Price Elasticity of Gasoline Smuggling: a Semi-Structural Estimation ApproachI Hamed Ghoddusi 1 , Nima Rafizadeh 2 , Mohammad H. Rahmati 3 Abstract We estimate the price elasticity of the demand for gasoline smuggling in Iran. For this purpose, we employ a detailed panel of monthly gasoline consumption data from 160 distribution hubs during the period 2005-2014. We apply two different approaches which are diff-in-diff and panel data estimations. The results suggest that the foreign-to-home gasoline price ratios have a significant impact on the time-varying elasticity of demand. This finding supports the hypothesis that an increase in domestic gasoline prices will significantly reduce the demand for smuggling. In addition, as the distance of a region from its closest higherprice neighboring country diminishes, the price elasticity of demand for gasoline smuggling for that region declines as well. Finally, we find that when the ratio of foreign to domestic prices is higher, the gasoline demand sensitivities to price in neighboring countries go up. Our work offers new insights regarding the welfare impact of removing fuel subsidies and modifying fuel pricing policies. Keywords: Gasoline Smuggling, Fuel Subsidy Removal, Price Elasticity, Gasoline Price Differential, Panel Data Estimation JEL Classification Codes: C23, F15, H77, Q41 I This paper is based on the masters thesis of Nima Rafizadeh at the Sharif University of Technology supervised by the other two co-authors. 1 School of Business, Stevens Institute of Technology, Hoboken, NJ, USA. Email: hghoddus@stevens.edu, website: www.ghoddusi.com 2 Graduate Department of Management and Economics, Sharif University of Technology, Tehran, Iran. Email: nima.rafizadeh90@gmail.com 3 Corresponding Author, Graduate Department of Management and Economics, Sharif University of Technology, Tehran, Iran. Email: rahmati@sharif.edu Preprint submitted to SSRN Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2954034 November 28, 2017 1. Introduction Smuggling is a common problem across international borders where variation in tax or subsidy policy might create a price differential between the source and destination regions. A notable example is the case of smuggling the heavily-subsidized gasoline from Iran to its neighboring countries, where the price of gasoline has typically been much higher than Iran. The literature on smuggling1 suggests that the prerequisite for smuggling homogeneous goods (e.g. gasoline or beverages) is a price differential for the very same good in two areas. Since gasoline is very close to a homogeneous good, the substantial difference in the price of gasoline between Iran and its neighboring countries has created opportunities for an outbound smuggling of gasoline from Iran. For example, before the (partial) subsidy removal in 2010, the price of gasoline in Iran was on average one-fifteenth of the price in Turkey. Such a non-trivial price gap motivated individuals to earn income by the smuggling and transferring of gasoline to Turkey2 . The gasoline price in Iran has always been set by the government and is constant across all parts of the country. Following a national plan to reduce and eventually eliminate fuel subsidies, the government increased the nominal price of gasoline in three major events over the past couple of years. The new fuel pricing policy aims to set the domestic price at the worldwide equilibrium to narrow down the gap between domestic and foreign fuel prices. This policy was expected to mitigate or cut incentives for selling subsidized fuel to neighboring countries that typically have higher fuel prices. Capping the fuel smuggling was one of the key motives behind the fuel subsidy reforms (Victor (2009) and Dartanto (2013)). The other motives of this policy shift included controlling the ever increasing domestic demand and releasing the fiscal burden of the gasoline subsidies from the government. The policy has been implemented. For the past few years Iranian domestic fuel prices 1 For a more in depth understanding of smuggling, see Kanbur and Keen (1993), Trandel (1994), Haufler (1996), Wang (1999), Ohsawa (1999), Scharf (1999) and Nielsen (2001, 2002). 2 The smuggling could be carried out through illegal border crossing or via quasi-legal means such as filling the tanks of large trucks and pickups and withdrawing the gasoline right outside Irans border. 2 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2954034 have been closer to the fuel prices in neighboring countries. However, the effectiveness of this policy experiment on reducing the extent of smuggled fuel has not been empirically examined. Our paper is the first to rigorously evaluate such outcomes. The objective of this paper is to use domestic variations in order to provide estimates of the price elasticity of the demand for gasoline smuggling in various regions of the country. We use the fact that gasoline prices in Iran are determined by a central government as a key identification factor. Our research uses administrative regional-level data (for 160 distribution hubs) during the years 2005-2014. We utilize the heterogeneity of the various provinces and their closest higher-price neighbors. As all of the provinces are forced to follow the same gasoline price, we estimate the elasticity of the demand for gasoline smuggling as a function of price differentials between Iran and neighboring countries, and the distance to the border. We offer multiple contributions to the existing research. First, we provide empirical evidence for the impact of changing government-set fuel prices to the demand for smuggling. To the best of our knowledge, this is the first attempt to provide such results in the context of a resource-rich country. Removing domestic fuel subsidies and bringing prices closer to the international levels have been the subject of recent heated debates. Due to various factors, several oil-rich countries have already started removing or reducing domestic fuel subsidies and narrowing the gap between domestic and international prices. However, there is not much literature concerning ex-post empirical evaluation of the results of such policies. We fill this gap by offering empirical evidence from Iran, a vast and largely populated oil-rich country that undertook an ambitious fuel subsidy removal program in 2010. Second, our paper contributes to the literature of public finance and the demand for smuggling. Prior research has focused on various goods (especially luxury goods such as beverages and cigarettes). We provide evidence for gasoline, a homogeneous and essential good. Despite the typical reliable data collection issues in developing countries, we believe that 3 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2954034 the granularity of our quantity and price observations in conjunction with the particular institutional setups, which we exploit for causal identification, enable us to provide a reasonably reliable estimate of the elasticity. We also offer multiple robustness tests to address or mitigate potential concerns. The paper is structured as follows. Section 2 presents the literature review on the estimation of goods demanded with regard to smuggling, cross-border shopping, and subsidizing fuel. Section 3 presents data. In Section 4 the empirical method used for the estimation of gasoline demand is discussed. Sections 5 and 6 deal with results and robustness checks. Finally, Section 7 draws the conclusion. 2. Literature Review 2.1. Cross-Border Shopping and Smuggling A seminal work in this area has been conducted by Leal et al. (2010) who provide a comprehensive review of the literature on cross-border shopping as a result of tax differentials. According to Mikesell (1970), tax differences between various states in the United States induced an interest in cross-border shopping from the mid-1930s. The first applied research, however, was performed between the 1950s and 1970s.3 In such works, the most general form for each good was calculated in a demand function with the goods sold in each region as the dependent variable. Explanatory variables include the price and the relative taxation of the regarded goods in each region compared to its neighbors, the income in considered territories, the cost of travel between neighbouring territories, and a set of other standard control variables. Fox (1986) was the first paper to explicitly incorporate variables related to transport costs into empirical models. More recent papers have also introduced new controls such as the number of Fridays in the month to explain the sales of alcohol (Asplund et al. (2007)), the stock of vehicles to explain the sales of gasoline (Banfi et al. (2005)), as well as 3 For instance, see Mikesell (1970, 1971), Maliet (1955), McAllister (1961) and Hamovitch (1966). 4 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2954034 the expenditure on advertising by tobacco companies to explain the sales of tobacco (Coats (1995)). Regularly, the specifications take a multiplicative form, which favors subsequent logarithmic transformation and a direct interpretation of the estimated coefficients in terms of elasticity. An illustration of this is provided by the work of Walsh and Jones (1988). Their results suggest that the residents of the counties that border West Virginia choose to purchase outside their state in order to avoid paying higher taxes. Following the methodology proposed by Walsh and Jones (1988), Asplund et al. (2007) estimate how the monthly sales of alcohol in Sweden respond to prices in Denmark and Germany. They conclude that in urban areas close to the border, the elasticity of domestic demand with respect to foreign prices is approximately 30%. These estimates are reduced to 20% (10%) when the distance is widened to 150 (400) kilometers. In sum, both distance and price differentials critically influence the size of cross-border shopping. Other works have tested the cross-border purchases of alcoholic drinks, such as Crawford and Tanner (1995) and Crawford et al. (1999) for the United Kingdom, Smith (1976) and Beard et al. (1997) for the United States, and Fleenor (1999) for Canada and the United States. There are also studies that focus on the cross-border shopping for tobacco in the United States where smuggling tobacco has been a traditional concern of authorities (Fisher (2007)). The existence of cross-border shopping has been demonstrated empirically by, among others, Wertz (1971), Warner (1982), Coats (1995), Saba et al. (1995), Fleenor (1998), and more recently by Chiou et al. (2008), Lovenheim (2008) and Merriman (2010). The results obtained by the literature consistently show that between 2% and 6% of the cigarettes consumed in the United States are smuggled. With regards to cross-border fueling, Banfi et al. (2005) employ a panel dataset to estimate the impact of gasoline price differences between the border regions of Switzerland and adjacent areas in Germany, Italy, and France on the demand for fuel in the Swiss border areas. Their results establish a strong association between cross-border shopping and price 5 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2954034 differentials. If the price of gasoline in Switzerland were to be reduced by 10%, the demand for gasoline in Swiss border areas would have increased by almost 17.5%. 