1 The Anatomy of an LBO: Leverage, Control and Value Aswath Damodaran Professor of Finance and David Margolis Teaching Fellow Leonard N. Stern School of Business, New York University New York City In a typical leveraged buyout, there are three components. The acquirers borrow a significant portion of a publicly traded firm’s value (leverage), take a key role in the management of the firm (control) and often take it off public markets (going private). None of these three components is new to markets and there can clearly be good reasons for each of them. Starting with traditional corporate finance first principles, we examine the conditions that are necessary for each component to make sense. Using the aborted Harman LBO, where KKR and Goldman were lead players, as a case study, we argue that choosing the wrong target for a leveraged buyout is a recipe for disaster even for the most reputed players in the business. In other words, no amount of deal expertise can overcome poor financial fundamentals. In closing, we argue that the three components in an LBO are separable and that bundling them together as essential pieces of every deal is a mistake. This paper is derived from a presentation made at the AIMR Equity Research and Valuation Techniques conference held in Los Angeles on 4–5 December 2007. In September 2007, Kohlberg Kravis Roberts & Co. (KKR) and Goldman Sachs withdrew from a leveraged buyout (LBO) of Harman International Industries. My intention is to examine that LBO attempt from the perspectives of corporate financial theory and valuation first principles to see not only why the deal failed but to draw general lessons on what needs to happen for a deal to be successful. In the process, I intend to demonstrate how basic principles of corporate finance and valuation are sometimes ignored in deals, especially in boom times, and how such flaws lead predictably to the collapse of many transactions. My intent in picking on KKR and Goldman, widely regarded among the elite in the business, is not to showcase their failures but to illustrate that even smart investors are not immune from mistakes. Electronic Electroniccopy copyavailable availableat: at:https://ssrn.com/abstract=1162862 http://ssrn.com/abstract=1162862 2 I will first provide a general description of the Harman deal and then examine it in the context of the three possible components of an LBO: (1)the disproportionate funding with debt, which leads to a significant increase in financial leverage, (2) a change in control of the firm, which is the opportunity to alter the way in which a company is run, and (3) going private, which entails taking a public company private or quasi-private. Figure 1 captures the three components: Figure 1: The Components of a Leveraged Buyout (LBO) Increase financial leverage/ debt Leverage Control Leveraged Buyout Take the company private or quasiprivate Change the way the company is run (often with existing managers) Public/ Private One of the problems with leveraged buyouts is that these three components are seen as inextricably linked rather than as components that can be considered independently of one another. Furthermore, I will argue that Harman never had the characteristics that would allow investors to take advantage of any of the three basic components. Harman was not the right company against which to borrow large amounts, it did not need to be managed differently, and it was not an appropriate candidate for being taken private. In addition, the flaws inherent in the Harman deal were representative of many leveraged buyouts done during 2006 and 2007. In short, many companies selected for LBOs were unsuited for the transaction in the first place, and there should be no surprise at how many of these deals have unraveled since. Electronic Electroniccopy copyavailable availableat: at:https://ssrn.com/abstract=1162862 http://ssrn.com/abstract=1162862 3 Harman LBO Overview Harman International Industries is a company known for making highend audio equipment. Before the transaction, Harman was funded predominantly by equity, with $5.5 billion in publicly traded equity and only $371 million in debt (mostly leases), which yielded a debt-to-equity ratio of less than 7%. Goldman Sachs and KKR joined with the managers at Harman to arrange an LBO with a total value of about $8 billion. Of the funding for the LBO, $4 billion was to come from debt; $3 billion, from Goldman Sachs, KKR, and company managers; and $1 billion, from other equity investors. The principals, therefore, were paying a premium of more than $2 billion to buy out existing equity investors and leave Harman as a private company with a capital structure consisting of 50 percent debt and 50 percent equity. Figure 2 captures the changes expected at Harman: Figure 2: The Proposed Harman LBO Predeal Postdeal Debt $ 4 billion Debt (mostly leases) $371 Publlicly traded equity $ 5.5 billion KKR & Goldman would buy out existing equity investors Firm will become a quasi-private company with 75% of the equity held by KKR, Goldman and managers. KKR, Goldman & Managers $3 billion Public $ 1 billion Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=1162862 4 The questions that are worth examining are the following: (1) Where is the increase of more than $ 2 billion (from $5.9 billion to $8 billion) in value coming from? (2) Can Harman carry a mix of roughly equal amounts of debt and equity? (3) What is the motivation for taking Harman private? I. Leverage and Value The question of whether changing the mix of debt and equity can alter the value of a business has long been debated in finance. When examining the leverage component of an LBO, it is essential to determine whether changing the mix of debt and equity in a company can change the value of the company. But before I can determine that, I must first define what I mean by debt in this discussion. Debt Defined. While most analysts use the accounting measure of debt from the balance sheet, the accounting definition of debt is far too narrow, in some cases, and far too loose, in others. It is to contest this definition that I will begin by listing three criteria that I see as central to categorizing financing as debt. 1. Debt gives rise to fixed contractual obligations that have to be met in both good times and bad. Equity, in contrast, is a residual claim, where cash flows are paid out (example: dividends) only if the firm feels it can make these payments. 2. The fixed payments in debt are usually tax deductible. In contrast, cash flows to equity are not (in most tax jurisdictions) 3. Failing to meet the fixed commitments can result in loss of control of the firm. Using these criteria, a company’s debt will include all interest-bearing debt, both short term and long term, but not non-interest bearing obligations such as accounts payable or suppler credit. The latter may carry a cost (in the firm of higher costs of goods sold), but the absence of an explicit interest payment weighs against their treatment as debt. In addition, there are some Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=1162862 5 items off the balance sheet that should be part of debt. In particular, long term leases and the commitments that ensue meet all the criteria for debt – fixed commitments in the form of lease payments that are tax deductible and that give rise to negative consequences if not met. Therefore, all lease commitments, both operating and capital, should be considered as debt. For many service firms, such as retailers and restaurants, lease commitments are the primary form of debt. One way to draw a contrast with the accounting balance sheet is to set up a financial balance sheet. On a financial balance sheet, only two items appear on the asset side—assets in place (investments already made) and growth assets (investments expected to be made in the future) and two on the liability side – debt and equity. Figure 3 illustrates a financial balance sheet: Figure 3: Financial Balance Sheet Assets Existing Investments Generate cashflows today Includes long lived (fixed) and short-lived(working capital) assets Expected Value that will be created by future investments Liabilities Assets in Place Debt Growth Assets Equity Fixed Claim on cash flows Little or No role in management Fixed Maturity Tax Deductible Residual Claim on cash flows Significant Role in management Perpetual Lives For example, Google traded at a $200 billion market capitalization in late 2007. Of this value, it is possible that $20 billion was for investments already made, but the remaining $180 billion represented expectations for the future. The financing of companies should reflect the breakdown of their assets into assets in place and growth assets. Verizon, which gets the bulk of its value from assets in place, can afford to use more debt (as a percent of market value) than Google because the latter’s growth assets do not generate cash flows. For debt to affect value, therefore, the use of debt must have benefits and costs relative to the use of equity. Furthermore, if the benefits of using debt exceed the costs of using debt, the value of the business will increase with the use of the debt. If the costs of using debt exceed the benefits, the value of Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=1162862 6 the business will decrease when debt is increased. Just to complete the circle, it is also possible that the benefits of debt exactly offset the costs, making debt a neutral factor in firm valuation. Benefits and Costs of Debt. Debt has two key benefits, relative to equity, as a mode of financing. First, the interest paid on debt financing is tax deductible, whereas cash flows to equity (such as dividends) are generally not.1 Therefore, the higher the tax rate, the greater the tax benefit of using debt. This is absolutely true in the United States and partially true in most parts of the world. The second benefit of debt financing is more subtle. The use of debt, it can be argued, induces managers to be more disciplined in project selection. That is, the managers of a company funded entirely by equity, and with strong cash flows, have a tendency to become lazy. For example, if a project turns sour, the managers can hide evidence of their failure under large operating cash flows, and few investors notice the effect in the aggregate. But if those same managers had to use debt to fund projects, then bad projects are less likely to go unnoticed. Since debt requires the company to make interest payments, investing in too many bad projects can lead to financial distress or even bankruptcy, and managers may lose their jobs. In effect, this was Michael Jensen’s free cash flow justification for debt and the leverage buyout boom of the 1980s. Relative to equity, the use of debt has three disadvantages—an expected bankruptcy cost, an agency cost, and the loss of future financing flexibility. • The expected bankruptcy cost has two components. One is simply that as debt increases, so does the probability of bankruptcy. The other component is the cost of bankruptcy, which can be separated into two parts. One is the direct cost of going bankrupt, such as legal fees and court costs, which can eat up to a significant portion of the value of the assets of a bankrupt firm. This is clearly the case in the United States. There are other markets, such as Brazil, where equity cash flows also provide tax advantages. Even in those markets, the tax advantages for debt tend to be higher than the tax advantages for equity. 1 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=1162862 7 The other (and more devastating) cost is the effect on operations of being perceived as being in financial trouble.. Thus, when customers learn that a company is in financial trouble, they tend to stop buying the company’s products. Suppliers stop extending credit, and employees start looking for more reliable employment elsewhere. Borrowing too much money can create a downward spiral that ends in bankruptcy. • Agency costs arise from the different and competing interests of equity investors and lenders in a firm. Equity investors see more upside from risky investments than lenders to. Consequently, left to their own devices, equity investors will tend to take more risk in investments than lenders would want them to and to alter financing and dividend policies to serve their interests as well. As lenders become aware of this potential, they alter the terms of loan agreements to protect themselves in two ways. One is by adding covenants to these agreements, restricting investing, financing and dividend policies in the future; these covenants create legal and monitoring costs. The other is by assuming that there will be some game playing by equity investors and by charging higher interest rates to compensate for expected future losses. In both instances, the borrower bears the agency costs. • As firms borrow more money today, they lose the capacity to tap this borrowing capacity in the future. The loss of future financing flexibility implies that the firm may