Labor Economics 5. Human Capital Martin Halla University of Innsbruck Department of Public Finance Last update: June 10, 2015 Martin Halla (U Innsbruck) Labor Economics — 5 1/29 Human Capital I Theory of compensating differentials suggests that wages will vary among workers because jobs are different I Wages also will vary because workers are different I I I Why do some workers obtain a lot of schooling, and other workers drop out at an early age? I I Trade-off between lower earnings today and higher earnings later; financial and institutional constraints Is the money spent on education is a good investment? I I Workers bring into the labor market a unique set of abilities and acquired skills, called human capital Most of our human capital is acquired in school and in formal and informal on-the-job training programs Rate of return to schooling compare vs. other investments We will assume: workers choose human capital to maximize the present value of lifetime earnings Martin Halla (U Innsbruck) Labor Economics — 5 2/29 women, but that there are substantial differences among racial and ethnic groups. By 2010, about 8 percent Market: of white personsSome did not have a high schoolFacts diploma, (I) as opposed Education inonly the Labor Stylized to 13 percent of African Americans and 34 percent of Hispanics. In contrast, more than 38 percent of whites had at least a college diploma, as compared to only 20 percent of African Americans and 14 percent of Hispanics.1 TABLE 6-1 Educational Attainment of U.S. Population, 2010 (Persons Aged 25 and Over) Source: U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, Annual Demographic Supplement of the Current Population Surveys, March 2010. Highest Grade Completed (Percentage of Population in Education Category) Less Than High School Group All Persons Gender: Male Female Race/ethnicity: White Black Hispanic 1 High School Graduates Some College 11.6% 32.5% 16.8% 11.3 12.0 31.7 33.3 17.1 16.5 8.1 13.4 34.3 32.5 37.3 12.5 17.5 20.0 12.9 Associate Degree 9.1% Bachelor’s Degree Advanced Degree 19.4% 10.5% 10.2 8.0 18.4 10.4 10.2 10.9 9.7 9.4 6.3 26.4 13.3 10.1 11.9 6.6 3.8 A careful study of the differences in educational attainment among race/ethnic groups is given by I Little divergence Stephen V.across Cameron and James J. Heckman, “The across Dynamicsethnicities of Educational Attainment for Black, sexes, large differences Hispanic, and White Males,” Journal of Political Economy 109 (June 2001): 455–499. I Patterns are highly correlated with labor force participation rates, unemployment rates, and earnings (see next slide) Martin Halla (U Innsbruck) Labor Economics — 5 3/29 Education in the Labor Market: Some Stylized Facts (II) Human Capital 237 TABLE 6-2 Labor Market Characteristics, by Education Group, 2010 (Persons Aged 25–64) Source: U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, Annual Demographic Supplement of the Current Population Surveys, March 2010. Less Than High School High School Graduates Some College Labor force participation rate Unemployment rate Annual earnings (in $1000) 61.9 16.9 22.1 76.0 12.2 33.1 79.9 8.7 40.5 85.8 4.7 69.8 Labor force participation rate Unemployment rate Annual earnings (in $1000) 74.0 17.8 25.8 83.1 13.9 38.1 85.6 10.0 48.9 91.6 5.1 85.6 Labor force participation rate Unemployment rate Annual earnings (in $1000) 48.2 15.4 17.2 68.2 9.9 26.5 75.0 7.5 32.6 80.4 4.3 53.8 Labor force participation rate Unemployment rate Annual earnings (in $1000) 56.3 17.8 24.7 76.4 11.2 35.3 80.4 7.9 42.6 86.1 4.1 71.9 Black Labor force participation rate Unemployment rate Annual earnings (in $1000) 49.5 23.3 19.5 70.9 17.7 29.0 77.8 12.6 33.5 87.2 7.9 56.1 Hispanic Labor force participation rate Unemployment rate Annual earnings (in $1000) 69.6 15.3 21.1 79.0 12.3 28.2 80.9 9.7 36.3 84.8 5.6 57.9 All workers: Gender: Men Women Race/ethnicity: White College Graduates differences in educational attainment among workers are significant because, as I Education playsThe a crucial role in improving labor market out- comes for both men Table 6-2 shows, education is strongly correlated with labor force participation rates, and women and for workers in all racial groupsrate of persons who lack unemployment rates, and earnings. Theand labor ethnic