Microeconomics: Theory and Applications with Calculus Fifth Edition Chapter 19 Contracts and Moral Hazards The contracts of at least 33 major league baseball players have incentive clauses providing a bonus if that player is named Most Valuable Player in a Division Series. Unfortunately, no such award is given for a Division Series. Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Chapter 19 Outline Challenge: Health Insurance 19.1 Principal-Agent Problem 19.2 Production Efficiency 19.3 Trade-Off Between Efficiency in Production and in Risk Bearing 19.4 Monitoring to Reduce Moral Hazard 19.5 Contract Choice 19.6 Checks on Principals Challenge Solution Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Challenge: Clawing Back Bonuses • Background: – A major cause of the 2007–2009 worldwide financial crisis was that managers and other employees of banks, insurance companies, and other firms took excessive risk. – Bank managers three accepted lending practices out the window, rewarding mortgage brokers for bringing in large numbers of new mortgages regardless of risk. Brokers and their managers in response issued these risky mortgages. – One response called for in the 2010 Dodd-Frank Consumer Protection Act was that firms institute clawback provisions that would all firms to claw back or reclaim some earlier bonus payments to managers if their past actions resulted in later losses. • Questions: – Solved Problem 19.1: Why did executives a these banks take extra risks that resulted in major lost shareholder value? – Challenge Solution: Does evaluating a manger’s performance over a longer period using delayed compensation or clawback provisions lead to better management? Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved 19.1 Principal-Agent Problem • In a principal-agent relationship a principal, such as an employer, contracts with an agent, such as an employee, to take some action that benefits the principal. • Moral hazard in a principal-agent relationship is referred to as a principal-agent problem or agency problem. – Example: You pay someone by the hour to prepare your tax return, but don’t know whether he/she worked all the hours that were billed. Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved 19.1 Types of Contracts • Three common types of contracts: 1. Fixed-fee contracts ▪ Payment to the agent is independent of the agent’s actions, the state of nature, or the outcome. ▪ Principal keeps the residual profit 2. Hire contracts ▪ Payment to the agent depends on the agent’s actions as they are observed by principal. ▪ Types include hourly rate and piece rate. 3. Contingent contracts ▪ Payments to principal and agent depend on state of nature, which may be unknown when contract is written. ▪ In a sharing contract, payoffs to each person are a fraction of total profit. Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved 19.1 Efficiency • Type of contract used depends on what the parties observe. – Hire contract used if principal can easily monitor agent’s actions. – Contingent contract used if state of nature observed after work is completed. – Fixed-fee contract has no observation requirements. • An efficient contract has provisions that ensure no party can be made better off without harming the other party. – Results in efficiency in production, where combined payoffs are maximized. – Results in efficiency in risk bearing, where person who least minds risk bears more of the risk. Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Solved Problem 19.1: S&L Loans • Setup: An S&L can make one of two types of loans – Mortgages: 0.75 probability of earning $100million and 0.25 probability of earning $80m – Oil Speculators: 0.25 probability of earning $400million and 0.75 probability of losing $160 million – S&L manager receives 1% of S&L earnings, but protected from losses • Questions – Which decision would Bernie make? – Which decision is best for S&L shareholders? • Answers 利益冲突 – Bernie’s expected earnings: ▪ Mortgages 0.75 1,000,000 0.25 800,000 $950,000 ▪ Oil speculators 0.25 4,000,000 0.75 0 $1,000,000 – Shareholders’ expected earnings: ▪ Mortgages 0.75 100,000,000 0.25 80,000,000 950,000 94.05million ▪ Oil speculators 0.25 400,000,000 0.75 160,000,000 1,000,000 21 million Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved 19.1 Application: Honest Cabbie? • You arrive in a strange city and get in a cab. Will the driver take you to your destination by the shortest route, or will you get ripped off? • Experiment (Balafoutas et al., 2013) – Two groups of native-speaking Greeks in Athens ▪ Moral Hazard: “I would like to get to Fill in the blank. Do you know where it is? I am not from Athens.” ▪ Control: “Can I get a receipt at the end of the ride?” or “Can I get a receipt at the end of the ride? I need it in order to have my expenses reimbursed by my employer.” • Results: – Moral Hazard group: Overcharging in 36.5% of cases – Control group: Overcharging in 19.5% of cases – Fares averaged 17% higher in moral hazard group Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved 19.2 Production Efficiency • The type of contract that an agent and principal use affects production efficiency. • To be efficient and maximize the joint profit of the agent and principal, a contract needs two properties: 1. Contract must provide large enough payoff that agent is willing to participate in the contract. 2. Contract must be incentive compatible in that it makes the agent want to perform assigned tasks rather than engage in opportunistic behavior. Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved 19.2 Production Efficiency Example (1 of 2) • Buy-A-Duck store sells wooden duck carvings – Paula is the principal (owner) and Arthur is the agent (manager) – Joint profit is a function of the number of ducks sold (a), which is determined by Arthur’s actions and the marginal cost of producing one more carving, m: (a ) R(a ) ma • How many ducks must Arthur sell to maximize join profit? d(a ) dR(a ) m 0 da da • We can analyze this graphically with a few assumptions. – FOC: Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved 19.2 Production Efficiency Example (2 of 2) • Assuming m = 12 and inverse demand is p 24 12 a, Arthur maximizes his profit and joint profit at a = 12. Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved 19.2 Full Information: Fixed-Fee Rental Contract • Assume both Paula and Arthur have full information about Arthur’s actions and the effect on profit. • In this situation, are there incentive-compatible fixed-fee contracts that do not require monitoring and supervision? – Arthur earns a residual profit; profit less fixed rent he pays Paula. – FOC is unchanged, so profit is still maximized when Arthur sells 12 ducks. – This occurs because Arthur gets entire marginal profit from selling one more duck. Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved 19.2 Full Information: Hire Contract • Now suppose Paula contracts to pay Arthur for each duck he sells (a hire contract). – If she pays him $12 per duck, Arthur just breaks even on each sale because m = 12. – Even if he agrees to this contract, he requires supervision because he gets no marginal profit from selling one more duck. • Paula must offer Arthur more than m per duck for him to have incentive to sell as many as he can. – Such a contract is not incentive compatible. – Joint profit maximization requires MR = MC, and Paula’s offer >m means she directs Arthur to sell fewer ducks than is optimal. Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved 19.2 Full Information: Revenue-Sharing Contract • Now suppose Paula and Arthur use a contingent contract to share the revenue. – Arthur receives ¾ R; Paula receives ¼ R. • Under this revenue-sharing contract, Arthur’s MR curve is below MR in a different type of contract. – For example, selling 12 ducks no longer brings in $12 in additional revenue; 12 ducks brings in ¾ $12 = $9 in MR. • Thus, joint profit is not maximized when the agent maximizes his own profit in this type of contract. Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved 19.2 Full Information: Revenue Sharing • Agent chooses a to maximize ¾ revenue less entire cost. • Agent chooses inefficient effort. Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved 19.2 Full Information: Profit-Sharing Contract • Now suppose Paula and Arthur use a contingent contract to share the profit. – Arthur receives one-third of the joint profit. • Under this profit-sharing contract, Arthur only earns onethird of the profit, but also only bears one-third of the MC. • Joint profit is maximized when the agent maximizes his own profit; profit-sharing is efficient. Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved 19.2 Full Information: Profit Sharing Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved 19.2 Asymmetric Information • Now assume that the principal, Paula, has less information than the agent, Arthur. – She can’t observe the number of ducks he sells or the revenue. • What occurs under the four different contract types? – Fixed-fee contract yields joint-profit-maximizing quantity. – Hire contract results in less-than-optimal quantity if Arthur is honest and greater-than-optimal quantity if he is not. – Revenue-sharing contract is still inefficient. – Profit-sharing contract is efficient if he reports revenue and cost to Paula honestly. Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved 19.2 Production Efficiency Summary (1 of 2) • With asymmetric information, only a fixed-fee contract is efficient and has no moral hazard problem. Fixed-fee rental contract Contract Full Information Production Efficiency Asymmetric Information Production Efficiency Asymmetric Information Moral Hazard Problem Yes Yes No Full Information Production Efficiency Asymmetric Information Production Efficiency Asymmetric Information Moral Hazard Problem Pay equals marginal cost Noa Nob Yes Pay is greater than marginal cost Noc No Yes Rent (to principal) Hire contract, per unit pay Contract Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved 19.2 Production Efficiency Summary (2 of 2) Contingent contract Contract Full Information Production Efficiency Asymmetric Information Production Efficiency Asymmetric Information Moral Hazard Problem Share revenue No Nob Yes Share profit Yes Nob Yes aThe agent may not participate and has no incentive to sell the optimal number of carvings. Efficiency can be achieved only if the principal supervises. bUnless cThe the agent steals all the revenue (or profit) from an extra sale, inefficiency results. agent sells too many or the principal directs the agent to sell too few carvings. Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved 19.3 Trade-Off Between Efficiency in Production and in Risk Bearing (1 of 2) • Usually, a contract does not achieve efficiency in production and in risk bearing. – There exist trade-offs between these two objectives. • Example: Contracting with a lawyer – Pam is the principal who has been injured in a traffic accident. – Alfredo is the agent and is her lawyer. – Pam faces uncertainty due to risk and asymmetric information. – Trial outcome depends on Alfredo’s hours of effort, a, and attitudes of the jury (state of nature, θ). – Pam never learns θ, so if she loses the case, she doesn’t know if it was because Alfredo didn’t work hard enough. Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved 19.3 Trade-Off Between Efficiency in Production and in Risk Bearing (2 of 2) • The choice of various possible contracts between Pam and Alfredo affects whether they achieve efficiency in production or in risk bearing. Type of Contract Fixed Fee to Lawyer Lawyer’s payoff Client’s payoff Production efficiency? (a, ) F No* Who bears risk? Client F Fixed Payment Lawyer Paid to Client by the Hour (a, ) F F Yes Lawyer wa (a, ) wa No* Client Contingent Contract (a, ) (1 )(a, ) No* Shared *Production efficiency is possible if the client can monitor and enforce optimal effort by the lawyer. Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved 19.3 Choosing the Best Contract • The best contract between Pam and Alfredo depends on, among other factors: – Attitudes toward risk – The degree of risk – The difficulty of monitoring Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved 19.4 Monitoring to Reduce Moral Hazard (1 of 5) • When a firm can’t use piece rates or rewards, they usually pay fixed-fee salaries or hourly wages. – These methods may encourage shirking and/or inflating work hours. – Firm can reduce shirking through increased monitoring. • Monitoring eliminates the asymmetric information problem because both the employer and the employee know how hard the employee works. Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved 19.4 Monitoring to Reduce Moral Hazard (2 of 5) • Types of monitoring: – Requiring punching a time clock – Installing surveillance cameras – Installing assembly lines (sets work pace) – Recording employees’ voicemail, email, phone calls – Reviewing employees’ computer files • Monitoring is most common in the financial sector, in which 81% of firms use the above techniques. • Monitoring may lower morale and, in turn, productivity. Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved 19.4 Monitoring to Reduce Moral Hazard (3 of 5) • A direct approach to ensuring good behavior by agents is to require they deposit funds guaranteeing good behavior. – A performance bond is an amount of money that will be given to the principal if the agent doesn’t complete assigned duties or achieve specific goals. • Suppose worker’s value on gain from shirking is $G and the worker must post a bond of $B, which is forfeited if he is caught shirking. – If θ is the probability of being caught shirking, a riskneutral worker won’t shirk if G ≤ θB (gain ≤ expected penalty). Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved 19.4 Monitoring to Reduce Moral Hazard (4 of 5) • The minimum bond that discourages shirking is G B – Bond must be larger the higher the value the employee places on shirking and the lower the probability of being caught. • Employers like bonds because it reduces monitoring necessary to discourage moral hazards. – More commonly used to deter theft than shirking. – Workers may not have enough money to post a bond. Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved 19.4 Monitoring to Reduce Moral Hazard (5 of 5) • Firms discourage shirking by raising an employee’s cost of losing a job. • An alternative is for the firm to pay an unusually high wage, called an efficiency wage. – If the going wage is w , an efficiency wage is w w , • The extra earnings, w w , serves the same function as the bond, B, in discouraging bad employee behavior. w w G Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved 19.5 Contract Choice (1 of 2) • A firm may choose to concentrate on hiring industrious workers rather than on stopping lazy workers from shirking. – Such a firm seeks to avoid moral hazard problems by preventing adverse selection. • Firms may be able to determine which prospective workers will work hard by giving them a contract choice. – Those who select contingent contracts, in which pay depends on how hard they work, signal they are hard workers. – Those who choose fixed-fee contracts signal they are lazy workers. Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved 19.5 Contract Choice (2 of 2) • Workers sort themselves when the firm offers two different contracts Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved 19.6 Checks on Principals (1 of 3) • Because employers (principals) often pay employees (agents) after work is completed, employers have many opportunities to exploit workers. • Source of employer’s opportunistic behavior: asymmetric information. • Solutions: – Firms provide workers with information about company profits – Firms may rely on a good reputation. – Use less efficient contracts, such as ones that base employee payments on easily observed revenues rather than less reliable profit reports. Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved 19.6 Checks on Principals (2 of 3) • During recessions, why are layoffs more common than wage reductions? • Workers cannot observe actual profits of their employers. • For wage cuts, firms have incentive to claim conditions are bad, even when they are good. Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved 19.6 Checks on Principals (3 of 3) • But with layoffs, firms have the incentive to honestly report conditions to workers. Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Challenge Solution • Question – Does evaluating a manger’s performance over a longer period using delayed compensation or clawback provisions lead to better management? • Concerns – In a multiyear problem in which manager shares profits but not losses – Managers may increase this year’s profit in a way that lowers profits in future years – Manager receives bonus for this year’s profit, but is not penalized for losses in future years – Manager engages in reckless behavior that increases this year’s profit but bankrupts the firm next year • Solution – Pay bonuses based on multi-year performance – Manager takes into account effect of current actions on future profits Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Copyright This work is protected by United States copyright laws and is provided solely for the use of instructors in teaching their courses and assessing student learning. Dissemination or sale of any part of this work (including on the World Wide Web) will destroy the integrity of the work and is not permitted. The work and materials from it should never be made available to students except by instructors using the accompanying text in their classes. All recipients of this work are expected to abide by these restrictions and to honor the intended pedagogical purposes and the needs of other instructors who rely on these materials. Copyright © 2020, 2017, 2014 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved