Summary Document ISSSV1855 International Politics Author + required (R) Summary done (x) Abrahams, Max x Aistrope x Allison x Aron (no access to article) Ayres x Averre x Avey x Bandarage x Bellamy x Braumoeller x Busby x Dov x Draege x Dyke x Floyd x Fravel x Gleditsch x Hansen Lene x Keywords Höglund x Howard x Jaffe Kagan x Kaarbo x Kirshner x Khong x Kohli x Kuchins x Laurens x Mazarr (in progress) Mearsheimer x Milliken x Monaco (in progress) Pisarska x Putnam x Quek x Robinson a x Robinson b x Sandler x Schweller x Sørli x Tannenwald x Valbjørn x Walt, 1998 x Walt, 2015 (in progress) Walter x Wohlforth (in progress) 46 articles in total → 4 summaries left Abrahms, Max. "Why terrorism does not work." Terrorist groups attack civilians to coerce their governments into making policy concessions, but does this strategy work? If target countries systematically resist rewarding terrorism, the international community is armed with a powerful message to deter groups from terrorizing civilians. The prevailing view within the field of political science, however, is that terrorism is an effective coercive strategy. The implications of this perspective are grim; as target countries are routinely coerced into making important strategic and ideological concessions to terrorists, their victories will reinforce the strategic logic for groups to attack civilians, spawning even more terrorist attacks. This pessimistic outlook is unwarranted; there has been scant empirical research on whether terrorism is a winning coercive strategy, that is, whether groups tend to exact policy concessions from governments by attacking their civilian populations. Thomas Schelling asserted more than a decade ago that terrorists frequently accomplish “intermediate means toward political objectives . . . but with a few exceptions it is hard to see that the attention and publicity have been of much value except as ends in themselves.” This study corroborates that view; the twenty-eight groups of greatest significance to U.S. counterterrorism policy have achieved their forty-two policy objectives less than 10 percent of the time. As the political mediation literature would predict, target countries did not make concessions when terrorist groups had maximalist objectives. Yet even when groups expressed limited, ambiguous, or idiosyncratic policy objectives, they failed to win concessions by primarily attacking civilian targets. This suggests not only that terrorism is an ineffective instrument of coercion, but that its poor success rate is inherent to the tactic of terrorism itself. Why are terrorist groups unable to coerce governments when they primarily attack civilian targets? Terrorism miscommunicates groups’ objectives because of its extremely high correspondence. The responses of Russia to the September 1999 apartment bombings, the United States to the attacks of September 11, and Israel to Palestinian terrorism in the arst intifada provide evidence that target countries infer the objectives of terrorist groups not from their stated goals, but from the short-term consequences of terrorist acts. Target countries view the deaths of their citizens and the resulting turmoil as proof that the perpetrators want to destroy their societies, their publics, or both. Countries are therefore reluctant to make concessions when their civilians are targeted irrespective of the perpetrators’ policy demands. Four policy implications follow for the war on terrorism. 1. First, terrorists will and it extremely difacult to transform or annihilate a country’s political system. 2. Second, the jihadists stand to gain from restricting their violence to military targets. Already, mounting U.S. casualties in Iraq and the absence of a post–September 11 attack on the homeland have eroded U.S. support for maintaining a military presence in Iraq.124 Terrorist strikes on the U.S. homeland will only undermine the terrorists’ message that their purpose is to alter unpopular U.S. policies in the Muslim world. Even sporadic attacks on American civilians—if seen as the dominant component of alQaida’s overall strategy—will undermine support for an exit strategy. 3. Third, the self-defeating policy consequences of terrorism will ultimately dissuade potential jihadists from supporting it. Although guerrilla attacks against U.S. forces in Iraq show no signs of abating, polling data from Muslim countries suggest that the terrorism backlash is already under way. The Pew Research Center reported in its July 2005 Global Attitudes Project that compared with its polls conducted in 2002, “In most majority-Muslim countries surveyed support for suicide bombings and other acts of violence in defense of Islam has declined signiacantly,” as has “conadence in Osama bin Laden to do the right thing in world affairs.” Similarly, major Islamist groups and leaders are increasingly denouncing terrorist attacks as counterproductive, even as they encourage guerrilla warfare against the Iraqi occupation. 4. Fourth, it is commonly said that terrorists cannot be deterred because they are willing to die for their cause and that they lack a “return address” to threaten with a retaliatory strike. But perhaps the greatest reason deterrence breaks down is because of the widespread, albeit erroneous, belief that attacking civilians is an effective strategy for terrorist groups to advance their policy goals. Disabusing terrorists of this notion would go a long way toward defusing the cycles of violent reprisal. Further research is needed in three areas. First, why do terrorist groups target civilians if doing so is strategically ineffective? Second, future research may demonstrate that in international relations the attribute-effect linkage diminishes over time. Third, correspondent inference theory may have prescriptive utility for conducting a more strategic and humane war on terrorism. If countries impute terrorists’ motives from the consequences of their actions, then the communities in which terrorists thrive may impute states’ motives from the consequences of their counterterrorism policies, reinforcing the strategic logic of minimizing collateral damage. Correspondent inference theory can explain not only why terrorist campaigns rarely work, but also perhaps why counterterrorism campaigns tend to breed even more terrorism. Aistrope, Tim, and Roland Bleiker. "Conspiracy and foreign policy." We argue that claims about conspiracies should be seen as narratives that are intrinsically linked to power relations and the production of foreign policy knowledge. We illustrate the links between conspiracies, legitimacy and power by examining multiple conspiracies associated with 9/11 and the War on Terror. Two trends are visible. On the one hand, US officials identified a range of conspiracies and presented them as legitimate and rational, even though some, such as the alleged covert development of weapons of mass destruction in Iraq, are now widely considered false. On the other hand, conspiracies circulating in the Arab-Muslim world were dismissed as irrational and pathological, even though some, like those concerned with the covert operation of US power in the Middle East, were based on credible concerns. “...we have stressed in this article that conspiracy narratives are legitimized or delegitimized within the hierarchies of authority and modes of knowledge production present in particular interpretive communities. We have shown that studying conspiracy narratives that emerge around moments of crisis and controversy like 9/11 provides a unique insight into the social production of foreign policy knowledge, which is the basis for consequential decision-making on matters of war and peace.” Allison This article offers a multifaceted analysis of Russian intervention in Ukraine, but focuses on the persuasiveness of Russian legal claims and on alternative, but overlapping, explanations of Russian conduct. The first part of this article assesses and deconstructs Moscow’s ‘legal rhetoric’. For years there have been entrenched beliefs within the Russian security and foreign policy elite that in a highly competitive and increasingly conflictual world, western political ideals and regional structures mask strategic goals. Russian intervention in Crimea and eastern Ukraine between February and September 2014, using coercion and force to take control of and destabilize the territories of a neighbour state, is a frontal challenge to the post-Cold War European regional order. This is important since Russia is a major power, with a permanent seat on the UN Security Council, which aspires to shape and constrain interpretations of law and international norms in the wider community of states as well as in its own neighbourhood. For more than six weeks after the Crimean occupation Putin explicitly denied that Russian soldiers had been involved. However, in April 2014 he suddenly shifted to admit that ‘Russian servicemen did back the Crimean self-defence forces’, that in Crimea ‘Russia created conditions—with the help of special armed groups and the Armed Forces... for the expression of the will of the people living in Crimea and Sevastopol’. Moscow continued to deny that regular forces were involved, but the scale of the Russian military intervention in August and September was such that Russian denials convinced very few states... Russia cloaked its actions in legal language, as other major states have done in the past, with the aim of fostering a reputation as a lawful actor... It is thus very important to assess how Russia ‘broke the rules’, for the language and claims involved go far beyond mere diplomatic jousting. 1. Russian legal claims have been constructed to mobilize and consolidate Russian domestic opinion around Putin’s leadership. They include justifications for the Russian use of force and the annexation of Crimea, blanketed in partial truth and disinformation, cast in terms which appeal to deeper sentiments and grievances in Russian society and among Russian elites. 2. Making unfounded assertions of ‘facts’ (especially ostensible threats to Russians and Russian-speakers). 3. Grey areas and flux in legal and normative development as well as playing back to western states their own liberal discourse. These included: a. the claim to be protecting Russian citizens from danger (a rationale following the occasional practice by certain countries of carrying out rescue operations for their own nationals without the consent of the country concerned, though this was not at the fore of the Russian case over Crimea); b. the claim to be intervening by invitation (relying on some earlier cases of intervention, especially in western Africa, that depended on the consent of deposed democratically elected governments); c. and reference to the western focus on human protection and Kosovo’s secession from Serbia (used by Moscow to argue the case for remedial secession). Vote on 27 February by an unverifiable number of deputies in the seized Crimean parliament building to hold a Crimean referendum on the issue of enlarging Crimea’s autonomy. Thereafter a ‘declaration of independence’ was adopted by the Crimean parliament on 11 March,7 and a referendum (offering the option of secession to Crimean residents) was conducted on 16 March. Putin described this as an expression of the popular will of the Crimeans to secede from Ukraine. He claimed he would ‘respect the choice of the Crimean people’. However, article 2 (4) of the UN Charter prohibits states from engaging in not only the use of force but any threats of such use against other states, and it was difficult to deny that Russian conduct in Crimea fell into this category of coercive activity. Allison proceeds to present Russia’s formal position as set out by UN Security Council meetings and Putin: Ayres, Alyssa. "Will India Start Acting Like a Global Power?" The country with the world’s third-largest military by personnel strength, fifth-largest defense budget, and seventh-largest economy isn’t a member of the UN Security Council. It isn’t even a member of the G-7, the exclusive club of major industrialized economies. It is India, a country long regarded as an emerging power rather than a major global player. In fairness, for years, this assessment was not off the mark, and India’s reality did not match up to its vaunted potential. And indeed, India still faces daunting developmental challenges. It is home to around 270 million people living in extreme poverty. Its infrastructure is in need of major investment—to the tune of $1.5 trillion over a decade, according to India’s finance minister. Discrimination among India’s famously diverse population persists, whether on the basis of gender, caste, religion, or region. Because of these challenges, and because the country has been kept on the margins of the global institutions central to U.S. diplomacy, India’s impressive economic power and defense capabilities have often gone unnoticed. But that is changing. A more confident India has already begun to shape the global agenda on climate change, clean energy, and worker mobility. And spurred by China’s increasingly assertive regional posture, India has ramped up its own military capacity. Averre and Davies (2015) Russia, humanitarian intervention and the Responsibility to Protect: the case of Syria What follows are excerpts from the article made by Alex Moltzau Most western analysis perceives Russian approaches to humanitarian intervention and the Responsibility to Protect (R2P) as running counter to (largely) western-inspired international norms. Scholars of Russian foreign policy have offered a more thoughtful explanation of Moscow’s approach that downplays material and ‘geopolitical’ factors and highlights Russian concerns about domestic political legitimacy. (outlook rooted in the powerful elite that surrounds Putin) However this article argues that the Syria case reflects important developments in Russia’s broader foreign policy thinking. In this article we seek not to add to the substantial literature on the legal aspects of intervention, but rather to investigate their place in Russian foreign policy thinking; for evolving debates on international practice depend to a large extent on understanding the respective positions of the major powers. (p. 814) Russia’s normative position, aimed at strengthening its international and regional influence and affirming its legitimacy in the changing global order, has been increasingly accompanied by values-based narratives which fundamentally challenge western liberalism. Ian Hurd has argued: international law should be seen as a resource that is used by states, rather than as a fixed standard against which we can assess behaviour ... the practice of humanitarian intervention exists in a space between legality and illegality, one where each instance of the practice can be plausibly seen as either compliance or noncompliance with international law. Canadian International Commission on Intervention and State Sovereignty (ICISS) carried out extensive consultations across the globe and drew up a report which asserted that states have internal responsibility towards their own peoples and external responsibility to react as members of the ‘international community’ in cases of (to use Kofi Annan’s words) ‘gross and systematic violations of human rights. Three key principles for military intervention for R2P purposes. 1. The ‘just cause’ threshold states that interven- tion may be warranted in the case of large-scale loss of life arising from deliberate state action or from neglect or inability to act (for example, in a ‘failed state’ situation), or from ethnic cleansing. 2. ‘precautionary principles’ come into play: these focus on right intention, which should be to halt or avert human suffering; on last resort, with military force being justified only when non-military options have been explored; 3. Finally, the principle of ‘right authority’ dealt with the process of obtaining legal authority to act. It reaffirmed the primary authority of the UNSC and stipulated that states in favour of intervention should formally request its authorization. The World Summit Outcome (WSO) document, published in 2005, took up the ICISS framework but omitted some of its key provisions. This document adopted a narrow reading, affirming the responsibility to protect civilians from four ‘crimes’: genocide, war crimes, ethnic cleansing and crimes against humanity.11 This reading was subsequently reaffirmed in UNSC Resolutions 1674 (2006) and 63/308 (2009). Avey, Paul C., and Michael C. Desch. "What do policymakers want from us? Results of a survey of current and former senior national security decision makers." What do the most senior national security policymakers want from international relations scholars? To answer that question, we administered a unique survey to current and former policymakers to gauge when and how they use academic social science to inform national security decision making. We find that policymakers do regularly follow academic social science research and scholarship on national security affairs, hoping to draw upon its substantive expertise. But our results call into question the direct relevance to policymakers of the most scientific approaches to international relations. And they at best seriously qualify the “trickle down” theory that basic social science research eventually influences policymakers. To be clear, we are not arguing that policymakers never find scholarship based upon the cutting-edge research techniques of social science useful. But policymakers often find contemporary scholarship less-than-helpful when it employs such methods across the board, for their own sake, and without a clear sense of how such scholarship will contribute to policymaking. 