force participation a high school diploma is only 62 percent, as compared to 86 percent for college graduates. Similarly, the unemployment rate of high school dropouts in the midst of a deep recession Martin Halla (U Innsbruck) Labor Economics — 5 4/29 Present Value I Any study of any investment decision must contrast expenditures and receipts incurred at different time periods I The notion of present value (P V ) allows us to compare dollar amounts spent and received in different time periods. I Assuming an discount rate of r, the P V of a payment y dollars next year is given by y PV = 1+r P V tells us how much needs to be invested today in order to have y dollars next year I I P V of y dollars received t years from now equals PV = Martin Halla (U Innsbruck) y (1 + r)t Labor Economics — 5 5/29 The Schooling Model I First analyzed by Jacob Mincer (JPE, 1958) I Workers acquire the education level that maximizes the PV of lifetime earnings I I Ignore other pos. effects of education (e.g., marriage market) Going to school involves two different types of costs 1. Opportunity cost: A year spent in school is a year spent out of the labor force (i.e., forgo some earnings) 2. Direct cost: tuition, books, and fees I Since school has no intrinsic value to the student, employers will have to offer higher wages I I Compensating wage differential for schooling costs See age-earnings profile (that is, the wage path over the life cycle) on next slide Martin Halla (U Innsbruck) Labor Economics — 5 6/29 Potential Earnings Streams I A high school graduate can earn wHS from age 18 until the age of retirement I If s/he decides to go to college, s/he forgoes these earnings and incurs a cost of H dollars for four years and then earns wCOL until retirement age I wCOL > wHS Martin Halla (U Innsbruck) Labor Economics — 5 7/29 Present Value of Age-Earnings Profiles I P V of the earnings stream for high school (HS) graduate P VHS = wHS + I wHS wHS wHS + ... + + (1 + r) (1 + r)2 (1 + r)46 (1) P V of the earnings stream for college (COL) graduate H H H P VCOL = −H − − − (1 + r) (1 + r)2 (1 + r)3 | {z } Direct cost wCOL wCOL wCOL + + + ... + (1 + r)4 (1 + r)5 (1 + r)46 | {z } (2) Post-college Earnings Stream I College attendance if: P VCOL > P VHS I Discount rate plays a crucial role I The higher the rate of discount (less value is attached to future earnings), the less likely a worker will invest in education Martin Halla (U Innsbruck) Labor Economics — 5 8/29 The Wage-Schooling Locus I Wage-schooling locus gives the salary that a particular worker would earn if he completed a particular level of schooling I If the worker graduates from high school, he earns $20,000 annually. I If he goes to college for one year, he earns $23,000. Martin Halla (U Innsbruck) Labor Economics — 5 9/29 The Wage-Schooling Locus Is I Market determined: salary for each level of schooling is determined by the intersection of the supply demand for those particular workers I Upward sloping: To attract educated workers, employers must compensate those workers for the costs incurred in acquiring an education I Slope: provides the rate of return to schooling (increase in wage due to an additional year of schooling) I Is concave: Law of diminishing returns applies to human capital accumulation. Each extra year of schooling generates less incremental knowledge and lower additional earnings than previous years. Martin Halla (U Innsbruck) Labor Economics — 5 10/29 The Schooling Decision I MRR schedule gives the marginal rate of return to schooling (i.e, % increase in earnings resulting from an additional year of school: ∆w/∆s) I Maximization of P V of lifetime earnings: go to school until the marginal rate of return to schooling equals the rate of discount I Optimal stopping rule I A worker with discount rate r goes to school for s∗ years I A worker with discount rate r 0 goes to school for s years Martin Halla (U Innsbruck) Labor Economics — 5 0 11/29 The Schooling Decision: Further Aspects I Other benefits of education I Idisyncratic-factors: chance encounters with influential teachers or ‘significant others’ I Uncertainty in the rewards to particular types of education I We assumed that students the shape of the wage-schooling locus I Economic and social conditions change