-undershoots-in -australia-why-its-a-concern Let’s consider a simple example. Imagine that, in the base year, bananas are much cheaper than coffees and so consumers buy more bananas than coffees. When the ABS constructs the basket of goods, it will include more bananas than coffees. But think about what happens when the price of bananas rises dramatically due to storms, like it did in 2007 and 2010. Consumers will naturally respond to the price changes by buying more coffees and fewer bananas. Yet, when calculating the consumer price index, the ABS uses a fixed basket, which in essence assumes that consumers continue buying the now-expensive bananas in the same quantities as before. For this reason, the index will measure a much larger increase in the cost of living than consumers actually perceive. The second problem with the consumer price index is the introduction of new goods. When a new good is introduced, consumers have more variety from which to choose. Greater variety, in turn, makes each dollar more valuable, so consumers need fewer dollars to maintain any given standard of living. Yet because the consumer price index is based on a fixed basket of goods, it does not reflect this change in the purchasing power of the dollar. Again, let’s consider an example. When streaming services like Spotify and Apple Music were introduced, consumers could access all kinds of music on their devices without having to purchase individual albums or songs, no matter where they were. These new services increased consumers’ wellbeing by expanding their consumption choices. A perfect costof-living index would reflect this change as a decrease in the cost of living. The consumer 123 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 6 Measuring the cost of living 06_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 123 24/08/20 4:31 PM price index, however, did not decrease in response to the introduction of streaming services. The ABS revises the basket of goods to include new services, but the category ‘Audio, visual and computing media and services’ is only 0.7 percent of the consumer price index, and streaming services would be a very small part of this category, so reductions in the cost of living associated with streaming services would not show up in the index. The third problem with the consumer price index is unmeasured quality change. If the quality of a good deteriorates from one year to the next, the value of a dollar falls, even if the price of the good stays the same. (A dollar buys a good of lower quality.) Similarly, if the quality rises from one year to the next, the value of a dollar rises. The ABS does its best to account for quality change. When the quality of a good in the basket changes – for example, when a car model has more horsepower or gets better petrol consumption per kilometre from one year to the next – the ABS adjusts the price of the good to account for the quality change. It is, in essence, trying to calculate the price of a basket of goods of constant quality. Nonetheless, changes in quality remain a problem, because quality is so hard to measure. There is still much debate among economists about how severe these measurement problems are and what should be done about them. The issue is important because many government programs use the consumer price index to adjust for changes in the overall level of prices. Some economists have suggested modifying these programs to correct for the measurement problems. For example, most studies conclude that the consumer price index overstates inflation by 0.5 to 2.0 percentage points per year. In response to these findings, the federal government could change benefits programs so that benefits increased every year by the measured inflation rate minus one percentage point. Such a change would provide a crude way of offsetting the measurement problems and, at the same time, reduce benefits outlays significantly. LO6.3 The GDP deflator versus the consumer price index In the preceding chapter, we saw another measure of the overall level of prices in the economy – the GDP deflator. The GDP deflator is the ratio of nominal GDP to real GDP. Because nominal GDP is current output valued at current prices and real GDP is current output valued at base-year prices, the GDP deflator reflects the current level of prices relative to the level of prices in the base year. Economists and policymakers monitor both the GDP deflator and the consumer price index to gauge how quickly prices are rising. Usually, these two statistics tell a similar story. Yet there are two important differences that can cause them to diverge. The first difference is that the GDP deflator reflects the prices of all goods and services produced domestically, whereas the consumer price index reflects the prices of all goods and services bought by consumers. For example, suppose that the price of a ship produced by Australian shipbuilders and sold to the Navy rises. Even though the ship is part of GDP, it is not part of the basket of goods and services bought by a typical consumer. Thus, the price increase shows up in the GDP deflator but not in the consumer price index. As another example, suppose that Subaru raises the price of its cars. Because Subarus are made in Japan, the car is not part of Australian GDP. But some Australian consumers do buy Subarus and so the car is part of the typical consumer’s basket of goods. Hence, a price increase in an imported consumption good, like a Subaru, shows up in the consumer price index but not in the GDP deflator. 124 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 3 The data of macroeconomics 06_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 124 24/08/20 4:31 PM This first difference between the consumer price index and the GDP deflator is particularly important if a country imports a significant proportion of its oil. As a result, oil and oil products like petrol and heating oil are a much larger share of consumer spending than they are of GDP. When the price of oil rises, the consumer price index rises by much more than does the GDP deflator. This is more significant in some countries than others. Australia is a net exporter of oil products, so a change in the price of oil is reflected both in the GDP deflator and the consumer price index. The second and more subtle difference between the GDP deflator and the consumer price index concerns how various prices are weighted to yield a single number for the overall level of prices. The consumer price index compares the price of a fixed basket of goods and services with the price of the basket in the base year. The ABS changes the basket of goods once every four or five years. In contrast, the GDP deflator compares the price of currently produced goods and services with the price of the same goods and services in the base year. Thus, the group of goods and services used to calculate the GDP deflator changes automatically over time. This difference is not important when all prices are changing proportionately. But if the prices of different goods and services are changing by varying amounts, the way we weight the various prices matters for the overall inflation rate. Figure 6.5 shows the inflation rate as measured by both the GDP deflator and the consumer price index for each year since 1970. You can see that sometimes the two measures diverge. When they do diverge, it is possible to go behind these numbers and explain the divergence with the two differences we have discussed. The figure shows, however, that divergence between these two measures is the exception rather than the rule. In the mid1970s, both the GDP deflator and the consumer price index show high rates of inflation. In the mid-1980s and mid-1990s, both measures showed low rates of inflation. FIGURE 6.5 Two measures of inflation 20.0 15.0 % per year GDP price delfator 10.0 CPI 5.0 0.0 –5 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 2015 2020 Year This figure shows the inflation rate – the percentage change in the level of prices – as measured by the GDP deflator and the consumer price index using annual data since 1970. Notice that the two measures of inflation generally move together. Source: ABS Data, Cat Nos 5206.05, 6401.06 125 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 6 Measuring the cost of living 06_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 125 24/08/20 4:31 PM Source: B. Rich/Hedgeye https://app.hedgeye.com/insights/37735-cartoon-of-the-day-inflationt-rex?type=cartoons CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING Explain briefly what the consumer price index is trying to measure. How does the consumer price index differ from the GDP deflator? LO6.4 Correcting economic variables for the effects of inflation The purpose of measuring the overall level of prices in the economy is to permit comparison between dollar figures from different points in time. Now that we know how price indexes are calculated, let’s see how we might use such an index to compare a dollar figure from the past with a dollar figure in the present. Dollar figures from different times We first return to the issue of Phar Lap’s winnings. Were his earnings of $19 000 in 1930 high or low compared with the earnings in today’s race? To answer this question, we need to know the level of prices in 1930 and the level of prices today. Part of the increase in prize money just compensates the owners of racehorses for the higher level of prices today. To compare Phar Lap’s winnings with those of today’s horses, we need to inflate Phar Lap’s winnings to turn 1930 dollars into today’s dollars. A price index determines the size of this inflation correction. (Remember that Phar Lap’s earnings were in pounds, but we are using the equivalent dollar amounts.) The Reserve Bank of Australia shows a price index of 2.7 for 1930 and 112.9 for 2018. (The base year is 2012.) Thus, the overall level of prices has risen by a factor of 41.8 (which 126 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 3 The data of macroeconomics 06_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 126 24/08/20 4:31 PM equals 112.9/2.7). We can use these numbers to measure Phar Lap’s winnings in 2016 dollars. The calculation is: Winnings in 1930 × Price level in 2018 Winnings in 2018 = Price level in 1930 19 000 × 112.9 = 794 730 2.7 We find that Phar Lap’s 1930 winnings are equivalent to winnings today of about $795 000. That is a lot of money for a horse, but nothing like the Melbourne Cup winner’s earnings 2018. It is not even as much as what the second-placed horse receives. The example does show that it is important to make these comparisons using the same dollars. Over three-quarters of a million dollars looks much better than $19 000. Let’s also examine Prime Minister Scullin’s 1930 salary of £1000, or roughly $2000. To translate that figure into 2018 dollars, we again multiply the ratio of the price levels in the two years. We find that Scullin’s salary is equivalent to $2000 × (112.9.7/2.7), or $83 656 in 2018 dollars. This is well below the current Prime Minister’s salary of $538 460. It seems that Prime Minister Scullin did not earn very much compared with the famous racehorse or today’s prime minister. = Indexation As we have just seen, price indexes are used to correct for the effects of inflation when comparing dollar figures from different times. This type of correction shows up in many places in the economy. When some dollar amount is automatically corrected for inflation by law or contract, the amount is said to be indexed for inflation. For example, for many years, the basic wage in Australia was indexed to the consumer price index. Such a provision automatically raises the wage whenever the consumer price index rises. Indexation is also a feature of many laws. Pension benefits, for example, are frequently adjusted to compensate the elderly for increases in prices. There are, however, many ways in which the tax system is not indexed for inflation, even when perhaps it should be. For example, the brackets of income tax – the income levels at which the tax rates change – are not indexed for inflation. We discuss these issues more fully when we discuss the costs of inflation later in this book. indexation the automatic correction of a dollar amount for the effects of inflation by law or contract LO6.5 Real and nominal interest rates Correcting economic variables for the effects of inflation is particularly important, and somewhat tricky, when we look at data on interest rates. When you deposit your savings in a bank account, you will earn interest on your deposit. Conversely, when you borrow from a bank to pay for a car, you will pay interest on your loan. Interest represents a payment in the future for a transfer of money in the past. As a result, interest rates always involve comparing amounts of money at different points in time. To fully understand interest rates, we need to know how to correct for the effects of inflation. Let’s consider an example. Suppose that Sally Saver deposits $1000 in a bank account that pays an annual interest rate of 10 per cent. After a year passes, Sally has accumulated $100 in interest. Sally then withdraws her $1100. Is Sally $100 richer than she was when she made the deposit a year earlier? The answer depends on what we mean by the word ‘richer’. Sally does have $100 more than she had before. In other words, the number of dollars has risen by 10 per cent. But if prices have risen at the same time, each dollar now buys less than it did a year ago. Thus, her purchasing power has not risen by 10 per cent. If the inflation rate was 4 per cent, then the 127 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 6 Measuring the cost of living 06_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 127 24/08/20 4:31 PM nominal interest rate the interest rate as usually reported without a correction for the effects of inflation real interest rate the interest rate corrected for the effects of inflation amount of goods she can buy has increased by only 6 per cent. And if the inflation rate was 15 per cent, then the price of goods has increased proportionately more than the number of dollars in her account. In that case, Sally’s purchasing power has actually fallen by 5 per cent. The interest rate that the bank pays is called the nominal interest rate, and the interest rate corrected for inflation is called the real interest rate. We can write the relationship of the nominal interest rate, the real interest rate and inflation as follows: Real interest rate = Nominal interest rate − Inflation rate The real interest rate is the difference between the nominal interest rate and the rate of inflation. The nominal interest rate tells you how fast the number of dollars in your bank account rises over time. The real interest rate tells you how fast the purchasing power of your bank account rises over time. Figure 6.6 shows real and nominal interest rates in Australia since 1970. The nominal interest rate is the interest rate on 90-day bank bills. The real interest rate is calculated by subtracting inflation – the percentage change in the consumer price index – from this nominal interest rate. FIGURE 6.6 Real and nominal interest rates 20 Inflation rate Interest rates (% per year) 15 Nominal interest rate 10 5 0 Real interest rate –5 –10 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 Year 2000 2005 2010 2015 2020 This figure shows nominal and real interest rates using annual data since 1970. The nominal interest rate is the rate on a 90-day bank bill. The real interest rate is the nominal interest rate minus the inflation rate as measured by changes in the consumer price index. Notice the nominal and real interest rates often do not move together. Source: Reserve Bank of Australia Bulletin, 2018 IN THE NEWS Mr Index goes to Hollywood What was the most popular film of all time? As the following article notes, answering this question requires an understanding of price indexes. Winner and still champ Director James Cameron has directed several well-known movies, including two of the most successful Hollywood films ever made – Titanic and Avatar. It had been over a decade since Cameron had directed Titanic, when he told producer Greg Coote about Avatar. He said ‘[It’s] a science-fiction environmental action film. I’ve been working on the 128 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 3 The data of macroeconomics 06_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 128 24/08/20 4:31 PM Getty Images/Bettmann script since 1994, before I’d even started Titanic. It’s set in the year 2154 on a moon in the Alpha Centauri system called Pandora.’ Coote apparently responded, ‘What . . . Terminator vs. Alien? The Sinking of the Lusitania?’ Obviously, he was not impressed. But Cameron’s Avatar went on to gross nearly US$3 billion. Surely, that’s the highest grossing movie ever? Well, not really. It’s a lot of money, but when you adjust the earnings for inflation, Titanic (#5) outdoes Avatar (#15), but Gone with the Wind, released in 1939, outdoes them all. The Box Office Mojo website lists the top-grossing films of all time using today’s dollars. In 1939, a ticket to the movies cost about $0.25. Today a movie ticket is about $9.00 – an increase of over 3000%! The chart below lists the all-time highest grossing movies in dollars of the day and adjusted for inflation. Notice how few of the movies in the adjusted list were made since 2000. This list tells ‘Frankly, my dear, I don’t give a us a lot about the effects of inflation . . . and that damn about the effects of inflation.’ movies aren’t as popular as they used to be. Domestic grosses: Adjusted for ticket price inflation Rank Title Adjusted gross Unadjusted gross Year 1 Gone with the Wind $1 895 421 694 $200 852 579 1939 2 Star Wars [ep. 4: A New Hope] $1 668 979 715 $460 998 507 1977 3 The Sound of Music $1 335 086 324 $159 287 539 1965 4 E.T.: The Extra-Terrestrial $1 329 174 791 $435 110 554 1982 5 Titanic $1 270 101 626 $659 363 944 1997 6 The Ten Commandments $1 227 470 000 $65 500 000 1956 7 Jaws $1 200 098 356 $260 000 000 1975 8 Doctor Zhivago $1 163 149 635 $111 721 910 1965 9 The Exorcist $1 036 314 504 $232 906 145 1973 $1 021 330 000 $184 925 486 1937 $1 013 038 487 $936 662 225 2015 10 11 Snow White and the Seven Dwarfs Star Wars: Episode VII: The Force Awakens 12 101 Dalmatians $936 225 101 $144 880 014 1961 13 Star Wars: Episode V: The Empire Strikes Back $919 244 787 $290 271 960 1980 14 Ben-Hur $918 699 453 $74 422 622 1959 15 Avatar $911 790 952 $760 507 625 2009 16 Avengers: Endgame $892 669 593 $858 373 000 2019 17 Star Wars: Episode VI: Return of the Jedi $881 336 578 $309 306 177 1983 18 Jurassic Park $858 893 554 $402 828 120 1993 19 Star Wars: Episode I – The Phantom Menace $846 224 377 $474 544 677 1999 20 The Lion King $835 301 768 $422 783 777 1994 Source: Box Office Mojo, http://www.boxofficemojo.com 129 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 6 Measuring the cost of living 06_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 129 24/08/20 4:31 PM You can see that real and nominal interest rates do not always move together. For example, in the mid-1970s, nominal interest rates were high. But since inflation was very high, real interest rates were low. Indeed, in some years, real interest rates were negative, for inflation eroded people’s savings more quickly than nominal interest payments increased them. In contrast, in both 1985 and 1990, even though nominal interest rates were high, low inflation meant that real interest rates were relatively high. In the coming chapters, when we study the causes and effects of changes in interest rates, it will be important for us to keep in mind the distinction between real and nominal interest rates. CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING If the real interest rate is 3.5 per cent and the nominal interest rate is 5 per cent, then what is the inflation rate? Conclusion When McDonald’s was introduced into Australia, a Big Mac, fries and a Coke cost about a dollar. Now the same meal costs about $11 (if purchased separately). A dollar’s not worth what it used to be. Indeed, throughout recent history, the purchasing power of the dollar has not been stable. Persistent increases in the overall level of prices have been the norm. Such inflation reduces the purchasing power of each unit of money over time. When comparing dollar figures from different times, it is important to keep in mind that a dollar today is not the same as a dollar 20 years ago or, most likely, 20 years from now. This chapter has discussed how economists measure the overall level of prices in the economy and how they use price indexes to correct economic variables for the effects of inflation. This analysis is only a starting point. We have not yet examined the causes and effects of inflation or how inflation interacts with other economic variables. To do that, we need to go beyond issues of measurement. Indeed, that is our next task. Having explained how economists measure macroeconomic quantities and prices in the past chapters, we are now ready to develop the models that explain long-run and short-run movements in these variables. 130 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 3 The data of macroeconomics 06_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 130 24/08/20 4:31 PM LO6.1 The consumer price index shows the cost of a basket of goods and services relative to the cost of the same basket in the base year. The index is used to measure the overall level of prices in the economy. The percentage change in the consumer price index measures the inflation rate. LO6.2 The consumer price index is an imperfect measure of the cost of living for three reasons. First, it does not take into account consumers’ ability to substitute goods that become relatively cheaper over time. Second, it does not take into account increases in the purchasing power of the dollar due to the introduction of new goods. Third, it is distorted by unmeasured changes in the quality of goods and services. Because of these measurement problems, the consumer price index overstates annual inflation by about one percentage point. LO6.3 Although the GDP deflator also measures the overall level of prices in the economy, it differs from the consumer price index because it includes goods and services produced rather than goods and services consumed. As a result, imported goods affect the consumer price index but not the GDP deflator. In addition, whereas the consumer price index uses a fixed basket of goods, the GDP deflator automatically changes the group of goods and services over time as the composition of GDP changes. LO6.4 Dollar figures from different points in time cannot be used to make valid comparisons of purchasing power. To compare a dollar figure from the past with a dollar figure today, the older figure should be inflated using a price index. Various laws and private contracts use price indexes to correct for the effects of inflation. The tax laws, however, are only partially indexed for inflation. LO6.5 A correction for inflation is especially important when looking at data on interest rates. The nominal interest rate is the interest rate usually reported; it is the rate at which the number of dollars in a savings account increases over time. In contrast, the real interest rate takes into account changes in the value of the dollar over time. The real interest rate equals the nominal interest rate minus the rate of inflation. STUDY TOOLS Summary Key concepts consumer price index (CPI), p. 116 indexation, p. 127 inflation, p. 116 inflation rate, p. 118 nominal interest rate, p. 128 producer price index, p. 119 real interest rate, p. 128 Practice questions Questions for review 1 2 3 4 5 Which do you think has a greater effect on the consumer price index: An 8 per cent increase in the price of an iPhone or an 8 per cent increase in the price of electricity? Why? Explain briefly the three problems associated with measuring the cost of living. If the price of a Royal Australian Air Force fighter jet rises, is the consumer price index or the GDP deflator affected more? Why? If you were a government official deciding to increase the pension age to 70, would you have to take inflation into account in any way? Explain. If you were a businesswoman trying to decide on a 10-year investment in a service industry in Australia, would you use the same measure? Why or why not? Explain the meaning of nominal interest rate and real interest rate. How are they related? Multiple choice 1 Housing is just over 20% of the basket of goods contained in the CPI. If the cost of housing rises, then the CPI will a rise by the same amount. b rise by less than the rise in the cost of housing. 131 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 6 Measuring the cost of living 06_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 131 24/08/20 4:31 PM 2 3 4 5 c rise or fall depending on what happens to the prices of other goods in the basket. d fall as housing isn’t very important in the CPI. If you borrow money at 7%, and the inflation rate is on average 4% over the life of your loan, then the amount you pay back in real terms is: a 9% b 6% c 3% d greater than what you borrowed. If Apple doubled the price of Apple Music, it would cause the CPI to a double. b go up by less than double. c remain unaffected because people would shift to Spotify. d go up by the percentage increase in Apple Music weighted by how significant Apple music is in the CPI. Which of the following are reasons why the CPI should not be used to measure the cost of living in Australia: a If the price of a good goes up, people look for cheaper substitutes. b The CPI measures prices in all capital cities in Australia. c The CPI is updated frequently to account for the introduction of new goods and services. d The base year changes from time to time. Uber has been introduced into several cities in Australia. As a result, the price of getting rides around these cities has fallen. This will have the following impact on the CPI: a It will cause the CPI to fall as the price of rides has fallen. b It will have no effect because Uber is not currently counted in the CPI. c It will increase the CPI as taxi fares will have to rise as a result of fewer passengers in taxis. d It will have a big impact because it is such a good way to travel. Problems and applications 1 Suppose that people consume only three goods, as shown in this table: Computers Sushi Boost Juice® 2020 price $20 $175 $4.50 2020 quantity 100 10 200 2021 price $24 $240 $5 2021 quantity 100 10 200 a 2 3 Calculate the percentage change in the price of each of the three goods. What is the percentage change in the overall price level? b Does sushi become more or less expensive relative to Boost Juice? Does the wellbeing of some people change relative to the wellbeing of others? Explain. Suppose that the residents of Veggieland spend all of their income on cauliflower, broccoli and carrots. In 2020, they buy 75 heads of cauliflower for $100, 50 bunches of broccoli for $120 and 600 carrots for $90. In 2021 they buy 60 heads of cauliflower for $200, 60 bunches of broccoli for $150 and 600 carrots for $150. If the base year is 2020, what is the CPI in both years? What is the inflation rate in 2021? From 1950 to 2016 the consumer price index in Australia rose around 2600 per cent. Use this fact to adjust each of the following 1950 prices for the effects of inflation. Which items cost less in 2016 than in 1950 after adjusting for inflation? Which items cost more? Item 1950 price 2020 price A day at the footy $0.25 $76 Woman’s Day magazine $0.05 $4.40 Orange juice $0.12 $6.95 $700.00 $42 000.00 $1.28 $11.20 A Holden ‘BT1’ commodore sedan Sending a package by air from Melbourne to Germany 132 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 3 The data of macroeconomics 06_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 132 24/08/20 4:31 PM 4 In late 2012, Uber launched in Australia. The price of getting driven around Australia’s capital cities suddenly got cheaper. But taxis drivers complained that Uber wasn’t as safe as taking a taxi. If you were the chief statistician for the ABS, how would you change the CPI to reflect the increased use of Uber? Could you simply say the price of taxi fares went down? 5 Which of the problems in the construction of the CPI might be illustrated by each of the following situations? Explain. a the invention of the Fitbit b the introduction of zero-emission cars c decreased purchases of beef in response to an increase in its price d more scoops of sultanas in each package of Sultana Bran® e increased purchases of the Smart car 6 The Age newspaper cost $0.05 in 1970 and $2.50 in 2016. The average wage in manufacturing was $3.35 per hour in 1970 and $45 per hour in 2016. a By what percentage did the price of a newspaper rise? b By what percentage did the wage rise? c In each year, how many minutes does a worker have to work to earn enough to buy a newspaper? d Did workers’ purchasing power in terms of newspapers rise or fall? 7 For years, British citizens who are resident in Australia have tried to convince the UK government to index the pensions they receive, just as they would be if they were in the UK. But the UK government has steadfastly refused to index the pensions of British people who have settled in Australia for their retirement. a If you were a British citizen contemplating retirement in the Aussie sunshine, how would the lack of indexing affect your decisions? What could you do to overcome the disadvantage of having a pension that wasn’t indexed? b Suppose Australia’s inflation rate is 2 per cent per year and the UK’s inflation rate is 4 per cent per year. If the UK government indexed all pensions, would British people who had migrated to Australia be better or worse off than if they’d stayed in the UK (ignoring the impact of nicer weather in Australia)? c Now suppose that inflation and indexing are as suggested in part (b), but Australia has a much higher rate of increase in the price of health care. How does that change your answer to part (b)? 8 Suppose that a borrower and a lender agree on the nominal interest rate to be paid on a loan. Then inflation turns out to be higher than they both expected. a Is the real interest rate on this loan higher or lower than expected? b Does the lender gain or lose from this unexpectedly high inflation? Does the borrower gain or lose? c If you were taking out a mortgage today, how would your expectations about inflation in the next 10 years affect your decision about whether to fix your mortgage rate or let it vary? 9 Since the Global Financial Crisis of 2008–09, inflation has actually been much lower than people expected it to be. How has this impacted on homeowners who are on fixed-rate mortgages in the mid-2000s? How did it affect the banks that lent them the money? 10 The chapter defines the real interest rate as the nominal interest rate less inflation. Because, under Australian tax laws, nominal interest income is taxed, we can define the after-tax real interest rate as the nominal interest rate after taxes, less inflation. a Suppose that the inflation rate is 1 per cent, the nominal interest rate is 1.5 per cent, and the tax rate is 37 per cent. What is the real interest rate? What is the after-tax real interest rate? What is the effective tax rate on real interest income (the percentage reduction in real interest income due to taxes)? b Now suppose that the inflation rate rises to 3 per cent, and the nominal interest rate rises to 3 per cent. What is the real interest rate now? What is the after-tax real interest rate? What is the effective tax rate on real interest income? c Some economists argue that because of our tax system, inflation discourages saving. Use your answers to parts (a) and (b) to explain this view. 11 In Australia, income tax brackets are not indexed. When inflation pushed up nominal incomes, what do you think happened to real tax revenue? (Hint: This phenomenon is known as ‘bracket creep’.) 133 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 6 Measuring the cost of living 06_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 133 24/08/20 4:31 PM PART PARTFOUR ONE Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 07_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 134 24/08/20 6:12 PM The real economy in the long run Chapter 7 Production and growth Chapter 8 Saving, investment and the financial system Chapter 9 The natural rate of unemployment Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 07_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 135 24/08/20 6:12 PM 7 Production and growth Learning objectives After reading this chapter, you should be able to: LO7.1 understand economic growth around the world LO7.2 understand the role of productivity and its determinants LO7.3 examine economic growth and public policy. 136 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 07_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 136 24/08/20 6:12 PM Introduction When you travel around the world, you see tremendous variation in the standard of living. The average person in a high-income country, like Australia, the United States, or Norway, has an income more than 20 times as high as the average person in a low-income country, like Bangladesh, Kenya, or Haiti. Figure 7.1 shows a map that is a visual representation of these differences, whereby darker colours represent higher income per person (adjusted for the purchasing power to be comparable across countries). FIGURE 7.1 Economic prosperity differs substantially across countries GDP per capita, 2016 No Data $0 $5000 $10,000 $20,000 $30,000 $40,000 >$50,000 The figure shows 2016 GDP per person across the globe in US dollars (adjusted for differences in price levels). Source: Maddison Project Database, version 2018. Bolt, Jutta, Robert Inklaar, Herman de Jong and Jan Luiten van Zanden (2018), “Rebasing ‘Maddison’: new income comparisons and the shape of long-run economic development”, Maddison Project Working paper 10 (CC BY 4.0) These large differences in production and incomes are reflected in large differences in the quality of life. Richer countries not only have more cars and more televisions, but they also have better health care and nutrition, higher literacy rates, lower child mortality and longer life expectancy. Even within a country, there are large changes in the standard of living over time. In Australia over the past 100 years, average income as measured by real GDP per person has grown by about 1.6 per cent per year (using the Maddison project data available at http:// www.ggdc.net/maddison/maddison-project/home.htm). Although 1.6 per cent might seem a small number, this rate of growth has led to average income today being nearly five times as high as average income a century ago. As a result, the typical Australian enjoys much greater economic prosperity today than back in the early twentieth century. Income growth rates vary substantially from country to country. In some East Asian countries, like Hong Kong, Singapore, South Korea and Taiwan, average income has risen around 4 to 7 per cent per year in recent decades. At this rate, average income doubles every 10 to 17.5 years. These countries have, in the length of two generations, gone from being fairly poor to being among the richest in the world. In contrast, in countries like Venezuela, North Korea or some in sub-Saharan Africa, average income has been stagnant for several decades. Zimbabwe has had one of the worst growth experiences: From 1991 to 2014, income per person fell by a total of 60 per cent. 137 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN Chapter 02-200-202 7 Production and growth 07_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 137 24/08/20 6:12 PM economic growth increases in real GDP (and prosperity) over time The effects of these differences in growth rates can be seen in Australia. Even though the typical Australian enjoys a greater level of economic prosperity now relative to his or her ancestors, the standard of living in Australia has not increased as rapidly as it has in some other countries. For example, in 1870, GDP per capita in Australia was 1.35 times GDP per capita in the United States. By 1992, Australian GDP per capita was only about 0.74 times US GDP per capita (although in 2014 it was already 0.85 times). The fact that Australia slipped in the rankings of GDP per capita is not necessarily cause for concern, but it does indicate that the Australian economy has not always performed as well as it perhaps could. What explains these diverse experiences? How can wealthy countries be sure to maintain their high standard of living? What policies should low-income countries pursue to prosper? These are among the most important questions in macroeconomics. As economist Robert Lucas put it (1988, p. 5): ‘The consequences for human welfare in questions like these are simply staggering: Once one starts to think about them, it is hard to think about anything else’. (‘On the mechanics of economic development’, Journal of Monetary Economics, 22 (1988), pp. 3–42.) In the previous two chapters we showed how economists measure macroeconomic quantities and prices. In this chapter we start studying the forces that determine these variables. As we have seen, an economy’s gross domestic product (GDP) measures not only the quantity of goods and services produced in the economy, but also (as you may recall from the circular-flow diagram) the total income earned and the economy’s total expenditure. We have also discussed how the level of real GDP per capita is a decent (although not perfect) measure of a country’s prosperity and people’s wellbeing. Consequently, the growth rate of real GDP, commonly referred to as economic growth, represents the dynamic perspective: Improvements in prosperity over time. In this chapter, we focus on the long-run determinants of both the level and the growth rate of real GDP. Later in this book we will study the shortrun fluctuations of real GDP around its long-run trend. We proceed here in three steps. First, we examine international data on real GDP per person. These data will give you some sense of how much living standards vary around the world and over time. Second, we examine the role of productivity – the amount of goods and services produced for each hour of a worker’s time. In particular, you will see that a nation’s standard of living is determined by the productivity of its workers and consider the factors that determine a nation’s productivity. Third, we explore the link between productivity and the economic policies that a nation pursues. LO7.1 Economic growth around the world As a starting point for our study of long-run economic growth, consider a fact that many people find surprising: It is a relatively recent phenomenon! Widespread increases in incomes, that we now take for granted, only started about two and a half centuries ago with the onset of the Industrial Revolution. Before that, the prosperity of ordinary people was stagnant for many centuries and possibly millennia (see, for example, the book A Farewell to Alms: A Brief Economic History of the World by Professor Gregory Clark). While the reasons for this ‘birth’ of economic growth in the eighteenth century are not fully known, the rest of the chapter will offer some insights in this respect. To understand the more recent developments, Table 7.1 shows data on real GDP per person for 17 selected countries over the past six to seven decades. The second column of the table presents the time periods, which differ somewhat from country to country because of differences in data availability. The third and fourth columns show real GDP per person in the early 1950s and in 2017. 138 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 4 The real economyCopyright in the long run 07_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 138 24/08/20 6:12 PM Country Period Real GDP per capita at beginning of period ($)* Real GDP per capita at end of period* Average growth rate (%) Botswana 1960–2017 405 14 997 6.5 South Korea 1953–2017 988 36 265 5.8 Japan 1950–2017 2 531 40 374 4.2 China 1952–2017 1 073 13 043 3.9 Malaysia 1955–2017 2 144 22 776 3.9 Indonesia 1960–2017 1 282 10 594 3.8 Brazil 1950–2017 1 510 13 813 3.4 India 1950–2017 841 6 422 3.1 Pakistan 1950–2017 1 268 5 303 2.2 Australia 1950–2017 12 283 47 393 2.0 Canada 1950–2017 11 186 42 907 2.0 United States 1950–2017 14 569 54 795 2.0 New Zealand 1950–2017 10 703 36 538 1.8 Bangladesh 1959–2017 1 356 3 436 1.6 Russia 1990–2017 15 262 22 581 1.5 Venezuela 1950–2017 5 436 7 697 0.5 Niger 1960–2017 1 368 909 –0.7 Source: The Penn World Table (Mark 9.1), Feenstra, R.C., R. Inklaar & M.P. Timmer (2015), ‘The Next Generation of the Penn World Table’, American Economic Review, 105(10), 3150–3182, available for download at http://www.ggdc.net/pwt (CC BY 4.0) TABLE 7.1 The variety of growth experiences across countries *Real GDP is expressed in 2011 (internationally comparable) dollars. The data on real GDP per person show that living standards vary widely from country to country. Income per person in Australia, for instance, is over three and a half times that in China and seven times that in India. Some countries have average levels of income that have not been seen in Australia for many decades. The typical Indonesian in 2017 had about as much real income as the typical New Zealander in 1950. The typical person in Pakistan in 2017 had roughly the same income as the typical Venezuelan in 1950. You may also be surprised that the typical person in Niger had higher income than the typical South Korean in the early 1950s, whereas in 2017 she had nearly 40 times less income. The last column of the table shows each country’s average annual growth rate over the whole period. The growth rate measures how rapidly real GDP per person grew in the typical year. In Australia, for example, real GDP per person was $12 283 in 1950 and $47 393 in 2017 (these amounts can be compared as they are both measured in 2011 dollars). The average annual growth rate over this period was 2.0 per cent per year. This means that if real GDP per person, beginning at $12 283, were to increase by 2.0 per cent for each of the 67 years, it would end up at $47 393. Of course, real GDP per person did not actually rise exactly 2.0 per cent every year – there were short-run fluctuations around the long-run trend growth rate. The countries in Table 7.1 are ordered by their GDP per capita growth rate from the most to the least rapid. Botswana (South Africa’s neighbour) tops the list with an average growth rate of 6.5 per cent per year. China’s average growth rate was 3.9 per cent over that period, and double that amount in the past two decades. While it is growing rapidly, it still has a relatively low per capita GDP. Even at its current growth rates, it would still take many years before China’s average income is in the world’s top 10. 139 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN Chapter 02-200-202 7 Production and growth 07_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 139 24/08/20 6:12 PM Seventy years ago, Japan and South Korea were not rich countries. Their average incomes were higher than Indonesia’s average incomes, but they were less than half of Venezuela’s average income. But because of their spectacular growth (during the 1950–90 period in the case of Japan and during 1965–95 in South Korea), they are today economic superpowers, with average income almost the same as Australia’s and New Zealand’s. Countries like Australia, Canada, the US and New Zealand all have similar growth rates (at or close to 2%) because they were all relatively developed at the start of the period. At the bottom of the list of countries is Niger, which has experienced hardly any growth at all over most of the past half-century; the typical resident of Niger lives in poverty similar to that experienced by his or her great-grandparents. It should, however, be said that the economic situation of many low-income countries has been improving. For example, Niger has experienced positive growth in the last few years, and a number of countries in Africa and Asia like Chad or Afghanistan have had average incomes growing as high as 8 per cent annually since the start of the twenty-first century. Later in the chapter there is more discussion on how global poverty has been decreasing over the past three decades. FYI The magic of compounding and the rule of 70 It may be tempting to dismiss differences in growth rates as insignificant. If one country’s real GDP grows at 1 per cent while another’s grows at 3 per cent, so what? What difference can 2 percentage points make? The answer is clear: A big difference. Even growth rates that seem small when written in percentage terms seem large after they are compounded for many years. Compounding refers to the accumulation of a growth rate over a period of time. Consider an example. Suppose that two university graduates – Delta and Bec – both take their first jobs at the age of 22 earning $30 000 a year. Delta lives in an economy where real incomes grow at 1 per cent per year, whereas Bec lives in one (otherwise identical) where real incomes grow at 3 per cent per year. Straightforward calculations show what happens. Forty years later, when both are 62 years old, Delta earns $45 000 a year, and Bec earns $98 000 (you can double-check these numbers using an online compound growth calculator, for example, at http://www.investo-pedia.com/calculator/ cagr.aspx). Because of that difference of 2 percentage points in the growth rate, Bec’s salary in real terms will be more than twice Delta’s. An old rule of thumb, called the rule of 70, is helpful in understanding growth rates and the effects of compounding. According to the rule of 70, if a variable grows at a rate of x per cent per year, then that variable doubles in approximately 70/x years. In Delta’s economy, real incomes grow at 1 per cent per year, so it takes about 70 years for them to double. In Bec’s economy, real incomes grow at 3 per cent per year, so it takes about 70/3, or 23, years for them to double. The rule of 70 applies not only to a growing economy but also to a growing savings account. Here is an example. Suppose that when Governor Phillip left office in 1792, he gave $5000 to be invested for a period of 200 years to benefit scientific research into early Australian history. If this money had earned 7 per cent per year (which would, in fact, have been very possible to do), the investment would have doubled in value every 10 years. Over 200 years, it would have doubled 20 times. At the end of 200 years of compounding, the investment would have been worth 220 × $5000, which is about $5 billion. As these examples show, growth rates compounded over many years can lead to some spectacular results. That is probably why some people call compounding ‘the greatest mathematical discovery of all time’. 140 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 4 The real economyCopyright in the long run 07_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 140 24/08/20 6:12 PM Because of differences in GDP growth rates, the ranking of countries by income changes substantially over time. Japan is a country that has risen relative to others between 1950 and 1990 and has fallen since then. The rise of China and other South East Asian countries still continues. Two countries that have fallen behind are New Zealand and Argentina. In 1950, New Zealand was one of the richest countries in the world, with average income nearly as high as the United States and well above the United Kingdom. Today, average income in New Zealand is well below average income in the US and in Australia. In 1950, Venezuela had almost four times the income of its South American neighbour, Brazil. Today, Venezuela’s average income is only just over half that of Brazil’s. Australia’s story is somewhere in between these two. In 1900, Australia had the highest per capita income in the world, but by 1970 it had fallen to around seventh in the rankings. By 1991, Australia was no longer in the top 10 and had fallen behind most western European countries in relative terms. Since then, Australia’s relatively strong economic growth (we have had no recession since 1992) has seen Australia’s ranking rise, attacking the top 10 again. These data show that the world’s richest countries have no guarantee that they will stay the richest and that the world’s poorest countries are not doomed forever to remain in poverty. But what explains these changes over time? Why do some countries zoom ahead while others lag behind? These are precisely the questions that we take up next. CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING What has been the approximate annual growth rate of real GDP per person in Australia and China over the past half century? Before reading the rest of the chapter, can you suggest any possible explanations for the differences in economic growth rates between Australia and China over this period? LO7.2 Productivity: Its role and determinants Explaining the large variation in living standards around the world is, in one sense, very easy. As we will see, the explanation can be summarised in a single word – productivity. But, in another sense, the international variation is deeply puzzling. To explain why incomes are so much higher in some countries than in others, we must look at the many (economic as well as non-economic) factors that determine a nation’s productivity. Why is productivity so important? Let’s begin our study of productivity and economic growth by developing a simple model based loosely on Daniel Defoe’s famous novel, Robinson Crusoe. Robinson Crusoe, as you may recall, is a sailor stranded on a desert island. Because Crusoe lives alone, he catches his own fish, grows his own vegetables and makes his own clothes. We can think of Crusoe’s activities – his production and consumption of fish, vegetables and clothing – as being a simple economy. By examining Crusoe’s economy, we can learn some lessons that also apply to more complex and realistic economies. What determines Crusoe’s standard of living? The answer is obvious. If Crusoe is good at catching fish, growing vegetables and making clothes, he lives well. If he is bad at doing these things, he lives poorly. Because Crusoe gets to consume only what he produces, his living standard is tied to his productive ability. 141 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN Chapter 02-200-202 7 Production and growth 07_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 141 24/08/20 6:12 PM The term productivity refers to the quantity of goods and services that a worker can produce for each hour of work. In the case of Crusoe’s economy, it is easy to see that productivity is the key determinant of living standards and that growth in productivity is the key determinant of improvements in living standards. The more fish Crusoe can catch per hour, the more he can eat at dinner. If Crusoe finds a better place to catch fish or a smarter way of doing so, his productivity rises. This increase in productivity makes Crusoe better off – he could eat the extra fish, or he could spend less time fishing and devote more time to other activities he enjoys. The key role of productivity in determining living standards is as true for nations as it is for stranded sailors. Recall that an economy’s gross domestic product (GDP) measures three things at once – the total production, the total income earned in the economy and the total expenditure on the economy’s goods and services. The reason GDP can measure these three things simultaneously is that, for the economy as a whole, they must be equal. Put simply, workers and owners of capital get paid their income for what they produce and use this income to purchase the goods and services produced in the economy. The implication is that Australians are more prosperous than Nigerians mainly because Australian workers are more productive than Nigerian workers. The Chinese have enjoyed more rapid growth in living standards than Venezualans primarily because Chinese workers have experienced more rapidly growing productivity. Indeed, one of the Ten Principles of Economics in chapter 1 is that a country’s standard of living depends on its ability to produce goods and services. The above discussion implies that in order to understand the large differences in living standards across countries or over time, we must focus on the production of goods and services. But seeing the link between prosperity and productivity is only the first step. It leads naturally to the next question: Why are some economies so much better at producing goods and services than others? How is labour productivity determined? Although productivity is uniquely important in determining Robinson Crusoe’s standard of living, many factors determine Crusoe’s productivity. Crusoe will catch more fish, for instance, if he has more fishing rods, if he has been trained in the best fishing techniques, if his island has a plentiful fish supply or if he has figured out the best places and times on his island to fish. Each of these determinants of Crusoe’s productivity – which we can call physical capital, human capital, natural resources and technological knowledge – has a counterpart in more complex and realistic economies. Let’s consider each of these factors in turn. Physical capital physical capital the stock of equipment and structures that are used to produce goods and services Workers are more productive if they have tools with which to work. The stock of equipment and structures that are used to produce goods and services is called physical capital, or just capital. For example, when woodworkers make furniture, they use saws, lathes and drill presses. More tools allow work to be done more quickly and more accurately. That is, a worker with only basic hand tools can make less furniture each week than a worker with sophisticated and specialised woodworking equipment. As you may recall from chapter 2, the inputs used to produce goods and services are called the factors of production. An important feature of physical capital is that, unlike labour, it is a produced factor of production. That is, capital is an input into the production process that in the past was an output from the production process. The woodworker uses a lathe to make the leg of a table. Earlier, the lathe itself was the output of a firm that manufactures lathes. The lathe manufacturer in turn used other equipment to make its product. Thus, capital is a factor of production used to produce all kinds of goods and services, including more capital. 142 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 4 The real economyCopyright in the long run 07_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 142 24/08/20 6:12 PM Human capital A very important determinant of productivity is human capital. Human capital is the economist’s term for the knowledge and skills that workers acquire through education, training and experience. Human capital includes the skills accumulated in early childhood programs, primary school, secondary school, university and on-the-job training for adults in the labour force. Although education, training and experience are less tangible than lathes, bulldozers and factory buildings, human capital is like physical capital because it raises a nation’s ability to produce goods and services. Also, like physical capital, human capital is a produced factor of production. Producing human capital requires inputs in the form of teachers, libraries and student time. Indeed, students can be viewed as ‘workers’ who have the important job of producing the human capital that will be used in future production. human capital the knowledge and skills that workers acquire through education, training and experience Natural resources Another (although less important) determinant of productivity is natural resources. Natural resources are inputs into production that are provided by nature, like land, rivers and mineral deposits. Natural resources take two forms – renewable and non-renewable. A forest is usually given as an example of a renewable resource. When one tree is cut down, a seedling can be planted in its place to be harvested in the future (although you may rightly point out that it sometimes takes a long time). Oil is an example of a non-renewable resource. Because oil is produced by nature over many thousands of years, there is only a limited supply. Once the supply of oil is depleted, it is impossible to create more, and we would have to turn to its natural or human-made alternatives. Differences in natural resources are responsible for some of the differences in standards of living around the world. The historical success of Australia was driven in part by the large supply of land well suited to agriculture. Today, some countries in the Middle East, like Kuwait and Saudi Arabia, are rich because they are on top of some of the largest pools of oil in the world. But while natural resources can be beneficial, they are not necessary for an economy to be productive and to have high economic growth. Singapore, for instance, is one of the most prosperous countries in the world, despite having few natural resources. International trade makes Singapore’s success possible. Singapore imports most of the natural resources it needs and exports its manufactured goods to economies rich in natural resources. natural resources the production inputs provided by nature, like land, rivers and mineral deposits Technological knowledge An essential determinant of productivity is technological knowledge – the understanding of the best ways to produce goods and services. A hundred years ago, most Australians worked on farms, because farm technology required a high input of labour in order to feed the entire population. Today, thanks to advances in the technology of farming, a small fraction of the population can produce enough food to feed the entire country. Technological knowledge takes many forms. Some technology is common knowledge – after it becomes used by one person, everyone can take advantage of it. For example, once Henry Ford successfully introduced production in assembly lines, other carmakers quickly followed suit. A more recent example is the Internet. Other technology is proprietary – it is known only by the company that discovers it. Only the Coca-Cola Company, for instance, knows the secret recipe for making its soft drink. Some other technology is proprietary for a short time. When a drug company discovers a new drug, the patent system gives that company a temporary right to be the exclusive manufacturer of this particular drug. When the patent expires, however, other companies are allowed to make the drug. It is worthwhile to summarise the differences between technological knowledge, human capital, physical capital and labour. Roughly speaking, physical capital is the quantity of machines whereas technological knowledge refers to the quality of machines and production technological knowledge society’s understanding of the best ways to produce goods and services 143 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN Chapter 02-200-202 7 Production and growth 07_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 143 24/08/20 6:12 PM processes. Similarly, labour relates to the quantity of workers in terms of the number of hours they supply, while human capital expresses the quality and intellectual capacity of people with regard to economic activities. To use a relevant metaphor, technological knowledge is the quality of society’s textbooks, whereas human capital is the zeal and ingenuity with which individuals write these textbooks and learn from them. Based on the above discussion, it will probably not surprise you that labour productivity depends on physical capital and human capital, as well as technological knowledge. You will, however, soon see that physical capital only has a temporary effect: Ongoing increases in the number of machines per worker cannot permanently sustain economic growth. This is in contrast to human capital and technological knowledge, both of which improve the quality of the production inputs rather than just adding more inputs. CASE STUDY Are natural resources or global warming limits to growth? The world’s population is far larger today than it used to be (in 1800 it was around one billion, one-seventh of what it is now), and most people are enjoying a much higher standard of living. A perennial debate concerns whether this growth in population and living standards can continue in the future. Many commentators have argued that natural resources provide a limit to how much the world’s economies can grow. At first, this argument might seem hard to ignore. If the world has only a fixed supply of non-renewable natural resources, how can population, production and living standards continue to grow over time? Eventually, won’t supplies of oil and minerals start to run out? When these shortages start to occur, won’t they stop economic growth and, perhaps, even force living standards to fall? In the early 1970s, a group of researchers at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology (MIT) in the US were commissioned to undertake analysis of whether this would in fact happen. They published a book called The Limits to Growth. They concluded that by about 2020, we would reach peak production – that we would not be able to continue to increase our output of goods as we would run out of key inputs of non-renewable resources. The researchers were criticised – their computer modelling made simplistic assumptions, they didn’t consider technological advances and so on. It appears that they weren’t entirely accurate about their predictions … and yet … We are experiencing changes to our climate that may force us to limit our production to prevent catastrophic changes to our environment. Most economists are less concerned about running out of resources as the source of limits. Technological progress has led to discoveries that have replaced many nonrenewable resources with renewables or that allow us to recycle the non-renewables. If we compare the economy today with the economy of the past, we see various ways in which the use of natural resources has improved. Modern cars, particularly hybrids, require fewer litres of petrol per kilometre. New houses have better insulation and require less energy to heat and cool them. Recycling allows some non-renewable resources to be reused. Solar panels on houses and the use of batteries to store energy generated during the day are now fairly common. Half a century ago, some people were concerned about the excessive use of tin and copper. At the time, these were crucial commodities – tin was used to make many food containers, and copper was used to make telephone wire. Some people advocated mandatory recycling and rationing of tin and copper so that supplies would be available for future generations. Today, however, plastic has replaced tin as a material for making many food containers, and phone calls often travel over fibre-optic cables, which are made from sand. Technological progress has made once-crucial natural resources less necessary. But are all these technological efforts enough to permit continued economic growth? One way to answer this question is to look at the prices of natural resources. In a market 144 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 4 The real economyCopyright in the long run 07_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 144 24/08/20 6:12 PM iStockphoto/alantobey What happens when these wells run dry? economy, scarcity is reflected in market prices. If the world were running out of natural resources without any alternatives in sight, then the prices of those resources would be rising over time. But this does not seem to be the case. The prices of most natural resources (adjusted for overall inflation) are stable over the long term or even falling. It appears that our ability to conserve these resources and/or discover new reserves is growing more rapidly than their supplies are dwindling (for example, reported oil reserves of the eight main OPEC countries are more than five times larger now than in 1980, although these numbers are disputed). Market prices for most resources give no reason to believe that natural resources are a hard limit to economic growth. The same can be said about other main drivers of prosperity: Human capital and technological progress. Given that human creativity and passion for self-improvement seem limitless, it is very unlikely that there exists a certain fixed technological frontier that would bring economic growth to a halt. Does this mean that all is well and economic growth can continue the same way we are used to? Not exactly. The IPCC produced a report in 2014 that detailed ways in which climate change might affect different industries. A couple of examples highlight how an increase in global temperatures might affect economic growth. Water resources may be less available, so industries that use a great deal of water may not experience the same level of growth. Agriculture, a significant export sector for Australia, is being affected by longer and longer periods of drought, leading to reduced levels of output. Climate change will certainly affect tourism – whether it be reduced ski seasons because of warmer weather or greater storm activity and severity leading to fewer people sitting on beaches. For some tropical economies, these affects will be significant. (See chapter 10 of Climate Change 2014: Impacts, Adaptation, and Vulnerability. Part A: Global and Sectoral Aspects. Contribution of Working Group II to the Fifth Assessment Report of the Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change for more detailed descriptions of climate change impacts on various economic sectors.) Questions Can technological progress reduce the effects of climate change? (Hint: Think about how the production process affects climate change.) 145 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN Chapter 02-200-202 7 Production and growth 07_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 145 24/08/20 6:12 PM The production function Economists often use a production function to describe the relationship between the quantity of inputs used in production and the quantity of output from production. To formalise our previous discussion, suppose Y denotes the quantity of real output, for the production of which five inputs are used. Three of them are ‘tangible’ (i.e. quantity-type inputs) whereas two are ‘non-tangible’ (i.e. quality-type inputs). In terms of the tangible factors of production, L denotes the quantity of labour, K the quantity of physical capital and N the quantity of natural resources. In terms of the non-tangible factors, H expresses human capital (the quality of a typical worker) and A captures technological knowledge (the quality of the available production technology). Then we might write: Y = F (L; K; N; H; A) returns to scale the effect on output of increasing all (tangible) inputs in the same proportion where F( ) is some function that shows how the inputs are combined to produce output. The specific form of this function is not important for our purposes; what matters is that as any of the five production inputs rises, the economy produces more output. A common question is whether it is better for productivity to be a small or a large country. The answer depends on a property of the production function called returns to scale. This concept describes what happens if all three tangible inputs L, K and N are increased in the same proportion. For example, assume that you double the number of workers (L), the number of machines (K) and the amount of natural resources (N), keeping the non-tangible inputs unchanged. Three scenarios can occur as a consequence. First, if a production function has constant returns to scale, then a doubling of all the tangible inputs causes the amount of output to double as well. In such cases it makes no difference if a country is large or small. Second, if output more than doubles then the production function has increasing returns to scale, and being a bigger country is better for productivity. Third, if doubling all tangible inputs results in less than a doubling of output then there are decreasing returns to scale; i.e. it is better to be a small country. Do economies have constant, increasing or decreasing returns to scale? A lot of economic research attempts to answer this question, and the conclusion is not clear-cut. But as we see both small and large countries among the richest countries as well as among the poorest countries, it makes sense to focus on the case of constant returns to scale. Mathematically, a production function has constant returns to scale if, for any positive number x: xY = F (xL, xK, xN, H, A) The right-hand side shows the tangible inputs changing in the same proportion; for example, doubling in the case of x = 2. And the left-hand side shows the output changing in the same proportion (i.e. doubling) too. Production functions with constant returns to scale have an interesting implication. To see what it is, set x = 1/L. Then the equation becomes: Y/L = F (1, K/L, N/L, H, A) Notice that output per worker (Y/L), which is a measure of labour productivity, does not depend on the number of workers L. Under constant returns to scale, the L variable disappears from the right-hand side of the equation. Instead, productivity depends on physical capital per worker (K/L), natural resources per worker (N/L), as well as society’s technology (A) and human capital (H). This equation thus provides a mathematical summary of the four determinants of productivity we have discussed. You may wonder why productivity depends on A and H rather than A/L and H/L; that is, why A and H do not have to be increased in proportion with the tangible inputs. The first reason is that A and H in our production function represent the (average) quality of technology and workers, not the sum of all technology or knowledge in the society. But more 146 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 4 The real economyCopyright in the long run 07_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 146 24/08/20 6:12 PM fundamentally, it is because these two non-tangible inputs generate a positive externality. We will discuss the meaning of this concept in our section on education, but in a nutshell: A smart person comes up with more efficient ways of doing things, and the benefit from this accrues not only to that person, but also to many other people who can enjoy the person’s ideas and technological innovations. Ideas and technologies are (at least partly) public goods. This is in contrast to a machine (K) or a piece or iron ore (N) that is used in a certain factory and cannot be utilised by many people at the same time. And this positive externality is what makes H and A special. CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING What are the key determinants of labour productivity? Which one do you think is most important? Explain your reasoning. LO7.3 Economic growth and public policy So far, we have determined that a society’s standard of living, at least on the material level, depends on its ability to produce goods and services, and that its productivity depends on physical capital, human capital, natural resources and technological knowledge (and possibly other factors that will be discussed below). Let’s now turn to the question faced by policymakers around the world: What can government policy do to raise productivity and living standards? The importance of saving and investment Because both physical and human capital are produced factors of production, a society can change the amount of capital it has. If today the economy produces a large quantity of new capital goods or invests in people’s education, then tomorrow it will have a larger stock of capital and be able to produce more of all types of goods and services, or enjoy more leisure time. Thus, one way to raise future productivity is to invest more current resources in the production of physical and human capital. One of the Ten Principles of Economics presented in chapter 1 is that people face tradeoffs. This principle is especially important when considering the accumulation of capital. Because resources are scarce, devoting more resources to producing capital requires devoting fewer resources to producing goods and services for current consumption. That is, for society to invest more in physical or human capital, it must consume less and save more of its current income. If Robinson Crusoe wants to increase his production of vegetables, he must spend more time planting them, or come up with more efficient ways of looking after them, or become smarter about harvesting them. The growth that arises from capital accumulation is not a free lunch – it requires that society sacrifice consumption of goods and services in the present in order to enjoy higher consumption in the future. This implies that encouraging saving and investment is one way that a government can foster economic growth and, in the long run, raise people’s standard of living. To see the importance of investment for economic growth, consider Figure 7.2, which displays data for 17 countries. Panel (a) shows each country’s economic growth rate (on average) over a 65-year period. 