Essentials of Economics Fifth Edition Chapter 4 1 Market Efficiency and Market Failure Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Chapter Outline 4.1 Consumer Surplus and Producer Surplus 4.2 The Efficiency of Competitive Markets 4.3 Government Intervention in the Market: Price Floors and Price Ceilings 4.4 Externalities and Economic Efficiency 4.5 Government Policies to Deal with Externalities Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Should the Government Control Apartment Rents? Rent control puts a legal limit on the rent that landlords can charge for an apartment. Since rent controlled rents are usually far below market rents, it seems clear that this doesn’t make landlords better off. • Does it make tenants better off? • Would you prefer to look for an apartment in a city with or without rent control? Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved 4.1 Consumer Surplus and Producer Surplus Distinguish between the concepts of consumer surplus and producer surplus. Surplus (noun): Something that remains above what is used or needed Economists use the idea of “surplus” to refer to the benefit that people derive from engaging in market transactions. • Consumer surplus is the difference between the highest price a consumer is willing to pay for a good or service and the actual price the consumer pays. • Producer surplus is the difference between the lowest price a firm would be willing to accept for a good or service and the price it actually receives. Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Figure 4.1 Deriving the Demand Curve for Chai Tea (1 of 2) Imagine four people are interested in buying a cup of chai tea. We can characterize them by the highest price they are willing to pay. At prices above $6, no chai tea will be sold. At $6, one cup will be sold, etc. Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Figure 4.1 Deriving the Demand Curve for Chai Tea (2 of 2) How much benefit do the potential tea consumers derive from this market? That depends on the price and their marginal benefit: the additional benefit to a consumer from consuming one more unit of a good or service If the price is low, many of the consumers benefit. If the price is high, few (if any) of the consumers benefit. Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Figure 4.2 Measuring Consumer Surplus (1 of 3) At $3.50 per cup, Theresa, Tom, and Terri will buy a cup. Theresa was willing to pay $6.00; a cup of chai tea is “worth” $6.00 to her. She paid $3.50, so she derives a net benefit of $6.00 − $3.50 = $2.50. Area A represents this net benefit, and is known as Theresa’s consumer surplus in the chai tea market. • Notice that the area A is $2.50 × 1 = $2.50 Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Figure 4.2 Measuring Consumer Surplus (2 of 3) Tom and Terri also obtain consumer surplus, equal to $1.50 (area B) and $0.50 (area C). The sum of the areas of rectangles A, B, and C is called the consumer surplus in the chai tea market. • Consumer surplus: area below the demand curve, above the price that consumers pay. Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Figure 4.2 Measuring Consumer Surplus (3 of 3) If the price falls to $3.00, Theresa, Tom, and Terri each gain an additional $0.50 of consumer surplus. Tim is indifferent between buying the cup and not; his well-being is the same either way. • The overall consumer surplus remains the area below the demand curve, above the (new) price. Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Figure 4.3 Total Consumer Surplus in the Market for Chai Tea The market for chai tea is larger than just our four consumers. • With many consumers, the market demand curve looks like “normal”: a straight line. Consumer surplus in this market is defined in just the same way: the area below the demand curve, above price. The graph shows consumer surplus if price is $2.00. Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Making the Connection: Consumer Surplus from Broadband Internet (1 of 2) Having access to a broadband internet connection is beneficial for consumers. • We can measure just how beneficial it is by estimating the consumer surplus derived in the market. What would we need to know in order to do this? • The demand curve for broadband internet service • The price of broadband internet service Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Producer Surplus Producer surplus can be thought of in much the same way as consumer surplus. • It is the difference between the lowest price a firm would accept for a good or service and the price it actually receives. What is the lowest price a firm would accept for a good or service? • The marginal cost of producing that good or service. Marginal cost: the additional cost to a firm of producing one more unit of a good or service. Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Figure 4.4 Measuring Producer Surplus (1 of 2) Heavenly Tea is a (very small) producer of chai tea. When the market price of tea is $2.00, Heavenly Tea receives producer surplus of $0.75 on the first cup (the area of rectangle A), $0.50 on the second cup (rectangle B), and $0.25 on the third cup (rectangle C). Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Figure 4.4 Measuring Producer Surplus (2 of 2) The total amount of producer surplus tea sellers receive from selling chai tea can be calculated by adding up for the entire market the producer surplus received on each cup sold. Total producer surplus is equal to the area above the supply curve and below the market price of $2.00. Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved What Do Consumer Surplus and Producer Surplus Measure? Consumer surplus measures the net benefit to consumers from participating in a market rather than the total benefit. • Consumer surplus in a market is equal to the total benefit received by consumers (measured in dollars) minus the total amount they must pay to buy the good or service. Similarly, producer surplus measures the net benefit received by producers from participating in a market. • Producer surplus in a market is equal to the total amount firms receive from consumers minus the cost of producing the good or service. Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved 4.2 The Efficiency of Competitive Markets Explain the concept of economic efficiency. We can think about efficiency in a market in two ways: 1. A market is efficient when the marginal benefit is equal to the marginal cost. 2. A market is efficient if it maximizes the sum of consumer and producer surplus (i.e. the total net benefit to consumers and firms), known as the economic surplus. This outcome is economically efficient because every tea has been produced where the marginal benefit to buyers is greater than or equal to the marginal cost to producers. Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Figure 4.5 Marginal Benefit Equals Marginal Cost Only at Competitive Equilibrium (1 of 2) Recall that the demand curve describes the marginal benefit of each additional cup of tea, while the supply curve describes the marginal cost of each additional cup of tea. If the quantity is too low, the value to consumers of the next unit exceeds the cost to producers. Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Figure 4.5 Marginal Benefit Equals Marginal Cost Only at Competitive Equilibrium (2 of 2) If the quantity is too high, the cost to producers of the last unit is greater than the value consumers derive from it. Only at competitive equilibrium is the last unit valued by consumers and producers equally—economic efficiency. Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Figure 4.6 Economic Surplus Equals the Sum of Consumer Surplus and Producer Surplus The figure shows the economic surplus (the sum of consumer and producer surplus) in the market for chai tea. At the competitive equilibrium quantity, the economic surplus is maximized. Our two concepts of economic efficiency result in the same level of output! Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Economic Efficiency Since our two ideas of economic efficiency coincide, we are in a position to define economic efficiency: Economic efficiency: A market outcome in which the marginal benefit to consumers of the last unit produced is equal to its marginal cost of production and in which the sum of consumer surplus and producer surplus is at a maximum. Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Figure 4.7 When a Market is Not in Equilibrium, There Is a Deadweight Loss (1 of 2) At Competitive Equilibrium At a Price of $2.20 Consumer Surplus A+B+C A Producer Surplus D+E B+D Deadweight Loss None C+E Blank When the price of chai tea is $2.20 instead of $2.00, consumer surplus declines from an amount equal to the sum of areas A, B, and C to just area A. Producer surplus increases from the sum of areas D and E to the sum of areas B and D. Economic surplus decreases by the sum of areas C and E. Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Figure 4.7 When a Market is Not in Equilibrium, There Is a Deadweight Loss (2 of 2) At Competitive Equilibrium At a Price of $2.20 Consumer Surplus A+B+C A Producer Surplus D+E B+D Deadweight Loss None C+E Blank The reduction in economic surplus resulting from a market not being in competitive equilibrium is known as deadweight loss. Deadweight loss can be thought of as the amount of inefficiency in a market. In competitive equilibrium, deadweight loss is zero. Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved … Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved 4.3 Government Intervention in the Market: Price Floors and Price Ceilings Explain the economic effect of government-imposed price floors and price ceilings. One option a government has for affecting a market is the imposition of a price ceiling or a price floor. • Price ceiling: A legally determined maximum price that sellers can charge. • Price floor: A legally determined minimum price that sellers may receive. Price ceilings and floors in the USA are uncommon, but include: • Minimum wages • Rent controls • Agricultural price controls Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Figure 4.8 The Economic Effect of a Price Floor in the Wheat Market (1 of 2) The equilibrium price in the market for wheat is $6.50 per bushel; 2.0 billion bushels are traded at this price. If wheat farmers convince the government to impose a price floor of $8.00 per bushel, quantity traded falls to 1.8 billion. Area A is the surplus transferred from consumers to producers. Economic surplus is reduced by area B + C, the deadweight loss. Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Figure 4.8 The Economic Effect of a Price Floor in the Wheat Market (2 of 2) Unfortunately, the situation may be even worse: • If farmers do not realize they will not be able to sell all of their wheat, they will produce 2.2 billion bushels. • This results in a surplus, or excess supply, of 400 million bushels of wheat. Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Making the Connection: Price Floors in Labor Markets Supporters of the minimum wage see it as a way of raising the incomes of low-skilled workers. Opponents argue that it results in fewer jobs and imposes large costs on small businesses. Assuming the minimum wage does decrease employment, it must result in a deadweight loss for society. Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Figure 4.9 The Economic Effect of a Rent Ceiling (1 of 2) Without rent control, the equilibrium rent is $2,500 per month. At that price, 2,000,000 apartments would be rented. If the government imposes a rent ceiling of $1,500, the quantity of apartments supplied falls to 1,900,000, and the quantity of apartments demanded increases to 2,100,000, resulting in a shortage of 200,000 apartments. Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Figure 4.9 The Economic Effect of a Rent Ceiling (2 of 2) Producer surplus equal to the area of the blue rectangle A is transferred from landlords to renters. There is a deadweight loss equal to the areas of yellow triangles B and C. This deadweight loss corresponds to the surplus that would have been derived from apartments that are no longer rented. Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Black Markets and Peer-to-Peer Sites The shortage of apartments may lead to a black market–a market in which buying and selling take place at prices that violate government price regulations. Alternatively, landlords might switch from long-term to short-term rentals in order to avoid rent controls; peer-to-peer rental sites such as Airbnb have facilitated this. • These markets may alleviate some of the deadweight loss by allowing additional apartments to be rented, but buyers and sellers lose valuable legal protections. Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved The Results of Government Price Controls It is clear that when a government imposes price controls: • Some people are made better off, • Some people are made worse off, and • The economy generally suffers, as deadweight loss will generally occur. Economists seldom recommend price controls, with the possible exception of minimum wage laws. Why minimum wage laws? • Price controls might be justified if there are strong equity effects to override the efficiency loss. • The people benefitting from minimum wage laws are generally poor. Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Making the Connection: Why is Uber Such a Valuable Company? Uber is a mobile app used to order a taxi-like ride from an individual serving as an independent contractor. • Users benefit from cheaper rides. • Operators benefit from being able to operate a taxi-like service without expensive licenses. • Uber allows these parties to communicate and avoid restrictive taxi-licensing laws that restrict output in the market. Uber’s estimated market value is $50 billion, giving a sense of the size of the deadweight loss (due to restricted output) it is trying to alleviate. Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved 4.4 Externalities and Economic Efficiency Identify examples of positive and negative externalities and use graphs to show how externalities affect economic efficiency Externality: a benefit or cost that affects someone who is not directly involved in the production or consumption of a good or service. • Think of an externality like a side effect. For example, pollution is an externality: no one sets out to create pollution, but the effect of pollution is felt by many who were not involved in its creation. Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Electricity Production Electricity production is an incredibly important industry for a modern economy. Consider the market for electricity. It consists of: • Sellers, who face increasing marginal costs to produce electricity • Buyers, who face decreasing marginal benefits of additional electricity The actions of these groups generate market supply and demand curves for electricity. Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Cost of Electricity Production When firms produce electricity, they bear certain costs of production: • Buildings • Equipment • Fuel • Labor, etc. Those firms make their decisions about how much to produce based on these private costs. But because of pollution the social cost is higher: the total cost to society of producing a good or service, including both the private cost and any external cost. Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Figure 4.10 The Effect of Pollution on Economic Efficiency (1 of 3) Supply curve S1 represents just the marginal private cost that the electricity producer has to pay. Supply curve S2 represents the marginal social cost, which includes the costs to those affected by pollution. The optimal level of production for society is QEfficient; at this quantity, the marginal cost to society is just equal to the marginal benefit. Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Figure 4.10 The Effect of Pollution on Economic Efficiency (2 of 3) However, the market equilibrium results from the decisions of producers, who see their cost of production given by S1. Price (PMarket) is “too low” and quantity (QMarket) is “too high”: the cost to society of the additional electricity exceeds its benefit to society. Deadweight loss results. Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Figure 4.10 The Effect of Pollution on Economic Efficiency (3 of 3) When there is a negative externality in producing or consuming a good or service, too much of the good or service will be produced at market equilibrium. Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Types of Externalities Pollution is an example of a negative externality in production. • Negative externalities might result from consumption. • Example: cigarette smoke. Externalities might also be positive when the private benefit (the benefit received by the consumer of a good or service) is less than the social benefit (the total benefit from consuming a good or service, including both the private benefit and any external benefit). • Example: college education Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Figure 4.11 The Effect of a Positive Externality on Economic Efficiency (1 of 2) College educations have positive externalities. The marginal social benefit from a college education is greater than the marginal private benefit to college students. Because only the marginal private benefit is represented in the market demand curve D1, the quantity of college educations produced, QMarket, is too low. Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Figure 4.11 The Effect of a Positive Externality on Economic Efficiency (2 of 2) When there is a positive externality in producing or consuming a good or service, too little of the good or service will be produced at market equilibrium. Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Externalities and Market Failure If there are negative or positive externalities, the market equilibrium will not result in the efficient quantity being produced. • Overproduction with negative externalities; underproduction with positive externalities. • There will be deadweight loss. This is an example of market failure: a situation in which the market fails to produce the efficient level of output. • The larger the externality, the greater is likely to be the size of the deadweight loss—the extent of the market failure. Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved What Causes Externalities? Externalities arise because of incomplete property rights, or from the difficulty of enforcing property rights in certain situations. Property rights: The rights individuals or businesses have to the exclusive use of their property, including the right to buy or sell it. Suppose a farmer and a paper mill share a stream. • If no-one owns the stream, the paper mill will discharge waste into the stream, making it unusable for the farmer. • If the farmer owns the stream, he can: • Prevent the mill from discharging into the stream, or • Allow the mill to discharge for a fee, if that is beneficial to him. • Either way, good property rights avoid the market failure. Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved 4.5 Government Policies to Deal with Externalities Analyze government policies to achieve economic efficiency in a market with an externality. Earlier in the chapter, we learned that taxes caused inefficiency (deadweight loss) by moving the level of production away from the efficient level. In this chapter, externalities cause inefficiency for the same reason. • A tax of just the right size could cause these two effects to cancel out, returning us to the efficient level of production. Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Figure 4.12 When There Is a Negative Externality, a Tax Can Lead to the Efficient Level of Output (1 of 2) Utilities do not bear the cost of pollution, so they produce too much. If the government imposes a tax equal to the cost of the pollution, the utilities will internalize the externality. • The supply curve will shift up, from S1 to S2. • The market equilibrium quantity falls to the economically efficient level. Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Figure 4.12 When There Is a Negative Externality, a Tax Can Lead to the Efficient Level of Output (2 of 2) The price of electricity will rise from PMarket, which does not include the cost of acid rain, to PEfficient, which does include the cost. Consumers pay the price PEfficient, while producers receive a price P, which is equal to PEfficient minus the amount of the tax. Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Can Taxes “Solve” Positive Externalities Too? Taxes worked to solve the problem of negative externalities because: • Negative externalities caused too much to be produced, while • Taxes reduced the amount of output. When there are positive externalities, too little will be produced. • Taxes won’t work; but subsidies might. Subsidy: An amount paid to producers or consumers to encourage the production or consumption of a good. Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Figure 4.13 When There Is a positive Externality, a Subsidy Can Bring about the Efficient Level of Output (1 of 2) Individuals make decisions about whether or not to “consume” a college education, with a resulting market price and quantity. But what if there are positive externalities to a college education? • It is good for us all if other people are smart and make good decisions. • This is an argument for a subsidy in the market for college education. Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Figure 4.13 When There Is a positive Externality, a Subsidy Can Bring about the Efficient Level of Output (2 of 2) The subsidy will cause the demand curve to shift up, from D1 to D2. The market equilibrium quantity will shift from QMarket to QEfficient, the economically efficient equilibrium quantity. Producers receive the price PEfficient, while consumers pay a price P, which is equal to PEfficient minus the amount of the subsidy. Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Corrective Taxes and Subsidies The taxes and subsidies seen in the last few slides “correct” the externality problem. They are known as Pigovian taxes and subsidies, after the English economist Arthur Cecil Pigou, who first demonstrated the use of government taxes and subsidies in bringing about an efficient level of output in the presence of externalities. Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Making the Connection: Should We Tax Cigarettes and Soda? (1 of 2) The consumption of cigarettes and soda are thought to have negative externalities. Why? • Both cigarettes and soda have negative health consequences. • This by itself is not sufficient to be a negative externality. • But people’s medical expenses are shared with others, either via public or private health insurance. Therefore we expect there to be too much consumption of cigarettes and soda, and they are candidates for Pigovian taxes. In general, cigarettes are taxed much more heavily than soda. Is this appropriate? Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Making the Connection: Should We Tax Cigarettes and Soda? (2 of 2) Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Alternatives to Taxation for Solving Externalities The traditional solution to the externality problem is commandand-control: a policy that involves the government imposing quantitative limits on the amount of pollution firms are allowed to emit, or requiring firms to install specific pollution control devices. Example: Requiring car manufacturers to equip cars with catalytic converters. Problem: What if firms have very different costs of reducing pollution? It may not be efficient for them to reduce pollution by the same amount. • i.e. the same amount of pollution-reduction could be achieved with less cost Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Two Car Manufacturers Suppose Ford can reduce pollution in its cars very cheaply, while GM has very high costs of reducing pollution. • If we want to achieve a particular level of pollution reduction, it would be efficient to ask Ford to reduce pollution more than GM. • But this doesn’t seem fair to Ford; why should GM be held to a lesser standard? The efficient solution has Ford perform more pollution reduction, but have GM compensate Ford; both companies can be made better off, compared with requiring both to reduce pollution by a moderate amount, while keeping the amount of pollution reduction the same. Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Tradable Emissions Permits This is the concept behind tradable emissions permits, also known as cap-and-trade: • The government establishes an allowable amount of emissions. • Emissions permits are distributed. • Firms can trade emissions permits. ‒ Firms with high costs of reducing pollution will buy permits from firms with low costs of reducing pollution, ensuring that pollution is reduced at the lowest possible cost. • Hence the market is used to achieve efficient pollution reduction. Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved The Sulfur Dioxide Cap-and-Trade System In 1990, Congress enacted a cap-and-trade system for sulfur dioxide emissions. • Improvements in pollution reduction technology resulted, with the cost of compliance ending up almost 90 percent less than firm initially estimated. This program was very effective, with benefits at least 25 times the cost of implementing the program. Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved The End of the Sulfur Dioxide Cap-andTrade System By 2013, the program had effectively ended. Why? • Further emissions reductions were needed; President Bush attempted to lower the cap, but Congress resisted. • As a result, the EPA decided to return to a command-andcontrol approach in order to achieve the reductions. While cap-and-trade appears to be very effective, any policy needs political backing to have a chance at success. Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Criticisms of Cap-and-Trade Environmentalists object to cap-and-trade as it gives firms “licenses to pollute.” • But pollution has a benefit; it allows cheap production. • Every production decision uses up some scarce resource: time, natural resources, clean air, etc. • In this sense, paying for using the clean air seems appropriate. Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved Copyright Copyright © 2017, 2015, 2013 Pearson Education, Inc. All Rights Reserved