Michel Dimou Professor in Urban and Regional Economics 4 many series of theoretical work: ▪ Land use according to the economic activity. The prices and costs of production are fixed, the market is concentrated in a single point. The explanatory variable is distance (transport costs). ▪ The location of a firm. The prices and costs of production are fixed, the market is concentrated in a single point. The explanatory variable is distance (transport costs). ▪ The location of a firm according to its competitors. The prices and costs of production depend upon the state of competition (free competition, oligopoly, duopoly) the market is dispersed in a homogeneous plane. The explanatory variable is distance (transport costs). ▪ The location of an economic agent in a generalized spatial equilibrium. The prices and costs of production depend upon the state of competition (free competition, oligopoly, duopoly) the market is dispersed in a homogeneous plane. The explanatory variable is distance (transport costs). 2 The market and the exchanges are concentrated in a single point. No possible exchange beyond this point Heterogenous land The market and the exchanges are randomly distributed. The population is randomly distributed, the expected density is the same everywhere. Homogenous plaine 3 H. Von Thunen 4 Von Thunen (1826) The isolated State (Der isolierte Staat) ▪ What do farmers produce around a town (market)? ▪ Where do farmers produce agricultural products? An innovating analysis : - The spatial dimension of economic activity - Transport costs govern the use of land - First marginalist approach – - The concept of bid rent The main assomptions are: ▪ Land is rare. ▪ Land fertility is the same everywhere. (homogeneity assumption). Land productivity is the same. ▪ No geological specificity. ▪ Farming activity is in a stationary state. ▪ Each farmer has the knowledge to produce and aims in maximising his profit (rationality hypothesis). ▪ Price is determined by demand and supply. ▪ Each farmer has access to transport. 5 ▪ An environment of free competition ▪ Land is scarce ▪ The soil productivity is not the same RICARDO’S MODEL OF LAND USE Price Rent Production cost Land fertility (decreasing) 6 Cost/price Total cost C B Price Rent Transport cost A Production cost D The triangle ABC corresponds to a rent due to location The soil’s productivity is the same everywhere. The land value depends upon its distance to the center Distance to center 7 Total Cost = CP + CT = 10 + X ▪ Price is P depends on Demand Price 20 ▪ CP: production cost ▪ CT : transport cost ▪ R is surplus Production cost 10 A single product case: wheat ▪ CP : 10 ▪ P : 20, ▪ CT : 1 per Km. ▪ Surplus = P – (CP + CT*X) with X distance . ▪ 0 when X = 10 ▪ max (10) when X=0 Distance to center 0 10 Rent 10 0 10 Distance to center 8 9 Rent ▪ What happens if: ▪ the price grows? 0 Distance to center ▪ the cost of production falls? ▪ the transport cost falls? ▪ A sprawl of the farming area. ▪ The boundaries of the wilderness are pushed away from the town 10 Rent 20 15 corn ▪ Two products: wheat and corn 10 ▪ CP wheat: 10, CP corn: 15 ▪ P wheat: 20, P corn: 30 wheat 0 5 7,5 10 ▪ CT wheat: 1 per km, CT corn: 2 per km. Distance to market ▪ Surplus wheat = P – (CP + CT*X) ▪ 0 when X = 10 ; max (10) when X= 0 ▪ Surplus corn = P – (CP + CT*X) ▪ 0 when X = 7,5 ; max (15) when X= 0 ▪ Resolution ▪ Pwh - (Cwh + X)= Pcorn - (Ccorn + 2X) => X = 5 11 Initial situation (1) • • • • 2 goods, wheat & corn. CP wheat: 10, CP corn: 15 P wheat: 20, P corn: 30 CT wheat: 1 per km, CT corn: 2 per km. First change (2) • • • • 2 goods, wheat & corn. CP wheat: 10, CP corn: 15 P wheat: 20, P corn: 30 CT wheat: 1 per km, CT corn: 1 per km. Second change (3) • • • • 2 goods, wheat & corn. CP wheat: 10, CP corn: 15 P wheat: 20, P corn: 35 CT wheat: 1 per km, CT corn: 2 per km. 12 Situation 1 & 2 Rent 20 Situation 1 Surplus wheat = P – (CP + CT*X) 15 ▪ 0 when X = 10 ; max (10) when X= 0 corn 10 Surplus corn = P – (CP + CT*X) corn (2) ▪ 0 when X = 7,5 ; max (15) when X= 0 Situation 2 wheat 0 7,5 10 Surplus wheat = P – (CP + CT*X) 15 Distance to market ▪ 0 when X = 10 ; max (10) when X= 0 Surplus corn = P – (CP + CT*X) urban sprawl & substitution ▪ 0 when X = 15 ; max (15) when X= 0 13 Situation 1 & 3 Rent 20 15 Situation 1 corn 10 Surplus wheat = P – (CP + CT*X) ▪ 0 when X = 10 ; max (10) when X= 0 corn (2) Surplus corn = P – (CP + CT*X) wheat ▪ 0 when X = 7,5 ; max (15) when X= 0 Situation 2 0 7,5 10 15 Distance to market Surplus wheat = P – (CP + CT*X) ▪ 0 when X = 10 ; max (10) when X= 0 Substitution without urban sprawl (if Price climbs) Surplus corn = P – (CP + CT*X) ▪ 0 when X = 10 ; max (20) when X= 0 14 In Von Thunen’s model land is assumed to be heterogeneous. ▪ The town already exists ▪ The town is built around the city-center (the market) ▪ When no more human activity subsists, there is only wilderness. ▪ The real estate price of wilderness is null (0) 15 Von Thunen doesn’t model a separate transport cost function. In Von Thunen’s transport system it is necessary to transport both the products and the energy of transport (a char driven by an ox – which consumes a part of the product for energy purposes). This additional load is proportional to the final product the ox char is transporting and which is to be delivered to the market. Y = ÿ(1 – ax) ▪ Y: final product delivered at the market place, ▪ ÿ: total product (final product + energy) ▪ a: part of the total load consumed by km for transport ▪ x: the distance. 16 ▪ According to Samuelson the load is getting less heavy as the ox consumes a part of it, which means that the ox moves faster. ▪ But in Von Thunen’s function of cost, the marginal cost is always the same. Marginal cost is linear to distance. 17 Getting smaller, going faster…. The melting of the iceberg is exponential because in every moment it is proportional of the remaining load Y = ÿe-ax Y: final product delivered at the market place, ÿ: total product (final product + energy) a: part of the total load consumed by km for transport x: the distance. 18 19 3 main concepts : ▪ The CBD ▪ The monocentric urban configuration ▪ The bid rent Alonso, Muth, Fujita, Thisse. What can people be paying Manhattan or downtown Chicago rents for, if not to be with other people? R. Lucas, 1987, Nobel Prize in Economics. 20 21 Place du Chatelet La Défense Piccadilly Circus The City 22 23 24 ▪ The main goal of the model is to explain the empirical regularities that we observe in cities ▪ The main mechanism is the relationship between commuting costs, housing prices, and housing consumption ▪ The main output is spatial equilibrium within the city where households feature identical utility levels and firms identical profits across space 25 26 Land use in Paris Housing prices in Berlin 27 ▪ A pattern of declining density radiating from the center. ▪ •Tall multi-family buildings tend to be located near the city center, while single-family houses are at the fringe ▪ •Land and housing prices per square meter/foot tend to be high near the city center and lower farther away 28 ▪ Land rent (R) is the price for using one unit of land, say a hectare, for one unit of time, say a year. ▪ Land value (V) is the price of buying one unit of land, again say a hectare ▪ •Land is an asset; like any asset its price (=value) is the present value of the benefits (=net rent) from owning it. 29 Housing is measured in units of housing services = q ▪ q= quality-adjusted square meters V= the value of a housing unit = the present value of the rental flow ▪ Depends on housing characteristics ▪ For now, we assume that floor space is the only characteristic So, with a long lifetime T, for housing: p= the price (rent) per unit of q per year r= rent for a housing unit = pq ▪ If the unit is a rental apartment, r= contract rent ▪ If the unit is owner-occupied, r is not observed 30 1. All jobs are in the city center (CBD) 2.The city has a dense network of radial roads 3.The city contains identical households or consumers or workers ▪ Same income/wage (y) and preferences (will be relaxed later) 4.The residents consume only two goods: housing (q) and a composite good (c) ▪ The price of the composite good is the same everywhere (equal to 1) Commuting costs 1. The per-kilometer cost of commuting is t, so a resident living at distance x from the CBD incurs a commuting cost tx ▪ •Commuting has only a monetary cost ▪ •Later we will introduce the opportunity cost of time used in commuting 2. This leaves y –tx for expenditure on housing and the composite good (= disposable income) ▪ •Disposable income decreases as x increases ▪ Land and the housing that sits on it are allocated to the highest bidder at each location 31 Housing consumption A housing unit or a dwelling has a variety of characteristics ▪ Floor space, yard size, construction quality, age, number of rooms, amenities We assume that dwellings differ only in size ▪ q represents square meters and p is measured as rental price per square meter The consumer’s budget constraint is y –tx= pq+ c Consumer’s analysis Consumers want to maximize the utility (welfare) they get from consuming housing and the common good, while taking into account their budget constraint The consumer chooses the c and q to maximize utility U(c, q) subject to the budget constraint at each distance x ▪ Location “choice” enters the problem only through commuting costs ▪ Dwellings differ only with respect to size. The expenditure on common good and housing is equal to disposable income after commuting costs 32 Everyone wants to live right next to the CBD, but everyone can’t live in the same location This equilibrium can hold only if price per housing per square meter falls as distance increases Since higher commuting costs mean that disposable income falls as x increases, some offsetting benefit must be present to keep utility from falling Lower p at more distant locations serves as a compensating differential The price of the composite good is the same everywhere, and doesn’t play a compensating role 33 ▪ The consumer chooses the point where the indifference curve is tangent to the budget line (c1, q1) ▪ •This is the highest possible indifference curve that the consumer can reach within the budget constraint 34 35 What magnitude must the price of housing p1 be at distance x1 to ensure that the suburban consumer reach the same indifference curve as the central-city consumer? ▪ Prices per m² are higher in central-city, p0> p1 ▪ The suburban resident consumes more housing space (q1> q0) and less common good (c1< c0) than the central-city resident ▪ This means that dwelling size q increases as distance x from the CBD increases The model’s two main predictions are 1. Price per square meter p of housing falls as distance x increases 2. Size of the dwellings q increases when x increases 36 How does the total rent (pq) for a small centralcity dwelling compare to the total rent of a larger suburban house? ▪ Since p falls with x while q increases, the product pq could either increase or decrease. It depends on the consumer’s preferences or the shape of the indifference curve ▪ The price curve is convex if housing increases with x. Consumers substitute cheaper housing for common goods, so housing prices don’t have to decline as quickly to compensate consumers. 37 The assumptions =V − A −F with p = profit, V = sales (income), A = other costs, F = real estate costs. and V = V(Kq) where: K = distance to the centre and q = size of the plant. A = A(V, K, q) F = P(K)q, where P(K) = real estate price at a distance K from city center Two equations The location equation dV dA dV dA dP − − +q =0 dK dV dK dK dK The land consumption equation dV dA dV dA dP − − − =0 dq dV dq dq dq 38 surface surface q2 q q q1 U1 U1 K distance K1 K K2 distance 39 40 The German theory of location (W. Roscher, A. Schäffle, W. Launhardt) The Fermat/Toricelli Point: in a triangle, which is the point that minimizes the aggregated distance to these points? Describes how/where to find the optimal location for a: ▪ manufacturing firm. Its purpose it to place a firm in a location ▪ where the final cost of transportation, labor, and materials are minimized. 