147 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN Chapter 02-200-202 7 Production and growth 07_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 147 24/08/20 6:12 PM FIGURE 7.2 The relationship between investment and economic growth (a) (b) Botswana South Korea Japan China Malaysia Indonesia Brazil India Pakistan Australia Canada United States New Zealand Bangladesh Russia Venezuela Niger –2 –1 Botswana South Korea Japan China Malaysia Indonesia Brazil India Pakistan Australia Canada United States New Zealand Bangladesh Russia Venezuela Niger 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 0% 5% 10% 15% 20% 25% 30% 35% (a) Average GDP growth rate (%), 1950–2017 (b) Average investment (% of GDP), 1950–2017 Panel (a) shows the average annual growth rate of GDP for 17 countries over the period 1950–2017. Panel (b) shows the percentage of GDP that each country devoted to investment on average over this period. High GDP growth countries generally have high rates of investment, although they are some exceptions. Source: The Penn World Table (Mark 9.1), Feenstra, R.C., R. Inklaar & M.P. Timmer (2015), ‘The Next Generation of the Penn World Table’, American Economic Review, 105(10), 3150–3182, available for download at http://www.ggdc.net/pwt (CC BY 4.0) The countries are ordered by their growth rates, from most to least rapid. Panel (b) shows the percentage of GDP that each country devotes to investment. The correlation between growth and investment, although not perfect, is strong (in this case 0.44). Countries that devote a large share of GDP to investment, like Korea and China, tend to have high growth rates. Countries that devote a small share of GDP to investment, like Pakistan and Bangladesh, tend to have low growth rates. Studies that examine a more comprehensive list of countries confirm this strong correlation between investment and economic growth. There is, however, a problem in interpreting these data. As the appendix to chapter 2 discussed, a correlation between two variables does not establish which variable is the cause and which is the effect. It is possible that high investment causes high economic growth, but it is also possible that high GDP growth causes high investment. (Or, perhaps, high GDP growth and high investment are both caused by a third variable that has been omitted from the analysis.) The data by themselves cannot tell us the direction of causality. Nonetheless, both economic theory and careful econometric analysis reveals that high investment tends to lead to more rapid economic growth, at least temporarily. Diminishing returns to physical capital and the catch-up effect 148 Suppose that a government, convinced by the evidence in Figure 7.2, pursues policies that raise the nation’s saving rate – the percentage of GDP devoted to saving rather than consumption. What happens? With the nation saving more, fewer resources are needed to make consumption goods, and more resources are available to make capital goods. As a result, the stock of physical capital increases (assume for the time being that there is no change in H or A). The increase in K leads to rising productivity and more rapid growth in future GDP (note that GDP temporarily falls due to shifting from consumption to saving, which is why some short-sighted governments tend not to encourage people to save). But how long does a higher GDP rate of growth, driven by increases in K, last? Assuming that the saving rate remains at its new higher level, do both the level of GDP and the growth rate of GDP stay high indefinitely or only for a limited period of time? 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 4 The real economyCopyright in the long run 07_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 148 24/08/20 6:12 PM Economic analysis shows that physical capital is subject to diminishing returns – as the stock of physical capital per worker rises, the extra output produced from an additional unit of capital falls. In other words, when each worker already has a large quantity of physical capital to use in producing goods and services, giving them an additional unit (another machine) increases their production only slightly. The contribution of this additional machine to output may still be positive, but it is less than the contribution of the previous machines. In our Robinson Crusoe example, the first fishing rod he made increased his productivity substantially – much more than the second rod. The important implication is that because of diminishing returns to physical capital, a sustained increase in the saving rate leads to a permanently higher level of GDP, but only to a temporary increase in the growth rate of GDP. Why is that? The higher saving rate allows more physical capital per worker to be accumulated, but the benefits from additional capital become smaller as each worker has to operate an increasing number of machines. Therefore, the growth rate of GDP slows down. In summary, in the long run a higher saving rate and the resulting greater physical capital investment lead to a higher level of productivity and income, but not to higher growth in these variables. Reaching this long run, however, can take quite a while. According to studies of international data on economic growth, increasing the saving rate can lead to substantially higher economic growth for a period of several decades. You should now be able to answer the following question: What is the difference between the two concepts we discussed, namely returns to scale and returns to an input like physical capital? Recall that when considering returns to scale we increase all the tangible inputs L, K and N in the same proportion. In contrast, when considering returns to an input we only increase the one input (for example, K), but leave all the other inputs unchanged. In the latter case Robinson Crusoe’s economy would have a second fishing rod, whereas in the former there would also be another person to operate the rod (you may recall Friday who appeared on the island one day and became Crusoe’s friend). Once you understand this difference, it is straightforward to see why we usually see diminishing returns to physical capital (or other tangible inputs, labour and natural resources), but at the same time the economy has constant returns to scale. In the first case we keep adding only one input which creates an imbalance between the inputs. In the second case we add all of the tangible inputs proportionately so this imbalance does not occur, and nor does a fall in productivity. The diminishing returns to physical capital feature have another important implication – other things being equal, it is easier for a country to grow fast if it starts out relatively poor. This effect of initial conditions on subsequent growth is sometimes called the catch-up (or convergence) effect. In poor countries, workers lack even the most rudimentary tools and, as a result, have low productivity. Small amounts of capital investment would substantially raise these workers’ productivity. In contrast, workers in high-income countries already have large amounts of physical capital with which to work, and this partly explains their high productivity. But in this case additional capital investment has a relatively small effect on productivity. Studies of international data on economic growth confirm this catch-up effect. Controlling for other variables, like the percentage of GDP devoted to investment, human capital or political stability, less-industrial countries do grow faster than moreindustrial countries. This catch-up effect can help us understand some of the puzzling results in Figure 7.2. Over this 67-year period, Australia and Japan devoted a similar share of GDP to investment. Yet Australia experienced only moderate growth of below 2 per cent, whereas Japan experienced high growth of 4.6 per cent. The explanation is the convergence predicted by diminishing returns to physical capital. In 1950, Japan had GDP per person around one-fifth the Australian level, in part because previous investment had been so low. With a small diminishing returns the property whereby the benefit from each extra unit of an input declines as the quantity of the input increases catch-up (or convergence) effect low-income countries tend to grow more rapidly than highincome countries 149 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN Chapter 02-200-202 7 Production and growth 07_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 149 24/08/20 6:12 PM initial capital stock, the benefits to capital accumulation were much greater in Japan, and this gave Japan a higher subsequent growth rate. In the 1960s annual economic growth in Japan was around 10 per cent, and this rate fell every decade until the 1990s, whereby growth virtually disappeared. It is almost certain that the high rate of economic growth in China, which is to a large extent driven by extensive industrialisation, will keep falling over time for exactly the same reason as Japan’s did – due to diminishing returns to physical capital. But in the meantime, China’s GDP per capita will be converging to levels observed in high-income countries. This catch-up effect shows up in other aspects of life. When a school gives an endof-year award to the ‘most improved’ student, that student is usually one who began the year with relatively poor performance. Students who began the year not studying find improvement easier than students who always worked hard. Note that it is good to be ‘most improved’, given the starting point, but it is arguably even better to be ‘best student’. Similarly, economic growth over the last few decades has been much more rapid in China than in Australia, but GDP per person is still much higher in Australia. Investment from abroad So far, we have discussed how policies aimed at increasing a country’s saving rate can increase investment and, thereby, long-term economic growth. Yet saving by domestic residents is not the only way for a country to invest in new capital. The other way is investment by foreigners. Investment from abroad takes several forms. An Australian university might build a campus in Thailand. A capital investment that is owned and operated by a foreign entity is called foreign direct investment. Alternatively, an Australian might buy shares in a Thai corporation (that is, buy a share of the ownership of the corporation); the Thai corporation can use the proceeds from the sale of shares to build a new factory. An investment that is financed with foreign money but operated by domestic residents is called foreign portfolio investment. In both cases, Australians provide the resources necessary to increase the stock of capital in Thailand. That is, Australian saving is being used to finance Thai investment. When foreigners invest in a country, they do so because they expect to earn a return on their investment. If an Australian university were to open a Thai campus, that would increase the Thai stock of capital and, therefore, increase Thai productivity and GDP. Yet, in this case, the university takes some of this additional income back to Australia in the form of profit. Similarly, when an Australian investor buys shares in a Thai corporation, the investor has a right to a portion of the profit that the corporation earns. Investment from abroad, therefore, affects GDP and GNP differently. Recall that gross domestic product is the income earned within a country by both residents and non-residents, whereas gross national product is the income earned by residents of a country both at home and abroad. If the University of Melbourne opens a campus in Thailand, some of the income the university generates accrues to people who do not live in Thailand. As a result, this investment raises Thailand’s GDP more than Thailand’s GNP, and it raises Australia’s GNP more than Australia’s GDP. Investment from abroad is one way for a country to increase its stock of capital and grow. Even though some of the benefits from this investment flow back to the foreign owners, this investment does increase the economy’s stock of capital, leading to higher productivity and higher wages. Moreover, investment from abroad is one way for emerging countries to learn the state-of-the-art technologies and processes used in richer countries. For these reasons, many economists who advise governments in low-income economies advocate 150 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 4 The real economyCopyright in the long run 07_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 150 24/08/20 6:12 PM policies that encourage investment from abroad. Often, this means removing restrictions that governments have imposed on foreign ownership of domestic capital. An institution that tries to encourage the flow of investment to low-income countries is the World Bank. This international organisation obtains funds from the world’s advanced countries, like Australia, and uses these resources to make loans to low-income countries so that they can invest in roads, sewer systems, schools and other types of capital. It also offers the countries advice about how the funds might best be used. The World Bank, together with its sister organisation, the International Monetary Fund, was set up after the Second World War. One lesson from the war was that economic distress often leads to political turmoil, international tensions and military conflict. Thus, every country has an interest in promoting economic prosperity around the world. The World Bank and the International Monetary Fund aim to achieve that common goal. Education Our earlier discussion implies that education – investment in human capital – is no less important for a country’s long-run economic success than investment in physical capital. In Australia, each year of schooling raises a person’s wage on average by about 8 per cent, and some studies indicate as much as 15 per cent at the tertiary level. In low-income countries, where human capital is especially scarce, the gap between the wages of educated and uneducated workers is even larger. Thus, one way in which government policy can enhance the standard of living is to provide good schools and to encourage the population to take advantage of them. Investment in human capital, like investment in physical capital, has an opportunity cost. When students are in school or university, they forgo the wages they could have earned. In less prosperous countries, children often drop out of school at an early age, even though the benefit of additional schooling is very high, simply because their labour is needed to help support the family. We mentioned that human capital is particularly important for economic growth because it conveys positive externalities. An externality is the effect of one person’s actions on the wellbeing of a bystander. An educated person, for instance, might generate new ideas about how best to produce goods and services. If these ideas enter society’s pool of knowledge so everyone can use them, then the ideas are an external benefit of education. This ‘public good’ property of human capital and technology seems to be the reason why these two nontangible production inputs H and A do not have diminishing returns – unlike the tangible inputs L, K and N. One of the implications of this positive externality is that the return to schooling is even greater for society than for the individual, which may justify the large subsidies for human-capital investment that we observe in the form of public education. On the other hand, it is conceivable that these subsidies partly distort the education market at the tertiary level, and lead some people to make the wrong decision about whether to study, and what to study (you may recall a funny line from the movie Gothika: ‘All that education, but you can’t remember an umbrella?’). CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING If university education was fully paid for by the Australian government, what could this do to the level of human capital in Australia? Discuss the pros and cons. 151 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN Chapter 02-200-202 7 Production and growth 07_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 151 24/08/20 6:12 PM One problem facing some countries is the brain drain – the emigration of many of the highly educated workers to richer countries, where these workers can enjoy a higher standard of living. This is particularly a problem for low-income countries. If human capital does have positive externalities, then this brain drain makes those people left behind poorer than they otherwise would be. This problem poses a dilemma for policymakers. On the one hand, Australia, the United States and other high-income countries have better systems of higher education, and it would seem natural for low-income countries to send their best students abroad to earn higher degrees. On the other hand, those students who have spent time abroad may choose not to return home and this brain drain would reduce the lowincome nation’s stock of human capital even further. CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING How can a country deal with brain drain? In order for governments of low-income countries to reduce this problem, some require the recipients of their scholarships in foreign countries to commit to returning home and working for the government for a certain number of years. What is your view of this arrangement? Let us now discuss several additional factors that may be important for prosperity but have not been included in our production function. Health and nutrition The term human capital usually refers to intellectual skills, but the broader concept also includes a person’s ability to look after their health. There is no doubt that, other things being equal, healthier workers are more productive. The implication for governments is that the right investments in the health of the population provide one way for a nation to increase productivity and raise living standards. Economic historian Robert Fogel, the recipient of the 1993 Nobel Prize in Economics, has suggested that a significant factor in long-run economic growth is improved health from better nutrition. He estimated that in Great Britain in 1780, about one in five people were so malnourished that they were incapable of manual labour. Among those who could work, insufficient caloric intake substantially reduced the work effort they could put forth. As nutrition improved, so did workers’ productivity. Fogel studies these historical trends in part by looking at the height of the population. Short stature can be an indicator of malnutrition, especially during gestation and the early years of life. Fogel finds that as nations develop economically, people eat more and the population gets taller. From 1775 to 1975, the average caloric intake in Great Britain rose by 26 per cent and the height of the average man rose by 9.1 cm. Similarly, during the spectacular economic growth in South Korea from 1962 to 1995, caloric consumption rose by 44 per cent and average male height rose by 5.1 cm. Of course, a person’s height is determined by a combination of genetics and environment. But because the genetic make-up of a population is slow to change, such rapid increases in average height are most likely due to changes in the environment – nutrition being the obvious explanation. Fogel concluded that ‘improved gross nutrition accounts for roughly 30 per cent of the growth of per capita income in Britain between 1790 and 1980’. Moreover, studies have found that height is an indicator of productivity. Looking at data on a large number of workers at a point in time, researchers have found that taller workers tend to earn more. Because wages reflect a worker’s productivity, this finding suggests that taller workers tend to be more productive. The effect of height on wages is especially pronounced in poorer countries, where malnutrition is a bigger risk. 152 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 4 The real economyCopyright in the long run 07_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 152 24/08/20 6:12 PM Today, malnutrition is fortunately rare in high-income nations like Australia, the UK and the United States. (Obesity is a more widespread problem.) But for people in low-income nations, poor health and inadequate nutrition remain obstacles to higher productivity and improved living standards. The United Nations estimates that almost a third of the population in sub-Saharan Africa is undernourished, although the situation has been improving as you will find out below. The causal link between health and wealth runs in both directions. Poor countries are poor in part because their populations are not healthy, and their populations are not healthy in part because they are poor and cannot afford adequate health care and nutrition. It is a vicious circle. But this fact opens the possibility of a virtuous circle: Policies that lead to more rapid economic growth tend to improve health outcomes, which in turn further promote economic growth. And we can indeed see this virtuous circle in the data. Swedish Professor Hans Rosling has convincingly argued that the standard distinction between ‘developed’ and ‘developing’ countries is no longer appropriate. To show this he created an online application called the Gapminder (http://www.gapminder.org), which allows anyone to find out more about economic, social and health trends, and the relationships between many variables. In his accompanying videos Rosling demonstrates that on many dimensions, for example, child mortality or the number of children per family in urban areas, low-income countries have made substantial progress. They are now much more similar to high-income countries than several decades ago, with this catch-up likely to continue in the future. Rosling therefore makes a plea for us all to move beyond our prejudices and see the fast transforming world rather than its outdated caricature. CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING What are some of the key factors that link health and nutrition to human capital? Property rights, markets, trust and political stability Another way in which policymakers can foster economic growth is by protecting property rights and promoting political stability. As we first noted when we discussed economic interdependence in chapter 2, production in market economies arises from the interactions of millions of individuals and firms. When you buy a car, for instance, you are buying the output of a car dealer, a car manufacturer, a steel company, an iron ore mining company and so on. This division of production among many firms allows the economy’s factors of production to be used as effectively as possible. To achieve this outcome, the economy has to coordinate transactions among these firms, as well as between firms and consumers. Market economies achieve this coordination through market prices. That is, market prices are the instrument with which the ‘invisible hand of the marketplace’ brings supply and demand into balance. (In his 1776 landmark book The Wealth of Nations, economist Adam Smith referred to the seemingly undirected operation of the marketplace as being guided by an ‘invisible hand’.) A key prerequisite for the price system to work is an economy-wide respect for property rights. In fact, Austrian economist Friedrich August Hayek, the 1974 recipient of the Nobel Prize in Economics, argued that they are ‘the most important guarantee of freedom’. Property rights refer to the ability of people to exercise authority over the resources they own. A mining company will not make the effort to mine iron ore if it expects the ore to be stolen. The company mines the ore only if it is confident that it will benefit from the ore’s subsequent sale. For this reason, courts serve an important role in a market economy – they enforce property rights. Through the criminal justice system, the courts discourage theft and corruption. In addition, through the civil justice system, the courts ensure that buyers 153 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN Chapter 02-200-202 7 Production and growth 07_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 153 24/08/20 6:12 PM and sellers live up to their contracts, and that no one can be forced into a contract they do not wish to make. Most people do not realise just how costly in terms of productivity various breaches of property rights and similar rules are. Think about the criminal system. The number of police, lawyers and judges involved in dealing with people who break the law is very large, and growing. If individuals refrained from criminal behaviour (ideally for moral reasons rather than for fear of imprisonment) many of these law enforcement workers could devote their capacity to another profession. John Maynard Keynes once controversially argued that in a recession, ‘The government should pay people to dig holes in the ground and then fill them up’. Crime (including traffic infringements like speeding or drink-diving) is in some sense similar to digging unnecessary holes, and the law enforcement sector is similar to filling them up. As valuable as the job of police officers and judges currently is, in the absence of crime many people in these occupations could switch to some other productive activity, which would greatly enhance the country’s prosperity. Although people in high-income countries tend to take property rights and other legal checks and balances for granted, those living in less prosperous countries see firsthand how a lack of property rights and weak law enforcement can be a major problem. In many countries, the system of justice does not work well. Contracts are hard to enforce and fraud often goes unpunished. In more extreme cases, the government not only fails to enforce property rights but actually infringes upon them. To do business in some countries, firms are expected to bribe powerful government officials. Such corruption impedes the coordinating power of markets. It also discourages domestic saving and investment from abroad (to find out more, see the Corruption Perceptions Index annually calculated by Transparency International at http://www.transparency.org/research/cpi/overview). One threat to property rights is political instability. When revolutions and coups are common, there is doubt about whether property rights will be respected in the future. If a revolutionary government might confiscate the capital of some businesses, as was often true after communist revolutions, domestic residents have less incentive to save, invest and start new businesses. At the same time, foreigners have less incentive to invest in the country. Even the mere threat of such a scenario can depress a nation’s standard of living. Thus, economic prosperity depends in part on political stability. A country with an efficient court system, honest government officials, well-functioning markets and a stable political system will enjoy a higher economic standard of living than a country with a poor legal system, corrupt officials, central planning and frequent revolutions. You may be interested to see the Index of Economic Freedom (available at http://www.heritage. org/index/ranking), which shows a strong relationship between economic freedom and prosperity. Hong Kong, Singapore, New Zealand, Switzerland and Australia were the topranked countries in 2016, whereas North Korea, Cuba, Zimbabwe and Venezuela were at the bottom of the list, based on economic freedom. An often-overlooked contributor to prosperity is the degree of social trust within a nation. Data show that the proportion of people who believe that their fellow citizens can be trusted is positively associated with economic growth. And it is encouraging to note that social trust in Australia has been on the rise. In the 2014 wave of the World Values Survey (http://www.worldvaluessurvey.org), 51.4 per cent believed that ‘Most people can be trusted’. This is close to the New Zealand’s figure of 55.3 per cent, and much higher than the 34.8 per cent of Americans, 27.8 per cent of Russians and 7.1 per cent of Brazilians. Free trade Some of the world’s poorest countries have tried to achieve more rapid economic growth by pursuing inward-oriented policies. These policies are aimed at raising productivity and living standards within the country by avoiding interaction with the rest of the world. Domestic 154 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 4 The real economyCopyright in the long run 07_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 154 24/08/20 6:12 PM firms sometimes claim they need protection from foreign competition in order to grow. This ‘infant industry’ argument, together with a general distrust of foreigners, has at times led policymakers to impose tariffs and other trade restrictions (we will examine the effect of these in our chapter on open economies). Most economists today believe that emerging countries are better off pursuing outwardoriented policies that integrate these countries into the world economy. Chapter 3 showed how international trade can improve the economic wellbeing of a country’s citizens. Trade is, in some ways, a type of technology. When a country exports wheat and imports steel, the country benefits in the same way as if it had invented a technology for turning wheat into steel. A country that eliminates trade restrictions will, therefore, experience the same kind of economic growth that would occur after a major technological advance. The adverse impact of inward orientation becomes clear when one considers the small size of many less-prosperous economies. The GDP of Finland or Denmark, for instance, is about that of Sydney. Imagine what would happen if Sydney residents were prohibited from trading with people living outside the city. Without being able to take advantage of the gains from trade, Sydney would need to produce all the goods it consumes. It would also have to produce all its own capital goods, rather than importing state-of-the-art equipment from other cities. Living standards in Sydney would fall immediately and the problem would be likely to get worse over time. This is precisely what happens when countries pursue inwardoriented policies, like Argentina did throughout much of the twentieth century, North Korea did over the past several decades, and the United States may do if President Trump delivers on his pre-election promises. In contrast, countries pursuing outward-oriented policies, like South Korea, Singapore and Taiwan, have enjoyed high rates of economic growth. The amount that a nation trades with others is determined not only by government policy but also by geography. Countries with good natural seaports find trade easier than countries without this resource. It is not a coincidence that many of the world’s major cities, like New York, Shanghai, Tokyo and Hong Kong, are located next to oceans. Similarly, because landlocked countries find international trade more difficult, they tend to have lower levels of income than countries with easy access to the world’s waterways. The United Nation’s development goals In September 2000, world leaders came together at the United Nations Headquarters in New York to adopt the United Nations Millennium Declaration. It committed their nations to specific targets on eight key issues that perpetuate poverty, with a deadline of 2015. These have become known as the Millennium Development Goals. In September 2015, nations agreed on a new agenda for the next 15 years, consisting of 17 Sustainable Development Goals. Below we provide a summary of the original Development Goals and outcomes. (See https://www.brookings.edu/blog/future-development/2017/01/11/ how-successful-were-the-millennium-development-goals/ for an assessment of progress.) While some of the goals have not been fully achieved, progress has been made in alleviating poverty and improving outcomes of the less fortunate. The UN also set out Sustainable Development Goals for the period from 2016–2030. These can be seen in the graphic below. IN THE NEWS Millennium Development Goal No 1: Eradicate extreme poverty and hunger Poverty has decreased substantially all around the world. The number of people living below the poverty line (on less than US$1.25 a day, adjusted for the changes in price levels) was 836 million in 2015, a decline from 1.9 billion in 1990. 155 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN Chapter 02-200-202 7 Production and growth 07_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 155 24/08/20 6:12 PM Millennium Development Goal No 2: Achieve universal primary education Primary school enrolment rate increased from 83 per cent in 2000 to 91 per cent in 2015. While this shows substantial improvement, the original goal of achieving universal primary education has not been achieved (yet). Some geographic areas progressed more than others. For example, primary school net enrolment rate in sub-Saharan Africa increased from 52 per cent to 80 per cent between 1990 and 2015. Millennium Development Goal No 3: Promote gender equality and empower women The majority of low-income countries, about two-thirds of them, have seen the number of girls enrolled in primary education catch up with boy’s enrolment. For example, in Southern Asia, the number of girls in primary school per 100 boys increased from 74 in 1990 to 103 in 2015. Millennium Development Goal No 4: Reduce child mortality The proportion of children who die before they turn 5 has more than halved, falling from 90 to 43 deaths per 1000 live births between 1990 and 2015. Millennium Development Goal No 5: Improve maternal health The global proportion of mothers who die during pregnancy or birth has decreased by nearly half – falling from 380 per 100 000 births in 1990 to 210 in 2013. Millennium Development Goal No 6: Combat HIV/AIDS, malaria and other diseases The number of new HIV infections declined by approximately 40 per cent between 2000 and 2013. Nevertheless, the target of reversing the spread of HIV/ AIDS by 2015 has not been achieved. FIGURE 7.3 Various measures of improvements in people’s lives. Millions of lives improved compared to 1990–2000* trend 500 471 400 300 200 111 100 19 0 –100 (99) –200 –300 (169) Water Primary school completion Extreme income poverty Sanitation Undernourishment Sub-Saharan Africa China India Rest of developing world Note: For primary school completion, data do not allow for regional breakdown outside of Africa. * Years adjusted to account for data availability where needed. Source: Global Economy and Development program, The Brookings Institution. John W. McArthur, Krista Rasmussen, Change of Pace: Accelerations and advances during the millennium development goal era, Figure E2, p. v., Authors’ calculations based on World Bank (2016b, c), U.N.-DESA (2015). 156 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 4 The real economyCopyright in the long run 07_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 156 24/08/20 6:12 PM Millennium Development Goal No 7: Ensure environmental sustainability Between 1990 and 2015, more than 2.5 billion people have gained access to improved drinking water. Despite such progress, more than 600 million people globally still do not have access to drinking water of satisfactory quality. Millennium Development Goal No 8: Develop a global partnership for development Assistance of high-income to low-income countries rose by 66 per cent (in real terms) during the 2000–2014 period. Most high-income countries are, however, still below the agreed global target of 0.7 per cent of Gross National Income (GNI). Unfortunately, Australia and New Zealand are both in this category, with each spending 0.27 per cent of GNI on official development assistance. This contrasts with 0.71 per cent in the UK, 1.05 per cent in Norway and 1.4 per cent in Sweden. FIGURE 7.4 The United Nation’s 17 Sustainable Development Goals for the 2016–30 period Source: © UNITED NATIONS 2020. The content of this publication has not been approved by the United Nations and does not reflect the views of the United Nations or its officials or Member States. https://www.un.org/sustainabledevelopment/ CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING Describe the global trends in poverty over the past several decades. Find out more about the Sustainable Development Goals for the 2016–2030 period and discuss which of them you believe are likely to be achieved. Think about some specific ideas for how environmental sustainability can be enhanced globally. 157 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN Chapter 02-200-202 7 Production and growth 07_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 157 24/08/20 6:12 PM Discouraging excessive population growth A country’s productivity and living standards are determined in part by its population growth. Obviously, population is a key determinant of a country’s labour force. It is no surprise, therefore, that countries with large populations (like the United States and China) tend to produce a greater GDP than countries with small populations (like Australia and New Zealand). But as you already know, total GDP is not a good measure of economic wellbeing. For policymakers concerned about living standards, GDP per person is more important, since it tells us the quantity of goods and services available for a typical individual in the economy. How does growth in the number of people affect the amount of GDP per person? Early nineteenth-century economist Thomas Malthus believed that population growth is undesirable and likely to lead to famine and poverty – an idea known as the Malthusian trap. While this idea is generally incorrect, data suggest that excessive population growth may be associated with some problems. The most important of them is insufficient education and lack of human capital. Countries with very high population growth have large numbers of school-age children, which places a major burden on the educational system. It is not surprising, therefore, that educational attainment tends to be low in such countries. The differences in population growth around the world are still large, despite getting smaller. In high-income countries, like Australia, the United States and countries in western Europe, the population has risen about 1 per cent per year in recent decades, and it is expected to rise more slowly (or even shrink) in the future. In contrast, in many African countries, population growth has been about 3 per cent per year. You can calculate, using the rule of 70, that at this rate the population doubles every 23 years. Reducing the rate of population growth is widely thought to be one way that low-income countries can raise their standards of living. In some countries, this goal is accomplished directly with laws regulating the number of children families may have. China, for instance, used to allow only one child per family under most circumstances; couples who violated this rule were subject to substantial fines. In countries with greater freedom, the goal of reduced population growth is accomplished less directly by increasing awareness of birth control techniques. The final way in which a country can influence population growth is to apply one of the Ten Principles of Economics – people respond to incentives. Bearing a child, like any decision, has an opportunity cost. When the opportunity cost rises, people will choose to have smaller families. In particular, women with the opportunity to receive good education and desirable employment tend to want fewer children than those with unappealing opportunities outside the home. Hence, policies that foster equal treatment of women are one way to reduce the rate of population growth. And encouraging results can already be seen in the data. Population growth has decreased in virtually all low- and middle-income countries hand in hand with improvements in incomes. Let us provide some numbers. Total world fertility has halved over the past six decades – the average number of children per woman decreased from about 5 in 1950 to less than 2.5 in 2016, and continues to decrease. For example, in Turkey the total fertility rate decreased from 7 to just over 2, which is comparable to the current rate in the United States and New Zealand, and only slightly higher than Australia’s figure of 1.8. Similarly, Bangladesh’s fertility rate was between 6 and 7 during 1950–80, and since then has decreased to around 2.3. Even in Yemen, a country which had a fertility rate of 9 as recently as 1980, the average number of children per woman decreased to 3.7, and keeps falling. Let us note that it is not just excessively high fertility rates that can cause problems; it is also excessively low fertility rates. If the number of children per woman falls below the 158 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 4 The real economyCopyright in the long run 07_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 158 24/08/20 6:12 PM ‘replacement rate’ of 2.1, the population starts shrinking (in the absence of immigration). And most high-income countries are in this category. In fact, many countries have fertility rates in a dangerous territory of below 1.5: for example, Japan, South Korea, Russia, Germany, Italy and the Czech Republic. Not to mention Singapore and Macau, whose fertility rates are the lowest in the world – below 1. One of the resulting problems of insufficient population growth is ensuring sustainability of public finances. In most high-income countries, pensions and health care systems are designed on the pay-as-you-go basis, whereby government expenditure each year is paid for by the tax revenue from that year. Very low fertility leads to an ageing population with an increasing number of retirees per worker. This results in an increase in pension and health care expenditures but a fall in tax revenue, and therefore a growing budget deficit and debt. You will find out more about this problem in the next chapter. The link between population growth and technological progress Some economists have argued that rapid population growth may depress economic prosperity by reducing the amount of capital each worker has. This view believes that there are diminishing returns to labour, for the same reason as there are diminishing returns to physical capital. On the other hand, other economists have suggested that world population growth has been an engine of technological progress and economic prosperity, essentially arguing that there are increasing returns to scale and/or positive externalities from human capital accumulation. The mechanism is simple: If there are more people, then there are more scientists, inventors and engineers to contribute to technological advances, which benefits everyone. Economist Michael Kremer has provided some support for this hypothesis in an article titled ‘Population Growth and Technological Change: One Million B.C. to 1990’, which was published in the Quarterly Journal of Economics in 1993. Kremer begins by noting that over the broad span of human history, world GDP growth rates have increased with world population. For example, world economic growth was more rapid when the world population was one billion (which occurred around the year 1800) than when the population was only 100 million (around 500 BC). This fact is consistent with the hypothesis that a larger population induces more technological progress. Kremer’s second piece of evidence comes from comparing regions of the world. The melting of the polar icecaps at the end of the Ice Age around 10 000 BC flooded the land bridges and separated the world into several distinct regions that could not communicate with one another for thousands of years. If technological progress is more rapid when there are more people to discover things, then larger regions should have experienced more rapid growth. According to Kremer, that is exactly what happened. The most successful region of the world in 1500 (when Columbus re-established technological contact) comprised the ‘Old World’ civilisations of the large Eurasia–Africa region. Next in technological development were the Aztec and Mayan civilizations in the Americas, followed by the hunter-gatherers of Australia, and then the people of Tasmania, who lacked even firemaking and most stone and bone tools. The smallest isolated region was Flinders Island, a tiny island between Tasmania and Australia. With a very small population, Flinders Island had few opportunities for technological advancement and, indeed, seemed to regress. Around 3000 BC, human society on Flinders Island died out completely. A large population, Kremer concludes, is a prerequisite for technological advancement. CASE STUDY Questions 1 What do you think are the pros and cons to the economy of having a larger population? 2 Do you believe Michael Kremer’s prerequisite for having a larger population is valid? 159 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN Chapter 02-200-202 7 Production and growth 07_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 159 24/08/20 6:12 PM CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING What is your view of immigration? How does immigration affect the economy? If you were the prime minister in your home country, how would you design the immigration system? Research and development An important reason that living standards are higher today than they were a century ago is that technological knowledge has advanced. The mobile phone, the silicon chip and the solar panel are among the thousands of innovations that have improved our ability to produce goods and services at a lower cost. Although most technological advances come from private research by firms and individual inventors, there is also a public interest in promoting these efforts. We mentioned that to a large extent, knowledge is a public good – once a person discovers an idea, the idea enters society’s pool of knowledge, and other people can use it freely. Therefore, just as the government has a role in providing public goods like national defence, it may also help to encourage research and development of new technologies. The Australian government has long played a major role in the creation and dissemination of technological knowledge. The government funds research in institutions like the CSIRO (the Commonwealth Scientific and Industrial Research Organisation). It also provides funding for research in universities across the country through research grants from the Australian Research Council and the National Health and Medical Research Council, and tax breaks for firms engaging in research and development. Yet another way in which government policy has attempted to encourage research is through the patent system. When a person or firm invents a new product, like a new drug, the inventor can apply for a patent. The idea is that if the product is deemed truly original, the government awards the patent, which gives the inventor the exclusive right to make the product for a specified number of years. In essence, the patent gives the inventor a property right over the invention, turning the new idea from a public good into a private good. It is argued that by allowing inventors to profit from their inventions – even if only temporarily – the patent system enhances the incentive for individuals and firms to engage in research. This traditional view of the patent system has, however, been forcefully challenged by recent research. Most notably, Professors Michele Boldrin and David Levine argue that: ‘intellectual property is a government grant of a costly and dangerous private monopoly over ideas’. In their 2008 book titled Against Intellectual Monopoly they show convincingly through economic theory, data and numerous historical examples that ‘intellectual monopoly is not necessary for innovation and as a practical matter is damaging to growth, prosperity and liberty’. To do what they preach, they make the entire book available on the internet for free (http://www.dklevine.com/general/intellectual/againstfinal.htm). Let us summarise their case. Boldrin and Levine argue that patents are not essential for innovation by showing that technology-heavy industries, like the early software industry, have flourished without patent protection. The authors then report data on many instances where patents clearly hindered competition and innovation: for example, James Watt’s steam engine patents in the second half of the nineteenth century. The book documents the incredible growth in patents in recent decades (for example, Microsoft adding more than 1000 patent applications each month!). It then offers three main reasons for why excessive patent protection is likely to be undesirable. First, attempts to get patent protection and enforce it are associated with a lot of expensive and unproductive (primarily legal) actions. The recent Apple vs Samsung patent wars with more than 50 court cases serve as a telling example. Second, the danger that a rival company patents ‘your’ idea 160 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 4 The real economyCopyright in the long run 07_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 160 24/08/20 6:12 PM just before you do arguably discourages innovation. As Boldrin and Levine state: ‘Insofar as innovators have unique ideas, it may make sense to reward them with monopolies to make sure we get advantage of their unusual talents … As it happens, simultaneous discoveries tend to be the rule rather than the exception’. Third and most importantly, excessive patent protection inhibits a key driver of prosperity, namely learning from others. As the authors argue: ‘Imitation is a great thing. It is among the most powerful technologies humans have ever developed’. CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING Why is research and development (R&D) important for long-run economic growth? IN THE NEWS Using experiments to evaluate aid and ignite prosperity To figure out what policies are effective in low-income nations, economists are increasingly turning to randomised controlled experiments used in medical trials. What it takes to lift families out of poverty by Michaeleen Doucleff 15 May 2015 Eighteen years ago, Dean Karlan was a fresh, bright-eyed graduate student in economics at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology. He wanted to answer what seemed like a simple question: ‘Does global aid work?’ Karlan says. He was reading a bunch of studies on the topic. But none of them actually answered the question. ‘We were tearing our hair out reading these papers because it was frustrating,’ he says. ‘[We] never really felt like the papers were really satisfactory.’ One problem was that no one was actually testing global aid programs — methodically — to see if they really changed people’s lives permanently. ‘They haven’t been taking the scientific method to problems of poverty,’ he says. Take, for instance, a charity that gives a family a cow. The charity might check on the family a year later and say, ‘Wow! The family is doing so much better with this cow. Cows must be the reason.’ But maybe it wasn’t the cow that improved the family’s life. Maybe it had a bumper crop that year or property values went up in the neighborhood. Researchers really weren’t doing those experiments, Karlan says. So he and a bunch of his colleagues had a radical idea: Test aid with the same method doctors use to test drugs (that is, randomized control trials). The idea is quite simple. Give some families aid but others nothing. Then follow both groups, and see if the aid actually made a difference in the long run. Karlan, who’s now a professor at Yale University, says many people were skeptical. ‘I have many conversations with people who say, ‘You want to do what? Why would you want to do that?’ One issue is that some families go home empty-handed, with no aid. So the idea seems unethical. But Karlan disagrees. ‘The whole point of this is to help more people,’ he says. ‘If we find out what works and what doesn’t, in five years we can have a much bigger impact.’ So Karlan and collaborators around the world, including those at the Abdul Latif Jameel Poverty Action Lab at MIT and the nonprofit Innovations for Poverty Action, decided to try out the idea with one of the toughest problems out there: helping families get out of extreme poverty. An anti-poverty program in Bangladesh, called BRAC, looked like it was successful. It seemed to help nearly 400 000 families who were living off less than $1.25 each day. 161 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN Chapter 02-200-202 7 Production and growth 07_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 161 24/08/20 6:12 PM So Karlan and his colleagues wanted to test the program and see if it could work in other countries. They teamed up with a network of researchers and nonprofits in six developing countries. They went to thousands of communities and found the poorest families. Then they divided the families into two groups. They gave half the families nothing. And the other half a whole smorgasbord of aid for one to two years. They gave them: 1. Some livestock for making money, such as goats for milk, bees for honey, or guinea pigs for selling. ‘Depending on the site, there were different things specifically appropriate for that context,’ Karlan says. 2. Training about how to raise the livestock 3. Food or cash so they wouldn’t eat the livestock 4. A savings account 5. Help with their health – both physical and mental Karlan and his colleagues reported the results of the massive experiment in the journal Science this week. So what did they find? Well, the strategy worked pretty well in five of the six countries they tried it in. Families who got the aid started making a little more money, and they had more food to eat. ‘We see mental health go up. Happiness go up. We even saw things like female power increase,’ Karlan says. But here’s what sets this study apart from the rest: Families continued to make a bit more money even a year after the aid stopped. ‘People were stuck. They give them this big push, and they seem to be on a sustained increased income level,’ says Justin Sandefur, an economist at the Center for Global Development in Washington, who wasn’t involved in the study. ‘What I found exciting and unique about this study is that the impact of the aid was durable and sustainable,’ he added. The results suggest that the right kind of aid does help people in multiple places. It lifted the families up just a little bit so they could finally start inching out of extreme poverty. But we shouldn’t get too excited yet. These people are still very poor, says Sarah Baird, an economist at George Washington University. The effect of the aid was actually quite small, she says. Families’ incomes and food consumption together went up by only a small amount — about 5 percent, on average, when compared with the control group. And it’s still unknown how long this bump will last. The researchers looked at the change only a year after the aid stopped. ‘Moving poverty is hard,’ Baird says. ‘The fact that they [Karlan and colleagues] were able to move it, and it was sustainable after a year, I think is important.’ The findings are a leap forward, she says, because it shows charities and governments a basic strategy that often works. And even a little bit of extra money can make a huge difference in these peoples’ lives, she says. It can help them send their kids to school. Or even just give them a little more hope. Source: © 2015 National Public Radio, Inc, NPR news report titled ‘What it takes to lift families out of poverty’ by Michaeleen Doucleff was originally published on npr.org on May 15 2015, and is used with permission of NPR. Any unauthorised duplication is strictly prohibited. CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING Refer to the previous article ‘What it takes to lift families out of poverty’. Do you think global aid works? 162 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 4 The real economyCopyright in the long run 07_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 162 24/08/20 6:12 PM Conclusion: The importance of long-run growth In this chapter we have discussed what determines the standard of living in a nation and how policymakers can endeavour to raise it through policies that promote economic growth. A part of this chapter is summarised in one of the Ten Principles of Economics – a country’s standard of living depends on its ability to produce goods and services. Policymakers who want to encourage improvements in prosperity should aim to increase their nation’s productive ability by encouraging accumulation of physical and human capital as well as technological knowledge, and enabling people to use natural resources as effectively and sustainably as possible. This chapter argued that there do not seem to be technological limits to economic growth, but highlighted likely environmental and physical constraints relating to our energy usage. Our simple economy of Robinson Crusoe offered further insights that refute some people’s criticisms of economic growth. First, economic growth needs neither inflation nor debt – Crusoe did not use money on the island, but could still increase his output. Second, it is possible to improve wellbeing without increases in real GDP – when Crusoe became more productive, he could enjoy the same output with more leisure. Third, economic growth does not have to be hostile to the environment. It does not necessarily require an ever-increasing amount of natural resources since technological progress finds ways of using resources more effectively. Fourth, excessive focus on high output today may be costly in terms of future growth. The latter requires investing time and resources into accumulation of capital and technology – Crusoe taking the time to make better tools that increase his future productivity rather than only maximising his current harvest. Economists differ in their views on the role of government in promoting economic growth. At the very least, the government can lend support to the invisible hand of the market by maintaining property rights and political stability. A more controversial debate is whether government should target and subsidise specific industries that might be especially important for technological progress. There is no doubt that these issues are among the most important in economics. The success of one generation’s policymakers in learning and heeding the fundamental lessons about economic growth determines what kind of world the next generation will inherit. 163 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN Chapter 02-200-202 7 Production and growth 07_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 163 24/08/20 6:12 PM STUDY TOOLS Summary LO7.1 Economic growth is the result of growth in labour and physical capital as well as human capital and technological knowledge. Different countries grow at different rates because they start out with differing levels of these economic variables. Economies get a particular boost from increases in human capital and technological knowledge. LO7.2 The accumulation of physical capital is subject to diminishing returns – the more physical capital each worker has, the less additional output she produces from an extra unit of it. Because of diminishing returns, higher saving leads to higher economic growth for a period of time, but growth eventually slows down as the economy approaches a higher level of capital, productivity and income per person. Also because of diminishing returns, the return on physical capital is especially high in less industrial countries. These countries can therefore grow faster and catch up with richer countries. LO7.3 Government policies can influence the economy’s growth rate in many ways – fostering education, promoting saving, encouraging investment (both domestic and from abroad), maintaining property rights and political stability, allowing free trade, discouraging excessive population growth, and promoting the research and development of new technologies. Key concepts catch-up (or convergence) effect, p. 149 diminishing returns, p. 149 economic growth, p. 138 human capital, p. 143 natural resources, p. 143 physical capital, p. 142 returns to scale, p. 146 technological knowledge, p. 143 Practice questions Questions for review 1 2 3 4 5 6 What do the level of GDP per person and the growth rate of GDP per person tell us about the standard of living in a society? Why is productivity important? Highlight the main determinants of labour productivity. Which one do you think is most important? Do you think a country can ‘over-invest’ in physical capital? Do you think a country can ‘overinvest’ in human capital? Explain and highlight the pros and cons. What are the differences and similarities between returns to scale and returns to an input (like natural resources)? Why are decreasing returns to scale less likely than diminishing returns to physical capital? Carefully explain. How does the rate of immigration influence the level of GDP per person in a country such as Australia? Does it matter what educational level the immigrants have achieved before they arrive in the new country? Can you offer any solutions to the recent European migration crisis? Describe two ways in which the Australian government tries to encourage advances in technological knowledge. Try to propose some additional measures. Multiple choice 1 Over the past century, real GDP per person in Australia has grown about . which means it doubles approximately every a 0.4 per cent per year, 175 months b 8.7 per cent per year, 8 years c 1.6 per cent per year, 44 years d 3.2 per cent per month, 32 years , 164 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 4 The real economyCopyright in the long run 07_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 164 24/08/20 6:12 PM 2 3 4 Most economists are _______________ that natural resources will eventually limit economic growth. As evidence, they note that the prices of most natural resources, adjusted for overall inflation, have tended to_______________over time. a concerned, rise b concerned, fall c not concerned, rise d not concerned, fall Because physical capital is subject to diminishing returns, higher saving and investment do not lead to a higher a level of income in the long run. b level of income in the short run. c growth rate of income in the long run. d growth rate of income in the short run. Thomas Robert Malthus believed that population growth would a lead to food shortages and famine. b spread the capital stock too thinly across the labour force, lowering each worker’s productivity. c promote technological progress, because there would be more scientists and inventors. d eventually decline to sustainable levels, as birth control improved and people had smaller families. Problems and applications 1 2 3 4 5 Use the data in the table to answer the following questions. Year Billions of $AUD (constant prices) 2015 1185 2016 1230 2017 1270 2018 1285 2019 1310 a Calculate the economic growth rate for each year from 2015 to 2019. b Calculate the average annual economic growth rate from 2015 to 2019. Comment on your answer. Suppose that society decided to permanently increase the saving rate and investment. a How would this change affect the level of real GDP and the rate of economic growth, both in the short term and long term? b Would it matter what type of investment (physical vs human capital) was undertaken? c What groups in society would benefit from this change? What groups might be hurt? d Why are politicians often reluctant to encourage people to save, despite this enhancing the nation’s prosperity in the long term? Australian (inflation adjusted) income per person today is around five times what it was a century ago. Many other countries have also experienced significant economic growth over that period. What are some specific ways in which your standard of living differs from that of your great-grandparents? Is your standard of living higher in every regard, or can you think of counter-examples? Suppose that a computer-manufacturing company owned entirely by Japanese citizens opens a new factory in Melbourne, Australia. a What sort of foreign investment would this represent? b What would be the effect of this investment on Australian GDP? Would the effect on Australian GNP be larger or smaller? How would it affect Japanese GDP and GNP? Do you think free trade is good for a country such as Australia? What two factors determine the amount that nations trade? 165 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN Chapter 02-200-202 7 Production and growth 07_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 165 24/08/20 6:12 PM 6 7 8 Different governments grant patents for different numbers of years, although the general trend of the past decades has been to increase the breadth and depth of patent protection (so that patents not only cover genuine innovations but also some very obvious ‘ideas’). a How do you think country differences in patent protection affect the decisions of multinational corporations about where to conduct their research and development? b Suppose governments everywhere increased the number of years a patent lasts. What do you think would be the effect of this change on the incentive to do research and on the growth rate of GDP? Outline the various arguments. International data show a positive correlation between political stability and economic growth. a Through what mechanism could political stability lead to strong economic growth? b Through what mechanism could strong economic growth lead to political stability? Why is research and development (R&D) important for long-run economic growth? How has the Australian government played a role in facilitating R&D? 166 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 4 The real economyCopyright in the long run 07_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 166 24/08/20 6:12 PM 8 Saving, investment and the financial system Learning objectives After reading this chapter, you should be able to: LO8.1 identify important financial institutions in the Australian and world economy LO8.2discuss the role of the financial system and its relationship to key macroeconomic variables LO8.3analyse how the interest rate is determined, and how market forces and economic policies impact equilibrium saving and investment LO8.4examine how government budget deficits and surpluses affect the Australian and world economy. 167 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 08_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 167 24/08/20 4:33 PM Introduction financial system the group of institutions in the economy that help to match saving with investment Imagine that you have just graduated from university (with a degree in economics, of course) and you decide to start your own business – a consulting firm. Before you make any money selling your economic insights to firms, you have to incur substantial costs to set up your business. You have to buy computer hardware and software with which to make your analysis, as well as desks and chairs to furnish your new office and a phone to communicate with your clients. Each of these is a type of capital that your firm will use to produce and sell its services. How do you obtain the funds to invest in these capital goods? Perhaps you are able to pay for them out of your past savings. More likely, however, like most entrepreneurs, you do not have enough money of your own to finance the start of your business. As a result, you have to get the money you need from other sources. There are various ways for you to finance these capital investments. You could borrow the money, perhaps from a bank or from a friend. In this case, you would promise not only to return the money at a later date but also to pay interest. Alternatively, you could convince someone to provide the money you need for your business in exchange for a share of your future profits. In either case, your investment in computers and office equipment is being financed by someone else’s saving. The financial system consists of those institutions in the economy that help to match one person’s saving with another person’s investment. As we discussed in the previous chapter, saving and investment are key ingredients to economic growth. When a country saves a good portion of its GDP, more resources are available for investment in capital, and higher capital generally raises a country’s productivity and living standard. But that chapter did not explain how the economy coordinates saving and investment. At any time, some people want to save part of their income for the future and others want to borrow in order to finance investments in new and growing businesses. How are these two groups of people brought together? What ensures that the supply of funds from those who want to save exactly balances the demand for funds from those who want to invest? This chapter answers these questions by examining how the financial system works. First, we discuss the large variety of institutions that make up the financial system in our economy. Second, we discuss the relationship between the financial system and some key macroeconomic variables – notably saving and investment. Third, we develop a model of the supply of and demand for funds in financial markets. In the model, the interest rate is the price that adjusts to balance supply and demand. The model enables us to show how various economic developments and government policies affect the interest rate and, thereby, society’s allocation of scarce resources. LO8.1 Financial institutions in the Australian economy At the broadest level, the financial system moves the economy’s scarce resources from savers (people who spend less than they earn) to borrowers (people who spend more than they earn). Savers save for various reasons – to put a child through university in several years’ time or to retire comfortably in several decades. Similarly, borrowers borrow for various reasons – to buy a house in which to live or to start a business with which to make a living. Savers supply their money to the financial system with the expectation that they will get it back with interest at a later date. Borrowers demand money from the financial system with the knowledge that they will be required to pay it back with interest at a later date. The financial system is made up of various financial institutions that help coordinate the actions of savers and borrowers. As a prelude to analysing the economic forces that drive the financial system, let’s discuss the most important of them. Financial institutions can be grouped into two categories – financial markets and financial intermediaries. 168 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 4 The real economyCopyright in the long run 08_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 168 24/08/20 4:33 PM Financial markets Financial markets are the institutions through which a person who wants to save can directly supply funds to a person who wants to borrow. The two most important financial markets in our economy are the bond market and the stock market. The bond market When BHP, the big international resources company, wants to borrow to finance construction of a new copper mine, it can borrow directly from the public. It does this by selling bonds. A bond is a certificate of indebtedness that specifies the obligations of the borrower to the holder of the bond. Put simply, a bond is just an IOU (I owe you). It identifies the time at which the loan will be repaid, called the date of maturity, and the rate of interest that will be paid periodically until the loan matures. Buyers of bonds give their money to BHP in exchange for the promise of interest and eventual repayment of the amount borrowed (called the principal). Buyers can hold the bonds until maturity or sell them at an earlier date to someone else. There are hundreds of different kinds of bonds in the Australian economy. When large corporations or governments need to borrow to finance the purchase of a new factory or a new jet fighter, they usually do so by issuing bonds. If you look at the Australian Financial Review or the Australian Securities Exchange website (http://www.asx.com.au), you will find a listing of the prices and interest rates on some of the most important bonds. Although they differ in many ways, three characteristics of bonds are most important. The first characteristic is a bond’s term – the length of time until the bond matures. Some bonds have short terms, like a few months, and others have terms as long as 100 years. (The British government has even issued a bond that never matures, called a perpetuity. This bond pays interest forever, but the principal is never repaid.) The interest rate on a bond depends, in part, on its term. Long-term bonds are riskier than short-term bonds because holders of long-term bonds have to wait longer for repayment of the principal. If a holder of a long-term bond needs the money earlier than the distant date of maturity, the buyer has no choice but to sell the bond to someone else, perhaps at a reduced price. To compensate for this risk, long-term bonds usually pay higher interest rates than short-term bonds. The second important characteristic of a bond is its credit risk – the probability that the borrower will fail to pay some of the interest or principal. Such a failure to pay is called a default. Borrowers default on their loans by declaring bankruptcy. When bond buyers perceive that the probability of default is high, they demand a higher interest rate to compensate them for this risk. Therefore, the relationship between risk and returns for various types of assets is an upward sloping curve; see Figure 8.1. Because most governments, including Australia’s, are considered safe borrowers with no or little credit risk, government bonds tend to pay low interest rates. They are in the bottom left-hand part of the risk-versus-returns curve. In contrast, financially shaky corporations raise money by issuing junk bonds, which pay very high interest rates. These are in the top right-hand part of the risk-versus-returns curve of Figure 8.1. Buyers of bonds can judge credit risk by checking with various private credit-rating agencies that evaluate the credit risk of different bonds. For example, Standard & Poor’s rates bonds from AAA (the safest) to D (already in default). financial markets financial institutions through which savers can directly provide funds to borrowers bond a certificate of indebtedness CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING What are the three important characteristics of a bond? Can you construct a diagram for the saying: ‘the higher risk, the higher the reward’? 