2.2. Subsidy on Fuel Oil-rich countries often fund fuel subsidies to distribute the resource rent among the people. It effectively lowers their transportation costs and increases gasoline’s affordability for the public. However well-intentioned, the policy will distort the gasoline market with the resulting inefficiencies, not to mention external costs associated with high gasoline consumption such as the emission of local pollutants, traffic congestion, and motor vehicle accidents (Davis (2014)). The World Bank recommends that developing nations abandon the gasoline subsidy (Loveless (2015)). The opportunity cost of such policy is high and rising (Coady et al. (2010)). The most common strategy for the removal of subsidies is to implement a phase-out policy. The government only partially cuts the subsidy at any one time. Indonesia has done so in 2000, 2002 and 2003 (Sindo (2014)) and Malaysia has also carried out such measures in 2010 and 2013 (Bridel and Lontoh (2014)). When resistance starts to build up due to negative side effects, the government will then back down on the removal plan. We call this policy a gradual elimination of subsidies or percentage cut, while lifting the whole subsidy is the ultimate goal of the policy. In this case, the government has greater flexibility. Several governments have also attempted a partial subsidy removal plan with compensation benefits paid to the people. For instance, such a policy was implemented in Indonesia in 2005 and 2008 (WorldBank (2012)), as well as Iran in 2010 (Guillaume et al. (2011)). 3. Data and Institutional Context 3.1. Background on the Iranian Gasoline Market In Iran the national fuel price has always been set by the government in a fixed rate across all regions. In fact, there is no equilibrium market price or regional pricing in the country. A key institutional fact is that there are no private oil providers, and the government-affiliated 6 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2954034 National Iranian Oil Products Distribution Company (NIOPDC)4 is the sole importer and distributor of fuels. Historically, gasoline and diesel prices have been heavily subsidized in Iran, and the country had been experiencing one of the lowest average retail prices of fuels (in particular gasoline and diesel) in the world. There is no price difference between personal and commercial users of fuel; all vehicles pay the same price. The low price of fuels not only motivates outward smuggling, but also contributes to the ever-increasing domestic consumption. (Guillaume et al. (2011)) In a reaction to the rise in domestic consumption and the consequent increasing import of gasoline, the government implemented a comprehensive plan to mitigate the growth of fuel demand. Two major components of the plan were to increase the domestic prices (by removing the subsidies) and to ration the subsidized fuel per each vehicle. The rationed price was subsidized, yet it was only offered in limited quantities per vehicle5 . The rationing plan was in place from June 2007 until May 2015. Following the national plan to reduce fuel subsidies, the government increased the nominal price of gasoline in three major events over the past years (June 27 2007, December 19 2010, and April 24 2014). The rationing policy required all consumers to use their so-called “fuel card” when pumping their vehicles at any of the fuel stations6 . Figure 1 presents the monthly retail prices for gasoline (in USD terms) in Iran and its neighboring countries between 2005 and 2014. The dollar price of gasoline for Iran is flat for a long period because both the nominal price of gasoline and the exchange rate were held fixed. After the major subsidy removal in 2010 the exchange rate was also floated; thus, the real Iranian gasoline prices have been fluctuating since then. 4 Website: https://www.niopdc.ir Commercial vehicles including taxis and trucks were eligible to receive a larger quantity of rationed fuel. 6 For detail discussion of the policy in 2014 see Rahmati and Vesal (2017) 5 7 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2954034 Figure 1: Gasoline Price in Iran and Its Neighboring Countries 3.1.1. Fuel Smuggling Fuel smuggling is a major challenge in Iran. Unfortunately, official data on the volume of smuggled gasoline does not exist. However, unofficial and informal estimates suggest that the country is losing a significant volume of highly-subsidized fuels to its neighboring countries (especially Turkey) every year. For example, according to Iranian counter-smuggling authorities the estimated value of the petroleum products smuggling in 2014 was about 3.8 billion USD 7 . There are several methods for smuggling, including: fuel tank of personal vehicles, auxiliary tanks attached to trucks and pickups, small and mid-size boats, underground illegal pipelines, fuel tanker trucks, and even animals carrying barrels of gasoline. Anti-smuggling authorities have been in work to prevent illegal cross border flows. The law suggests that the penalty for smuggling is three times of the market value of discovered goods. The Iranian police have setup stations along major smuggling routes and in areas close to the borders. Suspicious vehicles are regularly checked for items such as auxiliary tanks and fuel containers. The stringency of anti-smuggling activities though varies across different provinces. Anecdotal evidence suggests that in regions with a high rate 7 Source: www.mehrnews.com/news/2961496/ 8 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2954034 of poverty and unemployment, government officials tolerate ”small-scale” (personal) smuggling functions because of insufficient social security system. Thus, they sometime disregard small-scale activities by local residents and focus their efforts on the large-scale professional transportation of fuel8 . 3.2. Data 3.2.1. Gasoline Consumption The administrative gasoline consumption data is directly obtained from the NIOPDC. The data set contains monthly observations of regular and premium gasoline consumption in 160 distribution hubs of NIOPDC between 2005 and 2014. We also collect official gasoline prices, which is one price in all distribution hubs. Hubs of NIOPDC are responsible for the logistics and distribution of various grades of gasoline to stations. There are 160 regional hubs, each covering a few urban and rural areas. Furthermore, since premium gasoline has a higher price than regular gasoline, and is considered a luxury good, we assume that the gasoline smuggling demand is mainly for the regular gasoline9 . In this paper, we estimate the demand for regular gasoline. Hereafter, whenever we talk about gasoline, we are referring to the regular one. The administrative gasoline sales data collection is managed through a fully automated nationwide system. All consumers are required to use their fuel card when buying gasoline at all the fuel stations. This data is then transmitted to a central system. At the end of each day the aggregate consumption for each region is recorded. Relying on such an accurate data provides confidence that our consumption data is most likely free of measurement errors. 8 The province-level fixed-effects in our panel data specification attempt to partially capture the heterogeneity in anti-smuggling activities. 9 We had explored the option to use the premium gasoline as a robustness test (or the placebo effect, as the other reviewer also suggested) from the beginning. However, after collecting and cleaning the data we realized a great deal of data recording problems, many missing observations, sparsity, outliers, and also a small sample size problem (the premium gasoline is not available in many locations). Moreover, the share of the premium gasoline is only 3.5% and mainly in large cities. Despite all these challenges, we report the estimations using the premium gasoline in Appendix B. As expected, due to the above reasons, the results are not significant. We relate the lack of significance to the small sample size as well as data problems. 9 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2954034 Moreover, since the price is set by the central administrative authority, our observation of price is also accurate. Descriptive statistics of the gasoline consumption data are summarized in Table 1. The highest quantity of gasoline consumption is observed in Tehran in August 2008. The lowest one was in Savadkooh located in Mazandaran province (the northern strip of Iran) in January 2006. 