01 The Great Enrichment & the Great Divergence Readings: Broadberry, et al. (2011); Allen, et al. (2011); Nordhaus (1996) Living standards • Living standards / standard of living • The quantity and quality of goods and services, material comforts, and leisure consumed by an individual (typically, the average individual in a society) • Material well-being • NOT happiness, satisfaction, purposefulness, pleasure, joy, etc. • NOT some normative level • i.e., NOT a standard to be achieved or some standard set by expectations Living standards in 1800 CE Source: Francisco Goya, Summer (1786-87) Living standards in 1800 CE Source: Clark (2007), pg. 38-39 Two phenomena: • The Great Enrichment • • • • Dierdre McCloskey’s term Modern living standards are vastly higher than living standards 200 years ago Growth rates in living standards are vastly faster than 200 years ago Even for relatively low-income economies! • The Great Divergence • The transition to modern economic growth happened in different places at different paces • Large differences in living standards between economies today Measuring living standards • Real GDP, • Market value of all final goods and services in produced in the economy in one year • Adjusted for prices • AKA real output, real income, real aggregate output, real aggregate income, economic output, etc. • Real GDP per capita, • Real GDP divided by population, = • AKA average output, average income, income per capita, output per capita, GDP per capita, etc. Why use GDP per captia not GDP? Economy #1 • $3,300 billion of real output ( ) 50 x larger economy than #2 • 194,000,000 people ( ) = $17,000 Economy #2 • $65 billion of real output ( ) • 580,000 people ( ) = $112,000 *IMF estimates, 2020, measured in 2020 international USD Source: https://ourworldindata.org/economic-growth Sophomoric criticism… “GDP per capita doesn’t measure X, therefore it’s a poor measure of living standards.” • Here X is some desirable attribute. • • • • Income equality Health Dire poverty Etc… • GDP per capita tends to be correlated with X Correlation coefficient, 1 Stronger negative correlation No correlation 0 Stronger positive correlation Perfect negative correlation +1 Perfect positive correlation Correlation Causation Gini Coefficient (2010-2018) Higher household pretax/transfer market income 1 inequality GDP per capita and Gini Coefficient (2010-2018) 0.9 0.8 0.7 R² = 0.1617 ZAF 0.6 NAM SWZ BRA BWA HND AGO LCA GNB COL PAN COG GTM CRI BEN SYC CMR NIC PRY MEX CHL ECU COM LSO MWI PHL ZWE RWA DOM GHA TCD TGO NGA PER UGA MDG CPV BOL COD TUR ARG USA HTI MYS IRN TZA SEN KENCIV DJI MAR BGR LKA URY IDN ISR MNE SLV BDI CHN GAB IND RUS BTN LTU MUS FJI YEM LAO THA GEO SRB ROU ITA GMB VNM LVA BFA ETH GBR ESP GRC ARM AUS CHELUX NER LBR SLE MKD TJKSDN PRT JPN CAN JOR GIN PAK PSE ALB MLI BIH NPL IRL TUN MNG MRT BGD LBNMDV HRV KOR FRADEU ARE EGY CYP MMR HUN ESTMLT POL AUT IRQ SWE DNK NLD KGZ DZA KAZ BEL FINISL NOR MDA UKR BLR SVK SVN CZE CAF 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 MOZ ZMBSTP 0.1 Most high income countries have extensive taxes & transfers. Gini coefficients for consumption are likely lower. 0 6 = 0.40 7 8 9 10 11 12 ln(GDP per capita, 2018), 2017 USD PPP Higher GDP per capita Caution: Correlation is NOT causation. Limited sample. Source: Penn World Table [link], United Nations [link], own analysis Labor sahre (as modeled by ILO) Higher fraction of real GDP accruing to 80 labor GDP per capita and labor share of income, 2017, latest available R² = 0.0674 70 CHE LSO NGA HND TTO NLD BELISL CHL ESP FRACAN AUT BRA DEU MDA BRB NIC USA ARG SVN ITA EST HRV BHS GIN GBRDNK AUS BDI FINSWE LUX CRI TCD CAF GUY OMN JPN PRT BOL ZAF HKG KOR LVA COG ISR ALB COL SRB NOR PRY ECU RUS CHN NZL AZE SVK CZE MLI ZMB DOMBGR GNQ GRC BLZ LAO LCA MOZ HTI BFA GEO TZA CYP MLT THA BLR HUN POL BRNSGP GHA INDAGO NAMVCT SUR LTU LBN MDG SLE URY BEN TKM DZA ARM PER FJIBWA MNE BTN MUS SLV TUN ROU ETH KEN MKD MAR MRT UKR YEM PAK DJICPV BIH MDV MYS UZB STPBGD KAZ VNMSWZ MNG GMB COD SYR TGO LBRGNB GTM UGA PSE IDNLKA KHM NPL ARE IRL JOR CMR TUR IRN RWA MWI EGY COM SDN MEX ZWE SEN SAU NER PAN BHR KWT TJK CIV IRQ GAB PHL 60 50 40 30 JAM 20 QAT 10 0 6 = +0.26 7 8 9 10 ln(GDP per capita, 2018), 2017 USD PPP 11 12 Higher GDP per capita Caution: Correlation is NOT causation. Source: Penn World Table [link], United Nations [link], own analysis Fraction <$1.90 USD PPP/day, 2008-18 More dire poverty = GDP per capita and Poverty ($1.90/day), 2008-2018, latest available 80 COD MDG BDI 70 MWI CAF MOZ 60 GNB RWA 50 ZMB NGA TGO MLI BEN TZA NER 40 BFA LBR UGA SLE TCD GIN HTI 20 YEM 10 SEN KENCOG ZWE STP ETH LSO 30 GMB 7 0.80 Note: Threshold value uses 2011 USD PPP CIV R² = 0.6355 SWZ CMR LAO IND ZAF COM HNDDJI BWA NPL BGD NAM SDNGHA GTM PHL SRB TJK MRT LCA BOL IDN GEO BRA MKD COL PAK ROU GAB ECU EGY NIC CPV PER IRQ ARM MMR VNM ALB MEX MNE PAN PRY BTN SLV FJI CRI SVK ITA BGR USA SYC PSEMARMDA ARG LTU GRC KGZ LVA LKA ESP JPN HUN DZA CHN HRV CAN MNG AUS DOM PRT CHL EST IRN POL AUT TUN GBR MUS ISR KOR SWE NLD NORLUX BIH FIN DNK URY TUR BEL IRL JOR THA BLR CYPCZE FRA DEU CHE UKR LBN MDV MYS KAZ RUS SVNMLT ISL ARE 0 6 AGO 8 9 10 11 12 ln(GDP per capita, 2018), 2017 USD PPP Higher GDP per capita Caution: Correlation is NOT causation. Limited sample. Source: Penn World Table [link], United Nations [link], own analysis Fraction <=$3.20 USD PPP/day, 2017 More dire poverty GDP per capita and Poverty ($3.20/day) 80 TZA 70 STP ZWE 60 R² = 0.6274 50 LSO 40 DJI HND 30 20 MMR KGZ 10 GEO BTN COL GAB PER BRA MKD SRB ECU ALB ARM ROUPAN PRY ARG CRIBGR IRN DOM MUS ITA CAN GRC LVA LTU TUR HUN HRV ESP MDA PRT CHL POL EST