be unable to make investments that it otherwise would have liked to make, simply because it will be unable to line up financing for these investments. Figure 4 captures the trade off inherent in the use of debt as opposed to equity. Figure 4: Trade off on Debt versus Equity Advantages of Debt Disadvantages of Debt 1. Tax Benefits of Debt: As tax rates 1. Expected Bankruptcy Costs: As increase, the tax benefits of debt firms borrow more, the probability of increase bankruptcy increases. Multiplying by Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=1162862 8 2. Added Discipline: Debt can make the cost of going bankrupt yields the managers at all equity-funded firms expected bankruptcy cost. with significant cashflows more 2. Agency Costs: As conflicts between prudent about the investments that equity investors and lenders increase, they make. the costs to borrowers will rise (from monitoring costs and higher interest payments) 3. Loss of future financing flexibility: As firms use their debt capacity today, they lose the capacity to use that debt capacity in the future. In the special case where there are no taxes, no default risk and no agency issues (between managers and stockholders as well as between stockholders and bondholders), debt has neither advantages nor disadvantages. This, of course, is the classic Miller-Modigliant world, where debt has no effect on value. In the real world, where there are tax benefits, agency problems and default looms as a problem, there is clearly an optimal mix of debt and equity for a firm. Firms can borrow too much as well as too little, and both have adverse effects on value. Tools for Assessing Debt. I will use three basic tools to determine how much debt a company can take on: the basic cost of capital approach which ignores indirect bankruptcy costs, an enhanced cost of capital approach that tries to incorporate indirect bankruptcy costs, and an adjusted present value (APV) approach that tries to capture the benefits of debt separately in value. 1. In the cost of capital approach, the optimal debt-to-equity ratio is the one that minimizes a company’s cost of capital. In effect, we keep operating cash flows fixed and assume that changing debt changes only the cost of capital. By minimizing the cost of capital, we are maximizing firm value. Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=1162862 9 2. The enhanced cost of capital approach introduces indirect bankruptcy costs into the analysis. In this case, the optimal debt ratio creates a combination of cash flows and cost of capital that maximizes a company’s value. 3. In the adjusted present value approach, debt is separated from operations, and the company is valued as if it had no debt. Then, the positive and negative value effects of debt are considered as separate components. 1. Cost of capital approach. The cost of capital approach has its roots in the discounted cash flow model for valuing a firm, where expected cash flows to the firm (prior to debt payments but after taxes and reinvestment needs) are discounted back at the cost of capital. Value of firm = t =∞ ∑ Free cash flow to the firmt t =1 (1 + Cost of capital )t . If a company can keep its cash flows unchanged and lower its cost of capital, it will increase its present value. Therefore, the optimal debt ratio is the one at which the cost of capital is minimized. At first sight, the answer to what will happen to the cost of capital as the debt ratio is increased seems trivial, given that the cost of debt is almost always lower than the cost of equity for a business. However, that solution misses the dynamic effects of introducing debt into a business. To see these effects, consider the two components that drive the cost of capital— the cost of equity and cost of debt: Equity Debt Cost of capital = Cost of equity + Pretax cost of debt (1 − Tax rate ) . Debt + Equity Debt + Equity As the company borrows more money, its equity will become riskier. Even though it has the same operating assets (and income), it now has to make interest payments, and financial leverage magnifies the risk in equity earnings. Thus, the cost of equity will be an increasing function of the debt ratio. Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=1162862 10 Furthermore, as borrowing increases, so does default risk, which, in turn, increases the cost of debt. The trade off on debt’s effect on the cost of capital can be summarized as follows: replacing equity with debt has the positive effect of replacing a more expensive mode of funding with a less expensive one but in the process the increased risk in both debt and equity will push up the costs of both components, creating a negative effect. Whether the cost of capital increases or decreases will be a function of which effect dominates. Figure 5 captures the trade off: Figure 5: Trade off on Cost of Capital and Debt Bankruptcy costs are built into both the cost of equity the pre-tax cost of debt Tax benefit is here Cost of capital = Cost of Equity (Equity/ (Debt + Equity)) + Pre-tax cost of debt (1- tax rate) (Debt/ (Debt + Equity) As you borrow more, he equity in the firm will become more risky as financial leverage magnifies business risk. The cost of equity will increase As you borrow more, your default risk as a firm will increase pushing up your cost of debt. At some level of borrowing, your tax benefits may be put at risk, leading to a lower tax rate. To understand the mechanics of the cost of capital approach, we will work through it in steps. Step 1: Start with a risk and return model for estimating the cost of equity. For instance, with the capital asset pricing model Cost of equity = Rf + Equity Beta (Equity Risk Premium) In this equation, Rf is the riskfree rate and neither this number nor the equity risk premium will change as the debt ratio changes, leaving us with only one input to estimate – the equity beta. To estimate this number, you should start with an asset or unlevered beta.2 As the company increases borrowing, The simplest way to estimate an unlevered beta is by looking at publicly traded firms in the business, computing an average regression beta across these firms and then cleaning up for the debt to equity ratios of these companies. The process is described in more detail in other papers on my website. 2 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=1162862 11 recompute the debt-to-equity ratio and compute a levered beta based on this recomputed ratio:3 Debt Levered beta = Unlevered beta 1 + (1 − t ) . Equity The levered beta is the equity beta and will risk inexorably as the firm borrows more money. As the equity beta climbs, so will the cost of equity. Step 2: Now, consider the cost of debt, which is the rate at which you can borrow money long term today, given the firm’s default risk. Pretax cost of debt = Rf + Default spread. As the firm borrows more money, its default risk (and the default spread) will go up. To get a simple measure of default risk, estimate the interest expense at each debt level and compute an interest coverage ratio based on expense: Interest coverage ratio = Operating income . Interest expense As debt increases, interest expenses will increase; holding the operating income fixed, this will result in lower interest coverage ratios at higher levels of debt. Using a look-up table developed by looking at rated firms in the United States, I estimate a synthetic rating at each level of debt and use the rating to establish a default spread, which, when added to the risk-free rate, should yield the pretax cost of debt. Figure 6 captures the essential steps in the process: This is one variation on the levered beta equation. There are others that assume a beta for debt and still others that ignore the tax effect. Using any of these approaches consistently yields similar results. 3 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=1162862 12 Figure 6: Cost of capital computation Cost of Equity = Rf + Beta (Equity Risk Premium) Pre-tax cost of debt = Rf + Defautl sprread Start with the beta of the business (asset or unlevered beta) Estimate the interest expense at each debt level As the firm borrows more, recompute the debt to equity ratio (D/E) . Compute an interest coverage ratio based on expense Interest coverage ratio = Operating income/ Interest expense Compute a levered beta based on this debt to equity ratio Levered beta = Unlevered beta (1 + (1-t) (D./E)) Estimate a synthetic rating at each level of debt Use the rating to come up with a default spread, which when added to the riskfree rate should yield the pre-tax cost of debt Estimate the cost of equity based on the levered beta This approach is used to derive the costs of debt and equity for Harman at different debt ratios, with the results summarized in Table 1: Debt Ratio 0% 10% 20% 30% 40% 50% 60% 70% 80% 90% Beta 1.45 1.55 1.67 1.83 2.05 2.39 3.06 4.08 6.12 12.98 Cost of Equity 10.30% 10.70% 11.20% 11.84% 12.70% 14.04% 16.74% 20.82% 28.98% 56.40% Bond Rating AAA AAA A BB BCC C C C D Interest rate on debt 4.85% 4.85% 5.35% 7.00% 10.50% 14.50% 16.50% 16.50% 16.50% 24.50% Tax Rate 38.00% 38.00% 38.00% 38.00% 38.00% 35.46% 25.97% 22.26% 19.48% 11.66% Cost of Debt (after-tax) 3.01% 3.01% 3.32% 4.34% 6.51% 9.36% 12.21% 12.83% 13.29% 21.64% WACC 10.30% 9.93% 9.62% 9.59% 10.22% 11.70% 14.02% 15.22% 16.42% 25.12% Firm Value (G) $5,660 $6,063 $6,443 $6,485 $5,740 $4,507 $3,342 $2,938 $2,616 $1,401 Table 1: Costs of Equity, Debt and Capital: Harman The unlevered beta is 1.45, which indicates that Harman is already a fairly risky business. I then estimate its levered beta at 10% increments on the debt ratio, up to 90 percent debt. . The table also shows the effect of the rising debt ratio on the company’s bond ratings, interest rate on debt, tax rate, cost of debt, weighted average cost of capital (WACC), and firm value. The cost of equity and cost of debt both rise as debt increases, but the cost of capital drops and the firm value increases, at least initially. The benefits of debt exceed its costs until the debt reaches 30 percent, at which point, the cost of capital starts climbing again and the firm value begins to drop. To minimize the cost of capital for Harman, the optimal debt ratio would be about 30 percent, or $1.8 billion in debt. Before the LBO, Harman was clearly under levered at a 7% debt ratio. But if the LBO had gone through and achieved its Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=1162862 13 goal of a 50 percent debt ratio, Harman would have been overlevered after the transaction. As powerful as the cost of capital approach is, it clearly has flaws that may lead firms to choose the wrong financing mix. In particular, there are three elements of the analysis that are troublesome. 1. Indirect bankruptcy costs: One flaw is the assumption that cash flow can remain fixed even as the debt ratio is increased. Indirect bankruptcy costs should preclude a company with a rising debt ratio (and lower bond ratings) from maintaining the operating income at its existing level. 2. Static approach in a dynamic world: A second flaw is that the approach itself is static; it is based on the previous year’s operating income and prevailing values for interest rates and default spreads. But conditions change. A recession for a cyclical firm, a loss of a major contract or increase in competition can all change the optimal debt ratio for a firm. 3. Risk Bearing Assumptions: It makes rigid assumptions about the ways in which market risk and default risk are borne by different claim holders as a company continues to increase debt. For instance, the approach that we have used for levering and unlevering betas assumes that all market risk is borne only by the equity investors. 2. Enhanced cost of capital approach. Through the enhanced cost of capital approach, I introduce three innovations. First, indirect costs are built into the expected operating income. As the rating of the company declines, the operating income is adjusted to reflect the loss in operating income that will occur when customers, suppliers, and investors react. In this way, I account for distress costs, such as indirect bankruptcy costs. Second, I can make the analysis more dynamic. Rather than examining a single, static number for operating income, I allow for the use of a distribution of operating income, thus allowing for a range of optimal debt ratios. Third, the levered beta formulations can be modified to reflect the fact that debt holders sometimes bear market Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=1162862 14 risk (the beta of debt is greater than zero). Since the latter two modifications create little in the optimal debt ratio, we will present just the first modification in this section. To quantify the distress costs, I tie operating income to a company’s bond rating. As shown in Table 2, once a company’s rating drops below A (that is, below investment grade), distress costs occur in the form of a percentage decrease in earnings. Table 2: Operating Income and Bond Rating Rating A or higher