169 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in WCN 02-200-202and the financial system Chapter 8 part. Saving, investment 08_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 169 24/08/20 4:33 PM FIGURE 8.1 The trade-off between risk and return Aggressive High Balanced Real return Conservative Low Cash Risk High When people increase the percentage of their savings that they have invested in shares as opposed to bonds, they increase the average return they can expect to earn, but they also increase the risks they face. The third important characteristic of a bond is its tax treatment – the way in which the tax laws treat the interest earned on the bond. The interest on most bonds is taxable income, so the bond owner has to pay a portion of the interest he earns in income taxes. In some countries, e.g. in the United States, the owners of state and local governments’ bonds, called municipal bonds, are not required to pay federal income tax on the interest income. Because of this tax advantage, bonds issued by state and local governments in the United States pay a lower interest rate than bonds issued by corporations or the federal government. However, in Australia, interest earned on all bonds is treated as any other type of income and taxed at the normal rate. The stock market shares a claim to partial ownership in a firm Another way for BHP to raise funds to build a new copper mine is to sell shares in the company. Shares (stocks) represent ownership in a firm and are, therefore, a claim to the profits that the firm makes. For example, if BHP sells a total of one million shares, then each share represents ownership of 1/1 000 000 of the business. The sale of shares to raise money is called equity finance, whereas the sale of bonds is called debt finance. Although corporations use both equity and debt finance to raise money for new investments, shares and bonds are very different. The owner of shares in BHP is a part-owner of BHP; the owner of a BHP bond is a creditor of the corporation. If BHP is very profitable, the shareholders enjoy the benefits of these profits, whereas the bondholders get only the interest on their bonds. But if BHP runs into financial difficulty, the bondholders are paid what they are due before shareholders receive anything at all. Compared with bonds, shares offer the holder both higher risk and potentially higher return; see this relationship in Figure 8.1. CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING How can a firm raise capital to finance investment projects? What are the main differences between shares and bonds? Highlight and compare. 170 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 4 The real economyCopyright in the long run 08_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 170 24/08/20 4:33 PM Shutterstock.com/charnsitr After a corporation sells shares to the public, these shares trade among shareholders on organised stock exchanges. In these transactions, the corporation itself receives no money when its shares change hands. The most important stock exchange in the Australian economy is the ASX (the Australian Securities Exchange Ltd). It makes the top 10 stock exchanges in the world based on market capitalisation; the value of all the shares issued and traded there is around $2 trillion with close to 2200 listed companies and issuers (as of early 2020). Given the interconnectedness of financial markets, it is no surprise that our stock market is also influenced by stock markets overseas. Some of the key ones are the New York Stock Exchange and NASDAQ in the United States, the Tokyo Stock Exchange, the Stock Exchange of Hong Kong, the Shanghai Stock Exchange and the London Stock Exchange. Most of the world’s countries have their own stock exchanges on which the shares of local companies trade. The share prices observed on stock exchanges are determined by supply and demand. Because shares represent ownership in a corporation, the demand for a share reflects people’s perception of the corporation’s future profitability and/or expected future price movements. When people become optimistic about a company’s future (or for whatever reason believe that its share price will increase), they raise their demand for its shares and thereby bid up the price of a share. Conversely, when people expect a company to have little profit or even losses, the demand falls, reducing the share price. Various share indexes are available to monitor the overall level of share prices. A share index is calculated as an average of a group of share prices. The oldest Australian share index is the All Ordinaries, which is an index of common shares listed on the ASX. The most widely used Australian index is the S&P/ASX 200 introduced in 2000. Its components are weighted based on their market value, so larger companies form a greater proportion of the index than smaller companies. One of the world’s most famous share indexes is the Dow Jones Industrial Average in the United States, which has been calculated since 1896. It is now based on the prices of the shares of 30 major US companies, like Apple, Nike, Visa, Coca-Cola, Boeing, McDonald’s and Microsoft. Other well-known share indexes include the Nikkei in Tokyo, the Hang Seng in Hong Kong, the FTSE in London and Standard & Poor’s 500 Index in the United States. Because share prices reflect expected profitability, these share indexes are watched closely as possible indicators of future economic conditions. 171 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in WCN 02-200-202and the financial system Chapter 8 part. Saving, investment 08_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 171 24/08/20 4:33 PM CASE STUDY Key numbers for stock watchers When following the stock of any company investors keep an eye on four key numbers. These numbers are reported on the financial pages of some newspapers, and you can easily obtain them online as well (like at Yahoo! Finance or the ASX website). • Price. The single most important piece of information about a share is its price. The newspaper usually presents several prices. The ‘closing’ price is the price of the last transaction that occurred before the stock exchange closed the previous day. Many newspapers also give the ‘high’ and ‘low’ prices over the past day of trading and, sometimes, over the past year as well. • Volume. Most newspapers present the number of shares sold during the past day or week of trading. These figures are called the daily volume and the weekly volume. A higher volume is generally preferred by investors as it means they can more easily sell the shares if they need to. • Dividend. Corporations pay out some of their profits to their shareholders; this amount is called the dividend. (Profits not paid out are called retained profits and are used by the corporation for additional investment.) Newspapers often report the dividend paid over the previous year for each share. They sometimes report the dividend yield, which is the dividend expressed as a percentage of the share’s price. • Price–earnings ratio. This ratio, often called the P/E ratio, is the price of a corporation’s share divided by the amount the corporation earned per share over the past year. Historically, the typical price–earnings ratio is about 15. A higher P/E ratio indicates that a corporation’s shares are expensive relative to its recent earnings; this might mean either that people expect earnings to rise in the future or that the shares are overvalued. Conversely, a lower P/E ratio may imply the opposite. You may be interested to know that Warren Buffett, one of the worlds’ richest people, based his investment strategy on finding such undervalued companies. According to Investopedia.com, a $10 000 investment in Buffett’s Berkshire Hathaway in 1965 would have been worth nearly $30 million by 2005, 60 times more than an investment in the S&P 500 stock market index. But before you break your piggy bank and rush to invest in the stock market you should know that many have tried Buffett’s approach – called ‘value investing’ – and were unable to replicate his success. In the list below, we’ve included one Australian company that is listed on the US index, NASDAQ. Atlassian is a very successful tech company that has achieved a very high price by Australian standards – nearly USD120 per share. It hasn’t paid a dividend yet, so the dividend yield can’t be calculated. Symbol for company’s shares Name of company ASX Code CBA WBC NAB Commonwealth Bank of Australia Westpac Banking Corporation National Australia Bank Market capitalisation (total value) Last sale price in billion $ in $ High Low in million shares in % 139.92 79.170 83.990 67.310 1.78 5.44 16.3 97.97 27.420 30.500 23.300 15.0 6.35 13.950 81.94 28.470 30.000 22.520 8.38 5.83 16.60 42.330 Highest and Price/ Daily Dividend lowest price over earnings volume yield the past year ratio BHP BHP 110.03 37.300 29.062 5.70 5.14 16.320 CSL CSL Limited 118.6 261.340 263.180 173.000 0.369 1.02 43.27 TLS Telstra Corporation 41.75 3.510 3.978 2.663 13.56 2.85 19.39 TEAM Atlassian USD14.5Bn 118.95 149.80 65.17 1.42 – 2294 Sources: https://www.asx.com.au/asx/share-price-research/company. Prices at 10 Nov 2019. For TEAM (Atlassian, listed on the US NASDAQ): https://www.nasdaq.com/market-activity/stocks/team 172 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 4 The real economyCopyright in the long run 08_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 172 24/08/20 4:33 PM Questions 1 2 Based on the data provided in the above table, which company has the lowest daily volume? What does a lower daily volume generally mean? Which company has the highest price–earnings ratio? What does a higher price–earnings ratio generally mean? Financial intermediaries Financial intermediaries are financial institutions through which savers can indirectly provide funds to borrowers. The term intermediary reflects the role of these institutions in standing between savers and borrowers. Here we consider two of the most important financial intermediaries – banks and managed funds. financial intermediaries financial institutions through which savers can indirectly provide funds to borrowers Banks Chris owns a small grocery store and wants to finance a business expansion. The strategy taken is probably quite different from that of BHP. Unlike BHP, Chris would find it difficult to raise funds in the bond and stock markets. Most buyers of shares and bonds prefer to buy those issued by larger, more familiar companies. Chris is therefore likely to finance his business expansion with a loan from a local bank. Banks are the financial intermediaries with which people are most familiar. One of the main jobs of banks is to take in deposits from people who want to save and use these deposits to make loans to people who want to borrow. Banks pay depositors interest on their deposits and charge borrowers slightly higher interest on their loans. The difference between these rates of interest covers the banks’ costs and returns some profit to the owners of the banks. Before we proceed it should be noted that the standard process of taking deposits and then offering loans can run in reverse. In the fractional reserve banking system used around the world, which we will discuss in a later chapter, commercial banks can decide to give a loan and only then create a deposit of that value, without waiting for a deposit from one of their clients. Some economists are critical of the fact that commercial banks can create money out of thin air and even circumvent the savers (see for example http://en.wikipedia. org/wiki/The_Chicago_Plan_Revisited). Besides being financial intermediaries, banks also facilitate purchases of goods and services by allowing people to write cheques or use debit cards (EFTPOS) against their deposits. In other words, banks help create a special asset that people can use as a medium of exchange. A medium of exchange is an item that people can easily use to make payments. A bank’s role in providing a medium of exchange distinguishes it from many other financial institutions. Shares and bonds, like bank deposits, are a possible store of value for the wealth that people have accumulated in past saving, but access to this wealth is not as easy, cheap and immediate as just writing a cheque or using a debit card. For now, we ignore this second role of banks, but we will return to it when we discuss the monetary system in a later chapter. Managed funds Another financial intermediary is a managed fund. It is a type of financial investment that allows investors to own a selection, or portfolio, of various types of shares and bonds without buying them individually. When an individual investor puts money into a managed fund, a manager or trustee makes the decisions about which shares or bonds to purchase. However, the individual investor in the managed fund accepts all the risk and return associated with managed fund an institution that allows investors to own a portfolio of various types of shares and/or bonds 173 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in WCN 02-200-202and the financial system Chapter 8 part. Saving, investment 08_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 173 24/08/20 4:33 PM the portfolio. If the value of the portfolio rises, the investor benefits; if the value of the portfolio falls, the investor suffers the loss. The main advantage of managed funds is that they allow people with small amounts of money to diversify risk. Buyers of shares and bonds are well advised to follow the advice ‘don’t put all your eggs in one basket’. Because the value of any single share or bond is tied to the fortunes of one company, holding a single kind of share or bond is very risky. In contrast, people who hold a diverse portfolio of shares and bonds face less risk because they have only a small stake in each company. Managed funds make this risk diversification easy. With only a few hundred dollars, a person can buy shares in a managed fund and, indirectly, become the partial owner or creditor of hundreds of major companies. For this service, the company operating the managed fund charges shareholders a fee, most commonly around 2 per cent of assets each year. A second advantage claimed by managed fund companies is that managed funds give ordinary people access to the skills of professional money managers. The managers of most managed funds are paid to closely monitor the developments and prospects of the companies in which they buy shares. These managers buy the shares of those companies that they view as having a profitable future and sell the shares of companies with less promising prospects. This professional management, it is argued, should increase the return that managed fund depositors earn on their savings. Financial economists, however, are often sceptical of the latter argument. With thousands of money managers paying close attention to each company’s prospects, it is hard to ‘beat the market’ by buying good shares and selling bad ones. In fact, managed funds called index funds, which buy all the shares in a given share index and hold them (passive investing), deliver investors a greater (risk-adjusted) return on average than managed funds that engage the services of professional money managers and trade frequently (active investing). The main explanation for the superior performance of index funds is that they keep costs low (some charge only 0.05 per cent of assets, which is 40 times less than the average of 2 per cent mentioned above for active asset management). This saving of index funds is achieved by buying and selling very rarely and by not having to pay the salaries of professional money managers (the restaurant conversation between Matthew McConaughey and Leonardo DiCaprio in the 2013 movie The Wolf of Wall Street offers some pointers in this regard). CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING What are the differences between banks and managed funds? Summing up The Australian economy contains a large variety of financial institutions. In addition to the bond market, the stock market, banks and managed funds, there are also credit unions, insurance companies, superannuation (pension) funds, and even the local loan shark. These institutions differ in many ways. When analysing the macroeconomic role of the financial system, however, it is more important to keep in mind the similarities of these institutions rather than the differences. These financial institutions all help direct the resources of 174 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 4 The real economyCopyright in the long run 08_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 174 24/08/20 4:33 PM savers into the hands of borrowers. Does this imply that policymakers should treat financial institutions ‘with extra care’ when they get into trouble? This is discussed in the box below, and more details follow in our chapter on the 2008 crisis in Chapter 17. Financial institutions in trouble: To bail or let them sink? In September 2008, a New York-based financial services company, Lehman Brothers, went bankrupt. With over US$600 billion in assets it was the largest bankruptcy in US history (almost five times bigger than the 2009 bankruptcies of the automobile giants General Motors and Chrysler combined). The failure of Lehman Brothers was a shock to the financial system, as there had not been a major financial house bankruptcy since the savings and loan failures of the late 1980s and early 1990s. Many commentators at the time predicted a collapse of the global financial system. The US government and the Federal Reserve undertook to stabilise the situation by providing liquidity to those banks and other financial institutions that were in danger of failing in late 2008. Similar rescue actions, called bailouts, were subsequently performed by many European policymakers. There is ongoing debate about whether or not the governments should have done this, and whether they should do it again in the future in similar situations. We briefly outline the ‘bailout is good’ and the ‘bailout is bad’ arguments so that you can decide whether you think we should bail out financial institutions or not. Even though these articles refer to something that happened over a decade ago, these issues are real and current. Prevent financial panic and instil confidence The pro-bailout commentators argue that because confidence is crucial to the smooth operation of the economy, and because major financial institutions (banks, insurance companies, mutual funds etc.) are heavily interconnected, policymakers must not let them go bankrupt. They are ‘too-big-to-fail’ in the sense that their collapse would cause panic in the financial market and lead to ‘bank runs’ (many people trying to withdraw all their deposits). Such financial contagion would damage even healthy institutions, and impair the ability of the financial system to serve its purpose of linking investors with savers. This could have a detrimental effect on firms, and lead to increases in unemployment, declines in the stock market and a substantial loss of household wealth. For example, Professor Paul Krugman, the recipient of the 2008 Nobel Prize in IN THE NEWS Economics, argues that the bailout acts as the fire brigade of the financial system. He believes that letting large banks fail ‘is a bad idea for the same reason that it’s a bad idea to stand aside while an urban office building burns. In both cases, the damage has a tendency to spread.’ Don’t reward excessively risky behaviour Those against bailouts argue that such implicit insurance of the government to the ‘too-big-to-fail’ financial institutions creates the wrong incentives. Knowing that they are not gambling with their own money but rather with taxpayers’ money encourages financial institutions to take on excessive risk – the so-called ‘moral hazard’ problem. This increases the danger of a costly financial crisis in the future, and the likelihood that bailouts will indeed be necessary. Professor Tyler Cowen used the 1998 bailout of the Long-Term Capital Management hedge fund as an example 175 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in WCN 02-200-202and the financial system Chapter 8 part. Saving, investment 08_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 175 24/08/20 4:33 PM of this problem in the run-up to the Global Financial Crisis of 2008. He argues that this bailout set a bad precedent: ‘Creditors came to believe that their loans to unsound financial institutions would be made good by the Fed [America’s central bank] – as long as the collapse of those institutions would threaten the global credit system. Bolstered by this sense of security, bad loans mushroomed’. We will revisit this topic in chapter 17 on the monetary system, in which you will learn how to formally show excessive leverage and bad loans in a bank’s balance sheet. Chapter 17 discusses the Global Financial Crisis and how loans to people who were not good prospects for repaying their mortgages plus an overheated property market led to the collapse of banks and put the financial position of entire countries at risk. Source: Paul Krugman, ‘The Fire Next Time’, The New York Times, 15 April 2010, http://www.nytimes.com/ 2010/04/16/opinion/16krugman.html; Tyler Cowen, ‘Bailout of Long-Term Capital: A Bad Precedent?’, The New York Times, 26 December 2008, http://www.nytimes.com/2008/12/28/business/ economy/28view.html CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING Concept Jan Libich © 2017, drawing Veronika Mojžíšová What is your view of the bailout debate? If you had been in charge of economic policy in the United States, would you have let Lehman Brothers collapse in September 2008? How would you deal with the too-big-to-fail problem going forward? (Hint: You can find some pointers in the following cartoon.) LO8.2 Saving and investment in the national income accounts Events that occur within the financial system are central to understanding developments in the overall economy. As we have just seen, the institutions that make up this system have the role of coordinating the economy’s saving and investment, which are important determinants 176 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 4 The real economyCopyright in the long run 08_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 176 24/08/20 4:33 PM of long-run economic growth and living standards. As a result, macroeconomists need to understand how financial markets work and how various events and policies affect them. As a starting point for an analysis of financial markets, we discuss the key macroeconomic variables that measure activity in these markets. Our emphasis here is not on behaviour but on accounting. Accounting refers to how various numbers are defined and added up. A personal accountant might help individuals calculate their income and expenses. A national income accountant does the same thing for the economy as a whole. The national income accounts include, in particular, GDP and the many related statistics. The rules of national income accounting include several important identities. Recall that an identity is an equation that must be true because of the way the variables in the equation are defined. Identities are useful to keep in mind, for they clarify how different variables are related to one another. Here we consider some accounting identities that shed light on the macroeconomic role of financial markets. national income accounts an accounting system that tracks an economy’s performance Some important identities Recall that gross domestic product (GDP) for a certain period of time is (i) the total production of the economy, (ii) the total income that workers and capital owners receive for this production, and (iii) the total expenditure by households, firms and the government on the produced goods and services. Focusing on the latter perspective, GDP (denoted as Y ) is made up of four expenditure components: consumption (C ), investment (I ), government purchases (G ) and net exports (NX ). We can write: Y = C + I + G + NX This equation is an identity because every dollar of expenditure that shows up on the left-hand side also shows up in one of the four components on the right-hand side. Because of the way each of the variables is defined and measured, this equation must always hold. In this chapter, we simplify our discussion by examining a closed economy; one that does not interact with other economies. In particular, a closed economy does not engage in international trade in goods and services, nor does it participate in international borrowing and lending. Of course, actual economies, perhaps except North Korea, are open economies; that is, they interact with other economies around the world. (We will examine the macroeconomics of open economies later in this book.) Assuming a closed economy is a useful simplification with which we can learn some lessons that apply to all economies. Moreover, this assumption applies perfectly to the world economy since interplanetary trade does not yet exist. Because a closed economy does not engage in international trade, both imports and exports are exactly zero. Therefore, net exports (NX ) are also zero. We can therefore simplify the identity as: Y=C+I+G This equation states that each unit of output sold in a closed economy is consumed, invested, or bought by the government. To see what this identity can tell us about financial markets, subtract C and G from both sides of this equation: Y–C–G=I The left-hand side of this equation (Y – C – G) is the total income in the economy that remains after paying for consumption and government purchases. This amount is called national saving, or just saving, and is denoted S. Substituting S for Y – C – G, we can write the last equation as: S=I national saving (saving) the total income in the economy that remains after paying for consumption and government purchases 177 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in WCN 02-200-202and the financial system Chapter 8 part. Saving, investment 08_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 177 24/08/20 4:33 PM This equation states that saving equals investment. To understand the meaning of national saving, it is helpful to manipulate the equation a bit more. Let T denote the amount that the government collects from households in taxes (strictly speaking, it is taxes minus the amount it pays back to households in the form of transfer payments like pension benefits or social security payments, but below we will sometimes disregard this to simplify the language). We can then write national saving in either of two ways: S=Y–C–G or private saving the income that households have left after paying for taxes and consumption public saving the tax revenue that the government has left after paying for its spending (and transfers) budget surplus an excess of tax revenue over government spending budget deficit government spending exceeding tax revenue S = (Y – T – C) + (T – G) These equations are the same, since the two Ts in the second equation cancel each other, but each reveals a different way of thinking about national saving. In particular, the second equation separates national saving into two pieces: Private saving (Y – T – C ) and public saving (T – G ). Private saving is the amount of income that households have left after paying their taxes and paying for their consumption; that is, Y – T – C. Public saving is the amount of tax revenue that the government has left after paying for its spending. The government receives T in tax revenue (minus transfers) and spends G on goods and services. If T exceeds G, the government runs a budget surplus because it receives more money than it spends. This surplus of T – G represents public saving. If the government spends more than it receives in tax revenue (as has been the case in most high-income countries over the past few decades), then G is larger than T. In this case, the government runs a budget deficit, and public saving T – G is a negative number. The obvious consequence of deficits is an accumulation of public debt. Now consider how these accounting identities are related to financial markets. The equation S = I reveals an important fact – for the economy as a whole, saving must be equal to investment. Yet this fact raises some important questions. What mechanisms lie behind this identity? What coordinates those people who are deciding how much to save and those people who are deciding how much to invest? The answer is the financial system. The bond market, the stock market, banks, managed funds and other financial markets and intermediaries stand between the two sides of the S = I equation. They take in the nation’s saving and channel it to the nation’s investors. The meaning of saving and investment The terms saving and investment can sometimes be confusing. Most people use these terms casually and sometimes interchangeably. In contrast, the macroeconomists who put together the national income accounts use these terms carefully and distinctly. Consider an example. Suppose that Mary earns more than she spends and deposits her unspent income in a bank or uses it to buy a bond or some shares from a corporation. Because Mary’s income exceeds her consumption, she adds to the nation’s saving. Mary might think of herself as ‘investing’ her money, but a macroeconomist would call Mary’s act ‘saving’ rather than ‘investment’. In the language of macroeconomics, investment refers to the purchase of new capital, like equipment or buildings. When Jerry builds himself a new house using money borrowed from the bank, he adds to the nation’s investment. Similarly, when the Curly Corporation builds a new factory using proceeds from selling shares, it also adds to the nation’s investment. 178 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 4 The real economyCopyright in the long run 08_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 178 24/08/20 4:33 PM Although the accounting identity S = I shows that saving and investment are equal for the economy as a whole, this does not have to be true for every individual household or firm. Mary’s saving can be greater than her investment, and she can deposit the excess in a bank. Jerry’s saving can be less than his investment and he can borrow the shortfall from a bank. Banks and other financial institutions make these individual differences between saving and investment possible by allowing one person’s saving to finance another person’s investment. LO8.3 The market for loanable funds Having discussed some of the important financial institutions in our economy and their role, we are ready to build a model of financial markets. Our purpose in doing so is to explain how financial markets coordinate the economy’s saving and investment. The model also gives us a tool with which we can analyse various economic developments and government policies that influence saving and investment. To keep things simple, we assume that the economy has only one financial market, called the market for loanable funds. All savers go to this market to deposit their savings and all borrowers go to this market to get their loans. In this market there is one interest rate, which is both the return on saving and the cost of borrowing. The assumption of a single financial market is, of course, not realistic. We have seen that the economy has many types of financial institutions and instruments. But, as we discussed in chapter 2, the art in building an economic model is simplifying the world in order to explain it. For our purposes here, we can ignore the diversity of financial institutions and assume that the economy has a single financial market. market for loanable funds a (virtual) place where those who supply and demand funds interact FYI Present value Imagine that someone offered to give you $100 today or $100 in 10 years. Which would you choose? This is an easy question. Getting $100 today is clearly better, because you can always deposit the money in a bank, still have it in 10 years and earn interest along the way. The lesson: Money today is more valuable than the same amount of money in the future. Now consider a harder question: Imagine that someone offered you $100 today or $200 in 10 years. Which would you choose? To answer this question, you need some way to compare sums of money from different points of time. Economists do this with a concept called present value. The present value of any future sum of money is the amount today that would be needed, at current interest rates, to produce that future sum. To learn how to use the concept of present value, let’s work through a couple of simple problems. Question: If you put $100 in a bank account (that pays interest) today, how much money will you have in N years? That is, what will be the future value of this $100? Answer: Let’s use r to denote the interest rate expressed in decimal form (so an interest rate of 5 per cent means r = 0.05). If interest is paid each year, and if this interest paid remains in the bank account to earn more interest (a process called compounding, which you learnt about in an earlier chapter), the $100 will become (1 + r) × $100 after 1 year, (1 + r) × (1 + r) × $100 after 2 years, (1 + r) × (1 + r) × (1 + r) × $100 after 3 years and so on. After N years, the $100 becomes (1 + r)N × $100. For example, if the interest rate is 5 per cent, then the value of the $100 in 10 years’ time will be (1.05)10 × $100, which is $163. Question: Now suppose you are going to be paid $200 in N years. What is the present value of this future payment? 179 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in WCN 02-200-202and the financial system Chapter 8 part. Saving, investment 08_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 179 24/08/20 4:33 PM That is, how much would you have to deposit in a bank right now to yield $200 in N years? Answer: To answer this question, just turn the previous answer on its head. In the last question, we computed a future value from a present value by multiplying by the factor (1 + r)N. To compute a present value from a future value, we divide by the factor (1 + r)N. Thus, the present value of $200 deposited today in N years is $200/ (1 + r)N. For instance, if the interest rate is 5 per cent, the present value of $200 in 10 years is $200/(1.05)10, which is $123. This illustrates the general formula: If r is the interest rate, then the amount X to be received in N years has a present value of X/(1 + r)N. Let’s now return to our earlier question: Should you choose $100 today or $200 in 10 years? We can infer from our calculation of present value that if the interest rate is 5 per cent, you should prefer the $200 in 10 years. The future $200 has a present value of $123, which is greater than $100. You are, therefore, better off waiting for the future sum. Notice that the answer to our question depends on the interest rate. If the interest rate were 8 per cent, then the $200 in 10 years would have a present value of $200/(1.05)10, which is only $93. In this case, you should take the $100 today. Why should the interest rate matter for your choice? The answer is that the higher the interest rate, the more you can earn by depositing your money at the bank, so the more attractive getting $100 today becomes. Using one of the Ten Principles of Economics introduced in chapter 1, since a higher (real) interest rate increases the opportunity cost of spending money now, it makes people substitute current consumption for future consumption. The concept of present value is useful in many applications, including the decisions that companies face when evaluating investment projects. For instance, imagine that Nissan is thinking about building a new factory. Suppose that the factory will cost $100 million today and will yield the company $200 million in 10 years. Should Nissan undertake the project? You can see that this decision is exactly like the one we have been studying. To make its decision, the company will compare the present value of the $200 million return to the $100 million cost. The company’s decision, therefore, will depend on the interest rate. If the interest rate is 5 per cent, then the present value of the $200 million return from the factory is $123 million, and the company will choose to pay the $100 million cost. By contrast, if the interest rate is 8 per cent, then the present value of the return is only $93 million, and the company will decide to forgo the project. Thus, the concept of present value helps explain why investment declines when the interest rate rises. Here is another application of present value: Suppose you win a million-dollar lottery, but the prize is going to be paid out as $20 000 a year for 50 years. How much is the prize really worth? After performing 50 calculations similar to those above (one calculation for each payment) and adding up the results, you would learn that the present value of this million-dollar prize at a 7 per cent interest rate is only $276 000. This is one way that lotteries make money – by selling tickets in the present and paying out prizes in the future. Supply of and demand for loanable funds supply of loanable funds saving from households and the government The market for loanable funds, like other markets in the economy, is governed by supply and demand. What are the sources of supply and demand in that market? The supply of loanable funds comes from those people who have some extra money they want to save and lend out, and from the government when its tax revenue (net of transfers) is in excess of its expenditures. This lending can occur directly, like when a household buys a bond from a firm. Or it can occur indirectly, when a household makes a deposit in a bank which then uses the funds to make loans. In both cases, saving is the source of the supply of loanable funds. 180 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 4 The real economyCopyright in the long run 08_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 180 24/08/20 4:33 PM The demand for loanable funds is driven by the need to finance investments. It is composed primarily of firms borrowing to buy new equipment or build factories. Nevertheless, it also includes households taking out mortgages to buy homes (recall that all other purchases by households, for example, getting a car, are classified as consumption not investment). The interest rate expresses the price of a loan. It represents the amount that borrowers pay for loans and the return that lenders receive on their saving. Because a high interest rate makes borrowing more expensive, the quantity of loanable funds demanded falls as the interest rate rises. Similarly, because a high interest rate makes saving more attractive, the quantity of loanable funds supplied rises as the interest rate rises. In other words, the demand curve for loanable funds slopes downwards and the supply curve for loanable funds slopes upwards. (In the figures below, we plot them as linear for simplicity; in the real world they may not be straight lines, but the same intuition still applies.) Recall that economists distinguish between the real interest rate and the nominal interest rate. The nominal interest rate is the monetary return to saving and the monetary cost of borrowing. It is the interest rate as usually reported. The real interest rate is the nominal interest rate corrected for inflation; it equals the nominal interest rate minus the inflation rate. Which one do you think better reflects the actual return on saving and the cost of borrowing that households and firms are interested in? Because inflation erodes the value of money over time, it is the real interest rate. Therefore, in our model, the supply of and demand for loanable funds will depend on the real (rather than nominal) interest rate, which features on the vertical axis of Figure 8.2. For the rest of this chapter, when you see the term interest rate, you should remember that we are talking about the real interest rate. Figure 8.2 shows the real interest rate that balances the supply of and demand for loanable funds. The adjustment of the interest rate towards the equilibrium level occurs for the usual reasons. If the interest rate is lower than the equilibrium level, the quantity of loanable funds supplied is less than the quantity of loanable funds demanded. The resulting shortage of loanable funds encourages lenders to raise the interest rate they charge. Intuitively, you can think of it as an auction in which there are a lot of potential buyers who bid up the price. demand for loanable funds demand from firms looking to invest and households buying real estate FIGURE 8.2 The market for loanable funds Interest rate Supply 5% Demand 0 $120 Loanable funds (in millions of dollars) The (real) interest rate in the economy adjusts to clear the market for loanable funds, i.e. to balance the supply and demand. Here, the equilibrium interest rate is 5 per cent at which $120 million of loanable funds are supplied and demanded. 181 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in WCN 02-200-202and the financial system Chapter 8 part. Saving, investment 08_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 181 24/08/20 4:33 PM Conversely, if the interest rate is higher than the equilibrium level, the quantity of loanable funds supplied exceeds the quantity of loanable funds demanded. As lenders compete for the scarce borrowers, interest rates are driven down. This is similar to an auction in which there are currently no buyers so the seller needs to drop the price to attract them. In this way, the interest rate approaches the equilibrium level at which the supply of and demand for loanable funds exactly balance. This model of the supply of and demand for loanable funds shows that financial markets work much like other markets in the economy. In the market for milk, for instance, the price of milk adjusts so that the quantity of milk supplied balances the quantity of milk demanded and the market reaches its equilibrium. In this way, the ‘invisible hand’ coordinates the behaviour of dairy farmers and the behaviour of milk drinkers. Once we realise that saving represents the supply of loanable funds and investment represents the demand, we can see how the invisible hand helps coordinate saving and investment. You may have heard some critiques of the concept of equilibrium and the invisible hand, jokes like ‘The invisible hand was nowhere to be seen’. While entertaining, they are often based on an incorrect interpretation of these concepts. The invisible hand does not imply that the market allocation will always be efficient (recall the discussion of market failure in earlier chapters), and equilibrium does not mean that the market will remain there all the time. Because market conditions change frequently, the equilibrium does too. So you should think of it in a dynamical sense as the direction in which market forces are moving prices and quantities, not in a static sense as some fixed outcomes. It is about the adjustment process itself. CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING What are loanable funds? Why do firms demand loanable funds? Who supplys loanable funds? LO8.4 How government policies can affect saving and investment We can now use the analysis of the market for loanable funds to examine various government policies that affect the economy’s saving and investment, following the three steps discussed in chapter 4. First, we decide whether the policy shifts the supply curve or the demand curve. Second, we determine the direction of the shift. Third, we use the supplyand-demand diagram to see how the equilibrium changes. Policy 1: Taxes and saving In 2017, Australian families saved 3.51 per cent of their disposable income according to OECD data. This is a smaller proportion than their counterparts in some other countries; for example, in China it was close to 36 per cent and in Sweden and Switzerland between 15 and 19 per cent. But Australian households still saved more than families in other countries like Japan (nearly 3 per cent) or New Zealand (where the savings rate was actually negative). Although all the reasons for these large international differences are not fully understood, and although the saving rate of Australians increased in recent years (from 1 per cent in 2005), many Australian policymakers view inadequate Australian saving as a problem. They also point out that the saving rate is likely to decline in the future due to demographic trends of an ageing population. One of the Ten Principles of Economics in chapter 1 is that a country’s standard of living depends on its ability to produce goods and services. And, as we discussed in the previous chapter, saving is an important long-run determinant of a 182 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 4 The real economyCopyright in the long run 08_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 182 24/08/20 4:33 PM nation’s productivity. If Australia could somehow raise its saving rate, more resources would be available for investment and capital accumulation, GDP would grow more rapidly and, over time, Australians would enjoy a higher standard of living. Another of the Ten Principles of Economics is that people respond to incentives. Many economists have used this principle to suggest that the relatively low saving rate in Australia is at least partly attributable to tax laws that discourage saving. The Australian government collects revenue by taxing income, including interest and dividend income. To see the effects of this policy, consider a 25-year-old who saves $1000 and buys a 30-year bond that pays an interest rate of 9 per cent. In the absence of taxes, the $1000 grows to $13 268 when the individual reaches age 55. Yet if that interest is taxed at a rate of, say, 33.3 per cent, then the after-tax interest rate is only 6 per cent. In this case, the $1000 grows to only $5743 after 30 years. The tax on interest income substantially reduces the future pay-off from current saving and, as a result, reduces the incentive for people to save. Following the Global Financial Crisis, the returns have generally been much lower than in the past: for example, the yield on a 30-year US government bond was just above 2 per cent and on a 15-year Australia bond it was around 1.3 per cent in early 2020. While this reduces the quantitative impact of taxes on people’s returns from saving, their thinking at the margin implies that incentives and decisions will still be affected by tax legislation. In response to this problem, some economists and lawmakers have attempted to change the tax laws to encourage greater saving. For instance, under the 10 per cent consumption tax that John Howard introduced in 2000 (commonly known as goods and services tax, GST), money spent effectively gets taxed more than money saved. Most countries have something similar to a GST; in Europe it is referred to as a VAT or value-added tax, and its value is usually higher (between 17 and 25 per cent). More recent proposals have included reduced taxes on contributions to superannuation funds that allow people to shelter some of their saving from taxation. Let’s consider the effect of such a saving incentive on the market for loanable funds in Figure 8.3. First, which FIGURE 8.3 A tax incentive to save Interest rate 5% Supply, S1 A 4% B C 2. ... which reduces the equilibrium interest rate ... S2 1. Tax incentives for saving increase the supply of loanable funds by $60 million for any interest rate ... Demand 0 $120 $160 $180 Loanable funds (in millions of dollars) 3. ... and raises the equilibrium quantity of loanable funds, but by less than $60 million. A change in the tax laws encouraging people to save more shifts the supply of loanable funds to the right from S1 to S2. As a consequence, the equilibrium real interest rate must fall and the new equilibrium quantity of loanable funds saved and invested rises. 183 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in WCN 02-200-202and the financial system Chapter 8 part. Saving, investment 08_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 183 24/08/20 4:33 PM curve does this policy affect? Because this tax change alters the incentive for households to save at any given interest rate, it affects the quantity of loanable funds supplied at each interest rate. Thus, the supply of loanable funds shifts. The tax change does not directly affect the amount that borrowers want to borrow at any given interest rate, so the demand for loanable funds is largely unchanged. Second, which way does the supply curve shift? If saving is taxed less heavily than under current law, households increase their saving by consuming a smaller fraction of their income. Households use this additional saving to increase their deposits in banks or to buy more bonds. The supply of loanable funds therefore increases and the supply curve shifts to the right from S1 to S2, as shown in Figure 8.3. Finally, we compare the new equilibrium (point C in the figure) with the old equilibrium (point A). We can see that if a change in the tax laws encouraged greater saving, the result would be lower interest rates and greater investment. However, we can also see that the increase in the equilibrium quantity of loanable funds saved and invested, in our example from $120 million to $160 million, is smaller than the initial increase (horizontal shift) in private saving of $60 million. Can you think of an explanation for that? The story is as follows. For all the new saving to be absorbed in the market it must become cheaper. That is, the equilibrium interest rate must fall (from 5 per cent to 4 per cent). This leads to two other movements in Figure 8.3 – along the demand and supply curves. Specifically, the lower interest rate attracts additional investment as households and firms have an incentive to borrow more. This is represented by a movement along the demand curve from point A to C. At the same time, some households are no longer willing to save at the lower interest rate, and there is a movement along the supply curve from point B to C. This partly offsets the initial increase in private saving, and means that the equilibrium change of loanable funds saved and invested is less than what it would be under the original interest rate of 5 per cent. In Figure 8.3 the equilibrium increase is only $40 million rather than $60 million. Although this analysis of the effects of increased saving is widely accepted among economists, there is less consensus about what kinds of tax changes should be enacted. Many economists endorse tax reform aimed at increasing saving in order to stimulate investment and economic growth. Yet others are sceptical that these tax changes would have much effect on national saving. These sceptics also doubt the equity of the proposed reforms. They argue that, in many cases, the benefits of the tax changes would accrue primarily to the wealthy, who are least in need of tax relief. Policy 2: Taxes and investment Suppose that federal parliament passed a law giving a tax reduction to any firm building a new factory. In essence, this is what happens when government institutes an investment tax credit, which policymakers do from time to time. Let’s consider the effect of such a law on the market for loanable funds in Figure 8.4. First, does the law affect supply or demand? Because the tax credit alters the incentive of firms to borrow and invest in new capital, it alters the demand for loanable funds. Because the tax credit does not directly affect the amount that households save at any given interest rate, it leaves the supply of loanable funds largely unaffected. Second, which way does the demand curve shift? Because firms have an incentive to increase investment at any interest rate, the quantity of loanable funds demanded is higher at any given interest rate. Thus, the demand curve for loanable funds shifts to the right from D1 to D2 in Figure 8.4. Third, consider how the equilibrium changes. The increased demand for loanable funds raises the equilibrium interest rate from 5 per cent to 6 per cent and the equilibrium quantity of loanable funds supplied and demanded from $120 million to $140 million. Note that this 184 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 4 The real economyCopyright in the long run 08_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 184 24/08/20 4:33 PM FIGURE 8.4 A tax incentive to invest Interest rate Supply C 6% 5% B A 2. ... which raises the equilibrium interest rate ... 1. An investment tax credit increases the demand for loanable funds by $50 million for any interest rate ... D2 Demand, D1 0 $120 $140 $170 Loanable funds (in millions of dollars) 3. ... and raises the equilibrium quantity of loanable funds, but by less than $50 million. An investment tax credit encourages firms to invest more, increasing the demand for loanable funds from D1 to D2. As a result, the equilibrium interest rate rises and the equilibrium quantity of loanable funds saved and invested rises too. increase of $20 million is less than the horizontal shift of $50 million. This is because the higher interest rate discourages some investors — there is a movement along the new demand curve from point B to C. On the other hand, due to the higher interest rate some households are willing to save more, which causes a movement along the supply curve from point A to C. In summary, if a change in the tax laws encouraged greater investment, the result would be higher interest rates and greater saving. Policy 3: Government budgets – surplus or deficit? One of the most widely discussed issues of macroeconomic policy is the government budget balance. When the government takes in more revenue than it spends, the excess is called the budget surplus. When the government spends more than it receives in tax revenue, the shortfall is called the budget deficit. The accumulation of past budget deficits is called government debt. When a government runs a budget surplus, it can reduce the size of the accumulated government debt. Up until the Global Financial Crisis, the Australian government had run budget surpluses for a decade and had retired almost all of its debt (the public debt to GDP ratio was below 10 per cent in 2007). It was therefore, unlike many countries with high public debt, in a good position to stimulate the economy with increased government expenditure when the crisis hit. During national elections in Australia, there is always much debate about which party is more fiscally responsible. To see why this debate may be relevant, imagine that the government starts with a balanced budget and then, because of an increase in government spending, starts running a budget deficit. We can analyse the effects of such a newly created budget deficit by following our three steps in the market for loanable funds, which is illustrated in Figure 8.5. First, which curve shifts when the budget moves into a deficit? Recall that national saving – the source of the supply of loanable funds – is composed of private saving and public saving. A change towards a (greater) deficit represents a change in public saving and, 185 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in WCN 02-200-202and the financial system Chapter 8 part. Saving, investment 08_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 185 24/08/20 4:33 PM FIGURE 8.5 The effect of a government budget deficit Interest rate S2 C 6% 5% A B Supply, S 1 1. A budget deficit decreases the supply of loanable funds by $70 million for any interest rate ... 2. ... which raises the equilibrium interest rate ... Demand 0 $50 $80 $120 Loanable funds (in millions of dollars) 3. ... and reduces the equilibrium quantity of loanable funds, but by less than $70 million. When the government spends more than it receives, the resulting budget deficit lowers national saving – compared to a balanced budget situation. The supply of loanable funds decreases from S1 to S2 and, as a consequence, the equilibrium interest rate rises and the quantity of loanable funds saved and invested falls. crowding out effect a decrease in private investment resulting from government borrowing thereby, in the supply of loanable funds. Because the budget deficit does not, in a major way, influence the amount that households and firms want to borrow to finance investment at any given interest rate, it does not alter the demand for loanable funds. Second, which way does the supply curve shift? When the government moves from a balanced budget to a budget deficit, public saving becomes negative and this reduces national saving. In other words, when the government borrows to finance its budgetary shortfall, it reduces the supply of loanable funds available to finance investment by households and firms. Intuitively, the deficit sucks up some of the funds that would otherwise be available for investment. Thus, a budget deficit shifts the supply curve for loanable funds to the left from S1 to S2 in Figure 8.5. Third, we compare the old equilibrium with the new one. In the figure, when the budget deficit reduces the supply of loanable funds, the interest rate rises from 5 per cent to 6 per cent. This higher interest rate then alters the behaviour of the households and firms that participate in the loan market. In particular, some demanders of loanable funds are discouraged by the higher interest rate. Fewer families buy new homes and fewer firms choose to build new factories. This fall in private investment due to government borrowing is called the crowding out effect. It is represented in the figure by the movement along the demand curve between points A and C from a quantity of $120 million to $80 million. That is, when the government borrows to finance its budget deficit, it crowds out private borrowers who are trying to finance investment. But it should be noted that the higher interest rate leads to an inflow of additional saving in the market (a movement along the new supply curve from point B to C), which partly offsets the drop in public saving. 186 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 4 The real economyCopyright in the long run 08_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 186 24/08/20 4:33 PM Thus, one of the basic lessons about budget deficits follows directly from their effects on the supply of and demand for loanable funds – when the government reduces national saving by running a budget deficit, the real interest rate rises and investment falls. Because private investment is important for long-run economic growth, frequent and large government budget deficits tend to reduce the economy’s growth rate. It should, however, be said that while most economists would agree with this conclusion under normal economic circumstances, they would argue that in some situations the economy may respond differently. For example, some economists point to the post-Global Financial Crisis period of 2008–16, in which budget deficits in countries like the United States, Japan and Australia did not lead to higher interest rates. Likewise, with the stimulus to the economy during the coronavirus crisis – most economists agree that this will not lead to an increase in interest rates. You will find out why this may be the case in chapter 7, which discusses the so-called ‘liquidity trap’. FYI Why, you might ask, does a budget deficit affect the supply of loanable funds, rather than the demand for them? After all, the government finances a budget deficit by selling bonds, thereby borrowing from the private sector. Why does increased borrowing from the government shift the supply curve, while increased borrowing by private investors shifts the demand curve? The model as presented here takes the term ‘loanable funds’ to mean the flow of resources available to fund private investment; thus, a government budget deficit reduces the supply of loanable funds. If, instead, we had defined the term ‘loanable funds’ to mean the flow of resources available from private saving, then the government budget deficit would increase demand rather than reduce supply. Changing the interpretation of the term would cause a semantic change in how we described the model, but the bottom line from the analysis would be the same. In either case, a budget deficit increases the interest rate, thereby crowding out private borrowers who are relying on financial markets to fund private investment projects. CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING Assume the Australian government wants to increase human capital by providing an additional $1.5 billion dollars to fund tertiary education. Assuming there is no change in tax revenues, what happens to the demand for and supply of loanable funds? How will this affect the real interest rate and the quantity of investment? Is the change in equilibrium investment the same, more or less than the initial change (horizontal shift) in government spending? Why? Demonstrate your answers using a diagram. So far, we have examined a budget deficit that results from an increase in government spending, but a budget deficit that results from a tax cut has similar effects. A tax cut reduces public saving, T − G. Private saving, Y − T − C, might increase because of lower T. But as long as households respond to the lower taxes by consuming more, C increases, private saving rises by less than public saving and their sum, national saving (S = Y − C − G), declines. Once again, the budget deficit reduces the supply of loanable funds, drives up the interest rate and crowds out borrowers trying to finance investments. 187 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in WCN 02-200-202and the financial system Chapter 8 part. Saving, investment 08_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 187 24/08/20 4:33 PM CASE STUDY public debt the amount owed by a country’s government Government debt and the sustainability of public finances The word ‘debt’ has recently become one of the most commonly used economic terms. Many observers argue that excessive debt of households, banks and governments was one of the causes of the 2008 Global Financial Crisis, possibly the main one. The subsequent debt crises in several European countries and the ‘fiscal cliff’ or the ‘debt ceiling’ negotiations in the US all attracted the attention of the media and were closely watched by investors. Has all this attention been justified? Yes and no. Yes, because too much debt creates economic imbalances, and can thus cripple an economy with dire consequences for the wellbeing of individuals. No, because much of the debt focus has been misplaced, with policymakers putting out current ‘debt fires’ rather than implementing reforms that prevent future ‘debt blazes’. Earlier in this chapter we discussed the danger of excessively risky behaviour and indebtedness on the part of banks and other financial institutions. Let’s now focus on public debt, which is the amount of money that a country’s government officially owes to its creditors. Obviously, as the government does not have any money of its own, the country’s taxpayers are ultimately liable for this debt. Let’s first look at the ‘yes’ part, using Greece as a recent example of damaging public debt. Due to three decades of excessive government spending (and indirectly also the effects of the introduction of the euro), the public debt of Greece in 2013 reached 175 per cent of its gross domestic product. (Contrast this with Australia, where we had a debt level of 18.9% of GDP or around $326bn.) This is despite repeated financial support from other European Union countries and international organisations. Excessive public debt has led to low confidence of investors and households, and a need for sudden drastic expenditure cutbacks (the so-called ‘austerity measures’). These in turn have greatly contributed to a deep economic downturn with unemployment rates above 24 per cent, and even 50 per cent among young people in 2016. The financial and social burden of these outcomes on Greek citizens and society is enormous and long-lasting. Now turn to the ‘no’ part. What many people do not realise is that most advanced countries may follow in Greece’s footsteps and experience a debt crisis within one or two generations if they do not adjust their current policies. You may be hesitant to believe this claim, so let us support it with numbers. Figure 8.6 shows public debt for selected countries as a proportion of GDP. We can see that for many countries, debt is high – close to, or more than, 100 per cent of GDP. Economic theory explains why there is no universal threshold debt level above which a country goes bankrupt; there are many specific factors at play. But the examples of Russia in 1998 and Argentina in 2001, both experiencing solvency crises with public debt of less than 80 per cent of GDP, suggest policymakers would be ill-advised to ignore accelerating public debt. Unfortunately, this is exactly what has been happening. What Figure 8.6 does not show is that most countries are predicted to see sizable increases in their public debt in the next few decades. What is the reason for such pessimistic debt projections? A large part of the story is the observed demographic trend of ‘ageing populations’. It is well documented that increases in incomes and prosperity are associated with people having fewer children and higher life expectancy. These trends, however, lead to decreases in the ratio of workers per retiree. Half a century ago this ratio was between 6 and 7 in high-income countries, whereas now it is about half that, and within the next 40 years this ratio is predicted to fall below 2 in most rich countries. To appreciate this, Figure 8.7 presents the old-age dependency ratios – the proportion of population aged 65 or more relative to population aged 15–64. It shows the predicted trend towards an older population. By itself, such demographic shifts would not pose a major problem since labour and capital markets can adapt to expected trends. The problem lies in the pay-as-yougo system of public finances where government expenditures are paid for by the tax revenues in the same year. A reduction in the worker-per-retiree ratio means higher expenditures on pensions and health care, but lower tax revenues. This makes it 188 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 4 The real economyCopyright in the long run 08_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 188 24/08/20 4:33 PM FIGURE 8.6 Gross public debt – selected countries (% of GDP, estimate for 2017) Gross Public Debt - selected countries (% of DGP, estimate for 2017) Japan 237.6 Greece 181.8 Lebanon 146.8 Italy 131.8 Congo, Republic of the 130.8 Singapore 111.1 Jamaica 101 Belize 99 France 96.8 Syria 94.8 Canada 89.7 United States 78.8 Vietnam 58.5 Fiji 48.9 Australia 40.8 New Zealand 31.7 Saudi Arabia 17.2 Country 0 0 50 100 150 200 250 Source:Data: CIA The World Factbook FIGURE 8.7 Ageing populations: old-age dependency ratios for selected countries 80 Old-age dependency ratio (in %) 70 60 China Japan 50 India 40 Italy Germany 30 United States 20 Australia 10 19 5 19 0 5 19 5 6 19 0 6 19 5 7 19 0 7 19 5 8 19 0 8 19 5 9 19 0 9 20 5 0 20 0 0 20 5 1 20 0 1 20 5 2 20 0 2 20 5 3 20 0 3 20 5 4 20 0 4 20 5 5 20 0 5 20 5 6 20 0 6 20 5 70 20 7 20 5 8 20 0 8 20 5 9 20 0 9 21 5 00 0 Each line shows the proportion of the population aged 65 and above, relative to population aged 15–64; the 1960–2014 period shows actual data, years from 2015 show predicted data. Source: Data: United Nations, http://data.un.org harder for the government to balance its books. The demographic trends thus imply growing budget deficits and public debt in the next several decades, and increasing likelihood of a future debt crisis. In this context, many economists, most notably Professor Laurence Kotlikoff from Boston University and his co-authors, have argued that the official measures of public 189 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in WCN 02-200-202and the financial system Chapter 8 part. Saving, investment 08_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 189 24/08/20 4:33 PM debt are misleading. They underestimate the true extent of the debt problem by omitting many future items to which governments have committed, like future public pension liabilities. These authors therefore advocate a more comprehensive debt measure, the so-called ‘fiscal gap’, which is the present value difference between all projected future government spending and revenue. For example, in the United States as of 2015, the authors calculate the fiscal gap to be around US$210 trillion, which is much higher than the official government debt of around US$19 trillion! And the fiscal gap tends to rise rapidly as the large cohort of ‘baby boomers’ approaches retirement. In addition, uncertainty about the future of public finances may lead to many related problems: for example, higher and more variable inflation resulting from excessive money printing (see the 1981 study by Tom Sargent and Neil Wallace or research by Eric Leeper). For all these reasons, 17 Nobel Laureates and many others endorse the INFORM Act, a bipartisan bill which would require key public institutions in the US to report fiscal gap accounting annually. In summary, the above developments call for a major reform of public finances in most high-income countries that would put them (especially their pension and health care systems) on a sustainable path. Nevertheless, for political reasons only a handful of countries have attempted to seriously and conceptually tackle this longterm problem. Kotlikoff compares the situation to ‘a cancer patient whose tumour is growing, but whose doctors are too afraid to operate because the patient doesn’t like pain’. Instead, politicians have engaged in short-sighted austerity measures in the form of arbitrary budget cuts that increase economic uncertainty and often turn out to be counter-productive by undermining economic growth. This is reflected in the reputable Global Risks Reports by the World Economic Forum, whereby over 500 experts evaluate the main risks facing the world. Out of the several dozen economic, geopolitical, societal, environmental and technological risks, ‘fiscal crises’ were ranked the no. 1 global risk in terms of the predicted financial losses as recently as 2014! Australia is in a much better situation than most other high-income countries, due to a lower level of existing debt, the pension reform in the early 1990s, and relatively high fertility and immigration. However, it is still likely to face some fiscal challenges in the future due to an ageing population. Like most policy debates, the debate over government budgets and debt has many facets. But the basic elements of this debate should already be clear. Whenever policymakers consider the government’s budget and its impact on the economy, foremost in their minds should be saving, investment and interest rates, as well as the long-term sustainability of public finances. Sources: Laurence Kotlikoff, ‘America’s Hidden Credit Card Bill’, The New York Times, 31 July 2014, http://www. nytimes.com/2014/08/01/opinion/laurence-kotlikoff-on-fiscal-gap-accounting.html; http://www.theinformact.org Questions 1 Why is rising public debt a risk to the economy? 2 Why are demographic trends important for understanding a country’s debt level? Explain. CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING Watch the video-interview of Dr Jan Libich with Dr Stephen Kirchner titled ‘The Public Debt Crisis and Fiscal Solutions’ (http://youtu.be/4XW4J3oTCig). Summarise the debt problem facing advanced countries, and suggest some possible solutions. 190 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 4 The real economyCopyright in the long run 08_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 190 24/08/20 4:33 PM Conclusion ‘Neither a borrower nor a lender be’, Polonius advises his son in Shakespeare’s Hamlet. If everyone followed this advice, this chapter would have been unnecessary. Few economists would agree with Polonius. In our economy, people borrow and lend often, and usually for good reason. You may borrow one day to start your own business or to buy a home. And people may lend to you in the hope that the interest you pay will allow them to enjoy a more prosperous future, e.g. retirement. The financial system has the important job of coordinating all this borrowing and lending activity. In many ways, financial markets are like other markets in the economy. The price of loanable funds – the interest rate – is governed by the forces of supply and demand, just as other prices in the economy are. When financial markets bring the supply of and demand for loanable funds into balance, they help allocate the economy’s scarce resources to their most efficient uses. In one way, however, financial markets are special. Financial markets, unlike most other markets, serve the important role of linking the present and the future. Those who supply loanable funds – savers – do so because they want to convert some of their current income into future purchasing power. Those who demand loanable funds – borrowers – do so because they want to invest today in order to have additional capital in the future to produce goods and services. Thus, financial markets are important not only for current generations, but also for future generations who will inherit many of the resulting benefits. But the Global Financial Crisis of 2008 gave arguments to those economists and policymakers who see ‘something wrong’ with the incentives and behaviour of certain financial institutions. Our discussion of government bailouts mentioned excessive risktaking and gambling with taxpayers’ money. Given the importance of financial markets for the running of the economy, we will revisit these issues in later chapters. 