AUT RUS KAZ NLD UKR THA URY MLT BEL DNK CYP CZE FIN SWE BLR SVN FRA BOL SLV 0 7 = EGY IDN 7.5 0.79 Note: Threshold value uses 2011 USD PPP 8 8.5 9 9.5 10 10.5 11 NOR LUX CHE 11.5 12 ln(GDP per capita, 2018), 2017 USD PPP Higher GDP per capita Caution: Correlation is NOT causation. Limited sample. Source: Penn World Table [link], The World Bank [link], own analysis Fraction <=$5.50 USD PPP/day, 2017 More dire poverty GDP per capita and Poverty ($5.50/day) 100 TZA 90 STP ZWE 80 LSO 70 60 KGZ IDN MMR HND 50 GEO ARM BTN ALB GAB SLV COL BOL PER ECU BRA MKD SRB DOM MDA PRY IRN MUSROUPAN CRI ARG TUR THA BGR KAZ GRC UKR LTU ESP RUS HRV LVA ITA HUN URYCHL PRT POL EST BLR AUT SWE CZE NLD BEL MLT DNK CYP FRA FINCAN SVN 40 R² = 0.7602 30 20 10 0 7 = EGY DJI 7.5 0.87 Note: Threshold value uses 2011 USD PPP 8 8.5 9 9.5 10 10.5 11 NOR LUX CHE 11.5 12 ln(GDP per capita, 2018), 2017 USD PPP Higher GDP per capita Caution: Correlation is NOT causation. Limited sample. Source: Penn World Table [link], The World Bank [link], own analysis GDP per capita and life expectancy at birth, 2018 Longer life expectancy Life expectancy at birth (years) 90 85 HKG JPN SGP ESP ITA AUS CHE ISL ISR KOR SWE FRA MLT CAN GRCPRT NZL NLD NORLUX IRL FIN BEL AUT SVN GBRDEU CYP DNK QAT CRI CHL CZE BRB USA LBNMDV HRVPAN EST POL DMA ALB URY ARE OMN TUR SVK BIH BHR COLATG THAMNE LKA ECU DZA CHN HUN TUN ARG MAR PER IRN LCA MYS ROU SRBMEX BRA MKD LTU BRN VNM HND SAU KWT ARM MUS LVA BGR BLR KNA BLZPSE JAM JORPRY NIC GTM DOM BHS GEO TTO SYC KAZ AZE CPVSLV GRD RUS BGD UKR SYRPHL MDAVCT EGY UZB SUR BTN IDN BOL TJK NPL IRQ STP GUY MNG KHM IND BWA RWA TKM SEN LAO FJI PAK MDG DJI KEN GAB YEM ETH SDN TZA MRT COG COM GHA MWI LBR HTI UGA ZMB NAM ZAF NER GMB BEN BDI COD BFA GIN ZWE TGO AGO MOZ SWZ CMR GNQ GNB MLI CIV 80 75 70 R² = 0.652 65 60 55 TCD SLE CAF LSO NGA 50 45 40 6 = +0.81 7 8 9 10 ln(GDP per capita, 2018), 2017 USD PPP 11 12 Higher GDP per capita Caution: Correlation is NOT causation. Source: Penn World Table [link], United Nations [link], own analysis GDP per capita and Gender Inequality Index More gender inequality Gender Inequality Index, 2019 1 0.9 0.8 YEM 0.6 0.5 VEN 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0 4 = 0.85 R² = 0.7225 TCD 0.7 5 6 CAF MLI NER LBR CIV HTI SLE MRT COD GMB BEN BFA TGO COG SWZ IRQ MWI CMR TZA LSO SDN ZMB PAK GHA AGO BGD UGA SENSTP ZWE GAB MOZ KEN ETH BDI SYR GTM IDN MMR IND KHM GUY LAO IRNBWA DOM MAR NPL JOR EGY PRY NAM SUR PHL DZA NIC COL HND BTN BOL BLZ LBN BRA PAN ZAF RWA LKA LCA CPV JAM PER KGZ SLV ECU FJITHA MDV MUS BHS ARG TTO AZEMEX MNG GEO TJK TUR OMN VNM TUN UZB CRI URYROU BRN MYS BRB SAUKWT CHL ARM UKR HUN RUS BHRUSA BGR KAZ MDA SVK QAT ALB LVA MLT CHN BIH MKD CZE SRB BLR LTU NZL GBR GRC POL ISR MNEHRV AUS IRL CYP ESTJPN DEU PRT ESP ITACAN AUTARESGP LUX KOR SVN ISL FRA FIN NOR NLD CHE BEL SWE DNK 7 8 9 10 ln(GDP per capita, 2018), 2017 USD PPP 11 12 Higher GDP per capita Caution: Correlation is NOT causation. Source: Penn World Table [link], United Nations [link], own analysis GDP per capita and child labor, 2010-2019, latest available % of children age 5-17 engaged in child labor More children working in 80 dire conditions = 0.79 70 60 R² = 0.6211 50 ETH 40 NER BDI CAF COD 30 20 MWI 10 BFA TCD HTIGNB CMR NGA COM ZWE SLEGIN TZA BEN ZMB SEN TGO CIV NPL GHA RWA STPSDN UGA GMB COG LBR MRT MLILSO PAK KHM LAO AGO VNM PSE SLV SWZ BLZ 0 6 6.5 7 7.5 8 8.5 JAM 9 PRY MNG PER GUY GAB MNE MKD SRB DOM CHL BRA EGY MEX IRQ DZA SUR URY ARM COL ZAF BTN LCA ALB UKR PAN TUN JOR BRB GEO CRI BLR TKM TTO 9.5 ln(GDP per capita, 2018), 2017 USD PPP “Definition: Percentage of children ages 5–11 who, during the reference week, engaged in at least one hour of economic activity and/or involved in unpaid household services for more than 21 hours; children ages 12–14 who, during the reference week, engaged in at least 14 hours of economic activity and/or involved in unpaid household services for more than 21 hours; children ages 15–17 who, during the reference week, engaged in at least 43 hours of economic activity; or children ages 5–17 who, during the reference week, engaged in hazardous working conditions or any worst forms of child labor other than hazardous.” 10 10.5 11 Higher GDP per capita Caution: Correlation is NOT causation. Source: Penn World Table [link], United Nations [link], own analysis % under 5 Two SD below median height for age (according to WHO) More childhood malnutrition = 0.72 GDP per capita and childhood malnutrition, 2010-2019, latest available 80 70 60 BDI 50 NER GTM YEM COD MOZMDG MWI TCD RWA SDNPAK AGO CAF ETH NGA NPL IND LSOZMB BTN DJI LAO TZA BEN COM KHM BGD IDN GIN PHL LBR UGA SLE CMR BWA SYR GNB MLI ZAF KEN GNQ SWZ BFA ECU TGO ZWE VNM MRT NAM EGY HND HTI CIV COG MYS BRN GMB SEN PAN AZEMDV TJK LKAGAB NIC STP GHA BOL BLZ MAR SLV COL IRQ PER DZA ALB GUY GEO UZB URY TKMOMN THAMNE ARM MNG TTO BIH SUR MEX TUN CHN KAZ ARG SYC JOR BRB PSE JAM JPN DOM BRA BGR IRN KWT MDA PRY SRB TUR CRI MKD USA POL KOR DEU LCA AUS CHL 40 30 20 10 0 6 7 R² = 0.5142 8 9 10 ln(GDP per capita, 2018), 2017 USD PPP 11 12 Higher GDP per capita Caution: Correlation is NOT causation. Source: Penn World Table [link], United Nations [link], own analysis More murders per capita GDP per capita and homicide rate, 2013-2018, latest available 80 Homicides per 100,000 70 60 SLV 50 HND BLZ NGA VCTZAF 30 DMA 20 GTM CAF 10 UGA YEM TZA HTI RWA SLE BFA GNB BDI 0 6 = 0.33 R² = 0.1064 JAM LSO 40 7 BRA COL LCA MEX TTOBHS GUY URY SYC CRI IRQ DOM BRB GRD PAN RUS PER NIC CPVPHL PRY UKR BOL MNG ECU ZMB KEN SUR ARG KAZ USA LTU LVA CHL MDA PAK IND MUS THAMNE TUR IRN LBN HUN LKA BLR NPL FJI ALB GEO AZE