Economic Modelling 94 (2021) 104–120 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Economic Modelling journal homepage: www.journals.elsevier.com/economic-modelling The effect of financial fragility on employment Michael Chletsos a, *, Andreas Sintos b a b University of Piraeus, Department of Economics, 80, Karaoli and Dimitriou Str, 18534 Piraeus, Greece University of Ioannina, Department of Economics, University Campus, 45110 Ioannina, Greece A R T I C L E I N F O A B S T R A C T JEL classification: G1 J21 C2 Financial fragility increases economic uncertainty and restricts credit to firms, leading to lower economic growth and employment. Despite voluminous research on the relation between financial fragility and growth, the effect of financial fragility on employment is understudied. Using a global panel for the period 1998–2017, we identify a negative effect of financial fragility on employment, even after accounting for unobserved country heterogeneity. The impact of financial fragility is stronger in the post-crisis period and in more rigid labor markets, and the magnitude of the effect is higher in developing/emerging economies than in developed countries. Nevertheless, this negative effect can be mitigated in countries with a higher level of financial market development. Our results are robust to the use of several robustness tests, including different measures of financial fragility and an instrumental variables approach. Keywords: Financial fragility Employment Panel data models 1. Introduction The financial sector has always played an important role in the economic process. The trend of the economic output is strongly affected by changes in the financial markets. The financial crisis of 2007–2008 showed clearly its negative impact on economic growth. There was a 4% decrease in the GDP in 2009 and 0.1% in 2010 in both the EU27 and the euro area (Koopman and Szekely, 2009). Many papers analyzed the relationship between the financial market and economic growth, focusing on the impact of financial stability or financial fragility on the output of goods and services. As far as the meaning of financial fragility is concerned, there is no a widely accepted definition. Granville and Mallick (2009, p.663) define financial stability “in terms of changes in share prices, interest rate spreads, the nominal effective exchange rate, house price inflation and bank deposit-loan ratio.” According to De Graeve et al. (2008, p.206) “financial stability is defined and measured as a bank’s probability of distress according to the supervisor’s definition of problem banks used for supervisory policy.” Financial fragility can be defined either at the macro- or micro-level. At the macro-level, financial fragility is considered to be the risk of financial instability (Tymoigne, 2012). At the micro-level, financial fragility characterizes the economic unit as having difficulties meeting its liability commitments or having a high reliance on debt refinancing. Financial fragility is related to uncertainty and credit risk and therefore influences the well-functioning of the financial and goods markets. Credit risk is the link between the financial market and the real economy (Foster and Geanakoplos, 2008; Geanakoplos, 2010; Brunnermeier and Pedersen, 2009). A strand of the literature on financial fragility analyzes its role in the banking system and the money market (De Graeve et al., 2008; Diamond and Rajan, 2001; Granville and Mallick, 2009). Other papers emphasize the impact of financial fragility or financial instability on the output of goods and services. Financial instability has a negative impact on economic growth in short-run periods (Batuo et al., 2018) and can be detrimental for economic performance especially in the case of less-developed and closed economies (Bonfiglioli and Mendicino, 2004). The possible effects of financial fragility have already been documented (Loayza and Ranciere, 2006). However, in most cases, scholars have treated financial fragility as no more than part of a banking crisis (e.g., Laeven and Valencia, 2013). Using more established measurements of financial fragility Demetriades et al. (2017) point to its adverse effects on economic growth. Financial fragility, in terms of financial stress conditions, plays an important role in output fluctuation (Mallick and Sousa, 2013). Furthermore, Mallick and Sousa (2013) support that a contractionary monetary policy, which could be a cause of financial fragility, also has a negative impact on output. Although the relevant literature on financial fragility investigates the role it has played either in the banking system and financial market or in economic growth, there are few papers which study the impact of financial fragility on employment. As far as we know, Boeri et al.’s (2013) paper investigates the impact of financial shocks on employment, taking * Corresponding author. E-mail addresses: mhletsos@otenet.gr, mchletsos@unipi.gr (M. Chletsos), a.sintos@uoi.gr (A. Sintos). https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econmod.2020.09.017 Received 7 September 2019; Received in revised form 20 September 2020; Accepted 22 September 2020 Available online 5 October 2020 0264-9993/© 2020 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. M. Chletsos, A. Sintos Economic Modelling 94 (2021) 104–120 bidirectional (Beck, 2012; Levine, 2005). However, Deida and Fatouch (2002) and Rioja and Valev (2004) suggest the existence of a non-monotonic relationship between finance and growth. Mallick et al. (2016) indicate that financial development has a positive effect on countries’ technological change. Their findings suggest that there is a non-linear relationship between financial development, technological change, and technological catch-up. The role of the financial sector to enhance economic growth is important. Levine (2003) argues that countries with better-developed financial systems grow faster. A greater access to finance increases savings (Allen et al., 2016) and therefore investment also increases, which leads to higher economic growth. Financial liberalization facilitates the access of poorer economies to foreign rather than domestic financial markets and has a strong impact on economic growth. Financial liberalization is defined as the implementation of a set of measures aimed at eliminating the different financial restrictions and institutions of a country that could hinder the well-functioning of its economy. One strand of the literature posits that there is a positive relationship between financial liberalization and economic growth and development (Batuo et al., 2018). Empirical results indicate that financial liberation has a positive effect on economic growth (Bumann et al., 2013). Studies on the relationship between financial liberalization and economic growth in African countries have showed that financial liberalization increases financial instability and financial crises (Al-Suwailem, 2014) and financial liberalization has a weak positive effect on economic growth (Batuo et al., 2018). Financial liberalization could cause extreme volatility, resulting in financial crises, which could negatively affect economic growth (Dimitras et al., 2015). The possible negative outcomes of financial liberalization are also reported by Martin and Rey (2002). The main strand of the literature which investigates the relationship between financial fragility and economic growth cannot directly explain the effect of financial fragility at the employment level. The explanation given is based on the mediator role of economic growth in the labor market. The employment level is affected by changes in economic growth caused by financial fragility. There are few papers which try to explain the direct effect of financial fragility on employment. Several studies examine the impact of financial conditions on employment by comparing the labor market conditions before and after changes in financial regulations, taking into account periods of recession. However, they mainly focus on industrial countries (Boustanifar, 2014; Chodorow-Reich, 2014; Haltenhof et al., 2014; Mian and Sufi, 2014) and use only firm-level data (Pagano and Pica, 2012). The results are ambiguous and depend on the sample and methodology used. Boeri et al. (2013) refer to how the literature explains the link between finance and labor, and they support the belief that labor market tightness and unemployment are more likely to respond to a financial shock in a high credit market. Farmer (1985) states that in the case of an absence of liquidity the firm is obliged to finance its activities, including the hiring of labor, at a higher interest rate, which causes a decrease in employment. Similarly, Marques et al. (2017) indicate that restricted access to credit leads firms to cut down on payroll taxes and affects the level of employment due to the changes in either the number of employed persons or the number of working hours. Wasmer and Weil (2004) agree that the deregulation of the labor market goes hand in hand with the liberalization of the financial market. The deregulation of the labor market describes a situation in which there is an increase in the share of workers employed under temporary contracts. The deregulation of the labor market is a response to financial shocks and protects overall employment by decreasing the share of fixed-term contracts in favor of part-time and temporary contracts. The change in overall employment could be better understood if we take into account the reallocation of labor due to job creation and destruction (Davis and Haltiwanger, 1992). The driving forces behind employment fluctuations are due to allocative disturbances (Davis and Haltiwanger, 1999). As mentioned above, financial fragility affects the employment level both directly and indirectly. Labor market structures also depend on the into account the different labor market structures and the degree of the firms’ financial strength in each country. More specifically, they conclude that more leveraged firms have larger job creation and job destruction than low leveraged firms. The purpose of this paper is to provide empirical evidence on the impact of financial fragility on the employment level. This paper contributes to the existing literature review on the relationship between financial fragility and employment. The main research question to be answered is how financial fragility affects the employment level. Policymakers have a strong interest in this subject. The variation of employment has social consequences and can threaten social cohesion. The implementation of policies to eliminate the consequences of financial fragility could enhance employment. Using a novel database of financial fragility for a world sample of countries over the period 1998–2017, which provides various measures of financial fragility, each focusing on a different aspect of vulnerability in the financial system, we empirically investigate the relation between financial fragility and employment. Our main results reveal that financial fragility has significantly negative effects on employment. The results suggest that the vulnerability of the financial sector could cause large fluctuations of employment. Economic growth and the structure of the labor market determine the employment level. Financial fragility negatively affects economic growth and therefore employment growth. Limited access to the financial market deteriorates the economic situation of employees who are seeking financial protection and they therefore demand more social protection benefits. So, this causes an increase in the rigidity of the labor market. In more rigid labor markets, employment increases with a smaller rate than in less rigid/more flexible labor markets. Finally, our IV estimation confirms the adverse effects of financial fragility on employment. The rest of the paper proceeds as follows. In Section 2 we present the literature review on the relation between financial fragility, economic growth, and employment level. In Section 3 we present the empirical methodology and the data used in this model. The empirical results are presented in Section 4. Finally, Section 5 concludes the paper. Details concerning the list of countries used for this paper, pairwise correlations matrix, and regressions which were carried out to assess the robustness of our results are provided in Appendix at the end of the paper. 