191 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in WCN 02-200-202and the financial system Chapter 8 part. Saving, investment 08_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 191 24/08/20 4:33 PM STUDY TOOLS Summary LO8.1 The Australian financial system is made up of many types of financial institutions, like the bond market, the stock market, banks and managed funds. All these institutions act to direct the resources of households who want to save into the hands of households and firms who want to borrow. LO8.2 National income accounting identities reveal some important relationships among macroeconomic variables. In particular, for a closed economy, national saving must equal investment. Financial institutions are the mechanism through which the economy matches one person’s saving with another person’s investment. LO8.3 The real interest rate is determined by the supply of and demand for loanable funds. The supply of loanable funds comes from households who want to save some of their income. The demand for loanable funds comes from households and firms who want to borrow for investment. To analyse how any policy or event affects the interest rate, one must consider how it affects the supply of and demand for loanable funds. LO8.4 National saving equals private saving plus public saving. A government budget deficit represents negative public saving and, therefore, reduces national saving and the supply of loanable funds available to finance private investment. This usually crowds out private investment and reduces the growth of GDP and productivity. Key concepts bond, p. 169 budget deficit, p. 178 budget surplus, p. 178 crowding out effect, p. 186 demand for loanable funds, p. 181 financial intermediaries, p. 173 financial markets, p. 169 financial system, p. 168 managed fund, p. 173 market for loanable funds, p. 179 national income accounts, p. 177 national saving (saving), p. 177 private saving, p. 178 public debt, p. 188 public saving, p. 178 shares, p. 170 supply of loanable funds, p. 180 Practice questions Questions for review 1 2 3 4 5 6 Highlight the importance of the financial system. Why is it crucial for a country’s long-run economic growth? Describe two types of financial intermediaries. What is national saving? What is private saving? What is public saving? Why must S = I (savings equals investment) in a closed economy? How does an economist’s definition of investment differ from the ordinary usage of the term? Describe a change in the tax laws that might decrease private saving. If this policy were implemented, how would it affect the market for loanable funds? What are the differences between (government) budget surplus and budget deficit? How do these affect interest rates, investment and economic growth? Consider an increase in the supply for loanable funds. What will happen to the equilibrium quantity of national saving and investment? Will these quantities change by more or by less than the initial change (horizontal shift) in the supply? Carefully explain. Multiple choice 1 Tony wants to buy and operate an ice-cream truck but doesn’t have the financial resources to start the business. He borrows $20 000 from his brother Terry, to whom he promises a nominal interest rate of 6.5 per cent. He further gets another $10 000 from his friend Travis, to whom he promises a third of his profits. What best describes this situation? a Terry is a stockholder, and Tony is a bondholder. b Terry is a stockholder, and Travis is a bondholder. 192 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 4 The real economyCopyright in the long run 08_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 192 24/08/20 4:33 PM c Travis is a stockholder, and Tony is a bondholder. d Travis is a stockholder, and Terry is a bondholder. 2 If the government collects more in tax revenue than it spends, and households consume more than they get in after-tax income, then a private and public saving are both positive. b private and public saving are both negative. c private saving is positive, but public saving is negative. d private saving is negative, but public saving is positive. 3 A closed economy has income of $1100, government spending of $300, taxes of $250 and investment of $350. What is private saving? a $200 b $300 c $400 d $500 4 If a popular TV show on personal finance convinces Australians to save more for retirement, the ___________ curve for loanable funds would shift, driving the equilibrium interest rate ___________ . a supply, up b supply, down c demand, up d demand, down 5 If the business community becomes more optimistic about the profitability of capital, the _________ curve for loanable funds would shift, driving the equilibrium interest rate __________. a supply, up b supply, down c demand, up d demand, down 6 After the Global Financial Crisis of 2008, the ratio of government debt to GDP in Australia and most other countries a increased markedly. b decreased markedly. c was stable at a historically high level. d was stable at a historically low level. Problems and applications 1 2 3 4 For each of the following pairs, which bond would you expect to pay a higher interest rate? Explain. a A bond of the Australian government or a bond of a government in a war-torn country b A bond that repays the principal in the year 2030 or a bond that repays the principal in the year 2040 c A bond from the Coles Group or a bond from a software company your friend runs in his garage d A bond issued by the federal government or a bond issued to finance the construction of a new airport for Brisbane Using some online sources, find information on the main credit rating agencies. Are they public or private? What was the controversy regarding their role in the lead-up to the 2008 Global Financial Crisis? Has there been any reforms of the rating agencies? Can you propose some? Following the collapse of Lehman Brothers in September 2008, banks in Australia did not lower the interest they charged for home loans to the same extent that the Reserve Bank of Australia lowered its cash rate target. They argued that their cost of capital – that is, what they had to pay to borrow money on the world’s financial markets – had increased. Use the loanable funds model to explain why banks may have been justified in doing this. Using some online data, compare the return on an actively managed mutual fund with the return on a passive index fund (to minimise the effect of luck, it is better to compare a longer time period). What could explain the differences? 193 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in WCN 02-200-202and the financial system Chapter 8 part. Saving, investment 08_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 193 24/08/20 4:33 PM 5 Many workers hold large amounts of shares issued by the firms at which they work. Why do you suppose companies encourage this behaviour? Can you see any problems with that? 6 Two investors are discussing their investment strategies. One says she always looks for companies that seem to have good prospects, but have low price–earnings ratios. The other says he only invests in shares of companies that are in strongly growing industries. What are the merits of each investment strategy? What are the pitfalls? 7 Explain the difference between saving and investment as used by a macroeconomist. Which of the following situations represent investment? And which saving? Explain. a Your family refinances their mortgage to buy a new car. b You use your $350 pay cheque to buy shares in Apple Inc. c Your sister earns $150 and deposits it in her bank account. d You borrow $1500 from a bank to buy a scooter to use as an Uber Eats delivery driver. 8 If more Australians adopted a ‘live for today’ approach to life, and borrowed heavily to finance higher consumption (or purchases of investment properties), how would this affect saving, investment and the real interest rate? 9 Suppose the government borrows $7 billion more next year than this year (for example, they move from a balanced budget to a $7 billion deficit or from a $10 billion deficit to a $17 billion deficit). a Use a supply-and-demand diagram to analyse this policy. What happens to the interest rate? b What happens to investment? To private saving? To public saving? To national saving? Compare the size of the equilibrium changes with the $7 billion of extra borrowing. Is it the same, less or more? Carefully explain why and distinguish the various movements in the diagram. c How do the elasticities of supply of and demand for loanable funds (i.e. the slopes of the curves) affect the size of these changes? (Hint: See chapter 2 to review the definition of elasticity.) d Suppose households believe that greater government saving today implies lower future taxes since there will be little government debt. What does this belief do to private saving and the supply of loanable funds today? Does it increase or decrease the effects you discussed in parts (a) and (b)? 10 What are the reasons behind the demographic trend of an ageing population? What are its economic implications? Can you think of some political implications as well? In terms of the latter, Lenten and Libich propose (Australian Financial Review, 19 February 2016) a slight deviation from Australia’s compulsory voting by making it optional for those reaching retirement age. What do you think motivates the proposal? Can you think of some alternative policies that may achieve a similar outcome? 194 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 4 The real economyCopyright in the long run 08_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 194 24/08/20 4:33 PM 9 The natural rate of unemployment Learning objectives After reading this chapter, you should be able to: LO9.1find out what unemployment means, what the natural rate of unemployment is, and discuss its various types and causes LO9.2how ‘classical’ unemployment can result from the real wage being too high due to minimum-wage laws, union wage bargaining, or efficiency wages LO9.3get to know how ‘frictional’ unemployment is driven by the process of job search LO9.4discover how ‘structural’ unemployment arises in the labour market from a mismatch between the skills that workers have and the skills that employers need. 195 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 09_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 195 24/08/20 4:33 PM Introduction natural rate of unemployment unemployment accounted for by longer-term (not cyclical) factors cyclical unemployment the short-term deviations of unemployment from its natural rate due to the business cycle 196 Losing a job can be the most distressing economic event in a person’s life. Most people rely on their work not only to maintain their standard of living and make their monthly mortgage repayments, but also to get a sense of personal accomplishment. A job loss means a lower level of prosperity in the present, anxiety about the future and possibly reduced selfesteem. It is not surprising, therefore, that politicians, campaigning for office, often speak about how their proposed policies will help create jobs. In the last two chapters, we have seen some of the forces that determine the growth of a country’s GDP and the standard of living. For instance, a country that saves and invests a good fraction of its income enjoys more rapid growth in its physical and human capital, and subsequently in its GDP, than a similar country that saves and invests less. An even more obvious determinant of a country’s standard of living is the amount of unemployment it typically experiences. People who would like to work but cannot find a job are not contributing to the economy’s production of goods and services. Although some degree of unemployment is inevitable in a complex economy with thousands of firms and millions of workers searching for their dream job, the amount of unemployment varies substantially over time and across countries. When a country’s workers are fully employed, the country achieves a higher level of GDP than if many of its workers stood idle. On the other hand, you know from the chapter on economic growth that not all jobs are created equal, and the workers’ productivity matters a great deal for their prosperity. In countries, like Cuba, United Arab Emirates and Kuwait, where over 80 per cent of the nationals work in the public sector, labour productivity tends to be lower than in countries with a much smaller share of public sector jobs. For example, Australia’s figure is 18 per cent, New Zealand is 12 per cent, and Singapore, Japan and South Korea have less than 10 per cent public sector employment. Given the importance of employment for prosperity, this chapter provides some insights into the labour market with a focus on the driving forces behind unemployment. They can be separated into two broad categories – long term and short term. The economy’s natural rate of unemployment relates to the long-term perspective and describes the amount of unemployment that the economy normally experiences. Conversely, cyclical unemployment refers to the short-run fluctuations in unemployment around its natural rate and it is closely associated with the short-run ups and downs of economic activity during the business cycle. Cyclical unemployment has its own explanations, which we defer until we study short-run economic fluctuations later in the book. In this chapter we discuss the determinants of an economy’s natural rate of unemployment. It is often referred to as the ‘non-accelerating-inflation rate of unemployment’ (NAIRU), or the level at which the economy is at ‘full employment’. As we will see, the designation ‘natural’ does not in any way imply that this rate of unemployment is desirable or inevitable. It just means that this natural unemployment does not go away on its own, even in the long run. So, it is important to keep in mind that the term full employment does not mean that all people willing to work actually have a job. We begin the chapter by looking at some of the relevant facts that describe unemployment. In particular, we examine three questions: How do we measure the economy’s rate of unemployment? What problems arise in interpreting the unemployment data? How long are the unemployed typically without work? We then turn to the reasons why economies always experience some unemployment and the ways in which policymakers attempt to reduce the number of people without jobs. We discuss three components of the natural rate of unemployment: structural, frictional and classical. Structural unemployment arises from a skill mismatch: The skills some workers have differ from those employers need. Frictional unemployment occurs when workers are searching for a new job and are temporarily unemployed in the meantime. Finally, classical 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 4 The real economyCopyright in the long run 09_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 196 24/08/20 4:33 PM unemployment arises when the real wage in the labour market is too high for employers to be able to hire all the workers willing to work at that wage. We examine three reasons for why the real wage may be too high and not adjusted to balance labour supply and demand, namely minimum-wage laws, unions and efficiency wages. You will see that long-run unemployment does not arise from a single problem. Instead, it reflects a variety of underlying causes. As a result, there is no easy way for policymakers to eliminate the economy’s natural rate of unemployment and to alleviate the hardships experienced by the unemployed. LO9.1 Identifying unemployment We begin this chapter by examining more precisely what the term unemployment means. How is unemployment measured? Measuring unemployment in Australia is the job of the Australian Bureau of Statistics (ABS). Every month the ABS produces data on unemployment and on other aspects of the labour market, like types of employment, length of the average working week and the duration of unemployment. These data come from a regular survey of around 0.33 per cent of the civilian population aged 15 years and over, called the Labour Force Survey. Based on the answers to the survey questions, the ABS places each such individual in each surveyed household into one of three categories: • employed • unemployed • not in the labour force. A person is considered employed if he or she spent at least one hour of the previous week working at a paid job (including self-employment) or family business. For a person to be classified as unemployed a key criterion is that he or she is actively looking for a job; not having a job is insufficient. The exceptions are people who are on a temporary layoff and waiting to start a new job. A person who is neither employed nor unemployed falls in the third category with a somewhat odd name, not in the labour force. This includes groups inactive in the labour market like full-time students, stay-at-home parents, the disabled and retirees. Figure 9.1 shows this breakdown for October 2019. Once the ABS has placed all the individuals covered by the survey in a category, it calculates various statistics to summarise the state of the labour market. Let us consider the key ones. The ABS defines the labour force as the sum of the employed and the unemployed: Labour force = Number of employed + Number of unemployed The ABS defines the unemployment rate as the proportion of the labour force (not the entire adult population) that falls in the unemployed category: Unemployment rate = Number of unemployed × 100 Labour force The ABS calculates unemployment rates for the entire adult population and for more narrow groups – men, women, youth and so on. The ABS uses the same survey to produce data on labour-force participation. The labour-force participation rate is the percentage of the total adult population that is either employed or unemployed: Labour-force participation rate = Labour force × 100 Adult population labour force the total number of workers, including both the employed and the unemployed unemployment rate the percentage of the labour force that is unemployed labour-force participation rate the proportion of the adult population that is in the labour force This statistic tells us the fraction of the population that has chosen to participate in the labour market, so its numerator includes the unemployed as well. The labour-force participation rate, like the unemployment rate, is calculated both for the entire adult population and for more narrow groups. 197 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or inChapter part. WCN 02-200-202 9 The natural rate of unemployment 09_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 197 24/08/20 4:33 PM FIGURE 9.1 The breakdown of the adult population in terms of the labour market (October 2019) Employed (12 935 693) Labour force (13 658 083) Adult population (20 680 657) Unemployed (722 390) Not in labour force (7 022 574) The ABS divides the adult population into three categories – employed, unemployed, and not in the labour force. Source: Based on statistical data from the ABS, Cat. No. 6202.0 To see how these data are calculated, consider the figures for October 2019. The adult population was about 20.68 million, out of which about 12.94 million people were employed and 0.72 million people were unemployed. These numbers imply the following: Labour Force participation rate = 13.66 × 100 = 66.1 20.68 Labour Force = 12.94 + 0.72 = 13.66 0.72 Unemployment rate = × 100 = 5.3% 13.66 Hence, in October 2019, about two-thirds of the Australian adult population were participating in the labour market and one in 19 of them (5.3 per cent) was unemployed. Table 9.1 shows the statistics on unemployment and labour-force participation for various groups within the Australian population. Three comparisons are most apparent. First, women have lower rates of labour-force participation than men (although as you will see later, the difference has been getting smaller and it is reversed in the youth cohort). Second, once in the labour force women and men have similar rates of unemployment. Third, migrants to Australia have slightly higher unemployment and participation rates than the overall population. Fourth, teenagers have much lower rates of labour-force participation and much higher rates of unemployment than the overall population. More generally, these data show that labour-market experiences vary widely among groups within the economy. It should be mentioned that the basic labour market statistics summarise the situation in a given point in time (i.e. they are stock variables); they do not show the dynamic story of people moving between the three main categories (i.e. the flows). For example, even if the number of employed and unemployed people remains unchanged, there are always people who get a new job. This may be either within the employed category (people changing between jobs) or from the unemployed category (formerly unemployed people replacing some formerly employed people). 198 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 4 The real economyCopyright in the long run 09_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 198 24/08/20 4:33 PM Demographic group Unemployment rate (in %) Labour-force participation rate (in %) Adults (aged 15 and over) Total 5.3 66.1 Male 5.4 71.1 Female 5.2 61.3 Recent migrants and temporary residents * 7.4 69.8 Total 17.7 55.0 Male 19.7 53.4 Female 15.7 56.6 Teenagers (aged 15–19) Source: ABS DATA, cat. 6202.0, Tables 1, 17, Cat. 6250.0, Table 5 TABLE 9.1 The labour-market experiences of various demographic groups (May 2016) *denotes June 2017 data In recent years, economists and policymakers have become concerned about how many hours employed people are working and whether the labour force is underutilised – that is, people working less than they could or would like to. They attempt to explain the seemingly contradictory phenomenon of the past three decades whereby both full-time and parttime workers work longer hours than before, but the average number of hours worked per employed person has trended downwards. How can it be? Essentially, more and more people are working part-time rather than full-time, which more than offsets the fact that both full-time and part-time workers are working longer hours. ABS surveys suggest that while most part-time workers are happy with their reduced workload, about a quarter of them would prefer to work more hours. These workers are classified as underemployed. ABS data show a worrying trend, namely that the underemployment rate increased from 2.6 per cent in early 1978 to 8.5 per cent in October 2019. As Professor Jeff Borland documents in his 2016 survey of the Australian labour market (Labour market snapshot #25, March 2016), the largest increases in underemployment have occurred among young workers aged 15–24 years, from about 3 per cent in 1978 to 17 per cent in 2015. The underemployment rate for this age group in October 2019 was 20.7 per cent. He also reports that ‘the incidence of part-time employment has grown particularly among the least educated’. The ABS also reports the labour underutilisation rate, which is the number of unemployed plus the underemployed, as a percentage of the labour force. This rate for all the total work force has stayed fairly constant for the last decade, from 13.2 per cent in 2009 to 13.8 per cent in 2019. If you are in the 15–24 age bracket, though, the news isn’t so good – the underutilisation rate for this group rose from 25.7 in 2009 to 30.2 in 2019. Policymakers and economists monitor the data on the various measures of employment and unemployment as a way to see how the economy is performing over time. We mentioned the natural rate of unemployment at the start of the chapter – this rate is important because it tells us whether we are likely to see wages increase as more people find work. The RBA has estimated that the NAIRU has declined from 6 per cent in 2003 to around 5 per cent in 2017. What this means in practice is that more people finding jobs won’t necessarily put pressure on wages to increase. Quoting Jeff Borland again, ‘The decline of trade unions, changes in bargaining power suggests, if anything, you may be able to push the rate of unemployment lower without causing a big breakout in wage inflation.’ (https://www.theguardian.com/ australia-news/2018/mar/02/who-is-to-blame-for-australias-stalled-wages) Even though many economists think the NAIRU may be lower, this isn’t spread evenly across all states. Figure 9.2 shows the unemployment rate for each state, along with 199 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or inChapter part. WCN 02-200-202 9 The natural rate of unemployment 09_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 199 24/08/20 4:33 PM an estimate of its NAIRU. Those states that have an unemployment rate close to its NAIRU are more likely to see wages growth as employment increases. FIGURE 9.2 Estimate of NAIRU, 2016–17 (%) Oct 2017 unemployment rate 7 6 5 4 3 NSW Vic Qld WA SA Tas NT ACT Source: Goldman Sachs, reprinted in Australian Financial Review, ‘“Natural” unemployment rate may be lower than Reserve Bank estimates, say economists’, 8 February 2018 Labour-force participation of men and women in the Australian economy The role of women in Australian society has changed dramatically over the past century. In part, the change is due to new technologies, like the washing machine, clothes dryer, refrigerator, freezer and dishwasher, which have reduced the amount of time required to complete routine household tasks. In part, the change is attributable to improved birth control, which was one of the factors behind a reduction in the number of children born to the typical family. And, of course, the change in a woman’s role is also partly attributable to changing political and social attitudes; for example, university degrees becoming widely accessible to women. Together, these developments have had a profound impact on society in general and on the economy in particular. Nowhere is that impact more obvious than in data on labour-force participation. Just after the Second World War, men and women had very different roles in society. Only around 30 per cent of women were working or looking for work, in contrast to over 85 per cent of men. This is apparent in Figure 9.3 showing the labour-force participation rates of men and women in Australia since 1978. Over the past several decades, the difference between the participation rates of men and women has gradually diminished as growing numbers of women have entered the labour force and some men have left it. At the end of 2019, 61.3 per cent of women and 71.1 per cent of men were More women are working now than ever before. in the labour force. So while labourforce participation rates are still higher for men than women, they have been converging over time. It is most apparent in the 55–64 age category in which the participation rate for women increased from 38.3 per cent to 59.9 per cent between 2002 and 2018. Source: Shutterstock.com/Jacob Lund CASE STUDY 200 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 4 The real economyCopyright in the long run 09_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 200 24/08/20 4:33 PM FIGURE 9.3 Labour-force participation rates in Australia for men and women since 1978 90.0 80.0 70.0 60.0 50.0 40.0 30.0 20.0 Feb-2018 Feb-2016 Feb-2014 Feb-2012 Feb-2010 Feb-2008 Feb-2006 Feb-2004 Feb-2002 Feb-2000 Feb-1998 Feb-1996 Feb-1992 Feb-1990 Feb-1988 Feb-1986 Feb-1984 Feb-1982 Feb-1980 Feb-1978 0.0 Feb-1994 Participation rate; > Males; Percent Trend PERCENT Month Participa0on rate; > Females; Percent Trend PERCENT Month 10.0 Over the past several decades, the proportion of Australian women who enter the labour force has been increasing, and the proportion of such men decreasing. Source: ABS DATA, Cat. No. 6202.0, Table 1 The increase in women’s labour-force participation is easy to understand, but the fall in men’s may seem puzzling. There are several reasons for this decline. First, young men now stay in school longer than their fathers and grandfathers did. Second, with more women employed, more fathers now stay at home to raise their children (some companies in Australia now allow men to take parental leave). Third, as the average age in the Australian population grows due to increases in life expectancy and declines in fertility (a trend towards an ageing population discussed in an earlier chapter), more men move into higher age brackets where labour-force participation rates are lower. In fact, the latter seems to be the main explanation for the recent declines in the overall labour-force participation rate of Australian men, because over the past decade the participation rate has increased for every individual age group. In summary, the increases in the proportion of full-time students, stay-at-home fathers and retirees, all of whom are counted as not in the labour force, imply a drop in the labour-force participation rate. Questions 1 What factors have led to the fall in men’s labour-force participation rate? 2 Will this have an impact on median income? Explain. Is unemployment measured correctly? Measuring the amount of unemployment in the economy is not as straightforward as it might seem. Although it is easy to distinguish between a person with a full-time job and a person who is not working at all, it is much harder to distinguish between a person who is unemployed and a person who is not in the labour force. Movements in and out of the labour force are, in fact, very common. More than one third of the unemployed are recent entrants into the labour force. These entrants include young 201 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or inChapter part. WCN 02-200-202 9 The natural rate of unemployment 09_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 201 24/08/20 4:33 PM discouraged workers individuals who would like to work but have given up looking for a job IN THE NEWS workers looking for their first jobs, like recent university graduates. They also include older workers who had previously left the labour force but have now returned to look for work. Moreover, not all unemployment ends with the job seeker finding a job. Almost half of all spells of unemployment end when the unemployed person leaves the labour force. Because people move in and out of the labour force so often, statistics on unemployment are difficult to interpret. On the one hand, some of those who report being unemployed may not, in fact, be trying very hard to find a job. They may be reporting themselves as unemployed to qualify for one of the government programs that provide financial assistance for the unemployed. It would be more realistic to view some of these individuals as not in the labour force. On the other hand, some of those who are classified as not in the labour force may, in fact, want to work. These individuals may have tried to find a job but have given up after an unsuccessful search. Such individuals, called discouraged workers, do not show up in unemployment statistics, even though they are truly workers without jobs. This is a non-trivial problem in Australia. For the last five years, Australia has had over one million people who the ABS designate as having ‘… marginal attachment to the labour force’. These are people who are employed part-time and would like more work and have applied for jobs, registered with job agencies and so forth. Of the one million in this category, around 90 000 (in 2019) were designated ‘discouraged workers’ – they wanted to work but had given up looking. For example, the total number of discouraged workers in Switzerland, Denmark and Austria was less than 10 000 in that year – despite their combined population being comparable to Australia’s. Even the United Kingdom, with triple the population, has had fewer than 50 000 discouraged workers in for the last five years, with only 34 000 in 2019. One of the implications is that if all Australian discouraged workers were put into the unemployed category, the unemployment rate would increase significantly, from 5.3 to over 5.9 per cent as of December 2019. As the following box discusses, some believe that the labour market situation in Australia is even worse than the OECD statistics show. Is true Australian unemployment double the official rate? Roy Morgan Research has conducted weekly labour market surveys in the form of face-to-face interviews since 2007. Their estimates imply that official unemployment statistics by the ABS may underestimate the real unemployment rate. For example, Roy Morgan Research estimated the unemployment rate to be 10.9 per cent in March 2019, which was over double the rate calculated by the ABS. Roy Morgan Research further reported 9.7 per cent of the workforce to be underemployed – working part-time but attempting to find additional work. Using Roy Morgan Research’s methodology implies over 20 per cent of workingage Australians are either unemployed or underemployed. Roy Morgan Research estimates are considered controversial by many, and their accuracy disputed by the government. Nevertheless, they suggest that various labour market statistics should be examined carefully and broadly to get an accurate picture of employment conditions. Unfortunately, there is no generally agreed-upon way to adjust the unemployment rate as reported by the ABS to make it a more reliable indicator. In the end, it is best to view the reported unemployment rate as a useful but imperfect measure of joblessness, and use various sources for comparison. Source: Roy Morgan Research, http://www.roymorgan.com/findings/7948-roy-morganaustralian-unemployment-march-2019-201904160632 202 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 4 The real economyCopyright in the long run 09_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 202 24/08/20 4:33 PM CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING How do we measure the unemployment rate? Can it overstate or understate the true amount of joblessness? How long are the unemployed without work? In judging how serious the problem of unemployment is, one question to consider is whether unemployment is typically a short-term or long-term condition. If unemployment is short term, one might conclude that it is not a big problem. Workers may require a few weeks between jobs to find the openings that best suit their skills and tastes. Yet if unemployment is long term, one might conclude that it is a serious problem. Workers unemployed for many months are more likely to suffer economic shortages, skill deterioration, isolation or psychological hardship. Research even shows that they are less likely to get married and more likely to get divorced. Because the duration of unemployment can affect our view about how costly unemployment is, economists have devoted much energy to studying data on the duration of unemployment spells. In this work, they have uncovered a result that is important, subtle and seemingly contradictory – most spells of unemployment are short, but most unemployment observed at any given time is long term. To see how this statement can be true, consider an example. Suppose that you visited an unemployment office every month for a year to survey the unemployed. Each month you find that there are four unemployed workers. Three of these workers are the same individuals for the whole year, whereas the fourth person changes every month. Based on this experience, would you say that unemployment is typically short term or long term? Some simple calculations help answer this question. In this example, you meet a total of 15 unemployed people – 12 of them are unemployed for one month and three are unemployed for the full year. Thus, 12/15, or 80 per cent, of unemployment spells end in one month. That is, most spells of unemployment are short. Yet consider the total amount of unemployment at some given month. Out of the four unemployed people, three are unemployed for a full year. This means that 75 per cent of unemployment observed at any given time is long term. This subtle conclusion implies that economists and policymakers must be careful when interpreting data on unemployment and when designing policies to help the unemployed. Most people who become unemployed will soon find jobs, and they generally need little help. Yet most of the economy’s unemployment problem is attributable to the relatively few workers who are jobless for long periods of time. Why is there unemployment? Now that you have a good idea about what unemployment is and how it is measured, let us explain why economies experience unemployment. In most markets in the economy, prices and product features adjust to bring the quantity supplied and demanded into balance. In an ideal labour market, wages and workers’ skills would adjust to balance the quantity of labour supplied and the quantity of labour demanded. This adjustment of wages and skills would ensure that all workers are always fully employed. Of course, reality does not resemble this ideal. There are always some workers without jobs, even when the overall economy is doing well. In other words, the natural unemployment rate never falls to zero; instead, it fluctuates around the natural rate of unemployment. Three types of unemployment help explain why natural unemployment never falls to zero. 203 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or inChapter part. WCN 02-200-202 9 The natural rate of unemployment 09_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 203 24/08/20 4:33 PM One is frictional unemployment. This is unemployment associated with job search – people being temporarily unemployed while they look for a new job. This type of unemployment is usually of a short duration for the individual, but from the society’s point of view it is a long-term phenomenon as there are always such workers in between jobs. Another type of unemployment is called structural unemployment. This is unemployment that results from a mismatch between the skills that businesses require and the skills that workers have. Austrian-American economist Joseph Schumpeter called the dynamic process within markets ‘creative destruction’, whereby new ideas, products and jobs constantly replace the old ones. Structural unemployment tends to be longer in duration because it takes time for people to acquire new skills that the labour market demands. The third type of unemployment is called classical unemployment. It arises because the real wage in the labour market is above the market clearing level that equates supply of and demand for labour. In the next section we will examine three reasons for such high wage unemployment, namely minimum-wage laws, unions and efficiency wages. LO9.2 Classical unemployment The real wage that occurs in the labour market may sometimes be too high to equate supply of and demand for labour. For example, Guy Debelle and James Vickery estimated for Australia that ‘slower real wage growth of 2 per cent below trend for one year could result in a permanent reduction in the unemployment rate of about one percentage point’ (RBA Conference 1998, ‘The Macroeconomics of Australian unemployment’, https://www.rba. gov.au/publications/confs/1998/debelle-vickery.html). The following sections present three main reasons for an above-equilibrium wage, and show how they lead to what is called classical (or real-wage) unemployment. Minimum-wage laws We begin by reviewing how unemployment arises from minimum-wage laws. It is a natural place to start because, as we will see, it can be used to understand some of the other reasons for unemployment. Figure 9.4 reviews the basic economics of a minimum wage. When a minimum-wage law forces the wage to remain above the level that balances supply and demand, it raises the quantity of labour supplied and reduces the quantity of labour demanded compared with the equilibrium level. There is a surplus of labour, that is, classical type unemployment. There are more workers willing to work than there are jobs, and some workers are therefore unemployed. Minimum-wage laws create a gap between supply and demand for labour. We focus here on their effect in the labour market. Before doing so, it is however important to note that minimum-wage laws are not a predominant reason for unemployment. It is because most workers in the economy earn higher wages. Minimum-wage laws are binding most often for the least skilled and least experienced members of the labour force so it is only among these workers that minimum-wage laws may explain the existence of unemployment. Although Figure 9.4 was drawn to show the effects of a minimum-wage law, it demonstrates a more general lesson – if the wage is kept above the equilibrium level for any reason, the result is classical unemployment. Minimum-wage laws are just one reason that wages may be ‘too high’. We can break down the quantity LS into the following three categories. First, the quantity of labour LD are workers who have kept their jobs and now enjoy a higher wage than before. Due to a higher income these workers are better off. Second, the quantity LE – LD are workers 204 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 4 The real economyCopyright in the long run 09_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 204 24/08/20 4:33 PM FIGURE 9.4 Unemployment resulting from minimum wage legislation forcing wages above the equilibrium level Wage Labour supply Surplus of labour classical unemployment Minimum wage WE Labour demand 0 LD LE LS Quantity of labour (in hours) In this labour market, the (real) wage at which supply and demand balance is WE. At this equilibrium wage, the quantity of labour supplied and the quantity of labour demanded both equal LE. In contrast, if the wage is forced to remain above the equilibrium level, perhaps because of a minimum-wage law, the quantity of labour supplied rises to LS, and the quantity of labour demanded falls to LD. The resulting excess supply of labour, LS–LD, represents classical unemployment. who had a job before the minimum wage was implemented, but lost it as a consequence of this law. They are undoubtedly worse off than before. Third, the quantity LS – LE are new entrants. These workers were not in the labour force at the equilibrium wage WE, but were attracted by the higher minimum wage. Nevertheless, given the surplus of labour they are unable to find a job at this wage so they are also arguably worse off than before. Australia has a system of minimum wages that take the form of awards. These are minimum wage levels that are set for certain jobs in broad industry categories. So, in contrast to a simple minimum wage, the award system affords some flexibility to take into account differences in industry conditions and job skills. In the next two sections, we consider two other reasons that may keep wages above the equilibrium level – unions and efficiency wages. The basic economics of unemployment in these cases is the same as that shown in Figure 9.4, but these explanations of unemployment can apply to many more of the economy’s workers. CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING Keynesian economists stress the fact that recipients of the higher minimum wage will spend more, which increases demand for products and services and makes firms hire more labour. How could you incorporate this argument into Figure 9.4? Can you think of some other arguments and important factors not captured in the simple model of Figure 9.4 (including those that could justify minimum wage legislation not only on equity grounds but also on efficiency grounds)? If the level of minimum wages rises, what happens to labour demand, labour supply and the unemployment level? Based on your answer, do you think minimum wages should rise? 205 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or inChapter part. WCN 02-200-202 9 The natural rate of unemployment 09_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 205 24/08/20 4:33 PM Unions and collective bargaining union a worker association that bargains with employers over wages and working conditions collective bargaining the process by which unions and firms agree on the terms of employment In some industries, labour markets do not operate according to the simple principles of supply and demand. In industries like transport, teaching and mining, wages are determined by negotiations between unions and employers. A union is a type of cartel. Like any cartel, a union is a group of sellers acting together in the hope of exerting their joint market power. Many workers in the economy discuss their wages, benefits and working conditions with their employers as individuals. In contrast, workers in a union do so as a group. The process by which unions and firms agree on the terms of employment is called collective bargaining. The role of unions has been the source of considerable debate in Australia. Every year it seems that workers and employers in some industry, whether it be air transport, meat processing, or the waterfront, are in a dispute. Unionisation was partly a response to very poor working conditions in those industries. There was a time when being a member of a union was seen as very important to achieving better work conditions. However, as depicted in Figure 9.5, both trade union membership as a proportion of the workforce and the numbers of workers in unions have declined over the past three decades. Young workers are less likely to join a union, and union membership is no longer compulsory. There has also been a decline in the sectors that have traditionally been heavily unionised, such as car manufacturing and clothing, textile and footwear workers. There have been increases in union membership among police, nursing and midwifery and education. FIGURE 9.5 Unionisation rate in Australia 50 2.5 40 2.0 30 1.5 20 1.0 10 0.5 0 0 Union membership–Million 3.0 Union members (RHS) Union density (LHS) 1976 1982 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2016 Trade union density–per cent 60 Source: Parliament of Australia, Geoff Gilfillan and Chris McGann Statistics and Mapping Section, Trends in union membership in Australia, 15 October 2018. Based on 1976–1993: ABS, Trade Union Members, cat. no. 6325.0; 1994–2013: ABS, Employee Earnings Benefits and Trade Union Membership, cat. no. 6310.0; 2014–2016: ABS, Characteristics of Employment, cat. no. 6333.0[1] https://www.aph.gov.au/About_Parliament/Parliamentary_Departments/Parliamentary_Library/pubs/rp/rp1819/ UnionMembership#_Toc527380727 Unionisation varies greatly across countries. For example, in 2017–18, Scandinavian countries such as Sweden (66%) and Denmark (67%) had high rates of unionisation, whereas Germany (16.5%) and the United States (10.1%) had much lower rates. The economics of unions When a union bargains with a firm, it asks for higher wages, greater benefits and better working conditions than the firm would offer in the absence of a union. If the union and the firm do not reach agreement, the union can organise a withdrawal of labour from the firm, 206 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 4 The real economyCopyright in the long run 09_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 206 24/08/20 4:33 PM called a strike. Because a strike reduces production, sales and profit, a firm facing a strike threat is more likely to agree to pay higher wages than it otherwise would. When a union raises the wage above the equilibrium level, it raises the quantity of labour supplied and reduces the quantity of labour demanded, resulting in classical unemployment. The graphical representation is identical to the one in Figure 9.4. Those workers who remain employed are better off, but those who were previously employed and are now unemployed are worse off. Indeed, unions are sometimes thought to cause conflict between different groups of workers – the insiders who benefit from high union wages and the outsiders who do not get the better paid jobs. The outsiders can respond to their status in one of two ways. Some of them remain unemployed and wait for the chance to become insiders and earn the high union wage. Others take jobs in firms that are not unionised. Thus, when unions raise wages in one part of the economy, the supply of labour increases in other parts of the economy. This increase in labour supply, in turn, generally reduces wages in industries that are not unionised. In other words, it is believed that workers in unions often reap the benefit of collective bargaining, whereas workers not in unions bear some of the cost. The end result is that the existence of unions can cause wages to be higher in some industries and, hence, some workers to be unemployed. However, the ability of unions to exert this control depends on their specific goals. Many unions are explicitly concerned about unemployment levels and are willing to negotiate wage arrangements that promote existing employment levels. Let us give two Australian examples. During the 1980s, these negotiations were assisted by the Hawke government, which offered workers tax cuts in order to preserve their after-tax real incomes. Similarly, in 1992 the Keating government introduced a pension reform and the unions agreed that a 3 per cent reduction in the pay rise was to be put into the workers’ individual superannuation accounts. strike organised temporary withdrawal of labour from a firm FYI Why do strikes occur? Strikes are costly to both firms and workers. To firms they represent lost output; to workers lost income. The longer the strike, the costlier it is to both parties. So why do they occur? In reality, strikes occur because negotiations do not always run smoothly. Negotiations break down. During times of disagreement, unions wish to demonstrate their resolve by striking and being willing to forgo income. Management also wants to demonstrate to the union that it can weather a strike and hold out as well. In this case, disagreements are the result of ‘brinkmanship’ – an attempt by both parties to temporarily use threats to demonstrate the value of their work to the firm. If both unions and management had a better understanding of the costs of strike action, brinkmanship might not occur. In this way, strikes can be seen as the result of a lack of information. Unions might believe that a company does not appreciate their full value. Management might believe that unions do not appreciate the competitive pressures of the market and the risks inherent in the economy. Nonetheless, in the past – whether because of simple misunderstanding or differences in information – many workdays were lost to industrial action. To reduce the problem, Australia has had government involvement in the resolution of industrial disputes. At its core is a dispute resolution body – the Fair Work Commission (previously the Industrial Relations Commission performed the role). Whenever a union contemplates strike action, the commission’s task was to step in and arbitrate the dispute. Its rulings are binding. 207 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or inChapter part. WCN 02-200-202 9 The natural rate of unemployment 09_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 207 24/08/20 4:33 PM The strengthening of the arbitration system, together with the Accord between the government and the trade unions regarding wage restraint, resulted in a substantial reduction in workdays lost due to industrial disputes. This is apparent in Figure 9.6. Such reduction occurred in most high-income countries, but some, for example, France and Denmark, still experience much more frequent strikes than Australia. FIGURE 9.6 Industrial disputes in Australia Working 120 days lost per 1000 100 employees 80 60 40 20 Mar-15 Dec-13 Jun-11 Sep-12 Mar-10 Dec-08 Jun-06 Sep-07 Mar-05 Dec-03 Jun-01 Sep-02 Mar-00 Dec-98 Jun-96 Sep-97 Mar-95 Dec-93 Jun-91 Sep-92 Mar-90 Dec-88 Jun-86 Sep-87 Mar-85 0 Year Source: Based on statistical data from the ABS, various years, Cat. No. 6321.0.55.001, http://www.abs.gov.au/AUSSTATS/ abs@.nsf/DetailsPage/6321.0.55.001Mar%202013?OpenDocument#Time The theory of efficiency wages efficiency wage above-equilibrium wages paid by firms in order to increase worker productivity Our third and final explanation for an above-equilibrium wage and the resulting classical unemployment comes from practices designed to improve workplace performance. Firms may set wages high so as to motivate workers to perform well in their jobs. This wage is called an efficiency wage. Since it exceeds the level under which supply equals demand, it can potentially explain unemployment; the same way as minimum wages in Figure 9.4. Why should firms want to keep wages high? In some ways, this decision seems odd, for wages are a large part of firms’ costs. Normally, we expect profit-maximising firms to want to keep costs – and therefore wages – as low as possible. If a firm pays a wage above the equilibrium, workers employed by that firm will want to work harder to keep that job as moving to another firm will lower their wages. The novel insight of efficiency-wage theory is that paying above-equilibrium wages might be profitable because it might raise the efficiency of a firm’s workers by more than it costs. There are several types of the efficiency-wage theory, each suggesting a different explanation for why firms may want to pay high wages. Let’s consider four of these theories. Worker health The first type of efficiency-wage theory dates back to the 1920s and emphasises the link between wages and worker health. Better paid workers can afford to eat a more nutritious diet and should therefore be healthier and more productive. This type of efficiency-wage theory is not relevant for firms in high-income countries like Australia where the equilibrium wage for most workers is well above the level needed for an adequate diet. Paying higher wages to raise worker health is more relevant for firms in less prosperous countries where inadequate nutrition is a more common problem. In such countries, health concerns may explain why firms do not cut wages despite a surplus of labour. 208 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 4 The real economyCopyright in the long run 09_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 208 24/08/20 4:33 PM Worker turnover A second type of efficiency-wage theory focuses on the link between wages and worker turnover. Workers quit jobs for many reasons – to take jobs in other firms, to move to other parts of the country, to leave the labour force and so on. The frequency with which they quit depends on the entire set of incentives they face, including the benefits of leaving and the benefits of staying with their current employer. The more a firm pays its workers, the less often its workers choose to leave. Thus, a firm can reduce turnover among its workers by paying them a higher wage. Why do firms care about turnover? The reason is that it is costly for firms to hire and train new workers. Moreover, even after they are trained, newly hired workers are not as productive as experienced workers. Firms with higher turnover, therefore, tend to have higher production costs. Firms may therefore find it profitable to pay wages above the equilibrium level in order to reduce worker turnover. Henry Ford and the generous $5-a-day wage Henry Ford was an industrial visionary. As founder of the Ford Motor Company, he was responsible for introducing modern techniques of production. Rather than building cars with small teams of skilled craftsmen, Ford built cars on assembly lines in which unskilled workers were taught to perform the same simple tasks over and over again. The output of this assembly process was the Model T Ford, one of the most famous early cars. In 1914, Ford introduced another innovation – the $5 workday. This might not seem like much today, but back then $5 was about twice the going wage (using your knowledge from an earlier chapter, you should be able to tell what information is needed to work out that the $5 amount in 1914 corresponds to roughly $300 in 2019 dollars). It was also far above the wage that balanced supply and demand. When the new $5-a-day wage was announced, long lines of job seekers formed outside the Ford factories. The number of workers willing to work at this wage far exceeded the number of workers Ford needed. Ford’s high-wage policy had many of the effects predicted by efficiency-wage theory. Turnover fell, absenteeism was halved and productivity rose by more than 50 per cent according to the company’s calculations. Workers were so much more efficient that Ford’s production costs were lower even though wages were much higher. Thus, paying a wage above the equilibrium level was profitable for the firm. Henry Ford himself called the $5-a-day wage ‘one of the finest cost-cutting moves we ever made’. Why did it take Henry Ford to introduce this efficiency wage? Why were other firms not already taking advantage of this seemingly profitable business strategy? According to some analysts, Ford’s decision was closely linked to his use of the assembly line. Workers organised in an assembly line are highly interdependent. If one worker is absent or works slowly, other workers are less able to complete their own tasks. Thus, while assembly lines made production more efficient, they also raised the importance of low worker turnover, high worker quality and high worker effort. As a result, paying efficiency wages may have been a more appropriate strategy for the Ford Motor Company than for other businesses at the time. CASE STUDY Questions 1 Do you think Ford’s high wage was a good predictor of efficiency-wage theory? 2 Do you think the $5 workday improved Ford’s production efficiency? 209 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or inChapter part. WCN 02-200-202 9 The natural rate of unemployment 09_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 209 24/08/20 4:33 PM Worker effort A third type of efficiency-wage theory highlights the link between wages and worker effort. In many jobs, workers have some discretion over how hard to work. As a result, firms monitor the efforts of their workers, and workers caught shirking their responsibilities are fired. But not all shirkers are caught immediately because monitoring workers is costly and imperfect. A firm can respond to this problem by paying wages above the equilibrium level. Higher wages make workers more eager to keep their jobs and, thereby, give workers an incentive to put forward their best effort. In a high unemployment economy, the threat of unemployment can, in principle, be used by employers to reduce wages. In a low unemployment environment, however, employers cannot use this ‘stick’, and they therefore use the ‘carrot’ by paying wages above the equilibrium level. This causes classical unemployment while providing an incentive for workers not to shirk their responsibilities. Worker quality A fourth type of efficiency-wage theory emphasises the link between wages and worker quality. When a firm hires new workers, it cannot perfectly observe the quality of the applicants. By paying a high wage, the firm attracts a better pool of workers to apply for its jobs. To see how this might work, consider a simple example. Waterwell Company owns one well and needs one worker to pump water from the well. Two workers, Bill and Ben, are interested in the job. Bill, a proficient worker, is willing to work for $30 per hour. Below that wage, he would rather start his own lawn-mowing business. Ben, a complete incompetent, is willing to work for $10 per hour. Below that wage, he would rather sit on the beach. Economists say that Bill’s reservation wage – the lowest wage he would accept – is $30, and Ben’s reservation wage is $10. What wage should the firm set? If the firm were interested in minimising labour costs, it would set the wage at $10 per hour. At this wage, the quantity of workers supplied (one) would balance the quantity demanded. Ben would take the job and Bill would not apply for it. Yet suppose Waterwell knows that only one of these two applicants is competent, but it does not know whether it is Bill or Ben. If the firm hires the incompetent worker, he will damage the well, causing the firm huge losses. In this case, the firm has a better strategy than paying the equilibrium wage of $10 and hiring Ben. It can offer $30 per hour, inducing both Bill and Ben to apply for the job. By choosing between these two applicants, the firm has at least a 50–50 chance of hiring the competent worker (probably higher since it can infer the quality of the workers from their résumés and interviews). In contrast, if the firm offers any lower wage, it is sure to hire the incompetent worker. This story illustrates a general phenomenon. When a firm has an excess supply of workers, it might seem profitable to reduce the wage it is offering. But by reducing the wage, the firm would induce an adverse change in the mix of its workers and job applicants. CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING Why might firms pay wages to employees that are above equilibrium wage? 210 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 4 The real economyCopyright in the long run 09_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 210 24/08/20 4:33 PM FYI The economics of asymmetric information: Adverse selection and moral hazard In many situations in life, information is asymmetric – one person in a transaction knows more about what is going on than the other person. This possibility raises a variety of interesting problems for economists. We have just seen some of these problems raised in the context of the theory of efficiency wages. These problems, however, go beyond the study of unemployment. The worker-quality variant of the efficiency-wage theory illustrates a general phenomenon called adverse selection. Adverse selection arises when one person knows more about the attributes of a good or service than another and, as a result, the uninformed person runs the risk of being sold a good or service of low quality. In the worker-quality story of Bill and Ben, for instance, workers have better information about their own abilities than firms do. When a firm cuts the wage it pays to below $30, the selection of workers changes in a way that is adverse to the firm – only the less competent remains. Adverse selection arises in many other circumstances. Here are two examples: • Sellers of used cars know their cars’ defects whereas buyers often do not. Because owners of the worst cars are more likely to sell them than are the owners of the best cars, car buyers are correctly apprehensive about getting a low-quality car, a ‘lemon’. As a result, many people avoid buying cars in the second-hand market. • Buyers of private health insurance know more about their own health problems than do health funds. Because people with greater hidden health problems are more likely to buy private health insurance than are other people, the price of health insurance reflects the costs of a sicker-than-average person. As a result, relatively healthier people are discouraged from buying private health insurance. In each case, the market for the product – used cars or private health insurance – does not work as well as it might because of the problem of adverse selection. Can you think of some solutions to the problem? To give one example, a common way of reducing the adverse selection problem in the second-hand car market is to offer a warranty. If it is sufficiently comprehensive, it sends a strong signal to the buyer that the product is not a lemon, and increases the buyer’s willingness to purchase it at a higher price. The worker-effort variant of efficiency-wage theory illustrates a different phenomenon called moral hazard. Moral hazard arises when one person, called the agent, is performing some task on behalf of another person, called the principal. Because the principal cannot perfectly monitor the agent’s behaviour, the agent tends to undertake less effort than the principal considers desirable. The term ‘moral hazard’ refers to the risk of dishonest or otherwise inappropriate behaviour by the agent. In such a situation, the principal tries various ways to encourage the agent to act more responsibly. In an employment relationship, the firm is the principal and the worker is the agent. The moral-hazard problem is the temptation of imperfectly monitored workers to shirk their responsibilities. According to the worker-effort variant of efficiency-wage theory, the principal can encourage the agent not to shirk by paying a wage above the equilibrium level because then the agent has more to lose if caught shirking. In this way, high wages reduce the problem of moral hazard. 211 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or inChapter part. WCN 02-200-202 9 The natural rate of unemployment 09_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 211 24/08/20 4:33 PM Moral hazard arises in many other situations. Here are some examples: A homeowner with fire insurance buys too few fire extinguishers. The reason is that the homeowner bears the cost of the extinguisher whereas the insurance company receives much of the benefit. • A babysitter allows children to watch more television than the parents of the children prefer. The reason is that more educational activities are beneficial for the children, but require more effort from the babysitter. • A family lives near a river with a high risk of flooding. The reason it continues to live there is that the family enjoys the scenic views and the government will bear part of the cost when it provides disaster relief after a flood. Can you identify the principal and the agent in each of these situations? How do you think the principal in each case might solve the problem of moral hazard? For example, the insurance company may offer the homeowner a ‘no claim discount’, which encourages her to increase the number of fire extinguishers to a level that is optimal to the insurance company. It is important to understand the key difference between the two asymmetric information problems. Adverse selection relates to uncertainty about the type of good or worker (e.g. competence of job applicants), and this information asymmetry occurs before the economic transaction (hiring a worker) takes place. In contrast, moral hazard refers to the incentives and behaviour of one party, and occurs after the transaction has been completed (e.g. shirking after the job contract was signed). • LO9.3 Frictional unemployment job search the process by which workers find appropriate jobs All three reasons we have just discussed that cause classical unemployment have one thing in common: They lead to the real wage being too high to support jobs for all willing workers. But we can observe some unemployment even if the real wage is at its ‘correct’ level. One reason for this is the time it takes for workers to find a new job. Job search is the process of matching workers with appropriate jobs. If all workers and all jobs were the same, so that all workers were equally well suited for all jobs, job search would not be a problem. Laid-off workers would quickly find new jobs that were well suited to them. But, in fact, workers differ in their tastes and skills, jobs differ in their attributes, and information about job candidates and job vacancies is disseminated with varying speed among the many firms and households in the economy. The inevitability of frictional unemployment Search unemployment is often the result of changes in the demand for labour among different firms. When consumers decide that they prefer Samsung phones over BlackBerrys, Samsung increases employment and BlackBerry Limited lays off workers. Its former workers must now search for new jobs and Samsung must decide which new workers to hire for the various jobs that have opened up. The result of this transition is temporary unemployment. Similarly, because different regions of the country produce different goods, employment can rise in one region and fall in another. Consider, for instance, what happens when the world price of coal falls (due to people switching to cleaner fuels). Coal mines in Western Australia respond to the lower price by decreasing production and employment. At the same time, cheaper coal decreases electricity costs, so aluminium refineries in Queensland that are electricity-intensive increase production and employment. Changes in the composition of demand among industries or regions are called sectoral shifts. Because it takes time for workers to search for jobs in the new sectors, sectoral shifts temporarily cause unemployment. 212 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 4 The real economyCopyright in the long run 09_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 212 24/08/20 4:33 PM Public policy and job search Even if some search unemployment is inevitable, public policy can nonetheless affect its prevalence. To the extent that policy can reduce the time it takes unemployed workers to find new jobs, it can reduce search unemployment. Government programs try to facilitate job finding in various ways. The main way is through government-sponsored employment agencies, which give out information about job vacancies in order to match workers and jobs more quickly. Critics of these programs question whether the government should get involved with the process of job search. They argue that it is better to let the market match workers and jobs. In fact, most job searches in the economy take place without intervention by the government. Newspaper advertisements, job newsletters, university placement offices, head-hunters and word of mouth all help spread information about job openings and job candidates. Furthermore, the Internet has improved information flows and greatly simplified the job search process. In Australia, the government largely outsources these services through the Jobactive platform (which replaced the Jobs Services Australia network in mid-2015). It pools together a number of both for-profit and non-profit organisations that have a contract with the Australian government to offer employment services. Unemployment benefits One government program that increases the amount of search unemployment, without intending to do so, is the provision of unemployment benefits. This program is designed to offer workers partial protection against income loss. Any permanent resident who becomes unemployed is eligible for such benefits. The length of eligibility in Australia has changed over time, and is currently about one year if a person does not undertake reasonable efforts to regain employment. Regardless, unemployment benefits are usually only a fraction of a worker’s previous wage. Although unemployment benefits reduce the hardship of unemployment, they also increase the amount of unemployment. The explanation is based on one of the Ten Principles of Economics in chapter 1 – people respond to incentives. Because unemployment benefits stop when a worker takes a new job, the unemployed devote less effort to job search and are more likely to turn down less attractive job offers. In addition, because unemployment benefits make unemployment less onerous, workers are less likely to seek guarantees of job security when they negotiate with employers over the terms of employment. Many studies by labour economists have explored the incentive effects of unemployment benefits, usually finding their adverse effect on employment. For example, a 2013 research paper by Marcus Hagedorn and co-authors examined US labour market data in the aftermath of the Global Financial Crisis. It found that extending the duration of unemployment benefits (from 26 to 99 weeks in some states) led to a marked reduction in employment, with the long-term effect being stronger than the short-term effect. Many studies confirm that the design of the unemployment benefits system influences the effort that some of the unemployed devote to job search. Professor Jeff Borland provided another piece of evidence. According to the 1997 time use data, only 15 to 20 per cent of the unemployed people in Australia reported job search activity on any given day. The average time spent searching among those people was 80–100 minutes per day. The average time spent job searching across all unemployed people was only 16 minutes per day (less than two hours per week). Despite all these findings, we cannot automatically conclude that providing unemployment benefits is a bad policy overall. The program does achieve its primary goal of reducing the income uncertainty and threat of poverty that workers face. In addition, when workers turn down unattractive job offers, they have the opportunity to look for jobs that better suit their tastes and skills. Some economists have argued that unemployment benefits improve the ability of the economy to match each worker with the most appropriate job. unemployment benefits a government program that partially protects workers’ incomes against job loss 213 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or inChapter part. WCN 02-200-202 9 The natural rate of unemployment 09_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 213 24/08/20 4:33 PM Therefore, while most economists agree that eliminating unemployment benefits would reduce the amount of unemployment, there is disagreement on whether economic wellbeing would be enhanced or diminished by this policy change. LO9.4 Structural unemployment The third and final component of the natural rate is structural unemployment. It arises if the skills demanded in the labour market by employers are not matched by the skills that workers possess. For example, the late 1990s saw a boom in the ICT industry (the dotcom bubble), with a sudden decline in the early 2000s. Soon after, most countries experienced a surge in the construction sector (the housing bubble) which culminated in the Global Financial Crisis. It is not surprising that some of the computer specialists and programmers that became redundant in the early 2000s struggled to re-train and become builders to shift to the newly booming industry. Such cases, which are larger sectoral shifts, are captured as part of structural unemployment. Like frictional unemployment, some structural unemployment is inevitable simply because the economy is always changing. A century ago, the sectors with the largest employment in Australia were primary industries like agriculture and mining. Today, the largest employers are in services including retail trade and health care. As this transition took place, jobs were created in some firms and destroyed in others, the above-mentioned process of ‘creative destruction’. The end result of this process has been greater productivity and higher living standards. But, along the way, workers in declining industries found themselves out of work, some unable to find a new job for a long time due to a skill mismatch. IN THE NEWS The Terminator’s move from the big screen to the labour market near you Many people worry that technological progress characterised by automation of the production process and the use of robots will lead to growing unemployment. Laurence Kotlikoff from Boston University and Jan Libich from La Trobe University explored the relevance of these concerns in their November 2016 article in the Sydney Morning Herald. Will robots eat our lunch or serve us our dinner? 18 November 2016 The outcome of the U.S. presidential election is widely seen as a protest vote; people showing discontent with their economic situation. Central to this are subpar labour market outcomes of most Americans and growing income inequality over the past three decades. Let us therefore explore what the future holds, and why it is important what kind of employment policies global leaders pursue. Economic research shows that the main challenges to American (low-skilled) workers may not be coming from Mexico or China, but from continued technological progress leading to increased automation and use of robots. Many associated questions have been carefully examined, for example: Does technological progress lead to growing unemployment? Are ever improving robots and machines pushing people out of jobs? Should we fight back by destroying them the way the Luddite movement did in England two centuries ago? The idea that ongoing automation wipes out jobs is most commonly associated with Karl Marx, who in his 1867 book Das Kapital discussed the struggle between workers and machines and the resulting reserve army of labour. Rather than considering whether Marx actually claimed that industrialisation would lead to ever-rising unemployment, let us consider this popular hypothesis at face value. 214 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 4 The real economyCopyright in the long run 09_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 214 24/08/20 4:33 PM Looking back, data strongly reject this hypothesis. Following Ludd and Marx, industrialisation and automation continued at a very high pace, and technological advances led to the substitution of workers by machines in most areas. But unemployment generally remained at very low levels. For example, a century after Das Kapital was published the unemployment rate in advanced countries was around one or two per cent despite real GDP increasing by more than 500% – largely due to technological progress. And countries with the fastest rate of industrialisation generally saw lower, not higher unemployment levels. Economists have carefully examined why the hypothesis failed to eventuate in the past. In short, the economy is a dynamically evolving process of ‘creative destruction’ where new jobs constantly arise and replace old jobs. People whose jobs get taken over by machines simply do different jobs, often in newly emerging industries. In line with this explanation we have seen major shifts away from agriculture to manufacturing and later into services, and importantly into research and development. In essence, the more machines and robots help us with existing jobs, the more time we have to invent new ones. Does this mean that all is well and human labour is safe from automation and robotisation going forward? Not necessarily. There are three important qualifications to the above discussion. First, major sectoral shifts require workers’ re-training and thus may be associated with structural unemployment, a mismatch between the skills available and required in the labour market. Its extent depends on the quality and flexibility of the education system, i.e. whether it produces people capable of adapting to technological change. If education doesn’t keep up with technology, the share of workers who can’t find work could grow. Second, even if automation does not lead to higher unemployment, it may still change the nature of the jobs left to humans and their compensation. Recent research shows that this may partly explain the rise in inequality in most high-income countries (especially the United States) over the past three decades. If humans go from having high- to low-paying jobs, an ironic possibility arises. They may become too poor to purchase the products produced by robots. As Benzell, Kotlikoff, LaGarda and Sachs show in their recent paper, this can under some circumstances produce what Marx predicted, a situation in which capitalism sows the seeds of its own destruction or, at least, a long-run decline in output and economic wellbeing. The dynamic involves young, poorly paid workers unable to save as much as their parents’ generation. This spells lower national investment. Over time, the economy ends up with better technology (smarter robots), but less physical capital available to help produce output. Whether this grim view prevails remains to be seen unless governments ensure that the advent of smart machines benefits all generations, not just those who are old enough to temporarily control the means of production. Third, it is conceivable that the future of robotics will represent a fundamentally different era of technological progress. For example, consider the scenario of some science-fiction movies such as the Terminator franchise. Artificial intelligence progresses greatly and robots do not just assemble themselves but are capable of selfimprovement, of inventing a technologically more advanced type. In such a futuristic scenario it may indeed be the case that human labour input becomes largely redundant in production. But if the crystal ball of the Terminator creators is more accurate than that of the Luddites movement, lack of jobs would be the least of people’s worry. In such case humans would be ‘occupied’ with trying to control such hyper-intelligent robots and ward off their dominance over humankind. As we know from the big screen, Arnold Schwarzenegger needs help to avert the Judgement day. Source: Laurence Kotlikoff and Jan Libich, Canberra Times, http://www.canberratimes.com.au/comment/willrobots-eat-our-lunch-or-serve-us-our-dinner-20161117-gsrdn7.html 215 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or inChapter part. WCN 02-200-202 9 The natural rate of unemployment 09_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 215 24/08/20 4:33 PM You should now be able to contrast structural unemployment with the two other types of unemployment we discussed. In the case of classical unemployment arising from minimum-wage laws, unions and efficiency wages, the real wage is above the equilibrium level, so the quantity of labour supplied exceeds the quantity of labour demanded. Workers are unemployed because they are essentially waiting for jobs to open up. In the case of frictional and structural unemployment, real wages are not excessive – workers are simply searching for jobs. The difference is that frictional unemployment is temporary; there is a suitable job for each worker and it is just a matter of time for their search to be successful. However, structural unemployment is a more serious and longer lasting condition. While there are jobs available in the economy, some workers will remain unemployed as there are no suitable jobs for them in their geographical area. Sometimes a distinction is made between two interconnected drivers of structural unemployment – occupational immobility (skill mismatch) and geographical immobility (location mismatch). Spain offers an example of the latter. The natural rate of unemployment for the country as a whole approached 25 per cent in the aftermath of the Global Financial Crisis, but the south of the country generally featured rates above 35 per cent whereas the north only half that. One similarity of structural and frictional unemployment is that various government programs attempt to reduce both of them, and help people get suitable jobs. Most countries offer public training programs, which aim to ease the transition of workers from declining to growing industries and to help disadvantaged groups escape poverty. Again, there exist critics. They argue that most worker education is done privately, either through schools or through on-the-job training, and that the government is no better – and most likely worse – at deciding what kinds of worker training would be most valuable. They claim that these decisions are best made privately by workers and employers. What is your view on that? CASE STUDY The differences in unemployment within Australia and across countries Popular discussions of unemployment rarely consider the composition of the unemployed. Even though unemployment in certain groups is sometimes targeted (for instance, youth or ethnic minority), there is still a tendency to view unemployment in the aggregate around the country. But the data show that this is a mistake. Table 9.2 reports the unemployment rate for Australian states and territories. It shows large differences across the states. While the ACT, New South Wales and the Northern Territory feature a low rate of unemployment, South Australia’s and Tasmania’s rates are much higher. Looking more deeply within states reveals even larger differences, with the official unemployment rate being higher in regional Australia than in the cities. To give one example, in outback Queensland it was around 13 per cent in 2019, over double the national average. Unemployment rates across countries show an even greater variation, which may not surprise you given the large differences in economic growth we saw in an earlier chapter. In 2019, unemployment rates below 3 per cent could be found in, for example, Switzerland, Japan, Singapore and the Czech Republic. Still fairly low rates of around 5 per cent were reported from the United States, Russia, New Zealand and the Philippines. At the other end of the spectrum, South Africa, Namibia and Palestine had unemployment rates between 25 and 45 per cent. Similar differences can be observed in youth unemployment. For example, based on OECD data, Greece and Spain had over 30 per cent youth unemployment and South Africa over 60 per cent in 2019. In contrast, Japan, Kazakhstan and Switzerland had less than 10 per cent. Source: US Bureau of Labour Statistics, Eurostat, OECD 216 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 4 The real economyCopyright in the long run 09_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 216 24/08/20 4:33 PM Labour force region Unemployment rate (%) Australian Capital Territory 4.1 Northern Territory 4.4 New South Wales 4.3 Western Australia 6.1 Australia-wide average 5.0 Victoria 4.6 Queensland 5.9 Tasmania 6.5 South Australia 5.9 Source: ABS DATA, Cat 6202.0, Table 12, March 2019 TABLE 9.2 Differences in unemployment between Australian states and territories Questions 1 What do you think explains the differences in Australian state and territory unemployment? 2 If global demand for coal falls, will that have an impact on the employment level in Western Australia, which heavily relies on its coal export industry? CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING How would a tax on carbon emissions impact the amount of search unemployment? Is this unemployment necessarily undesirable? What public policies might affect the amount of unemployment caused by this price change? Conclusion In this chapter, we discussed the measurement of unemployment and the reasons why economies always have people without jobs. You could see the many driving forces behind classical, frictional and structural types of unemployment. Which of these explanations for the natural rate of unemployment are the most important? Unfortunately, there is no easy way to tell, and the answer differs across countries and time. Unemployment is not a simple problem with a simple solution. Instead, it has various explanations and is affected by a number of public policies. When policymakers debate the minimum wage, the laws regulating collective bargaining, unemployment benefits, or job matching and re-training programs, they should always carefully consider the impact of these policies on the economy’s natural rate of unemployment. 217 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or inChapter part. WCN 02-200-202 9 The natural rate of unemployment 09_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 217 24/08/20 4:33 PM STUDY TOOLS Summary LO9.1 The unemployed are those who would like to work but do not have jobs. The ABS calculates the unemployment rate statistics monthly, based on a survey of thousands of households. LO9.2 One explanation for the existence of ‘classical’ unemployment is a real wage kept at a level that is too high. This can be due to minimum-wage laws, which raise the wage of unskilled and inexperienced workers and thus lead to excess supply of labour over demand. LO9.3 Frictional unemployment does not require wages to be too high. It relates to the process of workers’ searching for jobs where there is no skill mismatch, and it is just a matter of time for each worker to find a job that best suits their skills and tastes. LO9.4 Structural unemployment also does not require wages to be too high and relates to the process of workers searching for jobs. However, an occupational or geographical mismatch exists, and therefore some workers are unable to find jobs despite vacancies being available. Key concepts collective bargaining, p. 206 cyclical unemployment, p. 196 discouraged workers, p. 202 efficiency wage, p. 208 job search, p. 212 labour force, p. 197 labour-force participation rate, p. 197 natural rate of unemployment, p. 196 strike, p. 207 unemployment benefits, p. 213 unemployment rate, p. 197 union, p. 206 Practice questions Questions for review 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Explain the three categories into which the ABS divides the population. How does it calculate the labour force, the unemployment rate and the labour-force participation rate? What factors determine whether unemployment is short term or long term? Explain. Are minimum-wage laws a better explanation for unemployment among teenagers or among university graduates? Why? Why should economists and policymakers be careful when interpreting data on unemployment? Why does the level of unemployment vary widely from region to region within Australia and across countries? If you were advising the government, what would you suggest to reduce the regional differences in unemployment? Explain four ways in which a firm might increase its profits by raising the wages it pays. What are the main differences between frictional and structural unemployment? Are there ways in which the government can reduce search unemployment? Multiple choice 1 Consider a country with a population of 110 people: 40 work full-time, 20 work part-time but would prefer to work full-time, 10 are looking for a job, 10 would like to work but are so discouraged they have given up looking, 10 are not interested in working because they are full-time students, 10 are children below 15 years of age, and 10 are retired. What is the official number of the unemployed? a 10 b 20 c 30 d 40 218 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 4 The real economyCopyright in the long run 09_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 218 24/08/20 4:33 PM 2 3 4 5 6 Using the labour market data in question 1, what is the size of the country’s labour force? a 50 b 60 c 70 d 80 Using the labour market data in question 1, what is the rate of unemployment? a 10 b 20 c 30 d 40 Using the labour market data in question 1, what is the labour-force participation rate? a 50 b 60 c 70 d 80 The main policy goal of unemployment benefits is to reduce the a search effort of the unemployed. b income uncertainty that workers face. c role of unions in wage setting. d amount of frictional unemployment. Which of the following is more likely to raise the unemployment rate? a Establishing more effective trade unions in an economy b Introducing a minimum wage in the economy c Firms are willing to pay efficiency wages in an economy d All of the above Problems and applications 1 2 The ABS reported in December 2019 that of all adult Australians 12 976 300 were employed, 703 600 were unemployed, and the participation rate was 66.0 per cent. The civilian population over 15 years of age was 20 701 918. How many people were not in the labour force? How big was the labour force? What was the unemployment rate? The following table shows the underemployment rate for men, women and all people aged 25–34 over the 1978 to 2015 period. Why is this information useful for policymakers? Men 25–34 3 4 Women 25–34 All people 25–34 1978 1.3% 5.4% 2.7% 2015 9.3% 13.2% 11.1% Draw a diagram of the labour market with the wage being at the equilibrium level. a Draw a minimum wage that is above the equilibrium level. Show the effect of its introduction on the number of workers supplied and demanded as well as the amount of unemployment. Discuss the intuition behind the effect. b Draw a minimum wage that is below the equilibrium level and answer the questions in part a. During the mining boom, it was suggested that Australia had a two-speed economy – that is, some sectors that were doing really well and some sectors that weren’t. a If we had perfectly flexible labour markets, what would you expect to happen to wages in the two sectors? Explain. b What government policies would you recommend to overcome the two-speed economy? 219 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or inChapter part. WCN 02-200-202 9 The natural rate of unemployment 09_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 219 24/08/20 4:33 PM 5 6 7 8 9 The following situations involve moral hazard. In each case, identify the principal and the agent, and explain why there is asymmetric information. How does the action described reduce the problem of moral hazard? a Landlords require tenants to pay security deposits. b Firms compensate top executives with options to buy company shares at a given price in the future. c Car insurance companies offer discounts to older drivers or those who have had fewer accidents. Suppose that the Live-Long-and-Prosper Health Fund charges $8000 annually for family health cover. The fund’s managing director suggests that the firm raise the annual price to $10 000 in order to increase its profits. If the firm followed this suggestion, what economic problem might arise? Would the firm’s pool of customers tend to become more or less healthy on average? Would the firm’s profits necessarily increase? Explain. How will the following affect the supply of labour? Illustrate your answer with a diagram. a The retirement age has increased from 67 to 68 years. b Australia experiences a productivity increase causing real wages to rise. c Social security benefits are decreased. d Australians decide to have more children (you need to consider both short-run and long-run effects). (This problem is challenging, in your answers try to be quantitative when you can, but even an intuitive discussion is fine.) Suppose that the federal government passes a law requiring employers to provide employees some benefit (like private health care) that raises the cost of an employee by $6 per hour. a What effect does this legal requirement have on the demand for labour? b If employees place a value on this benefit exactly equal to its cost, what effect does this legal requirement have on the supply of labour? c If the wage is free to balance supply and demand, how does this legal requirement affect the wage and the level of employment? Are employers better or worse off? Are employees better or worse off? d If a minimum-wage law prevents the wage from balancing supply and demand, how does the legal requirement affect the wage and the level of unemployment? Are employers better or worse off? Are employees better or worse off? e Now suppose that workers do not value the benefit at all. How does this alternative assumption change your answers to parts (b), (c) and (d)? For each of the following scenarios, identify whether the unemployment is frictional or structural. a Alex lost his job when the car manufacturing company closed down. He does not have the skills to work in another industry and thus has been unemployed for more than a year. b Lauren had a job as a primary school teacher but quit when her husband was transferred to another state. She was only unemployed for a month before she found a new job that she liked. c Ethan completed his bachelor’s degree and has been looking for work over the last five weeks. He turned down a few offers because they did not allow him to apply the skills he gained at university, but now he has a job in his field of study. 220 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 4 The real economyCopyright in the long run 09_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 220 24/08/20 4:33 PM 221 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 9 Application: International trade 09_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 221 24/08/20 4:33 PM PART FIVE Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 10_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 222 24/08/20 4:34 PM Money and prices in the long run Chapter 10 The monetary system Chapter 11 Inflation: Its causes and costs Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 10_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 223 24/08/20 4:34 PM 10 The monetary system Learning objectives After reading this chapter, you should be able to: LO10.1 explain what money is and what functions money has in the economy LO10.2 discuss the Reserve Bank of Australia and the tools it uses to influence liquidity conditions in the economy LO10.3 examine how the banking system influences the amount of money in the economy. 224 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 10_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 224 24/08/20 4:34 PM Introduction When you walk into a restaurant to buy a meal, you get something of value – your hunger satisfied. To pay for this service, you might hand the restaurateur several worn-out pieces of coloured plastic decorated with strange symbols, government buildings and the portraits of famous dead Australians. Or you might tap your watch or phone to electronically access your cheque or savings account. Whether you pay by cash or through a mobile payment app, the restaurateur is happy to work hard to satisfy your gastronomical desires in exchange for these internet transfers, which, in and of themselves, are worthless. To anyone who has lived in a modern economy, this social custom is not at all odd. Even though plastic money has no intrinsic value, the restaurateur is confident that, in the future, some third person will accept it in exchange for something that the restaurateur does value. And that third person is confident that some fourth person will accept the money, with the knowledge that yet a fifth person will accept the money … and so on. To the restaurateur and to other people in our society, your cash represents a claim to goods and services in the future. The social custom of using money for transactions is extraordinarily useful in a large, complex society. Imagine, for a moment, that there was no item in the economy widely accepted in exchange for goods and services. People would have to rely on barter – the exchange of one good or service for another – to obtain the things they need. To get your restaurant meal, for instance, you would have to offer the restaurateur something of immediate value. You could offer to wash some dishes, clean the floor, or help with the restaurant’s accounts. An economy that relies on barter will have trouble allocating its scarce resources efficiently. In such an economy, trade is said to require the double coincidence of wants – the unlikely occurrence that two people each have a good or service that the other wants at the same time. The existence of money makes trade easier. Our restaurateur, George, does not care whether you can produce a valuable good or service for him. He is happy to accept your money, knowing that other people will do the same for him. Such a convention allows trade to be roundabout – a coincidence of desires to trade is not required. George accepts your money and uses it to pay Eleni, his chef; Eleni uses her pay cheque to send her child to day care; the day care centre uses these fees to pay Vinh, a teacher; and Vinh hires you to mow his lawn. As money flows from person to person in the economy, it facilitates production and trade, thereby allowing people to specialise in what they do best and raising everyone’s standard of living. In this chapter, we begin to examine the role of money in the economy. We discuss what money is, the various forms that money takes, how the banking system helps create money and how the government influences the quantity of money in circulation. Because money is so important in the economy, we devote much effort in the rest of this book to learning how money is linked to various economic variables, including inflation, interest rates, production and employment. Consistent with our long-run focus in the last three chapters, we will examine the long-run effects of changes in monetary policy in the next chapter. The short-run effects of monetary changes are a more complex topic, which we take up later in the book. This chapter provides the background for all of this further analysis. LO10.1 The meaning of money What is money? This might seem like an odd question. When you read that billionaire Gina Rinehart has a lot of money, you know what that means – she is so rich that she can buy almost anything she wants. In this sense, the term money is used to mean wealth. Economists, however, use the word in a more specific sense. Money is the set of assets in the economy that people regularly use to buy goods and services from other people. The cash in your wallet is money because you can use it to buy a meal at a restaurant or a money the set of assets in an economy that people regularly use to buy goods and services from other people 225 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN Chapter 02-200-202 10 The monetary system 10_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 225 24/08/20 4:34 PM shirt at a clothing shop. In contrast, if you happened to be a major shareholder in Hancock Prospecting, as Gina Rinehart is, you would be wealthy, but this asset is not considered a form of money. You could not buy a meal or a shirt with this wealth without first obtaining some money. According to the economist’s definition, money includes only those few types of wealth that are regularly accepted by sellers in exchange for goods and services. The functions of money medium of exchange an item that buyers give to sellers when they want to purchase goods and services unit of account the yardstick people use to post prices and record debts store of value an item that people can use to transfer purchasing power from the present to the future liquidity the ease with which an asset can be converted into the economy’s medium of exchange Money has three functions in the economy – it is a medium of exchange, a unit of account and a store of value. These three functions together distinguish money from other assets. A medium of exchange is an item that buyers give to sellers when they purchase goods and services. When you buy a shirt at a clothing shop, the shop gives you the shirt and you give the shop your money. This transfer of money from buyer to seller allows the transaction to take place. When you walk into a shop, you are confident that the shop will accept your money for the items it is selling because money is the commonly accepted medium of exchange. A unit of account is the yardstick people use to post prices and record debts. When you go shopping, you might observe that a shirt costs $40 and a meat pie costs $4. Even though it would be accurate to say that the price of a shirt is 10 meat pies and the price of a meat pie is 1/10 of a shirt, prices are never quoted in this way. Similarly, if you take out a loan from a bank, the size of your future loan repayments will be measured in dollars, not in a quantity of goods and services. When we want to measure and record economic value, we use money as the unit of account. A store of value is an item that people can use to transfer purchasing power from the present to the future. When a seller accepts money today in exchange for a good or service, that seller can hold the money and become a buyer of another good or service at another time. Of course, money is not the only store of value in the economy. A person can also transfer purchasing power from the present to the future by holding shares, bonds, real estate, art, or even old stamps. The term wealth is used to refer to the total of all stores of value, including both money and non-monetary assets. Economists use the term liquidity to describe the ease with which an asset can be converted into the economy’s medium of exchange. Because money is the economy’s medium of exchange, it is the most liquid asset available. Other assets vary widely in their liquidity. Most shares and bonds can be sold easily at little or no cost, so they are relatively liquid assets. In contrast, selling a house, a Rembrandt painting or a 1948 Don Bradman cricket bat requires more time and effort, so these assets are less liquid. When people decide in what form to hold their wealth, they have to balance the liquidity of each possible asset against the asset’s usefulness as a store of value. Money is the most liquid asset, but it is far from perfect as a store of value. When prices rise, the value of money falls. In other words, when goods and services become more expensive, each dollar in your wallet can buy less. This link between the price level and the value of money will turn out to be important for understanding how money affects the economy. Kinds of money commodity money money that takes the form of a commodity with intrinsic value When money takes the form of a commodity with intrinsic value, it is called commodity money. The term intrinsic value means that the item would have value even if it were not used as money. One example of commodity money is gold. Gold has intrinsic value because it is used in industry and in the making of jewellery. Although today we no longer use gold as money, historically gold has been a common form of money because it is relatively easy to carry, measure and verify for impurities. And in times of great uncertainty, like in the Global 226 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 5 Money and pricesCopyright in the long run 10_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 226 24/08/20 4:34 PM fiat money money without intrinsic value that is used as money because of government decree Source: Cartoon by Steve Nease/neasecartoons.com Financial Crisis of 2008, people hold gold because it is seen as a safer asset. When an economy uses gold as money (or uses plastic or paper money that is convertible into gold on demand), it is said to be operating under a gold standard. Another example of commodity money is cigarettes. In prisoner-of-war camps during the Second World War, prisoners traded goods and services with one another using cigarettes as the store of value, unit of account and medium of exchange. Similarly, as the Soviet Union was breaking up in the late 1980s, cigarettes started replacing the rouble as the preferred currency in Moscow. In both cases, even non-smokers were happy to accept cigarettes in an exchange, knowing that they could use the cigarettes to buy other goods and services. In the early days of the Australian colonies, rum was used as commodity money. Workers were paid in gallons of rum and they then used this as a medium of exchange. It didn’t serve as much of a store of value, though – you could say it was a very liquid asset! Money without intrinsic value is called fiat money. A fiat is simply an order or decree, and fiat money is established as money by government decree. For example, compare the plastic dollars in your wallet (printed by the Reserve Bank of Australia) and the paper dollars from a game of Monopoly® (printed by the Parker Brothers game company). Why can you use the first to pay your bill at a restaurant but not the second? The answer is that the Australian government has decreed its dollars to be valid money. Each note in your wallet reads ‘This Australian note is legal tender throughout Australia and its territories’. Although the government is central to establishing and regulating a system of fiat money (like by prosecuting counterfeiters), other factors are also required for the success of such a monetary system. To a large extent, the acceptance of fiat money depends as much on expectations and social convention as on government decree. The Soviet government in the 1980s never abandoned the rouble as the official currency yet the people of Moscow preferred to accept cigarettes (or even American dollars) in exchange for goods and services, because they were more confident that these alternative monies would be accepted by others in the future. The same thing happened in Indonesia in the 1990s, where the value of the rupiah dropped dramatically in a short period of time. Some places in Indonesia would accept only American dollars in payment for goods or services. 227 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN Chapter 02-200-202 10 The monetary system 10_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 227 24/08/20 4:34 PM Money in the Australian economy money supply the quantity of money available in the economy currency the plastic notes and metal coins in the hands of the public current deposits balances in bank accounts that depositors can access on demand by using a debit card or writing a cheque IN THE NEWS As we will see, the quantity of money circulating in the economy, called the money supply, has a powerful influence on important economic variables. We will find out in the next chapter how closely money supply and the level of inflation are linked. But before we consider why that is true, we need to ask a preliminary question. What is the quantity of money? In particular, suppose you were given the task of measuring how much money there is in the Australian economy. What would you include in your measure? The most obvious asset to include is currency – the plastic notes and metal coins in the hands of the public. Currency is clearly the most widely accepted medium of exchange in our economy. There is no doubt that it is part of the money supply. Yet currency is not the only asset that you can use to buy goods and services. Most shops today also accept debit cards, or offer EFTPOS facilities. (EFTPOS stands for ‘electronic funds transfer at point of sale’.) There is a distinction between the plastic card itself and the funds in savings or cheque accounts that the card allows consumers to access. (See the FYI box ‘Credit cards, debit cards, smart cards and money’.) Some shops also accept personal cheques. Wealth held in your savings or cheque account is almost as convenient for buying things as wealth held in your wallet. To measure the money supply, therefore, you might want to include current deposits – balances in bank accounts that depositors can access on demand simply by using a debit card or writing a cheque. Ever heard the expression ‘cold, hard cash’? In times gone by, some people would only accept gold coins in exchange for their goods. They didn’t trust any other sort of payment. Now we have online exchanges that accept virtual money – bitcoin. And it’s making some governments nervous. They worry that bitcoin use will mean they won’t be able to control their monetary policy. As the following articles argue, it may be too late to stop the tide of virtual money. Banning Bitcoin is stupid. Non-state digital currencies will soon sweep away our monopoly money The winner of this week’s King Canute prize for attempting to hold back the tide goes to the government of Thailand. Why? They have just decided to ban Bitcoin, the new digital currency. Bitcoin – which exists only as a string of computer source code, and in so far as people are willing to exchange ownership of it for other things – cannot lawfully be used to buy and sell in Thailand. Monetary authorities in Bangkok fear that this upstart currency cannot be subject to capital controls. And they are right. It can’t. But banning Bitcoin won’t end a very 21stcentury conundrum for governments everywhere. A digital tide is coming in, and it will sweep away the post-Bretton Woods system of monopoly money. No government, in Thailand, or elsewhere, will ultimately be able to stop it. Personally, I am a bit of a Bitcoin sceptic. I suspect it might be to the future of private currencies what the ZX Spectrum was to the future of personal computing. Much hyped, we can all sense it might just be the start of something big. Yet for all that, no one seems entirely sure what to do with it. To catch a glimpse of our monetary future, perhaps we should look not to Bitcoin, but to Africa. No, not the half-baked idea of an East African monetary union, but to the success of something called Mpesa. Ostensibly a way of paying for things using mobile phone credits, Mpesa allows tens of millions of Africans to do so without a costly banking system attached. Payment without banking! 228 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 5 Money and pricesCopyright in the long run 10_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 228 24/08/20 4:34 PM Yep. But that’s only the start. Imagine if a mobile phone company were to decouple the value of its credits from the local official currency. With monopoly money inflation in double digits, it would only be a matter of time before folk used a virtual payment system to store wealth, not just buy stuff. Money without a government! Try to imagine what might happen here in the West if we were to have 1970s levels of inflation, combined with 2019 rates of internet usage? We might not have to wait too long to find out. A generation ago, the last time our monopoly money currency was seriously debauched, there were – as the Thai authorities would appreciate – capital controls. Only very rich people could safeguard their wealth by buying old masters paintings, or other such assets. Thanks to the internet, today ordinary folk can not just shop around. They can do so in all sorts of currencies. Whatever the law says in Thailand or elsewhere – unless the authorities plan on monitoring every online transaction – we’ll be able to store wealth online in all kinds of ways. Currency competition and non-state-issued money is only a matter of time. Far from being a product of deliberate design, I suspect the successful non-state currencies of the future might be almost accidental; an online supermarket voucher scheme, perhaps, which retains its worth better than the Bank of England alternative? The whole point about King Canute trying to hold back the tide is that he knew at the outset that he couldn’t. He was, so the story goes, trying to demonstrate to his underlings the limits of a ruler’s power. A thousand years on, it seems many have still not learned the lesson. Source: © Telegraph Media Group Limited, 13 July 2013 How safe is Bitcoin? In a lot of ways, bitcoin is safer than ‘real’ money. It is based on blockchain technology, which ‘In essence … is a shared, trusted, public ledger that everyone can inspect, but which no single user controls. The participants in a blockchain system collectively keep the ledger up to date: it can be amended only according to strict rules and by general agreement. Bitcoin’s blockchain ledger prevents double-spending and keeps track of transactions continuously. It is what makes possible a currency without a central bank.’ According to The Economist, the technology underlying bitcoin is even more interesting than the currency. It could replace institutions that trade in trust – banks, clearing houses and other government agencies that facilitate our transactions – because it is based on a secure (and therefore trustworthy) technology. Like a lot of things in the digital economy, no one is quite sure where it could take us, but it will most certainly transform how we conduct our transactions. Based on: The trust machine, The Economist, 31 October 2015, http://www.economist.com/ news/ leaders/21677198-technology-behind-bitcoin-could-transform-how-economy-works-trust-machine Once you start to consider balances in savings or cheque accounts as part of the money supply, you are led to consider the large variety of other accounts that people hold at banks and other financial institutions. Bank depositors usually cannot write cheques against the balances in their savings accounts, but they can easily transfer funds from other accounts into cheque accounts or use debit cards to access their funds. Thus, these accounts should plausibly be part of the Australian money supply. In a complex economy like ours, it is not easy to draw a line between assets that can be called ‘money’ and assets that cannot. The coins in your pocket are clearly part of the money supply and the Sydney Opera House clearly is not, but there are many assets in between these extremes for which the choice is less clear. Therefore, various measures of the money supply are available for the Australian economy. Table 10.1 shows the three most important monetary aggregates – currency, M3 and broad money. Each of these measures uses a slightly different criterion for distinguishing monetary from non-monetary assets. 229 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN Chapter 02-200-202 10 The monetary system 10_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 229 24/08/20 4:34 PM Measure Currency M3 Amount in 2019 ($ million) 76 200 2 149 500 What’s included Notes and coins Current deposits with banks Travellers cheques Savings deposits Certificates of deposit Broad money 2 163 000 Everything in M3 Deposits in non-bank financial institutions and bank deposits by non-bank financial institutions Source: Reserve Bank of Australia Bulletin TABLE 10.1 Three measures of the money supply for the Australian economy Source: Rod Clement, The Economic Rationalist’s Guide to Sex, Harper Collins, Australia 1997. Reproduced with permission of Harper Collins Publishers For our purposes in this book, we need not dwell on the differences between the various measures of money. The important point is that the money supply for the Australian economy includes not just currency but also deposits in banks and other financial institutions that can be readily accessed and used to buy goods and services. CASE STUDY Whose currency is the fairest in the land? For over 50 years, the US dollar has been the currency that everyone wants. People around the world have been willing to accept US dollars in payment for goods and services in preference to their own currencies. In fact, in 1960, it was estimated that half of all US currency in circulation was held outside the US. Today, it is estimated that up to 70 per cent of US currency is held overseas. So what function is the US dollar serving? Why would foreigners want to hold so much US currency? And will the US dollar continue to be so desirable? This question has been asked a lot more since the Global Financial Crisis showed the US economy to be more vulnerable than most people thought. The US dollar has been used outside the US for several purposes – as a reserve currency (held by foreign governments as a store of value), as a medium of exchange in countries that don’t have a stable monetary system, and as a store of value for tax evaders, drug dealers and other criminals. For most people in the US economy, currency is not a particularly good way to hold wealth. Currency can be lost or stolen. Moreover, currency does not earn interest, whereas money in a bank account does. Thus, most people in the US hold only small amounts of currency. In contrast, criminals may prefer not to hold their wealth in banks. A bank deposit would 230 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 5 Money and pricesCopyright in the long run 10_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 230 24/08/20 4:34 PM give police a paper trail with which to trace their illegal activities. For criminals, currency may be the best store of value available. But why would other governments hold US dollars? It’s not because someone decreed that they should. It’s because the US economy is the largest in the world (at least for the time being), it is important in world trade, it has open financial markets, its currency is easily convertible and several countries peg their currency to the US dollar. All of these things make it a good store of value for other governments. In the 1980s, the Japanese yen was a threat to the dominance of the US dollar, as was the euro throughout most of the 2000s. However, most economists don’t see a decline in the significance of the US dollar in the global market any time soon. Even though China is closing in on the US position as the dominant economy in the world, the Chinese government still fixes the rate at which its currency, the yuan or renminbi, is traded, so it is not likely to replace the US dollar as the preferred reserve currency. Questions 1 Why is the US dollar used outside of the United States? 2 What factors make the US dollar a store of value? CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING List the three functions of money. Why are they important?. LO10.2 The Reserve Bank of Australia Whenever an economy relies on a system of fiat money, as the Australian economy does, some agency must be responsible for regulating the system. In Australia, that agency is the Reserve Bank of Australia (RBA). If you look at an Australian note, you will see that it is signed by the Secretary to the Treasury and the Governor of the Reserve Bank of Australia. The RBA is an example of a central bank – an institution designed to oversee the banking system and financial conditions of the economy. Other major central banks around the world include the Federal Reserve System of the United States, the Bank of England, the Bank of Japan and the European Central Bank. Reserve Bank of Australia (RBA) the central bank of Australia central bank an institution designed to oversee the banking system and regulate the quantity of money in the economy FYI Shutterstock.com/Marie C Fields Credit cards, debit cards, smart cards and money Is this money? It might seem natural to include credit cards as part of the economy’s supply of money. After all, people use credit cards to make many of their purchases. Aren’t credit cards, therefore, a medium of exchange? Although at first this argument may seem persuasive, credit cards are excluded from all measures of the quantity of money. The reason is that credit cards are not really a method 231 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN Chapter 02-200-202 10 The monetary system 10_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 231 24/08/20 4:34 PM of payment but a method of deferring payment, like taking out a short-term loan. When you buy a meal with a credit card, the bank that issued the card pays the restaurant what is due. At a later date, you will have to repay the bank (perhaps with interest). When the time comes to pay your credit card bill, you will probably do so by transferring funds from your savings or cheque account electronically or through phone banking. The balance in your savings or cheque account is part of the economy’s supply of money. Notice that credit cards are very different from debit cards, which automatically withdraw funds from a bank account to pay for items bought. Rather than allowing the user to postpone payment for a purchase, a debit card allows the user immediate access to deposits in a bank account. In this sense, a debit card is more similar to a cheque than to a credit card. The account balances that lie behind debit cards are included in measures of the quantity of money. Smart cards are similar to debit cards in that they aren’t a form of loan like credit cards – they either access your cheque or savings account balances or are ‘topped up’ with transfers from your accounts or with cash. They usually have a set amount transferred to them and then can be used until these balances are drawn down. So, they aren’t ‘money’ either because you can’t use them unless you have money to transfer to them. Even though credit cards are not considered a form of money, they are nonetheless important in analysing the monetary system. People who have credit cards can pay many of their bills all at once at the end of the month, rather than sporadically as they make purchases. As a result, people who have credit cards probably carry less money on average than people who do not have credit cards. Thus, the introduction and increased popularity of credit cards may reduce the amount of money that people choose to carry. Organisation of the RBA 232 The origins of the RBA are in the Commonwealth Bank of Australia, which was established in 1911 in response to the banking crisis of the 1890s. It combined the roles of a commercial bank and a central bank. Central bank functions developed gradually until the Second World War when the powers of the central banking arm were increased to include control over exchange rates and administration of monetary and banking policy. In 1945, these powers were formalised in the Commonwealth Bank Act and the Banking Act. The RBA was created in its current form by the Reserve Bank Act of 1959, when it was separated from the Commonwealth Bank and given its own board. The Reserve Bank Board is responsible for determining the bank’s monetary and banking policy. The board consists of nine members, including the Governor and Deputy Governor and the Secretary to the Treasury. The Governor and Deputy Governor are appointed by the Governor-General on the recommendation of the government. The remaining members of the board are drawn from industry, universities and, in the past, the trade union movement. Individuals who are employed by banks are not eligible to be members of the board as this would represent a conflict of interest. The Reserve Bank Board determines monetary policy after advice from the various departments within the RBA. The Economic Group is responsible for economic analysis of international and domestic markets, forecasting and research relevant to the framing of monetary policy. The Financial Markets Group is responsible for implementation of policy decisions. The RBA operates independently of the government of the day, but in cases of irreconcilable differences over policy, legislation provides for the government to be able to overrule the RBA. However, this is clearly a measure of last resort. The procedures required to do this are politically demanding and thus reinforce the RBA’s independence. For the most part, the RBA and the government interact on a consultative basis. 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 5 Money and pricesCopyright in the long run 10_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 232 24/08/20 4:34 PM Changes in the RBA’s role The RBA has, historically, had three related jobs. The first is to monitor individual banks and ensure their stability. The RBA monitors each bank’s financial condition and makes recommendations to the bank if it is experiencing financial difficulties and is unable to meet depositors’ demands. This is known as prudential supervision. (This role has been shifted to APRA, the Australian Prudential Regulation Authority, discussed below.) A related role is acting as a guarantor of stability in the banking system. As part of this role, the RBA also facilitates bank transactions by clearing cheques. This helps ensure that the banking system has sufficient liquidity at any one time. Unlike the Federal Reserve in the United States, the RBA does not act as a lender of last resort. In the United States, when financially troubled banks find themselves short of cash, the Federal Reserve acts as a lender to those who cannot borrow anywhere else – in order to maintain stability in the overall banking system. In Australia, the RBA has not specifically acted in this capacity, although under a new agreement between the former Treasurer, Wayne Swan, and the Reserve Bank, the bank will provide liquidity to the system if not to a specific bank. It will continue to monitor liquidity in the system and assist troubled banks to find a solution to their problems. For instance, the RBA has played a role in facilitating mergers and acquisitions of troubled banks by other banks. The RBA’s third job is to determine monetary policy. Monetary policy is the management by the central bank of liquidity conditions in the economy. Liquidity conditions refers to the price and availability of funding for the economy’s expenditure. According to the RBA’s charter, the objectives of monetary policy are to ‘contribute to stability of the currency …, the maintenance of full employment, and the economic prosperity and welfare of the people of Australia’. The RBA’s main contribution to these objectives is to control inflation. It has an announced target for monetary policy of keeping inflation to around 2–3 per cent over time. The long-run objective of monetary policy is to influence the rate of growth in the economy and the level of prices. When overall economic growth is too fast and the economy is overheating, this puts upward pressure on prices. The RBA will implement a tightening of monetary policy to slow the economy. On the other hand, when the economy is experiencing slow growth, the RBA will implement expansionary monetary policy. This process is described in detail next. The functions of the RBA have changed in the last two decades. An inquiry into the financial sector, known as the Wallis Inquiry, recommended the separation of these three roles. A new regulatory body, the Australian Prudential Regulation Authority (APRA), was created in 1998. APRA performs many of the functions of prudential supervision of banks – as well as other financial institutions, like insurance companies – that the RBA had previously performed, and the RBA has been left in charge of monetary policy and operation of the payments system, or the settlement of cheques between banks. In the past, the RBA used its instruments of monetary policy to exercise prudential control over the banking system, but with changes in the implementation of monetary policy and innovations in the financial sector in the last two decades, these controls were no longer considered useful. Under the new regulatory structure, the RBA no longer has an obligation to protect the interests of bank depositors, nor does it supervise any individual financial institution. Instead, it concentrates more broadly on the overall stability of the financial system. We discuss later in this chapter how the RBA actually influences the amount of cash in the economy, but it is worth noting here that the RBA’s main policy target is the cash rate – the interest rate that financial institutions can earn on overnight loans of their currency or reserves. The process that the RBA uses to change the cash rate is explained below. The cash rate is important because it signals whether the Reserve Bank thinks the economy needs stimulating (indicated by a drop in the cash rate) or slowing down (indicated by an increase in the cash rate). monetary policy the management by the central bank of liquidity conditions in the economy liquidity conditions the price and availability of funding for the economy’s expenditure 233 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN Chapter 02-200-202 10 The monetary system 10_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 233 24/08/20 4:34 PM IN THE NEWS What does ‘money’ mean? Are we kidding ourselves? Does money really exist? We certainly spend a lot of time and effort trying to get more of it, but the next article suggests that it’s all an illusion. So if people will accept Bitcoin, or any other cryptocurrency, in payment for a good or service, then it’s money. You Don’t Understand Bitcoin Because You Think Money Is Real U.S. dollars is just an illusion more widely and fiercely believed 1 December 2017 Bitcoin is an illusion, a mass hallucination, so one hears. It’s just numbers in cyberspace, a mirage, insubstantial as a soap bubble. Bitcoin is not backed by anything other than the faith of the fools who buy it and of the greater fools who buy it from these lesser fools. And you know? Fair enough. All this is true. What may be less easy to grasp is that U.S. dollars are likewise an illusion. They too consist mainly of numbers out there in cyberspace. Sometimes they’re stored in paper or coins, but while the paper and coins are material, the dollars they represent are not. U.S. dollars are not backed by anything other than the faith of the fools who accept it as payment and of other fools who agree in turn to accept it as payment from them. The main difference is that, for the moment at least, the illusion, in the case of dollars, is more widely and more fiercely believed. In fact, almost all of our U.S. dollars, about 90 percent, are purely abstract – they literally do not exist in any tangible form. James Surowiecki reported in 2012 that ‘only about 10 percent of the U.S. money supply – about $1 trillion of the roughly $10 trillion total – exists in the form of paper cash and coins.’ (The number now appears to be about $1.5 trillion out of $13.7 trillion.) There is nothing stopping our banking system from creating more dollars whenever the mood strikes. Of the $13.7 trillion in the M2 money supply as of October 2017, $13.5 trillion was created after 1959 – or, to put it another way, M2 has expanded by almost 50 times. The U.S. dollar is what is known as a ‘fiat’ currency. Fiat is Latin for ‘let there be,’ as in fiat lux, let there be light; hence, fiat denarii, let there be lire, bolivars, dollars, and rubles. The temptation for leaders of nation-states to manufacture money has historically been practically irresistible. One evident result of this wantonness is inflation: The purchasing power of $1 in 1959 is now a little under 12 cents. The bitcoin blockchain was created, in part, to address this historical weakness. After the 21 millionth bitcoin is mined, in around 2140, the system will produce no more. Charlatans and thieves will forever try to game the various structures put in place to control and/or account for any monetary system and, indeed, any store of value (see: the crooks of the Panama and Paradise Papers, Bernies Cornfeld and Madoff, the London Whale, LTCM and BCCI, the clever and quiet thieves of treasures from the Gardner Museum in Boston, the 2008 financial crisis and associated bailouts, and the thefts at Mt. Gox, the DAO, and Tether). All stores of value are targets. And using any system of exchange – through fair means or foul – fortunes can and will be made and lost. And yet, surprising as it may sometimes seem, there are enough people acting in good faith to prevent monetary systems from collapsing entirely. There are a few radical differences between cryptocurrencies and U.S. dollars. For example, the transactions conducted in the bitcoin system are recorded in an unfalsifiable ledger that relies not on the authority of banks or governments, but on the strength of a public computer network that (theoretically, at least) anyone is free to join. Also, again, the supply of bitcoins is ultimately fixed. The anonymity of cryptocurrency is not, perhaps, quite as bulletproof as the anonymity of (unmarked) cash. 234 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 5 Money and pricesCopyright in the long run 10_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 234 24/08/20 4:34 PM Money itself is an illusion, a mass hallucination. You’re working hard to make it, grow it, and keep it, but even so, the only real thing about it is its symbolic power. Which is indeed awesome, considered from a certain angle. Our shared understanding of the value of that green-tinted piece of paper, that Krugerrand, ether token, or pound coin, is all that counts. And that shared understanding has no fixed meaning; it’s in eternal flux. The ‘value’ of all money, all stores of exchange, is unstable and abstract, even in the face of every attempt to secure it – say, with a set rate of exchange against various assets – or to regulate its flow by setting interest rates. Money is only a shifting network of agreements made in and on behalf of the hive, and that’s all it has ever been – a fragile thread in a web of human trust. Consider the ‘flight capital’ that refugees are forced to trade at a huge loss in order to cross a hostile border. That is money, but exactly what does it have in common with the invisible money that is your paycheck, a string of numbers colliding in the ether with the string of numbers that is your bank account? Maybe the price of avocados or coffee goes up or down between the time of the electronic collision in your bank and the day you go to the market. There are natural disasters in which people must suddenly become willing to pay vastly inflated sums for a few gallons of clean water. What, then, is ‘the value of a dollar’? All the common arguments against cryptocurrencies such as bitcoin, and the blockchain technology that undergirds them, invariably fail to take this fact – the provisional and fragile nature of ordinary money – into account. Cryptocurrencies cannot be understood even a little bit by anyone who thinks money is real, solid, or ‘backed by’ anything other than human trust in institutions whose stability is always uncertain. A U.S. dollar is ‘backed by’ ‘the full faith and credit of the United States.’ But what exactly does this mean? It means that if you take one dollar to the U.S. Treasury and ask them to redeem it, they will: They’ll give you … one dollar. Or four quarters, if you want, probably. The unfortunate fact is that monetary crises in unstable governments like those of Greece, Venezuela, and Spain have already precipitated a number of spikes in the crypto markets. When the Cypriot government sought to resolve the country’s 2013 banking crisis by subjecting its citizens’ bank deposits to a nearly 7 percent haircut, the price of bitcoin shot up, likely because, at that point, many southern European holders of euros with debt-ridden governments surmised that bitcoin might represent a more reliable home for their money than the Cypriot banks could provide. Spanish bank depositors must have wondered: Would their own banks be next? Our existing financial institutions are deeply flawed, in short, and permanently prone to corruption, and this was so long before bitcoin was a gleam in its mysterious inventor’s eye. Satoshi Nakamoto made a point of stating it plain as day in the so-called genesis block that started bitcoin rolling: ‘The Times 03/Jan/2009 Chancellor on brink of second bailout for banks.’ Bitcoin was a politically motivated project from the first, a new system explicitly built to provide a tamperproof digital means of exchange on which a better alternative to our existing banking systems might be based. The theory behind all cryptocurrencies, including bitcoin, is that the records produced by a distributed computer network can be made tamperproof, thus theoretically guaranteeing the soundness of a currency better than governments can. And so far, despite some substantial bumps in the road, the blockchain system on which bitcoin is built has at least partially proved this theory. A million or more bitcoins have been stolen since 2009, but the underlying system’s distributed ledger, the accounting system on which bitcoin is based, has so far remained stable and incorruptible. The many thefts and ripoffs that occurred in the early days of bitcoin call to mind the movie The Treasure of Sierra Madre, a fine drama of greed and corruption set during the 1920’s. There can be no question that the prospect of instantaneous wealth, almost close enough to touch, can drive people insane. Note, however, that the propensity of greed to produce crime and insanity did not cause the value of gold to evaporate. 235 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN Chapter 02-200-202 10 The monetary system 10_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 235 24/08/20 4:34 PM The real caveat here is that the incorruptibility of the bitcoin ledger survived, not only because of the system’s distribution, not only because of its clever cryptographic safeguards, but because of the good faith and good sense of individual developers who shepherded the project through its wobbly-legged infancy. Without the sangfroid of Gavin Andresen, who was effectively bitcoin’s sole steward during many of its early moments of crisis, the project might easily have died. Even today, the various forks and growing pains still bedeviling the bitcoin system are providing a kind of stress test. At present (this is just my opinion) the relative untrustworthiness of bitcoin’s core devs, who are thought by many to be strategizing for their own benefit, may be inflicting lasting damage not only to the cause of bitcoin, but also to the promise of blockchain technology in general. Source: Maria Bustillos/popula.com https://medium.com/s/the-crypto-collection/you-dont-understand-bitcoinbecause-you-think-money-is-real-5aef45b8e952 Read more about bitcoin at: https://www.rba.gov.au/publications/bulletin/2019/jun/ cryptocurrency-ten-years-on.html The RBA is an important institution because changes in monetary policy can profoundly affect the economy. One of the Ten Principles of Economics in chapter 1 is that prices rise when the government prints too much money. Another of the Ten Principles of Economics is that society faces a short-run trade-off between inflation and unemployment. The power of the RBA rests on these principles. For reasons we discuss more fully in the coming chapters, the RBA’s policy decisions have an important influence on the economy’s rate of inflation in the long run and the economy’s employment and production in the short run. CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING Historically, what were the RBA’s functions? Why have they changed in the last two decades? LO10.3 Banks and the money supply So far, we have introduced the concept of ‘money’ and will discuss later in the chapter how the RBA influences the liquidity or cash in the system by buying and selling government securities in open-market operations. But as we saw in Table 10.1, the amount of ‘money’ in the system is much greater than the amount of ‘cash’. How does this work? We explain this by examining the role that banks play in the monetary system through their acceptance of deposits and issuing of loans. Recall that the amount of money you hold includes both currency (the notes in your wallet and coins in your pocket) and deposits at banks (the balances in your savings and cheque accounts). Because deposits are held in banks, the behaviour of banks can influence the quantity of deposits in the economy and, therefore, the money supply. This section examines how banks affect the money supply and how they complicate the job of controlling the interest rate and thus the money supply. The simple case of 100 per cent reserve banking To see how banks influence the money supply, it is useful to imagine first a world without any banks at all. In this simple world, currency is the only form of money. To be concrete, let’s suppose that the total quantity of currency is $100. The supply of money is, therefore, $100. 