MYS ESTMLT CAN BEL ARM FIN ISR MAR JOR CMR BGDGHA PSE DZA ROU SAU BGR CYP GBR SRB MKD FRA BTN BIH SWE UZB SVK BEN DNK AUT SYR ISL IRL QAT GRC DEU AUS PRT MDV POL NZL HKG CHE ESP ITA KOR NLDARE HRV CZE SVN NOR CHN BHR BRN IDN SEN OMN JPN LUX SGP SWZ 8 9 10 ln(GDP per capita, 2018), 2017 USD PPP 11 12 Higher GDP per capita Caution: Correlation is NOT causation. Source: Penn World Table [link], United Nations [link], own analysis GDP per capita and Political Rights, 2018 Political Rights, 2018 More political rights 50 45 40 NZL AUS NLD NOR SWE JPN CAN DNK URY GBR FIN PRT SVN BELDEU CHE IRL LTU BHS LUX BRBLCA CRI CYP EST ESP FRA MUS AUT DMA CHL CZE TWN ISL GHA CPV GRD HRV MNG BLZ KNASVKPOL MLT ISR ITA VCT ROU PAN LVA IND GRC STP SLV SUR JAM BEN ATG BGR ARGTTO KOR USA ZAF GUY PERBRA SEN NAM TUN IDN COL ALB BWA SLE SRB SYC BOL BTN HUN PHL PRY LBR LSO MWI MDA UKRGEO MEX DOM MNE NGA NPL ECU MDG LKA COM FJI BFA GTM TZA ZMB BIHMKD MOZ NER HND PAK KEN BGD CIV SGP MYS TGO MLI HTI GIN IRQ TUR GNB ARM HKG MAR MDV MMR KWT NIC KGZ JOR LBN UGA AGO DZA EGY ZWE KHM CMR MRT RWA QAT DJI IRN OMN THA BLR BRN RUS ARE KAZ BDICAF TCD ETH SDN COD GAB AZE VNM BHR COG TJK LAOSWZ YEM UZB GNQ SYR TKM SAU CHN 35 30 R² = 0.157 25 20 15 10 5 0 6 = +0.40 7 8 9 10 ln(GDP per capita, 2018), 2017 USD PPP 11 12 Higher GDP per capita Caution: Correlation is NOT causation. Source: Penn World Table [link], Freedom House [link], own analysis GDP per capita and Civil Rights, 2018 More civil liberties 60 FINSWE NLD NORLUX URY ISL BRB PRT NZL CAN AUS DNK CHL CHE IRL AUT TWN DMA ESTMLT ESP CYPCZE JPN BELDEU VCT GBR SVN USA CPV LCA CRI KNA LTU BHS ITA MUSSVK FRA LVA GRD KOR GRC BLZ ATG ARG HRV BEN STP MNG ROU POL PAN NAM ZAFBRA BGR TTO GHA SRB HKG SUR BWA HUN ISR SEN IND JAM GUY DOMMNE SYC PER TUN ALB BOL GEO SLE MWI MKD BFA LSO PRY UKR COL MEX SLV ECU FJI LBR PHL MDAIDN BIH ZMB GTM SGP CIV MOZ MDG NIC LBN COM LKA TZA NPL ARM TGO KEN NER MLI BTN MYS UGA HND BGDNGA THA DZA HTIGNB GIN PAK KGZ MAR JOR KWT BRN MRT MDV ZWE KHM COG DJI GAB MMR VNM KAZOMN QAT EGY AGO SWZ IRQ RWA BLR TUR RUS TCD CHN BDI COD CMR YEM ARE IRN LAO TJK BHR AZE ETH SAU UZB GNQ CAF TKM SDN SYR Civil Rights, 2018 50 R² = 0.2202 40 30 20 10 0 6 = +0.47 7 8 9 10 ln(GDP per capita, 2018), 2017 USD PPP 11 12 Higher GDP per capita Caution: Correlation is NOT causation. Source: Penn World Table [link], Freedom House [link], own analysis GDP per capita: Correlated with good things Positively correlated with: Negatively correlated with: • • • • • Inequality as measured by Gini coefficient (moderate) • % <=$1.90/day (strong) • % <=$3.20/day (strong) • % <=$5.50/day (very strong) • Gender inequality index (very strong) • % child labor (very strong) • Childhood malnutrition (strong) • Homicide rate (weak) Life expectancy at birth (very strong) Labor share (weak) Political rights (weak/moderate) Civil rights (weak/moderate) GDP per capita: Correlated with good things Positively correlated with: • • • • Negatively correlated with: Life expectancy birth (veryisstrong) Inequalitymeasure as measured by Gini coefficient GDP at per capita an excellent •catch-all for human (moderate) Labor share (weak) population well-being, as it is •correlated with(strong) most % <=$1.90/day Political rights (weak/moderate) everything one thinks of when• thinking about(strong) human well% <=$3.20/day Civil rights (weak/moderate) being. • % <=$5.50/day (very strong) • It’s not perfect, but it does•an outstanding Gender inequalityjob index (very strong) • What’s the superior alternative? • % child labor (very strong) • Childhood malnutrition (strong) • Homicide rate (weak) GDP per capita and UN Human Development Index (HDI), 2018 Higher HDI Human Development Index (HDI) 1 NOR IRL DEU ISL HKG SWE AUS NLD CHE DNK FIN BEL GBR CAN NZL AUTUSA SGP JPN ISR KOR LUX SVN ESP FRA MLT ITA ARE ESTCZE CYP GRC POL LTU LVA PRT SVK SAU BHR HUN CHL HRV QAT ARG BRN MNE BLRMYS ROU RUS KAZ TUR URY BGR OMN BHS PAN BRB CRI KWT GEO SRB MUS TTO ALB SYC IRN LKA BIH MEXKNA UKR GRD THA ATG ARM PER MKD COL BRA ECU LCA AZE DOM LBN DZACHN MDA FJI TUN DMA VCT MNG SUR JAM MDV BWA JOR PRY UZB BLZPSE BOL IDN PHL TKM ZAF EGY VNM GUY GAB MAR IRQ SLV CPV TJK NIC IND GTM NAMBTN HND STPBGDGHA LAOSWZ KEN NPL ZMB KHM AGO GNQ COG ZWE SYR CMR MRT COM PAK BEN RWA CIV NGA MDG UGA TZA LSO DJI SEN SDN HTI TGO GMB COD ETH MWI LBR GNB GIN YEM MOZ SLE BFAMLI BDI CAF NER TCD 0.9 0.8 0.7 0.6 0.5 0.4 R² = 0.8488 0.3 0.2 All HDI is measuring is GDP per captia!!! 0.1 0 = +0.92 6 7 8 9 10 ln(GDP per capita, 2018), 2017 USD PPP 11 12 Higher GDP per capita “Definition: A composite index measuring average • HDI is about 1/3 GDP per capita achievement in three basic dimensions of human • Life expectancy & educational attainment development—a long and healthy life, knowledge highly correlated w/ GDP per capita Caution: Correlation is NOT causation. and a decent standard of living.” Source: Penn World Table [link], United Nations [link], own analysis Levels vs. rates of change • Levels • Economic output (GDP, ) • Living standards (GDP per capita, ) • Rates of change • Economic growth rate per annum (how GDP changes each year, %) = • Growth rate of living standards p.a. (how GDP per capita changes each year, %) = y Measuring living standards over time • Economic growth • “sustained increase in the total output of goods and services produced by a given society” (Cameron & Neal, 2003, p. 8) • Sustained increase in real GDP • Long-run phenomenon • Do not confuse with “economic expansion” (a short-run, business cycle phenomenon) • Growth in living standards • Sustained increase in real GDP per capita over time • Since we’re looking