10 3.2.2. Gasoline Prices and the Distance from the Border The two key variables which are expected to have significant impacts on the elasticity of gasoline demand are: 1) the ratio of foreign to domestic price; 2) the distance from the closest higher-price border. Variations in these variables enable us to identify foreign and domestic demand in each region. Since we employ the price ratio, gasoline prices in Iran and its neighboring countries have all been expressed in terms of the United States Dollars. Table 1 illustrates that gasoline price in Iran is almost always less than its neighboring countries.11 We assume that gasoline demand for domestic consumption and for smuggling use is made up from both the rationed gasoline price and the non-rationed price; hence, the average of the real price for rationed and non-rationed gasoline is used for domestic price. As for the distance from the border variable, each region’s distance from its closest higher-price neighbour has been extracted meticulously both manually and with the aid of Google Maps. 3.2.3. Further Socio-Economic Variables One of the limitations of the current paper (as many other works in similar contexts) is the lack of granular socio-economic data to be used as perfect controls. In certain cases, the data series exist; however, their time frequency or spatial resolution does not fit with our 10 It should be noted that gasoline consumption data associated with September 2007 has been ruled out due to inconsistency with other information. The gasoline consumption in that particular month was inconsistent with the observations from other months in that year, and also with the similar months in the previous and following years. Thus, we treated it as a possible data recording error. 11 It is possible that prices on the non-Iranian side of the border are endogenous to the volume of smuggling. Ideally, one should use regional prices on the non-Iranian side of the border to estimate the price ratios. However, reliable and long-spanning data on regional prices do not exist. Thus, we use the nationwide average gasoline prices of the country as a close proxy. If the size of smuggled fuel compared to the total fuel consumption of the region is small, the price effect will also be small and this concern will be alleviated. 10 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2954034 Table 1: Summary Statistics of Key Variables Variable (Location) Type Measure Mean Max Min Gasoline consumption Regional hub/Monthly 1000 L 13,912 311,621 9 Real price of rationed gasoline in Iran Country/Monthly Rial/L 2,329 4,630 1,188 Real price of non-rationed gasoline in Iran Country/Monthly Rial/L 4,826 8,102 1,606 Price of rationed gasoline in Iran Country/Monthly US Dollar/L 0.15 0.39 0.09 Price of non-rationed gasoline in Iran Country/Monthly US Dollar/L 0.31 0.67 0.09 Price of gasoline in Turkey (NW) Country/Monthly US Dollar/L 2.16 2.86 0.75 Price of gasoline in Armenia (NW) Country/Monthly US Dollar/L 1.12 1.50 0.43 Price of gasoline in Afghanistan (E) Country/Monthly US Dollar/L 1.03 1.46 0.42 Price of gasoline in Pakistan (SE) Country/Monthly US Dollar/L 0.95 1.28 0.34 Price of gasoline in Azerbaijan (NW) Country/Monthly US Dollar/L 0.77 1.59 0.30 Price of gasoline in Iraq (W) Country/Monthly US Dollar/L 0.69 1.09 0.28 Price of gasoline in Persian Gulf (S) Country/Monthly US Dollar/L 0.44 0.63 0.18 Price of gasoline in Turkmenistan (N) Country/Monthly US Dollar/L 0.18 0.31 0.02 Distance of each region from its the closest higher-price neighboring countries Region/Monthly Kilometers 138 560 1 GDP per capita Province/Yearly Thousand Rials 683 3,214 215 Cars per capita Province/Seasonal Stock 0.105 0.195 0.047 Motorcycles per capita Province/Seasonal Stock 0.060 0.187 0.007 Unemployment rate Province/Seasonal - 0.127 0.330 0.039 GDP and gasoline price in Iran are based on real data in 2011 using consumer price index. Gasoline prices in neighboring countries have been transformed into monthly from their annual reports using gasoline price variation in the Persian Gulf FOB. NW, E, SE, W, S and N stand for northwest, east, southwest, west, south, and north, respectively. 11 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2954034 unit of analysis. Despite these expected limitations, we did our best to collect the annual GDP, the number of the cars and motorcycles, and the seasonal rate of unemployment at the province level. We turn all variables to per-capita to make them comparable across different locations. 4. Empirical Method 4.1. Identification The key institutional feature of our identification strategy is the existence of an administratively set national price of gasoline. The non-varying prices across time and provinces mitigate the potential endogeneity concern of equilibrium prices at the regional level. If the price was determined through market forces, or even through an administrative mechanism instituted at the regional level, one could argue that the demand for smuggling directly affects the price. We assume that the fuel prices in the neighboring countries are set based on their domestic considerations. Therefore, we can use the exogenous variations of gasoline prices in different countries, time, and distances as a useful variation to identify the elasticity parameters. Moreover, we exploit the panel structure of the data and control for regional hub fixed effects. The central object of our analysis is to identify the price elasticity of smuggling. It expresses the sensitivity of smuggling to changes in the relative price of gasoline in the foreign and domestic markets and will be defined explicitly in the following section. 4.2. Overview of the Model In Iran, the government sets nationwide identical official gasoline prices for all regions. Noticeably, as discussed in Section 3 at each time t, the gasoline price inside the country is at least less than one of its neighboring countries, and smuggling would become profitable. Two underlying assumptions are taken into account in this paper which support two different empirical approaches. First, according to the literature presented in Section 2, by increasing the distance of a region from its neighboring countries, the tendency to smuggle is expected 12 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2954034 to decrease. Therefore, it is expected that the demand for gasoline smuggling is insignificant after a certain threshold. Under this assumption, the difference-in-difference approach is applicable because the smuggling behavior is different in bordering areas (treatment) compared with central ones (control). However, if the demand for gasoline smuggling is accrued from the demand in all regions, then the difference-in-difference approach can no longer be applied. Therefore, it is necessary to assume a structure for the demand to separate domestic from smuggling use. The structure we assume is that the propensity of the demand for smuggling is a linear function of the price ratios of the two countries and the distance from the closest higher-price border. Interestingly, we show that even with different gasoline demand functions for each of the two countries, this structure allows us to identify the smuggling elasticity as a function of price ratios and distances. In other words, the structural model can be pinned down to a reduced form estimation; in a way that the elasticity can be estimated using reduced form coefficients. The coefficient of distance in this semi-structural approach provides an implicit test for the underlying assumption behind the difference-in-difference approach. This method is explained in Section 4.4. For simplicity, region i which is located inside the country is shown by Hi and its closest higher-price neighboring country at time t, is indicated by Fit . 4.3. Difference in Difference Approach From a theoretical perspective, aggregate gasoline consumption in a country responds when the price has changed in its neighboring countries. However, the effect of this channel is not significant in provinces and distribution hubs (Hi ), which have a distance from Fit ¯ We implicitly assume that national factors (e.g. more than a threshold as denoted by d. GDP growth, travel days, gasoline prices, etc) affect symmetrically all distribution hubs. Notwithstanding, the demand for smuggling only shows up in border hubs. Therefore, the foreign gasoline demand which stimulates smuggling can be identified through using a diff- 13 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2954034 in-diff approach for hubs close and far from the borders (treatment vs. control). Th E[ln(Dit )|Pith , Pitf , Xit ] = Π0 + Π1 ln(Pith ) + Π2 ln( Pitf Pitf ¯ + γ3 Xit (1) ) + Π ln( ) ∗ Dummy(dit , d) 3 Pith Pith 1 if dit 6 d¯ ¯ Dummy(dit , d) = 0 if d > d¯ it (2) Where DitT h is the logarithm of the gasoline demand function in region i at time t that includes both domestic and smuggling uses. Domestic and foreign prices are denoted by (Pith ) and (Pitf ), respectively. Xit is other covariates including regional hub fixed effects, month fixed effects, GDP per capital, vehicle per capita, and unemployment rate. Domestic use would not change by variation in foreign prices. Therefore, we can claim that after controlling for month fixed effects the elasticity of demand with respect to foreign prices solely represents the elasticity demands for smuggling in each region i at time t as follows:12 it = T h) ∂ ln(Dit ∂ ln(Pitf ) = T h) ∂ ln(Dit ∂ Pf ln( Pith ) it ¯ = Π2 + Π3 ∗ Dummy(dit , d) (3) 4.4. Semi-Structural Approach Consider a hypothetical isolated region i where there is no smuggling and its gasoline demand at time t is equal to Dith . If smuggling takes place in this region, then its total demand would be DitT h . Obviously, DitT h > Dith , because smuggling would add up to domestic uses. However, the amount of demand related to smuggling is cannot be distinguished, so in order to identify the smuggling effect, we take the part of consumption in Hi into account that is demanded by smuggling, i.e. DitT h − Dith . Such demand is resulted from the higher price in Fit , and the smuggler demands for gasoline to gain a profit by selling it across 12 Notice that this variation in time and spatial of elasticity stems from the change in dit as the closest higher-price may be changed as gasoline prices vary independently in the neighboring countries. 