236 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 5 Money and pricesCopyright in the long run 10_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 236 24/08/20 4:34 PM Now suppose that someone opens a bank, called First State Bank. First State Bank is only a depository institution. That is, the bank accepts deposits but does not make loans. The purpose of the bank is to give depositors a safe place to keep their money. Whenever people deposit some money, the bank keeps the money in its vault until the depositors come to withdraw it or write cheques against their balances. Deposits that banks have received but have not loaned out are called reserves. In this imaginary economy, all deposits are held as reserves, so this system is called 100 per cent reserve banking. We can express the financial position of First State Bank with a T-account, which is a simplified accounting statement that shows changes in a bank’s assets and liabilities. Here is the T-account for First State Bank if the economy’s entire $100 of money is deposited in the bank: reserves deposits that banks have received but have not lent out First State Bank Assets Reserves Liabilities $100.00 Deposits $100.00 On the left-hand side of the T-account are the bank’s assets of $100 (the reserves it holds in its vaults). On the right-hand side of the T-account are the bank’s liabilities of $100 (the amount it owes to its depositors). Notice that the assets and liabilities of First State Bank exactly balance. Now consider the money supply in this imaginary economy. Before First State Bank opens, the money supply is the $100 of currency that people are holding. After the bank opens and people deposit their currency, the money supply is the $100 of current deposits. (There is no longer any currency outstanding, for it is all in the bank vault.) Each deposit in the bank reduces currency and raises current deposits by exactly the same amount, leaving the money supply unchanged. Thus, if banks hold all deposits in reserve, banks do not influence the supply of money. Money creation with fractional-reserve banking Eventually, the bankers at First State Bank may start to reconsider their policy of 100 per cent reserve banking. Leaving all that money sitting idle in their vaults seems unnecessary. Why not use some of it to make loans? Families buying houses, firms building new factories and students paying for university would all be happy to pay interest to borrow some of that money for a while. Of course, First State Bank has to keep some reserves so that currency is available if depositors want to make withdrawals. But if the flow of new deposits is roughly the same as the flow of withdrawals, First State needs to keep only a fraction of its deposits in reserve. Thus, First State adopts a system called fractional-reserve banking. Let’s suppose that First State decides to keep 10 per cent of its deposits in reserve and to lend the rest. Banks may hold reserves because people may want to withdraw some cash from their accounts. We say that the reserve ratio – the fraction of total deposits that the bank holds as reserves – is 10 per cent. Now let’s look again at the bank’s T-account: First State Bank Assets Reserves Loans Liabilities $10.00 Deposits fractional-reserve banking a banking system in which banks hold only a fraction of deposits as reserves reserve ratio the fraction of deposits that banks hold as reserves $100.00 90.00 First State still has $100 in liabilities because making the loans did not alter the bank’s obligation to its depositors. But now the bank has two kinds of assets – it has $10 of reserves in its vault and it has loans of $90. (These loans are liabilities of the people taking out the 237 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN Chapter 02-200-202 10 The monetary system 10_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 237 24/08/20 4:34 PM Source: REALITY CHECK © 2008 Dave Whamond. Reprinted by permission of ANDREWS MCMEEL SYNDICATION for UFS. All rights reserved loans but they are assets of the bank making the loans, because the borrowers will later repay the bank.) In total, First State’s assets still equal its liabilities. Once again consider the supply of money in the economy. Before First State makes any loans, the money supply is the $100 of deposits in the bank. Yet when First State makes these loans, the money supply increases. The depositors still have current deposits totalling $100, but now the borrowers hold $90 in currency. The money supply (which equals currency plus current deposits) equals $190. Thus, when banks hold only a fraction of deposits in reserve, banks create money. At first, this creation of money by fractional-reserve banking may seem too good to be true because it appears that the bank has created money out of thin air. To make this creation of money seem less miraculous, note that when First State Bank lends some of its reserves and creates money, it does not create any wealth. Loans from First State give the borrowers some currency and thus the ability to buy goods and services. Yet the borrowers are also taking on debts, so the loans do not make them any richer. In other words, as a bank creates the asset of money, it also creates a corresponding liability for its borrowers. At the end of this process of money creation, the economy is more liquid in the sense that there is more of the medium of exchange, but the economy is no wealthier than before. The money multiplier The creation of money does not stop with First State Bank. Suppose the borrower from First State uses the $90 to buy something from someone who then deposits the currency in Second State Bank. Here is the T-account for Second State Bank: Second State Bank Assets Liabilities Reserves $9.00 Deposits Loans 81.00 $90.00 After the deposit, this bank has liabilities of $90. If Second State also has a reserve ratio of 10 per cent, it keeps assets of $9 in reserve and makes $81 in loans. In this way, Second State Bank creates an additional $81 of money. If this $81 is eventually deposited in Third State Bank, which also has a reserve ratio of 10 per cent, this bank keeps $8.10 in reserve and makes $72.90 in loans. Here is the T-account for Third State Bank: Third State Bank Assets Liabilities Reserves $8.10 Deposits Loans 72.90 $81.00 238 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 5 Money and pricesCopyright in the long run 10_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 238 24/08/20 4:34 PM The process goes on and on. Each time that money is deposited and a bank loan is made, more money is created. The ‘money’ in the system is in the form of currency plus deposits, which are considered to be part of the money supply. Remember that there is still only $100 of currency in the system. How much money is eventually created in this economy? Let’s add it up: Original deposit First State lending Second State lending Third State lending • • • Total money supply = $ 100.00 = 90.00 [= 0.9 × $100.00] = 81.00 [= 0.9 × $90.00] = 72.90 [= 0.9 × $81.00] • • • = $1000.00 It turns out that even though this process of money creation can continue forever, it does not create an infinite amount of money. If you laboriously add the infinite sequence of numbers in the foregoing example, you find the $100 of reserves generates $1000 of money. The amount of money the banking system generates with each dollar of reserves is called the money multiplier. In this imaginary economy, where the $100 of reserves (the currency deposited originally in First State Bank) generates $1000 of money ($900 of which is in the form of deposits), the money multiplier is 10. What determines the size of the money multiplier? It turns out that the answer is simple – the money multiplier is the reciprocal of the reserve ratio. If all banks in the economy had the same reserve ratio, R, then each dollar of reserves generates 1/R dollars of money. In our example, R = 1/10, so the money multiplier is 10. This reciprocal formula for the money multiplier makes sense. If a bank holds $1000 in deposits, then a reserve ratio of 1/10 (10 per cent) means that the bank must hold $100 in reserves. The money multiplier just turns this idea around – if the banking system holds a total of $100 in reserves, it can have only $1000 in deposits. Similarly, if the reserve ratio were 1/5 (20 per cent), the banking system must have five times as much in deposits as in reserves, implying a money multiplier of 5. The higher the reserve ratio, the less of each deposit banks lend, and the smaller the money multiplier. In the special case of 100 per cent reserve banking, the reserve ratio is 1, the money multiplier is 1 and banks do not create money. money multiplier the amount of money the banking system generates with each dollar of reserves Bank capital, leverage and the Global Financial Crisis of 2008 In the previous sections, we have seen a very simplified explanation of how banks work. The reality of modern banking, however, is a bit more complicated and this complex reality played a leading role in the Global Financial Crisis of 2008. Before looking at that crisis, we need to learn a bit more about how banks actually function. In the bank balance sheets you have seen so far, a bank accepts deposits and uses those deposits either to make loans or to hold reserves. More realistically, a bank gets financial resources not only from accepting deposits but also, like other companies, from issuing equity and debt. The resources that a bank obtains from issuing equity to its owners are called bank capital. A bank uses these financial resources in various ways to generate profit for its owners. It not only makes loans and holds reserves but also buys financial securities, like stocks and bonds. Here is a more realistic example of a bank’s balance sheet: More Realistic National Bank Assets Liabilities and owners’ equity Reserves $200 Deposits $800 Loans $700 Debt $150 Securities $100 Capital (owners’ equity) $50 239 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN Chapter 02-200-202 10 The monetary system 10_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 239 24/08/20 4:34 PM On the right side of this balance sheet are the bank’s liabilities and capital (also known as owners’ equity). This bank obtained $50 of resources from its owners. It also took in $800 of deposits and issued $150 of debt. The total of $1000 was put to use in three ways; these are listed on the left side of the balance sheet, which shows the bank’s assets. This bank held $200 in reserves, made $700 in bank loans and used $100 to buy financial securities, like government or corporate bonds. The bank decides how to allocate its resources among asset classes based on their risk and return, as well as on any regulations (like reserve requirements) that restrict the bank’s choices. By the rules of accounting, the reserves, loans and securities on the left side of the balance sheet must always equal, in total, the deposits, debt and capital on the right side of the balance sheet. There is no magic in this equality. It occurs because the value of the owners’ equity is, by definition, the value of the bank’s assets (reserves, loans and securities) minus the value of its liabilities (deposits and debt). Therefore, the left- and right-hand sides of the balance sheet always sum to the same total. Many businesses in the economy rely on leverage, the use of borrowed money to supplement existing funds for investment purposes. Indeed, whenever anyone uses debt to finance an investment project, he or she is applying leverage. Leverage is particularly important for banks, however, because borrowing and lending are at the heart of what they do. To fully understand banking, therefore, it is crucial to understand how leverage works. The leverage ratio is the ratio of the bank’s total assets to bank capital. In this example, the leverage ratio is $1000/$50, or 20. A leverage ratio of 20 means that for every dollar of capital that the bank owners have contributed, the bank has $20 of assets. Of the $20 of assets, $19 are financed with borrowed money – either by taking in deposits or issuing debt. You may have learned in a science class that a lever can amplify a force: A boulder that you cannot move with your arms alone will move more easily if you use a lever. A similar result occurs with bank leverage. To see how this works, let’s continue with this numerical example. Suppose that the bank’s assets were to rise in value by 5 per cent because, say, some of the securities the bank was holding rose in price. Then the $1000 of assets would now be worth $1050. Because the depositors and debt holders are still owed $950, the bank capital rises from $50 to $100. Thus, when the leverage rate is 20, a 5 per cent increase in the value of assets increases the owners’ equity by 100 per cent. The same principle works on the downside, but with troubling consequences. Suppose that some people who borrowed from the bank default on their loans, reducing the value of the bank’s assets by 5 per cent, to $950. Because the depositors and debt holders have the legal right to be paid before the bank owners, the value of the owners’ equity falls to zero. Thus, when the leverage ratio is 20, a 5 per cent fall in the value of the bank assets leads to a 100 per cent fall in bank capital. If the value of assets were to fall by more than 5 per cent, the bank’s assets would fall below its liabilities. In this case, the bank would be insolvent and it would be unable to pay off its debt holders and depositors in full. Bank regulators require banks to hold a certain amount of capital. The goal of such a capital requirement is to ensure that banks will be able to pay off their depositors. The amount of capital required depends on the kind of assets a bank holds. If the bank holds safe assets like government bonds, regulators require less capital than if the bank holds risky assets like loans to borrowers whose credit is of dubious quality. In Australia, the Australian Prudential Regulation Authority (APRA) requires institutions that accept deposits, like banks, to hold 8 per cent of their assets in high-quality, safe form. This is called the prudential capital ratio. In 2008, many banks in the US found themselves with too little capital after they had incurred losses on some of their assets – specifically, mortgage loans and securities backed by mortgage loans. The shortage of capital induced the banks to reduce their lending, a phenomenon sometimes called a credit crunch, which in turn contributed to a severe downturn in economic activity. To address this problem, the US Treasury, working together with the Federal Reserve (the US central bank), put many billions of dollars of public funds 240 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 5 Money and pricesCopyright in the long run 10_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 240 24/08/20 4:34 PM into the banking system to increase the amount of bank capital. As a result, it temporarily made the US taxpayer a part owner of many banks. The goal of this unusual policy was to recapitalise the banking system so that bank lending could return to a more normal level, which in fact occurred by late 2009. Monetary policy in Australia today We can see from our discussion of fractional-reserve banking that banks have a significant influence on the amount of money in the economy – how much the banks decide to keep as reserves and how much they loan out determines the overall level of deposits in the economy. Since deposits are considered to be part of the money supply, banks have a big impact on the money supply. Does this mean the RBA can simply change the amount of reserves banks are required to keep to change the money supply? Not exactly. Up until 1993, the RBA required banks to keep a fixed percentage of their deposits as reserves, so the RBA could exercise control over the money supply through the money multiplier. (The RBA also used other direct controls over banks prior to 1993.) But APRA no longer requires all banks to have the same level of reserves for prudential purposes. The amount of reserves each bank keeps depends on the riskiness of their loans and their projected demand for cash. In our example in the previous section, all banks kept 10 per cent of their deposits as reserves. But today they are neither required to do so nor do they choose to do so. So how does the RBA conduct monetary policy if they can’t control the money supply? Instead of focusing on the amount of money in the system, the RBA targets the cash rate, as we indicated earlier in this chapter. The RBA uses the cash rate to influence the level of economic activity rather than attempting to control the money supply. The RBA announces a cash rate and then either injects cash or removes cash from the short-term money market, the overnight market for cash, to ensure that the target rate is the equilibrium rate in the market. Thus, the RBA allows the money supply to adjust to money demand to ensure that the targeted rate is the actual rate. The cash rate is then used as a benchmark rate from which other interest rates in the economy are determined. Each bank keeps deposits with the Reserve Bank to facilitate their transactions with each other and with the government. These deposits are called exchange settlement (ES) accounts. The banks use these accounts to resolve any imbalances they have with each other or with the government at the end of the day. This market is known as the overnight money market. The deposits in the ES accounts earn a rate of interest from the RBA just below the cash rate and banks can borrow from the RBA at just above the cash rate if they are short of deposits. This band, or channel, around the cash rate ensures that the target cash rate announced by the RBA is the actual cash rate in the overnight money market, where banks can borrow and lend to each other on a short-term basis. The following examples illustrate how this works: Suppose Matt gets a notice from the Australian Tax Office (ATO) that he owes them $100. He has an account with the ABC Bank. He does an electronic funds transfer from his account at ABC to the ATO. Since the ATO is a government organisation, its bank is the RBA. So the ATO’s account at the RBA goes up by $100. Now suppose Margie pays for her trip to Bali using her account with the ANB Bank. She does an electronic funds transfer of $500 from her account at the ANB to her travel agent’s account at the ABC Bank. These transfers are all handled through the banks’ exchange settlement accounts at the RBA. What’s the result of these transactions at the end of the day? The ABC’s ES account at the RBA has gone up by $400 – which is equal to the $500 transferred from Margie’s account with the ANB minus the $100 that Matt owes to the ATO. The ANB’s ES account has gone down by $500. And the ATO’s account has gone up by $100. Suppose that ANB doesn’t have the $500 in its ES account. But it ‘owes’ the money to the ABC. If it is short of money at the end of the day, it can borrow money from the overnight cash the amount of currency and bank reserves in the economy 241 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN Chapter 02-200-202 10 The monetary system 10_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 241 24/08/20 4:34 PM money market to make up the shortfall. And the rate that it pays for borrowing this money overnight is essentially the cash rate. This overnight money market facility gives the RBA great control over the cash rate. If the RBA supplies more funds to the exchange settlement funds than the banks want to hold, they will lend this money out in the overnight money market. This increase in funds leads to a decrease in the cash rate. If the RBA removes funds from the overnight money market, the cash rate will increase, as banks who want to borrow money bid up the rate. Thus, the cash rate, sitting within the channel, is determined in the money market as a result of the interaction between the demand for and supply of overnight funds. Open-market operations open-market operations the purchase and sale of Australian government securities by the RBA cash rate the interest rate that financial institutions can earn on overnight loans of their currency or reserves The last piece of this picture is how the RBA adds funds to the market or withdraws funds from the market. The RBA uses something called open-market operations to guarantee that its target rate is the equilibrium interest rate in the short-term money market. An openmarket operation is the purchase or sale of Australian government securities. If the RBA sees that there is an excess supply of funds in the overnight market at the target interest rate, it will withdraw funds from the market by selling government securities. When it sells government securities, it takes in cash from the financial institutions purchasing the government securities by reducing their ES funds, thus reducing the cash in the system. If there is an excess demand for funds at the target interest rate, the RBA will buy government securities, increasing the ES funds of the financial institutions selling the securities, thus increasing the cash in the system. When the RBA increases or decreases the amount of cash in the system, this changes the price of cash – the cash rate. In essence, the RBA is setting the ‘price’ of money, and allowing the quantity to adjust to achieve that price. (This is explained in greater detail in chapter 15.) In this way, the RBA can ensure that its target cash rate is the actual cash rate in the market. In practice, the RBA often uses something called a repo, or repurchase agreement, to affect the level of exchange settlement funds. These repos are agreements between the RBA and a commercial financial institution that the securities that have been bought or sold will be resold or repurchased, effectively reversing the transaction, at an agreed date and price in the future. Repos increased in use during the late 1990s and 2000s as the number of government securities issued declined due to reductions in government debt and the reduced need of government to borrow from the public to fund its expenditures. Figure 10.1 shows that the actual cash rate nearly always equals the target rate. The RBA determines the target cash rate by examining several factors that bear directly on the rate of inflation and the level of economic activity in the short run. These include aggregate demand, the rate of jobs growth, the change in the level of unemployment, capacity levels in the economy and the impact of international economic conditions. The board makes a judgement about whether current economic conditions are likely to produce an increase in inflation or whether the economy is slowing down. For example, when the RBA Board announces that the cash rate won’t change in a particular month, it puts out a statement to explain its decision. Go to the RBA website, look for its media release about the latest board decision and read the Governor’s reasoning. The cash rate is significant because it is the interest rate that is the foundation for all other interest rates in the economy. The cash rate is like a wholesale rate that financial institutions charge one another for borrowing and lending. When financial institutions then decide to lend to businesses or private individuals, they use the cash rate as a basis for determining the interest rates they will charge. How does the change in the cash rate affect the level of economic activity throughout the economy? If the economy is growing too fast, the RBA will announce a higher target 242 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 5 Money and pricesCopyright in the long run 10_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 242 24/08/20 4:34 PM FIGURE 10.1 The target cash rate and the actual cash rate Chart Title 16.00 Target cash rate 14.00 Inter bank rate 12.00 10.00 8.00 6.00 4.00 2.00 0.00 May-1990 Oct-1995 Apr-2001 Oct-2006 Apr-2012 Sep-2017 The graph shows the cash rate the RBA targets and the overnight rate actually obtained. Source: Reserve Bank of Australia for the cash rate. The RBA will undertake open-market operations to ensure that the cash rate moves up to the higher target level. The higher cash rate tends to push up deposit and borrowing rates at financial institutions in general. For some borrowers, it will now not make sense to borrow money for previously intended purposes, whether it be an investment project, a consumer item, or the acquisition of financial assets. Hence there are fewer opportunities for banks and other financial institutions to profitably expand their balance sheets by making more loans. The pace of money and credit creation slows as a result. In addition, the demand for real goods and services falls or grows more slowly and pressure on resource usage in the economy lessens, resulting in a fall in prices or in their rate of increase. This process will be described in more detail in chapter 15 but this brief explanation helps us understand how the RBA’s actions in the short-term money market affect the short-run position of the economy. Open-market operations are easy to conduct. In fact, the RBA’s purchases and sales of government securities in the nation’s bond markets are similar to the transactions that individuals might undertake for their own portfolios. (Of course, when an individual buys or sells a security, money changes hands, but the amount of money in circulation remains the same.) In addition, the RBA can use open-market operations to effect small or large changes in the cash rate on any day without major changes in laws or banking regulations. (For more information on monetary policy operations, see: https://www.rba.gov.au/monetarypolicy/) Problems in controlling the money supply The RBA uses the cash rate as its policy instrument because it cannot control the money supply for two reasons, each of which arises because much of the money supply is created by our system of fractional-reserve banking. The first problem is that the RBA does not control the amount of money that households choose to hold as deposits in banks. The more money that households deposit, the more reserves banks have and the more money the banking system can create. The less money that households deposit, the less reserves banks have and the less money the banking 243 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN Chapter 02-200-202 10 The monetary system 10_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 243 24/08/20 4:34 PM system can create. To see why this is a problem, suppose that one day people begin to lose confidence in the banking system and, therefore, decide to withdraw deposits and hold more currency. When this happens, the banking system loses reserves and creates less money. The money supply falls, even without any RBA action. This problem is confounded by innovations in the way that people pay for their goods and services. As we’ve seen, people don’t need to have cash to pay for the things that they buy. They can use credit cards, debits cards and smart cards and there are probably even more methods on the way. All of this means that it is harder to predict how much cash people will actually need and how much they will leave as deposits. The second problem of monetary control is that the RBA does not control the amount that bankers choose to lend. Once money is deposited in a bank, it creates more money only when the bank lends it out. Yet banks can choose the amount of reserves they wish to hold. To see why variations in the amount of reserves complicate control of the money supply, suppose that one day bankers become more cautious about economic conditions and decide to make fewer loans and hold greater reserves. In this case, the banking system creates less money than it otherwise would. Because of the bankers’ decision, the money supply falls. We saw this during the Global Financial Crisis, particularly in the US and in Europe, in financial systems that were more affected by the GFC than Australia. Hence, in a system of fractional-reserve banking, the amount of money in the economy depends in part on the behaviour of depositors and bankers. Because the RBA cannot control or perfectly predict this behaviour, it cannot perfectly control the money supply. Partly for this reason, the RBA chose to shift its emphasis from controlling the money supply to targeting interest rates. The RBA still collects data on deposits and reserves from banks and non-bank financial institutions (NBFIs) every week, so it is quickly aware of any changes in depositor or banker behaviour. However, it has much more control over the cash rate and can implement changes in the cash rate fairly quickly. This can be seen in Figure 10.1 where the target cash rate is graphed against the actual cash rate. This graph shows that when the RBA sets a target cash rate, it is able to achieve this rate fairly precisely. CASE STUDY Bank runs and the money supply Although bank runs are infrequent occurrences, they do happen occasionally. There were bank runs in Victoria in 1990–91. A bank run occurs when depositors suspect that a bank may go bankrupt and, therefore, ‘run’ to the bank to withdraw their deposits. Bank runs are a problem for banks under fractional-reserve banking. Because a bank holds only a fraction of its deposits in reserve, it cannot satisfy withdrawal requests from all depositors. Even if the bank is in fact solvent (meaning that its assets exceed its liabilities), it will not have enough cash on hand to allow all depositors immediate access to all of their money. When a run occurs, the bank is forced to close its doors until some bank loans are repaid or until some arrangement is made by the RBA to provide it with the currency it needs to satisfy depositors. Bank runs complicate the control of the money supply. An important example of this problem occurred during the Great Depression in the early 1930s. After a wave of bank runs and bank closures, households and bankers became more cautious. Households withdrew their deposits from banks, preferring to hold their money in the form of currency. This decision reversed the process of money creation, as bankers responded to falling reserves by reducing bank loans. At the same time, bankers increased their reserve ratios so that they would have enough cash on hand to meet their depositors’ demands in any future bank runs. The higher reserve ratio reduced the money multiplier, which also reduced the money supply. This contraction in money supply occurred even though 244 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 5 Money and pricesCopyright in the long run 10_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 244 24/08/20 4:34 PM there was no deliberate action by the Commonwealth Bank of Australia. However, the effects of the contraction in deposits were less severe in Australia than in other countries. Many economists nonetheless point to this fall in the money supply to explain the high unemployment and falling prices that prevailed during this period. (In later chapters we examine the mechanisms by which changes in the money supply affect unemployment and prices.) Today, bank runs are not a major problem for the banking system or the RBA. Even though the RBA and APRA do not specifically guarantee the safety of deposits at specific banks, they discourage bank runs through ensuring stability of the financial system. (In October 2008, after the collapse of Lehman Brothers in the US, the Australian government issued a guarantee of bank deposits up to $1 million. This guarantee came from the government, not the RBA.) As a result, most people see bank runs only in films. In some other countries, though, other means are used to prevent people from making runs on banks. During the 2008– 09 Global Financial Crisis, authorities in different countries imposed controls on various types of financial transactions to prevent people from withdrawing their deposits from the banking system. And we’ve seen a major bailout of banks in the United States precisely because of fears of runs on the banks in the US. Questions 1 Why are bank runs an issue under fractional-reserve banking? 2 How do bank runs affect the supply of money? CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING How does the RBA ensure that the target rate is in equilibrium? Explain briefly. Conclusion Several years ago, a book made the bestseller list in the United States with the title Secrets of the Temple: How the Federal Reserve Runs the Country. Although no doubt an exaggeration, this title highlights the important role of the monetary system in our daily lives. Whenever we buy or sell anything, we are relying on the extraordinarily useful social convention called ‘money’. Now that we know what money is and what determines its supply, we can discuss how money supply and money demand interact to affect interest rates and hence the level of economic activity. We begin to discuss that topic in the next chapter. 245 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN Chapter 02-200-202 10 The monetary system 10_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 245 24/08/20 4:34 PM STUDY TOOLS Summary LO10.1 The term money refers to assets that people regularly use to buy goods and services. Money serves three functions. As a medium of exchange, it provides the item used to make transactions. As a unit of account, it provides the way in which prices and other economic values are recorded. As a store of value, it provides a way of transferring purchasing power from the present to the future. Commodity money, like gold, is money that has intrinsic value – it would be valued even if it were not used as money. Fiat money, like plastic dollars, is money without intrinsic value – it would be worthless if it were not used as money. In the Australian economy, money takes the form of currency and various types of bank deposits, like cheque accounts. LO10.2 The Reserve Bank of Australia, Australia’s central bank, is responsible for regulating the Australian monetary system. The RBA sets interest rates to reach a target range of inflation. It does this through open-market operations – the purchase of government securities increases the amount of cash in the economy, thus lowering the interest rate, and the sale of government securities decreases the amount of cash in the economy, thus increasing the interest rate. LO10.3 When banks lend some of their deposits, they increase the quantity of money in the economy. Because of this role of banks in determining the money supply, the RBA’s control of the money supply is imperfect. Key concepts cash, p. 241 cash rate, p. 242 central bank, p. 231 commodity money, p. 226 currency, p. 228 current deposits, p. 228 fiat money, p. 227 fractional-reserve banking, p. 237 liquidity, p. 226 liquidity conditions, p. 233 medium of exchange, p. 226 monetary policy, p. 233 money, p. 225 money multiplier, p. 239 money supply, p. 228 open-market operations, p. 242 Reserve Bank of Australia (RBA), p. 231 reserve ratio, p. 237 reserves, p. 237 store of value, p. 226 unit of account, p. 226 Practice questions Questions for review 1 What distinguishes money from other assets in the economy? 2 What is the difference between commodity money and fiat money? Which is more often used and why? 3 Why should current deposits be included in the supply of money? 4 What are the three measures of money supply for the Australian economy? Where would Bitcoin (a cryptocurrency currency) fall into these measures? 5 What is the cash rate? What happens to the money supply when the RBA raises the cash rate? 6 How do changes in the cash rate affect all other interest rates in the economy? 7 Why would financial institutions say they no longer strictly follow movements in the cash rate to determine the interest rates that they charge people who borrow money from them? 8 What are reserve requirements? Why are some commentators calling for a reintroduction of reserve requirements? 9 How will an increase in Bitcoin use affect the ability of the RBA to administer monetary policy? 10 What is meant by ‘prudential supervision’? Which agency is now responsible for this function in the Australian financial system? 246 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 5 Money and pricesCopyright in the long run 10_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 246 24/08/20 4:34 PM Multiple choice 1 2 3 4 5 Which of the following are not good to use as a medium of exchange? a a car you own b gold c coins d plastic notes from the RBA Which of the following are good to use for a store of value? a very expensive caviar b a very rare painting by a Dutch master c currency from a country with a very high inflation rate d iTunes songs If banks had to keep 100% of their deposits as reserves, what would happen to the supply of money in the economy? a It would go down as people would deposit more money in the bank. b It would stay the same as people don’t use banks as much as they used to. c It would go down as banks couldn’t loan out money any more. d It wouldn’t matter as money is printed by the RBA. If Bitcoin becomes more acceptable, what effect will it have on the effectiveness of monetary policy? a It will increase it because people will have more ways to purchase goods and services. b It will decrease it because people will use Australian currency only for buying Australian goods. c It will have no effect because Bitcoin requires people to have internet accounts. d It will decrease effectiveness because it gives people an alternative to the official Australian currency. Which of the following is not the job of the Reserve Bank of Australia? a to ensure the stability of the banking system b to set the inflation rate c to set monetary policy d to monitor economic conditions in the economy Problems and applications 1 2 3 4 5 6 Which of the following is money in the Australian economy? Which is not? Explain your answers by discussing each of the three functions of money. a an Australian dollar coin b a euro (the currency of the European Union) c a Lamborghini d Apple Pay Suppose the RBA decided to decrease the cash rate. How will this affect all other interest rates in the economy? Explain the process of how the RBA will achieve this. Most people think their house is their biggest asset. Consider the three functions of money. Does your family home perform these three functions well? Consider how the following situations would affect the economy’s monetary system. a Suppose that more shops start accepting Bitcoin in payment. What would this do to the RBA’s ability to influence interest rates in the economy? Explain. b Suppose that someone in Australia discovered an easy way to counterfeit Bitcoin. How would this development affect the Australian monetary system? Explain. Your aunt repays a $100 loan from Third State Bank (TSB) by writing a $100 cheque on her TSB cheque account. Use T-accounts to show the effect of this transaction on your aunt and on TSB. Has your aunt’s wealth changed? Explain. Iron Bank (IB) holds $350 million in deposits and maintains a reserve ratio of 10 per cent. a Show a T-account for IB. b Now suppose that IB’s largest depositor withdraws $10 million from her account in cash. If IB decides to restore its reserve ratio by reducing the amount of loans outstanding, show its new T-account. c Explain what effect IB’s action will have on other banks. 247 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN Chapter 02-200-202 10 The monetary system 10_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 247 24/08/20 4:34 PM 7 8 9 d Why might it be difficult for IB to take the action described in part (b)? Discuss another way for IB to return to its original reserve ratio. What would be the impact on the money supply, bank reserves and interest rates if the RBA announced that from tomorrow coins would no longer be accepted as legal tender (and the RBA did not issue any new notes)? Happy Bank starts with $200 in bank capital. It then takes in $800 in deposits. It keeps 8 per cent (1/12th) of deposits in reserve. It uses the rest of its assets to make bank loans. a Show the balance sheet of Happy Bank. b What is Happy Bank’s leverage ratio? c Suppose that 10 per cent of the borrowers from Happy Bank default and these bank loans become worthless. Show the bank’s new balance sheet. d By what percentage do the bank’s total assets decline? By what percentage does the bank’s capital decline? Which change is larger? Why? Suppose that the T-account for First State Bank (FSB) is as follows: First State Bank Assets Reserves Loans Liabilities $100 000 Deposits $1 000 000 900 000 a 10 11 12 13 Suppose a borrower from FSB pays off their loan and no one else wants to take out a loan. (Suppose they had a $200 000 loan from FSB.) How does this affect their balance sheet? b If people aren’t taking out loans, how does this affect the money supply? Suppose that banks hold reserves of 5 per cent against cheque account deposits. a If the RBA sells $1 million of government securities, what is the effect on the economy’s reserves and money supply? b Suppose banks decide to increase their reserves to 10 per cent. Why might banks choose to do so? What effect does this have on the money supply? Suppose MacroComp, a major software company, buys PCGames, a small Australian company that produces computer games. They draw a cheque on their account at Which Bank for $100 million. The owners of PC Games deposit this cheque in their account at That Bank. a Show what happens to the balance sheet of both Which Bank and That Bank. b Show the balance sheet of their exchange settlement accounts at the RBA. c If the sale of the software company is the largest transaction of the day, which of the two banks is more likely to have to borrow money on the short-term money market? (This problem is challenging.) The economy of the Seven Kingdoms contains 3000 $1 notes. If people hold all money as currency, what is the quantity of money? a If people hold all money as current deposits and banks maintain 100 per cent reserves, what is the quantity of money? b If people hold equal amounts of currency and current deposits and banks maintain 100 per cent reserves, what is the quantity of money? c If people hold all money as current deposits and banks maintain a reserve ratio of 10 per cent, what is the quantity of money? d If people hold equal amounts of currency and current deposits and banks maintain a reserve ratio of 10 per cent, what is the quantity of money? What are the two problems in controlling the supply of money? Explain them. 248 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 5 Money and pricesCopyright in the long run 10_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 248 24/08/20 4:34 PM 11 Inf lation: Its causes and costs Learning objectives After reading this chapter, you should be able to: LO11.1 discuss the causes of inflation and hyperinflation, and explain the principle of monetary neutrality LO11.2 discuss the various costs that inflation imposes on society. 249 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 11_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 249 24/08/20 4:34 PM Introduction Although today you need more than a dollar or two to buy yourself an ice-cream, life was very different 50 years ago. If you were walking along Bondi Beach on a hot summer’s day and wanted to buy an ice-cream, it would have cost you about 5 cents. You are probably not surprised at the increase in the price of ice-cream. In our economy, most prices tend to rise over time. This increase in the overall level of prices is called inflation. Earlier in the book we examined how economists measure the inflation rate as the percentage change in the consumer price index, the GDP deflator, or some other index of the overall price level. These price indexes show that, over the past 50 years, prices have risen on average about 5 per cent per year. Accumulated over so many years, a 5 per cent annual inflation rate leads to almost a 15-fold increase in the price level. Inflation may seem natural and inevitable to a person who grew up in Australia during the second half of the twentieth century, but in fact it is not inevitable at all. There were long periods in the nineteenth century during which most prices fell – a phenomenon called deflation. The average level of prices in the Australian economy was 20 per cent lower in 1898 than in 1889. Farmers who had accumulated large debts suffered when the fall in crop prices reduced their incomes and thus their ability to pay off their debts. It was a time of great turmoil in the colonies. Although inflation has been the norm in more recent history, there has been substantial variation in the rate at which prices rise. From 1990 to 2016, prices rose at an average rate of about 2.7 per cent per year, with inflation dropping below 2 per cent from 2015–16. In contrast, in the 1970s, prices rose by almost 11 per cent per year, which meant the price level increased by more than 2½ times over the decade. The public often views such high rates of inflation as a major economic problem. In fact, when Malcolm Fraser led the Coalition to victory in the 1975 election, high inflation was one of the major issues of the campaign. Fraser promised to ‘fight inflation first’. International data show an even broader range of inflation experiences. Germany after the First World War experienced a spectacular example of inflation. The price of a newspaper rose from 0.3 of a mark in January 1921 to 70 000 000 marks less than two years later. Other prices rose by similar amounts. An extraordinarily high rate of inflation like this is called hyperinflation. New Zealand had such high inflation in the 1970s and 1980s that the central bank made low inflation its number one priority in the 1990s. In 1996, the Reserve Bank of New Zealand announced an inflation target of between 0 per cent and 3 per cent per year. Other countries, like Japan, have experienced very low rates of inflation. In 2010, Japan had negative inflation – that is, prices declined by 1.4 per cent on average. What determines whether an economy experiences inflation and, if so, how much? This chapter answers the question by developing the quantity theory of money. Chapter 1 summarised this theory as one of the Ten Principles of Economics – prices rise when the government prints too much money. This insight has a long and venerable tradition among economists. The quantity theory was discussed by the famous eighteenth-century philosopher David Hume and has been advocated more recently by the prominent economist Milton Friedman. This theory of inflation can explain both moderate inflations, like those we have experienced in Australia, and hyperinflations, like those experienced in interwar Germany and, more recently, in some Latin American and African countries. After developing a theory of inflation, we turn to a related question: Why is inflation a problem? At first glance, the answer to this question may seem obvious – inflation is a problem because people don’t like it. In the 1970s, when Australia experienced relatively high rates of inflation, opinion polls placed inflation as one of the most important issues facing the nation. This sentiment was echoed in other countries as well. In the United States, President Ford called inflation ‘public enemy number one’. Ford briefly wore a ‘WIN’ button on his lapel – for Whip Inflation Now. But what, exactly, are the costs that inflation imposes on a society? The answer may surprise you. Identifying the various costs of inflation is not as straightforward as it first appears. As a result, although all economists decry hyperinflation, some economists argue that the costs of moderate inflation are not nearly as large as the general public believes. 250 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 5 Money and pricesCopyright in the long run 11_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 250 24/08/20 4:34 PM LO11.1 The causes of inf lation We begin our study of inf lation by developing the quantity theory of money. Most economists rely on this theory for explaining the long-run determinants of the price level and the inflation rate. The level of prices and the value of money Suppose we observe over some period of time the price of an ice-cream rising from 5 cents to a dollar. What conclusion should we draw from the fact that people are willing to give up so much more money in exchange for an ice-cream? It is possible that people have come to enjoy ice-cream more (perhaps because some celebrity chef has developed a miraculous new flavour). Yet that is probably not the case. It is more likely that people’s enjoyment of ice-cream has stayed roughly the same and that, over time, the money used to buy icecream has become less valuable. Indeed, the first insight about inflation is that it is more about the value of money than about the value of goods. This insight helps point the way towards a theory of inflation. When the consumer price index and other measures of the price level rise, commentators are often tempted to look at the many individual prices that make up these price indexes: ‘The CPI rose by 3 per cent last month, led by a 20 per cent rise in the price of coffee and a 30 per cent rise in the price of petrol’. Although this approach does contain some interesting information about what’s happening in the economy, it also misses a key point – inflation is an economy-wide phenomenon that concerns, first and foremost, the value of the economy’s medium of exchange. The economy’s overall price level can be viewed in two ways. So far, we have viewed the price level as the price of a basket of goods and services. When the price level rises, people have to pay more for the goods and services they buy. Alternatively, we can view the price level as a measure of the value of money. A rise in the price level means a lower value of money because each dollar in your wallet now buys a smaller quantity of goods and services. It may help to express these ideas mathematically. Suppose P is the price level as measured, for instance, by the consumer price index or the GDP deflator. Then P measures the number of dollars needed to buy a basket of goods and services. Now turn this idea around – the quantity of goods and services that can be bought with $1 equals 1/P. In other words, if P is the price of goods and services measured in terms of money, 1/P is the value of money measured in terms of goods and services. Thus, when the overall price level rises, the value of money falls. Money supply, money demand and monetary equilibrium What determines the value of money? The answer to this question, like many in economics, is supply and demand. Just as the supply of and demand for bananas determine the price of bananas, the supply of and demand for money determine the value of money. Thus, our next step in developing the quantity theory of money is to consider the determinants of money supply and money demand. First consider money demand. There are many determinants of the quantity of money demanded, just as there are many determinants of the quantity demanded of other goods and services. How much money people choose to hold in their wallets, for instance, depends on how much they rely on credit cards and on whether an automatic teller machine is easy to find. And, as we will emphasise in a later chapter, the quantity of money demanded depends on the interest rate that a person could earn by using the money to buy an interest-bearing bond rather than leaving it in a wallet or low-interest cheque account. Although many variables affect the demand for money, one variable stands out in importance – the average level of prices in the economy. People hold money because it is the medium of exchange. Unlike other assets, like bonds or shares, people can use money to 251 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 11 Inflation: Its causes and costs 11_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 251 24/08/20 4:34 PM buy the goods and services on their shopping lists. How much money they choose to hold for this purpose depends on the prices of those goods and services. The higher prices are, the more money the typical transaction requires and the more money people will choose to hold in their wallets and cheque accounts. That is, a higher price level (a lower value of money) increases the quantity of money demanded for transaction purposes. Now consider the money supply. In the last chapter, we discussed how the Reserve Bank of Australia (RBA), together with the banking system, influences the supply of money. The RBA no longer sets a target for the level of the money supply. Some central banks still do, though. In the following explanation, we begin to see why modern central banks focus on interest rates and inflation rather than targeting the level of the money supply. To help us understand the relationship between the level of prices and the value of money, let’s consider an economy called Zoobooloo. In the land of Zoobooloo, the Central Bank sets the level of money supply. What ensures that the quantity of money the Zoobooloo Central Bank (ZCB) supplies balances the quantity of money people demand? The answer, it turns out, depends on the time horizon being considered. Later in this book we will examine the short-run answer and we will see that interest rates play a key role. In the long run, however, the answer is different and much simpler. In the long run, the overall level of prices adjusts to the level at which the demand for money equals the supply. If the price level is above the equilibrium level, people will want to hold more money than the ZCB has created, so the price level must fall to balance supply and demand. If the price level is below the equilibrium level, people will want to hold less money than the ZCB has created and the price level must rise to balance supply and demand. At the equilibrium price level, the quantity of money that people want to hold exactly balances the quantity of money supplied by the ZCB. Figure 11.1 illustrates these ideas. The horizontal axis of this graph shows the quantity of money. The left-hand vertical axis shows the value of money and the right-hand vertical FIGURE 11.1 H ow the supply of and demand for money in Zoobooloo determine the equilibrium price level Value of money (High) Price level Money supply 1 1 / 1.33 3 4 / 1 2 Equilibrium value of money (Low) A (Low) 2 Equilibrium price level 4 / 1 4 Money demand 0 Quantity fixed by the ZCB Quantity of money (High) The horizontal axis shows the quantity of money. The left vertical axis shows the value of money and the right vertical axis shows the price level. The supply curve for money is vertical because the quantity of money supplied is fixed by the ZCB. The demand curve for money is downwardsloping because people want to hold a larger quantity of money when each dollar buys less. At the equilibrium, point A, the value of money (on the left axis) and the price level (on the right axis) have adjusted to bring the quantity of money supplied and the quantity of money demanded into balance. 252 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 5 Money and pricesCopyright in the long run 11_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 252 24/08/20 4:34 PM axis shows the price level. Notice that the price level axis is inverted – when the value of money is high (as measured on the left axis), the price level is low (as measured on the right axis). The supply curve for money in this figure is vertical, indicating that the ZCB has fixed the quantity of money available. The demand curve for money is downward-sloping, indicating that when the value of money is low, people demand a larger quantity of it to buy goods and services. At the equilibrium, shown in the figure as point A, the quantity of money demanded balances the quantity of money supplied. This equilibrium of money supply and money demand determines the value of money and the price level. The effects of a monetary injection Let’s see what happens to the value of the Zoobooloo dollar (Z$) when the ZCB increases the money supply. To do so, imagine that the economy is in equilibrium and then, suddenly, the ZCB does as economist Milton Friedman suggested and doubles the supply of money by printing some more and dropping it around the country from helicopters. (Or, less dramatically and more realistically, the ZCB could inject money into the economy by buying some government bonds from the public in open-market operations.) What happens after such a monetary injection? How does the new equilibrium compare with the old one? Figure 11.2 shows what happens. The monetary injection shifts the supply curve to the right from MS1 to MS2, and the equilibrium moves from point A to point B. As a result, the value of money (shown on the left axis) decreases from ½ to ¼ and the equilibrium price level (shown on the right axis) increases from 2 to 4. In other words, when an increase in the money supply makes dollars more plentiful, the result is an increase in the price level that makes each dollar less valuable. FIGURE 11.2 An increase in the money supply Value of money (High) 2. … decreases the value of money … MS1 Price level MS2 1 1 1. An increase in the money supply ... / 3 4 / 1 2 1.33 A 2 B / 1 4 (Low) 3. … and increases the price level. 4 Money demand (Low) (High) 0 M1 M2 Quantity of money When the ZCB increases the supply of money, the money supply curve shifts from MS1 to MS2. The value of money (on the left axis) and the price level (on the right axis) adjust to bring supply and demand back into balance. The equilibrium moves from point A to point B. Thus, when an increase in the money supply makes dollars more plentiful, the price level increases, making each dollar less valuable. 253 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 11 Inflation: Its causes and costs 11_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 253 24/08/20 4:34 PM CASE STUDY IN THE NEWS This explanation of how the price level is determined and why it might change over time is called the quantity theory of money. According to the quantity theory, the quantity of money available in the economy determines the value of money, and growth in the quantity of money is the primary cause of inflation. As Milton Friedman once put it: ‘Inflation is always and everywhere a monetary phenomenon’. The long-lasting effect of printing money Our example of Zoobooloo shows what happens when a central bank prints more money. Most Western central banks now focus more on interest rates rather than money supply, but the dangers of printing too much money are still very present today. According to Steve Hanke of Forbes magazine, in Zimbabwe inflation was estimated at 6.5 quindecillion novemdecillion per cent (65 followed by 107 zeros) in December 2008 because the Zimbabwean Reserve Bank printed too much money. It’s hard to even imagine what that means. As Hanke said, it means prices double nearly every 24 hours. There were signs in public toilets that said Zimbabwe Dollar Returns, a Decade After It Became Worthless By Antony Sguazzin and Ray Ndlovu 24 June 2019 Zimbabwe has brought back its own currency, the Zimbabwe dollar, just over a decade after its usefulness was destroyed by hyperinflation. The central bank said that effective immediately, currencies including the U.S. dollar and the South African rand, in use since 2009, will no longer be accepted as legal tender. A local quasi currency known as bond notes, which was introduced in 2016 but can’t trade outside the country, and their electronic equivalent, the RTGS dollar, will now be known as the Zimbabwe dollar. The authorities had abandoned the Zimbabwe dollar after inflation reached an estimated 500 billion percent in 2008, according to the International Monetary the Zim dollar wasn’t even good for toilet paper! More than a decade later, the Zim dollar has returned, but it’s still being discounted on the street, as Figure 11.3 shows. Getty Images/EFP/Desmond Kwande quantity theory of money a theory asserting that the quantity of money available determines the price level and that the growth rate in the quantity of money available determines the inflation rate Fund. While the country has since used a basket of currencies from the continent and abroad as well as bond notes and the RTGS$, some government departments and agencies have until recently demanded payment in the greenback. The central bank made it clear in its announcement that money held in foreign-currency accounts will not be affected, but the step will be greeted with alarm and memories of the lives wrecked and pensions and savings lost in 2008. Recollections of what effectively became a barter economy in a country where a suitcase full of bank notes was needed to purchase a pair of jeans will be hard to erase. The central bank also announced a series of other measures, including raising the rate on its overnight window to 50% from 15%, to buttress the currency. 254 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 5 Money and pricesCopyright in the long run 11_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 254 24/08/20 4:34 PM something backing the currency. There’s no way that something like this will be maintained. People will not trust the currency. It will promote more off-market activity even more if that’s possible.’ ‘Any attempt by the officials to bring a new currency would require confidence,’ said Jee-A van der Linde, an economist at NKC African Economics in Paarl, South Africa. ‘People aren’t sure that there’s FIGURE 11.3 Zimbabwe dollar vs US dollar 14 RTGS$ per U.S. dollar 12 Interbank rate for RTGS$ RTGS$ parallel exchange rate 10 8 6 4 2 0 Mar 29 Apr 15 Apr 30 May 15 May 31 Jun 14 Source: Reserve Bank of Zimbabwe, Bloomberg In February, the central bank introduced the RTGS$ and said it and bond notes would no longer be pegged to the U.S. currency. This precipitated a rapid depreciation in both the newly introduced interbank rate and the blackmarket value. Inflation, at 97.9%, is now at its highest since at least 2008. This ‘will worsen the situation,’ said Christopher Mugaga, the chief executive officer of the Zimbabwe National Chamber of Commerce. Companies ‘with real dollars will simply go underground,’ he said. Finance Minister Mthuli Ncube said Monday’s announcement gives the central bank ‘flexibility’ to conduct monetary policy. The authorities in Zimbabwe have previously said the central bank plans to establish a Monetary Policy Committee. ‘We can also expect the creation of a monetary policy committee as part of the micro institutions that are going towards stabilizing the value of the currency,’ he said on state television. Source: Used with permission of Bloomberg L.P. Copyright©2020. All rights reserved. Question How does the quantity theory of money relate to Zimbabwe over the last two decades? A brief look at the adjustment process So far, we have compared the old equilibrium and the new equilibrium after an injection of money. How does the economy get from the old to the new equilibrium? A complete answer to this question requires an understanding of short-run fluctuations in the economy, which we examine later in this book. Yet, even now, it is instructive to consider briefly the adjustment process that occurs after a change in money supply. The immediate effect of a monetary injection is to create an excess supply of money. Before the injection, the economy was in equilibrium (point A in Figure 11.2). At the prevailing price level, people had exactly as much money as they wanted. But after the 255 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 11 Inflation: Its causes and costs 11_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 255 24/08/20 4:34 PM helicopters drop the new money and people pick it up in the streets, people have more dollars in their wallets than they want. At the prevailing price level, the quantity of money supplied now exceeds the quantity demanded. People try to get rid of this excess supply of money in various ways. They might buy goods and services with their excess holdings of money. Or they might use this excess money to make loans to others by buying bonds or by depositing the money in a bank savings account. These loans allow other people to buy goods and services. In either case, the injection of money increases the demand for goods and services. Because the economy’s ability to produce goods and services has not changed, this greater demand for goods and services causes the prices of goods and services to increase. The increase in the price level, in turn, increases the quantity of money demanded. Eventually, the economy reaches a new equilibrium (point B in Figure 11.2) at which the quantity of money demanded again equals the quantity of money supplied. In this way, the overall price level for goods and services adjusts to bring money supply and money demand into balance. The classical dichotomy and monetary neutrality nominal variables variables measured in monetary units real variables variables measured in physical units classical dichotomy the theoretical separation of nominal and real variables We have seen how changes in the money supply lead to changes in the average level of prices of goods and services. How do these monetary changes affect other important macroeconomic variables, like production, employment, real wages and real interest rates? This question has long intrigued economists. Indeed, the great philosopher David Hume wrote about it in the eighteenth century. Hume and his contemporaries suggested that economic variables should be divided into two groups. The first group consists of nominal variables – variables measured in monetary units. The second group consists of real variables – variables measured in physical units. For example, the income of corn farmers is a nominal variable because it is measured in dollars, whereas the quantity of corn they produce is a real variable because it is measured in bushels. Nominal GDP is a nominal variable because it measures the dollar value of the economy’s output of goods and services; real GDP is a real variable because it measures the total quantity of goods and services produced and is not influenced by the current prices of those goods and services. The separation of real and nominal variables is now called the classical dichotomy. (A dichotomy is a division into two groups, and classical refers to the earlier economic thinkers.) Applying the classical dichotomy is tricky when we turn to prices. Most prices are quoted in units of money and, therefore, are nominal variables. When we say that the price of corn is $2 a bushel or that the price of wheat is $1 a bushel, both prices are nominal variables. But what about a relative price – the price of one thing compared with another? In our example, we could say that the price of a bushel of corn is 2 bushels of wheat. This relative price is not measured in terms of money. When comparing the prices of any two goods, the dollar signs cancel and the resulting number is measured in physical units. Thus, while dollar prices are nominal variables, relative prices are real variables. This lesson has many applications. For instance, the real wage (the dollar wage adjusted for inflation) is a real variable because it measures the rate at which people exchange goods and services for a unit of labour. Similarly, the real interest rate (the nominal interest rate adjusted for inflation) is a real variable because it measures the rate at which people exchange goods and services today for goods and services in the future. Why separate variables into these groups? The classical dichotomy is useful because different forces influence real and nominal variables. According to classical analysis, nominal variables are influenced by developments in the economy’s monetary system, whereas money is largely irrelevant for explaining real variables. This idea was implicit in our discussion of the real economy in the long run. In previous chapters, we examined how real GDP, saving, investment, real interest rates 256 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 5 Money and pricesCopyright in the long run 11_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 256 24/08/20 4:34 PM and unemployment are determined without mentioning the existence of money. In that analysis, the economy’s production of goods and services depends on productivity and factor supplies, the real interest rate balances the supply and demand for loanable funds, the real wage balances the supply and demand for labour and unemployment results when the real wage is for some reason kept above its equilibrium level. These conclusions have nothing to do with the quantity of money supplied. Changes in the supply of money, according to classical analysis, affect nominal variables but not real variables. When the central bank doubles the money supply, the price level doubles, the dollar wage doubles and all other dollar values double. Real variables, like production, employment, real wages and real interest rates, are unchanged. This irrelevance of monetary changes for real variables is called monetary neutrality. An analogy sheds light on the meaning of monetary neutrality. Recall that, as the unit of account, money is the yardstick we use to measure economic transactions. When a central bank doubles the money supply, all prices double and the value of the unit of account falls by half. A similar change would occur if the government were to reduce the length of a metre from 100 cm to 50 cm – as a result of the new unit of measurement, all measured distances (nominal variables) would double, but the actual distances (real variables) would remain the same. The dollar, like the metre, is merely a unit of measurement, so a change in its value should not have important real effects. Is this conclusion of monetary neutrality a realistic description of the world in which we live? The answer is ‘not completely’. A change in the length of a metre from 100 cm to 50 cm would not matter much in the long run, but in the short run it would certainly lead to confusion and various mistakes. Similarly, most economists today believe that over short periods of time – within the span of a year or two – there is reason to think that monetary changes do have important effects on real variables. Hume himself also doubted that monetary neutrality would apply in the short run. (We will turn to the study of short-run non-neutrality in a later chapter.) Yet most economists today accept the classical analysis’ conclusion as a description of the economy in the long run. Over the course of a decade, for instance, monetary changes have important effects on nominal variables but only negligible effects on real variables. When studying long-run changes in the economy, the neutrality of money offers a good description of how the world works. monetary neutrality the proposition that changes in the money supply do not affect real variables Velocity and the quantity equation We can obtain another perspective on the quantity theory of money by considering the following question: How many times per year is the typical dollar coin used to pay for a newly produced good or service? The answer to this question is given by a variable called the velocity of money. In physics, the term velocity refers to the speed (and direction) at which an object travels. In economics, the velocity of money refers to the speed at which the typical note or coin travels around the economy from wallet to wallet. To calculate the velocity of money, we divide the nominal value of output (nominal GDP) by the quantity of money. If P is the price level (the GDP deflator), Y the quantity of output (real GDP) and M the quantity of money (notes and coins), then velocity is: V= velocity of money the rate at which money changes hands (P × Y ) M To see why this makes sense, imagine a simple economy that produces only pizza. Suppose that the economy produces 100 pizzas in a year, that a pizza sells for $10, and that the quantity of money in the economy is $50, consisting of 50 dollar coins. Then the velocity of money is: ($10 × 100) $50 = 20 V= 257 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 11 Inflation: Its causes and costs 11_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 257 24/08/20 4:34 PM In this economy, people spend a total of $1000 per year on pizza. For this $1000 of spending to take place with only $50 of money, each dollar coin must change hands 20 times per year. With slight algebraic rearrangement, this equation can be rewritten as: M×V=P×Y quantity equation the equation M × V = P × Y, which relates the quantity of money, the velocity of money and the dollar value of the economy’s output of goods and services CASE STUDY This equation states that the quantity of money (M) times the velocity of money (V ) equals the price of output (P) times the amount of output (Y ). It is called the quantity equation because it relates the quantity of money (M) to the nominal value of output (P × Y ). The quantity equation shows that an increase in the quantity of money in an economy must be reflected in one of the other three variables – the price level must rise, the quantity of output must rise, or the velocity of money must fall. If we assume that the velocity of money is relatively stable, we have a clear relationship between money and prices in the long run. We now have all the elements necessary to explain the equilibrium price level and inflation rate. Here they are: 1 Assume the velocity of money is relatively stable over time. 2 Because velocity is stable, if a central bank were to change the quantity of money (M ), it would cause proportionate changes in the nominal value of output (P × Y ). 3 The economy’s output of goods and services (Y ) is primarily determined by factor supplies and the available technology. In particular, because money is neutral, money does not affect output. 4 With output (Y ) determined by factor supplies and technology, if the central bank alters the money supply (M ) and induces parallel changes in the nominal value of output (P × Y ), these changes are reflected in changes in the price level (P). 5 Therefore, if the central bank increases the money supply rapidly, the result is a high rate of inflation. Money and prices during four hyperinflations The five steps discussed above are the essence of the quantity theory of money. Although earthquakes can wreak havoc on a society, they have the beneficial by-product of providing much useful data for seismologists. These data can shed light on alternative theories and, thereby, help society predict and deal with future threats. Similarly, hyperinflations offer monetary economists a natural experiment they can use to study the effects of money on the economy. Hyperinflations are interesting in part because the changes in the money supply and price level are so large. Indeed, hyperinflation is generally defined as inflation that exceeds 50 per cent per month. This means that the price level increases more than 100-fold over the course of a year. The data on hyperinflation show a clear link between the quantity of money and the price level. Figure 11.4 graphs data from four classic hyperinflations that occurred during the 1920s in Austria, Hungary, Germany and Poland. Each graph shows the quantity of money in the economy and an index of the price level. The slope of the money line represents the rate at which the quantity of money was growing and the slope of the price line represents the inflation rate. The steeper the lines, the higher the rates of money growth or inflation. Notice that in each graph the quantity of money and the price level are almost parallel. In each instance, growth in the quantity of money is moderate at first and so is inflation. But over time, the quantity of money in the economy starts growing faster and faster. At about the same time, inflation also takes off. Then when the quantity of money stabilises, the price level stabilises as well. These episodes illustrate well one of the Ten Principles of Economics – prices rise when the government prints too much money. Question What can explain the almost perfectly synchronised pattern between the price level and money supply in Figure 11.4? 