at changes over time, we need to account for price changes over time… • Unless otherwise specified, I’ll always talk in real terms (i.e., inflation-adjusted) Measuring living standards over time • Economic development “economic growth accompanied by a substantial structural or organizational change in the economy, such as a shift from a local subsistence economy to markets and trade or the growth of manufacturing and service outputs relative to agriculture” (Cameron & Neal, 2003, p. 9) • Typically, • • • • Growing GDP per capita Growing urbanization Growing internal & external trade Shift from agriculture to manufacturing & services United Kingdom sectoral shares of GDP, 1381 CE - 1841 CE Sectoral share of GDP at current prices 50.00% 40.00% 30.00% 20.00% Agriculture Industry 10.00% 0.00% 1350 Structural change economic development Services 1450 1550 1650 1750 1850 Year Note: England only before 1700. Source: Broadberry, et al. (2011), p. 35 Two basic approaches estimating historical living standards over time Sector price Sector real output 1) Wage-based approach • Most people were workers, so use real wages • Archival data on wages & consumer prices • Some assumptions 2) Output-based approach • Archival data on outputs and prices of each of sub-sectors • Some assumptions • Sum them all up • Divide by population = • • • Agriculture • Grain • Beef • Etc. Industry • Metals • Textiles • Etc. Service • Commerce • Household • Etc. = N Adjusting for price changes • In history, no government-collected official CPI data • Step #1: calculate nominal prices for a basket of good • • • • Come up with a yearly consumer basket of goods Archival research/extrapolate/guess how much of each good is purchased ( ) Archival research/extrapolate/guess the price of each good each year ( ) Price of basket each year ( ) for goods: = + + + • Allen (2001) provides a typical example basket for Europe • Widely used/cited in economic history Add up the products × About 17 oz. of beer per day 410.074 Price of the yearly consumer basket in Strasbourg in 1745—1754 in grams of silver Note: The table reports rounded prices, but a non-rounded sum. I’ve added the correct sum (in red) from the rounded figures show. The non-rounded calculations are available here: [link] Source: Allen (2001), p. 421, own calculation Adjusting for price changes • Step #2: construct a price index • Put each year’s basket price in terms of some base year × 100 • Here, base year is 1500 • Example: 288.7821 147.7 195.5182 Consumer basket prices in London (grams of silver) 1300 1400 288.7821 292.3010 Price Index (1500=100) 147.7 149.5 1500 1600 1700 195.5182 457.5061 542.4459 100.0 234.0 277.4 1800 1,377.7546 704.7 Year ( ) Source: Robert Allen’s Research Website (accessed 7/28/21) [link], own calculations Adjusting for price changes • Step #3: For each year, divide nominal value by its price index number Nominal × 100 Price Index • Here, agricultural wages in Southern England ( ) to estimate living standards Daily wage of Southern England agricultural laborers (grams of silver) Year ( ) Price Index Nominal (1500=100) (grams of silver) 1300 147.7 1.9844 Real (1500 London prices) 1.34 1400 1500 149.5 100.0 3.8033 2.8768 2.54 2.88 1600 1700 234.0 277.4 4.1521 5.5679 1.77 2.01 1800 704.7 7.8879 1.12 Source: Robert Allen’s Research Website (accessed 7/28/21) [link], own calculations Output-based approach Modern-day (2018) equivalents GDP per capita, 2011 USD PPP United Kingdom GDP per capita, 1252 CE - 2018 CE $40,000 Belgium ($39,800) $35,000 New Zealand ($35,300) $30,000 Czech Rep. ($30,700) $25,000 Russia ($24,700) $20,000 Romania ($20,100) $15,000 Costa Rica ($14,700) $10,000 Ukraine ($9,800) Honduras ($5,000) $5,000 $0 1250 Malawi ($1,100) 1350 1450 1550 1650 1750 1850 1950 Year Note: England only before 1700. Sources: Broadberry, et al. (2015), Maddison Project Database 2020 [link] English Gini coefficient over time Gini coefficient interpretation: 0 = perfect equality 1 = perfect inequality Year 1688 1759 1798 1846 1867 Post-war period Today Gini Estimate 0.54 0.53 0.60 0.58 0.48 <0.30 0.40 Modern-day Brazil Pre-tax/transfer market income only Substantial taxes/transfers from 1945 onward, mean these are likely overestimates from a consumption perspective Source: Allen (2019), p. 110-111 (England) From the 1650s to the 1850s, the annual earnings of English agricultural workers (i.e., the lowest on the occupational hierarchy) rose in tandem with GDP per capita. Source: Modified from Humphries & Weisdorf (2017), p. 12; own edits Using the log of GDP per capita, ln Modern-day (2018) equivalents United Kingdom GDP per capita, 1252 CE - 2018 CE ln(GDP per capita, 2011 USD PPP) 11.5 11.0 Switzerland (11.0) 10.5 South Korea (10.5) 10.0 Chile (10.0) 9.5 Brazil (9.5) 9.0 Philippines (9.0) 8.5 Nicaragua (8.5) 8.0 Tanzania (8.0) 7.5 Ethiopia (7.5) 7.0 Malawi (7.0) 6.5 1250 Burundi (6.5) 1350 1450 1550 1650 1750 1850 1950 Year Note: England only before 1700. Sources: Broadberry, et al. (2015), Maddison Project Database 2020 [link], own calculations Calculating average yearly growth rate • Continuous compounding formula (PERT) = • is the future value • is the present (initial) value • is Euler’s number 2.71828 • is the continuous growth rate of value • is the number of years in the future Calculating average yearly growth rate • Example: Real GDP per capita in the United States is about $63,500. Predict what real GDP per capita in the United States will be in 20 years, continuously compounded at a 1.5% annual rate. $63,500 . × $85,716.03 • What if real GDP per capita only grows at a 1.0% annual rate? $63,500 . × $77,559.08 