ABBB BB+ BB B+ B BCCC CC C D Drop in EBITDA No effect 2.00% 5.00% 10.00% 15.00% 20.00% 20.00% 25.00% 40.00% 40.00% 40.00% 50.00% The result of this enhancement to the cost of capital approach can be seen in Table 3, where we compute the costs of capital, operating income and firm valuse at different debt ratios for Harman: Table 3: Firm Value, Cost of capital and Debt ratios: Enhanced Cost of Capital Debt Ratio 0% 10% 20% 30% 40% 50% 60% 70% 80% 90% Beta 1.45 1.55 1.67 1.92 2.33 2.80 3.49 4.66 6.99 13.98 Cost of Equity 10.30% 10.70% 11.20% 12.17% 13.82% 15.68% 18.48% 23.14% 32.46% 60.42% Bond Rating AAA AAA AC D D D D D D Interest rate on debt 4.85% 4.85% 5.50% 16.50% 24.50% 24.50% 24.50% 24.50% 24.50% 24.50% Tax Rate 38.00% 38.00% 38.00% 24.55% 8.94% 7.16% 5.96% 5.11% 4.47% 3.98% Cost of Debt (after-tax) 3.01% 3.01% 3.41% 12.45% 22.31% 22.75% 23.04% 23.25% 23.40% 23.53% WACC 10.30% 9.93% 9.64% 12.26% 17.21% 19.21% 21.21% 23.21% 25.21% 27.21% Firm Value (G) $5,549 $6,141 $6,480 $1,276 $365 $308 $266 $234 $209 $189 As long as the bond ratings remain investment grade, Harman’s value remains intact. Its value, in fact, achieves its highest level at an A– rating and a debt ratio of 20 percent. But as soon as the rating drops below investment grade, the distress costs begin to take effect, and Harman’s value drops precipitously. Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=1162862 15 Thus, the debt ratio of 30 percent that seemed optimal under the unmodified cost of capital approach now appears to be entirely imprudent. The optimal debt ratio is now 20 percent, which means that Harman should be leveraged to about $1.2 billion, not $1.8 billion and certainly not the $4 billion proposed in the LBO bid of Goldman Sachs and KKR. In fact, at the 50% debt ratio, there is a very real danger of the firm getting caught up in the whirlwind of indirect bankruptcy costs. 3. Adjusted present value approach. In the adjusted present value approach, we explicitly add the value added by the tax benefits from the use of debt and subtract the value destroyed by higher bankruptcy costs from the value of the firm with no debt (unlevered firm value). Firm value = Unlevered firm value + (Tax benefits of debt − Expected bankruptcy costs from debt ). As in the other two approaches, the optimum debt level is the one that maximizes the firm’s value. Three steps are needed for the adjusted present value approach. First, the value of the unlevered company must be estimated, and this can be done in two different ways: (1) Estimate the unlevered beta, which is the cost of equity based on the unlevered beta, and value the company using this cost of equity (which will also be the cost of capital in an unlevered company) (2) Start with the current market value of the company, subtract the current tax benefits of debt, and add the expected bankruptcy costs from debt. In effect, remove those components of market value that reflect the influence of the debt that the firm currently has on its books. Second, calculate the present value of tax benefits at different levels of debt. The simplest assumption is that the tax benefits are perpetual, in which case the following equation applies: Tax benefits = Dollar debt × Tax rate. Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=1162862 16 Note that this equation can be easily adapted to meet more general descriptions of the debt. The key is that the interest tax savings are being discounted at the pre-tax cost of debt to arrive at the value of the tax savings. (In some modifications of the APV approach, the tax benefits are discounted back at the unlevered cost of equity) Third, estimate a probability of bankruptcy at each debt level and multiply that by the cost of bankruptcy (including direct and indirect costs) to estimate the expected bankruptcy cost. The probability of bankruptcy can usually be estimated using the synthetic ratings process described earlier in computing the cost of debt. However, estimating direct and indirect costs of bankruptcy is the most difficult task in the APV exercise and is often skipped. But if these costs, which represent the disadvantages of debt, are not estimated, the optimal debt ratio will be 100 percent, which is the reason that adjusted present value is the approach preferred by many proponents of high financial leverage. Assuming that direct and indirect bankruptcy costs are roughly 25 percent of Harman’s firm value, I developed Table 4. Debt Ratio 0% 10% 20% 30% 40% 50% 60% 70% 80% 90% $ Debt $0 $563 $1,127 $1,690 $2,253 $2,817 $3,380 $3,943 $4,506 $5,070 Tax Rate 38.00% 38.00% 38.00% 38.00% 38.00% 35.95% 17.73% 15.20% 13.30% 11.82% Unlevered Firm Value Tax Benefits $5,596 $0 $5,596 $214 $5,596 $428 $5,596 $642 $5,596 $856 $5,596 $1,013 $5,596 $599 $5,596 $599 $5,596 $599 $5,596 $599 Bond Rating AAA AAA A B+ CC CC D D D D Probability of Default Expected Bankruptcy ValueCost of Levered Firm 0.01% $0 $5,596 0.01% $0 $5,810 0.53% $8 $6,016 19.28% $301 $5,938 65.00% $1,049 $5,404 65.00% $1,074 $5,535 100.00% $1,549 $4,647 100.00% $1,549 $4,647 100.00% $1,549 $4,647 100.00% $1,549 $4,647 Table 4: Adjusted Present Value for Harman Note that the unlevered firm value stays the same at every debt ratio. Up to a point, the tax benefits increase as debt increases, but then level off once the interest expenses exceed the operation income. The expected bankruptcy costs also increase, as the probability of bankruptcy rises at high debt ratios. As with the enhanced cost of capital approach, the value of the firm reaches its Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=1162862 17 highest point with a 20 percent debt ratio. Therefore, all three approaches give an optimal debt ratio far below the 50 percent recommended by Goldman Sachs and KKR. Debt assessment tool summary. All three of these approaches rely on sustainable cash flow to determine the optimal debt ratio. They do not rely on market value or growth prospects, and I believe that is appropriate. The more stable and predictable a company’s cash flow and the greater the magnitude of these cash flows—as a percentage of enterprise value—the higher the company’s optimal debt ratio can be. Furthermore, the most significant benefit of debt is the tax benefit. Higher tax rates should lead to higher debt ratios. Based on the insights offered so far, the best candidates for large amounts of financial leverage will be mature or declining companies that have large, reliable cash flows. Growth companies—companies with their best days ahead of