in unpredictable ways I Martin Halla (U Innsbruck) Labor Economics — 5 12/29 Education and Earnings I I I I I Martin Halla (U Innsbruck) Labor Economics — 5 13/29 Schooling and Earnings: Different Rates of Discount Figure : Al has a higher rate of discount (rAL ) than Bo (rBO ), so that Bo graduates from high school but Al drops out. Al chooses point PAL on the wage-schooling locus and Bo chooses point PBO . The observed data on wages and schooling in the labor market trace out the common wage-schooling locus of the workers. As long as workers differ only in their discount rates, therefore, we can calculate the marginal rate of return to schooling from the wage differential between two workers who differ in their educational attainment. Martin Halla (U Innsbruck) Labor Economics — 5 14/29 Schooling and Earnings: Different Abilities Figure : Ace and Bob have the same discount rate (r), but each worker faces a different wage-schooling locus. Ace drops out of high school and Bob gets a high school diploma. The wage differential between Bob and Ace (or wHS − wDROP ) arises both because Bob goes to school for one more year and because Bob is more able. As a result, this wage differential does not tell us by how much Ace’s earnings would increase if he were to complete high school (or wACE − wDROP ). Martin Halla (U Innsbruck) Labor Economics — 5 15/29 Estimating the Rate of Return to Schooling I I I I I Martin Halla (U Innsbruck) Labor Economics — 5 16/29 Policy Application: School Construction in Indonesia I I I I I Martin Halla (U Innsbruck) Labor Economics — 5 17/29 Policy Application: School Quality and Earnings I I I I I Martin Halla (U Innsbruck) Labor Economics — 5 18/29 School Quality and the Rate of Return to Schooling Figure : Source: David Card and Alan B. Krueger, "Does School Quality Matter? Returns to Education and the Characteristics of Public Schools in the United States," Journal of Political Economy 100 (February 1992), Tables 1 and 2. The data in the graphs refer to the rate of return to school and the school quality variables for the cohort of persons born in 1920-1929. Martin Halla (U Innsbruck) Labor Economics — 5 19/29 Do Workers Maximize Lifetime Earnings? I I I I I Martin Halla (U Innsbruck) Labor Economics — 5 20/29 Schooling as a Signal I I I I I Martin Halla (U Innsbruck) Labor Economics — 5 21/29 Education as a Signal Figure : Workers get paid $200,000 if they get less than ȳ years of college, and $300,000 if they get at least ȳ years. Low-productivity workers find it expensive to invest in college, and will not get ȳ years. High-productivity workers do obtain ȳ years. As a result, the worker’s education signals if he is a low-productivity or a high-productivity worker Martin Halla (U Innsbruck) Labor Economics — 5 22/29 Postschool Human Capital Investments I I I I I Martin Halla (U Innsbruck) Labor Economics — 5 23/29 Age-Earnings Profiles of Full-Time Workers, 2010 Figure : Source: U.S. Bureau of Labor Statistics, Annual Demographic Supplement of the Current Population Surveys, 2010. Martin Halla (U Innsbruck) Labor Economics — 5 24/29 On-the-Job Training I I I I I Martin Halla (U Innsbruck) Labor Economics — 5 25/29 On-the-Job Training and the Age-Earnings Profile I I I I I Martin Halla (U Innsbruck) Labor Economics — 5 26/29 The Acquisition of Human Capital over the Life Cycle Figure : The marginal revenue of an efficiency unit of human capital declines as the worker ages (so that M R2 0, the marginal revenue of a unit acquired at age 20, lies above M R3 0 ). At each age, the worker equates the marginal revenue with the marginal cost, so that more units are acquired when the worker is younger. Martin Halla (U Innsbruck) Labor Economics — 5 27/29 The Age-Earnings Profile Implied by Human Capital Theory Figure : The age-earnings profile is upward-sloping and concave. Older workers earn more because they invest less in human capital and because they are collecting the returns from earlier investments. The rate of growth of earnings slows down over time because workers accumulate less human capital as they get older. Martin Halla (U Innsbruck) Labor Economics — 5 28/29 Policy Application: Evaluating Government Training Programs I I I I I Martin Halla (U Innsbruck) Labor Economics — 5 29/29