2. Theoretical considerations Economic growth is an important determinant of employment. The employment effects of economic growth are ambiguous and dependent on the drivers of economic growth. The empirical relationship between economic growth and employment is investigated using employment elasticity. Empirical studies show that the effects of trade liberalization (McMillan and Rodrik, 2011; Winters et al., 2004), labor market flexibility (Cazes and Verick, 2010), and monetary and fiscal policy (Moghadam, 2011; Rodrik, 2013) on job creation are inconclusive. In contrast to the above empirical findings, McMillan and Rodrik (2011) prove that the impact of industrial policy on job creation is positive. Similar findings are found by Fu and Balasubramanyam (2005) and Lall (1995) as far as the impact of investment policy on job growth is concerned. Financial fragility affects employment either directly or indirectly through the channel of economic growth. Financial fragility is related to a heavy reliance on external finance, implying a high agency cost of investment and therefore low and inefficient investment which negatively affects economic growth (Bernanke and Gertler, 1990). The literature on financial fragility suggests that macroeconomic stability is linked to the strong growth of credit to asset markets, asset prices, and credit relative to output, which are indicators of rising financial fragility (Bezemer and Grydaki, 2014). Low levels of financial inclusion decrease the overall supply of credit to small firms (Beck et al., 2008). Financial fragility also implies lower liquidity, which affects entrepreneurs and therefore economic growth (Rodrik and Velasco, 1999; Diamond and Rajan, 2001). The relation between finance and growth is, under certain conditions, 105 M. Chletsos, A. Sintos Economic Modelling 94 (2021) 104–120 financial conditions of the economy and therefore affect the level of employment. The employment adjustment of the firms depends on several factors which are interrelated to: a) the access to credit, and b) the labor market structure. Ahamed and Mallick (2019) argue that the effect of financial development, and specifically financial sector inclusiveness, contributes to greater bank stability. Thus, a higher level of financial market development can reduce financial fragility which in turn creates a more flexible labor market and boosts the employment level. Given a certain level of access to credit, employment growth will be greater in a deregulated labor market. The question raised concerns the relationship between financial markets and employment structure. According to Bertola (2008) workers find it more useful to increase wages and decrease employment when facing difficulties in gaining financial access. Employees are interested in obtaining insurance against job loss either through the financial markets or via the social protection system. If access to the financial market is difficult, workers receive higher minimum wages and higher unemployment benefits. Therefore, the labor costs increase and employment decreases. An understanding of the changes in employment, caused by job creation, destruction, and job reallocation within industries and within the economy, should be taken into account. All in all, these considerations suggest that financial fragility is linked to decreasing employment levels. Hence, for the empirical analysis the following hypotheses are proposed: Table 1 Summary statistics. Variable Source: World Bank (World Development Indicators) Employment Secondary schooling GDP per capita Government spending Trade openness Investment share Population growth Age dependency Source: World Bank (Global Financial Development Database) Bank non-performing loans Bank cost to income ratio Bank return on assets Bank Z-score Lerner index (World Bank) Source: Clerides et al. (2015) Adjusted Lerner index Lerner index Source: Gwartney et al. (2019) Labor market regulation Source: World Bank (Doing Business) Starting a business Bureaucracy index Source: Andrianova et al. (2015) Impaired loans Costs ROAA Z-score Source: Svirydzenka (2016) Financial market development H1. Financial fragility is negatively associated with employment at the country level. H2. The magnitude of this negative effect depends on the country’s growth patterns and the structure of the labor market. While H1 is the general hypothesis, primarily relevant from an empirical perspective, H2 aims to shed light on the proposed theoretical mechanisms, through which financial fragility affects the employment level. 3. Empirical strategy and data Mean Standard Deviation Min Max 57.433 80.599 15.055 16.275 87.23 23.763 1.287 59.516 11.061 29.537 19.572 5.702 51.315 7.241 1.391 17.818 26.293 5.291 0.22 1.34 0.175 3.949 9.081 15.743 87.818 163.935 111.968 92.601 442.62 67.911 16.7 111.939 7.058 57.177 1.295 13.32 27.108 7.685 14.644 2.354 8.644 15.891 0.092 19.895 29.117 0.017 160.869 74.1 218.087 65.837 96.68 153.407 21.679 26.999 12.482 11.918 17.9 12.4 77.8 78.7 6.400 1.454 2.1 9.73 34.352 643.616 43.996 269.973 0.5 120 697 1800 7.075 61.515 1.19 15.209 7.989 22.27 2.517 11.377 0.12 4.863 47.43 14.328 83 382.166 15.773 94.157 28.559 29.635 0 99.501 3.1. Data dependency ratio is measured as a percentage of the working age population and is the ratio of dependents – people younger than 15 or older than 64 – to working age population (15–64). Population growth refers to the annual population growth rate, expressed as a percentage. The main explanatory variable of our specification is a measure of financial fragility. The variables which present financial fragility are the Global Financial Development Database (GFDD) of World Bank and are available for a period from 1998 to 2017. The measures of financial fragility used in this study include bank non-performing loans ratio and bank costs to income ratio. The bank non-performing loan ratio is measured as the number of defaulting loans (payments of interest and principal past due by 90 days or more) divided by total gross loans (total value of loan portfolio). A higher ratio implies greater financial fragility. The bank costs to income ratio, is associated with managerial efficiency—it maximizes income efficiency of resources, reduces operating costs. A larger ratio implies a lower level of efficiency, which deteriorates financial fragility.4 This study uses data for a maximum of 161 countries over the period 1998 to 2017.1 Both the number of countries and time period are based on the availability of our variables.2 Table 1 includes summary statistics of the variables used.3 Our data comes from World Development Indicators and the Global Financial Development Database (GFDD). The dependent variable captures the employment of the working age population and, along with the covariates-control variables, trade openness, secondary schooling, GDP per capita, government spending, investments, age dependency ratio, and population growth, is from World Development Indicators. Employment over the time period and countries of our sample lies within 26–87% from 1998 to 2017. Trade openness is measured as a percentage of the GDP and is the sum of exports and imports of goods and services. GPD per capita is in constant 2010 US $. GDP per capita is entered in our specification as its natural logarithm. Government spending is also reported as a ratio of the GDP and it includes all current government expenditures for the purchases of goods and services (including compensation of employees). Secondary schooling is measured as the gross enrolment ratio of total enrolment of the population that officially corresponds to the level of secondary education. Investments also reported as a share of the GDP are officially named as the gross capital formation (% of GDP) and consists of outlays on additions to the fixed assets of the economy plus net changes in the level of inventories. The age 3.2. Empirical identification To estimate the benchmark relationship between financial fragility and employment we begin with the following specification: 4 Table A3 of the Appendix reports the correlation coefficients between the explanatory variables. The results indicate the absence of any serious multicollinearity between the explanatory variables, except for those variables characterizing the level of human capital, population growth, and age dependency. 1 Table A1 of the Appendix lists all countries included in the study. A briefly description of the variables is reported in Table A2 of the Appendix. 3 106 M. Chletsos, A. Sintos Lit ¼ α þ βX 0it þ γFFit þ κ i þ μt þ εit Economic Modelling 94 (2021) 104–120 (1) Table 2 Employment and financial fragility. where L represents employment to population ratio, FF a measure of financial fragility, X the vector of control variables, as discussed above, α is constant, κ and μ represents country and year fixed effects, respectively, and ε is an independent identically distributed random error.5 Subscript i indexes individual countries, whereas t indexes time. The coefficient of interest is γ, which measures the responsiveness of employment to financial fragility. While our baseline model includes the common determinants of employment, there is a possibility that our estimation strategy could be affected by omitted variables correlated with employment and financial fragility indicators, leading to endogeneity issues. We utilize an instrumental variable in our empirical model to partially mitigate this concern. To serve as an instrument, a variable must fulfil two criteria: first, the ‘exclusion criterion’ is that it must not affect the outcome except via financial fragility; second, the ‘relevance criterion’ is that it must be partially correlated with financial fragility once other exogenous variables have been netted out (Wooldridge, 2010). Specifically, we propose the index of Lerner, which measures the banking power in the banking market, as an instrument of the explanatory variable which is financial fragility. The impact of competition on stability is controversial. On the one hand, the theoretical and empirical literature supports the view that higher competition leads to instability (fragility) (e.g., Allen and Gale, 2004; Anginer et al., 2014; Jimenez et al., 2013; Keeley, 1990). On the other hand, it has been pointed out that competition enhances stability through the effect of competition on loans interest rates (higher competition tends to decrease interest rates for loans, which in turn reduces non-performing loans and increases stability) (e.g., Boyd and De Nicolo, 2005; Schaeck et al., 2009).6 For this purpose, we use the variable from Clerides et al. (2015) who constructed a