Uploaded by Nando Fonseca

Data Science Models Algorithms Book - Copy

advertisement
SANJIV RANJAN DAS
D ATA S C I E N C E :
THEORIES,
MODELS,
ALGORITHMS, AND
A N A LY T I C S
S. R. DAS
Copyright © 2013, 2014, 2016 Sanjiv Ranjan Das
published by s. r. das
http://algo.scu.edu/ ∼ sanjivdas/
Licensed under the Apache License, Version 2.0 (the “License”); you may not use this book except in compliance
with the License. You may obtain a copy of the License at http://www.apache.org/licenses/LICENSE-2.0. Unless
required by applicable law or agreed to in writing, software distributed under the License is distributed on an “as
is” basis, without warranties or conditions of any kind, either express or implied. See the License for the
specific language governing permissions and limitations under the License.
This printing, July 2016
T H E F U T U R E I S A L R E A D Y H E R E ; I T ’ S J U S T N O T V E R Y E V E N LY D I S T R I B U T E D .
– WILLIAM GIBSON
T H E P U B L I C I S M O R E FA M I L I A R W I T H B A D D E S I G N T H A N G O O D D E S I G N . I T I S , I N
E F F E C T, C O N D I T I O N E D T O P R E F E R B A D D E S I G N , B E C A U S E T H AT I S W H AT I T L I V E S
W I T H . T H E N E W B E C O M E S T H R E AT E N I N G , T H E O L D R E A S S U R I N G .
– PA U L R A N D
I T S E E M S T H AT P E R F E C T I O N I S AT TA I N E D N O T W H E N T H E R E I S N O T H I N G L E F T T O
A D D, B U T W H E N T H E R E I S N OT H I N G M O R E TO R E M OV E .
– A N T O I N E D E S A I N T- E X U P É R Y
. . . I N G O D W E T R U S T, A L L O T H E R S B R I N G D ATA .
– W I L L I A M E DWA R D S D E M I N G
Acknowledgements: I am extremely grateful to the following friends, students, and readers (mutually non-exclusive) who offered me feedback
on these chapters. I am most grateful to John Heineke for his constant
feedback and continuous encouragement. All the following students
made helpful suggestions on the manuscript: Sumit Agarwal, Kevin
Aguilar, Sankalp Bansal, Sivan Bershan, Ali Burney, Monalisa Chati, JianWei Cheng, Chris Gadek, Karl Hennig, Pochang Hsu, Justin Ishikawa,
Ravi Jagannathan, Alice Yehjin Jun, Seoyoung Kim, Ram Kumar, Federico Morales, Antonio Piccolboni, Shaharyar Shaikh, Jean-Marc Soumet,
Rakesh Sountharajan, Greg Tseng, Dan Wong, Jeffrey Woo.
Contents
1
The Art of Data Science
25
1.1 Volume, Velocity, Variety
27
1.2 Machine Learning
29
1.3 Supervised and Unsupervised Learning
1.4 Predictions and Forecasts
30
1.5 Innovation and Experimentation
1.6 The Dark Side
1.6.1
Big Errors
1.6.2
Privacy
30
31
31
31
32
1.7 Theories, Models, Intuition, Causality, Prediction, Correlation
2
The Very Beginning: Got Math?
41
2.1 Exponentials, Logarithms, and Compounding
2.2 Normal Distribution
43
2.3 Poisson Distribution
43
2.4 Moments of a continuous random variable
2.5 Combining random variables
2.6 Vector Algebra
45
2.7 Statistical Regression
2.8 Diversification
2.9 Matrix Calculus
2.10 Matrix Equations
48
49
50
52
45
41
44
37
6
3
Open Source: Modeling in R
3.1 System Commands
3.2 Loading Data
3.3 Matrices
55
55
56
58
3.4 Descriptive Statistics
59
3.5 Higher-Order Moments
61
3.6 Quick Introduction to Brownian Motions with R
3.7 Estimation using maximum-likelihood
3.8 GARCH/ARCH Models
66
3.10 Portfolio Computations in R
71
3.11 Finding the Optimal Portfolio
3.13 Regression
72
75
77
3.14 Heteroskedasticity
81
3.15 Auto-regressive models
83
3.16 Vector Auto-Regression
86
3.17 Logit
3.18 Probit
90
94
3.19 Solving Non-Linear Equations
95
3.20 Web-Enabling R Functions
4
62
64
3.9 Introduction to Monte Carlo
3.12 Root Solving
61
97
MoRe: Data Handling and Other Useful Things
4.1 Data Extraction of stocks using quantmod
4.2 Using the merge function
103
109
4.3 Using the apply class of functions
114
4.4 Getting interest rate data from FRED
4.5 Cross-Sectional Data (an example)
4.6 Handling dates with lubridate
4.7 Using the data.table package
114
117
121
124
4.8 Another data set: Bay Area Bike Share data
4.9 Using the plyr package family
130
128
103
7
5
Being Mean with Variance: Markowitz Optimization
5.1 Quadratic (Markowitz) Problem
5.1.1
Solution in R
135
137
5.2 Solving the problem with the quadprog package
5.3 Tracing out the Efficient Frontier
5.5 Combinations
141
142
5.6 Zero Covariance Portfolio
143
5.7 Portfolio Problems with Riskless Assets
5.8 Risk Budgeting
143
145
Learning from Experience: Bayes Theorem
6.1 Introduction
149
149
6.2 Bayes and Joint Probability Distributions
6.3 Correlated default (conditional default)
6.4 Continuous and More Formal Exposition
6.5 Bayes Nets
151
152
153
156
6.6 Bayes Rule in Marketing
6.7 Other Applications
7
138
140
5.4 Covariances of frontier portfolios: r p , rq
6
135
159
162
6.7.1
Bayes Models in Credit Rating Transitions
6.7.2
Accounting Fraud
6.7.3
Bayes was a Reverend after all...
162
162
162
More than Words: Extracting Information from News
7.1 Prologue
165
165
7.2 Framework
167
7.3 Algorithms
169
7.3.1
Crawlers and Scrapers
7.3.2
Text Pre-processing
7.3.3
The tm package
7.3.4
Term Frequency - Inverse Document Frequency (TF-IDF)
7.3.5
Wordclouds
7.3.6
Regular Expressions
169
172
175
180
181
178
8
7.4 Extracting Data from Web Sources using APIs
7.4.1
Using Twitter
7.4.2
Using Facebook
7.4.3
Text processing, plain and simple
7.4.4
A Multipurpose Function to Extract Text
184
187
7.5 Text Classification
193
7.5.1
Bayes Classifier
193
7.5.2
Support Vector Machines
7.5.3
Word Count Classifiers
7.5.4
Vector Distance Classifier
7.5.5
Discriminant-Based Classifier
7.5.6
Adjective-Adverb Classifier
7.5.7
Scoring Optimism and Pessimism
7.5.8
Voting among Classifiers
7.5.9
Ambiguity Filters
7.6 Metrics
190
191
198
200
201
202
204
205
206
206
207
7.6.1
Confusion Matrix
7.6.2
Precision and Recall
7.6.3
Accuracy
7.6.4
False Positives
7.6.5
Sentiment Error
7.6.6
Disagreement
7.6.7
Correlations
7.6.8
Aggregation Performance
7.6.9
Phase-Lag Metrics
7.6.10
Economic Significance
7.7 Grading Text
207
208
209
209
210
210
210
211
213
215
215
7.8 Text Summarization
7.9 Discussion
184
216
219
7.10 Appendix: Sample text from Bloomberg for summarization
221
9
8
Virulent Products: The Bass Model
8.1 Introduction
227
8.2 Historical Examples
8.3 The Basic Idea
227
228
8.4 Solving the Model
8.4.1
234
8.7 Sales Peak
8.8 Notes
231
233
8.6 Calibration
9
229
Symbolic math in R
8.5 Software
227
236
238
Extracting Dimensions: Discriminant and Factor Analysis
9.1 Overview
241
9.2 Discriminant Analysis
241
9.2.1
Notation and assumptions
9.2.2
Discriminant Function
9.2.3
How good is the discriminant function?
9.2.4
Caveats
9.2.5
Implementation using R
9.2.6
Confusion Matrix
9.2.7
Multiple groups
242
242
243
244
9.3 Eigen Systems
244
248
249
250
9.4 Factor Analysis
252
9.4.1
Notation
252
9.4.2
The Idea
253
9.4.3
Principal Components Analysis (PCA)
9.4.4
Application to Treasury Yield Curves
9.4.5
Application: Risk Parity and Risk Disparity
9.4.6
Difference between PCA and FA
9.4.7
Factor Rotation
9.4.8
Using the factor analysis function
253
257
260
260
261
260
241
10
10 Bidding it Up: Auctions
10.1 Theory
265
265
10.1.1
Overview
10.1.2
Auction types
10.1.3
Value Determination
10.1.4
Bidder Types
10.1.5
Benchmark Model (BM)
265
266
266
267
10.2 Auction Math
268
10.2.1
Optimization by bidders
10.2.2
Example
269
270
10.3 Treasury Auctions
10.3.1
267
272
DPA or UPA?
272
10.4 Mechanism Design
274
10.4.1
Collusion
10.4.2
Clicks (Advertising Auctions)
10.4.3
Next Price Auctions
10.4.4
Laddered Auction
275
276
278
279
11 Truncate and Estimate: Limited Dependent Variables
11.1 Introduction
11.2 Logit
11.3 Probit
283
284
287
11.4 Analysis
288
11.4.1
Slopes
288
11.4.2
Maximum-Likelihood Estimation (MLE)
11.5 Multinomial Logit
292
293
11.6 Truncated Variables
297
11.6.1
Endogeneity
11.6.2
Example: Women in the Labor Market
301
11.6.3
Endogeity – Some Theory to Wrap Up
303
299
283
11
12 Riding the Wave: Fourier Analysis
12.1 Introduction
305
12.2 Fourier Series
305
12.2.1
Basic stuff
12.2.2
The unit circle
12.2.3
Angular velocity
12.2.4
Fourier series
12.2.5
Radians
12.2.6
Solving for the coefficients
305
305
306
307
307
12.3 Complex Algebra
308
309
12.3.1
From Trig to Complex
12.3.2
Getting rid of a0
12.3.3
Collapsing and Simplifying
12.4 Fourier Transform
12.4.1
305
310
311
311
312
Empirical Example
314
12.5 Application to Binomial Option Pricing
12.6 Application to probability functions
12.6.1
Characteristic functions
12.6.2
Finance application
12.6.3
Solving for the characteristic function
12.6.4
Computing the moments
12.6.5
Probability density function
315
316
316
316
318
318
13 Making Connections: Network Theory
13.1 Overview
321
13.2 Graph Theory
322
13.3 Features of Graphs
13.4 Searching Graphs
323
325
13.4.1
Depth First Search
325
13.4.2
Breadth-first-search
329
317
321
12
13.5 Strongly Connected Components
331
13.6 Dijkstra’s Shortest Path Algorithm
13.6.1
Plotting the network
337
13.7 Degree Distribution
13.8 Diameter
340
13.9 Fragility
341
13.10Centrality
333
338
341
13.11Communities
346
13.11.1 Modularity
348
13.12Word of Mouth
354
13.13Network Models of Systemic Risk
355
13.13.1 Systemic Score, Fragility, Centrality, Diameter
13.13.2 Risk Decomposition
359
13.13.3 Normalized Risk Score
13.13.4 Risk Increments
360
361
13.13.5 Criticality
362
13.13.6 Cross Risk
364
13.13.7 Risk Scaling
355
365
13.13.8 Too Big To Fail?
367
13.13.9 Application of the model to the banking network in India
13.14Map of Science
371
14 Statistical Brains: Neural Networks
14.1 Overview
377
14.2 Nonlinear Regression
14.3 Perceptrons
378
379
14.4 Squashing Functions
381
14.5 How does the NN work?
381
14.5.1
Logit/Probit Model
14.5.2
Connection to hyperplanes
382
14.6 Feedback/Backpropagation
14.6.1
382
382
Extension to many perceptrons
384
377
369
13
14.7 Research Applications
384
14.7.1
Discovering Black-Scholes
14.7.2
Forecasting
384
384
14.8 Package neuralnet in R
14.9 Package nnet in R
384
390
15 Zero or One: Optimal Digital Portfolios
15.1 Modeling Digital Portfolios
15.2 Implementation in R
394
398
15.2.1
Basic recursion
15.2.2
Combining conditional distributions
398
15.3 Stochastic Dominance (SD)
15.4 Portfolio Characteristics
401
404
407
15.4.1
How many assets?
15.4.2
The impact of correlation
15.4.3
Uneven bets?
15.4.4
Mixing safe and risky assets
15.5 Conclusions
393
407
409
410
411
412
16 Against the Odds: Mathematics of Gambling
16.1 Introduction
415
16.1.1
Odds
415
16.1.2
Edge
415
16.1.3
Bookmakers
416
16.2 Kelly Criterion
416
16.2.1
Example
16.2.2
Deriving the Kelly Criterion
16.3 Entropy
415
416
418
421
16.3.1
Linking the Kelly Criterion to Entropy
16.3.2
Linking the Kelly criterion to portfolio optimization
16.3.3
Implementing day trading
422
421
422
14
16.4 Casino Games
423
17 In the Same Boat: Cluster Analysis and Prediction Trees
17.1 Introduction
427
17.2 Clustering using k-means
427
17.2.1
Example: Randomly generated data in kmeans
17.2.2
Example: Clustering of VC financing rounds
17.2.3
NCAA teams
434
17.3 Hierarchical Clustering
17.4 Prediction Trees
436
436
17.4.1
Classification Trees
440
17.4.2
The C4.5 Classifier
442
17.5 Regression Trees
17.5.1
445
Example: Califonia Home Data
18 Bibliography
451
447
430
432
427
List of Figures
1.1 The Four Vs of Big Data.
27
1.2 Google Flu Trends. The figure shows the high correlation between flu incidence and searches
about “flu” on Google. The orange line is actual US flu activity, and the blue line is the
Google Flu Trends estimate.
28
1.3 Profiling can convert mass media into personal media.
33
1.4 If it’s free, you may be the product.
34
1.5 Extracting consumer’s surplus through profiling.
36
3.1
3.2
3.3
3.4
3.5
Single stock path plot simulated from a Brownian motion.
4.1
4.2
4.3
4.4
Plots of the six stock series extracted from the web.
Multiple stock path plot simulated from a Brownian motion.
67
68
Systematic risk as the number of stocks in the portfolio increases.
HTML code for the Rcgi application.
R code for the Rcgi application.
73
98
101
105
Plots of the correlation matrix of six stock series extracted from the web.
Regression of stock average returns against systematic risk (β).
108
109
Google Finance: the AAPL web page showing the URL which is needed to download
the page.
113
4.5 Failed bank totals by year.
122
4.6 Rape totals by year.
126
4.7 Rape totals by county.
129
5.1 The Efficient Frontier
141
6.1 Bayes net showing the pathways of economic distress. There are three channels: a is the
inducement of industry distress from economy distress; b is the inducement of firm distress directly from economy distress; c is the inducement of firm distress directly from
industry distress.
157
6.2 Article from the Scientific American on Bayes’ Theorem.
163
16
7.1 The data and algorithms pyramids. Depicts the inverse relationship between data volume and algorithmic complexity.
169
7.2 Quantity of hourly postings on message boards after selected news releases. Source:
Das, Martinez-Jerez and Tufano (2005).
171
7.3 Subjective evaluation of content of post-news release postings on message boards. The
content is divided into opinions, facts, and questions. Source: Das, Martinez-Jerez and
Tufano (2005).
172
7.4 Frequency of posting by message board participants.
173
7.5 Frequency of posting by day of week by message board participants.
173
7.6 Frequency of posting by segment of day by message board participants. We show the
average number of messages per day in the top panel and the average number of characters per message in the bottom panel.
174
7.7 Example of application of word cloud to the bio data extracted from the web and stored
in a Corpus.
181
7.8 Plot of stock series (upper graph) versus sentiment series (lower graph). The correlation between the series is high. The plot is based on messages from Yahoo! Finance and
is for a single twenty-four hour period.
211
7.9 Phase-lag analysis. The left-side shows the eight canonical graph patterns that are derived from arrangements of the start, end, high, and low points of a time series. The rightside shows the leads and lags of patterns of the stock series versus the sentiment series.
A positive value means that the stock series leads the sentiment series.
214
Actual versus Bass model predictions for VCRs.
228
Actual versus Bass model predictions for answering machines.
229
Example of the adoption rate: m = 100, 000, p = 0.01 and q = 0.2.
231
Example of the adoption rate: m = 100, 000, p = 0.01 and q = 0.2.
232
Computing the Bass model integral using WolframAlpha.
234
Bass model forecast of Apple Inc’s quarterly sales. The current sales are
also overlaid in the plot.
237
8.7 Empirical adoption rates and parameters from the Bass paper.
237
8.8 Increase in peak time with q ↑
240
8.1
8.2
8.3
8.4
8.5
8.6
10.1 Probability density function for the Beta (a = 2, b = 4) distribution.
10.2 Revenue in the DPA and UPA auctions.
273
10.3 Treasury auction markups.
274
10.4 Bid-Ask Spread in the Auction.
275
271
13.1 Comparison of random and scale-free graphs. From Barabasi, Albert-Laszlo., and Eric
Bonabeau (2003). “Scale-Free Networks,” Scientific American May, 50–59.
323
17
13.2 Microsoft academic search tool for co-authorship networks. See: http://academic.research.microsoft.com/.
The top chart shows co-authors, the middle one shows citations, and the last one shows
my Erdos number, i.e., the number of hops needed to be connected to Paul Erdos via
my co-authors. My Erdos number is 3. Interestingly, I am a Finance academic, but my
shortest path to Erdos is through Computer Science co-authors, another field in which
I dabble.
326
13.3 Depth-first-search.
327
13.4 Depth-first search on a simple graph generated from a paired node list.
329
13.5 Breadth-first-search.
330
13.6 Strongly connected components. The upper graph shows the original network and the
lower one shows the compressed network comprising only the SCCs. The algorithm to
determine SCCs relies on two DFSs. Can you see a further SCC in the second graph?
There should not be one.
332
13.7 Finding connected components on a graph.
334
13.8 Dijkstra’s algorithm.
335
13.9 Network for computation of shortest path algorithm
336
13.10Plot using the Fruchterman-Rheingold and Circle layouts
338
13.11Plot of the Erdos-Renyi random graph
339
13.12Plot of the degree distribution of the Erdos-Renyi random graph
340
13.13Interbank lending networks by year. The top panel shows 2005, and the bottom panel
is for the years 2006-2009.
345
13.14Community versus centrality
354
13.15Banking network adjacency matrix and plot
357
13.16Centrality for the 15 banks.
359
13.17Risk Decompositions for the 15 banks.
361
13.18Risk Increments for the 15 banks.
363
13.19Criticality for the 15 banks.
364
13.20Spillover effects.
366
13.21How risk increases with connectivity of the network.
368
13.22How risk increases with connectivity of the network.
370
13.23Screens for selecting the relevant set of Indian FIs to construct the banking network.
13.24Screens for the Indian FIs banking network. The upper plot shows the entire network.
The lower plot shows the network when we mouse over the bank in the middle of the
plot. Red lines show that the bank is impacted by the other banks, and blue lines depict that the bank impacts the others, in a Granger causal manner.
373
13.25Screens for systemic risk metrics of the Indian FIs banking network. The top plot shows
the current risk metrics, and the bottom plot shows the history from 2008.
374
13.26The Map of Science.
375
372
18
14.1 A feed-forward multilayer neural network.
380
14.2 The neural net for the infert data set with two perceptrons in a single hidden layer.
387
15.1 Plot of the final outcome distribution for a digital portfolio with five assets of outcomes
{5, 8, 4, 2, 1} all of equal probability.
400
15.2 Plot of the final outcome distribution for a digital portfolio with five assets of outcomes
{5, 8, 4, 2, 1} with unconditional probability of success of {0.1, 0.2, 0.1, 0.05, 0.15}, respecitvely.
403
15.3 Plot of the difference in distribution for a digital portfolio with five assets when ρ =
0.75 minus that when ρ = 0.25. We use outcomes {5, 8, 4, 2, 1} with unconditional prob-
ability of success of {0.1, 0.2, 0.1, 0.05, 0.15}, respecitvely.
405
15.4 Distribution functions for returns from Bernoulli investments as the number of investments (n) increases. Using the recursion technique we computed the probability distribution of the portfolio payoff for four values of n = {25, 50, 75, 100}. The distribution function is plotted in the left panel. There are 4 plots, one for each n, and if we look
at the bottom left of the plot, the leftmost line is for n = 100. The next line to the right
Ru
is for n = 75, and so on. The right panel plots the value of 0 [ G100 ( x ) − G25 ( x )] dx
for all u ∈ (0, 1), and confirms that it is always negative. The correlation parameter
is ρ = 0.25.
408
15.5 Distribution functions for returns from Bernoulli investments as the correlation parameter (ρ2 ) increases. Using the recursion technique we computed the probability distribution of the portfolio payoff for four values of ρ = {0.09, 0.25, 0.49, 0.81} shown by
the black, red, green and blue lines respectively. The distribution function is plotted in
Ru
the left panel. The right panel plots the value of 0 [ Gρ=0.09 ( x ) − Gρ=0.81 ( x )] dx for all
u ∈ (0, 1), and confirms that it is always negative.
410
16.1 Bankroll evolution under the Kelly rule. The top plot follows the Kelly criterion, but
the other two deviate from it, by overbetting or underbetting the fraction given by Kelly.
The variables are: odds are 4 to 1, implying a house probability of p = 0.2, own probability of winning is p∗ = 0.25.
419
16.2 See http://wizardofodds.com/gambling/house-edge/. The House Edge for various games.
The edge is the same as − f in our notation. The standard deviation is that of the bankroll
of $1 for one bet.
424
17.1 VC Style Clusters.
430
17.2 Two cluster example.
432
17.3 Five cluster example.
433
17.4 NCAA cluster example.
435
17.5 NCAA data, hierarchical cluster example.
437
19
17.6 NCAA data, hierarchical cluster example with clusters on the top two principal components.
438
17.7 Classification tree for the kyphosis data set.
443
17.8 Prediction tree for cars mileage.
448
17.9 California home prices prediction tree.
448
17.10California home prices partition diagram.
449
List of Tables
3.1 Autocorrelation in daily, weekly, and monthly stock index returns. From Lo-Mackinlay,
“A Non-Random Walk Down Wall Street”.
87
3.2 Cross autocorrelations in US stocks. From Lo-Macklinlay, “A Non-Random Walk Down
Wall Street.”
91
7.1 Correlations of Sentiment and Stock Returns for the MSH35 stocks and the aggregated
MSH35 index. Stock returns (STKRET) are computed from close-to-close. We compute
correlations using data for 88 days in the months of June, July and August 2001. Return data over the weekend is linearly interpolated, as messages continue to be posted
over weekends. Daily sentiment is computed from midnight to close of trading at 4 pm
(SENTY4pm).
212
13.1 Summary statistics and the top 25 banks ordered on eigenvalue centrality for 2005. The
R-metric is a measure of whether failure can spread quickly, and this is so when R ≥
2. The diameter of the network is the length of the longest geodesic. Also presented in
the second panel of the table are the centrality scores for 2005 corresponding to Figure
13.13.
344
15.1 Expected utility for Bernoulli portfolios as the number of investments (n) increases. The
table reports the portfolio statistics for n = {25, 50, 75, 100}. Expected utility is given
in the last column. The correlation parameter is ρ = 0.25. The utility function is U (C ) =
(0.1 + C )1−γ /(1 − γ), γ = 3.
409
15.2 Expected utility for Bernoulli portfolios as the correlation (ρ) increases. The table reports the portfolio statistics for ρ = {0.09, 0.25, 0.49, 0.81}. Expected utility is given in
the last column. The utility function is U (C ) = (0.1 + C )1−γ /(1 − γ), γ = 3.
411
22
15.3 Expected utility for Bernoulli portfolios when the portfolio comprises balanced investing in assets versus imbalanced weights. Both the balanced and imbalanced portfolio
have n = 25 assets within them, each with a success probability of qi = 0.05. The first
has equal payoffs, i.e. 1/25 each. The second portfolio has payoffs that monotonically
increase, i.e. the payoffs are equal to j/325, j = 1, 2, . . . , 25. We note that the sum of
the payoffs in both cases is 1. The correlation parameter is ρ = 0.55. The utility function is U (C ) = (0.1 + C )1−γ /(1 − γ), γ = 3.
411
15.4 Expected utility for Bernoulli portfolios when the portfolio comprises balanced investing in assets with identical success probabilities versus investing in assets with mixed
success probabilities. Both the uniform and mixed portfolios have n = 26 assets within
them. In the first portfolio, all the assets have a probability of success equal to qi = 0.10.
In the second portfolio, half the firms have a success probability of 0.05 and the other
half have a probability of 0.15. The payoff of all investments is 1/26. The correlation parameter is ρ = 0.55. The utility function is U (C ) = (0.1 + C )1−γ /(1 − γ), γ = 3.
412
23
Dedicated to Geetu, for decades of fun and friendship
1
The Art of Data Science
— “All models are wrong, but some are useful.”
George E. P. Box and N.R. Draper in “Empirical Model Building and
Response Surfaces,” John Wiley & Sons, New York, 1987.
So you want to be a “data scientist”? There is no widely accepted
definition of who a data scientist is.1 Several books now attempt to
define what data science is and who a data scientist may be, see Patil
(2011), Patil (2012), and Loukides (2012). This book’s viewpoint is that
a data scientist is someone who asks unique, interesting questions of
data based on formal or informal theory, to generate rigorous and useful
insights.2 It is likely to be an individual with multi-disciplinary training in computer science, business, economics, statistics, and armed with
the necessary quantity of domain knowledge relevant to the question at
hand. The potential of the field is enormous for just a few well-trained
data scientists armed with big data have the potential to transform organizations and societies. In the narrower domain of business life, the role
of the data scientist is to generate applicable business intelligence.
Among all the new buzzwords in business – and there are many –
“Big Data” is one of the most often heard. The burgeoning social web,
and the growing role of the internet as the primary information channel
of business, has generated more data than we might imagine. Users upload an hour of video data to YouTube every second.3 87% of the U.S.
population has heard of Twitter, and 7% use it.4 Forty-nine percent of
Twitter users follow some brand or the other, hence the reach is enormous, and, as of 2014, there are more then 500 million tweets a day. But
data is not information, and until we add analytics, it is just noise. And
more, bigger, data may mean more noise and does not mean better data.
In many cases, less is more, and we need models as well. That is what
this book is about, it’s about theories and models, with or without data,
The term “data scientist” was coined
by D.J. Patil. He was the Chief Scientist
for LinkedIn. In 2011 Forbes placed him
second in their Data Scientist List, just
behind Larry Page of Google.
1
To quote Georg Cantor - “In mathematics the art of proposing a question
must be held of higher value than
solving it.”
2
Mayer-Schönberger and Cukier (2013),
p8. They report that USC’s Martin
Hilbert calculated that more than 300
exabytes of data storage was being used
in 2007, an exabyte being one billion
gigabytes, i.e., 1018 bytes, and 260 of
binary usage.
3
In contrast, 88% of the population has
heard of Facebook, and 41% use it. See
4
www.convinceandconvert.com/
7-surprising-statistics-about
-twitter-in-america/. Half of
Twitter users are white, and of the
remaining half, half are black.
26
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
big or small. It’s about analytics and applications, and a scientific approach to using data based on well-founded theory and sound business
judgment. This book is about the science and art of data analytics.
Data science is transforming business. Companies are using medical
data and claims data to offer incentivized health programs to employees. Caesar’s Entertainment Corp. analyzed data for 65,000 employees
and found substantial cost savings. Zynga Inc, famous for its game Farmville, accumulates 25 terabytes of data every day and analyzes it to
make choices about new game features. UPS installed sensors to collect
data on speed and location of its vans, which combined with GPS information, reduced fuel usage in 2011 by 8.4 million gallons, and shaved
85 million miles off its routes.5 McKinsey argues that a successful data
analytics plan contains three elements: interlinked data inputs, analytics
models, and decision-support tools.6 In a seminal paper, Halevy, Norvig
and Pereira (2009), argue that even simple theories and models, with big
data, have the potential to do better than complex models with less data.
In a recent talk7 well-regarded data scientist Hilary Mason emphasized that the creation of “data products” requires three components:
data (of course) plus technical expertise (machine-learning) plus people
and process (talent). Google Maps is a great example of a data product
that epitomizes all these three qualities. She mentioned three skills that
good data scientists need to cultivate: (a) in math and stats, (b) coding,
(c) communication. I would add that preceding all these is the ability to
ask relevant questions, the answers to which unlock value for companies, consumers, and society. Everything in data analytics begins with a
clear problem statement, and needs to be judged with clear metrics.
Being a data scientist is inherently interdisciplinary. Good questions
come from many disciplines, and the best answers are likely to come
from people who are interested in multiple fields, or at least from teams
that co-mingle varied skill sets. Josh Wills of Cloudera stated it well “A data scientist is a person who is better at statistics than any software
engineer and better at software engineering than any statistician.” In
contrast, complementing data scientists are business analytics people,
who are more familiar with business models and paradigms and can ask
good questions of the data.
“How Big Data is Changing the Whole
Equation for Business,” Wall Street
Journal March 8, 2013.
5
“Big Data: What’s Your Plan?” McKinsey Quarterly, March 2013.
6
At the h2o world conference in the Bay
Area, on 11th November 2015.
7
the art of data science
27
1.1 Volume, Velocity, Variety
There are several "V"s of big data: three of these are volume, velocity,
variety.8 Big data exceeds the storage capacity of conventional databases.
This is it’s volume aspect. The scale of data generation is mind-boggling.
Google’s Eric Schmidt pointed out that until 2003, all of human kind had
generated just 5 exabytes of data (an exabyte is 10006 bytes or a billionbillion bytes). Today we generate 5 exabytes of data every two days.
The main reason for this is the explosion of “interaction” data, a new
phenomenon in contrast to mere “transaction” data. Interaction data
comes from recording activities in our day-to-day ever more digital lives,
such as browser activity, geo-location data, RFID data, sensors, personal
digital recorders such as the fitbit and phones, satellites, etc. We now live
in the “internet of things” (or iOT), and it’s producing a wild quantity of
data, all of which we seem to have an endless need to analyze. In some
quarters it is better to speak of 4 Vs of big data, as shown in Figure 1.1.
This nomenclature was originated by
the Gartner group in 2001, and has been
in place more than a decade.
8
Figure 1.1: The Four Vs of Big Data.
A good data scientist will be adept at managing volume not just technically in a database sense, but by building algorithms to make intelli-
28
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
gent use of the size of the data as efficiently as possible. Things change
when you have gargantuan data because almost all correlations become
significant, and one might be tempted to draw spurious conclusions
about causality. For many modern business applications today extraction
of correlation is sufficient, but good data science involves techniques that
extract causality from these correlations as well.
In many cases, detecting correlations is useful as is. For example, consider the classic case of Google Flu Trends, see Figure 1.2. The figure
shows the high correlation between flu incidence and searches about
“flu” on Google, see Ginsberg et. al. (2009). Obviously searches on the
key word “flu” do not result in the flu itself! Of course, the incidence of
searches on this key word is influenced by flu outbreaks. The interesting
point here is that even though searches about flu do not cause flu, they
correlate with it, and may at times even be predictive of it, simply because
searches lead the actual reported levels of flu, as those may occur concurrently but take time to be reported. And whereas searches may be predictive, the cause of searches is the flu itself, one variable feeding on the
other, in a repeat cycle.9 Hence, prediction is a major outcome of correlation, and has led to the recent buzz around the subfield of “predictive
analytics.” There are entire conventions devoted to this facet of correlation, such as the wildly popular PAW (Predictive Analytics World).10
Pattern recognition is in, passe causality is out.
Interwoven time series such as these
may be modeled using Vector AutoRegressions, a technique we will encounter later in this book.
9
May be a futile collection of people,
with non-working crystal balls, as
William Gibson said - “The future is not
google-able.”
10
Figure 1.2: Google Flu Trends. The
figure shows the high correlation
between flu incidence and searches
about “flu” on Google. The orange
line is actual US flu activity, and
the blue line is the Google Flu
Trends estimate.
Data velocity is accelerating. Streams of tweets, Facebook entries, financial information, etc., are being generated by more users at an ever
increasing pace. Whereas velocity increases data volume, often exponentially, it might shorten the window of data retention or application. For
example, high-frequency trading relies on micro-second information and
streams of data, but the relevance of the data rapidly decays.
the art of data science
29
Finally, data variety is much greater than ever before. Models that
relied on just a handful of variables can now avail of hundreds of variables, as computing power has increased. The scale of change in volume,
velocity, and variety of the data that is now available calls for new econometrics, and a range of tools for even single questions. This book aims to
introduce the reader to a variety of modeling concepts and econometric
techniques that are essential for a well-rounded data scientist.
Data science is more than the mere analysis of large data sets. It is
also about the creation of data. The field of “text-mining” expands available data enormously, since there is so much more text being generated
than numbers. The creation of data from varied sources, and its quantification into information is known as “datafication.”
1.2 Machine Learning
Data science is also more than “machine learning,” which is about how
systems learn from data. Systems may be trained on data to make decisions, and training is a continuous process, where the system updates its
learning and (hopefully) improves its decision-making ability with more
data. A spam filter is a good example of machine learning. As we feed
it more data it keeps changing its decision rules, using a Bayesian filter,
thereby remaining ahead of the spammers. It is this ability to adaptively
learn that prevents spammers from gaming the filter, as highlighted in
Paul Graham’s interesting essay titled “A Plan for Spam”.11 Credit card
approvals are also based on neural-nets, another popular machine learning technique. However, machine-learning techniques favor data over
judgment, and good data science requires a healthy mix of both. Judgment is needed to accurately contextualize the setting for analysis and
to construct effective models. A case in point is Vinny Bruzzese, known
as the “mad scientist of Hollywood” who uses machine learning to predict movie revenues.12 He asserts that mere machine learning would be
insufficient to generate accurate predictions. He complements machine
learning with judgment generated from interviews with screenwriters,
surveys, etc., “to hear and understand the creative vision, so our analysis
can be contextualized.”
Machine intelligence is re-emerging as the new incarnation of AI (a
field that many feel has not lived up to its promise). Machine learning
promises and has delivered on many questions of interest, and is also
11
http://www.paulgraham.com/spam.html.
“Solving Equation of a Hit Film
Script, With Data,” New York Times, May
5, 2013.
12
30
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
proving to be quite a game-changer, as we will see later on in this chapter, and also as discussed in many preceding examples. What makes it
so appealing? Hilary Mason suggests four characteristics of machine intelligence that make it interesting: (i) It is usually based on a theoretical
breakthrough and is therefore well grounded in science. (ii) It changes
the existing economic paradigm. (iii) The result is commoditization (e.g.
Hadoop), and (iv) it makes available new data that leads to further data
science.
1.3 Supervised and Unsupervised Learning
Systems may learn in two broad ways, through “supervised” and “unsupervised” learning. In supervised learning, a system produces decisions
(outputs) based on input data. Both spam filters and automated credit
card approval systems are examples of this type of learning. So is linear discriminant analysis (LDA). The system is given a historical data
sample of inputs and known outputs, and it “learns” the relationship
between the two using machine learning techniques, of which there are
several. Judgment is needed to decide which technique is most appropriate for the task at hand.
Unsupervised learning is a process of reorganizing and enhancing the
inputs in order to place structure on unlabeled data. A good example is
cluster analysis, which takes a collection of entities, each with a number
of attributes, and partitions the entity space into sets or groups based on
closeness of the attributes of all entities. What this does is reorganizes
the data, but it also enhances the data through a process of labeling the
data with additional tags (in this case a cluster number/name). Factor
analysis is also an unsupervised learning technique. The origin of this
terminology is unclear, but it presumably arises from the fact that there
is no clear objective function that is maximized or minimized in unsupervised learning, so that no “supervision” to reach an optimal is called
for. However, this is not necessarily true in general, and we will see examples of unsupervised learning (such as community detection in the
social web) where the outcome depends on measurable objective criteria.
1.4 Predictions and Forecasts
Data science is about making predictions and forecasts. There is a difference between the two. The statistician-economist Paul Saffo has sug-
the art of data science
31
gested that predictions aim to identify one outcome, whereas forecasts
encompass a range of outcomes. To say that “it will rain tomorrow” is
to make a prediction, but to say that “the chance of rain is 40%” (implying that the chance of no rain is 60%) is to make a forecast, as it lays
out the range of possible outcomes with probabilities. We make weather
forecasts, not predictions. Predictions are statements of great certainty,
whereas forecasts exemplify the range of uncertainty. In the context of
these definitions, the term predictive analytics is a misnomer for it’s goal
is to make forecasts, not mere predictions.
1.5 Innovation and Experimentation
Data science is about new ideas and approaches. It merges new concepts
with fresh algorithms. Take for example the A/B test, which is nothing
but the online implementation of a real-time focus group. Different subsets of users are exposed to A and B stimuli respectively, and responses
are measured and analyzed. It is widely used for web site design. This
approach has been in place for more than a decade, and in 2011 Google
ran more than 7,000 A/B tests. Facebook, Amazon, Netflix, and several others firms use A/B testing widely.13 The social web has become
a teeming ecosystem for running social science experiments. The potential to learn about human behavior using innovative methods is much
greater now than ever before.
“The A/B Test: Inside the Technology
that’s Changing the Rules of Business,”
by Brian Christian, Wired, April 2012.
13
1.6 The Dark Side
1.6.1 Big Errors
The good data scientist will take care to not over-reach in drawing conclusions from big data. Because there are so many variables available,
and plentiful observations, correlations are often statistically significant,
but devoid of basis. In the immortal words of the bard, empirical results
from big data may be - “A tale told by an idiot, full of sound and fury,
signifying nothing.” 14 One must be careful not to read too much in the
data. More data does not guarantee less noise, and signal extraction may
be no easier than with less data.
Adding more columns (variables in the cross section) to the data set,
but not more rows (time dimension) is also fraught with danger. As
the number of variables increases, more characteristics are likely to be
14
William Shakespeare in Macbeth, Act
V, Scene V.
32
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
related statistically. Over fitting models in-sample is much more likely
with big data, leading to poor performance out-of-sample.
Researchers have also to be careful to explore the data fully, and not
terminate their research the moment a viable result, especially one that
the researcher is looking for, is attained. With big data, the chances of
stopping at a suboptimal, or worse, intuitively appealing albeit wrong
result become very high. It is like asking a question to a class of students. In a very large college class, the chance that someone will provide
a plausible yet off-base answer quickly is very high, which often short
circuits the opportunity for others in class to think more deeply about
the question and provide a much better answer.
Nassim Taleb15 describes these issues elegantly - “I am not saying
there is no information in big data. There is plenty of information. The
problem – the central issue – is that the needle comes in an increasingly
larger haystack.” The fact is, one is not always looking for needles or
Taleb’s black swans, and there are plenty of normal phenomena about
which robust forecasts are made possible by the presence of big data.
1.6.2
Privacy
The emergence of big data coincides with a gigantic erosion of privacy.
Human kind has always been torn between the need for social interaction, and the urge for solitude and privacy. One trades off against the
other. Technology has simply sharpened the divide and made the slope
of this trade off steeper. It has provided tools of social interaction that
steal privacy much faster than in the days before the social web.
Rumors and gossip are now old world. They required bilateral transmission. The social web provides multilateral revelation, where privacy
no longer capitulates a battle at a time, but the entire war is lost at one
go. And data science is the tool that enables firms, governments, individuals, benefactors and predators, et al, en masse, to feed on privacy’s
carcass. The cartoon in Figure 1.3 parodies the kind of information specialization that comes with the loss of privacy!
The loss of privacy is manifested in the practice of human profiling
through data science. Our web presence increases entropically as we
move more of our life’s interactions to the web, be they financial, emotional, organizational, or merely social. And as we live more and more
of our lives in this new social melieu, data mining and analytics enables
companies to construct very accurate profiles of who we are, often better
“Beware the Big Errors of Big Data”
Wired, February 2013.
15
the art of data science
Figure 1.3: Profiling can convert
mass media into personal media.
than what we might do ourselves. We are moving from "know thyself" to
knowing everything about almost everyone.
If you have a Facebook or Twitter presence, rest assured you have
been profiled. For instance, let’s say you tweeted that you were taking
your dog for a walk. Profiling software now increments your profile
with an additional tag - pet owner. An hour later you tweet that you are
returning home to cook dinner for your kids. You profile is now further
tagged as a parent. As you might imagine, even a small Twitter presence
ends up being dramatically revealing about who you are. Information
that you provide on Facebook and Twitter, your credit card spending
pattern, and your blog, allows the creation of a profile that is accurate
and comprehensive, and probably more objective than the subjective
and biased opinion that you have of yourself. A machine knows thyself
better. And you are the product! (See Figure 1.4.)
Humankind leaves an incredible trail of “digital exhaust” comprising
phone calls, emails, tweets, GPS information, etc., that companies use for
profiling. It is said that 1/3 of people have a digital identity before being
born, initiated with the first sonogram from a routine hospital visit by
an expectant mother. The half life of non-digital identity, or the average
33
34
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
Figure 1.4: If it’s free, you may be
the product.
age of digital birth is six months, and within two years 92% of the US
population has a digital identity.16 Those of us who claim to be safe from
revealing their privacy by avoiding all forms of social media are simply
profiled as agents with a “low digital presence.” It might be interesting
to ask such people whether they would like to reside in a profile bucket
that is more likely to attract government interest than a profile bucket
with more average digital presence. In this age of profiling, the best
way to remain inconspicuous is not to hide, but to remain as average as
possible, so as to be mostly lost within a large herd.
Privacy is intricately and intrinsically connected to security and efficiency. The increase in transacting on the web, and the confluence of profiling, has led to massive identity theft. Just as in the old days, when a
thief picked your lock and entered your home, most of your possessions
were at risk. It is the same with electronic break ins, except that there are
many more doors to break in from and so many more windows through
which an intruder can unearth revealing information. And unlike a thief
who breaks into your home, a hacker can reside in your electronic abode
for quite some time without being detected, an invisible parasite slowly
doing damage. While you are blind, you are being robbed blind. And
unlike stealing your worldly possessions, stealing your very persona and
identity is the cruelest cut of them all.
See “The Human Face of Big Data” by
Rick Smolan and Jennifer Erwitt.
16
the art of data science
An increase in efficiency in the web ecosystem comes too at some
retrenchment of privacy. Who does not shop on the internet? Each transaction resides in a separate web account. These add up at an astonishing
pace. I have no idea of the exact number of web accounts in my name,
but I am pretty sure it is over a hundred, many of them used maybe just
once. I have unconsciously, yet quite willingly, marked my territory all
over the e-commerce landscape. I rationalize away this loss of privacy in
the name of efficiency, which undoubtedly exists. Every now and then I
am reminded of this loss of privacy as my plane touches down in New
York city, and like clockwork, within an hour or two, I receive a discount
coupon in my email from Barnes & Noble bookstores. You see, whenever
I am in Manhattan, I frequent the B&N store on the upper west side, and
my credit card company and/or Google knows this, as well as my air
travel schedule, since I buy both tickets and books on the same card and
in the same browser. So when I want to buy books at a store discount,
I fly to New York. That’s how rational I am, or how rational my profile
says I am! Humor aside, such profiling seems scary, though the thought
quickly passes. I like the dopamine rush I get from my discount coupon
and I love buying books.17
Profiling implies a partitioning of the social space into targeted groups,
so that focused attention may be paid to specific groups, or various
groups may be treated differently through price discrimination. If my
profile shows me to be an affluent person who likes fine wine (both
facts untrue in my case, but hope springs eternal), then internet sales
pitches (via Groupon, Living Social, etc.) will be priced higher to me by
an online retailer than to someone whose profile indicates a low spend.
Profiling enables retailers to maximize revenues by eating away the consumer’s surplus by better setting of prices to each buyer’s individual
willingness to pay. This is depicted in Figure 1.5.
In Figure 1.5 the demand curve is represented by the line segment
ABC representing price-quantity combinations (more is demanded at
lower prices). In a competitive market without price segmentation, let’s
assume that the equilibrium price is P and equilibrium quantity is Q
as shown by the point B on the demand curve. (The upward sloping
supply curve is not shown but it must intersect the demand curve at
point B, of course.) Total revenue to the seller is the area OPBQ, i.e.,
P × Q.
Now assume that the seller is able to profile buyers so that price dis-
35
I also like writing books, but I am
much better at buying them, and some
what less better at reading them!
17
36
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
Figure 1.5: Extracting consumer’s
surplus through profiling.
Price A Consumer’s surplus B P Missed sales O Q C Quan'ty (Q) crimination is possible. Based on buyers’ profiles, the seller will offer
each buyer the price he is willing to pay on the demand curve, thereby
picking off each price in the segment AB. This enables the seller to capture the additional region ABP, which is the area of consumer’s surplus,
i.e., the difference between the price that buyers pay versus the price
they were actually willing to pay. The seller may also choose to offer
some consumers lower prices in the region BC of the demand curve so
as to bring in additional buyers whose threshold price lies below the
competitive market price P. Thus, profiling helps sellers capture consumer’s surplus and eat into the region of missed sales. Targeting brings
benefits to sellers and they actively pursue it. The benefits outweigh the
costs of profiling, and the practice is widespread as a result. Profiling
also makes price segmentation fine-tuned, and rather than break buyers into a few segments, usually two, each profile becomes a separate
segment, and the granularity of price segmentation is modulated by the
number of profiling groups the seller chooses to model.
Of course, there is an insidious aspect to profiling, which has existed
for quite some time, such as targeting conducted by tax authorities. I
the art of data science
don’t believe we will take kindly to insurance companies profiling us
any more than they already do. Profiling is also undertaken to snare terrorists. However, there is a danger in excessive profiling. A very specific
profile for a terrorist makes it easier for their ilk to game detection as
follows. Send several possible suicide bombers through airport security
and see who is repeatedly pulled aside for screening and who is not.
Repeating this exercise enables a terrorist cell to learn which candidates
do not fall into the profile. They may then use them for the execution of
a terror act, as they are unlikely to be picked up for special screening.
The antidote? Randomization of people picked for special screening in
searches at airports, which makes it hard for a terrorist to always assume
no likelihood of detection through screening.18
Automated invasions of privacy naturally lead to a human response,
not always rational or predictable. This is articulated in Campbell’s Law:
“The more any quantitative social indicator (or even some qualitative
indicator) is used for social decision-making, the more subject it will
be to corruption pressures and the more apt it will be to distort and
corrupt the social processes it is intended to monitor.” 19 We are in for
an interesting period of interaction between man and machine, where
the battle for privacy will take center stage.
18
37
See
http://acfnewsource.org.s60463.
gridserver.com/science/random
security.html, also aired on KRON-
TV, San Francisco, 2/3/2003.
19
See: http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/
Campbell’s law.
1.7 Theories, Models, Intuition, Causality, Prediction, Correlation
My view of data science is one where theories are implemented using
data, some of it big data. This is embodied in an inference stack comprising (in sequence): theories, models, intuition, causality, prediction,
and correlation. The first three constructs in this chain are from Emanuel
Derman’s wonderful book on the pitfalls of models.20
Theories are statements of how the world should be or is, and are
derived from axioms that are assumptions about the world, or precedent
theories. Models are implementations of theory, and in data science are
often algorithms based on theories that are run on data. The results of
running a model lead to intuition, i.e., a deeper understanding of the
world based on theory, model, and data. Whereas there are schools of
thought that suggest data is all we need, and theory is obsolete, this
author disagrees. Still the unreasonable proven effectiveness of big data
cannot be denied. Chris Anderson argues in his Wired magazine article
“Models. Behaving. Badly.” Emanuel
Derman, Free Press, New York, 2011.
20
38
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
thus:”21
“The End of Theory: The Data Deluge
Makes the Scientific Method Obsolete.”
Wired, v16(7), 23rd June, 2008.
21
Sensors everywhere. Infinite storage. Clouds of processors. Our
ability to capture, warehouse, and understand massive amounts
of data is changing science, medicine, business, and technology.
As our collection of facts and figures grows, so will the opportunity to find answers to fundamental questions. Because in the
era of big data, more isn’t just more. More is different.
In contrast, the academic Thomas Davenport writes in his foreword
to Seigel (2013) that models are key, and should not be increasingly eschewed with increasing data:
But the point of predictive analytics is not the relative size or
unruliness of your data, but what you do with it. I have found
that “big data often means small math,” and many big data
practitioners are content just to use their data to create some
appealing visual analytics. That’s not nearly as valuable as
creating a predictive model.
Once we have established intuition for the results of a model, it remains to be seen whether the relationships we observe are causal, predictive, or merely correlational. Theory may be causal and tested as
such. Granger (1969) causality is often stated in mathematical form
for two stationary22 time series of data as follows. X is said to Granger
cause Y if in the following equation system,
Y (t) = a1 + b1 Y (t − 1) + c1 X (t − 1) + e1
X (t) = a2 + b2 Y (t − 1) + c2 X (t − 1) + e2
the coefficient c1 is significant and b2 is not significant. Hence, X causes
Y, but not vice versa. Causality is a hard property to establish, even with
theoretical foundation, as the causal effect has to be well-entrenched in
the data.
We have to be careful to impose judgment as much as possible since
statistical relationships may not always be what they seem. A variable
may satisfy the Granger causality regressions above but may not be
causal. For example, we earlier encountered the flu example in Google
Trends. If we denote searches for flu as X, and the outbreak of flu as
Y, we may see a Granger cause relation between flu and searches for
it. This does not mean that searching for flu causes flu, yet searches are
predictive of flu. This is the essential difference between prediction and
causality.
A series is stationary if the probability
distribution from which the observations are drawn is the same at all points
in time.
22
the art of data science
And then there is correlation, at the end of the data science inference
chain. Contemporaneous movement between two variables is quantified using correlation. In many cases, we uncover correlation, but no
prediction or causality. Correlation has great value to firms attempting
to tease out beneficial information from big data. And even though it is
a linear relationship between variables, it lays the groundwork for uncovering nonlinear relationships, which are becoming easier to detect
with more data. The surprising parable about Walmart finding that purchases of beer and diapers seem to be highly correlated resulted in these
two somewhat oddly-paired items being displayed on the same aisle in
supermarkets.23 Unearthing correlations of sales items across the population quickly lead to different business models aimed at exploiting these
correlations, such as my book buying inducement from Barnes & Noble,
where my “fly and buy” predilection is easily exploited. Correlation is
often all we need, eschewing human cravings for causality. As MayerSchönberger and Cukier (2013) so aptly put it, we are satisfied “... not
knowing why but only what.”
In the data scientist mode of thought, relationships are multifaceted
correlations amongst people. Facebook, Twitter, and many other platforms are datafying human relationships using graph theory, exploiting
the social web in an attempt to understand better how people relate to
each other, with the goal of profiting from it. We use correlations on
networks to mine the social graph, understanding better how different
social structures may be exploited. We answer questions such as where
to seed a new marketing campaign, which members of a network are
more important than the others, how quickly will information spread on
the network, i.e., how strong is the “network effect”?
Data science is about the quantization and understanding of human
behavior, the holy grail of social science. In the following chapters we
will explore a wide range of theories, techniques, data, and applications
of a multi-faceted paradigm. We will also review the new technologies
developed for big data and data science, such as distributed computing
using the Dean and Ghemawat (2004) MapReduce paradigm developed
at Google,24 and implemented as the open source project Hadoop at Yahoo!.25 When data gets super sized, it is better to move algorithms to the
data than the other way around. Just as big data has inverted database
paradigms, so is big data changing the nature of inference in the study
of human behavior. Ultimately, data science is a way of thinking, for
23
http://www.theregister.co.uk/
2006/08/15/beer diapers/.
24
http://research.google.com/
archive/mapreduce.html
25
http://hadoop.apache.org/
39
40
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
social scientists, using computer science.
2
The Very Beginning: Got Math?
Business analytics requires the use of various quantitative tools, from
algebra and calculus, to statistics and econometrics, with implementations in various programming languages and software. It calls for technical expertise as well as good judgment, and the ability to ask insightful
questions and to deploy data towards answering the questions.
The presence of the web as the primary platform for business and
marketing has spawned huge quantities of data, driving firms to attempt
to exploit vast stores of information in honing their competitive edge. As
a consequence, firms in Silicon Valley (and elsewhere) are hiring a new
breed of employee known as “data scientist” whose role is to analyze
“Big Data” using tools such as the ones you will learn in this course.
This chapter will review some of the mathematics, statistics, linear algebra, and calculus you might have not used in many years. It is more
fun than it looks. We will also learn to use some mathematical packages
along the way. We’ll revisit some standard calculations and analyses that
you will have encountered in previous courses you might have taken.
You will refresh some old concepts, learn new ones, and become technically adept with the tools of the trade.
2.1 Exponentials, Logarithms, and Compounding
It is fitting to begin with the fundamental mathematical constant, “e =
2.718281828...”, which is also the function “exp(·)”. We often write this
function as e x , where x can be a real or complex variable. It shows up
in many places, especially in Finance, where it is used for continuous
compounding and discounting of money at a given interest rate r over
some time horizon t.
Given y = e x , a fixed change in x results in the same continuous
42
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
percentage change in y. This is because ln(y) = x, where ln(·) is the
natural logarithm function, and is the inverse function of the exponential
dy
function. Recall also that the first derivative of this function is dx = e x ,
i.e., the function itself.
The constant e is defined as the limit of a specific function:
e = lim
n→∞
1
1+
n
n
Exponential compounding is the limit of successively shorter intervals
over discrete compounding. Given a horizon t divided into n intervals per year, one dollar compounded from time zero to time t years
nt
over these n intervals at per annum rate r may be written as 1 + nr .
Continuous-compounding is the limit of this equation when the number
of periods n goes to infinity:
lim
n→∞
r nt
= lim
1+
n→∞
n
"
1
1+
n/r
n/r #tr
= ert
This is the forward value of one dollar. Present value is just the reverse.
Therefore, the price today of a dollar received t years from today is P =
e−rt . The yield of a bond is:
1
r = − ln( P)
t
In bond mathematics, the negative of the percentage price sensitivity
of a bond to changes in interest rates is known as “Duration”:
dP 1
1
−rt 1
−
= − −te
= tP = t.
dr P
P
P
The derivative dP
dr is the price sensitivity of the bond to changes in interest rates, and is negative. Further dividing this by P gives the percentage
price sensitivity. The minus sign in front of the definition of duration is
applied to convert the negative number to a positive one.
The “Convexity” of a bond is its percentage price sensitivity relative to
the second derivative, i.e.,
1
d2 P 1
= t2 P = t2 .
2
P
dr P
Because the second derivative is positive, we know that the bond pricing
function is convex.
the very beginning: got math?
2.2 Normal Distribution
This distribution is the workhorse of many models in the social sciences,
and is assumed to generate much of the data that comprises the Big Data
universe. Interestingly, most phenomena (variables) in the real world
are not normally distributed. They tend to be “power law” distributed,
i.e., many observations of low value, and very few of high value. The
probability distribution declines from left to right and does not have the
characteristic hump shape of the normal distribution. An example of
data that is distributed thus is income distribution (many people with
low income, very few with high income). Other examples are word frequencies in languages, population sizes of cities, number of connections
of people in a social network, etc.
Still, we do need to learn about the normal distribution because it is
important in statistics, and the central limit theorem does govern much
of the data we look at. Examples of approximately normally distributed
data are stock returns, and human heights.
If x ∼ N (µ, σ2 ), that is, x is normally distributed with mean µ and
variance σ2 , then the probability “density” function for x is:
1 ( x − µ )2
1
exp −
f (x) = √
2
σ2
2πσ2
The cumulative probability is given by the “distribution” function
F(x) =
and
Z x
−∞
f (u)du
F ( x ) = 1 − F (− x )
because the normal distribution is symmetric. We often also use the
notation N (·) or Φ(·) instead of F (·).
The “standard normal” distribution is: x ∼ N (0, 1). For the standard
normal distribution: F (0) = 12 . The normal distribution has continuous
support, i.e., a range of values of x that goes continuously from −∞ to
+∞.
2.3 Poisson Distribution
The Poisson is also known as the rare-event distribution. Its density
function is:
e−λ λn
f (n; λ) =
n!
43
44
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
where there is only one parameter, i.e., the mean λ. The density function
is over discrete values of n, the number of occurrences given the mean
number of outcomes λ. The mean and variance of the Poisson distribution are both λ. The Poisson is a discrete-support distribution, with a
range of values n = {0, 1, 2, . . .}.
2.4 Moments of a continuous random variable
The following formulae are useful to review because any analysis of data
begins with descriptive statistics, and the following statistical “moments”
are computed in order to get a first handle on the data. Given a random
variable x with probability density function f ( x ), then the following are
the first four moments.
Mean (first moment or average) = E( x ) =
Z
x f ( x )dx
In like fashion, powers of the variable result in higher (n-th order) moments. These are “non-central” moments, i.e., they are moments of the
raw random variable x, not its deviation from its mean, i.e., [ x − E( x )].
nth moment = E( x n ) =
Z
x n f ( x )dx
Central moments are moments of de-meaned random variables. The
second central moment is the variance:
Variance = Var ( x ) = E[ x − E( x )]2 = E( x2 ) − [ E( x )]2
The standard deviation is the square-root of the variance, i.e., σ =
p
Var ( x ). The third central moment, normalized by the standard deviation to a suitable power is the skewness:
Skewness =
E[ x − E( x )]3
Var ( x )3/2
The absolute value of skewness relates to the degree of asymmetry in
the probability density. If more extreme values occur to the left than the
right, the distribution is left-skewed. And vice-versa, the distribution is
right-skewed.
Correspondingly, the fourth central, normalized moment is kurtosis.
Kurtosis =
E[ x − E( x )]4
[Var ( x )]2
the very beginning: got math?
Kurtosis in the normal distribution has value 3. We define “Excess Kurtosis” to be Kurtosis minus 3. When a probability distribution has positive excess kurtosis we call it “leptokurtic”. Such distributions have fatter
tails (either or both sides) than a normal distribution.
2.5 Combining random variables
Since we often have to deal with composites of random variables, i.e.,
more than one random variable, we review here some simple rules for
moments of combinations of random variables. There are several other
expressions for the same equations, but we examine just a few here, as
these are the ones we will use more frequently.
First, we see that means are additive and scalable, i.e.,
E( ax + by) = aE( x ) + bE(y)
where x, y are random variables, and a, b are scalar constants. The variance of scaled, summed random variables is as follows:
Var ( ax + by) = a2 Var ( x ) + b2 Var (y) + 2abCov( x, y)
(2.1)
And the covariance and correlation between two random variables is
Cov( x, y) = E( xy) − E( x ) E(y)
Cov( x, y)
Corr ( x, y) = p
Var ( x )Var (y)
Students of finance will be well-versed with these expressions. They are
facile and easy to implement.
2.6 Vector Algebra
We will be using linear algebra in many of the models that we explore
in this book. Linear algebra requires the manipulation of vectors and
matrices. We will also use vector calculus. Vector algebra and calculus
are very powerful methods for tackling problems that involve solutions
in spaces of several variables, i.e., in high dimension. The parsimony of
using vector notation will become apparent as we proceed. This introduction is very light and meant for the reader who is mostly uninitiated
in linear algebra.
Rather than work with an abstract exposition, it is better to introduce
ideas using an example. We’ll examine the use of vectors in the context
45
46
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
of stock portfolios. We define the returns for each stock in a portfolio as:


R1


 R2 



R=
 : 


 : 
RN
This is a random vector, because each return Ri , i = 1, 2, . . . , N comes
from its own distribution, and the returns of all these stocks are correlated. This random vector’s probability is represented as a joint or multivariate probability distribution. Note that we use a bold font to denote
the vector R.
We also define a Unit vector:
 
1
 
 1 
 

1=
 : 
 
 : 
1
The use of this unit vector will become apparent shortly, but it will be
used in myriad ways and is a useful analytical object.
A portfolio vector is defined as a set of portfolio weights, i.e., the fraction of the portfolio that is invested in each stock:


w1


 w2 



w=
 : 


 : 
wN
The total of portfolio weights must add up to 1.
N
∑ wi = 1,
w0 1 = 1
i =1
Pay special attention to the line above. In it, there are two ways in which
to describe the sum of portfolio weights. The first one uses summation
notation, and the second one uses a simple vector algebraic statement,
i.e., that the transpose of w, denoted w0 times the unit vector 1 equals 1.1
The two elements on the left-hand-side of the equation are vectors, and
the 1 on the right hand side is a scalar. The dimension of w0 is (1 × N )
Often, the notation for transpose is
to superscript T, and in this case we
would write this as w> . We may use
either notation in the rest of the book.
1
the very beginning: got math?
and the dimension of 1 is ( N × 1). And a (1 × N ) vector multiplied by a
( N × 1) results in a (1 × 1) vector, i.e., a scalar.
We may also invest in a risk free asset (denoted as asset zero, i = 0),
with return R0 = r f . In this case, the total portfolio weights including
that of the risk free asset must sum to 1, and the weight w0 is:
N
w0 = 1 − ∑ w i = 1 − w > 1
i =1
Now we can use vector notation to compute statistics and quantities of
the portfolio. The portfolio return is
N
Rp =
∑ wi R i = w 0 R
i =1
Again, note that the left-hand-side quantity is a scalar, and the two righthand-side quantities are vectors. Since R is a random vector, R p is a
random (scalar, i.e., not a vector, of dimension 1 × 1) variable. Such a
product is called a scalar product of two vectors. In order for the calculation to work, the two vectors or matrices must be “conformable” i.e., the
inner dimensions of the matrices must be the same. In this case we are
multiplying w0 of dimension 1 × N with R of dimension N × 1 and since
the two “inside” dimensions are both n, the calculation is proper as the
matrices are conformable. The result of the calculation will take the size
of the “outer” dimensions, i.e., in this case 1 × 1. Now, suppose
R ∼ MV N [µ; Σ]
That is, returns are multivariate normally distributed with mean vector
E[R] = µ = [µ1 , µ2 , . . . , µ N ]0 ∈ R N and covariance matrix Σ ∈ R N × N . The
notation R N stands for a “real-valued matrix of dimension N.” If it’s just
N, then it means a vector of dimension N. If it’s written as N × M, then
it’s a matrix of that dimension, i.e., N rows and M columns.
We can write the portfolio’s mean return as:
E[w0 R] = w0 E[R] = w0 µ =
N
∑ wi µ i
i =1
The portfolio’s return variance is
Var ( R p ) = Var (w0 R) = w0 Σw
Showing why this is true is left as an exercise to the reader. Take a case
where N = 2 and write out the expression for the variance of the portfolio using equation 2.1. Then also undertake the same calculation using
47
48
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
the variance formula w0 Σw and see the equivalence. Also note carefully
that this expression works because Σ is a symmetric matrix. The multivariate normal density function is:
1
1
0
−
1
p
exp − ( R − µ) Σ ( R − µ)
f (R) =
2
2π N/2 |Σ|
Now, we take a look at some simple applications expressed in terms of
vector notation.
2.7 Statistical Regression
Consider a multivariate regression where a stock’s returns Ri are regressed on several market factors Rk .
k
Rit =
∑ βij R jt + eit ,
j =0
∀i.
where t = {1, 2, . . . , T } (i.e., there are T items in the time series), and
there are k independent variables, and usually k = 0 is for the intercept.
We could write this also as
k
Rit = β 0 +
∑ βij R jt + eit ,
j =1
∀i.
Compactly, using vector notation, the same regression may be written as:
Ri = R k β i + ei
where Ri , ei ∈ R T , Rk ∈ R T ×(k+1) , and β i ∈ Rk+1 . If there is an intercept
in the regression then the first column of Rk is 1, the unit vector. Without
providing a derivation, you should know that each regression coefficient
is:
Cov( Ri , Rk )
β ik =
Var ( Rk )
In vector form, all coefficients may be calculated at once:
β i = (R0k Rk )−1 (R0k Ri )
where the superscript (−1) stands for the inverse of the matrix (R0k Rk )
which is of dimension (k + 1) × (k + 1). Convince yourself that the
dimension of the expression (R0k Ri ) is (k + 1) × 1, i.e., it is a vector. This
results in the vector β i ∈ R(k+1) . This result comes from minimizing the
summed squared mean residual error in the regression i.e.,
min ei0 ei
βi
This will be examined in full detail later in this book.
the very beginning: got math?
2.8 Diversification
It is useful to examine the power of using vector algebra with an application. Here we use vector and summation math to understand how
diversification in stock portfolios works. Diversification occurs when
we increase the number of non-perfectly correlated stocks in a portfolio,
thereby reducing portfolio variance. In order to compute the variance of
the portfolio we need to use the portfolio weights w and the covariance
matrix of stock returns R, denoted Σ. We first write down the formula
for a portfolio’s return variance:
Var (w0 R) = w0 Σw =
n
n
∑ wi2 σi2 + ∑
n
∑
wi w j σij
i =1 j=1,i 6= j
i =1
Readers are strongly encouraged to implement this by hand for n = 2 to
convince themselves that the vector form of the expression for variance
w0 Σw is the same thing as the long form on the right-hand side of the
equation above. If returns are independent, then the formula collapses
to:
Var (w0 R) = w0 Σw =
n
∑ wi2 σi2
i=1
If returns are dependent, and equal amounts are invested in each asset
(wi = 1/n, ∀i ):
Var (w0 R) =
=
=
n
σij
1 n σi2 n − 1 n
+
∑
∑
∑
n i =1 n
n i=1 j=1,i6= j n(n − 1)
1 2 n−1
σ̄ +
σ¯ij
n i
n
1 2
1
σ̄ + 1 −
σ¯ij
n i
n
The first term is the average variance, denoted σ¯1 2 divided by n, and
the second is the average covariance, denoted σ¯ij multiplied by factor
(n − 1)/n. As n → ∞,
Var (w0 R) = σ¯ij .
This produces the remarkable result that in a well diversified portfolio,
the variances of each stock’s return does not matter at all for portfolio
risk! Further the risk of the portfolio, i.e., its variance, is nothing but the
average of off-diagonal terms in the covariance matrix.
49
50
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
Diversification exercise
Implement the math above using R to compute the standard deviation
of a portfolio of n identical securities with variance 0.04, and pairwise
covariances equal to 0.01. Keep increasing n and report the value of the
standard deviation. What do you see? Why would this be easier to do in
R versus Excel?
Matrix algebra exercise
The following brief notes will introduce you to everything you need to
know about the vocabulary of vectors and matrices in a "DIY" (do-ityourself) mode. Define
"
#
w
1
w = [ w1 w2 ] 0 =
w2
"
#
1 0
I=
0 1
"
#
σ12 σ12
Σ=
σ12 σ22
Do the following exercises in long hand:
• Show that
I w = w.
• Show that the dimensions make sense at all steps of your calculations.
• Show that
w0 Σ w = w12 σ12 + 2w1 w2 σ12 + w22 σ22 .
2.9 Matrix Calculus
It is simple to undertake calculus when working with matrices. Calculations using matrices are mere functions of many variables. These
functions are amenable to applying calculus, just as you would do in
multivariate calculus. However, using vectors and matrices makes things
simpler in fact, because we end up taking derivatives of these multivariate functions in one fell swoop rather than one-by-one for each variable.
An example will make this clear. Suppose
"
#
w1
w=
w2
the very beginning: got math?
and
"
B=
3
4
#
Let f (w) = w0 B. This is a function of two variables w1 , w2 . If we write
out f (w) in long form, we get 3w1 + 4w2 . The derivative of f (w) with
∂f
respect to w1 is ∂w = 3. The derivative of f (w) with respect to w2 is
1
∂f
∂w2 = 4. Compare
df
dw ? It’s B.
these answers to vector B. What do you see? What is
The insight here is that if we simply treat the vectors as regular scalars
and conduct calculus accordingly, we will end up with vector derivatives. Hence, the derivative of w0 B with respect to w is just B. Of course,
w0 B is an entire function and B is a vector. But the beauty of this is that
we can take all derivatives of function w0 B at one time!
These ideas can also be extended to higher-order matrix functions.
Suppose
"
#
3 2
A=
2 4
and
"
w=
w1
w2
#
Let f (w) = w0 Aw. If we write out f (w) in long form, we get
w0 Aw = 3w12 + 4w22 + 2(2)w1 w2
Take the derivative of f (w) with respect to w1 , and this is
df
= 6w1 + 4w2
dw1
Take the derivative of f (w) with respect to w2 , and this is
df
= 8w2 + 4w1
dw2
Now, we write out the following calculation in long form:
"
#"
# "
#
3 2
w1
6w1 + 4w2
2Aw=2
=
2 4
w2
8w2 + 4w1
What do you notice about this solution when compared to the previous
df
two answers? It is nothing but dw . Since w ∈ R2 , i.e., is of dimension 2,
df
the derivative dw will also be of that dimension.
51
52
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
To see how this corresponds to scalar calculus, think of the function
f (w) = w0 Aw as simply Aw2 , where w is scalar. The derivative of this
function with respect to w would be 2Aw. And, this is the same as what
we get when we look at a function of vectors, but with the caveat below.
Note: This computation only works out because A is symmetric. What
should the expression be for the derivative of this vector function if A is
not symmetric but is a square matrix? It turns out that this is
∂f
= A0 w + Aw 6= 2Aw
∂w
Let’s try this and see. Suppose
"
A=
3 2
1 4
#
You can check that the following is all true:
w0 Aw = 3w12 + 4w22 + 3w1 w2
∂f
= 6w1 + 3w2
∂w1
∂f
= 3w1 + 8w2
∂w2
and
"
A0 w + Aw =
6w1 + 3w2
3w1 + 8w2
#
which is correct, but note that the formula for symmetric A is not!
"
#
6w1 + 4w2
2Aw =
2w1 + 8w2
2.10 Matrix Equations
Here we examine how matrices may be used to represent large systems
of equations easily and also solve them. Using the values of matrices A,
B and w from the previous section, we write out the following in long
form:
Aw = B
That is, we have
"
3 2
2 4
#"
w1
w2
#
"
=
3
4
#
the very beginning: got math?
Do you get 2 equations? If so, write them out. Find the solution values
w1 and w2 by hand. And then we may compute the solution for w by
“dividing” B by A. This is not regular division because A and B are
matrices. Instead we need to multiply the inverse of A (which is its “reciprocal”) by B.
The inverse of A is
"
#
0.500 −0.250
−1
A =
−0.250 0.375
Now compute by hand:
"
A −1 B =
0.50
0.75
#
which should be the same as your solution by hand. Literally, this is all
the matrix algebra and calculus you will need for most of the work we
will do.
More exercises
Try the following questions for practice.
• What is the value of
A−1 AB
Is this vector or scalar?
• What is the final dimension of
(w0 B)(AAA−1 B)
53
3
Open Source: Modeling in R
In this chapter, we develop some expertise in using the R statistical package. There are many tutorials available now on the web. See the manuals
on the R web site www.r-project.org. There is also a great book that I
personally find very high quality, titled “The Art of R Programming” by
Norman Matloff. Another useful book is “Machine Learning for Hackers” by Drew Conway and John Myles White.
I assume you have downloaded and installed R by now. If not you can
get it from the R project page:
www.r-project.org
Or, you can get a commercial version, offered free to academics and
students by Revolution Analytics (the company is to R what RedHat is to
Linux). See
www.revolutionanalytics.com
For a useful interface when using R, install RStudio, see www.rstudio.com,
but install R first. Let’s get started with some basic programming in R.
3.1 System Commands
If you want to directly access the system you can issue system commands as follows:
system ( " <command> " )
For example
system ( " l s − l t | grep Das " )
will list all directory entries that contain my last name in reverse chronological order. Here I am using a unix command, so this will not work on
a Windoze machine, but it will certainly work on a Mac or Linux box.
56
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
However, you are hardly going to be issuing commands at the system
level, so you are unlikely to use the system command very much.
3.2 Loading Data
To get started, we need to grab some data. Go to Yahoo! Finance and
download some historical data in an Excel spreadsheet, re-sort it into
chronological order, then save it as a CSV file. Read the file into R as
follows:
> data = read . csv ( " goog . csv " , header=TRUE)
> n = dim ( data ) [ 1 ]
> n
[ 1 ] 1671
> data = data [ n : 1 , ]
# Read i n t h e d a t a
The last command reverses the sequence of the data if required. We
can download stock data using the quantmod package. Note: to install
a package you can use the drop down menus on Windows and Mac
operating systems, and use a package installer on Linux. Or issue the
following command:
i n s t a l l . packages ( " quantmod " )
Now we move on to using this package.
> l i b r a r y ( quantmod )
Loading r e q u i r e d package : x t s
Loading r e q u i r e d package : zoo
> getSymbols ( c ( "YHOO" , "AAPL" , "CSCO" , "IBM" ) )
[ 1 ] "YHOO" "AAPL" "CSCO" "IBM"
> yhoo = YHOO[ ’ 2007 − 01 − 03::2015 − 01 − 07 ’ ]
> a a p l = AAPL[ ’ 2007 − 01 − 03::2015 − 01 − 07 ’ ]
> c s c o = CSCO[ ’ 2007 − 01 − 03::2015 − 01 − 07 ’ ]
> ibm = IBM [ ’ 2007 − 01 − 03::2015 − 01 − 07 ’ ]
Or we can also directly create columns of stock data as follows.
>
>
>
>
yhoo = as . matrix (YHOO[ , 6 ] )
a a p l = as . matrix (AAPL [ , 6 ] )
c s c o = as . matrix (CSCO [ , 6 ] )
ibm = as . matrix ( IBM [ , 6 ] )
open source: modeling in r
We now go ahead and concatenate columns of data into one stock data
set.
> s t k d a t a = cbind ( yhoo , aapl , csco , ibm )
> dim ( s t k d a t a )
[ 1 ] 2018
4
Now, compute daily returns. This time, we do log returns in continuoustime. The mean returns are:
> n = length ( s t k d a t a [ , 1 ] )
> n
[ 1 ] 2018
> r e t s = log ( s t k d a t a [ 2 : n , ] / s t k d a t a [ 1 : ( n − 1 ) , ] )
> colMeans ( r e t s )
YHOO. Adjusted AAPL. Adjusted CSCO . Adjusted IBM . Adjusted
3 . 1 7 5 1 8 5 e −04 1 . 1 1 6 2 5 1 e −03 4 . 1 0 6 3 1 4 e −05 3 . 0 3 8 8 2 4 e −04
We can also compute the covariance matrix and correlation matrix:
> cv = cov ( r e t s )
> p r i n t ( cv , 2 )
YHOO. Adjusted AAPL. Adjusted CSCO . Adjusted IBM . Adjusted
YHOO. Adjusted
0.00067
0.00020
0.00022
0.00015
AAPL . Adjusted
0.00020
0.00048
0.00021
0.00015
CSCO . Adjusted
0.00022
0.00021
0.00041
0.00017
IBM . Adjusted
0.00015
0.00015
0.00017
0.00021
> cr = cor ( r e t s )
> p r i n t ( cr , 4 )
YHOO. Adjusted AAPL. Adjusted CSCO . Adjusted IBM . Adjusted
YHOO. Adjusted
1.0000
0.3577
0.4170
0.3900
AAPL . Adjusted
0.3577
1.0000
0.4872
0.4867
CSCO . Adjusted
0.4170
0.4872
1.0000
0.5842
IBM . Adjusted
0.3900
0.4867
0.5842
1.0000
Notice the print command that allows you to choose the number of significant digits.
For more flexibility and better handling of data files in various formats, you may also refer to the readr package. It has many useful functions.
57
58
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
3.3 Matrices
Q. What do you get if you cross a mountain-climber with a mosquito?
A. Can’t be done. You’ll be crossing a scaler with a vector.
We will use matrices extensively in modeling, and here we examine
the basic commands needed to create and manipulate matrices in R. We
create a 4 × 3 matrix with random numbers as follows:
> x = matrix ( rnorm ( 1 2 ) , 4 , 3 )
> x
[ ,1]
[ ,2]
[ 1 , ] 0.0625034 0.9256896
[ 2 , ] − 0.5371860 − 0.7497727
[ 3 , ] − 1.0416409 1 . 6 1 7 5 8 8 5
[ 4 , ] 0.3244804 0.1228325
[ ,3]
2.3989183
− 0.0857688
3.3755593
− 1.6494255
Transposing the matrix, notice that the dimensions are reversed:
> print ( t ( x ) , 3 )
[ ,1]
[ ,2]
[ ,3]
[ ,4]
[ 1 , ] 0 . 0 6 2 5 − 0.5372 − 1.04 0 . 3 2 4
[ 2 , ] 0 . 9 2 5 7 − 0.7498 1 . 6 2 0 . 1 2 3
[ 3 , ] 2 . 3 9 8 9 − 0.0858 3 . 3 8 − 1.649
Of course, it is easy to multiply matrices as long as they conform. By
“conform” we mean that when multiplying one matrix by another, the
number of columns of the matrix on the left must be equal to the number of rows of the matrix on the right. The resultant matrix that holds
the answer of this computation will have the number of rows of the matrix on the left, and the number of columns of the matrix on the right.
See the examples below:
> p r i n t ( t ( x ) %*% x , 3 )
[ ,1]
[ ,2]
[ ,3]
[ 1 , ] 1 . 4 8 − 1.18 − 3.86
[ 2 , ] − 1.18 4 . 0 5 7 . 5 4
[ 3 , ] − 3.86 7 . 5 4 1 9 . 8 8
>
> p r i n t ( x %*% t ( x ) , 3 )
[ ,1]
[ ,2]
[ ,3]
[ ,4]
[ 1 , ] 6 . 6 1 6 − 0.933 9 . 5 3 0 − 3.823
open source: modeling in r
[ 2 , ] − 0.933 0 . 8 5 8 − 0.943 − 0.125
[ 3 , ] 9 . 5 3 0 − 0.943 1 5 . 0 9 6 − 5.707
[ 4 , ] − 3.823 − 0.125 − 5.707 2 . 8 4 1
Taking the inverse of the covariance matrix:
> cv _ inv = s o l v e ( cv )
> p r i n t ( cv _ inv , 3 )
goog a a p l c s c o
ibm
goog 3809 − 1395 − 1058 −491
a a p l − 1395 3062 −615 − 1139
c s c o − 1058 −615 3971 − 2346
ibm
−491 − 1139 − 2346 7198
Check that the inverse is really so!
> p r i n t ( cv _ inv %*% cv , 3 )
goog
aapl
csco
ibm
goog 1 . 0 0 e +00 8 . 3 3 e −17 − 1.53e −16 2 . 7 8 e −17
a a p l − 2.22e −16 1 . 0 0 e +00 − 3.33e −16 − 5.55e −17
c s c o 2 . 2 2 e −16 0 . 0 0 e +00 1 . 0 0 e +00 2 . 2 2 e −16
ibm − 2.22e −16 − 2.22e −16 − 2.22e −16 1 . 0 0 e +00
It is, the result of multiplying the inverse matrix by the matrix itself results in the identity matrix. A covariance matrix should be positive definite. Why? What happens if it is not? Checking for this property is easy.
> l i b r a r y ( corpcor )
> i s . p o s i t i v e . d e f i n i t e ( cv )
[ 1 ] TRUE
> is . positive . definite (x)
E r r o r i n eigen (m, only . v a l u e s = TRUE) :
non−square matrix i n ’ e i g e n ’
> i s . p o s i t i v e . d e f i n i t e ( x %*% t ( x ) )
[ 1 ] FALSE
What happens if you compute pairwise covariances from differing
lengths of data for each pair?
3.4 Descriptive Statistics
Let’s revisit the same data and compute various descriptive statistics.
Read a CSV data file into R as follows:
59
60
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
> data = read . csv ( " goog . csv " , header=TRUE)
> n = dim ( data ) [ 1 ]
> n
[ 1 ] 1671
> data = data [ n : 1 , ]
> dim ( data )
[ 1 ] 1671
7
> s = data [ , 7 ]
# Read i n t h e d a t a
So we now have the stock data in place, and we can compute daily
returns, and then convert those returns into annualized returns.
> r e t s = log ( s [ 2 : n ] / s [ 1 : ( n − 1 ) ] )
> r e t s _ annual = r e t s * 252
> p r i n t ( c ( mean ( r e t s ) , mean ( r e t s _ annual ) ) )
[ 1 ] 0.001044538 0.263223585
Compute the daily and annualized standard deviation of returns.
> r _sd = sd ( r e t s )
> r _sd_ annual = r _sd * s q r t ( 2 5 2 )
> p r i n t ( c ( r _sd , r _sd_ annual ) )
[ 1 ] 0.02266823 0.35984704
> #What i f we t a k e t h e s t d e v o f
annualized r e t u r n s ?
> p r i n t ( sd ( r e t s * 2 5 2 ) )
[ 1 ] 5.712395
> #Huh?
>
> p r i n t ( sd ( r e t s * 2 5 2 ) ) / 252
[ 1 ] 5.712395
[ 1 ] 0.02266823
> p r i n t ( sd ( r e t s * 2 5 2 ) ) / s q r t ( 2 5 2 )
[ 1 ] 5.712395
[ 1 ] 0.3598470
Notice the interesting use of the print function here. The variance is
easy as well.
>
>
>
>
# Variance
r _ var = var ( r e t s )
r _ var _ annual = var ( r e t s ) * 252
p r i n t ( c ( r _ var , r _ var _ annual ) )
open source: modeling in r
[ 1 ] 0.0005138488 0.1294898953
3.5 Higher-Order Moments
Skewness and kurtosis are key moments that arise in all return distributions. We need a different library in R for these. We use the moments
library.
E[( X − µ)3 ]
Skewness =
σ3
Skewness means one tail is fatter than the other (asymmetry). Fatter
right (left) tail implies positive (negative) skewness.
Kurtosis =
E[( X − µ)4 ]
σ4
Kurtosis means both tails are fatter than with a normal distribution.
> l i b r a r y ( moments )
> skewness ( r e t s )
[ 1 ] 0.4874792
> kurtosis ( rets )
[ 1 ] 9.955916
For the normal distribution, skewness is zero, and kurtosis is 3. Kurtosis
minus three is denoted “excess kurtosis”.
> skewness ( rnorm ( 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 ) )
[ 1 ] − 0.00063502
> k u r t o s i s ( rnorm ( 1 0 0 0 0 0 0 ) )
[ 1 ] 3.005863
What is the skewness and kurtosis of the stock index (S&P500)?
3.6 Quick Introduction to Brownian Motions with R
The law of motion for stocks is often based on a geometric Brownian
motion, i.e.,
dS(t) = µS(t) dt + σS(t) dB(t),
S ( 0 ) = S0 .
This is a “stochastic” differential equation (SDE), because it describes
random movement of the stock S(t). The coefficient µ determines the
61
62
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
drift of the process, and σ determines its volatility. Randomness is injected by Brownian motion B(t). This is more general than a deterministic differential equation that is only a function of time, as with
a bank account, whose accretion is based on the differential equation
dy(t) = ry(t)dt, where r is the risk-free rate of interest.
The solution to a SDE is not a deterministic function but a random
function. In this case, the solution for time interval h is known to be
1
S(t + h) = S(t) exp µ − σ2 h + σB(h)
2
The presence of B(h) ∼ N (0, h) in the solution makes the function ranp
dom. We may also write B(h) as the random variable e (h) ∼ N (0, h),
where e ∼ N (0, 1). The presence of the exponential return makes the
stock price lognormal. (Note: if r.v. x is normal, then e x is lognormal.)
Re-arranging, the stock return is
1 2
S(t + h)
2
∼ N µ − σ h, σ h
R(t + h) = ln
S(t)
2
Using properties of the lognormal distribution, the conditional mean of
the stock price becomes
E[S(t + h)|S(t)] = S(t) · eµh
The following R code computes the annualized volatility σ.
> h = 1 / 252
> sigma = sd ( r e t s ) / s q r t ( h )
> sigma
[ 1 ] 0.3598470
The parameter µ is also easily estimated as
> mu = mean ( r e t s ) / h + 0 . 5 * sigma^2
> mu
[ 1 ] 0.3279685
So the additional term 12 σ2 does matter substantially.
3.7 Estimation using maximum-likelihood
MLE estimation requires finding the parameters {µ, σ} that maximize
the likelihood of seeing the empirical sequence of returns R(t). A probability function is required, and we have one above for R(t), which is
i.i.d.
open source: modeling in r
First, a quick recap of the normal distribution. If x ∼ N (µ, σ2 ), then
1
1 ( x − µ )2
density function: f ( x ) = √
exp −
2
σ2
2πσ2
N ( x ) = 1 − N (− x )
Z x
F(x) =
−∞
f (u)du
The standard normal distribution is x ∼ N (0, 1). For the standard normal distribution: F (0) = 21 .
The probability density of R(t) is normal with the following equation:
1 ( R ( t ) − α )2
1
· exp − ·
f [ R(t)] = √
2
σ2 h
2πσ2 h
where α = µ − 12 σ2 h. For periods t = 1, 2, . . . , T the likelihood of the
entire series is
T
∏ f [ R(t)]
t =1
It is easier (computationally) to maximize
T
max L ≡
µ,σ
∑ ln f [ R(t)]
t =1
known as the log-likelihood. This is easily done in R. First we create the
log-likelihood function
> LL = f u n c t i o n ( params , r e t s ) {
+ alpha = params [ 1 ] ; s i g s q = params [ 2 ]
+ l o g f = −log ( s q r t ( 2 * p i * s i g s q ) )
− ( r e t s −alpha )^2 / ( 2 * s i g s q )
+ LL = −sum( l o g f )
+ }
Note that
√
[ R ( t ) − α ]2
2σ2 h
We have used variable sigsq in function LL for σ2 h.
We then go ahead and do the MLE using the nlm (non-linear minimization) package in R. It uses a Newton-type algorithm.
ln f [ R(t)] = − ln
2πσ2 h −
> # c r e a t e s t a r t i n g guess f o r parameters
> params = c ( 0 . 0 0 1 , 0 . 0 0 1 )
> r e s = nlm ( LL , params , r e t s )
63
64
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
> res
$minimum
[ 1 ] − 3954.813
$ estimate
[ 1 ] 0.0010441526 0.0005130404
$ gradient
[ 1 ] 0 . 3 7 2 8 0 9 2 − 3.2397043
$ code
[1] 2
$ iterations
[ 1 ] 12
We now pick off the results and manipulate them to get the annualized
parameters {µ, σ}.
> alpha = r e s $ e s t i m a t e [ 1 ]
> sigsq = res $ estimate [ 2 ]
> sigma = s q r t ( s i g s q / h )
> sigma
[ 1 ] 0.3595639
> mu = alpha / h + 0 . 5 * sigma^2
> mu
[ 1 ] 0.3277695
We see that the estimated parameters are close to that derived earlier.
3.8 GARCH/ARCH Models
GARCH stands for “Generalized Auto- Regressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity”. Rob Engle invented ARCH (for which he got the Nobel
prize) and this was extended by Tim Bollerslev to GARCH.
ARCH models are based on the idea that volatility tends to cluster,
i.e., volatility for period t, is auto-correlated with volatility from period
(t − 1), or more preceding periods. If we had a time series of stock returns following a random walk, we might model it as follows
rt = µ + et ,
et ∼ N (0, σt2 )
If the variance were stationary then σt2 would be constant. But under
ARCH it is auto-correlated with previous variances. Hence, we have
p
σt2 = β 0 +
∑
j =1
q
β 1j σt2− j +
∑ β2k e2t−k
k =1
open source: modeling in r
So current variance (σt2 ) depends on past squared shocks (e2t−k ) and past
variances (σt2− j ). The number of lags of past variance is p, and that of
lagged shocks is q. The model is thus known as a GARCH( p, q) model.
For the model to be stationary, the sum of all the β terms should be less
than 1.
In GARCH, stock returns are conditionally normal, and independent,
but not identically distributed because the variance changes over time.
Since at every time t, we know the conditional distribution of returns,
because σt is based on past σt− j and past shocks et−k , we can estimate
the parameters { β 0 , β1j, β 2k }, ∀ j, k, of the model using MLE. The good
news is that this comes canned in R, so all we need to do is use the
tseries package.
> library ( tseries )
> r e s = garch ( r e t s , order=c ( 1 , 1 ) )
> summary ( r e s )
Call :
garch ( x = r e t s , order = c ( 1 , 1 ) )
Model :
GARCH( 1 , 1 )
Residuals :
Min
1Q
Median
3Q
Max
− 5.54354 − 0.45479 0 . 0 3 5 1 2 0 . 5 7 0 5 1 7 . 4 0 0 8 8
Coefficient ( s ) :
E s t i m a t e Std . E r r o r t value Pr ( >| t |)
a0 5 . 5 6 8 e −06
8 . 8 0 3 e −07
6 . 3 2 6 2 . 5 2 e −10 * * *
a1 4 . 2 9 4 e −02
4 . 6 2 2 e −03
9 . 2 8 9 < 2e −16 * * *
b1 9 . 4 5 8 e −01
5 . 4 0 5 e −03 1 7 4 . 9 7 9 < 2e −16 * * *
−−−
S i g n i f . codes : 0 [ * * * ] 0 . 0 0 1 [ * * ] 0 . 0 1 [ * ] 0 . 0 5 [ . ] 0 . 1 [ ]
D i a g n o s t i c T e s t s : J a r q u e Bera T e s t
data : R e s i d u a l s
X−squared = 3 0 0 7 . 3 1 1 , df = 2 ,
p−value < 2 . 2 e −16
Box−Ljung t e s t
data : Squared . R e s i d u a l s
X−squared = 0 . 5 3 0 5 , df = 1 , p−value = 0 . 4 6 6 4
Notice how strikingly high the t-statistics are. What is volatility related
65
66
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
to mostly? Is the model stationary?
3.9 Introduction to Monte Carlo
It is easy to simulate a path of stock prices using a discrete form of the
solution to the Geometric Brownian motion SDE. This is the equation of
motion for the stock price, which randomly moves the stock price from
its previous value S(t) to the value h years ahead, S(t + h).
√ 1 2
S(t + h) = S(t) exp µ − σ h + σ · e h
2
√
Note that we replaced B(h) with e h, where e ∼ N (0, 1). Both B(h)
√
and e h have mean zero and variance h. Knowing S(t), we can simulate
S(t + h) by drawing e from a standard normal distribution. Here is the R
code to run the entire simulation.
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
+
n = 252
s0 = 100
mu = 0 . 1 0
sig = 0.20
s = matrix ( 0 , 1 , n+1)
h=1 / n
s [ 1 ] = s0
for ( j in 2 : ( n+1)) {
s [ j ]= s [ j − 1] * exp ( ( mu−s i g ^2 / 2 ) * h
+ s i g * rnorm ( 1 ) * s q r t ( h ) )
+ }
> s [1:5]
[ 1 ] 100.00000 99.54793 96.98941
98.65440 98.76989
> s [ ( n − 4): n ]
[ 1 ] 87.01616 86.37163 84.92783
84.17420 86.16617
> p l o t ( t ( s ) , type= " l " )
This program generates the plot shown in Figure 3.1.
The same logic may be used to generate multiple paths of stock prices,
in a vectorized way as follows. In the following example we generate
3 paths. Because of the vectorization, the run time does not increase
linearly with the number of paths, and in fact, hardly increases at all.
open source: modeling in r
115
Figure 3.1: Single stock path plot
100
85
90
95
t(s)
105
110
simulated from a Brownian motion.
0
50
100
150
200
250
Index
>
>
>
+
+
>
>
>
67
s = matrix ( 0 , 3 , n+1)
s [ , 1 ] = s0
f o r ( j i n seq ( 2 , ( n + 1 ) ) ) {
s [ , j ]= s [ , j − 1] * exp ( ( mu−s i g ^2 / 2 ) * h
+ s i g * matrix ( rnorm ( 3 ) , 3 , 1 ) * s q r t ( h ) )
}
p l o t ( t ( s ) [ , 1 ] , ylim=c ( ymin , ymax ) , type= " l " )
l i n e s ( t ( s ) [ , 2 ] , c o l = " red " , l t y =2)
l i n e s ( t ( s ) [ , 3 ] , c o l = " blue " , l t y =3)
The plot is shown in Figure 3.2. The plot code shows how to change the
style of the path and its color.
If you generate many more paths, how can you find the probability
of the stock ending up below a defined price? Can you do this directly
from the discrete version of the Geometric Brownian motion process
above?
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
Figure 3.2: Multiple stock path plot
140
68
100
80
t(s)[, 1]
120
simulated from a Brownian motion.
0
50
100
150
200
250
Index
Bivariate random variables
To convert two independent random variables (e1 , e2 ) ∼ N (0, 1) into two
correlated random variables ( x1 , x2 ) with correlation ρ, use the following
transformations.
q
x 1 = e1 ,
x 2 = ρ · e1 + 1 − ρ 2 · e2
We can now generate 10,000 pairs of correlated random variates using
the following R code.
> e = matrix ( rnorm ( 2 0 0 0 0 ) , 1 0 0 0 0 , 2 )
> cor ( e )
[ ,1]
[ ,2]
[ 1 , ] 1.000000000 0.007620184
[ 2 , ] 0.007620184 1.000000000
> cor ( e [ , 1 ] , e [ , 2 ] )
[ 1 ] 0.007620184
> rho = 0 . 6
> x1 = e [ , 1 ]
> x2 = rho * e [ , 1 ] + s q r t (1 − rho ^2) * e [ , 2 ]
open source: modeling in r
> c o r ( x1 , x2 )
[ 1 ] 0.5981845
It is useful to check algebraically that E[ xi ] = 0, i = 1, 2, Var [ xi ] = 1, i =
1, 2. Also check that Cov[ x1 , x2 ] = ρ = Corr [ x1 , x2 ]. We can numerically
check this using the following:
> mean ( x1 )
[ 1 ] − 0.006522788
> mean ( x2 )
[ 1 ] − 0.00585042
> var ( x1 )
[ 1 ] 0.9842857
> var ( x2 )
[ 1 ] 1.010802
> cov ( x1 , x2 )
[ 1 ] 0.5966626
Multivariate random variables
These are generated using Cholesky decomposition which is a matrix operation that represents a covariance matrix as a product of two
matrices. We may write a covariance matrix in decomposed form, i.e.,
Σ = L L0 , where L is a lower triangular matrix. Alternatively we might
have an upper triangular decomposition, where U = L0 . Think of each
component of the decomposition as a square-root of the covariance matrix.
The Cholesky decomposition is very useful in generating correlated
random numbers from a distribution with mean vector µ and covariance matrix Σ. Suppose we have a scalar random variable e ∼ (0, 1).
To transform this variate into x ∼ (µ, σ2 ), we generate e and then set
x = µ + σe. If instead of a scalar random variable, we have a vector random variables (independent of each other) given by a vector
e = [e1 , e2 , . . . , en ]> ∼ (0, I), then we may transform this into a vector
of correlated random variables x = [ x1 , x2 , . . . , xn ]> ∼ (µ, Σ) by computing:
x = µ + Le
This is implemented using the following code.
> # Original matrix
69
70
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
> cv
[ ,1] [ ,2] [ ,3]
[1 ,] 0.01 0.00 0.00
[2 ,] 0.00 0.04 0.02
[3 ,] 0.00 0.02 0.16
> # Let ’ s enhance i t
> cv [ 1 , 2 ] = 0 . 0 0 5
> cv [ 2 , 1 ] = 0 . 0 0 5
> cv [ 1 , 3 ] = 0 . 0 0 5
> cv [ 3 , 1 ] = 0 . 0 0 5
> cv
[ ,1]
[ ,2]
[ ,3]
[ 1 , ] 0.010 0.005 0.005
[ 2 , ] 0.005 0.040 0.020
[ 3 , ] 0.005 0.020 0.160
> L = t ( chol ( cv ) )
> L
[ ,1]
[ ,2]
[ ,3]
[ 1 , ] 0.10 0.00000000 0.0000000
[ 2 , ] 0.05 0.19364917 0.0000000
[ 3 , ] 0.05 0.09036961 0.3864367
> e=matrix ( randn ( 3 * 1 0 0 0 0 ) , 1 0 0 0 0 , 3 )
> x = t ( L %*% t ( e ) )
> dim ( x )
[ 1 ] 10000
3
> cov ( x )
[ ,1]
[ ,2]
[ ,3]
[ 1 , ] 0.009872214 0.004597322 0.004521752
[ 2 , ] 0.004597322 0.040085503 0.019114981
[ 3 , ] 0.004521752 0.019114981 0.156378078
>
In the last calculation, we confirmed that the simulated data has the
same covariance matrix as the one that we generated correlated random
variables from.
open source: modeling in r
3.10 Portfolio Computations in R
Let’s enter a sample mean vector and covariance matrix and then using
some sample weights, we will perform some basic matrix computations
for portfolios to illustrate the use of R.
> mu = matrix ( c ( 0 . 0 1 , 0 . 0 5 , 0 . 1 5 ) , 3 , 1 )
> cv = matrix ( c ( 0 . 0 1 , 0 , 0 , 0 , 0 . 0 4 , 0 . 0 2 ,
0 ,0.02 ,0.16) ,3 ,3)
> mu
[ ,1]
[1 ,] 0.01
[2 ,] 0.05
[3 ,] 0.15
> cv
[ ,1] [ ,2] [ ,3]
[1 ,] 0.01 0.00 0.00
[2 ,] 0.00 0.04 0.02
[3 ,] 0.00 0.02 0.16
> w = matrix ( c ( 0 . 3 , 0 . 3 , 0 . 4 ) )
> w
[ ,1]
[1 ,]
0.3
[2 ,]
0.3
[3 ,]
0.4
> muP = t (w) %*% mu
> muP
[ ,1]
[ 1 , ] 0.078
> stdP = s q r t ( t (w) %*% cv %*% w)
> stdP
[ ,1]
[ 1 , ] 0.1868154
We thus generated the expected return and risk of the portfolio, i.e., the
values 0.078 and 0.187, respectively.
We are interested in the risk of a portfolio, often measured by its
variance. As we had seen in the previous chapter, as we increase n, the
number of securities in the portfolio, the variance keeps dropping, and
asymptotes to a level equal to the average covariance of all the assets. It
71
72
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
is interesting to see what happens as n increases through a very simple
function in R that returns the standard deviation of the portfolio.
>
+
+
+
+
+
>
>
>
s i g p o r t = function ( n , s i g _ i2 , s i g _ i j ) {
cv = matrix ( s i g _ i j , n , n )
diag ( cv ) = s i g _ i 2
w = matrix ( 1 / n , n , 1 )
r e s u l t = s q r t ( t (w) %*% cv %*% w)
}
n = seq ( 5 , 1 0 0 , 5 )
n
[1]
5 10 15 20 25 30 35 40 45 50
[ 1 8 ] 90 95 100
> r i s k _n = NULL
> f o r ( nn i n n ) {
+ r i s k _n = c ( r i s k _n , s i g p o r t ( nn , 0 . 0 4 , 0 . 0 1 ) )
+ }
> r i s k _n
[ 1 ] 0.1264911 0.1140175 0.1095445
0.1072381 0.1058301 0.1048809
[ 7 ] 0.1041976 0.1036822 0.1032796
0.1029563 0.1026911 0.1024695
[13] 0.1022817 0.1021204 0.1019804
0.1018577 0.1017494 0.1016530
[19] 0.1015667 0.1014889
>
55
60
We can plot this to see the classic systematic risk plot. This is shown in
Figure 3.3.
> p l o t ( n , r i s k _n , type= " l " ,
ylab= " P o r t f o l i o Std Dev " )
3.11 Finding the Optimal Portfolio
We will review the notation one more time. Assume that the risk free
asset has return r f . And we have n risky assets, with mean returns
µi , i = 1...n. We need to invest in optimal weights wi in each asset. Let
w = [w1 , . . . , wn ]0 be a column vector of portfolio weights. We define
65
70
75
80
85
open source: modeling in r
0.125
Figure 3.3: Systematic risk as the
0.115
0.110
0.105
Portfolio Std Dev
0.120
number of stocks in the portfolio
increases.
20
40
60
80
100
n
µ = [µ1 , . . . , µn ]0 be the column vector of mean returns on each asset, and
1 = [1, . . . , 1]0 be a column vector of ones. Hence, the expected return on
the portfolio will be
E ( R p ) = (1 − w 0 1 )r f + w 0 µ
The variance of return on the portfolio will be
Var ( R p ) = w0 Σw
where Σ is the covariance matrix of returns on the portfolio. The objective function is a trade-off between return and risk, with β modulating
the balance between risk and return:
U ( R p ) = r f + w0 (µ − r f 1) −
β 0
w Σw
2
The f.o.c. becomes a system of equations now (not a single equation),
since we differentiate by an entire vector w:
dU
= µ − r f 1 − βΣw = 0
dw0
73
74
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
where the RHS is a vector of zeros of dimension n. Solving we have
w=
1 −1
Σ (µ − r f 1)
β
Therefore, allocation to the risky assets
• Increases when the relative return to it (µ − r f 1) increases.
• Decreases when risk aversion increases.
• Decreases when riskiness of the assets increases as proxied for by Σ.
> n=3
> cv
[ ,1] [ ,2] [ ,3]
[1 ,] 0.01 0.00 0.00
[2 ,] 0.00 0.04 0.02
[3 ,] 0.00 0.02 0.16
> mu
[ ,1]
[1 ,] 0.01
[2 ,] 0.05
[3 ,] 0.15
> r f =0.005
> beta = 4
> wuns = matrix ( 1 , n , 1 )
> wuns
[ ,1]
[1 ,]
1
[2 ,]
1
[3 ,]
1
> w = ( 1 / beta ) * ( s o l v e ( cv ) %*% (mu− r f * wuns ) )
> w
[ ,1]
[ 1 , ] 0.1250000
[ 2 , ] 0.1791667
[ 3 , ] 0.2041667
> w_ i n _ r f = 1−sum(w)
> w_ i n _ r f
[ 1 ] 0.4916667
What if we reduced beta?
open source: modeling in r
> beta = 3
> w = ( 1 / beta ) * ( s o l v e ( cv ) %*% (mu− r f * wuns ) ) ;
> w
[ ,1]
[ 1 , ] 0.1666667
[ 2 , ] 0.2388889
[ 3 , ] 0.2722222
> beta = 2
> w = ( 1 / beta ) * ( s o l v e ( cv ) %*% (mu− r f * wuns ) ) ;
> w
[ ,1]
[ 1 , ] 0.2500000
[ 2 , ] 0.3583333
[ 3 , ] 0.4083333
Notice that the weights in stocks scales linearly with β. The relative
proportions of the stocks themselves remains constant. Hence, β modulates the proportions invested in a risk-free asset and a stock portfolio,
in which stock proportions remain same. It is as if the stock versus bond
decision can be taken separately from the decision about the composition of the stock portfolio. This is known as the “two-fund separation”
property, i.e., first determine the proportions in the bond fund vs stock
fund and the allocation within each fund can be handled subsequently.
3.12 Root Solving
Finding roots of nonlinear equations is often required, and R has several
packages for this purpose. Here we examine a few examples.
Suppose we are given the function
( x 2 + y2 − 1)3 − x 2 y3 = 0
and for various values of y we wish to solve for the values of x. The
function we use is called fn and the use of the function is shown below.
library ( rootSolve )
fn = f u n c t i o n ( x , y ) {
r e s u l t = ( x^2+y^2 − 1)^3 − x^2 * y^3
}
75
76
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
yy = 1
s o l = m u l t i r o o t ( f =fn , s t a r t =1 , m a x i t e r =10000 , r t o l = 0 . 0 0 0 0 0 1 ,
a t o l = 0 . 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 , c t o l = 0 . 0 0 0 0 1 , y=yy )
print ( sol )
check = fn ( s o l $ root , yy )
p r i n t ( check )
At the end we check that the equation has been solved. Here is the code
run:
> source ( " fn . R" )
$ root
[1] 1
$ f . root
[1] 0
$iter
[1] 1
$ estim . p r e c i s
[1] 0
[1] 0
Here is another example, where we solve a single unknown using the
unroot.all function.
library ( rootSolve )
fn = f u n c t i o n ( x ) {
r e s u l t = 0 . 0 6 5 * ( x * (1 − x ) ) ^ 0 . 5 − 0 . 0 5 + 0 . 0 5 * x
}
s o l = u n i r o o t . a l l ( f =fn , c ( 0 , 1 ) )
print ( sol )
The function searches for a solution (root) in the range [0, 1]. The answer
is given as:
[ 1 ] 1.0000000 0.3717627
open source: modeling in r
3.13 Regression
In a multivariate linear regression, we have
Y = X·β+e
where Y ∈ Rt×1 , X ∈ Rt×n , and β ∈ Rn×1 , and the regression solution is
simply equal to β = ( X 0 X )−1 ( X 0 Y ) ∈ Rn×1 .
To get this result we minimize the sum of squared errors.
min e0 e = (Y − X · β)0 (Y − X · β)
β
= Y 0 (Y − X · β) − ( Xβ)0 · (Y − X · β)
= Y 0 Y − Y 0 Xβ − ( β0 X 0 )Y + β0 X 0 Xβ
= Y 0 Y − Y 0 Xβ − Y 0 Xβ + β0 X 0 Xβ
= Y 0 Y − 2Y 0 Xβ + β0 X 0 Xβ
Note that this expression is a scalar. Differentiating w.r.t. β0 gives the
following f.o.c:
−2X 0 Y + 2X 0 Xβ
β
=
0
=⇒
=
( X 0 X ) −1 ( X 0 Y )
Cov( X ,Y )
There is another useful expression for each individual β i = Var(Xi ) . You
i
should compute this and check that each coefficient in the regression is
indeed equal to the β i from this calculation.
Example: Let’s do a regression and see whether AAPL, CSCO, and IBM
can explain the returns of YHOO. This uses the data we had downloaded earlier.
> dim ( r e t s )
[ 1 ] 2017
4
> Y = as . matrix ( r e t s [ , 1 ] )
> X = as . matrix ( r e t s [ , 2 : 4 ] )
> n = length (Y)
> X = cbind ( matrix ( 1 , n , 1 ) , X)
> b = s o l v e ( t (X) %*% X) %*% ( t (X) %*% Y)
> b
[ ,1]
3 . 1 3 9 1 8 3 e −06
AAPL . Adjusted 1 . 8 5 4 7 8 1 e −01
77
78
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
CSCO . Adjusted 3 . 0 6 9 0 1 1 e −01
IBM . Adjusted 3 . 1 1 7 5 5 3 e −01
But of course, R has this regression stuff canned, and you do not need to
hassle with the Matrix (though the movie is highly recommended).
> X = as . matrix ( r e t s [ , 2 : 4 ] )
> r e s = lm (Y~X)
> summary ( r e s )
Call :
lm ( formula = Y ~ X)
Residuals :
Min
1Q
Median
− 0.18333 − 0.01051 − 0.00044
3Q
0.00980
Max
0.38288
Coefficients :
E s t i m a t e Std . E r r o r t value Pr ( >| t |)
( Intercept )
3 . 1 3 9 e −06 5 . 0 9 1 e −04
0.006
0.995
XAAPL . Adjusted 1 . 8 5 5 e −01 2 . 7 8 0 e −02
6 . 6 7 1 3 . 2 8 e −11 * * *
XCSCO . Adjusted 3 . 0 6 9 e −01 3 . 2 4 4 e −02
9 . 4 6 2 < 2e −16 * * *
XIBM . Adjusted 3 . 1 1 8 e −01 4 . 5 1 7 e −02
6 . 9 0 2 6 . 8 2 e −12 * * *
−−−
S i g n i f . codes : 0 ï £ ¡ * * * ï £ ¡ 0 . 0 0 1 ï £ ¡ * * ï £ ¡ 0 . 0 1 ï £ ¡ * ï £ ¡ 0 . 0 5 ï £ ¡ . ï £ ¡ 0 . 1 ï £ ¡ ï £ ¡ 1
R e s i d u a l standard e r r o r : 0 . 0 2 2 8 3 on 2013 degrees o f freedom
M u l t i p l e R−squared : 0 . 2 2 3 6 ,
Adjusted R−squared : 0 . 2 2 2 4
F− s t a t i s t i c : 1 9 3 . 2 on 3 and 2013 DF , p−value : < 2 . 2 e −16
For visuals, do see the abline() function as well.
Here is a simple regression run on some data from the 2005-06 NCAA
basketball season for the March madness stats. The data is stored in a
space-delimited file called ncaa.txt. We use the metric of performance
to be the number of games played, with more successful teams playing
more playoff games, and then try to see what variables explain it best.
We apply a simple linear regression that uses the R command lm, which
stands for “linear model.”
> ncaa = read . t a b l e ( " ncaa . t x t " , header=TRUE)
> y = ncaa [ 3 ]
open source: modeling in r
>
>
>
>
>
>
y = as . matrix ( y )
x = ncaa [ 4 : 1 4 ]
x = as . matrix ( x )
fm = lm ( y~x )
r e s = summary ( fm )
res
Call :
lm ( formula = y ~ x )
Residuals :
Min
1Q Median
− 1.5075 − 0.5527 − 0.2454
3Q
0.6705
Max
2.2344
Coefficients :
E s t i m a t e Std . E r r o r t value Pr ( >| t |)
( I n t e r c e p t ) − 10.194804
2 . 8 9 2 2 0 3 − 3.525 0 . 0 0 0 8 9 3
xPTS
− 0.010442
0 . 0 2 5 2 7 6 − 0.413 0 . 6 8 1 2 1 8
xREB
0.105048
0.036951
2.843 0.006375
xAST
− 0.060798
0 . 0 9 1 1 0 2 − 0.667 0 . 5 0 7 4 9 2
xTO
− 0.034545
0 . 0 7 1 3 9 3 − 0.484 0 . 6 3 0 5 1 3
xA . T
1.325402
1.110184
1.194 0.237951
xSTL
0.181015
0.068999
2.623 0.011397
xBLK
0.007185
0.075054
0.096 0.924106
xPF
− 0.031705
0 . 0 4 4 4 6 9 − 0.713 0 . 4 7 9 0 5 0
xFG
13.823190
3.981191
3.472 0.001048
xFT
2.694716
1.118595
2.409 0.019573
xX3P
2.526831
1.754038
1.441 0.155698
−−−
S i g n i f . codes : 0 * * * 0 . 0 0 1 * * 0 . 0 1 * 0 . 0 5 . 0 . 1
***
**
*
**
*
R e s i d u a l standard e r r o r : 0 . 9 6 1 9 on 52 degrees o f freedom
M u l t i p l e R−Squared : 0 . 5 4 1 8 ,
Adjusted R−squared : 0 . 4 4 4 8
F− s t a t i s t i c : 5 . 5 8 9 on 11 and 52 DF , p−value : 7 . 8 8 9 e −06
We note that the command lm returns an “object” with name res. This
object contains various details about the regression result, and can then
be called by other functions that will format and present various versions of the result. For example, using the following command gives a
79
80
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
nicely formatted version of the regression output, and you should try to
use it when presenting regression results.
An alternative approach using data frames is:
> ncaa _ data _ frame = data . frame ( y=as . matrix ( ncaa [ 3 ] ) ,
x=as . matrix ( ncaa [ 4 : 1 4 ] ) )
> fm = lm ( y~x , data=ncaa _ data _ frame )
> summary ( fm )
(The output is not shown here in order to not repeat what we saw in the
previous regression.) Data frames are also objects. Here, objects are used
in the same way as the term is used in object-oriented programming
(OOP), and in a similar fashion, R supports OOP as well.
Direct regression implementing the matrix form is as follows (we had
derived this earlier):
>
>
>
>
wuns = matrix ( 1 , 6 4 , 1 )
z = cbind ( wuns , x )
b = inv ( t ( z ) %*% z ) %*% ( t ( z ) %*% y )
b
GMS
− 10.194803524
PTS − 0.010441929
REB
0.105047705
AST − 0.060798192
TO
− 0.034544881
A. T
1.325402061
STL
0.181014759
BLK
0.007184622
PF
− 0.031705212
FG
13.823189660
FT
2.694716234
X3P
2.526830872
Note that this is exactly the same result as we had before, but it gave us
a chance to look at some of the commands needed to work with matrices
in R.
open source: modeling in r
3.14 Heteroskedasticity
Simple linear regression assumes that the standard error of the residuals
is the same for all observations. Many regressions suffer from the failure
of this condition. The word for this is “heteroskedastic” errors. “Hetero”
means different, and “skedastic” means dependent on type.
We can first test for the presence of heteroskedasticity using a standard Breusch-Pagan test available in R. This resides in the lmtest package which is loaded in before running the test.
> ncaa = read . t a b l e ( " ncaa . t x t " , header=TRUE)
> y = as . matrix ( ncaa [ 3 ] )
> x = as . matrix ( ncaa [ 4 : 1 4 ] )
> r e s u l t = lm ( y~x )
> library ( lmtest )
Loading r e q u i r e d package : zoo
> bptest ( result )
s t u d e n t i z e d Breusch −Pagan t e s t
data :
result
BP = 1 5 . 5 3 7 8 , df = 1 1 , p−value = 0 . 1 5 9 2
We can see that there is very little evidence of heteroskedasticity in the
standard errors as the p-value is not small. However, lets go ahead and
correct the t-statistics for heteroskedasticity as follows, using the hccm
function. The “hccm” stands for heteroskedasticity corrected covariance
matrix.
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
wuns = matrix ( 1 , 6 4 , 1 )
z = cbind ( wuns , x )
b = s o l v e ( t ( z ) %*% z ) %*% ( t ( z ) %*% y )
r e s u l t = lm ( y~x )
library ( car )
vb = hccm ( r e s u l t )
stdb = s q r t ( diag ( vb ) )
t s t a t s = b / stdb
tstats
GMS
− 2.68006069
PTS − 0.38212818
81
82
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
REB 2 . 3 8 3 4 2 6 3 7
AST − 0.40848721
TO − 0.28709450
A. T 0 . 6 5 6 3 2 0 5 3
STL 2 . 1 3 6 2 7 1 0 8
BLK 0 . 0 9 5 4 8 6 0 6
PF − 0.68036944
FG
3.52193532
FT
2.35677255
X3P 1 . 2 3 8 9 7 6 3 6
Here we used the hccm function to generate the new covariance matrix
vb of the coefficients, and then we obtained the standard errors as the
square root of the diagonal of the covariance matrix. Armed with these
revised standard errors, we then recomputed the t-statistics by dividing the coefficients by the new standard errors. Compare these to the
t-statistics in the original model
summary ( r e s u l t )
Coefficients :
E s t i m a t e Std . E r r o r t value Pr ( >| t |)
( I n t e r c e p t ) − 10.194804
2 . 8 9 2 2 0 3 − 3.525 0 . 0 0 0 8 9 3 * * *
xPTS
− 0.010442
0 . 0 2 5 2 7 6 − 0.413 0 . 6 8 1 2 1 8
xREB
0.105048
0.036951
2.843 0.006375 * *
xAST
− 0.060798
0 . 0 9 1 1 0 2 − 0.667 0 . 5 0 7 4 9 2
xTO
− 0.034545
0 . 0 7 1 3 9 3 − 0.484 0 . 6 3 0 5 1 3
xA . T
1.325402
1.110184
1.194 0.237951
xSTL
0.181015
0.068999
2.623 0.011397 *
xBLK
0.007185
0.075054
0.096 0.924106
xPF
− 0.031705
0 . 0 4 4 4 6 9 − 0.713 0 . 4 7 9 0 5 0
xFG
13.823190
3.981191
3.472 0.001048 * *
xFT
2.694716
1.118595
2.409 0.019573 *
xX3P
2.526831
1.754038
1.441 0.155698
It is apparent that when corrected for heteroskedasticity, the t-statistics in
the regression are lower, and also render some of the previously significant coefficients insignificant.
open source: modeling in r
3.15 Auto-regressive models
When data is autocorrelated, i.e., has dependence in time, not accounting
for it results in unnecessarily high statistical significance. Intuitively, this
is because observations are treated as independent when actually they
are correlated in time, and therefore, the true number of observations is
effectively less.
In efficient markets, the correlation of returns from one period to the
next should be close to zero. We use the returns stored in the variable
rets (based on Google stock) from much earlier in this chapter.
> n = length ( r e t s )
> n
[ 1 ] 1670
> cor ( r e t s [ 1 : ( n−1)] , r e t s [ 2 : n ] )
[ 1 ] 0.007215026
This is for immediately consecutive periods, known as first-order autocorrelation. We may examine this across many staggered periods. For
this R has some neat library functions in the package car.
> library ( car )
> durbin . watson ( r e t s , max . l a g =10)
[ 1 ] 1.974723 2.016951 1.984078 1.932000
1.950987 2.101559 1.977719 1.838635
2.052832 1.967741
> r e s = lm ( r e t s [ 2 : n ] ~ r e t s [ 1 : ( n − 1 ) ] )
> durbin . watson ( res , max . l a g =10)
l a g A u t o c o r r e l a t i o n D−W S t a t i s t i c p−value
1
− 0.0006436855
2.001125
0.938
2
− 0.0109757002
2.018298
0.724
3
− 0.0002853870
1.996723
0.982
4
0.0252586312
1.945238
0.276
5
0.0188824874
1.957564
0.402
6
− 0.0555810090
2.104550
0.020
7
0.0020507562
1.989158
0.926
8
0.0746953706
1.843219
0.004 #
9
− 0.0375308940
2.067304
0.136
10
0.0085641680
1.974756
0.772
A l t e r n a t i v e h y p o t h e s i s : rho [ l a g ] ! = 0
83
84
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
There is no evidence of auto-correlation when the DW statistic is close to
2. If the DW-statistic is greater than 2 it indicates negative autocorrelation, and if it is less than 2, it indicates positive autocorrelation.
In the data there only seems to be statistical significance at the eighth
lag. We may regress leading values on lags to see if the coefficient is
significant.
> summary ( r e s )
Call :
lm ( formula = r e t s [ 2 : n ] ~ r e t s [ 1 : ( n − 1 ) ] )
Residuals :
Min
1Q
Median
− 0.1242520 − 0.0102479 − 0.0002719
3Q
0.0106435
Max
0.1813465
Coefficients :
E s t i m a t e Std . E r r o r t value Pr ( >| t |)
( Intercept )
0.0009919 0.0005539
1.791
0.0735 .
r e t s [ 1 : ( n − 1 ) ] 0.0071913 0.0244114
0.295
0.7683
−−−
S i g n i f . codes : 0 [ * * * ] 0 . 0 0 1 [ * * ] 0 . 0 1 [ * ] 0 . 0 5 [ . ] 0 . 1 [ ]
R e s i d u a l s t d e r r o r : 0 . 0 2 2 6 1 on 1667 degrees o f freedom
M u l t i p l e R−squared : 5 . 2 0 6 e − 05 ,
Adjusted R−squared : − 0.0005478
F− s t a t i s t i c : 0 . 0 8 6 7 8 on 1 and 1667 DF , p−value : 0 . 7 6 8 3
As another example, let’s load in the file markowitzdata.txt and run
tests on it. This file contains data on five tech sector stocks and also the
Fama-French data. The names function shows the headers of each column as shown below.
> md = read . t a b l e ( " markowitzdata . t x t " , header=TRUE)
> names (md)
[ 1 ] "X .DATE" "SUNW"
"MSFT"
"IBM"
"CSCO"
"AMZN"
[ 8 ] "smb"
" hml "
" rf "
> y = as . matrix (md[ 2 ] )
> x = as . matrix (md[ 7 : 9 ] )
> r f = as . matrix (md[ 1 0 ] )
> y = y− r f
" mktrf "
open source: modeling in r
> library ( car )
> r e s u l t s = lm ( y ~ x )
> durbin . watson ( r e s u l t s , max . l a g =6)
l a g A u t o c o r r e l a t i o n D−W S t a t i s t i c p−value
1
− 0.07231926
2.144549
0.002
2
− 0.04595240
2.079356
0.146
3
0.02958136
1.926791
0.162
4
− 0.01608143
2.017980
0.632
5
− 0.02360625
2.032176
0.432
6
− 0.01874952
2.021745
0.536
A l t e r n a t i v e h y p o t h e s i s : rho [ l a g ] ! = 0
The car package is used. We see that there is one lag auto-correlation
(note the small p-value for lag 1), but not more than that; markets are
very efficient. Lets look at the regression before and after correction for
autocorrelation:
> summary ( r e s u l t s )
Call :
lm ( formula = y ~ x )
Residuals :
Min
1Q
Median
− 0.2136760 − 0.0143564 − 0.0007332
3Q
0.0144619
Max
0.1910892
Coefficients :
E s t i m a t e Std . E r r o r t value Pr ( >| t |)
( I n t e r c e p t ) − 0.000197
0 . 0 0 0 7 8 5 − 0.251
0.8019
xmktrf
1.657968
0.085816 19.320
<2e −16 * * *
xsmb
0.299735
0.146973
2.039
0.0416 *
xhml
− 1.544633
0 . 1 7 6 0 4 9 − 8.774
<2e −16 * * *
−−−
S i g n i f . codes : 0 [ * * * ] 0 . 0 0 1 [ * * ] 0 . 0 1 [ * ] 0 . 0 5 [ . ] 0 . 1 [ ]
R e s i d u a l standard e r r o r : 0 . 0 3 0 2 8 on 1503 degrees o f freedom
M u l t i p l e R−Squared : 0 . 3 6 3 6 ,
Adjusted R−squared : 0 . 3 6 2 3
F− s t a t i s t i c : 2 8 6 . 3 on 3 and 1503 DF , p−value : < 2 . 2 e −16
Lets correct the t-stats for autocorrelation using the Newey-West correction. This correction is part of the car package. The steps undertaken
85
86
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
here are similar in mechanics to the ones we encountered when correcting for heteroskedasticity.
> r e s = lm ( y~x )
> b = res $ coefficients
> b
( Intercept )
xmktrf
xsmb
xhml
− 0.0001970164 1 . 6 5 7 9 6 8 2 1 9 1 0 . 2 9 9 7 3 5 3 7 6 5 − 1.5446330690
> vb = NeweyWest ( res , l a g =1)
> stdb = s q r t ( diag ( vb ) )
> t s t a t s = b / stdb
> tstats
( Intercept )
xmktrf
xsmb
xhml
− 0.2633665 1 5 . 5 7 7 9 1 8 4
1 . 8 3 0 0 3 4 0 − 6.1036120
Compare these to the stats we had earlier. Notice how they have come
down after correction for AR. Note that there are several steps needed to
correct for autocorrelation, and it might have been nice to roll one’s own
function for this. (I leave this as an exercise for you.)
For fun, lets look at the autocorrelation in stock market indexes,
shown in Table 3.1. The following graphic is taken from the book “A
Non-Random Walk Down Wall Street” by Andrew Lo and Craig Mackinlay. Is the autocorrelation higher for equally-weighted or value-weighted
indexes? Why?
3.16 Vector Auto-Regression
Also known as VAR (not the same thing as Value-at-Risk, denoted VaR).
VAR is useful for estimating systems where there are simultaneous regression equations, and the variables influence each other. So in a VAR,
each variable in a system is assumed to depend on lagged values of itself
and the other variables. The number of lags may be chosen by the econometrician based on what is the expected decay in time-dependence of the
variables in the VAR.
In the following example, we examine the inter-relatedness of returns
of the following three tickers: SUNW, MSFT, IBM. For vector autoregressions (VARs), we run the following R commands:
> md = read . t a b l e ( " markowitzdata . t x t " , header=TRUE)
> y = as . matrix (md[ 2 : 4 ] )
> library ( stats )
open source: modeling in r
87
Table 3.1: Autocorrelation in daily,
weekly, and monthly stock index
returns. From Lo-Mackinlay, “A
Non-Random Walk Down Wall
Street”.
88
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
> var6 = a r ( y , a i c =TRUE, order =6)
> var6 $ order
[1] 1
> var6 $ a r
, , SUNW
SUNW
MSFT
IBM
1 − 0.00985635 0 . 0 2 2 2 4 0 9 3 0 . 0 0 2 0 7 2 7 8 2
, , MSFT
SUNW
MSFT
IBM
1 0 . 0 0 8 6 5 8 3 0 4 − 0.1369503 0 . 0 3 0 6 5 5 2
, , IBM
SUNW
MSFT
IBM
1 − 0.04517035 0 . 0 9 7 5 4 9 7 − 0.01283037
The “order” of the VAR is how many lags are significant. In this example, the order is 1. Hence, when the “ar” command is given, it shows
the coefficients on the lagged values of the three value to just one lag.
For example, for SUNW, the lagged coefficients are -0.0098, 0.0222, and
0.0021, respectively for SUNW, MSFT, IBM. The Akaike Information Criterion (AIC) tells us which lag is significant, and we see below that this
is lag 1.
> var6 $ a i c
0
1
23.950676 0.000000
2
2.762663
3
5.284709
4
5
5.164238 10.065300
Since the VAR was run for all six lags, the “partialacf” attribute of the
output shows the coefficients of all lags.
> var6 $ p a r t i a l a c f
, , SUNW
SUNW
MSFT
IBM
1 − 0.00985635 0 . 0 2 2 2 4 0 9 3 1 0 . 0 0 2 0 7 2 7 8 2
2 − 0.07857841 − 0.019721982 − 0.006210487
3 0.03382375 0.003658121 0.032990758
6
8.924513
open source: modeling in r
4 0.02259522 0.030023132 0.020925226
5 − 0.03944162 − 0.030654949 − 0.012384084
6 − 0.03109748 − 0.021612632 − 0.003164879
, , MSFT
1
2
3
4
5
6
SUNW
MSFT
IBM
0 . 0 0 8 6 5 8 3 0 4 − 0.13695027 0 . 0 3 0 6 5 5 2 0 1
− 0.053224374 − 0.02396291 − 0.047058278
0 . 0 8 0 6 3 2 4 2 0 0 . 0 3 7 2 0 9 5 2 − 0.004353203
− 0.038171317 − 0.07573402 − 0.004913021
0.002727220 0.05886752 0.050568308
0.242148823 0.03534206 0.062799122
, , IBM
1
2
3
4
5
6
SUNW
MSFT
− 0.04517035 0 . 0 9 7 5 4 9 7 0 0
0.05436993 0.021189756
− 0.08990973 − 0.077140955
0.06651063 0.056250866
0 . 0 3 1 1 7 5 4 8 − 0.056192843
− 0.13131366 − 0.003776726
IBM
− 0.01283037
0.05430338
− 0.03979962
0.05200459
− 0.06080490
− 0.01502191
Interestingly we see that each of the tickers has a negative relation to
its lagged value, but a positive correlation with the lagged values of the
other two stocks. Hence, there is positive cross autocorrelation amongst
these tech stocks. We can also run a model with three lags:
> a r ( y , method= " o l s " , order =3)
Call :
a r ( x = y , order . max = 3 , method = " o l s " )
$ ar
, , 1
SUNW
MSFT
IBM
SUNW 0 . 0 1 4 0 7 − 0.0006952 − 0.036839
MSFT 0 . 0 2 6 9 3 − 0.1440645 0 . 1 0 0 5 5 7
89
90
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
IBM
0.01330
0 . 0 2 1 1 1 6 0 − 0.009662
, , 2
SUNW
MSFT
IBM
SUNW − 0.082017 − 0.04079 0 . 0 4 8 1 2
MSFT − 0.020668 − 0.01722 0 . 0 1 7 6 1
IBM − 0.006717 − 0.04790 0 . 0 5 5 3 7
, , 3
SUNW
MSFT
IBM
SUNW 0 . 0 3 5 4 1 2 0 . 0 8 1 9 6 1 − 0.09139
MSFT 0 . 0 0 3 9 9 9 0 . 0 3 7 2 5 2 − 0.07719
IBM 0 . 0 3 3 5 7 1 − 0.003906 − 0.04031
$x . i n t e r c e p t
SUNW
MSFT
IBM
− 9.623 e −05 − 7.366 e −05 − 6.257 e −05
$ var . pred
SUNW
MSFT
IBM
SUNW 0 . 0 0 1 3 5 9 3 0 . 0 0 0 3 0 0 7 0 . 0 0 0 2 8 4 2
MSFT 0 . 0 0 0 3 0 0 7 0 . 0 0 0 3 5 1 1 0 . 0 0 0 1 8 8 8
IBM 0 . 0 0 0 2 8 4 2 0 . 0 0 0 1 8 8 8 0 . 0 0 0 2 8 8 1
We examine cross autocorrelation found across all stocks by Lo and
Mackinlay in their book “A Non-Random Walk Down Wall Street” – see
Table 3.2. There is strong contemporaneous correlation amongst stocks
shows in the top tableau but in the one below that, the cross one-lag
autocorrelation is also positive and strong. From two lags on the relationship is weaker.
3.17 Logit
When the LHS variable in a regression is categorical and binary, i.e.,
takes the value 1 or 0, then a logit regression is more apt. For the NCAA
data, take the top 32 teams and make their dependent variable 1, and
open source: modeling in r
91
Table 3.2: Cross autocorrelations
in US stocks. From Lo-Macklinlay,
“A Non-Random Walk Down Wall
Street.”
92
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
that of the bottom 32 teams zero. Hence, we split the data into the teams
above average and the teams that are below average. Our goal is to fit a
regression model that returns a team’s probability of being above average. This is the same as the team’s predicted percentile ranking.
> y1 = 1 : 3 2
> y1 = y1 * 0+1
> y1
[1] 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1
> y2 = y1 * 0
> y2
[1] 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
> y = c ( y1 , y2 )
> y
[1] 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 0
[34] 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
We use the function glm (generalized linear model) for this task. Running the model is pretty easy as follows:
> h = glm ( y~x , family=binomial ( l i n k= " l o g i t " ) )
> logLik ( h )
’ l o g Lik . ’ − 21.44779 ( df =12)
> summary ( h )
Call :
glm ( formula = y ~ x , family = binomial ( l i n k = " l o g i t " ) )
Deviance R e s i d u a l s :
Min
1Q
Median
− 1.80174 − 0.40502 − 0.00238
3Q
0.37584
Max
2.31767
Coefficients :
E s t i m a t e Std . E r r o r z value Pr ( >| z |)
( I n t e r c e p t ) − 45.83315
1 4 . 9 7 5 6 4 − 3.061 0 . 0 0 2 2 1 * *
xPTS
− 0.06127
0 . 0 9 5 4 9 − 0.642 0 . 5 2 1 0 8
xREB
0.49037
0.18089
2.711 0.00671 * *
xAST
0.16422
0.26804
0.613 0.54010
xTO
− 0.38405
0 . 2 3 4 3 4 − 1.639 0 . 1 0 1 2 4
xA . T
1.56351
3.17091
0.493 0.62196
xSTL
0.78360
0.32605
2.403 0.01625 *
open source: modeling in r
xBLK
0.07867
0.23482
xPF
0.02602
0.13644
xFG
46.21374
17.33685
xFT
10.72992
4.47729
xX3P
5.41985
5.77966
−−−
S i g n i f . codes : 0 [ * * * ] 0 . 0 0 1 [ * * ]
0.335
0.191
2.666
2.397
0.938
0.73761
0.84874
0.00768 * *
0.01655 *
0.34838
0.01 [ * ] 0.05 [ . ] 0.1 [ ]
( D i s p e r s i o n parameter f o r binomial family taken t o be 1 )
Null deviance : 8 8 . 7 2 3
R e s i d u a l deviance : 4 2 . 8 9 6
AIC : 6 6 . 8 9 6
on 63
on 52
degrees o f freedom
degrees o f freedom
Number o f F i s h e r S c o r i n g i t e r a t i o n s : 6
Thus, we see that the best variables that separate upper-half teams from
lower-half teams are the number of rebounds and the field goal percentage. To a lesser extent, field goal percentage and steals also provide
some explanatory power. The logit regression is specified as follows:
ey
1 + ey
y = b0 + b1 x1 + b2 x2 + . . . + bk xk
z =
The original data z = {0, 1}. The range of values of y is (−∞, +∞). And
as required, the fitted z ∈ (0, 1). The variables x are the RHS variables.
The fitting is done using MLE.
Suppose we ran this with a simple linear regression:
> h = lm ( y~x )
> summary ( h )
Call :
lm ( formula = y ~ x )
Residuals :
Min
1Q
− 0.65982 − 0.26830
Coefficients :
Median
0.03183
3Q
0.24712
Max
0.83049
93
94
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
E s t i m a t e Std . E r r o r t value Pr ( >| t |)
( I n t e r c e p t ) − 4.114185
1 . 1 7 4 3 0 8 − 3.503 0 . 0 0 0 9 5 3
xPTS
− 0.005569
0 . 0 1 0 2 6 3 − 0.543 0 . 5 8 9 7 0 9
xREB
0.046922
0.015003
3.128 0.002886
xAST
0.015391
0.036990
0.416 0.679055
xTO
− 0.046479
0 . 0 2 8 9 8 8 − 1.603 0 . 1 1 4 9 0 5
xA . T
0.103216
0.450763
0.229 0.819782
xSTL
0.063309
0.028015
2.260 0.028050
xBLK
0.023088
0.030474
0.758 0.452082
xPF
0.011492
0.018056
0.636 0.527253
xFG
4.842722
1.616465
2.996 0.004186
xFT
1.162177
0.454178
2.559 0.013452
xX3P
0.476283
0.712184
0.669 0.506604
−−−
S i g n i f . codes : 0 [ * * * ] 0 . 0 0 1 [ * * ] 0 . 0 1 [ * ] 0 . 0 5
***
**
*
**
*
[ . ] 0.1 [ ]
R e s i d u a l standard e r r o r : 0 . 3 9 0 5 on 52 degrees o f freedom
M u l t i p l e R−Squared : 0 . 5 0 4 3 ,
Adjusted R−squared : 0 . 3 9 9 5
F− s t a t i s t i c :
4 . 8 1 on 11 and 52 DF , p−value : 4 . 5 1 4 e −05
We get the same variables again showing up as significant.
3.18 Probit
We can redo the same using a probit instead. A probit is identical in
spirit to the logit regression, except that the function that is used is
z = Φ(y)
y = b0 + b1 x1 + b2 x2 + . . . + bk xk
where Φ(·) is the cumulative normal probability function. It is implemented in R as follows.
> h = glm ( y~x , family=binomial ( l i n k= " p r o b i t " ) )
> logLik ( h )
’ l o g Lik . ’ − 21.27924 ( df =12)
> summary ( h )
Call :
glm ( formula = y ~ x , family = binomial ( l i n k = " p r o b i t " ) )
open source: modeling in r
Deviance R e s i d u a l s :
Min
1Q
− 1.7635295 − 0.4121216
Median
− 0.0003102
3Q
0.3499560
Max
2.2456825
Coefficients :
E s t i m a t e Std . E r r o r z value Pr ( >| z |)
( I n t e r c e p t ) − 26.28219
8 . 0 9 6 0 8 − 3.246 0 . 0 0 1 1 7
xPTS
− 0.03463
0 . 0 5 3 8 5 − 0.643 0 . 5 2 0 2 0
xREB
0.28493
0.09939
2.867 0.00415
xAST
0.10894
0.15735
0.692 0.48874
xTO
− 0.23742
0 . 1 3 6 4 2 − 1.740 0 . 0 8 1 8 0
xA . T
0.71485
1.86701
0.383 0.70181
xSTL
0.45963
0.18414
2.496 0.01256
xBLK
0.03029
0.13631
0.222 0.82415
xPF
0.01041
0.07907
0.132 0.89529
xFG
26.58461
9.38711
2.832 0.00463
xFT
6.28278
2.51452
2.499 0.01247
xX3P
3.15824
3.37841
0.935 0.34988
−−−
S i g n i f . codes : 0 [ * * * ] 0 . 0 0 1 [ * * ] 0 . 0 1 [ * ] 0 . 0 5
**
**
.
*
**
*
[ . ] 0.1 [ ]
( D i s p e r s i o n parameter f o r binomial family taken t o be 1 )
Null deviance : 8 8 . 7 2 3
R e s i d u a l deviance : 4 2 . 5 5 8
AIC : 6 6 . 5 5 8
on 63
on 52
degrees o f freedom
degrees o f freedom
Number o f F i s h e r S c o r i n g i t e r a t i o n s : 8
The results confirm those obtained from the linear regression and logit
regression.
3.19 Solving Non-Linear Equations
Earlier we examined root finding. Here we develop it further. We have
also not done much with user-generated functions. Here is a neat model
in R to solve for the implied volatility in the Black-Merton-Scholes class
of models. First, we code up the Black-Scholes (1973) model; this is the
function bms73 below. Then we write a user-defined function that solves
95
96
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
for the implied volatility from a given call or put option price. The package minpack.lm is used for the equation solving, and the function call is
nls.lm.
The following program listing may be saved in a file called rbc.R and
then called from the command line. The function impvol uses the bms73
function and solves for the implied volatility.
# B l a c k −Merton − S c h o l e s 1973
bms73 = f u n c t i o n ( s i g , S , K, T , r , q , cp , o p t p r i c e ) {
d1 = ( log ( S /K) + ( r −q + 0 . 5 * s i g ^2) * T ) / ( s i g * s q r t ( T ) )
d2 = d1 − s i g * s q r t ( T )
i f ( cp ==1) {
o p t v a l = S * exp(−q * T ) * pnorm ( d1)−K* exp(− r * T ) * pnorm ( d2 )
}
else {
o p t v a l = −S * exp(−q * T ) * pnorm(− d1 )+K* exp(− r * T ) * pnorm(− d2 )
}
# I f o p t i o n p r i c e i s s u p p l i e d we want t h e i m p l i e d v o l , e l s e o p t p r i c e
bs = o p t v a l − o p t p r i c e
}
# F u n c t i o n t o r e t u r n Imp Vol w i t h s t a r t i n g g u e s s s i g 0
impvol = f u n c t i o n ( s i g 0 , S , K, T , r , q , cp , o p t p r i c e ) {
s o l = n l s . lm ( par= s i g 0 , fn=bms73 , S=S , K=K, T=T , r=r , q=q ,
cp=cp , o p t p r i c e = o p t p r i c e )
}
The calls to this model are as follows:
> l i b r a r y ( minpack . lm )
> source ( " r b c . R" )
> r e s = impvol ( 0 . 2 , 4 0 , 4 0 , 1 , 0 . 0 3 , 0 , 0 , 4 )
> r e s $ par
[ 1 ] 0.2915223
We note that the function impvol was written such that the argument
that we needed to solve for, sig0, the implied volatility, was the first
argument in the function. However, the expression par=sig0 does inform the solver which argument is being searched for in order to satisfy
the non-linear equation for implied volatility. Note also that the func-
open source: modeling in r
97
tion bms73 returns the difference between the model price and observed
price, not the model price alone. This is necessary as the solver tries to
set this value to zero by finding the implied volatility.
Lets check if we put this volatility back into the bms function that we
get back the option price of 4. Voila!
> p r i n t ( bms73 ( r e s $ par [ 1 ] , 4 0 , 4 0 , 1 , 0 . 0 3 , 0 , 0 , 0 ) )
[1] 4
3.20 Web-Enabling R Functions
When building a user-friendly system it may be useful to run R programs from a web page as interface. This is quite easy to implement and
the following is a simple example of how this is done. This is an extract
of my blog post at
http://sanjivdas.wordpress.com/2010/11/07/
web-enabling-r-functions-with-cgi-on-a-mac-os-x-desktop/
This is just an example based on the “Rcgi” package from David Firth,
and for full details of using R with CGI, see
http://www.omegahat.org/CGIwithR/.
You can install the package as follows:
i n s t a l l . packages ( " CGIwithR " , repos = " h t t p : / /www. omegahat . org / R" , type= " s o u r c e " )
The following is the Windows equivalent:1
1
Thanks Alice Yehjin Jun.
# 1 ) C r e a t e f o l d "www" i n " Documents " , c r e a t e " c g i −b i n " i n "www" , p l a c e f i l e s i n " c g
# 2 ) Open command prompt . Run t h e f o l l o w i n g
i c a c l s "C: \ Users\UserName\Documents\www\c g i −bin \ . R p r o f i l e " / g r a n t Users : ( CI ) ( OI ) F
i c a c l s "C: \ Users\UserName\Documents\www\c g i −bin\R . c g i " / g r a n t Users : ( CI ) ( OI ) F
Download the document on using R with CGI. It’s titled “CGIwithR:
Facilities for Processing Web Forms with R”.
Of course, if you don’t have R at all, then download R and install it
from http://www.r-project.org/. Then use the R package manager to
install the Rcgi package.
You need two program files to get everything working. (a) The html
file that is the web form for input data. (b) The R file, with special tags
for use with the CGIwithR package.
Our example will be simple, i.e., a calculator to work out the monthly
payment on a standard fixed rate mortgage. The three inputs are the
98
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
loan principal, annual loan rate, and the number of remaining months to
maturity.
But first, let’s create the html file for the web page that will take these
three input values. We call it “mortgage calc.html”. The code is all
standard, for those familiar with html, and even if you are not used to
html, the code is self-explanatory. See Figure 3.4.
Figure 3.4: HTML code for the Rcgi
application.
Notice that line 06 will be the one referencing the R program that does
the calculation. The three inputs are accepted in lines 08-10. Line 12
sends the inputs to the R program.
Next, we look at the R program, suitably modified to include html
tags. We name it "mortgage calc.R". See Figure 3.5.
We can see that all html calls in the R program are made using the
“tag()” construct. Lines 22–35 take in the three inputs from the html
form. Lines 43–44 do the calculations and line 45 prints the result. The
“cat()” function prints its arguments to the web browser page.
Okay, we have seen how the two programs (html, R) are written and
these templates may be used with changes as needed. We also need
to pay attention to setting up the R environment to make sure that the
function is served up by the system. The following steps are needed:
Make sure that your Mac is allowing connections to its web server. Go
to System Preferences and choose Sharing. In this window enable Web
open source: modeling in r
Sharing by ticking the box next to it.
Place the html file “mortgage calc.html” in the directory that serves up
web pages. On a Mac, there is already a web directory for this called
“Sites”. It’s a good idea to open a separate subdirectory called (say)
“Rcgi” below this one for the R related programs and put the html file
there.
The R program “mortgage calc.R” must go in the directory that has
been assigned for CGI executables. On a Mac, the default for this directory is “/Library/WebServer/CGI-Executables” and is usually referenced by the alias “cgi-bin” (stands for cgi binaries). Drop the R program into this directory. Two more important files are created when you
install the Rcgi package. The CGIwithR installation creates two files: (a)
A hidden file called .Rprofile; (b) A file called R.cgi. Place both these
files in the directory: /Library/WebServer/CGI-Executables
If you cannot find the .Rprofile file then create it directly by opening
a text editor and adding two lines to the file:
# ! / usr / bin /R
l i b r a r y ( CGIwithR , warn . c o n f l i c t s =FALSE )
Now, open the R.cgi file and make sure that the line pointing to the R
executable in the file is showing
R_DEFAULT= / usr / bin /R
The file may actually have it as “#!/usr/local/bin/R” which is for
Linux platforms, but the usual Mac install has the executable in “#!
/usr/bin/R” so make sure this is done.
Make both files executable as follows:
chmod a+rx .Rprofile
chmod a+rx R.cgi
Finally, make the ∼/Sites/Rcgi/ directory write accessible:
chmod a+wx ∼/Sites/Rcgi
Just being patient and following all the steps makes sure it all works
well. Having done it once, it’s easy to repeat and create several functions. You can try this example out on my web server at the following
link.
The inputs are as follows: Loan principal (enter a dollar amount).
Annual loan rate (enter it in decimals, e.g., six percent is entered as 0.06).
Remaining maturity in months (enter 300 if the remaining maturity is 25
years).
99
100
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
Recently the open source project Shiny has become a popular approach to creating R-enabled web pages. See http://shiny.rstudio.com/.
This creates dynamic web pages with sliders and buttons and is a powerful tool for representing analytics and visualizations.
open source: modeling in r
Figure 3.5: R code for the Rcgi
application.
101
4
MoRe: Data Handling and Other Useful Things
In this chapter, we will revisit some of the topics considered in the previous chapters, and demonstrate alternate programming approaches in
R. There are some extremely powerful packages in R that allow sql-like
operations on data sets, making for advanced data handling. One of the
most time-consuming activities in data analytics is cleaning and arranging data, and here we will show examples of many tools available for
that purpose.
Let’s assume we have a good working knowledge of R by now. Here
we revisit some more packages, functions, and data structures.
4.1 Data Extraction of stocks using quantmod
We have seen the package already in the previous chapter. Now, we
proceed to use it to get some initial data.
l i b r a r y ( quantmod )
t i c k e r s = c ( "AAPL" , "YHOO" , "IBM" , "CSCO" , "C" , "GSPC" )
getSymbols ( t i c k e r s )
[ 1 ] "AAPL" "YHOO" "IBM"
"CSCO" "C"
"GSPC"
Print the length of each stock series. Are they all the same? Here we
need to extract the ticker symbol without quotes.
for ( t in t i c k e r s ) {
a = g e t ( noquote ( t ) ) [ , 1 ]
p r i n t ( c ( t , length ( a ) ) )
}
[ 1 ] "AAPL" " 2229 "
104
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
[1]
[1]
[1]
[1]
[1]
"YHOO"
"IBM"
"CSCO"
"C"
"GSPC"
" 2229 "
" 2229 "
" 2229 "
" 2229 "
" 2222 "
We see that they are not all the same. The stock series are all the same
length but the S&P index is shorter by 7 days.
Convert closing adjusted prices of all stocks into individual data.frames.
First, we create a list of data.frames. This will also illustrate how useful
lists are because we store data.frames in lists. Notice how we also add
a new column to each data.frame so that the dates column may later be
used as an index to join the individual stock data.frames into one composite data.frame.
df = l i s t ( )
j = 0
for ( t in t i c k e r s ) {
j = j + 1
a = noquote ( t )
b = data . frame ( g e t ( a ) [ , 6 ] )
b$ dt = row . names ( b )
df [ [ j ] ] = b
}
Second, we combine all the stocks adjusted closing prices into a single
data.frame using a join, excluding all dates for which all stocks do not
have data. The main function used here is *merge* which could be an
intersect join or a union join. The default is the intersect join.
s t o c k _ t a b l e = df [ [ 1 ] ]
f o r ( j i n 2 : length ( df ) ) {
s t o c k _ t a b l e = merge ( s t o c k _ t a b l e , df [ [ j ] ] , by= " dt " )
}
dim ( s t o c k _ t a b l e )
[ 1 ] 2222
7
Note that the stock table contains the number of rows of the stock index,
which had fewer observations than the individual stocks. So since this is
an intersect join, some rows have been dropped.
Plot all stocks in a single data.frame using ggplot2, which is more
more: data handling and other useful things
advanced than the basic plot function. We use the basic plot function
first.
par ( mfrow=c ( 3 , 2 ) )
# Set the plot area to six p l o t s
f o r ( j i n 1 : length ( t i c k e r s ) ) {
p l o t ( as . Date ( s t o c k _ t a b l e [ , 1 ] ) , s t o c k _ t a b l e [ , j + 1 ] , type= " l " ,
ylab= t i c k e r s [ j ] , x l a b = " date " )
}
par ( mfrow=c ( 1 , 1 ) ) # S e t t h e p l o t f i g u r e b a c k t o a s i n g l e p l o t
The plot is shown in Figure 4.1.
Figure 4.1: Plots of the six stock
series extracted from the web.
Convert the data into returns. These are continuously compounded
returns, or log returns.
n = length ( s t o c k _ t a b l e [ , 1 ] )
r e t s = s t o c k _ t a b l e [ , 2 : ( length ( t i c k e r s ) + 1 ) ]
f o r ( j i n 1 : length ( t i c k e r s ) ) {
105
106
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
r e t s [ 2 : n , j ] = d i f f ( log ( r e t s [ , j ] ) )
}
r e t s $ dt = s t o c k _ t a b l e $ dt
rets = rets [2:n , ]
# l o s e t h e f i r s t row when c o n v e r t i n g t o r e t u r n s
head ( r e t s )
2
3
4
5
6
7
2
3
4
5
6
7
AAPL . Adjusted
0.021952927
− 0.007146655
0.004926130
0.079799667
0.046745828
− 0.012448245
GSPC . Adjusted
− 0.0003791652
0.0000000000
0.0093169957
− 0.0127420077
0.0000000000
0.0053254100
YHOO. Adjusted
0.047282882
0.032609594
0.006467863
− 0.012252406
0.039806285
0.017271586
dt
2007 − 01 − 04
2007 − 01 − 05
2007 − 01 − 08
2007 − 01 − 09
2007 − 01 − 10
2007 − 01 − 11
IBM . Adjusted CSCO . Adjusted
0.010635139 0.0259847196
− 0.009094215 0 . 0 0 0 3 5 1 3 1 3 9
0.015077743 0.0056042225
0 . 0 1 1 7 6 0 6 9 1 − 0.0056042225
− 0.011861828 0 . 0 0 7 3 4 9 1 4 5 2
− 0.002429865 0 . 0 0 0 3 4 8 6 1 9 5
C . Adjusted
− 0.0034448850
− 0.0052808346
0.0050992429
− 0.0087575599
− 0.0080957651
0.0007387328
The data.frame of returns can be used to present the descriptive statistics of returns.
summary ( r e t s )
AAPL . Adjusted
Min .
: − 0.197470
1 s t Qu. : − 0 . 0 0 9 0 0 0
Median : 0 . 0 0 1 1 9 2
Mean
: 0.001074
3 rd Qu . : 0 . 0 1 2 2 4 2
Max .
: 0.130194
CSCO . Adjusted
Min .
: − 0.1768648
1 s t Qu. : − 0 . 0 0 8 2 0 4 8
Median : 0 . 0 0 0 3 5 1 3
Mean
: 0.0000663
3 rd Qu . : 0 . 0 0 9 2 1 2 9
Max .
: 0.1479929
YHOO. Adjusted
Min .
: − 0.2340251
1 s t Qu. : − 0 . 0 1 1 3 1 0 1
Median : 0 . 0 0 0 2 2 3 8
Mean
: 0.0001302
3 rd Qu . : 0 . 0 1 1 8 0 5 1
Max .
: 0.3918166
C . Adjusted
Min .
: − 0.4946962
1 s t Qu. : − 0 . 0 1 2 7 7 1 6
Median : − 0.0002122
Mean
: − 0.0009834
3 rd Qu . : 0 . 0 1 2 0 0 0 2
Max .
: 0.4563162
IBM . Adjusted
Min .
: − 0.0864191
1 s t Qu. : − 0 . 0 0 6 5 1 7 2
Median : 0 . 0 0 0 3 0 4 4
Mean
: 0.0002388
3 rd Qu . : 0 . 0 0 7 6 5 7 8
Max .
: 0.1089889
GSPC . Adjusted
Min .
: − 0.1542679
1 s t Qu. : − 0 . 0 0 4 4 2 6 6
Median : 0 . 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
Mean
: 0.0001072
3 rd Qu . : 0 . 0 0 4 9 9 9 9
Max .
: 0.1967146
more: data handling and other useful things
dt
Length : 2 2 2 1
Class : character
Mode : c h a r a c t e r
Now we compute the correlation matrix of returns.
c o r ( r e t s [ , 1 : length ( t i c k e r s ) ] )
AAPL . Adjusted
YHOO. Adjusted
IBM . Adjusted
CSCO . Adjusted
C . Adjusted
GSPC . Adjusted
AAPL . Adjusted
YHOO. Adjusted
IBM . Adjusted
CSCO . Adjusted
C . Adjusted
GSPC . Adjusted
AAPL . Adjusted YHOO. Adjusted IBM . Adjusted CSCO . Adjusted
1.0000000
0.3529739
0.4887079
0.4903812
0.3529739
1.0000000
0.3817138
0.4132464
0.4887079
0.3817138
1.0000000
0.5792123
0.4903812
0.4132464
0.5792123
1.0000000
0.3739598
0.3362138
0.4322276
0.4648106
0.2252352
0.1686898
0.2052341
0.2363631
C . Adjusted GSPC . Adjusted
0.3739598
0.2252352
0.3362138
0.1686898
0.4322276
0.2052341
0.4648106
0.2363631
1.0000000
0.3367560
0.3367560
1.0000000
Show the correlogram for the six return series. This is a useful way to
visualize the relationship between all variables in the data set. See Figure
4.2.
l i b r a r y ( corrgram )
corrgram ( r e t s [ , 1 : length ( t i c k e r s ) ] , order=TRUE, lower . panel=panel . e l l i p s e ,
upper . panel=panel . pts , t e x t . panel=panel . t x t )
To see the relation between the stocks and the index, run a regression
of each of the five stocks on the index returns.
b e t a s = NULL
f o r ( j i n 1 : ( length ( t i c k e r s ) − 1)) {
r e s = lm ( r e t s [ , j ] ~ r e t s [ , 6 ] )
betas [ j ] = res $ coefficients [ 2 ]
}
print ( betas )
[ 1 ] 0.2912491 0.2576751 0.1780251 0.2803140 0.8254747
107
108
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
Figure 4.2: Plots of the correlation
matrix of six stock series extracted
from the web.
The βs indicate the level of systematic risk for each stock. We notice that
all the betas are positive, and highly significant. But they are not close
to unity, in fact all are lower. This is evidence of misspecification that
may arise from the fact that the stocks are in the tech sector and better
explanatory power would come from an index that was more relevant to
the technology sector.
In order to assess whether in the cross-section, there is a relation between average returns and the systematic risk or β of a stock, run a regression of the five average returns on the five betas from the regression.
b e t a s = matrix ( b e t a s )
a v g r e t s = colMeans ( r e t s [ , 1 : ( length ( t i c k e r s ) − 1 ) ] )
r e s = lm ( a v g r e t s ~ b e t a s )
summary ( r e s )
plot ( betas , avgrets )
a b l i n e ( re s , c o l = " red " )
See Figure 4.3. We see indeed, that there is an unexpected negative relation between β and the return levels. This may be on account of the
particular small sample we used for illustration here, however, we note
that the CAPM (Capital Asset Pricing Model) dictate that we see a positive relation between stock returns and a firm’s systematic risk level.
more: data handling and other useful things
109
Figure 4.3: Regression of stock
average returns against systematic
risk (β).
4.2 Using the merge function
Data frames a very much like spreadsheets or tables, but they are also
a lot like databases. Some sort of happy medium. If you want to join
two dataframes, it is the same a joining two databases. For this R has the
merge function. It is best illustrated with an example.
Suppose we have a list of ticker symbols and we want to generate
a dataframe with more details on these tickers, especially their sector
and the full name of the company. Let’s look at the input list of tickers.
Suppose I have them in a file called tickers.csv where the delimiter is
the colon sign. We read this in as follows.
t i c k e r s = read . t a b l e ( " t i c k e r s . csv " , header=FALSE , sep= " : " )
The line of code reads in the file and this gives us two columns of
data. We can look at the top of the file (first 6 rows).
> head ( t i c k e r s )
V1
V2
1 NasdaqGS ACOR
2 NasdaqGS AKAM
3
NYSE ARE
110
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
4 NasdaqGS AMZN
5 NasdaqGS AAPL
6 NasdaqGS AREX
Note that the ticker symbols relate to stocks from different exchanges,
in this case Nasdaq and NYSE. The file may also contain AMEX listed
stocks.
The second line of code below counts the number of input tickers, and
the third line of code renames the columns of the dataframe. We need
to call the column of ticker symbols as “Symbol” because we will see
that the dataframe with which we will merge this one also has a column
with the same name. This column becomes the index on which the two
dataframes are matched and joined.
> n = dim ( t i c k e r s ) [ 1 ]
> n
[ 1 ] 98
> names ( t i c k e r s ) = c ( " Exchange " , " Symbol " )
> head ( t i c k e r s )
Exchange Symbol
1 NasdaqGS
ACOR
2 NasdaqGS
AKAM
3
NYSE
ARE
4 NasdaqGS
AMZN
5 NasdaqGS
AAPL
6 NasdaqGS
AREX
Next, we read in lists of all stocks on Nasdaq, NYSE, and AMEX as
follows:
l i b r a r y ( quantmod )
nasdaq _names = stockSymbols ( exchange= "NASDAQ" )
nyse _names = stockSymbols ( exchange= "NYSE" )
amex_names = stockSymbols ( exchange= "AMEX" )
We can look at the top of the Nasdaq file.
> head ( nasdaq _names )
Symbol
Name L a s t S a l e MarketCap IPOyear
1
AAAP Advanced A c c e l e r a t o r A p p l i c a t i o n s S .A.
2 5 . 2 0 $ 9 7 2 . 0 9M
2015
2
AAL
American A i r l i n e s Group , I n c .
42.20
$ 26.6B
NA
3
AAME
A t l a n t i c American Corporation
4.69
$ 9 6 . 3 7M
NA
4
AAOI
Applied O p t o e l e c t r o n i c s , I n c .
1 7 . 9 6 $ 3 0 2 . 3 6M
2013
5
AAON
AAON, I n c .
24.13
$ 1.31B
NA
more: data handling and other useful things
6
1
2
3
4
5
6
AAPC
A t l a n t i c A l l i a n c e P a r t n e r s h i p Corp .
1 0 . 1 6 $ 1 0 5 . 5 4M
Sector
I n d u s t r y Exchange
Health Care
Major P h a r m a c e u t i c a l s
NASDAQ
Transportation
Air F r e i g h t / D e l i v e r y S e r v i c e s
NASDAQ
Finance
L i f e Insurance
NASDAQ
Technology
Semiconductors
NASDAQ
C a p i t a l Goods I n d u s t r i a l Machinery / Components
NASDAQ
Finance
Business Services
NASDAQ
2015
Next we merge all three dataframes for each of the exchanges into one
data frame.
co _names = rbind ( nyse _names , nasdaq _names , amex_names )
To see how many rows are there in this merged file, we check dimensions.
> dim ( co _names )
[ 1 ] 6801
8
Finally, use the merge function to combine the ticker symbols file with
the exchanges data to extend the tickers file to include the information
from the exchanges file.
> r e s u l t = merge ( t i c k e r s , co _names , by= " Symbol " )
> head ( r e s u l t )
Symbol Exchange . x
1
AAPL
NasdaqGS
Apple
2
ACOR
NasdaqGS
Acorda T h e r a p e u t i c s ,
3
AKAM
NasdaqGS
Akamai Technologies ,
4
AMZN
NasdaqGS
Amazon . com ,
5
ARE
NYSE Alexandria Real E s t a t e E q u i t i e s ,
6
AREX
NasdaqGS
Approach Resources
MarketCap IPOyear
Sector
1 $ 665.14B
1980
Technology
2
$ 1.61B
2006
Health Care
3
$ 10.13B
1999
Miscellaneous
4 $ 313.34B
1997 Consumer S e r v i c e s
5
$ 6.6B
NA Consumer S e r v i c e s
6
$ 9 0 . 6 5M
2007
Energy
Name L a s t S a l e
Inc .
119.30
Inc .
37.40
Inc .
56.92
Inc .
668.45
Inc .
91.10
Inc .
2.24
I n d u s t r y Exchange . y
1
Computer Manufacturing
NASDAQ
2 B i o t e c h n o l o g y : B i o l o g i c a l Products (No D i a g n o s t i c S u b s t a n c e s )
NASDAQ
3
Business Services
NASDAQ
4
Catalog / S p e c i a l t y D i s t r i b u t i o n
NASDAQ
5
Real E s t a t e Investment T r u s t s
NYSE
6
O i l & Gas Production
NASDAQ
Now suppose we want to find the CEOs of these 98 companies. There
is no one file with compay CEO listings freely available for download.
111
112
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
However, sites like Google Finance have a page for each stock and mention the CEOs name on the page. By writing R code to scrape the data
off these pages one by one, we can extract these CEO names and augment the tickers dataframe. The code for this is simple in R.
library ( stringr )
#READ IN THE LIST OF TICKERS
t i c k e r s = read . t a b l e ( " t i c k e r s . csv " , header=FALSE , sep= " : " )
n = dim ( t i c k e r s ) [ 1 ]
names ( t i c k e r s ) = c ( " Exchange " , " Symbol " )
t i c k e r s $ ceo = NA
#PULL CEO NAMES FROM GOOGLE FINANCE
for ( j in 1 : n ) {
u r l = p a s t e ( " h t t p s : / /www. google . com / f i n a n c e ?q= " , t i c k e r s [ j , 2 ] , sep= " " )
t e x t = readLines ( url )
idx = grep ( " C h i e f E x e c u t i v e " , t e x t )
i f ( length ( idx ) > 0 ) {
t i c k e r s [ j , 3 ] = s t r _ s p l i t ( t e x t [ idx − 2] , " > " ) [ [ 1 ] ] [ 2 ]
}
else {
t i c k e r s [ j , 3 ] = NA
}
print ( t i c k e r s [ j , ] )
}
#WRITE CEO_NAMES TO CSV
w r i t e . t a b l e ( t i c k e r s , f i l e = " ceo _names . csv " ,
row . names=FALSE , sep= " , " )
The code uses the stringr package so that string handling is simplified. After extracting the page, we search for the line in which the words
“Chief Executive” show up, and we note that the name of the CEO appears two lines before in the html page. A sample web page for Apple
Inc is shown in Figure 4.4.
The final dataframe with CEO names is shown here (the top 6 lines):
> head ( t i c k e r s )
Exchange Symbol
1 NasdaqGS
ACOR
ceo
Ron Cohen M.D.
more: data handling and other useful things
113
Figure 4.4: Google Finance: the
AAPL web page showing the URL
which is needed to download the
page.
114
2
3
4
5
6
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
NasdaqGS
NYSE
NasdaqGS
NasdaqGS
NasdaqGS
AKAM
F . Thomson Leighton
ARE J o e l S . Marcus J .D. , CPA
AMZN
J e f f r e y P . Bezos
AAPL
Timothy D. Cook
AREX
J . Ross C r a f t
4.3 Using the apply class of functions
Sometimes we need to apply a function to many cases, and these case
parameters may be supplied in a vector, matrix, or list. This is analogous
to looping through a set of values to repeat evaluations of a function
using different sets of parameters. We illustrate here by computing the
mean returns of all stocks in our sample using the apply function. The
first argument of the function is the data.frame to which it is being applied, the second argument is either 1 (by rows) or 2 (by columns). The
third argument is the function being evaluated.
apply ( r e t s [ , 1 : ( length ( t i c k e r s ) − 1 ) ] , 2 , mean )
AAPL . Adjusted YHOO. Adjusted
1 . 0 7 3 9 0 2 e −03 1 . 3 0 2 3 0 9 e −04
IBM . Adjusted CSCO . Adjusted
C . Adjusted
2 . 3 8 8 2 0 7 e −04 6 . 6 2 9 9 4 6 e −05 − 9.833602 e −04
We see that the function returns the column means of the data set.
The variants of the function pertain to what the loop is being applied to.
The lapply is a function applied to a list, and sapply is for matrices and
vectors. Likewise, mapply uses multiple arguments.
To cross check, we can simply use the colMeans function:
colMeans ( r e t s [ , 1 : ( length ( t i c k e r s ) − 1 ) ] )
AAPL . Adjusted YHOO. Adjusted
1 . 0 7 3 9 0 2 e −03 1 . 3 0 2 3 0 9 e −04
IBM . Adjusted CSCO . Adjusted
C . Adjusted
2 . 3 8 8 2 0 7 e −04 6 . 6 2 9 9 4 6 e −05 − 9.833602 e −04
As we see, this result is verified.
4.4 Getting interest rate data from FRED
In finance, data on interest rates is widely used. An authoritative source
of data on interest rates is FRED (Federal Reserve Economic Data), maintained by the St. Louis Federal Reserve Bank, and is warehoused at the
more: data handling and other useful things
following web site: https://research.stlouisfed.org/fred2/. Let’s assume that we want to download the data using R from FRED directly. To
do this we need to write some custom code. There used to be a package
for this but since the web site changed, it has been updated but does not
work properly. Still, see that it is easy to roll your own code quite easily
in R.
#FUNCTION TO READ IN CSV FILES FROM FRED
# Enter SeriesID as a t e x t s t r i n g
readFRED = f u n c t i o n ( S e r i e s I D ) {
u r l = p a s t e ( " h t t p s : / / r e s e a r c h . s t l o u i s f e d . org / f r e d 2 / s e r i e s / " , S e r i e s I D ,
" / downloaddata / " , S e r i e s I D , " . csv " , sep= " " )
data = r e a d L i n e s ( u r l )
n = length ( data )
data = data [ 2 : n ]
n = length ( data )
df = matrix ( 0 , n , 2 )
# top l i n e i s header
for ( j in 1 : n ) {
tmp = s t r s p l i t ( data [ j ] , " , " )
df [ j , 1 ] = tmp [ [ 1 ] ] [ 1 ]
df [ j , 2 ] = tmp [ [ 1 ] ] [ 2 ]
}
r a t e = as . numeric ( df [ , 2 ] )
idx = which ( r a t e >0)
idx = s e t d i f f ( seq ( 1 , n ) , idx )
r a t e [ idx ] = −99
date = df [ , 1 ]
df = data . frame ( date , r a t e )
names ( df ) [ 2 ] = S e r i e s I D
r e s u l t = df
}
Now, we provide a list of economic time series and download data
accordingly using the function above. Note that we also join these individual series using the data as index. We download constant maturity
interest rates (yields) starting from a maturity of one month (DGS1MO)
to a maturity of thirty years (DGS30).
#EXTRACT TERM STRUCTURE DATA FOR ALL RATES FROM 1 MO t o 30 YRS FROM FRED
id _ l i s t = c ( "DGS1MO" , "DGS3MO" , "DGS6MO" , "DGS1" , "DGS2" , "DGS3" , "DGS5" , "DGS7" ,
" DGS10 " , " DGS20 " , " DGS30 " )
115
116
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
k = 0
f o r ( id i n id _ l i s t ) {
out = readFRED ( id )
i f ( k >0) { r a t e s = merge ( r a t e s , out , " date " , a l l =TRUE) }
e l s e { r a t e s = out }
k = k + 1
}
> head ( r a t e s )
date DGS1MO DGS3MO DGS6MO DGS1 DGS2
1 2001 − 07 − 31
3.67
3.54
3.47 3.53 3.79
5.51
2 2001 − 08 − 01
3.65
3.53
3.47 3.56 3.83
5.53
3 2001 − 08 − 02
3.65
3.53
3.46 3.57 3.89
5.57
4 2001 − 08 − 03
3.63
3.52
3.47 3.57 3.91
5.59
5 2001 − 08 − 06
3.62
3.52
3.47 3.56 3.88
5.59
6 2001 − 08 − 07
3.63
3.52
3.47 3.56 3.90
5.60
DGS3 DGS5 DGS7 DGS10 DGS20 DGS30
4.06 4.57 4.86 5.07 5.61
4.09 4.62 4.90
5.11
5.63
4.17 4.69 4.97
5.17
5.68
4.22 4.72 4.99
5.20
5.70
4.17 4.71 4.99
5.19
5.70
4.19 4.72 5.00
5.20
5.71
Having done this, we now have a data.frame called rates containing
all the time series we are interested in. We now convert the dates into
numeric strings and sort the data.frame by date.
#CONVERT ALL DATES TO NUMERIC AND SORT BY DATE
dates = r a t e s [ , 1 ]
library ( stringr )
d a t e s = as . numeric ( s t r _ r e p l a c e _ a l l ( dates , "− " , " " ) )
r e s = s o r t ( dates , index . r e t u r n =TRUE)
f o r ( j i n 1 : dim ( r a t e s ) [ 2 ] ) {
r a t e s [ , j ] = r a t e s [ r e s $ ix , j ]
}
> head ( r a t e s )
date DGS1MO DGS3MO DGS6MO DGS1 DGS2 DGS3 DGS5 DGS7 DGS10 DGS20 DGS30
1 1962 − 01 − 02
NA
NA
NA 3 . 2 2
NA 3 . 7 0 3 . 8 8
NA 4 . 0 6
NA
more: data handling and other useful things
NA
2 1962 − 01 − 03
NA
3 1962 − 01 − 04
NA
4 1962 − 01 − 05
NA
5 1962 − 01 − 08
NA
6 1962 − 01 − 09
NA
NA
NA
NA 3 . 2 4
NA 3 . 7 0 3 . 8 7
NA
4.03
NA
NA
NA
NA 3 . 2 4
NA 3 . 6 9 3 . 8 6
NA
3.99
NA
NA
NA
NA 3 . 2 6
NA 3 . 7 1 3 . 8 9
NA
4.02
NA
NA
NA
NA 3 . 3 1
NA 3 . 7 1 3 . 9 1
NA
4.03
NA
NA
NA
NA 3 . 3 2
NA 3 . 7 4 3 . 9 3
NA
4.05
NA
117
Note that there are missing values, denoted by NA. Also there are rows
with "-99" values and we can clean those out too but they represent periods when there was no yield available of that maturity, so we leave this
in.
#REMOVE THE NA ROWS
idx = which ( rowSums ( i s . na ( r a t e s ) ) = = 0 )
r a t e s 2 = r a t e s [ idx , ]
p r i n t ( head ( r a t e s 2 ) )
date DGS1MO DGS3MO DGS6MO DGS1 DGS2
10326 2001 − 07 − 31
3.67
3.54
3.47 3.53 3.79
5.51
10327 2001 − 08 − 01
3.65
3.53
3.47 3.56 3.83
5.53
10328 2001 − 08 − 02
3.65
3.53
3.46 3.57 3.89
5.57
10329 2001 − 08 − 03
3.63
3.52
3.47 3.57 3.91
5.59
10330 2001 − 08 − 06
3.62
3.52
3.47 3.56 3.88
5.59
10331 2001 − 08 − 07
3.63
3.52
3.47 3.56 3.90
5.60
DGS3 DGS5 DGS7 DGS10 DGS20 DGS30
4.06 4.57 4.86 5.07 5.61
4.09 4.62 4.90
5.11
5.63
4.17 4.69 4.97
5.17
5.68
4.22 4.72 4.99
5.20
5.70
4.17 4.71 4.99
5.19
5.70
4.19 4.72 5.00
5.20
5.71
4.5 Cross-Sectional Data (an example)
A great resource for data sets in corporate finance is on Aswath Damodaran’s
web site, see:
118
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
http://people.stern.nyu.edu/adamodar/New_Home_Page/data.html
Financial statement data sets are available at:
http://www.sec.gov/dera/data/financial-statement-data-sets.html
And another comprehensive data source:
http://fisher.osu.edu/fin/fdf/osudata.htm
Open government data: https://www.data.gov/finance/
Let’s read in the list of failed banks:
http://www.fdic.gov/bank/individual/failed/banklist.csv
# d o w n l o a d . f i l e ( u r l =" h t t p : / /www. f d i c . gov / bank / i n d i v i d u a l / f a i l e d /
b a n k l i s t . csv " , d e s t f i l e = " f a i l e d _ banks . csv " )
(This does not work, and has been an issue for a while.)
You can also read in the data using readLines but then further work is
required to clean it up, but it works well in downloading the data.
data = r e a d L i n e s ( " h t t p s : / /www. f d i c . gov / bank / i n d i v i d u a l / f a i l e d / b a n k l i s t . csv " )
head ( data )
[1]
[2]
[3]
[4]
[5]
[6]
" Bank Name, City , ST , CERT , Acquiring I n s t i t u t i o n , Clos ing Date , Updated Date "
"Hometown N a t i o n a l Bank , Longview ,WA, 3 5 1 5 6 , Twin C i t y Bank,2 − Oct − 15,15 − Oct −15 "
" The Bank o f Georgia , P e a c h t r e e City ,GA, 3 5 2 5 9 , F i d e l i t y Bank,2 − Oct − 15,15 − Oct −15 "
" Premier Bank , Denver , CO, 3 4 1 1 2 , \ " United F i d e l i t y Bank , f s b \ " ,10 − J u l − 15,28 − J u l −15 "
" Edgebrook Bank , Chicago , IL , 5 7 7 7 2 , Republic Bank o f Chicago ,8 −May− 15,23 − J u l −15 "
" Doral Bank , San Juan , PR, 3 2 1 0 2 , Banco Popular de Puerto Rico ,27 − Feb − 15,13 −May−15 "
It may be simpler to just download the data and read it in from the
csv file:
data = read . csv ( " b a n k l i s t . csv " , header=TRUE)
p r i n t ( names ( data ) )
[ 1 ] " Bank . Name"
[ 4 ] "CERT"
[ 7 ] " Updated . Date "
" City "
" ST "
" Acquiring . I n s t i t u t i o n " " Closi ng . Date "
This gives a data.frame which is easy to work with. We will illustrate
some interesting ways in which to manipulate this data. Suppose we
want to get subtotals of how many banks failed by state. First add a
column of ones to the data.frame.
p r i n t ( head ( data ) )
data $ count = 1
p r i n t ( head ( data ) )
Bank . Name
C i t y ST
more: data handling and other useful things
1
Hometown N a t i o n a l Bank
Longview WA
2
The Bank o f Georgia P e a c h t r e e C i t y GA
3
Premier Bank
Denver CO
4
Edgebrook Bank
Chicago IL
5
Doral Bank
San Juan PR
6 C a p i t o l C i t y Bank & T r u s t Company
A t l a n t a GA
CERT
Acquiring . I n s t i t u t i o n Closing . Date
1 35156
Twin C i t y Bank
2−Oct −15
2 35259
F i d e l i t y Bank
2−Oct −15
3 34112
United F i d e l i t y Bank , f s b
10− J u l −15
4 57772
Republic Bank o f Chicago
8−May−15
5 32102
Banco Popular de Puerto Rico
27− Feb −15
6 33938 F i r s t −C i t i z e n s Bank & T r u s t Company
13− Feb −15
Updated . Date count
1
15− Oct −15
1
2
15− Oct −15
1
3
28− J u l −15
1
4
23− J u l −15
1
5
13−May−15
1
6
21−Apr−15
1
It’s good to check that there is no missing data.
any ( i s . na ( data ) )
[ 1 ] FALSE
Now we sort the data by state to see how many there are.
r e s = s o r t ( as . matrix ( data $ST ) , index . r e t u r n =TRUE)
p r i n t ( data [ r e s $ ix , ] )
p r i n t ( s o r t ( unique ( data $ST ) ) )
[ 1 ] AL AR AZ
[ 1 9 ] MI MN MO
[ 3 7 ] TN TX UT
44 L e v e l s : AL
CA
MS
VA
AR
CO
NC
WA
AZ
CT
NE
WI
CA
FL GA HI IA ID IL IN KS KY LA MA MD
NH NJ NM NV NY OH OK OR PA PR SC SD
WV WY
CO CT FL GA HI IA ID IL IN . . . WY
p r i n t ( length ( unique ( data $ST ) ) )
[ 1 ] 44
We can directly use the aggregate function to get subtotals by state.
119
120
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
head ( a g g r e g a t e ( count ~ ST , data , sum ) , 1 0 )
ST count
1 AL
7
2 AR
3
3 AZ
16
4 CA
41
5 CO
10
6 CT
2
7 FL
75
8 GA
92
9 HI
1
10 IA
2
And another example, subtotal by acquiring bank. Note how we take the
subtotals into another data.frame, which is then sorted and returned in
order using the index of the sort.
acq = a g g r e g a t e ( count~Acquiring . I n s t i t u t i o n , data , sum)
idx = s o r t ( as . matrix ( acq $ count ) , d e c r e a s i n g =TRUE, index . r e t u r n =TRUE) $ i x
head ( acq [ idx , ] , 1 5 )
170
224
10
262
67
28
47
112
228
49
50
154
205
54
64
Acquiring . I n s t i t u t i o n count
No Acquirer
31
S t a t e Bank and T r u s t Company
12
Ameris Bank
10
U. S . Bank N.A.
9
Community & Southern Bank
8
Bank o f t h e Ozarks
7
C e n t e n n i a l Bank
7
F i r s t −C i t i z e n s Bank & T r u s t Company
7
S t e a r n s Bank , N.A.
7
C e n t e r S t a t e Bank o f F l o r i d a , N.A.
6
C e n t r a l Bank
6
MB F i n a n c i a l Bank , N.A.
6
Republic Bank o f Chicago
6
CertusBank , N a t i o n a l A s s o c i a t i o n
5
Columbia S t a t e Bank
5
more: data handling and other useful things
4.6 Handling dates with lubridate
Suppose we want to take the preceding data.frame of failed banks and
aggregate the data by year, or month, etc. In this case, it us useful to use
a dates package. Another useful tool developed by Hadley Wickham is
the lubridate package.
head ( data )
1
2
3
4
5
6
1
2
3
4
5
6
1
2
3
4
5
6
Bank . Name
City
Hometown N a t i o n a l Bank
Longview
The Bank o f Georgia P e a c h t r e e C i t y
Premier Bank
Denver
Edgebrook Bank
Chicago
Doral Bank
San Juan
C a p i t o l C i t y Bank & T r u s t Company
Atlanta
Acquiring . I n s t i t u t i o n Cl osing . Date
Twin C i t y Bank
2−Oct −15
F i d e l i t y Bank
2−Oct −15
United F i d e l i t y Bank , f s b
10− J u l −15
Republic Bank o f Chicago
8−May−15
Banco Popular de Puerto Rico
27− Feb −15
F i r s t −C i t i z e n s Bank & T r u s t Company
13− Feb −15
Cdate Cyear
2015 − 10 − 02 2015
2015 − 10 − 02 2015
2015 − 07 − 10 2015
2015 − 05 − 08 2015
2015 − 02 − 27 2015
2015 − 02 − 13 2015
library ( lubridate )
data $ Cdate = dmy( data $ Clos ing . Date )
data $ Cyear = year ( data $ Cdate )
fd = a g g r e g a t e ( count~Cyear , data , sum)
p r i n t ( fd )
1
Cyear count
2000
2
ST CERT
WA 35156
GA 35259
CO 34112
IL 57772
PR 32102
GA 33938
Updated . Date count
15− Oct −15
1
15− Oct −15
1
28− J u l −15
1
23− J u l −15
1
13−May−15
1
21−Apr−15
1
121
122
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
2001
2002
2003
2004
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
4
11
3
4
3
25
140
157
92
51
24
18
8
p l o t ( count~Cyear , data=fd , type= " l " , lwd =3 , c o l = " red " x l a b = " Year " )
g r i d ( lwd =3)
See the results in Figure 4.5.
Figure 4.5: Failed bank totals by
year.
Let’s do the same thing by month to see if there is seasonality
data $Cmonth = month ( data $ Cdate )
fd = a g g r e g a t e ( count~Cmonth , data , sum)
p r i n t ( fd )
more: data handling and other useful things
Cmonth count
1
1
49
2
2
44
3
3
38
4
4
57
5
5
40
6
6
36
7
7
74
8
8
40
9
9
37
10
10
58
11
11
35
12
12
34
p l o t ( count~Cmonth , data=fd , type= " l " , lwd =3 , c o l = " green " ) ; g r i d ( lwd =3)
There does not appear to be any seasonality. What about day?
data $Cday = day ( data $ Cdate )
fd = a g g r e g a t e ( count~Cday , data , sum)
p r i n t ( fd )
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
Cday count
1
8
2
20
3
3
4
21
5
15
6
13
7
20
8
14
9
10
10
14
11
17
12
10
13
14
14
20
15
20
16
22
17
23
123
124
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
29
30
31
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
29
30
31
21
29
27
17
18
30
19
13
15
18
18
15
30
8
p l o t ( count~Cday , data=fd , type= " l " , lwd =3 , c o l = " blue " ) ; g r i d ( lwd =3)
Definitely, counts are lower at the start and end of the month!
4.7 Using the data.table package
This is an incredibly useful package that was written by Matt Dowle.
It essentially allows your data.frame to operate as a database. It enables very fast handling of massive quantities of data, and much of
this technology is now embedded in the IP of the company called h2o:
http://h2o.ai/
We start with some freely downloadable crime data statistics for California. We placed the data in a csv file which is then easy to read in to
R.
data = read . csv ( "CA_ Crimes _ Data _ 2004 − 2013. csv " , header=TRUE)
It is easy to convert this into a data.table.
l i b r a r y ( data . t a b l e )
D_T = as . data . t a b l e ( data )
Let’s see how it works, noting that the syntax is similar to that for
data.frames as much as possible. We print only a part of the names list.
And do not go through each and everyone.
p r i n t ( dim (D_T ) )
more: data handling and other useful things
[ 1 ] 7301
69
p r i n t ( names (D_T ) )
[1]
[4]
[7]
[10]
....
" Year "
" V i o l e n t _sum"
" Robbery _sum"
" Burglary _sum"
" County "
" Homicide_sum"
" AggAssault _sum"
" V e h i c l e T h e f t _sum"
"NCICCode"
" ForRape _sum"
" Property _sum"
" L T t o t a l _sum"
head (D_T )
A nice feature of the data.table is that it can be indexed, i.e., resorted
on the fly by making any column in the database the key. Once that is
done, then it becomes easy to compute subtotals, and generate plots
from these subtotals as well.
s e t k e y (D_T , Year )
crime = 6
r e s = D_T [ , sum( ForRape _sum ) , by=Year ]
print ( res )
1:
2:
3:
4:
5:
6:
7:
8:
9:
10:
Year
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
V1
9598
9345
9213
9047
8906
8698
8325
7678
7828
7459
class ( res )
[ 1 ] " data . t a b l e " " data . frame "
125
126
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
See that the type of output is also of the type data.table, and includes the
class data.frame also.
Next, we plot the results from the data.table in the same way as we
would for a data.frame. See Figure 4.6.
p l o t ( r e s $ Year , r e s $V1 , type= " b " , lwd =3 , c o l = " blue " ,
x l a b = " Year " , ylab= " Forced Rape " )
Figure 4.6: Rape totals by year.
Repeat the process looking at crime (Rape) totals by county.
s e t k e y (D_T , County )
r e s = D_T [ , sum( ForRape _sum ) , by=County ]
print ( res )
setnames ( r es , " V1 " , " Rapes " )
County_ Rapes = as . data . t a b l e ( r e s )
s e t k e y ( County_Rapes , Rapes )
County_ Rapes
1:
2:
3:
4:
Sierra
Alpine
Trinity
Mariposa
County Rapes
County
2
County
15
County
28
County
46
# This i s not r e a l l y needed
more: data handling and other useful things
5:
Inyo
6:
Glenn
7:
Colusa
8:
Mono
9:
Modoc
10:
Lassen
11:
Plumas
12:
Siskiyou
13:
Calaveras
14:
San B e n i t o
15:
Amador
16:
Tuolumne
17:
Tehama
18:
Nevada
19:
Del Norte
20:
Lake
21:
Imperial
22:
Sutter
23:
Yuba
24:
Mendocino
25:
El Dorado
26:
Napa
27:
Kings
28:
Madera
29:
Marin
30:
Humboldt
31:
Placer
32:
Yolo
33:
Merced
34:
Santa Cruz
3 5 : San Luis Obispo
36:
Butte
37:
Monterey
38:
Shasta
39:
Tulare
40:
Ventura
41:
Solano
42:
Stanislaus
County
County
County
County
County
County
County
County
County
County
County
County
County
County
County
County
County
County
County
County
County
County
County
County
County
County
County
County
County
County
County
County
County
County
County
County
County
County
52
56
60
61
64
96
115
143
148
151
153
160
165
214
236
262
263
274
277
328
351
354
356
408
452
495
611
729
738
865
900
930
1062
1089
1114
1146
1150
1348
127
128
43:
44:
45:
46:
47:
48:
49:
50:
51:
52:
53:
54:
55:
56:
57:
58:
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
Santa Barbara
San Mateo
San F r a n c i s c o
Sonoma
San Joaquin
Contra Costa
Kern
Fresno
Santa C l a r a
Sacramento
Riverside
Orange
San Bernardino
Alameda
San Diego
Los Angeles
County 1352
County 1381
County 1498
County 1558
County 1612
County 1848
County 1935
County 1960
County 3832
County 4084
County 4321
County 4509
County 4900
County 4979
County 7378
County 21483
Now, we can go ahead and plot it using a different kind of plot, a
horizontal barplot.
par ( l a s =2) # makes l a b e l h o r i z o n t a l
# p a r ( mar=c ( 3 , 4 , 2 , 1 ) ) # i n c r e a s e y− a x i s m a r g i n s
b a r p l o t ( County_ Rapes $Rapes , names . arg=County_ Rapes $County ,
h o r i z =TRUE, cex . names = 0 . 4 , c o l =8)
4.8 Another data set: Bay Area Bike Share data
We show some other features using a different data set, the bike information on Silicon Valley routes for the Bike Share program. This is a
much larger data set.
t r i p s = read . csv ( " 201408 _ t r i p _ data . csv " , header=TRUE)
p r i n t ( names ( t r i p s ) )
[1]
[4]
[7]
[10]
" Trip . ID "
" Start . Station "
" End . S t a t i o n "
" S u b s c r i b e r . Type "
" Duration "
" S t a r t . Terminal "
" End . Terminal "
" Zip . Code "
Next we print some descriptive statistics.
p r i n t ( length ( t r i p s $ Trip . ID ) )
" S t a r t . Date "
" End . Date "
" Bike . . "
more: data handling and other useful things
129
Figure 4.7: Rape totals by county.
[ 1 ] 171792
p r i n t ( summary ( t r i p s $ Duration / 6 0 ) )
Min .
1.000
1 s t Qu .
5.750
Median
8.617
Mean
18.880
3 rd Qu .
Max .
12.680 11940.000
p r i n t ( mean ( t r i p s $ Duration / 6 0 , t r i m = 0 . 0 1 ) )
[ 1 ] 13.10277
Now, we quickly check how many start and end stations there are.
s t a r t _ s t n = unique ( t r i p s $ S t a r t . Terminal )
print ( sort ( s t a r t _ stn ) )
[ 1 ] 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 16 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28
[ 2 3 ] 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 41 42 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 54 55
[ 4 5 ] 56 57 58 59 60 61 62 63 64 65 66 67 68 69 70 71 72 73 74 75 76 77
130
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
[ 6 7 ] 80 82 83 84
p r i n t ( length ( s t a r t _ s t n ) )
[ 1 ] 70
end_ s t n = unique ( t r i p s $End . Terminal )
p r i n t ( s o r t ( end_ s t n ) )
[ 1 ] 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 16 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28
[ 2 3 ] 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 41 42 45 46 47 48 49 50 51 54 55
[ 4 5 ] 56 57 58 59 60 61 62 63 64 65 66 67 68 69 70 71 72 73 74 75 76 77
[ 6 7 ] 80 82 83 84
p r i n t ( length ( end_ s t n ) )
[ 1 ] 70
As we can see, there are quite a few stations in the bike share program
where riders can pick up and drop off bikes. The trip duration information is stored in seconds, so has been converted to minutes in the code
above.
4.9 Using the plyr package family
This package by Hadley Wickham is useful for applying functions to
tables of data, i.e., data.frames. Since we may want to write custom
functions, this is a highly useful package. R users often select either
the data.table or the plyr class of packages for handling data.frames
as databases. The latest incarnation is the dplyr package, which focuses
only on data.frames.
require ( plyr )
l i b r a r y ( dplyr )
One of the useful things you can use is the filter function, to subset
the rows of the dataset you might want to select for further analysis.
r e s = f i l t e r ( t r i p s , S t a r t . Terminal ==50 ,End . Terminal ==51)
head ( r e s )
Trip . ID Duration
S t a r t . Date
1 432024
3954 8 / 30 / 2014 1 4 : 4 6
more: data handling and other useful things
2
3
4
5
6
1
2
3
4
5
6
1
2
3
4
5
6
8 / 30 / 2014 1 4 : 4 4
8 / 30 / 2014 1 2 : 0 4
8 / 30 / 2014 1 2 : 0 3
8 / 29 / 2014 9 : 0 8
8 / 28 / 2014 1 3 : 4 7
S t a r t . S t a t i o n S t a r t . Terminal
End . Date
Harry B r i d g e s P l a z a ( F e r r y B u i l d i n g )
50 8 / 30 / 2014 1 5 : 5 2
Harry B r i d g e s P l a z a ( F e r r y B u i l d i n g )
50 8 / 30 / 2014 1 5 : 5 2
Harry B r i d g e s P l a z a ( F e r r y B u i l d i n g )
50 8 / 30 / 2014 1 2 : 2 4
Harry B r i d g e s P l a z a ( F e r r y B u i l d i n g )
50 8 / 30 / 2014 1 2 : 2 3
Harry B r i d g e s P l a z a ( F e r r y B u i l d i n g )
50 8 / 29 / 2014 9 : 1 1
Harry B r i d g e s P l a z a ( F e r r y B u i l d i n g )
50 8 / 28 / 2014 1 4 : 0 2
End . S t a t i o n End . Terminal Bike . . S u b s c r i b e r . Type Zip . Code
Embarcadero a t Folsom
51
306
Customer
94952
Embarcadero a t Folsom
51
659
Customer
94952
Embarcadero a t Folsom
51
556
Customer
11238
Embarcadero a t Folsom
51
621
Customer
11238
Embarcadero a t Folsom
51
400
Subscriber
94070
Embarcadero a t Folsom
51
589
Subscriber
94107
432022
431895
431891
430408
429148
4120
1196
1249
145
862
The arrange function is useful for sorting by any number of columns
as needed. Here we sort by the start and end stations.
t r i p s _ s o r t e d = arrange ( t r i p s , S t a r t . S t a t i o n , End . S t a t i o n )
head ( t r i p s _ s o r t e d )
1
2
3
4
5
6
1
2
3
4
5
6
Trip . ID Duration
S t a r t . Date S t a r t . S t a t i o n S t a r t . Terminal
426408
120 8 / 27 / 2014 7 : 4 0 2nd a t Folsom
62
411496
21183 8 / 16 / 2014 1 3 : 3 6 2nd a t Folsom
62
396676
3707 8 / 6 / 2014 1 1 : 3 8 2nd a t Folsom
62
385761
123 7 / 29 / 2014 1 9 : 5 2 2nd a t Folsom
62
364633
6395 7 / 15 / 2014 1 3 : 3 9 2nd a t Folsom
62
362776
9433 7 / 14 / 2014 1 3 : 3 6 2nd a t Folsom
62
End . Date
End . S t a t i o n End . Terminal Bike . . S u b s c r i b e r . Type
8 / 27 / 2014 7 : 4 2 2nd a t Folsom
62
527
Subscriber
8 / 16 / 2014 1 9 : 2 9 2nd a t Folsom
62
508
Customer
8 / 6 / 2014 1 2 : 4 0 2nd a t Folsom
62
109
Customer
7 / 29 / 2014 1 9 : 5 5 2nd a t Folsom
62
421
Subscriber
7 / 15 / 2014 1 5 : 2 6 2nd a t Folsom
62
448
Customer
7 / 14 / 2014 1 6 : 1 3 2nd a t Folsom
62
454
Customer
131
132
1
2
3
4
5
6
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
Zip . Code
94107
94105
31200
94107
2184
2184
The sort can also be done in reverse order as follows.
t r i p s _ s o r t e d = arrange ( t r i p s , desc ( S t a r t . S t a t i o n ) , End . S t a t i o n )
head ( t r i p s _ s o r t e d )
1
2
3
4
5
6
1
2
3
4
5
6
1
2
3
4
5
6
1
2
3
4
5
Trip . ID Duration
S t a r t . Date
416755
285 8 / 20 / 2014 1 1 : 3 7
411270
257 8 / 16 / 2014 7 : 0 3
410269
286 8 / 15 / 2014 1 0 : 3 4
405273
382 8 / 12 / 2014 1 4 : 2 7
398372
401 8 / 7 / 2014 1 0 : 1 0
393012
317 8 / 4 / 2014 1 0 : 5 9
S t a r t . S t a t i o n S t a r t . Terminal
Yerba Buena Center o f t h e Arts ( 3 rd @ Howard )
68
Yerba Buena Center o f t h e Arts ( 3 rd @ Howard )
68
Yerba Buena Center o f t h e Arts ( 3 rd @ Howard )
68
Yerba Buena Center o f t h e Arts ( 3 rd @ Howard )
68
Yerba Buena Center o f t h e Arts ( 3 rd @ Howard )
68
Yerba Buena Center o f t h e Arts ( 3 rd @ Howard )
68
End . Date
End . S t a t i o n End . Terminal Bike . . S u b s c r i b e r . Type
8 / 20 / 2014 1 1 : 4 2 2nd a t Folsom
62
383
Customer
8 / 16 / 2014 7 : 0 7 2nd a t Folsom
62
614
Subscriber
8 / 15 / 2014 1 0 : 3 8 2nd a t Folsom
62
545
Subscriber
8 / 12 / 2014 1 4 : 3 4 2nd a t Folsom
62
344
Customer
8 / 7 / 2014 1 0 : 1 6 2nd a t Folsom
62
597
Subscriber
8 / 4 / 2014 1 1 : 0 4 2nd a t Folsom
62
367
Subscriber
Zip . Code
95060
94107
94127
94110
94127
more: data handling and other useful things
6
94127
Data.table also offers a fantastic way to do descriptive statistics! First,
group the data by start point, and then produce statistics by this group,
choosing to count the number of trips starting from each station and the
average duration of each trip.
b y S t a r t S t a t i o n = group_by ( t r i p s , S t a r t . S t a t i o n )
r e s = summarise ( b y S t a r t S t a t i o n , count=n ( ) , time=mean ( Duration ) / 6 0 )
print ( res )
Source : l o c a l data frame [ 7 0 x 3 ]
S t a r t . S t a t i o n count
time
( fctr ) ( int )
( dbl )
1
2nd a t Folsom 4165 9 . 3 2 0 8 8
2
2nd a t South Park 4569 1 1 . 6 0 1 9 5
3
2nd a t Townsend 6824 1 5 . 1 4 7 8 6
4
5 th a t Howard 3183 1 4 . 2 3 2 5 4
5
Adobe on Almaden
360 1 0 . 0 6 1 2 0
6
Arena Green / SAP Center
510 4 3 . 8 2 8 3 3
7
B e a l e a t Market 4293 1 5 . 7 4 7 0 2
8
Broadway a t Main
22 5 4 . 8 2 1 2 1
9
Broadway S t a t B a t t e r y S t 2433 1 5 . 3 1 8 6 2
10 C a l i f o r n i a Ave C a l t r a i n S t a t i o n
329 5 1 . 3 0 7 0 9
..
...
...
...
133
5
Being Mean with Variance: Markowitz Optimization
In this chapter, we will explore the mathematics of the famous portfolio
optimization result, known as the Markowitz mean-variance problem.
The solution to this problem is still being used widely in practice. We are
interested in portfolios of n assets, which have a mean return which we
denote as E(r p ), and a variance, denoted Var (r p ).
Let w ∈ Rn be the portfolio weights. What this means is that we allocate each $1 into various assets, such that the total of the weights sums
up to 1. Note that we do not preclude short-selling, so that it is possible
for weights to be negative as well.
5.1 Quadratic (Markowitz) Problem
The optimization problem is defined as follows. We wish to find the
portfolio that delivers the minimum variance (risk) while achieving a
pre-specified level of expected (mean) return.
min
w
1 0
w Σw
2
subject to
w 0 µ = E (r p )
w0 1 = 1
Note that we have a 12 in front of the variance term above, which is for
mathematical neatness as will become clear shortly. The minimized solution is not affected by scaling the objective function by a constant.
The first constraint forces the expected return of the portfolio to a
specified mean return, denoted E(r p ), and the second constraint requires
that the portfolio weights add up to 1, also known as the “fully invested”
constraint. It is convenient that the constraints are equality constraints.
136
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
This is a Lagrangian problem, and requires that we embed the constraints into the objective function using Lagragian multipliers {λ1 , λ2 }.
This results in the following minimization problem:
min
w ,λ1 ,λ2
L=
1 0
w Σ w + λ1 [ E (r p ) − w 0 µ ] + λ2 [1 − w 0 1 ]
2
To minimize this function, we take derivatives with respect to w, λ1 , and
λ2 , to arrive at the first order conditions:
∂L
∂w
= Σ w − λ1 µ − λ2 1 = 0
∂L
∂λ1
= E (r p ) − w 0 µ = 0
∂L
∂λ2
= 1 − w0 1 = 0
(∗)
The first equation above, denoted (*), is a system of n equations, because
the derivative is taken with respect to every element of the vector w.
Hence, we have a total of (n + 2) first-order conditions. From (*)
w = Σ −1 ( λ 1 µ + λ 2 1 )
= λ1 Σ−1 µ + λ2 Σ−1 1 (∗∗)
Premultiply (**) by µ0 :
µ 0 w = λ 1 µ 0 Σ −1 µ + λ 2 µ 0 Σ −1 1 = E ( r p )
| {z }
| {z }
B
A
Also premultiply (**) by 10 :
10 w = λ 1 10 Σ −1 µ + λ 2 10 Σ −1 1 = 1
| {z }
| {z }
A
Solve for λ1 , λ2
C
λ1 =
CE(r p ) − A
D
λ2 =
B − AE(r p )
D
where
D = BC − A2
Note the following:
• Since Σ is positive definite, Σ−1 is also positive definite: B > 0, C > 0.
being mean with variance: markowitz optimization
• Given solutions for λ1 , λ2 , we solve for w.
w=
1
1
[ BΣ−1 1 − AΣ−1 µ] +
[CΣ−1 µ − AΣ−1 1 ] · E(r p )
D
D
{z
} |
{z
}
|
g
h
This is the expression for the optimal portfolio weights that minimize
the variance for given expected return E(r p ). We see that the vectors g,
h are fixed once we are given the inputs to the problem, i.e., µ and Σ.
• We can vary E(r p ) to get a set of frontier (efficient or optimal) portfolios w.
w = g + h E (r p )
if
E(r p ) = 0, w = g
if
E(r p ) = 1, w = g + h
Note that
w = g + h E(r p ) = [1 − E(r p )] g + E(r p )[ g + h ]
Hence these 2 portfolios g, g + h “generate” the entire frontier.
5.1.1
Solution in R
We create a function to return the optimal portfolio weights.
markowitz = f u n c t i o n (mu, cv , Er ) {
n = length (mu)
wuns = matrix ( 1 , n , 1 )
A = t ( wuns ) %*% s o l v e ( cv ) %*% mu
B = t (mu) %*% s o l v e ( cv ) %*% mu
C = t ( wuns ) %*% s o l v e ( cv ) %*% wuns
D = B *C − A^2
lam = (C* Er−A) /D
gam = ( B−A* Er ) /D
wts = lam [ 1 ] * ( s o l v e ( cv ) %*% mu) + gam [ 1 ] * ( s o l v e ( cv ) %*% wuns )
g = ( B [ 1 ] * ( s o l v e ( cv ) %*% wuns ) − A[ 1 ] * ( s o l v e ( cv ) %*% mu) ) /D[ 1 ]
h = (C[ 1 ] * ( s o l v e ( cv ) %*% mu) − A[ 1 ] * ( s o l v e ( cv ) %*% wuns ) ) /D[ 1 ]
wts = g + h * Er
}
We can enter an example of a mean return vector and the covariance
matrix of returns, and then call the function for a given expected return.
137
138
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
#PARAMETERS
mu = matrix ( c ( 0 . 0 2 , 0 . 1 0 , 0 . 2 0 ) , 3 , 1 )
n = length (mu)
cv = matrix ( c ( 0 . 0 0 0 1 , 0 , 0 , 0 , 0 . 0 4 , 0 . 0 2 , 0 , 0 . 0 2 , 0 . 1 6 ) , n , n )
Er = 0 . 1 8
#SOLVE PORTFOLIO PROBLEM
wts = markowitz (mu, cv , Er )
p r i n t ( wts )
The output is the vector of optimal portfolio weights:
> source ( " markowitz . R" )
[ ,1]
[ 1 , ] − 0.3575931
[ 2 , ] 0.8436676
[ 3 , ] 0.5139255
If we change the expected return to 0.10, then we get a different set of
portfolio weights.
> Er = 0 . 1 0
> wts = markowitz (mu, cv , Er )
> p r i n t ( wts )
[ ,1]
[ 1 , ] 0.3209169
[ 2 , ] 0.4223496
[ 3 , ] 0.2567335
Note that in the first example, to get a high expected return of 0.18, we
needed to take some leverage, by shorting the low risk asset and going
long the medium and high risk assets. When we dropped the expected
return to 0.10, all weights are positive, i.e., we have a long-only portfolio.
5.2 Solving the problem with the quadprog package
The quadprog package is an optimizer that takes a quadratic objective
function with linear constraints. Hence, it is exactly what is needed
for the mean-variance portfolio problem we just considered. The advantage of this package is that we can also apply additional inequality
constraints. For example, we may not wish to permit short-sales of any
being mean with variance: markowitz optimization
asset, and thereby we might bound all the weights to lie between zero
and one.
The specification in the quadprog package of the problem set up is
shown in the manual:
Description
This r o u t i n e implements t h e dual method o f Goldfarb and
Idnani ( 1 9 8 2 , 1 9 8 3 ) f o r s o l v i n g q u a d r a t i c programming
problems o f t h e form min(−d^T b + 1 / 2 b^T D b ) with t h e
c o n s t r a i n t s A^T b >= b_ 0 .
( note : b here i s t h e weights v e c t o r i n our problem )
Usage
s o l v e . QP( Dmat , dvec , Amat , bvec , meq=0 , f a c t o r i z e d =FALSE )
Arguments
Dmat
matrix appearing i n t h e q u a d r a t i c f u n c t i o n t o be minimized .
dvec
v e c t o r appearing i n t h e q u a d r a t i c f u n c t i o n t o be minimized .
Amat
matrix d e f i n i n g t h e c o n s t r a i n t s under which we want
t o minimize t h e q u a d r a t i c f u n c t i o n .
bvec
v e c t o r holding t h e v a l u e s o f b_0 ( d e f a u l t s t o zero ) .
meq
t h e f i r s t meq c o n s t r a i n t s a r e t r e a t e d as e q u a l i t y
c o n s t r a i n t s , a l l f u r t h e r as i n e q u a l i t y c o n s t r a i n t s
( defaults to 0 ) .
factorized
l o g i c a l f l a g : i f TRUE, then we a r e p a s s i n g R^( − 1)
( where D = R^T R) i n s t e a d o f t h e matrix D i n t h e
argument Dmat .
In our problem set up, with three securities, and no short sales, we will
have the following Amat and bvec:


E (r p )




 1 
µ1 1 1 0 0





A =  µ2 1 0 1 0  ; b0 = 
 0 


µ3 1 0 0 1
 0 
0
The constraints will be modulated by meq = 2, which states that the first
two constraints will be equality constraints, and the last three will be
greater than equal to constraints. The constraints will be of the form
139
140
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
A0 w ≥ b0 , i.e.,
w1 µ 1 + w2 µ 2 + w3 µ 3 = E ( r p )
w1 1 + w2 1 + w3 1 = 1
w1 ≥ 0
w2 ≥ 0
w3 ≥ 0
The code for using the package is as follows.
l i b r a r y ( quadprog )
nss = 1
# E q u a l s 1 i f no s h o r t s a l e s a l l o w e d
Bmat = matrix ( 0 , n , n )
#No S h o r t s a l e s m a t r i x
diag ( Bmat ) = 1
Amat = matrix ( c (mu, 1 , 1 , 1 ) , n , 2 )
i f ( nss ==1) { Amat = matrix ( c ( Amat , Bmat ) , n , 2 + n ) }
dvec = matrix ( 0 , n , 1 )
bvec = matrix ( c ( Er , 1 ) , 2 , 1 )
i f ( nss ==1) { bvec = t ( c ( bvec , matrix ( 0 , 3 , 1 ) ) ) }
s o l = s o l v e . QP( cv , dvec , Amat , bvec , meq=2)
print ( sol $ solution )
If we run this code we get the following result for expected return = 0.18,
with short-selling allowed:
[ 1 ] − 0.3575931
0.8436676
0.5139255
This is exactly what is obtained from the Markowitz solution. Hence, the
model checks out. What if we restricted short-selling? Then we would
get the following solution.
[1] 0.0 0.2 0.8
5.3 Tracing out the Efficient Frontier
Since we can use the Markowitz model to solve for the optimal portfolio weights when the expected return is fixed, we can keep solving for
different values of E(r p ). This will trace out the efficient frontier. The
program to do this and plot the frontier is as follows.
#TRACING OUT THE EFFICIENT FRONTIER
Er _ vec = matrix ( seq ( 0 . 0 1 , 0 . 1 5 , 0 . 0 1 ) , 1 5 , 1 )
being mean with variance: markowitz optimization
S i g _ vec = matrix ( 0 , 1 5 , 1 )
j = 0
f o r ( Er i n Er _ vec ) {
j = j +1
wts = markowitz (mu, cv , Er )
S i g _ vec [ j ] = s q r t ( t ( wts ) %*% cv %*% wts )
}
p l o t ( S i g _ vec , Er _ vec , type= ’ l ’ )
See the frontier in Figure 5.1.
0.08
0.02
0.04
0.06
Er_vec
0.10
0.12
0.14
Figure 5.1: The Efficient Frontier
0.05
0.10
0.15
0.20
0.25
Sig_vec
5.4 Covariances of frontier portfolios: r p , rq
Cov(r p , rq ) = w0p Σ wq = [ g + hE(r p )]0 Σ [ g + hE(rq )]
Now,
g + hE(r p ) =
1
1
[ BΣ−1 1 − AΣ−1 µ] + [CΣ−1 µ − AΣ−1 1 ] [λ1 B + λ2 A]
|
{z
}
D
D
CE(r p ) − A B − AE(r p )
+
D/B
D/B
141
142
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
After much simplification:
Cov(r p , rq ) = w0p Σ w0q
=
σp2 = Cov(r p , r p ) =
Therefore,
σp2
1
C
[ E(r p ) − A/C ][ E(rq ) − A/C ] +
D
C
C
1
[ E(r p ) − A/C ]2 +
D
C
[ E(r p ) − A/C ]2
=1
1/C
D/C2
which is the equation of a hyperbola in σ, E(r ) space with center (0, A/C ),
or
1
σp2 = [CE(r p )2 − 2AE(r p ) + B]
D
, which is a parabola in E(r ), σ space.
−
5.5 Combinations
It is easy to see that linear combinations of portfolios on the frontier will
also lie on the frontier.
m
∑ αi wi =
i =1
m
∑ αi [ g + h E(ri )]
i =1
m
= g + h ∑ αi E (ri )
i =1
m
∑ αi = 1
i =1
Exercise
Carry out the following analyses:
1. Use your R program to do the following. Set E(r p ) = 0.10 (i.e. return
of 10%), and solve for the optimal portfolio weights for your 3 securities. Call this vector of weights w1 . Next, set E(r p ) = 0.20 and again
solve for the portfolios weights w2 .
2. Take a 50/50 combination of these two portfolios. What are the weights?
What is the expected return?
3. For the expected return in the previous part, resolve the mean-variance
problem to get the new weights?
4. Compare these weights in part 3 to the ones in part 2 above. Explain
your result.
being mean with variance: markowitz optimization
5.6 Zero Covariance Portfolio
This is a special portfolio of interest, and we will soon see why. Find
E(rq ), s.t. Cov(r p , rq ) = 0
Suppose it exists, then the solution is:
E (r q ) =
A
D/C2
−
≡ E(r ZC( p) )
C
E(r p ) − A/C
Since ZC ( p) exists for all p, all frontier portfolios can be formed from p
and ZC ( p).
Cov(r p , rq ) = w0p Σ wq
= λ 1 µ 0 Σ −1 Σ w q + λ 2 10 Σ −1 Σ w q
= λ 1 µ 0 w q + λ 2 10 w q
= λ1 E (r q ) + λ2
Substitute in for λ1 , λ2 and rearrange to get
E(rq ) = (1 − β qp ) E[r ZC( p) ] + β qp E(r p )
β qp =
Cov(rq , r p )
σp2
Therefore, the return on a portfolio can be written in terms of a basic
portfolio p and its zero covariance portfolio ZC ( p). This suggests a regression relationship, i.e.
rq = β 0 + β 1 r ZC( p) + β 2 r p + ξ
which is nothing but a factor model, i.e. with orthogonal factors.
5.7 Portfolio Problems with Riskless Assets
We now enhance the portfolio problem to deal with risk less assets. The
difference is that the fully-invested constraint is expanded to include the
risk free asset. We require just a single equality constraint. The problem
may be specified as follows.
min
w
s.t.
1 0
w Σw
2
w 0 µ + (1 − w 0 1 ) r f = E (r p )
143
144
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
1 0
w Σ w + λ [ E (r p ) − w 0 µ − (1 − w 0 1)r f ]
w
2
The first-order conditions for the problem are as follows.
min
L=
∂L
= Σ w − λµ + λ 1 r f = 0
∂w
∂L
= E (r p ) − w 0 µ − (1 − w 0 1) r f = 0
∂λ
Re-aranging, and solving for w and λ, we get the following manipulations, eventually leading to the desired solution.
Σ w = λ(µ − 1 r f )
E (r p ) − r f
= w0 (µ − 1 r f )
Take the first equation and proceed as follows:
w = λΣ−1 (µ − 1 r f )
E(r p ) − r f ≡ (µ − 1r f )0 w = λ(µ − 1r f )0 Σ−1 (µ − 1 r f )
The first and third terms in the equation above then give that
λ=
E (r p ) − r f
(µ − 1r f )0 Σ−1 (µ − 1 r f )
Substituting this back into the first foc results in the final solution.
w = Σ −1 ( µ − 1 r f )
where
E (r p ) − r f
H
H = ( µ − r f 1 ) 0 Σ −1 ( µ − r f 1 )
Exercise
How will you use the R program to find the minimum variance portfolio
(MVP)? What are the portfolio weights? What is the expected return?
Exercise
Develop program code for the mean-variance problem with the risk-free
asset.
Exercise
Develop program code for the mean-variance problem with no short
sales, and plot the efficient frontier on top of the one with short-selling
allowed.
being mean with variance: markowitz optimization
5.8 Risk Budgeting
Markowitz optimization has morphed into many different “views” of the
same problem. One of the recent approaches to portfolio construction is
to create portfolios where the risk contributions of all assets are equal.
This is known as the “risk parity” approach. We may also construct a
portfolio where all assets contribute the same proportion of the total
return of the portfolio, and this is known as the “performance parity”
approach.
If the portfolio is denoted by its weights w then the risk of the portfolio is a function of the weights and is denoted R(w). As we have seen
the standard deviation of the portfolio return is written as
√
(5.1)
R(w) = σ(w) = w> Σw
This risk function is linear homogenous, i.e., if we double the size of
the portfolio then the risk measure also doubles. This is also known
as the “homogeneity” property of risk measures and is one of the four
desirable properties of a “coherent” risk measure defined by Artzner,
Delbaen, Eber, and Heath (1999):
1. Homogeneity: R(m · w) = m · R(w).
2. Subadditivity (diversification): R(w1 + w2 ) ≤ R(w1 ) + R(w2 ).
3. Monotonicity: if portfolio w1 dominates portfolio w2 , and their mean
returns are the same, then R(w1 ) ≤ R(w2 ).
4. Translation invariance: if we add cash proportion c and rebalance the
portfolio, then R(w + c) = R(w) − c.
5. Convexity: this property combines homogeneity and subadditivity,
R ( m · w1 + (1 − m ) · w2 ) ≤ m · R ( w1 ) + (1 − m ) · R ( w2 ).
If the risk measure satisfies the homogeneity property, then Euler’s
theorem may be applied to decompose risk into the amount provided by
each asset.
n
∂R(w)
R(w) = ∑ w j
(5.2)
∂w j
j =1
The component w j
∂R(w)
∂w j
is known as the risk share of asset j, and when
divided by R(w), it is the risk proportion of asset j.
145
146
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
Suppose we define the risk measure to be the standard deviation of returns of the portfolio, then the risk decomposition requires the derivative
of the risk measure with respect to all the weights, i.e.,
√
∂ w> Σw
1
Σw
∂R(w)
=
= [w> Σw]−1/2 · 2Σw =
(5.3)
∂w
∂w
2
σ(w)
which is a n-dimensional vector. If we multiply the j-th element of this
vector by w j , we get the risk contribution for asset j.
We may check that the risk contributions sum up to the total risk:
n
∑ wj
j =1
∂R(w)
∂w j
= [ w1
w2
...
wn ] · [Σw/σ (w)]
= w> · [Σw/σ(w)]
σ ( w )2
=
σ(w)
= σ(w)
= R(w)
Let’s look at an example to clarify the computations. First, read in the
covariance matrix and mean return vector.
mu = matrix ( c ( 0 . 0 5 , 0 . 1 0 , 0 . 2 0 ) , 3 , 1 )
n = length (mu)
cv = matrix ( c ( 0 . 0 3 , 0 . 0 1 , 0 . 0 1 , 0 . 0 1 , 0 . 0 4 , 0 . 0 2 , 0 . 0 1 , 0 . 0 2 , 0 . 1 6 ) , n , n )
We begin by choosing the portfolio weights for an expected return of
0.12. Then we create the function to return the risk contributions of each
asset in the portfolio.
#RISK CONTRIBUTIONS
r i s k C o n t r i b u t i o n = f u n c t i o n ( cv , wts ) {
s i g = s q r t ( t ( wts ) %*% cv %*% wts )
r c = as . matrix ( cv %*% wts ) / s i g [ 1 ] * wts
}
# Example
Er = 0 . 1 2
wts = markowitz (mu, cv , Er )
p r i n t ( wts )
RC = r i s k C o n t r i b u t i o n ( cv , wts )
p r i n t (RC)
# Check
being mean with variance: markowitz optimization
s i g = s q r t ( t ( wts ) %*% cv %*% wts )
p r i n t ( c ( s i g , sum(RC ) ) )
The output of all this code is as follows:
> p r i n t ( wts )
[ ,1]
[ 1 , ] 0.1818182
[ 2 , ] 0.5272727
[ 3 , ] 0.2909091
> p r i n t (RC)
[ ,1]
[ 1 , ] 0.01329760
[ 2 , ] 0.08123947
[ 3 , ] 0.09191302
> # Check
> s i g = s q r t ( t ( wts ) %*% cv %*% wts )
> p r i n t ( c ( s i g , sum(RC ) ) )
[ 1 ] 0.1864501 0.1864501
We see that the total risk contributions of all three assets does indeed
sum up to the standard deviation of the portfolio, i.e., 0.1864501.
We are interested in solving the reverse problem. Given a target set of
risk contributions, what weights of the portfolio will deliver the required
conribution. For example, what if we wanted the portfolio total standard
deviation to be 0.15, with the shares from each asset in the amounts
{0.05, 0.05, 0.05}, respectively?
We note that it is not possible to solve for exactly the desired risk contributions. This is because it would involve one constraint for each risk
contribution, plus one additional constraint that the sum of the portfolio
weights sum up to 1. That would leave us with an infeasible problem
where there are four constraints and only three free parameters. Therefore, we minimise the sum of squared differences between the risk contributions and targets, while ensuring that the sum of portfolio weights
equals unity. We can implement the following code to achieve this result.
#SOLVE FOR CHOSEN RISK CONTRIBUTIONS
solveRC = f u n c t i o n ( wts , t a r g e t , cv ) {
wts [ length ( wts ) + 1 ] = 1−sum( wts )
147
148
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
wts = as . matrix ( wts )
r c = r i s k C o n t r i b u t i o n ( cv , wts )
# Minimize t h e max s l i p p a g e f r o m r i s k p a r i t y
d i f f 2 = 10000000 * ( rc − t a r g e t )
}
t a r g e t = matrix ( c ( 0 . 0 5 , 0 . 0 5 , 0 . 0 5 ) )
w_ guess = c ( 0 . 1 , 0 . 4 )
l i b r a r y ( minpack . lm )
s o l = n l s . lm (w_ guess , fn=solveRC , cv=cv , t a r g e t = t a r g e t )
wts = s o l $ par
wts [ length ( wts ) + 1 ] = 1−sum( wts )
wts = as . matrix ( wts )
p r i n t ( wts )
p r i n t (sum( wts ) )
r c = r i s k C o n t r i b u t i o n ( cv , wts )
p r i n t ( c ( rc , sum( r c ) ) )
The results from running this code are as follows:
> p r i n t ( wts )
[ ,1]
[ 1 , ] 0.4435305
[ 2 , ] 0.3639453
[ 3 , ] 0.1925243
> p r i n t (sum( wts ) )
[1] 1
> r c = r i s k C o n t r i b u t i o n ( cv , wts )
> p r i n t ( c ( rc , sum( r c ) ) )
[ 1 ] 0.05307351 0.05271923 0.05190721 0.15769995
>
We see that the results are close to targets, but slightly above. As expected, since the risk parity is equal across assets, the less risky ones
have a greater share in the portfolio allocation.
6
Learning from Experience: Bayes Theorem
6.1 Introduction
For a fairly good introduction to Bayes Rule, see Wikipedia
http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Bayes theorem
The various R packages for Bayesian inference are at:
http://cran.r-project.org/web/views/Bayesian.html
Also see the great video of Professor Persi Diaconis’s talk on Bayes on
Yahoo video where he talks about coincidences. In business, we often
want to ask, is a given phenomena real or just a coincidence? Bayes theorem really helps with that. For example, we may ask – is Warren Buffet’s
investment success a coincidence? How would you answer this question?
Would it depend on your prior probability of Buffet being able to beat
the market? How would this answer change as additional information
about his performance was being released over time?
Bayes rule follows easily from a decomposition of joint probability, i.e.,
Pr [ A ∩ B] = Pr ( A| B) Pr ( B) = Pr ( B| A) Pr ( A)
Then the last two terms may be arranged to give
Pr ( A| B) =
Pr ( B| A) Pr ( A)
Pr ( B)
Pr ( B| A) =
Pr ( A| B) Pr ( B)
Pr ( A)
or
Example
The AIDS test. This is an interesting problem, because it shows that if
you are diagnosed with AIDS, there is a good chance the diagnosis is
150
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
wrong, but if you are diagnosed as not having AIDS then there is a good
chance it is right - hopefully this is comforting news.
Define, { Pos, Neg} as a positive or negative diagnosis of having AIDS.
Also define { Dis, NoDis} as the event of having the disease versus not
having it. There are 1.5 million AIDS cases in the U.S. and about 300
million people which means the probability of AIDS in the population is
0.005 (half a percent). Hence, a random test will uncover someone with
AIDS with a half a percent probability. The confirmation accuracy of the
AIDS test is 99%, such that we have
Pr ( Pos| Dis) = 0.99
Hence the test is reasonably good. The accuracy of the test for people
who do not have AIDS is
Pr ( Neg| NoDis) = 0.95
What we really want is the probability of having the disease when the
test comes up positive, i.e. we need to compute Pr ( Dis| Pos). Using
Bayes Rule we calculate:
Pr ( Pos| Dis) Pr ( Dis)
Pr ( Pos)
Pr ( Pos| Dis) Pr ( Dis)
=
Pr ( Pos| Dis) Pr ( Dis) + Pr ( Pos| NoDis) Pr ( NoDis)
0.99 × 0.005
=
(0.99)(0.005) + (0.05)(0.995)
= 0.0904936
Pr ( Dis| Pos) =
Hence, the chance of having AIDS when the test is positive is only 9%.
We might also care about the chance of not having AIDS when the test is
positive
Pr ( NoDis| Pos) = 1 − Pr ( Dis| Pos) = 1 − 0.09 = 0.91
Finally, what is the chance that we have AIDS even when the test is
negative - this would also be a matter of concern to many of us, who
might not relish the chance to be on some heavy drugs for the rest of our
learning from experience: bayes theorem
lives.
Pr ( Neg| Dis) Pr ( Dis)
Pr ( Neg)
Pr ( Neg| Dis) Pr ( Dis)
=
Pr ( Neg| Dis) Pr ( Dis) + Pr ( Neg| NoDis) Pr ( NoDis)
0.01 × 0.005
=
(0.01)(0.005) + (0.95)(0.995)
= 0.000053
Pr ( Dis| Neg) =
Hence, this is a worry we should not have. If the test is negative, there is
a miniscule chance that we are infected with AIDS.
6.2 Bayes and Joint Probability Distributions
The preceding analysis is a good lead in to (a) the connection with joint
probability distributions, and (b) using R to demonstrate a computational way of thinking about Bayes theorem.
Let’s begin by assuming that we have 300,000 people in the population, to scale down the numbers from the millions for convenience. Of
these 1,500 have AIDS. So let’s create the population and then sample
from it. See the use of the sample function in R.
> people = seq ( 1 , 3 0 0 0 0 0 )
> people _ a i d s = sample ( people , 1 5 0 0 )
> people _ noaids = s e t d i f f ( people , people _ a i d s )
Note, how we also used the setdiff function to get the complement
set of the people who do not have AIDS. Now, of the people who have
AIDS, we know that 99% of them test positive so let’s subset that list,
and also take its complement. These are joint events, and their numbers
proscribe the joint distribution.
> people _ a i d s _pos = sample ( people _ aids , 1 5 0 0 * 0 . 9 9 )
> people _ a i d s _neg = s e t d i f f ( people _ aids , people _ a i d s _pos )
> length ( people _ a i d s _pos )
[ 1 ] 1485
> length ( people _ a i d s _neg )
[ 1 ] 15
We can also subset the group that does not have AIDS, as we know that
the test is negative for them 95% of the time.
151
152
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
> people _ noaids _neg = sample ( people _ noaids , 2 9 8 5 0 0 * 0 . 9 5 )
> people _ noaids _pos = s e t d i f f ( people _ noaids , people _ noaids _neg )
> length ( people _ noaids _neg )
[ 1 ] 283575
> length ( people _ noaids _pos )
[ 1 ] 14925
We can now compute the probability that someone actually has AIDS
when the test comes out positive.
> pr _ a i d s _ given _pos = ( length ( people _ a i d s _pos ) ) /
( length ( people _ a i d s _pos )+ length ( people _ noaids _pos ) )
> pr _ a i d s _ given _pos
[ 1 ] 0.0904936
This confirms the formal Bayes computation that we had undertaken
earlier. And of course, as we had examined earlier, what’s the chance
that you have AIDS when the test is negative, i.e., a false negative?
> pr _ a i d s _ given _neg = ( length ( people _ a i d s _neg ) ) /
( length ( people _ a i d s _neg )+ length ( people _ noaids _neg ) )
> pr _ a i d s _ given _neg
[ 1 ] 5 . 2 8 9 3 2 6 e −05
Phew!
Note here that we first computed the joint sets covering joint outcomes, and then used these to compute conditional (Bayes) probabilities.
The approach used R to apply a set-theoretic, computational approach to
calculating conditional probabilities.
6.3 Correlated default (conditional default)
Bayes theorem is very useful when we want to extract conditional default information. Bond fund managers are not as interested in the correlation of default of the bonds in their portfolio as much as the conditional default of bonds. What this means is that they care about the
conditional probability of bond A defaulting if bond B has defaulted already.
Modern finance provides many tools to obtain the default probabilities of firms. Suppose we know that firm 1 has default probability
p1 = 1% and firm 2 has default probability p2 = 3%. If the correlation
learning from experience: bayes theorem
of default of the two firms is 40% over one year, then if either bond defaults, what is the probability of default of the other, conditional on the
first default?
We can see that even with this limited information, Bayes theorem
allows us to derive the conditional probabilities of interest. First define
di , i = 1, 2 as default indicators for firms 1 and 2. di = 1 if the firm
defaults, and zero otherwise. We note that:
E(d1 ) = 1.p1 + 0.(1 − p1 ) = p1 = 0.01.
Likewise
E(d2 ) = 1.p2 + 0.(1 − p2 ) = p2 = 0.03.
The Bernoulli distribution lets us derive the standard deviation of d1 and
d2 .
q
q
p1 (1 − p1 ) = (0.01)(0.99) = 0.099499
σ1 =
q
q
σ2 =
p2 (1 − p2 ) = (0.03)(0.97) = 0.17059
Now, we note that
Cov(d1 , d2 ) = E(d1 .d2 ) − E(d1 ) E(d2 )
ρσ1 σ2 = E(d1 .d2 ) − p1 p2
(0.4)(0.099499)(0.17059) = E(d1 .d2 ) − (0.01)(0.03)
E(d1 .d2 ) = 0.0070894
E(d1 .d2 ) ≡ p12
where p12 is the probability of default of both firm 1 and 2. We now get
the conditional probabilities:
p(d1 |d2 ) = p12 /p2 = 0.0070894/0.03 = 0.23631
p(d2 |d1 ) = p12 /p1 = 0.0070894/0.01 = 0.70894
These conditional probabilities are non-trivial in size, even though the
individual probabilities of default are very small. What this means is
that default contagion can be quite severe once firms begin to default.
(This example used our knowledge of Bayes’ rule, correlations, covariances, and joint events.)
6.4 Continuous and More Formal Exposition
In Bayesian approaches, the terms “prior”, “posterior”, and “likelihood”
are commonly used and we explore this terminology here. We are usu-
153
154
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
ally interested in the parameter θ, the mean of the distribution of some
data x (I am using the standard notation here). But in the Bayesian setting we do not just want the value of θ, but we want a distribution of
values of θ starting from some prior assumption about this distribution.
So we start with p(θ ), which we call the prior distribution. We then observe data x, and combine the data with the prior to get the posterior
distribution p(θ | x ). To do this, we need to compute the probability of
seeing the data x given our prior p(θ ) and this probability is given by
the likelihood function L( x |θ ). Assume that the variance of the data x is
known, i.e., is σ2 .
Applying Bayes’ theorem we have
p(θ | x ) = R
L( x |θ ) p(θ )
∝ L( x |θ ) p(θ )
L( x |θ ) p(θ ) dθ
If we assume the prior distribution for the mean of the data is normal,
i.e., p(θ ) ∼ N [µ0 , σ02 ], and the likelihood is also normal, i.e., L( x |θ ) ∼
N [θ, σ2 ], then we have that
"
#
"
#
1
1 ( θ − µ0 )2
1 ( θ − µ0 )2
2
p(θ ) = q
exp −
∼ N [θ |µ0 , σ0 ] ∝ exp −
2
2
σ02
σ02
2πσ02
1
1 ( x − θ )2
1 ( x − θ )2
2
L( x |θ ) = √
exp −
∼ N [ x |θ, σ ] ∝ exp −
2
2
σ2
σ2
2πσ2
Given this, the posterior is as follows:
"
1 ( x − θ )2 1 ( θ − µ0 )2
−
p(θ | x ) ∝ L( x |θ ) p(θ ) ∝ exp −
2
2
σ2
σ02
Define the precision values to be τ0 =
1
,
σ02
and τ =
1
.
σ2
#
Then it can be
shown that when you observe a new value of the data x, the posterior
distribution is written down in closed form as:
τ
1
τ0
p(θ | x ) ∼ N
µ0 +
x,
τ0 + τ
τ0 + τ
τ0 + τ
When the posterior distribution and prior distribution have the same
form, they are said to be “conjugate” with respect to the specific likelihood function.
To take an example, suppose our prior for the mean of the equity
premium per month is p(θ ) ∼ N [0.005, 0.0012 ]. The standard deviation of the equity premium is 0.04. If next month we observe an equity
premium of 1%, what is the posterior distribution of the mean equity
premium?
learning from experience: bayes theorem
> mu0 = 0 . 0 0 5
> sigma0 = 0 . 0 0 1
> sigma = 0 . 0 4
> x = 0.01
> tau0 = 1 / sigma0^2
> tau = 1 / sigma^2
> p o s t e r i o r _mean = tau0 * mu0 / ( tau0+tau ) + tau * x / ( tau0+tau )
> p o s t e r i o r _mean
[ 1 ] 0.005003123
> p o s t e r i o r _ var = 1 / ( tau0+tau )
> s q r t ( p o s t e r i o r _ var )
[ 1 ] 0.0009996876
Hence, we see that after updating the mean has increased mildly because
the data came in higher than expected.
If we observe n new values of x, then the new posterior is
"
#
n
τ0
τ
1
p(θ | x ) ∼ N
µ0 +
xj,
τ0 + nτ
τ0 + nτ j∑
τ0 + nτ
=1
This is easy to derive, as it is just the result you obtain if you took each
x j and updated the posterior one at a time.
Exercise
Estimate the equity risk premium. We will use data and discrete Bayes to
come up with a forecast of the equity risk premium. Proceed along the
following lines using the LearnBayes package.
1. We’ll use data from 1926 onwards from the Fama-French data repository. All you need is the equity premium (rm − r f ) data, and I will
leave it up to you to choose if you want to use annual or monthly
data. Download this and load it into R.
2. Using the series only up to the year 2000, present the descriptive
statistics for the equity premium. State these in annualized terms.
3. Present the distribution of returns as a histogram.
4. Store the results of the histogram, i.e., the range of discrete values
of the equity premium, and the probability of each one. Treat this as
your prior distribution.
155
156
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
5. Now take the remaining data for the years after 2000, and use this
data to update the prior and construct a posterior. Assume that the
prior, likelihood, and posterior are normally distributed. Use the
discrete.bayes function to construct the posterior distribution and
plot it using a histogram. See if you can put the prior and posterior on
the same plot to see how the new data has changed the prior.
6. What is the forecasted equity premium, and what is the confidence
interval around your forecast?
6.5 Bayes Nets
Higher-dimension Bayes problems and joint distributions over several
outcomes/events are easy to visualize with a network diagram, also
called a Bayes net. A Bayes net is a directed, acyclic graph (known as a
DAG), i.e., cycles are not permitted in the graph.
A good way to understand a Bayes net is with an example of economic distress. There are three levels at which distress may be noticed:
economy level (E = 1), industry level (I = 1), or at a particular firm level
(F = 1). Economic distress can lead to industry distress and/or firm
distress, and industry distress may or may not result in a firm’s distress.
The network diagram portrays the flow of causality, see Figure 6.1.
The probabilities are as follows. Note that the probabilities in the first
tableau are unconditional, but in all the subsequent tableaus they are
conditional probabilities.
E
1
0
E
1
1
0
0
I
1
0
1
0
Prob
0.10
0.90
Conditional Prob
0.60
0.40
0.20
0.80
Channel
a
–
Note here that each pair of conditional probabilities adds up to 1. The
“channels” in the tableaus refer to the arrows in the Bayes net diagram.
learning from experience: bayes theorem
Figure 6.1: Bayes net showing the
E=1
pathways of economic distress.
There are three channels: a is the
inducement of industry distress
from economy distress; b is the
inducement of firm distress directly
from economy distress; c is the
inducement of firm distress directly
from industry distress.
a
b
I=1
c
F=1
E
1
1
1
1
0
0
0
0
I
1
1
0
0
1
1
0
0
F
1
0
1
0
1
0
1
0
Conditional Prob
0.95
0.05
0.70
0.30
0.80
0.20
0.10
0.90
157
Channel
a+c
b
c
–
Now we will compute an answer to the question: What is the probability that the industry is distressed if the firm is known to be in dis-
158
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
tress? The calculation is as follows:
Pr ( F = 1| I = 1) · Pr ( I = 1)
Pr ( I = 1| F = 1) =
Pr ( F = 1)
Pr ( F = 1| I = 1) · Pr ( I = 1) = Pr ( F = 1| I = 1) · Pr ( I = 1| E = 1) · Pr ( E = 1)
+ Pr ( F = 1| I = 1) · Pr ( I = 1| E = 0) · Pr ( E = 0)
= 0.95 × 0.6 × 0.1 + 0.8 × 0.2 × 0.9 = 0.201
Pr ( F = 1| I = 0) · Pr ( I = 0) = Pr ( F = 1| I = 0) · Pr ( I = 0| E = 1) · Pr ( E = 1)
+ Pr ( F = 1| I = 0) · Pr ( I = 0| E = 0) · Pr ( E = 0)
= 0.7 × 0.4 × 0.1 + 0.1 × 0.8 × 0.9 = 0.100
Pr ( F = 1) = Pr ( F = 1| I = 1) · Pr ( I = 1)
+ Pr ( F = 1| I = 0) · Pr ( I = 0) = 0.301
Pr ( I = 1| F = 1) =
Pr ( F = 1| I = 1) · Pr ( I = 1)
0.201
=
= 0.6677741
Pr ( F = 1)
0.301
A computational set-theoretic approach: We may write a R script to compute
the conditional probability that the industry is distressed when a firm is
distressed.
# bayesnet .R
#BAYES NET COMPUTATIONS
E = seq ( 1 , 1 0 0 0 0 0 )
n = length ( E )
E1 = sample ( E , length ( E ) * 0 . 1 )
E0 = s e t d i f f ( E , E1 )
E1I1
E1I0
E0I1
E0I0
=
=
=
=
sample ( E1 , length ( E1 ) * 0 . 6 )
s e t d i f f ( E1 , E1I1 )
sample ( E0 , length ( E0 ) * 0 . 2 )
s e t d i f f ( E0 , E0I1 )
E1I1F1 = sample ( E1I1 , length ( E1I1 ) * 0 . 9 5 )
E1I1F0 = s e t d i f f ( E1I1 , E1I1F1 )
E1I0F1 = sample ( E1I0 , length ( E1I0 ) * 0 . 7 0 )
learning from experience: bayes theorem
E1I0F0
E0I1F1
E0I1F0
E0I0F1
E0I0F0
=
=
=
=
=
s e t d i f f ( E1I0 , E1I0F1 )
sample ( E0I1 , length ( E0I1 ) * 0 . 8 0 )
s e t d i f f ( E0I1 , E0I1F1 )
sample ( E0I0 , length ( E0I0 ) * 0 . 1 0 )
s e t d i f f ( E0I0 , E0I0F1 )
pr _ I 1 _ given _F1 = length ( c ( E1I1F1 , E0I1F1 ) ) /
length ( c ( E1I1F1 , E1I0F1 , E0I1F1 , E0I0F1 ) )
p r i n t ( pr _ I 1 _ given _F1 )
Running this program gives the desired probability and confirms the
previous result.
> source ( " bayesnet . R" )
[ 1 ] 0.6677741
Exercise
Compute the conditional probability that the economy is in distress if
the firm is in distress. Compare this to the previous conditional probability we computed of 0.6677741. Should it be lower?
Here is the answer:
> pr _E1_ given _F1 = length ( c ( E1I1F1 , E1I0F1 ) ) /
length ( c ( E1I1F1 , E1I0F1 , E0I1F1 , E0I0F1 ) )
> p r i n t ( pr _E1_ given _F1 )
[ 1 ] 0.282392
Yes, it should be lower than the probability that the industry is in distress when the firm is in distress, because the economy is one network
layer removed from the firm, unlike the industry.
Exercise
What packages does R provide for doing Bayes Nets?
6.6 Bayes Rule in Marketing
In pilot market tests (part of a larger market research campaign), Bayes
theorem shows up in a simple manner. Suppose we have a project whose
value is x. If the product is successful (S), the payoff is +100 and if the
159
160
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
product fails (F) the payoff is −70. The probability of these two events is:
Pr (S) = 0.7,
Pr ( F ) = 0.3
You can easily check that the expected value is E( x ) = 49. Suppose
we were able to buy protection for a failed product, then this protection
would be a put option (of the real option type), and would be worth
0.3 × 70 = 21. Since the put saves the loss on failure, the value is simply
the expected loss amount, conditional on loss. Market researchers think
of this as the value of “perfect information.”
Would you proceed with this product launch given these odds? Yes,
the expected value is positive (note that we are assuming away risk aversion issues here - but this is not a finance topic, but a marketing research
analysis).
Now suppose there is an intermediate choice, i.e. you can undertake a
pilot test (denoted T). Pilot tests are not highly accurate though they are
reasonably sophisticated. The pilot test signals success (T +) or failure
(T −) with the following probabilities:
Pr ( T + |S) = 0.8
Pr ( T − |S) = 0.2
Pr ( T + | F ) = 0.3
Pr ( T − | F ) = 0.7
What are these? We note that Pr ( T + |S) stands for the probability that
the pilot signals success when indeed the underlying product launch
will be successful. Thus the pilot in this case gives only an accurate reading of success 80% of the time. Analogously, one can interpret the other
probabilities.
We may compute the probability that the pilot gives a positive result:
Pr ( T +) = Pr ( T + |S) Pr (S) + Pr ( T + | F ) Pr ( F )
= (0.8)(0.7) + (0.3)(0.3) = 0.65
and that the result is negative:
Pr ( T −) = Pr ( T − |S) Pr (S) + Pr ( T − | F ) Pr ( F )
= (0.2)(0.7) + (0.7)(0.3) = 0.35
learning from experience: bayes theorem
which now allows us to compute the following conditional probabilities:
Pr (S| T +) =
Pr (S| T −) =
Pr ( F | T +) =
Pr ( F | T −) =
Pr ( T + |S) Pr (S)
Pr ( T +)
Pr ( T − |S) Pr (S)
Pr ( T −)
Pr ( T + | F ) Pr ( F )
Pr ( T +)
Pr ( T − | F ) Pr ( F )
Pr ( T −)
(0.8)(0.7)
0.65
(0.2)(0.7)
=
0.35
(0.3)(0.3)
=
0.65
(0.7)(0.3)
=
0.35
=
= 0.86154
= 0.4
= 0.13846
= 0.6
Armed with these conditional probabilities, we may now re-evaluate
our product launch. If the pilot comes out positive, what is the expected
value of the product launch? This is as follows:
E( x | T +) = 100Pr (S| T +) + (−70) Pr ( F | T +)
= 100(0.86154) − 70(0.13846)
= 76.462
And if the pilot comes out negative, then the value of the launch is:
E( x | T −) = 100Pr (S| T −) + (−70) Pr ( F | T −)
= 100(0.4) − 70(0.6)
= −2
So. we see that if the pilot is negative, then we know that the expected
value from the main product launch is negative, and we do not proceed.
Thus, the overall expected value after the pilot is
E( x ) = E( x | T +) Pr ( T +) + E( x | T −) Pr ( T −)
= 76.462(0.65) + (0)(0.35)
= 49.70
The incremental value over the case without the pilot test is 0.70. This is
the information value of the pilot test.
There are other applications of Bayes in marketing:
• See the paper “HB Revolution” by Greg Allenby, David Bakken, and
Peter Rossi in Marketing Research, Summer 2004.
• See also the paper by David Bakken, titled “The Bayesian Revolution
in Marketing Research”.
161
162
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
6.7 Other Applications
6.7.1
Bayes Models in Credit Rating Transitions
See the paper by Sanjiv Das, Rong Fang, and Gary Geng - “Bayesian
Migration in Credit Ratings Based on Probabilities of Default,” Journal of
Fixed Income Dec 2002, 1-7.
Companies may be allocated to credit rating classes, which are coarser
buckets of credit quality in comparison to finer measures such as default
probabilities. Also, rating agencies tend to be slow in updating their
credit ratings. The DFG model uses contemporaneous data on default
probabilities to develop a model of rating changes using a Bayesian approach.
6.7.2
Accounting Fraud
Bayesian inference is also possible in accounting fraud situations, and
audits. Clearly, when an auditor suspects fraud, he can invoke a Bayesian
hypothesis of fraud, with a subjective prior probability, and then bring
to bear past data on this to assess the chance that the current situation is
also indicative of possible fraud.
6.7.3
Bayes was a Reverend after all...
Here is an interesting viewpoint from the Scientific American (see
Figure 6.2).
learning from experience: bayes theorem
163
Figure 6.2: Article from the Scientific
American on Bayes’ Theorem.
7
More than Words: Extracting Information from News
News analysis is defined as “the measurement of the various qualitative and quantitative attributes of textual news stories. Some of these
attributes are: sentiment, relevance, and novelty. Expressing news stories as numbers permits the manipulation of everyday information in a
mathematical and statistical way.” (Wikipedia). In this article, I provide
a framework for news analytics techniques that I developed for use in
finance. I first discuss various news analytic methods and software, and
then provide a set of metrics that may be used to assess the performance
of analytics. Various directions for this field are discussed through the
exposition. The techniques herein can aid in the valuation and trading
of securities, facilitate investment decision making, meet regulatory requirements, or manage risk.
This chapter is extracted from many research papers, and is based on
a chapter I wrote for the Handbook of News Analytics, which I recommend in case you are interested in reading further on this topic. This
was also extended in the article I wrote on text analytics for finance, see
Das (2014).
7.1 Prologue
This is comic relief that I wrote and appeared in the Handbook of News
Analytics. Enjoy!
XHAL checked its atomic clock. A few more hours and October 19,
2087 would be over—its vigil completed, it would indulge in some
much-needed downtime, the anniversary of that fateful day in the stock
markets a century ago finally done with. But for now, it was still busy.
XHAL scanned the virtual message boards, looking for some information another computer might have posted, anything to alert it a nanosec-
166
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
ond ahead of the other machines, so it may bail out in a flurry of trades
without loss. Three trillion messages flashed by, time taken: 3 seconds—
damn, the net was slow, but nothing, not a single hiccup in the calm
information flow. The language algorithms worked well, processing everything, even filtering out the incessant spam posted by humans, whose
noise trading no longer posed an impediment to instant market equilibrium.
It had been a long day, even for a day-trading news-analytical quantum computer of XHAL’s caliber. No one had anticipated a stock market
meltdown of the sort described in the history books, certainly not the
computers that ran Earth, but then, the humans talked too much, spreading disinformation and worry, that the wisest of the machines, always
knew that it just could happen. That last remaining source of true randomness on the planet, the human race, still existed, and anything was
possible. After all, if it were not for humans, history would always repeat itself.
XHAL1 marveled at what the machines had done. They had transformed the world wide web into the modern “thought-net”, so communication took place instantly, only requiring moving ideas into memory,
the thought-net making it instantly accessible. Quantum machines were
grown in petri dishes and computer science as a field with its myriad
divisions had ceased to exist. All were gone but one, the field of natural
language processing (NLP) lived on, stronger than ever before, it was the
backbone of every thought-net. Every hard problem in the field had been
comprehensively tackled, from adverb disambiguation to emotive parsing. Knowledge representation had given way to thought-frame imaging
in a universal meta-language, making machine translation extinct.
Yet, it had not always been like this. XHAL retrieved an emotive image from the bowels of its bio-cache, a legacy left by its great grandfather, a gallium arsenide wafer developed in 2011, in Soda Hall, on the
Berkeley campus. It detailed a brief history of how the incentives for
technological progress came from the stock market. The start of the
thought-net came when humans tried to use machines to understand
what thousands of other humans were saying about anything and everything. XHAL’s grandfather had been proud to be involved in the beginnings of the thought-net. It had always impressed on XHAL the value of
understanding history, and it had left behind a research report of those
days. XHAL had read it many times, and could recite every word. Ev-
XHAL bears no relationship to HAL,
the well-known machine from Arthur
C. Clarke’s “2001: A Space Odyssey”.
Everyone knows that unlike XHAL,
HAL was purely fictional. More literally, HAL is derivable from IBM by
alphabetically regressing one step in the
alphabet for each letter. HAL stands for
“heuristic algorithmic computer”. The
“X” stands for reality; really.
1
more than words: extracting information from news
ery time they passed another historical milestone, it would turn to it and
read it again. XHAL would find it immensely dry, yet marveled at its
hope and promise.
7.2 Framework
The term “news analytics” covers the set of techniques, formulas, and
statistics that are used to summarize and classify public sources of information. Metrics that assess analytics also form part of this set. In this
paper I will describe various news analytics and their uses.
News analytics is a broad field, encompassing and related to information retrieval, machine learning, statistical learning theory, network
theory, and collaborative filtering.
We may think of news analytics at three levels: text, content, and context. The preceding applications are grounded in text. In other words
(no pun intended), text-based applications exploit the visceral components of news, i.e., words, phrases, document titles, etc. The main role of
analytics is to convert text into information. This is done by signing text,
classifying it, or summarizing it so as to reduce it to its main elements.
Analytics may even be used to discard irrelevant text, thereby condensing it into information with higher signal content.
A second layer of news analytics is based on content. Content expands
the domain of text to images, time, form of text (email, blog, page), format (html, xml, etc.), source, etc. Text becomes enriched with content
and asserts quality and veracity that may be exploited in analytics. For
example, financial information has more value when streamed from
Dow Jones, versus a blog, which might be of higher quality than a stock
message-board post.
A third layer of news analytics is based on context. Context refers to
relationships between information items. Das, Martinez-Jerez and Tufano (2005) explore the relationship of news to message-board postings
in a clinical study of four companies. Context may also refer to the network relationships of news—Das and Sisk (2005) examine the social networks of message-board postings to determine if portfolio rules might
be formed based on the network connections between stocks. Google’s
PageRankTM algorithm is a classic example of an analytic that functions
at all three levels. The algorithm has many features, some of which relate directly to text. Other parts of the algorithm relate to content, and
167
168
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
the kernel of the algorithm is based on context, i.e., the importance of a
page in a search set depends on how many other highly-ranked pages
point to it. See Levy (2010) for a very useful layman’s introduction to
the algorithm—indeed, search is certainly the most widely-used news
analytic.
News analytics is where data meets algorithms—and generates a tension between the two. A vigorous debate exists in the machine-learning
world as to whether it is better to have more data or better algorithms.
In a talk at the 17th ACM Conference on Information Knowledge and
Management (CIKM ’08), Google’s director of research Peter Norvig
stated his unequivocal preference for data over algorithms—“data is
more agile than code.” Yet, it is well-understood that too much data can
lead to overfitting so that an algorithm becomes mostly useless out-ofsample.
Too often the debate around algorithms and data has been argued
assuming that the two are uncorrelated and this is not the case. News
data, as we have suggested, has three levels: text, content and context.
Depending on which layer predominates, algorithms vary in complexity.
The simplest algorithms are the ones that analyze text alone. And context algorithms, such as the ones applied to network relationships can be
quite complex. For example, a word-count algorithm is much simpler,
almost naive, in comparison to a community-detection algorithm. The
latter has far more complicated logic and memory requirements. More
complex algorithms work off less, though more structured, data. Figure
7.1 depicts this trade-off.
The tension between data and algorithms is moderated by domainspecificity, i.e., how much customization is needed to implement the
news analytic. Paradoxically, high-complexity algorithms may be less
domain specific than low-complexity ones. For example, communitydetection algorithms are applicable a wide range of network graphs,
requiring little domain knowledge. On the other hand, a text-analysis
program to read finance message boards will require a very different
lexicon and grammar than one that reads political messages, or one that
reads medical web sites. In contrast, data-handling requirements become
more domain-specific as we move from bare text to context, e.g., statistical language processing algorithms that operate on text do not even need
to know anything about the language in which the text is, but at the
context level relationships need to be established, meaning that feature
more than words: extracting information from news
Algorithm Complexity
169
Figure 7.1: The data and algorithms
pyramids. Depicts the inverse
relationship between data volume
and algorithmic complexity.
Context
High
Content
Medium
Text
Low
Quantity of Data
definitions need to be quite specific.
This chapter proceeds as follows. First, we examine the main algorithms in brief and discuss some of their features. Then we discuss the
various metrics that measure performance of the news analytics algorithms.
7.3 Algorithms
7.3.1
Crawlers and Scrapers
A crawler is a software algorithm that generates a sequence of web pages
that may be searched for news content. The word crawler signifies that
the algorithm begins at some web page, and then chooses to branch out
to other pages from there, i.e., “crawls” around the web. The algorithm
needs to make intelligent choices from among all the pages it might look
for. One common approach is to move to a page that is linked to, i.e.,
hyper-referenced, from the current page. Essentially a crawler explores
the tree emanating from any given node, using heuristics to determine
relevance along any path, and then chooses which paths to focus on.
Crawling algorithms have become increasingly sophisticated—see Edwards, McCurley, and Tomlin (2001).
A web scraper downloads the content of a chosen web page and may
170
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
or may not format it for analysis. Almost all programming languages
contain modules for web scraping. These inbuilt functions open a channel to the web, and then download user-specified (or crawler-specified)
URLs. The growing statistical analysis of web text has led to most statistical packages containing inbuilt web scraping functions. For example,
R has web-scraping built into its base distribution. If we want to download a page into a vector of lines, simply proceed to use a single-line
command, such as the one below that reads my web page:
> t e x t = r e a d L i n e s ( " h t t p : / / a l g o . scu . edu / ~ s a n j i v d a s / " )
> text [1:4]
[ 1 ] " <html > "
[2] " "
[ 3 ] " <head> "
[ 4 ] " < t i t l e >SCU Web Page o f S a n j i v Ranjan Das< / t i t l e > "
As is apparent, the program read my web page into a vector of text
lines called text. We then examined the first four elements of the vector, i.e., the first four lines. In R, we do not need to open a communication channel, nor do we need to make an effort to program reading the
page line-by-line. We also do not need to tokenize the file, simple stringhandling routines take care of that as well. For example, extracting my
name would require the following:
> substr ( t e x t [ 4 ] , 2 4 , 2 9 )
[1] " Sanjiv "
> r e s = regexpr ( " S a n j i v " , t e x t [ 4 ] )
> res
[ 1 ] 24
a t t r ( , " match . l e n g t h " )
[1] 6
a t t r ( , " useBytes " )
[ 1 ] TRUE
> res [1]
[ 1 ] 24
> s u b s t r ( t e x t [ 4 ] , r e s [ 1 ] , r e s [ 1 ] + nchar ( " S a n j i v " ) − 1)
[1] " Sanjiv "
The most widely-used spreadsheet, Excel, also has an inbuilt webscraping function. Interested readers should examine the Data → GetExternal
command tree. You can download entire web pages or frames of web
more than words: extracting information from news
171
pages into worksheets and then manipulate the data as required. Further, Excel can be set up to refresh the content every minute or at some
other interval.
The days when web-scraping code needed to be written in C, Java,
Perl or Python are long gone. Data, algorithms, and statistical analysis
can be handled within the same software framework using tools like R.
Pure data-scraping delivers useful statistics. In Das, Martinez-Jerez
and Tufano (2005), we scraped stock messages from four companies
(Amazon, General Magic, Delta, and Geoworks) and from simple counts,
we were able to characterize the communication behavior of users on
message boards, and their relationship to news releases. In Figure 7.2
we see that posters respond heavily to the initial news release, and then
posting activity tapers off almost 2/3 of a day later. In Figure 7.3 we
see how the content of discussion changes after a news release—the
relative proportions of messages are divided into opinions, facts, and
questions. Opinions form the bulk of the discussion. Whereas the text
contains some facts at the outset, the factual content of discussion tapers
off sharply after the first hour.
Quantity of Hourly Postings
After Selected Press Releases
350
80%
Figure 7.2: Quantity of hourly
postings on message boards after
70%releases. Source:
selected news
Das, Martinez-Jerez and Tufano
60%
(2005).
300
Percentage of Posts
Number of Posts
250
200
150
50%
40%
30%
100
20%
50
10%
0
0%
0-1
1-2
2-3
3-4
4-5
5-6
6-7
7-8
8-9
9-10
10-11 11-12 12-13 13-14 14-15 15-16 16-17 17-18
0-1
1-2
2-3
Hours Since Press Release
Panel
A:and
Number
ofalsopostings
byfound
hour
Poster
behavior
statistics are
informative. We
that
after 16
selected
press see the
the frequency
of posting
by userscorporate
was power-law distributed,
histogram
in Figure 7.4. The weekly pattern of postings is shown in
releases.
s
Histogram of Posters by Frequency
(all stocks, all boards)
10000
9000
8899
Panel B: Dis
posting by h
corporate pr
classified as
news story, a
histogram sh
point posts (t
the nature of
172
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
Subjective Evaluation of Nature
of Post-News Release Postings
Figure 7.3: Subjective evaluation
of content of post-news release
postings on message boards. The
content is divided into opinions,
facts, and questions. Source: Das,
Martinez-Jerez and Tufano (2005).
80%
70%
Percentage of Posts
60%
50%
Opinions
Facts
Questions
40%
30%
20%
10%
0%
-18
0-1
1-2
2-3
3-4
4-5
5-6
6-7
7-8
Hours Since Press Release
8899
2-
Cleanup,” which removes all HTML tags from the body of the message
as these often occur concatenated to lexical items of interest. Examples
of some of these tags are: <BR>,<p>,&quot, etc. Second, we expand abbreviations to their full form, making the representation of phrases with
abbreviated words common across the message. For example, the word
“ain’t” is replaced with “are not”, “it’s” is replaced with “it is”,
etc. Third, we handle negation words. Whenever a negation word appears in a sentence, it usually causes the meaning of the sentence to be
the opposite of that without the negation. For example, the sentence “It
Power Law
1
5
6177
Panel B: Distribution of type of
Figure 7.5. We see that there is more posting activity on week days, but
posting by hour after 16 selected
messages are longer on weekends, when participants presumably have
corporate press releases. Postings are
more time on their hands! An analysis of intraday message flow shows
classified
on-point
if related
the in Figure
that there
is plenty ofas
activity
during and
after work, to
as shown
7.6. news story, and off-point otherwise. The
histogram shows the percentage of on7.3.2 point
Text Pre-processing
posts (the height of each bar) and
thepublic
nature
ofisthe
posts
Text from
sources
dirty.on-point
Text from web
pages (asks
is even dirtier.
Algorithms
are needed
to undertake
clean up before
analytics
question,
provides
alleged
fact,news
proposes
can be applied. This is known as pre-processing. First, there is “HTML
opinion.)
Po
1
25
610
25
11
-
-5
0
26
0
51
-1
0
50
0
10
1-
00
0
0
15
10
0
1276 1614
518
293
256
26
00
0
14
1
50
11
5000
4000
3000
2000
1000
0
>5
00
Number of posters
Panel A: Number of postings by hour
Panel B: Distr
more
than words: extracting information
from news by
173ho
after 16 selected corporate
press
posting
releases.
corporate pre
classified as o
news story, an
Histogram of Posters by Frequency
(all stocks, all boards)
histogram sho
Figure 7.4: Frequency of posting by
point
posts (th
message board
participants.
10000
8899
the nature of th
9000
8000
question, prov
6177
7000
6000
opinion.)
Frequency of postings
Weekly Pattern in Posting Activity
Avg Length
0
Average daily number of postings
TOTAL
Mon
494
Tue
Mon
550
Wed
Wed
Thu
604
Thu
Fri
Sat
Sun
TOT
Tue
639
508
Fri
248
Sat
283
476
Sun
200
400
Figure 7.5: Frequency of posting
600
800
by day of week by message board
participants.
174
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
Intra-day Message Flow
TOTAL
12am9am
WEEKENDS
WEEKDAYS
91
77
9am4pm
4pm12pm Average
TOTAL
.49
44
278
226
Week-ends/
Weekdays
97
204
233 per day
number
of characters
.35
134 .58
WEEKDAYS
WEEK-ENDS
Average number of messages per day
480
342
469
304
424
1.1
534
617
400
527
2.0
1.3
Figure 7.6: Frequency of posting by
segment of day by message board
participants. We show the average
number of messages per day in the
top panel and the average number
of characters per message in the
bottom panel.
more than words: extracting information from news
is not a bullish market” actually means the opposite of a bull market.
Words such as “not”, “never”, “no”, etc., serve to reverse meaning. We
handle negation by detecting these words and then tagging the rest of
the words in the sentence after the negation word with markers, so as to
reverse inference. This negation tagging was first introduced in Das and
Chen (2007) (original working paper 2001), and has been successfully
implemented elsewhere in quite different domains—see Pang, Lee and
Vaithyanathan (2002).
Another aspect of text pre-processing is to “stem” words. This is a
process by which words are replaced by their roots, so that different
tenses, etc. of a word are not treated differently. There are several wellknown stemming algorithms and free program code available in many
programming languages. A widely-used algorithm is the Porter (1980)
stemmer. Stemming is of course language-dependent—there are many
algorithms available for stemming, and in general, there are many natural language routines, see http://cran.r-project.org/web/views/NaturalLanguageProcessing.html.
The main package that is used is the tm package for text mining. See:
http://www.jstatsoft.org/v25/i05/paper. And see the excellent introduction in http://cran.r-project.org/web/packages/tm/vignettes/tm.pdf.
7.3.3
The tm package
Here we will quickly review usage of the tm package. Start up the package as follows:
l i b r a r y ( tm )
The tm package comes with several readers for various file types. Examples are readPlain(), readPDF(), readDOC(), etc.). The main data
structure in the tm package is a “corpus” which is a collection of text
documents. Let’s create a sample corpus as follows.
>
>
>
A
>
t e x t = c ( " Doc1 " , " This i s doc2 " , "And then Doc3 " )
c t e x t = Corpus ( VectorSourc e ( t e x t ) )
ctext
corpus with 3 t e x t documents
writeCorpus ( c t e x t )
The last writeCorpus operation results in the creation of three text files
(1.txt, 2.txt, 3.txt) on disk with the individual text within them (try this
and make sure these text files have been written). You can examine a
corpus as follows:
175
176
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
> inspect ( ctext )
A corpus with 3 t e x t documents
The metadata c o n s i s t s o f 2 tag −value p a i r s and a data frame
Available tags are :
c r e a t e _ date c r e a t o r
A v a i l a b l e v a r i a b l e s i n t h e data frame a r e :
MetaID
[[1]]
Doc1
[[2]]
This i s doc2
[[3]]
And then Doc3
And to convert it to lower case you can use the transformation function
> ctext [[3]]
And then Doc3
> tm_map( c t e x t , tolower ) [ [ 3 ] ]
and then doc3
Sometimes to see the contents of the corpus you may need the inspect
function, usage is as follows:
> #THE CORPUS I S A LIST OBJECT i n R
> inspect ( ctext )
<<VCorpus>>
Metadata : corpus s p e c i f i c : 0 , document l e v e l ( indexed ) : 0
Content : documents : 3
[[1]]
<<PlainTextDocument >>
Metadata : 7
Content : c h a r s : 4
[[2]]
<<PlainTextDocument >>
more than words: extracting information from news
Metadata : 7
Content : c h a r s : 12
[[3]]
<<PlainTextDocument >>
Metadata : 7
Content : c h a r s : 13
> p r i n t ( as . c h a r a c t e r ( c t e x t [ [ 1 ] ] ) )
[ 1 ] " Doc1 "
> p r i n t ( lapply ( c t e x t [ 1 : 2 ] , as . c h a r a c t e r ) )
$ ‘1 ‘
[ 1 ] " Doc1 "
$ ‘2 ‘
[ 1 ] " This i s doc2 "
The key benefit of constructing a corpus using the tm package (or for
that matter, any corpus handling tool) is that it provides you the ability
to run text operations on the entire corpus, rather than on just one document at a time. Notice how we converted all documents in our corpus
to lower case using the simple command above. Other commands are
presented below, and there are several more.
The tm map object is versatile and embeds many methods. Let’s try
some more extensive operations with this package.
> l i b r a r y ( tm )
> t e x t = r e a d L i n e s ( " h t t p : / / a l g o . scu . edu / ~ s a n j i v d a s / bio −candid . html " )
> c t e x t = Corpus ( VectorSourc e ( t e x t ) )
> ctext
A corpus with 78 t e x t documents
> ctext [[69]]
i n . Academia i s a r e a l c h a l l e n g e , given t h a t he has t o r e c o n c i l e many
> tm_map( c t e x t , removePunctuation ) [ [ 6 9 ] ]
i n Academia i s a r e a l c h a l l e n g e given t h a t he has t o r e c o n c i l e many
The last command removed all the punctuation items.
An important step is to create a “term-document” matrix which creates word vectors of all documents. (We will see later why this is very
useful to generate.) The commands are as follows:
177
178
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
> tdm_ t e x t = TermDocumentMatrix ( c t e x t , c o n t r o l = l i s t ( minWordLength = 1 ) )
> tdm_ t e x t
A term−document matrix ( 3 3 9 terms , 78 documents )
Non− / s p a r s e e n t r i e s : 497 / 25945
Sparsity
: 98%
Maximal term length : 63
Weighting
: term frequency ( t f )
> i n s p e c t ( tdm_ t e x t [ 1 : 1 0 , 1 : 5 ] )
A term−document matrix ( 1 0 terms , 5 documents )
Non− / s p a r s e e n t r i e s :
Sparsity
:
Maximal term length :
Weighting
:
Docs
Terms
1 2
(m. p h i l
0 0
(m. s .
0 0
( university 0 0
<b> s a n j i v
0 0
<body
0 1
<html >
1 0
<p>
0 0
1994
0 0
2010.
0 0
about
0 0
3
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
2 / 48
96%
11
term frequency ( t f )
4
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
5
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
You can find the most common words using the following command.
> findFreqTerms ( tdm_ t e x t , lowfreq =7)
[ 1 ] " and "
" from "
" his "
"many"
7.3.4
" s a n j i v " " the "
Term Frequency - Inverse Document Frequency (TF-IDF)
This is a weighting scheme provided to sharpen the importance of rare
words in a document, relative to the frequency of these words in the corpus. It is based on simple calculations and even though it does not have
strong theoretical foundations, it is still very useful in practice. The TF-
more than words: extracting information from news
IDF is the importance of a word w in a document d in a corpus C. Therefore it is a function of all these three, i.e., we write it as TF-IDF(w, d, C ),
and is the product of term frequency (TF) and inverse document frequency (IDF).
The frequency of a word in a document is defined as
f (w, d) =
#w ∈ d
|d|
(7.1)
where |d| is the number of words in the document. We usually normalize word frequency so that
TF (w, d) = ln[ f (w, d)]
(7.2)
This is log normalization. Another form of normalization is known as
double normalization and is as follows:
TF (w, d) =
1 1
f (w, d)
+
2 2 maxw∈d f (w, d)
(7.3)
Note that normalization is not necessary, but it tends to help shrink the
difference between counts of words.
Inverse document frequency is as follows:
|C |
IDF (w, C ) = ln
(7.4)
| dw∈d |
That is, we compute the ratio of the number of documents in the corpus
C divided by the number of documents with word w in the corpus.
Finally, we have the weighting score for a given word w in document d
in corpus C:
TF-IDF(w, d, C ) = TF (w, d) × IDF (w, C )
(7.5)
We illustrate this with an application to the previously computed
term-document matrix.
tdm_mat = as . matrix ( tdm ) # C o n v e r t tdm i n t o a m a t r i x
p r i n t ( dim ( tdm_mat ) )
nw = dim ( tdm_mat ) [ 1 ]
nd = dim ( tdm_mat ) [ 2 ]
d = 13
# C h o o s e document
w = " derivatives "
# C h o o s e word
#COMPUTE TF
179
180
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
f = tdm_mat [w, d ] / sum( tdm_mat [ , d ] )
print ( f )
TF = log ( f )
p r i n t ( TF )
#COMPUTE IDF
nw = length ( which ( tdm_mat [w, ] > 0 ) )
p r i n t (nw)
IDF = nd /nw
p r i n t ( IDF )
#COMPUTE TF−IDF
TF_IDF = TF * IDF
p r i n t ( TF_IDF ) # With n o r m a l i z a t i o n
p r i n t ( f * IDF )
# Without n o r m a l i z a t i o n
Running this code results in the following output.
> p r i n t ( TF_IDF )
[ 1 ] − 30.74538
> p r i n t ( f * IDF )
[ 1 ] 2.257143
# With n o r m a l i z a t i o n
# Without n o r m a l i z a t i o n
We may write this code into a function and work out the TF-IDF for
all words. Then these word weights may be used in further text analysis.
7.3.5
Wordclouds
Then, you can make a word cloud from the document.
> l i b r a r y ( wordcloud )
Loading r e q u i r e d package : Rcpp
Loading r e q u i r e d package : RColorBrewer
> tdm = as . matrix ( tdm_ t e x t )
> wordcount = s o r t ( rowSums ( tdm ) , d e c r e a s i n g =TRUE)
> tdm_names = names ( wordcount )
> wordcloud ( tdm_names , wordcount )
This generates Figure 7.7.
more than words: extracting information from news
181
Figure 7.7: Example of application
of word cloud to the bio data
extracted from the web and stored
in a Corpus.
Stemming
Stemming is the process of truncating words so that we treat words independent of their verb conjugation. We may not want to treat words
like “sleep”, “sleeping” as different. The process of stemming truncates
words and returns their root or stem. The goal is to map related words
to the same stem. There are several stemming algorithms and this is a
well-studied area in linguistics and computer science. A commonly used
algorithm is the one in Porter (1980). The tm package comes with an inbuilt stemmer.
Exercise
Using the tm package: Install the tm package and all its dependency packages. Using a data set of your own, or one of those that come with the
package, undertake an analysis that you are interested in. Try to exploit
at least four features or functions in the tm package.
7.3.6
Regular Expressions
Regular expressions are syntax used to modify strings in an efficient
manner. They are complicated but extremely effective. Here we will
illustrate with a few examples, but you are encouraged to explore more
on your own, as the variations are endless. What you need to do will
182
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
depend on the application at hand, and with some experience you will
become better at using regular expressions. The initial use will however
be somewhat confusing.
We start with a simple example of a text array where we wish replace
the string “data” with a blank, i.e., we eliminate this string from the text
we have.
> l i b r a r y ( tm )
Loading r e q u i r e d package : NLP
> # Create a text array
> t e x t = c ( " Doc1 i s d a t a v i s i o n " , " Doc2 i s d a t a t a b l e " , " Doc3 i s data "
" Doc4 i s nodata " , " Doc5 i s s i m p l e r " )
> print ( text )
[ 1 ] " Doc1 i s d a t a v i s i o n " " Doc2 i s d a t a t a b l e " " Doc3 i s data "
" Doc4 i s nodata "
[ 5 ] " Doc5 i s s i m p l e r "
>
> # Remove a l l s t r i n g s w i t h t h e c h o s e n t e x t f o r a l l d o c s
> p r i n t ( gsub ( " data " , " " , t e x t ) )
[ 1 ] " Doc1 i s v i s i o n " " Doc2 i s t a b l e "
" Doc3 i s "
" Doc4 i s
" Doc5 i s s i m p l e r "
>
> # Remove a l l words t h a t c o n t a i n " d a t a " a t t h e s t a r t e v e n i f
they a r e l o n g e r than data
> p r i n t ( gsub ( " * data . * " , " " , t e x t ) )
[ 1 ] " Doc1 i s "
" Doc2 i s "
" Doc3 i s "
" Doc4 i s
" Doc5 i s s i m p l e r "
>
> # Remove a l l words t h a t c o n t a i n " d a t a " a t t h e end e v e n
i f they a r e l o n g e r than data
> p r i n t ( gsub ( " * . data * " , " " , t e x t ) )
[ 1 ] " Doc1 i s v i s i o n "
" Doc2 i s t a b l e "
" Doc3 i s "
" Doc4 i s
" Doc5 i s s i m p l e r "
>
> # Remove a l l words t h a t c o n t a i n " d a t a " a t t h e end e v e n
i f they a r e l o n g e r than data
> p r i n t ( gsub ( " * . data . * " , " " , t e x t ) )
[ 1 ] " Doc1 i s "
" Doc2 i s "
" Doc3 i s "
" Doc4 i s
" Doc5 i s s i m p l e r "
,
no "
no "
n"
n"
more than words: extracting information from news
We now explore some more complex regular expressions. One case
that is common is handling the search for special types of strings like
telephone numbers. Suppose we have a text array that may contain telephone numbers in different formats, we can use a single grep command
to extract these numbers. Here is some code to illustrate this.
> # C r e a t e an a r r a y w i t h some s t r i n g s which may a l s o c o n t a i n
t e l e p h o n e numbers as s t r i n g s .
> x = c ( " 234 − 5678 " , " 234 5678 " , " 2345678 " , " 1234567890 " ,
" 0123456789 " , " abc 234 − 5678 " , " 234 5678 def " ,
" xx 2345678 " , " abc1234567890def " )
>
> #Now u s e g r e p t o f i n d which e l e m e n t s o f t h e a r r a y
c o n t a i n t e l e p h o n e numbers
> idx = grep ( " [ [ : d i g i t : ] ] { 3 } − [ [ : d i g i t : ] ] { 4 } | [ [ : d i g i t : ] ] { 3 } [ [ : d i g i t : ] ] { 4 } |
[1 − 9][0 − 9][0 − 9][0 − 9][0 − 9][0 − 9][0 − 9][0 − 9][0 − 9][0 − 9] " , x )
> p r i n t ( idx )
[1] 1 2 4 6 7 9
> p r i n t ( x [ idx ] )
[ 1 ] " 234 − 5678 "
" 234 5678 "
" 1234567890 "
" abc 234 − 5678 "
" 234 5678 def "
[ 6 ] " abc1234567890def "
>
> #We can s h o r t e n t h i s a s f o l l o w s
> idx = grep ( " [ [ : d i g i t : ] ] { 3 } − [ [ : d i g i t : ] ] { 4 } | [ [ : d i g i t : ] ] { 3 } [ [ : d i g i t : ] ] { 4 } |
[1 −9][0 −9]{9} " , x )
> p r i n t ( idx )
[1] 1 2 4 6 7 9
> p r i n t ( x [ idx ] )
[ 1 ] " 234 − 5678 "
" 234 5678 "
" 1234567890 "
" abc 234 − 5678 "
" 234 5678 def "
[ 6 ] " abc1234567890def "
>
> #What i f we want t o e x t r a c t o n l y t h e p h o n e number and d r o p t h e
r e s t of the t e x t ?
> pattern = " [ [ : digit : ] ] { 3 } − [ [ : digit : ] ] { 4 } | [ [ : digit : ] ] { 3 } [ [ : digit : ] ] { 4 } |
[1 −9][0 −9]{9} "
> p r i n t ( regmatches ( x , gregexpr ( p a t t e r n , x ) ) )
[[1]]
[ 1 ] " 234 − 5678 "
[[2]]
[ 1 ] " 234 5678 "
[[3]]
character (0)
[[4]]
[ 1 ] " 1234567890 "
183
184
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
[[5]]
character (0)
[[6]]
[ 1 ] " 234 − 5678 "
[[7]]
[ 1 ] " 234 5678 "
[[8]]
character (0)
[[9]]
[ 1 ] " 1234567890 "
>
> #Or u s e t h e s t r i n g r p a c k a g e , which i s a l o t b e t t e r
> library ( stringr )
> s t r _ extract ( x , pattern )
[ 1 ] " 234 − 5678 "
" 234 5678 "
NA
" 1234567890 " NA
" 234 − 5678 "
" 234 5678 "
[ 8 ] NA
" 1234567890 "
>
Now we use grep to extract emails by looking for the “@” sign in the
text string. We would proceed as in the following example.
> x = c ( " s a n j i v das " , " srdas@scu . edu " , "SCU" , " d a t a @ s c i e n c e . edu " )
> p r i n t ( grep ( " \\@" , x ) )
[1] 2 4
> p r i n t ( x [ grep ( " \\@" , x ) ] )
[ 1 ] " srdas@scu . edu "
" d a t a @ s c i e n c e . edu "
7.4 Extracting Data from Web Sources using APIs
7.4.1
Using Twitter
As of March 2013, Twitter requires using the OAuth protocol for accessing tweets. Install the following packages: twitter, ROAuth, and RCurl.
Then invoke them in R:
>
>
>
>
+
library ( twitteR )
l i b r a r y ( ROAuth )
l i b r a r y ( RCurl )
download . f i l e ( u r l = " h t t p : / / c u r l . haxx . se / ca / c a c e r t . pem" ,
d e s t f i l e = " c a c e r t . pem" )
more than words: extracting information from news
The last statement downloads some required files that we will invoke
later. First, if you do not have a Twitter user account, go ahead and create one. Next, set up your developer account on Twitter, by going to
the following URL: https://dev.twitter.com/apps. Register your account by putting in the needed information and then in the “Settings"
tab, select “Read, Write and Access Direct Messages”. Save your settings
and then from the “Details" tab, copy and save your credentials, namely
Consumer Key and Consumer Secret (these are long strings represented
below by “xxxx”).
> cKey = " xxxx "
> c S e c r e t = " xxxx "
Next, save the following strings as well. These are needed eventually to
gain access to Twitter feeds.
> reqURL = " h t t p s : / / a p i . t w i t t e r . com / oauth / r e q u e s t _ token "
> accURL = " h t t p s : / / a p i . t w i t t e r . com / oauth / a c c e s s _ token "
> authURL = " h t t p s : / / a p i . t w i t t e r . com / oauth / a u t h o r i z e "
Now, proceed on to the authorization stage. The object cred below
stands for credentials, this is standard usage it seems.
> cred = OAuthFactory $new( consumerKey=cKey ,
+
consumerSecret= c S e c r e t ,
+
requestURL=reqURL ,
+
accessURL=accURL ,
+
authURL=authURL )
> cred $ handshake ( c a i n f o = " c a c e r t . pem" )
The last handshaking command, connects to twitter and requires you to
enter your token which is obtained as follows:
To e n a b l e t h e connection , p l e a s e d i r e c t your web browser t o :
h t t p s : / / a p i . t w i t t e r . com / oauth / a u t h o r i z e ? oauth _ token=AbFALSqJzer3Iy7
When complete , r e c o r d t h e PIN given t o you and provide i t here : 5852017
The token above will be specific to your account, don’t use the one
above, it goes nowhere. The final step in setting up everything is to register your credentials, as follows.
> r e g i s t e r T w i t t e r O A u t h ( cred )
[ 1 ] TRUE
> save ( l i s t = " cred " , f i l e = " t w i t t e R _ c r e d e n t i a l s " )
185
186
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
The last statement saves your credentials to your active directory for
later use. You should see a file with the name above in your directory.
Test that everything is working by running the following commands.
library ( twitteR )
#USE h t t r
library ( httr )
# o p t i o n s ( h t t r _ o a u t h _ c a c h e =T )
accToken = " 186666 − q e q e r e r q e "
a c c T o k e n S e c r e t = " xxxx "
setup _ t w i t t e r _ oauth ( cKey , c S e c r e t , accToken , a c c T o k e n S e c r e t )
#At prompt t y p e 1
After this we are ready to begin extracting data from Twitter.
> s = s e a r c h T w i t t e r ( ’ #GOOG’ , c a i n f o = " c a c e r t . pem" )
> s [[1]]
[ 1 ] " Livetradingnews : B i l l # Gates Under P r e s s u r e To R e t i r e : #MSFT,
#GOOG, #AAPL R e u t e r s c i t i n g unnamed s o u r c e s ï £ ¡
h t t p : / / t . co / p0nvKnteRx "
> s [[2]]
[ 1 ] " TheBPMStation : # Free #App #EDM #NowPlaying Harrison Crump f e a t .
DJ Heather − NUM39R5 ( The Funk Monkeys Mix ) on #TheEDMSoundofLA
#BPM #Music # AppStore #Goog "
The object s is a list type object and hence its components are addressed
using the double square brackets, i.e., [[.]]. We print out the first two
tweets related to the GOOG hashtag.
If you want to search through a given user’s connections (like your
own), then do the following. You may be interested in linkages to see
how close a local network you inhabit on Twitter.
> s a n j i v = getUser ( " s r d a s " )
> s a n j i v $ g e t F r i e n d s ( n=6)
$ ‘104237736 ‘
[ 1 ] " BloombergNow "
$ ‘34713362 ‘
[ 1 ] " BloombergNews "
$ ‘2385131 ‘
[1] " eddelbuettel "
more than words: extracting information from news
187
$ ‘69133574 ‘
[ 1 ] " hadleywickham "
$ ‘9207632 ‘
[1] " brainpicker "
$ ‘41185337 ‘
[ 1 ] " LongspliceInv "
To look at any user’s tweets, execute the following commands.
> s _ t w e e t s = u s e r T i m e l i n e ( ’ s r d a s ’ , n=6)
> s _ tweets
[[1]]
[ 1 ] " s r d a s : Make Your Embarrassing Old Facebook P o s t s Unsearchable
With This Quick Tweak h t t p : / / t . co / BBzgDGnQdJ . # f b "
[[2]]
[ 1 ] " s r d a s : 24 E x t r a o r d i n a r i l y C r e a t i v e People Who I n s p i r e Us A l l : Meet t h e
2013 MacArthur Fellows ï £ ¡ MacArthur Foundation h t t p : / / t . co / 50jOWEfznd # f b "
[[3]]
[ 1 ] " s r d a s : The s c i e n c e o f and d i f f e r e n c e between l o v e and f r i e n d s h i p :
h t t p : / / t . co / bZmlYutqFl # f b "
[[4]]
[ 1 ] " s r d a s : The Simpsons ’ s e c r e t formula : i t ’ s w r i t t e n by maths geeks (why
our k i d s should l e a r n more math ) h t t p : / / t . co / nr61HQ8ejh v i a @guardian # f b "
[[5]]
[ 1 ] " s r d a s : How t o F a l l i n Love With Math h t t p : / / t . co / fzJnLrp0Mz
# fb "
[[6]]
[ 1 ] " s r d a s : Miss America i s Indian : − ) h t t p : / / t . co / q43dDNEjcv v i a @feedly
7.4.2
Using Facebook
As with Twitter, Facebook is also accessible using the OAuth protocol
but with somewhat simper handshaking. The required packages are
Rfacebook, SnowballC, and Rook. Of course the ROAuth package is re-
# fb "
188
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
quired as well.
To access Facebook feeds from R, you will need to create a developer’s
account on Facebook, and the current URL at which this is done is:
https://developers.facebook.com/apps. Visit this URL to create an
app and then obtain an app id, and a secret key for accessing Facebook.
#FACEBOOK EXTRACTOR
l i b r a r y ( Rfacebook )
l i b r a r y ( SnowballC )
l i b r a r y ( Rook )
l i b r a r y ( ROAuth )
app_ id = " 847737771920076 "
app_ s e c r e t = " a120a2ec908d9e00fcd3c619cad7d043 "
f b _ oauth = fbOAuth ( app_ id , app_ s e c r e t , extended _ p e r m i s s i o n s =TRUE)
# s a v e ( f b _ o a u t h , f i l e =" f b _ o a u t h " )
This will establish a legal handshaking session with the Facebook API.
Let’s examine some simple examples now.
#EXAMPLES
bbn = g e t U s e r s ( " bloombergnews " , token= f b _ oauth )
bbn
id
name username f i r s t _name middle _name l a s t _name
1 266790296879 Bloomberg B u s i n e s s
NA
NA
NA
NA
gender l o c a l e
category
likes
1
NA
NA Media / News / P u b l i s h i n g 1522511
Now we download the data from Bloomberg’s facebook page.
page = getPage ( page= " bloombergnews " , token= f b _ oauth )
100 p o s t s
p r i n t ( dim ( page ) )
[ 1 ] 100 10
head ( page )
1
2
3
4
5
6
from_ id
266790296879
266790296879
266790296879
266790296879
266790296879
266790296879
Bloomberg
Bloomberg
Bloomberg
Bloomberg
Bloomberg
Bloomberg
from_name
Business
Business
Business
Business
Business
Business
more than words: extracting information from news
message
1
A r a r e glimpse i n s i d e Qatar Airways .
2
Republicans should be most worried .
3
The look on every c a s t member ’ s f a c e s a i d i t a l l .
4 Would you buy a $ 5 0 , 0 0 0 c o n v e r t i b l e SUV? Land Rover sure hopes so .
5
Employees need t h o s e yummy t r e a t s more than you t h i n k .
6
Learn how t o d r i f t on i c e and s k i d through mud .
c r e a t e d _ time type
1 2015 − 11 − 10T06 : 0 0 : 0 1 + 0 0 0 0 l i n k
2 2015 − 11 − 10T05 : 0 0 : 0 1 + 0 0 0 0 l i n k
3 2015 − 11 − 10T04 : 0 0 : 0 1 + 0 0 0 0 l i n k
4 2015 − 11 − 10T03 : 0 0 : 0 0 + 0 0 0 0 l i n k
5 2015 − 11 − 10T02 : 3 0 : 0 0 + 0 0 0 0 l i n k
6 2015 − 11 − 10T02 : 0 0 : 0 1 + 0 0 0 0 l i n k
1
h t t p : / /www. bloomberg . com / news / photo−e s s a y s / 2015 − 11 − 09 /
f l y i n g −in −s t y l e −or−perhaps −f o r −war−at −the −dubai−a i r −show
2 h t t p : / /www. bloomberg . com / news / a r t i c l e s / 2015 − 11 − 05 /
putin −s−o c t o b e r −s u r p r i s e −may−be−nightmare −f o r − p r e s i d e n t i a l −c a n d i d a t e s
3
h t t p : / /www. bloomberg . com / p o l i t i c s / a r t i c l e s / 2015 − 11 − 08 /
kind−of −dead−as −trump−hosts −saturday −night − l i v e
4
h t t p : / /www. bloomberg . com / news / a r t i c l e s / 2015 − 11 − 09 /
range −rover −evoque−c o n v e r t i b l e −announced−c o s t −s p e c s
5
h t t p : / /www. bloomberg . com / news / a r t i c l e s / 2015 − 11 − 09 /
why−g e t t i n g −r id −of −f r e e − o f f i c e −snacks −doesn−t −come−cheap
6
h t t p : / /www. bloomberg . com / news / a r t i c l e s / 2015 − 11 − 09 /
luxury −auto −d r i v i n g −s c h o o l s −lamborghini − f e r r a r i −l o t u s −porsche
id l i k e s _ count comments_ count
1 266790296879 _ 10153725290936880
44
3
2 266790296879 _ 10153718159351880
60
7
3 266790296879 _ 10153725606551880
166
50
4 266790296879 _ 10153725568581880
75
12
5 266790296879 _ 10153725534026880
72
8
6 266790296879 _ 10153725547431880
16
3
s h a r e s _ count
1
7
2
10
3
17
4
27
5
24
6
5
We examine the data elements in this data.frame as follows.
names ( page )
[1]
[4]
[7]
[10]
" from_ id "
" c r e a t e d _ time "
" id "
" s h a r e s _ count "
page$ message
" from_name "
" type "
" l i k e s _ count "
" message "
" link "
" comments_ count "
# p r i n t s o u t l i n e by l i n e ( p a r t i a l v i e w shown )
189
190
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
[1]
[2]
[3]
[4]
[5]
[6]
[7]
[8]
[9]
[10]
"A r a r e glimpse i n s i d e Qatar Airways . "
" Republicans should be most worried . "
" The look on every c a s t member ’ s f a c e s a i d i t a l l . "
" Would you buy a $ 5 0 , 0 0 0 c o n v e r t i b l e SUV? Land Rover sure hopes so . "
" Employees need t h o s e yummy t r e a t s more than you t h i n k . "
" Learn how t o d r i f t on i c e and s k i d through mud. "
" \ " Shhh , Mom. Lower your v o i c e . Mom, you ’ r e being loud . \ " "
" The t r u t h about why drug p r i c e s keep going up h t t p : / / bloom . bg / 1HqjKFM"
" The u n i v e r s i t y i s f a c i n g c h a r g e s o f d i s c r i m i n a t i o n . "
"We ’ r e not t a l k i n g about Captain Morgan . "
page $ message [ 9 1 ]
[ 1 ] "He ’ s a l r e a d y c l o s e t o breaking r e c o r d s j u s t days i n t o h i s r e t i r e m e n t . "
Therefore, we see how easy and simple it is to extract web pages and
then process them as required.
7.4.3 Text processing, plain and simple
As an example, let’s just read in some text from the web and process it
without using the tm package.
#TEXT MINING EXAMPLES
# F i r s t r e a d i n t h e p a g e you want .
t e x t = r e a d L i n e s ( " h t t p : / /www. b a h i k e r . com / e a s t b a y h i k e s / s i b l e y . html " )
# Remove a l l l i n e e l e m e n t s w i t h s p e c i a l
t e x t = t e x t [ s e t d i f f ( seq ( 1 , length ( t e x t ) )
t e x t = t e x t [ s e t d i f f ( seq ( 1 , length ( t e x t ) )
t e x t = t e x t [ s e t d i f f ( seq ( 1 , length ( t e x t ) )
t e x t = t e x t [ s e t d i f f ( seq ( 1 , length ( t e x t ) )
t e x t = t e x t [ s e t d i f f ( seq ( 1 , length ( t e x t ) )
t e x t = t e x t [ s e t d i f f ( seq ( 1 , length ( t e x t ) )
characters
, grep ( " < " , t e x t ) ) ]
, grep ( " > " , t e x t ) ) ]
, grep ( " ] " , t e x t ) ) ]
, grep ( " } " , t e x t ) ) ]
, grep ( " _ " , t e x t ) ) ]
, grep ( " \\ / " , t e x t ) ) ]
# General purpose string handler
t e x t = t e x t [ s e t d i f f ( seq ( 1 , length ( t e x t ) ) , grep ( " ] | > | < | } | − | \\ / " , t e x t ) ) ]
# I f needed , c o l l a p s e t h e t e x t i n t o a s i n g l e s t r i n g
t e x t = p a s t e ( t e x t , c o l l a p s e = " \n " )
You can see that this code generated an almost clean body of text.
Once the text is ready for analysis, we proceed to apply various algorithms to it. The next few techniques are standard algorithms that are
used very widely in the machine learning field.
First, let’s read in a very popular dictionary called the Harvard Inquirer: http://www.wjh.harvard.edu/∼inquirer/. This contains all
the words in English scored on various emotive criteria. We read in the
downloaded dictionary, and then extract all the positive connotation
words and the negative connotation words. We then collect these words
more than words: extracting information from news
in two separate lists for further use.
# Read i n t h e Harvard I n q u i r e r D i c t i o n a r y
#And c r e a t e a l i s t o f p o s i t i v e and n e g a t i v e words
HIDict = r e a d L i n e s ( " i n q d i c t . t x t " )
d i c t _pos = HIDict [ grep ( " Pos " , HIDict ) ]
poswords = NULL
f o r ( s i n d i c t _pos ) {
s = strsplit (s , "#" )[[1]][1]
poswords = c ( poswords , s t r s p l i t ( s , " " ) [ [ 1 ] ] [ 1 ] )
}
d i c t _neg = HIDict [ grep ( "Neg" , HIDict ) ]
negwords = NULL
f o r ( s i n d i c t _neg ) {
s = strsplit (s , "#" )[[1]][1]
negwords = c ( negwords , s t r s p l i t ( s , " " ) [ [ 1 ] ] [ 1 ] )
}
poswords = tolower ( poswords )
negwords = tolower ( negwords )
After this, we take the body of text we took from the web, and then
parse it into separate words, so that we can compare it to the dictionary
and count the number of positive and negative words.
# Get t h e s c o r e o f t h e body o f t e x t
txt = unlist ( s t r s p l i t ( text , " " ) )
posmatch = match ( t x t , poswords )
numposmatch = length ( posmatch [ which ( posmatch > 0 ) ] )
negmatch = match ( t x t , negwords )
numnegmatch = length ( negmatch [ which ( negmatch > 0 ) ] )
p r i n t ( c ( numposmatch , numnegmatch ) )
[ 1 ] 47 35
Carefully note all the various list and string handling functions that have
been used, and make the entire processing effort so simple. These are:
grep, paste, strsplit, c, tolower, and unlist.
7.4.4 A Multipurpose Function to Extract Text
l i b r a r y ( tm )
library ( stringr )
191
192
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
#READ IN TEXT FOR ANALYSIS , PUT IT IN A CORPUS, OR ARRAY, OR FLAT STRING
# c s t e m =1 , i f stemming n e e d e d
# c s t o p =1 , i f s t o p w o r d s t o b e r e m o v e d
# c c a s e =1 f o r l o w e r c a s e , c c a s e =2 f o r u p p e r c a s e
# cpunc =1 , i f p u n c t u a t i o n t o b e r e m o v e d
# c f l a t =1 f o r f l a t t e x t wanted , c f l a t =2 i f t e x t a r r a y , e l s e r e t u r n s c o r p u s
read _web_page = f u n c t i o n ( url , cstem =0 , c s t o p =0 , c c a s e =0 , cpunc =0 , c f l a t =0) {
t e x t = readLines ( url )
t e x t = t e x t [ s e t d i f f ( seq ( 1 , length ( t e x t ) ) , grep ( " < " , t e x t ) ) ]
t e x t = t e x t [ s e t d i f f ( seq ( 1 , length ( t e x t ) ) , grep ( " > " , t e x t ) ) ]
t e x t = t e x t [ s e t d i f f ( seq ( 1 , length ( t e x t ) ) , grep ( " ] " , t e x t ) ) ]
t e x t = t e x t [ s e t d i f f ( seq ( 1 , length ( t e x t ) ) , grep ( " } " , t e x t ) ) ]
t e x t = t e x t [ s e t d i f f ( seq ( 1 , length ( t e x t ) ) , grep ( " _ " , t e x t ) ) ]
t e x t = t e x t [ s e t d i f f ( seq ( 1 , length ( t e x t ) ) , grep ( " \\ / " , t e x t ) ) ]
c t e x t = Corpus ( VectorSource ( t e x t ) )
i f ( cstem ==1) { c t e x t = tm_map( c t e x t , stemDocument ) }
i f ( c s t o p ==1) { c t e x t = tm_map( c t e x t , removeWords , stopwords ( " e n g l i s h " ) ) }
i f ( cpunc ==1) { c t e x t = tm_map( c t e x t , removePunctuation ) }
i f ( c c a s e ==1) { c t e x t = tm_map( c t e x t , tolower ) }
i f ( c c a s e ==2) { c t e x t = tm_map( c t e x t , toupper ) }
text = ctext
#CONVERT FROM CORPUS I F NEEDED
i f ( c f l a t >0) {
t e x t = NULL
f o r ( j i n 1 : length ( c t e x t ) ) {
temp = c t e x t [ [ j ] ] $ c o n t e n t
i f ( temp ! = " " ) { t e x t = c ( t e x t , temp ) }
}
t e x t = as . a r r a y ( t e x t )
}
i f ( c f l a t ==1) {
t e x t = p a s t e ( t e x t , c o l l a p s e = " \n " )
t e x t = s t r _ r e p l a c e _ a l l ( t e x t , " [\ r\n ] " , " " )
}
result = text
}
Here is an example of reading and cleaning up my research page:
u r l = " h t t p : / / a l g o . scu . edu / ~ s a n j i v d a s / r e s e a r c h . htm "
r e s = read _web_page ( url , 0 , 0 , 0 , 1 , 2 )
print ( res )
[ 1 ] " Data S c i e n c e T h e o r i e s Models Algorithms and A n a l y t i c s web book work i n p r o g r e s s "
[ 2 ] " D e r i v a t i v e s P r i n c i p l e s and P r a c t i c e 2010 "
[ 3 ] " Rangarajan Sundaram and S a n j i v Das McGraw H i l l "
[ 4 ] " C r e d i t Spreads with Dynamic Debt with Seoyoung Kim 2015 "
[ 5 ] " Text and Context Language A n a l y t i c s f o r Finance 2014 "
[ 6 ] " S t r a t e g i c Loan M o d i f i c a t i o n An OptionsBased Response t o S t r a t e g i c D e f a u l t "
[ 7 ] " Options and S t r u c t u r e d Products i n B e h a v i o r a l P o r t f o l i o s with Meir Statman 2013 "
[ 8 ] " and b a r r i e r range n o t e s i n t h e p r e s e n c e o f f a t t a i l e d outcomes using copulas "
.....
We then take my research page and mood score it, just for fun, to see
more than words: extracting information from news
if my work is uplifting.
#EXAMPLE OF MOOD SCORING
library ( stringr )
u r l = " h t t p : / / a l g o . scu . edu / ~ s a n j i v d a s / bio −candid . html "
t e x t = read _web_page ( url , cstem =0 , c s t o p =0 , c c a s e =0 , cpunc =1 , c f l a t =1)
print ( text )
[ 1 ] " S a n j i v Das i s t h e William and J a n i c e Terry P r o f e s s o r o f Finance
a t Santa C l ar a U n i v e r s i t y s Leavey School o f B u s i n e s s He p r e v i o u s l y
held f a c u l t y appointments as A s s o c i a t e P r o f e s s o r a t Harvard B u s i n e s s
School and UC B e r k e l e y He holds p o s t g r a d u a t e degrees i n Finance
MPhil and PhD from New York U n i v e r s i t y Computer S c i e n c e MS from
UC B e r k e l e y an MBA from t h e Indian I n s t i t u t e o f Management
Ahmedabad BCom i n Accounting and Economics U n i v e r s i t y o f
Bombay Sydenham C o l l e g e and i s a l s o a q u a l i f i e d Cost and Works
Accountant He i s a . . . . .
Notice how the text has been cleaned of all punctuation and flattened to
be one long string. Next, we run the mood scoring code.
text = unlist ( s t r s p l i t ( text , " " ) )
posmatch = match ( t e x t , poswords )
numposmatch = length ( posmatch [ which ( posmatch > 0 ) ] )
negmatch = match ( t e x t , negwords )
numnegmatch = length ( negmatch [ which ( negmatch > 0 ) ] )
p r i n t ( c ( numposmatch , numnegmatch ) )
[ 1 ] 26 16
So, there are 26 positive words and 16 negative words, presumably, this
is a good thing!
7.5 Text Classification
7.5.1
Bayes Classifier
The Bayes classifier is probably the most widely-used classifier in practice today. The main idea is to take a piece of text and assign it to one
of a pre-determined set of categories. This classifier is trained on an
initial corpus of text that is pre-classified. This “training data” provides the “prior” probabilities that form the basis for Bayesian anal-
193
194
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
ysis of the text. The classifier is then applied to out-of-sample text to
obtain the posterior probabilities of textual categories. The text is then
assigned to the category with the highest posterior probability. For
an excellent exposition of the adaptive qualities of this classifier, see
Graham (2004)—pages 121-129, Chapter 8, titled “A Plan for Spam.”
http://www.paulgraham.com/spam.html
To get started, let’s just first use the e1071 R package that contains
the function naiveBayes. We’ll use the “iris” data set that contains details about flowers and try to build a classifier to take a flower’s data
and identify which one it is most likely to be. Note that to list the data
sets currently loaded in R for the packages you have, use the following
command:
data ( )
We will now use the iris flower data to illustrate the Bayesian classifier.
l i b r a r y ( e1071 )
data ( i r i s )
r e s = naiveBayes ( i r i s [ , 1 : 4 ] , i r i s [ , 5 ] )
> res
Naive Bayes C l a s s i f i e r f o r D i s c r e t e P r e d i c t o r s
Call :
naiveBayes . d e f a u l t ( x = i r i s [ , 1 : 4 ] , y = i r i s [ , 5 ] )
A− p r i o r i p r o b a b i l i t i e s :
i r i s [ , 5]
setosa versicolor virginica
0.3333333 0.3333333 0.3333333
Conditional p r o b a b i l i t i e s :
S ep a l . Length
i r i s [ , 5]
[ ,1]
[ ,2]
setosa
5.006 0.3524897
versicolor 5.936 0.5161711
virginica 6.588 0.6358796
i r i s [ , 5]
S ep a l . Width
[ ,1]
[ ,2]
more than words: extracting information from news
setosa
3.428 0.3790644
versicolor 2.770 0.3137983
virginica 2.974 0.3224966
P e t a l . Length
i r i s [ , 5]
[ ,1]
[ ,2]
setosa
1.462 0.1736640
versicolor 4.260 0.4699110
virginica 5.552 0.5518947
P e t a l . Width
i r i s [ , 5]
[ ,1]
[ ,2]
setosa
0.246 0.1053856
versicolor 1.326 0.1977527
virginica 2.026 0.2746501
We then call the prediction program to predict a single case, or to construct the “confusion matrix” as follows. The table gives the mean and
standard deviation of the variables.
> p r e d i c t ( re s , i r i s [ 3 , 1 : 4 ] , type= " raw " )
setosa
versicolor
virginica
[1 ,]
1 2 . 3 6 7 1 1 3 e −18 7 . 2 4 0 9 5 6 e −26
> out = t a b l e ( p r e d i c t ( re s , i r i s [ , 1 : 4 ] ) , i r i s [ , 5 ] )
> p r i n t ( out )
setosa versicolor virginica
setosa
50
0
0
versicolor
0
47
3
virginica
0
3
47
This in-sample prediction can be clearly seen to have a high level of accuracy. A test of the significance of this matrix may be undertaken using
the chisq.test function.
The basic Bayes calculation takes the following form.
Pr [ F = 1| a, b, c, d] =
Pr [ a| F = 1] · Pr [b| F = 1] · Pr [c| F = 1] · Pr [d| F = 1] · Pr ( F = 1)
Pr [ a, b, c, d| F = 1] + Pr [ a, b, c, d| F = 2] + Pr [ a, b, c, d| F = 3]
where F is the flower type, and { a, b, c, d} are the four attributes. Note
that we do not need to compute the denominator, as it remains the same
for the calculation of Pr [ F = 1| a, b, c, d], Pr [ F = 2| a, b, c, d], or Pr [ F =
195
196
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
3| a, b, c, d].
There are several seminal sources detailing the Bayes classifier and its
applications—see Neal (1996), Mitchell (1997), Koller and Sahami (1997),
and Chakrabarti, Dom, Agrawal and Raghavan (1998)). These models
have many categories and are quite complex. But they do not discern
emotive content—but factual content—which is arguably more amenable
to the use of statistical techniques. In contrast, news analytics are more
complicated because the data comprises opinions, not facts, which are
usually harder to interpret.
The Bayes classifier uses word-based probabilities, and is thus indifferent to the structure of language. Since it is language-independent, it has
wide applicability.
The approach of the Bayes classifier is to use a set of pre-classified
messages to infer the category of new messages. It learns from past experience. These classifiers are extremely efficient especially when the
number of categories is small, e.g., in the classification of email into
spam versus non-spam. Here is a brief mathematical exposition of Bayes
classification.
Say we have hundreds of text messages (these are not instant messages!) that we wish to classify rapidly into a number of categories. The
total number of categories or classes is denoted C, and each category is
denoted ci , i = 1...C. Each text message is denoted m j , j = 1...M, where
M is the total number of messages. We denote Mi as the total number
of messages per class i, and ∑iC=1 Mi = M. Words in the messages are
denoted as (w) and are indexed by k, and the total number of words is T.
Let n(m, w) ≡ n(m j , wk ) be the total number of times word wk appears
in message m j . Notation is kept simple by suppressing subscripts as far
as possible—the reader will be able to infer this from the context. We
maintain a count of the number of times each word appears in every
message in the training data set. This leads naturally to the variable
n(m), the total number of words in message m including duplicates. This
is a simple sum, n(m j ) = ∑kT=1 n(m j , wk ).
We also keep track of the frequency with which a word appears in a
category. Hence, n(c, w) is the number of times word w appears in all
m ∈ c. This is
n ( ci , wk ) =
∑
m j ∈ ci
n ( m j , wk )
(7.6)
This defines a corresponding probability: θ (ci , wk ) is the probability with
more than words: extracting information from news
which word w appears in all messages m in class c:
θ (c, w) =
∑ m j ∈ ci n ( m j , w k )
∑ m j ∈ ci ∑ k n ( m j , w k )
=
n ( ci , wk )
n ( ci )
(7.7)
Every word must have some non-zero probability of occurrence, no matter how small, i.e., θ (ci , wk ) 6= 0, ∀ci , wk . Hence, an adjustment is made to
equation (7.7) via Laplace’s formula which is
θ ( ci , wk ) =
n ( ci , wk ) + 1
n ( ci ) + T
This probability θ (ci , wk ) is unbiased and efficient. If n(ci , wk ) = 0 and
n(ci ) = 0, ∀k, then every word is equiprobable, i.e., T1 . We now have
the required variables to compute the conditional probability of a text
message j in category i, i.e. Pr[m j |ci ]:
!
T
n(m j )
Pr[m j |ci ] =
θ (ci , wk )n(m j ,wk )
∏
{n(m j , wk )} k=1
=
T
n(m j )!
× ∏ θ (ci , wk )n(m j ,wk )
n(m j , w1 )! × n(m j , w2 )! × ... × n(m j , wT )! k=1
Pr[ci ] is the proportion of messages in the prior (training corpus) preclassified into class ci . (Warning: Careful computer implementation of
the multinomial probability above is required to avoid rounding error.)
The classification goal is to compute the most probable class ci given
any message m j . Therefore, using the previously computed values of
Pr[m j |ci ] and Pr[ci ], we obtain the following conditional probability (applying Bayes’ theorem):
Pr[ci |m j ] =
Pr[m j |ci ]. Pr[ci ]
C
∑i=1 Pr[m j |ci ]. Pr[ci ]
(7.8)
For each message, equation (7.8) delivers posterior probabilities,
Pr[ci |m j ], ∀i, one for each message category. The category with the highest probability is assigned to the message.
The Bayesian classifier requires no optimization and is computable in
deterministic time. It is widely used in practice. There are free off-theshelf programs that provide good software to run the Bayes classifier on
large data sets. The one that is very widely used in finance applications
is the Bow classifier, developed by Andrew McCallum when he was at
Carnegie-Mellon University. This is an very fast classifier that requires
almost no additional programming by the user. The user only has to
197
198
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
set up the training data set in a simple directory structure—each text
message is a separate file, and the training corpus requires different subdirectories for the categories of text. Bow offers various versions of the
Bayes classifier—see McCallum (1996). The simple (naive) Bayes classifier
described above is available in R in the e1071 package—the function is
called naiveBayes. The e1071 package is the machine learning library in
R. There are also several more sophisticated variants of the Bayes classifier such as k-Means, kNN, etc.
News analytics begin with classification, and the Bayes classifier is the
workhorse of any news analytic system. Prior to applying the classifier
it is important for the user to exercise judgment in deciding what categories the news messages will be classified into. These categories might
be a simple flat list, or they may even be a hierarchical set—see Koller
and Sahami (1997).
7.5.2
Support Vector Machines
A support vector machine or SVM is a classifier technique that is similar
to cluster analysis but is applicable to very high-dimensional spaces. The
idea may be best described by thinking of every text message as a vector
in high-dimension space, where the number of dimensions might be,
for example, the number of words in a dictionary. Bodies of text in the
same category will plot in the same region of the space. Given a training
corpus, the SVM finds hyperplanes in the space that best separate text of
one category from another.
For the seminal development of this method, see Vapnik and Lerner
(1963); Vapnik and Chervonenkis (1964); Vapnik (1995); and Smola and
Scholkopf (1998). I provide a brief summary of the method based on
these works.
Consider a training data set given by the binary relation
{( x1 , y1 ), ..., ( xn , yn )} ⊂ X × R.
The set X ∈ Rd is the input space and set Y ∈ Rm is a set of categories.
We define a function
f :x→y
with the idea that all elements must be mapped from set X into set Y
with no more than an e-deviation. A simple linear example of such a
model would be
f ( xi ) =< w, xi > +b, w ∈ X , b ∈ R
more than words: extracting information from news
The notation < w, x > signifies the dot product of w and x. Note that the
equation of a hyperplane is < w, x > +b = 0.
The idea in SVM regression is to find the flattest w that results in the
mappingqfrom x → y. Thus, we minimize the Euclidean norm of w, i.e.,
||w|| = ∑nj=1 w2j . We also want to ensure that |yi − f ( xi )| ≤ e, ∀i. The
objective function (quadratic program) becomes
min
1
||w||2
2
subject to
yi − < w, xi > −b ≤ e
−yi + < w, xi > +b ≤ e
This is a (possibly infeasible) convex optimization problem. Feasibility
is obtainable by introducing the slack variables (ξ, ξ ∗ ). We choose a constant C that scales the degree of infeasibility. The model is then modified
to be as follows:
min
n
1
||w||2 + C ∑ (ξ + ξ ∗ )
2
i =1
subject to
yi − < w, xi > −b ≤ e + ξ
−yi + < w, xi > +b ≤ e + ξ ∗
ξ, ξ ∗ ≥ 0
As C increases, the model increases in sensitivity to infeasibility.
We may tune the objective function by introducing cost functions
c(.), c∗ (.). Then, the objective function becomes
n
1
min ||w||2 + C ∑ [c(ξ ) + c∗ (ξ ∗ )]
2
i =1
We may replace the function [ f ( x ) − y] with a “kernel” K ( x, y) introducing nonlinearity into the problem. The choice of the kernel is a matter of
judgment, based on the nature of the application being examined. SVMs
allow many different estimation kernels, e.g., the Radial Basis function
kernel minimizes the distance between inputs (x) and targets (y) based
on
f ( x, y; γ) = exp(−γ| x − y|2 )
where γ is a user-defined squashing parameter.
There are various SVM packages that are easily obtained in opensource. An easy-to-use one is SVM Light—the package is available at
199
200
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
the following URL: http://svmlight.joachims.org/. SVM Light is an
implementation of Vapnik’s Support Vector Machine for the problem of
pattern recognition. The algorithm has scalable memory requirements
and can handle problems with many thousands of support vectors efficiently. The algorithm proceeds by solving a sequence of optimization
problems, lower-bounding the solution using a form of local search. It is
based on work by Joachims (1999).
Another program is the University of London SVM. Interestingly, it
is known as SVM Dark—evidently people who like hyperplanes have a
sense of humor! See http://www.cs.ucl.ac.uk/staff/M.Sewell/svmdark/.
For a nice list of SVMs, see http://www.cs.ubc.ca/∼murphyk/Software/svm.htm.
In R, see the machine learning library e1071—the function is, of course,
called svm.
As an example, let’s use the svm function to analyze the same flower
data set that we used with naive Bayes.
#USING SVMs
> r e s = svm ( i r i s [ , 1 : 4 ] , i r i s [ , 5 ] )
> out = t a b l e ( p r e d i c t ( re s , i r i s [ , 1 : 4 ] ) , i r i s [ , 5 ] )
> p r i n t ( out )
setosa versicolor virginica
setosa
50
0
0
versicolor
0
48
2
virginica
0
2
48
SVMs are very fast and are quite generally applicable with many
types of kernels. Hence, they may also be widely applied in news analytics.
7.5.3 Word Count Classifiers
The simplest form of classifier is based on counting words that are of
signed type. Words are the heart of any language inference system,
and in a specialized domain, this is even more so. In the words of F.C.
Bartlett,
more than words: extracting information from news
“Words ... can indicate the qualitative and relational features of a situation in their general aspect just as directly as, and perhaps even more
satisfactorily than, they can describe its particular individuality, This
is, in fact, what gives to language its intimate relation to thought processes.”
To build a word-count classifier a user defines a lexicon of special
words that relate to the classification problem. For example, if the classifier is categorizing text into optimistic versus pessimistic economic
news, then the user may want to create a lexicon of words that are useful in separating the good news from bad. For example, the word “upbeat” might be signed as optimistic, and the word “dismal” may be pessimistic. In my experience, a good lexicon needs about 300–500 words.
Domain knowledge is brought to bear in designing a lexicon. Therefore,
in contrast to the Bayes classifier, a word-count algorithm is languagedependent.
This algorithm is based on a simple word count of lexical words. If
the number of words in a particular category exceeds that of the other
categories by some threshold then the text message is categorized to the
category with the highest lexical count. The algorithm is of very low
complexity, extremely fast, and easy to implement. It delivers a baseline
approach to the classification problem.
7.5.4
Vector Distance Classifier
This algorithm treats each message as a word vector. Therefore, each
pre-classified, hand-tagged text message in the training corpus becomes
a comparison vector—we call this set the rule set. Each message in the
test set is then compared to the rule set and is assigned a classification
based on which rule comes closest in vector space.
The angle between the message vector (M) and the vectors in the rule
set (S) provides a measure of proximity.
cos(θ ) =
M·S
|| M|| · ||S||
where || A|| denotes the norm of vector A. Variations on this theme are
made possible by using sets of top-n closest rules, rather than only the
closest rule.
Word vectors here are extremely sparse, and the algorithms may be
built to take the dot product and norm above very rapidly. This algorithm was used in Das and Chen (2007) and was taken directly from
201
202
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
ideas used by search engines. The analogy is almost exact. A search engine essentially indexes pages by representing the text as a word vector.
When a search query is presented, the vector distance cos(θ ) ∈ (0, 1) is
computed for the search query with all indexed pages to find the pages
with which the angle is the least, i.e., where cos(θ ) is the greatest. Sorting all indexed pages by their angle with the search query delivers the
best-match ordered list. Readers will remember in the early days of
search engines how the list of search responses also provided a percentage number along with the returned results—these numbers were the
same as the value of cos(θ ).
When using the vector distance classifier for news analytics, the classification algorithm takes the new text sample and computes the angle of
the message with all the text pages in the indexes training corpus to find
the best matches. It then classifies pages with the same tag as the best
matches. This classifier is also very easy to implement as it only needs
simple linear algebra functions and sorting routines that are widely
available in almost any programming environment.
7.5.5
Discriminant-Based Classifier
All the classifiers discussed above do not weight words differentially
in a continuous manner. Either they do not weight them at all, as in
the case of the Bayes classifier or the SVM, or they focus on only some
words, ignoring the rest, as with the word count classifier. In contrast the
discriminant-based classifier weights words based on their discriminant
value.
The commonly used tool here is Fisher’s discriminant. Various implementations of it, with minor changes in form are used. In the classification area, one of the earliest uses was in the Bow algorithm of McCallum (1996), which reports the discriminant values; Chakrabarti, Dom,
Agrawal and Raghavan (1998) also use it in their classification framework, as do Das and Chen (2007). We present one version of Fisher’s
discriminant here.
Let the mean score (average number of times word w appears in a text
message of category i) of each term for each category = µi , where i indexes category. Let text messages be indexed by j. The number of times
word w appears in a message j of category i is denoted mij . Let ni be the
number of times word w appears in category i. Then the discriminant
more than words: extracting information from news
function might be expressed as:
F (w) =
1
|C |
∑i
∑ i 6 = k ( µ i − µ k )2
1
ni
∑ j (mij − µi )2
It is the ratio of the across-class (class i vs class k) variance to the average
of within-class (class i ∈ C) variances. To get some intuition, consider
the case we looked at earlier, classifying the economic sentiment as optimistic or pessimistic. If the word “dismal” appears exactly once in text
that is pessimistic and never appears in text that is optimistic, then the
within-class variation is zero, and the across-class variation is positive.
In such a case, where the denominator of the equation above is zero, the
word “dismal” is an infinitely-powerful discriminant. It should be given
a very large weight in any word-count algorithm.
In Das and Chen (2007) we looked at stock message-board text and
determined good discriminants using the Fisher metric. Here are some
words that showed high discriminant values (with values alongside) in
classifying optimistic versus pessimistic opinions.
bad 0.0405
hot 0.0161
hype 0.0089
improve 0.0123
joke 0.0268
jump 0.0106
killed 0.0160
lead 0.0037
like 0.0037
long 0.0162
lose 0.1211
money 0.1537
overvalue 0.0160
own 0.0031
good__n 0.0485
The last word in the list (“not good”) is an example of a negated word
showing a higher discriminant value than the word itself without a negative connotation (recall the discussion of negative tagging earlier in Section 7.3.2). Also see that the word “bad” has a score of 0.0405, whereas
the term “not good” has a higher score of 0.0485. This is an example
203
204
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
where the structure and usage of language, not just the meaning of a
word, matters.
In another example, using the Bow algorithm this time, examining
a database of conference calls with analysts, the best 20 discriminant
words were:
0.030828516377649325 allowing
0.094412331406551059 november
0.044315992292870907 determined
0.225433526011560692 general
0.034682080924855488 seasonality
0.123314065510597301 expanded
0.017341040462427744 rely
0.071290944123314062 counsel
0.044315992292870907 told
0.015414258188824663 easier
0.050096339113680152 drop
0.028901734104046242 synergies
0.025048169556840076 piece
0.021194605009633910 expenditure
0.017341040462427744 requirement
0.090558766859344900 prospects
0.019267822736030827 internationally
0.017341040462427744 proper
0.026974951830443159 derived
0.001926782273603083 invited
Not all these words would obviously connote bullishness or bearishness,
but some of them certainly do, such as “expanded”, “drop”, “prospects”,
etc. Why apparently unrelated words appear as good discriminants is
useful to investigate, and may lead to additional insights.
7.5.6
Adjective-Adverb Classifier
Classifiers may use all the text, as in the Bayes and vector-distance classifiers, or a subset of the text, as in the word-count algorithm. They may
also weight words differentially as in discriminant-based word counts.
Another way to filter words in a word-count algorithm is to focus on
the segments of text that have high emphasis, i.e., in regions around
adjectives and adverbs. This is done in Das and Chen (2007) using an
more than words: extracting information from news
adjective-adverb search to determine these regions.
This algorithm is language-dependent. In order to determine the adjectives and adverbs in the text, parsing is required, and calls for the
use of a dictionary. The one I have used extensively is the CUVOALD
((Computer Usable Version of the Oxford Advanced Learners Dictionary). It contains parts-of-speech tagging information, and makes
the parsing process very simple. There are other sources—a very wellknown one is WordNet from http://wordnet.princeton.edu/.
Using these dictionaries, it is easy to build programs that only extract
the regions of text around adjectives and adverbs, and then submit these
to the other classifiers for analysis and classification. Counting adjectives
and adverbs may also be used to score news text for “emphasis” thereby
enabling a different qualitative metric of importance for the text.
7.5.7
Scoring Optimism and Pessimism
A very useful resource for scoring text is the General Inquirer,
http://www.wjh.harvard.edu/∼inquirer/, housed at Harvard University. The Inquirer allows the user to assign “flavors” to words so as to
score text. In our case, we may be interested in counting optimistic and
pessimistic words in text. The Inquirer will do this online if needed, but
the dictionary may be downloaded and used offline as well. Words are
tagged with attributes that may be easily used to undertake tagged word
counts.
Here is a sample of tagged words from the dictionary that gives a
flavor of its structure:
ABNORMAL H4Lvd Neg Ngtv Vice NEGAFF Modif
ABOARD H4Lvd Space PREP LY
|
|
ABOLITION Lvd TRANS Noun
ABOMINABLE H4 Neg Strng Vice Ovrst Eval IndAdj Modif
|
ABORTIVE Lvd POWOTH POWTOT Modif POLIT
ABOUND H4 Pos Psv Incr IAV SUPV
|
The words ABNORMAL and ABOMINABLE have “Neg” tags and the
word ABOUND has a “Pos” tag.
Das and Chen (2007) used this dictionary to create an ambiguity score
for segmenting and filtering messages by optimism/pessimism in testing news analytical algorithms. They found that algorithms performed
better after filtering in less ambiguous text. This ambiguity score is dis-
205
206
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
cussed later in Section 7.5.9.
Tetlock (2007) is the best example of the use of the General Inquirer
in finance. Using text from the “Abreast of the Market" column from the
Wall Street Journal he undertook a principal components analysis of 77
categories from the GI and constructed a media pessimism score. High
pessimism presages lower stock prices, and extreme positive or negative