258 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 5 Money and pricesCopyright in the long run 11_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 258 24/08/20 4:34 PM FIGURE 11.4 Money and prices during four hyperinflations (a) Austria (b) Hungary Index (Jan. 1921 = 100) Index (July 1921 = 100) 100 000 100 000 Price level Price level 10 000 10 000 Money supply 1 000 100 Money supply 1 000 1921 1922 1923 1924 1925 100 1921 1922 1924 1925 (d) Poland (c) Germany Index (Jan. 1921 = 100) Index (Jan. 1921 = 100) 100 000 000 000 000 1 000 000 000 000 10 000 000 000 100 000 000 1 000 000 10 000 100 1 1923 10 000 000 Price level Money supply Price level 1 000 000 Money supply 100 000 10 000 1 000 1921 1922 1923 1924 1925 100 1921 1922 1923 1924 1925 This figure shows the quantity of money and the price level during four hyperinflations. (Note that these variables are graphed on logarithmic scales. This means that equal vertical distances on the graph represent equal percentage changes in the variable.) In each case, the quantity of money and the price level move closely together. The strong association between these two variables is consistent with the quantity theory of money, which states that growth in the money supply is the primary cause of inflation. Source: Adapted from Thomas J. Sargent, ‘The end of four big inflations’ in Robert Hall (ed.), Inflation (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1983), pp. 41–93 The inf lation tax If inf lation is so easy to explain, why do countries experience hyperinflation? That is, why do the central banks of these countries choose to print so much money that its value is certain to fall rapidly over time? The answer is that the governments of these countries are using money creation as a way to pay for their spending. When the government wants to build roads, pay salaries to police officers, or give transfer payments to the poor or elderly, it first has to raise the necessary funds. Normally, the government does this by levying taxes, like income and sales taxes, and by borrowing from the public by selling government bonds. Yet the government can also pay for spending by simply printing the money it needs. When the government raises revenue by printing money, it is said to levy an inflation tax. The inflation tax is not exactly like other taxes, however, because no one receives a bill from the government for this tax. Instead, the inflation tax is more subtle. When the government prints money, the price level rises, and the dollars in your wallet are less valuable. Thus, the inflation tax is like a tax on everyone who holds money. The importance of the inflation tax varies from country to country and over time. In Australia in the 1970s, the inflation tax was a significant source of revenue. However, one of inflation tax the revenue the government raises by creating money 259 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 11 Inflation: Its causes and costs 11_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 259 24/08/20 4:34 PM the most striking examples was the German hyperinflation after the First World War. The German government was required to pay war reparations to the Allies, but it was unable to collect sufficient tax revenue to meet the debt. It financed the debt by borrowing freshly minted money from the Reichsbank, the German central bank. By 1922, prices were 1475 times their pre-war level. Almost all hyperinflations follow the same pattern as the hyperinflation following the First World War in Germany. The government has high spending, inadequate tax revenue and limited ability to borrow. As a result, it turns to the printing press to pay for its spending. The massive increases in the quantity of money lead to massive inflation. The inflation ends when the government institutes fiscal reforms – like cuts in government spending – that eliminate the need for the inflation tax. The Fisher effect According to the principle of monetary neutrality, an increase in the rate of money growth raises the rate of inflation but does not affect any real variable. An important application of this principle concerns the effect of money on interest rates. Interest rates are important variables for macroeconomists to understand because they link the economy of the present and the economy of the future through their effects on saving and investment. To understand the relationship between money, inflation and interest rates, recall the distinction between the nominal interest rate and the real interest rate. The nominal interest rate is the interest rate you hear about at your bank. If you have a savings account, for instance, the nominal interest rate tells you how fast the number of dollars in your account will rise over time. The real interest rate corrects the nominal interest rate for the effect of inflation in order to tell you how fast the purchasing power of your savings account will rise over time. The real interest rate is the nominal interest rate minus the inflation rate: Real interest rate = Nominal interest rate − Inflation rate For example, if the bank posts a nominal interest rate of 7 per cent per year and the inflation rate is 3 per cent per year, then the real value of the deposits grows by 4 per cent per year. We can rewrite this equation to show that the nominal interest rate is the sum of the real interest rate and the inflation rate: Nominal interest rate = Real interest rate + Inflation rate This way of looking at the nominal interest rate is useful because different economic forces determine each of the two terms on the right-hand side of this equation. As we discussed in an earlier chapter, the supply of and demand for loanable funds determine the real interest rate. And, according to the quantity theory of money, growth in the money supply determines the inflation rate. IN THE NEWS Fighting the war … on inflation? Of all of the devastating effects of war, the one that is least mentioned is the impact on the economy, prices in particular. In Syria, the war effort has led to spikes in the prices of most essential items. When governments resort to printing money to fund their war efforts, its citizens inevitably suffer, through higher prices of food, as well as the destruction of infrastructure and basic economic interactions. The article lists the sometimes forgotten implications of war – the economic consequences. 260 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 5 Money and pricesCopyright in the long run 11_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 260 24/08/20 4:34 PM The Cost of Conflict Middle East strife is exacting a heavy toll on regional economies. Nowhere in the world has conflict been as frequent or as violent over the past 50 years as in the Middle East and North Africa. On average, countries in this region have experienced some form of warfare every three years. Today, rarely a day passes without media reports of violence, large-scale human suffering, and major destruction in such countries as Iraq, Syria, and Yemen. These conflicts have enormous human and economic costs, both for countries directly involved and for their neighbors. Libya, Syria, and Yemen experienced deep declines in their economies with sharp increases in inflation between 2010 and 2016. Iraq’s economy remains fragile owing to the conflict with the Islamic State (ISIS) and the fall in oil prices since 2014. Clashes have also spilled over to other countries, causing problems that are expected to persist—such as economic pressures from hosting refugees. Violent conflict has worsened conditions for a region already facing structural deficiencies, low investment, and, more recently, the oil price drop, which has had a substantial impact on oil-producing economies. Girls washing clothes at Atmeh displaced persons camp, Syria Key channels There are four major channels through which conflict affects economies. First, death, injury, and displacement seriously erode human capital. While the figures are difficult to verify, half a million civilians and combatants are estimated to Getty Images Plus/iStock Unreleased/Joel Carillet Phil de Imus, Gaëlle Pierre and Björn Rother December 2017 have died from the conflicts in the region since 2011. Moreover, as of the end of 2016, the region accounted for almost half of the world’s population of forcibly displaced people: 10 million refugees and 20 million internally displaced people from the region have had to abandon their homes. Syria alone has nearly 12 million displaced people, the largest number of any country in the region. Conflict also reduces human capital by spreading poverty. Poverty in conflict countries, even outside regions directly affected by violence, tends to rise as employment declines. The quality of education and health services also deteriorates, a problem that deepens the longer a conflict continues. Syria provides a dramatic example. Unemployment jumped from 8.4 percent in 2010 to more than 50 percent in 2013, school dropout rates reached 52 percent, and estimated life expectancy fell from 76 years before the conflict to 56 years in 2014. Since then, the situation has deteriorated even more. Second, physical capital and infrastructure are damaged or destroyed. Houses, buildings, roads, bridges, schools, and hospitals – as well as the water, power, and sanitation infrastructure – have been hit hard. In some areas, entire urban systems were virtually wiped out. In addition, infrastructure related to key economic sectors such as oil, agriculture, and manufacturing has been seriously degraded, with significant repercussions for growth, fiscal and export revenues, and foreign reserves. In Syria, more than a quarter of the housing stock has been destroyed or damaged since the war’s onset, while in Yemen, infrastructure damage has exacerbated drought conditions and contributed to severe food insecurity and disease. The country’s agricultural sector, which employed more than half the population, was hit hard, experiencing a 37 percent drop in cereal production in 2016 from the previous fiveyear average. Third, economic organization and institutions are hurt. The deterioration in economic governance has been particularly acute where institutional quality was already poor before the 261 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 11 Inflation: Its causes and costs 11_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 261 24/08/20 4:34 PM outbreak of violence, as was the case in Iraq, Libya, Syria, and Yemen. This damage has led to reduced connectivity, higher transportation costs, and disruptions in supply chains and networks. Institutions can also become corrupt as the warring parties try to exert control over political and economic activity. Fiscal spending and credit, for example, might be redirected to the constituencies of those in power. More broadly, many critical economic institutions – central banks, ministries of finance, tax authorities, and commercial courts – have seen their effectiveness diminish because they have lost touch with the more remote parts of their countries. The World Bank estimates that disruptions to economic organization were about 20 times costlier than capital destruction in the first six years of the Syrian conflict. Lastly, the stability of the region and its longer-term development through its impact on confidence and social cohesion are threatened. The conflicts in the Middle East and North Africa have heightened insecurity and reduced confidence, manifested by declining foreign and domestic investment, deteriorating financial sector performance, higher security spending, and shrinking tourism and trade. Social trust has also weakened, negatively affecting economic transactions and political decision making. Direct and indirect effects The macroeconomic damage can be staggering. Syria’s 2016 GDP, for example, Fisher effect the one-for-one adjustment of the nominal interest rate to the inflation rate is estimated to be less than half its 2010 preconflict level. Yemen lost an estimated 25 to 35 percent of its GDP in 2015 alone, while in Libya – where dependence on oil has made growth extremely volatile – GDP fell by 24 percent in 2014 as violence picked up. The West Bank and Gaza offers a longer-term perspective on what can happen to growth in a fragile situation: its economy has been virtually stagnant over the past 20 years in contrast with average growth of nearly 250 percent in other countries of the region during that period. Furthermore, these conflicts have led to high inflation and exchange rate pressures. In Iraq, inflation peaked at more than 30 percent during the mid2000s; in Libya and Yemen it rose above 15 percent in 2011, on the back of a collapse in the supply of critical goods and services combined with strong recourse to monetary financing of the budget. Syria is an even more extreme case, with consumer prices rising by about 600 percent between 2010 and late 2016. Such inflation dynamics are usually accompanied by strong depreciation pressure on local currencies, which the authorities may try to resist through heavy intervention and regulation of crossborder flows. These forces have clearly been at work in Syria: the Syrian pound, which floated freely in 2013, officially trades at about one-tenth its prewar value against the US dollar. Source: IMF, Finance & Development, December 2017, Vol. 54, No. 4, https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/ fandd/2017/12/imus.htm Let’s go back to Zoobooloo to consider how the growth in the money supply affects interest rates. In the long run, over which money is neutral, a change in money growth should not affect the real interest rate. The real interest rate is, after all, a real variable. For the real interest rate not to be affected, the nominal interest rate must adjust one-for-one to changes in the inflation rate. Thus, when the ZCB increases the rate of money growth, the result is both a higher inflation rate and a higher nominal interest rate. This adjustment of the nominal interest rate to the inflation rate is called the Fisher effect, after economist Irving Fisher (1867–1947), who first studied it. The Fisher effect is, in fact, crucial for understanding changes over time in the nominal interest rate. Figure 11.5 shows the nominal interest rate and the inflation rate in the Australian economy since 1976. The close association between these two variables is clear. The nominal interest rate rose from 1980 to 1990 because inflation was also rising during this time. Similarly, the nominal interest rate fell from the early to mid-1990s due to the 1991 recession and because the RBA finally got inflation under control. 262 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 5 Money and pricesCopyright in the long run 11_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 262 24/08/20 4:34 PM FIGURE 11.5 The nominal interest rate and the inflation rate 20 90-day bank bill 18 CPI 16 14 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 –2 1976 1981 1986 1991 1996 2001 2006 2011 2016 This figure uses annual data since 1976 to show the nominal interest rate on 90-day bank bills and the inflation rate as measured by the consumer price index. The close association between these two variables is evidence for the Fisher effect – when the inflation rate rises, so does the nominal interest rate. Source: The Reserve Bank of Australia CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING If a government of a country increases the growth rate of the money supply from 10 per cent per year to 50 per cent per year, what happens to the price level? What happens to nominal interest rates? Why might a government choose this course of action? LO11.2 The costs of inflation In the early 1980s, when the Australian inflation rate was above 10 per cent per year, inflation dominated debates over economic policy. Even though inflation dropped significantly during the first half of the 1990s, inflation remained a closely watched macroeconomic variable. One 1996 study found that inflation was the economic term mentioned most often in Australian newspapers and magazines. Inflation is closely watched and widely discussed because it is thought to be a serious economic problem; in fact, its importance has led to a profound change in the way most central banks, including the RBA, manage monetary policy. But is that true? And if so, why? 263 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 11 Inflation: Its causes and costs 11_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 263 24/08/20 4:34 PM Source: PEANUTS © 1984 Peanuts Worldwide LLC. Distributed by ANDREWS MCMEEL SYNDICATION. Reprinted with permission. All rights reserved A fall in purchasing power? The inflation fallacy If you ask ordinary people why inflation is bad, they will tell you that the answer is obvious – inflation robs them of the purchasing power of their hard-earned dollars. When prices rise, each dollar of income buys fewer goods and services. Thus, it might seem that inflation directly lowers living standards. Yet further thought reveals a fallacy in this answer. When prices rise, buyers of goods and services do pay more for what they buy. At the same time, however, sellers of goods and services get more for what they sell. Because most people earn their incomes by selling their services, like their labour, inflation in incomes goes hand in hand with inflation in prices. Thus, inflation does not in itself reduce people’s real purchasing power. People believe the inflation fallacy because they do not appreciate the principle of monetary neutrality. Workers who receive an annual wage increase of 10 per cent tend to view it as a reward for their own talents and efforts. When an inflation rate of 6 per cent reduces the real value of that wage increase to only 4 per cent, workers might feel that they have been cheated of what is rightfully their due. In fact, as we discussed in previous chapters, real incomes are determined by real variables, like physical capital, human capital, natural resources and the available production technology. Nominal incomes are determined by those factors and the overall price level. If the RBA were to lower the inflation rate from 6 per cent to zero, workers’ annual wage increase would fall from 10 per cent to 4 per cent. They might feel less robbed by inflation, but their real income would not rise more quickly. But if nominal incomes tend to keep pace with rising prices, why then is inflation a problem? It turns out that there is no single answer to this question. Instead, economists have identified several costs of inflation. Each of these costs shows some way in which persistent growth in the money supply does, in fact, have some effect on real variables. Shoeleather costs shoeleather costs the resources wasted when inflation encourages people to reduce their money holdings As we have discussed, inflation is like a tax on the holders of money. The tax itself is not a cost to society – it is only a transfer of resources from households to the government. Yet most taxes give people an incentive to alter their behaviour to avoid paying the tax and this distortion of incentives causes efficiency losses for society as a whole. Like other taxes, the inflation tax also causes efficiency losses, as people waste scarce resources trying to avoid it. How can a person avoid paying the inflation tax? Because inflation erodes the real value of the money in your wallet, you can avoid the inflation tax by holding less money. One way to do this is to go to the bank more often. For example, rather than withdrawing $200 every four weeks, you might withdraw $50 once a week. By making more frequent trips to the bank, you can keep more of your wealth in your interest-bearing savings account and less in your wallet, where inflation erodes its value. The cost of reducing your money holdings is called the shoeleather costs of inflation because making more frequent trips to the bank causes your shoes to wear out more quickly. Of course, this term is not to be taken literally – the actual cost of reducing your money 264 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 5 Money and pricesCopyright in the long run 11_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 264 24/08/20 4:34 PM holdings is not the wear and tear on your shoes but the time and convenience you must sacrifice to keep less money on hand than you would if there were no inflation. The shoeleather costs of inflation may seem trivial. And, in fact, they are in the Australian economy, which has had only moderate inflation in recent years. But this cost is magnified in countries experiencing hyperinflation. Here is a description of one person’s experience in Bolivia during its hyperinflation (as reported in the 13 August 1985 issue of the Wall Street Journal, p. 1): When Edgar Miranda gets his monthly teacher’s pay of 25 million pesos, he hasn’t a moment to lose. Every hour, pesos drop in value. So, while his wife rushes to market to lay in a month’s supply of rice and noodles, he is off with the rest of the pesos to change them into black-market dollars. Mr Miranda is practising the First Rule of Survival amid the most out-of- control inflation in the world today. Bolivia is a case study of how runaway inflation undermines a society. Price increases are so huge that the figures build up almost beyond comprehension. In one six-month period, for example, prices soared at an annual rate of 38 000%. By official count, however, last year’s inflation reached 2000%, and this year’s is expected to hit 8000% – though other estimates range many times higher. In any event, Bolivia’s rate dwarfs Israel’s 370% and Argentina’s 1100% – two other cases of severe inflation. It is easier to comprehend what happens to the thirty-eight-year-old Mr Miranda’s pay if he doesn’t quickly change it into dollars. The day he was paid 25 million pesos, a dollar cost 500 000 pesos. So he received $50. Just days later, with the rate at 900 000 pesos, he would have received $27. Source: © Reprinted by permission of the Wall Street Journal, © 1985 Dow Jones & Company, Inc. All Rights Reserved Worldwide As this story shows, the shoeleather costs of inflation can be substantial. With the high inflation rate, Mr Miranda does not have the luxury of holding the local money as a store of value. Instead, he is forced to convert his pesos quickly into goods or into US dollars, which offer a more stable store of value. The time and effort that Mr Miranda expends to reduce his money holdings are a waste of resources. If the monetary authority pursued a low-inflation policy, Mr Miranda would be happy to hold pesos, and he could put his time and effort to more productive use. In fact, shortly after this article was written, the Bolivian inflation rate was reduced substantially with more restrictive monetary policy. Menu costs Most firms do not change the prices of their products every day. Instead, firms often announce prices and leave them unchanged for weeks, months or even years. One survey found that the typical Australian firm changes its prices about once a year. One very visible exception to this is petrol prices, which are often changed several times during the week. Firms change prices infrequently because there are costs of changing prices. Costs of price adjustment are called menu costs, a term derived from a restaurant’s cost of printing a new menu. Menu costs include the cost of printing new price lists and catalogues, the cost of sending these new price lists and catalogues to dealers and customers, the cost of advertising the new prices, the cost of deciding on new prices and even the cost of dealing with customer annoyance over price changes. (Of course, for some methods of selling, like Internet-based sales, the cost of price changes is relatively low, so they can change much more frequently.) Inflation increases the menu costs that firms must bear. In the current Australian economy, with its low inflation rate, annual price adjustment is an appropriate business strategy for many firms. But when high inflation makes firms’ costs rise rapidly, annual price adjustment is impractical. During hyperinflations, for example, firms must change their prices daily or even more often just to keep up with all the other prices in the economy. menu costs the costs of changing prices 265 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 11 Inflation: Its causes and costs 11_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 265 24/08/20 4:34 PM Relative-price variability and the misallocation of resources Suppose that the Eatabit Eatery prints a new menu with new prices every January and then leaves its prices unchanged for the rest of the year. If there is no inflation, Eatabit’s relative prices – the prices of its meals compared with other prices in the economy – would be constant over the course of the year. In contrast, if the inflation rate is 12 per cent per year, Eatabit’s relative prices will automatically fall by 1 per cent each month. The restaurant’s prices will be relatively high in the early months of the year, just after it has printed a new menu, and relatively low in the later months. And the higher the inflation rate, the greater this automatic variability. Thus, because prices change only once in a while, inflation causes relative prices to vary more than they otherwise would. Why does this matter? The reason is that market economies rely on relative prices to allocate scarce resources. Consumers decide what to buy by comparing the quality and prices of various goods and services. Through these decisions, they determine how the scarce factors of production are allocated among industries and firms. When inflation distorts relative prices, consumer decisions are distorted and markets are less able to allocate resources to their best uses. Inflation-induced tax distortions Almost all taxes distort incentives, cause people to alter their behaviour and lead to a less efficient allocation of the economy’s resources. Many taxes, however, become even more problematic in the presence of inflation. The reason is that lawmakers often fail to take inflation into account when writing the tax laws. Economists who have studied the tax laws conclude that inflation tends to raise the tax burden on income earned from savings. One example is the tax treatment of interest income. Income tax treats the nominal interest earned on savings as income, even though part of the nominal interest rate merely compensates for inflation. To see the effects of this policy, consider the numerical example in Table 11.1. The table compares two economies, both of which tax interest income at a rate of 25 per cent. In Economy 1, inflation is zero, and the nominal and real interest rates are both 4 per cent. In this case, the 25 per cent tax on interest income reduces the real interest rate from 4 per cent to 3 per cent. In Economy 2, the real interest rate is again 4 per cent, but the inflation rate is 8 per cent. As a result of the Fisher effect, the nominal interest rate is 12 per cent. Because the income tax treats this entire 12 per cent interest as income, the government takes 25 per cent of it, leaving an after-tax nominal interest rate of only 9 per cent and an after-tax real interest rate of only 1 per cent. In this case, the 25 per cent tax on interest income reduces the real interest rate from 4 per cent to 1 per cent. Because the aftertax real interest rate provides the incentive to save, saving is much less attractive in the economy with inflation (Economy 2) than in the economy with stable prices (Economy 1). TABLE 11.1 How inflation raises the tax burden on saving In the presence of zero inflation, a 25 per cent tax on interest income reduces the real interest rate from 4 per cent to 3 per cent. In the presence of 8 per cent inflation, the same tax reduces the real interest rate from 4 per cent to 1 per cent. Economy 1 (price stability) % Economy 2 (inflation) % Real interest rate 4 4 Inflation rate 0 8 Nominal interest rate (real interest rate + inflation rate) 4 12 Reduced interest due to 25% tax (0.25 × nominal interest rate) 1 3 After-tax nominal interest rate (0.75 × nominal interest rate) 3 9 After-tax real interest rate (after-tax nominal interest rate – inflation rate) 3 1 266 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 5 Money and pricesCopyright in the long run 11_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 266 24/08/20 4:34 PM The taxes on nominal interest income are one example of how tax laws interact with inflation. There are many others. Because of these inflation-induced tax changes, higher inflation tends to discourage people from saving. Recall that the economy’s saving provides the resources for investment, which in turn is a key ingredient of long-run economic growth. Thus, when inflation raises the tax burden on saving, it tends to depress the economy’s long-run growth rate. There is, however, no consensus among economists about the size of this effect. One solution to this problem, other than eliminating inflation, is to index the tax system. That is, the tax laws could be rewritten to take account of the effects of inflation. This is already done in the case of capital gains. A capital gain is the profit made by selling an asset for more than its purchase price. For example, if you purchased shares in XYZ Company in 1980 for $10 and then sold the same shares in 1998 for $50, you would have made a capital gain of $40. But if the overall price level had doubled between 1980 and 1998, then the increase in the value of your asset was really only $20. If the tax laws did not take into account the effects of inflation, you would pay tax on the profit of $40 instead of $20. The tax laws in Australia adjust the purchase price using a price index and assess the tax only on the real gain. In the case of interest income, the government could tax only real interest income by excluding that portion of the interest income that merely compensates for inflation. To some extent, the tax laws have moved in the direction of indexation, as demonstrated above with capital gains. However, the income levels at which marginal income tax rates change are not adjusted automatically for inflation. In an ideal world, the tax laws would be written so that inflation would not alter anyone’s real tax liability. In the world in which we live, however, tax laws are far from perfect. More complete indexation would probably be desirable, but it would further complicate tax laws that many people already consider too complex. Confusion and inconvenience Imagine that we took a poll and asked people the following question: ‘This year the metre is 100 cm. How long do you think it should be next year?’ Assuming we could get people to take us seriously, they would tell us that the metre should stay the same length – 100 cm. Anything else would just complicate life needlessly. What does this finding have to do with inflation? Recall that money, as the economy’s unit of account, is what we use to quote prices and record debts. In other words, money is the yardstick with which we measure economic transactions. The job of the RBA is a bit like the job of Standards Australia – to ensure the reliability of a commonly used unit of measurement. When inflation occurs, it erodes the real value of the unit of account. The RBA’s response, as we will see in later chapters, is to limit this erosion. It is difficult to judge the costs of the confusion and inconvenience that arise from inflation. Earlier we discussed how the tax laws incorrectly measure real incomes in the presence of inflation. Similarly, accountants incorrectly measure firms’ profits when prices are rising over time. Because inflation causes dollars at different times to have different real values, calculating a firm’s profit – the difference between its revenue and costs – is more complicated in an economy with inflation. Therefore, to some extent, unexpected inflation makes investors less able to sort out successful from unsuccessful firms, which in turn impedes financial markets in their role of allocating the economy’s saving to alternative types of investment. A special cost of unexpected inflation: Arbitrary redistributions of wealth So far, most of the costs of inflation we have discussed occur even if inflation is steady and predictable. Inflation has an additional cost, however, when it comes as a surprise. 267 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 11 Inflation: Its causes and costs 11_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 267 24/08/20 4:34 PM Unexpected inflation redistributes wealth among the population in a way that has nothing to do with either merit or need. These redistributions occur because many loans in the economy are specified in terms of the unit of account – money. Consider an example. Suppose that Sam Student takes out a $20 000 loan at a 7 per cent interest rate from Bigbank to attend university. In 10 years, the loan will come due. After his debt has compounded for 10 years at 7 per cent, Sam will owe Bigbank $40 000. The real value of this debt will depend on inflation over the decade. If Sam is lucky, the economy will have hyperinflation. In this case, wages and prices will rise so high that Sam will be able to pay the $40 000 debt out of small change. In contrast, if the economy goes through a major deflation, then wages and prices will fall and Sam will find the $40 000 debt a greater burden than he anticipated. This example shows that unexpected changes in prices redistribute wealth among debtors and creditors. Hyperinflation enriches Sam at the expense of Bigbank because it diminishes the real value of the debt; Sam can repay the loan in dollars that are less valuable than he anticipated. Deflation enriches Bigbank at Sam’s expense because it increases the real value of the debt; in this case, Sam has to repay the loan in dollars that are more valuable than he anticipated. If inflation were predictable, then Bigbank and Sam could take inflation into account when setting the nominal interest rate. (Recall the Fisher effect.) But if inflation is hard to predict, it imposes risk on Sam and Bigbank that both would prefer to avoid. This cost of unexpected inflation is important to consider together with another fact – inflation is especially volatile and uncertain when the average rate of inflation is high. This is seen most simply by examining the experience of different countries. Countries with low average inflation, like Germany in the late twentieth century, tend to have stable inflation. Countries with high average inflation, like many countries in Latin America, tend also to have unstable inflation. There are no known examples of economies with high, stable inflation. This relationship between the level and volatility of inflation points to another cost of inflation. If a country pursues a high-inflation monetary policy, it will have to bear not only the costs of high expected inflation but also the arbitrary redistributions of wealth associated with unexpected inflation. CASE STUDY The Wonderful Wizard of Oz and the free-silver debate As a child, you may have seen the film The Wizard of Oz, based on a children’s book written in 1900. The film and book tell the story of a young girl, Dorothy, who finds herself lost in a strange land far from home. You probably did not know, however, that the story is actually an allegory about US monetary policy in the late nineteenth century. From 1880 to 1896, the price level in the US economy fell by 23 per cent. Because this event was unanticipated, it led to a major redistribution of wealth. Most farmers in the western part of the country were debtors. Their creditors were the bankers in the east. When the price level fell, it caused the real value of these debts to rise, which enriched the banks at the expense of the farmers. According to populist politicians of the time, the solution to the farmers’ problem was the free coinage of silver. During this period, the United States was operating with a gold standard. The quantity of gold determined the money supply and, thereby, the price level. The free-silver advocates wanted silver, as well as gold, to be used as money. If adopted, this proposal would have increased the money supply, pushed up the price level and reduced the real burden of the farmers’ debts. The debate over silver was heated and it was central to the politics of the 1890s. A common election slogan of the populists was ‘We are mortgaged; all but our votes’. One prominent advocate of 268 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 5 Money and pricesCopyright in the long run 11_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 268 24/08/20 4:34 PM free silver was William Jennings Bryan, the Democrat nominee for president in 1896. He is remembered in part for a speech at the Democratic Party’s nominating convention in which he said: ‘You shall not press down upon the brow of labor this crown of thorns. You shall not crucify mankind upon a cross of gold’. Rarely since then have politicians waxed so poetic about alternative approaches to monetary policy. Nonetheless, Bryan lost the election to Republican William McKinley, and the United States remained on the gold standard. DOROTHY: TOTO: SCARECROW: L. Frank Baum, the author of The Wonderful Wizard of Oz, was a midwestern journalist. When he sat down to write a story for children, he made the characters represent protagonists in the major political battle of his time. Although modern commentators on the story differ somewhat in the interpretation they assign to each character, there is no doubt that the story highlights the debate over monetary policy. Here is how economic historian Hugh Rockoff, writing in the August 1990 issue of the Journal of Political Economy, interprets the story: Traditional American values Prohibitionist party, also called the Teetotallers Farmers TIN WOODSMAN: Industrial workers COWARDLY LION: William Jennings Bryan [Democrat nominee for president in 1896] MUNCHKINS: Citizens of the east WICKED WITCH OF THE EAST: Grover Cleveland [Democrat president 1893–97] WICKED WITCH OF THE WEST: William McKinley [Republican president 1897–1901] WIZARD: Marcus Alonzo Hanna [chairman of the Republican party at the time] OZ: Abbreviation for ounce of gold Source: Alamy Stock Photo/World History Archive YELLOW BRICK ROAD: Gold standard An early debate over monetary policy In the end of Baum’s story, Dorothy does find her way home, but it is not by just following the yellow brick road. After a long and perilous journey, she learns that the wizard is incapable of helping her or her friends. Instead, Dorothy finally discovers the magical power of her silver slippers. (When the book was made into the film The Wizard of Oz, in 1939, Dorothy’s slippers were changed from silver to ruby. Apparently, the Hollywood filmmakers were not aware that they were telling a story about nineteenth-century monetary policy.) Although the populists lost the debate over the free coinage of silver, they did eventually get the monetary expansion and inflation that they wanted. In 1898, 269 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 11 Inflation: Its causes and costs 11_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 269 24/08/20 4:34 PM prospectors discovered gold near the Klondike River in Alaska. Increased supplies of gold also arrived from the Canadian Yukon and the gold mines of South Africa. As a result, the money supply and the price level started to rise in the United States and other countries operating on the gold standard. Within 15 years, prices in the United States were back to the levels that had prevailed in the 1880s, and farmers were better able to handle their debts. IN THE NEWS Questions 1 How did the unexpected fall in the price level cause a redistribution of wealth during the 1880s? 2 What factors in the early twentieth century led to the price level being restored to the prices prevailing in the 1880s? How did this affect the supply of money? If inflation is bad, then deflation must be good … right? This chapter has discussed the causes and impact of inflation, but sometimes economies experience deflation. Given everything we’ve said about inflation being a concern, deflation must be good, right? Well, not exactly. Deflation means an economy is experiencing a lack of demand and as we will see in chapter 14 that’s not necessarily better than having inflation. And when deflation persists for long periods, it can have negative effects on consumer confidence as well, as the following article discusses. Forget inflation. We should be concerned about deflation By Robert J. Samuelson May 1, 2019 There are times when it seems we’re worrying about things that aren’t worth worrying about. A good example these days is inflation. Amazingly, the complaint is that it’s not rising fast enough. In March, the consumer price index, or CPI, had increased 1.9 percent over the past year. The gain of another inflation indicator, the ‘deflator’ of the personal consumption expenditures, or PCE, was 1.5 percent. What’s not to like? Despite criticism from President Trump, all this qualifies as good news. Prices have hardly risen. Indeed, technical difficulties in measuring inflation — for example, how to account for new products, such as smartphones — suggest that actual inflation could be close to zero. Some prices go up (new vehicles, 0.7 percent over the past year); other prices go down (televisions, 19 percent). The PCE is the Federal Reserve’s preferred inflation indicator. For workers, this means that if their wages and fringe benefits rose by more than 1.5 percent over the year, they would’ve received a modest boost to their ‘real’ (inflationadjusted) incomes. And yet, some respected economists worry that inflation is too low. To those of us, including me, old enough to have lived through the double-digit inflation of late 1970s and early 1980s, this is crazy. High and uncontrolled inflation (annually, it peaked at 13 percent in 1979) was a scourge. It sowed almost-universal anxiety and was wildly unpopular. People felt they had lost control of their lives. Government seemed powerless to stop it. Why would anyone want to re-create this anarchy? Three reasons are typically given. For starters, critics complain that the Fed isn’t hitting its own inflation target, which is 2 percent on the PCE. This suggests incompetence. If the Fed can’t hit its target, the assumption goes, what else can’t it do? Frankly, this is fearmongering; the Fed simply isn’t powerful enough to 270 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 5 Money and pricesCopyright in the long run 11_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 270 24/08/20 4:34 PM hit a precise target. As long as reported inflation stays between zero and 2 percent, the Fed is delivering a crude price stability. A more realistic concern involves the Fed’s ability to respond to a recession. Typically, the Fed cuts interest rates to reverse an economic downturn. But interest rates, reflecting inflation, are already low. The fear is that the Fed won’t be able to cut rates enough to prevent a recession from getting worse. Consider. The fed funds rate — the rate on overnight loans and the rate most influenced by the Fed — is now set at about 2.5 percent. By contrast, it was 5.25 percent in 2007, the start of the last recession, and higher earlier. If the Fed can only cut rates modestly before they hit zero, then the next recession could be lengthy and stubborn. That’s the argument. This brings us to the most serious of inflation’s alleged shortcomings. Paradoxically, it’s ‘deflation’ — or falling prices. Of course, some prices are falling even when the overall price level is rising. To take an obvious example: Computers and other tech products have experienced massive price cuts. No one is against these. By contrast, deflation signifies declines in most prices, and this prospect can do enormous economic damage. The most terrifying example is the Great Depression of the 1930s, when the wholesale price index fell a staggering 33 percent from 1929 to 1933. The result was to prolong the Depression. Deflation causes people to delay major purchases — they think that prices will go even lower. Deflation also makes it harder for debtors to repay their loans. The economy gets caught in a vicious circle of deflation, weak consumer spending and more loan defaults. In the 1930s, annual unemployment peaked at around 25 percent. Higher inflation is cast as the antidote to deflation. It’s an extra cushion of protection. This sounds sensible, but it overlooks the likely reality that the transition to higher inflation would create a new set of problems, involving interest rates, exchange rates, consumer and business uncertainty and the stock market, to name just a few. Moreover, it presumes that deflation would quickly attain Depression-like proportions, when a more likely outcome would be modest deflation. Probably many Americans wouldn’t notice slight price declines; others might seize on them as an opportunity to go bargainhunting. Indeed, the combination of rigid wages and falling prices would enhance consumer purchasing power and could stimulate an economic recovery. We have a case study in the probabilities: Japan. It’s been grappling with deflation for years, but price declines have been puny. From 2001 to 2010, the average annual decline was 0.3 percent (that’s one-third of 1 percent), says the International Monetary Fund. Millions of Americans are unaware of our disastrous experience with doubledigit inflation. They have either forgotten or weren’t yet born. The Fed says it won’t abandon its current inflation target of 2 percent. That’s a promise the Fed needs to keep. Source: Reproduced by permission of the Washington Post. Robert J. Samuelson, May 1, 2019 https:// www.washingtonpost.com/opinions/do-we-have-adeflation-problem/2019/05/01/8541daac-6c41-11e98f44-e8d8bb1df986_story.html?noredirect=on CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING Briefly describe the six costs of inflation. 271 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 11 Inflation: Its causes and costs 11_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 271 24/08/20 4:34 PM Conclusion This chapter discussed the causes and costs of inflation. The main cause of inflation is simply growth in the quantity of money. When a central bank creates money in large quantities, the value of money falls quickly over time. To maintain stable prices, the central bank must maintain strict control over interest rates or the money supply. The costs of inflation are more subtle. They include shoeleather costs, menu costs, increased variability of relative prices, unintended changes in tax liabilities, confusion and inconvenience, and arbitrary redistributions of wealth. Are these costs, in total, large or small? All economists agree that they become huge during hyperinflation. But their size for moderate inflation – when prices rise by less than 10 per cent per year – is more open to debate. Although this chapter presented many of the most important lessons about inflation, the discussion is incomplete. When a central bank reduces the rate of money growth, prices rise less rapidly, as the quantity theory suggests. Yet as the economy makes the transition to this lower inflation rate, the change in monetary policy will have disruptive effects on production and employment. That is, even though monetary policy is neutral in the long run, it has profound effects on real variables in the short run. Later in this book we will examine the reasons for short-run monetary non-neutrality in order to enhance our understanding of the causes and costs of inflation. 272 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 5 Money and pricesCopyright in the long run 11_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 272 24/08/20 4:34 PM LO11.1 If a central bank increases the supply of money, it causes the price level to rise. Persistent growth in the quantity of money supplied leads to continuing inflation. The principle of monetary neutrality asserts that changes in the quantity of money influence nominal variables but not real variables. Most economists believe that monetary neutrality approximately describes the behaviour of the economy in the long run. One application of the principle of monetary neutrality is the Fisher effect. According to the Fisher effect, when the inflation rate rises, the nominal interest rate rises by the same amount, so that the real interest rate remains the same. A government can pay for some of its spending simply by printing money. When countries rely heavily on this ‘inflation tax’, the result is hyperinflation. Many people think that inflation makes them poorer because it raises the cost of what they buy. This view is a fallacy, however, because inflation also raises nominal incomes. LO11.2 Economists have identified six costs of inflation: shoeleather costs associated with reduced money holdings; menu costs associated with more frequent adjustment of prices; increased variability of relative prices; unintended changes in tax liabilities due to non-indexation of the tax laws; confusion and inconvenience resulting from a changing unit of account; and arbitrary redistributions of wealth between debtors and creditors. Many of these costs are large during hyperinflation, but the size of these costs for moderate inflation is less clear. Key concepts classical dichotomy, p. 256 Fisher effect, p. 262 inflation tax, p. 259 menu costs, p. 265 monetary neutrality, p. 257 nominal variables, p. 256 STUDY TOOLS Summary quantity equation, p. 258 quantity theory of money, p. 254 real variables, p. 256 shoeleather costs, p. 264 velocity of money, p. 257 Practice questions Questions for review 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 Explain how an increase in the price level affects the real value of money. According to the quantity theory of money, what is the effect of a decrease in the quantity of money? What happens if a central bank increases the money supply rapidly? What is the difference between nominal and real interest rates? Suppose the nominal interest rate is 8 per cent and the real interest rate is 3.5 per cent. What is the inflation rate? The quantity equation is given by M × V = P × Y. Solve this equation for Y and explain in words: What happens to Y if the numerator rises faster than the denominator, and vice-versa? In what sense is inflation like a tax? How does thinking about inflation as a tax help explain hyperinflation? According to the Fisher effect, how does an increase in the inflation rate affect the real interest rate and the nominal interest rate? What are the costs of inflation? Which of these costs do you think are most important for the Australian economy? If inflation is greater than expected, who benefits – debtors or creditors? Explain. Multiple choice 1 A fall in inflation a hurts retirees. b benefits lenders. c benefits borrowers. d makes wage increases more likely. 273 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 11 Inflation: Its causes and costs 11_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 273 24/08/20 4:34 PM 2 3 4 5 6 A new form of payment, like Apple Pay, does what to the velocity of money? a It decreases it because people need less cash. b It increases it because people buy more because they don’t realise they are spending money. c It decreases it because people don’t need as much cash when they travel overseas. d It increases it because each note or coin supports more transactions. If the interest rate is 6% and the inflation rate is –1%, then the real interest rate is a 5%. b 7%. c –1%. d 6%. If the Australian government keeps the income tax brackets the same from year to year, but the inflation rate rises, are people being taxed a more in real terms. b less in real terms. c about the same in real terms. d less in nominal terms. Suppose the Australian government is worried about money laundering, and so they decide to take $100 out of circulation. What would have to happen to velocity to handle the same level of nominal income? a It would have to increase. b It would have to decrease. c It would stay the same. d It wouldn’t have any bearing on the velocity of money. Individuals who take out mortgages with fixed rates of interest will most likely a suffer a loss if the inflation rate is higher than anticipated. b benefit if the inflation rate is lower than anticipated. c experience a rise in their real interest rate. d benefit if the inflation rate is higher than anticipated. Problems and applications 1 2 3 4 5 6 Central banks around the world, including the United States’ Federal Reserve Bank, do not have inflation targeting as a monetary policy objective. Can you build a case for why the US Fed could switch to inflation targeting? The previous chapter showed that there are several different measures of the money stock, with the larger measures including more types of assets than the smaller ones. How can the quantity equation hold for all of these measures? The economist John Maynard Keynes wrote: ‘Lenin is said to have declared that the best way to destroy the capitalist system was to debauch the currency. By a continuing process of inflation, governments can confiscate, secretly and unobserved, an important part of the wealth of their citizens’. Justify Lenin’s assertion. Suppose that a country’s inflation rate increases sharply. What happens to the inflation tax on the holders of money? Why is wealth that is held in savings accounts not subject to a change in the inflation tax? Can you think of any way in which holders of savings accounts are hurt by the increase in the inflation rate? In the lead-up to the last federal election, some political parties made the case for increased direction of RBA monetary policy by the government of the day so that monetary policy and fiscal policy were better coordinated. Do you agree or not? If you were writing a policy paper for your political party, which would you argue for – independence of the RBA or direction of monetary policy by the government? Be sure to explain your conclusions thoroughly – the leader of your party wants to make a credible case to the public. Suppose that Nick is a potato farmer and Aneta is a carrot farmer. Nick and Aneta are the only people in the economy and both always consume equal amounts of potatoes and carrots. In 2014 the price of potatoes was $5 and the price of carrots was $3. a Suppose that in 2015 the price of potatoes was $6 and the price of carrots was $7.50. What was inflation? Was Nick better off, worse off, or unaffected by the changes in prices? What about Aneta? 274 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 5 Money and pricesCopyright in the long run 11_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 274 24/08/20 4:34 PM b Now suppose that in 2015 the price of potatoes was $6 and the price of carrots stayed at $3. What was inflation? Was Nick better off, worse off, or unaffected by the changes in prices? What about Aneta? c Finally, suppose that in 2015 the price of potatoes was $4 and the price of carrots was $2.50. What was inflation? Was Nick better off, worse off, or unaffected by the changes in prices? What about Aneta? 7 Most companies no longer produce ‘books’ of prices, but have put all of their prices on computer. (Think of companies that produce a wide range of products in different specifications, like a steel company that produces steel pipes and tubes in a large variety of lengths, diameters and thicknesses.) How does this computerisation affect menu costs? Does computerisation of price lists make firms more or less likely to respond to changes in input prices by changes in their prices? How has this affected inflation? 8 If you lived in an economy which experienced rising inflation over the years, would you hold your wealth in cash or gold or buy some other asset, like paintings? Explain. 9 Suppose that Lauren is a savvy investor and expects inflation to equal 7 per cent in 2020, but, in fact, prices rise by only 4 per cent. How would this unexpectedly low inflation rate affect her in the following circumstances? a The federal government cuts income tax. b She has a fixed-rate mortgage home loan. c She is a casual worker with no labour contract in place. d She has invested in Treasury bonds. 10 Explain one harm associated with unexpected inflation that is not associated with expected inflation. Then explain one harm associated with both expected and unexpected inflation. 11 Explain whether the following statements are true, false, or uncertain. a ‘Inflation hurts borrowers and helps lenders, because borrowers must pay a higher rate of interest.’ b ‘If prices change in a way that leaves the overall price level unchanged, then no one is made better or worse off.’ c ‘Inflation does not reduce the purchasing power of most workers.’ 275 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 11 Inflation: Its causes and costs 11_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 275 24/08/20 4:34 PM PART SIX Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 12_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 276 24/08/20 4:35 PM The macroeconomics of open economies Chapter 12 Open-economy macroeconomics: Basic concepts Chapter 13 A macroeconomic theory of the open economy Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 12_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 277 24/08/20 4:35 PM 12 Open-economy macroeconomics: Basic concepts Learning objectives After reading this chapter, you should be able to: LO12.1define net exports and net foreign investments, and explain how they measure the international flow of goods and capital LO12.2 explain the meaning of the nominal exchange rate and the real exchange rate LO12.3 examine purchasing-power parity as a theory of how exchange rates are determined. 278 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 12_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 278 24/08/20 4:35 PM Introduction When you graduate from university and decide to buy a car, you may compare the latest models offered by Ford and Hyundai. When you take your next holiday, you may consider spending it on a beach in Queensland or in Tahiti. When you get a job and begin to save for your retirement, you may choose between a managed fund that buys shares in Australian companies and one that buys shares in foreign companies. In all of these cases, you will be participating not just in the Australian economy but in economies around the world. There are clear benefits to an economy that is open to international trade – trade allows people to produce what they produce best and to consume the great variety of goods and services produced around the world. Indeed, one of the Ten Principles of Economics highlighted in chapter 1 is that trade can make everyone better off. Chapter 3 examined the gains from trade more fully – that international trade can raise living standards in all countries by allowing each country to specialise in producing those goods and services in which it has a comparative advantage. So far, our development of macroeconomics has largely ignored the economy’s interaction with other economies around the world. For some economies, like that of the United States, many questions in macroeconomics can be discussed without considering international issues. However, for some economies, like the Australian economy, the effects of international trade are very important. We ignored the effects of international trade when we discussed topics like the natural rate of unemployment and the causes of inflation to keep our exposition simple and focused. Indeed, to keep their analysis simple, macroeconomists often assume a closed economy – an economy that does not interact with other economies. To build a complete picture of the economy, though, we need to examine an open economy – an economy that interacts freely with other economies around the world. This chapter and the next one, therefore, provide an introduction to open-economy macroeconomics. We begin in this chapter by discussing the key macroeconomic variables that describe an open economy’s interactions in world markets. You may have noticed mention of the variables exports, imports, the trade balance and exchange rates in newspapers or news bulletins. Our first job is to understand what these data mean. In the next chapter we develop a model to explain how these variables are determined and how they are affected by various government policies. closed economy an economy that does not interact with other economies in the world open economy an economy that interacts freely with other economies around the world LO12.1 The international flows of goods and capital An open economy interacts with other economies in two ways – it buys and sells goods and services in world product markets, and it buys and sells financial assets in world financial markets. Here we discuss these two activities and the close relationship between them. The flow of goods: Exports, imports and net exports As noted in chapter 3, exports are domestically produced goods and services that are sold abroad, and imports are foreign-produced goods and services that are sold domestically. When Airbus, the European aircraft manufacturer, builds a plane and sells it to Qantas, the sale is an export for France and an import for Australia. When Arnott’s in Australia makes Tim Tams and sells them to a US resident, the sale is an import for the United States and an export for Australia. The net exports of any country are the value of its exports minus the value of its imports. The Tim Tams sale raises Australian net exports and the Airbus purchase reduces Australian net exports. Because net exports tell us whether a country is, in total, a seller or a buyer in 279 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 12 Open-economy macroeconomics: Basic concepts 12_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 279 24/08/20 4:35 PM trade balance (net exports) spending on domestically produced goods by foreigners (exports) minus spending on foreign goods by domestic residents (imports) trade surplus an excess of exports over imports trade deficit an excess of imports over exports Fairfax Syndication/Matt Golding balanced trade a situation in which exports equal imports world markets for goods and services, net exports are also called the trade balance. If net exports are positive, exports are greater than imports, indicating that the country sells more goods and services abroad than it buys from other countries. In this case, the country is said to run a trade surplus. If net exports are negative, exports are less than imports, indicating that the country sells fewer goods and services abroad than it buys from other countries. In this case, the country is said to run a trade deficit. If net exports are zero, its exports and imports are exactly equal, and the country is said to have balanced trade. In the next chapter, we develop a theory that explains an economy’s trade balance, but even at this early stage it is easy to think of many factors that might influence a country’s exports, imports and net exports. Those factors include: • the tastes of consumers for domestic and foreign goods • the prices of goods at home and abroad • the rates at which people can exchange domestic currency for foreign currencies • the cost of transporting goods from country to country • the policies of the government towards international trade. As these variables change over time, so does the amount of international trade. CASE STUDY The importance of trade in the Australian economy International trade has always been a significant part of the Australian economy. Figure 12.1 shows the total value of goods and services exported to other countries and imported from other countries expressed as a percentage of gross domestic product. In the early 1950s, exports of goods and services averaged around 20 per cent of GDP. In the mid-1950s, they levelled off to around 13 per cent and stayed around that level until the mid-1990s, when they began to rise. Imports of goods and services have followed a similar pattern. After the Second World War, the fledgling Australian economy began to develop a manufacturing base, so more goods were produced in the domestic economy for domestic production. But trade has remained an important part of the national economy. Because Australia is a small economy, it has always relied on goods produced overseas for both investment and consumption. Many of the goods that Australians need to produce other goods or that Australians like to consume are not produced in the domestic economy. So we import these goods. Since Australia is physically a large country, well endowed with natural resources, for 280 Copyright 2021economies Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 6 The macroeconomics of open 12_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 280 24/08/20 4:35 PM FIGURE 12.1 The openness of the Australian economy 30.0 Exports % GDP Imports % GDP 25.0 % of GDP 20.0 15.0 10.0 5.0 0.0 Mar-1960 Dec-1973 Aug-1987 Apr-2001 Dec-2014 This figure shows exports and imports of the Australian economy as a percentage of Australian gross domestic product since 1960. Trade has always been important to the Australian economy, and has become even more so in recent times. Source: Reserve Bank of Australia years our most important exports have been minerals and primary products, particularly wool, hence the expression ‘riding on the sheep’s back’. Even though trade has always been important for Australia, trade has increased in importance globally. This increase in international trade is partly due to improvements in transportation. In 1950, the average merchant ship carried less than 10 000 tonnes of cargo; today, many ships carry more than 100 000 tonnes. The long-distance jet was introduced in 1958 and the wide-bodied jet in 1967, making air transport far cheaper. Because of these developments, goods that once had to be produced and consumed locally can now be traded around the world. Cut flowers, for instance, are now grown in Israel and flown to the United States to be sold. Fresh fruits and vegetables that can grow only in summer can now be eaten by consumers in the Northern Hemisphere in winter as well, because they can be shipped from countries in the Southern Hemisphere, like Australia. The increase in international trade has also been influenced by advances in telecommunications, which have allowed businesses to reach overseas customers more easily. Australia’s first intercontinental telephone connection was created in 1902 when a submarine cable was laid across the Pacific, linking Australia with Canada. The first transatlantic telephone cable was not laid until 1956, though. As recently as 1966, the technology allowed only 138 simultaneous conversations between North America and Europe. Today, communications satellites permit more than 1 million conversations to occur at the same time. 281 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 12 Open-economy macroeconomics: Basic concepts 12_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 281 24/08/20 4:35 PM Technological progress has also fostered international trade by changing the kinds of goods that economies produce. When bulky raw materials (like steel) and perishable goods (like wheat) were a large part of the world’s output, transporting goods was often costly and sometimes impossible. In contrast, goods produced with modern technology are often light and easy to transport. Consumer electronics, for instance, have low weight for every dollar of value, which makes them easy to produce in one country and sell in another. A more extreme example is the film industry. Once Fox Studios in Sydney makes a film, it can send copies of the film around the world at almost zero cost. Indeed, films are an export of many countries including Australia, the United States and India. The government’s trade policies have also been a factor in increasing international trade. As discussed in chapter 3, economists have long believed that free trade between countries is mutually beneficial. Over time, policymakers around the world have come to accept these conclusions. International agreements, like the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) and the General Agreement on Tariffs Questions 1 After the Second World War, what factor(s) contributed to increased international trade globally? How did these factor(s) change the composition of international trade? Explain. IN THE NEWS and Trade (GATT), now governed by the World Trade Organization (WTO), have gradually lowered trade barriers, like tariffs and import quotas. Australia is a leader both in lowering trade barriers and in encouraging other countries to do likewise. In fact, since 2000, Australia has signed free trade agreements with China, Japan, Korea, Malaysia, Chile, Thailand, Singapore and the USA. In 2016, the Trans Pacific Partnership (TPP) was signed, but ultimately never ratified as the United States pulled out of the agreement in 2017. This agreement would reduce trade barriers between Australia, Brunei, Canada, Chile, Japan, Malaysia, Mexico, Peru, New Zealand, Singapore, the United States and Vietnam. However, a new agreement was signed in 2018 by all countries, except the United States, and it was renamed the Comprehensive and Progressive Agreement for Trans-Pacific Partnership (CPTPP). As trade has always been a significant part of Australia’s economy, political parties of all stripes are concerned about what appears to be a shift towards protectionist policies in the USA as well as in the UK, with the UK exiting from the European Union (known as Brexit). 2 Economists believe that free trade agreements (FTAs) are mutually beneficial for the global economy. Provide examples of FTAs and briefly explain them. Can you think of arguments against FTAs? Australia’s trade balance – good news, but not on every front Australia continues to benefit from China’s demand for minerals to fuel their growing economy. And when countries like Brazil can’t export as much iron ore, Australia benefits again. Our imports have also gone down, contributing to the trade surplus, but this is not necessarily a good thing. It may mean people are lacking confidence in the economy, and as a result, are spending less and firms are buying less (imported) capital equipment. With a looming trade war between China and the US, Australia’s economic prospects are uncertain, so let’s enjoy the surplus while we can. 282 Copyright 2021economies Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 6 The macroeconomics of open 12_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 282 24/08/20 4:35 PM Trade surplus record papers over Australia’s worrying domestic economic trends Source: Getty Images/Ron D҆Raine/Bloomberg By Michael Janda 6 August 2019 A 5 per cent increase in metal ore sales was the biggest contributor to the rising exports. Australia has posted its biggest trade surplus on record and is on track to post its first current account surplus since Gough Whitlam was prime minister. In June, Australia sold $8 billion more goods and services to the rest of the world than it imported. That is a whopping $1.8 billion higher than the previous month, which was itself a record trade surplus. Over the quarter, the trade surplus widened to just under $20 billion, more than $5 billion above the March quarter, and over the year Australia accumulated surpluses totalling almost $50 billion. As Westpac economist Andrew Hanlan pointed out, the March quarter current account deficit was only $2.9 billion — the lowest in many years — meaning there is a very good chance Australia will post its first current account surplus since the June quarter of 1975, when the June quarter figures come out in a few weeks. A current account surplus basically means the nation is earning more from overseas than it is paying out. But, even if it eventuates, Australia’s stay in the black as against the rest of the world looks set to be fleeting. ‘Given the terms of trade has only limited upside from here and the income account remains in structural deficit, our expectation is for the current account to return to deficit in the medium term,’ JP Morgan’s Tom Kennedy warned. Although, in the short term, the record trade surplus is likely to stave off any risk that Australia’s economy shrank in the June quarter, with analysts agreeing it will contribute more to GDP than they had previously expected. Iron and coal boost exports There are no prizes for guessing how Australia is posting record trade surpluses, with surging iron ore prices and shipments of LNG contributing much of the improvement so far this year. Again in June, iron ore and other mineral exports rose 5 per cent, adding a further $554 million to the positive trade balance. 283 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 12 Open-economy macroeconomics: Basic concepts 12_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 283 24/08/20 4:35 PM While iron ore prices have slumped more than 20 per cent in recent weeks, they were higher than June levels for most of July, meaning there is a chance of an even bigger contribution to the next set of trade figures before this effect eases off. The other big export contributors to the improvement that month were coal (up by 4 per cent, or $232 million) and metals (excluding gold, up 21 per cent, adding $230 million). The biggest fall in exports was in rural goods, which dropped 4 per cent, led by a 36 per cent ($207 million) slump in grains, due to the drought conditions persisting across much of the country. As Citi’s economists noted, this export growth has come despite a trade war raging between China and the US. ‘The record run of Australian trade surpluses has occurred despite Australia’s largest export partner and most important strategic partner engaging in a trade war,’ Citi’s Josh Williamson said. ‘Australia is also exporting more to both nations. In original terms, exports to China increased by 5.9 per cent month-onmonth and 35 per cent year-on-year, while exports to the US increased by 9.9 per cent and 15 per cent, respectively.’ JP Morgan believes the trade war has actually boosted Australia’s export performance, with this the 18th consecutive monthly trade surplus. ‘Since the first round of tariffs was implemented in March 2018 Australia’s external sector has strengthened,’ Mr Kennedy said. ‘With local government infrastructure likely to be an important part of any further stimulus offset, we retain the view that the US–China trade conflict will have only a limited impact on the external sector.’ Concerning import fall However, while a 1.4 per cent rise in exports overall boosted the surplus, a 3.6 per cent slump in imports contributed more than twice as much to the improvement in the trade balance. On the one hand, the decline in imports may be a sign that the lower dollar is causing people to buy Australian. The other more concerning, and more likely, explanation is that the import slump simply reflects the fact that Australians are cutting back on spending in general. That is reflected in a 5 per cent drop in consumption good imports, which boosted the trade surplus by $450 million. According to the Bureau of Statistics, more than half of this decline in imports was due to ‘non-industrial transport equipment’ — cars and bikes — which fell 13 per cent, or $260 million. This is further confirmation of a very weak trend in new car sales that has persisted for many months. It is terrible news for car dealers, but not necessarily so bad for the economy now that all the nation’s cars are imported. Much more concerning was a 9 per cent ($600 million) slump in capital goods imports. This is the machinery and equipment that firms import to assist in their businesses and a fall in this category can signal weakness in investment and expansion, ultimately meaning lower economic and employment growth. The good news in the June figures was that the very volatile (because each one is so expensive) civil aircraft sector fell 46 per cent, accounting for $307 million of the drop, with industrial transport equipment accounting for most of the rest ($213 million). The volatile nature of some of these factors also means it is possible that June 2019 was as good as Australia’s trade surplus gets for quite a while, but while it lasts it is a welcome fillip for an economy that is generally otherwise spluttering. Source: Reproduced by permission of the Australian Broadcasting Corporation – Library Sales Michael Janda © 2019 ABC https://www.abc.net.au/news/ 2019-08-06/trade-surplus-record-masks-grimeconomic-trends/11387872 284 Copyright 2021economies Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 6 The macroeconomics of open 12_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 284 24/08/20 4:35 PM The flow of financial resources: Net foreign investment So far we have been discussing how residents of an open economy participate in world markets for goods and services. In addition, residents of an open economy participate in world financial markets. An Australian resident with $20 000 could use that money to buy a car from Hyundai, but she could instead use that money to buy shares in the Hyundai corporation. The first transaction would represent a flow of goods, whereas the second would represent a flow of capital. The term net foreign investment (sometimes referred to as net capital outflow) refers to the purchase of foreign assets by domestic residents minus the purchase of domestic assets by foreigners. When an Australian resident buys shares in British Telecom, the British phone company, the purchase raises Australian net foreign investment. When a Japanese resident buys a bond issued by the Australian government, the purchase reduces Australian net foreign investment. Recall that foreign investment takes two forms. When the Australian Pie Company opens up a bakery in Moscow, that is an example of foreign direct investment. Alternatively, if an Australian buys shares in a Russian corporation, that is an example of foreign portfolio investment. In the first case, the Australian owner is actively managing the investment, whereas in the second case the Australian owner has a more passive role. So the distinction is the degree of control. In both cases, Australian residents are buying assets located in another country, so both purchases increase Australian net foreign investment. We develop a theory to explain net foreign investment in the next chapter. Here, let’s consider briefly some of the more important variables that influence net foreign investment: • the real interest rates being paid on foreign assets • the real interest rates being paid on domestic assets • the perceived economic and political risks of holding assets abroad • the government policies that affect foreign ownership of domestic assets. For example, consider Australian investors deciding whether to buy Japanese government bonds or Australian government bonds. (Recall that a bond is, in effect, an IOU of the issuer.) To make this decision, Australian investors compare the real interest rates offered on the two bonds. The higher a bond’s real interest rate, the more attractive it is. While making this comparison, however, Australian investors must also take into account the risk that one of these governments might default on its debt (that is, not pay interest or principal when it is due), as well as any restrictions that the Japanese government has imposed, or might impose in the future, on foreign investors in Japan. Globalisation of the food supply chain can lead to much benefit … but we should be aware of the costs as well The next time you’re enjoying that chocolate bar while you study or having a hot chocolate on a cold winter’s night, think of where that chocolate came from. The cocoa it’s made from might well have been harvested by child labour. Despite global companies like Mars, Nestlé and Hershey pledging to stop using cocoa from child labour, there is evidence they are still doing so. The following article is extracted from an investigative report done by The Washington Post. To read the rest of the article, and find out in detail what the major companies are doing to combat this issue, go to: https://www. washingtonpost.com/graphics/2019/business/hershey-nestle-mars-chocolatechild-labor-west-africa/ net foreign investment the purchase of foreign assets by domestic residents minus the purchase of domestic assets by foreigners IN THE NEWS 285 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 12 Open-economy macroeconomics: Basic concepts 12_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 285 24/08/20 4:35 PM Cocoa’s child laborers By Peter Whoriskey and Rachel Siegel June 5, 2019 GUIGLO, Ivory Coast — Five boys are swinging machetes on a cocoa farm, slowly advancing against a wall of brush. Their expressions are deadpan, almost vacant, and they rarely talk. The only sounds in the still air are the whoosh of blades slicing through tall grass and metallic pings when they hit something harder. Each of the boys crossed the border months or years ago from the impoverished West African nation of Burkina Faso, taking a bus away from home and parents to Ivory Coast, where hundreds of thousands of small farms have been carved out of the forest. These farms form the world’s most important source of cocoa and are the setting for an epidemic of child labor that the world’s largest chocolate companies promised to eradicate nearly 20 years ago. ‘How old are you?’ a Washington Post reporter asks one of the older-looking boys. ‘Nineteen,’ Abou Traore says in a hushed voice. Under Ivory Coast’s labor laws, that would make him legal. But as he talks, he casts nervous glances at the farmer who is overseeing his work from several steps away. When the farmer is distracted, Abou crouches and with his finger, writes a different answer in the gray sand: 15. Then, to make sure he is understood, he also flashes 15 with his hands. He says, eventually, that he’s been working the cocoa farms in Ivory Coast since he was 10. The other four boys say they are young, too — one says he is 15, two are 14 and another, 13. Abou says his back hurts, and he’s hungry. ‘I came here to go to school,’ Abou says. ‘I haven’t been to school for five years now.’ The world’s chocolate companies have missed deadlines to uproot child labor from their cocoa supply chains in 2005, 2008 and 2010. Next year, they face another target date and, industry officials indicate, they probably will miss that, too. As a result, the odds are substantial that a chocolate bar bought in the United States is the product of child labor. About two-thirds of the world’s cocoa supply comes from West Africa where, according to a 2015 U.S. Labor Department report, more than 2 million children were engaged in dangerous labor in cocoagrowing regions. When asked this spring, representatives of some of the biggest and best-known brands — Hershey, Mars and Nestlé — could not guarantee that any of their chocolates were produced without child labor. ‘I’m not going to make those claims,’ an executive at one of the large chocolate companies said. 286 Copyright 2021economies Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 6 The macroeconomics of open 12_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 286 24/08/20 4:35 PM One reason is that nearly 20 years after pledging to eradicate child labor, chocolate companies still cannot identify the farms where all their cocoa comes from, let alone whether child labor was used in producing it. Mars, maker of M&M’s and Milky Way, can trace only 24 percent of its cocoa back to farms; Hershey, the maker of Kisses and Reese’s, less than half; Nestlé can trace 49 percent of its global cocoa supply to farms. To succeed, the companies would have to overcome the powerful economic forces that draw children into hard labor in one of the world’s poorest places. And they would have to develop a certification system to assure consumers that a bag of M&M’s or a Reese’s Peanut Butter Cup did not originate with the swinging of a machete by a boy like Abou. In all, the industry, which collects an estimated $103 billion in sales annually, has spent more than $150 million over 18 years to address the issue. But when the businesses initially made the promise to eradicate child labor, according to industry insiders and documents, the companies had little idea of how to do so. Their subsequent efforts have been stalled by indecision and insufficient financial commitment, according to industry critics. Their most prominent effort — buying cocoa that has been ‘certified’ for ethical business practices by third-party groups such as Fairtrade and Rainforest Alliance, has been weakened by a lack of rigorous enforcement of child labor rules. Typically, the third-party inspectors are required to visit fewer than 10 percent of cocoa farms. ‘The companies have always done just enough so that if there were any media attention, they could say, “Hey guys, this is what we’re doing”,’ said Antonie Fountain, managing director of the Voice Network, an umbrella group seeking to end child labor in the cocoa industry. ‘It’s always been too little, too late. It still is.’ Source: Reproduced by permission of the Washington Post. Peter Whoriskey and Rachel Siegel, June 5, 2019 https://www.washingtonpost.com/graphics/2019/ business/hershey-nestle-mars-chocolate-child-laborwest-africa/ The equality of the current account and the capital and financial accounts We have seen that an open economy interacts with the rest of the world in two ways – in world markets for goods and services and in world financial markets. The current account and the capital and financial accounts (usually considered together) each measure a type of imbalance in these markets. The current account measures an imbalance between a country’s exports and its imports of goods and services – its net exports (NX) – as well as the flow of income and current transfers. Income and current transfers are important to the Australian economy because many Australians own property overseas or earn income from overseas companies and many foreigners own property in Australia or earn income from Australian companies. The net flow of income to and from Australia is referred to as net income (NY). Current transfers include items like Australian aid to other countries (like food aid provided to the victims of the 2013 cyclone in the Philippines) or pensions paid to foreign citizens now resident in Australia. We call the net flow of transfers net transfers (NT). We can now write our current account balance (CAB) as: CAB = NX + NY + NT The capital and financial accounts measure an imbalance between the amount of foreign assets bought by domestic residents and the amount of domestic assets bought by foreigners. Following international convention, Australia separates this into capital transfers (which happen when Australia gives aid to another country to build a bridge) and financial transactions that represent a transfer of ownership of Australia’s assets between Australians and foreigners. (You might have noticed a similarity between current transfers and consumption expenditure in GDP – both are for current consumption and not for longer term investments. Just as investment in GDP is a measure of how much of national income is used to build things that help us produce more in the future, so are capital transfers – they represent Australia’s contribution to investment in other countries.) To simplify our 287 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 12 Open-economy macroeconomics: Basic concepts 12_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 287 24/08/20 4:35 PM analysis, we will combine the capital and financial accounts together and refer to them as net foreign investment. An important but subtle fact of accounting states that, for an economy as a whole, these two imbalances must offset each other. That is, net foreign investment (NFI) always equals the current account balance (CAB): NFI = CAB This equation holds because every transaction that affects one side of this equation must also affect the other side by exactly the same amount. This equation is an identity – an equation that must hold by the way the variables in the equation are defined and measured. To see why this accounting identity is true, consider an example. Suppose that Fisher & Paykel, the New Zealand whitegoods manufacturer, sells some refrigerators to a Japanese hotel. In this sale, a New Zealand company gives fridges to a Japanese company, and a Japanese company gives yen to a New Zealand company. Notice that two things have occurred simultaneously. New Zealand has sold to a foreigner some of its output (the refrigerators), and this sale increases New Zealand net exports. In addition, New Zealand has acquired some foreign assets (the yen) and this acquisition increases New Zealand’s net foreign investment. Although Fisher & Paykel most likely will not hold onto the yen it has acquired in this sale, any subsequent transaction will preserve the equality of net exports and net foreign investment. For example, Fisher & Paykel may exchange its yen for New Zealand dollars with a New Zealand stockbroker that wants the yen to buy shares in Sony Corporation, the Japanese maker of consumer electronics. In this case, Fisher & Paykel’s net export of refrigerators equals the stockbroker’s net foreign investment in Sony shares. Hence, NX and NFI rise by an equal amount. Alternatively, Fisher & Paykel may exchange its yen for New Zealand dollars with another New Zealand company that wants to buy computers from Toshiba, the Japanese computer maker. In this case, New Zealand imports (of computers) exactly offset New Zealand exports (of refrigerators). The sales by Fisher & Paykel and Toshiba together affect neither New Zealand net exports nor New Zealand net foreign investment. That is, NX and NFI are the same as they were before these transactions took place. The equality of the current account and net foreign investment follows from the fact that every international transaction is an exchange. When a seller country transfers a good or service to a buyer country, the buyer country gives up some asset to pay for this good or service. The value of that asset equals the value of the good or service sold. When we add everything up, the net value of goods and services sold by a country and the net income it earns from overseas (CAB) must equal the net value of assets acquired (NFI). The international flow of goods and services and income and the international flow of capital are two sides of the same coin. Saving, investment and their relationship to the international flows 288 A nation’s saving and investment are, as we have seen in previous chapters, crucial to its long-run economic growth. Let’s therefore consider how these variables are related to the international flows of goods and capital, as measured by the current account and net foreign investment. We can do this most easily with the help of some simple mathematics. As you may recall, when we discussed the components of gross domestic product earlier in the book, we didn’t account for the fact that not only do we earn income from our exports and spend some of that income on imports, but we also earn income from our overseas investments. We need to adjust our definition of income to reflect this. If you recall, the economy’s gross domestic product (Y ) is divided among four components: consumption (C), investment (I ), government purchases (G) and net exports (NX ). To take account of our Copyright 2021economies Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 6 The macroeconomics of open 12_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 288 24/08/20 4:35 PM earnings from overseas investments, we define our gross national disposable income, GNDY, (what we have to spend or save) as: GNDY = GDP + NY + NT Total income available for expenditure on the economy’s output is the sum of gross domestic product (GDP) and what we earn from investments overseas (net income, NY) and gifts and grants from overseas (net transfers, NT). Recall that ‘national saving’ is the income of the nation that is left after paying for current consumption and government purchases. Gross national saving (S) equals GNDY – C – G. If we rearrange the equation to reflect this fact, we obtain: S = GNDY − C − G If we substitute in our definition of disposable income, we find: S = C + I + G + NX + NY + NT − C − G = I + NX + NY + NT = I + CAB Because our current account balance (CAB) also equals net foreign investment (NFI), we can also write this equation as: S = I + NFI Saving = Domestic investment + Net foreign investment This equation shows that a nation’s saving must equal its domestic investment plus its net foreign investment. In other words, when Australian citizens save a dollar of their income for the future, that dollar can be used to finance accumulation of domestic capital or it can be used to finance the purchase of capital abroad. This equation should look somewhat familiar. Earlier in the book, when we analysed the role of the financial system, we considered this identity for the special case of a closed economy. In a closed economy, net foreign investment is zero (NFI = 0), so saving equals investment (S = I). In contrast, an open economy has two uses for its saving – domestic investment and net foreign investment. As before, we can view the financial system as standing between the two sides of this identity. For example, suppose the Barnes family decides to save some of its income for retirement. This decision contributes to national saving, the left-hand side of our equation. If the Barnes family deposits their saving in a managed fund, the managed fund may use some of the deposit to buy shares issued by BHP, which uses the proceeds to build a processing factory in Victoria. In addition, the managed fund may use some of the Barnes family’s deposit to buy shares issued by Toyota, which uses the proceeds to build a factory in Osaka. These transactions show up on the right-hand side of the equation. From the standpoint of Australian accounting, the BHP expenditure on a new factory is domestic investment and the purchase of Toyota shares by an Australian resident is net foreign investment. Thus, all saving in the Australian economy shows up as investment in the Australian economy or as Australian net foreign investment. Saving, investment and net foreign investment of Australia Since the late 1970s, Australia has relied in part on foreign investment to fund its domestic investment. We can use our macroeconomic accounting identities to help us understand why this would be so. In panel (a) of Figure 12.2, we show national saving and domestic investment for the Australian economy as a percentage of GDP since 1960. Panel (b) shows net foreign investment as a percentage of GDP. Notice that, as the identities require, domestic investment plus net foreign investment always equals national saving. CASE STUDY 289 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 12 Open-economy macroeconomics: Basic concepts 12_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 289 24/08/20 4:35 PM FIGURE 12.2 National saving, domestic investment and net foreign investment a Chart Title 40 % 35 % Gross Inv % GDP 30 % 25 % 20 % 15 % Gross saving % GDP 10 % 5% 0% 1960 b 1970 1980 1990 2000 2010 2000 2010 NFI % GDP 3 2 1 0 −1 −2 −3 −4 −5 −6 −7 −8 1960 1970 1980 1990 Panel (a) shows national saving and domestic investment as a percentage of GDP. Panel (b) shows net foreign investment as a percentage of GDP. You can see from the figure that national saving has been lower since 1976 than it was before 1976. This fall in national saving has been reflected mainly in reduced net foreign investment rather than in reduced domestic investment. Source: ABS DATA, catalogue 5204.08 The figure shows a change beginning in the late 1970s. Before 1975, national saving and domestic investment were very close and so net foreign investment was small. After 1976, however, national saving fell dramatically. (This decline was due in part to increased government budget deficits and in part to a fall in private saving.) Yet the Australian economy did not experience a similar fall in domestic investment. As a result, net foreign investment became a large negative number, indicating that foreigners were buying more assets in Australia than Australians were buying abroad. One of the consequences of having a high level of foreign investment in Australia is that Australia must then pay interest and dividend payments on that investment. Australians pay much more in dividends and interest than they 290 Copyright 2021economies Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 6 The macroeconomics of open 12_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 290 24/08/20 4:35 PM receive in dividends and interest from overseas. This difference, what we’ve called net income and net transfers, is Questions 1 Why did net foreign investment (NFI) become such a large negative number after 1976? 2 If the value of exports and imports were $3978 million and $8751 added to net exports to come up with the current account (CAB in our model). million, respectively, and income and transfers were –$88 072, what is the current account balance (CAB)? What does it mean if the CAB is negative? CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING Define net exports and net foreign investment. Explain how they are related. LO12.2 The prices for international transactions: Real and nominal exchange rates So far, we have discussed measures of the flow of goods and services and the flow of capital across a nation’s border. In addition to these quantity variables, macroeconomists also study variables that measure the prices at which these international transactions take place. Just as the price in any market serves the important role of coordinating buyers and sellers in that market, international prices help coordinate the decisions of consumers and producers as they interact in world markets. Here we discuss the two most important international prices – the nominal and real exchange rates. Nominal exchange rates The nominal exchange rate is the rate at which a person can trade the currency of one country for the currency of another. For example, if you go to a bank, you might see a posted exchange rate of 80 yen per dollar. If you give the bank one Australian dollar, it will give you 80 Japanese yen; and if you give the bank 80 Japanese yen, it will give you one Australian dollar. (In reality, the bank will post slightly different prices for buying and selling yen. The difference gives the bank some profit for offering this service. For our purposes here, we can ignore these differences.) An exchange rate can always be expressed in two ways. If the exchange rate is 80 yen per dollar, it is also 1/80 (0.0125) dollar per yen. Throughout this book, we always express the nominal exchange rate as units of foreign currency per Australian dollar, like 80 yen per dollar. If the exchange rate changes so that a dollar buys more foreign currency, that change is called an appreciation of the dollar. If the exchange rate changes so that a dollar buys less foreign currency, that change is called a depreciation of the dollar. For example, when the exchange rate rises from 80 to 90 yen per dollar, the dollar is said to appreciate. At the same time, because a Japanese yen now buys less of the Australia currency, the yen is said to depreciate. When the exchange rate falls from 80 to 70 yen per dollar, the dollar is said to depreciate and the yen is said to appreciate. At times you may have heard the media report that the dollar is either ‘strong’ or ‘weak’. These descriptions usually refer to recent changes in the nominal exchange rate. When a nominal exchange rate the rate at which a person can trade the currency of one country for the currency of another appreciation an increase in the value of a currency as measured by the amount of foreign currency it can buy depreciation a decrease in the value of a currency as measured by the amount of foreign currency it can buy 291 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 12 Open-economy macroeconomics: Basic concepts 12_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 291 24/08/20 4:35 PM currency appreciates, it is said to strengthen because it can then buy more foreign currency. Similarly, when a currency depreciates, it is said to weaken. For any country, there are many nominal exchange rates. The Australian dollar can be used to buy Japanese yen, British pounds, euros, Thai baht and so on. When economists study changes in the exchange rate, they often use indexes that average these many exchange rates. Just as the consumer price index turns the many prices in the economy into a single measure of the price level, an exchange rate index turns these many exchange rates into a single measure of the international value of the currency. So when economists talk about the dollar appreciating or depreciating, they often are referring to an exchange rate index that takes into account many individual exchange rates. Real exchange rates real exchange rate the rate at which a person can trade the goods and services of one country for the goods and services of another The real exchange rate is the rate at which a person can trade the goods and services of one country for the goods and services of another. For example, suppose that you go shopping and find that a case of German beer is twice as expensive as a case of Australian beer. We would then say that the real exchange rate is a ½ case of German beer per case of Australian beer. Notice that, like the nominal exchange rate, the real exchange rate is expressed as units of the foreign item per unit of the domestic item. But in this instance the item is a good rather than a currency. Real and nominal exchange rates are closely related. To see how, consider an example. Suppose that a tonne of Australian rice sells for $100, and a tonne of Japanese rice sells for 18 000 yen. What is the real exchange rate between Australian and Japanese rice? To answer this question, we must first use the nominal exchange rate to convert the prices into a common currency. If the nominal exchange rate is 90 yen per dollar, then a price for Australian rice of $100 per tonne is equivalent to 9000 yen per tonne. Australian rice is half as expensive as Japanese rice. The real exchange rate is a ½ tonne of Japanese rice per tonne of Australian rice. We can summarise this calculation for the real exchange rate with the following formula: Real exchange rate = Nominal exchange rate × Domestic price Foreign price Using the numbers in our example, the formula applies as follows: Real exchange rate = (90 yen per dollar) × ($100 per tonne of Australian rice) 18 000 yen per tonne of Japanese rice = 9 000 yen per tonne of Australian rice 18 000 yen per tonne of Japanese rice = 1 tonne of Japanese rice per tonne of Australian rice 2 Thus, the real exchange rate depends on the nominal exchange rate and on the prices of goods in the two countries measured in the local currencies. Why does the real exchange rate matter? As you might guess, the real exchange rate is a key determinant of how much a country exports and imports. When Woolworths is deciding whether to buy Australian rice or Japanese rice to put on its shelves, for example, it will ask which rice is cheaper. The real exchange rate gives the answer. As another example, imagine that you are deciding whether to take a seaside holiday in Cairns in Queensland or in Phuket in Thailand. You might ask your travel agent the price of a hotel room in Cairns (measured in dollars), the price of a hotel room in Phuket (measured in baht), and the exchange rate between baht and dollars. If you decide where to holiday by comparing costs, you are basing your decision on the real exchange rate. 292 Copyright 2021economies Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 6 The macroeconomics of open 12_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 292 24/08/20 4:35 PM When studying an economy as a whole, macroeconomists focus on overall prices rather than the prices of individual items. That is, to measure the real exchange rate, they use price indexes, like the consumer price index. By using a price index for Australia (P), a price index for prices abroad (P*), and the nominal exchange rate between the Australian dollar and foreign currencies (e), we can calculate the overall real exchange rate between Australia and other countries as follows: Real exchange rate = (e × P) P* This real exchange rate measures the price of a basket of goods and services available domestically relative to a basket of goods and services available abroad. As we will see more fully in the next chapter, a country’s real exchange rate is a key determinant of its net exports of goods and services. A depreciation (fall) in the Australian real exchange rate means that Australian goods have become cheaper relative to foreign goods. This change encourages consumers both at home and abroad to buy more Australian goods and fewer goods from other countries. As a result, Australian exports rise, and Australian imports fall, and both of these changes raise Australian net exports. Conversely, an appreciation (rise) in the Australian real exchange rate means that Australian goods have become more expensive compared with foreign goods, so Australian net exports fall. CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING Define nominal exchange rate and real exchange rate, and explain how they are related. If the nominal exchange rate goes from 100 yen to 80 yen per dollar, has the dollar appreciated or depreciated? LO12.3 A first theory of exchange-rate determination: Purchasing-power parity Exchange rates vary substantially over time. In 1974, an Australian dollar could be used to buy 1.49 US dollars, 402 Japanese yen, 0.579 of a British pound or 618 Indonesian rupiah. In 2014, an Australian dollar bought 0.89 of a US dollar, 90 Japanese yen, 0.579 of a British pound or 10 367 Indonesian rupiah. In other words, over this period the value of the dollar fell by 40 per cent compared with the US dollar. The value of the Australian dollar fell by almost 80 per cent relative to the Japanese yen. And yet it appreciated by over 1580 per cent compared with the Indonesian rupiah. What explains these large changes? Economists have developed many models to explain how exchange rates are determined, each emphasising some of the many forces at work. Here we develop the simplest theory of exchange rates, called purchasing-power parity. This theory states that a unit of any given currency should be able to buy the same quantity of goods in all countries. Many economists believe that purchasing-power parity describes the forces that determine exchange rates in the long run. We now consider the logic on which this long-run theory of exchange rates is based, as well as the theory’s implications and limitations. purchasing-power parity a theory of exchange rates whereby a unit of any given currency should be able to buy the same quantity of goods in all countries The basic logic of purchasing-power parity The theory of purchasing-power parity is based on a principle called the law of one price. This law asserts that a good must sell for the same price in all locations. Otherwise, there 293 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 12 Open-economy macroeconomics: Basic concepts 12_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 293 24/08/20 4:35 PM would be opportunities for profit left unexploited. For example, suppose that coffee beans sold for less in Brisbane than in Perth. A person could buy coffee in Brisbane for, say, $20 a kilo and then sell it in Perth for $30 a kilo, making a profit of $10 per kilo from the difference in price. The process of taking advantage of differences in prices in different markets is called arbitrage. In our example, as people took advantage of this arbitrage opportunity, they would increase the demand for coffee in Brisbane and increase the supply in Perth. The price of coffee would rise in Brisbane (in response to greater demand) and fall in Perth (in response to greater supply). This process would continue until, eventually, the prices were the same in the two markets, ignoring transaction costs. Now consider how the law of one price applies to the international marketplace. If a dollar (or any other currency) could buy more coffee in Australia than in Japan, international traders could profit by buying coffee in Australia and selling it in Japan. This export of coffee from Australia to Japan would drive up the Australian price of coffee and drive down the Japanese price. Conversely, if a dollar could buy more coffee in Japan than in Australia, traders could buy coffee in Japan and sell it in Australia. This import of coffee into Australia from Japan would drive down the Australian price of coffee and drive up the Japanese price. In the end, the law of one price tells us that a dollar must buy the same amount of coffee in all countries. This logic leads us to the theory of purchasing-power parity. According to this theory, a currency must have the same purchasing power in all countries. That is, an Australian dollar must buy the same quantity of goods in Australia and Japan, and a Japanese yen must buy the same quantity of goods in Japan and Australia. Indeed, the name of this theory describes it well. Parity means equality, and purchasing power refers to the value of money. Purchasing-power parity states that one unit of every currency must have the same real value in every country. Implications of purchasing-power parity What does the theory of purchasing-power parity say about exchange rates? It tells us that the nominal exchange rate between the currencies of two countries depends on the price levels in those countries. If a dollar buys the same quantity of goods in Australia (where prices are measured in dollars) as in Japan (where prices are measured in yen), then the number of yen per dollar must reflect the prices of goods in Australia and Japan. For example, if a kilo of coffee costs 1500 yen in Japan and $20 in Australia, then the nominal exchange rate must be 75 yen per dollar (1500 yen/$20 = 75 yen per dollar). Otherwise, the purchasing power of the dollar would not be the same in the two countries. To see more fully how this works, it is helpful to use just a bit of mathematics. Suppose that P is the price level in Australia (measured in dollars), P* is the price level in Japan (measured in yen), and e is the nominal exchange rate (the number of yen a dollar can buy). Now consider the quantity of goods a dollar can buy at home and abroad. At home, the price level is P, so the purchasing power of $1 at home is 1/P. Abroad, a dollar can be exchanged into e units of foreign currency, which in turn have purchasing power e/P*. For the purchasing power of a dollar to be the same in the two countries, it must be the case that: 1/P = e/P* With rearrangement, this equation becomes: 1 = eP/P* Notice that the left-hand side of this equation is a constant, and the right-hand side is the real exchange rate. Thus, if the purchasing power of the dollar is always the same at 294 Copyright 2021economies Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 6 The macroeconomics of open 12_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 294 24/08/20 4:35 PM home and abroad, then the real exchange rate – the relative price of domestic and foreign goods – cannot change. To see the implication of this analysis for the nominal exchange rate, we can rearrange the last equation to solve for the nominal exchange rate: e = P*/P That is, the nominal exchange rate equals the ratio of the foreign price level (measured in units of the foreign currency) to the domestic price level (measured in units of the domestic currency). According to the theory of purchasing-power parity, the nominal exchange rate between the currencies of two countries must reflect the different price levels in those countries. A key implication of this theory is that nominal exchange rates change when price levels change. As we saw in the preceding chapter, the price level in any country adjusts to bring the quantity of money supplied and the quantity of money demanded into balance. Because the nominal exchange rate depends on the price levels, it also depends on the money supply and money demand in each country. When a central bank in any country increases the money supply and causes the price level to rise, it also causes that country’s currency to depreciate relative to other currencies in the world. In other words, when the central bank prints large quantities of money, that money loses value both in terms of the goods and services it can buy and in terms of the amount of other currencies it can buy. Purchasing-power parity and the Big Mac In 1986, The Economist devised an ingenious way to evaluate whether a currency is valued at the level predicted by the theory of purchasing-power parity. Their approach was to divide the price of a Big Mac in 120 countries by the American price and compare the result with the actual exchange rate. According to the burgernomic approach, the price of a Big Mac in Australia looks pretty good. You can go online and see which currencies are overvalued, which ones undervalued and which ones are about right. Go to http://www.economist.com and search for ‘the Big Mac index’. IN THE NEWS While the Big Mac is a good that can be found worldwide and therefore useful for comparing exchange rates, many economists object to the index because burgers aren’t really tradeable goods. An alternative was created by UBS, a Swiss bank. It uses the same burger to measure the purchasing power of local wages. It divides the price of a Big Mac by the average net hourly wage in cities around the world. A worker from Jakarta must toil for almost 2½ hours to buy a Big Mac, but a Moscow wage buys the burger in 21 minutes, a Tokyo salary buys one in just 12 minutes, and in Sydney it takes 14 minutes’ work to buy a Big Mac. Purchasing-power parity and the iPod In 2007, the Commonwealth Bank’s online trading company, CommSec, devised an alternative to the Big Mac index – the iPod index (now the iPad/iPhone indexes). This index does the same thing that the Big Mac index does, but uses a good that is tradeable. You can go to the CommSec website to see what the current iPad and iPhone index is telling us about purchasing power in Australia. Here’s an example from September 2018. (See Table 12.1.) IN THE NEWS 295 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 12 Open-economy macroeconomics: Basic concepts 12_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 295 24/08/20 4:35 PM CommSec iPhone index: Australia 4th cheapest by Craig James, Chief Economist, CommSec Economic trends • • • • • • Do we have a Goldilocks Aussie dollar – not too hot, not too cold, just about right? According to CommSec iPhone index Australia is now the 4th cheapest country in the world (of 51 nations) to buy an Apple iPhone 8 in US dollar terms. This time last year, Australia was the 25th cheapest country in the world to buy an Apple iPhone 7 (Aussie dollar US80 cents). In 2016 Australia was the 17th cheapest to buy the iPhone 6 Plus (Aussie dollar US76 cents) and in 2015 Australia was fourth cheapest to buy an iPhone (Aussie dollar US69 cents). An iPhone 8, 4.7 inch, 64GB is $1,079 in Australia (US$775.56 at exchange rates sourced on September 5). In the US, the same phone is US$699 (US$765.41 in Los Angeles with state and local taxes) – around 1.3 per cent cheaper. (The Aussie dollar has fallen further since all the data was compiled on September 5.) Apple is expected to release a new model of the iPhone on Wednesday and Australian consumers will be closely watching the local pricing of the must-have device. Turning to the CommSec iPad index. Australia is now the 3rd cheapest country in the world (of 51 nations) to buy an Apple iPad 2018; 9.7-inch tablet device, 32GB in US dollar terms. This time last year, Australia was the 17th cheapest country to buy an Apple iPad Pro 10.5-inch tablet device in US dollar terms. (2016: 20th cheapest; 2015: 2nd cheapest). In January 2007 CommSec launched its iPod index as a modern way of • looking at purchasing power theory. That is, the theory that the same good should be sold for the same price across the globe once taking into account exchange rates. On current iPad & iPhone pricing the Aussie dollar could be regarded as, at best, as a little ‘expensive’. Last year we thought the currency was slightly ‘over-valued’. On current pricing, Aussie tourists would only save $11 by buying an iPad in the cheapest country (Hong Kong) rather than in Australia. When the currency falls Aussie consumers may be better off buying goods locally, and that’s great news for Aussie retailers. … Purchasing power parity: In theory only • • • While the concept of purchasing power parity is good in theory, unfortunately there are complications in practice. As noted above, one of the biggest complications is tax with differing consumption tax rates applied across the globe. The other complication with purchasing power parity is freight or shipping cost. If the local price was relatively high and shipping costs weren't overly exorbitant then a buyer may decide to source goods from another country. If enough buyers were to source goods abroad, presumably it would force local retailers to re-assess pricing. On current exchange rates Australian consumers probably wouldn’t be tempted to buy their iPads and iPhones from abroad while on personal or business trips. For instance an Aussie traveller may save just $16 to buy an iPhone in Los Angeles or save $11 to buy an iPad in Hong Kong. 296 Copyright 2021economies Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 6 The macroeconomics of open 12_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 296 24/08/20 4:35 PM Highest Lowest Brazil $600.50 South Africa $363.26 Argentina $495.13 Singapore $360.87 Iceland $488.64 New Zealand $356.95 Greece $473.60 Taiwan $353.67 Serbia $472.13 Thailand $351.24 Slovenia $438.87 Japan $339.56 Denmark $434.80 Australia $337.10 Romania $432.64 Malaysia $331.55 Finland $427.28 Hong Kong $329.68 Portugal $427.28 Table source: CommSec Economics TABLE 12.1 Apple iPad 2018, 9.7 inch, 32GB, $US Source: Craig James, Chief Economist, CommSec Economics. https://www.commsec.com.au/content/dam/ EN/ResearchNews/2018Reports/September/ECO_Insights_110918_iPhone.pdf The nominal exchange rate during hyperinflation Macroeconomists cannot conduct controlled experiments. Instead, they must glean what they can from the natural experiments that history gives them. One natural experiment is hyperinflation – the high inflation that arises when a government turns to the printing press to pay for large amounts of government spending. Because hyperinflations are so extreme, they illustrate some basic economic principles with clarity. Consider the German hyperinflation of the early 1920s. Figure 12.3 shows the German money supply, the German price level and the nominal exchange rate (measured as US cents per German mark) for that period. Notice that these series move closely together. When the supply of money starts growing quickly, the price level also takes off, and the German mark depreciates. When the money supply stabilises, so does the price level and the exchange rate. The pattern shown in this figure appears during every hyperinflation. It leaves no doubt that there is a fundamental link between money, prices and the nominal exchange rate. The quantity theory of money discussed in the previous chapter explains how the money supply affects the price level. The theory of purchasing-power parity discussed here explains how the price level affects the nominal exchange rate. CASE STUDY Question Briefly explain why the price level and nominal exchange rate move together. 297 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 12 Open-economy macroeconomics: Basic concepts 12_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 297 24/08/20 4:35 PM FIGURE 12.3 Money, prices and the nominal exchange rate during the German hyperinflation Indexes (Jan. 1921 = 100) 1 000 000 000 000 000 Money supply 10 000 000 000 Price level 100 000 1 Exchange rate 0.00001 0.0000000001 1921 1922 1923 1924 1925 This figure shows the money supply, the price level and the exchange rate (measured as US cents per mark) for the German hyperinflation from January 1921 to December 1924. Notice how similarly these three variables move. When the quantity of money started growing quickly, the price level followed, and the mark depreciated relative to the dollar. When the German central bank stabilised the money supply, the price level and exchange rate stabilised as well. Source: Adapted from Thomas J. Sargent, ‘The end of four big inflations’ in Robert Hall, ed., Inflation (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1983), pp. 41–93 We can now answer the question that began this section: Why has the Australian dollar lost value compared with the US dollar and gained value compared with the Indonesian rupiah? The answer is that the US has pursued a less inflationary monetary policy than Australia, and Indonesia has pursued a more inflationary monetary policy. From 1970 to 2014, inflation in Australia was 5.5 per cent per year. In contrast, inflation was 4 per cent in the United States and over 13 per cent in Indonesia. As Australian prices rose relative to US prices, the value of the Australian dollar fell relative to the US dollar. Similarly, as Australian prices fell relative to Indonesian prices, the value of the Australian dollar rose relative to the rupiah. Limitations of purchasing-power parity Purchasing-power parity provides a simple model of how exchange rates are determined. For understanding many economic phenomena, the theory works well. In particular, it can explain many long-term trends, like the depreciation of the Australian dollar against the US dollar and the appreciation of the Australian dollar against the Indonesian rupiah. It can also explain the major changes in exchange rates that occur during hyperinflations. Yet the theory of purchasing-power parity is not completely accurate. That is, exchange rates do not always move to ensure that a dollar has the same real value in all countries all 298 Copyright 2021economies Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 6 The macroeconomics of open 12_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 298 24/08/20 4:35 PM the time. There are two reasons that the theory of purchasing-power parity does not always hold in practice. The first reason is that many goods are not easily traded. Imagine, for instance, that haircuts are more expensive in Paris than in Sydney. International travellers might avoid getting their haircuts in Paris and some hairdressers might move from Sydney to Paris. Yet such arbitrage would probably be too limited to eliminate the differences in prices. Thus, the deviation from purchasing-power parity might persist and a dollar (or euro) would continue to buy less of a haircut in Paris than in Sydney. The second reason that purchasing-power parity does not always hold is that even tradeable goods are not always perfect substitutes when they are produced in different countries. For example, some consumers prefer German beer and others prefer Australian beer. Moreover, consumer tastes for beer change over time. If German beer suddenly becomes more popular, the increase in demand will drive up the price of German beer. As a result, a dollar (or a euro) might then buy more beer in Australia than in Germany. But despite this difference in prices in the two markets, there might be no opportunity for profitable arbitrage because consumers do not view the two beers as equivalent. Thus, both because some goods are not tradeable and because some tradeable goods are not perfect substitutes with their foreign counterparts, purchasing-power parity is not a perfect theory of exchange-rate determination. For these reasons, real exchange rates do in fact fluctuate over time. Nonetheless, the theory of purchasing-power parity does provide a useful first step in understanding exchange rates. The basic logic is persuasive – as the real exchange rate drifts from the level predicted by purchasing-power parity, people have greater incentive to move goods across national borders. Even if the forces of purchasingpower parity do not completely fix the real exchange rate, they do provide a reason to expect that changes in the real exchange rate are most often small or temporary. As a result, large and persistent movements in nominal exchange rates typically reflect changes in price levels at home and abroad. CHECK YOUR UNDERSTANDING If the Reserve Bank of Australia (RBA) decreases the money supply, what happens to the price level? What happens to Australia’s currency relative to the other countries in the world? Use the equation, e = P*/P to help answer these questions. Conclusion The purpose of this chapter has been to develop some basic concepts that macroeconomists use to study open economies. You should now understand why a nation’s net exports must equal its net foreign investment and why national saving must equal domestic investment plus net foreign investment. You should also understand the meaning of the nominal and real exchange rates, as well as the implications and limitations of purchasing-power parity as a theory of how exchange rates are determined. The macroeconomic variables defined here offer a starting point for analysing an open economy’s interactions with the rest of the world. In the next chapter, we develop a model that can explain what determines these variables. We can then discuss how various events and policies affect a country’s trade balance and the rate at which nations make exchanges in world markets. 299 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 12 Open-economy macroeconomics: Basic concepts 12_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 299 24/08/20 4:35 PM STUDY TOOLS Summary LO12.1 Net exports are the value of domestic goods and services sold abroad minus the value of foreign goods and services sold domestically. Net foreign investment is the acquisition of foreign assets by domestic residents minus the acquisition of domestic assets by foreigners. Because every international transaction involves an exchange of an asset for a good or service, an economy’s net foreign investment always equals its net exports. An economy’s saving can be used either to finance investment at home or to buy assets abroad. Thus, national saving equals domestic investment plus net foreign investment. LO12.2 The nominal exchange rate is the relative price of the currency of two countries and the real exchange rate is the relative price of the goods and services of two countries. When the nominal exchange rate changes so that each dollar buys more foreign currency, the dollar is said to appreciate or strengthen. When the nominal exchange rate changes so that each dollar buys less foreign currency, the dollar is said to depreciate or weaken. LO12.3 According to the theory of purchasing-power parity, a dollar (or a unit of any other currency) should be able to buy the same quantity of goods in all countries. This theory implies that the nominal exchange rate between the currencies of two countries should reflect the price levels in those countries. As a result, countries with relatively high inflation should have depreciating currencies, and countries with relatively low inflation should have appreciating currencies. Key concepts appreciation, p. 291 balanced trade, p. 280 closed economy, p. 279 depreciation, p. 291 net foreign investment, p. 285 nominal exchange rate, p. 291 open economy, p. 279 purchasing-power parity, p. 293 real exchange rate, p. 292 trade balance (net exports), p. 280 trade deficit, p. 280 trade surplus, p. 280 Practice questions Questions for review 1 2 3 4 Consider the equation, S = I + NFI. Solve this equation for NFI (i.e. so that NFI is the variable of interest). If S > I, what happens to NFI? If S < I, what happens to NFI? If Australia decided to save more than it invests domestically, what must be true of its net foreign investment (NFI)? Describe the economic logic behind the theory of purchasing-power parity. What are the problems with the theory? If the Reserve Bank of Australia reduced printing quantities of Australian dollars (i.e. a decrease in the money supply), what would happen to the number of Japanese yen a dollar could buy? The number of US dollars an Australian dollar could buy? The number of Chinese RMB an Australian dollar could buy? Multiple choice 1 If an Australian resident invests in shares in Apple, which is listed on the US stock exchange, what does this do to net capital flows? a It increases capital outflow. b It increases capital inflow. c It has no effect because it is not a physical exchange of goods or services. d It causes a deficit in our capital account. 300 Copyright 2021economies Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 6 The macroeconomics of open 12_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 300 24/08/20 4:35 PM 2 3 4 5 If the real exchange rate rises, but inflation in Australia and our trading partner’s country is the same, what is happening to the nominal exchange rate? a It is increasing. b It is staying the same. c It is falling. d It depends on what is happening to our GDP. According to the Big Mac index, a currency is overvalued if a it costs more to buy a Big Mac in that currency than it does in other currencies. b it costs less to buy a Big Mac in that currency than it does in other currencies. c it costs the same – it doesn’t matter what a Big Mac costs. d it is rising relative to other currencies. Suppose the exchange rate between the dollar and the yen is ¥70 = $1, and then changes to ¥110 = $1. What is likely to happen next? a Australian exports will decrease and Australian imports will increase. b Australian exports will increase and Australian imports will increase. c Australian exports will decrease and Australian imports will decrease. d Australian exports will increase and Australian imports will decrease. Suppose that the US dollar (USD) depreciates against the Australian dollar (AUD). Assuming ceteris paribus, the real exchange rate of USD to AUD will a decrease. b increase. c remain the same. d decrease and then increase. Problems and applications 1 2 3 4 5 How would the following transactions affect Australian exports, imports and net exports? a An Australian chef spends the summer touring restaurants in Asia. b Department stores in Milan buy clothes designed by Australian designer Toni Maticevski. c Your older brother buys a Nissan GT-R. d Drake sells a million CDs in Australia. e A Chinese citizen shops at a store in Melbourne to avoid the Chinese goods and services tax (assuming that they can get their Australian GST rebated on departure from Australia). Based on the following, provide reasons as to why international trade has increased globally since the post-Second World War period: a abundant natural resources (such as iron ore and minerals in Australia) b transportation and telecommunications c technological progress d free trade agreements (FTAs) How would the following transactions affect Australian net foreign investment? Also, state whether each involves direct investment or portfolio investment. a An Australian mobile phone company establishes an office in Macedonia. b British pension funds buy shares in Rio Tinto. c Toyota closes its factory in Altona. d A Westpac mutual fund sells its News Ltd shares to a Chinese investor. Holding national saving constant, does an increase in net foreign investment increase, decrease, or have no effect on a country’s accumulation of domestic capital? The Australian Financial Review contains a table showing Australian exchange rates or you can find exchange rates on the Internet. Use either source to answer the following questions. a Does this table show nominal or real exchange rates? Explain. b What are the exchange rates between Australia and the United States and between Australia and Japan? Calculate the exchange rate between the United States and Japan. c If Australian inflation exceeds US inflation over the next year, would you expect the dollar to appreciate or depreciate relative to the US dollar? 301 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 12 Open-economy macroeconomics: Basic concepts 12_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 301 24/08/20 4:35 PM 6 Would each of the following groups be happy or unhappy if the Australian dollar depreciated? Explain. a Australian cattle growers who export beef to China b Australian companies who buy raw materials overseas c Australian students planning a study year in London d An Australian firm trying to purchase a plant located overseas that will produce goods to be sent back to Australia 7 What is happening to the Australian real exchange rate in each of the following situations? Explain. a The Australian nominal exchange rate is unchanged, but prices rise faster in overseas countries than in Australia. b The Australian nominal exchange rate is unchanged, but prices rise slower abroad than in Australia. c The Australian nominal exchange rate declines, and prices are unchanged in Australia and abroad. d The Australian nominal exchange rate declines, and prices rise faster abroad than in Australia. 8 List three goods for which the law of one price is likely to hold and three goods for which it is not. Justify your choices. 9 If a Japanese car costs 6 000 000 yen, if a similar Australian car costs $20 000, and if a dollar can buy 1000 yen, what are the nominal and real exchange rates? Does purchasing-power parity hold? 10 As the value of the Australian dollar rises, more and more people are buying goods from overseas on the Internet and having them shipped to Australia. Does this mean purchasing-power parity is more or less likely to hold for these goods? 11 Assume that Australian coal sells for $320 per tonne, Chinese coal sells for 1800 RMB (yuan) per tonne, and the nominal exchange rate is 6 RMB (yuan) per dollar. a Explain how you could make a profit from this situation. What would be your profit per tonne of coal? If other people exploit the same opportunity, what would happen to the price of coal in China and the price of coal in Australia? b Suppose that coal is the only commodity in the world. What would happen to the real exchange rate between Australia and China? c What would prevent the exchange rate from adjusting? 12 As you can see from The Economist website, the international news magazine regularly collects data on the price of a McDonald’s Big Mac hamburger in different countries in order to examine the theory of purchasing-power parity. a Why might the Big Mac be a good product to use for this purpose? b Based on the Big Mac data, purchasing-power parity appears to hold roughly across some countries, though not across others. Why might the assumptions underlying the theory of purchasing-power parity not hold exactly for Big Macs? c Do you think the UBS index on minutes worked required to buy a Big Mac would be a better measure of purchasing-power parity than the simple Big Mac index? Why or why not? d Why would the iPod index be a better measure than either Big Mac index? 302 Copyright 2021economies Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 6 The macroeconomics of open 12_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 302 24/08/20 4:35 PM 13 A macroeconomic theory of the open economy Learning objectives After reading this chapter, you should be able to: LO13.1build a model to explain an open economy’s trade balance and exchange rate LO13.2 use the model to analyse the effects of government budget deficits LO13.3 use the model to analyse the macroeconomic effects of trade policies LO13.4 use the model to analyse political instability and capital flight. 303 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 13_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 303 24/08/20 6:52 PM Introduction Since the 1970s, Australia’s trade balance has swung between surplus and deficit. Sometimes we export more goods and services than we import. Sometimes we import more than we export. Despite periods of trade surplus, economists debate whether the trade deficits are a problem for the Australian economy. The nation’s business community, however, has a strong opinion. Many business leaders claim that the trade deficits reflect unfair competition – foreign firms are allowed to sell their products in Australian markets, they contend, while foreign governments impede Australian firms selling Australian products abroad. Imagine that you are the prime minister and you want to end these trade deficits. What should you do? Should you try to limit imports, perhaps by increasing tariffs on the import of water heaters from China? Or should you try to influence the nation’s trade deficit in some other way? To understand what factors determine a country’s trade balance and how government policies can affect it, we need a macroeconomic theory of the open economy. The preceding chapter introduced some of the key macroeconomic variables that describe an economy’s relationship with other economies – including net exports, net foreign investment and the real and nominal exchange rates. This chapter develops a model that shows what forces determine these variables and how these variables are related to one another. To develop this macroeconomic model of an open economy, we build on our previous analysis in two important ways. First, the model takes the economy’s GDP as given. The economy’s output of goods and services, as measured by real GDP, is assumed to be determined by the supplies of the factors of production and by the available production technology that turns these inputs into output. Second, the model takes the economy’s price level as given. The price level is assumed to adjust to bring the supply and demand for money into balance. In other words, this chapter takes as a starting point the lessons learned in previous chapters about the determination of the economy’s output and price level. The goal of the model in this chapter is to highlight those forces that determine the economy’s trade balance and exchange rate. In one sense, the model is simple – it merely applies the tools of supply and demand to an open economy. Yet the model is also more complicated than others we have seen because it involves looking simultaneously at two related markets – the market for loanable funds and the market for foreign-currency exchange. After we develop this model of the open economy, we use it to examine how various events and policies affect the economy’s trade balance and exchange rate. We will then be able to determine the government policies that are most likely to reverse the trade deficits that the Australian economy has experienced from time to time over the past few decades. LO13.1 Supply of and demand for loanable funds and foreign-currency exchange To understand the forces at work in an open economy, we focus on supply and demand in two markets. The first is the market for loanable funds, which coordinates the economy’s saving and investment (including its net foreign investment). The second is the market for foreign-currency exchange, which coordinates people who want to exchange the domestic currency for the currency of other countries. In this section we discuss supply and demand in each of these markets. In the next section we put these markets together to explain the overall equilibrium for an open economy. 304 Copyright 2021economies Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 6 The macroeconomics of open 13_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 304 24/08/20 6:52 PM The market for loanable funds When we first analysed the role of the financial system earlier in this book, we made the simplifying assumption that the financial system consists of only one market, called the market for loanable funds. All savers go to this market to deposit their savings and all borrowers go to this market to get their loans. In this market, there is one interest rate, which is both the return on saving and the cost of borrowing. To understand the market for loanable funds in an open economy, the place to start is the identity discussed in the preceding chapter: S = I + NFI Saving = Domestic investment + Net foreign investment Whenever a nation saves a dollar of its income, it can use that dollar to finance the purchase of domestic capital or to finance the purchase of an asset abroad. The two sides of this identity represent the two sides of the market for loanable funds. The supply of loanable funds comes from national saving (S). The demand for loanable funds comes from domestic investment (I) and net foreign investment (NFI). Note that the purchase of a capital asset adds to the demand for loanable funds, regardless of whether that asset is located at home or abroad. Because net foreign investment can be either positive or negative, it can either add to or subtract from the demand for loanable funds that arises from domestic investment. As we learned in our earlier discussion of the market for loanable funds, the quantity of loanable funds supplied and the quantity of loanable funds demanded depend on the real interest rate. A higher real interest rate encourages people to save and, therefore, raises the quantity of loanable funds supplied. A higher interest rate also makes borrowing to finance capital projects more costly; thus, it discourages investment and reduces the quantity of loanable funds demanded. In addition to influencing national saving and domestic investment, the real interest rate in a country affects that country’s net foreign investment. To see why, consider two managed funds – one in Australia and one in Canada – deciding whether to buy an Australian government bond or a Canadian government bond. The managed funds would make this decision in part by comparing the real interest rates in Australia and Canada. When the Australian real interest rate rises, the Australian bond becomes more attractive to both managed funds. Thus, an increase in the Australian real interest rate discourages Australians from buying foreign assets and encourages foreigners to buy Australian assets. For both reasons, a high Australian real interest rate reduces Australian net foreign investment. We represent the market for loanable funds on the familiar supply-and-demand diagram in Figure 13.1. As in our earlier analysis of the financial system, the supply curve slopes upwards because a higher interest rate increases the quantity of loanable funds supplied and the demand curve slopes downwards because a higher interest rate decreases the quantity of loanable funds demanded. Unlike the situation in our previous discussion, however, the demand side of the market now represents the behaviour of both domestic investment and net foreign investment. That is, in an open economy, the demand for loanable funds comes not only from those who want to borrow funds to buy domestic capital goods but also from those who want to borrow funds to buy foreign assets. The interest rate adjusts to bring the supply of and demand for loanable funds into balance. If the interest rate were below the equilibrium level, the quantity of loanable funds supplied would be less than the quantity demanded. The resulting shortage of loanable funds would push the interest rate upwards. Conversely, if the interest rate were above the equilibrium level, the quantity of loanable funds supplied would exceed the quantity demanded. The surplus of loanable funds would drive the interest rate downwards. At the equilibrium interest rate, the supply of loanable funds exactly balances the demand. 305 Copyright 2021 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole part. WCN 02-200-202 Chapter 13orAinmacroeconomic theory of the open economy 13_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 305 24/08/20 6:52 PM FIGURE 13.1 The market for loanable funds Real interest rate Supply of loanable funds (from national saving) Equilibrium real interest rate Demand for loanable funds (for domestic investment and net foreign investment) Equilibrium quantity Quantity of loanable funds The interest rate in a large, open economy, as in a closed economy, is determined by the supply of and demand for loanable funds. National saving is the source of the supply of loanable funds. Domestic investment and net foreign investment are the sources of the demand for loanable funds. At the equilibrium interest rate, the amount that people want to save exactly balances the amount that people want to borrow for the purpose of buying domestic capital and foreign assets. That is, at the equilibrium interest rate, the amount that people want to save exactly balances the desired quantities of domestic investment and net foreign investment. The market for foreign-currency exchange The second market in our model of the open economy is the market for foreign-currency exchange. Participants in this market trade Australian dollars in exchange for foreign currencies. To understand the market for foreign-currency exchange, we begin with another identity from the last chapter: Net foreign investment = Current account balance This identity states that the imbalance between the purchase and sale of capital assets abroad (NFI) equals the imbalance between exports and imports of goods and services and the net flow of income and transfers (CAB). When the current account balance is negative, for instance, we are buying more foreign goods and services than foreigners are buying Australian goods and services, and we are sending more income and transfers overseas than foreigners are sending to Australia. What are foreigners doing with the Australian currency they are getting from this net sale of goods and services and net receipt of income and transfers from Australia? They must be using it to add to their holdings of Australian assets. These purchases of assets abroad are reflected in a negative value of net foreign investment. We can view the two sides of this identity as representing the two sides of the market for foreign-currency exchange. A positive value for net foreign investment represents the quantity of dollars supplied for the purpose of buying assets abroad. For example, when an Australian managed fund wants to buy a Japanese government bond, it needs to change 306 Copyright 2021economies Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. WCN 02-200-202 Part 6 The macroeconomics of open 13_Stonecash_8e_45658_SB_txt.indd 306 24/08/20 6:52 PM dollars into yen, so it supplies dollars in the market for foreign-currency exchange. The current account balance represents the quantity of dollars demanded for the purpose of buying Australian net exports of goods and services and sending income and transfers back to Australia. For example, when a Japanese steel mill wants to buy Australian coal, it needs to change its yen into dollars, so it demands dollars in the market for foreign-currency exchange. (This view is a simplification of the way foreign exchange markets actually work. We discuss this in greater detail below.) What is the price that balances the supply and demand in the market for foreign-currency exchange? The answer is the real exchange rate. As we saw in the preceding chapter, the real exchange rate is the relative price of domestic and foreign goods and, therefore, is a key determinant of net exports. When the Australian real exchange rate appreciates, Australian goods become more expensive relative to foreign goods, making Australian goods less attractive to consumers both at home and abroad. As a result, exports from Australia fall and imports into Australia rise. For both reasons, net exports fall. Hence, an appreciation of the real exchange rate reduces the quantity of dollars demanded in the market for foreigncurrency exchange. Figure 13.2 shows supply and demand in the market for foreign-currency exchange. The demand curve slopes downwards for the reason we just discussed – a higher real exchange rate makes Australian goods more expensive and reduces the quantity of dollars demanded to buy those goods. The supply curve is vertical because the quantity of dollars supplied for net foreign investment does not depend on the real exchange rate. (As discussed earlier, net foreign investment depends on the real interest rate. When discussing the market for foreign-currency exchange, we take the real interest rate and net foreign investment as given.) FIGURE 13.2 The market for foreign-currency exchange Real exchange rate Supply of dollars (from net foreign investment) Equilibrium real exchange rate Demand for dollars (for current account balance) Equilibrium quantity Quantity of dollars exchanged into foreign currency The real exchange rate is determined by the supply of and demand for foreign-currency exchange. The supply of dollars to be exchanged into foreign currency comes from net foreign investment. Because net foreign investment does not depend on the real exchange rate, the supply curve is vertical. The demand for dollars comes fr