them—are not good candidates for LBOs because such companies have high market values, relative to cash flows, and usually need to plough these cash flows back into the business (rather than pay interest expenses) to generate future growth. Finally, the macro environment has relatively little effect on optimal debt ratios, and two myths often asserted by market observers need to be dispelled. The first myth is that optimal debt ratios increase as interest rates decline. Certainly, it is true that lower interest rates decrease the cost of debt, but they also decrease the cost of equity and it is the relative costs that determine financing choices. The second myth is that optimal debt ratios increase as default spreads decline. It is true that lower default spreads lower the cost of debt, but periods where default spreads decrease are also usually periods when equity risk premiums also go down. In other words, the cost of debt and equity both decline when default spreads and equity risk premiums decline. It is only when one measure declines while the other remains unchanged that one mode of financing will dominate the other. The 2003-2007 period was an aberration in that sense, since default spreads decreased while equity risk premiums Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=1162862 18 remained relatively stable. Not surprisingly, this provided an incentive for firms to borrow more money and for leveraged deals. Value of Control Control is the second potential component in an LBO and it is a key factor in determining the value of a company. Investors targeting a company for an LBO generally assume that they can run that company better than it is run right now. In particular, the expected value of control is the product of two variables: (1) the value achieved by changing the way a company is operated and (2) the probability that such a change will occur. Note, though, that a leveraged buyout is not the only means of asserting control. Activist boards can force top management to change its behavior or replace it altogether. Proxy contests and activist investing can also be used to pressure underachieving managers into modifying their behavior. Such methods are relatively inexpensive to implement but require assertive behavior and may not be effective against entrenched management. Control Premium. There is significant evidence that investors value control and are willing to pay to acquire it. For instance, acquiring companies pay a premium for substantial control. When buying shares in a publicly traded company, investors often pay a premium for voting shares because of the control such shares afford. Conversely, when buying a minority stake in a private company, investors will frequently expect a discount because of the absence of control. In other words, a 49 percent share in a private business has a significantly lower value from a 51 percent share in that same business. In theory, the control premium is the difference between the current value of a company and its optimal value. Therefore, the premium should be larger for poorly managed companies and smaller for well-managed companies. Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=1162862 19 Because the control premium varies across companies, no simple rule of thumb applies for all companies. For example, the notion that control is worth 20–30 percent of the value of a company is not valid. Furthermore, the control premium will vary according to the reasons for a company’s underperformance. The control premium will be lower when external and uncontrollable factors are affecting a company’s performance and higher when the poor performance is being caused by bad management. Finally, the control premium will vary according to the ease with which management decisions can be made. For example, if a less than optimal financing mix is the primary flaw in management decision making, the control premium should be fairly large, because the problem can be easily and quickly remedied. If the management flaw is the retention of outdated physical plants that must be modernized, then the control premium will fall because of the higher costs involved. Harman Case. To assess the value of control in the case of Harman, I will start with a conventional discounted cash flow (DCF) valuation of Harman. I will begin my valuation of Harman by taking Harman as it is and call this valuation the “status quo” valuation. Figure 7, at the end of the paper, summarizes the status quo valuation. Note a few significant figures: Harman earns a 14.56 percent return on capital, and its cost of capital is 9.91 percent—a spread of just over 4.5 percentage points. That is a healthy number and not at all indicative of a badly managed company. What, then, would Goldman Sachs and KKR do differently to improve management? Based on this valuation, the value of this (or any other) company can be increased in only four ways, related either to either making operations more efficient or increasing growth value – increase cash flows from existing assets, increase the expected growth rate during the high growth period, lengthen the high growth period or reduce the cost of capital. When I compare Harman’s margins relative to those of other companies in its sector, I find that Harman’s margins are about 2 percent higher than those of others, so cost-cutting opportunities do not appear to abound. Perhaps Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=1162862 20 Harman can grow faster in the future, but the only two ways my analysis indicates that Harman can grow faster are by reinvesting more or reinvesting better. Harman reinvests about 42 percent of its after-tax operating income back into the business, so perhaps it could reinvest a bit more. But I do not see much room for improving its current reinvesting. With a 14.56 percent return on capital against a 9.91 percent cost of capital, Harman is doing much better than other companies in the sector. In summary, Harman appears to be a fairly well run company that is probably growing as fast as the market allows. Another tactic might be to put off being a mature company. In my status quo valuation, I assumed that Harman had five years of high growth. Beyond that, perhaps it can identify and capitalize on new comparative advantages or barriers to entry. It seems unlikely, however, that Goldman Sachs and KKR could identify new competitive advantages that Harman’s existing managers have not already considered. The one area that appears to have some potential for improvement is cost of capital. Certainly, Harman can carry more debt than 6 percent. In fact, the analysis of financial leverage in the last section suggests that the optimal debt ratio for Harman is between 20 and 30%. In summary, I revalued Harman with some simple changes in figure 8. First, I had the company reinvest more of its cash flow. Being a U.S.