Econ 200: Lecture 16 November 29, 2016 0. Learning Catalytics Session: 1. Monopolies 2. Monopoly Output and Prices 3. Comparing Monopoly to Perfect Competition What is Monopoly and Why Do We Study It? Monopoly is a market structure consisting of a firm that is the only seller of a good or service that does not have a close substitute. We study monopolies for two reasons: 1. Some firms truly are monopolists. 2. Firms might collude in order to act like a monopolist. 2 Are There Really Monopolies? Suppose you live in a small town with only one pizzeria. Is that pizzeria a monopoly? 1. It has competition from other fast-food restaurants. 2. It has competition from grocery stores that provide pizzas for you to cook at home. Note: The pizzeria’s unique position may afford it some monopoly power to raise prices, and obtain positive economic profit, even if it is not a true monopoly. 3 Reasons Why Monopolies Exist For a firm to exist as a monopoly, there must be barriers to entry preventing other firms coming in and competing with it. The four main reasons for these barriers to entry are: 1. Government restrictions on entry 2. Control over a key resource 3. Network externalities 4. Natural monopoly 4 1. Government Restrictions on Entry In the U.S., governments block entry in two main ways: a. Patents, copyrights, and trademarks. Patents and copyrights encourage innovation and creativity, since without them, firms would not be able to substantially profit from their endeavors. b. Public franchises A government designation that a firm is the only legal provider of a good or service is known as a public franchise. 5 2. Control Over a Key Resource For many years, the Aluminum Company of America (Alcoa) either owned or had long-term contracts for almost all the world’s supply of bauxite, the mineral from which we obtain aluminum. 6 3. Network Externalities Economists refer to network externalities as a situation in which the usefulness of a product increases with the number of consumers who use it. These network externalities can set off a virtuous cycle for a firm, allowing the value of its product to continue to increase, along with the price it can charge. 7 4. Natural Monopoly Natural monopoly: when economies of scale are so large that one firm can supply the entire market at a lower average total cost than can two or more firms. This is often because of high fixed costs; in this example, the cost of erecting power lines and transformers. 8 Calculating a Monopoly’s Revenue Comcast is a monopolist in the market for cable television services. They must accommodate downward sloping demand when choosing Q. 9 Calculating a Monopoly’s Revenue—continued As the monopolist seeks to expand its output, two effects occur: 1. Revenue is up from additional sales 2. Revenue is down due to lowered prices. So marginal revenue is always below demand for a monopolist. 10 Profit-Maximizing Price and Output for a Monopoly Just like the perfect competitor, MC = MR determines quantity for a monopolist. 11 Price and Output for a Monopoly—continued At this quantity, • The demand curve determines price, and • The average total cost (ATC) curve determines average cost. Profit is the difference between these (P–ATC), times quantity (Q). 12 Long-Run Profits for a Monopoly Since there are barriers to entry, additional firms cannot enter the market. • So there is no distinction between the short run and long run for a monopoly (except lower costs due to flexible inputs). We expect monopolists to continue to earn profits in the long run. 13 In this graph, which curve is conceptually the same as average revenue? a. b. c. d. The demand curve. The marginal revenue curve. Both curves. Neither curve. 14 In this graph, which curve is conceptually the same as average revenue? a. The demand curve. 15 Which point shows the price and output for a monopoly? a. b. c. d. A B C None of the above. 16 Relative to the price and output produced by a perfectly competitive industry, what price and output levels correspond to a monopoly in this graph? b. B 17 Comparing Monopoly and Perfect Competition Suppose that a market could be characterized by either perfect competition or monopoly. Which would be better? Imagine a single firm buys up all of the smartphones in the country. What would happen to: • Price and quantity traded? • Consumer surplus? 18 If a Perfect Competition Became a Monopoly… Now the market is supplied by a single firm. Since the single firm is made up of all of the smaller firms, the marginal cost curve for this new firm is identical to the old supply curve. 19 … Quantity Will Fall and Price Will Rise The new firm maximizes market profit, producing the quantity where MC = MR. This quantity (QM) is lower than the competitive quantity (QC)… … and PM is higher than the competitive price, PC. 20 Measuring the Efficiency Losses from Monopoly Fewer smartphones will be traded at a higher price. • Consumer surplus will fall (with the higher price). • Producer surplus must rise, otherwise the firm would have chosen the perfectly competitive price and quantity. Could the increase in producer surplus offset the decrease in consumer surplus? • No! 21 The Inefficiency of Monopoly With the higher monopoly price, CS decreases by A+B. PS falls by C, but rises by A; an overall increase. Area A is a transfer of surplus. But areas B and C are lost surpluses: deadweight loss. 22 How Large Are the Efficiency Losses? There are relatively few monopolies, so the loss of economic efficiency due to monopolies must be relatively small. But many firms have market power: the ability of a firm to charge a price greater than marginal cost. 23 How Large Are the Efficiency Losses? There are relatively few monopolies, so the loss of economic efficiency due to monopolies must be relatively small. But many firms have market power: the ability of a firm to charge a price greater than marginal cost. Still, economists estimate that overall, the loss of efficiency in the United States due to market power is probably less than 1% of total U.S. production—about $500 per person annually. 24 Calculate the profits of a monopoly facing demand Qd=100-p (MR=100-2Q) and MC=AC=4 (TC=4Q). P 100 52 4 MC MR 48 Qd 50 100 Q 25 Calculate the profits of a monopoly facing demand Qd=100-p (MR=100-2Q) and MC=AC=4 (TC=4Q). P 100 52 4 MC MR 48 Qd 50 100 Q Profits = P*Q-AC*Q = 52*48 – 4*48 = 2304 26 Calculate the deadweight loss from the monopoly when Qd=100-p (MR=100-2Q) and MC=4 (TC=4Q). (Hint: Point A is the perfectly competitive equilibrium point) P 100 52 A 4 MR 48 MC Qd 50 100 Q 27 Calculate the deadweight loss from the monopoly. (Hint: Point A is the perfectly competitive equilibrium point) P 100 52 DWL 4 A MR 48 MC Qd 50 96 100 Q DWL= ½ (52-4)*(96-48)=1152 28