14 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2954034 borders. Accordingly, while Hi is encountered with smuggling, the total gasoline demand in Hi at time t is influenced by two prices: Pith and Pitf . When the smuggling in Hi is zero, the amount of gasoline demand in Hi at time t is: h E[ln(Dit )|Pith , Xit ] = β0 + β1 ln(Pith ) + γ1 Xit (4) which is in fact the domestic gasoline demand requested by the consumer in Hi and is only a price function in (Pith ). Similarly, the amount of gasoline used by foreign consumers in Fit which is simply a function of price in Fit (Pitf ) is: f E[ln(Dit )|Pitf , Yit ] = β2 + β3 ln(Pitf ) + γ2 Yit (5) We define Sit as the influence ratio of gasoline demand in Fit from the lower price in Hi . In fact, the Sit function is the likelihood in which each representative consumer in Fit influenced by the lower price in Hi resorts to smuggling. We describe its aggregate as the ratio of the Fit demand influence of price in Hi . Two basic presuppositions are considered to obtain this ratio. First, Sit increases due to an increase in the marginal revenue derived from smuggling. Secondly, Sit decreases as long as gasoline smuggling costs increases from Hi to Fit . The smuggling likelihood function for the consumer i who is located at distance d from the closest bordering region, which has lower prices than the region of the consumer itself is defined as follows: Sit = φ + α ln( Pitf ) − δ ln(dit ) Pith (6) Lovenheim (2008) uses similar probability function for the demand of smuggling cigarettes, however he stated that the revenue from smuggling derived from the difference between the price logarithms in the region that purchase took place and residential prices. The cost of smuggling varies with the distance logarithm from the border. Moreover, φ denotes the fixed cost sustained by each consumer for smuggling. 15 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2954034 In Equation 6, with an increase in Pitf , the amount of Sit increases as well, so we hypothesize that α would be positive. φ, which is the smuggling fixed cost, has an inverse relationship with Sit . So, its coefficient’s sign should be negative. Eventually, with an increase in the distance of Hi and Fit , the smuggling appears to become much more costly. Consequently, the demand influence of foreign price reduces, and the δ coefficient’s sign in the function Sit is positive. The final step in the modeling of the total gasoline demand in Hi that is DitT h , is to extract a demand function that responds to smuggling in addition to domestic demand. As mentioned, when no smuggling activity is present, the demand available in Fit is obtained through Equation 5. However, when Fit is encountered with smuggling, the Fit region is influenced by the price available in Hi with the likelihood Sit . Hence, the mathematical expectation for the demand function of region Fit is as follows: Tf f fs E[ln(Dit )|Pith , Pitf , Yit ] = (1 − Sit ) E[ln(Dit )|Pitf , Yit ] + Sit E[ln(Dit )|Pith , Yit ] (7) Where Ditf s is the demand which is in Fit , but with price Pith . Thus, in the case of smuggling, compared to smuggling free situations, the mathematical expectation for the gasoline demand function in Fit alters as follows: Tf f fs f E[ln(Dit )|Pith , Pitf , Yit ] − E[ln(Dit )|Pitf , Yit ] = Sit (E[ln(Dit )|Pith , Yit ] − E[ln(Dit )|Pitf , Yit ]) (8) Any changes in the mathematical expectation of the gasoline demand function is going to be responded with smuggling from the resources inside Hi . In other words, at time t, besides the mathematical expectation for demand available in Hi for domestic consumption, the Fit region also requests gasoline from Hi according to Equation 8. Hence, the overall demand function which exists for gasoline in Hi at time t is as follows: fs f Th h E[ln(Dit )|Pith , Pitf , Xit ] = E[ln(Dit )|Pith , Xit ] + Sit (E[ln(Dit )|Pith , Yit ] − E[ln(Dit )|Pitf , Yit ]) 16 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2954034 (9) By replacing Equations 4, 5, and 6 in the above equation, the reduced form of the total gasoline demand function in Hi at time t is obtained as follows: Th E[ln(Dit )|Pith , Pitf , Xit ] = β0 + β1 ln(Pith ) − φβ3 ln( Pitf 2 Pitf Pitf ) − αβ [ln( )] + δβ ln( ) ∗ ln(dit ) + γ1 Xit 3 3 Pith Pith Pith (10) By defining the following equalities, the reduced form of the gasoline demand function is turned to Equation 11: A0 = β0 , A1 = β1 , A2 = −φβ3 , A3 = −αβ3 , A4 = δβ3 Th E[ln(Dit )|Pith , Pitf , Xit ] = A0 + A1 ln(Pith ) + A2 ln( Pitf Pitf 2 Pitf ) + A [ln( )] + A ln( ) ∗ ln(dit ) + γ1 Xit 3 4 Pith Pith Pith (11) Using the structural model and the intuition behind its deep parameters, we can determine the coefficient sign of the reduced form model. According to the law of demand, price and the demand for gasoline should have an inverse relationship.13 Hence, in Equations 4 and 5, β1 and β3 are negative. Now, the coefficient sign for A1 , A2 , A3 and A4 are extracted mathematically. With the aid of other coefficients stated in Equation 6 for Sit , the coefficient signs in the paper’s presuppositions are as follows: β1 < 0, A1 = β1 −→ A1 < 0 φ < 0, β3 < 0, A2 = −φβ3 −→ A2 < 0 α > 0, β3 < 0, A3 = −αβ3 −→ A3 > 0 δ > 0, β3 < 0, A4 = δβ3 −→ A4 < 0 It is expected that with an increase in gasoline prices in a country, its demand goes down. Hence, the A1 coefficient sign, which became mathematically negative, is compatible with our intuition. Similar to Equation 3, and based on Equation 11, gasoline demand elasticity 13 We assume that gasoline is not a Giffen good. 17 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2954034 with the proportion of foreign price to the domestic one in each i region at time t is as follows: ζit = T h) ∂ ln(Dit Pf = A2 + 2A3 ln( ∂ ln( Pith ) Pitf ) + A4 ln(dit ) Pith (12) it As it appears, Equation 12 is the sum of three phrases. It is recognized that when the foreign price exceeds the domestic price, the impetus for gasoline smuggling appears. It was also stated earlier that irrespective of the price differential and the distance from the border in each region, smuggling has a fixed cost (A2 ) which is almost the same in all the regions. Therefore, the coefficient sign is intuitively expected to be negative. In addition, for fixed domestic prices and a specific location, as the price of foreign gasoline increases, then the demand would be more elastic to foreign prices. Therefore, the A3 coefficient sign is anticipated to be positive. For the third phrase, it can be said that according to earlier assumptions, the more distance from the closest higher-price neighboring country, the less the elasticity. That is, an increase of one percent in the ratio of the foreign price to the domestic price has less influence on gasoline demand in faraway areas from the border, and the A4 coefficient sign is anticipated to be negative. 4.4.1. Discussion about variable of distance There might be a concern of the logarithm functional form we assumed in Equation 6 for distance. So, we also consider the linear relationship between smuggling demand as follows: Th E[ln(Dit )|Pith , Pitf , Xit ] = A0 +A1 ln(Pith )+A2 ln( Pitf Pitf 2 Pitf )+A [ln( )] +A ln( )∗(dit )+γ1 Xit (13) 3 4 Pith Pith Pith For robustness check, we also describe a dummy variable as in Equation 15 for the certain intervals of the border of the neighboring countries to capture non-linearity in demand by 18 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2954034 distance. Then, Equation 14 is applied for the gasoline demand in each i region at time t: Pf Pf it it E[ln(DitT h )|Pith , Pitf , Xit ] = η0 + η1 ln(Pith ) + η2 ln( Pith ) + η3 [ln( Pith )]2 + Pf η4 ln( Pith ) it ∗ Dummy(dit , (d0 , d1 )) + ... + Pf ηn+3 ln( Pith ) it Dummy(dit , (dp , dq )) = (14) ∗ Dummy(dit , (dn−1 , dn )) + γXit 1 if dit ∈ [dp , dq ) (15) 0 if dit ∈ / [dp , dq ) 5. Result 5.1. Estimation Gasoline prices are the same across all Iranian regions and hubs at any given time period. Moreover, the price in each month is less than at least one of Iran’s neighboring countries. Therefore, the assumptions presented in Section 4 for the modeling of the gasoline demand function are satisfied. As a result, we can estimate the coefficients presented in Section 4 using the data set introduced in Section 3. Moreover, in all the following approaches, standard errors for panel specifications are robust and clustered at the level of the cross-sectional unit to allow for arbitrary serial correlation. 5.1.1. Estimation Results of The Diff-in-Diff Approach Pf The coefficient associated with the log of price ratio ln( Pith ) is a key indicator for the it estimation of the elasticity of smuggling demand. The estimation results presented in Table 2 suggest that this coefficient is not significant in any of the various specifications (reported in various columns of Table 2).14 Pf The small and insignificant estimates of the coefficient of the log of price ratio ln( Pith ) it may stem from the inconsistent underlying assumption that smuggling took place with higher 14 It should be noted that the domestic price (Pith ) is constant across all hubs at a given time t. Hence, the domestic price is perfectly co-linear with the monthly dummy and thus, can not be identified. We dropped it from those regressions with month fixed effects, and reported those results. 19 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2954034 Variables Table 2: Demand Estimation with Diff-in-Diff Approach Dependent Variable: Dit (Gasoline consumption in the regions of Iran) (1) (2) (3) (4) Pf ln( Pith ) -0.00283 (0.0575) it Pf ln( Pith ) ∗ Dummy(dit , 1) it 0.00994 (0.0555) 0.0284 (0.0588) 0.0134 (0.0670) (5) 0.0676 (0.111) -0.209*** (0.0633) Pf ln( Pith ) ∗ Dummy(dit , 50) -0.0447 (0.0288) it Pf ln( Pith ) ∗ Dummy(dit , 100) -0.0572** (0.0274) it Pf ln( Pith ) ∗ Dummy(dit , 200) -0.0185 (0.0238) it Pf ln( Pith ) ∗ Dummy(dit , 400) -0.0692 (0.0930) it ln[(GDP per Capita)it ] 0.184 (0.143) 0.195 (0.145) 0.208 (0.146) 0.199 (0.145) 0.199 (0.145) ln[(Cars per Capita)it ] -0.100 (0.0834) -0.0943 (0.0831) -0.0895 (0.0830) -0.0897 (0.0836) -0.0909 (0.0835) ln[(Motorcycles per Capita)it ] 0.00986 (0.0604) 0.0206 (0.0609) 0.0225 (0.0604) 0.0214 (0.0610) 0.0196 (0.0609) -0.0358*** (0.0127) -0.0363*** (0.0128) -0.0348*** (0.0131) -0.0373*** (0.0127) -0.0375*** (0.0128) 15.00*** (2.271) 14.81*** (2.277) 14.61*** (2.302) 14.77*** (2.295) 14.79*** (2.281) Yes Yes 0.9522 Yes Yes 0.9521 Yes Yes 0.9522 Yes Yes 0.9520 Yes Yes 0.9521 ln[(Unemployment Rate)it ] Constant Region Fixed Effects Month Fixed Effects R-Squared Number of observations in each column: 16,552. Standard errors are robust and clustered by region to allow for arbitrary serial correlation. *** and **: indicate 1% and 5% significance levels, respectively. Standard errors are in parentheses. 