1. In conclusion, we first highlight the main findings of the policymaker survey. 2. Next, we offer what we think are the most important policy recommendations that flow from these findings. 3. Finally, we highlight some continuing puzzles and future research questions. Our results clearly show that policymakers do want scholarly expertise, challenging the scientific purists’ strict separation of science and policy. On both sides of the theory/policy divide, the majority of voices clamor for a bridge. But they also call into question when and how often the techniques of the modern science of international relations are directly useful to policymakers. Policymakers seem to prefer mid-range theories to help them make sense of the world and their presentation in brief and jargon-free formats. Finally, these results also speak to the question of the indirect influence of social science on policymakers: While some basic research clearly trickles down (more accurately, percolates up) to the policy world, it is generally not that which is based upon the most scientific approaches to the academic study of international relations. Indeed, our findings about the utility of social science for policymakers in many ways parallel those of the 1960s era “Project Hindsight,” which found that little natural science basic research actually translated into useful defense technology (see Sherwin and Isenson 1967:1571–1577). While it will be no surprise to scholars and policymakers that the gap between the Beltway and the Ivory Tower persists, and is probably even growing, we believe that this policymaker survey, in conjunction with the 2011 TRIP scholar survey, has documented that this gap is both substantive (what issues and areas matter) and also methodological (how we should study international relations and national security issues). The gap between the scientific aspirations of contemporary international relations scholarship and the needs of policymakers is greatest the higher one reaches in the policy world. More surprisingly, this gap tends to be greater the more educated the policymaker. This is consistent with the argument that familiarity with advanced techniques instills greater appreciation for both their promise and limits. (For a related argument, see Eriksson 2012:746– 749.) It is also worth reiterating that we are not advocating scholars abandon sophisticated research methods or suggesting that these methods are never useful for policy-relevant scholarship. Rather, we believe that policymakers operate under some logic of appropriateness in terms of their tolerance for sophisticated social science (especially statistics and formal models) based upon the particular issue in question. (added: The logic of appropriateness is a perspective that sees human action as driven by rules of. appropriate or exemplary behavior, organized into institutions. Rules are followed because. they are seen as natural, rightful, expected, and legitimate.) For example, respondents to our policymaker survey seemed amenable to the use of the latest social science tools and techniques in certain realms (economics and public opinion surveys), just not for their own sake. Another conclusion we draw from this survey is that a scholar’s broader visibility—both in government and among the public, whether through previous government service or publication in broader venues—enhances influence among policymakers more than his or her academic standing. Of course, we have long known that the primary constraint policymakers face in digesting scholarly, or any other writings, is lack of time. As one respondent put it, “any research papers that exceed 10–15 pages” are not useful to policymakers. Another noted that “I do not have the time to read much so cannot cite” many examples of useful social science scholarship. We were surprised by two other findings from our survey about how policymakers get their information: 1. First, unclassified newspaper articles were as important to policymakers as the classified information generated inside the government. This fact opens up an important avenue for scholarly influence upon policy if scholars can condense and convey their findings via this route. 2. Second, the Internet has not yet become an important source of information for policymakers, despite its ease of accessibility and the generally succinct nature of the presentation of its content. It could be a just a matter of time until a more web-oriented generation reaches the pinnacle of national security decision-making authority, but we also ought to consider whether the Internet suffers from weaknesses vis-a-vis traditional print media that dilute its influence. The plethora of Internet news and opinion outlets, many of questionable reliability, combined with the lack of an authoritative source among them, may mean that the Internet will continue to lag behind the elite print media because it exacerbates the signals to noise problem for policymakers. 3. But our most important findings concern what role policymakers think scholars ought to play in the policy process. Most recommended that scholars serve as “informal advisers” and as “creators of new knowledge.” There were two surprises for us here: First, policymakers ranked the educational and training role of scholars for future policymakers third behind these other two roles. They also confessed that they derived relatively little of their professional skills from their formal educations. The main contribution of scholars, in their view, was research. Second, and again somewhat surprisingly, they expressed a preference for scholars to produce “arguments” (what we would call theories) over the generation of specific “evidence” (what we think of as facts). In other words, despite their jaundiced view of cutting-edge tools and rarefied theory, the thing policymakers most want from scholars are frameworks for making sense of the world they have to operate in. Given these findings, we offer the following recommendations for scholars who aspire to influence policymakers. While scholars may want to participate in policymaking, they should do so not because of the superior contribution they can make to policymaking directly but rather because doing so will enrich their scholarship. Indeed, the most important roles for scholars to play are as both teachers and researchers, but our results suggest that both areas need careful rethinking. On the former, the findings of our survey should lead to some introspection about how we train students for careers in government service. We suspect that the focus on social science techniques and methods that dominates so much graduate, and increasingly undergraduate, training in political science is not useful across the board to policymakers. On the other hand, a purely descriptive, fact-based approach is not what policymakers seem to want from scholars either. Since policymakers think that the most important contributions scholars can make is in the area of research, it is worth thinking further about exactly what that should look like. Three aspects of scholarship appear to be most important: 1. First, policymakers appear to want mid-range theory. Policymakers do not reject methodologically sophisticated scholarship across the board but do seem to find much of it not useful. They prefer that scholars generate simple and straightforward frameworks that help them make sense of a complex world. (For related arguments, see Silver 2012:96–97; Mearsheimer and Walt 2013.) They seem not so much to be looking for direct policy advice as for background knowledge to help them put particular events into a more general context. We interpret policymakers’ preference for theories over facts to the fact that like most busy people, they are cognitive economizers who need ways to make good decisions quickly and under great uncertainty. Along these lines, Henry Kissinger reportedly demanded of his subordinates: “Don’t tell me facts, tell me what they mean.” 2. Second, brevity is key for policymakers. We suspect that the reason that Op/Eds are so influential among policymakers is only partly due to where they are published; another important aspect of their influence is their short length. We are by no means suggesting that scholars only write in that format, but we strongly believe that research findings that cannot be presented in that format are unlikely to shape policy. Therefore, our recommended model is one in which a scholar publishes his or her findings in traditional scholar outlets such as books or journals but also writes shorter and more accessible pieces reporting the same findings and telegraphing their policy implications in policy journals, opinion pieces, or even on blogs. 3. Finally, a related issue is accessibility: Policymakers find much current scholarly work—from across the methodological spectrum—inaccessible. Policymakers don’t want scholars to write in Greek or French, but rather just plain English. The results of this survey are by no means the last word on this large and very complex question of what policymakers want from scholars. At least, five particular puzzles or research challenges remain: a. First, why is it that policymakers are relatively tolerant of complex modeling and statistical work in economics and survey research but not in other areas of political science and international relations? One possibility is the logic of appropriateness argument we suggested above. But another possibility is that policymakers in international and national security affairs operate under a misconception about how influential some of those tools— particularly in economics—really are in policymaking (Krugman 1994: chapter 1). b. Second, why do scholars continue to do business in a way that they know is not useful to policymakers despite their clear desire to influence policy? While the “new scholasticism,” “the cult of the irrelevant,” and the “flight from reality” away from policy relevance among many scholars are well documented, we lack a comprehensive explanation for this phenomenon (Shapiro 2005; Mead 2010:453–464; Menand 2010; Van Evera 2010:4–9). c. Third, more work clearly needs to be done exploring why undergraduate and graduate training seem not to be contributing as much as they could to the preparation of aspiring policymakers. d. Fourth, since it is possible that lower-ranking analysts and policy-support officials may be more amenable to work based upon the most sophisticated social science approaches and tools, it would be worthwhile to survey them as well to get a complete sense of the various indirect routes by which social science can influence policymaking. e. Finally, it could be that the relative unimportance of the Internet to current policymakers is just an artifact of the high average age of our sample and the relative newness of the technology. But there may be elements of the Internet information architecture that make policymakers shy away from it that need to be considered. In sum, we hope that these results will be of use to scholars who are interested in contributing to security policymaking by helping them better understand when and how academic social science is of use to policymakers and suggesting pathways for them to make their work useful to national security policymakers. Bandarage, Asoka. “The‘Norwegian Model: Political Economy of NGO Peacemaking.” Abstract Norway is a leading donor of international development assistance. Since the 1993 Oslo Peace Accords, Norway has also emerged as the pre-eminent global peacemaker.1 The breadth and depth of Norwegian development, humanitarian assis tance, and peacemaking have significant global political economic as well as cultural implications. Almost all the analyses and evaluations of Norwegian international involvement come from internal Norwegian sources or those funded by them. On the other hand, there are critiques which present Norway as an agent of the West "recolonizing" the global south to advance economic liberalization and the dismemberment of states, but these lack sufficient empirical investigation. Independent, field-based research on Norwegian economic assistance and global peacemaking is clearly needed. While this paper is unable to fill that large vacuum in the literature, it seeks to delineate the structure and operation of the idealized "Norwegian Model" of peacemaking and its core feature, the close partnership between the Norwegian state and nongovernmental organizations (NGOs). The paper also presents critiques of Norwegian peacemaking from the global South as well as a discussion of Norway s expanding economic and military interests. The objective is to help broaden the discourse on the '"Norwegian Model" making it more transparent and accountable. Conclusion In a world where poverty, conflict, and violence are rampant, the value of Nor wegian economic and humanitarian assistance must be appreciated, not belittled. And Norwegian intervention in peacemaking should not be dismissed simply as a new form of colonialism. Nevertheless, the potential contradictions of Norwegian international involvement in conflict resolution and neoliberal globalization must be addressed. While some of the charges coming from the global South may be unjust and sensational, there is no doubt that international political and economic inter vention including NGO involvement has the power to do good as well as harm. Norwegian Foreign Minister Store's statement that, "Norway has certain interests, for example in the energy sector, but these must not be mixed up with our political engagement in conflict resolution," needs to be questioned in light of the increasing convergence of global political and economic interests and the cooptation of local movements by externally funded NGOs. Empirical and objective studies on NGOs and Norwegian peacemaking are needed, but they are difficult to undertake given the paucity of funding and other challenges facing scholars and activists with alternative perspectives. Unlike the state and private sectors, there are no international legal and ethical frameworks to hold the expanding "civil society sector" accountable. But, the so-called "non-state" actors and the "third sector" often have close ties to both the state and business sectors. Broadening the discourse on NGOs, peacemaking, and globalization to incorporate these concerns is a necessary step towards sustainable peace and global justice. Bellamy (2011) This article is about Libya and the right to protect Bellamy claims that Libya is the exception rather than the rule in three senses: 1. The threat of mass atrocities. Not since Rwanda has a regime so clearly signalled its intent to commit crimes against humanity. 2. The time frame was extremely short. None of the world’s risk assessment frameworks viewed the country as posing a threat to mass atrocities. Neither was a conflict anticipated. 3. The role played by the regional organizations. Braumoeller, Bear, Is War Disappearing? Abstract There is a large and growing belief, based on a handful of recent scholarly works, that the propensity of states to use force against one another is on the decline. I take issue with two lines of argument that support this conclusion. The first is the claim that, whereas the two World Wars were statistical anomalies, the “Long Peace” that followed is a meaningful trend: I show that both are very plausibly the result of the same stochastic process. The second is the claim that there is less war now than there was in the recent past: I examine what is meant by war, control for two confounding influences that resulted from the proliferation of states in the 20th century, and show that, taking those considerations into account, no such trend is evident. Keywords: war, international security, statistics, APSA Chicago 2013 Meeting Conclusion In this paper, I set out to explore the claim that there has been an overall decline in the propensity of states to use violence against one another in international relations. I’ve argued that per-capita deaths from war is a misleading and irrelevant statistic to use in answering this question, because it has no foundation in a coherent account of how wars actually happen. I argue instead that we should be examining uses of force that have the potential to become wars, because such actions are indicative of a willingness to use considerable violence even if that willingness is not realized. An initial glance at uses of force per year suggested that the propensity to use force is going up rather than down. This trend is plausibly an artifact of the division of the world into a larger number of political units with a larger number of conëict opportunities. At the same time, those units are on average smaller, weaker, and more distant. I therefore examine a new metric—uses of force per relevant dyad— that controls for both trends simultaneously. The results bear little resemblance to a decline in violence over time. A more reasonable characterization might be a semi-random oscillation, with more and less conëictual periods alternating across irregular periods. A pattern of that nature offers little basis to conclude that war is on the decline—or indeed, to conclude much of anything at all about its likely future direction. Busby, Josh (2015). 