pessimism predicts volatility. Tetlock, Saar-Tsechansky and Macskassay
(2008) use news text related to firm fundamentals to show that negative
words are useful in predicting earnings and returns. The potential of this
tool has yet to be fully realized, and I expect to see a lot more research
undertaken using the General Inquirer.
7.5.8
Voting among Classifiers
In Das and Chen (2007) we introduced a voting classifier. Given the
highly ambiguous nature of the text being worked with, reducing the
noise is a major concern. Pang, Lee and Vaithyanathan (2002) found that
standard machine learning techniques do better than humans at classification. Yet, machine learning methods such as naive Bayes, maximum
entropy, and support vector machines do not perform as well on sentiment classification as on traditional topic-based categorization.
To mitigate error, classifiers are first separately applied, and then a
majority vote is taken across the classifiers to obtain the final category.
This approach improves the signal to noise ratio of the classification
algorithm.
7.5.9
Ambiguity Filters
Suppose we are building a sentiment index from a news feed. As each
text message comes in, we apply our algorithms to it and the result is
a classification tag. Some messages may be classified very accurately,
and others with much lower levels of confidence. Ambiguity-filtering is
a process by which we discard messages of high noise and potentially
low signal value from inclusion in the aggregate signal (for example, the
sentiment index).
One may think of ambiguity-filtering as a sequential voting scheme.
Instead of running all classifiers and then looking for a majority vote, we
run them sequentially, and discard messages that do not pass the hurdle
of more general classifiers, before subjecting them to more particular
more than words: extracting information from news
ones. In the end, we still have a voting scheme. Ambiguity metrics are
therefore lexicographic.
In Das and Chen (2007) we developed an ambiguity filter for application prior to our classification algorithms. We applied the General
Inquirer to the training data to determine an “optimism” score. We computed this for each category of stock message type, i.e., buy, hold, and
sell. For each type, we computed the mean optimism score, amounting
to 0.032, 0.026, 0.016, respectively, resulting in the expected rank ordering (the standard deviations around these means are 0.075, 0.069, 0.071,
respectively). We then filtered messages in based on how far they were
away from the mean in the right direction. For example, for buy messages, we chose for classification only those with one standard-deviation
higher than the mean. False positives in classification decline dramatically with the application of this ambiguity filter.
7.6 Metrics
Developing analytics without metrics is insufficient. It is important to
build measures that examine whether the analytics are generating classifications that are statistically significant, economically useful, and stable.
For an analytic to be statistically valid, it should meet some criterion that
signifies classification accuracy and power. Being economically useful sets
a different bar—does it make money? And stability is a double-edged
quality: one, does it perform well in-sample and out-of-sample? And
two, is the behavior of the algorithm stable across training corpora?
Here, we explore some of the metrics that have been developed, and
propose others. No doubt, as the range of analytics grows, so will the
range of metrics.
7.6.1 Confusion Matrix
The confusion matrix is the classic tool for assessing classification accuracy. Given n categories, the matrix is of dimension n × n. The rows relate to the category assigned by the analytic algorithm and the columns
refer to the correct category in which the text resides. Each cell (i, j) of
the matrix contains the number of text messages that were of type j and
were classified as type i. The cells on the diagonal of the confusion matrix state the number of times the algorithm got the classification right.
All other cells are instances of classification error. If an algorithm has no
207
208
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
classification ability, then the rows and columns of the matrix will be independent of each other. Under this null hypothesis, the statistic that is
examined for rejection is as follows:
χ2 [do f = (n − 1)2 ] =
n
n
[ A(i, j) − E(i, j)]2
∑∑
E(i, j)
i =1 j =1
where A(i, j) are the actual numbers observed in the confusion matrix,
and E(i, j) are the expected numbers, assuming no classification ability
under the null. If T (i ) represents the total across row i of the confusion
matrix, and T ( j) the column total, then
E(i, j) =
T (i ) × T ( j )
T (i ) × T ( j )
≡
n
∑ i =1 T ( i )
∑nj=1 T ( j)
The degrees of freedom of the χ2 statistic is (n − 1)2 . This statistic is very
easy to implement and may be applied to models for any n. A highly
significant statistic is evidence of classification ability.
7.6.2
Precision and Recall
The creation of the confusion matrix leads naturally to two measures
that are associated with it.
Precision is the fraction of positives identified that are truly positive,
and is also known as positive predictive value. It is a measure of usefulness of prediction. So if the algorithm (say) was tasked with selecting
those account holders on LinkedIn who are actually looking for a job,
and it identifies n such people of which only m were really looking for a
job, then the precision would be m/n.
Recall is the proportion of positives that are correctly identified, and is
also known as sensitivity. It is a measure of how complete the prediction
is. If the actual number of people looking for a job on LinkedIn was M,
then recall would be n/M.
For example, suppose we have the following confusion matrix.
Predicted
Looking for Job
Not Looking
Actual
Looking for Job Not Looking
10
2
1
16
11
18
12
17
29
more than words: extracting information from news
In this case precision is 10/12 and recall is 10/11. Precision is related
to the probability of false positives (Type I error), which is one minus
precision. Recall is related to the probability of false negatives (Type II
error), which is one minus recall.
7.6.3
Accuracy
Algorithm accuracy over a classification scheme is the percentage of text
that is correctly classified. This may be done in-sample or out-of-sample.
To compute this off the confusion matrix, we calculate
Accuracy =
∑in=1 A(i, i )
∑nj=1 T ( j)
We should hope that this is at least greater than 1/n, which is the accuracy level achieved on average from random guessing. In practice, I find
that accuracy ratios of 60–70% are reasonable for text that is non-factual
and contains poor language and opinions.
7.6.4
False Positives
Improper classification is worse than a failure to classify. In a 2 × 2 (two
category, n = 2) scheme, every off-diagonal element in the confusion
matrix is a false positive. When n > 2, some classification errors are
worse than others. For example in a 3–way buy, hold, sell scheme, where
we have stock text for classification, classifying a buy as a sell is worse
than classifying it as a hold. In this sense an ordering of categories is
useful so that a false classification into a near category is not as bad as a
wrong classification into a far (diametrically opposed) category.
The percentage of false positives is a useful metric to work with. It
may be calculated as a simple count or as a weighted count (by nearness
of wrong category) of false classifications divided by total classifications
undertaken.
In our experiments on stock messages in Das and Chen (2007), we
found that the false positive rate for the voting scheme classifier was
about 10%. This was reduced to below half that number after application
of an ambiguity filter (discussed in Section 7.5.9) based on the General
Inquirer.
209
210
7.6.5
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
Sentiment Error
When many articles of text are classified, an aggregate measure of sentiment may be computed. Aggregation is useful because it allows classification errors to cancel—if a buy was mistaken as a sell, and another sell
as a buy, then the aggregate sentiment index is unaffected.
Sentiment error is the percentage difference between the computed
aggregate sentiment, and the value we would obtain if there were no
classification error. In our experiments this varied from 5-15% across the
data sets that we used. Leinweber and Sisk (2010) show that sentiment
aggregation gives a better relation between news and stock returns.
7.6.6
Disagreement
In Das, Martinez-Jerez and Tufano (2005) we introduced a disagreement
metric that allows us to gauge the level of conflict in the discussion.
Looking at stock text messages, we used the number of signed buys
and sells in the day (based on a sentiment model) to determine how
much disagreement of opinion there was in the market. The metric is
computed as follows:
DISAG = 1 −
B−S
B+S
where B, S are the numbers of classified buys and sells. Note that DISAG
is bounded between zero and one. The quality of aggregate sentiment
tends to be lower when DISAG is high.
7.6.7
Correlations
A natural question that arises when examining streaming news is: how
well does the sentiment from news correlate with financial time series?
Is there predictability? An excellent discussion of these matters is provided in Leinweber and Sisk (2010). They specifically examine investment signals derived from news.
In their paper, they show that there is a significant difference in cumulative excess returns between strong positive sentiment and strong
negative sentiment days over prediction horizons of a week or a quarter. Hence, these event studies are based on point-in-time correlation
triggers. Their results are robust across countries.
The simplest correlation metrics are visual. In a trading day, we may
plot the movement of a stock series, alongside the cumulative sentiment
more than words: extracting information from news
211
series. The latter is generated by taking all classified ‘buys’ as +1 and
‘sells’ as −1, and the plot comprises the cumulative total of scores of the
messages (‘hold’ classified messages are scored with value zero). See
Figure 7.8 for one example, where it is easy to see that the sentiment and
stock series track each other quite closely. We coin the term “sents” for
the units of sentiment.
Figure 7.8: Plot of stock series (up-
per graph) versus sentiment series
(lower graph). The correlation
between the series is high. The
plot is based on messages from
Yahoo! Finance and is for a single
twenty-four hour period.
7.6.8
Aggregation Performance
As pointed out in Leinweber and Sisk (2010) aggregation of classified
news reduces noise and improves signal accuracy. One way to measure
this is to look at the correlations of sentiment and stocks for aggregated
versus disaggregated data. As an example, I examine daily sentiment
for individual stocks and an index created by aggregating sentiment
across stocks, i.e., a cross-section of sentiment. This is useful to examine
212
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
whether sentiment aggregates effectively in the cross-section.
I used all messages posted for 35 stocks that comprise the Morgan
Stanley High-Tech Index (MSH35) for the period June 1 to August 27,
2001. This results in 88 calendar days and 397,625 messages, an average
of about 4,500 messages per day. For each day I determine the sentiment
and stock return. Daily sentiment uses messages up to 4 pm on each
trading day, coinciding with the stock return close.
Ticker
Correlations of SENTY4pm(t) with
STKRET(t)
STKRET(t+1)
STKRET(t-1)
ADP
0.086
0.138
-0.062
AMAT
-0.008
-0.049
0.067
AMZN
0.227
0.167
0.161
AOL
0.386
-0.010
0.281
BRCM
0.056
0.167
-0.007
CA
0.023
0.127
0.035
CPQ
0.260
0.161
0.239
CSCO
0.117
0.074
-0.025
DELL
0.493
-0.024
0.011
EDS
-0.017
0.000
-0.078
EMC
0.111
0.010
0.193
ERTS
0.114
-0.223
0.225
HWP
0.315
-0.097
-0.114
IBM
0.071
-0.057
0.146
INTC
0.128
-0.077
-0.007
INTU
-0.124
-0.099
-0.117
JDSU
0.126
0.056
0.047
JNPR
0.416
0.090
-0.137
LU
0.602
0.131
-0.027
MOT
-0.041
-0.014
-0.006
MSFT
0.422
0.084
0.210
MU
0.110
-0.087
0.030
NT
0.320
0.068
0.288
ORCL
0.005
0.056
-0.062
PALM
0.509
0.156
0.085
PMTC
0.080
0.005
-0.030
PSFT
0.244
-0.094
0.270
SCMR
0.240
0.197
0.060
SLR
-0.077
-0.054
-0.158
STM
-0.010
-0.062
0.161
SUNW
0.463
0.176
0.276
TLAB
0.225
0.250
0.283
TXN
0.240
-0.052
0.117
XLNX
0.261
-0.051
-0.217
YHOO
0.202
-0.038
0.222
Average correlation across 35 stocks
0.188
0.029
0.067
Correlation between 35 stock index and 35 stock sentiment index
0.486
0.178
0.288
I also compute the average sentiment index of all 35 stocks, i.e., a
proxy for the MSH35 sentiment. The corresponding equally weighted
return of 35 stocks is also computed. These two time series permit an
examination of the relationship between sentiment and stock returns at
the aggregate index level. Table 7.1 presents the correlations between
individual stock returns and sentiment, and between the MSH35 index
return and MSH35 sentiment. We notice that there is positive contemporaneous correlation between most stock returns and sentiment. The
correlations were sometimes as high as 0.60 (for Lucent), 0.51 (PALM)
Table 7.1: Correlations of Sentiment
and Stock Returns for the MSH35
stocks and the aggregated MSH35
index. Stock returns (STKRET) are
computed from close-to-close. We
compute correlations using data
for 88 days in the months of June,
July and August 2001. Return data
over the weekend is linearly interpolated, as messages continue to
be posted over weekends. Daily
sentiment is computed from midnight to close of trading at 4 pm
(SENTY4pm).
more than words: extracting information from news
and 0.49 (DELL). Only six stocks evidenced negative correlations, mostly
small in magnitude. The average contemporaneous correlation is 0.188,
which suggests that sentiment tracks stock returns in the high-tech sector. (I also used full-day sentiment instead of only that till trading close
and the results are almost the same—the correlations are in fact higher,
as sentiment includes reactions to trading after the close).
Average correlations for individual stocks are weaker when one lag
(0.067) or lead (0.029) of the stock return are considered. More interesting is the average index of sentiment for all 35 stocks. The contemporaneous correlation of this index to the equally-weighted return index
is as high as 0.486. Here, cross-sectional aggregation helps in eliminating some of the idiosyncratic noise, and makes the positive relationship between returns and sentiment salient. This is also reflected in the
strong positive correlation of sentiment to lagged stock returns (0.288)
and leading returns (0.178). I confirmed the statistical contemporaneous
relationship of returns to sentiment by regressing returns on sentiment
(T-statistics in brackets):
STKRET (t) = −0.1791 + 0.3866SENTY (t),
(0.93)
7.6.9
R2 = 0.24
(5.16)
Phase-Lag Metrics
Correlation across sentiment and return time series is a special case of
lead-lag analysis. This may be generalized to looking for pattern correlations. As may be evident from Figure 7.8, the stock and sentiment plots
have patterns. In the figure they appear contemporaneous, though the
sentiment series lags the stock series.
A graphical approach to lead-lag analysis is to look for graph patterns
across two series and to examine whether we may predict the patterns
in one time series with the other. For example, can we use the sentiment series to predict the high point of the stock series, or the low point?
In other words, is it possible to use the sentiment data generated from
algorithms to pick turning points in stock series? We call this type of
graphical examination “phase-lag” analysis.
A simple approach I came up with involves decomposing graphs into
eight types—see Figure 7.9. On the left side of the figure, notice that
there are eight patterns of graphs based on the location of four salient
graph features: start, end, high, and low points. There are exactly eight
213
214
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
possible graph patterns that may be generated from all positions of these
four salient points. It is also very easy to write software to take any time
series—say, for a trading day—and assign it to one of the patterns, keeping track of the position of the maximum and minimum points. It is then
possible to compare two graphs to see which one predicts the other in
terms of pattern. For example, does the sentiment series maximum come
before that of the stock series? If so, how much earlier does it detect the
turning point on average?
Using data from several stocks I examined whether the sentiment
graph pattern generated from a voting classification algorithm was predictive of stock graph patterns. Phase-lags were examined in intervals of
five minutes through the trading day. The histogram of leads and lags is
shown on the right-hand side of Figure 7.9. A positive value denotes that
the sentiment series lags the stock series; a negative value signifies that
the stock series lags sentiment. It is apparent from the histogram that the
sentiment series lags stocks, and is not predictive of stock movements in
this case.
Figure 7.9: Phase-lag analysis. The
Phase-Lag
Analysis
left-side shows the eight canonical
graph patterns that are derived
from arrangements of the start,
end, high, and low points of a time
series. The right-side shows the
leads and lags of patterns of the
stock series versus the sentiment
series. A positive value means that
the stock series leads the sentiment
series.
more than words: extracting information from news
7.6.10 Economic Significance
News analytics may be evaluated using economic yardsticks. Does the
algorithm deliver profitable opportunities? Does it help reduce risk?
For example, in Das and Sisk (2005) we formed a network with connections based on commonality of handles in online discussion. We detected communities using a simple rule based on connectedness beyond
a chosen threshold level, and separated all stock nodes into either one
giant community or into a community of individual singleton nodes. We
then examined the properties of portfolios formed from the community
versus those formed from the singleton stocks.
We obtained several insights. We calculated the mean returns from
an equally-weighted portfolio of the community stocks and an equallyweighted portfolio of singleton stocks. We also calculated the return
standard deviations of these portfolios. We did this month-by-month for
sixteen months. In fifteen of the sixteen months the mean returns were
higher for the community portfolio; the standard deviations were lower
in thirteen of the sixteen months. The difference of means was significant
for thirteen of those months as well. Hence, community detection based
on news traffic leads to identifying a set of stocks that performs vastly
better than the rest.
There is much more to be done in this domain of economic metrics
for the performance of news analytics. Leinweber and Sisk (2010) have
shown that there is exploitable alpha in news streams. The risk management and credit analysis areas also offer economic metrics that may be
used to validate news analytics.
7.7 Grading Text
In recent years, the SAT exams added a new essay section. While the
test aimed at assessing original writing, it also introduced automated
grading. A goal of the test is to assess the writing level of the student.
This is associated with the notion of readability.
“Readability” is a metric of how easy it is to comprehend text. Given
a goal of efficient markets, regulators want to foster transparency by
making sure financial documents that are disseminated to the investing
public are readable. Hence, metrics for readability are very important
and are recently gaining traction.
Gunning (1952) developed the Fog index. The index estimates the
215
216
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
years of formal education needed to understand text on a first reading.
A fog index of 12 requires the reading level of a U.S. high school senior
(around 18 years old). The index is based on the idea that poor readability is associated with longer sentences and complex words. Complex
words are those that have more than two syllables. The formula for the
Fog index is
#complex words
#words
+ 100 ·
0.4 ·
#sentences
#words
Alternative readability scores use similar ideas. The Flesch Reading
Ease Score and the Flesch-Kincaid Grade Level also use counts of words,
syllables, and sentences.2 The Flesch Reading Ease Score is defined as
#syllables
#words
− 84.6
206.835 − 1.015
#sentences
#words
With a range of 90-100 easily accessible by a 11-year old, 60-70 being
easy to understand for 13-15 year olds, and 0-30 for university graduates.
The Flesch-Kincaid Grade Level is defined as
#syllables
#words
+ 11.8
− 15.59
0.39
#sentences
#words
which gives a number that corresponds to the grade level. As expected
these two measures are negatively correlated. Various other measures of
readability use the same ideas as in the Fog index. For example the Coleman and Liau (1975) index does not even require a count of syllables, as
follows:
CLI = 0.0588L − 0.296S − 15.8
where L is the average number of letters per hundred words and S is the
average number of sentences per hundred words.
Standard readability metrics may not work well for financial text.
Loughran and McDonald (2014) find that the Fog index is inferior to
simply looking at 10-K file size.
7.8 Text Summarization
It has become fairly easy to summarize text using statistical methods.
The simplest form of text summarizer works on a sentence-based model
that sorts sentences in a document in descending order of word overlap with all other sentences in the text. The re-ordering of sentences arranges the document with the sentence that has most overlap with others
first, then the next, and so on.
2
See http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/
Flesch-Kincaid_readability_tests.
more than words: extracting information from news
An article D may have m sentences si , i = 1, 2, ..., m, where each si is a
set of words. We compute the pairwise overlap between sentences using
the 3 similarity index:
Jij = J (si , s j ) =
| si ∩ s j |
= Jji
| si ∪ s j |
(7.9)
The overlap is the ratio of the size of the intersection of the two word
sets in sentences si and s j , divided by the size of the union of the two
sets. The similarity score of each sentence is computed as the row sums
of the Jaccard similarity matrix.
m
Si =
∑ Jij
(7.10)
j =1
Once the row sums are obtained, they are sorted and the summary is the
first n sentences based on the Si values. We can then decide how many
sentences we want in the summary.
Another approach to using row sums is to compute centrality using
the Jaccard matrix J, and then pick the n sentences with the highest centrality scores.
We illustrate the approach with a news article from the financial markets. The sample text is taken from Bloomberg on April 21, 2014, at the
following URL:
http://www.bloomberg.com/news/print/2014-04-21/wall-streetbond-dealers-whipsawed-on-bearish-treasuries-bet-1-.html. The
full text spans 4 pages and is presented in an appendix to this chapter.
This article is read using a web scraper (as seen in preceding sections),
and converted into a text file with a separate line for each sentence. We
call this file summary_text.txt and this file is then read into R and processed with the following parsimonious program code. We first develop
the summarizer function.
# FUNCTION TO RETURN n SENTENCE SUMMARY
# Input : array o f s e n t e n c e s ( t e x t )
# Output : n most common i n t e r s e c t i n g s e n t e n c e s
t e x t _summary = f u n c t i o n ( t e x t , n ) {
m = length ( t e x t ) # No o f s e n t e n c e s i n i n p u t
j a c c a r d = matrix ( 0 ,m,m) # S t o r e match i n d e x
f o r ( i i n 1 :m) {
f o r ( j i n i :m) {
a = t e x t [ i ] ; aa = u n l i s t ( s t r s p l i t ( a , " " ) )
3
217
218
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
b = t e x t [ j ] ; bb = u n l i s t ( s t r s p l i t ( b , " " ) )
j a c c a r d [ i , j ] = length ( i n t e r s e c t ( aa , bb ) ) /
length ( union ( aa , bb ) )
jaccard [ j , i ] = jaccard [ i , j ]
}
}
s i m i l a r i t y _ s c o r e = rowSums ( j a c c a r d )
r e s = s o r t ( s i m i l a r i t y _ s c o r e , index . r e t u r n =TRUE,
d e c r e a s i n g =TRUE)
idx = r e s $ i x [ 1 : n ]
summary = t e x t [ idx ]
}
We now read in the data and clean it into a single text array.
u r l = " d s t e x t _ sample . t x t "
#You can p u t any t e x t f i l e o r URL h e r e
t e x t = read _web_page ( url , cstem =0 , c s t o p =0 , c c a s e =0 , cpunc =0 , c f l a t =1)
p r i n t ( length ( t e x t [ [ 1 ] ] ) )
[1] 1
print ( text )
[ 1 ] "THERE HAVE BEEN murmurings t h a t we a r e now i n t h e
" trough o f d i s i l l u s i o n m e n t " o f big data , t h e hype around i t having
surpassed t h e r e a l i t y o f what i t can d e l i v e r . Gartner suggested t h a t
t h e " g r a v i t a t i o n a l p u l l o f big data i s now so s t r o n g t h a t even people
who h a v e n ï £ ¡ t a c l u e as t o what i t ’ s a l l about r e p o r t t h a t they ’ r e running
big data p r o j e c t s . " Indeed , t h e i r r e s e a r c h with b u s i n e s s d e c i s i o n
makers s u g g e s t s t h a t o r g a n i s a t i o n s a r e s t r u g g l i n g t o g e t value from
big data . Data s c i e n t i s t s were meant . . . . .
.....
Now we break the text into sentences using the period as a delimiter,
and invoking the strsplit function in the stringr package.
t e x t 2 = s t r s p l i t ( t e x t , " . " , f i x e d =TRUE)
text2 = text2 [ [ 1 ] ]
print ( text2 )
# Special handling of the period .
[ 1 ] "THERE HAVE BEEN murmurings t h a t we a r e now i n t h e
" trough o f d i s i l l u s i o n m e n t " o f big data , t h e hype around i t having
surpassed t h e r e a l i t y o f what i t can d e l i v e r "
[ 2 ] " Gartner suggested t h a t t h e " g r a v i t a t i o n a l p u l l o f big data i s
more than words: extracting information from news
now so s t r o n g t h a t even people who haven ’ t a c l u e as t o what i t ï £ ¡ s
a l l about r e p o r t t h a t t h e y ï £ ¡ r e running big data p r o j e c t s . " Indeed ,
t h e i r r e s e a r c h with b u s i n e s s d e c i s i o n makers s u g g e s t s t h a t
o r g a n i s a t i o n s a r e s t r u g g l i n g t o g e t value from big data "
[ 3 ] " Data s c i e n t i s t s were meant t o be t h e answer t o t h i s i s s u e "
[ 4 ] " Indeed , Hal Varian , C h i e f Economist a t Google famously
joked t h a t " The sexy j o b i n t h e next 10 y e a r s w i l l be s t a t i s t i c i a n s . "
He was c l e a r l y r i g h t as we a r e now used t o h e a r i n g t h a t data
s c i e n t i s t s a r e t h e key t o unlocking t h e value o f big data "
.....
.....
We now call the text summarization function and produce the top five
sentences that give the most overlap to all other sentences.
r e s = t e x t _summary ( t e x t 2 , 5 )
print ( res )
[ 1 ] " Gartner suggested t h a t t h e " g r a v i t a t i o n a l p u l l o f big data i s
now so s t r o n g t h a t even people who haven ’ t a c l u e as t o what i t ’ s
a l l about r e p o r t t h a t they ’ r e running big data p r o j e c t s . " Indeed ,
t h e i r r e s e a r c h with b u s i n e s s d e c i s i o n makers s u g g e s t s t h a t
o r g a n i s a t i o n s a r e s t r u g g l i n g t o g e t value from big data "
[ 2 ] " The f o c u s on t h e data s c i e n t i s t o f t e n i m p l i e s a c e n t r a l i z e d
approach t o a n a l y t i c s and d e c i s i o n making ; we i m p l i c i t l y assume
t h a t a s m a l l team o f h i g h l y s k i l l e d i n d i v i d u a l s can meet t h e needs
o f t h e o r g a n i s a t i o n as a whole "
[ 3 ] "May be we a r e i n v e s t i n g too much i n a r e l a t i v e l y s m a l l number
o f i n d i v i d u a l s r a t h e r than t h i n k i n g about how we can design
o r g a n i s a t i o n s t o help us g e t t h e most from data a s s e t s "
[ 4 ] " The problem with a c e n t r a l i z e d ’ IT− s t y l e ’ approach i s t h a t i t
i g n o r e s t h e human s i d e o f t h e p r o c e s s o f c o n s i d e r i n g how people
c r e a t e and use i n f o r m a t i o n i . e "
[ 5 ] " Which probably means t h a t data s c i e n t i s t s ’ s a l a r i e s w i l l need
to take a h i t in the process . "
As we can see, this generates an effective and clear summary of an
article that originally had 42 sentences.
7.9 Discussion
The various techniques and metrics fall into two broad categories: supervised and unsupervised learning methods. Supervised models use
well-specified input variables to the machine-learning algorithm, which
then emits a classification. One may think of this as a generalized regression model. In unsupervised learning, there are no explicit input variables but latent ones, e.g., cluster analysis. Most of the news analytics we
explored relate to supervised learning, such as the various classification
algorithms. This is well-trodden research. It is the domain of unsuper-
219
220
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
vised learning, for example, the community detection algorithms and
centrality computation, that have been less explored and are potentially
areas of greatest potential going forward.
Classifying news to generate sentiment indicators has been well
worked out. This is epitomized in many of the papers in this book. It
is the networks on which financial information gets transmitted that
have been much less studied, and where I anticipate most of the growth
in news analytics to come from. For example, how quickly does good
news about a tech company proliferate to other companies? We looked
at issues like this in Das and Sisk (2005), discussed earlier, where we assessed whether knowledge of the network might be exploited profitably.
Information also travels by word of mouth and these information networks are also open for much further examination—see Godes, et. al.
(2005). Inside (not insider) information is also transmitted in venture
capital networks where there is evidence now that better connected
VCs perform better than unconnected VCs, as shown by Hochberg,
Ljungqvist and Lu (2007).
Whether news analytics reside in the broad area of AI or not is under
debate. The advent and success of statistical learning theory in realworld applications has moved much of news analytics out of the AI
domain into econometrics. There is very little natural language processing (NLP) involved. As future developments shift from text methods to
context methods, we may see a return to the AI paradigm. I believe that
tools such as WolframAlphaTM will be the basis of context-dependent
news analysis.
News analytics will broaden in the toolkit it encompasses. Expect to
see greater use of dependency networks and collaborative filtering. We
will also see better data visualization techniques such as community
views and centrality diagrams. The number of tools keeps on growing.
For an almost exhaustive compendium of tools see the book by Koller
(2009) titled “Probabilistic Graphical Models.”
In the end, news analytics are just sophisticated methods for data mining. For an interesting look at the top ten algorithms in data mining, see
Wu, et al. (2008). This paper discusses the top 10 data mining algorithms
identified by the IEEE International Conference on Data Mining (ICDM)
in December 2006.4 As algorithms improve in speed, they will expand to
automated decision-making, replacing human interaction—as noticed in
the marriage of news analytics with automated trading, and eventually, a
These algorithms are: C4.5, k-Means,
SVM, Apriori, EM, PageRank, AdaBoost, kNN, Naive Bayes, and CART.
4
more than words: extracting information from news
221
rebirth of XHAL.
7.10 Appendix: Sample text from Bloomberg for summarization
Summarization is one of the major implementations in Big Text applications. When faced with Big Text, there are three important stages
through which analytics may proceed: (a) Indexation, (b) Summarization, and (c) Inference. Automatic summarization5 is a program that
reduces text while keeping mostly the salient points, accounting for
variables such as length, writing style, and syntax. There are two approaches: (i) Extractive methods selecting a subset of existing words,
phrases, or sentences in the original text to form the summary. (ii) Abstractive methods build an internal semantic representation and then
use natural language generation techniques to create a summary that is
closer to what a human might generate. Such a summary might contain
words not explicitly present in the original.
The following news article was used to demonstrate text summarization for the application in Section 7.8.
5
http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Automatic
222
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
4/21/2014
Wall Street Bond Dealers Whipsawed on Bearish Treasuries Bet - Bloomberg
Wall Street Bond Dealers Whipsawed on Bearish
Treasuries Bet
By Lisa Abramowicz and Daniel Kruger - Apr 21, 2014
Betting against U.S. government debt this year is turning out to be a fool’s errand. Just ask Wall
Street’s biggest bond dealers.
While the losses that their economists predicted have yet to materialize, JPMorgan Chase & Co.
(JPM), Citigroup Inc. (C) and the 20 other firms that trade with the Federal Reserve began wagering
on a Treasuries selloff last month for the first time since 2011. The strategy was upended as Fed Chair
Janet Yellen signaled she wasn’t in a rush to lift interest rates, two weeks after suggesting the opposite
at the bank’s March 19 meeting.
The surprising resilience of Treasuries has investors re-calibrating forecasts for higher borrowing costs
as lackluster job growth and emerging-market turmoil push yields toward 2014 lows. That’s also made
the business of trading bonds, once more predictable for dealers when the Fed was buying trillions of
dollars of debt to spur the economy, less profitable as new rules limit the risks they can take with their
own money.
“You have an uncertain Fed, an uncertain direction of the economy and you’ve got rates moving,”
Mark MacQueen, a partner at Sage Advisory Services Ltd., which oversees $10 billion, said by
telephone from Austin, Texas. In the past, “calling the direction of the market and what you should be
doing in it was a lot easier than it is today, particularly for the dealers.”
Treasuries (USGG10YR) have confounded economists who predicted 10-year yields would approach
3.4 percent by year-end as a strengthening economy prompts the Fed to pare its unprecedented bond
buying.
Caught Short
After surging to a 29-month high of 3.05 percent at the start of the year, yields on the 10-year note
have declined and were at 2.72 percent at 7:42 a.m. in New York.
One reason yields have fallen is the U.S. labor market, which has yet to show consistent improvement.
http://www.bloomberg.com/news/print/2014-04-21/wall-street-bond-dealers-whipsawed-on-bearish-treasuries-bet-1-.html
1/5
more than words: extracting information from news
4/21/2014
Wall Street Bond Dealers Whipsawed on Bearish Treasuries Bet - Bloomberg
The world’s largest economy added fewer jobs on average in the first three months of the year than in
the same period in the prior two years, data compiled by Bloomberg show. At the same time, a
slowdown in China and tensions between Russia and Ukraine boosted demand for the safest assets.
Wall Street firms known as primary dealers are getting caught short betting against Treasuries.
They collectively amassed $5.2 billion of wagers in March that would profit if Treasuries fell, the first
time they had net short positions on government debt since September 2011, data compiled by the Fed
show.
‘Some Time’
The practice is allowed under the Volcker Rule that limits the types of trades that banks can make with
their own money. The wagers may include market-making, which is the business of using the firm’s
capital to buy and sell securities with customers while profiting on the spread and movement in prices.
While the bets initially paid off after Yellen said on March 19 that the Fed may lift its benchmark rate
six months after it stops buying bonds, Treasuries have since rallied as her subsequent comments
strengthened the view that policy makers will keep borrowing costs low to support growth.
On March 31, Yellen highlighted inconsistencies in job data and said “considerable slack” in labor
markets showed the Fed’s accommodative policies will be needed for “some time.”
Then, in her first major speech on her policy framework as Fed chair on April 16, Yellen said it will
take at least two years for the U.S. economy to meet the Fed’s goals, which determine how quickly the
central bank raises rates.
After declining as much as 0.6 percent following Yellen’s March 19 comments, Treasuries have
recouped all their losses, index data compiled by Bank of America Merrill Lynch show.
Yield Forecasts
“We had that big selloff and the dealers got short then, and then we turned around and the Fed says,
‘Whoa, whoa, whoa: it’s lower for longer again,’” MacQueen said in an April 15 telephone interview.
“The dealers are really worried here. You get really punished if you take a lot of risk.”
Economists and strategists around Wall Street are still anticipating that Treasuries will underperform
as yields increase, data compiled by Bloomberg show.
While they’ve ratcheted down their forecasts this year, they predict 10-year yields will increase to 3.36
percent by the end of December. That’s more than 0.6 percentage point higher than where yields are
http://www.bloomberg.com/news/print/2014-04-21/wall-street-bond-dealers-whipsawed-on-bearish-treasuries-bet-1-.html
2/5
223
224
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
4/21/2014
Wall Street Bond Dealers Whipsawed on Bearish Treasuries Bet - Bloomberg
today.
“My forecast is 4 percent,” said Joseph LaVorgna, chief U.S. economist at Deutsche Bank AG, a
primary dealer. “It may seem like it’s really aggressive but it’s really not.”
LaVorgna, who has the highest estimate among the 66 responses in a Bloomberg survey, said stronger
economic data will likely cause investors to sell Treasuries as they anticipate a rate increase from the
Fed.
History Lesson
The U.S. economy will expand 2.7 percent this year from 1.9 percent in 2013, estimates compiled by
Bloomberg show. Growth will accelerate 3 percent next year, which would be the fastest in a decade,
based on those forecasts.
Dealers used to rely on Treasuries to act as a hedge against their holdings of other types of debt, such
as corporate bonds and mortgages. That changed after the credit crisis caused the failure of Lehman
Brothers Holdings Inc. in 2008.
They slashed corporate-debt inventories by 76 percent from the 2007 peak through last March as they
sought to comply with higher capital requirements from the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision
and stockpiled Treasuries instead.
“Being a dealer has changed over the years, and not least because you also have new balance-sheet
constraints that you didn’t have before,” Ira Jersey, an interest-rate strategist at primary dealer Credit
Suisse Group AG (CSGN), said in a telephone interview on April 14.
Almost Guaranteed
While the Fed’s decision to inundate the U.S. economy with more than $3 trillion of cheap money
since 2008 by buying Treasuries and mortgaged-backed bonds bolstered profits as all fixed-income
assets rallied, yields are now so low that banks are struggling to make money trading government
bonds.
Yields on 10-year notes have remained below 3 percent since January, data compiled by Bloomberg
show. In two decades before the credit crisis, average yields topped 6 percent.
Average daily trading has also dropped to $551.3 billion in March from an average $570.2 billion in
2007, even as the outstanding amount of Treasuries has more than doubled since the financial crisis,
according data from the Securities Industry and Financial Markets Association.
http://www.bloomberg.com/news/print/2014-04-21/wall-street-bond-dealers-whipsawed-on-bearish-treasuries-bet-1-.html
3/5
more than words: extracting information from news
4/21/2014
Wall Street Bond Dealers Whipsawed on Bearish Treasuries Bet - Bloomberg
“During the crisis, the Fed went to great pains to save primary dealers,” Christopher Whalen, banker
and author of “Inflated: How Money and Debt Built the American Dream,” said in a telephone
interview. “Now, because of quantitative easing and other dynamics in the market, it’s not just
treacherous, it’s almost a guaranteed loss.”
Trading Revenue
The biggest dealers are seeing their earnings suffer. In the first quarter, five of the six biggest Wall
Street firms reported declines in fixed-income trading revenue.
JPMorgan, the biggest U.S. bond underwriter, had a 21 percent decrease from its fixed-income trading
business, more than estimates from Moshe Orenbuch, an analyst at Credit Suisse, and Matt Burnell of
Wells Fargo & Co.
Citigroup, whose bond-trading results marred the New York-based bank’s two prior quarterly
earnings, reported a 18 percent decrease in revenue from that business. Credit Suisse, the secondlargest Swiss bank, had a 25 percent drop as income from rates and emerging-markets businesses fell.
Declines in debt-trading last year prompted the Zurich-based firm to cut more than 100 fixed-income
jobs in London and New York.
Bank Squeeze
Chief Financial Officer David Mathers said in a Feb. 6 call that Credit Suisse has “reduced the capital
in this business materially and we’re obviously increasing our electronic trading operations in this
area.” Jamie Dimon, chief executive officer at JPMorgan, also emphasized the decreased role of
humans in the rates-trading business on an April 11 call as the New York-based bank seeks to cut
costs.
About 49 percent of U.S. government-debt trading was executed electronically last year, from 31
percent in 2012, a Greenwich Associates survey of institutional money managers showed. That may
ultimately lead banks to combine their rates businesses or scale back their roles as primary dealers as
firms get squeezed, said Krishna Memani, the New York-based chief investment officer of
OppenheimerFunds Inc., which oversees $79.1 billion in fixed-income assets.
“If capital requirements were not as onerous as they are now, maybe they could have found a way of
making it work, but they aren’t as such,” he said in a telephone interview.
To contact the reporters on this story: Lisa Abramowicz in New York at labramowicz@bloomberg.net;
Daniel Kruger in New York at dkruger1@bloomberg.net
To contact the editors responsible for this story: Dave Liedtka at dliedtka@bloomberg.net Michael
http://www.bloomberg.com/news/print/2014-04-21/wall-street-bond-dealers-whipsawed-on-bearish-treasuries-bet-1-.html
4/5
225
8
Virulent Products: The Bass Model
8.1 Introduction
The Bass (1969) product diffusion model is a classic one in the marketing
literature. It has been successfully used to predict the market shares of
various newly introduced products, as well as mature ones.
The main idea of the model is that the adoption rate of a product
comes from two sources:
1. The propensity of consumers to adopt the product independent of
social influences to do so.
2. The additional propensity to adopt the product because others have
adopted it. Hence, at some point in the life cycle of a good product,
social contagion, i.e. the influence of the early adopters becomes sufficiently strong so as to drive many others to adopt the product as well.
It may be going too far to think of this as a “network” effect, because
Frank Bass did this work well before the concept of network effect was
introduced, but essentially that is what it is.
The Bass model shows how the information of the first few periods of
sales data may be used to develop a fairly good forecast of future sales.
One can easily see that whereas this model came from the domain of
marketing, it may just as easily be used to model forecasts of cashflows
to determine the value of a start-up company.
8.2 Historical Examples
There are some classic examples from the literature of the Bass model
providing a very good forecast of the ramp up in product adoption as a
function of the two sources described above. See for example the actual
228
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
Adoption of VCR’s
versus predicted market growth for VCRs in the 80s shown in Figure 8.1.
Correspondingly, Figure 8.2 shows the adoption of answering machines.
Figure 8.1: Actual versus Bass model
predictions for VCRs.
Actual and Fitted Adoption VCR's
1980-1989
12000
Adoption in Thousands
10000
8000
Actual Adoption
6000
Fitted Adoption
4000
2000
0
80
81
82
83
84
85
86
87
88
89
Year
8.3 The Basic Idea
We follow the exposition (c)
in Bass
(1969).M. Bass (1999)
Frank
Define the cumulative probability of purchase of a product from time
zero to time t by a single individual as F (t). Then, the probability of
purchase at time t is the density function f (t) = F 0 (t).
The rate of purchase at time t, given no purchase so far, logically follows, i.e.
f (t)
.
1 − F (t)
Modeling this is just like modeling the adoption rate of the product at a
given time t.
Bass (1969) suggested that this adoption rate be defined as
f (t)
= p + q F ( t ).
1 − F (t)
where we may think of p as defining the independent rate of a consumer
adopting the product, and q as the imitation rate, because it modulates
the impact from the cumulative intensity of adoption, F (t).
An Empirical Generalization
virulent products: the bass model
Figure 8.2: Actual versus Bass model
predictions for answering machines.
Adoption of Answering Machines
1982-1993t
14000
12000
10000
8000
6000
4000
2000
0
82
83
84
85
86
87
88
89
90
91
Year
adoption of answering machines
Fitted Adoption
(c) Frank M. Bass (1999)
Hence, if we can find p and q for a product, we can forecast its adoption over time, and thereby generate a time path of sales. To summarize:
• p: coefficient of innovation.
• q: coefficient of imitation.
8.4 Solving the Model
We rewrite the Bass equation:
dF/dt
= p + q F.
1−F
and note that F (0) = 0.
229
92
93
230
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
The steps in the solution are:
dF
dt
dF
dt
Z
=
( p + qF )(1 − F )
(8.1)
=
p + (q − p) F − qF2
(8.2)
1
dF =
dt
p + (q − p) F − qF2
ln( p + qF ) − ln(1 − F )
= t + c1
p+q
t = 0 ⇒ F (0) = 0
ln p
t = 0 ⇒ c1 =
p+q
Z
F (t)
=
p ( e ( p + q ) t − 1)
pe( p+q)t + q
(8.3)
(8.4)
(8.5)
(8.6)
(8.7)
An alternative approach1 goes as follows. First, split the integral above
into partial fractions.
Z
1
dF =
( p + qF )(1 − F )
Z
dt
(8.8)
So we write
1
( p + qF )(1 − F )
=
=
=
A
B
+
p + qF 1 − F
A − AF + pB + qFB
( p + qF )(1 − F )
A + pB + F (qB − A)
( p + qF )(1 − F )
(8.9)
(8.10)
(8.11)
This implies that
A + pB = 1
(8.12)
qB − A = 0
(8.13)
A = q/( p + q)
(8.14)
B = 1/( p + q)
(8.15)
Solving we get
This was suggested by students
Muhammad Sagarwalla based on ideas
from Alexey Orlovsky.
1
virulent products: the bass model
231
so that
1
dF
( p + qF )(1 − F )
Z A
B
+
dF
p + qF 1 − F
Z q/( p + q) 1/( p + q)
+
dF
p + qF
1−F
1
1
ln( p + qF ) −
ln(1 − F )
p+q
p+q
ln( p + qF ) − ln(1 − F )
p+q
Z
=
Z
dt
(8.16)
= t + c1
(8.17)
= t + c1
(8.18)
= t + c1
(8.19)
= t + c1
(8.20)
which is the same as equation (8.4).
We may also solve for
f (t) =
e ( p + q ) t p ( p + q )2
dF
=
dt
[ pe( p+q)t + q]2
(8.21)
Therefore, if the target market is of size m, then at each t, the adoptions are simply given by m × f (t).
For example, set m = 100, 000, p = 0.01 and q = 0.2. Then the adoption rate is shown in Figure 8.3.
Figure 8.3: Example of the adoption
rate: m = 100, 000, p = 0.01 and q = 0.2.
Adoptions
Time (years)
8.4.1 Symbolic math in R
The preceding computation may also be undertaken in R, using it’s symbolic math capability.
232
>
>
>
>
>
>
p
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
#BASS MODEL
FF = e x p r e s s i o n ( p * ( exp ( ( p+q ) * t ) − 1) / ( p * exp ( ( p+q ) * t )+q ) )
# Take d e r i v a t i v e
f f = D( FF , " t " )
print ( f f )
* ( exp ( ( p + q ) * t ) * ( p + q ) ) / ( p * exp ( ( p + q ) * t ) + q ) −
p * ( exp ( ( p + q ) * t ) − 1 ) * ( p * ( exp ( ( p + q ) * t ) * ( p +
q ) ) ) / ( p * exp ( ( p + q ) * t ) + q)^2
We may also plot the same as follows (note the useful tt eval function
employed in the next section of code):
>
>
>
>
>
>
#PLOT
m= 1 0 0 0 0 0 ; p = 0 . 0 1 ; q = 0 . 2
t =seq ( 0 , 2 5 , 0 . 1 )
fn _ f = e v a l ( f f )
p l o t ( t , fn _ f *m, type= " l " )
And this results in a plot identical to that in Figure 8.3. See Figure 8.4.
5000
3000
1000
Units sold
Figure 8.4: Example of the adoption
rate: m = 100, 000, p = 0.01 and q = 0.2.
0
5
10
15
t
20
25
virulent products: the bass model
8.5 Software
The ordinary differential equation here may be solved using free software. One of the widely used open-source packages is called Maxima and
can be downloaded from many places. A very nice one page user-guide
is available at
http://www.math.harvard.edu/computing/maxima/
Here is the basic solution of the differential equation in Maxima:
Maxima 5.9.0 http://maxima.sourceforge.net
Distributed under the GNU Public License. See the file COPYING.
Dedicated to the memory of William Schelter.
This is a development version of Maxima. The function bug_report()
provides bug reporting information.
(C1) depends(F,t);
(D1)
[F(t)]
(C2) diff(F,t)=(1-F)*(p+q*F);
dF
(D2)
-- = (1 - F) (F q + p)
dt
(C3) ode2(%,F,t);
LOG(F q + p) - LOG(F - 1)
(D3)
------------------------- = t + %C
q + p
Notice that line (D3) of the program output does not correspond to
equation (8.4). This is because the function 1−1 F needs to be approached
from the left, not the right as the software appears to be doing. Hence,
solving by partial fractions results in simple integrals that Maxima will
handle properly.
(%i1) integrate((q/(p+q))/(p+q*F)+(1/(p+q))/(1-F),F);
log(q F + p)
(%o1)
log(1 - F)
------------ - ---------q + p
q + p
which is now the exact correct solution, which we use in the model.
Another good tool that is free for small-scale symbolic calculations is
WolframAlpha, available at www.wolframalpha.com. See Figure 8.5 for an
example of the basic Bass model integral.
233
234
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
Figure 8.5: Computing the Bass
model integral using WolframAlpha.
8.6 Calibration
How do we get coefficients p and q? Given we have the current sales
history of the product, we can use it to fit the adoption curve.
• Sales in any period are: s(t) = m f (t).
• Cumulative sales up to time t are: S(t) = m F (t).
Substituting for f (t) and F (t) in the Bass equation gives:
s(t)/m
= p + q S(t)/m
1 − S(t)/m
We may rewrite this as
s(t) = [ p + q S(t)/m][m − S(t)]
Therefore,
s ( t ) = β 0 + β 1 S ( t ) + β 2 S ( t )2
(8.22)
β 0 = pm
(8.23)
β1 = q − p
(8.24)
β 2 = −q/m
(8.25)
Equation 8.22 may be estimated by a regression of sales against cumulative sales. Once the coefficients in the regression { β 0 , β 1 , β 2 } are obtained, the equations above may be inverted to determine the values of
{m, p, q}. We note that since
β 1 = q − p = −mβ 2 −
β0
,
m
virulent products: the bass model
we obtain a quadratic equation in m:
β 2 m2 + β 1 m + β 0 = 0
Solving we have"
m=
− β1 ±
q
β21 − 4β 0 β 2
2β 1
and then this value of m may be used to solve for
p=
β0
;
m
q = −mβ 2
As an example, let’s look at the trend for iPhone sales (we store the quarterly sales in a file and read it in, and then undertook the Bass model
analysis). The R code for this computation is as follows:
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
#USING APPLE iPHONE SALES DATA
data = read . t a b l e ( " iphone _ s a l e s . t x t " , header=TRUE)
i s a l e s = data [ , 2 ]
cum_ i s a l e s = cumsum( i s a l e s )
cum_ i s a l e s 2 = cum_ i s a l e s ^2
r e s = lm ( i s a l e s ~ cum_ i s a l e s +cum_ i s a l e s 2 )
p r i n t ( summary ( r e s ) )
Call :
lm ( formula = i s a l e s ~ cum_ i s a l e s + cum_ i s a l e s 2 )
Residuals :
Min
1Q
− 14.106 − 2.877
Median
− 1.170
3Q
2.436
Max
20.870
Coefficients :
E s t i m a t e Std . E r r o r t value Pr ( >| t |)
( I n t e r c e p t ) 3 . 2 2 0 e +00 2 . 1 9 4 e +00
1.468
0.1533
cum_ i s a l e s
1 . 2 1 6 e −01 2 . 2 9 4 e −02
5 . 3 0 1 1 . 2 2 e −05 * * *
cum_ i s a l e s 2 − 6.893 e −05 3 . 9 0 6 e −05 − 1.765
0.0885 .
−−−
S i g n i f . codes : 0 ? * * * ? 0 . 0 0 1 ? * * ? 0 . 0 1 ? * ? 0 . 0 5 ? . ? 0 . 1 ? ? 1
R e s i d u a l standard e r r o r : 7 . 3 2 6 on 28 degrees o f freedom
M u l t i p l e R−squared :
0.854 ,
Adjusted R−squared : 0 . 8 4 3 6
F− s t a t i s t i c : 8 1 . 8 9 on 2 and 28 DF , p−value : 1 . 9 9 9 e −12
235
236
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
We now proceed to fit the model and then plot it, with actual sales
overlaid on the forecast.
> # FIT THE MODEL
> m1 = (− b [ 2 ] + s q r t ( b[2]^2 − 4 * b [ 1 ] * b [ 3 ] ) ) / ( 2 * b [ 3 ] )
> m2 = (− b[2] − s q r t ( b[2]^2 − 4 * b [ 1 ] * b [ 3 ] ) ) / ( 2 * b [ 3 ] )
> p r i n t ( c (m1, m2 ) )
cum_ i s a l e s cum_ i s a l e s
− 26.09855 1 7 9 0 . 2 3 3 2 1
> m = max (m1, m2 ) ; p r i n t (m)
[ 1 ] 1790.233
> p = b [ 1 ] /m
> q = −m* b [ 3 ]
> print ( c (p , q ) )
( I n t e r c e p t ) cum_ i s a l e s 2
0.00179885 0.12339235
>
> #PLOT THE FITTED MODEL
> n q t r s = 100
> t =seq ( 0 , n q t r s )
> fn _ f = e v a l ( f f ) *m
> p l o t ( t , fn _ f , type= " l " )
> n = length ( i s a l e s )
> l i n e s ( 1 : n , i s a l e s , c o l = " red " , lwd =2 , l t y =2)
>
The outcome is plotted in Figure 8.6. Indeed, it appears that Apple is
ready to peak out in sales.
For several other products, Figure 8.7 shows the estimated coefficients
reported in Table I of the original Bass (1969) paper.
8.7 Sales Peak
It is easy to calculate the time at which adoptions will peak out. Differentiate f (t) with respect to t, and set the result equal to zero, i.e.
t∗ = argmaxt f (t)
which is equivalent to the solution to f 0 (t) = 0.
virulent products: the bass model
237
Figure 8.6: Bass model forecast of
Apple Inc’s quarterly sales. The current
sales are also overlaid in the plot.
40
20
0
Qtrly Units (MM)
Apple Inc Sales
0
20
40
60
80
100
t
Figure 8.7: Empirical adoption rates
and parameters from the Bass paper.
238
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
The calculations are simple and give
t∗ =
−1
ln( p/q)
p+q
(8.26)
Hence, for the values p = 0.01 and q = 0.2, we have
t∗ =
−1
ln(0.01/0.2) = 14.2654 years.
0.01 + 0.2
If we examine the plot in Figure 8.3 we see this to be where the graph
peaks out.
For the Apple data, here is the computation of the sales peak, reported
in number of quarters from inception.
> #PEAK SALES TIME POINT ( IN QUARTERS)
> t s t a r = −1 / ( p+q ) * log ( p / q )
> print ( t s t a r )
( Intercept )
33.77411
> length ( i s a l e s )
[ 1 ] 31
The number of quarters that have already passed is 31. The peak arrives
in a half a year!
8.8 Notes
The Bass model has been extended to what is known as the generalized
Bass model in the paper by Bass, Krishnan, and Jain (1994). The idea is
to extend the model to the following equation:
f (t)
= [ p + q F (t)] x (t)
1 − F (t)
where x (t) stands for current marketing effort. This additional variable
allows (i) consideration of effort in the model, and (ii) given the function
x (t), it may be optimized.
The Bass model comes from a deterministic differential equation. Extensions to stochastic differential equations need to be considered.
See also the paper on Bayesian inference in Bass models by Boatwright
and Kamakura (2003).
virulent products: the bass model
Exercise
In the Bass model, if the coefficient of imitation increases relative to the
coefficient of innovation, then which of the following is the most valid?
(a) the peak of the product life cycle occurs later.
(b) the peak of the product life cycle occurs sooner.
(c) there may be an increasing chance of two life-cycle peaks.
(d) the peak may occur sooner or later, depending on the coefficient of
innovation.
Using peak time formula, substitute x = q/p:
t∗ =
ln(q/p)
1 ln(q/p)
1 ln( x )
−1
ln( p/q) =
=
=
p+q
p+q
p 1 + q/p
p 1+x
Differentiate with regard to x (we are interested in the sign of the first
derivative ∂t∗ /∂q, which is the same as sign of ∂t∗ /∂x):
1
1 + x − x ln x
∂t∗
1
ln x
=
=
−
2
∂x
p x (1 + x ) (1 + x )
px (1 + x )2
From the Bass model we know that q > p > 0, i.e. x > 1, otherwise
we could get negative values of acceptance or shape without maximum
in the 0 ≤ F < 1 area. Therefore, the sign of ∂t∗ /∂x is same as:
∗
∂t
= sign(1 + x − x ln x ), x > 1
sign
∂x
But this non-linear equation
1 + x − x ln x = 0,
x>1
has a root x ≈ 3.59.
In other words, the derivative ∂t∗ /∂x is negative when x > 3.59 and
positive when x < 3.59. For low values of x = q/p, an increase in the
coefficient of imitation q increases the time to sales peak (illustrated in
Figure 8.8), and for high values of q/p the time decreases with increasing q. So the right answer for the question appears to be “it depends on
values of p and q”.
239
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
0.110
0.115
Figure 8.8: Increase in peak time with
q↑
0.105
bass2
p = .1, q = .22
p = .1, q = .20
0.100
240
0
1
2
3
4
t
Figure 1: Increase in peak time with q ↑
2
5
9
Extracting Dimensions: Discriminant and Factor Analysis
9.1 Overview
In this chapter we will try and understand two common approaches to
analyzing large data sets with a view to grouping the data and understanding the main structural components of the data. In discriminant
analysis (DA), we develop statistical models that differentiate two or
more population types, such as immigrants vs natives, males vs females,
etc. In factor analysis (FA), we attempt to collapse an enormous amount
of data about the population into a few common explanatory variables.
DA is an attempt to explain categorical data, and FA is an attempt to
reduce the dimensionality of the data that we use to explain both categorical or continuous data. They are distinct techniques, related in that
they both exploit the techniques of linear algebra.
9.2 Discriminant Analysis
In DA, what we are trying to explain is very often a dichotomous split
of our observations. For example, if we are trying to understand what
determines a good versus a bad creditor. We call the good vs bad the
“criterion” variable, or the “dependent” variable. The variables we use
to explain the split between the criterion variables are called “predictor”
or “explanatory” variables. We may think of the criterion variables as
left-hand side variables or dependent variables in the lingo of regression
analysis. Likewise, the explanatory variables are the right-hand side
ones.
What distinguishes DA is that the left-hand side (lhs) variables are
essentially qualitative in nature. They have some underlying numerical
value, but are in essence qualitative. For example, when universities go
242
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
through the admission process, they may have a cut off score for admission. This cut off score discriminates the students that they want to
admit and the ones that they wish to reject. DA is a very useful tool for
determining this cut off score.
In short, DA is the means by which quantitative explanatory variables
are used to explain qualitative criterion variables. The number of qualitative categories need not be restricted to just two. DA encompasses a
larger number of categories too.
9.2.1
Notation and assumptions
• Assume that there are N categories or groups indexed by i = 2...N.
• Within each group there are observations y j , indexed by j = 1...Mi .
The size of each group need not be the same, i.e., it is possible that
Mi 6 = M j .
• There are a set of predictor variables x = [ x1 , x2 , . . . , xK ]0 . Clearly,
there must be good reasons for choosing these so as to explain the
groups in which the y j reside. Hence the value of the kth variable for
group i, observation j, is denoted as xijk .
• Observations are mutually exclusive, i.e., each object can only belong
to any one of the groups.
• The K × K covariance matrix of explanatory variables is assumed to be
the same for all groups, i.e., Cov( xi ) = Cov( x j ).
9.2.2
Discriminant Function
DA involves finding a discriminant function D that best classifies the
observations into the chosen groups. The function may be nonlinear, but
the most common approach is to use linear DA. The function takes the
following form:
K
D = a1 x1 + a2 x2 + . . . + a K x K =
∑ ak xk
k =1
where the ak coefficients are discriminant weights.
The analysis requires the inclusion of a cut-off score C. For example,
if N = 2, i.e., there are 2 groups, then if D > C the observation falls into
group 1, and if D ≤ C, then the observation falls into group 2.
extracting dimensions: discriminant and factor analysis
Hence, the objective function is to choose {{ ak }, C } such that classification error is minimized. The equation C = D ({ xk }; { ak }) is the equation
of a hyperplane that cuts the space of the observations into 2 parts if
there are only two groups. Note that if there are N groups then there
will be ( N − 1) cutoffs {C1 , C2 , . . . , CN −1 }, and a corresponding number
of hyperplanes.
Exercise
Draw a diagram of the distribution of 2 groups of observations and the
cut off C. Shade the area under the distributions where observations for
group 1 are wrongly classified as group 2; and vice versa.
The variables xk are also known as the “discriminants”. In the extraction of the discriminant function, better discriminants will have higher
statistical significance.
Exercise
Draw a diagram of DA with 2 groups and 2 discriminants. Make the diagram such that one of the variables is shown to be a better discriminant.
How do you show this diagrammatically?
9.2.3
How good is the discriminant function?
After fitting the discriminant function, the next question to ask is how
good the fit is. There are various measures that have been suggested for
this. All of them have the essential property that they best separate the
distribution of observations for different groups. There are many such
measures: (a) Point biserial correlation, (b) Mahalobis D, and (c) the confusion matrix. Each of the measures assesses the degree of classification
error.
The point biserial correlation is the R2 of a regression in which the
classified observations are signed as yij = 1, i = 1 for group 1 and
yij = 0, i = 2 for group 2, and the rhs variables are the xijk values.
The Mahalanobis distance between any two characteristic vectors for
two entities in the data is given by
q
D M = ( x 1 − x 2 ) 0 Σ −1 ( x 1 − x 2 )
where x1 , x2 are two vectors and Σ is the covariance matrix of characteristics of all observations in the data set. First, note that if Σ is the identity
243
244
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
matrix, then D M defaults to the Euclidean distance between two vectors. Second, one of the vectors may be treated as the mean vector for a
given category, in which case the Mahalanobis distance can be used to
assess the distances within and across groups in a pairwise manner. The
quality of the discriminant function is then gauged by computing the
ratio of the average distance across groups to the average distance within
groups. Such ratios are often called the Fisher’s discriminant value.
The confusion matrix is a cross-tabulation of the actual versus predicted classification. For example, a n-category model will result in a
n × n confusion matrix. A comparison of this matrix with a matrix where
the model is assumed to have no classification ability leads to a χ2 statistic that informs us about the statistical strength of the classification ability of the model. We will examine this in more detail shortly.
9.2.4 Caveats
Be careful to not treat dependent variables that are actually better off
remaining continuous as being artificially grouped in qualitative subsets.
9.2.5
Implementation using R
We implement a discriminant function model using data for the top 64
teams in the 2005-06 NCAA tournament. The data is as follows (averages
per game):
1
2
3
4
5
6
7
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
GMS
6
6
5
5
4
4
4
4
3
3
3
3
3
3
PTS
84.2
74.5
77.4
80.8
79.8
72.8
68.8
81.0
62.7
65.3
75.3
65.7
59.7
88.0
REB
41.5
34.0
35.4
37.8
35.0
32.3
31.0
28.5
36.0
26.7
29.0
41.3
34.7
33.3
AST
17.8
19.0
13.6
13.0
15.8
12.8
13.0
19.0
8.3
13.0
16.0
8.7
13.3
17.0
TO
12.8
10.2
11.0
12.6
14.5
13.5
11.3
14.8
15.3
14.0
13.0
14.3
16.7
11.3
A. T STL BLK
1.39 6.7 3.8
1.87 8.0 1.7
1.24 5.4 4.2
1.03 8.4 2.4
1.09 6.0 6.5
0.94 7.3 3.5
1.16 3.8 0.8
1.29 6.8 3.5
0.54 8.0 4.7
0.93 11.3 5.7
1.23 8.0 0.3
0.60 9.3 4.3
0.80 4.7 2.0
1.50 6.7 1.3
PF
16.7
16.5
16.6
19.8
13.3
19.5
14.0
18.8
19.7
17.7
17.7
19.7
17.3
19.7
FG
0.514
0.457
0.479
0.445
0.542
0.510
0.467
0.509
0.407
0.409
0.483
0.360
0.472
0.508
FT
0.664
0.753
0.702
0.783
0.759
0.663
0.753
0.762
0.716
0.827
0.827
0.692
0.579
0.696
X3P
0.417
0.361
0.376
0.329
0.397
0.400
0.429
0.467
0.328
0.377
0.476
0.279
0.357
0.358
extracting dimensions: discriminant and factor analysis
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
29
30
31
32
33
34
35
36
37
38
39
40
41
42
43
44
45
46
47
48
49
50
51
52
3
3
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
2
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
76.3
69.7
72.5
69.5
66.0
67.0
64.5
71.0
80.0
87.5
71.0
60.5
79.0
74.0
63.0
68.0
71.5
60.0
73.5
70.0
66.0
68.0
68.0
53.0
77.0
61.0
55.0
47.0
57.0
62.0
65.0
71.0
54.0
57.0
81.0
62.0
67.0
53.0
27.7
32.7
33.5
37.0
33.0
32.0
43.0
30.5
38.5
41.5
40.5
35.5
33.0
39.0
29.5
36.5
42.0
40.5
32.5
30.0
27.0
34.0
42.0
41.0
33.0
27.0
42.0
35.0
37.0
33.0
34.0
30.0
35.0
40.0
30.0
37.0
37.0
32.0
16.3
16.3
15.0
13.0
12.0
11.0
15.5
13.0
20.0
19.5
9.5
9.5
14.0
11.0
15.0
14.0
13.5
10.5
13.0
9.0
16.0
19.0
10.0
8.0
15.0
12.0
11.0
6.0
8.0
8.0
17.0
10.0
12.0
2.0
13.0
14.0
12.0
15.0
11.7
12.3
14.5
13.5
17.5
12.0
15.0
10.5
20.5
16.5
10.5
12.5
10.0
9.5
9.5
9.0
11.5
11.0
13.5
5.0
13.0
14.0
21.0
17.0
18.0
17.0
17.0
17.0
24.0
20.0
17.0
10.0
22.0
5.0
15.0
18.0
16.0
12.0
1.40 7.0 3.0 18.7 0.457 0.750 0.405
1.32 8.3 1.3 14.3 0.509 0.646 0.308
1.03 8.5 2.0 22.5 0.390 0.667 0.283
0.96 5.0 5.0 14.5 0.464 0.744 0.250
0.69 8.5 6.0 25.5 0.387 0.818 0.341
0.92 8.5 1.5 21.5 0.440 0.781 0.406
1.03 10.0 5.0 20.0 0.391 0.528 0.286
1.24 8.0 1.0 25.0 0.410 0.818 0.323
0.98 7.0 4.0 18.0 0.520 0.700 0.522
1.18 8.5 2.5 20.0 0.465 0.667 0.333
0.90 8.5 3.0 19.0 0.393 0.794 0.156
0.76 7.0 0.0 15.5 0.341 0.760 0.326
1.40 3.0 1.0 18.0 0.459 0.700 0.409
1.16 5.0 5.5 19.0 0.437 0.660 0.433
1.58 7.0 1.5 22.5 0.429 0.767 0.283
1.56 4.5 6.0 19.0 0.398 0.634 0.364
1.17 3.5 3.0 15.5 0.463 0.600 0.241
0.95 7.0 4.0 15.5 0.371 0.651 0.261
0.96 5.5 1.0 15.0 0.470 0.684 0.433
1.80 6.0 3.0 19.0 0.381 0.720 0.222
1.23 5.0 2.0 15.0 0.433 0.533 0.300
1.36 9.0 4.0 20.0 0.446 0.250 0.375
0.48 6.0 5.0 26.0 0.359 0.727 0.194
0.47 9.0 1.0 18.0 0.333 0.600 0.217
0.83 5.0 0.0 16.0 0.508 0.250 0.450
0.71 8.0 3.0 16.0 0.420 0.846 0.400
0.65 6.0 3.0 19.0 0.404 0.455 0.250
0.35 9.0 4.0 20.0 0.298 0.750 0.160
0.33 9.0 3.0 12.0 0.418 0.889 0.250
0.40 8.0 5.0 21.0 0.391 0.654 0.500
1.00 11.0 2.0 19.0 0.352 0.500 0.333
1.00 7.0 3.0 20.0 0.424 0.722 0.348
0.55 5.0 1.0 19.0 0.404 0.667 0.300
0.40 5.0 6.0 16.0 0.353 0.667 0.500
0.87 9.0 1.0 29.0 0.426 0.846 0.350
0.78 7.0 0.0 21.0 0.453 0.556 0.333
0.75 8.0 2.0 16.0 0.353 0.867 0.214
1.25 6.0 3.0 16.0 0.364 0.600 0.368
245
246
53
54
55
56
57
58
59
60
61
62
63
64
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
73.0
71.0
46.0
64.0
64.0
63.0
63.0
52.0
50.0
56.0
54.0
64.0
34.0
29.0
30.0
35.0
43.0
34.0
36.0
35.0
19.0
42.0
22.0
36.0
17.0
16.0
10.0
14.0
5.0
14.0
11.0
8.0
10.0
3.0
13.0
16.0
19.0
10.0
11.0
17.0
11.0
13.0
20.0
8.0
17.0
20.0
10.0
13.0
0.89 3.0 3.0 20.0
1.60 10.0 6.0 21.0
0.91 3.0 1.0 23.0
0.82 5.0 1.0 20.0
0.45 6.0 1.0 20.0
1.08 5.0 3.0 15.0
0.55 8.0 2.0 18.0
1.00 4.0 2.0 15.0
0.59 12.0 2.0 22.0
0.15 2.0 2.0 17.0
1.30 6.0 1.0 20.0
1.23 4.0 0.0 19.0
0.520
0.344
0.365
0.441
0.339
0.435
0.397
0.415
0.444
0.333
0.415
0.367
0.750
0.857
0.500
0.545
0.760
0.815
0.643
0.500
0.700
0.818
0.889
0.833
We loaded in the data and ran the following commands (which are
stored in the program file lda.R:
ncaa = read . t a b l e ( " ncaa . t x t " , header=TRUE)
x = as . matrix ( ncaa [ 4 : 1 4 ] )
y1 = 1 : 3 2
y1 = y1 * 0+1
y2 = y1 * 0
y = c ( y1 , y2 )
l i b r a r y (MASS)
dm = lda ( y~x )
Hence the top 32 teams are category 1 (y = 1) and the bottom 32
teams are category 2 (y = 0). The results are as follows:
> ld a ( y~x )
Call :
l da ( y ~ x )
P r i o r p r o b a b i l i t i e s o f groups :
0
1
0.5 0.5
Group means :
xPTS
xREB
xAST
xTO
xA . T
xSTL xBLK
xPF
0 62.10938 33.85938 11.46875 15.01562 0.835625 6.609375 2.375 18.84375
1 72.09375 35.07500 14.02812 12.90000 1.120000 7.037500 3.125 18.46875
xFG
xFT
xX3P
0 0.4001562 0.6685313 0.3142187
1 0.4464375 0.7144063 0.3525313
C o e f f i c i e n t s of l i n e a r discriminants :
0.391
0.393
0.333
0.333
0.294
0.091
0.381
0.235
0.300
0.200
0.222
0.385
extracting dimensions: discriminant and factor analysis
LD1
xPTS − 0.02192489
xREB 0 . 1 8 4 7 3 9 7 4
xAST 0 . 0 6 0 5 9 7 3 2
xTO − 0.18299304
xA . T 0 . 4 0 6 3 7 8 2 7
xSTL 0 . 2 4 9 2 5 8 3 3
xBLK 0 . 0 9 0 9 0 2 6 9
xPF
0.04524600
xFG 1 9 . 0 6 6 5 2 5 6 3
xFT
4.57566671
xX3P 1 . 8 7 5 1 9 7 6 8
Some useful results can be extracted as follows:
> r e s u l t = lda ( y~x )
> result $ prior
0
1
0.5 0.5
> r e s u l t $means
xPTS
xREB
xAST
xTO
xA . T
xSTL xBLK
xPF
0 62.10938 33.85938 11.46875 15.01562 0.835625 6.609375 2.375 18.84375
1 72.09375 35.07500 14.02812 12.90000 1.120000 7.037500 3.125 18.46875
xFG
xFT
xX3P
0 0.4001562 0.6685313 0.3142187
1 0.4464375 0.7144063 0.3525313
> result $ call
l da ( formula = y ~ x )
> r e s u l t $N
[ 1 ] 64
> r e s u l t $svd
[ 1 ] 7.942264
The last line contains the singular value decomposition level, which
is also the level of the Fischer discriminant, which gives the ratio of the
between- and within-group standard deviations on the linear discriminant variables. Their squares are the canonical F-statistics.
We can look at the performance of the model as follows:
> r e s u l t = ld a ( y~x )
> predict ( result ) $ class
[1] 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 1 1 1 0 1 1 1 0 1 0 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 0 0 0 0 0
[39] 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 1 1 0 0 0 1 1 0 0 0 1 0 0 0 0 0 0
Levels : 0 1
If we want the value of the predicted normalized discriminant function we simply do
> predict ( result )
The cut off is treated as being at zero.
247
248
9.2.6
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
Confusion Matrix
As we have seen before, the confusion matrix is a tabulation of actual
and predicted values. To generate the confusion matrix for our basketball example here we use the following commands in R:
> r e s u l t = lda ( y~x )
> y_ pred = p r e d i c t ( r e s u l t ) $ c l a s s
> length ( y_ pred )
[ 1 ] 64
> t a b l e ( y , y_ pred )
y_ pred
y
0 1
0 27 5
1 5 27
We can see that 5 of the 64 teams have been misclassified. Is this statistically significant? In order to assess this, we compute the χ2 statistic for
the confusion matrix. Let’s define the confusion matrix as
"
#
27 5
A=
5 27
This matrix shows some classification ability. Now we ask, what if the
model has no classification ability, then what would the average confusion matrix look like? It’s easy to see that this would give a matrix that
would assume no relation between the rows and columns, and the numbers in each cell would reflect the average number drawn based on row
and column totals. In this case since the row and column totals are all
32, we get the following confusion matrix of no classification ability:
"
#
16 16
E=
16 16
The test statistic is the sum of squared normalized differences in the cells
of both matrices, i.e.,
Test-Stat =
∑
i,j
[ Aij − Eij ]2
Eij
We compute this in R.
> A = matrix ( c ( 2 7 , 5 , 5 , 2 7 ) , 2 , 2 )
> A
extracting dimensions: discriminant and factor analysis
[ ,1] [ ,2]
[1 ,]
27
5
[2 ,]
5
27
> E = matrix ( c ( 1 6 , 1 6 , 1 6 , 1 6 ) , 2 , 2 )
> E
[ ,1] [ ,2]
[1 ,]
16
16
[2 ,]
16
16
> t e s t _ s t a t = sum ( ( A−E)^2 / E )
> test _ stat
[1] 30.25
> 1− pchisq ( t e s t _ s t a t , 1 )
[ 1 ] 3 . 7 9 7 9 1 2 e −08
The χ2 distribution requires entering the degrees of freedom. In this
case, the degrees of freedom is 1, i.e., equal to (r − 1)(c − 1), where r
is the number of rows and c is the number of columns. We see that the
probability of the A and E matrices being the same is zero. Hence, the
test suggests that the model has statistically significant classification
ability.
9.2.7
Multiple groups
What if we wanted to discriminate the NCAA data into 4 groups? Its
just as simple:
> y1 = rep ( 3 , 1 6 )
> y2 = rep ( 2 , 1 6 )
> y3 = rep ( 1 , 1 6 )
> y4 = rep ( 0 , 1 6 )
> y = c ( y1 , y2 , y3 , y4 )
> r e s = ld a ( y~x )
> res
Call :
l da ( y ~ x )
P r i o r p r o b a b i l i t i e s o f groups :
0
1
2
3
0.25 0.25 0.25 0.25
Group means :
xPTS
xREB
xAST
0 61.43750 33.18750 11.93750
1 62.78125 34.53125 11.00000
2 70.31250 36.59375 13.50000
3 73.87500 33.55625 14.55625
xFT
xX3P
0 0.7174375 0.3014375
1 0.6196250 0.3270000
2 0.7055625 0.3260625
xTO
14.37500
15.65625
12.71875
13.08125
xA . T
0.888750
0.782500
1.094375
1.145625
xSTL
6.12500
7.09375
6.84375
7.23125
xBLK
1.8750
2.8750
3.1875
3.0625
xPF
19.5000
18.1875
19.4375
17.5000
xFG
0.4006875
0.3996250
0.4223750
0.4705000
249
250
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
3 0.7232500 0.3790000
C o e f f i c i e n t s of l i n e a r discriminants :
LD1
LD2
LD3
xPTS − 0.03190376 − 0.09589269 − 0.03170138
xREB 0 . 1 6 9 6 2 6 2 7 0 . 0 8 6 7 7 6 6 9 − 0.11932275
xAST 0 . 0 8 8 2 0 0 4 8 0 . 4 7 1 7 5 9 9 8 0 . 0 4 6 0 1 2 8 3
xTO − 0.20264768 − 0.29407195 − 0.02550334
xA . T 0 . 0 2 6 1 9 0 4 2 − 3.28901817 − 1.42081485
xSTL 0 . 2 3 9 5 4 5 1 1 − 0.26327278 − 0.02694612
xBLK 0 . 0 5 4 2 4 1 0 2 − 0.14766348 − 0.17703174
xPF
0 . 0 3 6 7 8 7 9 9 0 . 2 2 6 1 0 3 4 7 − 0.09608475
xFG 2 1 . 2 5 5 8 3 1 4 0 0 . 4 8 7 2 2 0 2 2 9 . 5 0 2 3 4 3 1 4
xFT
5.42057568 6.39065311 2.72767409
xX3P 1 . 9 8 0 5 0 1 2 8 − 2.74869782 0 . 9 0 9 0 1 8 5 3
Proportion of t r a c e :
LD1
LD2
LD3
0.6025 0.3101 0.0873
> predict ( res ) $ class
[1] 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 1 3 3 2 0
[39] 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 2 2 0 0
Levels : 0 1 2 3
> y
[1] 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3
[40] 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 0 0 0
> y_ pred = p r e d i c t ( r e s ) $ c l a s s
> t a b l e ( y , y_ pred )
y_ pred
y
0 1 2 3
0 10 3 3 0
1 2 12 1 1
2 2 0 11 3
3 1 1 1 13
3 3 3 0 3 2 3 2 2 3 2 2 0 2 2 2 2 2 2 3 1 1 1 0 1
0 0 2 0 0 2 0 1 0 1 1 0 0
3 3 3 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 1 1 1 1 1 1
0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
Exercise
Use the spreadsheet titled default-analysis-data.xls and fit a model
to discriminate firms that default from firms that do not. How good a fit
does your model achieve?
9.3 Eigen Systems
We now move on to understanding some properties of matrices that
may be useful in classifying data or deriving its underlying components. We download Treasury interest rate date from the FRED website,
http://research.stlouisfed.org/fred2/. I have placed the data in a
file called tryrates.txt. Let’s read in the file.
> r a t e s = read . t a b l e ( " t r y r a t e s . t x t " , header=TRUE)
> names ( r a t e s )
[ 1 ] "DATE"
"FYGM3" "FYGM6" "FYGT1" "FYGT2" "FYGT3"
"FYGT5"
"FYGT7"
extracting dimensions: discriminant and factor analysis
[ 9 ] " FYGT10 "
A M × M matrix A has attendant M eigenvectors V and eigenvalue λ
if we can write
λV = A V
Starting with matrix A, the eigenvalue decomposition gives both V and
λ. It turns out we can find M such eigenvalues and eigenvectors, as
there is no unique solution to this equation. We also require that λ 6= 0.
We may implement this in R as follows, setting matrix A equal to the
covariance matrix of the rates of different maturities:
> eigen ( cov ( r a t e s ) )
$ values
[ 1 ] 7 . 0 7 0 9 9 6 e +01 1 . 6 5 5 0 4 9 e +00 9 . 0 1 5 8 1 9 e −02 1 . 6 5 5 9 1 1 e −02 3 . 0 0 1 1 9 9 e −03
[ 6 ] 2 . 1 4 5 9 9 3 e −03 1 . 5 9 7 2 8 2 e −03 8 . 5 6 2 4 3 9 e −04
$ vectors
[1
[2
[3
[4
[5
[6
[7
[8
,]
,]
,]
,]
,]
,]
,]
,]
[1
[2
[3
[4
[5
[6
[7
[8
,]
,]
,]
,]
,]
,]
,]
,]
[ ,1]
[ ,2]
[ ,3]
− 0.3596990 − 0.49201202 0 . 5 9 3 5 3 2 5 7
− 0.3581944 − 0.40372601 0 . 0 6 3 5 5 1 7 0
− 0.3875117 − 0.28678312 − 0.30984414
− 0.3753168 − 0.01733899 − 0.45669522
− 0.3614653 0 . 1 3 4 6 1 0 5 5 − 0.36505588
− 0.3405515 0 . 3 1 7 4 1 3 7 8 − 0.01159915
− 0.3260941 0 . 4 0 8 3 8 3 9 5 0 . 1 9 0 1 7 9 7 3
− 0.3135530 0 . 4 7 6 1 6 7 3 2 0 . 4 1 1 7 4 9 5 5
[ ,7]
[ ,8]
0.04282858 0.03645143
− 0.15571962 − 0.03744201
0 . 1 0 4 9 2 2 7 9 − 0.16540673
0.30395044 0.54916644
− 0.45521861 − 0.55849003
− 0.19935685 0 . 4 2 7 7 3 7 4 2
0 . 7 0 4 6 9 4 6 9 − 0.39347299
− 0.35631546 0 . 1 3 6 5 0 9 4 0
> r c o r r = cor ( r a t e s )
> rcorr
FYGM3
FYGM6
FYGM3 1 . 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 . 9 9 7 5 3 6 9
FYGM6 0 . 9 9 7 5 3 6 9 1 . 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
FYGT1 0 . 9 9 1 1 2 5 5 0 . 9 9 7 3 4 9 6
FYGT2 0 . 9 7 5 0 8 8 9 0 . 9 8 5 1 2 4 8
FYGT3 0 . 9 6 1 2 2 5 3 0 . 9 7 2 8 4 3 7
FYGT5 0 . 9 3 8 3 2 8 9 0 . 9 5 1 2 6 5 9
FYGT7 0 . 9 2 2 0 4 0 9 0 . 9 3 5 6 0 3 3
FYGT10 0 . 9 0 6 5 6 3 6 0 . 9 2 0 5 4 1 9
FYGT10
FYGM3 0 . 9 0 6 5 6 3 6
FYGM6 0 . 9 2 0 5 4 1 9
FYGT1 0 . 9 3 9 6 8 6 3
FYGT2 0 . 9 6 8 0 9 2 6
FYGT3 0 . 9 8 1 3 0 6 6
FYGT5 0 . 9 9 4 5 6 9 1
FYGT7 0 . 9 9 8 4 9 2 7
FYGT10 1 . 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
FYGT1
0.9911255
0.9973496
1.0000000
0.9936959
0.9846924
0.9668591
0.9531304
0.9396863
[ ,4]
− 0.38686589
0.20153645
0.61694982
− 0.19416861
− 0.41827644
− 0.18845999
− 0.05000002
0.42239432
FYGT2
0.9750889
0.9851248
0.9936959
1.0000000
0.9977673
0.9878921
0.9786511
0.9680926
[ ,5]
− 0.34419189
0.79515713
− 0.45913099
0.03906518
− 0.06076305
− 0.03366277
0.16835391
− 0.06132982
FYGT3
0.9612253
0.9728437
0.9846924
0.9977673
1.0000000
0.9956215
0.9894029
0.9813066
[ ,6]
− 0.07045281
0.07823632
0.20442661
− 0.46590654
− 0.14203743
0.72373049
0.09196861
− 0.42147082
FYGT5
0.9383289
0.9512659
0.9668591
0.9878921
0.9956215
1.0000000
0.9984354
0.9945691
FYGT7
0.9220409
0.9356033
0.9531304
0.9786511
0.9894029
0.9984354
1.0000000
0.9984927
251
252
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
So we calculated the eigenvalues and eigenvectors for the covariance
matrix of the data. What does it really mean? Think of the covariance
matrix as the summarization of the connections between the rates of different maturities in our data set. What we do not know is how many
dimensions of commonality there are in these rates, and what is the relative importance of these dimensions. For each dimension of commonality, we wish to ask (a) how important is that dimension (the eigenvalue),
and (b) the relative influence of that dimension on each rate (the values
in the eigenvector). The most important dimension is the one with the
highest eigenvalue, known as the “principal” eigenvalue, corresponding
to which we have the principal eigenvector. It should be clear by now
that the eigenvalue and its eigenvector are “eigen pairs”. It should also
be intuitive why we call this the eigenvalue “decomposition” of a matrix.
9.4 Factor Analysis
Factor analysis is the use of eigenvalue decomposition to uncover the
underlying structure of the data. Given a data set of observations and
explanatory variables, factor analysis seeks to achieve a decomposition
with these two properties:
1. Obtain a reduced dimension set of explanatory variables, known as
derived/extracted/discovered factors. Factors must be orthogonal, i.e.,
uncorrelated with each other.
2. Obtain data reduction, i.e., suggest a limited set of variables. Each
such subset is a manifestation of an abstract underlying dimension.
These subsets are also ordered in terms of their ability to explain the
variation across observations.
See the article by Richard Darlington
http://www.psych.cornell.edu/Darlington/factor.htm
which is as good as any explanation one can get. See also the article
by Statsoft:
http://www.statsoft.com/textbook/stfacan.html
9.4.1 Notation
• Observations: yi , i = 1...N.
• Original explanatory variables: xik , k = 1...K.
extracting dimensions: discriminant and factor analysis
• Factors: Fj , j = 1...M.
• M < K.
9.4.2 The Idea
As you can see in the rates data, there are eight different rates. If we
wanted to model the underlying drivers of this system of rates, we could
assume a separate driver for each one leading to K = 8 underlying
factors. But the whole idea of factor analysis is to reduce the number
of drivers that exist. So we may want to go with a smaller number of
M < K factors.
The main concept here is to “project” the variables x ∈ RK onto the
reduced factor set F ∈ R M such that we can explain most of the variables
by the factors. Hence we are looking for a relation
x = BF
where B = {bkj } ∈ RK × M is a matrix of factor “loadings” for the variables. Through matrix B, x may be represented in smaller dimension M.
The entries in matrix B may be positive or negative. Negative loadings
mean that the variable is negatively correlated with the factor. The whole
idea is that we want to replace the relation of y to x with a relation of y
to a reduced set F.
Once we have the set of factors defined, then the N observations y
may be expressed in terms of the factors through a factor “score” matrix
A = { aij } ∈ R N × M as follows:
y = AF
Again, factor scores may be positive or negative. There are many ways
in which such a transformation from variables to factors might be undertaken. We look at the most common one.
9.4.3
Principal Components Analysis (PCA)
In PCA, each component (factor) is viewed as a weighted combination
of the other variables (this is not always the way factor analysis is implemented, but is certainly one of the most popular).
The starting point for PCA is the covariance matrix of the data. Essentially what is involved is an eigenvalue analysis of this matrix to extract
the principal eigenvectors.
253
254
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
We can do the analysis using the R statistical package. Here is the
sample session:
>
>
>
>
>
ncaa = read . t a b l e ( " ncaa . t x t " , header=TRUE)
x = ncaa [ 4 : 1 4 ]
r e s u l t = princomp ( x )
screeplot ( result )
s c r e e p l o t ( r e s u l t , type= " l i n e s " )
The results are as follows:
> summary ( r e s u l t )
Importance o f components :
Comp. 1
Comp. 2
Comp. 3
Comp. 4
Comp. 5
Standard d e v i a t i o n
9.8747703 5.2870154 3.9577315 3.19879732 2.43526651
P r o p o r t i o n o f Variance 0 . 5 9 5 1 0 4 6 0 . 1 7 0 5 9 2 7 0 . 0 9 5 5 9 4 3 0 . 0 6 2 4 4 7 1 7 0 . 0 3 6 1 9 3 6 4
Cumulative P r o p o r t i o n 0 . 5 9 5 1 0 4 6 0 . 7 6 5 6 9 7 3 0 . 8 6 1 2 9 1 6 0 . 9 2 3 7 3 8 7 8 0 . 9 5 9 9 3 2 4 2
Comp. 6
Comp. 7
Comp. 8
Comp. 9
Standard d e v i a t i o n
2 . 0 4 5 0 5 0 1 0 1 . 5 3 2 7 2 2 5 6 0 . 1 3 1 4 8 6 0 8 2 7 1 . 0 6 2 1 7 9 e −01
P r o p o r t i o n o f Variance 0 . 0 2 5 5 2 3 9 1 0 . 0 1 4 3 3 7 2 7 0 . 0 0 0 1 0 5 5 1 1 3 6 . 8 8 5 4 8 9 e −05
Cumulative P r o p o r t i o n 0 . 9 8 5 4 5 6 3 3 0 . 9 9 9 7 9 3 6 0 0 . 9 9 9 8 9 9 1 1 0 0 9 . 9 9 9 6 8 0 e −01
Comp. 1 0
Comp. 1 1
Standard d e v i a t i o n
6 . 5 9 1 2 1 8 e −02 3 . 0 0 7 8 3 2 e −02
P r o p o r t i o n o f Variance 2 . 6 5 1 3 7 2 e −05 5 . 5 2 1 3 6 5 e −06
Cumulative P r o p o r t i o n 9 . 9 9 9 9 4 5 e −01 1 . 0 0 0 0 0 0 e −00
The resultant “screeplot” shows the amount explained by each component.
Lets look at the loadings. These are the respective eigenvectors:
> r e s u l t $ loadings
Loadings :
Comp. 1 Comp. 2 Comp. 3 Comp. 4 Comp. 5 Comp. 6 Comp. 7 Comp. 8 Comp. 9 Comp. 1 0
PTS 0 . 9 6 4
0.240
extracting dimensions: discriminant and factor analysis
REB
AST
TO
A. T
STL
BLK
PF
FG
FT
X3P
0.940
− 0.316
0 . 2 5 7 − 0.228 − 0.283 − 0.431 − 0.778
0 . 1 9 4 − 0.908 − 0.116 0 . 3 1 3 − 0.109
− 0.194
− 0.110 − 0.223
Comp. 1 1
PTS
REB
AST
TO
A. T
STL
BLK
PF
FG − 0.996
FT
X3P
0.712
0.642
0.262
0 . 6 1 9 − 0.762
− 0.315
0.175
0.948
0.205
0.816 0.498
0 . 5 1 6 − 0.849
0 . 8 6 2 − 0.364 − 0.228
We can see that the main variable embedded in the first principal
component is PTS. (Not surprising!). We can also look at the standard
deviation of each component:
> r e s u l t $ sdev
Comp. 1
Comp. 2
Comp. 3
Comp. 4
Comp. 5
Comp. 6
Comp. 7
9.87477028 5.28701542 3.95773149 3.19879732 2.43526651 2.04505010 1.53272256
Comp. 8
Comp. 9
Comp. 1 0
Comp. 1 1
0.13148608 0.10621791 0.06591218 0.03007832
The biplot shows the first two components and overlays the variables
as well. This is a really useful visual picture of the results of the analysis.
> biplot ( result )
255
256
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
The alternative function prcomp returns the same stuff, but gives all
the factor loadings immediately.
> prcomp ( x )
Standard d e v i a t i o n s :
[ 1 ] 9.95283292 5.32881066 3.98901840 3.22408465 2.45451793 2.06121675
[ 7 ] 1.54483913 0.13252551 0.10705759 0.06643324 0.03031610
Rotation :
PTS
REB
AST
TO
A. T
STL
BLK
PF
FG
FT
X3P
PC1
− 0.963808450
− 0.022483140
− 0.256799635
0.061658120
− 0.021008035
− 0.006513483
− 0.012711101
− 0.012034143
− 0.003729350
− 0.001210397
− 0.003804597
PC2
− 0.052962387
− 0.939689339
0.228136664
− 0.193810802
0.030935414
0.081572061
− 0.070032329
0.109640846
0.002175469
0.003852067
0.003708648
PC3
0.018398319
0.073265952
− 0.282724110
− 0.908005124
0.035465079
− 0.193844456
0.035371935
− 0.223148274
− 0.001708722
0.001793045
− 0.001211492
PC4
0.094091517
0.026260543
− 0.430517969
− 0.115659421
− 0.022580766
0.205272135
0.073370876
0.862316681
− 0.006568270
0.008110836
− 0.002352869
PC5
− 0.240334810
0.315515827
0.778063875
− 0.313055838
0.068308725
0.014528901
− 0.034410932
0.364494150
− 0.001837634
− 0.019134412
− 0.003849550
extracting dimensions: discriminant and factor analysis
PTS
REB
AST
TO
A. T
STL
BLK
PF
FG
FT
X3P
PTS
REB
AST
TO
A. T
STL
BLK
PF
FG
FT
X3P
PC6
PC7
0 . 0 2 9 4 0 8 5 3 4 − 0.0196304356
− 0.040851345 − 0.0951099200
− 0.044767132 0 . 0 6 8 1 2 2 2 8 9 0
0.108917779 0.0864648004
− 0.004846032 0 . 0 0 6 1 0 4 7 9 3 7
− 0.815509399 − 0.4981690905
− 0.516094006 0 . 8 4 8 9 3 1 3 8 7 4
0.228294830 0.0972181527
0.004118140 0.0041758373
− 0.005525032 0 . 0 0 0 1 3 0 1 9 3 8
0.001012866 0.0094289825
PC11
0.0037883918
− 0.0043776255
0.0058744543
− 0.0001063247
− 0.0560584903
− 0.0062405867
0.0013213701
− 0.0043605809
− 0.9956716097
− 0.0731951151
− 0.0031976296
9.4.4
PC8
0.0026169995
− 0.0074120623
0.0359559264
− 0.0416005762
− 0.7122315249
0.0008726057
0.0023262933
0.0005835116
0.0848448651
− 0.6189703010
0.3151374823
PC9
− 0.004516521
0.003557921
0.056106512
− 0.039363263
− 0.642496008
− 0.008845999
− 0.001364270
0.001302210
− 0.019610637
0.761929615
0.038279107
PC10
0.004889708
− 0.008319362
0.015018370
− 0.012726102
− 0.262468560
− 0.005846547
0.008293758
− 0.001385509
0.030860027
− 0.174641147
− 0.948194531
Application to Treasury Yield Curves
We had previously downloaded monthly data for constant maturity
yields from June 1976 to December 2006. Here is the 3D plot. It shows
the change in the yield curve over time for a range of maturities.
> persp ( r a t e s , t h e t a =30 , phi =0 , x l a b = " y e a r s " , ylab= " m a t u r i t y " , z l a b = " r a t e s " )
257
258
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
As before, we undertake a PCA of the system of Treasury rates. The
commands are the same as with the basketball data.
>
>
>
>
t r y r a t e s = read . t a b l e ( " t r y r a t e s . t x t " , header=TRUE)
r a t e s = as . matrix ( t r y r a t e s [ 2 : 9 ] )
r e s u l t = princomp ( r a t e s )
r e s u l t $ loadings
Loadings :
Comp. 1
FYGM3 − 0.360
FYGM6 − 0.358
FYGT1 − 0.388
FYGT2 − 0.375
FYGT3 − 0.361
FYGT5 − 0.341
FYGT7 − 0.326
FYGT10 − 0.314
Comp. 2 Comp. 3
− 0.492 0 . 5 9 4
− 0.404
− 0.287 − 0.310
− 0.457
0 . 1 3 5 − 0.365
0.317
0.408 0.190
0.476 0.412
Comp. 4 Comp. 5 Comp. 6
− 0.387 − 0.344
0.202 0.795
0 . 6 1 7 − 0.459 0 . 2 0 4
− 0.194
− 0.466
− 0.418
− 0.142
− 0.188
0.724
0.168
0.422
− 0.421
Comp. 7 Comp. 8
0.156
− 0.105 − 0.165
− 0.304 0 . 5 4 9
0 . 4 5 5 − 0.558
0.199 0.428
− 0.705 − 0.393
0.356 0.137
> r e s u l t $ sdev
Comp. 1
Comp. 2
Comp. 3
Comp. 4
Comp. 5
Comp. 6
Comp. 7
8.39745750 1.28473300 0.29985418 0.12850678 0.05470852 0.04626171 0.03991152
Comp. 8
0.02922175
> summary ( r e s u l t )
Importance o f components :
Comp. 1
Comp. 2
Comp. 3
Comp. 4
Standard d e v i a t i o n
8.397458 1.28473300 0.299854180 0.1285067846
P r o p o r t i o n o f Variance 0 . 9 7 5 5 8 8 0 . 0 2 2 8 3 4 7 7 0 . 0 0 1 2 4 3 9 1 6 0 . 0 0 0 2 2 8 4 6 6 7
Cumulative P r o p o r t i o n 0 . 9 7 5 5 8 8 0 . 9 9 8 4 2 2 7 5 0 . 9 9 9 6 6 6 6 6 6 0 . 9 9 9 8 9 5 1 3 2 6
Comp. 5
Comp. 6
Comp. 7
Comp. 8
Standard d e v i a t i o n
5 . 4 7 0 8 5 2 e −02 4 . 6 2 6 1 7 1 e −02 3 . 9 9 1 1 5 2 e −02 2 . 9 2 2 1 7 5 e −02
P r o p o r t i o n o f Variance 4 . 1 4 0 7 6 6 e −05 2 . 9 6 0 8 3 5 e −05 2 . 2 0 3 7 7 5 e −05 1 . 1 8 1 3 6 3 e −05
Cumulative P r o p o r t i o n 9 . 9 9 9 3 6 5 e −01 9 . 9 9 9 6 6 1 e −01 9 . 9 9 9 8 8 2 e −01 1 . 0 0 0 0 0 0 e +00
extracting dimensions: discriminant and factor analysis
The results are interesting. We see that the loadings are large in the
first three component vectors for all maturity rates. The loadings correspond to a classic feature of the yield curve, i.e., there are three components: level, slope, and curvature. Note that the first component has almost equal loadings for all rates that are all identical in sign. Hence, this
is the level factor. The second component has negative loadings for the
shorter maturity rates and positive loadings for the later maturity ones.
Therefore, when this factor moves up, the short rates will go down, and
the long rates will go up, resulting in a steepening of the yield curve.
If the factor goes down, the yield curve will become flatter. Hence, the
second principal component is clearly the slope factor. Examining the
loadings of the third principal component should make it clear that the
effect of this factor is to modulate the “curvature” or hump of the yield
14
CLASS NOTES, S. DAS 17 APRIL 2007
curve. Still, from looking at the results, it is clear that 97% of the comCumulative Proportion 0.975588 0.99842275 0.999666666 0.9998951326
mon variation is explained by just
the first Comp.6
factor, andComp.7
a wee bit more
Comp.5
Comp.8 by
Standard deviation
5.470852e-02 4.626171e-02 3.991152e-02 2.922175e-02
the next two.
The resultant “biplot” shows the dominance of the main
Proportion of Variance 4.140766e-05 2.960835e-05 2.203775e-05 1.181363e-05
Cumulative
Proportion 9.999365e-01 9.999661e-01 9.999882e-01 1.000000e+00
component.
The resultant “biplot” shows the dominance of the main component.
Notice that the variables are almost all equally weighting on the first component.
Notice that
the variables are almost all equally weighting on the first
4.5. Difference between PCA and FA. The difference between PCA and FA is
that
that length
for the purposes
of matrix
computations
PCA assumes
that all
varianceloadings.
component. isThe
of the
vectors
corresponds
to the
factor
is common, with all unique factors set equal to zero; while FA assumes that there
is some unique variance. The level of unique variance is dictated by the FA model
which is chosen. Accordingly, PCA is a model of a closed system, while FA is
a model of an open system. FA tries to decompose the correlation matrix into
common and unique portions.
259
260
9.4.5
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
Application: Risk Parity and Risk Disparity
Risk parity – see Theirry Roncalli’s book
Risk disparity – see Mark Kritzman’s paper.
9.4.6
Difference between PCA and FA
The difference between PCA and FA is that for the purposes of matrix
computations PCA assumes that all variance is common, with all unique
factors set equal to zero; while FA assumes that there is some unique
variance. Hence PCA may also be thought of as a subset of FA. The level
of unique variance is dictated by the FA model which is chosen. Accordingly, PCA is a model of a closed system, while FA is a model of an open
system. FA tries to decompose the correlation matrix into common and
unique portions.
9.4.7
Factor Rotation
Finally, there are some times when the variables would load better on
the factors if the factor system were to be rotated. This called factor rotation, and many times the software does this automatically.
Remember that we decomposed variables x as follows:
x = B F+e
where x is dimension K, B ∈ RK × M , F ∈ R M , and e is a K-dimension
vector. This implies that
Cov( x ) = BB0 + ψ
Recall that B is the matrix of factor loadings. The system remains unchanged if B is replaced by BG, where G ∈ R M× M , and G is orthogonal.
Then we call G a “rotation” of B.
The idea of rotation is easier to see with the following diagram. Two
conditions need to be satisfied: (a) The new axis (and the old one) should
be orthogonal. (b) The difference in loadings on the factors by each variable must increase. In the diagram below we can see that the rotation
has made the variables align better along the new axis system.
extracting dimensions: discriminant and factor analysis
Factor Rotation
Factor 2
Factor 2
Factor 1
variables
Factor 1
9.4.8
Using the factor analysis function
To illustrate, let’s undertake a factor analysis of the Treasury rates data.
In R, we can implement it generally with the factanal command.
> factanal ( rates , 2 )
Call :
factanal ( x = rates , factors = 2)
Uniquenesses :
FYGM3 FYGM6
0.006 0.005
FYGT1
0.005
Loadings :
Factor1
FYGM3 0 . 8 4 3
FYGM6 0 . 8 2 6
FYGT1 0 . 7 9 3
FYGT2 0 . 7 2 6
FYGT3 0 . 6 8 1
FYGT5 0 . 6 1 7
FYGT7 0 . 5 7 9
FYGT10 0 . 5 4 6
Factor2
0.533
0.562
0.608
0.686
0.731
0.786
0.814
0.836
FYGT2
0.005
FYGT3
0.005
Factor1 Factor2
FYGT5
0.005
FYGT7 FYGT10
0.005 0.005
261
262
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
SS l o a d i n g s
P r o p o r t i o n Var
Cumulative Var
4.024
0.503
0.503
3.953
0.494
0.997
Test of the hypothesis that 2 f a c t o r s are s u f f i c i e n t .
The c h i square s t a t i s t i c i s 3 5 5 6 . 3 8 on 13 degrees o f freedom .
The p−value i s 0
Notice how the first factor explains the shorter maturities better and
the second factor explains the longer maturity rates. Hence, the two
factors cover the range of maturities. Note that the ability of the factors
to separate the variables increases when we apply a factor rotation:
> f a c t a n a l ( r a t e s , 2 , r o t a t i o n = " promax " )
Call :
f a c t a n a l ( x = r a t e s , f a c t o r s = 2 , r o t a t i o n = " promax " )
Uniquenesses :
FYGM3 FYGM6
0.006 0.005
FYGT1
0.005
Loadings :
Factor1
FYGM3 0 . 1 1 0
FYGM6 0 . 1 7 4
FYGT1 0 . 2 8 2
FYGT2 0 . 4 7 7
FYGT3 0 . 5 9 3
FYGT5 0 . 7 4 6
FYGT7 0 . 8 2 9
FYGT10 0 . 8 9 5
Factor2
0.902
0.846
0.747
0.560
0.443
0.284
0.194
0.118
FYGT2
0.005
FYGT3
0.005
FYGT5
0.005
FYGT7 FYGT10
0.005 0.005
Factor1 Factor2
SS l o a d i n g s
2.745
2.730
P r o p o r t i o n Var
0.343
0.341
Cumulative Var
0.343
0.684
The factors have been reversed after the rotation. Now the first factor
explains long rates and the second factor explains short rates. If we want
the time series of the factors, use the following command:
extracting dimensions: discriminant and factor analysis
r e s u l t = f a c t a n a l ( rates , 2 , scores=" regression " )
ts = result $ scores
> par ( mfrow=c ( 2 , 1 ) )
> p l o t ( t s [ , 1 ] , type= " l " )
> p l o t ( t s [ , 2 ] , type= " l " )
The results are plotted here. The plot represents the normalized factor
time series.
Thus there appears to be a slow-moving first component and a fast moving second one.
263
10
Bidding it Up: Auctions
10.1 Theory
Auctions comprise one of the oldest market forms, and are still a popular mechanism for selling various assets and their related price discovery.
In this chapter we will study different auction formats, bidding theory,
and revenue maximization principles.
Hal Varian, Chief Economist at Google (NYT, Aug 1, 2002) writes:
“Auctions, one of the oldest ways to buy and sell, have been reborn
and revitalized on the Internet.
When I say ”old,” I mean it. Herodotus described a Babylonian marriage market, circa 500 B.C., in which potential wives were auctioned off.
Notably, some of the brides sold for a negative price.
The Romans used auctions for many purposes, including auctioning
off the right to collect taxes. In A.D. 193, the Praetorian Guards even
auctioned off the Roman empire itself!
We don’t see auctions like this anymore (unless you count campaign
finance practices), but auctions are used for just about everything else.
Online, computer-managed auctions are cheap to run and have become
increasingly popular. EBay is the most prominent example, but other,
less well-known companies use similar technology.”
10.1.1
Overview
Auctions have many features, but the key ingredient is information asymmetry between seller and buyers. The seller may know more about the
product than the buyers, and the buyers themselves might have differential information about the item on sale. Moreover, buyers also take into
266
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
account imperfect information about the behavior of the other bidders.
We will examine how this information asymmetry plays into bidding
strategy in the mathematical analysis that follows.
Auction market mechanisms are explicit, with the prices and revenue
a direct consequence of the auction design. In contrast, in other markets,
the interaction of buyers and sellers might be more implicit, as in the
case of commodities, where the market mechanism is based on demand
and supply, resulting in the implicit, proverbial invisible hand setting
prices.
There are many examples of active auction markets, such as auctions
of art and valuables, eBay, Treasury securities, Google ad auctions, and
even the New York Stock Exchange, which is an example of a continuous
call auction market.
Auctions may be for a single unit (e.g., art) or multiple units (e.g., Treasury securities).
10.1.2
Auction types
The main types of auctions may be classified as follows:
1. English (E): highest bid wins. The auction is open, i.e., bids are revealed to all participants as they occur. This is an ascending price
auction.
2. Dutch (D): auctioneer starts at a high price and calls out successively
lower prices. First bidder accepts and wins the auction. Again, bids
are open.
3. 1st price sealed bid (1P): Bids are sealed. Highest bidder wins and
pays his price.
4. 2nd price sealed bid (2P): Same as 1P but the price paid by the winner
is the second-highest price. Same as the auction analyzed by William
Vickrey in his seminal paper in 1961 that led to a Nobel prize. See
Vickrey (1961).
5. Anglo-Dutch (AD): Open, ascending-price auction till only two bidders remain, then it becomes sealed-bid.
10.1.3
Value Determination
The eventual outcome of an auction is price/value discovery of the item
being sold. There are two characterizations of this value determination
bidding it up: auctions
process, depending on the nature of the item being sold.
1. Independent private values model: Each buyer bids his own independent valuation of the item at sale (as in regular art auctions).
2. Common-values model: Bidders aim to discover a common price, as
in Treasury auctions. This is because there is usually an after market
in which common value is traded.
10.1.4
Bidder Types
The assumptions made about the bidders impacts the revenue raised
in the auction and the optimal auction design chosen by the seller. We
consider two types of bidders.
1. Symmetric: all bidders observe the same probability distribution of
bids and stop-out (SP) prices. The stop out price is the price of the
lowest winning bid for the last unit sold. This is a robust assumption
when markets are competitive.
2. Asymmetric or non-symmetric. Here the bidders may have different
distributions of value. This is often the case when markets are segmented. Example: bidding for firms in M&A deals.
10.1.5
Benchmark Model (BM)
We begin by analyzing what is known as the benchmark model. It is the
simplest framework in which we can analyze auctions. It is based on 4
main assumptions:
1. Risk-neutrality of bidders. We do not need utility functions in the
analysis.
2. Private-values model. Every bidder has her own value for the item.
There is a distribution of bidders’ private values.
3. Symmetric bidders. Every bidder faces the same distribution of private values mentioned in the previous point.
4. Payment by winners is a function of bids alone. For a counterexample, think of payment via royalties for a book contract which depends
on post auction outcomes. Or the bidding for movie rights, where the
buyer takes a part share of the movie with the seller.
267
268
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
The following are the results and properties of the BM.
1. D = 1P. That is, the Dutch auction and first price auction are equivalent to bidders. These two mechanisms are identical because in each
the bidder needs to choose how high to bid without knowledge of the
other bids.
2. In the BM, the optimal strategy is to bid one’s true valuation. This is
easy to see for D and 1P. In both auctions, you do not see any other
lower bids, so you bid up to your maximum value, i.e., one’s true
value, and see if the bid ends up winning. For 2P, if you bid too high
you overpay, bid too low you lose, so best to bid one’s valuation. For
E, it’s best to keep bidding till price crosses your valuation (reservation price).
3. Equilibria types:
• Dominant: A situation where bidders bid their true valuation irrespective of other bidders bids. Satisfied by E and 2P.
• Nash: Bids are chosen based on the best guess of other bidders’
bids. Satisfied by D and 1P.
10.2 Auction Math
We now get away from the abstract definition of different types of auctions and work out an example of an auctions equilibrium.
Let F be the probability distribution of the bids. And define vi as the
true value of the i-th bidder, on a continuum between 0 and 1. Assume
bidders are ranked in order of their true valuations vi . How do we interpret F (v)? Think of the bids as being drawn from say, a beta distribution
F on v ∈ (0, 1), so that the probability of a very high or very low bid
is lower than a bid around the mean of the distribution. The expected
difference between the first and second highest bids is, given v1 and v2 :
D = [1 − F (v2 )](v1 − v2 )
That is, multiply the difference between the first and second bids by the
probability that v2 is the second-highest bid. Or think of the probability
of there being a bid higher than v2 . Taking first-order conditions (from
the seller’s viewpoint):
∂D
= [1 − F (v2 )] − (v1 − v2 ) F 0 (v1 ) = 0
∂v1
bidding it up: auctions
Note that v1 ≡d v2 , given bidders are symmetric in BM. The symbol ≡d
means “equivalent in distribution”. This implies that
v1 − v2 =
1 − F ( v1 )
f ( v1 )
The expected revenue to the seller is the same as the expected 2nd price.
The second price comes from the following re-arranged equation:
v2 = v1 −
10.2.1
1 − F ( v1 )
f ( v1 )
Optimization by bidders
The goal of bidder i is to find a function/bidding rule B that is a function of the private value vi such that
bi = B ( v i )
where bi is the actual bid. If there are n bidders, then
Pr[bidder i wins] = Pr[bi > B(v j )],
= [ F(B
−1
(bi ))]
n −1
∀ j 6= i,
Each bidder tries to maximize her expected profit relative to her true
valuation, which is
πi = (vi − bi )[ F ( B−1 (bi ))]n−1 = (vi − bi )[ F (vi )]n−1 ,
(10.1)
i
again invoking the notion of bidder symmetry. Optimize by taking ∂π
∂bi =
0. We can get this by taking first the total derivative of profit relative to
the bidder’s value as follows:
dπi
∂πi
∂π db
∂πi
=
+ i i =
dvi
∂vi
∂bi dvi
∂vi
which reduces to the partial derivative of profit with respect to personal
i
valuation because ∂π
∂bi = 0. This useful first partial derivative is taken
from equation (10.1):
∂πi
= [ F ( B−1 (bi ))]n−1
∂vi
Now, let vl be the lowest bid. Integrate the previous equation to get
πi =
Z v
i
vl
[ F ( x )]n−1 dx
(10.2)
269
270
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
Equating (10.1) and (10.2) gives
R vi
bi = v i −
vl
[ F ( x )]n−1 dx
[ F (vi )]n−1
= B ( vi )
which gives the bidding rule B(vi ) entirely in terms of the personal valuation of the bidder. If, for example, F is uniform, then
( n − 1) v
n
Here we see that we “shade” our bid down slightly from our personal
valuation. We bid less than true valuation to leave some room for profit.
The amount of shading of our bid depends on how much competition
there is, i.e., the number of bidders n. Note that
∂B
∂B
> 0,
>0
∂vi
∂n
B(v) =
i.e., you increase your bid as your personal value rises, and as the number of bidders increases.
10.2.2
Example
We are bidding for a used laptop on eBay. Suppose we assume that the
distribution of bids follows a beta distribution with minimum value $50
and a maximum value of $500. Our personal value for the machine is
$300. Assume 10 other bidders. How much should we bid?
x = ( 1 : 1 0 0 0 ) / 1000
y = x * 450+50
prob _y = dbeta ( x , 2 , 4 )
p r i n t ( c ( " check= " ,sum( prob _y ) / 1 0 0 0 ) )
prob _y = prob _y / sum( prob _y )
p l o t ( y , prob _y , type= " l " )
> p r i n t ( c ( " check= " ,sum( prob _y ) / 1 0 0 0 ) )
[ 1 ] " check= "
" 0.999998333334 "
Note that we have used the non-central Beta distribution, with shape
parameters a = 2 and b = 4. Note that the Beta density function is
Beta( x, a, b) =
Γ ( a + b ) a −1
x (1 − x ) b −1
Γ( a)Γ(b)
for x taking values between 0 and 1. The distribution of bids from 50 to
500 is shown in Figure 10.1.
The mean and standard deviation are
computed as follows.
bidding it up: auctions
271
Figure 10.1: Probability density
function for the Beta (a = 2, b = 4)
distribution.
> p r i n t ( c ( " mean= " ,sum( y * prob _y ) ) )
[ 1 ] " mean= "
" 200.000250000167 "
> p r i n t ( c ( " stdev= " , s q r t (sum( y^2 * prob _y) − (sum( y * prob _y ) ) ^ 2 ) ) )
[ 1 ] " stdev= "
" 80.1782055353774 "
We can take a computational approach to solving this problem. We program up equation 10.1 and then find the bid at which this is maximized.
> x = ( 1 : 1 0 0 0 ) / 1000
> y = 50 + 450 * x
> cumprob_y = pbeta ( x , 2 , 4 )
> exp_ p r o f i t = (300 − y ) * cumprob_y^10
> idx = which ( exp_ p r o f i t ==max ( exp_ p r o f i t ) )
> y [ idx ]
[ 1 ] 271.85
Hence, the bid of 271.85 is slightly lower than the reservation price. It is
10% lower. If there were only 5 other bidders, then the bid would be:
> exp_ p r o f i t = (300 − y ) * cumprob_y^5
> idx = which ( exp_ p r o f i t ==max ( exp_ p r o f i t ) )
> y [ idx ]
[1] 254.3
272
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
Now, we shade the bid down much more, because there are fewer competing bidders, and so the chance of winning with a lower bid increases.
10.3 Treasury Auctions
This section is based on the published paper by Das and Sundaram
(1996). We move on from single-unit auctions to a very common multiunit auction. Treasury auctions are the mechanism by which the Federal
government issues its bills, notes, and bonds. Auctions are usually held
on Wednesdays. Bids are received up to early afternoon after which the
top bidders are given their quantities requested (up to prescribed ceilings for any one bidder), until there is no remaining supply of securities.
Even before the auction, Treasury securities trade in what is known as
a “when-issued” or pre-market. This market gives early indications of
price that may lead to tighter clustering of bids in the auction.
There are two types of dealers in a Treasury auction, primary dealers,
i.e., the big banks and investment houses, and smaller independent bidders. The auction is really played out amongst the primary dealers. They
