Australian Journal of Political Science, Vol. 45, No. 3, September 2010, pp. 353–369 The Return of Keynesianism in Australia: The Rudd Government and the Lessons of Recessions Past ALAN FENNA Curtin University The global recession of 2008–09 brought Keynesian countercyclical budgeting back into vogue – conveniently for governments of the Left such as the incoming Rudd Labor government in Australia. This paper reviews some of the key moments of 20th century macroeconomic policy to assess the reasons and rationale for this revival and concludes that the lessons of those experiences are not always what they seem to be. The paper argues that: (1) Keynesianism is often confused with a narrow focus on fiscal, rather than monetary, policy and an emphasis on full employment at any cost; (2) the return of Keynesianism in Australia has only been made possible by an unusual, if not unprecedented, convergence of conducive conditions; (3) the ‘automatic stabilisers’ significantly reduce the necessity for discretionary fiscal policy; and (4) policy achievements must be seen in the light of Australia’s external economy. Background Elected to office in November 2007 as the economy continued its 16-year growth run, the main economic challenge faced by the incoming Labor government in Australia was how to deliver on its spending and tax cut promises without stoking inflation. Within only a matter of months, the situation had reversed and Labor was confronted with the global financial crisis and ensuing global recession. The government responded unhesitatingly to the new threat with a succession of financial support and economic stimulus packages. Embracing the policy of countercyclical deficit spending with enthusiasm, Prime Minister Rudd made clear his government’s willingness to see Australia spend its way out of the recession. After a long period in the wilderness, Keynesianism was back. And, moreover, it seemed to be back with a flourish. While according to the IMF (2009), 2008–09 was ‘by far the deepest global recession since the Great Depression’, Australia sailed through almost Alan Fenna is Professor of Politics at the John Curtin Institute of Public Policy. He thanks John Phillimore and the Journal’s reviewers for questioning his interpretations. ISSN 1036-1146 print; ISSN 1363-030X online/10/030353-17 Ó 2010 Australian Political Studies Association DOI: 10.1080/10361146.2010.499863 354 A. FENNA unscathed — being one of only three OECD countries not to record negative growth over the year. ‘In its response to the global recession’, Prime Minister Rudd (2009) declared, ‘Australia has sought to learn some lessons of recessions past’. The lesson that the Prime Minister drew from that past experience was the importance of ‘strong, early and decisive action’ along Keynesian lines. The value of learning from the past in economic policy making is indisputable – after all, that, along with comparative experience, represents the bulk of what we have to go on empirically. Rather more disputable, though, is exactly what lessons we should learn from those previous experiences. This paper argues that the lessons of this recession, and of recessions past, are rather different from what the Prime Minister suggested and, indeed, from what is often assumed. The return of Keynesianism re-opens long-running questions about the scope and means for political control of the economy and the capacity for achieving ‘full employment’ in a capitalist society. Keynesianism is a touchstone of the left and critics argue that since the mid-1970s the full employment objective has been sacrificed on the altar of ‘neoliberalism’: governments choosing to tolerate persistent and sometimes high unemployment when more humane approaches were available. This paper takes issue with that view, arguing: (1) that, too often, Keynesianism is confused with ‘fiscalism’, or the view that economic management should be done predominantly through taxing and spending, and ‘functional finance’, or the view that short-term macroeconomic considerations should always take precedence in fiscal policy; (2) that the current burst of Keynesianism has been made possible only by a highly unusual convergence of a number of necessary conditions; (3) that the ‘automatic stabilisers’ of today’s welfare state make discretionary fiscal policy much less necessary than in the time that Keynes was writing; and (4) that Australia’s performance is heavily influenced by external factors beyond its short-term control. Keynesianism must be seen as largely a creature of time and place, with timeless lessons but limited direct applicability to any of the circumstances that have prevailed since the 1930s. Keynesianism and the ‘Full Employment’ Objective The formative event behind the revolution in economic policy represented by Keynesianism was the Great Depression of the 1930s, a downturn distinguished from anything that has occurred since by its depth, its duration and its deflationary character, as well as by the very limited degree of social services governments then provided. What created the conditions for a ‘revolution’ in economic policy was the degree to which the Great Depression was so evidently a ‘disaster of perverse economic policies’. These were policies that reinforced the downward spiral in a ‘procyclical’ way rather than attempting to arrest it ‘countercyclically’ – most notably, disastrously tight monetary policy (Ahamad 2009; Bernanke 1995; Eichengreen 1992; Eichengreen and Temin 2003; Hall and Ferguson 1998; Kindleberger 1986; Romer 1992). The Great Depression was not Australia’s worst downturn – that honour is claimed by the Depression of the 1890s (Fisher and Kent 1999), which paved the way for Federation – but it has been described as ‘an THE RETURN OF KEYNESIANISM 355 economic catastrophe of the first order’ and ‘the dominating economic event in Australia’ of the 20th century (Valentine 1987, 61). Put most simply, Keynesianism is the predisposition toward countercyclical rather than procyclical economic policy. It proposes that: (1) markets are not self-equilibrating and, in particular, are inherently prone to periods of involuntary unemployment typically caused by insufficient effective demand to stimulate adequate levels of investment and employment; (2) through their influence on effective demand, governments have both the capacity and the responsibility to moderate the extremes of the business cycle so as to reduce unemployment; (3) thanks in part to the ‘multiplier’ and ‘pump priming’ effects, budget deficits generated by stimulatory fiscal policy are legitimate and correctable; and (4) there is a psychological component to economic behaviour that increases the returns to policies of economic stimulus. Keynes focused on the need for appropriate monetary and fiscal settings, with the emphasis dependent on circumstances, but he was particularly outspoken about the contribution that a fiscal stimulus could make through large programs of public capital investment since they would yield what we could call a ‘triple divided’ of direct job creation, indirect job stimulation and long-term structural benefit. It is the proposition that countercyclical demand management will pay for itself that led Krugman (2008, 191) to extol Keynesianism as the economics of the ‘free lunch’. That said, there is no shortage of variants, from the ‘neoclassical synthesis’ and the mechanical textbook version that Coddington (1976, 1264) labelled ‘hydraulic Keynesianism’, to the more radical ‘Post-Keynesian’ perspectives. The victory of Keynesianism