4 Things the US Can Do to Reinforce China’s Actions on Climate Change. China recently reaffirmed its pledge to peak emissions around 2030 and to increase non-fossil energy to 20% by the same year. China also announced a new target to reduce CO2 emissions per unit of GDP (its carbon intensity) by 60 to 65 percent below 2005 levels. How can the US ensure that China sustains and even accelerates progress in this direction? Our starting premise is that air pollution is a more salient issue in China than climate change and that the country is likely to take more heroic and costly measures to reduce the threat of air pollution for Chinese citizens than they are to contribute to the global public good of climate change mitigation. From this perspective, much of the discussion of using climate change to produce co-benefits for air pollution is misplaced. We need to ensure that air pollution policies create co-benefits for the climate. As we note, some actions, reducing the use of coal, will be beneficial for both air pollution and climate goals. Other policies, such as producing synthetic gas from coal or relocating coal plants to the interior, might produce benefits for air pollution but make the climate problem worse. The US has limited leverage over this domestic dynamic in China, but we identify 4 strategies the US can engage in to make it more likely that China will choose policies that produce cobenefits for climate change. These include: 1. The US keeping its own climate commitments 2. Fostering transparency through research partnerships 3. Pursuing complementary processes to the UNFCCC 4. Considering border tax adjustments. The first point is that (1) China wants to avoid being perceived as a climate scofflaw. China will still have strong domestic incentives – energy security, air pollution, economic rebalancing – to continue its current trajectory of policies that reduce its carbon footprint, but some of these objectives could be achieved by policies that make the climate problem worse. Second point (2) The climate regime has evolved to one what analysts used to call “pledge and review” where countries make pledges of what they are prepared to do and other countries then subject them to international scrutiny. China and the United States, have made their pledges, so-called Intended Nationally Determined Contributions (INDCs). The third point (3) While the US should get as much as it can through the UNFCCC process, there may be other attractive opportunities to make progress on climate change with China. The U.S. has already seized the initiative on this through the potentially historic bilateral agreement that was reached last fall on the cusp of the APEC meeting. Here, we identified two other possible processes that might be worth pursuing. The fourth point (4) We close with a more controversial argument that the U.S. should consider implementing border tax adjustments which would require some national effort to put a price on carbon. Dov H. Levin; When the Great Power Gets a Vote: The Effects of Great Power Electoral Interventions on Election Results (2016) What are the electoral consequences of attempts by great powers to intervene in a partisan manner in another country’s elections? Great powers frequently deploy partisan electoral interventions as a major foreign policy tool. For example, the U.S. and the USSR/Russia have intervened in one of every nine competitive national level executive elections between 1946 and 2000. However, scant scholarly research has been conducted about their effects on the election results in the target. I argue that such interventions usually significantly increase the electoral chances of the aided candidate and that overt interventions are more effective than covert interventions. I then test these hypotheses utilizing a new, original dataset of all U.S. and USSR/Russian partisan electoral interventions between 1946 and 2000. I find strong support for both arguments. Conclusion and discussion Vojislav Kostunica’s campaign team had good reason to see the foreign support as critical to their victory. My findings demonstrate that, overall, partisan electoral interventions seem to substantively benefit the aided candidate or party. Furthermore, overt interventions prove to be significantly more effective than covert interventions in swaying elections. Of course, given the average effect that I find (about a 3 percent change in vote share), electoral interventions will not always assure victory for the great powers’ preferred candidates. However, such interventions often do swing elections. The evidence presented in this article suggests that in the foreseeable future, partisan electoral interventions will continue to be an effective way for great powers to determine the leadership of other states, regardless of whether their targets are governed by “competitive authoritarian,” partially democratic, or fully democratic regimes. These results also provide further—and cross-national— support for the finding of Corstange and Marinov (2012, 664–669) that no popular backlash effect existed in their survey experiment of overt intervention. Future research should focus on other effects of electoral interventions. Partisan electoral interventions affect a key democratic institution—the national level elections and the process by which the executive is peacefully replaced or retained. As a result, such interventions may have major effects on the target. For example, one important direction for future research in this regard would be to investigate whether electoral interventions have ramifications for the level of democracy in the target over the medium and long term. Another important direction for future research would be the possible effect of electoral interventions on the target’s domestic stability. Research on this question could investigate, for example, whether such interventions may inadvertently encourage various kinds of extraparliamentary opposition (such as mass protests, general strikes, riots, and terrorism) by the frustrated losing side. This study shows that even when foreign powers do not use force (whether overtly or covertly) toward a democracy, they can still exert a major influence over the nature of its leadership, and they are frequently willing and able to use this option. Indeed, in a world in which military interventions are increasingly costly and democracies are more common, partisan electoral interventions are likely to become an ever more central tool of the great powers’ foreign policy. For example, had the Arab Spring led to a new, more enduring crop of democratic and democratizing regimes (in addition to Tunisia) in the Middle East, it is quite likely that some of these countries would have become targets of partisan electoral interventions in order to prevent “undesirable” parties or leaders from winning power. Indeed, carrying out electoral interventions for this purpose was an option openly advocated during the initial aftermath of the Arab Spring by some segments of the US foreign policy community.53 Furthermore, given the fact that many of China’s and India’s neighbors and potential peer competitors are full or partial democracies, a future attempt by either power to rise to regional or global prominence may not necessarily lead to warfare as some theorists predict (compare Mearsheimer 2001, 396–402). Instead, either power may choose initially to invest its efforts in replacing foreign leaders strongly hostile to their geopolitical ambitions with “friendlier” ones through a partisan electoral intervention, thus preempting much of the resistance to their rise. Ballots thus may well supplant bullets in the twenty-first century but in a way quite different than usually conceived. Draege, Jonas Bergan. "The formation of Syrian opposition coalitions as two-level games." (2016) This article investigates coalition patterns between two main factions of the Syrian opposition before and after the 2011 uprising. The two factions united over common platforms on several occasions following the 2000 Damascus Spring, but failed to do so in 2011 despite repeated domestic and international pressure. Drawing upon two-level game theory to explain this change, this article argues that increased interest from both domestic and international audiences after 2011 made the two factions less flexible in negotiating a unified platform. Thus, paradoxically, it was increased pressure for unification that deterred the opposition factions from unifying. Dyke, James. Don’t wait for global politics to fix climate change – we can do it ourselves. The Conversation. (2015) Full article: https://theconversation.com/dont-wait-for-global-politics-to-fix-climate-change-wecan-do-it-ourselves-50687 Why has it proved so difficult to agree to limit carbon emissions? One reason stems from the fact the Earth’s atmosphere is a public good, just like street lighting, schools or public parks. A public good is non-rivalrous in that my use of it does not reduce your or anyone else’s access to it. A stable climate is a global public good as it is something all of humanity enjoys. We all, to a greater or lesser extent, affect it too. It makes no difference if carbon dioxide is released in Beijing, Birmingham or Baltimore. If the atmosphere is a global public good then, in the absence of enforcement via international law to limit carbon emissions, you may conclude we are doomed. There is nothing to stop someone from emitting more than their fair share – this is the free rider problem. Can we avoid climate tragedy? In 2009, US political scientist Elinor Ostrom received the Nobel Prize in Economic Sciences for her work on the management of public goods and common-pool resources. What Ostrom established is that, contrary to certain grim predictions, there are numerous examples of effectively managed public goods: Nepalese forests, American lobster fisheries, community irrigation schemes in Spain and many other systems are looked after sustainably through following a combination of eight principles. Climate change is as much a moral issue as a scientific one. Taking more than your fair share is wrong. Changing the climate which leads to people being harmed is wrong. Any effective agreement that emerges from Paris will not have come out of a vacuum, but as a consequence of many individuals’ and communities’ agitation for change – some locally, some through the internet. If we are going to address climate change, then recognising our shared values and interests is crucial. Humans are fundamentally a social species. We’ve only very recently appreciated that we are also a planet-altering species. Our moral senses know intuitively what we need to do in the light of such knowledge. Our economic and political institutions need to catch up rapidly. Floyd, Rita. "Parallels with the hate speech debate: the pros and cons of criminalising harmful securitising requests." Abstract This article argues that public expressions of Islamophobia are best understood as securitising requests (that is, calls on powerful figures/bodies to treat an issue in security mode so that extraordinary measures can be used to combat it), especially in those cases where Muslims are feared and disliked because of the perception that Islamic people are prone to terrorism. This article argues that harmful and derogatory securitising requests targeting racial, ethnic, or religious minorities are on par with hate speech and it highlights the fact that many contemporary societies are now seeking legal protections against such security speech (expressed most notably in the desire to ban Islamophobia). It is from this perspective that this article poses an important research question: With a view to protecting those adversely affected, are legal protections against harmful and offensive securitising requests justified? The research question can be answered by drawing parallels to the existing hate speech debate in legal and political theory. The research reveals that, although the case against legal protections of harmful and defamatory security speech is ultimately more convincing, security speech alone can be so damaging that it should be informed by a number of ethical considerations. This article goes on to suggest three criteria for governing the ethics of requesting securitisation. As such this article fills a lacuna in the ‘positive/negative debate’ on the ethics of security that has engaged with securitisation, but that has failed to consider the ethics of speaking security. Conclusion In contemporary Europe and elsewhere there is a discernible trend towards either tightening existing hate speech legislation or introducing new legislation in order to curtail the defamation of migrants and refugees as security threats and/or terrorists. For the time being, this is most clearly expressed by an increased willingness to ban Islamophobia. In the context of these developments, this article has critically engaged with the justifiability of criminalising requests to securitise that are harmful or derogatory to racial, ethnic, or religious minorities in order to protect those adversely affected. It has done so by drawing parallels to the existing hate speech debate in legal and political theory. As part of the analysis offered, this article developed the novel analytical concept securitising requests, which captures security speech uttered not by securitising actors intent on securitisation, but rather security speech expressed by (ordinary) people intent on persuading powerful actors to securitise. It was argued that even securitising requests that do not use overtly offensive language, but simply single out racial, ethnic, or religious minorities as security threats are tantamount to expressions of hate speech because the link to security due to who these groups are is in and of itself degrading. It was further argued that the recognition of securitising requests as expressions of hate speech reveals the important insight that harmful speech is based not only on hate, but also on fear. Conceived as such – from the point of view of security – the case against protections is more convincing. In part because one positive of liberal democracies is that citizens are allowed to express their security fears, including of government policy. The analysis further revealed that, although criminalising harmful and offensive securitising speech can lead to an increase in security for affected groups and that it can pre-empt violent counter-securitisation, punitive measures are a disproportionate response because even offensive and derogatory security speech causes only indirect harm (that is, they leave members of minorities feel insecure, or they offend members of religious, etc. groups). This is in line with the rationale behind many state’s longstanding hate speech legislation which seeks to prevent primarily the consequences of hate speech (that is, hate crime, terrorism), and which recognises the adverse consequences for democratic process if offensive speech is criminalised. On the basis of these arguments this article concluded that laws banning public expressions of Islamophobia – at least in those cases where Muslims are feared and disliked because of the perception that Islamic people are prone to terrorism, as well as similar securitising requests – are not justified. Far from negating the significance of indirect harm, however, this article went on to suggest that all persons ought to request security ethically. This article then outlined where the focus should be: when to request security and how to do so. In so doing, this article filled a lacuna in the research on ethics and securitisation, which has hitherto failed to engage with the ethics of speaking security. Fravel, M. Taylor. "Shifts in Warfare and Party Unity: Explaining China's Changes in Military Strategy." Abstract Since 1949, China has adopted nine national military strategies, known as “strategic guidelines.” The strategies adopted in 1956, 1980, and 1993 represent major changes in China's military strategy, or efforts by the People's Liberation Army (PLA) to wage war in a new way. Shifts in the conduct of warfare in the international system offer one explanation for why China, a developing country for most of this period, pursued major change in its military strategy. Such shifts in the conduct of warfare should be especially