new dataset on competition in national banking markets. The dataset covers 148 countries over the period 1997–2010. In their novel study, competition is measured in terms of the Lerner index, the adjusted-Lerner index, and the profit elasticity (with higher values reflecting higher marker power (lower competition)). As they discussed: “… we obtain these market-level measures by taking the weighted mean of the individual measures, with market shares as the weights. The reported values are effectively four new indices of banking-sector competition that (i) rely on efficient estimates of marginal cost, (ii) have the largest coverage compared to previous studies, and (iii) are constructed on the basis of a clean database …“. Following the above discussion, our instrument relies on the average estimate of market power (weighted by market shares) using the adjusted Lerner index, which accounts for the fact that banks may not choose prices and input levels that maximize profits.7 (1) (2) (3) (4) FE FE-IV FE FE-IV Bank non-performing loans Bank cost to income ratio 0.052** (0.022) – 0.107** (0.053) – – – Secondary schooling 0.034* (0.019) 0.215*** (0.077) 0.009 (0.041) 0.000 (0.007) 0.063* (0.033) 0.645** (0.268) 0.082* (0.046) 0.014 (0.011) 0.204*** (0.050) 0.059 (0.045) 0.004 (0.006) 0.086*** (0.029) 0.273** (0.111) 0.088** (0.038) 0.019** (0.008) 0.034** (0.016) 0.258*** (0.048) 0.026 (0.036) 0.004 (0.006) 0.025 (0.018) 0.589*** (0.216) 0.110*** (0.037) 0.053*** (0.019) 0.021** (0.010) 0.182*** (0.037) 0.090** (0.037) 0.010* (0.005) 0.056*** (0.016) 0.277*** (0.078) 0.028 (0.026) – 0.177*** (0.053) – 0.406*** (0.055) 5.57*** 8.08*** 7.35*** 10.32*** – 25.39*** – 60.65*** – 26.97*** – 74.71*** – 4.46** – 8.66*** – 4.57** – 8.81*** – 4.70** – 8.77*** 1583 902 2302 1243 GDP per capita Government spending Trade openness Investment share Population growth Age dependency First stage Adjusted Lerner index F-statistic Under identification test Kleibergen-Paap rk LM statistic Weak identification test Kleibergen-Paap Wald rk F statistic Weak-instrument-robust inference (tests of joint significance of the endogenous regressors in the main equation) Anderson-Rubin Wald F test Anderson-Rubin Wald Chisquare test Stock-Wright LM S Chisquare statistic Observations Notes: Clustered robust standard errors at the country-level in parentheses. Dependent variable is the employment to working age population ratio. To save space we do not report the first-stage results for the exogenous variables, which are included in the first-stage regression. F-statistic is the F test for the significance of the model. KP Wald Statistic is a weak identification test with the null hypothesis of weak identified model. K–P LM Stat. is the Kleibergen-Paap underidentification test with the null hypothesis of underidentified model. The weak-instrument robust-inference tests examine the null hypothesis that the coefficients of the endogenous regressors in the structural equation are jointly equal to zero and that the overidentifying restrictions are not rejected. Year effects are included in all models. Significance level is denoted by *** (1%), ** (5%) and * (10%). 4. Empirical results 4.1. Main results Table 2 reports our main results. For the examined year period 1998 to 2017, we obtain coefficient estimates using a fixed effects (FE) (columns 1 and 3) and a fixed effects with an instrumental variable (FE-IV) (columns 2 and 4) model. At the bottom of each column, we report the Fstatistic for the significance of each model. Standard errors are calculated using the robust-clustered Sandwich estimator, which adjusts for heteroscedasticity and serial correlation. The financial fragility variables we incorporate are bank non-performing loans (columns 1 and 2) and bank costs to income ratio (columns 3 and 4). Both estimates are significantly negative. In column 2, where the variable of bank non-performing loans is instrumented using the adjusted Lerner index, an increase in the share of bank non-performing loans by one standard deviation of 7.685 from the average of 7.058 results in a decrease in the linear prediction of 5 The specification of the model was chosen based on a standard Hausman test, which showed that the correct specification is the fixed effects model. 6 As we mentioned above, the instrument fulfils the ‘relevance criterion’ because of the banking power – competition in the banking sector can have a bidirectional effect on financial fragility (stability). Regarding the ‘exclusion criterion’ that the instrument has to fulfil, to the best of our knowledge, we are not aware of any mechanism through which the market power in the banking sector would affect employment other than financial fragility/stability. 7 In our IV estimates, the sample period is restricted to 1998–2010, since the Clerides et al. (2015) dataset ends in 2010. 107 M. Chletsos, A. Sintos Economic Modelling 94 (2021) 104–120 employment to working-age population ratio by 0.82 percentage points8 or by 1.5%, ceteris paribus. In the case of bank costs to income ratio (column 4), a one standard deviation increase (14.644) in bank costs to income ratio leads to a 0.87 percentage points or 1.6% decrease in the linear prediction of the share of employment, ceteris paribus. For the remaining control variables, the GDP per capita and population growth have the expected significant positive signs. While the negative sign of government spending and trade openness may not be expected, however, as mentioned in the empirical literature, increased government spending deteriorates the employment level (e.g., Abrams, 1999; Karras, 1993; Yuan and Li, 2000) and that trade liberalization may have mixed effects on employment (e.g., Dutt et al., 2009; Greenaway et al., 1999; Levinsohn, 1999). At the bottom of columns 2 and 4, the coefficient of the market power measure (using the adjusted Lerner index), first-stage results, is negative and statistically significant at the 1% level.9 Diagnostics statistics indicate that our instrumentation strategy is strong.10 Table 3 Fixed effects IV regressions – Instrumental variable: Lerner index. (1) (2) (3) (4) Bank non-performing loans Bank cost to income ratio 0.094* (0.067) – – – Secondary schooling 0.014 (0.011) 0.197*** (0.055) 0.061 (0.045) 0.004 (0.006) 0.091*** (0.032) 0.269** (0.111) 0.084** (0.038) 0.018** (0.012) 0.017* (0.010) 0.193*** (0.036) 0.105*** (0.037) 0.008* (0.005) 0.060*** (0.016) 0.268*** (0.075) 0.024 (0.025) 0.081* (0.050) – 0.141** (0.056) – 0.646*** (0.060) – 8.12*** GDP per capita Government spending Trade openness Investment share Population growth Age dependency 4.2. Robustness checks First stage Lerner index (Clerides et al., 2015) Lerner index (World Bank) In this subsection, we perform a series of robustness checks and briefly report the results here. First, we adopt an alternative measure of bank market power, using the Lerner index as an instrumental variable to account for the endogeneity of financial fragility (Table 3).11 Columns 1 and 2 use the Lerner index from Clerides et al. (2015) as an instrumental variable of financial fragility variables, while the instrument used in columns 3 and 4 is the Lerner index from the World Bank. The effect of financial fragility indicators remains significantly negative throughout, however, based on the coefficient results (significant threshold) in both stages and most of the IV diagnostic tests, the adjusted Lerner index (Table 2) constitutes a better instrumental variable for our specifications than the Lerner index. F-statistic Under identification test Kleibergen-Paap rk LM statistic Weak identification test Kleibergen-Paap Wald rk F statistic Weak-instrument-robust inference (tests of joint significance of the endogenous regressors in the main equation) Anderson-Rubin Wald F test Anderson-Rubin Wald Chisquare test Stock-Wright LM S Chisquare statistic 8 The percentage point effect is calculated as the difference between the linear prediction at the mean plus one standard deviation of the financial fragility meanþs:d: mean b L The percent variable minus the linear prediction at its mean. b L (%) effect is calculated as the ratio of the difference between the linear prediction at the mean plus one standard deviation of the financial fragility variable minus the linear prediction at its mean divided by the linear prediction at its meanþs:d: mean b b L *100 mean and multiplied by 100. L mean bL 9 Table A4 of the Appendix reports the full first-stage results of Table’s 2 FE-IV estimates. 10 We test whether our results hold under alternative model choices (Table A5 of the Appendix). We incorporate two models, the random effects (RE) and the pooled model (which is a combination of both within and between-country effects). Columns 1 to 4 report results using an RE and an RE-IV model, while the estimation method in columns 5 to 8 is the pooled and the pooled-IV model. Using the RE and RE-IV model, the estimates are very similar to the results presented in Section 4.1. To interpret, a one standard deviation increase in the share of bank non-performing loans results in a decrease in the linear prediction of employment share by 0.78 percentage points or 1.4% (column 2). A one standard deviation increase in bank costs to income ratio decreases the linear prediction of the share of employment by 3.30 percentage points or by 5.5% (column 4). Nevertheless, the coefficients on financial fragility variables (bank non-performing loans and bank costs to income ratio) using the pooled and pooled-IV model are greater in magnitude compared to those reported in Table 2. A one standard deviation increase in the share of non-performing loans decreases the linear prediction of the employment share by 2.08 percentage points or by 3.7% (column 6). An increase in the bank costs to income ratio by one standard deviation decreases the linear prediction of employment share by 9.94 percentage points or by 15.4% (column 8). 