was, if not total, certainly rapid and extensive. What had been a number of provocative proposals in the 1920s and early 1930s, and became a manifesto with the publication of Keynes’s (1936) General Theory, ‘had more or less established itself as the new orthodoxy’ by 1945 (Bleaney 1985, 83). It represented a major watershed in Australian public policy as it did elsewhere. It was officially signalled by the release of the Labor government’s 1945 White Paper Full Employment in Australia, a policy statement that followed the British lead and had Canadian and American equivalents.1 The White Paper declared that ‘Full employment is a fundamental aim of the Commonwealth Government’ and that ‘governments should accept the responsibility for stimulating spending on goods and services to the extent necessary to sustain full employment’. Following Keynes, it singled out infrastructure spending as the most expedient way to boost effective demand. It also acknowledged, though, that none of this is without risk. ‘Careful and detailed advance preparation will be required if public capital expenditure is to play a significant part in our development’. In addition, a spending-based approach creates the danger of ‘unstable public finances’, and full employment means government will need to ‘ensure . . . that undue sectional pressure for wage increases does not lead merely to a rising spiral of wages and prices 1 The British White Paper, Employment Policy, of 1944; the Canadian White Paper, Employment and Income, of 1945; and the US Full Employment Act of 1946. The American statement was the only one to assume any formal or legal standing; the others remained merely White Papers. That said, the American commitment to Keynesianism in the Full Employment Act was considerably watered down at the insistence of business. 356 A. FENNA without any real benefit – and perhaps with disadvantage – to the workers themselves’. Governments would have to keep public spending within bounds and build in mechanisms for controlling inflation. Keynesianism and Social Democracy Notwithstanding the fact that Keynes’s ‘patrician liberalism’ (Pierson 2001, 40) was quite at odds with the core elements of social democracy – particularly unions, which Keynes (e.g. [1926] 1972, 309) greatly deplored – there has always been a powerful affinity between Keynesianism and social democratic politics and policy. And although some prominent exercises in Left Keynesianism have been anything but successful – the Blum government in 1930s France and the Mitterrand government in 1980s France most notably – the affinity is strong. Arguably, it was Keynesianism that made social democracy viable: providing a way to square the circle of social reform in a capitalist economy by giving government responsibility for macroeconomic management and justifying progressive taxation and redistributive public spending. Although Hibbs’ (1977) original proposition that left-wing parties are naturally more Keynesian has been supported by others (see, for example, Cusack 2001; Hall 1989, 376), more recent research suggests that it was much truer of Hibbs’ period – the 1960s and 1970s – than it was of the 1980s and 1990s. After the failings of loose fiscal and monetary policy in the 1970s, argues Sakamoto (2008), parties of the left came under pressure to reform their ways and became as – or, indeed, more – fiscally responsible than parties of the right, and delivered improved economic outcomes as a result. One of the touchstones of the economic policy consensus that has emerged out of this convergence is the commitment to ‘balancing the budget over the economic cycle’. This was adopted in Australia by the incoming Coalition government in 1996 and endorsed by the Labor government following their return to office in 2007. Britain’s incoming Labour government had adopted the same stance a decade earlier. Critics of Britain’s ‘New Labour’ have argued that this ‘fiscal conservatism’, as Prime Minister Rudd called it approvingly, means that parties of the left have forsaken their Keynesianism and their commitment to full employment (see, for example, Arestis and Sawyer 2001, 2003, 2004; Hay 2004, 2007; Whyman 2006). They accuse Labour of having abandoned the Keynesian emphasis on countercyclical fiscal policy by transferring primary responsibility to monetary policy and committing to balanced budgets over the cycle. In Whyman’s (2006, 220) view, this must be reversed. ‘The revitalisation and evolution of Keynesian macroeconomic strategy is quite simply a prerequisite for a successful progressive–social democratic approach to economics.’ These critics overlook, though, both the extent to which economic policies must be fit for circumstances and the nuances of Keynesianism itself (see, for example, Clift and Tomlinson 2007). Keynesianism operates, like most other things, in a constrained world in which fiscalism may not always be the answer and social democracy does not have a fixed identify (Hindmoor 2005; Moschonas 2002). THE RETURN OF KEYNESIANISM 357 Constraint Factors In practice, Keynesianism has always faced a number of challenges, including inflationary pressures; the challenge of timeliness; fiscal imbalance; and the external economy. Prominent among these is the ‘inflation bias’ – Keynesianism’s potential to generate a disabling inflation through either or both of its support for full employment or its predisposition toward loose monetary and fiscal policy. From a Marxist perspective, free-lunch Keynesianism represents another instance of naı̈vité about the easy reconciliation of the conflict between capital and labour. In his 1943 article ‘Political Aspects of Full Employment’, Michał Kalecki argued that Keynesianism would be politically infeasible because business would not accept a framework that diminished their influence over public policy and their workplace authority over labour. Then, in a following article, Kalecki ([1944] 1990) argued that over the longer run Keynesianism would be economically infeasible: full employment is another one of those things that is too good to be true. In the full employment economy’s tight labour market the bargaining power of workers ‘will be very strongly enhanced’ and wage pressures will mount. The inflationary pressure of full employment in the absence of controls seemed to be empirically confirmed by A.W. Phillips’ (1958) famous study of British wage rates and employment levels. A century’s worth of data reveal, he advised, ‘a clear tendency for the rate of change of money wages to be high when unemployment is low and to be low or negative when unemployment is high’ (Phillips 1958, 290). Keynes wrote in a period when inflationary risks were minimal or nonexistent – an era of chronic deflation and generally ‘morbid’ expectations about the future (Overy 2009). By the time the Great Depression struck, the UK had already suffered through several years of economic stagnation, policyencouraged deflation and high unemployment. Nothing like such a deflationary stasis has occurred since. The great contrast between interwar conditions and those prevailing ever since is partially obscured by misuse of the term ‘deflation’ or ‘deflationary’ today to describe policies directed at reducing the inflation rate (see, for example, Bell 2004, 37–9). Keynesian economics also took shape in a period when timing was scarcely an issue. The tragedy of the interwar period was the sheer persistence of the slump. In both Britain and (as a consequence) Australia, the economy had already been in a deflationary recession before