powerful if a gap exists between a state's current strategy and the requirements of future warfare. The PLA has only been able to change strategy, however, when the Chinese Communist Party leadership is united and agrees on basic policies and the structure of authority. When the party is united, it delegates substantial responsibility for military affairs to the PLA leadership, which changes or adjusts military strategy in response to changes in China's security environment. Since 1949, China has adopted nine national military strategies Conclusion Significant shifts in the conduct of warfare in the international system best explain when China has pursued major changes in its military strategy. Yet China has been able to respond to these shifts and change its strategy only when the party is united and delegates substantial responsibility for military affairs to senior PLA officers. China pursued major changes in its military strategy in 1956 in response to lessons it observed from World War II, along with its own experience in Korea, during a period of unprecedented unity. China pursued major change in 1980, as lessons from the 1973 Arab-Israeli War shaped how the PLA assessed the Soviet threat, but it did so only after Deng Xiaoping had consolidated his authority as China's paramount leader in a power struggle with Hua Guofeng after Mao's death. In 1993, China pursued a major change in military strategy in response to the shift in the conduct in warfare highlighted by the Gulf War, but only once divisions among the elite over reform after Tiananmen were removed. In one case, 1964, the top party leader, Mao Zedong, intervened in China's military affairs to push for a new strategy, but the purpose was to justify a dramatic reversal in economic policy and attack political opponents he viewed as revisionist. The conditions under which China has pursued major change in its military strategy may help illuminate when and why future changes are likely to occur. Overall, China will continue to monitor closely other wars that occur in the international system, especially those involving U.S. forces. China will focus on the United States and its allies not just because of the potential for greater competition with the former in the Western Pacific, but also because the United States possesses the most advanced military power in the world, whose operations could signal a shift in the conduct of warfare. At the time same, China's rising power suggests that China may pursue minor changes in its strategy as its interests expand. But for the short to medium term, the main issues over which China would use force remain unresolved sovereignty and territorial disputes within East Asia, such as over Taiwan and the South China Sea. As a result, China's military strategy is likely to emphasize how to prevail in such conflicts, especially over Taiwan. Finally, China's ability to pursue either major or minor changes in strategy will depend on continued unity within the leadership of the CCP over basic policies and the structure of authority. Although periods of disunity within the party may be hard to predict, one important consequence is that they can prevent the adoption of a new military strategy. Gleditsch, Kristian Skrede. "Transnational dimensions of civil war." Journal of Peace Research (2007) KRISTIAN SKREDE GLEDITSCH Department of Government, University of Essex & Centre for the Study of Civil War, PRIO Abstract Existing research has related civil war primarily to country-specific factors or processes that take place within individual states experiencing conflict. Many contemporary civil wars, however, display a transnational character, where actors, resources, and events span national boundaries. This article challenges the ‘closed polity’ approach to the study of civil war, where individual states are treated as independent entities, and posits that transnational factors and linkages between states can exert strong influences on the risk of violent civil conflict. Previous research has shown that conflicts in a state’s regional context can increase the risk of conflict, but the research has not distinguished between different varieties of transnational linkages that may underlie geographic contagion, and it has failed to consider the potential influences of domestic attributes. The article develops and evaluates a series of hypotheses on how transnational factors can influence the risk of conflict and the prospects for maintaining peace in a conditional autologistic model, including country-specific factors often associated with civil wars. The results suggest that transnational linkages between states and regional factors strongly influence the risk of civil conflict. This, in turn, implies that the risk of civil war is not determined just by a country’s internal or domestic characteristics, but differs fundamentally, depending on a country’s linkages to other states. Discussion and Conclusions Most research on civil wars focuses exclusively on attributes of states and treats states as independent of one another. I have shown that some hypothesized transnational linkages appear to make civil wars more likely, and the risk of conflict varies, depending on the interactions and processes that cross national boundaries in ways that cannot be fully accounted for by attributes or processes within individual states. Understanding the dynamics of civil wars and the prospects for their resolution requires that we consider potential contributing factors both within states and in transnational relations and interactions across state boundaries. Civil wars that display clear transnational dimensions, such as the Albanian revolt in Macedonia, may have as much to do with events outside the boundaries of the country in question as the behavior of national governments. If we accept Blainey’s (1988) argument that the reasons why wars start must be related to why wars eventually end, then looking to the role of transnational factors for onset can suggest how international strategies may help contain internal conflicts. The international community can alter the prospects for conflict by regulating access to transnational support, mobilization, and the availability of arms. Just as transnational factors influenced the onset of a minor armed violent conflict in Macedonia, the actions of international third parties also helped prevent the conflict from escalating to a major war. The Organization for Cooperation and Security in Europe (OCSE) and NATO helped Macedonia close the border with Kosovo and supported the government’s relatively measured military response against the Albanian insurgents occupying cities in the border area. The behavior of the international community also helped the Macedonian government resist demands from Slav militants for more forceful actions against Albanians. Another critical international factor was the Albanian government’s refusal to endorse the NLA, despite widespread support for the organization from many ethnic Albanians. As such, international factors appear to have helped promote and sustain the Ohrid peace agreement between the rebels and the government. Numerous extensions can help improve on the present analysis and clarify further the transnational dimensions of civil war. One limitation of the present analysis is the exclusive use of national-level data, and there are clear benefits from trying to disaggregate the study of civil war. Just as wars may not be confined within the boundaries of a state, they rarely engulf the entire territory of a state. Whereas the conflict in Chechnya, for example, displays clear transnational linkages and entails significant risks of contagion for other states in the Caucasus, neighbors of Russia far from the Caucasus, such as Finland and Norway, have few links to actors in the conflict and little exposure to spillovers. Future research can benefit from improved data incorporating geographical information for the incidents in the Uppsala/PRIO conflict data (see Buhaug & Gates, 2002). Just as the dependent variable (conflict) is not well represented by the entire territory of states, there is an increasing recognition that existing research on civil war has tended to use rather crude national-level proxies for features and processes that often vary considerably within states and ignore the actors in civil war. There is an emerging wave of research considering disaggregated conflict data on the subnational level on explanatory factors such as terrain, resources, and population (e.g. Buhaug & Rød, 2006), and future research on the transnational dimensions of conflict can be enhanced by gathering additional data on the transnational linkages of actors that might increase or decrease prospects for peace at the group level. For example, transnational linkages may be particularly relevant in cases where disadvantaged ethnic groups are already mobilized in another country and can count on the support of ruling ethnic kin in other states or mobilize among refugees in neighboring states. However, new theoretical extensions and data-gathering on the specific constellations of transnational ethnic groups and third-party support that can increase the risks of conflict require an initial foundation to build on. This article clearly suggest that transnational factors exert important influences on the risk of civil war onset and provides a stepping stone for future research of this kind. Hansen Lene (2011), The politics of securitization and the Muhammad cartoon crisis: A post-structuralist perspective This article draws attention to and strengthens the post-structuralist elements in the writings of Buzan and Wæver, as this part of the theory has received less attention than those attributable to Schmitt and Austin. Starting from securitization theory as developed by Buzan and Wæver and engaging with later expansions of the theory, I suggest a post-structuralist framework built around three questions: 1. Through which discursive structures are cases and phenomena represented and incorporated into a larger discursive field? 2. What is the epistemic terrain through which phenomena are known? 3. And, what are the substantial modalities that define what kind of an issue a security problem is? Hansen opted for a more genealogical approach, starting with how recent securitization theorists have analysed the impact of post-structuralist philosophy on Buzan and Wæver’s canonical writings. Her critique claimed that while Balzacq and Stritzel set out to rescue securitization theory from its alleged internalist reliance on an idealized notion of language and its ‘vague and undertheorized terminology’ (Stritzel, 2007:358), Buzan and Wæver are less in need of rescue than Balzacq and Stritzel suggest. Both theorists offer, in turn, revisions that break with Buzan and Wæver’s discursive, poststructuralist assumptions.10 Whether one wants to go down the route indicated by Balzacq and Stritzel or to take the more post-structuralist approach that I then laid out in the second part of the article is up to each securitization scholar to decide. The three conceptual elaborations of securitization theory facilitated an analysis of the cartoon crisis that emphasized points that previous studies have either downplayed or overlooked: 1. The implications of the structural incorporation of ‘the crisis’ within the macrosecuritization of ‘the clash of civilizations’ for the subjects that were constituted; 2. The way in which debates over interpretation and epistemic certainty were part of ‘the crisis’ 3. The extent to which the crisis was one over political logics and referent objects. The three conceptual elaborations constitute one possible expansion of more general poststructuralist ideas. I think it thus quite likely that other post-structuralist attempts at deepening securitization might follow, in a similar way to that in which the engagement with Searle and Austin has produced a distinct body of second-generation securitization theories. Höglund, Kristine, and Isak Svensson. "Mediating between tigers and lions: Norwegian peace diplomacy in Sri Lanka's civil war." Contemporary South Asia 17.2 (2009) Abstract Sri Lanka has suffered from one of Asia’s most intractable civil wars, and is remarkably resistant to resolution. The peace process was initiated with a ceasefire between the separatist Liberation Tigers of Tamil Eelam and the Sri Lankan Government in 2002. This article explores the implications of the Norwegian mediation on this process. We argue that Norway’s aspiration to promote an image of being a global peacemaker and the consent from regional and global powers are important in explaining why Norway became involved. Moreover, the Norwegian mediation approach – based on impartiality, owner- ship by the two main parties, and internationalization – has had consequences for how the process has unfolded. For instance, it influenced the potential leverage of Norway and conceptions about bias. This article contributes to an understanding of how regional and global processes, as well as mediator characteristics and approaches, influence the dynamics of civil war termination. Keywords: Sri Lanka; Norway; mediation; civil war; conflict resolution Conclusion The civil war in Sri Lanka has shown itself remarkably resistant to resolution. The return to the battlefield after six years of, first, an actual and, then, a nominal ceasefire between the government and the LTTE marked an endpoint to the peace process. To give a definitive assessment of the success or failure of the Norwegian intervention is much too early at this stage. The ceasefire agreement, by implementing a lull in the fighting, saved a substantial number of lives. Also, during the period it was respected, it significantly and positively affected the living conditions for all civilians on the island. Moreover, the efforts by the Norwegian mediators could very well have laid the ground for future dialogue and solutions. Yet, the thirdparty intervention was also a failure. Our analysis identifies some points that need to be taken into account in the debate on this issue. A number of factors have driven the Norwegian engagement in Sri Lanka. These can be found at three different levels: the readiness of the mediator; the acceptance of the primary parties; and the consent of the regional and global powers. As argued above, the ambition of Norway to function as a peacemaker in the international system was one of the driving forces behind its willingness to act as a mediator in this conflict. The acceptance of the parties has to do with access, international recognition, and impartiality. India’s and the United States’ consent to accept. Norwegian peacemaking is found in an interest to keep other, more influential actors with more direct interests outside Sri Lanka. The Norwegian mediation revealed a weakness of the ownership approach to the process. Even if the approach is appealing in theory, it carries difficulties in practice. It puts the responsibility of the process entirely on the antagonists, who can face problems in seeing beyond escalatory dynamics. At the same time, the primacy of ownership is a reflection of a situation on the ground, where the two major armed parties, the government and the LTTE had the veto-power over the design of the process, which a mediator without authority, such as Norway, has really little influence over. The Norwegian approach to mediation was also built on impartiality. However, it was difficult to uphold the image of impartiality in the asymmetrical setting of the Sri Lankan conflict. The complexity created by the fact that Norway played multiple roles – taking a lead role in the monitoring mission, while at the same time facilitating the peace talks – also factored into the perceptions of bias. We have suggested that the regional and global power-dynamics created the particular context that made Norwegian mediation possible, but also undermined the possibility of success. The international community, by failing to convince the parties with the carrots of aid and financial support, or the sticks involving terrorist listing, was not effective in pushing or pulling the parties towards peace. Yet, it is important that actors like Norway exist in the international context and can function as channels of communication with non-state actors, who continue to be part of the international system. With the international war on terror, there are fewer mediators that are available to play this peacemaking role. At the same time, it is important to bear in mind that the Sri Lankan conflict has shown itself remarkably resistant to conflict resolution efforts, including international mediation. Ultimately, mediation and negotiation proved to be important, but insufficient, instruments for dealing with the state-formation conflict in Sri Lanka. Although they were fruitful in getting the process initiated, mediation and negotiation failed to address the basic underlying question of different forms of nationalism competing for state power. Moreover, the peace mediation in Sri Lanka did not succeed in addressing obstacles for a