11 We use the Lerner index from Clerides et al. (2015), who estimate the marginal cost using a semi-parametric method (the partial linear smooth coefficient model) which allows for improved flexibility in the functional form of the cost function (Delis et al., 2014). We also consider the equivalent Lerner index from the World Bank (which is available for a longer period from 1998 to 2014) where marginal costs are estimated using common parametric techniques and a translog cost function. Observations 0.024*** (0.009) 0.250*** (0.041) 0.019 (0.040) 0.002 (0.004) 0.095*** (0.028) 0.336*** (0.120) 0.040 0.024*** 0.022* (0.013) 0.025*** (0.008) 0.240*** (0.026) 0.092*** (0.034) 0.007* (0.004) 0.050*** (0.013) 0.308*** (0.087) 0.100*** 0.025*** – – 0.709** (0.031) 0.295*** (0.054) 10.57*** 9.36*** 12.28*** 13.45*** 84.31*** 9.24*** 87.11*** 13.54*** 117.69*** 9.67*** 29.56*** 2.13 2.51 2.49 2.71 2.19 2.55 2.54 2.75* 2.32 2.65 2.95* 3.15* 902 1243 1208 1594 Notes: Clustered robust standard errors at the country-level in parentheses. Dependent variable is the employment to working age population ratio. To save space we do not report the first-stage results for the exogenous variables, which are included in the first-stage regression. F-statistic is the F test for the significance of the model. KP Wald Statistic is a weak identification test with the null hypothesis of weak identified model. K–P LM Stat. is the Kleibergen-Paap underidentification test with the null hypothesis of underidentified model. The weak-instrument robust-inference tests examine the null hypothesis that the coefficients of the endogenous regressors in the structural equation are jointly equal to zero and that the overidentifying restrictions are not rejected. Year effects are included in all models. Significance level is denoted by *** (1%), ** (5%) and * (10%). Second, we conduct our analysis using financial stability indicators (Table 4). The measures of financial stability include the bank return on assets and the bank Z-score. The bank return on assets measures the earning capacity of an institution. The bank Z-score measures the distance the banking sector is from insolvency. The higher the Z-score, the more financially sound a country is. The effect of the bank return on assets and Z-score on employment is positive and statistically significant (at the 1% level) when they are instrumented (columns 2 and 4). An increase in the share of the bank return on assets by one standard deviation (2.354) results in an increase in the linear prediction of employment share by 0.62 percentage points or by 1.1%, ceteris paribus (column 2). In column 4, a one standard deviation (8.644) increase in the bank Zscore increases the linear prediction of the share of employment by 1.66 percentage points or by 2.9%, all other factors hold constant. In both 108 M. Chletsos, A. Sintos Economic Modelling 94 (2021) 104–120 cases, first-stage results indicate a positive and significant (at the 1% level) coefficient of the instrumental variable. Our diagnostic statistics for the instrument are strong.12 Table 4 Fixed effects estimates – Financial stability indicators. (1) (2) (3) (4) FE FE-IV FE FE-IV 0.057* (0.031) – 0.262*** (0.079) – – – 0.033** (0.016) 0.256*** (0.048) 0.034 (0.037) 0.004 (0.006) 0.025 (0.019) 0.591*** (0.209) 0.108*** (0.038) 0.018* (0.010) 0.215*** (0.037) 0.099*** (0.037) 0.005 (0.006) 0.051*** (0.016) 0.257*** (0.078) 0.023 (0.025) 0.001 (0.017) 0.033** (0.016) 0.255*** (0.048) 0.025 (0.036) 0.004 (0.006) 0.027 (0.019) 0.577*** (0.206) 0.109*** (0.037) 0.192*** (0.065) 0.023* (0.012) 0.192*** (0.041) 0.095** (0.039) 0.004 (0.006) 0.057*** (0.016) 0.150* (0.078) 0.050 (0.031) – 0.093*** (0.012) – 0.120*** (0.015) F-statistic Under identification test Kleibergen-Paap rk LM statistic Weak identification test Kleibergen-Paap Wald rk F statistic Weak-instrument-robust inference (tests of joint significance of the endogenous regressors in the main equation) Anderson-Rubin Wald F test Anderson-Rubin Wald Chisquare test Stock-Wright LM S Chisquare statistic 8.03*** 10.83*** 14.50*** 9.28*** – 48.15*** – 50.24*** – 63.60*** – 61.42*** – 11.19*** – 9.63*** – 11.39*** – 9.80*** – 11.13*** – 9.65*** Observations 2295 1286 2303 1242 Bank return on assets Bank Z-score Secondary schooling GDP per capita Government spending Trade openness Investment share Population growth Age dependency First stage Adjusted-Lerner index 4.3. Labor market regulation and growth In this subsection we bring together the country’s financial fragility, labor market structure, and patterns of growth, and briefly report the results here. To account for the structure of the labor market, we include several variables which capture regulations in the labor market and the business environment. Also, a subsample analysis is conducted for rigid and flexible labor markets. To account for growth patterns, we conduct subsample analyses for the pre- and post-crisis period, and between developing and developed economies. Lastly, we investigate how the channel of financial market development with financial fragility codetermines the employment level. In Table 5, we extend the vector of controls with variables that are related to labor market institutions and the business environment. The inclusion of further control variables corresponds to a more stringent test for the effect of financial fragility on employment and addresses additional concerns of omitted variable bias. In columns 1 to 4 of Table 5 we include a variable which capture countries’ labor market regulations, while columns 5 to 8 incorporate the ease of doing business and a bureaucracy index. While the signs of the additional variables are mainly statistically insignificant, we show that the effect of financial fragility remains robust (significantly negative) and the magnitude of the coefficients are relatively larger compared to those reported in Table 2. In the following three tables (Tables 6–8), we conduct a subsample analysis. We split our sample into i) pre-crisis (1998–2008) and postcrisis (2009–2017) period (Table 6), ii) countries with rigid and flexible labor market regulations (Table 7) according to the indicator of labor market regulation13 from the Gwartney et al. (2019) dataset (for our sample the mean value of the indicator is 6.4, countries below (and equal to) the mean are considered as countries with rigid labor market regulations, while countries above the mean are considered as countries with flexible labor market regulations), and iii) advanced (developed) economies and developing/emerging economies (Table 8) according to the International Monetary Fund (IMF) classification.14 We perform our analyses using an FE-IV model of estimation.15 In Table 6, we show that the negative effect of both financial fragility variables (bank costs to income ratio and bank non-performing loans) is relatively large and significant for the post-crisis period compared to the pre-crisis period. The Wald χ2 test for the difference in the coefficient between the pre- and post-crisis period shows that both the coefficients of the bank costs to income ratio and bank non-performing loans are significantly different at 5%. Interpreting the results for the post-crisis period, a one standard deviation increase of 6.876 from the average of 7.006 in the share of bank non-performing loans decreases the linear prediction of the share of employment by 1.66 percentage points or by about 3%, an increase of one standard deviation of 11.976 from the average of 57.663 in bank costs to income ratio decreases the linear prediction of employment share by 2.09 percentage points or by 3.6%. This significantly larger effect also remains for countries with more rigid labor markets compared to countries with flexible labor market regulations (Table 7). However, the Wald Notes: Clustered robust standard error at the country-level in parentheses. Dependent variable is the employment to working age population ratio. To save space we do not report the first-stage results for the exogenous variables, which are included in the first-stage regression. F-statistic is the F test for the significance of the model. K–P LM Stat. is the Kleibergen-Paap underidentification test with the null hypothesis of underidentified model. The weak-instrument robustinference tests examine the null hypothesis that the coefficients of the endogenous regressors in the structural equation are jointly equal to zero and that the overidentifying restrictions are not rejected. Year effects are included in all models. Significance level is denoted by *** (1%), ** (5%) and * (10%). 12 We replicate our findings using equivalent financial data from Andrianova et al. (2015) (New International Database on Financial Fragility (NIDFF)) reported in Table A6 of the Appendix. The NIDFF is available for a maximum of 124 countries covering a period from 1998 to 2012. While the data sources of the NIDFF is quite similar to the GFDD (the NIDFF uses data from the Bankscope and the main sources of the GFDD is the IMF and the Bankscope), various types of deposit-taking institutions are included in the national aggregates, and commercial banks account for only two-thirds of the total asset value of banks in the NIDFF – a feature which distinguishes it from the GFDD which focuses exclusively on commercial banks. For more details about the construction of the NIDFF see Andrianova et al. (2015). Consistent with the pathways discussed, we find that financial fragility indicators (impaired loans and costs) (columns 1 to 4) exert a significant negative effect on the share of employment. Regarding the financial stability indicators (return on average assets (ROAA) and Z-score) shown in columns 5 to 8, they exert a statistically significant positive effect on the share of employment. 13 The indicator of labor market regulation includes hiring regulations and minimum wage, hiring and firing regulations, centralized collective bargaining, hours regulations, mandated costs of worker dismissal, and conscription. Measured on a scale of 0–10 with higher scores indicating less regulation. 14 In Table A7, we report the mean and standard deviation for the financial fragility variables based on subsamples, which are used to interpret the results below. 15 In the subsample analysis for the pre- and post-crisis period, the instrumental variable used is the Lerner index from the World Bank (instead of the adjusted-Lerner index) to cover a larger period (until 2014) (Table 6). 109 M. Chletsos, A. Sintos Economic Modelling 94 (2021) 104–120 Table 5 Additional controls. (1) (2) FE FE-IV FE FE-IV FE FE-IV FE FE-IV 0.066** (0.026) – 0.120* (0.061) – – – – 0.017 (0.014) 0.224*** (0.072) 0.061 (0.053) 0.004 (0.006) 0.097*** (0.033) 0.246* (0.136) 0.098* (0.055) 0.076 (0.165) – 0.058*** (0.019) 0.349*** (0.127) 0.055 (0.091) 0.004 (0.010) 0.024 (0.034) 0.604** (0.285) 0.116** (0.053) – 0.018 (0.022) 0.597*** (0.095) 0.001 (0.059) 0.002 (0.011) 0.069* (0.036) 0.051 (0.090) 0.127** (0.057) – 0.017** (0.007) 0.050*** (0.016) 0.429*** (0.125) 0.068 (0.068) 0.004 (0.008) 0.031 (0.020) 0.729** (0.302) 0.106** (0.043) – 0.127*** (0.035) 0.017 (0.017) 0.554*** (0.087) 0.079* (0.046) 0.030*** (0.009) 0.088*** (0.021) 0.102 (0.108) 0.097** (0.043) – Starting a business 0.044** (0.020) 0.268** (0.108) 0.007 (0.092) 0.001 (0.008) 0.059 (0.036) 0.695** (0.305) 0.099** (0.049) 0.108 (0.212) – 0.066*** (0.025) 0.022* (0.013) 0.167*** (0.055) 0.091** (0.042) 0.011** (0.005) 0.078*** (0.019) 0.265* (0.146) 0.052 (0.032) 0.251 (0.141) – 0.258*** (0.063) – – 0.015* (0.008) 0.043** (0.018) 0.305*** (0.105) 0.021 (0.075) 0.000 (0.007) 0.056** (0.024) 0.683** (0.303) 0.128*** (0.046) 0.065 (0.201) – 0.118*** (0.028) – Bureaucracy index – – – – 0.003 (0.007) 0.001 (0.001) 0.002 (0.005) 0.003 (0.002) 0.009 (0.006) 0.003** (0.001) 0.006 (0.005) 0.001 (0.002) Bank non-performing loans Bank cost to income ratio Secondary schooling GDP per capita Government spending Trade openness Investment share Population growth Age dependency Labor market regulation First stage Adjusted Lerner index F-statistic Under identification test Kleibergen-Paap rk LM statistic Weak identification test Kleibergen-Paap Wald rk F statistic Weak-instrument-robust inference (tests of joint significance of the endogenous regressors in the main equation) Anderson-Rubin Wald F test Anderson-Rubin Wald Chi-square test Stock-Wright LM S Chi-square statistic Observations (3) 0.164*** (0.053) (4) (5) 0.366*** (0.071) (6) (7) 0.175*** (0.045) (8) 0.290*** (0.072) 5.35*** 9.03*** 6.10*** 10.38*** 8.51*** 13.69*** 6.92*** 10.68*** – 16.87*** – 41.20*** – 22.47*** – 19.05*** – 17.52*** – 46.65*** – 31.03*** – 22.12*** – – – 4.20** 4.32** 4.49** – – – 7.90*** 8.08*** 8.39*** – – – 14.12*** 14.67*** 13.94*** – – – 21.93*** 22.57*** 21.15*** 1398 763 1801 968 1160 528 1598 697 Notes: Clustered robust standard errors at the country-level in parentheses. Dependent variable is the employment to working age population ratio. To save space we do not report the first-stage results for the exogenous variables, which are included in the first-stage regression. F-statistic is the F test for