the Great Depression even struck in late 1929. For much of the period since the end of the war, the ambition of Keynesians has been the very different one of moderating short-run cyclical fluctuations in growth rates – sharp rises or falls that last 18 months or less. This was ‘fine tuning’ – rapid, relatively minor adjustments to monetary and fiscal policy that would anticipate those annual movements. It required a timeliness and calibration well beyond anything Keynes contemplated. The problem is one of uncertainty and the tendency of economic policy to lag too far behind the cycle, taking effect either when it is no longer needed or, worse yet, when it has become damagingly procyclical. This is particularly the case with fiscal policy, which can have pronounced ‘decision lags’ and ‘implementation lags’ (Blanchard and Perotti 2002). As John B. Taylor (2000, 27) has noted, monetary policy enjoys a distinct ‘comparative advantage over fiscal policy’ in these regards. ‘Experience has shown that the implementation lags are much 358 A. FENNA shorter for monetary policy’ and, in addition, monetary policy decisions are much easier to reverse. Keynes sought, above all, to liberate economic policy from the perversely procyclical balanced budget orthodoxy that required governments to cut spending and/or raise taxes to restore public finances in an economic depression. Thus, the test of Keynesianism in the popular mind is the government’s willingness to engage in deficit spending. However, for Keynes, deficit spending was a ‘last resort’ and one that ‘would be a sign of failure of the government’s overall economic stance’ (López 2003, 34). It was also very much a temporary measure, justified on the basis that it would be self-correcting. This is fundamentally different from the extreme ‘functional finance’ (Lerner 1943) doctrine that sees ongoing deficits as unproblematic and the maintenance of full employment as the only valid consideration for fiscal policy. That view is much more closely associated with Kalecki (see Feiwel 1975, 182–8) than it is with Keynes. Sweden’s pioneering experiment with democratic Keynesianism in the Great Depression illustrates the point well. Contributing to the great success of the Swedish Social Democrats in deficit spending was the way they anticipated the deficit concern from the outset – crafting their fiscal framework in a way explicitly directed to returning the budget to balance. For leading Swedish Social Democratic economist Gunnar Myrdal (1939, 107), this was a point of great importance: ‘The chief problem of fiscal policy in the business cycle’, he argued, is ‘to design formulas for public finance which, as part of the regular system, make room for deficit spending during depressions by securing the building of corresponding surpluses in good years.’ Myrdal (1939, 193) also acknowledged that ‘making room’ for countercyclical fiscal policy is easier said than done; balancing deficits with surpluses ‘assumes normal business cycles with good times alternating with the bad ones’. Finally, there is the problem of the international economy. When Keynes ([1931] 1972, 138) was first promoting the idea of spending one’s way out of the Depression, he reminded people that not only should they be out there buying goods, they must be buying ‘British, home-produced goods’ if the desired impact was to be achieved. Given the propensity to import and reliance on export income, ‘Keynesianism in one country’ is unlikely to be an option for anything but a very large economy. It is well recognised that this is particularly the case for Australia (see, for example, Gregory 1991, 111; Macfarlane 2005). The Great Depression in Australia Most important of the ‘lessons of recessions past’, according to the Prime Minister, is the lesson of the Great Depression. ‘The alternatives’ to the government’s stimulus packages, ‘were to do nothing or, worse, effectively replicate the Premiers’ Plan of 1931 when governments cut expenditure, thereby compounding the problems created by a private sector already in retreat. The result, of course, was an economic rout, appalling unemployment and a decade of negligible growth through the 1930s’ (Rudd 2009). Unfortunately, the data tell a rather different story. By the time the Premiers’ Plan was inked, Australia had been in recession for over three years. Indeed, because of its symbiotic ties to the British economy, which had been languishing THE RETURN OF KEYNESIANISM 359 through the decade, the Australian economy struggled through the entire period (Schedvin 1970, 49 and passim). The recession of the late 1920s culminated in the economic collapse of 1931 when GDP contracted by a catastrophic 9% (Valentine 1987, 65). Policy responses were tariff increases, currency devaluation, wage reductions and the Premiers’ Plan of a reduction in interest rates and the classic deflationary measures of orthodox public finance: public spending cuts and tax increases. Almost immediately from that point on, the Australian economy recovered strongly. The following year saw an 11% turn-around in GDP performance to growth of 1.7%, and the succeeding year, 1933, saw the economy grow an extraordinary 6%. Since ‘the Depression was almost completely imported’ (Valentine 1987, 76), recovery was dependent on external factors, notably access to cheap capital and demand for exports. The annus horribilis of 1931 followed directly from a collapse in exports and a blow-out in Australia’s current account deficit to 11% of GDP. Policies that supported export competitiveness – such as reducing wages (Valentine 1987, 73) – contributed to recovery but, to a large extent, Australia was at the mercy of British markets. Stimulating domestic consumption through deficit spending could not have addressed the external nature of the problem. At the same time, Australian governments were hobbled by massive public debt inherited from Commonwealth government expenditure in the First World War and State government infrastructure expenditure in the 1920s and earlier.2 Furthermore, the bulk of this debt was held overseas in the UK. All of this helps explain why Keynes himself publicly expressed wholehearted support for the Premiers’ Plan and associated actions (Markwell 2000). ‘I am sure the Premiers’ Plan last year saved the economic structure of Australia’, Keynes (1932) forthrightly declared. Keynesianism was undoubtedly the right policy for other countries, but it was not feasible in the Australian context. If there were obvious mistakes made, they lay most obviously in the realm of monetary policy, which was ‘tragically tight’ (Gruen and Clark 2009, 41). Australia was no different in this regard than the United States, where the real interest rate reached a punishing 20% in the depths of the Depression (Cecchetti 1992, 150). Bring Back the Golden Age For a number of commentators (Battin 1997; Bell 2000; Dow 2008; Nevile 2000), the question has been why have we waited so long to restore Keynesianism to its rightful place in Australian economic policy making? In their view, the Keynesian demand management techniques used so successfully in the 1950s and 1960s have been abandoned in favour of a callous ‘neoliberalism’. The crux of this argument lies in the proposition that there has been, in Stephen Bell’s (2000, 2–3) words, ‘a major re-orientation away from the postwar commitment to full employment’. Either explicitly or implicitly, this re-orientation is interpreted as representing a distinctly political choice, not one driven by or reflecting economic imperatives. Battin (1997, 8) 2 In 1932, Commonwealth government debt reached 60% of GDP and the aggregate government debt reached its all-time high of 205% of GDP (Barnard 1987, 256–7). 