41 Transfer-oriented firm: transport cost is the dominant factor in the location decision ➢ The firm chooses the location that minimizes total transport costs Two types of cost: - Procurement cost is the cost of transporting raw materials from the input source to the production facility - Distribution cost is the cost of transporting the firm’s output from the production facility to the market ▪ Four assumptions: 1.Single transferable output. The firm produces a fixed quantity of a single product, which is transported from the production facility to a market M 2.Single transferable input. The firm may use several inputs, but only one input is transported from an input source, F, to the production facility. All other inputs are ubiquitous. 3.Fixed-factor proportions. The firm produces its fixed quantity with fixed amounts of each input. No factor substitution 4.Fixed prices. The firm is so small that it does not affect the prices of its input or its output ➢ The only cost that varies across space is transport cost 42 A Single establishment M2 ▪ 2 inputs - 1 output d2 ▪ A fixed location of the raw materials/1st input, the labor market/2nd input and the final market K ▪ Distance is Euclidian. Transport costs are directly proportional to weight ▪ The profit of the firm is: = p3m3 − ( p1 + t1d1 )m1 − ( p2 + t2 d 2 )m2 − t3d3m3 d3 d1 M1 M3 3 Min Transport cost = mi ti d i i =1 43 A 1 2 3 3 2 1 B 3 2 1 C For 1 $, how much distance can the firm travel if carrying raw materials (A), labor force (B), or the final product (C)? 44 M3 Final Market The material index (I) is the ratio of the weights of the intermediate products (raw materials) to the final product. Output Transport Cost M1 steel Input Transport Cost M2 plastic M1 steel M3 Final Market M2 plastic • If I >1, the firm locates close to the raw materials source. • If I < 1, the firm locates close to the final market. 45 A Firm producing hockey bats Monetary weight input = mi ti = 10 $1 = $10 Monetary weight output = mo to = 3 $2 = $6 46 PC = mi ti x = 10 1 x DC = mo to ( xM − x ) = 3 2 ( xM − x ) Total transport cost (procurement cost plus distribution cost is minimized at the input source (the forest) because the monetary weight of the input (($10) exceeds the monetary weight of the output ($6) 47 A bottling firm of beveradges Monetary weight input = mi ti = 1 $1 = $1 Monetary weight output = mo to = 4 $1 = $4 48 Total transport cost is minimized at the final market because the monetary weight of the output (($4) exceeds the monetary weight of the input ($1) PC = mi ti x = 1 1 x DC = mo to ( xM − x ) = 4 1 ( xM − x ) 49 THE MOSES LOCATION PRODUCTION MODEL - The firm can substitute in favour of the cheaper inputs - The distance from the factory to the market, d3, is fixed - The firm chooses a location along the arc IJ 50 Looks at the price ratio between inputs m1 Can locate anywhere within specific distance from output market between L & J Envelope budget constraint The choice is then the combination of inputs L Output Isoquant J This allows the development of an envelope budget constraint q2 m2 51 input 1 A’ Q A J h O Variable-factor proportions. L Budget Constraint in L1 c The firm produces its fixed quantity with variables amounts of each input. Budget constraint in L2 B’ B Case 1: Minimizing the cost of production ❖ 1 firm, 1 product, ❖ A fixed volume of final product Q, input 2 Factor substitution Prices of inputs are different according to location. Location choice: a different combination of inputs. ❖ Different input prices in each locality. 52 input 1 A’ A Q2 Q3 Q1 kj 2 g t B’ B Case 2: Maximizing the quantity of production ❖ 1 firm, 1 product, ❖ Different input prices in each locality. input 2 Variable-factor proportions. The firm produces its fixed quantity with variables amounts of each input. Factor substitution Prices of inputs are different according to location. Location choice: a different combination of inputs. 