20 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2954034 intensity in the border regions. In contrast, we find that the demand declines more in border regions when the rent from smuggling increases (the sign of the coefficient for the interaction of the log of price ratio and the dummy for distance when threshold equals to 1 km Pf ln( Pith )∗Dummy(dit , 1) is negative in Column 1 of Table 2). In other words, the border areas it cannot be actually specified as the “treatment” group in response to exogenous domestic price increases. To validate whether there exists a variation in gasoline consumption between “treatment” and “control” in response to shocks, Figure 2 plots the average consumption for hubs in various distance thresholds similar to Columns 1-5 in Table 2. This figure, and the estimates in Table 2 indicate that if there are any differences between regions, though insignificant, there would appear to be less smuggling in areas near the border. Apparently, this finding contradicts the initial assumption that the smuggling reduces as the hub is located far from border. For seeing the frequency of distance of hubs from the closest higherprice border, we calculate the weighted average of the distance of hubs from the border for the period between 2005 and 2014, and report them in Table 3.15 Table 3: Frequency of Hubs When Weighted Average of Distance from the Border is Equal or Less than d¯ d¯ (km) 1 50 100 200 400 Frequency of Hubs 5 45 76 112 156 Total number of hubs: 160 5.1.2. Estimation of Semi-Structural Approach Table 4 shows the estimates of Equation 11 as the main finding of this paper. Column 1 reports the estimates of the panel model with a limited number of fixed effects. There exist unobserved time-invariant hub specific factors that appear to be correlated with price ratios. Excluding these fixed effects would bias the coefficients of Column 1 toward zero. Therefore, Pf Pf the coefficients of the log of price ratio ln( Pith ) , the log of quadratic price ratio [ln( Pith )]2 , it it f Pit and the interaction of the log of price ratio and the log of distance ln( P h ) ∗ ln(dit ) are it 15 Refer to Appendix C to see the distribution of distance of hubs from the closest higher-price border. 21 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2954034 Figure 2: Average of Gasoline Consumption Over Time for Various Thresholds Dotted lines are the average of gasoline consumption for hubs with a distance less than the indicated threshold in each plot. The solid lines are the same averages for hubs in the other side of the threshold. All figures are normalized to their first observations. The vertical lines show major policy changes (significant price increases and rationing). Also, increases in the amount of nominal prices are in parentheses. 22 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2954034 not significant. However, after adding month and region fixed effects we obtain promisingly significant results in the third column of Table 4. In the fixed effects estimation, heterogeneous intercepts are allowed for each hub. These intercepts capture the specific characteristics of each region such as the tendency to break the law (and enter the smuggling business), time invariant climate factors, natural barriers for smuggling, the stringency of anti-smuggling activities, outside options for employment, etc. We see that in comparison to the OLS method, the fixed effect estimation generates significant results. As described in Section 4 we would expect that the signs of the coefficients Pf of the log of domestic price ln(Pith ) and the log of price ratio ln( Pith ) to be negative and the it f Pit 2 sign of the coefficient of the log of quadratic price ratio [ln( P h )] to be positive. However, it the sign of the coefficient of the interaction of the log of price ratio and the log of distance Pf ln( Pith ) ∗ ln(dit ) is not in line with our prior assumptions. it The positive coefficient for the interaction of the log of price ratio and the log of distance Pf ln( Pith ) ∗ ln(dit ) suggests that the smuggling elasticity rises as the distance to the border it increases, keeping all other variables fixed. This finding initially appears to be puzzling, because we expect higher elasticity in areas close to the border. Importantly, the positive coefficient suggests that when the price increases in the neighboring country, those areas that are far from the border are more sensitive to such price changes. In Appendix A, we have provided a demonstrative theoretical framework that highlight this matter. 5.1.3. The Specification of Distance We are also interested in investigating the effects of the distance level rather than its logarithm. For this purpose, Equation 13 is estimated by including cross-sectional fixed effects as well as time period fixed effects in the model. Results in the first column of Table 5 illustrate that in comparison to the distance logarithm specification, the significance of the coefficient of the distance level is reduced from the 1% level to the 10% level. It suggests that a non-linear relationship between the distance and smuggling activities is more intuitive. We specify three dummies for the distance from the border to include hubs that are at 23 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2954034 Variables Table 4: Demand Estimation with The Semi-Structural Approach Dependent Variable: Dit (Gasoline consumption in the regions of Iran) (1) (2) ln(Pith ) (3) 0.0568 (0.176) -0.142*** (0.0489) 0.0995 (0.312) -0.122*** (0.0464) -0.221*** (0.0793) 0.0210 (0.0882) 0.0191* (0.0115) 0.0424*** (0.0144) ln( Pith ) ∗ ln(dit ) 0.0128 (0.0556) 0.0217*** (0.00708) 0.0226*** (0.00698) ln[(GDP per Capita)it ] 0.228 (0.180) 0.101 (0.103) 0.201 (0.143) ln[(Cars per Capita)it ] 0.0128 (0.267) -0.0226 (0.0719) -0.0867 (0.0826) ln[(Motorcycles per Capita)it ] -0.148 (0.176) -0.0105 (0.0552) 0.00831 (0.0595) ln[(Unemployment Rate)it ] -0.117 (0.156) -0.0644*** (0.0116) -0.0368*** (0.0125)) 11.36*** (3.349) 16.33*** (1.483) 14.97*** (2.257) No No 0.0193 Yes No 0.9469 Yes Yes 0.9523 Pf ln( Pith ) it Pf [ln( Pith )]2 it Pf it Constant Region Fixed Effects Month Fixed Effects R-squared Number of observations in each column: 16,552. Standard errors are robust and clustered by region to allow for arbitrary serial correlation. *** , ** and *: indicate 1%, 5% and 10% significance levels, respectively. Standard errors are in parentheses. 24 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2954034 a maximum of 100km from the border, between 100km and 200km, and beyond 200km. Only the estimate associated with the first dummy is significant, suggesting that smuggling activities are sensitive to the distance at the border regions. Consistent with the earlier findings the sign is negative. One plausible explanation is that smugglers who are living close to the border have a lower price elasticity compared to the professional smugglers that benefit from pumping of hubs in areas far from the border. The cost of smuggling also increases as the distance from the border increases. Thus, the demand for smuggling in central areas is probably more sensitive to the price differentials. 5.2. Disaggregated Elasticity Estimations After reporting the aggregate estimates of elasticity (for all time periods and over all regional hubs), we focus on the elasticity over time and across different regions. We conduct a system estimation for individual hubs based on the specification in Equation 12. 16 5.2.1. Time-Varying Elasticity Figure 3 presents the weighted average over all regions of the time-varying price elasticity of smuggling demand for gasoline. Four critical incidents are worth noticing. A good match between the timeline of real world events and our estimated values provide strong anecdotal support to the validity of our estimations. The first incident (fuel rationing) takes place around July 2007 and is related to a pure quantity effect. We observe that prior to the enforcement of the fuel rationing policy (July 2007), the level of smuggling elasticity is substantial. However, right after the start of the rationing policy (by obliging the consumers to use their electronic fuel card) a significant drop (almost to zero) is observed. 16 Some of the model-predicted smuggling elasticity values are negative (particularly in hubs that are close to the border.) These few negative values should be interpreted with some caution. As the theoretical model of Appendix B highlights, in the presence of fixed legal and transportation costs the smuggling only takes place when the price differential is larger than a certain threshold. The estimated intercept for the main equation is negative; thus, the predicted values of model are only valid when the price differential is sufficiently larger. 25 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2954034 Table 5: Demand Estimation with The Semi-Structural Approach, Alternative Distance Estimation Dependent Variable: Dit (Gasoline consumption in the regions of Iran) Variables (1) (2) Pf ln( Pith ) it Pf [ln( Pith )]2 it Pf ln( Pith ) ∗ (dit ) -0.156** (0.0685) -0.0899 (0.0696) 0.0459*** (0.0152) 0.0493*** (0.0161) 0.000208* (0.000116) it Pf ln( Pith )*Dummy(dit , (1, 100)) -0.0916*** (0.0315) it Pf ln( Pith )*Dummy(dit , (100, 200)) 0.00314 (0.0289) it Pf ln( Pith )*Dummy(dit , (200, 560)) -0.0303 (0.0224) it ln[(GDP per Capita)it ] 0.207 (0.144) 0.219 (0.144) ln[(Cars per Capita)it ] -0.0828 (0.0825) -0.0864 (0.0833) ln[(Motorcycles per Capita)it ] 0.0126 (0.0598) 0.00852 (0.0601) -0.0377*** (0.0125) -0.0360*** (0.0131) 14.89*** (2.282) 14.77*** (2.280) Yes Yes 0.9522 Yes Yes 0.9524 ln[(Unemployment Rate)it ] Constant Region Fixed Effects Month Fixed Effects R-Squared Number of observations in each column: 16,552. Standard errors are robust and clustered by region to allow for arbitrary serial correlation. *** , ** and *: indicate 1%, 5% and 10% significance levels, respectively. Standard errors are in parentheses. 