360 A. FENNA claims that ‘a reliance on economics alone to explain something like the shift away from Keynesianism is a barren enterprise’. Harking back to the Keynesian golden age of capitalism of the 1950s and 1960s is, as Macfarlane (1997) puts it, the ‘economics of nostalgia’. The economic performance of the period – ‘capitalism’s great leap forward’ (Beaud 2001, 213) – was indeed extraordinary, but little of that can be attributed to policy. Rather, the postwar boom was the result of underlying economic forces. From a different position on the ideological spectrum, Andrew Glyn (1995) judged similarly: ‘It is doubtful that ‘‘free lunch Keynesianism’’ . . . was ever very important in accounting for post-war full-employment.’ The postwar boom not only made Keynesian economic management largely redundant as far as ensuring full employment was concerned, it also contradicted, in a deeper way, Keynes’ own underlying pessimism about the continuing vitality of capitalism. Presumably, Keynesianism contributed to the virtuous circle of investment and growth – at the very least by its impact on expectations and, hence, consumption and investment decisions (Boltho 1989; also Nevile 2000). However, those high rates of investment and growth also eliminated many of the profound challenges of economic management that confronted governments before the war. The overwhelming feature of the postwar experience is the way that economic vigour caught economists and policy makers in Australia and elsewhere by surprise. ‘Learning the lesson of recessions past’, postwar reconstruction planning focused on Keynesian solutions to the slump that had caused such hardship at the end of the First World War. Paul Samuelson (1944a, 298; 1944b, 335), the ‘father of modern economics’, was not alone in warning of the ‘serious storm’ that was ‘on the horizon’ with demobilisation and in calling for ‘a vast expansion of useful public construction’; but he could not have been more wrong. No such slump eventuated, and planning quickly had to respond to the opposite challenge (Whitwell 1986, 83). This ‘forecasting debacle’ (Leijonhufvud 1968, 187) was a harbinger of things to come. The limitations of Keynesianism immediately became evident, first of all in the public works program. The kind of massive infrastructure investments that were to form the centrepiece of postwar countercyclical policy were imperative for social, microeconomic and developmental reasons, but would be unavoidably and dangerously procyclical under the unanticipated boom conditions (Whitwell 1986, 90–5). From the beginning, then, the continuing challenge was how to contain inflation under full employment conditions rather than how to maintain investment and jobs in a slump. What about short-term cyclical management? Under such benign conditions there is good reason to expect ‘fine tuning’ to have been a contributing factor to general economic welfare. That even this was the case, however, is not so clear. According to Whitwell (1986, 104–7), the first instance in Australia of a deliberately and openly Keynesian countercyclical intervention was the budget of 1951, brought down to cool a rapidly overheating economy and reduce inflationary pressures. But the budget came too late to have the desired effect, instead exacerbating a very sharp downturn that was already underway, and policy had to lurch back the following year to a more accommodating stance. Similarly, according to Whitwell (1986, 134), the failure of the mildly disinflationary budget of early 1961 to have much impact on inflationary THE RETURN OF KEYNESIANISM 361 pressures that were being stoked by wage increases, led to a severe fiscal and monetary tightening in November whose ‘effect on economic activity was abrupt and considerable and ushered in a recession which persisted well into 1962’.3 As Myrdal (1939, 187) noted, ‘fiscal policy is rather a clumsy instrument in crisis policy when utilized as the mobile factor in fighting against depressive forces which change from month to month and from week to week’. A clear reason for the failure of Keynesian fine tuning in the instances Whitwell analyses was an over-reliance on fiscal policy. Committed to a policy of cheap money, the government had foreclosed the option of using contractionary monetary policy earlier in the cycle to pre-empt the extremes (Bell 2004, 15; Rowse 2002, 230–232; Whitwell 1986, 105). The underlying problem here is the strong tendency to confuse Keynesian policy making with the use of fiscal rather than monetary instruments. Keynes expressed scepticism about the adequacy of monetary solutions to the Great Depression, but was not arguing for a general approach that privileged fiscal policy (Bibow 2002; Leijonhufvud 1968; Modigliani 1977; Moggridge and Howson 1974; Sheehan 2009; Tily 2007). Stagflation and the Death of Keynesianism? As is well known, Keynesianism met its nemesis in the 1970s, when the combination of slow growth, rising inflation and increasing deficits hamstrung countercyclical fiscal policy. With an unprecedented peacetime inflation (De Long 1997; Kaldor 1976) and slowing growth across the advanced industrial countries, the ‘golden age’ was over. Economic downturns up to and including the Great Depression saw inflation give way to deflation. Countercyclical fiscal policy made eminent sense in such cycles, but was stymied by an inflationary downturn. Debate continues over the causes of the stagflationary difficulties and the extent to which Keynesianism is implicated in some way or another. In some interpretations, the ‘Great Inflation’ was driven by exogenous factors – supplyshock factors, notably the oil price rise (Ball and Mankiw 1995; Blinder 1982; Blinder and Rudd 2010). From a Kaleckian perspective, by contrast, the Great Inflation was fundamentally endogenous: the predictable (and predicted) consequence of Keynesian full employment policies that generated increasing wage pressures and a ‘profit-squeeze’ (see, for example, Marglin 1990). From this perspective, ‘the seeds of the crisis of the 1970s were present in the prosperity of the 1960s’ (Beaud 2001, 223). Another view also implicates Keynesianism, but because of the bias Keynesianism gave to fiscal and monetary policy rather than via its impact on the labour market – there was a clear ‘toleration’ of inflation among policy makers (Leeson 2001, 100). It is a remarkable, and telling, feature of the early 1970s that real interest rates were close to zero and in some particularly high-inflation countries, such as Australia, actually negative (Allsopp and Glyn 1999, 3; Gregory 1991, 111). In respect of the United States at least, De Long (1997) has argued that loose 3 Unemployment was driven up to a peak of 3.1%, and stayed above 2% for over a year (Whitwell 1986, 137) and the government had to respond with more accommodating settings. 