-centric company, perhaps it could invest more in emerging markets. Second, I increased the debt ratio from 6 percent to 25 percent, which is in the range of the optimal ratio determined earlier. Such changes raise its value from $4.6 billion to $5.3 billion, thus creating $700 million of additional value. Undoubtedly, this is an improvement, but it is not a dramatic one, and the reason that the change is so small is that the company is well run. From a control perspective, Harman is once again a poor target for an LBO because its managers are already doing a good job. When a potential target is well managed, the expected value of control is small. But if the target company is badly managed, the value of control can be significant. If control is the motive for an acquisition, the target company should possess the following qualities: Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=1162862 21 • Its stock should be underperforming in its sector and in the market in general. • Its margins should be lower than those of comparable firms in its sector with no offsetting benefits, such as higher turnover ratios. • Its returns on equity and returns on capital should lag its costs of equity and capital. • The flaws should originate with the management of the company and should be repairable. Harman does not meet these characteristics. Its stock has earned returns similar to those earned by the rest of its sector. Its operating margin is 11 percent, and the average for its sector is 8 percent, so it is not underperforming the sector in that respect. Given its healthy excess returns and good reputation, there is no reason to believe that its managers are incompetent. Harman is not a badly managed company and does not look like a good target for control. Public to Private Transition The final component that drives value is the issue of taking a public company private. For decades in corporate finance, the assumed normal sequence of events is for businesses to start as private businesses and then make the transition to publicly traded companies for at least three reasons: • Raise capital. Although private companies today have more sources of capital (such as private equity and venture capital) than they had years ago, raising capital in public equity markets still tends to be less expensive and provide more choices than private equity, and can be done on a larger scale. • Monetize value. Even if a private company is valuable, that value is an abstraction. Being traded in the public market puts a price on a company and provides its owners with the capacity to monetize value. • Bear risk more efficiently. Much of the risk in any business is company specific and diversifiable. Private business owners are often invested Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=1162862 22 primarily in their own businesses, and are exposed to all of this risk. The investors in a public company are more likely to be diversified and will be able to eliminate a significant portion of the risk. The last reason is the most important one. The owners of a private company must contend with 100 percent of the company’s risk—both market risk and company-specific risk. But owners of a public company need contend only with market risk (i.e., the 10-30 percent of risk that is not diversifiable). Thus, a public company with a beta of 1.2 would, in private hands, probably expose the private investor to much higher risk – the equivalent of having a beta of 3 or 4. Applying this understanding to Harman, I can value it as both a public and a private company. As a public company, Harman has a market beta of 1.46, a cost of capital of 9.91 percent, and a value of $4.9 billion. To value Harman as a private company, I must scale up its beta to reflect total risk. I do this by dividing the market beta by Harman’s correlation with the market, which is approximately 0.5, which gives a total beta of 2.97 and a corresponding cost of capital of 15.6 percent. On this basis, the value of Harman as a private company is $2.4 billion. Given this huge drop in value from the public to private switch, why would I want to take Harman private? Listed below are four issues that may justify this transaction: • Agency issues. Because managers of a publicly traded company are spending stockholders’ money and not their own, they may have little incentive to do what is best for the company. By making it their private business, you may increase their incentives to do what is right for the business. • Disclosure costs. Publicly traded companies have to meet far more disclosure requirements than do private companies. Not only does disclosure cost money, but compliance with disclosure requirements may also provide competitors with valuable information on strategies and products. Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=1162862 23 • Time horizon. To the extent that publicly traded companies are at the mercy of the short-term whims of analysts and investors, going private may allow these companies to make better long-term decisions • Public pressure. More public pressure (by regulators, the financial press and investors, for instance) can be placed on a publicly traded company than on a private business. As already shown, such arguments must be weighed against the high cost of going private. In the case of Harman, I have estimated a loss in value of $2.5 billion caused by going private. To minimize privatizing costs, three specific steps can be taken. First, the acquiring investors, such as KKR, may hold a portfolio of private companies, thus increasing correlation with the market and lowering total beta. Second, the company that is going private may do so only temporarily, in which case the higher cost of capital will apply only until the company returns to the public market. Third, the private equity investor can go public (as did the Blackstone Group) and thereby reduce its residual risks. Based on the discussion so far, the best candidates for going private are companies that have the following characteristics: • Top managers are not significant stockholders in the company. • The actions needed to correct the company’s problems are likely to be painful in the short term, such as lower earnings, layoffs, and factory shutdowns. • Analysts following the company are not giving it credit for long-term actions and are focusing primarily on earnings in the near term. Harman does not meet these criteria. The Harman family has a large stockholding in the company and has been active in its management since it was founded. The company is run with long-term goals in mind, and any suitable changes apply primarily to optimizing Harman’s debt, not retooling its operations. I see little gain from going private. Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=1162862 24 In conclusion, Harman is not a good candidate for leverage. It is not a good candidate for control. And it is not a good candidate for going private. Harman should never have been targeted for a leveraged buyout. Interactions among the LBO Components In our discussion of the financial leverage, control and value, we have treated them as independent components with separate effects on value. However, there is the possibility that these three components could interact with each other, in both positive and negative ways, and create secondary effects on value. Leverage and Control. Begin by considering an LBO from a lender’s point of view. On the plus side, a company that is restructuring to fix its operating problems is likely to become healthier and, therefore, more likely to pay off its debt obligations. Restructuring in such a case should reduce a company’s default risk. On the minus side, companies that restructure are also changing themselves on multiple dimensions—business mix, cash flows, and assets. Lenders who do not monitor the process may discover that the assets that were intended to secure their loans have been eliminated with the restructuring, thus leaving them exposed. Furthermore, the equity investors who now control the business can direct cash flows (in the form of management fees and other compensation) into their own pockets. The implication, therefore, is that lenders in leveraged buyouts need to take an active role in the restructuring process and should demand an equity stake in the business. Control and Going Private. After a going-private transaction, the managers of a privatized business are now the owners. They are likely to become much more aware of default risk and distress costs, since it is their wealth that is on the line. Therefore, on the one hand, they are less likely to be overly aggressive risk takers, which is a positive turn for good management. On the other hand, if things start going bad and the managers decide that they have little to lose, they may start taking not just more risks but also imprudent risks. In effect, Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=1162862 25 their equity positions become options, and more risk makes them more valuable. Allowing managers/owners to make decisions in their companies can provide a license to steal. Therefore, lending should be restricted to businesses with transparent and easily understood operations, and when privatized companies get into trouble, lenders must be prepared to step in quickly and aggressively. Leverage and Going Private. Finally, consider the interaction between leverage and going private. An advantage is that lenders can make the owners of the private company personally liable for the loans taken by the company, which increases lenders’ security and reduces default costs. On the flip side, the owners and their lawyers may find creative loopholes for hiding cash and assets. Therefore, lenders should be wary of hot deals for which the borrowers set the terms of the leverage and protect their personal assets and keep track of the assets of the business to ensure that they are not being redirected into the wrong hands. Conclusion Each of the three potential components of an LBO—leverage, control, and privatization—can have either a positive or negative effect on a company’s value. But the components are separable, and there is no reason not to pick and choose among them. For example, some companies may be good candidates for leveraged recapitalizations, others may be ripe for a hostile acquisition, and still others may benefit from going private. A few companies may benefit from a combination of two out of the three components. But the list of companies that are right for all three components is a very short one. Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=1162862 26 Figure 7: Harmon Valuation (Status Quo) Harman: Status Quo Reinvestment Rate 42.00% Current Cashflow to Firm EBIT(1-t) : 248 - Nt CpX 67 - Chg WC 37 = FCFF 144 Reinvestment Rate = 104/248=42% Return on Capital 14.56% Expected Growth in EBIT (1-t) .42*.1456=.0613 6.13% Stable Growth g = 4%; Beta = 1.00; Cost of capital = 7.40% ROC= 12%; Tax rate=38% Reinvestment Rate=33.33% Terminal Value5=231(.074-.04) = 6799 Op. Assets 4,886 + Cash: 106 - Debt 350 =Equity 4,641 -Options 119 Value/Share $69.32 Year EBIT (1-t) - Reinvestment FCFF 1 $263 $111 $152 2 $279 $117 $162 3 $296 $125 $172 4 $314 $132 $182 5 $334 $140 $193 Discount atCost of Capital (WACC) = 10.34% (.94) + 3.01% (0.06) = 9.91% Cost of Equity 10.34% Riskfree Rate: Riskfree rate = 4.5% Cost of Debt (4.5%+%+.35%)(1-.38) =3.01% + Beta 1.46 Unlevered Beta for Sectors: 1.43 Weights E = 94%% D = 6% X Risk Premium 4% Firmʼs D/E Ratio: 6% Mature risk premium 4% Country Equity Prem 0.% Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=1162862 Term Yr 346.9 115.6 231.3 27 Figure 8: Harmon Valuation (Restructured) Harman: Restructured Reinvestment Rate 70.00% Current Cashflow to Firm EBIT(1-t) : 248 - Nt CpX 67 - Chg WC 37 = FCFF 144 Reinvestment Rate = 104/248=42% Return on Capital 15% Expected Growth in EBIT (1-t) .70*.15=.105 10.5% Stable Growth g = 4%; Beta = 1.00; Cost of capital = 7.48% ROC= 12%; Tax rate=38% Reinvestment Rate=33.33% Terminal Value5=284(.074-.04) = 8155 Op. Assets 5588 + Cash: 106 - Debt 350 =Equity 5,325 -Options 119 Value/Share $80.22 Year EBIT (1-t) - Reinvestment FCFF 1 $274.7 $192.3 $82.4 2 $303.5 $212.5 $91.1 3 $335.4 $234.8 $100.6 4 $370.6 $259.4 $111.2 5 $409.6 $286.7 $122.9 Discount atCost of Capital (WACC) = 10.90% (.80) + 3.41% (0.20) = 9.40% Cost of Equity 10.90% Riskfree Rate: Riskfree rate = 4.5% Cost of Debt (4.5%+%+1%)(1-.38) =3.41% + Beta 1.60 Unlevered Beta for Sectors: 1.43 Weights E = 80%% D = 20% X Risk Premium 4% Firmʼs D/E Ratio: 25% Mature risk premium 4% Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=1162862 Country Equity Prem 0.% Term Yr 425.9 141.9 284.0