the significance of the model. KP Wald Statistic is a weak identification test with the null hypothesis of weak identified model. K–P LM Stat. is the Kleibergen-Paap underidentification test with the null hypothesis of underidentified model. The weak-instrument robust-inference tests examine the null hypothesis that the coefficients of the endogenous regressors in the structural equation are jointly equal to zero and that the overidentifying restrictions are not rejected. Year effects are included in all models. Significance level is denoted by *** (1%), ** (5%) and * (10%). χ2 test for the difference in the coefficient between rigid and flexible labor market regulations shows that only the coefficients of bank costs to income ratio are significantly different at 5%. For countries with more rigid labor markets, a one standard deviation increase of 15.237 from the average of 59.553 in bank costs to income ratio results in a decrease in the linear prediction of employment share by 3.62 percentage points or by about 6%. This indicates that the impact of financial fragility on employment is stronger in the case of rigid labor markets than in the case of flexible labor markets. Lastly, the negative effect of the bank costs to income ratio appears to be larger for developing/emerging economies compared to developed countries (Table 8).16 For developing countries, a one standard deviation increase of 13.623 from the average of 58.230 in bank costs to income ratio decreases the linear prediction of the share of employment by 4.54 percentage points or by 7.4%. Finally, in Table 9, we provide evidence on the relationship between financial fragility, financial market development, and employment, by including in our analysis an index which captures the development in financial markets17 and the interaction term of financial market development with financial fragility variables. The results show that the coefficients on financial fragility variables remain significantly negative. Financial market development has a positive effect on the share of employment (statistically significant in column 2, where the financial fragility variable is the bank costs to income ratio). The interaction terms enter the specifications with a statistically significant positive coefficient. This implies that in countries with relatively higher levels of financial development (i.e., countries with higher values of financial market development), the negative effect of financial fragility can be mitigated. Figs. 1 and 2 visualize the marginal effect from a change in financial fragility variables on the predicted value of the dependent variable, for different levels of financial market development, with the associated 90% confidence intervals (red dashed lines). The magnitude of the marginal effect increases as the values of the financial market 16 Also, the Wald χ2 test for the difference in the coefficient between developing and developed countries shows that only the coefficients of bank cost to income ratio are significantly different at the 5%. 17 We use data from Svirydzenka (2016) who constructed an index of financial market development. It ranges between 0 and 100 (higher values more developed). 110 M. Chletsos, A. Sintos Economic Modelling 94 (2021) 104–120 Table 6 Subsample analysis: Pre- and post-crisis period. (1) (2) Table 7 Subsample analysis: Rigid and flexible labor market regulations. (3) (4) Pre-crisis Post-crisis Pre-crisis Post-crisis Bank non-performing loans Bank cost to income ratio 0.032 (0.059) – 0.238*** (0.078) – – – 0.036*** (0.005) Wald χ2 test Secondary schooling 4.444** 0.010 (0.011) 0.106** (0.048) 0.066 (0.045) 0.000 (0.005) 0.102*** (0.027) 0.130 (0.084) 0.122*** (0.038) 0.066*** (0.012) 0.342*** (0.073) 0.002 (0.056) 0.006 (0.007) 0.095** (0.044) 0.450** (0.215) 0.114*** (0.041) 0.005 (0.013) 4.954** 0.020* (0.011) 0.167*** (0.033) 0.117** (0.037) 0.001 (0.05) 0.033** (0.016) 0.193*** (0.061) 0.015 (0.029) 0.015 (0.014) 0.287* (0.146) 0.073 (0.084) 0.010 (0.007) 0.079*** (0.026) 1.021*** (0.271) 0.037 (0.049) 0.070** (0.033) 0.065** (0.026) 0.235*** (0.067) 0.398*** (0.104) 9.39*** 8.98*** 11.75*** 3.46*** 6.20** 25.76*** 38.65*** 32.71*** 6.03** 20.37*** 65.20*** 27.81*** 0.01 2.44 0.02 1.42 0.01 2.50 0.02 1.48 0.02 3.03* 0.03 1.68 745 456 1060 524 GDP per capita Government spending Trade openness Investment share Population growth Age dependency First stage Lerner index (World Bank) F-statistic Under identification test Kleibergen-Paap rk LM statistic Weak identification test Kleibergen-Paap Wald rk F statistic Weak-instrument-robust inference (tests of joint significance of the endogenous regressors in the main equation) Anderson-Rubin Wald F test Anderson-Rubin Wald Chisquare test Stock-Wright LM S Chisquare statistic Observations (1) to ðCoef post Coef pre Þ2 ðSE post Þ2 ðSE pre Þ2 (3) (4) Rigid Flexible Rigid Flexible Bank non-performing loans Bank cost to income ratio 0.139* (0.078) – 0.101 (0.093) – – – 0.035 (0.037) Wald χ2 test Secondary schooling 0.098 0.056*** (0.018) 0.163*** (0.061) 0.072 (0.070) 0.005 (0.013) 0.014 (0.050) 0.447** (0.211) 0.027 (0.048) 0.007 (0.012) 0.297*** (0.098) 0.060 (0.061) 0.008 (0.005) 0.127*** (0.037) 0.161 (0.103) 0.230*** (0.087) 0.061*** (0.022) 4.974** 0.046*** (0.016) 0.163*** (0.045) 0.060 (0.056) 0.006 (0.010) 0.043** (0.018) 0.247*** (0.078) 0.042 (0.033) 0.007 (0.012) 0.214*** (0.062) 0.117** (0.049) 0.009 (0.007) 0.065** (0.029) 0.311** (0.152) 0.028 (0.045) 0.170** (0.073) 0.157** (0.078) 0.475*** (0.087) 0.322*** (0.056) 5.50*** 5.23*** 6.31*** 5.87*** 13.36*** 8.63*** 34.20*** 38.85*** 13.78*** 17.61*** 43.34*** 26.77*** 4.12** 1.16 9.78*** 0.87 4.32** 1.22 10.15*** 0.90 5.04** 1.48 11.00*** 0.96 474 428 617 626 GDP per capita Government spending Trade openness Investment share Population growth Age dependency First stage Adjusted Lerner index F-statistic Under identification test Kleibergen-Paap rk LM statistic Weak identification test Kleibergen-Paap Wald rk F statistic Weak-instrument-robust inference (tests of joint significance of the endogenous regressors in the main equation) Anderson-Rubin Wald F test Anderson-Rubin Wald Chisquare test Stock-Wright LM S Chisquare statistic Observations Notes: Clustered robust standard errors at the country-level in parentheses. Dependent variable is the employment to working age population ratio. To save space we do not report the first-stage results for the exogenous variables, which are included in the first-stage regression. F-statistic is the F test for the significance of the model. KP Wald Statistic is a weak identification test with the null hypothesis of weak identified model. K–P LM Stat. is the Kleibergen-Paap underidentification test with the null hypothesis of underidentified model. The weak-instrument robust-inference tests examine the null hypothesis that the coefficients of the endogenous regressors in the structural equation are jointly equal to zero and that the overidentifying restrictions are not rejected. Year effects are included in all models. A Wald χ12 test with 1 degree of freedom, equal (2) Notes: Clustered robust standard errors at the country-level in parentheses. Dependent variable is the employment to working age population ratio. To save space we do not report the first-stage results for the exogenous variables, which are included in the first-stage regression. F-statistic is the F test for the significance of the model. KP Wald Statistic is a weak identification test with the null hypothesis of weak identified model. K–P LM Stat. is the Kleibergen-Paap underidentification test with the null hypothesis of underidentified model. The weak-instrument robust-inference tests examine the null hypothesis that the coefficients of the endogenous regressors in the structural equation are jointly equal to zero and that the overidentifying restrictions are not rejected. Year effects are included in all models. A Wald χ2 test with 1 degree of freedom, equal to ðCoef rigid Coef flexible Þ2 , tests the hypothesis that the difference in the coefficients , tests the hypothesis that the difference in the coefficients ðSE rigid Þ2 þ ðSE flexible Þ2 of financial fragility variables between rigid and flexible labor market regulations is equal to zero. The critical values for the Wald test of a two-sided hypothesis from the χ2-distribution with one degree of freedom are: 1%: 6.635; 5%: 3.841; 10%: 2.706. Significance level is denoted by *** (1%), ** (5%) and * (10%). þ of financial fragility variables between pre- and post-crisis period is equal to zero. The critical values for the Wald test of a two-sided hypothesis from the χ2-distribution with one degree of freedom are: 1%: 6.635; 5%: 3.841; 10%: 2.706. Significance level is denoted by *** (1%), ** (5%) and * (10%). 5. Concluding remarks development are increasing. Evidently, the marginal effect of bank nonperforming loans on the share of employment becomes positive for values of the financial market development index higher than 40 (Fig. 1), while the marginal effect of bank costs to income ratio on the share of employment is negative for values of the financial market development below 55, and turns positive for values greater than 55 (Fig. 2). Investigating the impact of financial fragility on employment is among the highest priorities of policymakers. The purpose of the government is to promote employment and reinforce social cohesion. The main strand of literature on financial stability analyzes the relationship between financial fragility and economic growth. Lessons from the financial crisis of 2007–2008 indicate that a financial crisis caused the 111 M. Chletsos, A. Sintos Economic Modelling 94 (2021) 104–120 Table 8 Subsample analysis: Developing and developed countries. (1) (2) (3) Table 9 Employment, financial market development and financial fragility. (4) (1) Developing Developed Developing Developed Bank non-performing loans Bank cost to income ratio 0.176 (0.121) – 0.120 (0.128) – – – Bank non-performing loans 0.014 (0.030) Bank cost to income ratio Wald χ2 test Secondary schooling 0.143 0.048** (0.022) 1.134*** (0.244) 0.080 (0.070) 0.034** (0.015) 0.056 (0.047) 0.144 (0.116) 0.108 (0.080) 0.015 (0.009) 0.131*** (0.046) 0.045 (0.074) 0.014 (0.008) 0.191*** (0.042) 0.517*** (0.165) 0.150*** (0.056) 0.078*** (0.023) 5.923** 0.059*** (0.016) 0.421** (0.170) 0.107** (0.044) 0.005 (0.010) 0.014 (0.019) 0.185 (0.121) 0.081** (0.037) 0.200*** (0.059) 0.099 (0.076) 0.447*** (0.061) 0.354** (0.143) 4.01*** 8.98*** 5.54*** 9.11*** 19.39*** 5.68** 60.02*** 38.85*** 20.83*** 15.48*** 78.04*** 10.26*** GDP per capita Government spending Trade openness Investment share Population growth Age dependency First stage Adjusted Lerner index F-statistic Under identification test Kleibergen-Paap rk LM statistic Weak identification test Kleibergen-Paap Wald rk F statistic Weak-instrument-robust inference (tests of joint significance of the endogenous regressors in the main equation) Anderson-Rubin Wald F test Anderson-Rubin Wald Chi-square test Stock-Wright LM S Chisquare statistic Observations Financial market development 0.020** (0.010) 0.124*** (0.038) 0.010 (0.060) 0.012** (0.006) 0.187*** (0.034) 0.290*** (0.079) 0.100** (0.051) 7.31*** 0.90 13.60*** 0.22 7.65*** 0.95 14.00*** 0.23 8.05*** 1.14 14.38*** 0.25 506 396 785 Bank non-performing loans*Financial market development Bank cost to income ratio*Financial market development Secondary schooling (2) FE-IV FE-IV 0.195** (0.089) – – 0.015 (0.011) 0.005** (0.002) – 0.087*** (0.024) 0.086*** (0.025) – 