peaceful solution, and in some aspects added to the intractability of the conflict. In this respect, mediation is a risky endeavor. Howard, Lise Morjé, and Alexandra Stark. "How Civil Wars End: The International System, Norms, and the Role of External Actors." International Security 42.3 (2018) Abstract Historically, civil wars ended in one-sided victory. With the end of the Cold War, however, the very nature of how civil wars end shifted: wars became two times more likely to terminate in negotiated settlement than in victory. Since the terrorist attacks of September 11, 2001, the proportion of victories has increased, especially for civil wars that include a terrorist group; wars are also ending less frequently. Why would civil war termination vary by time period? The literature on civil wars looks to three basic types of causes: domesticstructural factors, bargaining dynamics, and types of international intervention. Current explanations cannot account for why civil wars would end differently in different time periods because, as Kenneth Waltz might say, they are “reductionist” in nature. Material and ideational factors constitute the international political environment, which varies in different time periods. This environment drives outside actors' normative strategies of viewing victory, negotiation, or stabilization as the appropriate solution to civil war. These norms, in turn, directly affect how civil wars end. A novel, three-part methodological approach using quantitative analysis, case studies, and original content analysis demonstrates that civil wars tend to end the way external actors think they ought to end. Conclusion During the Cold War, civil wars most often ended in military victory for one side. After the Cold War, they ended mainly in negotiated settlement. Since the terrorist attacks of September 11, 2001, wars that do not involve terrorists still generally end in negotiation or low activity, whereas those with terrorist groups tend to end in one-sided victory; civil wars are also ending less often in general. Most civil war terminations involve external intervention, but the literature on civil wars has not offered a theory of why international actors would intervene differently in different time periods. For decades after World War II, the United States and its allies sought military victory for one preferred side in civil wars. After the Cold War, however, the material condition of unipolarity enabled the United States to seek to end civil wars as it chose. The United States decided, along with its allies, to end wars not in victory, but rather in negotiation, often using mediation as a tool to achieve settlements. There is nothing from the fact of material unipolarity that would necessitate such a choice, but the democratic character of the unipole compelled a shift toward negotiation. After the Cold War, the overarching international political environment was characterized by the United States' and its allies' quest for democratization. In this new environment, a norm of negotiated settlement arose, which in turn produced the material and social outcomes of negotiated settlements. After the September 11 attacks, the international political environment changed again. The new threat of terrorism, along with the failures of democratization in Iraq, Afghanistan, and elsewhere, spurred disillusionment with the quest for externally assisted democracy. As the 2000s progressed, many countries experienced democratic backsliding, and many democratization movements faltered. In place of the quest for democracy after war, stabilization has become the overarching normative impulse and policy goal. The norm trajectories we trace are different from most theoretical accounts of normative change. Usually, “norm entrepreneurs” set out to change “bads” such as apartheid, slavery, or the use of weapons of mass destruction. Activists convince powerful people and states to change policies. Thus notions of appropriateness create changes in outcomes. This standard causal chain fits to a certain extent with the processes of norm change after the Cold War, except rather than individual norm entrepreneurs, it was the great powers, led by the democratic unipole, that decided to change their methods for ending civil wars. In contrast, the normative shifts in the post–September 11 time period do not stem from the actions of one or a few powerful states, individuals, or social movements. They are more reactive than proactive. From the material facts of terrorist attacks, failures of democratization, and civil wars already ending in low activity, we see normative trends in the United States and the UN Security Council of the acceptance of the appropriateness of non-negotiation with terrorists, and the quest not for democracy but stabilization. Thus our argument is basically structural: actors are bound in large part by the international political environment in which they operate. That does not mean, however, that innovation and agency are impossible. Structures are hard to change, but norms are easier. When it comes to policy recommendations, much of the scholarly literature on war termination advocates a certain type of ending to achieve lasting peace: partition, negotiated settlement, or rebel victory. Our article makes explicit the implicit assumption in these arguments that external actors have the power to influence how civil wars end. External actors, however, are under the influence of the prevailing international political environment. By highlighting the character and pressures of this environment in different time periods, and the role of accompanying conflict resolution norms, it may be easier for actors to come to novel policy decisions that buck the prevailing trend. Sometimes, better outcomes may result when outsiders do not push for a negotiated settlement, but rather allow one side to win. Other times, it may be necessary to negotiate with terrorists in order to conclude a devastating civil war, despite the pressures of the international political environment. Regardless, having a better understanding of how and why civil wars conclude could give policymakers some tools to help end such wars and eliminate their attendant economic and humanitarian costs. Jaffe, Amy Myers. "Green Giant." Foreign Affairs. March/April 2018 (in progress) Kagan, Robert (2012). “Not fade away”. New Republic, January 11 Editor’s Note: In his State of the Union address on January 24, President Barack Obama argued, “Anyone who tells you that America is in decline or that our influence has waned, doesn’t know what they’re talking about.” According to a Foreign Policy report, the president was influenced by the following article, which originally appeared in The New Republic. Robert Kagan’s views on America’s role in the world are expanded upon in a new book, The World America Made. Is the United States in decline, as so many seem to believe these days? Or are Americans in danger of committing pre-emptive superpower suicide out of a misplaced fear of their own declining power? A great deal depends on the answer to these questions. The present world order—characterized by an unprecedented number of democratic nations; a greater global prosperity, even with the current crisis, than the world has ever known; and a long peace among great powers—reflects American principles and preferences, and was built and preserved by American power in all its political, economic, and military dimensions. If American power declines, this world order will decline with it. It will be replaced by some other kind of order, reflecting the desires and the qualities of other world powers. Or perhaps it will simply collapse, as the European world order collapsed in the first half of the twentieth century. The belief, held by many, that even with diminished American power “the underlying foundations of the liberal international order will survive and thrive,” as the political scientist G. John Ikenberry has argued, is a pleasant illusion. American decline, if it is real, will mean a different world for everyone. .... In sum: it may be more than good fortune that has allowed the United States in the past to come through crises and emerge stronger and healthier than other nations while its various competitors have faltered. And it may be more than just wishful thinking to believe that it may do so again. But there is a danger. It is that in the meantime, while the nation continues to struggle, Americans may convince themselves that decline is indeed inevitable, or that the United States can take a time-out from its global responsibilities while it gets its own house in order. To many Americans, accepting decline may provide a welcome escape from the moral and material burdens that have weighed on them since World War II. Many may unconsciously yearn to return to the way things were in 1900, when the United States was rich, powerful, and not responsible for world order. The underlying assumption of such a course is that the present world order will more or less persist without American power, or at least with much less of it; or that others can pick up the slack; or simply that the benefits of the world order are permanent and require no special exertion by anyone. Unfortunately, the present world order—with its widespread freedoms, its general prosperity, and its absence of great power conflict—is as fragile as it is unique. Preserving it has been a struggle in every decade, and will remain a struggle in the decades to come. Preserving the present world order requires constant American leadership and constant American commitment. In the end, the decision is in the hands of Americans. Decline, as Charles Krauthammer has observed, is a choice. It is not an inevitable fate—at least not yet. Empires and great powers rise and fall, and the only question is when. But the when does matter. Whether the United States begins to decline over the next two decades or not for another two centuries will matter a great deal, both to Americans and to the nature of the world they live in. Kaarbo, Juliet. (2015) A Foreign Policy Analysis Perspective on the Domestic Politics Turn in IR Theory Over the last 25 years, there has been a noteworthy turn across major International Relations (IR) theories to include domestic politics and decision-making factors. Neoclassical realism and variants of liberalism and constructivism, for example, have incorporated state motives, perceptions, domestic political institutions, public opinion, and political culture. These theoretical developments, however, have largely ignored decades of research in foreign policy analysis (FPA) examining how domestic political and decision-making factors affect actors’ choices and policies. This continues the historical disconnect between FPA and “mainstream” IR, resulting in contemporary IR theories that are considerably underdeveloped. This article revisits the reasons for this separation and demonstrates the gaps between IR theory and FPA research. I argue that a distinct FPA perspective, one that is psychologically-oriented and agent-based, can serve as a complement, a competitor, and an integrating crucible for the cross-theoretical turn toward domestic politics and decision making in IR theory. An FPA perspective is not superior to other perspectives, and it continues to suffer from weaknesses outlined earlier. FPA, moreover, is also not a single theory of international relations, but this does not make it unique or less developed than other IR “theories” that are today better characterized as schools of thought or branches of theoretical traditions. An FPA perspective is, however, parsimonious in that other factors and contexts can be funneled through the subjective understanding of the decision maker (although most FPA researchers would sacrifice parsimony in favor of accuracy and validity; Peterson 2006). In addition, FPA has a history of investigating—with a track record of theoretical conceptualization, methodological development, and empirical examination—all of these domestic and decisionmaking orientations that currently separate dominant IR theories. Kirshner, Jonathan. "The tragedy of offensive realism: Classical realism and the rise of China." Abstract What is the realist position on how to deal with the rise of China? One prominent realist approach, associated with John Mearsheimer, calls for the US to do whatever it can to slow China’s rise. However, while this is a realist perspective, it is not the realist perspective. In particular, realist approaches that derive from a classical foundation suggest policies fundamentally different from those favored by Mearsheimer. This article argues that realism should return to some of its classical traditions. It reviews why, from a classical realist perspective, the rise of China must be viewed with alarm, but argues that Mearsheimer’s approach — offensive realism — is wrong, and dangerous. Many of these errors are rooted in structuralism; a classical realist approach, which allows for the influence of history and politics, provides greater analytical purchase and wiser policy prescriptions than offensive realism. Keywords classical realism, International Relations, national security, offensive realism, policy relevance, rise of China. Conclusion: The unwritten future The trajectory of state choices — especially of great powers, which have room for maneuver — is uncertain, and contingent. This is true in general, and this is true for contemporary China. Structural realists, of course, cannot distinguish between the Japan of the 1920s and the Japan of the 1930s; for them the former was necessarily pregnant with the latter. Nor can they distinguish between Weimar Germany and Nazi Germany; or mourn the blunders of the Western powers in the 1920s, rooted in a tragically short-sighted and narrow (and un-realistic) conception of the national interest. Classical realists, on the other hand, looking back tend to see the catastrophes of the 1930s not as the inevitable consequences of physical laws, but rooted in the dismal political choices of the 1920s. A classical realist would have preferred to live in a world where Weimar thrived, and was reintegrated into the international economy, and, however a bitter pill this might be to swallow, to re-emerge with some respect of its power and interests. In Kennan’s view (1951: 69, 70), ‘the great misfortune of the west was not Hitler but the weakness of German society which made possible his triumph which takes us back to the question of the attitude of the Western democracies toward the Weimar Republic,’ and the ‘lost opportunities’ of the 1920s. For Morgenthau (1946: 150), ‘The German situation in 1932, for instance, contained essentially three such germinal developments: parliamentary democracy, military dictatorship, and Nazism,’ any one of which could have ‘finally materialize[d].’ Which one? The classical realist cannot be sure. It depended on ‘the contingent elements of the situation,’ and ‘could not be foreseen.’ This remains true today. ‘The first lesson the student of international politics must learn and never forget,’ Morgenthau lectured, ‘is that the complexities of international affairs make simple solutions and trustworthy prophecies impossible.’ This admonition weaves its way as a central theme throughout his writing (Morgenthau, 1960: 20, 21; 1946: 150, also pp. 129, 139, 146–8, 220, 221). This is not to duck the question at hand. Emphasizing contingency does not provide a get-outof-jail-free card — quite the opposite. It requires a political evaluation of a political question, more or less on a case-by-case basis, if informed by a consistent set of assumptions and analytical tools. As Morgenthau (1960: 10, 11) wrote, ‘Realism, then, considers prudence — the weighing of the consequences of alternative political actions — to be the supreme virtue in politics.’ For Kennan (1951: 47, 50), the ‘recognition of power realities’ would encourage ‘the gentle civilizer of national self-interest.’ What, then, are the consequences of alternative political actions for the US with regard to the rise of China? Almost all China hands and Asian security specialists consider its future foreign policy trajectory to be uncertain.14 It may emerge as a responsible great power, or it may blunder into a disastrous bid for hegemony. American foreign policy will be one factor among several that shapes this choice. An ‘offensive realist’ approach, designed to ‘make sure that China does not become a peer competitor’ (Mearsheimer, 2001: 400), is suspect (at best) in its logic, handcuffed by the limits of its structuralism, and, ironically, rooted in utopianism — an attempt to reshape the world as one would like to see it, rather than respecting the realities of power. It is also, from the perspective of the self-interest of the US, almost certainly a self-fulfilling, and self-defeating, prophesy. If it turns out (as is likely) that the US simply does not have the capability to inhibit China’s rise, certainly the prophesy of a powerful and hostile China will be realized by the attempt. If by chance it is ‘successful,’ the effort by the US to slow China’s rise would backfire, for three reasons: 1. it would be very costly 2. it would seriously harm America’s international political position 3. it would make China much more dangerous China holds over two trillion dollars in foreign exchange reserves, most of which are in the form of US dollar assets, in particular US government debt. This can sound ominous, but, in practice, this position gives China much less practical coercive leverage over the US than it might seem. China has found itself (if with mixed emotions after the financial crisis of 2007–8) with considerable vested interests in both the future of the dollar and in the general health of the US economy, its largest export market. China would be a big loser in a confrontation that undermined either the greenback or American consumer demand. But if push came to shove cooler heads would be unlikely to prevail, and a Sino-American macroeconomic tussle that seriously implicated the dollar would leave both countries much worse off.15 But it is not hard to imagine China going ‘financially nuclear’ in response to US policies explicitly designed to take down the People’s Republic. In aggressively confronting China, the US would be inviting the very high costs of an unwanted and major crisis of the dollar, which would seriously harm not just its economy, but America’s global military capacity as well (Kirshner, 2008: 431). The US would not be the only victim of its ‘success’ in damaging China’s economy — the collateral damage would be widespread and considerable, for China has become both a pillar and an engine of global economic growth. It is commonly reported with fanfare that China is the world’s second largest economy, and that it has surpassed Germany to become the world’s largest exporter. Less discussed is China’s increasing importance as an importer of other countries’ products. In 2008 China was the world’s third largest importer, and it is poised to take the number two slot, behind the United States.16 In 2008 China was the biggest export market for — among others — Argentina, Chile, Iran, Kazakhstan, Oman, Yemen, Burma, Taiwan, and South Korea (which exported twice as much to China as it did to the United States). China was the second most important importer of goods from a host of countries including Australia, Japan, and Peru, and was a very important export market for scores of others, including the United States, which exported more to China than it did to any other country except for Canada and Mexico (International Monetary Fund, 2009; World Trade Organization, 2009). China’s value as an export market for the world is only likely to increase in importance in the coming years, both as it recovers earlier than others from the ‘great recession’ and as it resumes high rates of annual economic growth. If, then, the US was somehow able, at great cost and effort, to knock down China’s rate of economic growth, it would also take the wind from the sails of China’s demand for imports, leaving behind an angry mob of exporting countries in distress, who would (correctly) blame the US for their economic (and subsequent political) woes. Finally, successful US policies that wounded the Chinese economy would generate perverse outcomes; the leadership of the Chinese Communist Party, desperate for a new foundation of legitimacy, could easily resort to virulent nationalism; and stripped of the expectation that many of its foreign policy goals will be best achieved implicitly as a natural consequence of its continued ascendance, China might adopt more aggressive, risk-acceptant international strategies, especially it if perceived its relative power to be diminishing. More generally, a highly antagonistic US posture toward China would almost certainly bring about that self-fulfilling prophecy; assuring a wounded, hostile, dangerous adversary. In sum, a full-blown confrontation with China along the lines suggested by offensive realism would be a self-mutilating geopolitical gesture that would damage the US, undermine its international political influence, and result in an angry and unstable China — and that is if it worked. Classical realism, on the other hand, expects a rising China to be more ambitious, assertive, and, often, difficult to deal with. There is cause for concern — even grave concern. But however wary and pessimistic as they approach the table, classical realists nevertheless place their (always) hedged bets on those policies that have the best chance of shaping China’s domestic political debates and international opportunities so as to encourage and accommodate its peaceful rise to great power status. Khong, Yuen Foong. "Primacy or World Order? The United States and China's Rise—A Review Essay." Conclusion Aaron Friedberg and Hugh White write on the assumption that time is running out for both the United States and China. I would argue that time has something to offer both sides. China is currently in no position to replace the United States as the Asian hegemon, which Chinese leaders recognize. Although it is hard to deny that in recent years China has acted more assertively, especially with respect to the territorial disputes in the East and South China Seas, these exertions are not about displacing the United States. If they are, the strategy is remarkably incompetent, because it helped pave the way for the United States’ pivot to Asia. China’s best shot at dislodging the United States is to continue growing at 6 to 8 percent annually for another quarter century. When China’s leaders say that they must continue to focus on internal economic development, and that in turn requires a peaceful and stable Asia, I read that to mean that they are in no hurry to displace the United States. Yan Xuetong seems content with his studied approach to drawing lessons of hegemonic statecraft from ancient Chinese thinkers. Deng Xiaoping’s adage about “hiding your strength and biding your time” remains relevant. Another twenty-ªve years of strong economic growth and China might be in a position to play the role that the United States played after World War II, in Asia and beyond. Chinese strategists adopting what Friedberg calls “the propensity of things” calculations (chap. 5) should worry about others provoking it to act prematurely on issues that, over time, may resolve themselves in China’s favor. Consider Taiwan. With Ma Jing Yeou (instead of Lee Teng Hui or Chen Shui Bian) in charge, China-Taiwan relations are on an even keel. Reuniªcation can wait. As China-Taiwan economic interdependence intensiªes, it is the Taiwanese captains of industry who are likely to push for uniªcation. In March 2013, a Taiwanese tycoon and his associates who favored “Taiwan’s absorption by China” tried but failed to acquire Taiwan’s largest newspaper. Owning the largest newspaper would have given the “pro-China businessman,” who already owns one Taiwanese media company, serious power to shape public opinion. Strong opposition to his owning a second company, however, scuttled the deal. A few decades from now, China’s political-military clout will also be such that Taiwan will have great difªculty resisting reuniªcation, peaceful or otherwise. It is Taiwan that does not have the luxury of biding its time: since the 1990s, Taiwanese leaders have been confronted with the “it’s now or never [to declare formal independence]” syndrome. Presidents Lee and Chen tested the waters of formal independence but were beaten back by Chinese as well as U.S. pressures. Both China and the United States would prefer that Taiwanese leaders put off moves toward formal independence indefinitely. The political military frictions between China and Taiwan in the 1990s (which embroiled the United States) have obfuscated Mao Zedong’s stance on Taiwan, conveyed to Henry Kissinger in 1973: China was in no great hurry to bring Taiwan back to its fold, it could “come after one hundred years.”32 For the United States, shelving the Taiwan issue is not only prudent; time will also be the best test of its conªdence in its ability to outcompete China and to retain its hegemonic position. Although China has the advantages of scale (four times the population) and geography (permanent resident of Asia), the United States has many other advantages, including its absolute wealth, democratic politics, military allies (with more than 700 bases worldwide), soft power, and a culture of innovation. Assumptions of continued Chinese growth are just that. Will China be able to maintain its high growth rates over the next two decades? Although the Chinese economy has deªed predictions about its implosion in the 1990s or being dragged down by the “hard landings” in the 2000s, Chinese policymakers are only too aware of the challenges they face in the future. Time will tell if China will muster the economic base and technological innovations to mount a credible challenge to U.S. hegemony. Perhaps the greatest advantage for the United States is that the current rules of the international economic and political systems are largely stacked in its favor.34 China has done remarkably well under those rules, and although it is safe to assume that China will want to change some of them, it comes to the table as a relatively satisfied power, not a dissatisfied one. Time will also allow the United States to help nudge along or witness China’s possible transformation into a democracy. For Friedberg, promoting “regime change” or nudging China to become a liberal democracy is an important element of U.S. policy (p. 2). Americans and others who put their faith in the sequential development of capitalism and democracy and who were disappointed by the Tiananmen crackdown may have a better chance of seeing their expectations realized with the expansion of the Chinese middle class in the next few decades. A democratic China, going by Friedberg’s analysis, would make it a much more acceptable Asian hegemon to the United States. Finally, if the United States–China contest is a long-haul endeavor (as Yan assumes), where one is thinking in terms of decades instead of years, both sides will have opportunities to experiment with policies capable of blunting the sharp edges of such a contest, even if they are unable to eliminate it. The United States’ pivot to East Asia, for example, has encouraged some in China to call for its own “pivot to the West” (i.e., Central Asia, South Asia, and the Middle East), not only to secure its energy needs, but also to expand its strategic space, such that over time, its economic and strategic well-being will not rely exclusively on developments in East Asia. The prospects for U.S.-China cooperation in these areas are deemed to be better, given their “common interests in economic investment, energy, anti-terrorism, non-proliferation and regional stability.”35 This would ªt with Kissinger’s view that there is room for “coevolution,” whereby “both countries pursue their domestic imperatives cooperating where possible, and adjust their relations to minimize conºict.”36 Competition will not be absent, but will manifest itself more on the economic and political, rather than military, fronts. Kissinger’s emphasis on “domestic imperatives” is pertinent and prescient. It can be read as a lament and warning to his fellow Americans about the dangers to the United States’ international standing of the political inªghting and dysfunction—witness the budget sequestration in the spring of 2013 and the government shutdown of October 2013—that have come to characterize the United States government of late. The world’s greatest democracy is having trouble agreeing on its domestic imperatives. The government shutdown forced President Obama to cancel his trip to Bali, Indonesia, to attend the East Asia Summit at a critical moment of the United States’ “pivot” to Asia. His absence was perceived as a setback for the pivot. It also made it hard for the United States to twist some arms on the TPP or reassure its Asian partners about the TPP’s clauses. The international and regional media were also quick to portray the Chinese as stealing a march on the United States. The implied comparator in Kissinger’s point about domestic imperatives is of course China. The Chinese leadership seems united in pursuing sustained economic development, in part because their political survival and legitimacy depend on it. The global market worries about “hard landings,” but has so far been pleasantly surprised by China’s economic resilience. Asian states interested in growing with China are reassured. Thus the argument about time is not about how it will nudge Chinese and U.S. interests toward convergence; that may or may not happen. It is about which side will be better able to marshal its domestic political, economic, technological, and cultural resources to implement a grand strategy that facilitates its becoming or staying the hegemon, in a manner that makes its leadership congenial to Asia and the rest of the world. Kohli, Atul. (2010). “Chapter 33: Politics and Redistribution in India” India has shifted from a reluctant pro-capitalist state with a socialist ideology to an enthusiastic pro-capitalist state with a neo-liberal ideology. This shift has significant implications for the politics of redistribution in India. The embrace of capital has led to economic growth This growth is leading to widening inequalities along a variety of dimensions: city, versus the countryside; across regions; and along class lines Conclusion While the rhetoric of redistribution and social justice is deeply embedded in Indian politics, concrete redistributive achievements have been limited. Limitations are rooted in nature of the society, but also the pattern of politics. The growing power of big capital define limits on the redistributive possibilities in India. The concluding issue: can democratic forces in India moderate the emerging class and other inequities? Evidence is also mixed. 1. First notice that whereas India’1s main model of development is being driven by a close alliance of state and capital, in order to win elections all national parties need to make promises to the poor. 2. Second, below near geenopmy evident at the national Centre, politics in state after state across India is moving in nearly opposite direction; even in Utta Pradesh, a party of the lowers castes and classes was just installed in power 3. And finally, whereas in the past members of the upper cases and clases readily controlled local governments, by now the process is a lot more compelx, forcing the political and social elites to channel som resources to those below them to secure their political support. The narrow ruling alliance of a technocratic elite and business groups in India wil thus continue to be under democratic and possibly not-so-democratic, pressure from the excluded masses. Kuchins, Andrew C., and Igor A. Zevelev. (2012). "Russian Foreign Policy: Continuity in Change." The imminent return of Vladimir Putin to the presidency of the Russian Federation in 2012 raises many questions about the future of Russian foreign and security policy as well as U.S.— Russia relations. To what extent will Putin seek to continue and implement the goals of current President Dmitri Medvedev’s modernization program? Will Putin reform the political system in the direction of decentralization of power and pluralism? Will the ‘‘reset’’ in U.S.—Russia relations endure? Even with these issues up in the air, the return of Putin as president will not significantly alter the course of Moscow’s foreign policy. Some argue that Putin never relinquished authority over foreign policy in the first place, and that may well be true. But even if it is, there are deeper structural reasons involving debates among Russian elites about foreign policy and Russia’s place in the world that are more important in explaining why Putin’s return will not usher in a significant policy shift. Liberals, Balancers, and Nationalists. The debating parameters over Russia’s national identity and its core foreign policy goals are rooted in five elements of Russian history. 1. An enduring belief exists that Russia is a great power and must be treated as such. 2. That international politics is essentially a Darwinian or Hobbesian competition in which ‘‘realist’’ and ‘‘neo-realist’’ state-centric power politics is the dominant paradigm. 3. That Russia from Peter the Great 300 years ago to Putin and Medvedev today continually faces challenges to ‘‘catch up’’ to the economic, technological, and military achievements of its rivals. 4. That strategies concerning how to catch up are based in, and continue to define, contested aspects of Russian national identity that link domestic economic and political order with foreign policy priorities and orientation. 