53 54 ▪ Land is homogeneous ▪ People are randomly distributed ▪ The expected density is the same in every point of the land 55 Hotelling Model… Price p1 + t.x p1 + t.x V V t z=0 Price x1 t p1 1/2 Shop 1 x1 z=1 p1 + t.x1 = V, so x1 = (V – p1)/t 56 Hotelling Model… Price p1 + t.x p1 + t.x Price V V p1 p2 z=0 x2 x1 1/2 x1 x2 z=1 Shop 1 57 Hotelling Model… ◼ Suppose that all consumers are to be served at price p. ❑ The highest price is that charged to the consumers at the ends of the market. ❑ Their transport costs are t/2 : since they travel ½ mile to the shop ❑ So they pay p + t/2 which must be no greater than V. ❑ So p = V – t/2. ◼ Suppose that marginal costs are c per unit. ◼ Suppose also that a shop has set-up costs of F. ◼ t Then profit is = N V − − c − F 2 58 Hotelling Model… Price p1 + t.x p2 + t.x p1 + t.x V p3 + 1/2t Price p2 + t.x V p1 p2 p3 z=0 x3 x2 x1 1/2 Shop 1 x1 x2 z=1 x3 59 The only stable equilibrium is not optimal neither for each prisoner nor for the collectivity (both prisoners). A non cooperative game 60 • A beach • A random distribution of people • 2 ice cream shops • Same ice cream • Same price • No ccoperation • Minimize distance from the ice cream shop 61 • A beach • A random distribution of people • 2 ice cream shops • Same ice cream • Same price • No ccoperation • Minimize distance from the ice cream shop 62 25% 25% 25% 25% 63 Transport costs Production cost Distance A B ▪ Transport cost 64 Transport Costs Production Costs Distance A B Agglomeration under certain circumstances 65 Hotelling Model… p1 + txm = p2 + t(1 - xm) 2txm = p2 - p1 + t xm(p1, p2) = (p2 - p1 + t)/2t There are N consumers in total So demand to firm 1 is D1 = N(p2 - p1 + t)/2t Price Price p2 p1 xm Shop 1 Shop 2 66 Hotelling Model… Profit to firm 1 is 1 = (p1 - c)D1 = N(p1 - c)(p2 - p1 + t)/2t 1 = N(p2p1 - p12 + tp1 + cp1 - cp2 -ct)/2t Differentiate with respect to p1 1/ p1 = N (p2 - 2p1 + t + c) = 0 2t p*1 = (p2 + t + c)/2 What about firm 2? By symmetry, it has a similar best response function. p*2 = (p1 + t + c)/2 EC 3322 (Industrial Organization I) Yohanes E. Riyanto 67 Hotelling Model… Finding the Bertrand-Nash Eq.: p*1 = (p2 + t + c)/2 p2 R1 p*2 = (p1 + t + c)/2 2p*2 = p1 + t + c R2 = p2/2 + 3(t + c)/2 c + t p*2 = t + c (c + t)/2 p*1 = t + c Profit per unit to each (c + t)/2 c + t firm is t Aggregate profit to each firm is Nt/2 p1 68 Hotelling Model… Price Price p*2 = t+c p*1 = t+c xm = (p2 - p1 + t)/2t xm =1/2 Shop 1 Shop 2 69 Strategic Complements and Substitutes… ❑ ❑ Suppose firm 2’s costs increase This causes Firm 2’s Cournot best response function to fall ◼ ❑ aggressive response by firm 1 q2 at any output for firm 1 firm 2 now wants to produce less Firm 1 Cournot Firm 1’s output increases and firm 2’s falls Firm 2 q1 ❑ Firm 2’s Bertrand best response function rises ◼ ❑ at any price for firm 1 firm 2 now wants to raise its price firm 1’s price increases as does firm 2’s p2 passive response by firm 1 Firm 1 Firm 2 Bertrand p1 70 Transport Costs Production Costs Distance A B ▪ High Transport costs prevent concentration ▪ Low Transport Costs prevent concentration. 71 Production cost B Production cost A Distance A B A different strategy ▪ A seeks agglomeration ▪ B flies away Distance prevent from competition 72 Transport costs Production costs Distance A B Assymety of the transport cost function 73 Production cost B Production cost A Distance A B Local market effects. 74 W. Christaller: the role of distance A. Lösch: the role of people welfare 75 The main asumptions: ▪ There is an isotropic plain of flat land throughout the plain. ▪ There is a homogenous preference among people since people will always purchase goods from the nearest place possible? ▪ Consumers bear the burden of shipping in terms of cost. ▪ That people act economically rationally. The cost of product is defined by: ▪ The cost of production (fixed). ▪ The cost of transport to get to the seller (depends on distance). 