0.010 (0.011) 0.272*** (0.074) 0.049 (0.046) 0.010* (0.005) 0.080** (0.034) 0.296*** (0.039) 0.085*** (0.039) 0.002*** (0.000) 0.020** (0.09) 0.190*** (0.033) 0.098*** (0.035) 0.012** (0.005) 0.056*** (0.015) 0.325*** (0.084) 0.039 (0.026) 0.111*** (0.031) 0.317*** (0.027) F-statistic Under identification test Kleibergen-Paap rk LM statistic Weak identification test Kleibergen-Paap Wald rk F statistic Weak-instrument-robust inference (tests of joint significance of the endogenous regressors in the main equation) Anderson-Rubin Wald F test Anderson-Rubin Wald Chi-square test Stock-Wright LM S Chi-square statistic 6.82*** 10.03*** 15.32*** 65.51*** 16.70*** 87.00*** 5.12** 5.26** 5.74** 13.02*** 13.28*** 13.09*** Observations 902 1224 GDP per capita Government spending Trade openness Investment share Population growth Age dependency First stage Adjusted Lerner index Notes: Clustered robust standard errors at the country-level in parentheses. Dependent variable is the employment to working age population ratio. To save space we do not report the first-stage results for the exogenous variables, which are included in the first-stage regression. F-statistic is the F test for the significance of the model. KP Wald Statistic is a weak identification test with the null hypothesis of weak identified model. K–P LM Stat. is the Kleibergen-Paap underidentification test with the null hypothesis of underidentified model. The weak-instrument robust-inference tests examine the null hypothesis that the coefficients of the endogenous regressors in the structural equation are jointly equal to zero and that the overidentifying restrictions are not rejected. Year effects are included in all models. Significance level is denoted by *** (1%), ** (5%) and * (10%). 458 Notes: Clustered robust standard errors at the country-level in parentheses. Dependent variable is the employment to working age population ratio. To save space we do not report the first-stage results for the exogenous variables, which are included in the first-stage regression. F-statistic is the F test for the significance of the model. KP Wald Statistic is a weak identification test with the null hypothesis of weak identified model. K–P LM Stat. is the Kleibergen-Paap underidentification test with the null hypothesis of underidentified model. The weak-instrument robust-inference tests examine the null hypothesis that the coefficients of the endogenous regressors in the structural equation are jointly equal to zero and that the overidentifying restrictions are not rejected. Year effects are included in all models. A Wald χ2 test with 1 degree of freedom, equal to ðCoef developing Coef developed Þ2 emphasize the negative impact of financial fragility on economic growth. Any changes in economic growth alter the employment level. Although financial flows have a positive impact on economic growth, economic growth may have indefinite results at the employment level. This depends on job creation, job destruction, and reallocation within the economy. An increase of financial fragility destabilizes financial flows and it consequently affects economic growth and therefore employment. Financial fragility restricts the available credit and affects firms’ ability to finance labor. In this paper financial fragility is presented by two different indexes. In order to solve the problem of endogeneity, we also use a novel instrument which is presented by the adjusted Lerner index. Most of the indices used are statistically significant and have the expected sign. The empirical results indicate that the vulnerability of the financial sector affects labor market outcomes. The impact of financial fragility is , tests the hypothesis that the difference in the coðSE developing Þ2 þ ðSE deveoped Þ2 efficients of financial fragility variables between developing and developed countries is equal to zero. The critical values for the Wald test of a two-sided hypothesis from the χ2-distribution with one degree of freedom are: 1%: 6.635; 5%: 3.841; 10%: 2.706. Significance level is denoted by *** (1%), ** (5%) and * (10%). economic crisis which then led to an economic recession. Most papers 2 Depending on the specification, the number of countries and observations differs. 112 M. Chletsos, A. Sintos Economic Modelling 94 (2021) 104–120 the size of the effect of financial fragility on employment level also depends on the degree of labor market flexibility. The more rigid the labor market, the less the employment growth rate is. It is showed that the capacity of the firm to have access to financial credit affects its decision at employment level through the economic growth channel. If firms face more difficulties getting financial credit, they will have a smaller economic expansion rate and they will have a lower increase in employment. Furthermore, there is an inverse relationship between the degree of access to financial markets and labor market structure. The rigidity of the labor market depends on the behavior of households that are seeking protection against the social risks. A generous social protection system makes the labor market more rigid and it is an obstacle to increasing employment easily. Thus, limited access to financial markets due to fragility causes the development of a more protective labor market and therefore decreases employment. From a policy perspective, our findings have important implications. The empirical results indicate that it is necessary to improve the stability of the banking system and generally of the financial sector in order to enhance economic growth and employment. Any improvement of their stability could eliminate the consequences of potential future shocks, protect the economy and increase employment. Hence, the main goals of bank policy should be to effectively utilize impaired loans, to keep the quality of assets, to decrease operation costs in order to increase efficiency, to use net loans to increase liquidity, and to reduce the banks’ risk exposure. All these measures could enhance economic growth and boost employment. Fig. 1. Marginal effect of bank non-performing loans on employment share at different values of financial market development. Ethical approval This article does not contain any studies with human participants or animals performed by any of the authors. Declaration of competing interest None. Acknowledgements We especially thank the journal’s editor Professor Sushanta Mallick and two anonymous referees for their very constructive remarks and suggestions. We would also like to thank Manthos Delis, Nikolaos Mylonidis and participants at the 23rd International Conference in Macroeconomic Analysis and International Finance (ICMAIF) (University of Crete) for their valuable comments. Andreas Sintos would like to acknowledge financial support from the State Scholarships Foundation (IKY), Greece. The usual disclaimer applies. Fig. 2. Marginal effect of bank cost to income ratio on employment share at different values of financial market development. stronger in the post-crisis period and the magnitude of the effect is higher in developing/emerging economies than in developed countries. There are few papers which analyze the effect of financial fragility on employment. This paper contributes to the literature by indicating that APPENDIX Table A1 List of countries Afghanistan Albania Algeria Angola Argentina Armenia Australia Austria Bahamas, The Bahrain Bangladesh Barbados (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, 14) 20) 13) 7) 20) 15) 3) 20) 15) 19) 19) 17) Lao PDR Latvia Lesotho Liberia Libya Lithuania Luxembourg Macao SAR, China Madagascar Malawi Malaysia Mali (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, 15) 20) 10) 4) 4) 20) 19) 19) 11) 19) 20) 17) (continued on next column) 113 M. Chletsos, A. Sintos Economic Modelling 94 (2021) 104–120 Table A1 (continued ) Belarus Belgium Belize Benin Bhutan Bolivia Botswana Brazil Brunei Darussalam Bulgaria Burkina Faso Burundi Cabo Verde Cambodia Cameroon Canada Central African Republic Chad Chile China Colombia Comoros Congo, Dem. Rep. Congo, Rep. Costa Rica Cote d’Ivoire Croatia Cuba Cyprus Czech Republic Denmark Dominican Republic Ecuador Egypt, Arab Rep. El Salvador Equatorial Guinea Eritrea Estonia Eswatini Ethiopia Finland France Gabon Gambia, The Georgia Germany Ghana Greece Guatemala Guinea Guyana Honduras Hong Kong SAR, China Hungary Iceland India Indonesia Iran, Islamic Rep. Iraq Ireland Israel Italy Jamaica Jordan Kazakhstan Kenya Korea, Rep. Kuwait Kyrgyz Republic (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, 11) 19) 17) 11) 17) 20) 11) 14) 19) 19) 18) 15) 10) 8) 18) 16) 4) 18) 19) 10) 18) 1) 9) 1) 19) 5) 18) 19) 17) 20) 20) 17) 19) 14) 20) 1) 5) 20) 18) 3) 20) 20) 3) 3) 16) 20) 18) 18) 19) 10) 10) 11) 17) 20) 20) 19) 20) 5) 5) 18) 19) 20) 17) 15) 12) 11) 20) 17) 17) Malta Mauritania Mauritius Mexico Moldova Mongolia Montenegro Morocco Mozambique Myanmar Nepal Netherlands New Zealand Nicaragua Niger Nigeria North Macedonia Norway Oman Pakistan Panama Papua New Guinea Paraguay Peru Philippines Poland Portugal Qatar Romania Russian Federation Rwanda Saudi Arabia Senegal Serbia Sierra Leone Singapore Slovak Republic Slovenia Solomon Islands South Africa South Sudan Spain Sri Lanka St. Lucia St. Vincent and the Grenadines Sudan Suriname Sweden Switzerland Tajikistan Tanzania Thailand Togo Tonga Tunisia Turkey Uganda Ukraine United Arab Emirates United Kingdom United States Uruguay Uzbekistan Vanuatu Venezuela, RB Vietnam West Bank and Gaza Zimbabwe (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, (20, 18) 19) 20) 20) 19) 10) 13) 15) 17) 3) 18) 18) 20) 11) 20) 17) 16) 20) 17) 15) 17) 1) 15) 20) 15) 20) 20) 8) 19) 16) 17) 5) 17) 19) 7) 2) 20) 20) 2) 19) 2) 20) 6) 17) 3) 17) 5) 20) 19) 11) 5) 17) 11) 11) 18) 19) 2) 16) 2) 19) 20) 18) 17) 4) 16) 1) 17) 7) Notes: In parentheses, the number before comma indicates the maximum number of years in the sample and the number after comma indicates the number (per country) of observations the fixed effects regressions use. 114 M. Chletsos, A. Sintos Economic Modelling 94 (2021) 104–120 Table A2 Description of variables Variable Description Employment Secondary schooling GDP per capita Government spending Trade openness Investment share Population growth Age dependency Bank non-performing loans Bank cost to income ratio Bank return on assets Bank Z-score Lerner index (World Bank) Employment to population ratio, ages 15 and older. Ages 15 and older are generally considered the working-age population. Total enrolment in secondary education, regardless of age, expressed as a percentage of total population. Log of GDP (constant 2010 US$) per capita. Government (final consumption expenditure) share of GDP. The sum of exports and imports of goods and services measured as a share of GDP. Gross domestic investment (formally gross capital formation) measured as a share of GDP. Annual percentage growth rate of total population by country and year. People younger than 15 or older than 64 to the working age population. Ratio of defaulting loans (payments of interest and principal past due by 90 days or more) to total gross loans (total value of loan portfolio). Operating expenses of a bank as a share of sum of net-interest revenue and other operating income. Commercial banks’ after-tax net income to yearly averaged total assets. It captures the probability of default of a country’s commercial banking system. A measure of market power in the banking market. It compares output pricing and marginal costs (that is, markup) (with