362 A. FENNA monetary policy resulted from a Keynesian predisposition against contractionary measures burned into the minds of a generation of economists and policy makers by the experience of the Great Depression (De Long 1997; Mayer 1998; Romer and Romer 2002). In this view, ‘the inflation of the 1970s was an accident waiting to happen’ (De Long 1997, 251). The solution was tight monetary policy – adopted early, consensually and undisruptively in Germany, later and more savagely in the United States, but highly effective in both cases (Beyer et al. 2010; Johnson 1998). One comparative study of the Australian experience argues that Australia’s relatively poor record on inflation in the 1980s reflected the failure to embrace monetarism and impose sufficiently contractionary monetary policy (Nelson 2005). Although the Accord did help moderate inflation rates during the 1980s, its main objective and achievement was to increase growth and employment instead (see also Bell 2004, 39–54). It was not until the recession of 1990 had made its mark that Australia joined the low-inflation club, with rates in the 2– 3% band rather than the average of 9% that had prevailed for the previous two decades (Edwards 2006, 31–2; Stevens 2003, 18). Although its extreme version, what Bradford De Long (2000) calls ‘political monetarism’, disproved itself in application, the main message of ‘classical monetarism’ has been absorbed into mainstream economic thinking and the practice of economic policy making. In US Federal Reserve Chairman Ben Bernanke’s (2003) words, ‘Friedman’s monetary framework has been so influential that, in its broad outlines at least, it has nearly become identical with modern monetary theory and practice.’ This applies equally to Australia, where the Reserve Bank finally adopted a coherent and determined inflation targeting regime when the opportunity arose in the aftermath of the 1990 recession (Bell 2004). Rebirth of Keynesianism? As Notermans (2000) argues, left-wing parties are much better positioned in times that call for Keynesian solutions than they are in times when price stability is a greater issue. Thus, the global financial crisis and subsequent recession provided auspicious conditions for the new Labor government. Active Keynesianism – the explicit and avowed use of discretionary fiscal policy for countercyclical demand management – quickly became the order of the day. Within weeks of the world downturn becoming evident, the government seized the initiative with the $10 billion cash handouts of its ‘Economy Security Strategy’ of October 2008. Supported by Treasury’s advice to ‘go early, go hard, go households’, the government delivered an upfront stimulus that was designed to minimise lags and maximise impact. The need for timely response was seen by Treasury as being the lesson of the 1990–91 recession (Gruen and Stevens 2000). When the full seriousness of the recession became evident, this was followed by the deficit budget and infrastructure-spending program of May 2009. From a projected surplus of 1.8% of GDP the government’s first budget moved into a 2.7% deficit by the end of the year – a $53 billion reversal. A deficit of 5.7% of GDP was projected for 2009–10 with substantial deficits continuing into the forward years. Reinforcing this countercyclical fiscal policy was aggressive interest rate cutting by the Reserve Bank. THE RETURN OF KEYNESIANISM 363 Such a willing embrace of traditional Keynesianism was made possible by a highly unusual confluence of conducive conditions at the level of theory, in the economy, in the fiscal position of government, the nature of the crisis and the international response. This is the first time since the postwar boom that there has been consensus support for deficit spending. Domestically, this has been most evident in the unusual degree of business support. Both the Business Council of Australia (see BCA 2009) and the Australian Industry Group (see Ridout 2009) endorsed a Keynesian approach. This is consistent with the urgent recommendations of the leading international economic policy bodies, the OECD and the IMF (Spilimbergo et al. 2008). Contributing to this consensus was the rehabilitation of Keynesianism within mainstream economics. For a number of leading macroeconomists, greater specification of Keynesianism’s microeconomic logic had given the approach a firmer theoretical basis (Akerlof 2007a, 2007b; Blinder 1988; Chari and Kehoe 2006; Mankiw 1992, 2006; Romer 1993). In the process, the ‘New Keynesians’ have revised the theory by, among other things, recognising the importance of both fiscal and monetary instruments, taking inflation more seriously and being more cautious about the possibilities of stabilisation policy. This was the first major downturn since a low-inflation environment was restored in the early 1990s. For the first time in decades, it became possible to reflate without reigniting inflation. In addition, having inflation under control has allowed fiscal policy to function in concert with monetary policy, with very low interest rates around the world supporting expansionary fiscal policy (OECD 2009b, 44). The economy also was maximally obliging as far as timing is concerned: with advance signals coming from the growing crisis in the financial sector overseas; the IMF (2008) announcing as early as April an impending global downturn; the collapse of Lehman Brothers in midSeptember confirming the seriousness of events; and the low risk of an immediate recovery, with the IMF (2009b, xv) warning over a year later against ‘premature exit from accommodative monetary and fiscal policies’. And fiscal conditions were equally auspicious. In addition to changing economic conditions, the greatly improved budgetary position of governments across the OECD had helped reinstate Keynesian fiscal policy – not least of all in Australia (Fenna 2007). But what to spend that money on? Here, again, circumstances were conducive. Calls to reverse the trend towards pro- rather than countercyclical public works spending by reviving the notion of an ongoing ‘ready shelf’ of capital works proposals (see, for example, Hughes 2001) reflected a broad sense that Australia’s capital stock had been neglected through years of fiscal tightening. The incoming Rudd government had already made largescale infrastructure investment a priority; funds had been set aside; the government was working through its revived model of cooperative federalism to inject substantial investment through the States into major transportation projects; and an infrastructure advisory body had been established (Albanese 2008). Finally, there has been the most benign external environment ever faced by the Australian economy in a recession. The coordinated and comprehensive response of the world’s major economies meant that Australia stood to benefit from a ‘global Keynesianism’. The contrast between that coordinated 364 A. FENNA international response and the beggar-thy-neighbour policies of the 1930s could not be starker. And it was not just the advanced economies. China responded to decline in demand for its manufactured exports by implementing a very large-scale Keynesian program of steel-based infrastructure investment. Australia benefited thus not just from the global Keynesianism but, most particularly, from the fact that the usual collapse in demand for its resource exports did not occur; this was the decisive factor in Australia’s outstanding success. Although the advanced economies in general experienced an 11.7% fall in exports in 2009, Australia’s exports grew by 0.6% (Treasury 2010). The extraordinary rise in Australia’s terms of trade of the past few years was briefly arrested, but only briefly; within months the minerals boom was back on and the talk was again of skills shortages. Again, the contrast with the 1930s could not be greater. Results Judging by the results, Australia’s born-again Keynesianism has been a great success; as one of only three OECD countries to avoid recession, Australia’s performance has been outstanding. In the government’s view, this was the result of public spending, ‘contributing around 2 percentage points to annual GDP growth’ (Treasury 2010). In the previous year’s Budget Papers, when the emphasis was on justifying the budget blowout rather than celebrating its success, Treasury noted, however, that a good part of the stimulatory deficit was entirely involuntary – deriving automatically from the downturn’s widening scissors effect of declining tax take and rising transfer payments. Indeed, the 2009 Budget Papers estimated that fully two-thirds to threequarters of the ‘deterioration in the budget position’ was to be accounted for this way (Treasury 2009). Thanks to the ‘automatic stabilisers’, any modern budget has Keynesian qualities under these circumstances unless governments take deliberate action to neutralise or moderate their effects (van den Noord 2000; also Darby and Melitz 2008). Most economic analysis points to the automatic stabilisers as not only making a substantial contribution to macroeconomic management, but as being, in most circumstances, a better tool than the discretionary fiscal policy that is often thought of as being what Keynesianism is about (Hemming, Mahfouz and Schimmelpfennig 2002; Taylor 2000). Ultimately, this points the way to propositions that Australia adopt a more cybernetic approach to macroeconomic fiscal policy, insulating it from the political process a là monetary policy (BCA 1999; Gruen 1997, 2000). The challenge of an active countercyclical public investment strategy has always been appropriateness and timeliness. Keynes advocated public works in a period when there was all too little danger of being caught out by a rapid recovery. Although measures such as the October 2008 stimulus package have the great advantage of taking immediate effect, using infrastructure investment as a countercyclical tool is enormously more challenging. Major capital works can easily take years from conception to full-scale construction. This is even more the case if, as the OECD (2009a) enjoins, they only proceed after being ‘carefully’ selected on the basis of cost–benefit analysis – for they must also be sound expenditures in their own THE RETURN OF KEYNESIANISM 365 right.4 Keynes ([1931] 1972, 139) verged on the reckless in this respect, suggesting in all seriousness that the government ‘pull down the whole of South London from Westminster to Greenwich’ and rebuild it as a public works project. There has been ample evidence that the Rudd government’s capital works spending on home insulation and school building has been compromised by the urgency. However, from a macroeconomic perspective, the main problem has been the perennial one of mistiming. The greatest part of the ‘Building the Education Revolution’ construction projects simply failed to get underway until the recession was over (Auditor-General 2010, 15–16). Conclusion Keynesianism’s enduring attraction lies in its promise that we can assert democratic control over one of the most important aspects of the capitalist economy – the supply of jobs. There is broad consensus that an international willingness to implement strong countercyclical fiscal policy was instrumental in averting an economic crisis of Depression-like dimensions in 2009. Under the Labor government, Australia led the way in that initiative and performed exceptionally. This paper has argued that only a highly unusual set of circumstances made Australia’s discretionary deficit spending look as appropriate and effective as it was. Critics such as Hay (2007) or Bell (2000) promote the idea that being Keynesian means spending one’s way to full employment and that anything less is evidence of a putative ‘neoliberalism’. This is the fallacy of ‘fiscalism’ – the ‘myth’ (Sheehan 2009, 246) that Keynesianism is defined by a fiscal, rather than a monetary, approach to countercyclical demand management and the use of fiscal stimulus, regardless of potentially adverse effects. This sort of myth has been sustained by another set of myths about the lessons to be learned from recessions (and economic booms) past. In particular, the sort of lessons from the Great Depression that the Prime Minister called upon to justify his government’s energetic fiscal policy would seem to be entirely mythical in both the colloquial sense of being only tenuously connected to reality, and in the technical sense of being a symbolically powerful interpretation of the past constructed to serve particular purposes in the present. If there are lessons to be drawn from Australia’s experience in the Great Depression – other than to tie oneself economically to a rising rather than a declining power – they are about the importance of starting from a strong budgetary position and following appropriate monetary policy. Keynesianism is about calibrating monetary and fiscal policy to favour full employment in the short term without creating lasting problems of debt or inflation. It entails investing in fiscal stimulus in conditions where substantial economic resources, both capital and labour, are idle; inflationary dangers are 4 This is redolent of Myrdal’s (1939, 193–4) otherwise very strong endorsement of his government’s deficit-spending program in the early 1930s. ‘Public works were generally begun too late; they were not prepared in advance and were, for this reason, delayed and scarcely aimed at the works which should have been selected before all others if a rational choice had been made. They were usually of much smaller scope than would otherwise have been desirable.’ 366 A. FENNA minimal; and current account problems do not threaten. Commitment to balancing the budget over the cycle is in no way contrary to Keynesianism and, indeed, is integral to Keynesianism-in-practice, as emphasised by Myrdal. Deliberate deficit spending to provide demand-side stimulation is the epitome of Keynesianism, but it is by no means everything that Keynesianism is about or implies. Conveniently for a party of the Left, the Rudd government came to office when an unusual combination of fiscal and economic circumstances made such classically Keynesian methods applicable once more: public debt had been retired; inflation rates were low; other, larger countries were following suit; and infrastructure backlogs beckoned. Ultimately, though, China’s success in maintaining its apparently insatiable demand for Australian resources was the key to Australia’s performance. The reality is that Keynesianism was developed as an alternative to procyclical policies in an era of deflation. There has been no deflation in this crisis and with the automatic stabilisers, there is little or no danger of perversely procyclical budgeting occurring. Discretionary deficit spending has been feasible for the first time in a long time, but given its limited impact, contribution to debt, administrative problems, waste and inefficiency, and inevitable lags, it may not have been advisable. References Ahamad, L. 2009. Lords of Finance: The Bankers Who Broke The World. New York: Penguin. Akerlof, G.A. 2007a. ‘The Missing Motivation in Macroeconomics.’ American Economic Review 97(1): 5–36. Akerlof, G.A. 2007b. ‘The New Case for Keynesianism.’ Challenge 50(4): 5–16. Albanese, A. 2008. A New Era in ‘‘Nation Building’’ Begins Today. Canberra: Commonwealth Government. Allsopp, C. and A. Glyn. 1999. ‘The Assessment: Real Interest Rates.’ Oxford Review of Economic Policy 15(2): 1–16. Arestis, P. and M. Sawyer. 2001. ‘The Economic Analysis Underlying the Third Way.’ New Political Economy 6(2): 255–78. Arestis, P. and M. Sawyer. 2003. ‘Reinventing Fiscal Policy.’ Journal of Post Keynesian Economics 26(1): 3–25. Arestis, P. and M. Sawyer. 2004. Re-examining Monetary and Fiscal Policy for the 21st Century. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. Auditor-General. 2010. Building the Education Revolution—Primary Schools for the 21st Century. Canberra: Australian National Audit Office. Ball, L. and N.G. Mankiw. 1995. ‘Relative-Price Changes as Aggregate Supply Shocks.’ Quarterly Journal of Economics 110(1): 161–93. Barnard, A. 1987. ‘Government Finance.’ In Australians: Historical Statistics, ed. W. Vamplew. Broadway, NSW: Fairfax, Syme and Weldon. Battin, T. 1997. Abandoning Keynes: Australia’s Capital Mistake. South Melbourne: Macmillan. BCA [Business Council of Australia]. 1999. Avoiding Boom/Bust: Macro-economic Reform for a Globalised Economy. Melbourne: Business Council of Australia. BCA [Business Council of Australia]. 2009. BCA Budget Submission 2009–10: How Can We Foster and Support Economic Resilience? Melbourne: Business Council of Australia. Beaud, M. 2001. A History of Capitalism, 1500–2000. New York: Monthly Review Press. Bell, S. 2000. ‘The Unemployment Crisis and Economic Policy.’ In The Unemployment Crisis in Australia: Which Way Out?, ed. S. Bell. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Bell, S. 2004. Australia’s Money Mandarins: The Reserve Bank and the Politics of Money. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Bernanke, B.S. 1995. ‘The Macroeconomics of the Great Depression: A Comparative Approach.’ Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 27(1): 1–28. Bernanke, B.S. 2003. ‘Remarks.’ Speech on the Legacy of Milton and Rose Friedman’s Free to Choose to Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas Conference, 24 October, Dallas, TX. THE RETURN OF KEYNESIANISM 367 Beyer, A., V. Gaspar, C. Gerbeding and O. Issing. 2010. ‘Opting Out of the Great Inflation: German Monetary Policy After the Breakdown of Bretton Woods.’ Paper presented to Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association, 4 January, Atlanta, GA. Bibow, J. 2002. ‘Keynes on Central Banking and the Structure of Monetary Policy.’ History of Political Economy 34(4): 749–787. Blanchard, O. and R. Perotti. 2002. ‘An Empirical Characterization of the Dynamic Effects of Changes in Government Spending on Output.’ Quarterly Journal of Economics 107(4): 1329–68. Bleaney, M. 1985. The Rise and Fall of Keynesian Economics: An Investigation of its Contribution to Capitalist Development. Basingstoke: Macmillan. Blinder, A.S. 1982. ‘The Anatomy of Double-Digit Inflation.’ In Inflation: Causes and Effects, ed. R.E. Hall. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press. Blinder, A.S. 1988. ‘The Fall and Rise of Keynesian Economics.’ Economic Record 64(187): 278–94. Blinder, A.S. and J.B. Rudd. 2010. ‘The Supply-Shock Explanation of the Great Stagflation Revisited.’ Paper presented to the Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association, 4 January, Atlanta, GA. Boltho, A. 1989. ‘Did Policy Activism Work?’ European Economic Review 33(9): 1709–26. Cecchetti, S.G. 1992. ‘Prices During the Great Depression: Was the Deflation of 1930–1932 Really Unanticipated?’ American Economic Review 82(1): 141–56. Chari, V.V. and P.J. Kehoe. 2006. ‘Modern Macroeconomics in Practice: How Theory is Shaping Policy.’ Journal of Economic Perspectives 20(4): 3–28. Clift, B. and J. Tomlinson. 2007. ‘Credible Keynesianism? New Labour Macroeconomic Policy and the Political Economy of Coarse Tuning.’ British Journal of Political Science 37(1): 47–69. Coddington, A. 1976. ‘Keynesian Economics: The Search for First Principles.’ Journal of Economic Literature 14(4): 1258–73. Cusack, T.R. 2001. ‘Partisanship in the Setting and Coordination of Fiscal and Monetary Policies.’ European Journal of Political Research 40(1): 93–115. Darby, J. and J. Melitz. 2008. ‘Social Spending and Automatic Stabilizers in the OECD.’ Economic Policy 23(56): 715–56. De Long, J.B. 1997. ‘America’s Peacetime Inflation: The 1970s.’ In Reducing Inflation: Motivation and Strategy, eds C.D. Romer and D.H. Romer. Chicago IL: University of Chicago Press. De Long, J.B. 2000. ‘The Triumph of Monetarism?’ Journal of Economic Perspectives 14(1): 83–94. Dow, G. 2008. ‘The Institutional Intractability of Recession.’ Journal of Australian Political Economy 61: 134–55. Edwards, J. 2006. Quiet Boom: How the Long Economic Upswing is Changing Australia and its Place in the World. Sydney: Lowy Institute. Eichengreen, B.J. 1992. Golden Fetters: The Gold Standard and the Great Depression. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Eichengreen, B. and P. Temin. 2003. ‘Ideology and the Shadow of History: A Perspective on the Great Depression.’ In The Economic Future in Historical Perspective, eds P.A. David and M. Thomas. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Feiwel, G.R. 1975. The Intellectual Capital of Michaeł Kalecki: A Study in Economic Theory and Policy. Knoxville, TN: University of Tennessee Press. Fenna, A. 2007. ‘Governing in Good Times: Fiscal Policy and Tax Reform in Australia 1996– 2006.’ Australian Journal of Political Science 42(2): 329–50. Fisher, C. and C. Kent. 1999. ‘Two Depressions, One Banking Collapse.’ In Research Discussion Papers. Sydney: Reserve Bank of Australia. Glyn, A. 1995. ‘Social Democracy and Full Employment.’ New Left Review 211: 33–55. Gregory, R.G. 1991. ‘How Much are Australia’s Economy and Economic Policy Influenced by the World Economy?’ In Australia Compared: People, Policies and Politics, ed. F.G. Castles. North Sydney: Allen & Unwin. Gruen, N. 1997. ‘Making Fiscal Policy Flexibly Independent of Government.’ Agenda 4(3): 297–307. Gruen, N. 2000. ‘Odysseus and the Sirens: A Vision of Our Fiscal Future.’ Agenda 7(3): 195–206. Gruen, D. and C. Clark. 2009. What Have We Learnt? The Great Depression in Australia from the Perspective of Today. Presented at the 19th Annual Colin Clark Memorial Lecture, 11 November, Brisbane. URL: 5http://www.treasury.gov.au/documents/1689/PDF/03_Colin_ Clark_speech.pdf4. Gruen, D. and G. Stevens. 2000. ‘Australian Macroeconomic Performance and Policies in the 1990s.’ In The Australian Economy in the 1990s, eds D. Gruen and S. Shrestha. Sydney: Reserve Bank of Australia. Hall, P.A., ed. 1989. The Political Power of Economic Ideas: Keynesianism Across Nations. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. 368 A. FENNA Hall, T.E., and J.D. Ferguson. 1998. The Great Depression: An International Disaster of Perverse Economic Policies. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press. Hay, C. 2004. ‘Credibility, Competitiveness and the Business Cycle in ‘‘Third Way’’ Political Economy: A Critical Evaluation of Economic Policy in Britain Since 1997.’ New Political Economy 9(1): 39–56. Hay, C. 2007. ‘What’s in a Name? New Labour’s putative Keynesianism.’ British Journal of Political Science 37(1): 187–92. Hemming, R,. S. Mahfouz and A. Schimmelpfennig. 2002. ‘Fiscal Policy and Economic Activity During Recessions in Advanced Economies.’ In IMF Working Papers. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. Hibbs, D.A. 1977. ‘Political Parties and Macroeconomic Policy.’ American Political Science Review 71(4): 1467–87. Hindmoor, A. 2005. New Labour at the Centre: Constructing Political Space. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Hughes, B. 2001. ‘Can the ‘‘Ready Shelf’’ be Restored to the Shelf?’ In Riding the Roller-coaster: The Role of Fiscal Policy in Avoiding and Easing Recessions, ed. ACOSS. Redfern, NSW: Australian Council of Social Service. IMF [International Monetary Fund]. 