26 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2954034 Figure 3: Weighted Average of monthly Elasticity of Gasoline Smuggling Demand in Iran The solid line is the estimate of the smuggling elasticity and the dotted line is one standard error of the elasticity computed by bootstrap (50 replications). The vertical lines show major policy changes (significant price increases and rationing). Also, increases in the amount of the nominal price are in parentheses. Finally, the dashed line is corresponding to the secondary vertical axis and is the gasoline price in Iran. The second interesting event window happens around mid-2008, when due to the drop in the global crude oil prices, gasoline prices in the neighboring countries also declined (while the domestic prices were kept constant). Third, the domestic gasoline prices experienced a more than two-fold increase in December 2010. We see that the elasticity of gasoline smuggling has reached its lowest bound in the past ten years, and that the average of monthly gasoline smuggling elasticity in the country is almost zero in the late 2011. Finally, starting in mid-2012, a significant deprecation of the Iranian currency reduced the dollar value of domestic gasoline prices and created a new wave of gasoline smuggling. Smuggling activities became profitable again and a slow upward trend in elasticity is observed which lasts until May 2014. Two observations are worth noting. First, in order to estimate smuggling, the fact that the major variation over time comes mainly from price differentials between Iran and neighboring countries actually works to our advantage. In the absence of smuggling, we would not expect the fuel prices in a neighboring country to affect the sales of gasoline in Iran; whereas, we observe a significant sensitivity of our estimated parameter to the prices in 27 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2954034 neighboring countries. Second, the time-varying elasticity estimates in Figure 3 are entirely estimated off of cross-sectional variation in the pairing of hubs to the neighboring countries. Thus, the correct matching of the smuggling source and the destination country is crucial for obtaining correct results. If the pairing is not reflective of actual smuggling patterns, this will introduce measurement error in the foreign price (Pitf ), which would attenuate the estimated smuggling elasticity. 5.2.2. Location-Specific Elasticity We also report estimates of smuggling elasticity at the provincial level. One expects that the elasticity must be higher in locations closer to major illegal export distinctions (e.g. Turkey in the case of our study). The weighted average of price elasticity of the demand for gasoline smuggling in each province (for the period 2005 and 2014) is shown in Figure 4. Gasoline smuggling intensity is distributed heterogeneously with respect to the distance from the border and the price differential with the closest higher-price neighbor country. The highest elasticity is estimated for West Azerbaijan (WA) with an approximate elasticity of 0.048. This province is the source for a large-scale smuggling to Turkey and Iraq. Razavi Khorasan (RK) and North Khorasan (NK) provinces with the elasticity of 0.037 and 0.033 come next. It might be interesting to know that the highest monthly elasticity of gasoline smuggling demand in Iran (0.14) belongs to Xoy, a small city located in West Azerbaijan that is 45 kilometers away from Turkey’s border. Note that in the model, the elasticity of smuggling is determined by the sum of two effects: 1) the “distance to the border” (- up to a point), 2) the “relative price at the closest higher-price border” (always +). What happens is that fuel prices are much higher in Turkey than in other countries; thus, the relative price effect dominates the (decreasing) distance effect and makes the elasticity for provinces close to Turkey very high. A meticulous question that arises after seeing Figure 4 is why are not enforcement efforts reallocated from low-smuggling hubs to high-smuggling hubs? First of all, we are not sure if the authorities can easily identify those hubs (our study might help them in this regard). 28 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2954034 Second, the hubs far from the border are typically located in urban areas (and connected to many individual gas stations). In practice it is almost impossible to identify a “smuggler” from a legit commercial or individual buyer of the fuel. Figure 4: Weighted Average Gasoline Smuggling Elasticity By Province Legend shows the intervals and number of provinces in each. Numbers in neighboring countries are average gasoline price per liter in terms of US dollar. Results are from 2005-2014. WA, KR and NK stand for West Azerbaijan, Razavi Khorasan and North Khorasan, respectively. 6. Discussion and Robustness Checks In this section we offer multiple robustness checks by changing critical specifications of the model. 17 17 As a robustness test, we included the quadratic price ratio term interacted with the log of distance in the semi-structural approach, but the results did not change in a significant way. 29 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2954034 6.1. Effect of Octane To properly interpret the price differentials between Iran and its neighboring countries, one should consider the octane level of gasoline produced and sold in these markets. Table 6 reports the usual gasoline octane level in the countries presented in our study. We see that except for Turkey, all other countries have an equal or a lower octane number compared to Iran. Though not always but typically a higher octane may imply a better type of gasoline, if it were true, the smuggled gasoline from Iran could be considered as a premium good in those destinations. Additionally, the Iranian gasoline should be sold at a discount in the Turkish market. Thus, the estimate for the elasticity in the Turkish market might be biased downward. Table 6: Gasoline’s Octane Rating in Iran and Its Neighboring Countries Country Iran Turkey Pakistan Azerbaijan Iraq Persian Gulf Octane Rating 92 95 90 92 87 91 6.2. Unemployment Rate The first robustness check considers the role of the unemployment rate. The negative sign of the estimated unemployment rate coefficient indicates that the gasoline demand is reduced by an increase in the unemployment rate. This influence might be different for regions closer to the border. Raising the unemployment rate in border areas leads to a reduction in income, so it may increase the incentive for the local population to smuggle gasoline. Therefore, unlike the inner provinces, a higher rate of unemployment in border provinces may indeed increase the recorded sales of gasoline in that region. To test for this alternative hypothesis, we conduct an analysis which is demonstrated in the first column of Table 7 . We define a dummy variable to represent provinces closer to the border and add an interaction term with the unemployment rate to the regression equation. If a higher local unemployment indeed encourages smuggling, we expect to see a positive sign for the coefficient of the interaction term. However, the negative sign of the estimated 30 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2954034 term suggests that gasoline demand diminishes with the increase of the unemployment rate even in regions near the border. Therefore, we conclude that either the local demand effect dominates that of the other variables, or that the province-level unemployment is not a significant determinant of the incentive for smuggling. 6.3. Reverse Smuggling Among Iran’s neighboring countries, Turkmenistan has always had a lower gasoline price throughout the time span of this study. Thus, a (reverse) smuggling route from Turkmenistan to Iran is conceivable. To gauge the effect of this possibly contaminating channel, we re-estimate the model after dropping certain cities. These cities include cities closed to Turkmenistan and cities that are closer to Afghanistan, but are also close enough to Turkmenistan as well. The results reported in the second column of Table 7 illustrate that the significance level and the coefficients size of the previous estimations are not different. 6.4. Domestic Price: Rationed or Non-Rationed? Following what we have stated in the data section, we assume that the demand for domestic consumption and smuggling are fulfilled through both rationed and non-rationed gasoline18 . Hence, as an additional robustness check, the average price for rationed and non-rationed gasoline is used. Moreover, the rationed (i.e. heavily subsidized) gasoline price is used for domestic demand and the non-rationed gasoline price (less subsidized) is applied for foreign demand estimation. The third column of Table 7 illustrates that the coefficients have not changed compared to previous estimations. Moreover, the coefficients still are significance at the same level, and only the significance of the coefficient for the log Pf of price ratio ln( Pith ) is reduced from the 1% level to 5% level in comparison to the previous it estimation. 18 Except for a short period of time in 2007, the rationing did not put any quantity restrictions on the consumer. It was possible to purchase any quantity of gasoline beyond the subsidized ration by paying a higher official price. This policy of dual prices lived for a few years and then was abandoned in 2015 toward a unified subsidy-free policy. 31 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2954034 6.5. Measurement Errors in Covariates Because we control for both region fixed effects and time fixed effects, aggregate variables like GDP per capita and unemployment rate are demeaned. Thus, their deviations help to identify their coefficients. It is likely that if these deviations are just measurement errors then including them in our estimation cuts the significance of other variables.19 In order to investigate this concern, we estimate the model by ignoring these two control variables. It is observed in the fourth column of Table 7 that in comparison to the previous estimation results, all the three important coefficients for the price elasticity of smuggling demand for gasoline have preserved their coefficient signs and significance levels. 6.6. Non-linearity in Distance Another concern is that the socio-economic conditions may be non-linear by distance so the way we model them in Equation 11 undermines these effects. In particular, the nonlinearity in the socio-economic conditions of hubs that are located very close to the border compared with hubs in border regions may derive our results. Hence, as the last robustness check, we omit the areas with a distance greater than d¯ and estimate the model with the ¯ 50km, 100km, 200km, remaining data. In Table 8, we consider the following amounts for d: 300km, and 400km. Results in Table 8 indicate that the coefficient of interaction of the Pf log of price ratio and the log of distance ln( Pith ) ∗ ln(dit ) is not significant for the areas it with a distance of less than 100km. In the areas with greater distances, however, all three important coefficients in the elactisity for smuggling are significant at the 1% level, and with the expected signs. 7. Conclusion This paper investigates the price elasticity of the demand for gasoline smuggling in Iran. Toward this goal, a panel of monthly gasoline consumption data has been used that contains 19 Fisher and Schlenker (2012) highlight the same issue in the context of climate change 32 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2954034 Variables Table 7: Semi-Structural Approach Estimation - Robustness Check Dependent Variable: Dit (Gasoline consumption in the regions of Iran) (1) (2) (3) Pf ln( Pith ) (4) -0.212*** (0.0791) -0.261*** (0.101) -0.156** (0.0699) -0.207*** (0.0781) 0.0414*** (0.0144) 0.0517*** (0.0154) 0.0347*** (0.0109) 0.0390*** (0.0148) 0.0213*** (0.00712) 0.0250*** (0.00728) 0.0155*** (0.00568) 0.0233*** (0.00706) ln[(GDP per Capita)it ] 0.177 (0.142) 0.222 (0.157) 0.205 (0.143) ln[(Cars per Capita)it ] -0.0919 (0.0824) -0.108 (0.0924) -0.0836 (0.0829) -0.0567 (0.0809) ln[(Motorcycles per Capita)it ] 0.00149 (0.0590) 0.00334 (0.0625) 0.00875 (0.0600) 0.00879 (0.0607) ln[(Unemployment Rate)it ] -0.0273** (0.0132) -0.0385*** (0.0124) -0.0386*** (0.0126) 15.31*** (2.262) 14.75*** (2.452) 15.25*** (2.556) 17.75*** (1.288) Yes Yes 16,552 0.9524 Yes Yes 14,305 0.9485 Yes Yes 16,552 0.9523 Yes Yes 16,552 0.9520 it Pf [ln( Pith )]2 it Pf ln( Pith ) ∗ ln(dit ) it ln[(Unemployment Rate)it ] *Dummy(dit , 1) Constant Region Fixed Effects Month Fixed Effects Observations R-squared -0.294*** (0.0685) Standard errors are robust and clustered by region to allow for arbitrary serial correlation. *** , ** and *: indicate 1%, 5% and 10% significance levels, respectively. Standard errors are in parentheses. 33 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2954034 Variables Table 8: Semi-Structural Approach Estimation - Distance Robustness Check Dependent Variable: Dit (Gasoline consumption in the regions of Iran) (1) (2) (3) (4) dit 6 50 dit 6 100 dit 6 200 dit 6 300 Pf ln( Pith ) (5) dit 6 400 -0.238** (0.101) -0.295*** (0.106) -0.314*** (0.106) -0.234*** (0.0884) -0.225*** (0.0799) 0.0798*** (0.0246) 0.0838*** (0.0273) 0.0591*** (0.0190) 0.0438*** (0.0157) 0.0455*** (0.0141) 0.000439 (0.0185) 0.0123 (0.0157) 0.0281*** (0.0103) 0.0245*** (0.00730) 0.0220*** (0.00685) ln[(GDP per Capita)it ] 0.163 (0.131) 0.262 (0.195) 0.241 (0.174) 0.220 (0.156) 0.206 (0.147) ln[(Cars per Capita)it ] -0.150** (0.0718) -0.0932 (0.131) -0.143 (0.117) -0.0920 (0.0923) -0.0891 (0.0834) ln[(Motorcycles per Capita)it ] 0.257*** (0.0984) 0.0401 (0.0873) 0.0296 (0.0695) 0.00247 (0.0620) 0.00701 (0.0597) -0.0619*** (0.0164) -0.0508*** (0.0165) -0.0308* (0.0164) -0.0295** (0.0129) -0.0348*** (0.0131) 11.02*** (1.518) 10.77*** (3.367) 13.08*** (2.810) 14.68*** (2.461) 14.84*** (2.320) Yes Yes 4,346 0.9640 Yes Yes 7,325 0.9343 Yes Yes 10,899 0.9431 Yes Yes 14,694 0.9489 Yes Yes 16,112 0.9516 it Pf [ln( Pith )]2 it Pf ln( Pith ) ∗ ln(dit ) it ln[(Unemployment Rate)it ] Constant Region Fixed Effects Month Fixed Effects Observations R-squared Standard errors are robust and clustered by region to allow for arbitrary serial correlation. *** , ** and *: indicate 1%, 5% and 10% significance levels, respectively. Standard errors are in parentheses. 34 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2954034 observations for 160 distribution hubs of the National Iranian Oil Products Distribution Company (NIOPDC) between 2005 and 2014. The aggregate estimation results of the elasticity of monthly gasoline smuggling demand shows the significant effect of gasoline price ratios between Iran and its neighboring countries. On the other side, as the distance of a region from its closest higher-price neighboring country diminishes, the price elasticity of demand for gasoline smuggling for that region declines as well. Our paper takes the first step to provide reliable quantitative evidence to support the effect of domestic price adjustments on the tendency to smuggle fuel. Our results suggest that adjusting domestic fuel prices to bring them closer to the international equilibrium can generate considerable fiscal savings. The key point of our study is that smuggling acts as a “variable” component of government budget. The higher the level of domestic prices, the lower is the demand for smuggling (thus, the lost subsidy to neighboring countries) as well as the domestic demand for gasoline. Both channels reduce the subsidy burden. The removal of subsidy basically replaces a variable level of subsidies with a time-invariant (in nominal terms) cash transfer. This paper can be extended in multiple directions. First, the unique method presented in the current paper can also be used to estimate the elasticity of domestic demand for gasoline. Second, our results do not include the public finance aspects of the problem. Future work can provide estimates of government subsidies and the fiscal saving and welfare implications of the price adjustment. Our results can also be combined with more granular socio-economic variables at the household level to examine the distributional effects of timevarying smuggling activities on households involved with those activities. Our model estimates the “changes in smuggling as a response to “changes in the relative price. However, it is not possible to estimate the baseline magnitude of smuggling using this model (because one can only observe the differential response). We added some unofficial figures to the introduction of the paper but there is no reliable estimate of the total volume of the smuggled gasoline. An important follow-up research can focus on estimating the 35 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2954034 magnitude of the smuggled fuels. Acknowledgment We are grateful for comments received following the presentation of an earlier draft of this paper at Sharif University of Technology and the members of NYC’s Dark Coffee Economics Discussion Group. We also would like to thank Djavad Salehi-Isfahani, Mohammad Vesal, Sorena Rahi and two anonymous reviewers for their very helpful comments on an earlier draft. The authors are, of course, responsible for all errors and omissions. 36 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2954034 Appendix A Relationship Between the Elasticity and the Distance We present a stylized theoretical model of smuggling in order to derive the relationship between the elasticity of the demand for smuggling and the distance from Hi to the border of Fit . Consider an economy with representative smugglers in each region. We solve the utility maximization problems of the representative smugglers to derive the equilibrium outcome of the smuggling intensity for a given level of price differentials (between home and foreign countries), probability of apprehension, level of penalty, and finally the distance from the border. The utility function of a smuggler in region i and at time t who smuggles qit amount of gasoline from Hi to Fit can be written as follows: Uit (qit ) = (1 − λit ) (Pitf − Pith )qit − Φ(qit , dit ) − Zλit qit (16) where, λit is the probability of the apprehension and penalizing of the smuggler by the police, Φ(qit , dit ) is the cost of transporting q units of gasoline from Hi to Fit , and Z is a fixed cost that the smuggler is obliged to pay per unit of gasoline when he is penalized. It should be noted that in each region i at time t, the prices, the distance and the probability may be have different values, and hence, the utility of the smuggler can vary over time and space. We define ∆Pit = Pitf − Pith and then write the F.O.C in the form of (1 − λit )∆Pit = (1 − λit )Φ1 (qit , dit ) + λit Z. We use the implicit function theorem to obtain the elasticity: it = ∆Pit ∂(qit ) ∆Pit −1 ∂ ln(qit ) = = ∂ ln(∆Pit ) qit ∂∆Pit qit Φ11 (qit , dit ) (17) In order to derive the relationship between the elasticity of the demand for smuggling 37 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2954034 and distance, we use the following derivative to obtain the relationship: ∂it ∂it ∂qit = = ∂dit ∂qit ∂dit ∆Pit ∆P Φ111 (qit , dit ) + 2 2 qit Φ11 (qit , dit ) Φ11 (qit , dit ) ! −Φ12 (qit , dit ) Φ11 (qit , dit ) ! If one assumes that Φ11 (qit , dit ) > 0, then if Φ12 (qit , dit ) < 0, we conclude that (18) ∂it ∂dit > 0, which is what we obtained from our estimates. This model corresponds to the notion that those who are far from the border, are more sensitive to price changes. Appendix B Estimation of the Demand for Premium Gasoline The premium gasoline is the higher quality version of the fuel with a higher octane. It