higher values reflect higher marker power (lower competition)). Adjusted-Lerner index measures potential market power (with higher values reflect higher marker power (lower competition)). Lerner index measures actual (exercised) market power (with higher values reflect higher marker power (lower competition)). An indicator of labor market regulation capturing how flexible are hiring regulations and minimum wage, hiring and firing regulations, centralized collective bargaining, hours regulations, mandated costs of worker dismissal, and conscription, on a scale from 0 to 10; higher values indicating less regulation. The number of calendar days needed to complete the procedures to legally operate a business. Time required to enforce a contract measured as the number of calendar days from the filing of the lawsuit in court until the final determination and, in appropriate cases, payment. The number of impaired loans (loans where payment is 90 days past its due date) divided by total gross loans. The cost of income ratio. The return on average assets (ROAA) measures the earning capacity of an institution. The Z-Score measures the distance the banking sector is from insolvency. A sub-index of financial development which is defined as a combination of depth, access and efficiency of financial markets. Adjusted Lerner index Lerner index Labor market regulation Starting a business Bureaucracy index Impaired loans Costs ROAA Z-score Financial market development 115 M. Chletsos, A. Sintos Table A3 Pairwise correlations matrix 116 Variables (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) (13) (14) (15) (16) (1) Employment (2) Bank non-performing loans (3) Bank return on assets (4) Bank Z-score (5) Bank cost to income ratio (6) Secondary schooling (7) GDP per capita (8) Government spending (9) Trade openness (10) Investment share (11) Population growth (12) Age dependency (13) Labor market regulation (14) Starting a business (15) Bureaucracy index (16) Financial market development 1 0.15* 0.09* 0.14* 0.05* 0.30* 0.02 0.20* 0.08* 0.00 0.30* 0.16* 0.05* 0.01 0.08* 0.02 1 0.16* 0.12* 0.08* 0.36* 0.32* 0.10* 0.11* 0.16* 0.04* 0.25* 0.10* 0.05* 0.15* 0.32* 1 0.06* 0.26* 0.13* 0.13* 0.00 0.02 0.01 0.12* 0.16* 0.06* 0.06* 0.04* 0.15* 1 0.12* 0.02 0.14* 0.01 0.16* 0.11* 0.17* 0.12* 0.14* 0.10* 0.00 0.15* 1 0.03 0.04* 0.06* 0.15* 0.16* 0.12* 0.18* 0.21* 0.05* 0.17* 0.07* 1 0.58* 0.27* 0.25* 0.01 0.53* 0.79* 0.18* 0.19* 0.23* 0.52* 1 0.21* 0.29* 0.05* 0.11* 0.48* 0.19* 0.19* 0.20* 0.74* 1 0.13* 0.00 0.21* 0.15* 0.11* 0.11* 0.09* 0.11* 1 0.08* 0.07* 0.26* 0.25* 0.07* 0.17* 0.20* 1 0.02 0.24* 0.03 0.04* 0.17* 0.01 1 0.44* 0.02 0.08* 0.10* 0.08* 1 0.19* 0.15* 0.20* 0.45* 1 0.12* 0.23* 0.19* 1 0.25* 0.21* 1 0.16* 1 Notes: * shows significance at the 5% level. Economic Modelling 94 (2021) 104–120 M. Chletsos, A. Sintos Economic Modelling 94 (2021) 104–120 Table A4 First-stage results Dependent variable: Adjusted Lerner index Secondary schooling GDP per capita Government spending Trade openness Investment share Population growth Age dependency Observations (1) (2) Bank non-performing loans Bank cost to income ratio 0.177*** (0.053) 0.006 (0.0495) 0.492** (0.196) 0.019 (0.189) 0.015 (0.030) 0.267** (0.114) 0.234 (0.393) 0.226 (0.194) 0.406*** (0.055) 0.079 (0.048) 0.395 (0.246) 0.194 (0.162) 0.038 (0.030) 0.057 (0.079) 0.220 (0.245) 0.219 (0.137) 902 1243 Notes: Clustered robust standard errors at the country-level in parentheses. Country and year effects are included in all models. Significance level is denoted by *** (1%) and ** (5%). Table A5 Alternative estimates (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) RE RE-IV RE RE-IV Pooled Pooled-IV Pooled Pooled-IV 0.056** (0.023) – 0.107* (0.091) – – – – 0.043** (0.018) 0.153*** (0.048) 0.024 (0.042) 0.002 (0.007) 0.069** (0.032) 0.712** (0.286) 0.049 (0.042) 0.020 (0.024) 0.156*** (0.056) 0.084 (0.073) 0.005 (0.009) 0.086* (0.049) 0.302* (0.181) 0.114* (0.062) 0.058* (0.033) 0.034 (0.023) 0.117** (0.045) 0.123** (0.055) 0.010 (0.007) 0.057** (0.027) 0.325** (0.129) 0.022 (0.043) 0.286* (0.448) – – 0.019** (0.008) 0.044*** (0.016) 0.210*** (0.036) 0.035 (0.036) 0.006 (0.006) 0.028 (0.018) 0.633*** (0.227) 0.085** (0.036) 0.248** (0.096) – 0.110** (0.056) 0.130*** (0.048) 0.200 (0.139) 0.021 (0.013) 0.034 (0.103) 1.746** (0.679) 0.007 (0.081) 0.113 (0.098) 0.119* (0.070) 0.213 (0.254) 0.020 (0.016) 0.128 (0.158) 1.251* (0.719) 0.032 (0.120) 0.057* (0.033) 0.134** (0.053) 0.187*** (0.048) 0.270* (0.138) 0.028** (0.014) 0.007 (0.095) 1.389*** (0.503) 0.004 (0.065) 0.174** (0.074) 0.082 (0.067) 0.187*** (0.056) 0.425** (0.176) 0.028 (0.017) 0.149 (0.123) 0.894* (0.504) 0.130 (0.092) – 0.180*** (0.033) – 0.407*** (0.045) – 0.179*** (0.033) – 0.593*** (0.051) Wald-test F-statistic Under identification test Kleibergen-Paap rk LM statistic Weak identification test Kleibergen-Paap Wald rk F statistic Weak-instrument-robust inference (tests of joint significance of the endogenous regressors in the main equation) Anderson-Rubin Wald F test Anderson-Rubin Wald Chi-square test Stock-Wright LM S Chi-square statistic 149.05*** – 104.50*** – 197.16*** – 138.76*** – – 5.34*** – 3.78*** – 5.60*** – 7.10*** – 12.70*** – 31.13*** – 11.20*** – 29.70*** – 15.54*** – 51.40*** – 11.13*** – 135.34*** – – – 1.12 1.15 1.42 – – – 2.65 2.69 2.88* – – – 2.44 2.45 2.55 – – – 5.43** 5.57** 7.15*** Observations 1583 909 2302 1251 1583 909 2302 1251 Bank non-performing loans Bank cost to income ratio Secondary schooling GDP per capita Government spending Trade openness Investment share Population growth Age dependency First-stage Adjusted Lerner index (8) Notes: Clustered robust standard error at the country-level in parentheses. Dependent variable is the employment to working age population ratio. To save space we do not report the first-stage results for the exogenous variables, which are included in the first-stage regression. The Wald-test (models (1) to (4)) and the F-statistic (models (5) to (8)) are reported for the overall significance of the models. KP Wald Statistic is a weak identification test with the null hypothesis of weak identified model. K–P LM Stat. is the Kleibergen-Paap underidentification test with the null hypothesis of underidentified model. The weak-instrument robust-inference tests examine the null hypothesis that the coefficients of the endogenous regressors in the structural equation are jointly equal to zero and that the overidentifying restrictions are not rejected. Year effects are included in all models. Significance level is denoted by *** (1%), ** (5%) and * (10%). 117 M. Chletsos, A. Sintos Economic Modelling 94 (2021) 104–120 Table A6 Fixed effects estimates – NIDFF dataset (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) FE FE-IV FE FE-IV FE FE-IV FE FE-IV – – – – – – 0.059*** (0.017) – – – – – 0.385*** (0.097) – – – 0.005 (0.015) 0.014 (0.025) 0.298*** (0.100) 0.120* (0.068) 0.019** (0.009) 0.033 (0.026) 0.939*** (0.304) 0.086 (0.058) 0.259*** (0.061) 0.000 (0.014) 0.287*** (0.061) 0.203*** (0.045) 0.019*** (0.007) 0.049*** (0.019) 0.069** (0.034) 0.647** (0.306) Financial fragility indicators Financial stability indicators Costs 0.027* (0.014) – 0.285*** (0.098) – ROAA – – 0.008** (0.004) – Z-score – – – – 0.082* (0.047) – Secondary schooling 0.013 (0.027) 0.291*** (0.109) 0.157* (0.084) 0.017 (0.013) 0.032 (0.030) 0.890** (0.446) 0.092 (0.072) 0.003 (0.018) 0.290*** (0.071) 0.184*** (0.059) 0.014 (0.012) 0.002 (0.028) 0.061 (0.076) 0.792** (0.324) 0.018 (0.024) 0.297*** (0.100) 0.148* (0.075) 0.020** (0.010) 0.032 (0.027) 0.978** (0.374) 0.087 (0.059) 0.024* (0.013) 0.261*** (0.061) 0.172*** (0.044) 0.022*** (0.006) 0.031 (0.021) 0.028 (0.035) 1.134*** (0.249) 0.014 (0.024) 0.299*** (0.100) 0.117* (0.066) 0.018* (0.009) 0.030 (0.026) 0.916*** (0.309) 0.083 (0.058) 0.019 (0.012) 0.264*** (0.055) 0.164*** (0.047) 0.010 (0.010) 0.034* (0.019) 0.047 (0.031) 1.065*** (0.243) – 0.147*** (0.040) – 0.662*** (0.137) – 0.101*** (0.017) – 0.150*** (0.022) 5.38*** 6.75*** 5.97*** 10.74*** 5.84*** 11.63*** 5.84*** 9.33*** – 13.74*** – 24.33*** – 30.59*** – 39.23*** – 13.25*** – 23.15*** – 35.42*** – 45.59*** – – – 20.99*** 21.53*** 23.78*** – – – 25.44*** 26.02*** 28.46*** – – – 25.44*** 26.02*** 28.46*** – – – 25.44*** 26.02*** 28.46*** 1137 883 1266 992 1293 992 1293 992 Impaired loans GDP per capita Government spending Trade openness Investment share Population growth Age dependency First stage Adjusted Lerner index F-statistic Under identification test Kleibergen-Paap rk LM statistic Weak identification test Kleibergen-Paap Wald rk F statistic Weak-instrument-robust inference (tests of joint significance of the endogenous regressors in the main equation) Anderson-Rubin Wald F test Anderson-Rubin Wald Chi-square test Stock-Wright LM S Chi-square statistic Observations Notes: Clustered robust standard errors at the country-level in parentheses. Dependent variable is the employment to working age population ratio. To save space we do not report the first-stage results for the exogenous variables, which are included in the first-stage regression. F-statistic is the F test for the significance of the model. KP Wald Statistic is a weak identification test with the null hypothesis of weak identified model. K–P LM Stat. is the Kleibergen-Paap underidentification test with the null hypothesis of underidentified model. The weak-instrument robust-inference tests examine the null hypothesis that the coefficients of the endogenous regressors in the structural equation are jointly equal to zero and that the overidentifying restrictions are not rejected. Year effects are included in all models. Significance level is denoted by *** (1%), ** (5%) and * (10%). Table A7 Mean and standard deviation of financial fragility variables based on subsamples Variable Bank non-performing Bank cost to income ratio Pre-crisis Post-crisis Rigid Flexible Developing Developed Mean S.D. Mean S.D. Mean S.D. Mean S.D. Mean S.D. Mean S.D. 7.675 57.111 8.272 13.548 7.006 57.663 6.876 11.976 7.620 59.553 8.304 15.237 6.955 55.687 6.985 16.269 8.677 58.230 8.038 13.623 5.895 56.060 6.159 16.651 Funding This research is co-financed by Greece and the European Union (European Social Fund- ESF) through the Operational Programme « Human Resources Development, Education and Lifelong Learning» in the context of the project “Strengthening Human Resources Research Potential via Doctorate Research” (MIS-5000432), implemented by the State Scholarships Foundation (ІΚΥ). 118 M. Chletsos, A. Sintos Economic Modelling 94 (2021) 104–120 Deidda, L., Fattouh, B., 2002. Non-linearity between finance and growth. Econ. Lett. 74 (3), 339–345. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0165-1765(01)00571-7. Delis, M., Iosifidi, M., Tsionas, E.G., 2014. On the estimation of marginal cost. Oper. Res. 62 (3), 543–556. https://doi.org/10.1287/opre.2014.1264. Demetriades, P.O., Rousseau, P.L., Rewilak, J., 2017. Finance, Growth and Fragility. Discussion Papers in Economics 17/13. Department of Economics, University of Leicester. Available at: https://www.le.ac.uk/economics/research/RePEc/lec/leec on/dp17-13.pdf. Diamond, D.W., Rajan, R.G., 2001. Liquidity risk, liquidity creation, and financial fragility: a theory of banking. J. Polit. Econ. 109 (2), 287–327. https://doi.org/ 10.1086/319552. Dimitras, A.I., Kyriakou, M.I., Iatridis, G., 2015. Financial crisis, GDP variation and earnings management in Europe. Res. Int. Bus. Finance 34, 338–354. https://doi.org/ 10.1016/j.ribaf.2015.02.017. Dutt, P., Mitra, D., Ranjan, P., 2009. International trade and unemployment: theory and cross-national evidence. J. Int. Econ. 78 (1), 32–44. https://doi.org/10.1016/ j.jinteco.2009.02.005. Farmer, R.E., 1985. Implicit contracts with asymmetric information and bankruptcy: the effect of interest rates on layoffs. Rev. Econ. Stud. 52 (3), 427–442. https://doi.org/ 10.2307/2297662. Fostel, A., Geanakoplos, J., 2008. Leverage cycles and the anxious economy. Am. Econ. Rev. 98 (4), 1211–1244. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.98.4.1211. Fu, X., Balasubramanyam, V.N., 2005. Exports, foreign direct investment and employment: the case of China. World Econ. 28 (4), 607–625. https://doi.org/ 10.1111/j.1467-9701.2005.00694.x. Geanakoplos, J., 2010. The leverage cycle. NBER Macroecon. Annu. 24 (1), 1–66. https:// doi.org/10.1086/648285. Granville, B., Mallick, S., 2009. Monetary and financial stability in the euro area: procyclicality versus trade-off. J. Int. Financ. Mark. Inst. Money 19 (4), 662–674. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.intfin.2008.11.002. Greenaway, D., Hine, R.C., Wright, P., 1999. An empirical assessment of the impact of trade on employment in the United Kingdom. Eur. J. Polit. Econ. 15 (3), 485–500. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0176-2680(99)00023-3. Gwartney, J.D., Lawson, R.A., Hall, J., Murphy, R., 2019. Economic Freedom Dataset, Published in Economic Freedom of the World: 2019 Annual Report. Fraser Institute. Available at: www.fraserinstitute.org/economic-freedom/dataset. Haltenhof, S., Lee, S.J., Stebunovs, V., 2014. The credit crunch and fall in employment during the great recession. J. Econ. Dynam. Contr. 43, 31–57. https://doi.org/ 10.1016/j.jedc.2014.03.013. Jimenez, G., Lopez, J.A., Saurina, J., 2013. How does competition affect bank risk-taking? J. Financ. Stabil. 9 (2), 185–195. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfs.2013.02.004. Karras, G., 1993. Employment and output effects of government spending: is government size important? Econ. Inq. 31 (3), 354–369. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.14657295.1993.tb01298.x. Keeley, M.C., 1990. Deposit insurance, risk, and market power in banking. Am. Econ. Rev. 1183–1200. Koopman, G.J., Szekely, I.P., 2009. Impact of the current economic and financial crisis on potential output. Eur. Econ. (49) Occasional Paper. Laeven, L., Valencia, F., 2013. Systemic banking crises database. IMF Econ. Rev. 61 (2), 225–270. https://doi.org/10.1057/imfer.2013.12. Lall, S., 1995. Employment and foreign investment: policy options for developing countries. Int. Lab. Rev. 134 (4–5), 521–540. Levine, R., 2003. More on finance and growth: more finance, more growth? Rev.-Federal Res. Bank Saint Louis 85 (4), 31–46. Available at: https://files.stlouisfed.org/files/h tdocs/publications/review/03/07/Levine.pdf. Levine, R., 2005. Chapter 12 finance and growth: theory and evidence. Handb. Econ. Growth 865–934. https://doi.org/10.1016/s1574-0684(05)01012-9. Levinsohn, J., 1999. Employment responses to international liberalization in Chile. J. Int. Econ. 47 (2), 321–344. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0022-1996(98)00026-9. Loayza, N., Ranciere, R., 2006. Financial development, financial fragility, and growth. J. Money Credit Bank. 38 (4), 1051–1076. https://doi.org/10.1353/mcb.2006.0060. Mallick, S.K., Sousa, R.M., 2013. The real effects of financial stress in the Eurozone. Int. Rev. Financ. Anal. 30, 1–17. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.irfa.2013.05.003. Mallick, S., Matousek, R., Tzeremes, N.G., 2016. Financial development and productive inefficiency: a robust conditional directional distance function approach. Econ. Lett. 145, 196–201. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.econlet.2016.06.019. Marques, A.M., Lima, G.T., Troster, V., 2017. Unemployment persistence in OECD countries after the great recession. Econ. Modell. 64, 105–116. https://doi.org/ 10.1016/j.econmod.2017.03.014. References Abrams, B.A., 1999. The effect of government size on the unemployment rate. Publ. Choice 99 (3–4), 395–401. https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1018349411246. Ahamed, M.M., Mallick, S.K., 2019. Is financial inclusion good for bank stability? International evidence. J. Econ. Behav. Organ. 157, 403–427. https://doi.org/ 10.1016/j.jebo.2017.07.027. Al-Suwailem, S., 2014. Complexity and endogenous instability. Res. Int. Bus. Finance 30, 393–410. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ribaf.2012.08.002. Allen, F., Gale, D., 2004. Competition and financial stability. J. Money Credit Bank. 453–480. https://doi.org/10.1353/mcb.2004.0038. Allen, F., Demirguc-Kunt, A., Klapper, L., Martinez Peria, M.S., 2016. The foundations of financial inclusion: understanding ownership and use of formal accounts. J. Financ. Intermediation 27, 1–30. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jfi.2015.12.003. Andrianova, S., Baltagi, B., Beck, T., Demetriades, P., Fielding, D., Hall, S.G., Koch, S., Lensink, R., Rewilak, Johan, Rousseau, P., 2015. A New International Database on Financial Fragility. Working Paper 15/18. University of Leicester, Department of Economics, University of Leicester. Available at: https://www.le.ac.uk/economic s/research/RePEc/lec/leecon/dp15-18.pdf. Anginer, D., Demirguc-Kunt, A., Zhu, M., 2014. How does competition affect bank systemic risk? J. Financ. Intermediation 23 (1), 1–26. https://doi.org/10.1016/ j.jfi.2013.11.001. Batuo, M., Mlambo, K., Asongu, S., 2018. Linkages between financial development, financial instability, financial liberalisation and economic growth in Africa. Res. Int. Bus. Finance 45, 168–179. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ribaf.2017.07.148. Bonfiglioli, A., Mendicino, C., 2004. Financial Liberalization, Bank Crises and Growth: Assessing the Links. Bank Crises and Growth: Assessing the Links. https://doi.org/ 10.2139/ssrn.1002285. October 2004. Beck, T., Demirgüç-Kunt, A., Laeven, L., Levine, R., 2008. Finance, firm size, and growth. J. Money Credit Bank. 40 (7), 1379–1405. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.15384616.2008.00164.x. Beck, T., 2012. The role of finance in economic development – benefits, risks, and politics. In: Müller, Dennis (Ed.), Oxford Handbook of Capitalism. Oxford University Press, pp. 161–203. https://doi.org/10.1093/oxfordhb/9780195391176.013.0007. Bernanke, B., Gertler, M., 1990. Financial fragility and economic performance. Q. J. Econ. 105 (1), 87–114. https://doi.org/10.2307/2937820. Bertola, G., 2008. Labour Markets in EMU - what Has Changed and what Needs to Change. CEPR Discussion Paper No. DP7049, Available at: SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=1311173. Bezemer, D., Grydaki, M., 2014. Financial fragility in the great moderation. J. Bank. Finance 49, 169–177. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2014.09.005. Brunnermeier, M.K., Pedersen, L.H., 2009. Market liquidity and funding liquidity. Rev. Financ. Stud. 22 (6), 2201–2238. https://doi.org/10.1093/rfs/hhn098. Boeri, T., Garibaldi, P., Moen, E.R., 2013. Financial shocks and labor: facts and theories. IMF Econ. Rev. 61 (4), 631–663. https://doi.org/10.1057/imfer.2013.20. Boustanifar, H., 2014. Finance and employment: evidence from US banking reforms. J. Bank. Finance 46, 343–354. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2014.06.006. Boyd, J.H., De Nicolo, G., 2005. The theory of bank risk taking and competition revisited. J. Finance 60 (3), 1329–1343. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1540-6261.2005.00763.x. Bumann, S., Hermes, N., Lensink, R., 2013. Financial liberalization and economic growth: a meta-analysis. J. Int. Money Finance 33, 255–281. https://doi.org/10.1016/ j.jimonfin.2012.11.013. Cazes, S., Verick, S., 2010. What Role for Labour Market Policies and Institutions in Development? Enhancing Security in Developing Countries and Emerging Economies. Employment Working Paper No 67. ILO, Geneva. Chodorow-Reich, G., 2014. The employment effects of credit market disruptions: firmlevel evidence from the 2008–9 financial crisis. Q. J. Econ. 129 (1), 1–59. https:// doi.org/10.1093/qje/qjt031. Clerides, S., Delis, M.D., Kokas, S., 2015. A new data set on competition in national banking markets. Financ. Mark. Inst. Instrum. 24 (2–3), 267–311. https://doi.org/ 10.1111/fmii.12030. Davis, S.J., Haltiwanger, J., 1992. Gross job creation, gross job destruction, and employment reallocation. Q. J. Econ. 107 (3), 819–863. https://doi.org/10.2307/ 2118365. Davis, S.J., Haltiwanger, J., 1999. On the driving forces behind cyclical movements in employment and job reallocation. Am. Econ. Rev. 89 (5), 1234–1258. https:// doi.org/10.1257/aer.89.5.1234. De Graeve, F., Kick, T., Koetter, M., 2008. Monetary policy and financial (in) stability: an integrated micro–macro approach. J. Financ. Stabil. 4 (3), 205–231. https://doi.org/ 10.1016/j.jfs.2007.09.003. 119 M. Chletsos, A. Sintos Economic Modelling 94 (2021) 104–120 Schaeck, K., Cihak, M., Wolfe, S., 2009. Are competitive banking systems more stable? J. Money Credit Bank. 41 (4), 711–734. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.15384616.2009.00228.x. Svirydzenka, K., 2016. IMF Working Paper: Introducing a New Broad-Based Index of Financial Development. INTERNATIONAL MONETARY FUND, USA. https://doi.org/ 10.5089/9781513583709.001. Tymoigne, E., 2012. Financial fragility. In: Handbook of Critical Issues in Finance. Edward Elgar Publishing, Cheltenham, UK. https://doi.org/10.4337/ 9781849805957.00020. Wasmer, E., Weil, P., 2004. The macroeconomics of labor and credit market imperfections. Am. Econ. Rev. 94 (4), 944–963. https://doi.org/10.1257/ 0002828042002525. Winters, L.A., McCulloch, N., McKay, A., 2004. Trade liberalization and poverty: the evidence so far. J. Econ. Lit. 42 (1), 72–115. https://doi.org/10.1257/ 002205104773558056. Wooldridge, J.M., 2010. Econometric Analysis of Cross-Section and Panel Data. MIT press. Yuan, M., Li, W., 2000. Dynamic employment and hours effects of government spending shocks. J. Econ. Dynam. Contr. 24 (8), 1233–1263. https://doi.org/10.1016/S01651889(99)00007-X. Martin, P., Rey, H., 2002. Financial Globalization and Emerging Markets: with or without Crash? (No. W9288). National Bureau of Economic Research. https://doi.org/ 10.3386/w9288. McMillan, M.S., Rodrik, D., 2011. Globalization, Structural Change and Productivity Growth (No. W17143). National Bureau of Economic Research. https://doi.org/ 10.3386/w17143. Mian, A., Sufi, A., 2014. What explains the 2007–2009 drop in employment? Econometrica 82 (6), 2197–2223. https://doi.org/10.3982/ECTA10451. Moghadam, R., 2011. New Growth Drivers for Low-Income Countries: the Role of BRICs. IMF, Strategy, Policy and Review Department, vol. 207. Available at: https ://www.imf.org/external/np/pp/eng/2011/011211.pdf. Pagano, M., Pica, G., 2012. Finance and employment. Econ. Pol. 27 (69), 5–55. https:// doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-0327.2011.00276.x. Rioja, F., Valev, N., 2004. Finance and the sources of growth at various stages of economic development. Econ. Inq. 42 (1), 127–140. https://doi.org/10.1093/ei/cbh049. Rodrik, D., Velasco, A., 1999. Short-term Capital Flows (No. W7364). National Bureau of Economic Research. https://doi.org/10.3386/w7364. Rodrik, D., 2013. The Past, Present and Future of Economic Growth. Working Paper 1, Global Citizen Foundation. Available at: https://www.sss.ias.edu/files/pdfs/Rodrik/ Research/GCF_Rodrik-working-paper-1_-6-24-13.pdf. 120