Notice: Small changes in growth rates compound greatly over time. Here, a 0.5pp slower grow . . rate reduced GDP per capita 20 years from now by × 100 9.5% . Calculating average yearly growth rate = • Re-arranging, ln = • For two years periods, = ln + ln ln ln ln and = Calculating average yearly growth rate = ln • For growth rate of living standards, ln = Year ln over two years ln Year = • Convention: multiply by 100% for percentage terms ln rise = = slope run Calculating average yearly growth rate • Example: Real GDP per capita in the United Kingdom in 1252 CE was $1,285. By 1649 CE, it was $1,508. Both figures are in 2011 USD PPP. Find the annual growth rate over this period. ln 1508 1649 7.318 1649 ln 1285 × 100 1252 7.185 × 100 1252 0.033% *I rounded the logs to the nearest thousandth for demonstration purposes. The answer is 0.04% if you don’t round. Sources: Broadberry, et al. (2015), Maddison Project Database 2020 [link], own calculations United Kingdom GDP per capita, 1252 CE - 2018 CE ln(GDP per capita, 2011 USD PPP) 11.5 Slope of line between two points on a log-GDP per capita graph is the average growth rate of GDP per capita over that period 11.0 10.5 10.0 9.5 9.0 8.5 8.0 1252-1649 7.318 Average 1649 growth rate: 0.03% p.a. 7.185 1252 0.00033 7.5 7.0 6.5 1250 1350 1450 1550 1650 1750 1850 1950 Year Note: England only before 1700. Growth rates calculated as average yearly growth rate. Sources: Broadberry, et al. (2015), Maddison Project Database 2020 [link], own calculations United Kingdom GDP per capita, 1252 CE - 2018 CE ln(GDP per capita, 2011 USD PPP) 11.5 11.0 10.547 9.311 2018 1950 10.5 10.0 9.5 9.0 8.5 8.0 1252-1649 Average growth rate: 0.03% p.a. 8.394 1849 7.277 1650 0.018 9.314 1949 0.0056 8.374 1850 0.0095 7.5 7.0 6.5 1250 1350 1450 1550 1650 1750 1850 1950 Year Note: England only before 1700. Sources: Broadberry, et al. (2015), Maddison Project Database 2020 [link], own calculations United Kingdom GDP per capita, 1252 CE - 2018 CE ln(GDP per capita, 2011 USD PPP) 11.5 1950-2018 Average growth rate: 1.8% p.a. 11.0 10.5 10.0 9.5 9.0 8.5 8.0 1650-1849 Average growth rate: 0.56% p.a. 1252-1649 Average growth rate: 0.03% p.a. 1850-1949 Average growth rate: 0.95% p.a. 7.5 7.0 6.5 1250 1350 1450 1550 1650 1750 1850 1950 Year Note: England only before 1700. Sources: Broadberry, et al. (2015), Maddison Project Database 2020 [link], own calculations The Great Enrichment GDP per capita, select European economies, 1250 CE - 2018 CE United Kingdom Netherlands France Spain Italy 11.5 ln(GDP per capita, 2011 USD PPP) 11 10.5 10 9.5 9 8.5 8 7.5 7 6.5 1250 1300 1350 1400 1450 1500 1550 1600 1650 1700 1750 1800 1850 1900 1950 2000 Note: United Kingdom is England only Year before 1700. Italy is Northern Italy only before 1871. Imagine error bars around each estimate. Sources: Broadberry, et al. (2015); Van Zanden & van Leeuwen (2012); Smits, et al. (2000); Scheidel & Friesen; Ridolfi (2016); Álvarez-Nogal & de la Escosura (2013); Malanima (2010); Baffigi (2011); Maddison Project Database 2020 [link]; own calculations GDP per capita, select Asian economies, 1250 CE - 2018 CE China India Japan Singapore 11.5 ln(GDP per capita, 2011 USD PPP) 11 10.5 10 9.5 9 8.5 8 7.5 7 6.5 1250 1300 1350 1400 1450 1500 1550 1600 1650 1700 1750 1800 1850 1900 1950 2000 Year Note: Imagine error bars around each estimate. Sources: Broadberry, et al. (2018); Xu, et al. (2016); Wu (2014); Broadberry, et al. (2015); Bassino, et al. (2018); Fukao, et al. (2015); Maddison Project Database 2020 [link]; own calculations GDP per capita, select American economies, 1250 CE - 2018 CE USA Mexico Argentina Peru Brazil 11.5 ln(GDP per capita, 2011 USD PPP) 11 10.5 10 9.5 9 8.5 8 7.5 7 6.5 1250 1300 1350 1400 1450 1500 1550 1600 1650 1700 1750 1800 1850 1900 1950 2000 Year Note: Imagine error bars Sources: McCusker, Sutch (2006), de la Escosura (2009), Abad & van Zanden (2016), Barro & Ursua (2008), around each estimate. Bertola & Ocampo (2012), Seminario (2015), Maddison Project Database 2020 [link]; own calculations GDP per capita, select African economies, 1250 CE - 2018 CE Egypt South Africa Angola Kenya Botswana 11.5 ln(GDP per capita, 2011 USD PPP) 11 10.5 10 9.5 9 8.5 8 7.5 7 6.5 1250 1300 1350 1400 1450 1500 1550 1600 1650 1700 1750 1800 1850 1900 1950 2000 Year Note: Imagine error bars around each estimate. Sources: Pamuk & Shatzmiller (2011), Pamuk (2006), Fourie & Van Zanden (2013), Maddison Project Database 2020 [link]; own calculations Increase in real GDP per capita from 1800 to 2018 1800 2018 How much better off? 11× 11× United Kingdom Netherlands $3,343 $4,184 $38,058 $47,474 United States China Japan $2,545 $926 $1,317 $55,335 $13,102 $38,674 22× 14× 29× Mexico South Africa $1,305 $1,529 $16,494 $12,166 13× 8× Note: All in 2011 USD PPP. Sources: Broadberry, et al. (2015); Van Zanden and van Leeuwen (2012); Sutch (2006); Prados de la Escosura (2009); Broadberry, et al. (2018); Xu, et al. (2016); Bassino, et al. (2018); Arroyo & van Zanden (2016); Fourie & Van Zanden (2013); Maddison Project Database 2020 [link]; own analysis But this underestimates improvement in living standards since 1800 CE 1) Improvements in life expectancy & health • Quantity & quality of life contribute to living standards • Life expectancy at birth ( ) is the average number of years somebody born at a certain time is expected to live 2) Improvements in leisure consumption • Leisure ( ) is time spent not working in the labor market 3) Technological change’s effect on consumption good quality and new consumption goods Jean Nocret’s The Family of Louis XIV, 1670 Elisabeth Marguerite dead at 