76 ▪ A unique product, different sellers distributed across space. ▪ The price at the shop is 5€, consumer’s gain ▪ Transport cost is 2€/km, 40€ ▪ The limit range of the product is 40€ (maximum price that an economic agent is ready to pay in order to buy this product), ▪ Market area: a radius of 17.5 km. 0 0 17,5 distance 77 ▪ The limit range depends upon 3 variables: • ▪ The price ▪ The transport cost ▪ The consumer’s budget consumer’s gain 40€ ▪ ▪ Transport cost depends upon: ▪ The transport mode ; ▪ The transport frequency (daily, weekly, monthly); 0 0 17,5 distance ▪ The product’s cost of production. ▪ The consumer’s budget. 78 79 • ▪ Each type of good has its own limit range (all producers behave the same way) consumer’s gain ▪ Two different types of goods have two different limit ranges. How do externalities interfere good 1 good 2 0 0 distance 80 • ▪ A market mechanism consumer’s gain ▪ Agglomeration ▪ Public administration analysis Example good 1 ▪ Kinder garden ▪ Primary school good 2 ▪ Secondary schools 0 ▪ Universities 0 distance 81 82 ▪ US city more segregationist than the European city (to be discussed) ▪ Two important parameters when studying the US city: ▪ Land consumption– neighbors. ▪ « Tell me who is your neighbor, I will guess where you live » ▪ US sociologists aim to understand economic, social and ethnical segregation in the US cities. 83 ▪ Park & Burgess – McKenzie: the geographical dimension of the social structure of Chicago. People change their location when climbing up the social ladder. Residential mobility. ▪ Hoyt takes into account the importance of transport infrastructures. Public equipment tend to settle down newcomers. ▪ Harris & Ullman: the importance of public equipment away from the city-center. A city is built on the aggregation of multiple neighborhoods. 84 ▪ 4 principles: ▪ principle of location (close or far from city center & transport cost). ▪ principle of agglomeration (scale and scope external economies). ▪ principle of exclusion (scale and scope negative external economies). ▪ principle of the best possible choice (all locations are not free). 85 The spatial & social organization of Chicago 86 • The importance of having an access to the city center. • Combining sociology to the monocentric city. 87 A functional organization of the monocentric city 88 The US city La ville Européenne The European city High income Households Industrial activity Median income Households Merchant Activities CBD Median income Households High income Households Students Ethnic districts Low income households 89 Europe: Rich people in city-center – poor people in the suburbs M.Freyssenet: not quite true ! How social segregation in Paris changed. ▪ In the early 1800, city center is poor. ▪ In 1950, city-center is heterogeneous but the suburbs are homogeneous (workers). ▪ In 1980, the city-center becomes homogeneous (bourgeois) but the suburbs are heterogeneous (newcomers, workers and median income families). before & after Baron Hausmann’s Paris 90 91 ▪ Imbert : in France, in the 1960s and the 1970s poor people live in large parts of the buildings in Paris’s city center (ancien and decrepit). But this changed within two decades. ▪ The historical value of buildings. ▪ City center is not only the economic but also the cultural center. ▪ Distance is also calculated in time of transport. 92 ▪ Urban renovation: a tool to move away the poor population out of the city center. ▪ Higher local taxes & higher housing prices. ▪ M.Anderson (1970), M.Castells (1970), H.Nonn (1977) : the victims of urban renovation. ▪ ▪ In France : the suburbs represent le « débordement de la ville ». 93 94 95 Micromotives and macrobehavior ▪ The US city was not a segregated area ▪ It became segregated through a double mechanism: ▪ The hazard ▪ People preferences ▪ Market mechanisms 96 97 - - Static or dynamic context Number of parameters that enter the location choice Type of land 98 • Transport costs and housing prices • The importance of land use • The neighbors • We didn’t introduce amenities