2008. World Economic Outlook: Housing and the Business Cycle. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. IMF [International Monetary Fund]. 2009a. World Economic Outlook: Crisis and Recovery. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. IMF [International Monetary Fund]. 2009b. World Economic Outlook: Sustaining The Recovery. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. Johnson, P.A. 1998. The Government of Money: Monetarism in Germany and the United States. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press. Kaldor, N. 1976. ‘Inflation and Recession in the World Economy.’ Economic Journal 86(344): 703–14. Kalecki, M. 1943. ‘Political Aspects of Full Employment.’ Political Quarterly 14(4): 322–31. Kalecki, M. [1944] 1990. Three Ways to Full Employment. In Capitalism: Business Cycles and Full Employment, ed. J. Osiatyński. Oxford: Clarendon Press. Keynes, J.M. [1926] 1972. ‘Liberalism and Labour.’ In Essays in Persuasion, ed. D.E. Moggridge. London: Macmillan. Keynes, J.M. [1931] 1972. ‘The Problem of Unemployment — II.’ In Essays in Persuasion, ed. D.E. Moggridge. London: Macmillan. Keynes, J.M. 1932. ‘J.M. Keynes Reviews Australia’s Position.’ The Herald. 27 June. Keynes, J.M. 1936. The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. London: Macmillan. Kindleberger, C.P. 1986. The World in Depression 1929–1939. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press. Krugman, P. 2008. The Return of Depression Economics and the Crisis of 2008. New York: Norton. Leeson, R. 2001. The Eclipse of Keynesianism: The Political Economy of the Chicago CounterRevolution. Basingstoke: Palgrave. Leijonhufvud, A. 1968. On Keynesian Economics and the Economics of Keynes: A Study in Monetary Theory. New York: Oxford University Press. Lerner, A.P. 1943. ‘Functional Finance and the Federal Debt.’ Social Research 10: 38–51. López, G.J. 2003. ‘Budget Deficits.’ In The Elgar Companion to Post Keynesian Economics, ed. J.E. King. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. Macfarlane, I. 1997. ‘The Economics of Nostalgia.’ Reserve Bank Bulletin (March): 1–7. Macfarlane, I.J. 2005. ‘Global Influences on the Australian Economy.’ Reserve Bank Bulletin (July): 1–6. Mankiw, N.G. 1992. ‘The Reincarnation of Keynesian Economics.’ European Economic Review 36(2–3): 559–65. Mankiw, N.G. 2006. ‘The Macroeconomist as Scientist and Engineer.’ Journal of Economic Perspectives 20(4): 29–46. Marglin, S.A. 1990. ‘Lessons of the Golden Age: An Overview.’ In The Golden Age of Capitalism: Reinterpreting the Postwar Experience, eds S.A. Marglin and J.B. Schor. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Markwell, D.J. 2000. ‘Keynes and Australia.’ In Research Discussion Papers. Sydney: Reserve Bank of Australia. Mayer, T. 1998. Monetary Policy and the Great Inflation in the United States: The Federal Reserve and the Failure of Macroeconomic Policy, 1965–79. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar. Modigliani, F. 1977. ‘The Monetarist Controversy or, Should We Forsake Stabilization Policies?’ American Economic Review 67(2): 1–19. Moggridge, D.E. and S. Howson. 1974. ‘Keynes on Monetary Policy, 1910–1946.’ Oxford Economic Papers 26(2): 243–5. THE RETURN OF KEYNESIANISM 369 Moschonas, G. 2002. In the Name of Social Democracy: The Great Transformation From 1945 to the Present, revised ed. London: Verso. Myrdal, G. 1939. ‘Fiscal Policy in the Business Cycle.’ American Economic Review 29(Suppl.): 183–93. Nelson, E. 2005. ‘Monetary Policy Neglect and the Great Inflation in Canada, Australia, and New Zealand.’ International Journal of Central Banking (May): 133–79. Nevile, J. 2000. ‘Can Keynesian Policy Stimulate Growth in Output and Employment?’ In The Unemployment Crisis in Australia: Which Way Out?, ed. S. Bell. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. van den Noord, P. 2000. The Size and Role of Automatic Stabilisers in the 1990s and Beyond. Economics Department Working Papers. Paris: OECD. Notermans, T. 2000. Money, Markets, and the State: Social Democratic Economic Policies since 1918. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. OECD [Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development]. 2009a. Economic Policy Reforms: Going for Growth 2009. Paris: OECD. OECD [Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development]. 2009b. OECD Economic Outlook. Paris: OECD. Overy, R. 2009. The Morbid Age: Britain Between the Wars. London: Allen Lane. Phillips, A.W. 1958. ‘The Relationship Between Unemployment and the Rate of Change of Money Wages in the United Kingdom, 1861–1957.’ Economica 25(100): 283–99. Pierson, C. 2001. Hard Choices: Social Democracy in the Twenty-First Century. Cambridge: Polity. Ridout, H. 2009. Federal Budget ‘A Matter of Give and Take’. Canberra: Australian Industry Group. Romer, C.D. 1992. ‘What Ended the Great Depression?’ Journal of Economic History 52(4): 757–84. Romer, D. 1993. ‘The New Keynesian Synthesis.’ Journal of Economic Perspectives 7(1): 5–22. Romer, C.D. and D.H. Romer. 2002. ‘The Evolution of Economic Understanding and Postwar Stabilization Policy.’ Presented at the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City symposium ‘Rethinking Stabilization Policy’, 29–31 August, Jackson Hole, WY. Rowse, T. 2002. Nugget Coombs: A Reforming Life. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Rudd, K. 2009. ‘Pain on the Road to Recovery.’ Sydney Morning Herald. 25 July. Sakamoto, T. 2008. Economic Policy and Performance in Industrial Democracies: Party Governments, Central Banks and the Fiscal–Monetary Policy Mix. London: Routledge. Samuelson, P.A. 1944a. ‘Unemployment Ahead: I. A Warning to the Washington Experts.’ New Republic 111(11): 297–9. Samuelson, P.A. 1944b. ‘Unemployment Ahead: II. The Coming Economic Crisis.’ New Republic 111(12): 333–5. Schedvin, C.B. 1970. Australia and the Great Depression: A Study of Economic Development and Policy in the 1920s and 1930s. Sydney: Sydney University Press. Sheehan, B. 2009. Understanding Keynes’ General Theory. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. Spilimbergo, A., S. Symansky, O. Blanchard and C. Cottarelli. 2008. Fiscal Policy for the Crisis, IMF Staff Position Notes. Washington, DC: International Monetary Fund. Stevens, G. 2003. ‘Inflation Targeting: A Decade of Australian Experience.’ Reserve Bank Bulletin (April): 17–19. Taylor, J.B. 2000. ‘Reassessing Discretionary Fiscal Policy.’ Journal of Economic Perspectives 14(3): 21–36. Tily, G. 2007. Keynes’ General Theory, the Rate of Interest and ‘Keynesian’ Economics: Keynes Betrayed. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. Treasury. 2009. Budget Paper No. 1: Budget Strategy and Outlook 2009–10. Canberra: Commonwealth of Australia. Treasury. 2010. Budget Paper No. 1: Budget Strategy and Outlook 2010–11. Canberra: Commonwealth of Australia. Valentine, T. 1987. ‘The Depression of the 1930s.’ In The Australian Economy in the Long Run, eds R. Maddock and I.W. McLean. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Whitwell, G. 1986. The Treasury Line. North Sydney: Allen & Unwin. Whyman, P.B. 2006. Third Way Economics: Theory and Evaluation. Basingstoke: Palgrave Macmillan. Copyright of Australian Journal of Political Science is the property of Routledge and its content may not be copied or emailed to multiple sites or posted to a listserv without the copyright holder's express written permission. However, users may print, download, or email articles for individual use.