49 Marguerite Louise Francois Madeleine dead at 76 dead at 15 Anne Marie dead at 65 (bladder infection) Henrietta of England Average age at King Louis XIV dead at 26 death of these dead at 76 Anne of Austria people: 36 years if Philippe I (gangrene) dead at 64 dead at 60 Queen Maria Theresa you include Louis François, 38 years (stroke) Marie Louise dead at 44 Henrietta Maria if you don’t (infection) dead at 26 dead at 59 Louis Philippe Charles (infection) (opioid overdose) dead at 49 dead at 3 (smallpox) Not pictured: (chest infection) Louis’s last son Marie Therese Ann & Marie Louis François, dead at 5 dead at 1 mo. dead at 5 mo. Sources: Charles (tuberculosis) Kenny & Wikipedia Source: Fogel (2004), p. 2 Anne, Queen of Great Britain (1702—1707) 17 pregnancies • 7 miscarriages • 5 still births • 5 live births • Mary, died at 20 months (smallpox) • Anne Sophia, died at 11 mo. • William, died at 11 years old (either scarlet fever or smallpox) • Mary, died after 2 hours • George, died after a few minutes Anne herself died at 49 years old (stroke). Sources: Phillip Magness & Wikipedia Source: Galor (2012) Crude, back-of-the envelope calculation = discount rate Example calculation for UK • Real GDP per capita in 1800: $3,343 • Real GDP per capita in 2018: $38,058 • That’s the 11 × increase Assuming = 0.03 & in 1800: 36 • = 0.011 • Discounted present value of lifetime average income $88,599 • • This is an underestimate • From 1800—2018 real income per capita grew ca. 1.1% per annum in 2018: 81 +45 years! • Discounted present value of lifetime average income $1,609,437 That’s an 18 × increase Here, ignoring life expectancy gains missed out on 40% of the gains in EPV lifetime income Source: Numbers from Fogel (2004), Broadberry, et al. (2015), Maddison Project Database (2020), United Nations, own analysis Late 20th century older veterans were less likely to have chronic diseases that older veterans in the early 20th century Source: Fogel (2004), p. 31 5’11” 5’7¾” 5’6” Average stature is far taller than in the past Source: Clark (2007), pg. 60 Improvements in life expectancy & health • For the USA from 1900 to 1995, the welfare gains from life-expectancy & health comparable to the gains from consumption (Nordhaus 2003) • This suggests that consumption alone underestimates improvement by approx. 50% • From 1960-2000 across the globe, the welfare gains from life expectancy & health comparable to the gains in income (Becker, et al. 2005) • For the poorest half of the globe, 40% of total welfare gains stemmed from life expectancy gains (Becker, et al. 2005) Improvements in life expectancy & health • Average incomes have risen relative to history, but so too has quantity and quality of life • only focusing on average incomes ignores the lifetime utility gains from longer life expectancy & health • improvements in average income underestimate improvements over historical living standards (well-being, utility) by a wide margin • People today are much better off relative to the past than implied only by per capita income b/c of improvements in life expectancy & health Leisure time • Leisure also enters the utility function ( , ) • Leisure ( ) is time spent not working in the labor market • “True leisure” • Household labor • Chores • Childcare Yes, chores make you better off! Time endowment Leisure time = + Market labor time • Over the past 150 years or so, in high-income countries, hours worked per year by employed persons have likely diminished substantially • Implies more Daily Time Use, Employed Adult Male 1800 CE London Daily Time Use, Employed Adult Male 2019 CE United States Other, 4 Sleep, 9 Work, 11 Other, 8.3 Personal care, including sleep, 9 Working and work-related, 6.7 Source: Voth (1998), American Time Use Survey [link] Daily Time Use, Employed Adult Male 1800 CE London Other, 4 Sleep, 9 Daily Time Use, Employed Adult Male 2019 CE United States Other (minus leisure & sports), 4.02 Other, 8.3 Personal Personal care, care, including sleep, including sleep, 99 Leisure & sports, 4.28 Work, 11 Workingand Working and workwork-related, related, 6.7 6.7 Work hours per day have fallen since 1800 Source: Voth (1998), American Time Use Survey [link] Work hours per week have fallen since 1900 The great decline in work hours in the USA occurred before Federal private sector collective bargaining rights & overtime rules Source: Sundstrom (2006) Annual hours of work (full-time employed workers) Select countries, 1870 CE -- 2000 CE Annual work hours 3200 Annual hours of work have fallen from 1870 2700 2200 1700 1200 1870 1890 1910 1930 1950 1970 1990 Year Australia France Germany UK USA Source: Huberman and Minns (2007), Table 3 Income elasticity: = % <0 inferior good >0 normal good <1 income inelastic > 1 income elastic Why have work hours fallen? Incomes are higher and people “buy” more leisure (income effect is greater than substitution effect) Leisure is an income elastic normal good People disproportionately “spent” increased incomes on leisure (not working) Source: Fogel (2004), p. 89 Increased “spending” on leisure Total real Real wage consumption = = = = = Labor time = + + • Can think of as real income • Can “spend” it on consumption or leisure (foregoing consumption) • What is the “price” of leisure? • Two effects as income rises • Income effect • Substitution effect and real Our previous comparisons were modern vs. 1800s People worked many more days per year in the 1800s than in the 1300s Supposing an 11 hour/day schedule, agricultural workers in 1400s CE England worked around 1,375 hours per year compared to 1,650 hours per year in England in 2000 Source: Humphries & Weisdorf (2019), p. 2880 Leisure time • Thus, GDP per capita underestimates the improvement in well-being and living standards because it doesn’t account for increased leisure time Real GDP per capita only measures this • People consume more stuff and more leisure time over longer, healthier lives Technology, quality improvement, and new goods • Inflation adjustments don’t take quality improvements in consumption goods due to technological change into account • Or quality improvement in leisure, for that matter… • Inflation adjustments don’t take new consumer goods from technological change into account • Therefore, they overestimate inflation and underestimate the change in real GDP per capita • i.e., traditional price indexes overestimate inflation over the long-run • things have improved versus history far, far more than the numbers suggest Hedonic adjustment • When you buy consumption goods, you’re buying service characteristics • Consumption goods are the input • Service characteristics are the output • For example, when you buy a lighting, some service characteristics • • • • • • • Illumination (measured in lumens) Wavelength Reliability Convenience Nordhaus: Let’s just focus on lumens Safety Durability Etc… Source: Nordhaus (1996), p. 45 “True” price of light • Lumens measure flow of light from source • Wax candle: 13 lumens • 100-Watt filament bulb: 1,200 lumens • 18-Watt compact florescent bulb: 1,290 lumens • Lighting efficiency: lumen hours per BTU Lumens per hour BTU (1,000s) • When you buy a source of light, it’s quality-adjusted “true” price is = Efficiency • Traditional price indexes ignore lighting efficiency and just measure prices of light sources. Source: Nordhaus (1996), p. 31 Source Open wood fire Approx. date Dawn of humankind Neolithic lamp with animal or 38,000 BCE to vegetable fat 9,000 BCE Babylonian lamp with sesame 1750 BCE oil Tallow candle 1800 CE Sperm oil lamp 1855 CE Kerosene lamp 1875-85 CE Edison bulb 1883 CE Filament bulb 1990 1st gen. compact florescent 1992 Lumen-hours per 1,000 BTU 0.69 4.4 17.5 22.2 23.0 46.6 762.0 4,152.0 20,011.1 Source: Nordhaus (1996), p. 36 “True” price of light • Modern 100-Watt incandescent bulb burning for 3 hours each night for a year • 1.5 million lumen-hours per year • Price: $1.86 (1992 $) • 8 minutes of work at 1992 CE average wage rate • 1800 CE, to get 1.5 million lumen-hours per year • 17,000 tallow candles • Price: $604 (1992 $) • Around 1,000 hours of work at average 1800 CE wage rate Source: Nordhaus (1996), p. 50-53, own calculations Date Hours worked True Price of per 1000 Lighting lumen-hours CPI “Light 1” “Light 2” Various traditional price indexes Price per 1000 lumen hours (efficiency/quality-adjusted) 500,000 BCE 10,000 BCE 1750 BCE 58 50 41.5 1800 1850 1900 5.4 3.0 0.2 100 92.5 10.0 100 62.3 67.0 100 59.8 55.0 100 59.8 55.0 1950 1992 0.002 0.0001 0.3 0.03 190.7 1066.3 85.2 503.9 65.8 281.1 Implies lighting prices 3,333x lower in 1992 versus 1800 Implies lighting prices 5x higher 1992 versus 1800 Note: True price is for technological frontier. Price indexes use 1800 as base year, i.e., 1800=100 Source: Nordhaus (1996), p. 46-47 Price indexes miss big technological changes • These big technological changes • Change the quality/efficiency of consumer goods • i.e., 1 BTU in 1800 buys a very different number of lumen-hours than in 1992 (or 2021) • Add new consumer options • Traditional price indexes adjust for neither • The bias is particularly bad in historical studies, where our indexes are prices consumer baskets held constant over time (Nordhaus 1996, p. 56) • Bias from not accounting for technological changes True Price ± Bias = Price Effect of price index bias • Even by 1800, already substantial improvements in the quality and composition of the consumer basket vs. 1300 • • • • • • Tea, sugar, tobacco, coffee Oranges, potatoes Coal instead of wood Earthenware instead of bark Cotton & silk instead of wool Gin instead of mead Daily wage of Southern England agricultural laborers (grams of silver) Year ( ) Price Index Nominal (1500=100) (grams of silver) Real (1500 London prices) 1300 1400 147.7 149.5 1.9844 3.8033 1.34 2.54 1500 1600 100.0 234.0 2.8768 4.1521 2.88 1.77 1700 1800 277.4 704.7 5.5679 7.8879 2.01 1.12 Effect of price index bias • Since the price index does not take these into account, it is an overestimate Daily wage of Southern England agricultural laborers (grams of silver) Year ( ) Price Index Nominal (1500=100) (grams of silver) Real (1500 London prices) • Since we divide nominal wage by the price index to get real, the real wage must be an… underestimate 1300 1400 147.7 149.5 1.9844 3.8033 1.34 2.54 1500 1600 100.0 234.0 2.8768 4.1521 2.88 1.77 • How much? Difficult to say… 1700 1800 277.4 704.7 5.5679 7.8879 2.01 1.12 Overestimate Underestimate 410.074 Note: The table reports rounded prices, but a non-rounded sum. I’ve added the correct sum (in red) from the rounded figures show. The non-rounded calculations are available here: [link] Source: Allen (2001), p. 421, own calculation Source: Nordhaus (1996), p. 57—58 Source: Nordhaus (1996), p. 57—58 Historic price level adjustments are tricky • Price indexes don’t take quality improvements into account • Price indexes don’t take new goods into account • Thus, they likely overestimate inflation and underestimate the increase in real GDP per capita and living standards • Speculation from Nordhaus (1996, p. 63) • Conventional estimates of median real wages increase 13x from 1800-1992 • If there is low bias in the price index due to quality, increase is 40x • If there is high bias in the price