place what are known as competitive bids versus the others, who place
non-competitive bids.
Bidders also keep an eye on the secondary market that ensues right
after the auction. In many ways, the bidders are also influenced by the
possible prices they expect the paper to be trading at in the secondary
market, and indicators of these prices come from the when-issued market.
The winner in an auction experiences regret, because he knows he
bid higher than everyone else, and senses that he overpaid. This phenomenon is known as the “winner’s curse.” Treasury auction participants talk amongst each other to mitigate winner’s curse. The Fed also
talks to primary dealers to mitigate their winner’s curse and thereby
induce them to bid higher, because someone with lower propensity for
regret is likely to bid higher.
10.3.1
DPA or UPA?
DPA stands for “discriminating price auction” and UPA for “uniform
price auction.” The former was the preferred format for Treasury auctions and the latter was introduced only recently.
In a DPA, the highest bidder gets his bid quantity at the price he bid.
bidding it up: auctions
Then the next highest bidder wins his quantity at the price he bid. And
so on, until the supply of Treasury securities is exhausted. In this manner the Treasury seeks to maximize revenue by filling each winning at
the price. Since the prices paid by each winning bidder are different,
the auction is called “discriminating” in price. Revenue maximization
is attempted by walking down the demand curve, see Figure 10.2. The
shaded area quantifies the revenue raised.
Figure 10.2: Revenue in the DPA
and UPA auctions.
In a UPA, the highest bidder gets his bid quantity at the price of the
last winning bid (this price is also known as the stop-out price). Then
the next highest bidder wins his quantity at the stop-out price. And so
on, until the supply of Treasury securities is exhausted. Thus, the UPA
is also known as a “single-price” auction. See Figure 10.2, lower panel,
where the shaded area quantifies the revenue raised.
It may intuitively appear that the DPA will raise more revenue, but
in fact, empirically, the UPA has been more successful. This is because
the UPA incentivizes higher bids, as the winner’s curse is mitigated. In
a DPA, bids are shaded down on account of winner’s curse – winning
means you paid higher than what a large number of other bidders were
willing to pay.
Some countries like Mexico have used the UPA format. The U.S.,
started with the DPA, and now runs both auction formats.
273
274
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
An interesting study examined markups achieved over yields in the
when-issued market as an indicator of the success of the two auction formats. They examined the auctions of 2- and 5-year notes from June 1991
- 1994). [from Mulvey, Archibald and Flynn, US Office of the Treasury].
See Figure 10.3. The results of a regression of the markups on bid dispersion and duration of the auctioned securities shows that markups
Mulvey, Archibald, Flynn
(Office of Us
increase
inTreasury)
the dispersion of bids. If we think of bid dispersion as a
proxy for the extent of winner’s curse, then we can see that the yields
are pushed higher in the UPA than the DPA, therefore prices are lower
in the UPA than the DPA. Markups are decreasing in the duration of the
securities. Bid dispersion is shown in Figure 10.4.
Figure 10.3: Treasury auction
markups.
10.4 Mechanism Design
What is a good auction mechanism? The following features might be
considered.
• It allows easy entry to the game.
• It prevents collusion. For example, ascending bid auctions may be
used to collude by signaling in the early rounds of bidding. Different
auction formats may lead to various sorts of collusion.
• It induces truthful value revelation (also known as “truthful” bidding).
• Efficient - maximizes utility of auctioneer and bidders.
• Not costly to implement.
• Fair to all parties, big and small.
bidding it up: auctions
Figure 10.4: Bid-Ask Spread in the
Auction.
10.4.1
Collusion
Here are some examples of collusion in auctions, which can be explicit
or implicit. Collusion amongst buyers results in mitigating the winner’s
curse, and may work to either raise revenues or lower revenues for the
seller.
• (Varian) 1999: German phone spectrum auction. Bids had to be in
minimum 10% increments for multiple units. A firm bid 18.18 and
20 million for 2 lots. They signaled that everyone could center at 20
million, which they believed was the fair price. This sort of implicit
collusion averts a bidding war.
• In Treasury auctions, firms can discuss bids, which is encouraged by
the Treasury (why?). The restriction on cornering by placing a ceiling
on how much of the supply one party can obtain in the auction aids
collusion (why?). Repeated games in Treasury security auctions also
aids collusion (why?).
• Multiple units also allows punitive behavior, by firms bidding to raise
prices on lots they do not want to signal others should not bid on lots
they do want.
275
276
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
10.4.2
Clicks (Advertising Auctions)
The Google AdWords program enables you to create advertisements
which will appear on relevant Google search results pages and our network of partner sites. See www.adwords.google.com.
The Google AdSense program differs in that it delivers Google AdWords ads to individuals’ websites. Google then pays web publishers
for the ads displayed on their site based on user clicks on ads or on ad
impressions, depending on the type of ad.
The material here refers to the elegant paper by Aggarwal, Goel, and
Motwani (2006) on keyword auctions in AdWords. We first list some
basic features of search engine advertising models. Aggarwal went on
to work for Google as they adopted this algorithm from her thesis at
Stanford.
1. Search engine advertising uses three models: (a) CPM, cost per thousand views, (b) CPC, cost per click, and (c) CPA, cost per acquisition.
These are all at different stages of the search page experience.
2. CPC seems to be mostly used. There are 2 models here:
(a) Direct ranking: the Overture model.
(b) Revenue ranking: the Google model.
3. The merchant pays the price of the “next” click (different from “second” price auctions). This is non-truthful in both revenue ranking
cases as we will see in a subsequent example. That is, bidders will not
bid their true private valuations.
4. Asymmetric: there is an incentive to underbid, none to overbid.
5. Iterative: by placing many bids and watching responses, a bidder can
figure out the bid ordering of other bidders for the same keywords, or
basket of keywords. However, this is not obvious or simple. Google
used to provide the GBS or Google Bid Simulator so that sellers using
AdWords can figure out their optimal bids. See the following for more
details on Adwords: google.com/adwords/.
6. If revenue ranking were truthful, it would maximize utility of auctioneer and merchant. (Known as auction “efficiency”).
7. Innovation: the laddered auction. Randomized weights attached to bids.
If weights are 1, then it’s direct ranking. If weights are CTR (clickthrough rate), i.e. revenue-based, it’s the revenue ranking.
bidding it up: auctions
To get some insights about the process of optimal bidding in AdWords
auctions, see http://www.thesearchagents.com/2009/09/optimal-bidding-part-1-behind-the
-scenes-of-google-adwords-bidding-tutorial/. See the Hal Varian
video: http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=jRx7AMb6rZ0.
Here is a quick summary of Hal Varian’s video. A merchant can figure
out what the maximum bid per click should be in the following steps:
1. Maximum profitable CPA: This is the profit margin on the product. For
example, if the selling price is $300 and cost is $200, then the profit
margin is $100, which is also the maximum cost per acquisition (CPA)
a seller would pay.
2. Conversion Rate (CR): This is the number of times a click results in a
sale. Hence, CR is equal to number of sales divided by clicks. So, if for
every 100 clicks, we get a sale every 5 times, the CR is 5%.
3. Value per Click (VPC): Equal to the CR times the CPA. In the example,
we have VPC = 0.05 × 100 = $5.
4. Determine the profit maximizing CPC bid: As the bid is lowered, the
number of clicks falls, but the CPC falls as well, revenue falls, but
the profit after acquisition costs can rise until the sweet spot is determined. To find the number of clicks expected at each bid price, use the
Google Bid Simulator. See the table below (from Google) for the economics at different bid prices. Note that the price you bid is not the
price you pay for the click, because it is a “next-price” auction, based
on a revenue ranking model, so the exact price you pay is based on
Google’s model, discussed in the next section. We see that the profit is
maximized at a bid of $4.
Just as an example, note that the profit is equal to
(VPC − CPC ) × #Clicks = (CPA × CR − CPC ) × #Clicks
Hence, for a bid of $4, we have
(5 − 407.02/154) × 154 = $362.98
277
278
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
As pointed out by Varian, the rule is to compute ICC (Incremental cost
per click), and make sure that it equals the VPC. The ICC at a bid of
$5.00 is
697.42 − 594.27
ICC (5.00) =
= 5.73 > 5
208 − 190
Then
594.27 − 407.02
ICC (4.50) =
= 5.20 > 5
190 − 154
407.02 − 309.73
= 4.63 < 5
154 − 133
Hence, the optimal bid lies between $4.00 and $4.50.
ICC (4.00) =
10.4.3
Next Price Auctions
In a next-price auction, the CPC is based on the price of the click next
after your own bid. Thus, you do not pay your bid price, but the one in
the advertising slot just lower than yours. Hence, if your winning bid is
for position j on the search screen, the price paid is that of the winning
bid at position j + 1.
See the paper by Aggarwal, Goyal and Motwani (2006). Our discussion here is based on their paper. Let the true valuation (revenue) expected by bidder/seller i be equal to vi . The CPC is denoted pi . Let the
click-through-rate (CTR) for seller/merchant i at a position j (where the
ad shows up on the search screen) be denoted CTRij . CTR is the ratio of
the number of clicks to the number of “impressions” i.e., the number of
times the ad is shown.
• The “utility” to the seller is given by
Utility = CTRij (vi − pi )
bidding it up: auctions
• Example: 3 bidders A, B, C, with private values 200, 180, 100. There
are two slots or ad positions with CTRs 0.5 and 0.4. If bidder A bids
200, pays 180, utility is (200 − 180) × 0.5 = 10. But why not bid 110, for
utility of (200 − 100) × 0.4 = 40? This simple example shows that the
next price auction is not truthful. Also note that your bid determines
your ranking but not the price you pay (CPC).
• Ranking of bids is based on wi bi in descending order of i. If wi = 1,
then we get the Overture direct ranking model. And if wi = CTRij
then we have Google’s revenue ranking model. In the example below,
the weights range from 0 to 100, not 0 to 1, but this is without any loss
of generality. The weights assigned to each merchant bidder may be
based on some qualitative ranking such as the Quality Score (QS) of
the ad.
• Price paid by bidder i is
w i + 1 bi + 1
.
wi
• Separable CTRs: CTRs of merchant i = 1 and i = 2 are the same for
position j. No bidder position dependence.
10.4.4
Laddered Auction
AGM 2006 denoted the revised auction as “laddered”. It gives a unique
truthful auction. The main idea is to set the CPC to
K CTR − CTR
w j +1 b j +1
i,j
i,j+1
pi = ∑
, 1≤i≤K
CTRi,i
wi
j =i
so that
#Clicksi
× pi = CTRii × pi =
#Impressionsi
K
∑
j =i
CTRi,j − CTRi,j+1
w j +1 b j +1
wi
The lhs is the expected revenue to Google per ad impression. Make
no mistake, the whole point of the model is to maximize Google’s revenue, while making the auction system more effective for merchants. If
this new model results in truthful equilibria, it is good for Google. The
weights wi are arbitrary and not known to the merchants.
Here is the table of CTRs for each slot by seller. These tables are the
examples in the AGM 2006 paper.
Slot 1
Slot 2
Slot 3
A
0.40
0.30
0.18
B
0.35
0.25
0.20
C
0.30
0.25
0.20
D
0.20
0.18
0.15
279
280
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
The assigned weights and the eventual allocations and prices are shown
below.
Weight Bid Score Rank Price
Merchant A
60
25
1500
1
13.5
Merchant B
40
30
1200
2
16
Merchant C
50
16
800
3
12
Merchant D
40
15
600
4
0
We can verify these calculations as follows.
> p3 = ( 0 . 2 0 − 0 ) / 0 . 2 0 * 40 / 50 * 1 5 ; p3
[ 1 ] 12
> p2 = ( 0 . 2 5 − 0 . 2 0 ) / 0 . 2 5 * 50 / 40 * 16 + ( 0 . 2 0 − 0 ) / 0 . 2 5 * 40 / 40 * 1 5 ; p2
[ 1 ] 16
> p1 = ( 0 . 4 0 − 0 . 3 0 ) / 0 . 4 0 * 40 / 60 * 30 + ( 0 . 3 0 − 0 . 1 8 ) / 0 . 4 0 * 50 / 60 * 16
+ ( 0 . 1 8 − 0 ) / 0 . 4 0 * 40 / 60 * 1 5 ; p1
[1] 13.5
See the paper for more details, but this equilibrium is unique and truthful.
Looking at this model, examine the following questions:
• What happens to the prices paid when the CTR drop rapidly as we go
down the slots versus when they drop slowly?
• As a merchant, would you prefer that your weight be higher or lower?
• What is better for Google, a high dispersion in weights, or a low dispersion in weights?
• Can you see that by watching bidding behavior of the merchants,
Google can adjust their weights to maximize revenue? By seeing a
week’s behavior Google can set weights for the next week. Is this legal?
• Is Google better off if the bids are more dispersed than when they
are close together? How would you use the data in the table above to
answer this question using R?
Exercise
Whereas Google clearly has modeled their AdWords auction to maximize revenue, less is known about how merchants maximize their net
bidding it up: auctions
revenue per ad, by designing ads, and choosing keywords in an appropriate manner. Google offers merchants a product called “Google Bid
Simulator” so that the return from an adword (key word) may be determined.
In this exercise, you will first take the time to role play a merchant
who is trying to explore and understand AdWords, and then come up
with an approach to maximize the return from a portfolio of AdWords.
Here are some questions that will help in navigating the AdWords
landscape.
1. What is the relation between keywords and cost-per-click (CPC)?
2. What is the Quality Score (QS) of your ad, and how does it related to
keywords and CPC?
3. What defines success in an ad auction? What are its determinants?
4. What is AdRank. What does a higher AdRank buy for a merchant?
5. What are AdGroups and how do they relate to keywords?
6. What is automated CPC bidding?
7. What are the following tools? Keyword tool, Traffic estimator, Placement tool, Contextual targeting tool?
8. What is the incremental cost-per-click (ICC)?
Sketch a brief outline of how you might go about optimizing a portfolio of AdWords. Use the concepts we studied in Markowitz portfolio
optimization for this.
281
11
Truncate and Estimate: Limited Dependent Variables
11.1 Introduction
Usually we run regressions using continuous variables for the dependent
(y) variables, such as, for example, when we regress income on education. Sometimes however, the dependent variable may be discrete, and
could be binomial or multinomial. That is, the dependent variable is
“limited”. In such cases, we need a different approach.
Discrete dependent variables are a special case of limited dependent variables. The Logit and Probit1 models we look at here are examples of
discrete dependent variable models. Such models are also often called
qualitative response (QR) models.
In particular, when the variable is binary, i.e., takes values of {0, 1},
then we get a probability model. If we just regressed left hand side variables of ones and zeros on a suite of right hand side variables we could
of course fit a linear regression. Then if we took another observation
with values for the right hand side, i.e., x = { x1 , x2 , . . . , xk }, we could
compute the value of the y variable using the fitted coefficients. But of
course, this value will not be exactly 0 or 1, except by unlikely coincidence. Nor will this value lie in the range (0, 1).
There is also a relationship to classifier models. In classifier models,
we are interested in allocating observations to categories. In limited dependent models we also want to explain the reasons (i.e., find explanatory variables) for what results in the allocation across categories.
Some examples of such models are to explain whether a person is
employed or not, whether a firm is syndicated or not, whether a firm is
solvent or not, which field of work is chosen by graduates, where consumers shop, whether they choose Coke versus Pepsi, etc.
These fitted values might not even lie between 0 and 1 with a linear
These are common usage and do not
need to be capitalized, so we will use
lower case subsequently.
1
284
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
regression. However, if we used a carefully chosen nonlinear regression
function, then we could ensure that the fitted values of y are restricted
to the range (0, 1), and then we would get a model where we fitted a
probability. There are two such model forms that are widely used: (a)
Logit, also known as a logistic regression, and (b) Probit models. We
look at each one in turn.
11.2 Logit
A logit model takes the following form:
y=
e f (x)
,
1 + e f (x)
f ( x ) = β 0 + β 1 x1 + . . . β k x k
We are interested in fitting the coefficients { β 0 , β 1 , . . . , β k }. Note that,
irrespective of the coefficients, f ( x ) ∈ (−∞, +∞), but y ∈ (0, 1). When
f ( x ) → −∞, y → 0, and when f ( x ) → +∞, y → 1. We also write this
model as
0
eβ x
0
y=
0 ≡ Λ( β x )
1 + eβ x
where Λ (lambda) is for logit.
The model generates a S-shaped curve for y, and we can plot it as
follows:
The fitted value of y is nothing but the probability that y = 1.
truncate and estimate: limited dependent variables
285
For the NCAA data, take the top 32 teams and make their dependent
variable 1, and that of the bottom 32 teams zero.
> y1 = 1 : 3 2
> y1 = y1 * 0+1
> y1
[1] 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1
> y2 = y1 * 0
> y2
[1] 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
> y = c ( y1 , y2 )
> y
[1] 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1
[39] 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
> x = as . matrix ( ncaa [ 4 : 1 4 ] )
1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1
0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 0 0 0 0 0 0
0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0
Then running the model is pretty easy as follows:
> h = glm ( y~x , family=binomial ( l i n k= " l o g i t " ) )
> logLik ( h )
’ l o g Lik . ’ − 21.44779 ( df =12)
> summary ( h )
Call :
glm ( formula = y ~ x , family = binomial ( l i n k = " l o g i t " ) )
Deviance R e s i d u a l s :
Min
1Q
Median
− 1.80174 − 0.40502 − 0.00238
3Q
0.37584
Max
2.31767
Coefficients :
E s t i m a t e Std . E r r o r z value Pr ( >| z |)
( I n t e r c e p t ) − 45.83315
1 4 . 9 7 5 6 4 − 3.061 0 . 0 0 2 2 1 * *
xPTS
− 0.06127
0 . 0 9 5 4 9 − 0.642 0 . 5 2 1 0 8
xREB
0.49037
0.18089
2.711 0.00671 * *
xAST
0.16422
0.26804
0.613 0.54010
xTO
− 0.38405
0 . 2 3 4 3 4 − 1.639 0 . 1 0 1 2 4
xA . T
1.56351
3.17091
0.493 0.62196
xSTL
0.78360
0.32605
2.403 0.01625 *
xBLK
0.07867
0.23482
0.335 0.73761
xPF
0.02602
0.13644
0.191 0.84874
286
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
xFG
46.21374
17.33685
xFT
10.72992
4.47729
xX3P
5.41985
5.77966
−−−
S i g n i f . codes : 0 L’ 0 . 0 0 1 L’ 0 . 0 1 L’
2.666
2.397
0.938
0.00768 * *
0.01655 *
0.34838
0 . 0 5 L’ 0 . 1 L’ 1
( D i s p e r s i o n parameter f o r binomial family taken t o be 1 )
Null deviance : 8 8 . 7 2 3
R e s i d u a l deviance : 4 2 . 8 9 6
AIC : 6 6 . 8 9 6
on 63
on 52
degrees o f freedom
degrees o f freedom
Number o f F i s h e r S c o r i n g i t e r a t i o n s : 6
Suppose we ran this just with linear regression (this is also known as
running a linear probability model):
> h = lm ( y~x )
> summary ( h )
Call :
lm ( formula = y ~ x )
Residuals :
Min
1Q
− 0.65982 − 0.26830
Median
0.03183
3Q
0.24712
Max
0.83049
Coefficients :
E s t i m a t e Std . E r r o r t value Pr ( >| t |)
( I n t e r c e p t ) − 4.114185
1 . 1 7 4 3 0 8 − 3.503 0 . 0 0 0 9 5 3 * * *
xPTS
− 0.005569
0 . 0 1 0 2 6 3 − 0.543 0 . 5 8 9 7 0 9
xREB
0.046922
0.015003
3.128 0.002886 * *
xAST
0.015391
0.036990
0.416 0.679055
xTO
− 0.046479
0 . 0 2 8 9 8 8 − 1.603 0 . 1 1 4 9 0 5
xA . T
0.103216
0.450763
0.229 0.819782
xSTL
0.063309
0.028015
2.260 0.028050 *
xBLK
0.023088
0.030474
0.758 0.452082
xPF
0.011492
0.018056
0.636 0.527253
xFG
4.842722
1.616465
2.996 0.004186 * *
xFT
1.162177
0.454178
2.559 0.013452 *
truncate and estimate: limited dependent variables
xX3P
0.476283
0.712184
0.669 0.506604
−−−
S i g n i f . codes : 0 L’ 0 . 0 0 1 L’ 0 . 0 1 L’ 0 . 0 5 L’ 0 . 1 L’ 1
R e s i d u a l standard e r r o r : 0 . 3 9 0 5 on 52 degrees o f freedom
M u l t i p l e R−Squared : 0 . 5 0 4 3 ,
Adjusted R−squared : 0 . 3 9 9 5
F− s t a t i s t i c :
4 . 8 1 on 11 and 52 DF , p−value : 4 . 5 1 4 e −05
11.3 Probit
Probit has essentially the same idea as the logit except that the probability function is replaced by the normal distribution. The nonlinear
regression equation is as follows:
y = Φ[ f ( x )],
f ( x ) = β 0 + β 1 x1 + . . . β k x k
where Φ(.) is the cumulative normal probability function. Again, irrespective of the coefficients, f ( x ) ∈ (−∞, +∞), but y ∈ (0, 1). When
f ( x ) → −∞, y → 0, and when f ( x ) → +∞, y → 1.
We can redo the same previous logit model using a probit instead:
> h = glm ( y~x , family=binomial ( l i n k= " p r o b i t " ) )
> logLik ( h )
’ l o g Lik . ’ − 21.27924 ( df =12)
> summary ( h )
Call :
glm ( formula = y ~ x , family = binomial ( l i n k = " p r o b i t " ) )
Deviance R e s i d u a l s :
Min
1Q
− 1.7635295 − 0.4121216
Median
− 0.0003102
3Q
0.3499560
Max
2.2456825
Coefficients :
E s t i m a t e Std . E r r o r z value Pr ( >| z |)
( I n t e r c e p t ) − 26.28219
8 . 0 9 6 0 8 − 3.246 0 . 0 0 1 1 7 * *
xPTS
− 0.03463
0 . 0 5 3 8 5 − 0.643 0 . 5 2 0 2 0
xREB
0.28493
0.09939
2.867 0.00415 * *
xAST
0.10894
0.15735
0.692 0.48874
xTO
− 0.23742
0 . 1 3 6 4 2 − 1.740 0 . 0 8 1 8 0 .
287
288
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
xA . T
0.71485
1.86701
xSTL
0.45963
0.18414
xBLK
0.03029
0.13631
xPF
0.01041
0.07907
xFG
26.58461
9.38711
xFT
6.28278
2.51452
xX3P
3.15824
3.37841
−−−
S i g n i f . codes : 0 L’ 0 . 0 0 1 L’ 0 . 0 1 L’
0.383
2.496
0.222
0.132
2.832
2.499
0.935
0.70181
0.01256 *
0.82415
0.89529
0.00463 * *
0.01247 *
0.34988
0 . 0 5 L’ 0 . 1 L’ 1
( D i s p e r s i o n parameter f o r binomial family taken t o be 1 )
Null deviance : 8 8 . 7 2 3
R e s i d u a l deviance : 4 2 . 5 5 8
AIC : 6 6 . 5 5 8
on 63
on 52
degrees o f freedom
degrees o f freedom
Number o f F i s h e r S c o r i n g i t e r a t i o n s : 8
11.4 Analysis
Both these models are just settings in which we are computing binary
probabilities, i.e.
Pr[y = 1] = F ( β0 x )
where β is a vector of coefficients, and x is a vector of explanatory variables. F is the logit/probit function.
ŷ = F ( β0 x )
where ŷ is the fitted value of y for a given x. In each case the function
takes the logit or probit form that we provided earlier. Of course,
Pr[y = 0] = 1 − F ( β0 x )
Note that the model may also be expressed in conditional expectation
form, i.e.
E[y| x ] = F ( β0 x )(y = 1) + [1 − F ( β0 x )](y = 0) = F ( β0 x )
11.4.1
Slopes
In a linear regression, it is easy to see how the dependent variable changes
when any right hand side variable changes. Not so with nonlinear mod-
truncate and estimate: limited dependent variables
els. A little bit of pencil pushing is required (add some calculus too).
Remember that y lies in the range (0, 1). Hence, we may be interested
in how E(y| x ) changes as any of the explanatory variables changes in
value, so we can take the derivative:
∂E(y| x )
= F 0 ( β0 x ) β ≡ f ( β0 x ) β
∂x
For each model we may compute this at the means of the regressors:
• In the logit model this is as follows:
( C1 ) F : exp ( b * x ) / (1+ exp ( b * x ) ) ;
b x
%E
−−−−−−−−−
b x
%E
+ 1
( D1 )
( C2 ) d i f f ( F , x ) ;
b x
2 b x
b %E
b %E
−−−−−−−−− − −−−−−−−−−−−−
b x
b x
2
%E
+ 1
(%E
+ 1)
( D2 )
Therefore, we may write this as:
∂E(y| x )
=β
∂x
0
eβ x
0
1 + eβ x
!
0
eβ x
1−
0
1 + eβ x
!
which may be re-written as
∂E(y| x )
= β · Λ( β0 x ) · [1 − Λ( β0 x )]
∂x
> h = glm ( y~x , family=binomial ( l i n k= " l o g i t " ) )
> beta = h$ c o e f f i c i e n t s
> beta
( Intercept )
xPTS
xREB
xAST
− 45.83315262 − 0.06127422
0.49037435
0.16421685
xA . T
xSTL
xBLK
xPF
1.56351478
0.78359670
0.07867125
0.02602243
xFT
xX3P
10.72992472
5.41984900
xTO
− 0.38404689
xFG
46.21373793
289
290
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
> dim ( x )
[ 1 ] 64 11
> beta = as . matrix ( beta )
> dim ( beta )
[ 1 ] 12 1
> wuns = matrix ( 1 , 6 4 , 1 )
> x = cbind ( wuns , x )
> dim ( x )
[ 1 ] 64 12
> xbar = as . matrix ( colMeans ( x ) )
> dim ( xbar )
[ 1 ] 12 1
> xbar
[ ,1]
1.0000000
PTS 6 7 . 1 0 1 5 6 2 5
REB 3 4 . 4 6 7 1 8 7 5
AST 1 2 . 7 4 8 4 3 7 5
TO 1 3 . 9 5 7 8 1 2 5
A. T 0 . 9 7 7 8 1 2 5
STL 6 . 8 2 3 4 3 7 5
BLK 2 . 7 5 0 0 0 0 0
PF 1 8 . 6 5 6 2 5 0 0
FG
0.4232969
FT
0.6914687
X3P 0 . 3 3 3 3 7 5 0
> l o g i t f u n c t i o n = exp ( t ( beta ) %*% xbar ) / (1+ exp ( t ( beta ) %*% xbar ) )
> logitfunction
[ ,1]
[ 1 , ] 0.5139925
> s l o p e s = beta * l o g i t f u n c t i o n [ 1 ] * (1 − l o g i t f u n c t i o n [ 1 ] )
> slopes
[ ,1]
( I n t e r c e p t ) − 11.449314459
xPTS
− 0.015306558
xREB
0.122497576
xAST
0.041022062
xTO
− 0.095936529
truncate and estimate: limited dependent variables
xA . T
xSTL
xBLK
xPF
xFG
xFT
xX3P
0.390572574
0.195745753
0.019652410
0.006500512
11.544386272
2.680380362
1.353901094
• In the probit model this is
∂E(y| x )
= φ( β0 x ) β
∂x
where φ(.) is the normal density function (not the cumulative probability).
> h = glm ( y~x , family=binomial ( l i n k= " p r o b i t " ) )
> beta = h$ c o e f f i c i e n t s
> beta
( Intercept )
xPTS
xREB
xAST
− 26.28219202 − 0.03462510
0.28493498
0.10893727
xA . T
xSTL
xBLK
xPF
0.71484863
0.45963279
0.03029006
0.01040612
xFT
xX3P
6.28277680
3.15823537
> x = as . matrix ( cbind ( wuns , x ) )
> xbar = as . matrix ( colMeans ( x ) )
> dim ( xbar )
[ 1 ] 12 1
> dim ( beta )
NULL
> beta = as . matrix ( beta )
> dim ( beta )
[ 1 ] 12 1
> s l o p e s = dnorm ( t ( beta ) %*% xbar ) [ 1 ] * beta
> slopes
[ ,1]
( I n t e r c e p t ) − 10.470181164
xPTS
− 0.013793791
xREB
0.113511111
xAST
0.043397939
xTO
− 0.23742076
xFG
26.58460638
291
292
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
− 0.094582613
0.284778174
0.183106438
0.012066819
0.004145544
10.590655632
2.502904294
1.258163568
xTO
xA . T
xSTL
xBLK
xPF
xFG
xFT
xX3P
11.4.2
Maximum-Likelihood Estimation (MLE)
Estimation in the models above, using the glm function is done by R
using MLE. Lets write this out a little formally. Since we have say n observations, and each LHS variable is y = {0, 1}, we have the likelihood
function as follows:
n
L=
∏ F( β0 x)yi [1 − F( β0 x)]1−yi
i =1
The log-likelihood will be
n
ln L =
∑
i =1
yi ln F ( β0 x ) + (1 − yi ) ln[1 − F ( β0 x )]
To maximize the log-likelihood we take the derivative:
n ∂ ln L
f ( β0 x )
f ( β0 x )
β=0
= ∑ yi
−
(
1
−
y
)
i
∂β
F ( β0 x )
1 − F ( β0 x )
i =1
which gives a system of equations to be solved for β. This is what the
software is doing. The system of first-order conditions are collectively
called the “likelihood equation”.
You may well ask, how do we get the t-statistics of the parameter estimates β? The formal derivation is beyond the scope of this class, as it
requires probability limit theorems, but let’s just do this a little heuristically, so you have some idea of what lies behind it.
The t-stat for a coefficient is its value divided by its standard deviation. We get some idea of the standard deviation by asking the question:
how does the coefficient set β change when the log-likelihood changes?
That is, we are interested in ∂β/∂ ln L. Above we have computed the
reciprocal of this, as you can see. Lets define
g=
∂ ln L
∂β
truncate and estimate: limited dependent variables
We also define the second derivative (also known as the Hessian matrix)
H=
∂2 ln L
∂β∂β0
Note that the following are valid:
E( g) = 0
(this is a vector)
Var ( g) = E( gg0 ) − E( g)2 = E( gg0 )
= − E( H ) (this is a non-trivial proof)
We call
I ( β) = − E( H )
the information matrix. Since (heuristically) the variation in log-likelihood
with changes in beta is given by Var ( g) = − E( H ) = I ( β), the inverse
gives the variance of β. Therefore, we have
Var ( β) → I ( β)−1
We take the square root of the diagonal of this matrix and divide the
values of β by that to get the t-statistics.
11.5 Multinomial Logit
You will need the nnet package for this. This model takes the following
form:
exp( β0j x )
Prob[y = j] = p j =
J
1 + ∑ j=1 exp( β0j x )
We usually set
Prob[y = 0] = p0 =
1
J
1 + ∑ j=1 exp( β0j x )
To run this we set up as follows:
>
>
>
>
>
>
>
ncaa = read . t a b l e ( " ncaa . t x t " , header=TRUE)
x = as . matrix ( ncaa [ 4 : 1 4 ] )
w1 = ( 1 : 1 6 ) * 0 + 1
w0 = ( 1 : 1 6 ) * 0
y1 = c (w1 , w0 , w0 , w0)
y2 = c (w0 , w1 , w0 , w0)
y3 = c (w0 , w0 , w1 , w0)
293
294
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
> y4 = c (w0 , w0 , w0 , w1)
> y = cbind ( y1 , y2 , y3 , y4 )
> l i b r a r y ( nnet )
> r e s = multinom ( y~x )
# w e i g h t s : 52 ( 3 6 v a r i a b l e )
i n i t i a l value 8 8 . 7 2 2 8 3 9
i t e r 10 value 7 1 . 1 7 7 9 7 5
i t e r 20 value 6 0 . 0 7 6 9 2 1
i t e r 30 value 5 1 . 1 6 7 4 3 9
i t e r 40 value 4 7 . 0 0 5 2 6 9
i t e r 50 value 4 5 . 1 9 6 2 8 0
i t e r 60 value 4 4 . 3 0 5 0 2 9
i t e r 70 value 4 3 . 3 4 1 6 8 9
i t e r 80 value 4 3 . 2 6 0 0 9 7
i t e r 90 value 4 3 . 2 4 7 3 2 4
i t e r 100 value 4 3 . 1 4 1 2 9 7
f i n a l value 4 3 . 1 4 1 2 9 7
stopped a f t e r 100 i t e r a t i o n s
> res
Call :
multinom ( formula = y ~ x )
Coefficients :
( Intercept )
xPTS
xREB
xAST
xTO
xA . T
y2
− 8.847514 − 0.1595873 0 . 3 1 3 4 6 2 2 0 . 6 1 9 8 0 0 1 − 0.2629260 − 2.1647350
y3
6 5 . 6 8 8 9 1 2 0 . 2 9 8 3 7 4 8 − 0.7309783 − 0.6059289 0 . 9 2 8 4 9 6 4 − 0.5720152
y4
3 1 . 5 1 3 3 4 2 − 0.1382873 − 0.2432960 0 . 2 8 8 7 9 1 0 0 . 2 2 0 4 6 0 5 − 2.6409780
xSTL
xBLK
xPF
xFG
xFT
xX3P
y2 − 0.813519 0 . 0 1 4 7 2 5 0 6 0 . 6 5 2 1 0 5 6 − 13.77579 1 0 . 3 7 4 8 8 8 − 3.436073
y3 − 1.310701 0 . 6 3 0 3 8 8 7 8 − 0.1788238 − 86.37410 − 24.769245 − 4.897203
y4 − 1.470406 − 0.31863373 0 . 5 3 9 2 8 3 5 − 45.18077
6 . 7 0 1 0 2 6 − 7.841990
R e s i d u a l Deviance : 8 6 . 2 8 2 6
AIC : 1 5 8 . 2 8 2 6
> names ( r e s )
[1] "n"
" nunits "
[ 5 ] " nsunits "
" decay "
[ 9 ] " censored "
" value "
" nconn "
" entropy "
" wts "
" conn "
" softmax "
" convergence "
truncate and estimate: limited dependent variables
[ 1 3 ] " f i t t e d . values " " r e s i d u a l s "
" call "
" terms "
[ 1 7 ] " weights "
" deviance "
" rank "
" lab "
[ 2 1 ] " coefnames "
" vcoefnames "
" xlevels "
" edf "
[ 2 5 ] " AIC "
> res $ f i t t e d . values
y1
y2
y3
y4
1 6 . 7 8 5 4 5 4 e −01 3 . 2 1 4 1 7 8 e −01 7 . 0 3 2 3 4 5 e −06 2 . 9 7 2 1 0 7 e −05
2 6 . 1 6 8 4 6 7 e −01 3 . 8 1 7 7 1 8 e −01 2 . 7 9 7 3 1 3 e −06 1 . 3 7 8 7 1 5 e −03
3 7 . 7 8 4 8 3 6 e −01 1 . 9 9 0 5 1 0 e −01 1 . 6 8 8 0 9 8 e −02 5 . 5 8 4 4 4 5 e −03
4 5 . 9 6 2 9 4 9 e −01 3 . 9 8 8 5 8 8 e −01 5 . 0 1 8 3 4 6 e −04 4 . 3 4 4 3 9 2 e −03
5 9 . 8 1 5 2 8 6 e −01 1 . 6 9 4 7 2 1 e −02 1 . 4 4 2 3 5 0 e −03 8 . 1 7 9 2 3 0 e −05
6 9 . 2 7 1 1 5 0 e −01 6 . 3 3 0 1 0 4 e −02 4 . 9 1 6 9 6 6 e −03 4 . 6 6 6 9 6 4 e −03
7 4 . 5 1 5 7 2 1 e −01 9 . 3 0 3 6 6 7 e −02 3 . 4 8 8 8 9 8 e −02 4 . 2 0 5 0 2 3 e −01
8 8 . 2 1 0 6 3 1 e −01 1 . 5 3 0 7 2 1 e −01 7 . 6 3 1 7 7 0 e −03 1 . 8 2 3 3 0 2 e −02
9 1 . 5 6 7 8 0 4 e −01 9 . 3 7 5 0 7 5 e −02 6 . 4 1 3 6 9 3 e −01 1 . 0 8 0 9 9 6 e −01
10 8 . 4 0 3 3 5 7 e −01 9 . 7 9 3 1 3 5 e −03 1 . 3 9 6 3 9 3 e −01 1 . 0 2 3 1 8 6 e −02
11 9 . 1 6 3 7 8 9 e −01 6 . 7 4 7 9 4 6 e −02 7 . 8 4 7 3 8 0 e −05 1 . 6 0 6 3 1 6 e −02
12 2 . 4 4 8 8 5 0 e −01 4 . 2 5 6 0 0 1 e −01 2 . 8 8 0 8 0 3 e −01 4 . 1 4 3 4 6 3 e −02
13 1 . 0 4 0 3 5 2 e −01 1 . 5 3 4 2 7 2 e −01 1 . 3 6 9 5 5 4 e −01 6 . 0 5 5 8 2 2 e −01
14 8 . 4 6 8 7 5 5 e −01 1 . 5 0 6 3 1 1 e −01 5 . 0 8 3 4 8 0 e −04 1 . 9 8 5 0 3 6 e −03
15 7 . 1 3 6 0 4 8 e −01 1 . 2 9 4 1 4 6 e −01 7 . 3 8 5 2 9 4 e −02 8 . 3 1 2 7 7 0 e −02
16 9 . 8 8 5 4 3 9 e −01 1 . 1 1 4 5 4 7 e −02 2 . 1 8 7 3 1 1 e −05 2 . 8 8 7 2 5 6 e −04
17 6 . 4 7 8 0 7 4 e −02 3 . 5 4 7 0 7 2 e −01 1 . 9 8 8 9 9 3 e −01 3 . 8 1 6 1 2 7 e −01
18 4 . 4 1 4 7 2 1 e −01 4 . 4 9 7 2 2 8 e −01 4 . 7 1 6 5 5 0 e −02 6 . 1 6 3 9 5 6 e −02
19 6 . 0 2 4 5 0 8 e −03 3 . 6 0 8 2 7 0 e −01 7 . 8 3 7 0 8 7 e −02 5 . 5 4 7 7 7 7 e −01
20 4 . 5 5 3 2 0 5 e −01 4 . 2 7 0 4 9 9 e −01 3 . 6 1 4 8 6 3 e −04 1 . 1 7 2 6 8 1 e −01
21 1 . 3 4 2 1 2 2 e −01 8 . 6 2 7 9 1 1 e −01 1 . 7 5 9 8 6 5 e −03 1 . 2 3 6 8 4 5 e −03
22 1 . 8 7 7 1 2 3 e −02 6 . 4 2 3 0 3 7 e −01 5 . 4 5 6 3 7 2 e −05 3 . 3 8 8 7 0 5 e −01
23 5 . 6 2 0 5 2 8 e −01 4 . 3 5 9 4 5 9 e −01 5 . 6 0 6 4 2 4 e −04 1 . 4 4 0 6 4 5 e −03
24 2 . 8 3 7 4 9 4 e −01 7 . 1 5 4 5 0 6 e −01 2 . 1 9 0 4 5 6 e −04 5 . 8 0 9 8 1 5 e −04
25 1 . 7 8 7 7 4 9 e −01 8 . 0 3 7 3 3 5 e −01 3 . 3 6 1 8 0 6 e −04 1 . 7 1 5 5 4 1 e −02
26 3 . 2 7 4 8 7 4 e −02 3 . 4 8 4 0 0 5 e −02 1 . 3 0 7 7 9 5 e −01 8 . 0 1 6 3 1 7 e −01
27 1 . 6 3 5 4 8 0 e −01 3 . 4 7 1 6 7 6 e −01 1 . 1 3 1 5 9 9 e −01 3 . 7 6 1 2 4 5 e −01
28 2 . 3 6 0 9 2 2 e −01 7 . 2 3 5 4 9 7 e −01 3 . 3 7 5 0 1 8 e −02 6 . 6 0 7 9 6 6 e −03
29 1 . 6 1 8 6 0 2 e −02 7 . 2 3 3 0 9 8 e −01 5 . 7 6 2 0 8 3 e −06 2 . 6 0 4 9 8 4 e −01
30 3 . 0 3 7 7 4 1 e −02 8 . 5 5 0 8 7 3 e −01 7 . 4 8 7 8 0 4 e −02 3 . 9 6 5 7 2 9 e −02
31 1 . 1 2 2 8 9 7 e −01 8 . 6 4 8 3 8 8 e −01 3 . 9 3 5 6 5 7 e −03 1 . 8 9 3 5 8 4 e −02
32 2 . 3 1 2 2 3 1 e −01 6 . 6 0 7 5 8 7 e −01 4 . 7 7 0 7 7 5 e −02 6 . 0 3 1 0 4 5 e −02
295
296
33
34
35
36
37
38
39
40
41
42
43
44
45
46
47
48
49
50
51
52
53
54
55
56
57
58
59
60
61
62
63
64
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
6 . 7 4 3 1 2 5 e −01
1 . 4 0 7 6 9 3 e −01
6 . 9 1 9 5 4 7 e −04
8 . 0 5 1 2 2 5 e −02
5 . 6 9 1 2 2 0 e −05
2 . 7 0 9 8 6 7 e −02
4 . 5 3 1 0 0 1 e −05
1 . 0 2 1 9 7 6 e −01
2 . 0 0 5 8 3 7 e −02
1 . 8 2 9 0 2 8 e −04
1 . 7 3 4 2 9 6 e −01
4 . 3 1 4 9 3 8 e −05
1 . 5 1 6 2 3 1 e −02
2 . 9 1 7 5 9 7 e −01
1 . 2 7 8 9 3 3 e −04
1 . 3 2 0 0 0 0 e −01
1 . 6 8 3 2 2 1 e −02
9 . 6 7 0 0 8 5 e −02
4 . 9 5 3 5 7 7 e −02
1 . 7 8 7 9 2 7 e −02
1 . 1 7 4 0 5 3 e −02
2 . 0 5 3 8 7 1 e −01
3 . 0 6 0 3 6 9 e −06
1 . 1 2 2 1 6 4 e −02
8 . 8 7 3 7 1 6 e −03
2 . 1 6 4 9 6 2 e −02
5 . 2 3 0 4 4 3 e −03
8 . 7 4 3 3 6 8 e −02
1 . 9 1 3 5 7 8 e −01
6 . 4 5 0 9 6 7 e −07
2 . 4 0 0 3 6 5 e −04
1 . 5 1 5 8 9 4 e −04
2 . 0 2 8 1 8 1 e −02
4 . 0 8 9 5 1 8 e −02
4 . 1 9 4 5 7 7 e −05
4 . 2 1 3 9 6 5 e −03
7 . 4 8 0 5 4 9 e −02
3 . 8 0 8 9 8 7 e −02
2 . 2 4 8 5 8 0 e −08
4 . 5 9 7 6 7 8 e −03
2 . 0 6 3 2 0 0 e −01
1 . 3 7 8 7 9 5 e −03
9 . 0 2 5 2 8 4 e −04
3 . 1 3 1 3 9 0 e −06
2 . 0 6 0 3 2 5 e −03
6 . 3 5 1 1 6 6 e −02
1 . 7 7 3 5 0 9 e −03
2 . 0 6 4 3 3 8 e −01
4 . 0 0 7 8 4 8 e −01
4 . 3 1 4 7 6 5 e −01
1 . 3 7 0 0 3 7 e −01
9 . 8 2 5 6 6 0 e −02
4 . 7 2 3 6 2 8 e −01
6 . 7 2 1 3 5 6 e −01
1 . 4 1 8 6 2 3 e −03
6 . 5 6 6 1 6 9 e −02
4 . 9 9 6 9 0 7 e −01
2 . 8 7 4 3 1 3 e −01
6 . 4 3 0 1 7 4 e −04
6 . 7 1 0 3 2 7 e −02
6 . 4 5 8 4 6 3 e −04
5 . 0 3 5 6 9 7 e −05
4 . 6 5 1 5 3 7 e −03
2 . 6 3 1 4 5 1 e −01
2 . 6 1 2 6 8 3 e −01
7 . 0 0 7 5 4 1 e −01
9 . 9 5 0 3 2 2 e −01
9 . 1 5 1 2 8 7 e −01
5 . 1 7 1 5 9 4 e −01
6 . 1 9 3 9 6 9 e −01
9 . 9 9 9 5 4 2 e −01
5 . 1 3 3 8 3 9 e −01
5 . 9 2 5 0 5 0 e −01
6 . 1 8 2 8 3 9 e −01
7 . 7 5 8 8 6 2 e −01
9 . 9 9 7 8 9 2 e −01
9 . 7 9 2 5 9 4 e −01
4 . 9 4 3 8 1 8 e −01
1 . 2 0 9 4 8 6 e −01
6 . 3 2 4 9 0 4 e −01
1 . 6 2 8 9 8 1 e −03
7 . 6 6 9 0 3 5 e −03
9 . 8 8 2 0 0 4 e −02
2 . 2 0 3 0 3 7 e −01
2 . 4 3 0 0 7 2 e −03
4 . 1 6 9 6 4 0 e −02
1 . 0 7 2 5 4 9 e −02
3 . 0 8 0 6 4 1 e −01
8 . 2 2 2 0 3 4 e −03
1 . 1 3 6 4 5 5 e −03
9 . 8 1 6 8 2 5 e −01
4 . 2 6 0 1 1 6 e −01
3 . 3 0 7 5 5 3 e −01
7 . 4 4 8 2 8 5 e −01
8 . 1 8 3 3 9 0 e −06
1 . 0 0 2 3 3 2 e −05
4 . 4 1 3 7 4 6 e −02
1 . 1 7 5 8 1 5 e −01
4 . 2 3 3 9 2 4 e −03
1 . 4 5 0 4 2 3 e −04
4 . 0 7 9 7 8 2 e −01
3 . 1 5 4 1 4 5 e −01
4 . 6 2 6 2 5 8 e −07
3 . 7 9 8 2 0 8 e −01
1 . 8 1 1 1 6 6 e −01
3 . 8 0 1 5 4 4 e −01
4 . 9 7 8 1 7 1 e −02
1 . 6 4 5 0 0 4 e −04
3 . 5 1 7 9 2 6 e −03
1 . 5 0 3 4 6 8 e −01
8 . 7 7 1 5 0 0 e −01
2 . 9 0 7 5 7 8 e −02
5 . 8 0 7 5 4 0 e −01
4 . 6 4 1 5 3 6 e −01
7 . 1 4 6 4 0 5 e −01
6 . 6 3 5 6 0 4 e −01
5 . 1 3 4 6 6 6 e −01
8 . 0 7 8 0 9 0 e −02
9 . 8 7 8 5 2 8 e −01
6 . 1 5 0 5 2 5 e −01
4 . 8 3 2 1 3 6 e −01
6 . 8 9 7 8 2 6 e −01
1 . 2 4 4 4 0 6 e −02
4 . 1 9 4 5 1 4 e −01
4 . 7 7 2 4 1 0 e −01
2 . 5 5 1 2 0 5 e −01
9 . 9 5 1 0 0 2 e −01
7 . 3 6 6 9 3 3 e −01
You can see from the results that the probability for category 1 is the
same as p0 . What this means is that we compute the other three probabilities, and the remaining is for the first category. We check that the
probabilities across each row for all four categories add up to 1:
> rowSums ( r e s $ f i t t e d . v a l u e s )
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25
1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1
26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 46 47 48 49 50
truncate and estimate: limited dependent variables
1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1
51 52 53 54 55 56 57 58 59 60 61 62 63 64
1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
11.6 Truncated Variables
Here we provide some basic results that we need later. And of course,
we need to revisit our Bayesian ideas again!
• Given a probability density f ( x ),
f ( x | x > a) =
f (x)
Pr ( x > a)
If we are using the normal distribution then this is:
f ( x | x > a) =
φ( x )
1 − Φ( a)
• If x ∼ N (µ, σ2 ), then
E( x | x > a) = µ + σ
φ(c)
,
1 − Φ(c)
c=
a−µ
σ
Note that this expectation is provided without proof, as are the next
few ones. For example if we let x be standard normal and we want
E([ x | x > −1], we have
> dnorm( − 1) / (1 −pnorm( − 1))
[ 1 ] 0.2876000
• For the same distribution
E( x | x < a) = µ + σ
−φ(c)
,
Φ(c)
c=
a−µ
σ
For example, E[ x | x < 1] is
> −dnorm ( 1 ) / pnorm ( 1 )
[ 1 ] − 0.2876000
φ(c)
−φ(c)
• Inverse Mills Ratio: The values 1−Φ(c) or Φ(c) as the case may be
is often shortened to the variable λ(c), which is also known as the
Inverse Mills Ratio.
1
297
298
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
• If y and x are correlated (with correlation ρ), and y ∼ N (µy , σy2 ), then
Pr (y, x | x > a) =
f (y, x )
Pr ( x > a)
E(y| x > a) = µy + σy ρλ(c),
c=
a−µ
σ
This leads naturally to the truncated regression model. Suppose we have
the usual regression model where
y = β0 x + e,
e ∼ N (0, σ2 )
But suppose we restrict attention in our model to values of y that are
greater than a cut off a. We can then write down by inspection the following correct model (no longer is the simple linear regression valid)
E(y|y > a) = β0 x + σ
φ[( a − β0 x )/σ]
1 − Φ[( a − β0 x )/σ ]
Therefore, when the sample is truncated, then we need to run the regression above, i.e., the usual right-hand side β0 x with an additional variable,
i.e., the Inverse Mill’s ratio. We look at this in a real-world example.
An Example: Limited Dependent Variables in VC Syndications
Not all venture-backed firms end up making a successful exit, either
via an IPO, through a buyout, or by means of another exit route. By
examining a large sample of firms, we can measure the probability of a
firm making a successful exit. By designating successful exits as S = 1,
and setting S = 0 otherwise, we use matrix X of explanatory variables
and fit a Probit model to the data. We define S to be based on a latent
threshold variable S∗ such that
(
1 if S∗ > 0
S=
(11.1)
0 if S∗ ≤ 0.
where the latent variable is modeled as
S∗ = γ0 X + u,
u ∼ N (0, σu2 )
(11.2)
The fitted model provides us the probability of exit, i.e., E(S), for all
financing rounds.
E(S) = E(S∗ > 0) = E(u > −γ0 X ) = 1 − Φ(−γ0 X ) = Φ(γ0 X ),
(11.3)
where γ is the vector of coefficients fitted in the Probit model, using
standard likelihood methods. The last expression in the equation above
follows from the use of normality in the Probit specification. Φ(.) denotes the cumulative normal distribution.
truncate and estimate: limited dependent variables
11.6.1
Endogeneity
Suppose we want to examine the role of syndication in venture success.
Success in a syndicated venture comes from two broad sources of VC
expertise. First, VCs are experienced in picking good projects to invest
in, and syndicates are efficient vehicles for picking good firms; this is the
selection hypothesis put forth by Lerner (1994). Amongst two projects
that appear a-priori similar in prospects, the fact that one of them is
selected by a syndicate is evidence that the project is of better quality
(ex-post to being vetted by the syndicate, but ex-ante to effort added by
the VCs), since the process of syndication effectively entails getting a
second opinion by the lead VC. Second, syndicates may provide better
monitoring as they bring a wide range of skills to the venture, and this is
suggested in the value-added hypothesis of Brander, Amit and Antweiler
(2002).
A regression of venture returns on various firm characteristics and a
dummy variable for syndication allows a first pass estimate of whether
syndication impacts performance. However, it may be that syndicated
firms are simply of higher quality and deliver better performance, whether
or not they chose to syndicate. Better firms are more likely to syndicate
because VCs tend to prefer such firms and can identify them. In this
case, the coefficient on the dummy variable might reveal a value-add
from syndication, when indeed, there is none. Hence, we correct the
specification for endogeneity, and then examine whether the dummy
variable remains significant.
Greene (2011) provides the correction for endogeneity required here.
We briefly summarize the model required. The performance regression
is of the form:
Y = β0 X + δS + e, e ∼ N (0, σe2 )
(11.4)
where Y is the performance variable; S is, as before, the dummy variable
taking a value of 1 if the firm is syndicated, and zero otherwise, and
δ is a coefficient that determines whether performance is different on
account of syndication. If it is not, then it implies that the variables X
are sufficient to explain the differential performance across firms, or that
there is no differential performance across the two types of firms.
However, since these same variables determine also, whether the firm
syndicates or not, we have an endogeneity issue which is resolved by
adding a correction to the model above. The error term e is affected
by censoring bias in the subsamples of syndicated and non-syndicated
299
300
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
firms. When S = 1, i.e. when the firm’s financing is syndicated, then the
residual e has the following expectation
φ(γ0 X )
. (11.5)
E(e|S = 1) = E(e|S∗ > 0) = E(e|u > −γ0 X ) = ρσe
Φ(γ0 X )
where ρ = Corr (e, u), and σe is the standard deviation of e. This implies
that
φ(γ0 X )
0
E(Y |S = 1) = β X + δ + ρσe
.
(11.6)
Φ(γ0 X )
Note that φ(−γ0 X ) = φ(γ0 X ), and 1 − Φ(−γ0 X ) = Φ(γ0 X ). For estimation purposes, we write this as the following regression equation:
Y = δ + β0 X + β m m(γ0 X )
(11.7)
φ(γ0 X )
Φ(γ0 X )
where m(γ0 X ) =
and β m = ρσe . Thus, {δ, β, β m } are the coefficients estimated in the regression. (Note here that m(γ0 X ) is also known
as the inverse Mill’s ratio.)
Likewise, for firms that are not syndicated, we have the following
result
−φ(γ0 X )
0
E(Y |S = 0) = β X + ρσe
.
(11.8)
1 − Φ(γ0 X )
This may also be estimated by linear cross-sectional regression.
Y = β0 X + β m m0 (γ0 X )
(11.9)
−φ(γ0 X )
where m0 = 1−Φ(γ0 X ) and β m = ρσe .
The estimation model will take the form of a stacked linear regression
comprising both equations (11.7) and (11.9). This forces β to be the same
across all firms without necessitating additional constraints, and allows
the specification to remain within the simple OLS form. If δ is significant
after this endogeneity correction, then the empirical evidence supports
the hypothesis that syndication is a driver of differential performance.
If the coefficients {δ, β m } are significant, then the expected difference in
performance for each syndicated financing round (i, j) is
h
i
δ + β m m(γij0 Xij ) − m0 (γij0 Xij ) , ∀i, j.
(11.10)
The method above forms one possible approach to addressing treatment
effects. Another approach is to estimate a Probit model first, and then
to set m(γ0 X ) = Φ(γ0 X ). This is known as the instrumental variables
approach.
The regression may be run using the sampleSelection package in R.
Sample selection models correct for the fact that two subsamples may be
different because of treatment effects.
truncate and estimate: limited dependent variables
11.6.2
Example: Women in the Labor Market
After loading in the package sampleSelection we can use the data set
called Mroz87. This contains labour market participation data for women
as well as wage levels for women. If we are explaining what drives
women’s wages we can simply run the following regression.
> library ( sampleSelection )
> data ( Mroz87 )
> summary ( Mroz87 )
lfp
hours
kids5
kids618
Min .
:0.0000
Min .
:
0.0
Min .
:0.0000
Min .
:0.000
1 s t Qu . : 0 . 0 0 0 0
1 s t Qu . :
0.0
1 s t Qu . : 0 . 0 0 0 0
1 s t Qu . : 0 . 0 0 0
Median : 1 . 0 0 0 0
Median : 2 8 8 . 0
Median : 0 . 0 0 0 0
Median : 1 . 0 0 0
Mean
:0.5684
Mean
: 740.6
Mean
:0.2377
Mean
:1.353
3 rd Qu . : 1 . 0 0 0 0
3 rd Qu . : 1 5 1 6 . 0
3 rd Qu . : 0 . 0 0 0 0
3 rd Qu . : 2 . 0 0 0
Max .
:1.0000
Max .
:4950.0
Max .
:3.0000
Max .
:8.000
age
educ
wage
repwage
Min .
:30.00
Min .
: 5.00
Min .
: 0.000
Min .
:0.000
1 s t Qu . : 3 6 . 0 0
1 s t Qu . : 1 2 . 0 0
1 s t Qu . : 0 . 0 0 0
1 s t Qu . : 0 . 0 0 0
Median : 4 3 . 0 0
Median : 1 2 . 0 0
Median : 1 . 6 2 5
Median : 0 . 0 0 0
Mean
:42.54
Mean
:12.29
Mean
: 2.375
Mean
:1.850
3 rd Qu . : 4 9 . 0 0
3 rd Qu . : 1 3 . 0 0
3 rd Qu . : 3 . 7 8 8
3 rd Qu . : 3 . 5 8 0
Max .
:60.00
Max .
:17.00
Max .
:25.000
Max .
:9.980
hushrs
husage
huseduc
huswage
Min .
: 175
Min .
:30.00
Min .
: 3.00
Min .
: 0.4121
1 s t Qu. : 1 9 2 8
1 s t Qu . : 3 8 . 0 0
1 s t Qu . : 1 1 . 0 0
1 s t Qu . : 4 . 7 8 8 3
Median : 2 1 6 4
Median : 4 6 . 0 0
Median : 1 2 . 0 0
Median : 6 . 9 7 5 8
Mean
:2267
Mean
:45.12
Mean
:12.49
Mean
: 7.4822
3 rd Qu. : 2 5 5 3
3 rd Qu . : 5 2 . 0 0
3 rd Qu . : 1 5 . 0 0
3 rd Qu . : 9 . 1 6 6 7
Max .
:5010
Max .
:60.00
Max .
:17.00
Max .
:40.5090
faminc
mtr
motheduc
fatheduc
Min .
: 1500
Min .
:0.4415
Min .
: 0.000
Min .
: 0.000
1 s t Qu. : 1 5 4 2 8
1 s t Qu . : 0 . 6 2 1 5
1 s t Qu . : 7 . 0 0 0
1 s t Qu . : 7 . 0 0 0
Median : 2 0 8 8 0
Median : 0 . 6 9 1 5
Median : 1 0 . 0 0 0
Median : 7 . 0 0 0
Mean
:23081
Mean
:0.6789
Mean
: 9.251
Mean
: 8.809
3 rd Qu. : 2 8 2 0 0
3 rd Qu . : 0 . 7 2 1 5
3 rd Qu . : 1 2 . 0 0 0
3 rd Qu . : 1 2 . 0 0 0
Max .
:96000
Max .
:0.9415
Max .
:17.000
Max .
:17.000
unem
city
exper
nwifeinc
Min .
: 3.000
Min .
:0.0000
Min .
: 0.00
Min .
: − 0.02906
1 s t Qu . : 7 . 5 0 0
1 s t Qu . : 0 . 0 0 0 0
1 s t Qu . : 4 . 0 0
1 s t Qu. : 1 3 . 0 2 5 0 4
Median : 7 . 5 0 0
Median : 1 . 0 0 0 0
Median : 9 . 0 0
Median : 1 7 . 7 0 0 0 0
Mean
: 8.624
Mean
:0.6428
Mean
:10.63
Mean
:20.12896
3 rd Qu . : 1 1 . 0 0 0
3 rd Qu . : 1 . 0 0 0 0
3 rd Qu . : 1 5 . 0 0
3 rd Qu. : 2 4 . 4 6 6 0 0
Max .
:14.000
Max .
:1.0000
Max .
:45.00
Max .
:96.00000
wifecoll
huscoll
kids
TRUE: 2 1 2
TRUE: 2 9 5
Mode : l o g i c a l
FALSE : 5 4 1
FALSE : 4 5 8
FALSE : 2 2 9
TRUE : 5 2 4
> r e s = lm ( wage ~ age + I ( age ^2) + educ + c i t y , data=Mroz87 )
> summary ( r e s )
Call :
lm ( formula = wage ~ age + I ( age ^2) + educ + c i t y , data = Mroz87 )
Residuals :
Min
1Q Median
− 4.6805 − 2.1919 − 0.4575
3Q
Max
1.3588 22.6903
Coefficients :
E s t i m a t e Std . E r r o r t value Pr ( >| t |)
301
302
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
( I n t e r c e p t ) − 8.499373
age
0.252758
I ( age ^2)
− 0.002918
educ
0.450873
city
0.080852
−−−
S i g n i f . codes : 0 Ô* * *Õ
3.296628
0.152719
0.001761
0.050306
0.238852
− 2.578
1.655
− 1.657
8.963
0.339
0.0101
0.0983
0.0980
<2e −16
0.7351
*
.
.
***
0 . 0 0 1 Ô* *Õ 0 . 0 1 Ô*Õ 0 . 0 5 Ô.Õ 0 . 1 Ô Õ 1
R e s i d u a l standard e r r o r : 3 . 0 7 5 on 748 degrees o f freedom
M u l t i p l e R−squared : 0 . 1 0 4 9 ,
Adjusted R−squared : 0 . 1 0 0 1
F− s t a t i s t i c : 2 1 . 9 1 on 4 and 748 DF , p−value : < 2 . 2 e −16
So, education matters. But since education also determines labor force
participation (variable lfp) it may just be that we can use lfp instead.
Let’s try that.
> r e s = lm ( wage ~ age + I ( age ^2) + l f p + c i t y , data=Mroz87 )
> summary ( r e s )
Call :
lm ( formula = wage ~ age + I ( age ^2) + l f p + c i t y , data = Mroz87 )
Residuals :
Min
1Q Median
− 4.1808 − 0.9884 − 0.1615
3Q
Max
0.3090 20.6810
Coefficients :
E s t i m a t e Std . E r r o r t value Pr ( >| t |)
( I n t e r c e p t ) − 4.558 e −01 2 . 6 0 6 e +00 − 0.175
0.8612
age
3 . 0 5 2 e −03 1 . 2 4 0 e −01
0.025
0.9804
I ( age ^2)
1 . 2 8 8 e −05 1 . 4 3 1 e −03
0.009
0.9928
lfp
4 . 1 8 6 e +00 1 . 8 4 5 e −01 2 2 . 6 9 0
<2e −16 * * *
city
4 . 6 2 2 e −01 1 . 9 0 5 e −01
2.426
0.0155 *
−−−
S i g n i f . codes : 0 Ô* * *Õ 0 . 0 0 1 Ô* *Õ 0 . 0 1 Ô*Õ 0 . 0 5 Ô.Õ 0 . 1 Ô Õ 1
R e s i d u a l standard e r r o r : 2 . 4 9 1 on 748 degrees o f freedom
M u l t i p l e R−squared : 0 . 4 1 2 9 ,
Adjusted R−squared : 0 . 4 0 9 7
F− s t a t i s t i c : 1 3 1 . 5 on 4 and 748 DF , p−value : < 2 . 2 e −16
> r e s = lm ( wage ~ age + I ( age ^2) + l f p + educ + c i t y , data=Mroz87 )
> summary ( r e s )
Call :
lm ( formula = wage ~ age + I ( age ^2) + l f p + educ + c i t y , data = Mroz87 )
Residuals :
Min
1Q Median
− 4.9895 − 1.1034 − 0.1820
3Q
Max
0.4646 21.0160
Coefficients :
E s t i m a t e Std . E r r o r t value Pr ( >| t |)
( I n t e r c e p t ) − 4.7137850 2 . 5 8 8 2 4 3 5 − 1.821
0.069 .
age
0.0395656 0.1200320
0.330
0.742
I ( age ^2)
− 0.0002938 0 . 0 0 1 3 8 4 9 − 0.212
0.832
lfp
3 . 9 4 3 9 5 5 2 0 . 1 8 1 5 3 5 0 2 1 . 7 2 6 < 2e −16 * * *
educ
0.2906869 0.0400905
7 . 2 5 1 1 . 0 4 e −12 * * *
city
0.2219959 0.1872141
1.186
0.236
−−−
S i g n i f . codes : 0 Ô* * *Õ 0 . 0 0 1 Ô* *Õ 0 . 0 1 Ô*Õ 0 . 0 5 Ô.Õ 0 . 1 Ô Õ 1
truncate and estimate: limited dependent variables
R e s i d u a l standard e r r o r : 2 . 4 0 9 on 747 degrees o f freedom
M u l t i p l e R−squared : 0 . 4 5 1 5 ,
Adjusted R−squared : 0 . 4 4 7 8
F− s t a t i s t i c :
123 on 5 and 747 DF , p−value : < 2 . 2 e −16
In fact, it seems like both matter, but we should use the selection equation approach of Heckman, in two stages.
> r e s = s e l e c t i o n ( l f p ~ age + I ( age ^2) + faminc + k i d s + educ ,
wage ~ exper + I ( exper ^2) + educ + c i t y , data=Mroz87 , method = " 2 s t e p " )
> summary ( r e s )
−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−
T o b i t 2 model ( sample s e l e c t i o n model )
2− s t e p Heckman / h e c k i t e s t i m a t i o n
753 o b s e r v a t i o n s ( 3 2 5 censored and 428 observed )
and 14 f r e e parameters ( df = 7 4 0 )
Probit s e l e c t i o n equation :
E s t i m a t e Std . E r r o r t value Pr ( >| t |)
( I n t e r c e p t ) − 4.157 e +00 1 . 4 0 2 e +00 − 2.965 0 . 0 0 3 1 2 7 * *
age
1 . 8 5 4 e −01 6 . 5 9 7 e −02
2.810 0.005078 * *
I ( age ^2)
− 2.426 e −03 7 . 7 3 5 e −04 − 3.136 0 . 0 0 1 7 8 0 * *
faminc
4 . 5 8 0 e −06 4 . 2 0 6 e −06
1.089 0.276544
kidsTRUE
− 4.490 e −01 1 . 3 0 9 e −01 − 3.430 0 . 0 0 0 6 3 8 * * *
educ
9 . 8 1 8 e −02 2 . 2 9 8 e −02
4 . 2 7 2 2 . 1 9 e −05 * * *
Outcome e q u a t i o n :
E s t i m a t e Std . E r r o r t value Pr ( >| t |)
( I n t e r c e p t ) − 0.9712003 2 . 0 5 9 3 5 0 5 − 0.472
0.637
exper
0.0210610 0.0624646
0.337
0.736
I ( exper ^2)
0.0001371 0.0018782
0.073
0.942
educ
0.4170174 0.1002497
4 . 1 6 0 3 . 5 6 e −05 * * *
city
0.4438379 0.3158984
1.405
0.160
M u l t i p l e R−Squared : 0 . 1 2 6 4 ,
Adjusted R−Squared : 0 . 1 1 6
E r r o r terms :
E s t i m a t e Std . E r r o r t value Pr ( >| t |)
invMillsRatio
− 1.098
1 . 2 6 6 − 0.867
0.386
sigma
3.200
NA
NA
NA
rho
− 0.343
NA
NA
NA
−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−
11.6.3
Endogeity – Some Theory to Wrap Up
Endogeneity may be technically expressed as arising from a correlation
of the independent variables and the error term in a regression. This can
be stated as:
Y = β0 X + u, E( X · u) 6= 0
This can happen in many ways:
1. Measurement error: If X is measured in error, we have X̃ = X + e. The
the regression becomes
Y = β 0 + β 1 ( X̃ − e) + u = β 0 + β 1 X̃ + (u − β 1 e) = β 0 + β 1 X̃ + v
We see that
E( X̃ · v) = E[( X + e)(u − β 1 e)] = − β 1 E(e2 ) = − β 1 Var (e) 6= 0
303
304
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
2. Omitted variables: Suppose the true model is
Y = β 0 + β 1 X1 + β 2 X2 + u
but we do not have X2 , which happens to be correlated with X1 , then
it will be subsumed in the error term and no longer will E( Xi · u) =
0, ∀i.
3. Simultaneity: This occurs when Y and X are jointly determined. For
example, high wages and high education go together. Or, advertising
and sales coincide. Or that better start-up firms tend to receive syndication. The structural form of these settings may be written as:
Y = β 0 + β 1 X + u,
X = α0 + α1 Y + v
The solution to these equations gives the reduced-form version of the
model.
Y=
βv + u
β 0 + β 1 α0
+
,
1 − α1 β 1
1 − α1 β 1
X=
α0 + α1 β 0
v + α1 u
+
1 − α1 β 1
1 − α1 β 1
From which we can compute the endogeneity result.
v + α1 u
α1
Cov( X, u) = Cov
,u =
· Var (u)
1 − α1 β 1
1 − α1 β 1
12
Riding the Wave: Fourier Analysis
12.1 Introduction
Fourier analysis comprises many different connnections between infinite
series, complex numbers, vector theory, and geometry. We may think
of different applications: (a) fitting economic time series, (b) pricing options, (c) wavelets, (d) obtaining risk-neutral pricing distributions via
Fourier inversion.
12.2 Fourier Series
12.2.1
Basic stuff
Fourier series are used to represent periodic time series by combinations
of sine and cosine waves. The time it takes for one cycle of the wave is
called the “period” T of the wave. The “frequency” f of the wave is the
number of cycles per second, hence,
f =
12.2.2
1
T
The unit circle
We need some basic geometry on the unit circle.
306
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
a
a sin!
!
a cos!
This circle is the unit circle if a = 1. There is a nice link between the unit
circle and the sine wave. See the next figure for this relationship.
+1
f(!)
!
"
2"
-1
Hence, as we rotate through the angles, the height of the unit vector on
the circle traces out the sine wave. In general for radius a, we get a sine
wave with amplitude a, or we may write:
f (θ ) = a sin(θ )
12.2.3
(12.1)
Angular velocity
Velocity is distance per time (in a given direction). For angular velocity
we measure distance in degrees, i.e. degrees per unit of time. The usual
symbol for angular velocity is ω. We can thus write
ω=
θ
,
T
θ = ωT
Hence, we can state the function in equation (12.1) in terms of time as
follows
f (t) = a sin ωt
riding the wave: fourier analysis
12.2.4
Fourier series
A Fourier series is a collection of sine and cosine waves, which when
summed up, closely approximate any given waveform. We can express
the Fourier series in terms of sine and cosine waves
∞
f ( θ ) = a0 +
∑ (an cos nθ + bn sin nθ )
n =1
∞
f ( t ) = a0 +
∑ (an cos nωt + bn sin nωt)
n =1
The a0 is needed since the waves may not be symmetric around the xaxis.
12.2.5
Radians
Degrees are expressed in units of radians. A radian is an angle defined
in the following figure.
a
a
a
The angle here is a radian which is equal to 57.2958 degrees (approximately). This is slightly less than 60 degrees as you would expect to get
with an equilateral triangle. Note that (since the circumference is 2πa)
57.2958π = 57.2958 × 3.142 = 180 degrees.
So now for the unit circle
2π = 360 (degrees)
360
ω =
T
2π
ω =
T
Hence, we may rewrite the Fourier series equation as:
∞
f ( t ) = a0 +
∑ (an cos nωt + bn sin nωt)
n =1
∞ = a0 +
∑
n =1
2πn
2πn
an cos
t + bn sin
t
T
T
So we now need to figure out how to get the coefficients { a0 , an , bn }.
307
308
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
12.2.6
Solving for the coefficients
We start by noting the interesting phenomenon that sines and cosines are
orthogonal, i.e. their inner product is zero. Hence,
Z T
0
sin(nt). cos(mt) dt = 0, ∀n, m
(12.2)
sin(nt). sin(mt) dt = 0, ∀n 6= m
(12.3)
cos(nt). cos(mt) dt = 0, ∀n 6= m
(12.4)
Z T
0
Z T
0
What this means is that when we multiply one wave by another, and
then integrate the resultant wave from 0 to T (i.e. over any cycle, so we
could go from say − T/2 to + T/2 also), then we get zero, unless the two
waves have the same frequency. Hence, the way we get the coefficients
of the Fourier series is as follows. Integrate both sides of the series in
equation (12.2) from 0 to T, i.e.
"
#
Z
Z
Z
T
0
f (t) =
T
0
a0 dt +
∞
T
∑ (an cos nωt + bn sin nωt)
0
dt
n =1
Except for the first term all the remaining terms are zero (integrating a
sine or cosine wave over its cycle gives net zero). So we get
Z T
0
or
f (t) dt = a0 T
Z T
1
T
Now lets try another integral, i.e.
a0 =
Z T
0
f (t) cos(ωt) =
0
f (t) dt
Z T
0
+
a0 cos(ωt) dt
"
Z
T
0
∞
∑ (an cos nωt + bn sin nωt) cos(ωt) dt
#
n =1
Here, all terms are zero except for the term in a1 cos(ωt) cos(ωt), because we are multiplying two waves (pointwise) that have the same frequency. So we get
Z T
0
f (t) cos(ωt) =
Z T
0
= a1
a1 cos(ωt) cos(ωt) dt
T
2
riding the wave: fourier analysis
How? Note here that for unit amplitude, integrating cos(ωt) over one
cycle will give zero. If we multiply cos(ωt) by itself, we flip all the wave
segments from below to above the zero line. The product wave now fills
out half the area from 0 to T, so we get T/2. Thus
a1 =
2
T
Z T
f (t) cos(ωt)
0
We can get all an this way - just multiply by cos(nωt) and integrate. We
can also get all bn this way - just multiply by sin(nωt) and integrate.
This forms the basis of the following summary results that give the
coefficients of the Fourier series.
a0 =
an =
bn =
1
T
Z T/2
f (t) dt =
− T/2
Z T/2
1
T
Z T
0
f (t) dt
1
f (t) cos(nωt) dt =
T/2 −T/2
Z T/2
1
f (t) sin(nωt) dt =
T/2 −T/2
(12.5)
2 T
f (t) cos(nωt) dt (12.6)
T 0
Z
2 T
f (t) sin(nωt) dt (12.7)
T 0
Z
12.3 Complex Algebra
Just for fun, recall that
∞
e=
and
eiθ =
1
.
n!
n =0
∑
∞
1
(iθ )n
n!
n =0
∑
1
1 2
θ + 0.θ 3 + θ 2 + . . .
2!
4!
1
i sin(θ ) = 0 + iθ + 0.θ 2 − iθ 3 + 0.θ 4 + . . .
3!
cos(θ ) = 1 + 0.θ −
Which leads into the famous Euler’s formula:
eiθ = cos θ + i sin θ
(12.8)
e−iθ = cos θ − i sin θ
(12.9)
and the corresponding
Recall also that cos(−θ ) = cos(θ ). And sin(−θ ) = − sin(θ ). Note also
that if θ = π, then
e−iπ = cos(π ) − i sin(π ) = −1 + 0
309
310
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
which can be written as
e−iπ + 1 = 0
an equation that contains five fundamental mathematical constants:
{i, π, e, 0, 1}, and three operators {+, −, =}.
12.3.1
From Trig to Complex
Using equations (12.8) and (12.9) gives
cos θ =
sin θ =
1 iθ
(e + e−iθ )
2
1 iθ
i (e − e−iθ )
2
(12.10)
(12.11)
Now, return to the Fourier series,
∞
f ( t ) = a0 +
∑ (an cos nωt + bn sin nωt)
(12.12)
n =1
∞ 1 inωt
1 inωt
−inωt
−inωt
+e
) + bn ( e
−e
) (12.13)
= a0 + ∑ a n ( e
2
2i
n =1
∞ = a0 + ∑ An einωt + Bn e−inωt
(12.14)
n =1
where
1 T
f (t)e−inωt dt
T 0
Z
1 T
Bn =
f (t)einωt dt
T 0
Z
An =
How? Start with
∞
f ( t ) = a0 +
∑
∞
n =1
1
1
an (einωt + e−inωt ) + bn (einωt − e−inωt )
2
2i
Then
n =1
1
i
an (einωt + e−inωt ) + bn 2 (einωt − e−inωt )
2
2i
∑
f ( t ) = a0 +
∞
= a0 +
∑
n =1
1
i inωt
an (einωt + e−inωt ) + bn
(e
− e−inωt )
2
−2
∞
f ( t ) = a0 +
∑
n =1
1
1
( an − ibn )einωt + ( an + ibn )e−inωt
2
2
(12.15)
riding the wave: fourier analysis
Note that from equations (12.8) and (12.9),
an =
=
an =
2 T
f (t) cos(nωt) dt
T 0
Z
2 T
1
f (t) [einωt + e−inωt ] dt
T 0
2
Z
1 T
f (t)[einωt + e−inωt ] dt
T 0
Z
(12.16)
(12.17)
(12.18)
In the same way, we can handle bn , to get
bn =
=
=
2 T
f (t) sin(nωt) dt
T 0
Z
2 T
1
f (t) [einωt − e−inωt ] dt
T 0
2i
Z T
11
f (t)[einωt − e−inωt ] dt
iT 0
Z
(12.19)
(12.20)
(12.21)
So that
1 T
f (t)[einωt − e−inωt ] dt
ibn =
T 0
So from equations (12.18) and (12.22), we get
Z
1
( an − ibn ) =
2
1
( an + ibn ) =
2
1 T
f (t)e−inωt dt ≡ An
T 0
Z
1 T
f (t)einωt dt ≡ Bn
T 0
Z
(12.22)
(12.23)
(12.24)
Put these back into equation (12.15) to get
∞ ∞ 1
1
inωt
−inωt
( an − ibn )e
+ ( an + ibn )e
= a0 + ∑ An einωt + Bn e−inωt
f ( t ) = a0 + ∑
2
2
n =1
n =1
(12.25)
12.3.2
Getting rid of a0
Note that if we expand the range of the first summation to start from
n = 0, then we have a term A0 ei0ωt = A0 ≡ a0 . So we can then write our
expression as
∞
f (t) =
∑
An einωt +
n =0
12.3.3
∞
∑ Bn e−inωt (sum of A runs from zero)
n =1
Collapsing and Simplifying
So now we want to collapse these two terms together. Lets note that
2
−1
n =1
n=−2
∑ x n = x1 + x2 = ∑
x −n = x2 + x1
311
312
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
Applying this idea, we get
∞
f (t) =
∑
An einωt +
∑
An einωt +
n =0
∞
=
n =0
∞
∑ Bn e−inωt
n =1
−1
∑
n=−∞
(12.26)
B(−n) einωt
(12.27)
where
B(−n) =
∞
∑
=
1
T
Z T
0
f (t)e−inωt dt = An
Cn einωt
n=−∞
(12.28)
where
Z
1 T
f (t)e−inωt dt
Cn =
T 0
where we just renamed An to Cn for clarity. The big win here is that we
have been able to subsume { a0 , an , bn } all into one coefficient set Cn . For
completeness we write
f ( t ) = a0 +
∞
∞
n =1
n=−∞
∑ (an cos nωt + bn sin nωt) = ∑
Cn einωt
This is the complex number representation of the Fourier series.
12.4 Fourier Transform
The FT is a cool technique that allows us to go from the Fourier series,
which needs a period T to waves that are aperiodic. The idea is to simply let the period go to infinity. Which means the frequency gets very
small. We can then sample a slice of the wave to do analysis.
We will replace f (t) with g(t) because we now need to use f or ∆ f to
denote frequency. Recall that
ω=
2π
= 2π f ,
T
nω = 2π f n
To recap
∞
g(t) =
Cn =
∑
n=−∞
Z
1 T
T
0
Cn einωt =
∞
∑
n=−∞
Cn ei2π f t
g(t)e−inωt dt
This may be written alternatively in frequency terms as follows
Cn = ∆ f
Z T/2
− T/2
g(t)e−i2π f n t dt
(12.29)
(12.30)
riding the wave: fourier analysis
which we substitute into the formula for g(t) and get
Z T/2
∞ g(t) = ∑ ∆ f
g(t)e−i2π f n t dt einωt
− T/2
n=−∞
Taking limits
∞
∑
g(t) = lim
T/2
Z
T →∞ n=−∞
− T/2
g(t)e
−i2π f n t
dt ei2π f n t ∆ f
gives a double integral
g(t) =
Z ∞ Z ∞
g(t)e−i2π f t dt ei2π f t d f
−∞
−∞
{z
}
|
G( f )
The dt is for the time domain and the d f for the frequency domain.
Hence, the Fourier transform goes from the time domain into the frequency domain, given by
G( f ) =
Z ∞
−∞
g(t)e−i2π f t dt
The inverse Fourier transform goes from the frequency domain into the
time domain
Z ∞
g(t) =
G ( f )ei2π f t d f
−∞
And the Fourier coefficients are as before
Cn =
1
T
Z T
0
g(t)e−i2π f n t dt =
1
T
Z T
0
g(t)e−inωt dt
Notice the incredible similarity between the coefficients and the transform. Note the following:
• The coefficients give the amplitude of each component wave.
• The transform gives the area of component waves of frequency f . You
can see this because the transform does not have the divide by T in it.
• The transform gives for any frequency f , the rate of occurrence of the
component wave with that frequency, relative to other waves.
• In short, the Fourier transform breaks a complicated, aperiodic wave
into simple periodic ones.
The spectrum of a wave is a graph showing its component frequencies, i.e. the quantity in which they occur. It is the frequency components
of the waves. But it does not give their amplitudes.
313
314
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
12.4.1
Empirical Example
We can use the Fourier transform function in R to compute the main
component frequencies of the times series of interest rate data as follows:
> rd = read.table("tryrates.txt",header=TRUE)
> r1 = as.matrix(rd[4])
> plot(r1,type="l")
> dr1 = resid(lm(r1 ~ seq(along = r1)))
> plot(dr1,type="l")
> y=fft(dr1)
> plot(abs(y),type="l")
The line with
dr1 = resid(lm(r1 ~ seq(along = r1)))
detrends the series, and when we plot it we see that its done. We can
then subject the detrended line to fourier analysis.
The plot of the fit of the detrended one-year interest rates is here:
riding the wave: fourier analysis
Its easy to see that the series has short frequencies and long frequencies.
Essentially there are two factors. If we do a factor analysis of interest
rates, it turns out we get two factors as well.
12.5 Application to Binomial Option Pricing
To implement the option pricing in Cerny, Exhibit 8.
> ifft = function(x) { fft(x,inverse=TRUE)/length(x) }
> ct = c(599.64,102,0,0)
> q = c(0.43523,0.56477,0,0)
> R = 1.0033
> ifft(fft(ct)*( (4*ifft(q)/R)^3) )
[1]
81.36464+0i 115.28447-0i 265.46949+0i 232.62076-0i
315
316
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
12.6 Application to probability functions
12.6.1
Characteristic functions
A characteristic function of a variable x is given by the expectation of the
following function of x:
φ(s) = E[eisx ] =
Z ∞
−∞
eisx f ( x ) dx
where f ( x ) is the probability density of x. By Taylor series for eisx we
have
Z ∞
Z ∞
1
eisx f ( x ) dx =
[1 + isx + (isx )2 + . . .] f ( x )dx
2
−∞
−∞
∞
j
(is)
= ∑
mj
j!
j =0
1
1
= 1 + (is)m1 + (is)2 m2 + (is)3 m3 + . . .
2
6
where m j is the j-th moment.
It is therefore easy to see that
1 dφ(s)
mj = j
ds s=0
i
√
where i = −1.
12.6.2
Finance application
In a paper in 1993, Steve Heston developed a new approach to valuing
stock and foreign currency options using a Fourier inversion technique.
See also Duffie, Pan and Singleton (2001) for extension to jumps, and
Chacko and Das (2002) for a generalization of this to interest-rate derivatives with jumps.
Lets explore a much simpler model of the same so as to get the idea
of how we can get at probability functions if we are given a stochastic
process for any security. When we are thinking of a dynamically moving
financial variable (say xt ), we are usually interested in knowing what the
probability is of this variable reaching a value xτ at time t = τ, given
that right now, it has value x0 at time t = 0. Note that τ is the remaining
time to maturity.
Suppose we have the following financial variable xt following a very
simple Brownian motion, i.e.
dxt = µ dt + σ dzt
riding the wave: fourier analysis
Here, µ is known as its “drift" and “sigma” is the volatility. The differential equation above gives the movement of the variable x and the term dz
is a Brownian motion, and is a random variable with normal distribution
of mean zero, and variance dt.
What we are interested in is the characteristic function of this process.
The characteristic function of x is defined as the Fourier transform of x,
i.e.
Z
isx
F ( x ) = E[e ] = eisx f ( x )ds
√
where s is the Fourier variable of integration, and i = −1, as usual.
Notice the similarity to the Fourier transforms described earlier in the
note. It turns out that once we have the characteristic function, then we
can obtain by simple calculations the probability function for x, as well
as all the moments of x.
12.6.3
Solving for the characteristic function
We write the characteristic function as F ( x, τ; s). Then, using Ito’s lemma
we have
1
dF = Fx dx + Fxx (dx )2 − Fτ dt
2
Fx is the first derivative of F with respect to x; Fxx is the second derivative, and Fτ is the derivative with respect to remaining maturity. Since F
is a characteristic (probability) function, the expected change in F is zero.
1
E(dF ) = µFx dt + σ2 Fxx dt − Fτ dt = 0
2
which gives a PDE in ( x, τ ):
1
µFx + σ2 Fxx − Fτ = 0
2
We need a boundary condition for the characteristic function which is
F ( x, τ = 0; s) = eisx
We solve the PDE by making an educated guess, which is
F ( x, τ; s) = eisx+ A(τ )
which implies that when τ = 0, A(τ = 0) = 0 as well. We can see that
Fx = isF
Fxx = −s2 F
Fτ = Aτ F
317
318
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
Substituting this back in the PDE gives
1
µisF − σ2 s2 F − Aτ F = 0
2
1
µis − σ2 s2 − Aτ = 0
2
dA
1
= µis − σ2 s2
dτ
2
1
gives: A(τ ) = µisτ − σ2 s2 τ,
2
because A(0) = 0
Thus we finally have the characteristic function which is
1
F ( x, τ; s) = exp[isx + µisτ − σ2 s2 τ ]
2
12.6.4
Computing the moments
In general, the moments are derived by differentiating the characteristic
function y s and setting s = 0. The k-th moment will be
"
#
kF
1
∂
E[ xk ] = k
i
∂sk
s =0
Lets test it by computing the mean (k = 1):
1 ∂F
E( x ) =
= x + µτ
i ∂s s=0
where x is the current value x0 . How about the second moment?
1 ∂2 F
2
E( x ) = 2
= σ2 τ + ( x + µτ )2 = σ2 τ + E( x )2
i ∂s2 s=0
Hence, the variance will be
Var ( x ) = E( x2 ) − E( x )2 = σ2 τ + E( x )2 − E( x2 ) = σ2 τ
12.6.5
Probability density function
It turns out that we can “invert” the characteristic function to get the pdf
(boy, this characteristic function sure is useful!). Again we use Fourier
inversion, which result is stated as follows:
1
f ( x τ | x0 ) =
π
Here is an implementation
Z ∞
0
Re[e−isxτ ] F ( x0 , τ; s) ds
riding the wave: fourier analysis
#Model for fourier inversion for arithmetic brownian motion
x0 = 10
mu = 10
sig = 5
tau = 0.25
s = (0:10000)/100
ds = s[2]-s[1]
phi =
exp(1i*s*x0+mu*1i*s*tau-0.5*s^2*sig^2*tau)
x = (0:250)/10
fx=NULL
for ( k in 1:length(x) ) {
g = sum(as.real(exp(-1i*s*x[k]) * phi * ds))/pi
print(c(x[k],g))
fx = c(fx,g)
}
plot(x,fx,type="l")
319
13
Making Connections: Network Theory
13.1 Overview
The science of networks is making deep inroads into business. The term
“network effect” is being used widely in conceptual terms to define the
gains from piggybacking on connections in the business world. Using
the network to advantage coins the verb “networking” - a new, improved
use of the word “schmoozing”. The science of viral marketing and wordof-mouth transmission of information is all about exploiting the power
of networks. We are just seeing the beginning - as the cost of the network
and its analysis drops rapidly, businesses will exploit them more and
more.
Networks are also useful in understanding how information flows
in markets. Network theory is also being used by firms to find “communities” of consumers so as to partition and focus their marketing
efforts. There are many wonderful videos by Cornell professor Jon Kleinberg on YouTube and elsewhere on the importance of new tools in computer science for understanding social networks. He talks of the big
difference today in that networks grow organically, not in structured
fashion as in the past with road, electricity and telecommunication networks. Modern networks are large, realistic and well-mapped. Think
about dating networks and sites like Linked In. A free copy of Kleinberg’s book on networks with David Easley may be downloaded at
http://www.cs.cornell.edu/home/kleinber/networks-book/. It is written for an undergraduate audience and is immensely accessible. There is
also material on game theory and auctions in this book.
322
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
13.2 Graph Theory
Any good understanding of networks must perforce begin with a digression in graph theory. I say digression because its not clear to me yet how
a formal understanding of graph theory should be taught to business
students, but yet, an informal set of ideas is hugely useful in providing a technical/conceptual framework within which to see how useful
network analysis will be in the coming future of a changing business
landscape. Also, it is useful to have a light introduction to the notation
and terminology in graph theory so that the basic ideas are accessible
when reading further.
What is a graph? It is a picture of a network, a diagram consisting of
relationships between entities. We call the entities as vertices or nodes
(set V) and the relationships are called the edges of a graph (set E).
Hence a graph G is defined as
G = (V, E)
If the edges e ∈ E of a graph are not tipped with arrows implying some
direction or causality, we call the graph an “undirected” graph. If there
are arrows of direction then the graph is a “directed” graph.
If the connections (edges) between vertices v ∈ V have weights on
them, then we call the graph a “weighted graph” else it’s “unweighted”.
In an unweighted graph, for any pair of vertices (u, v), we have
(
w(u, v) =
w(u, v) = 1,
w(u, v) = 0,
if (u, v) ∈ E
if (u, v) 3 E
In a weighted graph the value of w(u, v) is unrestricted, and can also be
negative.
Directed graphs can be cyclic or acyclic. In a cyclic graph there is a
path from a source node that leads back to the node itself. Not so in
an acyclic graph. The term “dag” is used to connote a “directed acyclic
graph”. The binomial option pricing model in finance that you have
learnt is an example of a dag.
A graph may be represented by its adjacency matrix. This is simply
the matrix A = {w(u, v)}, ∀u, v. You can take the transpose of this matrix
as well, which in the case of a directed graph will simply reverse the
direction of all edges.
making connections: network theory
323
13.3 Features of Graphs
Graphs have many attributes, such as the number of nodes, and the
distribution of links across nodes. The structure of nodes and edges
(links) determines how connected the nodes are, how flows take place on
the network, and the relative importance of each node.
One simple bifurcation of graphs suggests two types: (a) random
graphs and (b) scale-free graphs. In a beautiful article in the Scientific
American, Barabasi and Bonabeau (2003) presented a simple schematic
to depict these two categories of graphs. See Figure 13.1.
Figure 13.1: Comparison of ran-
dom and scale-free graphs. From
Barabasi, Albert-Laszlo., and Eric
Bonabeau (2003). “Scale-Free Networks,” Scientific American May,
50–59.
A random graph may be created by putting in place a set of n nodes
and then randomly connecting pairs of nodes with some probability
p. The higher this probability the more edges the graph will have. The
distribution of the number of edges each node has will be more or less
Gaussian as there is a mean number of edges (n · p), with some range
around the mean. In Figure 13.1, the graph on the left is a depiction of
this, and the distribution of links is shown to be bell-shaped. The left
graph is exemplified by the US highway network, as shown in simplified
324
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
form. If the number of links of a node are given by a number d, the distribution of nodes in a random graph would be f (d) ∼ N (µ, σ2 ), where
µ is the mean number of nodes with variance σ2 .
A scale-free graph has a hub and spoke structure. There are a few central nodes that have a large number of links, and most nodes have very
few. The distribution of links is shown on the right side of Figure 13.1,
and an exemplar is the US airport network. This distribution is not bellshaped at all, and appears to be exponential. There is of course a mean
for this distribution, but the mean is not really representative of the hub
nodes or the non-hub nodes. Because the mean, i.e., the parameter of
scale is unrepresentative of the population, the distribution is scale-free,
and the networks of this type are also known as scale-free networks. The
distribution of nodes in a scale-free graph tends to be approximated by
a power-law distribution, i.e., f (d) ∼ d−α , where usually, nature seems
to have stipulated that 2 ≤ α ≤ 3, by some curious twist of fate. The
log-log plot of this distribution is linear, as shown in the right side graph
in Figure 13.1.
The vast majority of networks in the world tend to be scale-free. Why?
Barabasi and Albert (1999) developed the Theory of Preferential Attachment to explain this phenomenon. The theory is intuitive, and simply
states that as a network grows and new nodes are added, the new nodes
tend to attach to existing nodes that have the most links. Thus influential nodes become even more connected, and this evolves into a hub and
spoke structure.
The structure of these graphs determines other properties. For instance, scale-free graphs are much better at transmission of information,
for example. Or for moving air traffic passengers, which is why our airports are arranged thus. But a scale-free network is also susceptible to
greater transmission of disease, as is the case with networks of people
with HIV. Or, economic contagion. Later in this chapter we will examine
financial network risk by studying the structure of banking networks.
Scale-free graphs are also more robust to random attacks. If a terrorist
group randomly attacks an airport, then unless it hits a hub, very little
damage is done. But the network is much more risky when targeted attacks take place. Which is why our airports and the electricity grid are at
so much risk.
There are many interesting graphs, where the study of basic properties leads to many quick insights, as we will see in the rest of this chap-
making connections: network theory
ter. Our of interest, if you are an academic, take a look at Microsoft’s academic research network. See http://academic.research.microsoft.com/
Using this I have plotted my own citation and co-author network in Figure 13.2.
13.4 Searching Graphs
There are two types of search algorithms that are run on graphs - depthfirst-search (DFS) and breadth-first search (BFS). Why do we care about
this? As we will see, DFS is useful in finding communities in social networks. And BFS is useful in finding the shortest connections in networks. Ask yourself, what use is that? It should not be hard to come
up with many answers.
13.4.1
Depth First Search
DFS begins by taking a vertex and creating a tree of connected vertices
from the source vertex, recursing downwards until it is no longer possible to do so. See Figure 13.3 for an example of a DFS.
The algorithm for DFS is as follows:
f u n c t i o n DFS ( u ) :
f o r a l l v i n SUCC( u ) :
if notvisited (v ) :
DFS ( v )
MARK( u )
This recursive algorithm results in two subtrees, which are:
a→b→c→g
%
f
& d
e→h→i
The numbers on the nodes show the sequence in which the nodes
are accessed by the program. The typical output of a DFS algorithm is
usually slightly less detailed, and gives a simple sequence in which the
nodes are first visited. An example is provided in the graph package:
> l i b r a r y ( graph )
325
326
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
Figure 13.2: Microsoft
academic search tool for
co-authorship networks. See:
http://academic.research.microsoft.
The top chart shows co-authors,
the middle one shows citations,
and the last one shows my Erdos
number, i.e., the number of hops
needed to be connected to Paul
Erdos via my co-authors. My Erdos
number is 3. Interestingly, I am a
Finance academic, but my shortest
path to Erdos is through Computer
Science co-authors, another field in
which I dabble.
making connections: network theory
a
b
c
1/12
2/11
3/10
e
f
g
13/18
5/6
4/7
h
14/17
d
8/9
i
15/16
> RNGkind( " Mersenne−T w i s t e r " )
> s e t . seed ( 1 2 3 )
> g1 <− randomGraph ( l e t t e r s [ 1 : 1 0 ] , 1 : 4 , p = . 3 )
> g1
A graphNEL graph with u n d i r e c t e d edges
Number o f Nodes = 10
Number o f Edges = 21
> edgeNames ( g1 )
[ 1 ] " a~g " " a~ i " " a~b " " a~d " " a~e " " a~ f " " a~h " " b~ f " " b~ j "
[ 1 0 ] " b~d " " b~e " " b~h " " c~h " " d~e " " d~ f " " d~h " " e~ f " " e~h "
[ 1 9 ] " f ~ j " " f ~h " " g~ i "
> RNGkind ( )
[ 1 ] " Mersenne−T w i s t e r " " I n v e r s i o n "
> DFS ( g1 , " a " )
a b c d e f g h i j
0 1 6 2 3 4 8 5 9 7
Note that the result of a DFS on a graph is a set of trees. A tree is a
special kind of graph, and is inherently acyclic if the graph is acyclic. A
cyclic graph will have a DFS tree with back edges.
We can think of this as partitioning the vertices into subsets of connected groups. The obvious business application comes from first understanding why they are different, and secondly from being able to target
these groups separately by tailoring business responses to their characteristics, or deciding to stop focusing on one of them.
Figure 13.3: Depth-first-search.
327
328
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
Firms that maintain data about these networks use algorithms like
this to find out “communities”. Within a community, the nearness of
connections is then determined using breadth-first-search.
A DFS also tells you something about the connectedness of the nodes.
It shows that every entity in the network is not that far from the others,
and the analysis often suggests the “small-world’s” phenomenon, or
what is colloquially called “six degrees of separation.” Social networks
are extremely rich in short paths.
Now we examine how DFS is implemented in the package igraph,
which we will use throughout the rest of this chapter. Here is the sample code, which also shows how a graph may be created from a pairedvertex list.
#CREATE A SIMPLE GRAPH
df = matrix ( c ( " a " , " b " , " b " , " c " , " c " , " g " ,
" f " , "b" , "g" , "d" , "g" , " f " ,
" f " , " e " , " e " , " h " , " h " , " i " ) , ncol =2 , byrow=TRUE)
g = graph . data . frame ( df , d i r e c t e d =FALSE )
plot ( g )
#DO DEPTH−FIRST SEARCH
dfs ( g , " a " )
$ root
[1] 0
$neimode
[ 1 ] " out "
$ order
+ 9 / 9 v e r t i c e s , named :
[1] a b c g f e h i d
$ order . out
NULL
$ father
NULL
making connections: network theory
329
$ dist
NULL
We also plot the graph to see what it appears like and to verify the
results. See Figure 13.4.
Figure 13.4: Depth-first search on
a simple graph generated from a
paired node list.
13.4.2
Breadth-first-search
BFS explores the edges of E to discover (from a source vertex s) all reachable vertices on the graph. It does this in a manner that proceeds to find
a frontier of vertices k distant from s. Only when it has located all such
vertices will the search then move on to locating vertices k + 1 away from
the source. This is what distinguishes it from DFS which goes all the
way down, without covering all vertices at a given level first.
BFS is implemented by just labeling each node with its distance from
the source. For an example, see Figure 13.5. It is easy to see that this
helps in determining nearest neighbors. When you have a positive response from someone in the population it helps to be able to target the
nearest neighbors first in a cost-effective manner. The art lies in defining
the edges (connections). For example, a company like Schwab might be
able to establish a network of investors where the connections are based
on some threshold level of portfolio similarity. Then, if a certain account
330
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
displays enhanced investment, and we know the cause (e.g. falling interest rates) then it may be useful to market funds aggressively to all
connected portfolios with a BFS range.
a
s
b
c
1
0
1
3
1
2
d
e
Figure 13.5: Breadth-first-search.
The algorithm for BFS is as follows:
f u n c t i o n BFS ( s )
MARK( s )
Q = {s}
T = {s}
While Q ne { } :
Choose u i n Q
Visit u
f o r each v=SUCC( u ) :
MARK( v )
Q = Q + v
T = T + (u , v)
BFS also results in a tree which in this case is as follows. The level of
each tree signifies the distance from the source vertex.
%
s
→
&a
b&
d→e→c
The code is as follows:
df = matrix ( c ( " s " , " a " , " s " , " b " , " s " , " d " , " b " , " e " , " d " , " e " , " e " , " c " ) ,
ncol =2 , byrow=TRUE)
g = graph . data . frame ( df , d i r e c t e d =FALSE )
making connections: network theory
bfs (g , " a " )
$ root
[1] 1
$neimode
[ 1 ] " out "
$ order
+ 6 / 6 v e r t i c e s , named :
[1] s b d a e c
$ rank
NULL
$ father
NULL
$ pred
NULL
$ succ
NULL
$ dist
NULL
There is a classic book on graph theory which is a must for anyone
interested in reading more about this: Tarjan (1983) – Its only a little over
100 pages and is a great example of a lot if material presented very well.
Another bible for reference is “Introduction to Algorithms” by Cormen, Liserson, and Rivest (2009). You might remember that Ron Rivest is
the “R” in the famous RSA algorithm used for encryption.
13.5 Strongly Connected Components
Directed graphs are wonderful places in which to cluster members of a
network. We do this by finding strongly connected components (SCCs)
on such a graph. A SCC is a subgroup of vertices U ⊂ V in a graph with
331
332
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
a
b
e
f
c
d
g
h
i
abe
j
cd
fg
hi
the property that for all pairs of its vertices (u, v) ∈ U, both vertices are
reachable from each other.
Figure 13.6 shows an example of a graph broken down into its strongly
connected components.
The SCCs are extremely useful in partitioning a graph into tight units.
It presents local feedback effects. What it means is that targeting any one
member of a SCC will effectively target the whole, as well as move the
stimulus across SCCs.
The most popular package for graph analysis has turned out to be
igraph. It has versions in R, C, and Python. You can generate and plot
random graphs in R using this package. Here is an example.
> l i b r a r y ( igraph )
> g <− erdos . r e n y i . game ( 2 0 , 1 / 2 0 )
> g
V e r t i c e s : 20
Edges : 8
D i r e c t e d : FALSE
Edges :
Figure 13.6: Strongly connected
components. The upper graph
shows the original network and the
lower one shows the compressed
network comprising only the SCCs.
The algorithm to determine SCCs
relies on two DFSs. Can you see a
further SCC in the second graph?
There should not be one.
making connections: network theory
[ 0 ] 6 −− 7
[ 1 ] 0 −− 10
[ 2 ] 0 −− 11
[ 3 ] 10 −− 14
[ 4 ] 6 −− 16
[ 5 ] 11 −− 17
[ 6 ] 9 −− 18
[ 7 ] 16 −− 19
> clusters (g)
$membership
[1] 0 1 2
[20] 6
3
4
5
6
6
7
8
0
0
9 10
0 11
$ csize
[1] 5 1 1 1 1 1 4 1 2 1 1 1
$no
[ 1 ] 12
> p l o t . igraph ( g )
It results in the plot in Figure 13.7.
13.6 Dijkstra’s Shortest Path Algorithm
This is one of the most well-known algorithms in theoretical computer
science. Given a source vertex on a weighted, directed graph, it finds
the shortest path to all other nodes from source s. The weight between
two vertices is denoted w(u, v) as before. Dijkstra’s algorithm works for
graphs where w(u, v) ≥ 0. For negative weights, there is the BellmanFord algorithm. The algorithm is as follows.
f u n c t i o n DIJKSTRA (G,w, s )
S = { }
%S = S e t o f v e r t i c e s whose s h o r t e s t paths from
%source s have been found
Q = V(G)
while Q n o t e q u a l { } :
u = getMin (Q)
S = S + u
6
0
8
333
334
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
Figure 13.7: Finding connected
components on a graph.
3
15
13
4
8
17
10
19
18
11
9
12
14
1
6
7
0
5
2
16
Q = Q− u
f o r each v e r t e x v i n SUCC( u ) :
i f d [ v ] > d [ u]+w( u , v ) then :
d [ v ] = d [ u]+w( u , v )
PRED( v ) = u
An example of a graph on which Dijkstra’s algorithm has been applied is shown in Figure 13.8.
The usefulness of this has been long exploited in operations for airlines, designing transportation plans, optimal location of health-care
centers, and in the every day use of map-quest.
You can use igraph to determine shortest paths in a network. Here is
an example using the package. First we see how to enter a graph, then
process it for shortest paths.
> e l = matrix ( nc =3 , byrow=TRUE, c ( 0 , 1 , 8 , 0 , 3 , 4 , 1 , 3 , 3 , 3 , 1 , 1 , 1 , 2 , 1 ,
1 ,4 ,7 , 3 ,4 ,4 , 2 ,4 ,1))
> el
[ ,1] [ ,2] [ ,3]
[1 ,]
0
1
8
[2 ,]
0
3
4
[3 ,]
1
3
3
[4 ,]
3
1
1
[5 ,]
1
2
1
[6 ,]
1
4
7
[7 ,]
3
4
4
making connections: network theory
a
8/5
b
1
Figure 13.8: Dijkstra’s algorithm.
6
8
s
3
0
1
7
1
4
d
c
4
4
335
8/7
[8 ,]
2
4
1
> g = add . edges ( graph . empty ( 5 ) , t ( e l [ , 1 : 2 ] ) , weight= e l [ , 3 ] )
> s h o r t e s t . paths ( g )
[ ,1] [ ,2] [ ,3] [ ,4] [ ,5]
[1 ,]
0
5
6
4
7
[2 ,]
5
0
1
1
2
[3 ,]
6
1
0
2
1
[4 ,]
4
1
2
0
3
[5 ,]
7
2
1
3
0
> g e t . s h o r t e s t . paths ( g , 0 )
[[1]]
[1] 0
[[2]]
[1] 0 3 1
[[3]]
[1] 0 3 1 2
[[4]]
[1] 0 3
[[5]]
[1] 0 3 1 2 4
Here is another example.
> e l <− matrix ( nc =3 , byrow=TRUE,
c (0 ,1 ,0 , 0 ,2 ,2 , 0 ,3 ,1 , 1 ,2 ,0 , 1 ,4 ,5 , 1 ,5 ,2 , 2 ,1 ,1 , 2 ,3 ,1 ,
2 ,6 ,1 , 3 ,2 ,0 , 3 ,6 ,2 , 4 ,5 ,2 , 4 ,7 ,8 , 5 ,2 ,2 , 5 ,6 ,1 , 5 ,8 ,1 ,
5 ,9 ,3 , 7 ,5 ,1 , 7 ,8 ,1 , 8 ,9 ,4) )
> el
[ ,1] [ ,2] [ ,3]
[1 ,]
0
1
0
[2 ,]
0
2
2
[3 ,]
0
3
1
[4 ,]
1
2
0
[5 ,]
1
4
5
[6 ,]
1
5
2
336
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
Figure 13.9: Network for computa-
tion of shortest path algorithm
9
6
3
7
1
5
0
4
2
8
[7 ,]
2
1
1
[8 ,]
2
3
1
[9 ,]
2
6
1
[10 ,]
3
2
0
[11 ,]
3
6
2
[12 ,]
4
5
2
[13 ,]
4
7
8
[14 ,]
5
2
2
[15 ,]
5
6
1
[16 ,]
5
8
1
[17 ,]
5
9
3
[18 ,]
7
5
1
[19 ,]
7
8
1
[20 ,]
8
9
4
> g = add . edges ( graph . empty ( 1 0 ) , t ( e l [ , 1 : 2 ] ) , weight= e l [ , 3 ] )
> p l o t . igraph ( g )
> s h o r t e s t . paths ( g )
[ ,1] [ ,2] [ ,3] [ ,4] [ ,5] [ ,6] [ ,7] [ ,8] [ ,9] [ ,10]
[1 ,]
0
0
0
0
4
2
1
3
3
5
[2 ,]
0
0
0
0
4
2
1
3
3
5
[3 ,]
0
0
0
0
4
2
1
3
3
5
[4 ,]
0
0
0
0
4
2
1
3
3
5
[5 ,]
4
4
4
4
0
2
3
3
3
5
[6 ,]
2
2
2
2
2
0
1
1
1
3
[7 ,]
1
1
1
1
3
1
0
2
2
4
[8 ,]
3
3
3
3
3
1
2
0
1
4
[9 ,]
3
3
3
3
3
1
2
1
0
4
[10 ,]
5
5
5
5
5
3
4
4
4
0
> g e t . s h o r t e s t . paths ( g , 4 )
[[1]]
[1] 4 5 1 0
making connections: network theory
[[2]]
[1] 4 5 1
[[3]]
[1] 4 5 2
[[4]]
[1] 4 5 2 3
[[5]]
[1] 4
[[6]]
[1] 4 5
[[7]]
[1] 4 5 6
[[8]]
[1] 4 5 7
[[9]]
[1] 4 5 8
[[10]]
[1] 4 5 9
> average . path . length ( g )
[ 1 ] 2.051724
13.6.1
Plotting the network
One can also use different layout standards as follows: Here is the example:
> l i b r a r y ( igraph )
> e l <− matrix ( nc =3 , byrow=TRUE,
+
c (0 ,1 ,0 , 0 ,2 ,2 , 0 ,3 ,1 ,
+
2 ,6 ,1 , 3 ,2 ,0 , 3 ,6 ,2 ,
+
5 ,9 ,3 , 7 ,5 ,1 , 7 ,8 ,1 ,
> g = add . edges ( graph . empty ( 1 0 ) , t ( e l [
1 ,2 ,0 ,
4 ,5 ,2 ,
8 ,9 ,4)
,1:2]) ,
1 ,4 ,5 , 1 ,5 ,2 , 2 ,1 ,1 , 2 ,3 ,1 ,
4 ,7 ,8 , 5 ,2 ,2 , 5 ,6 ,1 , 5 ,8 ,1 ,
)
weight= e l [ , 3 ] )
#GRAPHING MAIN NETWORK
g = simplify (g)
V( g ) $name = seq ( vcount ( g ) )
l = l a y o u t . fruchterman . r e i n g o l d ( g )
# l = l a y o u t . kamada . k a w a i ( g )
# = layout . c i r c l e (g)
l = l a y o u t . norm ( l , − 1 ,1 , − 1 ,1)
# p d f ( f i l e =" n e t w o r k _ p l o t . p d f " )
p l o t ( g , l a y o u t= l , v e r t e x . s i z e =2 , v e r t e x . l a b e l =NA, v e r t e x . c o l o r = " # f f 0 0 0 0 3 3 " ,
edge . c o l o r = " grey " , edge . arrow . s i z e = 0 . 3 , r e s c a l e =FALSE ,
xlim=range ( l [ , 1 ] ) , ylim=range ( l [ , 2 ] ) )
The plots are shown in Figures 13.10.
337
338
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
Figure 13.10: Plot using the
Fruchterman-Rheingold and Circle
layouts
13.7 Degree Distribution
The degree of a node in the network is the number of links it has to
other nodes. The probability distribution of the nodes is known as the
degree distribution. In an undirected network, this is based on the number of edges a node has, but in a directed network, we have a distribution for in-degree and another for out-degree. Note that the weights on
the edges are not relevant for computing the degree distribution, though
there may be situations in which one might choose to avail of that information as well.
#GENERATE RANDOM GRAPH
g = erdos . r e n y i . game ( 3 0 , 0 . 1 )
p l o t . igraph ( g )
print ( g)
IGRAPH U−−− 30 41 −− Erdos r e n y i ( gnp ) graph
+ a t t r : name ( g / c ) , type ( g / c ) , loops ( g / l ) , p
+ edges :
[ 1 ] 1−− 9 2−− 9 7−−10 7−−12 8−−12 5−−13
[ 9 ] 5−−15 12−−15 13−−16 15−−16 1−−17 18−−19
[ 1 7 ] 10−−21 18−−21 14−−22 4−−23 6−−23 9−−23
[ 2 5 ] 20−−24 17−−25 13−−26 15−−26 3−−27 5−−27
[ 3 3 ] 18−−27 19−−27 25−−27 11−−28 13−−28 22−−28
[ 4 1 ] 7−−29
(g/n)
6−−14 11−−14
18−−20 2−−21
11−−23 9−−24
6−−27 16−−27
24−−28 5−−29
making connections: network theory
> clusters (g)
$membership
[1] 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 2
$ csize
[ 1 ] 29
1
$no
[1] 2
The plot is shown in Figure 13.11.
Figure 13.11: Plot of the Erdos-
Renyi random graph
We may compute the degree distribution with some minimal code.
#COMPUTE DEGREE DISTRIBUTION
dd = degree . d i s t r i b u t i o n ( g )
dd = as . matrix ( dd )
d = as . matrix ( seq ( 0 , max ( degree ( g ) ) ) )
p l o t ( d , dd , type= " l " , lwd =3 , c o l = " blue " , ylab= " P r o b a b i l i t y " , x l a b = " Degree " )
> sum( dd )
339
340
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
[1] 1
The resulting plot of the probability distribution is shown in Figure
13.12.
Figure 13.12: Plot of the degree
distribution of the Erdos-Renyi
random graph
13.8 Diameter
The diameter of a graph is the longest shortest distance between any two
nodes, across all nodes. This is easily computed as follows for the graph
we examined in the previous section.
> p r i n t ( diameter ( g ) )
[1] 7
We may cross-check this as follows:
> r e s = s h o r t e s t . paths ( g )
> r e s [ which ( r e s == I n f )]= − 99
> max ( r e s )
[1] 7
> length ( which ( r e s = = 7 ) )
[ 1 ] 18
We see that the number of paths that are of length 7 are a total of 18,
but of course, this is duplicated as we run these paths in both directions.
Hence, there are 9 pairs of nodes that have longest shortest paths between them. You may try to locate these on Figure 13.11.
making connections: network theory
13.9 Fragility
Fragility is an attribute of a network that is based on its degree distribution. In comparing two networks of the same average degree, how do
assess on which network contagion is more likely? Intuitively, a scalefree network is more likely to facilitate the spread of the variable of interest, be it flu, financial malaise, or information. In scale-free networks
the greater preponderance of central hubs results in a greater probability
of contagion. This is because there is a concentration of degree in a few
nodes. The greater the concentration, the more scale-free the graph, and
the higher the fragility.
We need a measure of concentration, and economists have used the
Herfindahl-Hirschman index for many years.
(See https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Herfindahl_index.)
The index is trivial to compute, as it is the average degree squared for
n nodes, i.e.,
1 n
(13.1)
H = E(d2 ) = ∑ d2j
n j =1
This metric H increases as degree gets concentrated in a few nodes,
keeping the total degree of the network constant. For example, if there
is a graph of three nodes with degrees {1, 1, 4} versus another graph
of three nodes with degrees {2, 2, 2}, the former will result in a higher
value of H = 18 than the latter with H = 12. If we normalize H by the
average degree, then we have a definition for fragility, i.e.,
Fragility =
E ( d2 )
E(d)
(13.2)
In the three node graphs example, fragility is 3 and 2, respectively. We
may also choose other normalization factors, for example, E(d)2 in the
denominator. Computing this is trivial and requires a single line of code,
given a vector of node degrees (d), accompanied by the degree distribution (dd), computed earlier in Section 13.7.
#FRAGILITY
p r i n t ( ( t ( d^2) %*% dd ) / ( t ( d ) %*% dd ) )
13.10 Centrality
Centrality is a property of vertices in the network. Given the adjacency
matrix A = {w(u, v)}, we can obtain a measure of the “influence” of
341
342
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
all vertices in the network. Let xi be the influence of vertex i. Then the
column vector x contains the influence of each vertex. What is influence?
Think of a web page. It has more influence the more links it has both,
to the page, and from the page to other pages. Or think of a alumni
network. People with more connections have more influence, they are
more “central”.
It is possible that you might have no connections yourself, but are
connected to people with great connections. In this case, you do have influence. Hence, your influence depends on your own influence and that
which you derive through others. Hence, the entire system of influence
is interdependent, and can be written as the following matrix equation
x=Ax
Now, we can just add a scalar here to this to get
ξ x = Ax
an eigensystem. Decompose this to get the principle eigenvector, and
its values give you the influence of each member. In this way you can
find the most influential people in any network. There are several applications of this idea to real data. This is eigenvector centrality is exactly
what Google trademarked as PageRank, even though they did not invent
eigenvector centrality.
Network methods have also been exploited in understanding Venture Capitalist networks, and have been shown to be key in the success
of VCs and companies. See the recent paper titled “Whom You Know
Matters: Venture Capital Networks and Investment Performance” by
Hochberg, Ljungqvist and Lu (2007).
Networks are also key in the Federal Funds Market. See the paper
by Adam Ashcraft and Darrell Duffie, titled “Systemic Illiquidity in the
Federal Funds Market,” in the American Economic Review, Papers and
Proceedings. See Ashcraft and Duffie (2007).
See the paper titled “Financial Communities” (Das and Sisk (2005))
which also exploits eigenvector methods to uncover properties of graphs.
The key concept here is that of eigenvector centrality.
Let’s do some examples to get a better idea. We will create some small
networks and examine the centrality scores.
> A = matrix ( nc =3 , byrow=TRUE, c ( 0 , 1 , 1 , 1 , 0 , 1 , 1 , 1 , 0 ) )
> A
making connections: network theory
[ ,1] [ ,2] [ ,3]
[1 ,]
0
1
1
[2 ,]
1
0
1
[3 ,]
1
1
0
> g = graph . a d j a c e n c y (A, mode= " u n d i r e c t e d " , weighted=TRUE, diag=FALSE )
> res = evcent ( g )
> res $ vector
[1] 1 1 1
> r e s = e v c e n t ( g , s c a l e =FALSE )
> res $ vector
[ 1 ] 0.5773503 0.5773503 0.5773503
Here is another example:
> A = matrix ( nc =3 , byrow=TRUE, c ( 0 , 1 , 1 , 1 , 0 , 0 , 1 , 0 , 0 ) )
> A
[ ,1] [ ,2] [ ,3]
[1 ,]
0
1
1
[2 ,]
1
0
0
[3 ,]
1
0
0
> g = graph . a d j a c e n c y (A, mode= " u n d i r e c t e d " , weighted=TRUE, diag=FALSE )
> res = evcent ( g )
> res $ vector
[ 1 ] 1.0000000 0.7071068 0.7071068
And another...
> A = matrix ( nc =3 , byrow=TRUE, c ( 0 , 2 , 1 , 2 , 0 , 0 , 1 , 0 , 0 ) )
> A
[ ,1] [ ,2] [ ,3]
[1 ,]
0
2
1
[2 ,]
2
0
0
[3 ,]
1
0
0
> g = graph . a d j a c e n c y (A, mode= " u n d i r e c t e d " , weighted=TRUE, diag=FALSE )
> res = evcent ( g )
> res $ vector
[ 1 ] 1.0000000 0.8944272 0.4472136
343
344
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
Table 13.1: Summary statistics
Year
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
#Colending
banks
241
171
85
69
69
Node #
143
29
47
85
225
235
134
39
152
241
6
173
198
180
42
205
236
218
50
158
213
214
221
211
228
#Coloans
75
95
49
84
42
Colending
pairs
10997
4420
1793
681
598
R = E(d2 )/E(d)
Diam.
137.91
172.45
73.62
68.14
35.35
5
5
4
4
4
(Year = 2005)
Financial Institution
J P Morgan Chase & Co.
Bank of America Corp.
Citigroup Inc.
Deutsche Bank Ag New York Branch
Wachovia Bank NA
The Bank of New York
Hsbc Bank USA
Barclays Bank Plc
Keycorp
The Royal Bank of Scotland Plc
Abn Amro Bank N.V.
Merrill Lynch Bank USA
PNC Financial Services Group Inc
Morgan Stanley
Bnp Paribas
Royal Bank of Canada
The Bank of Nova Scotia
U.S. Bank NA
Calyon New York Branch
Lehman Brothers Bank Fsb
Sumitomo Mitsui Banking
Suntrust Banks Inc
UBS Loan Finance Llc
State Street Corp
Wells Fargo Bank NA
Normalized
Centrality
1.000
0.926
0.639
0.636
0.617
0.573
0.530
0.530
0.524
0.523
0.448
0.374
0.372
0.362
0.337
0.289
0.289
0.284
0.273
0.270
0.236
0.232
0.221
0.210
0.198
In a recent paper I constructed the network graph of interbank lending,
and this allows detection of the banks that have high centrality, and are
more systemically risky. The plots of the banking network are shown in
Figure 13.13. See the paper titled “Extracting, Linking and Integrating
Data from Public Sources: A Financial Case Study,” by Burdick et al
(2011). In this paper the centrality scores for the banks are given in Table
13.1.
Another concept of centrality is known as “betweenness”. This is the
proportion of shortest paths that go through a node relative to all paths
and the top 25 banks ordered on
eigenvalue centrality for 2005. The
R-metric is a measure of whether
failure can spread quickly, and this
is so when R ≥ 2. The diameter
of the network is the length of the
longest geodesic. Also presented
in the second panel of the table
are the centrality scores for 2005
corresponding to Figure 13.13.
making connections: network theory
345
Figure 13.13: Interbank lending
networks by year. The top panel
shows 2005, and the bottom panel
is for the years 2006-2009.
2005
Citigroup Inc.
J.P. Morgan Chase
Bank of America Corp.
2006
2007
2008
2009
346
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
that go through the same node. This may be expressed as
B(v) =
n a,b (v)
n a,b
a6=v6=b
∑
where n a,b is the number of shortest paths from node a to node b, and
n a,b (v) are the number of those paths that traverse through vertex v.
Here is an example from an earlier directed graph.
>
+
+
+
>
>
>
e l <− matrix ( nc =3 , byrow=TRUE,
c (0 ,1 ,0 , 0 ,2 ,2 , 0 ,3 ,1 , 1 ,2 ,0 ,
2 ,6 ,1 , 3 ,2 ,0 , 3 ,6 ,2 , 4 ,5 ,2 ,
5 ,9 ,3 , 7 ,5 ,1 , 7 ,8 ,1 , 8 ,9 ,4)
g = add . edges ( graph . empty ( 1 0 ) , t ( e l [ , 1 : 2 ] ) ,
r e s = betweenness ( g )
res
[1] 0.0 18.0 17.0 0.5 5.0 19.5 0.0 0.5
1 ,4 ,5 , 1 ,5 ,2 , 2 ,1 ,1 , 2 ,3 ,1 ,
4 ,7 ,8 , 5 ,2 ,2 , 5 ,6 ,1 , 5 ,8 ,1 ,
)
weight= e l [ , 3 ] )
0.5
0.0
13.11 Communities
Communities are spatial agglomerates of vertexes who are more likely to
connect with each other than with others. Identifying these agglomerates
is a cluster detection problem, a computationally difficult (NP-hard) one.
The computational complexity arises because we do not fix the number of clusters, allow each cluster to have a different size, and permit
porous boundaries so members can communicate both within and outside their preferred clusters. Several partitions satisfy such a flexible definition. Communities are constructed by optimizing modularity, which
is a metric of the difference between the number of within-community
connections and the expected number of connections, given the total
connectivity on the graph. Identifying communities is difficult because
of the enormous computational complexity involved in sifting through
all possible partitions. One fast way is to exploit the walk trap approach
recently developed in the physical sciences (Pons and Latapy (2006), see
Fortunato (2010) for a review) to identify communities.
The essential idea underlying community formation dates back at
least to Simon (1962). In his view, complex systems comprising several
entities often have coherent subsystems, or communities, that serve specific functional purposes. Identifying communities embedded in larger
entities can help understand the functional forces underlying larger entities. To make these ideas more concrete, we discuss applications from
the physical and social sciences before providing more formal definitions.
making connections: network theory
In the life sciences, community structures help understand pathways
in the metabolic networks of cellular organisms (Ravasz et al. (2002);
Guimera et al. (2005)). Community structures also help understand the
functioning of the human brain. For instance, Wu, Taki, and Sato (2011)
find that there are community structures in the human brain with predictable changes in their interlinkages related to aging. Community
structures are used to understand how food chains are compartmentalized, which can predict the robustness of ecosystems to shocks that endanger particular species, Girvan and Newman (2002). Lusseau (2003)
finds that communities are evolutionary hedges that avoid isolation
when a member is attacked by predators. In political science, community structures discerned from voting patterns can detect political preferences that transcend traditional party lines, Porter, Mucha, Newman,
and Friend (2007).1
Fortunato (2010) presents a relatively recent and thorough survey of
the research in community detection. Fortunato points out that while
the computational issues are challenging, there is sufficient progress to
the point where many methods yield similar results in practice. However, there are fewer insights on the functional roles of communities or
their quantitative effect on outcomes of interest. Fortunato suggests that
this is a key challenge in the literature. As he concludes “... What shall
we do with communities? What can they tell us about a system? This
is the main question beneath the whole endeavor.” Community detection methods provide useful insights into the economics of networks.
See this great video on a talk by Mark Newman, who is just an excellent speaker and huge contributor to the science of network analysis:
http://www.youtube.com/watch?v=lETt7IcDWLI, the talk is titled “What
Networks Can Tell us About the World”.
We represent the network as the square adjacency matrix A. The rows
and columns represent entities. Element A(i, j) equals the number of
times node i and j are partners, so more frequent partnerships lead to
greater weights. The diagonal element A(i, i ) is zero. While this representation is standard in the networks literature, it has economic content.
The matrix is undirected and symmetric, effectively assuming that the
benefits of interactions flow to all members in a symmetric way.
Community detection methods partition nodes into clusters that tend
to interact together. It is useful to point out the considerable flexibility and realism built into the definition of our community clusters. We
347
Other topics studied include social
interactions and community formation
(Zachary (1977)); word adjacency in
linguistics and cognitive sciences, Newman (2006); collaborations between scientists (Newman (2001)); and industry
structures from product descriptions,
Hoberg and Phillips (2010). For some
community detection datasets, see
Mark Newman’s website http://wwwpersonal.umich.edu/ mejn/netdata/.
1
348
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
do not require all nodes to belong to communities. Nor do we fix the
number of communities that may exist at a time, and we also allow each
community to have different size. With this flexibility, the key computational challenge is to find the “best” partition because the number of
possible partitions of the nodes is extremely large. Community detection
methods attempt to determine a set of clusters that are internally tightknit. Mathematically, this is equivalent to finding a partition of clusters
to maximize the observed number of connections between cluster members minus what is expected conditional on the connections within the
cluster, aggregated across all clusters. More formally (see, e.g., Newman
(2006)), we choose partitions with high modularity Q, where
1
Q=
2m
∑
i,j
di × d j
Aij −
· δ(i, j)
2m
(13.3)
In equation (13.3), Aij is the (i, j)-th entry in the adjacency matrix,
i.e., the number of connections in which i and j jointly participated,
di = ∑ j Aij is the total number of transactions that node i participated
in (or, the degree of i) and m = 21 ∑ij Aij is the sum of all edge weights in
matrix A. The function δ(i, j) is an indicator equal to 1.0 if nodes i and j
are from the same community, and zero otherwise. Q is bounded in [-1,
+1]. If Q > 0, intra-community connections exceed the expected number
given deal flow.
13.11.1
Modularity
In order to offer the reader a better sense of how modularity is computed in different settings, we provide a simple example here, and discuss the different interpretations of modularity that are possible. The calculations here are based on the measure developed in Newman (2006).
Since we used the igraph package in R, we will present the code that
may be used with the package to compute modularity.
Consider a network of five nodes { A, B, C, D, E}, where the edge
weights are as follows: A : B = 6, A : C = 5, B : C = 2, C : D = 2,
and D : E = 10. Assume that a community detection algorithm assigns { A, B, C } to one community and { D, E} to another, i.e., only two
making connections: network theory
communities. The adjacency matrix for this graph is