5. That the central debate today and for at least 200 years revolves around the extent to which Western liberalism is an appropriate model for Russia, and subsequently how closely Moscow should ally with the West, or certain partners in it, to achieve its goals. They go on to list different groups: liberals, balancers and nationalists. The group broadly defined as ‘‘Russian nationalists’’ may be especially adverse to U.S. and Western interests. It includes at least three subgroups, namely neo-imperialists, proponents of a Russian sphere of influence (Russia’s regional domination of the post-Soviet space), and ethnic nationalists. For most of the second half of the 20th century, the United States and the Soviet Union were locked in a competitive struggle for global power and hegemony, and each country viewed its adversary as the principal ‘‘other’’ around which much of its identity and foreign policy revolved. The most influential party that effectively backed neo-imperialism throughout the 1990s was the Communist Party of the Russian Federation. The essence of those in favor of regional domination, the second subgroup, is state-building within the borders of present-day Russia, accompanied by subjugating other successor states and creating a buffer zone of protectorates and dependent countries around Russia. Finally, the essence of an ethno-nationalist program is to unite Russia with the Russian communities in the near abroad and build the Russian state within the areas of settlement of ethnic Russians and other Eastern Slavs. ...the views of the United States held by pro-Western liberals influenced official Russian thinking strongly in 1992—1993. However, the results of the December 1993 parliamentary elections favored those who backed more aggressive and anti-Western policies such as Vladimir Zhirinovsky, whose misnamed Liberal Democratic Party won a plurality. From 1993—2003, Russian foreign policy was dominated by great power balancers who were joined by many liberals disappointed with reform and the West. Beginning in 1996, Evgeniy Primakov started playing the key role in Russian foreign policy and the views of pro-Western liberals, as noted earlier, were gradually marginalized. Great power balancers are well represented politically and have significant government influence. The founding father of the great power school of thought is Evgeniy Primakov, who was an academic, Russia’s prime minister in 1998—1999, and its foreign minister before that starting in 1996. Primakov is considered Russia’s Henry Kissinger, both for being a statesman and for his straightforward realist conception of international affairs. From 1996—2010, the most vocal advocate of the policy of domination was Yuri Luzhkov, the mayor of Moscow. Mid-2000s Russian foreign policy reflected growing confidence about Moscow’s own re-emergence. From 2000—2008, like many other nations in the world, Russia sought means to balance, or more correctly contain, U.S. unipolar hegemony. The global economic crisis has had a far deeper impact on Russian foreign policy than the Georgia War. The most significant factor for Moscow will be the world economy and its effect on oil prices. Laursen, Finn. (2002). Theories of European Intergration. Background Paper, Graduate Institute of European Studies, Tamkang University Introduction Since the start of the integration process in Europe in the early 1950s a number of theories of integration have been applied to study the process. Explanations - and predictions - require concepts to organize our knowledge. Theories provide us with such concepts and notions of their relations. Good theory not only helps us understand the world we live in, but also to have certain ideas about likely futures. The future is obviously uncertain; yet we need to think about it. Scientific inquiry is about developing better and better theories that will improve our explanations and predictions. Thinking about the past and the future is a question of using theories to see the fit between the predictions that follow from the theory and the reality we observe. Beyond trying to explain and predict it can be argued that scientific inquiry cannot escape the question of desirable futures. We can therefore add prescription to explanation and prediction as a part of scientific inquiry. Yet, many political scientists prefer to limit their inquiry to explanation or understanding. Prediction is difficult and prescription requires you to deal with values. Many prefer to leave the latter to politicians. In reality the separation is not so easy. Another way to look at theory is to see it as a kind of language. Political science and other social sciences have developed a number of different languages for discourse on European integration. Many, as the classical neo-functionalist integration theories developed in the 1950s and 1960s, have focussed upon explanation, but the literature on international integration has also dealt with questions about the likely and preferred futures of the process. Most integration theorists have probably seen the process as a desirable thing, whether they explicitly have said so or not. It has usually been seen as a process that would produce peace, security and economic welfare gains. 2 The concept of subsidiarity used recently in connection with the Maastricht Treaty on European Union (EU) is an example of a prescriptive concept which has entered not only the discourse of politicians, but which is clearly in need of clarification. Basically the concept suggests that decisions should be made on the most appropriate level of society. So European problems should be solved at the European level. But, in the end, it is through a political process that European states decide which problems are common European problems. (not a real summary) A number of younger European scholars now started wondering whether the dominant approaches to the study of European integration were too rationalistic, too, and paid too little attention to how interaction affects interests and identity. A special issue of the Journal of European Public Policy explored the issue in 1999 (Christiansen, Jørgensen and Wiener, 1999). Moravcsik was invited 15 to contribute. He asked whether something was rotten in the state of Denmark, referring also to the ‘Copenhagen school’ in security studies: “…the force of continental constructivist theories appears to radiate outward from the Danish capital, where it is the hegemonic discourse” (Moravcsik, 1999: 669). His judgment was harsh: “Hardly a single claim in this volume is formulated or tested in such a way that it could, even in principle, be declared empirically invalid” (ibid.: 670). Most of the contributors to the volume were criticized for not advancing testable theories. Based on his own research Moravcsik claimed that ideas are transmission belts for interests and indeed rather epiphenomenal. The authors did not take alternative theories seriously enough to test them. “Constructivism prevails by default rather than by surmounting the challenge of honest empirical validation” (ibid.: 676). Among those criticizing liberal intergovernmentalism we also find Marlene Wind, who said that … important institutional elements such as the evolution and change of norms, ideas and historically produced codes of conduct – discursive as well as behavioural, are completely expelled from analysis (Wind, 1997: 28). She further criticizes Moravcsik for underestimating the role of the Commission and personalities. “The member states are far from ‘in control’ of the process,” she says (Ibid.: 30). We can only conclude that the theoretical debate about how to explain European integration continues Mazarr, Michael J. "The Rise and Fall of the Failed-State Paradigm: Requiem for a Decade of Distraction." Foreign Affairs 93.1 (2014) (in progress) Mearsheimer, John J., and Stephen M. Walt. "Leaving theory behind: Why simplistic hypothesis testing is bad for International Relations." European Journal of International Relations 19.3 (2013) Abstract Theory creating and hypothesis testing are both critical components of social science, but the former is ultimately more important. Yet, in recent years, International Relations scholars have devoted less effort to creating and refining theories or using theory to guide empirical research. Instead, they increasingly focus on ‘simplistic hypothesis testing,’ which emphasizes discovering well-verified empirical regularities. Privileging simplistic hypothesis testing is a mistake, however, because insufficient attention to theory leads to misspecified empirical models or misleading measures of key concepts. In addition, the poor quality of much of the data in International Relations makes it less likely that these efforts will produce cumulative knowledge. This shift away from theory and toward simplistic hypothesis testing reflects a long-standing desire to professionalize and expand the International Relations field as well as the short-term career incentives of individual scholars. This tendency is also widening the gap between the ivory tower and the real world, making International Relations scholarship less useful to policymakers and concerned citizens. Unfortunately, this trend is likely to continue unless there is a collective decision to alter prevailing academic incentives. Keywords: cumulative knowledge, hypothesis testing, methodology, policy-relevance, professional norms, scientific realism, theory Conclusion The study of IR should be approached with humility. There is no single theory that makes understanding world politics easy, no magic methodological bullet that yields robust results without effort, and no search engine that provides mountains of useful and reliable data on every question that interests us. We therefore favor a diverse intellectual community where different theories and research traditions coexist. Given how little we know, and how little we know about how to learn more, overinvesting in any particular approach seems unwise. As Schrodt (2006: 336) wisely observes, ‘we need all the help we can get to figure out this whacko world.’ What matters most, however, is whether we create more powerful theories to explain key features of IR. Without good theories, we cannot trust our empirical findings, whether quantitative or qualitative in nature. Unless we have theories to make sense of them, we cannot even keep track of all the hypotheses that scholars keep piling up. There are many roads to better theory, but that should be our ultimate destination. Milliken, Jennifer and Keith Krause (2002), “State Failure, State Collapse and State Reconstruction”, Development and Change Practically and conceptually, the `state' is again under siege. Less than two decades after its `rediscovery' by scholars (Evans et al., 1985; Hall, 1986), the central unit of analysis in international relations and comparative politics seems once again in crisis. Some authors, such as Robert Kaplan, present a vision of future chaos resulting from (in a dystopic twist on Marx) the withering away of the central governments of modern states in favour of tribal domains, `city-states, shanty-states, [and] nebulous and anarchic regionalisms' (Kaplan, 1994: 24). Others welcome the weakening of the state in favour of either a more cosmopolitan (global) or more representative (local) vision of politics (Held, 1995, 1997; Rosenau, 1990, 1997). Still others, often accused of being anachronistic (or even reactionary), argue that in the absence of global or regional hegemons, the sovereign state remains the most appropriate solution to the problem of political order (Jackson, 2001; Krasner, 1999). Perhaps it was always so. The modern state, since it emerged out of the ashes of the medieval order, has always been a work in progress. The aspirations of its most ardent defenders for legitimate, representative, redistributive or just governance have shimmered on the horizon distant from the reality of contemporary states, whether in their eighteenth century absolutist, or twentieth century authoritarian, versions. But it is against this backdrop that the current discourse of `failed' or `collapsed' states must be understood. For every claim that a state has collapsed, is failing, or is going to fail, contains two usually implicit definitions or benchmarks. One concerns the `stateness' against which any given state should be measured as having succeeded or failed (the institutional dimension of state collapse), and the other concerns the normative and practical implications of such a failure (the functional dimension of state failure). Concern over the possibility of state failure thus often has as much to do with dashed expectations about the achievement of modern statehood, or the functions that modern states should fulfil, as it does with the empirically-observed decomposition or collapse of the institutions of governance in different parts of the world. The articles collected in this volume all work with such benchmarks and assumptions, seeking to reflect critically and synthetically on state failure and state collapse. The main aims of the volume are: To develop more precise and nuanced concepts of state failure and collapse, as situations distinctive in important ways from state decay, political crisis and civil war; To examine the different and contrasting paths that have led to state collapse, and the inter-relationships between the national and trans- national economic, political and social forces that are making instances of state collapse relatively more frequent in the contemporary era; To analyse the intervention strategies that the international community has adopted to respond to situations of state collapse, including con- sidering how the efforts of external intervenors are constrained and thwarted, and how their activities may have unintended (or dysfunctional) consequences. CONCLUSION The issues that frame this volume are really a large agenda for research, which a collection such as this can only begin to address. Nonetheless, the collection already makes several notable advances. Contributors carefully examine the phenomenon of state collapse, including historicizing this `other face' of state formation and drawing out how and why today's international context is less conducive to the maintenance of states than it was during the Cold War. They also give empirically-grounded insights into recent cases of state collapse, potentially emergent situations of this kind, and the conditions and dynamics that can lead to state collapse as well as to (at least partial) reconstitution. Finally, they analyse contemporary responses to state collapse, questioning the assumptions underlying relief, conflict resolution and reconstruction efforts and, when appropriate, proposing alternative strategies. These efforts serve collectively to extend the study of the issue of state collapse and to open avenues for further debate and research. We consider it important for such debate and research to recognize – as this volume has sought to – that state failure and state collapse must be distinguished from each other, and must not be subsumed under the vague, broad and ambiguous headings of political conflict or civil war. State collapse is different. It poses challenges both to the Whig narrative of a progressive worldwide march to modern (usually liberal) statehood, and to the `anti-statist' vision that regards the erosion of state forms as an opportunity for new forms of political community to emerge at the local or cosmopolitan (global) level. The modern state continues to be a work in progress, and the potential for failure or reversal remains present. Similarly, post-modern political forms of authority and legitimacy may emerge in different parts of the world, but these are just as likely to be dystopic as celebratory, and they still need to answer the fundamental questions of political order that animated the emergence of the modern state in Europe. A close study of the processes that can lead to state collapse, to the dynamic interplay of global and local forces in state collapse, and to the normative and practical underpinnings of the international community's efforts to recreate states after collapse, can shed light on some of these broader reshapings of the global political order in the twenty-first century. Monaco, Lisa. "Preventing the Next Attack." Foreign Affairs. Vol. 96 November/December 2017 (in progress) Pisarska, Katarzyna. "Peace Diplomacy and the Domestic Dimension of Norwegian Foreign Policy: The Insider's Accounts." Scandinavian Political Studies 38.2 (2015) By focusing on the internal conditions and rationale behind the development of Norwegian peace diplomacy (as seen by Norwegian diplomats and nongovernmental organisation representatives), this study argues that the high level of the country’s engagement in international peace efforts and its success in pursuing a ‘niche diplomacy’ can be attributed to two factors. 1. First, it is the ability of the Norwegian government to capitalise on the society’s belief that Norwegians are a ‘Peace Nation’ with a missionary obligation. 