index due to quality, increase is 190x That’s no error: the median wage earner would be consuming Up to 190 times more real value in 1992 than in 1800. Hedonic Adjustment Example 1800 2020 • • = • Suppose people only buy one good: “consumption baskets” • • = • Suppose people only buy one good: “consumption baskets” Price per basket doubled • = =5 , • , = = 50 Real average real income increased 10 × if we just look at consumption baskets 1800 2020 • • • • =5 •2 “True price” of consumption Price per basket doubled Real average income increased 10 × = 50 “Quality” increased 6 × • 12 Price of pleasure declined by 66% • = • Nominal • = Nominal = 10 • , . . People are 60 × better off after considering quality changes in the basket! = 600 Increase in real GDP per capita from 1800 to 2018 1800 2018 How much better off? 11× 11× United Kingdom Netherlands $3,343 $4,184 $38,058 $47,474 United States China Japan $2,545 $926 $1,317 $55,335 $13,102 $38,674 22× 14× 29× Mexico South Africa $1,305 $1,529 $16,494 $12,166 13× 8× or 200 40×× …or, if lifeexpectancy gains are 50% of the welfare gains 400 × Note: All in 2011 USD PPP. Sources: Broadberry, et al. (2015); Van Zanden and van Leeuwen (2012); Sutch (2006); Prados de la Escosura (2009); Broadberry, et al. (2018); Xu, et al. (2016); Bassino, et al. (2018); Arroyo & van Zanden (2016); Fourie & Van Zanden (2013); Maddison Project Database 2020 [link]; own analysis The Great Divergence Source: https://ourworldindata.org/economic-growth The “Little Divergence” • The “Little Divergence” • Within Europe • Early modern era (post-Black Death) • Chiefly, Northwestern Europe diverges • England • Low Countries (Holland & Flanders) • Evidence: • Output-based approach (GDP per capita) • Wage-based approach • Urbanization rates (proxies structural change) • Timing: • Black Death (1348 CE) • Atlantic Trade Boom ( 1500 CE) • BEFORE First Industrial Revolution ( 1800 CE) Around 1300: Centers of European Urban, Manufacturing, and Commercial Activity By 1800: Centers of European Urban, Manufacturing, and Commercial Activity GDP per capita, select European economies, 1250 CE - 2018 CE United Kingdom Netherlands France Spain Italy 11.5 ln(GDP per capita, 2011 USD PPP) 11 10.5 10 9.5 9 8.5 8 7.5 7 6.5 1250 1300 1350 1400 1450 1500 1550 1600 1650 1700 1750 1800 1850 1900 1950 2000 Note: United Kingdom is Year England only before 1700. Italy is Northern Italy only before 1871. Sources: Broadberry, et al. (2015); Van Zanden & van Leeuwen (2012); Smits, et al. (2000); Scheidel & Friesen; Ridolfi (2016); Álvarez-Nogal & de la Escosura (2013); Malanima (2010); Baffigi (2011); Maddison Project Database 2020 [link]; own calculations Source: Pamuk (2007), p. 297 Source: Pamuk (2007), p. 297 +20.9 pp +11.7 pp 1.5 pp +2.5 pp +1.9 pp The “Great Divergence” • The “Great Divergence” • NW Europe precocious outlier • Rest of Europe vs. Rest of World • Mostly 19th c./20th c. phenomenon • Evidence: • Output-based approach (GDP per capita) • Wage-based approach • Timing • NW Black Death (1348 CE) • NW Europe: Atlantic Trade Boom ( 1500 CE) • Rest of Europe: Industrialization (1800 CE) GDP per capita, select economies, 1250 CE - 2018 CE United Kingdom Netherlands France China India Japan 11.5 ln(GDP per capita, 2011 USD PPP) 11 10.5 10 9.5 9 8.5 8 7.5 A “Little Divergence” in East Asia, too? 7 6.5 1250 1300 1350 1400 1450 1500 1550 1600 1650 1700 1750 1800 1850 1900 1950 2000 Year Sources: Broadberry, et al. (2015); Van Zanden & van Leeuwen (2012); Smits, et al. (2000); Scheidel & Friesen; Ridolfi (2016); Broadberry, et al. (2018); Xu, et al. (2016); Wu (2014); Broadberry, et al. (2015); Note: United Kingdom is Bassino, et al. (2018); Fukao, et al. (2015); Maddison Project Database 2020 [link]; own calculations England only before 1700. Welfare Ratio interpretation: = 1 adult male yearly real labor market earnings enough to purchase subsistence basket for a family of 2 adults, 2 children Source: Allen, et al. (2011), p. 27 Source: Allen, et al. (2011), p. 28 1700 1800 United Kingdom: 13.3% United Kingdom: 22.1% Netherlands: 32.8% Netherlands: 28.8% Source: Xu, van Leeuwen, van Zanden (2015) Source: Frankema & van Waijenburg (2012), p. 913 Source: Frankema & van Waijenburg (2012), p. 913 Stylized facts (Great Enrichment) 1) For most of human history, living standards were very low compared to modern living standards 2) For most of human history, growth rates were very low compared to modern growth rates 3) High living standards are a relatively new phenomenon 4) Modern growth rates are a relatively new phenomenon Stylized facts (Great Divergence) 5) Modern living standards are uneven across countries 6) The onset of modern growth was uneven across countries a) Northwestern Europe (UK/Netherlands) seem to be the first economies to experience the transition to modern growth (“Little Divergence”) b) Followed by Western Europe (early-to-mid 1800s), rest of Europe (“Great Divergence”) c) The transition to modern growth for the rest of the world later (mid-to-late 1900s) Sophomoric explanations… • “Folk” theories explaining the Great Enrichment & Great Divergence • We’re rich because we’re “good”. They’re poor because they’re “bad”. • We’re rich because we’re “bad”. They’re poor because they’re “good”. • Unscientific, value-laden terms • Economics can provide a guide Economics & history Economics & history Theoretical economic models • Simplifications of reality • The goal is NOT to represent reality • The goal is to understand reality • The economic method • Use theory to build an economic model • Use the model to make predictions • Test against empirical evidence