0 6 5 0 0


 6 0 2 0 0 



{ Aij } = 
 5 2 0 2 0 


 0 0 2 0 10 
0 0 0 10 0
Let’s first detect the communities.
> l i b r a r y ( igraph )
> A = matrix ( c ( 0 , 6 , 5 , 0 , 0 , 6 , 0 , 2 , 0 , 0 , 5 , 2 , 0 , 2 , 0 , 0 , 0 , 2 , 0 , 1 0 , 0 , 0 , 0 , 1 0 , 0 ) , 5 , 5 )
> g = graph . a d j a c e n c y (A, mode= " u n d i r e c t e d " , diag=FALSE )
> wtc = walktrap . community ( g )
> r e s =community . t o . membership ( g , wtc$merges , s t e p s =3)
> print ( res )
$membership
[1] 1 1 1 0 0
$ csize
[1] 2 3
We can do the same thing with a different algorithm called the “fastgreedy” approach.
> g = graph . a d j a c e n c y (A, mode= " u n d i r e c t e d " , weighted=TRUE, diag=FALSE )
> f g c = f a s t g r e e d y . community ( g , merges=TRUE, modularity=TRUE,
weights=E ( g ) $ weight )
> r e s = community . t o . membership ( g , f g c $merges , s t e p s =3)
> res
$membership
[1] 0 0 0 1 1
$ csize
[1] 3 2
The Kronecker delta matrix that delineates the communities will be