is sold with a significant price premium (between 10% - 30% higher) in the Iranian market. To gain insights from a possible alternative estimation result, we repeat the semi-structural estimation procedure by replacing the regular gasoline price and quantity data with those of the premium gasoline. A summary of key results in this regard are reported in Table 9. The results suggest that none of the coefficients associated with the determinants of smuggling are significant when the estimation is done using the premium gasoline. There are multiple plausible explanations for this negative (i.e. insignificant) result. First, the premium gasoline is more expensive than the regular gasoline; however, the quality of the gasoline in the destination is not verifiable and it will be sold at the same price as the conventional one. Therefore, the price differentials between Iran and neighboring countries will be smaller for the premium gasoline, resulting in a lower incentive to smuggle this type of gasoline when the conventional type is available. Also, note that in the case of apprehension, the smuggler will lose a larger value of the confiscated good. Secondly, premium gasoline is mainly offered in larger cities far from the border. Therefore, it is more difficult to obtain a larger volume of the premium type in hubs near the border. Finally, the total market share of the premium gasoline is very small (only 3.5% of the total gasoline market). We also have noted data recording problems, missing observations, outliers, and finally small sample size problems in the premium gasoline data. As a result, the results of this estimation are likely 38 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2954034 Table 9: Demand Estimation with The Semi-Structural Approach Dependent Variable: Dit (Premium gasoline consumption in the regions of Iran) Variables (1) (2) Pf ln( Pith ) (3) 0.630* (0.377) -0.0699 (0.106) -0.137 (0.144) -0.117 (0.0917) -0.0432 (0.0396) 0.0533 (0.0425) ln( Pith ) ∗ ln(dit ) -0.0644 (0.0721) 0.0146 (0.0179) 0.0133 (0.0180) ln[(GDP per Capita)it ] 0.770** (0.300) 0.182 (0.254) 0.0741 (0.309) ln[(Cars per Capita)it ] 0.00723 (0.348) 0.947*** (0.127) 0.0908 (0.144) ln[(Motorcycles per Capita)it ] -0.0880 (0.235) -0.0795 (0.105) 0.0840 (0.0918) ln[(Unemployment Rate)it ] -0.0488 (0.213) -0.117** (0.0456) -0.104*** (0.0349) Constant 2.744 (5.204) 12.47*** (3.437) -6.323 (4.303) No No 0.066 Yes No 0.8050 Yes Yes 0.8802 it Pf [ln( Pith )]2 it Pf it Region Fixed Effects Month Fixed Effects R-squared Number of observations in each column: 9,461. Standard errors are robust and clustered by region to allow for arbitrary serial correlation. *** , ** and *: indicate 1%, 5% and 10% significance levels, respectively. Standard errors are in parentheses. 39 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2954034 to be subject to small sample and measurement errors. Appendix C Distribution of the Distance We plot the histogram for the weighted average of the distance of hubs from the border for the period between 2005 and 2014 in Figure 5. Figure 5: Histogram Plot of Weighted Average of Distance of Hubs from Border The numerical values above the bars show the frequency of hubs in each bin. 40 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2954034 References Asplund, M., Friberg, R., and Wilander, F. (2007). Demand and distance: Evidence on cross-border shopping. Journal of public Economics, 91(1):141–157. Banfi, S., Filippini, M., and Hunt, L. C. (2005). Fuel tourism in border regions: The case of switzerland. Energy Economics, 27(5):689–707. Beard, T. R., Gant, P. A., and Saba, R. P. (1997). Border-crossing sales, tax avoidance, and state tax policies: an application to alcohol. Southern Economic Journal, pages 293–306. Bridel, A. and Lontoh, subsidy reform. L. (2014). Lessons learned: Malaysias 2013 fuel https://www.iisd.org/GSI/sites/default/files/ffs_malaysia_ lessonslearned.pdf. Chiou, L., Muehlegger, E., et al. (2008). Crossing the line: The effect of cross border cigarette sales on state excise tax revenues. John F. Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University. Coady, D., Gillingham, R., Ossowski, R., Piotrowski, J., Tareq, S., and Tyson, J. (2010). Petroleum product subsidies: costly, inequitable, and rising. Coats, R. M. (1995). A note on estimating cross-border effects of state cigarette taxes. National Tax Journal, pages 573–584. Crawford, I., Smith, Z., and Tanner, S. (1999). Alcohol taxes, tax revenues and the single european market. Fiscal Studies, 20(3):287–304. Crawford, I. and Tanner, S. (1995). Bringing it all back home: Alcohol taxation and crossborder shopping. Fiscal Studies, 16(2):94–114. Dartanto, T. (2013). Reducing fuel subsidies and the implication on fiscal balance and poverty in indonesia: A simulation analysis. Energy Policy, 58:117–134. 41 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2954034 Davis, L. W. (2014). The economic cost of global fuel subsidies. The American Economic Review, 104(5):581–585. Fisher, A.C., H. W. R. M. and Schlenker, W. (2012). The economic impacts of climate change: evidence from agricultural output and random fluctuations in weather: comment. American Economic Review, pages 3749–3760. Fisher, R. (2007). State and local public finance (3rd ed.). Mason: Thompson South-Western. Fleenor, P. (1998). How excise tax differentials affect interstate smuggling and cross-border sales of cigarettes in the United States. Tax Foundation. Fleenor, P. (1999). How excise tax differentials affect cross-border sales of beer in the United States. Tax Foundation. Fox, W. F. (1986). Tax structure and the location of economic activity along state borders. National Tax Journal, pages 387–401. Guillaume, M. D. M., Zytek, M. R., and Farzin, M. M. R. (2011). Iran: The chronicles of the subsidy reform. Number 11-167. International Monetary Fund. Hamovitch, W. (1966). Effects of increases in sales tax rates on taxable sales in new york city. Financing Government in New York City, pages 619–634. Haufler, A. (1996). Tax coordination with different preferences for public goods: Conflict or harmony of interest? International Tax and Public Finance, 3(1):5–28. Kanbur, R. and Keen, M. (1993). Jeux sans frontieres: Tax competition and tax coordination when countries differ in size. American Economic Review, 83(4):877–92. Leal, A., Lopez-Laborda, J., and Rodrigo, F. (2010). Cross-border shopping: a survey. International Advances in Economic Research, 16(2):135–148. 42 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2954034 Loveless, B. (2015). World bank economists seek oil subsidies’ end. http://www.usatoday. com/story/money/business/2015/04/15/loveless-imf-world-bank-oilprices/ 25844293/. Lovenheim, M. F. (2008). How far to the border?: The extent and impact of cross-border casual cigarette smuggling. National Tax Journal, pages 7–33. Maliet, L. D. (1955). A comparative study of the Illinois retailers’ occupation tax and the Iowa retail sales and use taxes. PhD thesis, University of Illinois at Urbana-Champaign. McAllister, H. E. (1961). The border tax problem in washington. National Tax Journal, 14(4):362–374. Merriman, D. (2010). The micro-geography of tax avoidance: evidence from littered cigarette packs in chicago. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy, 2(2):61–84. Mikesell, J. L. (1970). Central cities and sales tax rate differentials: The border city problem. National Tax Journal, 23(2):206–213. Mikesell, J. L. (1971). Sales taxation and border county problem. Quarterly Review of Economics and Business, 11(1):23–29. Nielsen, S. B. (2001). A simple model of commodity taxation and cross-border shopping. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics, 103(4):599–623. Nielsen, S. B. (2002). Cross-border shopping from small to large countries. Economics Letters, 77(3):309–313. Ohsawa, Y. (1999). Cross-border shopping and commodity tax competition among governments. Regional Science and Urban Economics, 29(1):33–51. Rahmati, Mohammad H, A. H. T. and Vesal, M. (2017). What five hundred million transactions tell us about demand elasticity of gasoline? Sharif University of Technology. 43 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2954034 Saba, R. R., Beard, T. R., Ekelund, R. B., and Ressler, R. W. (1995). The demand for cigarette smuggling. Economic Inquiry, 33(2):189–202. Scharf, K. A. (1999). Scale economies in cross-border shopping and commodity taxation. International Tax and Public Finance, 6(1):89–99. Sindo, K. (2014). Sejarah harga bbm subsidi di indonesia. http://economy.okezone.com/ read/2014/08/28/19/1030923/sejarah-harga-bbm-subsidi-di-indonesia. Smith, R. T. (1976). The legal and illegal markets for taxed goods: pure theory and an application to state government taxation of distilled spirits. The Journal of Law and Economics, 19(2):393–429. Trandel, G. A. (1994). Interstate commodity tax differentials and the distribution of residents. Journal of Public Economics, 53(3):435–457. Victor, D. (2009). The politics of fossil-fuel subsidies: global subsidies initiative & the international institute for sustainable development. geneva: Global subsidies initiative. International Institute for Sustainable Development. Walsh, M. J. and Jones, J. D. (1988). More evidence on the ”border tax” effect: The case of west virginia, 1979-84. National Tax Journal, 41(2):261–265. Wang, Y.-Q. (1999). Commodity taxes under fiscal competition: Stackelberg equilibrium and optimality. The American Economic Review, 89(4):974–981. Warner, K. E. (1982). Cigarette excise taxation and interstate smuggling: an assessment of recent activity. National Tax Journal, 35(4):483–490. Wertz, K. L. (1971). Cigarette taxation by the american states. National Tax Journal, pages 487–492. 44 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2954034 WorldBank (2012). Bantuan Langsung Tunai (BLT) temporary unconditional cash transfer. Social assistance program and public expenditure. Public expenditure review (PER), page review no. 2. 45 Electronic copy available at: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2954034