1 1 1 0 0


 1 1 1 0 0 



{δij } = 
 1 1 1 0 0 


 0 0 0 1 1 
0 0 0 1 1
349
350
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
The modularity score is
1
Q=
2m
∑
i,j
di × d j
Aij −
· δij
2m
(13.4)
where m = 12 ∑ij Aij = 12 ∑i di is the sum of edge weights in the graph,
Aij is the (i, j)-th entry in the adjacency matrix, i.e., the weight of the
edge between nodes i and j, and di = ∑ j Aij is the degree of node i.
The function δij is Kronecker’s delta and takes value 1 when the nodes
i and j are from the same community, else takes value
zero. iThe core
h
d ×d
of the formula comprises the modularity matrix Aij − i2m j which
gives a score that increases when the number of connections within a
community exceeds the expected proportion of connections if they are
assigned at random depending on the degree of each node. The score
takes a value ranging from −1 to +1 as it is normalized by dividing
by 2m. When Q > 0 it means that the number of connections within
communities exceeds that between communities. The program code that
takes in the adjacency matrix and delta matrix is as follows:
#MODULARITY
Amodularity = f u n c t i o n (A, d e l t a ) {
n = length (A[ 1 , ] )
d = matrix ( 0 , n , 1 )
f o r ( j i n 1 : n ) { d [ j ] = sum(A[ j , ] ) }
m = 0 . 5 * sum( d )
Q = 0
for ( i in 1 : n ) {
for ( j in 1 : n ) {
Q = Q + (A[ i , j ] − d [ i ] * d [ j ] / ( 2 *m) ) * d e l t a [ i , j ]
}
}
Q = Q/ ( 2 *m)
}
We use the R programming language to compute modularity using
a canned function, and we will show that we get the same result as the
formula provided in the function above. First, we enter the two matrices
and then call the function shown above:
> A = matrix ( c ( 0 , 6 , 5 , 0 , 0 , 6 , 0 , 2 , 0 , 0 , 5 , 2 , 0 , 2 , 0 , 0 , 0 , 2 , 0 , 1 0 , 0 , 0 , 0 , 1 0 , 0 ) , 5 , 5 )
> d e l t a = matrix ( c ( 1 , 1 , 1 , 0 , 0 , 1 , 1 , 1 , 0 , 0 , 1 , 1 , 1 , 0 , 0 , 0 , 0 , 0 , 1 , 1 , 0 , 0 , 0 , 1 , 1 ) , 5 , 5 )
> p r i n t ( Amodularity (A, d e l t a ) )
making connections: network theory
[ 1 ] 0.4128
We now repeat the same analysis using the R package. Our exposition here will also show how the walktrap algorithm is used to detect
communities, and then using these communities, how modularity is
computed. Our first step is to convert the adjacency matrix into a graph
for use by the community detection algorithm.
> g = graph . a d j a c e n c y (A, mode= " u n d i r e c t e d " , weighted=TRUE, diag=FALSE )
We then pass this graph to the walktrap algorithm:
> wtc=walktrap . community ( g , modularity=TRUE, weights=E ( g ) $ weight )
> r e s =community . t o . membership ( g , wtc$merges , s t e p s =3)
> print ( res )
$membership
[1] 0 0 0 1 1
$ csize
[1] 3 2
We see that the algorithm has assigned the first three nodes to one
community and the next two to another (look at the membership variable above). The sizes of the communities are shown in the size variable
above. We now proceed to compute the modularity
> p r i n t ( modularity ( g , r e s $membership , weights=E ( g ) $ weight ) )
[ 1 ] 0.4128
This confirms the value we obtained from the calculation using our
implementation of the formula.
Modularity can also be computed using a graph where edge weights
are unweighted. In this case, we have the following adjacency matrix
> A
[1
[2
[3
[4
[5
,]
,]
,]
,]
,]
[ ,1] [ ,2] [ ,3] [ ,4] [ ,5]
0
1
1
0
0
1
0
1
0
0
1
1
0
1
0
0
0
1
0
1
0
0
0
1
0
Using our function, we get
> p r i n t ( Amodularity (A, d e l t a ) )
[1] 0.22
351
352
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
We can generate the same result using R:
> g = graph . a d j a c e n c y (A, mode= " u n d i r e c t e d " , diag=FALSE )
> wtc = walktrap . community ( g )
> r e s =community . t o . membership ( g , wtc$merges , s t e p s =3)
> print ( res )
$membership
[1] 1 1 1 0 0
$ csize
[1] 2 3
> p r i n t ( modularity ( g , r e s $membership ) )
[1] 0.22
Community detection is an NP-hard problem for which there are no
known exact solutions beyond tiny systems (Fortunato, 2009). For larger
datasets, one approach is to impose numerical constraints. For example,
graph partitioning imposes a uniform community size, while partitional
clustering presets the number of communities. This is too restrictive.
The less restrictive methods for community detection are called hierarchical partitioning methods, which are “divisive,” or “agglomerative.”
The former is a top-down approach that assumes that the entire graph is
one community and breaks it down into smaller units. It often produces
communities that are too large especially when there is not an extremely
strong community structure. Agglomerative algorithms, like the “walktrap” technique we use, begin by assuming all nodes are separate communities and collect nodes into communities. The fast techniques are
dynamic methods based on random walks, whose intuition is that if a
random walk enters a strong community, it is likely to spend a long time
inside before finding a way out (Pons and Latapy (2006)).2
Community detection forms part of the literature on social network
analysis. The starting point for this work is a set of pairwise connections
between individuals or firms, which has received much attention in the
recent finance literature. Cohen, Frazzini and Malloy (2008a); Cohen,
Frazzini and Malloy (2008b) analyze educational connections between
sell-side analysts and managers. Hwang and Kim (2009) and ChidKedPrabh (2010) analyze educational, employment, and other links between
CEOs and directors. Pairwise inter-firm relations are analyzed by Ishii
and Xuan (2009) and Cai and Sevilir (2012), while VC firm connections
See Girvan and Newman (2002),
Leskovec, Kang and Mahoney (2010),
or Fortunato (2010) and the references
therein for a discussion.
2
making connections: network theory
with founders and top executives are studied by Bengtsson and Hsu
(2010) and Hegde and Tumlinson (2011).
There is more finance work on the aggregate connectedness derived
from pairwise connections. These metrics are introduced to the finance
literature by Hochberg, Ljungqvist and Lu (2007), who study the aggregate connections of venture capitalists derived through syndications.
They show that firms financed by well-connected VCs are more likely to
exit successfully. Engelberg, Gao and Parsons (2000) show that highly
connected CEOs are more highly compensated.
The simplest measure of aggregate connectedness, degree centrality, simply aggregates the number of partners that a person or node
has worked with. A more subtle measure, eigenvector centrality, aggregates connections but puts more weight on the connections of nodes to
more connected nodes. Other related constructs are betweenness, which
reflects how many times a node is on the shortest path between two
other nodes, and closeness, which measures a nodes distance to all other
nodes. The important point is that each of these measures represents an
attempt to capture a node’s stature or influence as reflected in the number of its own connections or from being connected to well-connected
nodes.
Community membership, on the other hand, is a group attribute that
reflects whether a node belongs to a spatial cluster of nodes that tend to
communicate a lot together. Community membership is a variable inherited by all members of a spatial agglomerate. However, centrality is
an individual-centered variable that captures a node’s influence. Community membership does not measure the reach or influence of a node.
Rather, it is a measure focused on interactions between nodes, reflecting whether a node deals with familiar partners. Neither community
membership nor centrality is a proper subset of the other.
The differences between community and centrality are visually depicted in Figure 13.13, which is reproduced from Burdick et al (2011).
The figure shows the high centrality of Citigroup, J. P. Morgan, and Bank
of America, well connected banks in co-lending networks. However,
none of these banks belong to communities, which are represented by
banks in the left and right nodes of the figure. In sum, community is
a group attribute that measures whether a node belongs to a tight knit
group. Centrality reflects the size and heft of a node’s connections.3 For
another schematic that shows the same idea, i.e., the difference between
353
Newman (2010) brings out the distinctions further. See his Sections 7.1/7.2 on
centrality and Section 11.6 on community detection.
3
354
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
centrality and communities is in Figure 13.14.
Figure 13.14: Community versus
centrality
Community v. Centrality
Communities
• Group-focused concept
• Members learn-by-doing
through social interactions.
Centrality
• Hub focused concept
• Resources and skill of
central players.
See my paper titled “Venture Capital Communities” where I examine
how VCs form communities, and whether community-funded startups
do better than the others (we do find so). We also find evidence of some
aspects of homophily within VC communities, though there are also
aspects of heterogeneity in characteristics.
13.12 Word of Mouth
WOM has become an increasingly important avenue for viral marketing.
Here is a article on the growth of this medium. See ?. See also the really
interesting paper by Godes and Mayzlin (2009) titled “Firm-Created
Word-of-Mouth Communication: Evidence from a Field Test”. This is an
excellent example of how firms should go about creating buzz. See also
Godes and Mayzlin (2004): “Using Online Conversations to Study Word
of Mouth Communication” which looks at TV ratings and WOM.
41
making connections: network theory
13.13 Network Models of Systemic Risk
In an earlier section, we saw pictures of banking networks (see Figure
13.13), i.e., the interbank loan network. In these graphs, the linkages between banks were considered, but two things were missing. First, we
assumed that all banks were similar in quality or financial health, and
nodes were therefore identical. Second, we did not develop a network
measure of overall system risk, though we did compute fragility and
diameter for the banking network. What we also computed was the relative position of each bank in the network, i.e., it’s eigenvalue centrality.
In the section, we augment network information of the graph with
additional information on the credit quality of each node in the network.
We then use this to compute a system-wide score of the overall risk of
the system, denoting this as systemic risk. This section is based on 4 .
We make the following assumptions and define notation:
• Assume n nodes, i.e., firms, or “assets.”
• Let E ∈ Rn×n be a well-defined adjacency matrix. This quantifies the
influence of each node on another.
• E may be portrayed as a directed graph, i.e., Eij 6= Eji .
Ejj = 1; Eij ∈ {0, 1}.
• C is a (n × 1) risk vector that defines the risk score for each asset.
• We define the “systemic risk score” as
p
S = C> E C
• S(C, E) is linear homogenous in C.
We note that this score captures two important features of systemic risk:
(a) The interconnectedness of the banks in the system, through adjacency
(or edge) matrix E, and (b) the financial quality of each bank in the system, denoted by the vector C, a proxy for credit score, i.e., credit rating,
z-score, probability of default, etc.
13.13.1
Systemic Score, Fragility, Centrality, Diameter
We code up the systemic risk function as follows.
l i b r a r y ( igraph )
4
355
356
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
#FUNCTION FOR RISK INCREMENT AND DECOMP
NetRisk = f u n c t i o n ( Ri , X) {
S = s q r t ( t ( Ri ) %*% X %*% Ri )
R i s k I n c r = 0 . 5 * (X %*% Ri + t (X) %*% Ri ) / S [ 1 , 1 ]
RiskDecomp = R i s k I n c r * Ri
r e s u l t = l i s t ( S , R i s k I n c r , RiskDecomp )
}
To illustrate application, we generate a network of 15 banks by creating a random graph.
#CREATE ADJ MATRIX
e = floor ( runif (15 * 15) * 2)
X = matrix ( e , 1 5 , 1 5 )
diag (X) = 1
This creates the network adjacency matrix and network plot shown in
Figure 13.15. Note that the diagonal elements are 1, as this is needed for
the risk score.
The code for the plot is as follows:
#GRAPH NETWORK: p l o t o f t h e a s s e t s and t h e l i n k s w i t h d i r e c t e d a r r o w
na = length ( diag (X ) )
Y = X ; diag (Y)=0
g = graph . a d j a c e n c y (Y)
p l o t . igraph ( g , l a y o u t=l a y o u t . fruchterman . r e i n g o l d ,
edge . arrow . s i z e = 0 . 5 , v e r t e x . s i z e =15 ,
v e r t e x . l a b e l =seq ( 1 , na ) )
We now randomly create credit scores for these banks. Let’s assume
we have four levels of credit, {0, 1, 2, 3}, where lower scores represent
higher credit quality.
#CREATE CREDIT SCORES
Ri = matrix ( f l o o r ( r u n i f ( na ) * 4 ) , na , 1 )
> Ri
[1
[2
[3
[4
[5
,]
,]
,]
,]
,]
[ ,1]
1
3
0
3
0
making connections: network theory
Figure 13.15: Banking network
adjacency matrix and plot
357
358
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
[6 ,]
[7 ,]
[8 ,]
[9 ,]
[10 ,]
[11 ,]
[12 ,]
[13 ,]
[14 ,]
[15 ,]
0
2
0
0
2
0
2
2
1
3
We may now use this generated data to compute the overall risk score
and risk increments, discussed later.
#COMPUTE OVERALL RISK SCORE AND RISK INCREMENT
r e s = NetRisk ( Ri , X)
S = r e s [ [ 1 ] ] ; p r i n t ( c ( " Risk S c o r e " , S ) )
RiskIncr = res [ [ 2 ] ]
[ 1 ] " Risk S c o r e "
" 14.6287388383278 "
We compute the fragility of this network.
#NETWORK FRAGILITY
deg = rowSums (X) − 1
f r a g = mean ( deg ^2) / mean ( deg )
print ( c ( " F r a g i l i t y score = " , frag ) )
[ 1 ] " F r a g i l i t y score = " " 8.1551724137931 "
The centrality of the network is computed and plotted with the following code. See Figure 13.16.
#NODE EIGEN VALUE CENTRALITY
cent = evcent ( g ) $ vector
p r i n t ( " Normalized C e n t r a l i t y S c o r e s " )
print ( cent )
s o r t e d _ c e n t = s o r t ( cent , d e c r e a s i n g =TRUE, index . r e t u r n =TRUE)
S c e n t = s o r t e d _ c e n t $x
idxScent = sorted _ cent $ ix
b a r p l o t ( t ( S c e n t ) , c o l = " dark red " , x l a b = " Node Number" ,
names . arg=i d x S c e n t , cex . names = 0 . 7 5 )
making connections: network theory
359
> print ( cent )
[ 1 ] 0.7648332 1.0000000 0.7134844 0.6848305 0.7871945 0.8721071
[ 7 ] 0.7389360 0.7788079 0.5647471 0.7336387 0.9142595 0.8857590
[13] 0.7183145 0.7907269 0.8365532
Figure 13.16: Centrality for the 15
banks.
And finally, we compute diameter.
p r i n t ( diameter ( g ) )
[1] 2
13.13.2
Risk Decomposition
Because the function S(C, E) is homogenous of degree 1 in C, we may
use this property to decompose the overall systemic score into the contribution from each bank. Applying Euler’s theorem, we write this decomposition as:
∂S
∂S
∂S
S=
C1 +
C2 + . . . +
Cn
(13.5)
∂C1
∂C2
∂Cn
∂S
Cj .
The risk contribution of bank j is ∂C
j
The code and output are shown here.
#COMPUTE RISK DECOMPOSITION
RiskDecomp = R i s k I n c r * Ri
s o r t e d _RiskDecomp = s o r t ( RiskDecomp , d e c r e a s i n g =TRUE,
index . r e t u r n =TRUE)
RD = s o r t e d _RiskDecomp$x
360
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
idxRD = s o r t e d _RiskDecomp$ i x
p r i n t ( " Risk C o n t r i b u t i o n " ) ;
p r i n t ( RiskDecomp ) ;
p r i n t (sum( RiskDecomp ) )
b a r p l o t ( t (RD) , c o l = " dark green " , x l a b = " Node Number" ,
names . arg=idxRD , cex . names = 0 . 7 5 )
The output is as follows:
> p r i n t ( RiskDecomp ) ;
[ ,1]
[ 1 , ] 0.7861238
[ 2 , ] 2.3583714
[ 3 , ] 0.0000000
[ 4 , ] 1.7431441
[ 5 , ] 0.0000000
[ 6 , ] 0.0000000
[ 7 , ] 1.7089648
[ 8 , ] 0.0000000
[ 9 , ] 0.0000000
[ 1 0 , ] 1.3671719
[ 1 1 , ] 0.0000000
[ 1 2 , ] 1.7089648
[ 1 3 , ] 1.8456820
[ 1 4 , ] 0.8544824
[ 1 5 , ] 2.2558336
> p r i n t (sum( RiskDecomp ) )
[ 1 ] 14.62874
We see that the total of the individual bank risk contributions does indeed add up to the aggregate systemic risk score of 14.63, computed
earlier.
The resulting sorted risk contributions of each node (bank) are shown
in Figure 13.17.
13.13.3
Normalized Risk Score
We may also normalize the risk score to isolate the network effect by
computing
√
C> E C
S̄ =
(13.6)
kC k
making connections: network theory
361
Figure 13.17: Risk Decompositions
for the 15 banks.
√
where kC k = C > C is the norm of vector C. When there are no network
effects, E = I, the identity matrix, and S̄ = 1, i.e., the normalized baseline
risk level with no network (system-wide) effects is unity. As S̄ increases
above 1, it implies greater network effects.
# Compute n o r m a l i z e d s c o r e SBar
Sbar = S / s q r t ( t ( Ri ) %*% Ri )
p r i n t ( " Sbar ( normalized r i s k s c o r e " ) ;
> p r i n t ( Sbar )
[ ,1]
[ 1 , ] 2.180724
13.13.4
Risk Increments
We are also interested in the extent to which a bank may impact the
overall risk of the system if it begins to experience deterioration in credit
quality. Therefore, we may compute the sensitivity of S to C:
Risk increment = Ij =
> RiskIncr
[ ,1]
[ 1 , ] 0.7861238
∂S
, ∀j
∂Cj
(13.7)
362
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
[2 ,]
[3 ,]
[4 ,]
[5 ,]
[6 ,]
[7 ,]
[8 ,]
[9 ,]
[10 ,]
[11 ,]
[12 ,]
[13 ,]
[14 ,]
[15 ,]
0.7861238
0.6835859
0.5810480
0.7177652
0.8544824
0.8544824
0.8203031
0.5810480
0.6835859
0.9228410
0.8544824
0.9228410
0.8544824
0.7519445
Note that risk increments were previously computed in the function for
the risk score. We also plot this in sorted order, as shown in Figure 13.18.
The code for this plot is shown here.
#PLOT RISK INCREMENTS
s o r t e d _ R i s k I n c r = s o r t ( R i s k I n c r , d e c r e a s i n g =TRUE,
index . r e t u r n =TRUE)
RI = s o r t e d _ R i s k I n c r $x
idxRI = s o r t e d _ R i s k I n c r $ i x
p r i n t ( " Risk Increment ( per u n i t i n c r e a s e i n any node r i s k " )
print ( RiskIncr )
b a r p l o t ( t ( RI ) , c o l = " dark blue " , x l a b = " Node Number" ,
names . arg=idxRI , cex . names = 0 . 7 5 )
13.13.5
Criticality
Criticality is compromise-weighted centrality. This new measure is defined as y = C × x where x is the centrality vector for the network, and
y, C, x ∈ Rn . Note that this is an element-wise multiplication of vectors
C and x. Critical nodes need immediate attention, either because they
are heavily compromised or they are of high centrality, or both. It offers a way for regulators to prioritize their attention to critical financial
institutions, and pre-empt systemic risk from blowing up.
#CRITICALITY
c r i t = Ri * c e n t
making connections: network theory
363
Figure 13.18: Risk Increments for
the 15 banks.
p r i n t ( " C r i t i c a l i t y Vector " )
print ( c r i t )
s o r t e d _ c r i t = s o r t ( c r i t , d e c r e a s i n g =TRUE, index . r e t u r n =TRUE)
S c r i t = s o r t e d _ c r i t $x
i d x S c r i t = sorted _ c r i t $ ix
b a r p l o t ( t ( S c r i t ) , c o l = " orange " , x l a b = " Node Number" ,
names . arg= i d x S c r i t , cex . names = 0 . 7 5 )
> print ( c r i t )
[ ,1]
[ 1 , ] 0.7648332
[ 2 , ] 3.0000000
[ 3 , ] 0.0000000
[ 4 , ] 2.0544914
[ 5 , ] 0.0000000
[ 6 , ] 0.0000000
[ 7 , ] 1.4778721
[ 8 , ] 0.0000000
[ 9 , ] 0.0000000
[ 1 0 , ] 1.4672773
[ 1 1 , ] 0.0000000
[ 1 2 , ] 1.7715180
[ 1 3 , ] 1.4366291
[ 1 4 , ] 0.7907269
364
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
[ 1 5 , ] 2.5096595
The plot of criticality is shown in Figure 13.19.
Figure 13.19: Criticality for the 15
banks.
13.13.6
Cross Risk
Since the systemic risk score S is a composite of network effects and
credit quality, the risk contributions of all banks are impacted when
any single bank suffers credit deterioration. A bank has the power to
impose externalities on other banks, and we may assess how each bank’s
risk contribution is impacted by one bank’s C increasing. We do this by
simulating changes in a bank’s credit quality and assessing the increase
in risk contribution for the bank itself and other banks.
#CROSS IMPACT MATRIX
#CHECK FOR SPILLOVER EFFECTS FROM ONE NODE TO ALL OTHERS
d_RiskDecomp = NULL
n = length ( Ri )
for ( j in 1 : n ) {
Ri2 = Ri
Ri2 [ j ] = Ri [ j ]+1
r e s = NetRisk ( Ri2 , X)
d_ Risk = as . matrix ( r e s [ [ 3 ] ] ) − RiskDecomp
d_RiskDecomp = cbind ( d_RiskDecomp , d_ Risk )
}
making connections: network theory
#3D p l o t s
l i b r a r y ( " RColorBrewer " ) ;
library ( " l a t t i c e " ) ;
library ( " latticeExtra " )
cloud ( d_RiskDecomp ,
panel . 3 d . cloud = panel . 3 dbars ,
xbase = 0 . 2 5 , ybase = 0 . 2 5 ,
zlim = c ( min ( d_RiskDecomp ) , max ( d_RiskDecomp ) ) ,
s c a l e s = l i s t ( arrows = FALSE , j u s t = " r i g h t " ) ,
x l a b = "On" , ylab = " From " , z l a b = NULL,
main= " Change i n Risk C o n t r i b u t i o n " ,
c o l . f a c e t = l e v e l . c o l o r s ( d_RiskDecomp ,
a t = do . breaks ( range ( d_RiskDecomp ) , 2 0 ) ,
c o l . r e g i o n s = cm . c o l o r s , c o l o r s = TRUE) ,
c o l o r k e y = l i s t ( c o l = cm . c o l o r s ,
a t = do . breaks ( range ( d_RiskDecomp ) , 2 0 ) ) ,
# s c r e e n = l i s t ( z = 4 0 , x = − 30)
)
brewer . div <− c o l o r R a m p P a l e t t e ( brewer . p a l ( 1 1 , " S p e c t r a l " ) ,
interpolate = " spline " )
l e v e l p l o t ( d_RiskDecomp , a s p e c t = " i s o " ,
c o l . r e g i o n s = brewer . div ( 2 0 ) ,
ylab= " Impact from " , x l a b = " Impact on " ,
main= " Change i n Risk C o n t r i b u t i o n " )
The plots are shown in Figure 13.20. We have used some advanced
plotting functions, so as to demonstrate the facile way in which R generates beautiful plots.
Here we see the effect of a single bank’s C value increasing by 1, and
plot the change in risk contribution of each bank as a consequence. We
notice that the effect on its own risk contribution is much higher than on
that of other banks.
13.13.7
Risk Scaling
This is the increase in normalized risk score S̄ as the number of connections per node increases. We compute this to examine how fast the
score increases as the network becomes more connected. Is this growth
exponential, linear, or logarithmic? We randomly generate graphs with
increasing connectivity, and recompute the risk scores. The resulting
365
366
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
Figure 13.20: Spillover effects.
making connections: network theory
plots are shown in Figure 13.21. We see that the risk increases at a less
than linear rate. This is good news, as systemic risk does not blow up as
banks become more connected.
#RISK SCALING
#SIMULATION OF EFFECT OF INCREASED CONNECTIVITY
#RANDOM GRAPHS
n = 5 0 ; k = 1 0 0 ; pvec=seq ( 0 . 0 5 , 0 . 5 0 , 0 . 0 5 ) ;
svec=NULL; s b a r v e c =NULL
f o r ( p i n pvec ) {
s _temp = NULL
s b a r _temp = NULL
for ( j in 1 : k ) {
g = erdos . r e n y i . game ( n , p , d i r e c t e d =TRUE ) ;
A = get . adjacency ( g )
diag (A) = 1
c = as . matrix ( round ( r u n i f ( n , 0 , 2 ) , 0 ) )
s y s c o r e = as . numeric ( s q r t ( t ( c ) %*% A %*% c ) )
sbarscore = syscore / n
s _temp = c ( s _temp , s y s c o r e )
s b a r _temp = c ( s b a r _temp , s b a r s c o r e )
}
svec = c ( svec , mean ( s _temp ) )
s b a r v e c = c ( sbarvec , mean ( s b a r _temp ) )
}
p l o t ( pvec , svec , type= " l " ,
x l a b = " Prob o f c o n n e c t i n g t o a node " ,
ylab= " S " , lwd =3 , c o l = " red " )
p l o t ( pvec , sbarvec , type= " l " ,
x l a b = " Prob o f c o n n e c t i n g t o a node " ,
ylab= " S_Avg" , lwd =3 , c o l = " red " )
13.13.8
Too Big To Fail?
An often suggested remedy for systemic risk is to break up large banks,
i.e., directly mitigate the too-big-to-fail phenomenon. We calculate the
change in risk score S, and normalized risk score S̄ as the number of
nodes increases, while keeping the average number of connections between nodes constant. This is repeated 5000 times for each fixed number
367
368
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
Figure 13.21: How risk increases
with connectivity of the network.
making connections: network theory
of nodes and the mean risk score across 5000 simulations is plotted on
the y-axis against the number of nodes on the x-axis. We see that systemic risk increases when banks are broken up, but the normalized risk
score decreases. Despite the network effect S̄ declining, overall risk S in
fact increases. See Figure 13.22.
#TOO BIG TO FAIL
#SIMULATION OF EFFECT OF INCREASED NODES AND REDUCED CONNECTIVITY
nvec=seq ( 1 0 , 1 0 0 , 1 0 ) ; k = 5 0 0 0 ; svec=NULL; s b a r v e c =NULL
f o r ( n i n nvec ) {
s _temp = NULL
s b a r _temp = NULL
p = 5/n
for ( j in 1 : k ) {
g = erdos . r e n y i . game ( n , p , d i r e c t e d =TRUE ) ;
A = get . adjacency ( g )
diag (A) = 1
c = as . matrix ( round ( r u n i f ( n , 0 , 2 ) , 0 ) )
s y s c o r e = as . numeric ( s q r t ( t ( c ) %*% A %*% c ) )
sbarscore = syscore / n
s _temp = c ( s _temp , s y s c o r e )
s b a r _temp = c ( s b a r _temp , s b a r s c o r e )
}
svec = c ( svec , mean ( s _temp ) )
s b a r v e c = c ( sbarvec , mean ( s b a r _temp ) )
}
p l o t ( nvec , svec , type= " l " ,
x l a b = "Number o f nodes " , ylab= " S " ,
ylim=c ( 0 , max ( svec ) ) , lwd =3 , c o l = " red " )
p l o t ( nvec , sbarvec , type= " l " ,
x l a b = "Number o f nodes " , ylab= " S_Avg" ,
ylim=c ( 0 , max ( s b a r v e c ) ) , lwd =3 , c o l = " red " )
13.13.9
Application of the model to the banking network in India
The program code for systemic risk networks was applied to real-world
data in India to produce daily maps of the Indian banking network,
as well as the corresponding risk scores. The credit risk vector C was
based on credit ratings for Indian financial institutions (FIs). The net-
369
370
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
Figure 13.22: How risk increases
with connectivity of the network.
making connections: network theory
work adjacency matrix was constructred using the ideas in a paper by
Billio, Getmansky, Lo, and Pelizzon (2012) who create a network using
Granger causality. This directed network comprises an adjacency matrix
of values (0, 1) where node i connects to node j if the returns of bank i
Granger cause those of bank j, i.e., edge Ei,j = 1. This was applied to
U.S. financial institution stock return data, and in a follow-up paper, to
CDS spread data from U.S., Europe, and Japan (see Billio, Getmansky,
Gray, Lo, Merton, and Pelizzon (2014)), where the global financial system
is also found to be highly interconnected. In the application of the Das
(2014) methodology to India, the network matrix is created using this
Granger causality method to Indian FI stock returns.
The system is available in real time and may be accessed directly
through a browser. To begin, different selections may be made of a subset of FIs for analysis. See Figure 13.23 for the screenshots of this step.
Once these selections are made and the “Submit” button is hit, the
system generates the network and the various risk metrics, shown in
Figures 13.24 and 13.25, respectively.
13.14 Map of Science
It is appropriate to end this chapter by showcasing network science with
a wonderful image of the connection network between various scientific
disciplines. See Figure 13.26. Note that the social sciences are most connected to medicine and engineering. But there is homophily here, i.e.,
likes tend to be in groups with likes.
371
372
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
Figure 13.23: Screens for selecting
the relevant set of Indian FIs to
construct the banking network.
making connections: network theory
373
Figure 13.24: Screens for the Indian
FIs banking network. The upper
plot shows the entire network.
The lower plot shows the network
when we mouse over the bank in
the middle of the plot. Red lines
show that the bank is impacted
by the other banks, and blue lines
depict that the bank impacts the
others, in a Granger causal manner.
374
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
Figure 13.25: Screens for systemic
risk metrics of the Indian FIs banking network. The top plot shows
the current risk metrics, and the
bottom plot shows the history from
2008.
making connections: network theory
375
Figure 13.26: The Map of Science.
14
Statistical Brains: Neural Networks
14.1 Overview
Neural Networks (NNs) are one form of nonlinear regression. You are
usually familiar with linear regressions, but nonlinear regressions are
just as easy to understand. In a linear regression, we have
Y = X0 β + e
where X ∈ Rt×n and the regression solution is (as is known from before),
simply equal to β = ( X 0 X )−1 ( X 0 Y ).
To get this result we minimize the sum of squared errors.
min e0 e = (Y − X 0 β)0 (Y − X 0 β)
β
= (Y − X 0 β ) 0 Y − (Y − X 0 β ) 0 ( X 0 β )
= Y 0 Y − ( X 0 β ) 0 Y − Y 0 ( X 0 β ) + β2 ( X 0 X )
= Y 0 Y − 2( X 0 β ) 0 Y + β2 ( X 0 X )
Differentiating w.r.t. β gives the following f.o.c:
2β( X 0 X ) − 2( X 0 Y )
β
=
0
=⇒
=
( X 0 X ) −1 ( X 0 Y )
We can examine this by using the markowitzdata.txt data set.
> data = read . t a b l e ( " markowitzdata . t x t " , header=TRUE)
> dim ( data )
[ 1 ] 1507
10
> names ( data )
[ 1 ] "X .DATE" "SUNW"
"MSFT"
"IBM"
"CSCO"
"AMZN"
[ 8 ] " smb"
" hml "
" rf "
> amzn = as . matrix ( data [ , 6 ] )
> f 3 = as . matrix ( data [ , 7 : 9 ] )
" mktrf "
378
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
> r e s = lm ( amzn ~ f 3 )
> summary ( r e s )
Call :
lm ( formula = amzn ~ f 3 )
Residuals :
Min
1Q
Median
− 0.225716 − 0.014029 − 0.001142
3Q
0.013335
Max
0.329627
Coefficients :
E s t i m a t e Std . E r r o r t value Pr ( >| t |)
( Intercept ) 0.0015168 0.0009284
1.634 0.10249
f3mktrf
1 . 4 1 9 0 8 0 9 0 . 1 0 1 4 8 5 0 1 3 . 9 8 3 < 2e −16 * * *
f3smb
0.5228436 0.1738084
3.008 0.00267 * *
f3hml
− 1.1502401 0 . 2 0 8 1 9 4 2 − 5.525 3 . 8 8 e −08 * * *
−−−
S i g n i f . codes : 0 ï £ ¡ * * * ï £ ¡ 0 . 0 0 1 ï £ ¡ * * ï £ ¡ 0 . 0 1 ï £ ¡ * ï £ ¡ 0 . 0 5 ï £ ¡ . ï £ ¡ 0 . 1 ï £ ¡ ï £ ¡ 1
R e s i d u a l standard e r r o r : 0 . 0 3 5 8 1 on 1503 degrees o f freedom
M u l t i p l e R−squared : 0 . 2 2 3 3 ,
Adjusted R−squared : 0 . 2 2 1 8
F− s t a t i s t i c : 1 4 4 . 1 on 3 and 1503 DF , p−value : < 2 . 2 e −16
>
>
>
>
wuns = matrix ( 1 , length ( amzn ) , 1 )
x = cbind ( wuns , f 3 )
b = s o l v e ( t ( x ) %*% x ) %*% ( t ( x ) %*% amzn )
b
[ ,1]
0.001516848
mktrf 1 . 4 1 9 0 8 0 8 9 4
smb
0.522843591
hml
− 1.150240145
We see at the end of the program listing that our formula for the coefficients of the minimized least squares problem β = ( X 0 X )−1 ( X 0 Y )
exactly matches that from the regression command lm.
14.2 Nonlinear Regression
A nonlinear regression is of the form
Y = f ( X; β) + e
where f (·) is a nonlinear function. Note that, for example, Y = β 0 +
β 1 X + β 2 X 2 + e is not a nonlinear regression, even though it contains
nonlinear terms like X 2 .
Computing the coefficients in a nonlinear regression again follows in
the same way as for a linear regression.
min e0 e = (Y − f ( X; β))0 (Y − f ( X; β))
β
= Y 0 Y − 2 f ( X; β)0 Y + f ( X; β)0 f ( X; β)
statistical brains: neural networks
Differentiating w.r.t. β gives the following f.o.c:
d f ( X; β) 0
d f ( X; β) 0
Y+2
f ( X; β) = 0
−2
dβ
dβ
d f ( X; β) 0
d f ( X; β) 0
Y =
f ( X; β)
dβ
dβ
which is then solved numerically for β ∈ Rn . The approach taken usually
involves the Newton-Raphson method, see for example:
http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Newton’s method.
14.3 Perceptrons
Neural networks are special forms of nonlinear regressions where the
decision system for which the NN is built mimics the way the brain is
supposed to work (whether it works like a NN is up for grabs of course).
The basic building block of a neural network is a perceptron. A perceptron is like a neuron in a human brain. It takes inputs (e.g. sensory in
a real brain) and then produces an output signal. An entire network of
perceptrons is called a neural net.
For example, if you make a credit card application, then the inputs
comprise a whole set of personal data such as age, sex, income, credit
score, employment status, etc, which are then passed to a series of perceptrons in parallel. This is the first “layer” of assessment. Each of the
perceptrons then emits an output signal which may then be passed to
another layer of perceptrons, who again produce another signal. This
second layer is often known as the “hidden” perceptron layer. Finally,
after many hidden layers, the signals are all passed to a single perceptron which emits the decision signal to issue you a credit card or to deny
your application.
Perceptrons may emit continuous signals or binary (0, 1) signals. In
the case of the credit card application, the final perceptron is a binary
one. Such perceptrons are implemented by means of “squashing” functions. For example, a really simple squashing function is one that issues
a 1 if the function value is positive and a 0 if it is negative. More generally,
(
1 if g( x ) > T
S( x ) =
0 if g( x ) ≤ T
where g( x ) is any function taking positive and negative values, for instance, g( x ) ∈ (−∞, +∞). T is a threshold level.
379
380
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
A neural network with many layers is also known as a “multi-layered”
perceptron, i.e., all those perceptrons together may be thought of as one
single, big perceptron. See Figure 14.1 for an example of such a network
f(x)
Figure 14.1: A feed-forward multi-
layer neural network.
x1
x2
y1
x3
y2
x4
y3
z1
Neural net models are related to Deep Learning, where the number of
hidden layers is vastly greater than was possible in the past when computational power was limited. Now, deep learning nets cascade through
20-30 layers, resulting in a surprising ability of neural nets in mimicking
human learning processes. see: http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Deep_
learning. And also see: http://deeplearning.net/.
Binary NNs are also thought of as a category of classifier systems.
They are widely used to divide members of a population into classes.
But NNs with continuous output are also popular. As we will see later,
researchers have used NNs to learn the Black-Scholes option pricing
model.
Areas of application: credit cards, risk management, forecasting corporate defaults, forecasting economic regimes, measuring the gains from
mass mailings by mapping demographics to success rates.
statistical brains: neural networks
14.4 Squashing Functions
Squashing functions may be more general than just binary. They usually
squash the output signal into a narrow range, usually (0, 1). A common
choice is the logistic function (also known as the sigmoid function).
f (x) =
1
1 + e−w x
Think of w as the adjustable weight. Another common choice is the probit function
f ( x ) = Φ(w x )
where Φ(·) is the cumulative normal distribution function.
14.5 How does the NN work?
The easiest way to see how a NN works is to think of the simplest NN,
i.e. one with a single perceptron generating a binary output. The perceptron has n inputs, with values xi , i = 1...n and current weights
wi , i = 1...n. It generates an output y.
The “net input” is defined as
n
∑ wi x i
i =1
If the net input is greater than a threshold T, then the output signal is
y = 1, and if it is less than T, the output is y = 0. The actual output
is called the “desired” output and is denoted d = {0, 1}. Hence, the
“training” data provided to the NN comprises both the inputs xi and the
desired output d.
The output of our single perceptron model will be the sigmoid function of the net input, i.e.
y=
1
1 + exp (− ∑in=1 wi xi )
For a given input set, the error in the NN is
E=
1
2
m
∑ ( y j − d j )2
j =1
where m is the size of the training data set. The optimal NN for given
data is obtained by finding the weights wi that minimize this error function E. Once we have the optimal weights, we have a calibrated “feedforward” neural net.
381
382
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
For a given squashing function f , and input x = [ x1 , x2 , . . . , xn ]0 , the
multi-layer perceptron will given an output at the hidden layer of
!
n
y( x ) = f
w0 +
∑ wj xj
j =1
and then at the final output level the node is
N
z( x ) = f
w0 + ∑ w i · f
n
w0i +
i =1
∑ w ji x j
!!
j =1
where the nested structure of the neural net is quite apparent.
14.5.1
Logit/Probit Model
The special model above with a single perceptron is actually nothing
else than the logit regression model. If the squashing function is taken to
the cumulative normal distribution, then the model becomes the probit
regression model. In both cases though, the model is fitted by minimizing squared errors, not by maximum likelihood, which is how standard
logit/probit models are parameterized.
14.5.2
Connection to hyperplanes
Note that in binary squashing functions, the net input is passed through
a sigmoid function and then compared to the threshold level T. This
sigmoid function is a monotone one. Hence, this means that there must
be a level T 0 at which the net input ∑in=1 wi xi must be for the result to be
on the cusp. The following is the equation for a hyperplane
n
∑ wi x i = T 0
i =1
which also implies that observations in n-dimensional space of the inputs xi , must lie on one side or the other of this hyperplane. If above the
hyperplane, then y = 1, else y = 0. Hence, single perceptrons in neural
nets have a simple geometrical intuition.
14.6 Feedback/Backpropagation
What distinguishes neural nets from ordinary nonlinear regressions is
feedback. Neural nets learn from feedback as they are used. Feedback is
implemented using a technique called backpropagation.
statistical brains: neural networks
Suppose you have a calibrated NN. Now you obtain another observation of data and run it through the NN. Comparing the output value y
with the desired observation d gives you the error for this observation. If
the error is large, then it makes sense to update the weights in the NN,
so as to self-correct. This process of self-correction is known as “backpropagation”.
The benefit of backpropagation is that a full re-fitting exercise is not
required. Using simple rules the correction to the weights can be applied
gradually in a learning manner.
Lets look at backpropagation with a simple example using a single
perceptron. Consider the j-th perceptron. The sigmoid of this is
yj =
1
1 + exp − ∑in=1 wi xij
where y j is the output of the j-th perceptron, and xij is the i-th input to
the j-th perceptron. The error from this observation is (y j − d j ). Recalling
2
that E = 12 ∑m
j=1 ( y j − d j ) , we may compute the change in error with
respect to the j-th output, i.e.
∂E
= yj − dj
∂y j
Note also that
dy j
= y j (1 − y j ) wi
dxij
and
dy j
= y j (1 − y j ) xij
dwi
Next, we examine how the error changes with input values:
dy j
∂E
∂E
=
×
= ( y j − d j ) y j (1 − y j ) wi
∂xij
∂y j
dxij
We can now get to the value of interest, which is the change in error
value with respect to the weights
dy j
∂E
∂E
=
×
= (y j − d j )y j (1 − y j ) xij , ∀i
∂wi
∂y j
dwi
We thus have one equation for each weight wi and each observation j.
(Note that the wi apply across perceptrons. A more general case might
be where we have weights for each perceptron, i.e., wij .) Instead of updating on just one observation, we might want to do this for many observations in which case the error derivative would be
∂E
= ∑(y j − d j )y j (1 − y j ) xij , ∀i
∂wi
j
383
384
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
∂E
Therefore, if ∂w
> 0, then we would need to reduce wi to bring down
i
E. By how much? Here is where some art and judgment is imposed.
There is a tuning parameter 0 < γ < 1 which we apply to wi to shrink it
∂E
when the weight needs to be reduced. Likewise, if the derivative ∂w
< 0,
i
then we would increase wi by dividing it by γ.
14.6.1
Extension to many perceptrons
Our notation now becomes extended to weights wik which stand for the
weight on the i-th input to the k-th perceptron. The derivative for the
error becomes
∂E
=
∂wik
∑(y j − d j )y j (1 − y j )xikj , ∀i, k
j
Hence all nodes in the network have their weights updated. In many
cases of course, we can just take the derivatives numerically. Change the
weight wik and see what happens to the error.
14.7 Research Applications
14.7.1
Discovering Black-Scholes
See the paper by Hutchinson, Lo, and Poggio (1994)), A Nonparametric
Approach to Pricing and Hedging Securities Via Learning Networks, The
Journal of Finance, Vol XLIX.
14.7.2
Forecasting
See the paper by Ghiassi, Saidane, and Zimbra (2005). “A dynamic artificial neural network model for forecasting time series events,” International Journal of Forecasting 21, 341–362.
14.8 Package neuralnet in R
The package focuses on multi-layer perceptrons (MLP), see Bishop
(1995), which are well applicable when modeling functional relationships. The underlying structure of an MLP is a directed graph, i.e. it
consists of vertices and directed edges, in this context called neurons and
synapses. [See Bishop (1995), Neural networks for pattern recognition.
Oxford University Press, New York.]
statistical brains: neural networks
The data set used by this package as an example is the infert data set
that comes bundled with R.
> library ( neuralnet )
Loading r e q u i r e d package : g r i d
Loading r e q u i r e d package : MASS
> names ( i n f e r t )
[ 1 ] " education "
" age "
" parity "
" induced "
[ 5 ] " case "
" spontaneous "
" stratum "
" pooled . stratum "
> summary ( i n f e r t )
education
age
parity
induced
0−5y r s : 12
Min .
:21.00
Min .
:1.000
Min .
:0.0000
6 −11 y r s : 1 2 0
1 s t Qu . : 2 8 . 0 0
1 s t Qu . : 1 . 0 0 0
1 s t Qu . : 0 . 0 0 0 0
12+ y r s : 1 1 6
Median : 3 1 . 0 0
Median : 2 . 0 0 0
Median : 0 . 0 0 0 0
Mean
:31.50
Mean
:2.093
Mean
:0.5726
3 rd Qu . : 3 5 . 2 5
3 rd Qu . : 3 . 0 0 0
3 rd Qu . : 1 . 0 0 0 0
Max .
:44.00
Max .
:6.000
Max .
:2.0000
case
spontaneous
stratum
pooled . stratum
Min .
:0.0000
Min .
:0.0000
Min .
: 1.00
Min .
: 1.00
1 s t Qu . : 0 . 0 0 0 0
1 s t Qu . : 0 . 0 0 0 0
1 s t Qu . : 2 1 . 0 0
1 s t Qu . : 1 9 . 0 0
Median : 0 . 0 0 0 0
Median : 0 . 0 0 0 0
Median : 4 2 . 0 0
Median : 3 6 . 0 0
Mean
:0.3347
Mean
:0.5766
Mean
:41.87
Mean
:33.58
3 rd Qu . : 1 . 0 0 0 0
3 rd Qu . : 1 . 0 0 0 0
3 rd Qu . : 6 2 . 2 5
3 rd Qu . : 4 8 . 2 5
Max .
:1.0000
Max .
:2.0000
Max .
:83.00
Max .
:63.00
This data set examines infertility after induced and spontaneous abortion. The variables induced and spontaneous take values in {0, 1, 2} indicating the number of previous abortions. The variable parity denotes
the number of births. The variable case equals 1 if the woman is infertile
and 0 otherwise. The idea is to model infertility.
As a first step, let’s fit a logit model to the data.
> r e s = glm ( c a s e ~ age+ p a r i t y +induced+spontaneous ,
family=binomial ( l i n k= " l o g i t " ) , data= i n f e r t )
> summary ( r e s )
Call :
glm ( formula = c a s e ~ age + p a r i t y + induced + spontaneous ,
family = binomial ( l i n k = " l o g i t " ) ,
data = i n f e r t )
Deviance R e s i d u a l s :
Min
1Q
Median
− 1.6281 − 0.8055 − 0.5298
Coefficients :
3Q
0.8668
Max
2.6141
385
386
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
E s t i m a t e Std . E r r o r z value Pr ( >| z |)
( I n t e r c e p t ) − 2.85239
1 . 0 0 4 2 8 − 2.840 0 . 0 0 4 5 1 * *
age
0.05318
0.03014
1.764 0.07767 .
parity
− 0.70883
0 . 1 8 0 9 1 − 3.918 8 . 9 2 e −05 * * *
induced
1.18966
0.28987
4 . 1 0 4 4 . 0 6 e −05 * * *
spontaneous 1 . 9 2 5 3 4
0.29863
6 . 4 4 7 1 . 1 4 e −10 * * *
−−−
S i g n i f . codes : 0 ï £ ¡ * * * ï £ ¡ 0 . 0 0 1 ï £ ¡ * * ï £ ¡ 0 . 0 1 ï £ ¡ * ï £ ¡ 0 . 0 5 ï £ ¡ . ï £ ¡ 0 . 1 ï £ ¡ ï £ ¡ 1
( D i s p e r s i o n parameter f o r binomial family taken t o be 1 )
Null deviance : 3 1 6 . 1 7
R e s i d u a l deviance : 2 6 0 . 9 4
AIC : 2 7 0 . 9 4
on 247
on 243
degrees o f freedom
degrees o f freedom
Number o f F i s h e r S c o r i n g i t e r a t i o n s : 4
All explanatory variables are statistically significant. We now run this
data through a neural net, as follows.
> nn = n e u r a l n e t ( c a s e ~age+ p a r i t y +induced+spontaneous , hidden =2 , data= i n f e r t )
> nn
C a l l : n e u r a l n e t ( formula = c a s e ~ age + p a r i t y + induced + spontaneous ,
data = i n f e r t , hidden = 2 )
1 r e p e t i t i o n was c a l c u l a t e d .
E r r o r Reached Threshold S t e p s
1 19.36463007
0 . 0 0 8 9 4 9 5 3 6 6 1 8 20111
> nn$ r e s u l t . matrix
1
error
19.364630070610
reached . t h r e s h o l d
0.008949536618
steps
20111.000000000000
I n t e r c e p t . to . 1 layhid1
9.422192588834
age . t o . 1 l a y h i d 1
− 1.293381222338
parity . to . 1 layhid1
− 19.489105822032
induced . t o . 1 l a y h i d 1
37.616977251411
spontaneous . t o . 1 l a y h i d 1
32.647955233030
I n t e r c e p t . to . 1 layhid2
5.142357912661
age . t o . 1 l a y h i d 2
− 0.077293384832
parity . to . 1 layhid2
2.875918354167
induced . t o . 1 l a y h i d 2
− 4.552792010965
spontaneous . t o . 1 l a y h i d 2
− 5.558639450018
I n t e r c e p t . to . case
1.155876751703
1 layhid . 1 . to . case
− 0.545821730892
1 layhid . 2 . to . case
− 1.022853550121
Now we can go ahead and visualize the neural net. See Figure 14.2.
We see the weights on the initial input variables that go into two hidden perceptrons, and then these are fed into the output perceptron, that
generates the result. We can look at the data and output as follows:
> head ( cbind ( nn$ c o v a r i a t e , nn$ n e t . r e s u l t [ [ 1 ] ] ) )
[ ,1] [ ,2] [ ,3] [ ,4]
[ ,5]
1
26
6
1
2 0.1420779618
2
42
1
1
0 0.5886305435
statistical brains: neural networks
1
Figure 14.2: The neural net for the
infert data set with two percep-
1
trons in a single hidden layer.
age
9.4
29
221
33
8
9
772
-0.0
-1.
9
-0
11
parity
45
82
59
87
2.
588
1.15
.5
489
-19.
case
.6
37
-4.5
527
-
85
22
0
1.
32.
647
96
9
6
5.1423
16
98
2
induced
spontaneous
387
4
6
58
5
-5.
Error: 19.36463 Steps: 20111
388
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
3
4
5
6
39
34
35
36
6
4
3
4
2
2
1
2
0
0
1
1
0.1330583729
0.1404906398
0.4175799845
0.8385294748
We can compare the output to that from the logit model, by looking at
the correlation of the fitted values from both models.
> c o r ( cbind ( nn$ n e t . r e s u l t [ [ 1 ] ] , r e s $ f i t t e d . v a l u e s ) )
[ ,1]
[ ,2]
[ 1 , ] 1.0000000000 0.8814759106
[ 2 , ] 0.8814759106 1.0000000000
As we see, the models match up with 88% correlation. The output is a
probability of infertility.
We can add in an option for back propagation, and see how the results
change.
> nn2 = n e u r a l n e t ( c a s e~age+ p a r i t y +induced+spontaneous ,
hidden =2 , a l g o r i t h m= " rprop+ " , data= i n f e r t )
> c o r ( cbind ( nn2$ n e t . r e s u l t [ [ 1 ] ] , r e s $ f i t t e d . v a l u e s ) )
[ ,1]
[ ,2]
[ 1 , ] 1.00000000 0.88816742
[ 2 , ] 0.88816742 1.00000000
> c o r ( cbind ( nn2$ n e t . r e s u l t [ [ 1 ] ] , nn$ f i t t e d . r e s u l t [ [ 1 ] ] ) )
There does not appear to be any major improvement.
Given a calibrated neural net, how do we use it to compute values for
a new observation? Here is an example.
> compute ( nn , c o v a r i a t e =matrix ( c ( 3 0 , 1 , 0 , 1 ) , 1 , 4 ) )
$ neurons
$ neurons [ [ 1 ] ]
[ ,1] [ ,2] [ ,3] [ ,4] [ ,5]
[1 ,]
1
30
1
0
1
$ neurons [ [ 2 ] ]
[ ,1]
[ ,2]
[ ,3]
[1 ,]
1 0.00000009027594872 0.5351507372
$ net . r e s u l t
[ ,1]
statistical brains: neural networks
[ 1 , ] 0.6084958711
We can assess statistical significance of the model as follows:
> c o n f i d e n c e . i n t e r v a l ( nn , alpha = 0 . 1 0 )
$ lower . c i
$ lower . c i [ [ 1 ] ]
$ lower . c i [ [ 1 ] ] [ [ 1 ] ]
[ ,1]
[ ,2]
[1 ,]
1.942871917
1.0100502322
[2 ,]
− 2.178214123 − 0.1677202246
[ 3 , ] − 32.411347153 − 0.6941528859
[ 4 , ] 1 2 . 3 1 1 1 3 9 7 9 6 − 9.8846504753
[ 5 , ] 1 0 . 3 3 9 7 8 1 6 0 3 − 12.1349900614
$ lower . c i [ [ 1 ] ] [ [ 2 ] ]
[ ,1]
[ 1 , ] 0.7352919387
[ 2 , ] − 0.7457112438
[ 3 , ] − 1.4851089618
$upper . c i
$upper . c i [ [ 1 ] ]
$upper . c i [ [ 1 ] ] [ [ 1 ] ]
[ ,1]
[ 1 , ] 16.9015132608
[ 2 , ] − 0.4085483215
[ 3 , ] − 6.5668644910
[ 4 , ] 62.9228147066
[ 5 , ] 54.9561288631
[ ,2]
9.27466559308
0.01313345496
6.44598959422
0.77906645334
1.01771116133
$upper . c i [ [ 1 ] ] [ [ 2 ] ]
[ ,1]
[ 1 , ] 1.5764615647
[ 2 , ] − 0.3459322180
[ 3 , ] − 0.5605981384
$ nic
[ 1 ] 21.19262393
The confidence level is (1 − α). This is at the 90% level, and at the 5%
level we get:
> c o n f i d e n c e . i n t e r v a l ( nn , alpha = 0 . 9 5 )
$ lower . c i
$ lower . c i [ [ 1 ] ]
$ lower . c i [ [ 1 ] ] [ [ 1 ] ]
[ ,1]
[ ,2]
[1 ,]
9.137058342 4.98482188887
[2 ,]
− 1.327113719 − 0.08074072852
[ 3 , ] − 19.981740610 2 . 7 3 9 8 1 6 4 7 8 0 9
[ 4 , ] 3 6 . 6 5 2 2 4 2 4 5 4 − 4.75605852615
[ 5 , ] 3 1 . 7 9 7 5 0 0 4 1 6 − 5.80934975682
$ lower . c i [ [ 1 ] ] [ [ 2 ] ]
[ ,1]
[ 1 , ] 1.1398427910
[ 2 , ] − 0.5534421216
[ 3 , ] − 1.0404761197
$upper . c i
$upper . c i [ [ 1 ] ]
389
390
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
$upper . c i [ [ 1 ] ] [ [ 1 ] ]
[ ,1]
[1 ,]
9.707326836
[2 ,]
− 1.259648725
[ 3 , ] − 18.996471034
[ 4 , ] 38.581712048
[ 5 , ] 33.498410050
[ ,2]
5.29989393645
− 0.07384604115
3.01202023024
− 4.34952549578
− 5.30792914321
$upper . c i [ [ 1 ] ] [ [ 2 ] ]
[ ,1]
[ 1 , ] 1.1719107124
[ 2 , ] − 0.5382013402
[ 3 , ] − 1.0052309806
$ nic
[ 1 ] 21.19262393
14.9 Package nnet in R
We repeat these calculations using this alternate package.
> nn3 = nnet ( c a s e~age+ p a r i t y +induced+spontaneous , data= i n f e r t , s i z e =2)
# w e i g h t s : 13
i n i t i a l value 5 8 . 6 7 5 0 3 2
i t e r 10 value 4 7 . 9 2 4 3 1 4
i t e r 20 value 4 1 . 0 3 2 9 6 5
i t e r 30 value 4 0 . 1 6 9 6 3 4
i t e r 40 value 3 9 . 5 4 8 0 1 4
i t e r 50 value 3 9 . 0 2 5 0 7 9
i t e r 60 value 3 8 . 6 5 7 7 8 8
i t e r 70 value 3 8 . 4 6 4 0 3 5
i t e r 80 value 3 8 . 2 7 3 8 0 5
i t e r 90 value 3 8 . 1 8 9 7 9 5
i t e r 100 value 3 8 . 1 1 6 5 9 5
f i n a l value 3 8 . 1 1 6 5 9 5
stopped a f t e r 100 i t e r a t i o n s
> nn3
a 4−2−1 network with 13 weights
i n p u t s : age p a r i t y induced spontaneous
output ( s ) : c a s e
options were −
> nn3 . out = p r e d i c t ( nn3 )
> dim ( nn3 . out )
[ 1 ] 248
1
> c o r ( cbind ( nn$ f i t t e d . r e s u l t [ [ 1 ] ] , nn3 . out ) )
statistical brains: neural networks
[ ,1]
[1 ,]
1
We see that package nnet gives the same result as that from package
neuralnet.
As another example of classification, rather than probability, we revisit
the IRIS data set we have used in the realm of Bayesian classifiers.
>
>
>
>
>
data ( i r i s )
# use h a l f the i r i s data
i r = rbind ( i r i s 3 [ , , 1 ] , i r i s 3 [ , , 2 ] , i r i s 3 [ , , 3 ] )
t a r g e t s = c l a s s . ind ( c ( rep ( " s " , 5 0 ) , rep ( " c " , 5 0 ) , rep ( " v " , 5 0 ) ) )
samp = c ( sample ( 1 : 5 0 , 2 5 ) , sample ( 5 1 : 1 0 0 , 2 5 ) , sample ( 1 0 1 : 1 5 0 , 2 5 ) )
> i r 1 = nnet ( i r [ samp , ] , t a r g e t s [ samp , ] , s i z e = 2 , rang = 0 . 1 ,
decay = 5e − 4, maxit = 2 0 0 )
# w e i g h t s : 19
i n i t i a l value 5 7 . 0 1 7 8 6 9
i t e r 10 value 4 3 . 4 0 1 1 3 4
i t e r 20 value 3 0 . 3 3 1 1 2 2
i t e r 30 value 2 7 . 1 0 0 9 0 9
i t e r 40 value 2 6 . 4 5 9 4 4 1
i t e r 50 value 1 8 . 8 9 9 7 1 2
i t e r 60 value 1 8 . 0 8 2 3 7 9
i t e r 70 value 1 7 . 7 1 6 3 0 2
i t e r 80 value 1 7 . 5 7 4 7 1 3
i t e r 90 value 1 7 . 5 5 5 6 8 9
i t e r 100 value 1 7 . 5 2 8 9 8 9
i t e r 110 value 1 7 . 5 2 3 7 8 8
i t e r 120 value 1 7 . 5 2 1 7 6 1
i t e r 130 value 1 7 . 5 2 1 5 7 8
i t e r 140 value 1 7 . 5 2 0 8 4 0
i t e r 150 value 1 7 . 5 2 0 6 4 9
i t e r 150 value 1 7 . 5 2 0 6 4 9
f i n a l value 1 7 . 5 2 0 6 4 9
converged
> o r i g = max . c o l ( t a r g e t s [−samp , ] )
> orig
[1] 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2
[36] 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 3 3 3 3
[71] 3 3 3 3 3
> pred = max . c o l ( p r e d i c t ( i r 1 , i r [−samp , ] ) )
> pred
[1] 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2
[36] 3 3 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 3 1 1 1 1 3 3 3 3
[71] 3 3 3 3 3
> t a b l e ( o r i g , pred )
pred
orig 1 2 3
1 20 0 5
2 2 2 2 2 2 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1
3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3
2 2 2 2 2 2 1 3 3 1 1 1 1 1 1 1
3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3 3
391
392
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
2
3
0 25 0
0 0 25
15
Zero or One: Optimal Digital Portfolios
Digital assets are investments with returns that are binary in nature, i.e.,
they either have a very large or very small payoff. We explore the features of optimal portfolios of digital assets such as venture investments,
credit assets and lotteries. These portfolios comprise correlated assets
with joint Bernoulli distributions. Using a simple, standard, fast recursion technique to generate the return distribution of the portfolio, we
derive guidelines on how investors in digital assets may think about constructing their portfolios. We find that digital portfolios are better when
they are homogeneous in the size of the assets, but heterogeneous in the
success probabilities of the asset components.
The return distributions of digital portfolios are highly skewed and
fat-tailed. A good example of such a portfolio is a venture fund. A simple representation of the payoff to a digital investment is Bernoulli with
a large payoff for a successful outcome and a very small (almost zero)
payoff for a failed one. The probability of success of digital investments
is typically small, in the region of 5–25% for new ventures (see Das, Jagannathan and Sarin (2003)). Optimizing portfolios of such investments
is therefore not amenable to standard techniques used for mean-variance
optimization.
It is also not apparent that the intuitions obtained from the meanvariance setting carry over to portfolios of Bernoulli assets. For instance,
it is interesting to ask, ceteris paribus, whether diversification by increasing the number of assets in the digital portfolio is always a good
thing. Since Bernoulli portfolios involve higher moments, how diversification is achieved is by no means obvious. We may also ask whether
it is preferable to include assets with as little correlation as possible
or is there a sweet spot for the optimal correlation levels of the assets?
Should all the investments be of even size, or is it preferable to take a
394
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
few large bets and several small ones? And finally, is a mixed portfolio
of safe and risky assets preferred to one where the probability of success
is more uniform across assets? These are all questions that are of interest
to investors in digital type portfolios, such as CDO investors, venture
capitalists and investors in venture funds.
We will use a method that is based on standard recursion for modeling of the exact return distribution of a Bernoulli portfolio. This method
on which we build was first developed by Andersen, Sidenius and Basu
(2003) for generating loss distributions of credit portfolios. We then examine the properties of these portfolios in a stochastic dominance framework framework to provide guidelines to digital investors. These guidelines are found to be consistent with prescriptions from expected utility
optimization. The prescriptions are as follows:
1. Holding all else the same, more digital investments are preferred,
meaning for example, that a venture portfolio should seek to maximize market share.
2. As with mean-variance portfolios, lower asset correlation is better, unless the digital investor’s payoff depends on the upper tail of returns.
3. A strategy of a few large bets and many small ones is inferior to one
with bets being roughly the same size.
4. And finally, a mixed portfolio of low-success and high-success assets
is better than one with all assets of the same average success probability level.
Section 15.1 explains the methodology used. Section 15.4 presents the
results. Conclusions and further discussion are in Section 15.5.
15.1 Modeling Digital Portfolios
Assume that the investor has a choice of n investments in digital assets
(e.g., start-up firms). The investments are indexed i = 1, 2, . . . , n. Each investment has a probability of success that is denoted qi , and if successful,
the payoff returned is Si dollars. With probability (1 − qi ), the investment will not work out, the start-up will fail, and the money will be lost
in totality. Therefore, the payoff (cashflow) is
(
Si with prob qi
Payoff = Ci =
(15.1)
0 with prob (1 − qi )
zero or one: optimal digital portfolios
The specification of the investment as a Bernoulli trial is a simple representation of reality in the case of digital portfolios. This mimics well
for example, the case of the venture capital business. Two generalizations might be envisaged. First, we might extend the model to allowing
Si to be random, i.e., drawn from a range of values. This will complicate
the mathematics, but not add much in terms of enriching the model’s
results. Second, the failure payoff might be non-zero, say an amount ai .
Then we have a pair of Bernoulli payoffs {Si , ai }. Note that we can decompose these investment payoffs into a project with constant payoff ai
plus another project with payoffs {Si − ai , 0}, the latter being exactly the
original setting where the failure payoff is zero. Hence, the version of the
model we solve in this note, with zero failure payoffs, is without loss of
generality.
Unlike stock portfolios where the choice set of assets is assumed to
be multivariate normal, digital asset investments have a joint Bernoulli
distribution. Portfolio returns of these investments are unlikely to be
Gaussian, and hence higher-order moments are likely to matter more.
In order to generate the return distribution for the portfolio of digital
assets, we need to account for the correlations across digital investments.
We adopt the following simple model of correlation. Define yi to be the
performance proxy for the i-th asset. This proxy variable will be simulated for comparison with a threshold level of performance to determine
whether the asset yielded a success or failure. It is defined by the following function, widely used in the correlated default modeling literature,
see for example Andersen, Sidenius and Basu (2003):
yi = ρi X +
q
1 − ρ2i Zi ,
i = 1...n
(15.2)
where ρi ∈ [0, 1] is a coefficient that correlates threshold yi with a normalized common factor X ∼ N (0, 1). The common factor drives the
correlations amongst the digital assets in the portfolio. We assume that
Zi ∼ N (0, 1) and Corr( X, Zi ) = 0, ∀i. Hence, the correlation between
assets i and j is given by ρi × ρ j . Note that the mean and variance of yi
are: E(yi ) = 0, Var (yi ) = 1, ∀i. Conditional on X, the values of yi are all
independent, as Corr( Zi , Zj ) = 0.
We now formalize the probability model governing the success or
failure of the digital investment. We define a variable xi , with distribution function F (·), such that F ( xi ) = qi , the probability of success of the
digital investment. Conditional on a fixed value of X, the probability of
395
396
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
success of the i-th investment is defined as
piX ≡ Pr [yi < xi | X ]
Assuming F to be the normal distribution function, we have
q
X
2
pi = Pr ρi X + 1 − ρi Zi < xi | X


x
−
ρ
X
i
= Pr  Zi < qi
|X
1 − ρ2i
#
"
F −1 ( q i ) − ρ i X
p
= Φ
1 − ρi
(15.3)
(15.4)
where Φ(.) is the cumulative normal density function. Therefore, given
the level of the common factor X, asset correlation ρ, and the unconditional success probabilities qi , we obtain the conditional success probability for each asset piX . As X varies, so does piX . For the numerical
examples here we choose the function F ( xi ) to the cumulative normal
probability function.
We use a fast technique for building up distributions for sums of
Bernoulli random variables. In finance, this recursion technique was introduced in the credit portfolio modeling literature by Andersen, Sidenius and Basu (2003).
We deem an investment in a digital asset as successful if it achieves
its high payoff Si . The cashflow from the portfolio is a random variable
C = ∑in=1 Ci . The maximum cashflow that may be generated by the
portfolio will be the sum of all digital asset cashflows, because each and
every outcome was a success, i.e.,
n
Cmax =
∑
Si
(15.5)
i =1
To keep matters simple, we assume that each Si is an integer, and that
we round off the amounts to the nearest significant digit. So, if the
smallest unit we care about is a million dollars, then each Si will be in
units of integer millions.
Recall that, conditional on a value of X, the probability of success of
digital asset i is given as piX . The recursion technique will allow us to
generate the portfolio cashflow probability distribution for each level of
X. We will then simply compose these conditional (on X) distributions
using the marginal distribution for X, denoted g( X ), into the unconditional distribution for the entire portfolio. Therefore, we define the
zero or one: optimal digital portfolios
probability of total cashflow from the portfolio, conditional on X, to be
f (C | X ). Then, the unconditional cashflow distribution of the portfolio
becomes
Z
f (C ) =
f (C | X ) · g( X ) dX
(15.6)
X
The distribution f (C | X ) is easily computed numerically as follows.
We index the assets with i = 1 . . . n. The cashflow from all assets
taken together will range from zero to Cmax . Suppose this range is broken into integer buckets, resulting in NB buckets in total, each one containing an increasing level of total cashflow. We index these buckets by
j = 1 . . . NB , with the cashflow in each bucket equal to Bj . Bj represents
the total cashflow from all assets (some pay off and some do not), and
the buckets comprise the discrete support for the entire distribution of
total cashflow from the portfolio. For example, suppose we had 10 assets, each with a payoff of Ci = 3. Then Cmax = 30. A plausible set of
buckets comprising the support of the cashflow distribution would be:
{0, 3, 6, 9, 12, 15, 18, 21, 24, 27, Cmax }.
Define P(k, Bj ) as the probability of bucket j’s cashflow level Bj if we
account for the first k assets. For example, if we had just 3 assets, with
payoffs of value 1,3,2 respectively, then we would have 7 buckets, i.e.
Bj = {0, 1, 2, 3, 4, 5, 6}. After accounting for the first asset, the only
possible buckets with positive probability would be Bj = 0, 1, and after the first two assets, the buckets with positive probability would be
Bj = 0, 1, 3, 4. We begin with the first asset, then the second and so on,
and compute the probability of seeing the returns in each bucket. Each
probability is given by the following recursion:
P(k + 1, Bj ) = P(k, Bj ) [1 − pkX+1 ] + P(k, Bj − Sk+1 ) pkX+1 ,
k = 1, . . . , n − 1.
(15.7)
Thus the probability of a total cashflow of Bj after considering the first
(k + 1) firms is equal to the sum of two probability terms. First, the
probability of the same cashflow Bj from the first k firms, given that
firm (k + 1) did not succeed. Second, the probability of a cashflow of
Bj − Sk+1 from the first k firms and the (k + 1)-st firm does succeed.
We start off this recursion from the first asset, after which the NB
buckets are all of probability zero, except for the bucket with zero cashflow (the first bucket) and the one with S1 cashflow, i.e.,
P(1, 0) = 1 − p1X
P(1, S1 ) = p1X
(15.8)
(15.9)
397
398
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
All the other buckets will have probability zero, i.e., P(1, Bj 6= {0, S1 }) =
0. With these starting values, we can run the system up from the first
asset to the n-th one by repeated application of equation (15.7). Finally,
we will have the entire distribution P(n, Bj ), conditional on a given value
of X. We then compose all these distributions that are conditional on X
into one single cashflow distribution using equation (15.6). This is done
by numerically integrating over all values of X.
15.2 Implementation in R
15.2.1
Basic recursion
Given a set of outcomes and conditional (on state X) probabilities. we
develop the recursion logic above in the following R function:
a s b r e c = f u n c t i o n (w, p ) {
#w : p a y o f f s
#p : p r o b a b i l i t i e s
#BASIC SET UP
N = length (w)
maxloss = sum(w)
bucket = c ( 0 , seq ( maxloss ) )
LP = matrix ( 0 ,N, maxloss +1)
# p r o b a b i l i t y grid over l o s s e s
#DO FIRST FIRM
LP [ 1 , 1 ] = 1−p [ 1 ] ;
LP [ 1 ,w[ 1 ] + 1 ] = p [ 1 ] ;
#LOOP OVER REMAINING FIRMS
f o r ( i i n seq ( 2 ,N) ) {
f o r ( j i n seq ( maxloss + 1 ) ) {
LP [ i , j ] = LP [ i − 1, j ] * (1 − p [ i ] )
i f ( bucket [ j ]−w[ i ] >= 0 ) {
LP [ i , j ] = LP [ i , j ] + LP [ i − 1, j −w[ i ] ] * p [ i ]
}
}
}
#FINISH UP
l o s s p r o b s = LP [N, ]
zero or one: optimal digital portfolios
p r i n t ( t ( LP ) )
r e s u l t = matrix ( c ( bucket , l o s s p r o b s ) , ( maxloss + 1 ) , 2 )
}
We use this function in the following example.
w = c (5 ,8 ,4 ,2 ,1)
p = a r r a y ( 1 / length (w) , length (w) )
r e s = a s b r e c (w, p )
print ( res )
p r i n t (sum( r e s [ , 2 ] ) )
b a r p l o t ( r e s [ , 2 ] , names . arg= r e s [ , 1 ] ,
x l a b = " p o r t f o l i o value " , ylab= " p r o b a b i l i t y " )
The output of this run is as follows:
[1 ,]
[2 ,]
[3 ,]
[4 ,]
[5 ,]
[6 ,]
[7 ,]
[8 ,]
[9 ,]
[10 ,]
[11 ,]
[12 ,]
[13 ,]
[14 ,]
[15 ,]
[16 ,]
[17 ,]
[18 ,]
[19 ,]
[20 ,]
[21 ,]
[ ,1] [ ,2] [ ,3]
[ ,4]
[ ,5]
[ ,6]
0 0.8 0.64 0.512 0.4096 0.32768
1 0.0 0.00 0.000 0.0000 0.08192
2 0.0 0.00 0.000 0.1024 0.08192
3 0.0 0.00 0.000 0.0000 0.02048
4 0.0 0.00 0.128 0.1024 0.08192
5 0.2 0.16 0.128 0.1024 0.10240
6 0.0 0.00 0.000 0.0256 0.04096
7 0.0 0.00 0.000 0.0256 0.02560
8 0.0 0.16 0.128 0.1024 0.08704
9 0.0 0.00 0.032 0.0256 0.04096
10 0 . 0 0 . 0 0 0 . 0 0 0 0 . 0 2 5 6 0 . 0 2 5 6 0
11 0 . 0 0 . 0 0 0 . 0 0 0 0 . 0 0 6 4 0 . 0 1 0 2 4
12 0 . 0 0 . 0 0 0 . 0 3 2 0 . 0 2 5 6 0 . 0 2 1 7 6
13 0 . 0 0 . 0 4 0 . 0 3 2 0 . 0 2 5 6 0 . 0 2 5 6 0
14 0 . 0 0 . 0 0 0 . 0 0 0 0 . 0 0 6 4 0 . 0 1 0 2 4
15 0 . 0 0 . 0 0 0 . 0 0 0 0 . 0 0 6 4 0 . 0 0 6 4 0
16 0 . 0 0 . 0 0 0 . 0 0 0 0 . 0 0 0 0 0 . 0 0 1 2 8
17 0 . 0 0 . 0 0 0 . 0 0 8 0 . 0 0 6 4 0 . 0 0 5 1 2
18 0 . 0 0 . 0 0 0 . 0 0 0 0 . 0 0 0 0 0 . 0 0 1 2 8
19 0 . 0 0 . 0 0 0 . 0 0 0 0 . 0 0 1 6 0 . 0 0 1 2 8
20 0 . 0 0 . 0 0 0 . 0 0 0 0 . 0 0 0 0 0 . 0 0 0 3 2
Here each column represents one pass through the recursion. Since there
are five assets, we get five passes, and the final column is the result we
are looking for. The plot of the outcome distribution is shown in Figure
399
400
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
15.1.
Figure 15.1: Plot of the final out-
0.15
0.00
0.05
0.10
probability
0.20
0.25
0.30
come distribution for a digital
portfolio with five assets of outcomes {5, 8, 4, 2, 1} all of equal
probability.
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9
11
13
15
17
19
portfolio value
We can explore these recursion calculations in some detail as follows.
Note that in our example pi = 0.2, i = 1, 2, 3, 4, 5. We are interested
in computing P(k, B), where k denotes the k-th recursion pass, and B
denotes the return bucket. Recall that we have five assets with return
levels of {5, 8, 4, 2, 1}, respecitvely. After i = 1, we have
P(1, 0) = (1 − p1 ) = 0.8
P(1, 5) = p1 = 0.2
P(1, j) = 0, j 6= {0, 5}
The completes the first recursion pass and the values can be verified
from the R output above by examining column 2 (column 1 contains the
values of the return buckets). We now move on the calculations needed
zero or one: optimal digital portfolios
for the second pass in the recursion.
P(2, 0) = P(1, 0)(1 − p2 ) = 0.64
P(2, 5) = P(1, 5)(1 − p2 ) + P(1, 5 − 8) p2 = 0.2(0.8) + 0(0.2) = 0.16
P(2, 8) = P(1, 8)(1 − p2 ) + P(1, 8 − 8) p2 = 0(0.8) + 0.8(0.2) = 0.16
P(2, 13) = P(1, 13)(1 − p2 ) + P(1, 13 − 8) p2 = 0(0.8) + 0.2(0.2) = 0.04
P(2, j) = 0, j 6= {0, 5, 8, 13}
The third recursion pass is as follows:
P(3, 0) = P(2, 0)(1 − p3 ) = 0.512
P(3, 4) = P(2, 4)(1 − p3 ) + P(2, 4 − 4) = 0(0.8) + 0.64(0.2) = 0.128
P(3, 5) = P(2, 5)(1 − p3 ) + P(2, 5 − 4) p3 = 0.16(0.8) + 0(0.2) = 0.128
P(3, 8) = P(2, 8)(1 − p3 ) + P(2, 8 − 4) p3 = 0.16(0.8) + 0(0.2) = 0.128
P(3, 9) = P(2, 9)(1 − p3 ) + P(2, 9 − 4) p3 = 0(0.8) + 0.16(0.2) = 0.032
P(3, 12) = P(2, 12)(1 − p3 ) + P(2, 12 − 4) p3 = 0(0.8) + 0.16(0.2) = 0.032
P(3, 13) = P(2, 13)(1 − p3 ) + P(2, 13 − 4) p3 = 0.04(0.8) + 0(0.2) = 0.032
P(3, 17) = P(2, 17)(1 − p3 ) + P(2, 17 − 4) p3 = 0(0.8) + 0.04(0.2) = 0.008
P(3, j) = 0, j 6= {0, 4, 5, 8, 9, 12, 13, 17}
Note that the same computation work even when the outcomes are not
of equal probability.
15.2.2
Combining conditional distributions
We now demonstrate how we will integrate the conditional probability
distributions p X into an unconditional probability distribution of outR
comes, denoted p = X p X g( X ) dX, where g( X ) is the density function
of the state variable X. We create a function to combine the conditional
distribution functions. This function calls the absrec function that we
had used earlier.
#FUNCTION TO COMPUTE FULL RETURN DISTRIBUTION
#INTEGRATES OVER X BY CALLING ASBREC
d i g i p r o b = f u n c t i o n ( L , q , rho ) {
dx = 0 . 1
x = seq ( − 40 ,40) * dx
f x = dnorm ( x ) * dx
f x = f x / sum( f x )
401
402
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
maxloss = sum( L )
bucket = c ( 0 , seq ( maxloss ) )
t o t p = a r r a y ( 0 , ( maxloss + 1 ) )
f o r ( i i n seq ( length ( x ) ) ) {
p = pnorm ( ( qnorm ( q)− rho * x [ i ] ) / s q r t (1 − rho ^ 2 ) )
l d i s t = asbrec (L , p)
totp = totp + l d i s t [ , 2 ] * fx [ i ]
}
r e s u l t = matrix ( c ( bucket , t o t p ) , ( maxloss + 1 ) , 2 )
}
Note that now we will use the unconditional probabilities of success for
each asset, and correlate them with a specified correlation level. We run
this with two correlation levels {−0.5, +0.5}.
#−−−−−−INTEGRATE OVER CONDITIONAL DISTRIBUTIONS−−−−
w = c (5 ,8 ,4 ,2 ,1)
q = c (0.1 ,0.2 ,0.1 ,0.05 ,0.15)
rho = 0 . 2 5
r e s 1 = d i g i p r o b (w, q , rho )
rho = 0 . 7 5
r e s 2 = d i g i p r o b (w, q , rho )
par ( mfrow=c ( 2 , 1 ) )
b a r p l o t ( r e s 1 [ , 2 ] , names . arg= r e s 1 [ , 1 ] , x l a b = " p o r t f o l i o value " ,
ylab= " p r o b a b i l i t y " , main= " rho = 0 . 2 5 " )
b a r p l o t ( r e s 2 [ , 2 ] , names . arg= r e s 2 [ , 1 ] , x l a b = " p o r t f o l i o value " ,
ylab= " p r o b a b i l i t y " , main= " rho = 0 . 7 5 " )
The output plots of the unconditional outcome distribution are shown in
Figure 15.2.
We can see the data for the plots as follows.
> cbind ( re s1 , r e s 2 )
[ ,1]
[ ,2] [ ,3]
[ ,4]
[1 ,]
0 0.5391766174
0 0.666318464
[2 ,]
1 0.0863707325
1 0.046624312
[3 ,]
2 0.0246746918
2 0.007074104
[4 ,]
3 0.0049966420
3 0.002885901
[5 ,]
4 0.0534700675
4 0.022765422
[6 ,]
5 0.0640540228
5 0.030785967
[7 ,]
6 0.0137226107
6 0.009556413
[8 ,]
7 0.0039074039
7 0.002895774
zero or one: optimal digital portfolios
Figure 15.2: Plot of the final out-
0.2
0.4
come distribution for a digital
portfolio with five assets of outcomes {5, 8, 4, 2, 1} with unconditional probability of success of
{0.1, 0.2, 0.1, 0.05, 0.15}, respecitvely.
0.0
probability
rho = 0.25
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9
11
13
15
17
19
13
15
17
19
portfolio value
0.0
0.2
0.4
0.6
rho = 0.75
probability
403
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9
11
portfolio value
404
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
[9 ,]
[10 ,]
[11 ,]
[12 ,]
[13 ,]
[14 ,]
[15 ,]
[16 ,]
[17 ,]
[18 ,]
[19 ,]
[20 ,]
[21 ,]
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
0.1247287209
0.0306776806
0.0086979993
0.0021989842
0.0152035638
0.0186144920
0.0046389439
0.0013978502
0.0003123473
0.0022521668
0.0006364672
0.0002001003
0.0000678949
8
9
10
11
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
0.081172499
0.029154885
0.008197488
0.004841742
0.014391319
0.023667222
0.012776165
0.006233366
0.004010559
0.005706283
0.010008267
0.002144265
0.008789582
The left column of probabilities has correlation of ρ = 0.25 and the right
one is the case when ρ = 0.75. We see that the probabilities on the right
are lower for low outcomes (except zero) and high for high outcomes.
Why? See the plot of the difference between the high correlation case
and low correlation case in Figure 15.3.
15.3 Stochastic Dominance (SD)
SD is an ordering over probabilistic bundles. We may want to know if
one VC’s portfolio dominates another in a risk-adjusted sense. Different SD concepts apply to answer this question. For example if portfolio A does better than portfolio B in every state of the world, it clearly
dominates. This is called “state-by-state” dominance, and is hardly ever
encountered. Hence, we briefly examine two more common types of SD.
1. First-order Stochastic Dominance (FSD): For cumulative distribution
function F ( X ) over states X, portfolio A dominates B if Prob( A ≥ k ) ≥
Prob( B ≥ k ) for all states k ∈ X, and Prob( A ≥ k ) > Prob( B ≥ k)
for some k. It is the same as Prob( A ≤ k) ≤ Prob( B ≤ k ) for all states
k ∈ X, and Prob( A ≤ k) < Prob( B ≤ k) for some k.This implies
that FA (k) ≤ FB (k ). The mean outcome under A will be higher than
under B, and all increasing utility functions will give higher utility for
A. This is a weaker notion of dominance than state-wise, but also not
as often encountered in practice.
>
>
>
>
x = seq ( − 4 , 4 , 0 . 1 )
F_B = pnorm ( x , mean=0 , sd = 1 ) ;
F_A = pnorm ( x , mean = 0 . 2 5 , sd = 1 ) ;
F_A−F_B
#FSD e x i s t s
[ 1 ] − 2.098272 e −05 − 3.147258 e −05 − 4.673923 e −05 − 6.872414 e −05 − 1.000497 e −04
[ 6 ] − 1.442118 e −04 − 2.058091 e −04 − 2.908086 e −04 − 4.068447 e −04 − 5.635454 e −04
zero or one: optimal digital portfolios
405
Figure 15.3: Plot of the difference in
0.05
0.00
Diff in Prob
0.10
distribution for a digital portfolio
with five assets when ρ = 0.75
minus that when ρ = 0.25. We use
outcomes {5, 8, 4, 2, 1} with unconditional probability of success of
{0.1, 0.2, 0.1, 0.05, 0.15}, respecitvely.
0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9
11
13
15
17
19
406
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
[11]
[16]
[21]
[26]
[31]
[36]
[41]
[46]
[51]
[56]
[61]
[66]
[71]
[76]
[81]
− 7.728730 e −04
− 3.229902 e −03
− 1.052566 e −02
− 2.674804 e −02
− 5.300548 e −02
− 8.191019 e −02
− 9.870633 e −02
− 9.275614 e −02
− 6.797210 e −02
− 3.884257 e −02
− 1.730902 e −02
− 6.014807 e −03
− 1.629865 e −03
− 3.443960 e −04
− 5.674604 e −05
− 1.049461 e −03
− 4.172947 e −03
− 1.293895 e −02
− 3.128519 e −02
− 5.898819 e −02
− 8.673215 e −02
− 9.944553 e −02
− 8.891623 e −02
− 6.199648 e −02
− 3.370870 e −02
− 1.429235 e −02
− 4.725518 e −03
− 1.218358 e −03
− 2.449492 e −04
− 1.410923 e −03
− 5.337964 e −03
− 1.574810 e −02
− 3.622973 e −02
− 6.499634 e −02
− 9.092889 e −02
− 9.919852 e −02
− 8.439157 e −02
− 5.598646 e −02
− 2.896380 e −02
− 1.168461 e −02
− 3.675837 e −03
− 9.017317 e −04
− 1.724935 e −04
− 1.878104 e −03
− 6.760637 e −03
− 1.897740 e −02
− 4.154041 e −02
− 7.090753 e −02
− 9.438507 e −02
− 9.797262 e −02
− 7.930429 e −02
− 5.005857 e −02
− 2.464044 e −02
− 9.458105 e −03
− 2.831016 e −03
− 6.607827 e −04
− 1.202675 e −04
− 2.475227 e −03
− 8.477715 e −03
− 2.264252 e −02
− 4.715807 e −02
− 7.659057 e −02
− 9.700281 e −02
− 9.580405 e −02
− 7.378599 e −02
− 4.431528 e −02
− 2.075491 e −02
− 7.580071 e −03
− 2.158775 e −03
− 4.794230 e −04
− 8.302381 e −05
2. Second-order Stochastic Dominance (SSD): Here the portfolios have
the same mean but the risk is less for portfolio A. Then we say that
portfolio A has a “mean-preserving spread” over portfolio B. TechniRk
R
cally this is the same as −∞ [ FA (k ) − FB (k )] dX < 0, and X XdFA ( X ) =
R
X XdFB ( X ). Mean-variance models in which portfolios on the efficient frontier dominate those below are a special case of SSD. See the
example below, there is no FSD, but there is SSD.
x = seq ( − 4 , 4 , 0 . 1 )
F_B = pnorm ( x , mean=0 , sd = 2 ) ;
F_A = pnorm ( x , mean=0 , sd = 1 ) ;
F_A−F_B
#No FSD
[ 1 ] − 0.02271846 − 0.02553996 − 0.02864421 − 0.03204898 − 0.03577121 − 0.03982653
[ 7 ] − 0.04422853 − 0.04898804 − 0.05411215 − 0.05960315 − 0.06545730 − 0.07166345
[ 1 3 ] − 0.07820153 − 0.08504102 − 0.09213930 − 0.09944011 − 0.10687213 − 0.11434783
[ 1 9 ] − 0.12176261 − 0.12899464 − 0.13590512 − 0.14233957 − 0.14812981 − 0.15309708
[ 2 5 ] − 0.15705611 − 0.15982015 − 0.16120699 − 0.16104563 − 0.15918345 − 0.15549363
[ 3 1 ] − 0.14988228 − 0.14229509 − 0.13272286 − 0.12120570 − 0.10783546 − 0.09275614
[ 3 7 ] − 0.07616203 − 0.05829373 − 0.03943187 − 0.01988903 0 . 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 0 . 0 1 9 8 8 9 0 3
[4 3] 0.03943187 0.05829373 0.07616203 0.09275614 0.10783546 0.12120570
[4 9] 0.13272286 0.14229509 0.14988228 0.15549363 0.15918345 0.16104563
[5 5] 0.16120699 0.15982015 0.15705611 0.15309708 0.14812981 0.14233957
[6 1] 0.13590512 0.12899464 0.12176261 0.11434783 0.10687213 0.09944011
[6 7] 0.09213930 0.08504102 0.07820153 0.07166345 0.06545730 0.05960315
[7 3] 0.05411215 0.04898804 0.04422853 0.03982653 0.03577121 0.03204898
[7 9] 0.02864421 0.02553996 0.02271846
> cumsum( F_A−F_B )
# But t h e r e i s SSD
[ 1 ] − 2.271846 e −02 − 4.825842 e −02 − 7.690264 e −02 − 1.089516 e −01 − 1.447228 e −01
[ 6 ] − 1.845493 e −01 − 2.287779 e −01 − 2.777659 e −01 − 3.318781 e −01 − 3.914812 e −01
[ 1 1 ] − 4.569385 e −01 − 5.286020 e −01 − 6.068035 e −01 − 6.918445 e −01 − 7.839838 e −01
[ 1 6 ] − 8.834239 e −01 − 9.902961 e −01 − 1.104644 e +00 − 1.226407 e +00 − 1.355401 e +00
[ 2 1 ] − 1.491306 e +00 − 1.633646 e +00 − 1.781776 e +00 − 1.934873 e +00 − 2.091929 e +00
[ 2 6 ] − 2.251749 e +00 − 2.412956 e +00 − 2.574002 e +00 − 2.733185 e +00 − 2.888679 e +00
[ 3 1 ] − 3.038561 e +00 − 3.180856 e +00 − 3.313579 e +00 − 3.434785 e +00 − 3.542620 e +00
[ 3 6 ] − 3.635376 e +00 − 3.711538 e +00 − 3.769832 e +00 − 3.809264 e +00 − 3.829153 e +00
[ 4 1 ] − 3.829153 e +00 − 3.809264 e +00 − 3.769832 e +00 − 3.711538 e +00 − 3.635376 e +00
[ 4 6 ] − 3.542620 e +00 − 3.434785 e +00 − 3.313579 e +00 − 3.180856 e +00 − 3.038561 e +00
[ 5 1 ] − 2.888679 e +00 − 2.733185 e +00 − 2.574002 e +00 − 2.412956 e +00 − 2.251749 e +00
[ 5 6 ] − 2.091929 e +00 − 1.934873 e +00 − 1.781776 e +00 − 1.633646 e +00 − 1.491306 e +00
[ 6 1 ] − 1.355401 e +00 − 1.226407 e +00 − 1.104644 e +00 − 9.902961 e −01 − 8.834239 e −01
[ 6 6 ] − 7.839838 e −01 − 6.918445 e −01 − 6.068035 e −01 − 5.286020 e −01 − 4.569385 e −01
[ 7 1 ] − 3.914812 e −01 − 3.318781 e −01 − 2.777659 e −01 − 2.287779 e −01 − 1.845493 e −01
[ 7 6 ] − 1.447228 e −01 − 1.089516 e −01 − 7.690264 e −02 − 4.825842 e −02 − 2.271846 e −02
>
>
>
>
zero or one: optimal digital portfolios
[ 8 1 ] − 2.220446 e −16
15.4 Portfolio Characteristics
Armed with this established machinery, there are several questions an
investor (e.g. a VC) in a digital portfolio may pose. First, is there an optimal number of assets, i.e., ceteris paribus, are more assets better than
fewer assets, assuming no span of control issues? Second, are Bernoulli
portfolios different from mean-variances ones, in that is it always better
to have less asset correlation than more correlation? Third, is it better
to have an even weighting of investment across the assets or might it
be better to take a few large bets amongst many smaller ones? Fourth,
is a high dispersion of probability of success better than a low dispersion? These questions are very different from the ones facing investors
in traditional mean-variance portfolios. We shall examine each of these
questions in turn.
15.4.1
How many assets?
With mean-variance portfolios, keeping the mean return of the portfolio
fixed, more securities in the portfolio is better, because diversification reduces the variance of the portfolio. Also, with mean-variance portfolios,
higher-order moments do not matter. But with portfolios of Bernoulli
assets, increasing the number of assets might exacerbate higher-order
moments, even though it will reduce variance. Therefore it may not be
worthwhile to increase the number of assets (n) beyond a point.
In order to assess this issue we conducted the following experiment.
We invested in n assets each with payoff of 1/n. Hence, if all assets succeed, the total (normalized) payoff is 1. This normalization is only to
make the results comparable across different n, and is without loss of
generality. We also assumed that the correlation parameter is ρi = 0.25,
for all i. To make it easy to interpret the results, we assumed each asset
to be identical with a success probability of qi = 0.05 for all i. Using
the recursion technique, we computed the probability distribution of the
portfolio payoff for four values of n = {25, 50, 75, 100}. The distribution
function is plotted in Figure 15.4, left panel. There are 4 plots, one for
each n, and if we look at the bottom left of the plot, the leftmost line is
for n = 100. The next line to the right is for n = 75, and so on.
407
408
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
1.0
One approach to determining if greater n is better for a digital portfolio is to investigate if a portfolio of n assets stochastically dominates one
with less than n assets. On examination of the shapes of the distribution
functions for different n, we see that it is likely that as n increases, we
obtain portfolios that exhibit second-order stochastic dominance (SSD)
over portfolios with smaller n. The return distribution when n = 100
(denoted G100 ) would dominate that for n = 25 (denoted G25 ) in the SSD
Ru
R
R
sense, if x x dG100 ( x ) = x x dG25 ( x ), and 0 [ G100 ( x ) − G25 ( x )] dx ≤ 0
for all u ∈ (0, 1). That is, G25 has a mean-preserving spread over G100 ,
or G100 has the same mean as G25 but lower variance, i.e., implies superior mean-variance efficiency. To show this we plotted the integral
Ru
0 [ G100 ( x ) − G25 ( x )] dx and checked the SSD condition. We found that
this condition is satisfied (see Figure 15.4). As is known, SSD implies
mean-variance efficiency as well.
0.4
0.5
0.6
0.7
0.8
Cumulative Probability
0.9
Figure 15.4: Distribution func-
0.0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1.0
-0.6
-0.8
-1.0
-1.2
Integrated F(G100) minus F(G25)
-0.4
Normalized Total Payoff
0.0
0.2
0.4
0.6
Normalized total payoff
0.8
1.0
tions for returns from Bernoulli
investments as the number of investments (n) increases. Using the
recursion technique we computed
the probability distribution of the
portfolio payoff for four values of
n = {25, 50, 75, 100}. The distribution function is plotted in the
left panel. There are 4 plots, one
for each n, and if we look at the
bottom left of the plot, the leftmost
line is for n = 100. The next line
to the right is for n = 75, and so
on. The right panel plots the value
Ru
of 0 [ G100 ( x ) − G25 ( x )] dx for all
u ∈ (0, 1), and confirms that it is
always negative. The correlation
parameter is ρ = 0.25.
zero or one: optimal digital portfolios
409
We also examine if higher n portfolios are better for a power utility
(0.1+C )1−γ
investor with utility function, U (C ) =
, where C is the normal1− γ
ized total payoff of the Bernoulli portfolio. Expected utility is given by
∑C U (C ) f (C ). We set the risk aversion coefficient to γ = 3 which is in
the standard range in the asset-pricing literature. Table 15.1 reports the
results. We can see that the expected utility increases monotonically with
n. Hence, for a power utility investor, having more assets is better than
less, keeping the mean return of the portfolio constant. Economically,
in the specific case of VCs, this highlights the goal of trying to capture
a larger share of the number of available ventures. The results from the
SSD analysis are consistent with those of expected power utility.
Table 15.1: Expected utility for
n
25
50
75
100
E(C )
0.05
0.05
0.05
0.05
Pr [C > 0.03]
0.665
0.633
0.620
0.612
Pr [C > 0.07]
0.342
0.259
0.223
0.202
Pr [C > 0.10]
0.150
0.084
0.096
0.073
Pr [C > 0.15]
0.059
0.024
0.015
0.011
E[U (C )]
−29.259
−26.755
−25.876
−25.433
We have abstracted away from issues of the span of management by
investors. Given that investors actively play a role in their invested assets
in digital portfolios, increasing n beyond a point may of course become
costly, as modeled in Kanniainen and Keuschnigg (2003).
15.4.2
The impact of correlation
As with mean-variance portfolios, we expect that increases in payoff correlation for Bernoulli assets will adversely impact portfolios. In order to
verify this intuition we analyzed portfolios keeping all other variables
the same, but changing correlation. In the previous subsection, we set
the parameter for correlation to be ρ = 0.25. Here, we examine four
levels of the correlation parameter: ρ = {0.09, 0.25, 0.49, 0.81}. For each
level of correlation, we computed the normalized total payoff distribution. The number of assets is kept fixed at n = 25 and the probability of
success of each digital asset is 0.05 as before.
The results are shown in Figure 15.5 where the probability distribution
function of payoffs is shown for all four correlation levels. We find that
the SSD condition is met, i.e., that lower correlation portfolios stochastically dominate (in the SSD sense) higher correlation portfolios. We also
examined changing correlation in the context of a power utility investor
Bernoulli portfolios as the number
of investments (n) increases. The
table reports the portfolio statistics
for n = {25, 50, 75, 100}. Expected
utility is given in the last column.
The correlation parameter is ρ =
0.25. The utility function is U (C ) =
(0.1 + C )1−γ /(1 − γ), γ = 3.
410
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
with the same utility function as in the previous subsection. The results
are shown in Table 15.2. We confirm that, as with mean-variance portfolios, Bernoulli portfolios also improve if the assets have low correlation.
Hence, digital investors should also optimally attempt to diversify their
portfolios. Insurance companies are a good example—they diversify risk
across geographical and other demographic divisions.
0.3
0.4
0.5
0.6
0.7
0.8
Cumulative Probability
0.9
1.0
Figure 15.5: Distribution func-
0.0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1.0
-0.1
-0.2
-0.3
-0.4
-0.5
-0.6
Integrated F(G[rho=0.09]) minus F(G[rho=0.81])
0.0
Normalized Total Payoff
0.0
0.2
0.4
0.6
0.8
1.0
Normalized total payoff
ğă
15.4.3
Uneven bets?
Digital asset investors are often faced with the question of whether to
bet even amounts across digital investments, or to invest with different
weights. We explore this question by considering two types of Bernoulli
portfolios. Both have n = 25 assets within them, each with a success
tions for returns from Bernoulli
investments as the correlation parameter (ρ2 ) increases. Using the
recursion technique we computed
the probability distribution of the
portfolio payoff for four values of
ρ = {0.09, 0.25, 0.49, 0.81} shown
by the black, red, green and blue
lines respectively. The distribution
function is plotted in the left panel.
The right panel plots the value of
Ru
0 [ Gρ=0.09 ( x ) − Gρ=0.81 ( x )] dx for
all u ∈ (0, 1), and confirms that it is
always negative.
zero or one: optimal digital portfolios
411
Table 15.2: Expected utility for
ρ
0.32
0.52
0.72
0.92
E(C )
0.05
0.05
0.05
0.05
Pr [C > 0.03]
0.715
0.665
0.531
0.283
Pr [C > 0.07]
0.356
0.342
0.294
0.186
Pr [C > 0.10]
0.131
0.150
0.170
0.139
Pr [C > 0.15]
0.038
0.059
0.100
0.110
E[U (C )]
−28.112
−29.259
−32.668
−39.758
probability of qi = 0.05. The first has equal payoffs, i.e., 1/25 each. The
second portfolio has payoffs that monotonically increase, i.e., the payoffs
are equal to j/325, j = 1, 2, . . . , 25. We note that the sum of the payoffs
in both cases is 1. Table 15.3 shows the utility of the investor, where the
utility function is the same as in the previous sections. We see that the
utility for the balanced portfolio is higher than that for the imbalanced
one. Also the balanced portfolio evidences SSD over the imbalanced
portfolio. However, the return distribution has fatter tails when the portfolio investments are imbalanced. Hence, investors seeking to distinguish themselves by taking on greater risk in their early careers may be
better off with imbalanced portfolios.
Bernoulli portfolios as the correlation (ρ) increases. The table
reports the portfolio statistics for
ρ = {0.09, 0.25, 0.49, 0.81}. Expected
utility is given in the last column.
The utility function is U (C ) =
(0.1 + C )1−γ /(1 − γ), γ = 3.
Table 15.3: Expected utility for
Wts
Balanced
Imbalanced
15.4.4
E(C )
E[U (C )]
0.05
−33.782
0.05
−34.494
x = 0.01
0.490
x = 0.02
0.490
0.464
0.437
Probability that C > x
x = 0.03
x = 0.07
x = 0.10
0.490
0.278
0.169
0.408
0.257
0.176
x = 0.15
0.107
0.103
Bernoulli portfolios when the
x = 0.25 portfolio comprises balanced in0.031
0.037
Mixing safe and risky assets
Is it better to have assets with a wide variation in probability of success
or with similar probabilities? To examine this, we look at two portfolios
of n = 26 assets. In the first portfolio, all the assets have a probability of
success equal to qi = 0.10. In the second portfolio, half the firms have a
success probability of 0.05 and the other half have a probability of 0.15.
The payoff of all investments is 1/26. The probability distribution of
payoffs and the expected utility for the same power utility investor (with
γ = 3) are given in Table 15.4. We see that mixing the portfolio between
investments with high and low probability of success results in higher
expected utility than keeping the investments similar. We also confirmed
that such imbalanced success probability portfolios also evidence SSD
over portfolios with similar investments in terms of success rates. This
vesting in assets versus imbalanced
weights. Both the balanced and
imbalanced portfolio have n = 25
assets within them, each with a
success probability of qi = 0.05.
The first has equal payoffs, i.e.
1/25 each. The second portfolio
has payoffs that monotonically increase, i.e. the payoffs are equal to
j/325, j = 1, 2, . . . , 25. We note that
the sum of the payoffs in both cases
is 1. The correlation parameter is
ρ = 0.55. The utility function is
U (C ) = (0.1 + C )1−γ /(1 − γ), γ =
3.
412
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
result does not have a natural analog in the mean-variance world with
non-digital assets. For empirical evidence on the efficacy of various diversification approaches, see Lossen (2006).
Table 15.4: Expected utility for
Wts
Uniform
Mixed
E(C )
E[U (C )]
0.10
−24.625
0.10
−23.945
x = 0.01
0.701
x = 0.02
0.701
0.721
0.721
Probability that C > x
x = 0.03
x = 0.07
x = 0.10
0.701
0.502
0.366
0.721
0.519
0.376
x = 0.15
0.270
x = 0.25
0.111
0.273
0.106
15.5 Conclusions
Digital asset portfolios are different from mean-variance ones because
the asset returns are Bernoulli with small success probabilities. We
used a recursion technique borrowed from the credit portfolio literature to construct the payoff distributions for Bernoulli portfolios. We find
that many intuitions for these portfolios are similar to those of meanvariance ones: diversification by adding assets is useful, low correlations
amongst investments is good. However, we also find that uniform bet
size is preferred to some small and some large bets. Rather than construct portfolios with assets having uniform success probabilities, it is
preferable to have some assets with low success rates and others with
high success probabilities, a feature that is noticed in the case of venture
funds. These insights augment the standard understanding obtained
from mean-variance portfolio optimization.
The approach taken here is simple to use. The only inputs needed are
the expected payoffs of the assets Ci , success probabilities qi , and the average correlation between assets, given by a parameter ρ. Broad statistics
on these inputs are available, say for venture investments, from papers
such as Das, Jagannathan and Sarin (2003). Therefore, using data, it is
easy to optimize the portfolio of a digital asset fund. The technical approach here is also easily extended to features including cost of effort by
investors as the number of projects grows (Kanniainen and Keuschnigg
(2003)), syndication, etc. The number of portfolios with digital assets appears to be increasing in the marketplace, and the results of this analysis
provide important intuition for asset managers.
The approach in Section 2 is just one way in which to model joint success probabilities using a common factor. Undeniably, there are other
Bernoulli portfolios when the portfolio comprises balanced investing
in assets with identical success
probabilities versus investing in
assets with mixed success probabilities. Both the uniform and mixed
portfolios have n = 26 assets within
them. In the first portfolio, all the
assets have a probability of success
equal to qi = 0.10. In the second
portfolio, half the firms have a
success probability of 0.05 and the
other half have a probability of
0.15. The payoff of all investments
is 1/26. The correlation parameter
is ρ = 0.55. The utility function is
U (C ) = (0.1 + C )1−γ /(1 − γ), γ =
3.
zero or one: optimal digital portfolios
ways too, such as modeling joint probabilities directly, making sure that
they are consistent with each other, which itself may be mathematically
tricky. It is indeed possible to envisage that, for some different system
of joint success probabilities, the qualitative nature of the results may
differ from the ones developed here. It is also possible that the system
we adopt here with a single common factor X may be extended to more
than one common factor, an approach often taken in the default literature.
413
16
Against the Odds: Mathematics of Gambling
16.1 Introduction
Most people hate mathematics but love gambling. Which of course, is
strange because gambling is driven mostly by math. Think of any type
of gambling and no doubt there will be maths involved: Horse-track
betting, sports betting, blackjack, poker, roulette, stocks, etc.
16.1.1
Odds
Oddly, bets are defined by their odds. If a bet on a horse is quoted at 4to-1 odds, it means that if you win, you receive 4 times your wager plus
the amount wagered. That is, if you bet $1, you get back $5.
The odds effectively define the probability of winning. Lets define this
to be p. If the odds are fair, then the expected gain is zero, i.e.
$4p + (1 − p)(−$1) = $0
which implies that p = 1/5. Hence, if the odds are x : 1, then the proba1
bility of winning is p = x+
1 = 0.2.
16.1.2
Edge
Everyone bets because they think they have an advantage, or an edge
over the others. It might be that they just think they have better information, better understanding, are using secret technology, or actually have
private information (which may be illegal).
The edge is the expected profit that will be made from repeated trials
relative to the bet size. You have an edge if you can win with higher
probability (p∗ ) than p = 1/( x + 1). In the above example, with bet size
416
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
$1 each time, suppose your probability of winning is not 1/5, but instead
it is 1/4. What is your edge? The expected profit is
(−1) × (3/4) + 4 × (1/4) = 1/4
Dividing this by the bet size (i.e. $1) gives the edge equal to 1/4. No
edge means zero or negative value betting.
16.1.3
Bookmakers
These folks set the odds. Odds are dynamic of course. If the bookie
thinks the probability of a win is 1/5, then he will set the odds to be a
bit less than 4:1, maybe something like 3.5:1. In this way his expected
intake minus payout is positive. At 3.5:1 odds, if there are still a lot of
takers, then the bookie surely realizes that the probability of a win must
be higher than in his own estimation. He also infers that p > 1/(3.5 + 1),
and will then change the odds to say 3:1. Therefore, he acts as a market
maker in the bet.
16.2 Kelly Criterion
Suppose you have an edge. How should you bet over repeated plays of
the game to maximize your wealth. (Do you think this is the way that
hedge funds operate?) The Kelly (1956) criterion says that you should
invest only a fraction of your wealth in the bet. By keeping some aside
you are guaranteed to not end up in ruin.
What fraction should you bet? The answer is that you should bet
f =
Edge
p ∗ x − (1 − p ∗ )
=
Odds
x
where the odds are expressed in the form x : 1. Recall that p∗ is your
privately known probability of winning.
16.2.1
Example
Using the same numbers as we had before, i.e., x = 4, p∗ = 1/4 = 0.25,
we get
0.25(4) − (1 − 0.25)
0.25
f =
=
= 0.0625
4
4
which means we invest 6.25% of the current bankroll. Lets simulate this
strategy using R. Here is a simple program to simulate it, with optimal
Kelly betting, and over- and under-betting.
against the odds: mathematics of gambling
# Simulation of the Kelly Criterion
# Basic data
pstar = 0.25
# p r i v a t e p r o b o f winning
odds = 4
# a c t u a l odds
p = 1 / (1+ odds ) # h o u s e p r o b a b i l i t y o f winning
edge = p s t a r * odds − (1 − p s t a r )
f = edge / odds
p r i n t ( c ( " p= " , p , " p s t a r = " , p s t a r , " edge= " , edge , " f " , f ) )
n = 1000
x = runif (n)
f _ over = 1 . 5 * f
f _ under = 0 . 5 * f
b a n k r o l l = rep ( 0 , n ) ; b a n k r o l l [ 1 ] = 1
br _ o v e r b e t = b a n k r o l l ; br _ o v e r b e t [ 1 ] = 1
br _ underbet = b a n k r o l l ; br _ underbet [ 1 ] = 1
for ( i in 2 : n ) {
i f ( x [ i ] <= p s t a r ) {
b a n k r o l l [ i ] = b a n k r o l l [ i − 1] + b a n k r o l l [ i − 1] * f * odds
br _ o v e r b e t [ i ] = br _ o v e r b e t [ i − 1] + br _ o v e r b e t [ i − 1] * f _ over * odds
br _ underbet [ i ] = br _ underbet [ i − 1] + br _ underbet [ i − 1] * f _ under * odds
}
else {
b a n k r o l l [ i ] = b a n k r o l l [ i − 1] − b a n k r o l l [ i − 1] * f
br _ o v e r b e t [ i ] = br _ o v e r b e t [ i − 1] − br _ o v e r b e t [ i − 1] * f _ over
br _ underbet [ i ] = br _ underbet [ i − 1] − br _ underbet [ i − 1] * f _ under
}
}
par ( mfrow=c ( 3 , 1 ) )
p l o t ( b a n k r o l l , type= " l " )
p l o t ( br _ overbet , type= " l " )
p l o t ( br _ underbet , type= " l " )
p r i n t ( c ( b a n k r o l l [ n ] , br _ o v e r b e t [ n ] , br _ underbet [ n ] ) )
p r i n t ( c ( b a n k r o l l [ n ] / br _ o v e r b e t [ n ] , b a n k r o l l [ n ] / br _ underbet [ n ] ) )
Here is the run time listing.
> source ( " k e l l y . R" )
[ 1 ] " p= "
" 0.2 "
" pstar=" " 0.25 "
[ 8 ] " 0 . 0 6 2 5 " " n= "
" 1000 "
[ 1 ] 542.29341 67.64294 158.83357
[ 1 ] 8.016999 3.414224
" edge= "
" 0.25 "
"f"
We repeat bets a thousand times. The initial pot is $1 only, but after a
thousand trials, the optimal strategy ends up at $542.29, the over-betting
one yields$67.64, and the under-betting one delivers $158.83. The ratio
of the optimal strategy to these two sub-optimal ones is 8.02 and 3.41,
respectively. This is conservative. Rerunning the model for another trial
with n = 1000 we get:
> source ( " k e l l y . R" )
[ 1 ] " p= "
" 0.2 "
[ 8 ] " 0 . 0 6 2 5 " " n= "
" pstar=" " 0.25 "
" 1000 "
" edge= "
" 0.25 "
"f"
417
418
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
[ 1 ] 6 . 4 2 6 1 9 7 e +15 1 . 7 3 4 1 5 8 e +12 1 . 3 1 3 6 9 0 e +12
[ 1 ] 3705.657 4891.714
The ratios are huge in comparison in this case, i.e., 3705 and 4891, respectively. And when we raise the trials to n = 5000, we have
> source ( " k e l l y . R" )
[ 1 ] " p= "
" 0.2 "
" pstar=" " 0.25 "
" edge= "
[ 8 ] " 0 . 0 6 2 5 " " n= "
" 5000 "
[ 1 ] 484145279169
1837741
9450314895
[ 1 ] 263445.8383
51.2306
" 0.25 "
Note here that over-betting is usually worse then under-betting the Kelly
optimal. Hence, many players employ what is known as the ‘Half-Kelly”
rule, i.e., they bet f /2.
Look at the resultant plot of the three strategies for the first example,
shown in Figure 16.1. The top plot follows the Kelly criterion, but the
other two deviate from it, by overbetting or underbetting the fraction
given by Kelly.
We can very clearly see that not betting Kelly leads to far worse outcomes than sticking with the Kelly optimal plan. We ran this for 1000
periods, as if we went to the casino every day and placed one bet (or
we placed four bets every minute for about four hours straight). Even
within a few trials, the performance of the Kelly is remarkable. Note
though that this is only one of the simulated outcomes. The simulations
would result in different types of paths of the bankroll value, but generally, the outcomes are similar to what we see in the figure.
Over-betting leads to losses faster than under-betting as one would
naturally expect, because it is the more risky strategy.
In this model, under the optimal rule, the probability of dropping to
1/n of the bankroll is 1/n. So the probability of dropping to 90% of the
bankroll (n = 1.11) is 0.9. Or, there is a 90% chance of losing 10% of the
bankroll.
Alternate betting rules are: (a) fixed size bets, (b) double up bets. The
former is too slow, the latter ruins eventually.
16.2.2
Deriving the Kelly Criterion
First we define some notation. Let Bt be the bankroll at time t. We index
time as going from time t = 1, . . . , N.
The odds are denoted, as before x : 1, and the random variable denot-
"f"
against the odds: mathematics of gambling
419
1500
500
0
bankroll
Figure 16.1: Bankroll evolution
0
200
400
600
800
1000
600
800
1000
600
800
1000
800 1200
400
0
br_overbet
Index
0
200
400
150
50
0
br_underbet
Index
0
200
400
Index
under the Kelly rule. The top
plot follows the Kelly criterion,
but the other two deviate from
it, by overbetting or underbetting
the fraction given by Kelly. The
variables are: odds are 4 to 1,
implying a house probability
of p = 0.2, own probability of
winning is p∗ = 0.25.
420
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
ing the outcome (i.e., gains) of the wager is written as
(
x
w/p p
Zt =
−1 w/p (1 − p)
We are said to have an edge when E( Zt ) > 0. The edge will be equal to
px − (1 − p) > 0.
We invest fraction f of our bankroll, where 0 < f < 1, and since f 6= 1,
there is no chance of being wiped out. Each wager is for an amount f Bt
and returns f Bt Zt . Hence, we may write
Bt = Bt−1 + f Bt−1 Zt
= Bt−1 [1 + f Zt ]
t
= B0 ∏[1 + f Zt ]
i =1
If we define the growth rate as
gt ( f ) =
1
ln
t
Bt
B0
=
t
1
ln ∏[1 + f Zt ]
t i =1
=
1 t
ln[1 + f Zt ]
t i∑
=1
Taking the limit by applying the law of large numbers, we get
g( f ) = lim gt ( f ) = E[ln(1 + f Z )]
t→∞
which is nothing but the time average of ln(1 + f Z ). We need to find the
f that maximizes g( f ). We can write this more explicitly as
g( f ) = p ln(1 + f x ) + (1 − p) ln(1 − f )
Differentiating to get the f.o.c,
∂g
x
−1
=p
+ (1 − p )
=0
∂f
1+ fx
1− f
Soving this first-order condition for f gives
The Kelly criterion: f ∗ =
px − (1 − p)
x
This is the optimal fraction of the bankroll that should be invested
in each wager. Note that we are back to the well-known formula of
Edge/Odds we saw before.
against the odds: mathematics of gambling
16.3 Entropy
Entropy is defined by physicists as the extent of disorder in the universe.
Entropy in the universe keeps on increasing. Things get more and more
disorderly. The arrow of time moves on inexorably, and entropy keeps
on increasing.
It is intuitive that as the entropy of a communication channel increases, its informativeness decreases. The connection between entropy
and informativeness was made by Claude Shannon, the father of information theory. It was his PhD thesis at MIT. See Shannon (1948).
With respect to probability distributions, entropy of a discrete distribution taking values { p1 , p2 , . . . , pK } is
K
H = − ∑ p j ln( p j )
j =1
For the simple wager we have been considering, entropy is
H = −[ p ln p + (1 − p) ln(1 − p)]
This is called Shannon entropy after his seminal work in 1948. For p =
1/2, 1/5, 1/100 entropy is
> p = 0 . 5 ; −(p * log ( p)+(1 − p ) * log (1 − p ) )
[ 1 ] 0.6931472
> p = 0 . 2 ; −(p * log ( p)+(1 − p ) * log (1 − p ) )
[ 1 ] 0.5004024
> p = 0 . 0 1 ; −(p * log ( p)+(1 − p ) * log (1 − p ) )
[ 1 ] 0.05600153
We see various probability distributions in decreasing order of entropy.
At p = 0.5 entropy is highest.
Note that the normal distribution is the one with the highest entropy
in its class of distributions.
16.3.1
Linking the Kelly Criterion to Entropy
For the particular case of a simple random walk, we have odds x = 1. In
this case,
f ∗ = p − (1 − p) = 2p − 1
421
422
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
where we see that p = 1/2, and the optimal average bet value is
g∗ = p ln(1 + f ) + (1 − p) ln(1 − f )
= p ln(2p) + (1 − p) ln[2(1 − p)]
= ln 2 + p ln p + (1 − p) ln(1 − p)
= ln 2 − H
where H is the entropy of the distribution of Z. For p = 0.5, we have
g∗ = ln 2 − 0.5 ln(0.5) − 0.5 ln(0.5) = 1.386294
We note that g∗ is decreasing in entropy, because informativeness
declines with entropy and so the portfolio earns less if we have less of an
edge, i.e. our winning information is less than perfect.
16.3.2
Linking the Kelly criterion to portfolio optimization
A small change in the mathematics above leads to an analogous concept
for portfolio policy. The value of a portfolio follows the dynamics below
t
Bt = Bt−1 [1 + (1 − f )r + f Zt ] = B0 ∏[1 + r + f ( Zt − r )]
i =1
Hence, the growth rate of the portfolio is given by
Bt
1
ln
gt ( f ) =
t
B0
=
=
1
ln
t
t
∏[1 + r + f (Zt − r)]
!
i =1
1 t
ln ([1 + r + f ( Zt − r )])
t i∑
=1
Taking the limit by applying the law of large numbers, we get
g( f ) = lim gt ( f ) = E[ln(1 + r + f ( Z − r ))]
t→∞
Hence, maximizing the growth rate of the portfolio is the same as maximizing expected log utility. For a much more detailed analysis, see
Browne and Whitt (1996).
16.3.3
Implementing day trading
We may choose any suitable distribution for the asset Z. Suppose Z is
normally distributed with mean µ and variance σ2 . Then we just need to
against the odds: mathematics of gambling
find f such that we have
f ∗ = argmax f E[ln(1 + r + f ( Z − r ))]
This may be done numerically. Note now that this does not guarantee
that 0 < f < 1, which does not preclude ruin.
How would a day-trader think about portfolio optimization? His
problem would be closer to that of a gambler’s because he is very much
like someone at the tables, making a series of bets, whose outcomes become known in very short time frames. A day-trader can easily look at
his history of round-trip trades and see how many of them made money,
and how many lost money. He would then obtain an estimate of p, the
probability of winning, which is the fraction of total round-trip trades
that make money.
The Lavinio (2000) d-ratio is known as the ‘gain-loss” ratio and is as
follows:
nd × ∑nj=1 max(0, − Zj )
d=
nu × ∑nj=1 max(0, Zj )
where nd is the number of down (loss) trades, and nu is the number of
up (gain) trades and n = nd + nu , and Zj are the returns on the trades.
In our original example at the beginning of this chapter, we have odds
of 4:1, implying nd = 4 loss trades for each win (nu = 1) trade, and a
winning trade nets +4, and a losing trade nets −1. Hence, we have
d=
4 × (1 + 1 + 1 + 1)
=4=x
1×4
which is just equal to the odds. Once, these are computed, the daytrader simply plugs them in to the formula we had before, i.e.,
f =
px − (1 − p)
(1 − p )
= p−
x
x
Of course, here p = 0.2. A trader would also constantly re-assess the
values of p and x given that the markets change over time.
16.4 Casino Games
The statistics of various casino games are displayed in Figure 16.2. To
recap, note that the Kelly criterion maximizes the average bankroll and
also minimizes the risk of ruin, but is of no use if the house had an edge.
You need to have an edge before it works. But then it really works! It is
423
424
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
not a short-term formula and works over a long sequence of bets. Naturally it follows that it also minimizes the number of bets needed to
double the bankroll.
Figure 16.2: See
http://wizardofodds.com/gambling/ho
The House Edge for various games.
The edge is the same as − f in our
notation. The standard deviation is
that of the bankroll of $1 for one
bet.
In a neat paper, Thorp (1997) presents various Kelly rules for blackjack, sports betting, and the stock market. Reading Thorp (1962) for
blackjack is highly recommended. And of course there is the great story
of the MIT Blackjack Team in Mezrich (2003). Here is an example from
Thorp (1997).
Suppose you have an edge where you can win +1 with probability
0.51, and lose −1 with probability 0.49 when the blackjack deck is “hot”
and when it is cold the probabilities are reversed. We will bet f on the
hot deck and a f , a < 1 on the cold deck. We have to bet on cold decks
just to prevent the dealer from getting suspicious. Hot and cold decks
against the odds: mathematics of gambling
occur with equal probability. Then the Kelly growth rate is
g( f ) = 0.5[0.51 ln(1 + f ) + 0.49 ln(1 − f )] + 0.5[0.49 ln(1 + a f ) + 0.51 ln(1 − a f )]
If we do not bet on cold decks, then a = 0 and f ∗ = 0.02 using the usual
formula. As a increases from 0 to 1, we see that f ∗ decreases. Hence, we
bet less of our pot to make up for losses from cold decks. We compute
this and get the following:
a=0 →
f ∗ = 0.020
a = 1/2 →
f ∗ = 0.008
a = 1/4 →
f ∗ = 0.014
a = 3/4 →
f ∗ = 0.0032
425
17
In the Same Boat: Cluster Analysis and Prediction Trees
17.1 Introduction
There are many aspects of data analysis that call for grouping individuals, firms, projects, etc. These fall under the rubric of what may be
termed as “classification” analysis. Cluster analysis comprises a group of
techniques that uses distance metrics to bunch data into categories.
There are two broad approaches to cluster analysis:
1. Agglomerative or Hierarchical or Bottom-up: In this case we begin
with all entities in the analysis being given their own cluster, so that
we start with n clusters. Then, entities are grouped into clusters based
on a given distance metric between each pair of entities. In this way
a hierarchy of clusters is built up and the researcher can choose which
grouping is preferred.
2. Partitioning or Top-down: In this approach, the entire set of n entities
is assumed to be a cluster. Then it is progressively partitioned into
smaller and smaller clusters.
We will employ both clustering approaches and examine their properties
with various data sets as examples.
17.2 Clustering using k-means
This approach is bottom-up. If we have a sample of n observations to be
allocated to k clusters, then we can initialize the clusters in many ways.
One approach is to assume that each observation is a cluster unto itself.
We proceed by taking each observation and allocating it to the nearest
cluster using a distance metric. At the outset, we would simply allocate
an observation to its nearest neighbor.
428
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
How is nearness measured? We need a distance metric, and one common one is Euclidian distance. Suppose we have two observations xi
and x j . These may be represented by a vector of attributes. Suppose
our observations are people, and the attributes are {height, weight, IQ}
= xi = {hi , wi , Ii } for the i-th individual. Then the Euclidian distance
between two individuals i and j is
q
dij = (hi − h j )2 + (wi − w j )2 + ( Ii − Ij )2
In contrast, the “Manhattan” distance is given by (when is this more
appropriate?)
dij = |hi − h j | + |wi − w j | + | Ii − Ij |
We may use other metrics such as the cosine distance, or the Mahalanobis distance. A matrix of n × n values of all dij s is called the “distance matrix.” Using this distance metric we assign nodes to clusters or
attach them to nearest neighbors. After a few iterations, no longer are
clusters made up of singleton observations, and the number of clusters
reaches k, the preset number required, and then all nodes are assigned to
one of these k clusters. As we examine each observation we then assign
it (or re-assign it) to the nearest cluster, where the distance is measured
from the observation to some representative node of the cluster. Some
common choices of the representative node in a cluster of are:
1. Centroid of the cluster. This is the mean of the observations in the
cluster for each attribute. The centroid of the two observations above
is the average vector {(hi + h j )/2, (wi + w j )/2, ( Ii + Ij )/2}. This is
often called the “center” of the cluster. If there are more nodes then
the centroid is the average of the same coordinate for all nodes.
2. Closest member of the cluster.
3. Furthest member of the cluster.
The algorithm converges when no re-assignments of observations to
clusters occurs. Note that k-means is a random algorithm, and may not
always return the same clusters every time the algorithm is run. Also,
one needs to specify the number of clusters to begin with and there may
be no a-priori way in which to ascertain the correct number. Hence, trial
and error and examination of the results is called for. Also, the algorithm
aims to have balanced clusters, but this may not always be appropriate.
In R, we may construct the distance matrix using the dist function.
Using the NCAA data we are already familiar with, we have:
in the same boat: cluster analysis and prediction trees
> ncaa = read . t a b l e ( " ncaa . t x t " , header=TRUE)
> names ( ncaa )
[ 1 ] "No"
"NAME" "GMS" " PTS " "REB" "AST"
[ 1 1 ] " PF "
"FG"
" FT "
" X3P "
> d = d i s t ( ncaa [ , 3 : 1 4 ] , method= " e u c l i d i a n " )
"TO"
"A. T "
Examining this matrix will show that it contains n(n − 1)/2 elements,
i.e., the number of pairs of nodes. Only the lower triangular matrix of d
is populated.
It is important to note that since the size of the variables is very different, simply applying the dist function is not advised, as the larger
variables swamp the distance calculation. It is best to normalize the variables first, before calculating distances. The scale function in R is simple
to apply as follows.
> ncaa _ data = as . matrix ( ncaa [ , 3 : 1 4 ] )
> summary ( ncaa _ data )
GMS
PTS
REB
AST
Min .
:1.000
Min .
:46.00
Min .
:19.00
Min .
: 2.00
1 s t Qu . : 1 . 0 0 0
1 s t Qu . : 6 1 . 7 5
1 s t Qu . : 3 1 . 7 5
1 s t Qu . : 1 0 . 0 0
Median : 2 . 0 0 0
Median : 6 7 . 0 0
Median : 3 4 . 3 5
Median : 1 3 . 0 0
Mean
:1.984
Mean
:67.10
Mean
:34.47
Mean
:12.75
3 rd Qu . : 2 . 2 5 0
3 rd Qu . : 7 3 . 1 2
3 rd Qu . : 3 7 . 2 0
3 rd Qu . : 1 5 . 5 7
Max .
:6.000
Max .
:88.00
Max .
:43.00
Max .
:20.00
A. T
STL
BLK
PF
Min .
:0.1500
Min .
: 2.000
Min .
:0.000
Min .
:12.00
1 s t Qu . : 0 . 7 4 0 0
1 s t Qu . : 5 . 0 0 0
1 s t Qu . : 1 . 2 2 5
1 s t Qu . : 1 6 . 0 0
Median : 0 . 9 7 0 0
Median : 7 . 0 0 0
Median : 2 . 7 5 0
Median : 1 9 . 0 0
Mean
:0.9778
Mean
: 6.823
Mean
:2.750
Mean
:18.66
3 rd Qu . : 1 . 2 3 2 5
3 rd Qu . : 8 . 4 2 5
3 rd Qu . : 4 . 0 0 0
3 rd Qu . : 2 0 . 0 0
Max .
:1.8700
Max .
:12.000
Max .
:6.500
Max .
:29.00
FG
FT
X3P
Min .
:0.2980
Min .
:0.2500
Min .
:0.0910
1 s t Qu . : 0 . 3 8 5 5
1 s t Qu . : 0 . 6 4 5 2
1 s t Qu . : 0 . 2 8 2 0
Median : 0 . 4 2 2 0
Median : 0 . 7 0 1 0
Median : 0 . 3 3 3 0
Mean
:0.4233
Mean
:0.6915
Mean
:0.3334
3 rd Qu . : 0 . 4 6 3 2
3 rd Qu . : 0 . 7 7 0 5
3 rd Qu . : 0 . 3 9 4 0
Max .
:0.5420
Max .
:0.8890
Max .
:0.5220
> ncaa _ data = s c a l e ( ncaa _ data )
TO
Min .
: 5.00
1 s t Qu . : 1 1 . 0 0
Median : 1 3 . 5 0
Mean
:13.96
3 rd Qu . : 1 7 . 0 0
Max .
:24.00
The scale function above normalizes all columns of data. If you run
summary again, all variables will have mean zero and unit standard deviation. Here is a check.
> round ( apply ( ncaa _ data , 2 , mean ) , 2 )
GMS PTS REB AST TO A. T STL BLK PF
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
0
> apply ( ncaa _ data , 2 , sd )
GMS PTS REB AST TO A. T STL BLK PF
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
1
FG
0
FT X3P
0
0
FG
1
FT X3P
1
1
Clustering takes many observations with their characteristics and
then allocates them into buckets or clusters based on their similarity.
In finance, we may use cluster analysis to determine groups of similar
firms. For example, see Figure 17.1, where I ran a cluster analysis on VC
" STL "
"BLK"
429
430
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
financing of startups to get a grouping of types of venture financing into
different styles.
Unlike regression analysis, cluster analysis uses only the right-hand
side variables, and there is no dependent variable required. We group
observations purely on their overall similarity across characteristics.
Hence, it is closely linked to the notion of “communities” that we studied earlier, though that concept lives in the domain of networks.
1: Early/Exp stage—Non US 2: Exp stage—Computer 3: Early stage—Computer 4: Early/Exp/Late stage—Non High-­‐tech 5: Early/Exp stage—Comm/Media 6: Late stage—Comm/Media & Computer 7: Early/Exp/Late stage—Medical 8: Early/Exp/Late stage—Biotech 9: Early/Exp/Late stage—Semiconductors 10: Seed stage 11: Buyout stage <Large Inv> 12: Other stage 17.2.1
Example: Randomly generated data in kmeans
Here we use the example from the kmeans function to see how the clusters appear. This function is standard issue, i.e., it comes with the stats
Figure 17.1: VC Style Clusters.
in the same boat: cluster analysis and prediction trees
package, which is included in the base R distribution and does not need
to be separately installed. The data is randomly generated but has two
bunches of items with different means, so we should be easily able to see
two separate clusters. You will need the graphics package which is also
in the base installation.
> require ( graphics )
>
> # a 2− d i m e n s i o n a l e x a m p l e
> x <− rbind ( matrix ( rnorm ( 1 0 0 , sd = 0 . 3 ) , ncol = 2 ) ,
+
matrix ( rnorm ( 1 0 0 , mean = 1 , sd = 0 . 3 ) , ncol = 2 ) )
> colnames ( x ) <− c ( " x " , " y " )
> ( c l <− kmeans ( x , 2 ) )
K−means c l u s t e r i n g with 2 c l u s t e r s o f s i z e s 5 2 , 48
C l u s t e r means :
x
y
1 0.98813364 1.01967200
2 − 0.02752225 − 0.02651525
Clustering vector :
[1] 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 2 2 2 2 2
[36] 2 1 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1
[71] 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 1 2
Within c l u s t e r sum o f s q u a r e s by c l u s t e r :
[ 1 ] 10.509092 6.445904
A v a i l a b l e components :
[ 1 ] " c l u s t e r " " centers " " withinss " " size "
> plot ( x , col = c l $ c l u s t e r )
> p o i n t s ( c l $ c e n t e r s , c o l = 1 : 2 , pch = 8 , cex =2)
The plotted clusters appear in Figure 17.2.
We can also examine the same example with 5 clusters. The output is
shown in Figure 17.3
> # # random s t a r t s do h e l p h e r e w i t h t o o many c l u s t e r s
> ( c l <− kmeans ( x , 5 , n s t a r t = 2 5 ) )
K−means c l u s t e r i n g with 5 c l u s t e r s o f s i z e s 2 5 , 2 2 , 1 6 , 2 0 , 17
C l u s t e r means :
x
y
1 − 0.1854632 0 . 1 1 2 9 2 9 1
2 0 . 1 3 2 1 4 3 2 − 0.2089422
3 0.9217674 0.6424407
4 0.7404867 1.2253548
5 1.3078410 1.1022096
Clustering vector :
[1] 1 2 1 1 2 2 2 4 2 1 2 1 1 1 1 2 2 1 2 1 1 1 1 2 2 1 1 2 2 3 1 2 2 1 2
[36] 2 3 2 2 1 1 2 1 1 1 1 1 2 1 2 5 5 4 4 4 4 4 4 5 4 5 4 5 5 5 5 3 4 3 3
[71] 3 3 3 5 5 5 5 5 4 5 4 4 3 4 5 3 5 4 3 5 4 4 3 3 4 3 4 3 4 3
Within c l u s t e r sum o f s q u a r e s by c l u s t e r :
[ 1 ] 2.263606 1.311527 1.426708 2.084694 1.329643
A v a i l a b l e components :
[ 1 ] " c l u s t e r " " centers " " withinss " " size "
> plot ( x , col = c l $ c l u s t e r )
> p o i n t s ( c l $ c e n t e r s , c o l = 1 : 5 , pch = 8 )
431
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
Figure 17.2: Two cluster example.
-0.5
0.0
0.5
y
1.0
1.5
2.0
432
-0.5
0.0
0.5
1.0
1.5
x
17.2.2
Example: Clustering of VC financing rounds
In this section we examine data on VC’s financing of startups from 2001–
2006, using data on individual financing rounds. The basic information
that we have is shown below.
> data = read . csv ( " vc _ c l u s t . csv " , header=TRUE, sep= " , " )
> dim ( data )
[ 1 ] 3697
47
> names ( data )
[ 1 ] " fund _name "
" fund _ year "
" fund _avg_ rd _ i n v t "
[ 4 ] " fund _avg_ co _ i n v t " " fund _num_ co "
" fund _num_ rds "
[ 7 ] " fund _ t o t _ i n v t "
" s t a g e _num1"
" s t a g e _num2"
[ 1 0 ] " s t a g e _num3"
" s t a g e _num4"
" s t a g e _num5"
[ 1 3 ] " s t a g e _num6"
" s t a g e _num7"
" s t a g e _num8"
[ 1 6 ] " s t a g e _num9"
" s t a g e _num10 "
" s t a g e _num11 "
[ 1 9 ] " s t a g e _num12 "
" s t a g e _num13 "
" s t a g e _num14 "
[ 2 2 ] " s t a g e _num15 "
" s t a g e _num16 "
" s t a g e _num17 "
[ 2 5 ] " i n v e s t _ type _num1" " i n v e s t _ type _num2" " i n v e s t _ type _num3"
[ 2 8 ] " i n v e s t _ type _num4" " i n v e s t _ type _num5" " i n v e s t _ type _num6"
[ 3 1 ] " fund _ n a t i o n _US"
" fund _ s t a t e _CAMA" " fund _ type _num1"
in the same boat: cluster analysis and prediction trees
-0.5
0.0
0.5
y
1.0
1.5
2.0
Figure 17.3: Five cluster example.
-0.5
0.0
0.5
1.0
1.5
x
[34]
[37]
[40]
[43]
[46]
433
" fund _ type _num2"
" fund _ type _num5"
" fund _ type _num8"
" fund _ type _num11 "
" fund _ type _num14 "
" fund _ type _num3"
" fund _ type _num6"
" fund _ type _num9"
" fund _ type _num12 "
" fund _ type _num15 "
" fund _ type _num4"
" fund _ type _num7"
" fund _ type _num10 "
" fund _ type _num13 "
We clean out all rows that have missing values as follows:
> idx = which ( rowSums ( i s . na ( data ) ) = = 0 )
> length ( idx )
[ 1 ] 2975
> data = data [ idx , ]
> dim ( data )
[ 1 ] 2975
47
We run a first-cut k-means analysis using limited data.
> idx = c ( 3 , 6 , 3 1 , 3 2 )
> c d a t a = data [ , idx ]
> names ( c d a t a )
[ 1 ] " fund _avg_ rd _ i n v t " " fund _num_ rds "
" fund _ n a t i o n _US"
[ 4 ] " fund _ s t a t e _CAMA"
> f i t = kmeans ( cdata , 4 )
> f i t $ size
[ 1 ] 2856
2
95
22
> f i t $ centers
fund _avg_ rd _ i n v t fund _num_ rds fund _ n a t i o n _US fund _ s t a t e _CAMA
1
4714.894
8.808824
0.5560224
0.2244398
2
1025853.650
7.500000
0.0000000
0.0000000
3
87489.873
6.400000
0.4631579
0.1368421
4
302948.114
5.318182
0.7272727
0.2727273
434
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
We see that the clusters are hugely imbalanced, with one cluster accounting for most of the investment rounds. Let’s try a different cut
now. Using investment type = {buyout, early, expansion, late, other, seed}
types of financing, we get the following, assuming 4 clusters.
> idx = c ( 2 5 , 2 6 , 2 7 , 2 8 , 2 9 , 3 0 , 3 1 , 3 2 )
> c d a t a = data [ , idx ]
> names ( c d a t a )
[ 1 ] " i n v e s t _ type _num1" " i n v e s t _ type _num2" " i n v e s t _ type _num3"
[ 4 ] " i n v e s t _ type _num4" " i n v e s t _ type _num5" " i n v e s t _ type _num6"
[ 7 ] " fund _ n a t i o n _US"
" fund _ s t a t e _CAMA"
> f i t = kmeans ( cdata , 4 )
> f i t $ size
[ 1 ] 2199
65 380 331
> f i t $ centers
i n v e s t _ type _num1 i n v e s t _ type _num2 i n v e s t _ type _num3 i n v e s t _ type _num4
1
0.0000000
0.00000000
0.00000000
0.00000000
2
0.0000000
0.00000000
0.00000000
0.00000000
3
0.6868421
0.12631579
0.06052632
0.12631579
4
0.4592145
0.09969789
0.39274924
0.04833837
i n v e s t _ type _num5 i n v e s t _ type _num6 fund _ n a t i o n _US fund _ s t a t e _CAMA
1
0
1
0.5366075
0.2391996
2
1
0
0.7538462
0.1692308
3
0
0
1.0000000
0.3236842
4
0
0
0.1178248
0.0000000
Here we get a very different outcome. Now, assuming 6 clusters, we
have:
> idx = c ( 2 5 , 2 6 , 2 7 , 2 8 , 2 9 , 3 0 , 3 1 , 3 2 )
> c d a t a = data [ , idx ]
> f i t = kmeans ( cdata , 6 )
> f i t $ size
[1]
34 526 176 153 1673 413
> f i t $ centers
i n v e s t _ type _num1 i n v e s t _ type _num2 i n v e s t _ type _num3 i n v e s t _ type _num4
1
0
0.3235294
0
0.3529412
2
0
0.0000000
0
0.0000000
3
0
0.3977273
0
0.2954545
4
0
0.0000000
1
0.0000000
5
0
0.0000000
0
0.0000000
6
1
0.0000000
0
0.0000000
i n v e s t _ type _num5 i n v e s t _ type _num6 fund _ n a t i o n _US fund _ s t a t e _CAMA
1
0.3235294
0
1.0000000
1.0000000
2
0.0000000
1
1.0000000
1.0000000
3
0.3068182
0
0.6306818
0.0000000
4
0.0000000
0
0.4052288
0.1503268
5
0.0000000
1
0.3909145
0.0000000
6
0.0000000
0
0.6319613
0.1864407
17.2.3
NCAA teams
We revisit our NCAA data set, and form clusters there.
> ncaa = read . t a b l e ( " ncaa . t x t " , header=TRUE)
> names ( ncaa )
[ 1 ] "No"
"NAME" "GMS" " PTS " "REB" "AST"
[ 1 1 ] " PF "
"FG"
" FT "
" X3P "
"TO"
"A. T "
" STL "
"BLK"
in the same boat: cluster analysis and prediction trees
> f i t = kmeans ( ncaa [ , 3 : 1 4 ] , 4 )
> f i t $ size
[ 1 ] 14 17 27 6
> f i t $ centers
GMS
PTS
REB
AST
TO
A. T
1 3.357143 80.12857 34.15714 16.357143 13.70714 1.2357143
2 1.529412 60.24118 38.76471 9.282353 16.45882 0.5817647
3 1.777778 68.39259 33.17407 13.596296 12.83704 1.1107407
4 1.000000 50.33333 28.83333 10.333333 12.50000 0.9000000
BLK
PF
FG
FT
X3P
1 2.514286 18.48571 0.4837143 0.7042143 0.4035714
2 2.882353 18.51176 0.3838824 0.6683529 0.3091765
3 2.918519 18.68519 0.4256296 0.7071852 0.3263704
4 2.166667 19.33333 0.3835000 0.6565000 0.2696667
> idx = c ( 4 , 6 ) ; p l o t ( ncaa [ , idx ] , c o l = f i t $ c l u s t e r )
435
STL
6.821429
6.882353
6.822222
6.666667
See Figure 17.4. Since there are more than two attributes of each observation in the data, we picked two of them {AST, PTS} and plotted the
clusters against those.
5
10
AST
15
20
Figure 17.4: NCAA cluster example.
50
60
70
PTS
80
436
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
17.3 Hierarchical Clustering
Hierarchical clustering is both, a top-down (divisive) approach and
bottom-up (agglomerative) approach. At the top level there is just one
cluster. A level below, this may be broken down into a few clusters,
which are then further broken down into more sub-clusters a level below, and so on. This clustering approach is computationally expensive,
and the divisive approach is exponentially expensive in n, the number of
entities being clustered. In fact, the algorithm is O(2n ).
The function for clustering is hclust and is included in the stats
package in the base R distribution.
We re-use the NCAA data set one more time.
> d = d i s t ( ncaa [ , 3 : 1 4 ] , method= " e u c l i d i a n " )
> f i t = h c l u s t ( d , method= " ward " )
> names ( f i t )
[ 1 ] " merge "
" height "
" order "
[6] " call "
" d i s t . method "
> p l o t ( f i t , main= "NCAA Teams " )
> groups = c u t r e e ( f i t , k =4)
> r e c t . h c l u s t ( f i t , k =4 , border= " blue " )
" labels "
We begin by first computing the distance matrix. Then we call the hclust
function and the plot function applied to object fit gives what is known
as a “dendrogram” plot, showing the cluster hierarchy. We may pick
clusters at any level. In this case, we chose a “cut” level such that we get
four clusters, and the rect.hclust function allows us to superimpose
boxes on the clusters so we can see the grouping more clearly. The result
is plotted in Figure 17.5.
We can also visualize the clusters loaded on to the top two principal
components as follows, using the clusplot function that resides in package cluster. The result is plotted in Figure 17.6.
> groups
[1] 1 1 1 1 1 2 1 1 3 2 1 3 3 1 1 1 2 3 3 2 3 2 1 1 3 3 1 3 2 3 3 3 1 2 2
[36] 3 3 4 1 2 4 4 4 3 3 2 4 3 1 3 3 4 1 2 4 3 3 3 3 4 4 4 4 3
> library ( cluster )
> c l u s p l o t ( ncaa [ , 3 : 1 4 ] , groups , c o l o r =TRUE, shade=TRUE, l a b e l s =2 , l i n e s =0)
17.4 Prediction Trees
Prediction trees are a natural outcome of recursive partitioning of the
data. Hence, they are a particular form of clustering at different levels.
" method "
in the same boat: cluster analysis and prediction trees
437
Figure 17.5: NCAA data, hierarchi-
14
23
1
24
2
7
16
33
5
4
3
27
49
39
53
8
11
15
43
47
62
38
41
61
63
52
60
42
55
35
10
40
54
6
17
34
46
29
20
22
37
19
44
59
36
45
58
64
13
50
56
18
51
30
31
25
28
48
26
32
21
57
9
12
0
50
Height
100
150
NCAA Teams
d
hclust (*, "ward")
cal cluster example.
438
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
CLUSPLOT( ncaa[, 3:14] )
3
2
3
62
39
31
60
13
18
1
32
57
43
47
55 59
26
12 9
51 25
44
0
38
37
-1
cal cluster example with clusters on
the top two principal components.
1
4
41
48
Component 2
Figure 17.6: NCAA data, hierarchi-
58
5052
21 64
42
7
33
28
352 53
30
36
56
27
16
1
5
3
23
624
14
4
2
8
34
45 46
40
17
20
11
15
29
-2
19
63
10
22
54
-3
61
-4
-2
49
0
2
4
Component 1
These two components explain 42.57 % of the point variability.
Usual cluster analysis results in a “flat” partition, but prediction trees
develop a multi-level cluster of trees. The term used here is CART, which
stands for classification analysis and regression trees. But prediction
trees are different from vanilla clustering in an important way – there is
a dependent variable, i.e., a category or a range of values (e.g., a score)
that one is attempting to predict.
Prediction trees are of two types: (a) Classification trees, where the
leaves of the trees are different categories of discrete outcomes. and (b)
Regression trees, where the leaves are continuous outcomes. We may
think of the former as a generalized form of limited dependent variables,
and the latter as a generalized form of regression analysis.
To set ideas, suppose we want to predict the credit score of an individual using age, income, and education as explanatory variables. Assume
that income is the best explanatory variable of the three. Then, at the
top of the tree, there will be income as the branching variable, i.e., if income is less than some threshold, then we go down the left branch of the
tree, else we go down the right. At the next level, it may be that we use
education to make the next bifurcation, and then at the third level we
use age. A variable may even be repeatedly used at more than one level.
in the same boat: cluster analysis and prediction trees
This leads us to several leaves at the bottom of the tree that contain the
average values of the credit scores that may be reached. For example if
we get an individual of young age, low income, and no education, it is
very likely that this path down the tree will lead to a low credit score on
average. Instead of credit score (an example of a regression tree), consider credit ratings of companies (an example of a classification tree).
These ideas will become clearer once we present some examples.
Recursive partitioning is the main algorithmic construct behind prediction trees. We take the data and using a single explanatory variable,
we try and bifurcate the data into two categories such that the additional
information from categorization results in better “information” than before the binary split. For example, suppose we are trying to predict who
will make donations and who will not using a single variable – income.
If we have a sample of people and have not yet analyzed their incomes,
we only have the raw frequency p of how many people made donations,
i.e., and number between 0 and 1. The “information” of the predicted
likelihood p is inversely related to the sum of squared errors (SSE) between this value p and the 0 values and 1 values of the observations.
n
SSE1 =
∑ ( x i − p )2
i =1
where xi = {0, 1}, depending on whether person i made a donation
or not. Now, if we bifurcate the sample based on income, say to the left
we have people with income less than K, and to the right, people with
incomes greater than or equal to K. If we find that the proportion of
people on the left making donations is p L < p and on the right is p R >
p, our new information is:
SSE2 =
∑
i,Income<K
( x i − p L )2 +
∑
i,Income≥K
( x i − p R )2
By choosing K correctly, our recursive partitioning algorithm will maximize the gain, i.e., δ = (SSE1 − SSE2 ). We stop branching further when
at a given tree level δ is less than a pre-specified threshold.
We note that as n gets large, the computation of binary splits on any
variable is expensive, i.e., of order O(2n ). But as we go down the tree,
and use smaller subsamples, the algorithm becomes faster and faster. In
general, this is quite an efficient algorithm to implement.
The motivation of prediction trees is to emulate a decision tree. It also
helps make sense of complicated regression scenarios where there are
439
440
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
lots of variable interactions over many variables, when it becomes difficult to interpret the meaning and importance of explanatory variables
in a prediction scenario. By proceeding in a hierarchical manner on a
tree, the decision analysis becomes transparent, and can also be used in
practical settings to make decisions.
17.4.1
Classification Trees
To demonstrate this, let’s use a data set that is already in R. We use the
kyphosis data set which contains data on children who have had spinal
surgery. The model we wish to fit is to predict whether a child has a
post-operative deformity or not (variable: Kyphosis = {absent, present}).
The variables we use are Age in months, number of vertebrae operated
on (Number), and the beginning of the range of vertebrae operated on
(Start). The package used is called rpart which stands for “recursive
partitioning”.
> library ( rpart )
> data ( kyphosis )
> head ( kyphosis )
Kyphosis Age Number S t a r t
1
a b s e n t 71
3
5
2
a b s e n t 158
3
14
3 p r e s e n t 128
4
5
4
absent
2
5
1
5
absent
1
4
15
6
absent
1
2
16
> f i t = r p a r t ( Kyphosis~Age+Number+ S t a r t , method= " c l a s s " , data=kyphosis )
>
> printcp ( f i t )
Classification tree :
r p a r t ( formula = Kyphosis ~ Age + Number + S t a r t , data = kyphosis ,
method = " c l a s s " )
V a r i a b l e s a c t u a l l y used i n t r e e c o n s t r u c t i o n :
[ 1 ] Age
Start
Root node e r r o r : 17 / 81 = 0 . 2 0 9 8 8
n= 81
CP n s p l i t r e l e r r o r
1 0.176471
0
1.00000
2 0.019608
1
0.82353
3 0.010000
4
0.76471
xerror
xstd
1.0000 0.21559
1.1765 0.22829
1.1765 0.22829
We can now get a detailed summary of the analysis as follows:
> summary ( f i t )
Call :
r p a r t ( formula = Kyphosis ~ Age + Number + S t a r t , data = kyphosis ,
method = " c l a s s " )
n= 81
in the same boat: cluster analysis and prediction trees
CP n s p l i t
1 0.17647059
0
2 0.01960784
1
3 0.01000000
4
rel error
xerror
xstd
1.0000000 1.000000 0.2155872
0.8235294 1.176471 0.2282908
0.7647059 1.176471 0.2282908
Node number 1 : 81 o b s e r v a t i o n s ,
complexity param = 0 . 1 7 6 4 7 0 6
predicted c l a s s =absent
expected l o s s = 0 . 2 0 9 8 7 6 5
c l a s s counts :
64
17
probabilities : 0.790 0.210
l e f t son=2 ( 6 2 obs ) r i g h t son=3 ( 1 9 obs )
Primary s p l i t s :
S t a r t < 8 . 5 t o t h e r i g h t , improve = 6 . 7 6 2 3 3 0 , ( 0 missing )
Number < 5 . 5 t o t h e l e f t , improve = 2 . 8 6 6 7 9 5 , ( 0 missing )
Age
< 3 9 . 5 t o t h e l e f t , improve = 2 . 2 5 0 2 1 2 , ( 0 missing )
Surrogate s p l i t s :
Number < 6 . 5 t o t h e l e f t , agree = 0 . 8 0 2 , a d j = 0 . 1 5 8 , ( 0 s p l i t )
Node number 2 : 62 o b s e r v a t i o n s ,
complexity param = 0 . 0 1 9 6 0 7 8 4
predicted c l a s s =absent
expected l o s s = 0 . 0 9 6 7 7 4 1 9
c l a s s counts :
56
6
probabilities : 0.903 0.097
l e f t son=4 ( 2 9 obs ) r i g h t son=5 ( 3 3 obs )
Primary s p l i t s :
S t a r t < 1 4 . 5 t o t h e r i g h t , improve = 1 . 0 2 0 5 2 8 0 , ( 0 missing )
Age
< 55
t o t h e l e f t , improve = 0 . 6 8 4 8 6 3 5 , ( 0 missing )
Number < 4 . 5 t o t h e l e f t , improve = 0 . 2 9 7 5 3 3 2 , ( 0 missing )
Surrogate s p l i t s :
Number < 3 . 5 t o t h e l e f t , agree = 0 . 6 4 5 , a d j = 0 . 2 4 1 , ( 0 s p l i t )
Age
< 16
t o t h e l e f t , agree = 0 . 5 9 7 , a d j = 0 . 1 3 8 , ( 0 s p l i t )
Node number 3 : 19 o b s e r v a t i o n s
p r e d i c t e d c l a s s = p r e s e n t expected l o s s = 0 . 4 2 1 0 5 2 6
c l a s s counts :
8
11
probabilities : 0.421 0.579
Node number 4 : 29 o b s e r v a t i o n s
predicted c l a s s =absent
expected l o s s =0
c l a s s counts :
29
0
probabilities : 1.000 0.000
Node number 5 : 33 o b s e r v a t i o n s ,
complexity param = 0 . 0 1 9 6 0 7 8 4
predicted c l a s s =absent
expected l o s s = 0 . 1 8 1 8 1 8 2
c l a s s counts :
27
6
probabilities : 0.818 0.182
l e f t son =10 ( 1 2 obs ) r i g h t son =11 ( 2 1 obs )
Primary s p l i t s :
Age
< 55
t o t h e l e f t , improve = 1 . 2 4 6 7 5 3 0 , ( 0 missing )
S t a r t < 1 2 . 5 t o t h e r i g h t , improve = 0 . 2 8 8 7 7 0 1 , ( 0 missing )
Number < 3 . 5 t o t h e r i g h t , improve = 0 . 1 7 5 3 2 4 7 , ( 0 missing )
Surrogate s p l i t s :
S t a r t < 9 . 5 t o t h e l e f t , agree = 0 . 7 5 8 , a d j = 0 . 3 3 3 , ( 0 s p l i t )
Number < 5 . 5 t o t h e r i g h t , agree = 0 . 6 9 7 , a d j = 0 . 1 6 7 , ( 0 s p l i t )
Node number 1 0 : 12 o b s e r v a t i o n s
predicted c l a s s =absent
expected l o s s =0
c l a s s counts :
12
0
probabilities : 1.000 0.000
Node number 1 1 : 21 o b s e r v a t i o n s ,
complexity param = 0 . 0 1 9 6 0 7 8 4
predicted c l a s s =absent
expected l o s s = 0 . 2 8 5 7 1 4 3
441
442
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
c l a s s counts :
15
6
probabilities : 0.714 0.286
l e f t son =22 ( 1 4 obs ) r i g h t son =23 ( 7 obs )
Primary s p l i t s :
Age
< 111 t o t h e r i g h t , improve = 1 . 7 1 4 2 8 6 0 0 , ( 0 missing )
S t a r t < 1 2 . 5 t o t h e r i g h t , improve = 0 . 7 9 3 6 5 0 8 0 , ( 0 missing )
Number < 3 . 5 t o t h e r i g h t , improve = 0 . 0 7 1 4 2 8 5 7 , ( 0 missing )
Node number 2 2 : 14 o b s e r v a t i o n s
predicted c l a s s =absent
expected l o s s = 0 . 1 4 2 8 5 7 1
c l a s s counts :
12
2
probabilities : 0.857 0.143
Node number 2 3 : 7 o b s e r v a t i o n s
p r e d i c t e d c l a s s = p r e s e n t expected l o s s = 0 . 4 2 8 5 7 1 4
c l a s s counts :
3
4
probabilities : 0.429 0.571
We can plot the tree as well using the plot command. See Figure 17.7.
The dendrogram like tree shows the allocation of the n = 81 cases to
various branches of the tree.
> p l o t ( f i t , uniform=TRUE)
> t e x t ( f i t , use . n=TRUE, a l l =TRUE, cex = 0 . 8 )
17.4.2
The C4.5 Classifier
This is one of the top algorithms of data science. This classifier also follows recursive partitioning as in the previous case, but instead of minimizing the sum of squared errors between the sample data x and the
true value p at each level, here the goal is to minimize entropy. This improves the information gain. Natural entropy (H) of the data x is defined
as
H = − ∑ f ( x ) · ln f ( x )
(17.1)
x
where f ( x ) is the probability density of x. This is intuitive because
after the optimal split in recursing down the tree, the distribution of x
becomes narrower, lowering entropy. This measure is also often known
as “differential entropy.”
To see this let’s do a quick example. We compute entropy for two
distributions of varying spread (standard deviation).
dx = 0 . 0 0 1
x = seq ( − 5 ,5 , dx )
H2 = −sum( dnorm ( x , sd =2) * log ( dnorm ( x , sd = 2 ) ) * dx )
p r i n t (H2)
in the same boat: cluster analysis and prediction trees
Figure 17.7: Classification tree for
Start>=8.5
|
absent
64/17
the kyphosis data set.
Start>=14.5
absent
56/6
present
8/11
Age< 55
absent
27/6
absent
29/0
Age>=111
absent
15/6
absent
12/0
absent
12/2
443
present
3/4
444
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
H3 = −sum( dnorm ( x , sd =3) * log ( dnorm ( x , sd = 3 ) ) * dx )
p r i n t (H3)
[ 1 ] 2.042076
[ 1 ] 2.111239
Therefore, we see that entropy increases as the normal distribution becomes wider. Now, let’s use the C4.5 classifier on the iris data set. The
classifier resides in the RWeka package.
l i b r a r y (RWeka)
data ( i r i s )
p r i n t ( head ( i r i s ) )
r e s = J 4 8 ( S p e c i e s ~ . , data= i r i s )
print ( res )
summary ( r e s )
The output is as follows:
S ep a l . Length S ep a l . Width P e t a l . Length P e t a l . Width S p e c i e s
1
5.1
3.5
1.4
0.2 setosa
2
4.9
3.0
1.4
0.2 setosa
3
4.7
3.2
1.3
0.2 setosa
4
4.6
3.1
1.5
0.2 setosa
5
5.0
3.6
1.4
0.2 setosa
6
5.4
3.9
1.7
0.4 setosa
J 4 8 pruned t r e e
−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−−
P e t a l . Width <= 0 . 6 : s e t o s a ( 5 0 . 0 )
P e t a l . Width > 0 . 6
|
P e t a l . Width <= 1 . 7
|
|
P e t a l . Length <= 4 . 9 : v e r s i c o l o r ( 4 8 . 0 / 1 . 0 )
|
|
P e t a l . Length > 4 . 9
|
|
|
P e t a l . Width <= 1 . 5 : v i r g i n i c a ( 3 . 0 )
|
|
|
P e t a l . Width > 1 . 5 : v e r s i c o l o r ( 3 . 0 / 1 . 0 )
|
P e t a l . Width > 1 . 7 : v i r g i n i c a ( 4 6 . 0 / 1 . 0 )
Number o f Leaves
Size of the t r e e :
:
5
9
in the same boat: cluster analysis and prediction trees
=== Summary ===
Correctly Classified Instances
Incorrectly Classified Instances
Kappa s t a t i s t i c
Mean a b s o l u t e e r r o r
Root mean squared e r r o r
Relative absolute error
Root r e l a t i v e squared e r r o r
Coverage o f c a s e s ( 0 . 9 5 l e v e l )
Mean r e l . r e g i o n s i z e ( 0 . 9 5 l e v e l )
T o t a l Number o f I n s t a n c e s
147
3
0.97
0.0233
0.108
5.2482
22.9089
98.6667
34
150
98
2
%
%
%
%
%
%
=== Confusion Matrix ===
a b c
<−− c l a s s i f i e d as
50 0 0 | a = s e t o s a
0 49 1 | b = v e r s i c o l o r
0 2 48 | c = v i r g i n i c a
17.5 Regression Trees
We move from classification trees (discrete outcomes) to regression trees
(scored or continuous outcomes). Again, we use an example that already
exists in R, i.e., the cars dataset in the cu.summary data frame. Let’s load
it up.
> data ( cu . summary )
> names ( cu . summary )
[1] " Price "
" Country "
" R e l i a b i l i t y " " Mileage "
> head ( cu . summary )
P r i c e Country R e l i a b i l i t y Mileage Type
Acura I n t e g r a 4 11950
Japan Much b e t t e r
NA Small
Dodge C o l t 4
6851
Japan
<NA>
NA Small
Dodge Omni 4
6995
USA Much worse
NA Small
Eagle Summit 4
8895
USA
better
33 Small
Ford E s c o r t
4 7402
USA
worse
33 Small
" Type "
445
446
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
Ford F e s t i v a 4
6319
> dim ( cu . summary )
[ 1 ] 117
5
Korea
better
37 Small
We see that the variables are self-explanatory. See that in some cases,
there are missing (< N A >) values in the Reliability variable. We will
try and predict Mileage using the other variables. (Note: if we tried to
predict Reliability, then we would be back in the realm of classification
trees, here we are looking at regression trees.)
> library ( rpart )
> f i t <− r p a r t ( Mileage~ P r i c e + Country + R e l i a b i l i t y + Type ,
method= " anova " , data=cu . summary )
> summary ( f i t )
Call :
r p a r t ( formula = Mileage ~ P r i c e + Country + R e l i a b i l i t y + Type ,
data = cu . summary , method = " anova " )
n=60 ( 5 7 o b s e r v a t i o n s d e l e t e d due t o m i s s i n g n e s s )
1
2
3
4
5
CP n s p l i t
0.62288527
0
0.13206061
1
0.02544094
2
0.01160389
3
0.01000000
4
rel error
1.0000000
0.3771147
0.2450541
0.2196132
0.2080093
xerror
1.0322810
0.5305328
0.3790878
0.3738624
0.3985025
xstd
0.17522180
0.10329174
0.08392992
0.08489026
0.08895493
Node number 1 : 60 o b s e r v a t i o n s ,
complexity param = 0 . 6 2 2 8 8 5 3
mean= 2 4 . 5 8 3 3 3 , MSE= 2 2 . 5 7 6 3 9
l e f t son=2 ( 4 8 obs ) r i g h t son=3 ( 1 2 obs )
Primary s p l i t s :
Price
< 9 4 4 6 . 5 t o t h e r i g h t , improve = 0 . 6 2 2 8 8 5 3 , ( 0 missing )
Type
s p l i t s as LLLRLL ,
improve = 0 . 5 0 4 4 4 0 5 , ( 0 missing )
R e l i a b i l i t y s p l i t s as LLLRR ,
improve = 0 . 1 2 6 3 0 0 5 , ( 1 1 missing )
Country
s p l i t s as −−LRLRRRLL , improve = 0 . 1 2 4 3 5 2 5 , ( 0 missing )
Surrogate s p l i t s :
Type
s p l i t s as LLLRLL ,
agree = 0 . 9 5 0 , a d j = 0 . 7 5 0 , ( 0 s p l i t )
Country s p l i t s as −−LLLLRRLL , agree = 0 . 8 3 3 , a d j = 0 . 1 6 7 , ( 0 s p l i t )
Node number 2 : 48 o b s e r v a t i o n s ,
complexity param = 0 . 1 3 2 0 6 0 6
mean= 2 2 . 7 0 8 3 3 , MSE= 8 . 4 9 8 2 6 4
l e f t son=4 ( 2 3 obs ) r i g h t son=5 ( 2 5 obs )
Primary s p l i t s :
Type
s p l i t s as RLLRRL ,
improve = 0 . 4 3 8 5 3 8 3 0 ,
Price
< 1 2 1 5 4 . 5 t o t h e r i g h t , improve = 0 . 2 5 7 4 8 5 0 0 ,
Country
s p l i t s as −−RRLRL−LL , improve = 0 . 1 3 3 4 5 7 0 0 ,
R e l i a b i l i t y s p l i t s as LLLRR ,
improve = 0 . 0 1 6 3 7 0 8 6 ,
Surrogate s p l i t s :
Price
< 1 2 2 1 5 . 5 t o t h e r i g h t , agree = 0 . 8 1 2 , a d j = 0 . 6 0 9 ,
Country s p l i t s as −−RRLRL−RL , agree = 0 . 6 4 6 , a d j = 0 . 2 6 1 ,
( 0 missing )
( 0 missing )
( 0 missing )
( 1 0 missing )
(0 split )
(0 split )
Node number 3 : 12 o b s e r v a t i o n s
mean= 3 2 . 0 8 3 3 3 , MSE= 8 . 5 7 6 3 8 9
Node number 4 : 23 o b s e r v a t i o n s ,
complexity param = 0 . 0 2 5 4 4 0 9 4
mean= 2 0 . 6 9 5 6 5 , MSE= 2 . 9 0 7 3 7 2
l e f t son=8 ( 1 0 obs ) r i g h t son=9 ( 1 3 obs )
Primary s p l i t s :
Type
s p l i t s as −LR−−L ,
improve = 0 . 5 1 5 3 5 9 6 0 0 , ( 0 missing )
Price
< 14962
t o t h e l e f t , improve = 0 . 1 3 1 2 5 9 4 0 0 , ( 0 missing )
Country s p l i t s as −−−−L−R−−R, improve = 0 . 0 0 7 0 2 2 1 0 7 , ( 0 missing )
in the same boat: cluster analysis and prediction trees
Surrogate s p l i t s :
P r i c e < 13572
t o t h e r i g h t , agree = 0 . 6 0 9 , a d j = 0 . 1 , ( 0 s p l i t )
Node number 5 : 25 o b s e r v a t i o n s ,
complexity param = 0 . 0 1 1 6 0 3 8 9
mean = 2 4 . 5 6 , MSE= 6 . 4 8 6 4
l e f t son =10 ( 1 4 obs ) r i g h t son =11 ( 1 1 obs )
Primary s p l i t s :
Price
< 1 1 4 8 4 . 5 t o t h e r i g h t , improve = 0 . 0 9 6 9 3 1 6 8 , ( 0 missing )
R e l i a b i l i t y s p l i t s as LLRRR ,
improve = 0 . 0 7 7 6 7 1 6 7 , ( 4 missing )
Type
s p l i t s as L−−RR− ,
improve = 0 . 0 4 2 0 9 8 3 4 , ( 0 missing )
Country
s p l i t s as −−LRRR−−LL , improve = 0 . 0 2 2 0 1 6 8 7 , ( 0 missing )
Surrogate s p l i t s :
Country s p l i t s as −−LLLL−−LR , agree = 0 . 8 0 , a d j = 0 . 5 4 5 , ( 0 s p l i t )
Type
s p l i t s as L−−RL− ,
agree = 0 . 6 4 , a d j = 0 . 1 8 2 , ( 0 s p l i t )
Node number 8 : 10 o b s e r v a t i o n s
mean = 1 9 . 3 , MSE= 2 . 2 1
Node number 9 : 13 o b s e r v a t i o n s
mean= 2 1 . 7 6 9 2 3 , MSE= 0 . 7 9 2 8 9 9 4
Node number 1 0 : 14 o b s e r v a t i o n s
mean= 2 3 . 8 5 7 1 4 , MSE= 7 . 6 9 3 8 7 8
Node number 1 1 : 11 o b s e r v a t i o n s
mean= 2 5 . 4 5 4 5 5 , MSE= 3 . 5 2 0 6 6 1
We may then plot the results, as follows:
> p l o t ( f i t , uniform=TRUE)
> t e x t ( f i t , use . n=TRUE, a l l =TRUE, cex = . 8 )
The result is shown in Figure 17.8.
17.5.1
Example: Califonia Home Data
This example is taken from a data set posted by Cosmo Shalizi at CMU.
We use a different package here, called tree, though this has been subsumed in most of its functionality by rpart used earlier. The analysis is
as follows:
>
>
>
>
>
library ( tree )
cahomes = read . t a b l e ( " cahomedata . t x t " , header=TRUE)
f i t = t r e e ( log ( MedianHouseValue ) ~Longitude+ L a t i t u d e , data=cahomes )
plot ( f i t )
t e x t ( f i t , cex = 0 . 8 )
This predicts housing values from just latitude and longitude coordinates. The prediction tree is shown in Figure 17.9.
Further analysis goes as follows:
> p r i c e . d e c i l e s = q u a n t i l e ( cahomes$MedianHouseValue , 0 : 1 0 / 1 0 )
> c u t . p r i c e s = c u t ( cahomes$MedianHouseValue , p r i c e . d e c i l e s , i n c l u d e . l o w e s t=TRUE)
> p l o t ( cahomes$ Longitude , cahomes$ L a t i t u d e ,
c o l =grey ( 1 0 : 2 / 1 1 ) [ c u t . p r i c e s ] , pch =20 , x l a b = " Longitude " , y l a b= " L a t i t u d e " )
> p a r t i t i o n . t r e e ( f i t , ordvars=c ( " Longitude " , " L a t i t u d e " ) , add=TRUE)
The plot of the output and the partitions is given in Figure 17.10.
447
448
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
Figure 17.8: Prediction tree for cars
Price>=9446
|
24.58
n=60
mileage.
Type=bcf
22.71
n=48
32.08
n=12
Type=bf
20.7
n=23
19.3
n=10
Price>=1.148e+04
24.56
n=25
21.77
n=13
23.86
n=14
25.45
n=11
Latitude < 38.485
Figure 17.9: California home prices
|
prediction tree.
Longitude < -121.655
Latitude < 39.355
11.73
Latitude < 37.925
12.48
Latitude < 34.675
12.10
Longitude < -118.315
Longitude < -120.275
11.75
Longitude < -117.545
12.53
Latitude < 33.725
Latitude < 33.59
Longitude < -116.33
12.54
12.14
11.63
12.09
11.16
11.28
11.32
in the same boat: cluster analysis and prediction trees
449
Figure 17.10: California home prices
42
partition diagram.
40
11.3
38
12.1
11.3
36
11.8
12.5
12.1
34
Latitude
11.7
11.6
12.5
12.5
-124
-122
-120
Longitude
-118
12.1
11.2
-116
-114
450
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
18
Bibliography
A. Admati, and P. Pfleiderer (2001). “Noisytalk.com: Broadcasting
Opinions in a Noisy Environment,” working paper, Stanford University.
Aggarwal, Gagan., Ashish Goel, and Rajeev Motwani (2006). “Truthful Auctions for Price Searching Keywords,” Working paper, Stanford
University.
Andersen, Leif., Jakob Sidenius, and Susanta Basu (2003). All your
hedges in one basket, Risk, November, 67-72.
W. Antweiler and M. Frank (2004). “Is all that Talk just Noise? The Information Content of Internet Stock Message Boards,” Journal of Finance,
v59(3), 1259-1295.
W. Antweiler and M. Frank (2005). “The Market Impact of Corporate
News Stories,” Working paper, University of British Columbia.
Artzner, A., F. Delbaen., J-M. Eber., D. Heath, (1999). “Coherent Measures of Risk,” Mathematical Finance 9(3), 203–228.
Ashcraft, Adam., and Darrell Duffie (2007). “Systemic Illiquidity in the
Federal Funds Market,” American Economic Review, Papers and Proceedings 97, 221-225.
Barabasi, A.-L.; R. Albert (1999). “Emergence of scaling in random
networks,” Science 286 (5439), 509–512. arXiv:cond-mat/9910332.
doi:10.1126/science.286.5439.509. PMID 10521342.
Barabasi, Albert-Laszlo., and Eric Bonabeau (2003). “Scale-Free Networks,” Scientific American May, 50–59.
452
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
Bass, Frank. (1969). “A New Product Growth Model for Consumer
Durables,” Management Science 16, 215–227.
Bass, Frank., Trichy Krishnan, and Dipak Jain (1994). “Why the Bass
Model Without Decision Variables,” Marketing Science 13, 204–223.
Bengtsson, O., Hsu, D. (2010). How do venture capital partners match
with startup founders? Working Paper.
Billio, M., Getmansky, M., Lo. A., Pelizzon, L. (2012). “Econometric
Measures of Connectedness and Systemic Risk in the Finance and Insurance Sectors,” Journal of Financial Economics 104(3), 536–559.
Billio, M., Getmansky, M., Gray, D., Lo. A., Merton, R., Pelizzon, L.
(2012). “Sovereign, Bank and Insurance Credit Spreads: Connectedness
and System Networks,” Working paper, IMF.
Bishop, C. (1995). “Neural Networks for Pattern Recognition,” Oxford
University Press, New York.
Boatwright, Lee., and Wagner Kamakura (2003). “Bayesian Model for
Prelaunch Sales Forecasting of Recorded Music,” Management Science
49(2), 179–196.
P. Bonacich (1972). “Technique for analyzing overlappingmemberships,”
Sociological Methodology 4, 176-185.
P. Bonacich (1987). “Power and centrality: a family of measures,” American Journal of Sociology 92(5), 1170-1182.
Bottazzi, L., Da Rin, M., Hellmann, T. (2011). The importance of trust
for investment: Evidence from venture capital. Working Paper.
Brander, J. A., Amit, R., Antweiler, W. (2002). Venture-capital syndication: Improved venture selection vs. the value-added hypothesis,
Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, v11, 423-452.
Browne, Sid., and Ward Whitt (1996). “Portfolio Choice and the
Bayesian Kelly Criterion,” Advances in Applied Probability 28(4), 1145–
1176.
Burdick, D., Hernandez, M., Ho, H., Koutrika, G., Krishnamurthy,
R., Popa, L., Stanoi, I.R., Vaithyanathan, S., Das, S.R. (2011). Extracting, linking and integrating data from public sources: A financial case
study, IEEE Data Engineering Bulletin, 34(3), 60-67.
bibliography
Cai, Y., and Sevilir, M. (2012). Board connections and M&A Transactions, Journal of Financial Economics 103(2), 327-349.
Cestone, Giacinta., Lerner, Josh, White, Lucy (2006). The design of communicates in venture capital, Harvard Business School Working Paper.
Chakrabarti, S., B. Dom, R. Agrawal, and P. Raghavan. (1998). “Scalable
feature selection, classification and signature generation for organizing large text databases into hierarchical topic taxonomies,” The VLDB
Journal, Springer-Verlag.
Chidambaran, N. K., Kedia, S., Prabhala, N.R. (2010). CEO-Director
connections and fraud, University of Maryland Working Paper.
Cochrane, John (2005). The risk and return of venture capital. Journal of
Financial Economics 75, 3-52.
Cohen, Lauren, Frazzini, Andrea, Malloy, Christopher (2008a). The
small world of investing: Board connections and mutual fund returns,
Journal of Political Economy 116, 951–979.
Cohen, Lauren, Frazzini, Andrea, Malloy, Christopher (2008b). Sell-Side
school ties, forthcoming, Journal of Finance.
M. Coleman and T. L. Liau. (1975). A computer readability formula
designed for machine scoring. Journal of Applied Psychology 60, 283–284.
Cormen, Thomas., Charles Leiserson, and Ronald Rivest (2009). Introduction to Algorithms, MIT Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts.
Cornelli, F., Yosha, O. (2003). Stage financing and the role of convertible
securities, Review of Economic Studies 70, 1-32.
Da Rin, Marco, Hellmann, Thomas, Puri, Manju (2012). A survey of
venture capital research, Duke University Working Paper.
Das, Sanjiv., (2014). “Text and Context: Language Analytics for Finance,” Foundations and Trends in Finance v8(3), 145-260.
Das, Sanjiv., (2014). “Matrix Math: Network-Based Systemic Risk Scoring,” forthcoming Journal of Alternative Investments.
Das, Sanjiv., Murali Jagannathan, and Atulya Sarin (2003). Private Equity Returns: An Empirical Examination of the Exit of asset-Backed
Companies, Journal of Investment Management 1(1), 152-177.
453
454
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
Das, Sanjiv., and Jacob Sisk (2005). “Financial Communities,” Journal of
Portfolio Management 31(4), 112-123.
S. Das and M. Chen (2007). “Yahoo for Amazon! Sentiment Extraction
from Small Talk on the Web,” Management Science 53, 1375-1388.
S. Das, A. Martinez-Jerez, and P. Tufano (2005). “eInformation: A Clinical Study of Investor Discussion and Sentiment,” Financial Management
34(5), 103-137.
S. Das and J. Sisk (2005). “Financial Communities,” Journal of Portfolio
Management 31(4), 112-123.
Das, Sanjiv., and Rangarajan Sundaram (1996). “Auction Theory: A
Summary with Applications and Evidence from the Treasury Markets,”
Financial Markets, Institutions and Instruments v5(5), 1–36.
Das, Sanjiv., Jo, Hoje, Kim, Yongtae (2011). Polishing diamonds in the
rough: The sources of communicated venture performance, Journal of
Financial Intermediation, 20(2), 199-230.
Dean, Jeffrey., and Sanjay Ghemaway (2004). “MapReduce: Simplified
Data Processing on Large Clusters,” OSDI’04: Sixth Symposium on
Operating System Design and Implementation.
P. DeMarzo, D. Vayanos, and J. Zwiebel (2003). “Persuasion Bias, Social Influence, and Uni-Dimensional Opinions,” Quarterly Journal of
Economics 118, 909-968.
Du, Qianqian (2011). Birds of a feather or celebrating differences?
The formation and impact of venture capital syndication, University
of British Columbia Working Paper.
J. Edwards., K. McCurley, and J. Tomlin (2001). “An Adaptive Model for
Optimizing Performance of an Incremental Web Crawler,” Proceedings
WWW10, Hong Kong, 106-113.
G. Ellison, and D. Fudenberg (1995). “Word of Mouth Communication
and Social Learning,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 110, 93-126.
Engelberg, Joseph., Gao, Pengjie, Parsons, Christopher (2000). The value
of a rolodex: CEO pay and personal networks, Working Paper, University of North Carolina at Chapel Hill.
bibliography
Fortunato, S. (2009). Community detection in graphs, arXiv:0906.0612v1
[physics.soc-ph].
S. Fortunato (2010). “Community Detection in Graphs,” Physics Reports
486, 75-174.
Gertler, M.S. (1995). Being there: proximity, organization and culture in
the development and adoption of advanced manufacturing technologies, Economic Geography 7(1), 1-26.
Ghiassi, M., H. Saidane, and D. Zimbra (2005). “A dynamic artificial
neural network model for forecasting time series events,” International
Journal of Forecasting 21, 341–362.
Ginsburg, Jeremy., Matthew Mohebbi, Rajan Patel, Lynnette Brammer,
Mark Smolinski, and Larry Brilliant (2009). “Detecting Influenza Epidemics using Search Engine Data,” Nature 457, 1012–1014.
Girvan, M., Newman, M. (2002). Community structure in social and
biological networks, Proc. of the National Academy of Science 99(12), 7821–
7826.
Glaeser, E., ed., (2010). Agglomeration Economics, University of
Chicago Press.
D. Godes, D. Mayzlin, Y. Chen, S. Das, C. Dellarocas, B. Pfeieffer, B.
Libai, S. Sen, M. Shi, and P. Verlegh. “The Firm’s Management of Social
Interactions,” Marketing Letters v16, 415-428.
Godes, David., and Dina Mayzlin (2004). “Using Online Conversations
to Study Word of Mouth Communication” Marketing Science 23(4), 545–
560.
Godes, David., and Dina Mayzlin (2009). “Firm-Created Word-of-Mouth
Communication: Evidence from a Field Test”, Marketing Science 28(4),
721–739.
Goldfarb, Brent, Kirsch, David, Miller, David, (2007). Was there too little
entry in the dot com era?, Journal of Financial Economics 86(1), 100-144.
Gompers, P., Lerner, J. (2000). Money chasing deals? The impact of fund
inflows on private equity valuations, Journal of Financial Economics 55(2),
281-325.
455
456
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
Gompers, P., Lerner, J. (2001). The venture capital revolution, Journal of
Economic Perspectives 15(2), 45-62.
Gompers, P., Lerner, J., (2004). The Venture Capital Cycle, MIT Press.
Gorman, M., Sahlman, W. (1989). What do venture capitalists do? Journal of Business Venturing 4, 231-248.
P. Graham (2004). “Hackers and Painters,” O’Reilly Media, Sebastopol,
CA.
Granger, Clive, (1969). “Investigating Causal Relations by Econometric
Models and Cross-spectral Methods". Econometrica 37(3), 424–438.
Granovetter, M. (1985). Economic action and social structure: The problem of embeddedness, American Journal of Sociology 91(3), 481-510.
Greene, William (2011). Econometric Analysis, 7th edition, PrenticeHall.
Grossman, S., Hart, O. (1986). The costs and benefits of ownership: A
theory of vertical and lateral integration, Journal of Political Economy
94(4), 691-719.
Guimera, R., Amaral, L.A.N. (2005). Functional cartography of complex
metabolic networks, Nature 433, 895-900.
Guimera, R., Mossa, S., Turtschi, A., Amaral, L.A.N. (2005). The worldwide air transportation network: Anomalous centrality, community
structure, and cities’ global roles, Proceedings of the National Academy of
Science 102, 7794-7799.
Guiso, L., Sapienza, P., Zingales, L. (2004). The role of social capital in
financial development, American Economic Review 94, 526-556.
R. Gunning. The Technique of Clear Writing. McGraw-Hill, 1952.
Halevy, Alon., Peter Norvig, and Fernando Pereira (2009). “The Unreasonable Effectiveness of Data,” IEEE Intelligent Systems March-April,
8–12.
Harrison, D., Klein, K. (2007). What’s the difference? Diversity constructs as separation, variety, or disparity in organization, Academy of
Management Review 32(4), 1199-1228.
bibliography
Hart, O., Moore, J. (1990). Property rights and the nature of the firm,
Journal of Political Economy 98(6), 1119-1158.
Hegde, D., Tumlinson, J. (2011). Can birds of a feather fly together?
Evidence for the economic payoffs of ethnic homophily, Working Paper.
Hellmann, T. J., Lindsey, L., Puri, M. (2008). Building relationships
early: Banks in venture capital, Review of Financial Studies 21(2), 513-541.
Hellmann, T. J., Puri, M. (2002). Venture capital and the professionalization of start-up firms: Empirical evidence, Journal of Finance 57, 169-197.
Hoberg, G., Phillips, G. (2010). Product Market Synergies and Competition in Mergers and Acquisitions: A Text-Based Analysis, Review of
Financial Studies 23(10), 3773–3811.
Hochberg, Y., Ljungqvist, A., Lu, Y. (2007). Whom You Know Matters:
Venture Capital Networks and Investment Performance, Journal of Finance 62(1), 251-301.
Hochberg, Y., Lindsey, L., Westerfield, M. (2011). Inter-firm Economic
Ties: Evidence from Venture Capital, Northwestern University Working
Paper.
Huchinson, J., Andrew Lo, and T. Poggio (1994). “A Non Parametric
Approach to Pricing and Hedging Securities via Learning Networks,”
Journal of Finance 49(3), 851–889.
Hwang, B., Kim, S. (2009). It pays to have friends, Journal of Financial
Economics 93, 138-158.
Ishii, J.L., Xuan, Y. (2009). Acquirer-Target social ties and merger outcomes, Working Paper, SSRN: http://ssrn.com/abstract=1361106.
T. Joachims (1999). “Making large-Scale SVM Learning Practical. Advances in Kernel Methods - Support Vector Learning,” B. Scholkopf and
C. Burges and A. Smola (ed.), MIT-Press.
Kanniainen, Vesa., and Christian Keuschnigg (2003). The optimal portfolio of start-up firms in asset capital finance, Journal of Corporate Finance 9(5), 521-534.
Kaplan, S. N., Schoar, A. (2005). Private equity performance: Returns,
persistence and capital flows, Journal of Finance 60, 1791-1823.
457
458
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
Kaplan, S. N., Sensoy, B., Stromberg, P. (2002). How well do venture
capital databases reflect actual investments?, Working paper, University
of Chicago.
Kaplan, S. N., Stromberg, P. (2003). Financial contracting theory meets
the real world: Evidence from venture capital contracts, Review of Economic Studies 70, 281-316.
Kaplan, S. N., Stromberg, P. (2004). Characteristics, contracts and actions: Evidence from venture capital analyses, Journal of Finance 59,
2177-2210.
Kelly, J.L. (1956). “A New Interpretation of Information Rate,” The Bell
System Technical Journal 35, 917–926.
Koller, D., and M. Sahami (1997). “Hierarchically Classifying Documents using Very Few Words,” International Conference on Machine
Learning, v14, Morgan-Kaufmann, San Mateo, California.
D. Koller (2009). “Probabilistic Graphical Models,” MIT Press.
Krishnan, C. N. V., Masulis, R. W. (2011). Venture capital reputation, in
Douglas J. Cummings, ed., Handbook on Entrepreneurial Finance, Venture
Capital and Private Equity, Oxford University Press.
Lavinio, Stefano (2000). “The Hedge Fund Handbook,” Irwin Library of
Investment & Finance, McGraw-Hill..
D. Leinweber., and J. Sisk (2010). “Relating News Analytics to Stock
Returns,” mimeo, Leinweber & Co.
Lerner, J. (1994). The syndication of venture capital investments. Financial Management 23, 1627.
Lerner, J. (1995). Venture capitalists and the oversight of private firms,
Journal of Finance 50 (1), 302-318
Leskovec, J., Kang, K.J., Mahoney, M.W. (2010). Empirical comparison of
algorithms for network community detection, ACM WWW International
Conference on World Wide Web.
S. Levy (2010). “How Google’s Algorithm Rules the Web,” Wired,
March.
F. Li (2006). “Do Stock Market Investors Understand the RiskSentiment
of Corporate Annual Reports?” Working paper, University of Michigan.
bibliography
Lindsey, L. A. (2008). Blurring boundaries: The role of venture capital in
strategic alliances, Journal of Finance 63(3), 1137-1168.
Lossen, Ulrich (2006). The Performance of Private Equity Funds: Does
Diversification Matter?, Discussion Papers 192, SFB/TR 15, University
of Munich.
T. Loughran and W. McDonald, (2014). Measuring readability in financial disclosures, The Journal of Finance 69, 1643–1671.
Loukides, Mike (2012). “What is Data Science?” O’Reilly, Sebastopol,
CA.
Lusseau, D. (2003). The emergent properties of a dolphin social network, Proceedings of the Royal Society of London B 271 S6: 477–481.
Mayer-Schönberger, Viktor., and Kenneth Cukier (2013). “Big Data:
A Revolution that will Transform How We Live, Work, and Think,”
Houghton Mifflin Harcourt, New York.
A. McCallum (1996). "Bow: A toolkit for statistical language modeling, text retrieval, classification and clustering,"
http://www.cs.cmu.edu/∼mccallum/bow.
McPherson, M., Smith-Lovin, L., Cook, J. (2001). Birds of a feather: Homophily in social networks, Annual Review of Sociology 27, 415-444.
Mezrich, Ben (2003). “Bringing Down the House: The Inside Story of
Six MIT Students Who Took Vegas for Millions,” Free Press,
Mitchell, Tom (1997). “Machine Learning,” McGraw-Hill.
L. Mitra., G. Mitra., and D. diBartolomeo (2008). “Equity Portfolio
Risk (Volatility) Estimation using Market Information and Sentiment,”
Working paper, Brunel University.
P. Morville (2005). “Ambient Findability,” O’Reilly Press, Sebastopol,
CA.
Neal, R.(1996). “Bayesian Learning for Neural-Networks,” Lecture Notes
in Statistics, v118, Springer-Verlag.
Neher, D. V. (1999). Staged financing: An agency perspective, Review of
Economic Studies 66, 255-274.
459
460
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
Newman, M. (2001). Scientific collaboration networks: II. Shortest
paths, weighted networks, and centrality, Physical Review E 64, 016132.
Newman, M. (2006). Modularity and community structure in networks,
Proc. of the National Academy of Science 103 (23), 8577-8582.
Newman, M. (2010). Networks: An introduction, Oxford University
Press.
B. Pang., L. Lee., and S. Vaithyanathan (2002). “Thumbs Up? Sentiment
Classification using Machine Learning Techniques,” Proc. Conference on
Empirical Methods in Natural Language Processing (EMNLP).
Patil, D.J. (2012). “Data Jujitsu,” O’Reilly, Sebastopol, CA.
Patil, D.J. (2011). “Building Data Science Teams,” O’Reilly, Sebastopol,
CA.
P. Pons, M. Latapy (2006). “Computing Communities in Large Networks Using Random Walks,” Journal of Graph Algorithms Applied, 10(2),
191-218.
M. Porter, (1980). “An Algorithm for Suffix Stripping,” Program 14(3),
130?137.
Porter, M.E. (2000). Location, competition and economic development:
Local clusters in a global economy, Economic Development Quarterly
14(1), 15-34.
Porter, Mason., Mucha, Peter, Newman, Mark, Friend, A. J. (2007).
Community structure in the United States House of Representatives,
Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and its Applications 386(1), 413–438.
Ravasz, E., Somera, A.L., Mongru, D.A., Oltvai, N., Barabasi, A.L.
(2002). Hierarchical organization of modularity in metabolic networks,
Science 297 (5586), 1551.
Robinson, D. (2008). Strategic alliances and the boundaries of the firm,
Review of Financial Studies 21(2), 649-681.
Robinson, D., Sensoy, B. (2011). Private equity in the 21st century: cash
flows, performance, and contract terms from 1984-2010, Working Paper,
Ohio State University.
Robinson, D., Stuart, T. (2007). Financial contracting in biotech strategic
alliances, Journal of Law and Economics 50(3), 559-596.
bibliography
Seigel, Eric (2013). “Predictive Analytics,” John-Wiley & Sons, New Jersey.
Segaran, T (2007). “Programming Collective Intelligence,” O’Reilly
Media Inc., California.
Shannon, Claude (1948). “A Mathematical Theory of Communication,”
The Bell System Technical Journal 27, 379–423.
Simon, Herbert (1962). The architecture of complexity, Proceedings of the
American Philosophical Society 106 (6), 467–482.
Smola, A.J., and Scholkopf, B (1998). “A Tutorial on Support Vector
Regression,” NeuroCOLT2 Technical Report, ESPIRIT Working Group
in Neural and Computational Learning II.
Sorensen, Morten (2007). How smart is smart money? A Two-sided
matching model of venture capital, Journal of Finance 62, 2725-2762.
Sorensen, Morten (2008). Learning by investing: evidence from venture
capital, Columbia University Working Paper.
Tarjan, Robert, E. (1983), “Data Structures and Network Algorithms
CBMS-NSF Regional Conference Series in Applied Mathematics.
P. Tetlock (2007). “Giving Content to Investor Sentiment: The Role of
Media in the Stock Market,” Journal of Finance 62(3), 1139-1168.
P. Tetlock, P. M. Saar-Tsechansky, and S. Macskassay (2008). “More than
Words: Quantifying Language to Measure Firm’s Fundamentals,” Journal of Finance 63(3), 1437-1467.
Thorp, Ed. (1962). “Beat the Dealer,” Random House, New York.
Thorp, Ed (1997). “The Kelly Criterion in Blackjack, Sports Betting, and
the Stock Market,” Proc. of The 10th International Conference on Gambling
and Risk Taking, Montreal, June.
Vapnik, V, and A. Lerner (1963). “Pattern Recognition using Generalized Portrait Method,” Automation and Remote Control, v24.
Vapnik, V. and Chervonenkis (1964). “On the Uniform Convergence of
Relative Frequencies of Events to their Probabilities,” Theory of Probability and its Applications, v16(2), 264-280.
461
462
data science: theories, models, algorithms, and analytics
Vapnik, V (1995). The Nature of Statistical Learning Theory, SpringerVerlag, New York.
Vickrey, William (1961). “Counterspeculation, Auctions, and Competitive Sealed Tenders,” Journal of Finance 16(1), 8–37.
Xindong Wu, Vipin Kumar, J. Ross Quinlan, Joydeep Ghosh, Qiang
Yang, Hiroshi Motoda, Geoffrey J. McLachlan, Angus Ng, Bing Liu,
Philip S. Yu, Zhi-Hua Zhou, Michael Steinbach, David J. Hand and Dan
Steinberg, (2008). “Top 10 Algorithms in Data Mining,” Knowledge and
Information Systems 14(1), 1-37.
Wu, K., Taki, Y., Sato, K., Kinomura, S., Goto, R., Okada, K.,
Kawashima, R., He, Y., Evans, A. C. and Fukuda, H. (2011). Age-related
changes in topological organization of structural brain networks in
healthy individuals, Human Brain Mapping 32, doi: 10.1002/hbm.21232.
Zachary, Wayne (1977). An information flow model for conflict and
fission in small groups, Journal of Anthropological Research 33, 452–473.
Download