2. Second, it is the existence of the so-called ‘Norwegian Model’, which allows creating efficient interactions between government, civil society and research institutions in specific foreign policy efforts. Both factors combined make Norwegian peace diplomacy a model example representing New Public Diplomacy, where domestic civil society remains both an audience (‘Norway as a Peace Nation’ notion) and a driver (Norwegian model of cooperation) of state public diplomacy efforts. Peace diplomacy (PD) Study Conclusions By focusing on the internal conditions and rationale behind the development of Norwegian PD (as seen by Norwegian diplomats and NGO representatives), this article has challenged the common assumption that this public diplomacy initiative is merely a pre-calculated foreign policy effort aimed at reinforcing a positive image of Norway among foreign publics. Instead, the study has shown that the peace engagement is strongly linked to the very identity of the Norwegian nation. The author argues that the efficiency of Norwegian PD can be attributed to: the ability of the government to capitalise on Norwegian society’s belief that the country is a Peace Nation with a missionary obligation; and the existence of the so-called ‘Norwegian Model’, which allows for interaction between government, civil society and research institutions in specific foreign policy efforts. The attractiveness of the Norwegian foreign policy cause for its own society and Norwegian society’s direct engagement in the implementation of the policy assures domestic constituencies support and identify with state actions abroad, thus strengthening the country’s soft power outreach. From a more accidental involvement in conflict mediations, Norway has slowly gained a solid reputation in PD. Such a reputation, based on strong solidarity and egalitarian traditions, cooperative culture, small country size and noble history, has created important political capital for the state’s foreign policy. These findings add to the more general debate on the importance of including a domestic dimension in state public diplomacy efforts (Riordan 2005; Cull 2009; Fitzpatrick 2012; Huijgh 2013). This Norwegian case study provides evidence that domestic publics should be seen not just as an audience for foreign policy messaging and consultation, but more importantly as equal partners in public diplomacy’s formulation and implementation. Putnam, Robert D. “Diplomacy and Domestic Politics: The Logic of Two-Level Games.” International Organization, vol. 42, no. 3, 1988 Quek, Kai, and Alastair Iain Johnston. "Can China Back Down? Crisis De-escalation in the Shadow of Popular Opposition." International Security 42.3 (2018) Abstract Many pundits and analysts, both inside and outside China, claim that public sentiment is an important driver in China’s coercive diplomacy in the East and South China Seas. They argue that China’s leadership faces potential domestic instability arising from ethnic unrest, socioeconomic inequality, environmental degradation, and a slowing economy. The regime therefore has an interest in pursuing tough external policies, as variants of diversionary conoict theory might suggest. Moreover, owing to socialization into the “Century of Humiliation” narrative (namely, that China was bullied by stronger imperialist powers from 1840 to 1949), the Chinese public reacts angrily to any hints of government concessions on territory and sovereignty issues. Public opinion, therefore, can create the worst of all worlds for Chinese leaders’ ability to control the escalation of conoicts. It explains coercive external behavior that could give rise to militarized crises, but it also limits the regime’s options to de-escalate once militarized crises have broken out. Conclusion Our study relates generally to agency and options for governments constrained by public pressures in a crisis. Although the public costs of backing down enhance bargaining leverage, they can also entrap leaders looking for ways to prevent further escalation in a crisis. Our ªndings expand on previous work by specifying a wide range of realistic strategies available to governments—democracies and non-democracies alike—to de-escalate in the face of public pressure to remain tough. Some of these strategies appeal to nonrational thought processes in the public—role identities, for example. Others appeal to apparently rational calculations— economic costs, for instance. In cases where audience costs may exist but appear to be relatively ineffective in constraining leaders, scholars might look to see whether leaders have employed some of these strategies. We also show that the costs imposed on leaders for backing down or blufªng in a crisis are inºuenced by some of the population’s basic beliefs about nationalism and basic preferences regarding military spending. This ªnding suggests that the success of backing down or exercising restraint in a crisis can also rest on the distribution of nativist nationalists and hawks, as well as on the ability of the regime to mobilize nonnativists and doves. Our study also relates speciªcally to the Chinese government’s options and agency. Our research question assumes that leaders, for whatever reason, decide that the military option is too dangerous, or not desirable, or—at the very least—that they want the ºexibility to consider the option of deescalation. Once they make that decision, the issue then becomes how to reduce the domestic costs to the lowest possible level. We have shown that there may be a range of realistic strategies and reasons for backing down that may indeed reduce the costs imposed on Chinese leaders by their public.64 The Chinese public may be susceptible to arguments about the economic costs to using force. The Chinese public, on average, may also be more supportive of restraint if this is seen as normatively consistent with their perceived role identities as a peaceful people. They apparently also see beneªts from third-party mediation by the UN. They may, in particular, also be willing to accept economic sanctions as a substitute for the use of force in a territorial conºict. Different groups in society may be more or less susceptible to different appeals. In principle, this means that the Chinese leadership could combine different, but logically congruent, strategies to maximize its ºexibility. Thus, for example, invoking China’s peaceful identity, the economic costs of military conºict, and a threat of economic sanctions might lead to higher levels of support than invoking any single option. Our ªndings suggest that Chinese leaders have certain diplomatic and practical options for giving themselves more domestic space to pursue concessions in high-stake crises. Our ªndings also suggest, however, that controlling emotional nativist tendencies, and mobilizing more moderate “butter over guns” or dovish constituencies, may be critical if the regime wants to minimize the public costs of making concessions in a crisis. Mobilizing opinions in a wellcalibrated way is obviously not easy to do in an emerging crisis over territorial issues. In the tensions created by nationalist rhetoric and military moves, mobilizing moderate public opinion can be particularly difªcult. The regime would likely have to communicate quietly with the United States that it would use rhetoric and actions that give it more room for self-restraint and concessions—such as some combination of symbolic economic sanctions and requests for UN mediation—in return for the United States minimizing its public threats of intervention. This latter reassurance from the United States appears to be important for Chinese leaders’ agency. As our ªndings suggest, the Chinese public— particularly those segments of the public with nativist and hawkish beliefs —might increase rather than lower the costs for leaders should the latter back down in the face of U.S. military threats, especially highly public ones. This likelihood creates a tension in the arguments some pundits make in Washington for a tougher U.S. deterrence strategy against China in maritime disputes in East Asia. Given our ªndings, one cannot both argue—as some in Washington do—that popular nationalism constrains the Chinese leadership and that certain cost-imposition strategies (e.g., military deterrent threats) will constrain China’s coercive diplomacy. If general deterrence has failed and China and Japan face a crisis over the Diaoyu/Senkaku Islands, imposing costs for immediate deterrence purposes runs into this contradiction. If public opinion does indeed constrain Chinese leaders, then high-proªle immediate deterrent threats are likely to reduce the leadership’s ºexibility and, in turn, reduce the effectiveness of these deterrent threats. Robinson, David A. (2011a). “India’s Rise as a Great Power, Part One: Regional and Global Implications” India’s traditional strategy of non - alignment has shifted towards “poly - alignment” (bridging power between competing poles of US, Russia, China and EU). As a new regional power, India is increasing its naval, air force and missile capabilities. During this period of rapid development, domestic stability is a key challenge for India. The US supports Indian expansion, with the aim of balancing Chinese influence in Asia. In the decades to come, India will continue its rise to great power status aided by the United States, which sees it as helping to keep the global strategic balance in Washington’s favour. Following a strategy of “poly - alignment”, India will subsequently look to project greater power beyond its borders. This will particularly be the case in the Indian Ocean region, viewed by New Delhi as being essential to India’s economic and social stability. … its ascent depends on maintaining relative domestic stability, and carefully crafting its policies toward s the United States and its neighbours , Pakistan and China. All four states are nuclear powers, so the consequences of any conflict between them are potentially dire. Growing wealth + population From independence in 1947 → strategy of non-alignment Prioritising multilateral institutions Civilian nuclear development India’s other major challenge comes from its unstable neighbour Pakistan, with which full-scale war and nuclear exchange have been avoided, despite clashes in the Kargil region of Kashmir in 1999, and attacks on India by Pakistani-backed terrorists in 2001 and 2008. Despite India’s meteoric economic development, it can be said that India has both the best of the First World and the worst of the Third World within its borders, and faces unpre cedented human security challenges. India now has 410 million people living below the United Nations’ poverty line – 37.2 per cent of its population and actually 100 million more people than in 2004. Millions of India’s rural poor are faced with food price inflation of up to 17 per cent. Sixty per cent of Indian labour is still agricultural, and the integration of hundreds of millions of peasants into a modern economy may be an extremely painful process. Conclusion Since independence India has pursued non - alignment or poly - alignment, and has spurned the use of force as a tool of foreign policy. Despite India’s advocacy of a non - polar world, Indian policymakers nonetheless recognise the benefits of American sponsorship. Both nations agree tha t it serves neither US nor Indian interests for a powerful, authoritarian China to dominate the Asian landmass or for radical Islamic forces to wage wars that threaten the security of both states. Thus, as the United States perceives strategic advantage fr om assisting India’s rise to great power status, and India is receiving tangible military and economic benefits from this relationship, for the foreseeable future, India’s continued ascendance will be supported by the global hegemon. Robinson, David A. (2011b). “India’s Rise as a Great Power, Part Two: The Pakistan-China-India Dynamic” Pakistan is unstable and is accused by India of supporting regional terrorism. Nuclear exchange and accidents remain a key threat, with global implications. India perceives China to be strategically encircling it with South Asian allies, including Pakistan. India’s military expansion will not change the fundamental regional power balance. Summary In considering India’s rise as a great power, this paper focuses specifically on India’s relations with its strategically significant neighbours, Pakistan and China. Though India’s increasing projection of influence may change the regional dynamics, the fundamental balance of power among India and its neighbours will not change dramatically in the near future. Pakistan is already overwhelmed by the military strength of India, thus its strategic outlook will remain unchanged, while China and India have increasingly intertwined relations and evenly - matched conventional and nuclear forces, ensuring relative regional stability. Conclusion India’s rise to great power status is inevitable and will occur quickly over the coming decades, especially while the United States believes this will assist it in maintaining a global strategic balance. This will lead to a greater projection of India’s power outside of its borders and especially into the Ind ian Ocean region, which it sees as being essential for its economic and social stability. The two states that India’s ascent will have the greatest strategic impact on will be its neighbours, Pakistan and China. For contrasting reasons, however, this impact may not change the fundamental power balance that exists today. Pakistan is already overwhelmed by the military strength of India, and thus its primary defences are the threat of nuclear exchange or state disintegration – neither of which will definitely be undermined by rising Indian power. In contrast, China and India will have increasingly complex and intertwined relations, but the economic and strategic issues that bind them and the evenly - matched nature of their conventional and nuclear forces are likely to maintain relative peace and strategic stability. India sees itself as an emerging great power in an increasingly multi - power world, and is thus maintaining a strategy of poly - alignment. With the balance of forces developing as they are, that ambition is likely to become a reality. Sandler, Todd. "The analytical study of terrorism: Taking stock." Journal of Peace Research 51.2 (2014) Abstract This article presents an eclectic review of the analytical study of terrorism that views all agents as rational decision-makers. This analytical literature began in earnest with the seminal study of US skyjackings by William Landes in 1978. After 11 September 2001, the analytical literature on terrorism grew rapidly. Based on policy relevance, my survey article identifies five key areas of intense research interests. These include analyses of terrorist attack trends, the economic consequences of terrorism, the study of counterterrorism effectiveness, the causes of terrorism, and the relationship of terrorism and liberal democracies. New developments in the field focused on distinguishing key differences between domestic and transnational terrorism. Additionally, recent game-theoretic advances permitted more active agents and stages to the games. Other major developments involved the study of networked terrorists and the role of counterterrorism foreign aid. Fruitful future directions include using advanced econometric methods to discern the true impact of terrorism on growth, applying spatial econometrics to the study of terrorism, ascertaining the determinants of terrorist groups’ longevity, and learning how to foster international counterterrorism cooperation. Keywords: counterterrorism effectiveness, domestic and transnational terrorism, economic consequences of terrorism, game theory Directions for Future Research and concluding remarks What is the true impact of terrorism on growth? For regional aggregates, the literature’s consensus is that terrorism has a small, but significant, negative impact on per capita GDP growth (see e.g. Blomberg, Hess & Orphanides, 2004). There are, however, grounds for believing that terrorism typically has no effect on economic growth – e.g. most countries experience few attacks with little loss of life or property; much of terrorism’s impact is localized; and transference of economic activities can limit economic consequences. To date, the studies of this growth impact ignores biases – e.g. Nickell bias stemming from lagged per capita income on the right-hand side of the growth equation. Another crucial bias comes from cross-country dependence which causes an endogeneity bias. When accounting for these biases, Gaibulloev, Sandler & Sul (2013) found no influence of terrorism on economic growth for a host of regional samples. More work is needed because losses in economic growth are used to gauge offsetting fiscal and monetary policies. There is also a need for more spatial analysis of terrorist incidents and civil wars. Recently, georeferenced GTD data were used by Findley & Young (2012) to investigate the spatial and temporal relationship between terrorist incidents and civil wars. Spatial analysis can indicate the spread of terrorist campaigns across countries and regions. The analysis can also identify where vulnerabilities are the greatest within countries, and how terrorist attacks respond spatially to counterterrorism measures. There are additional issues concerning counterterrorism spending that require investigation. How much is enough in terms of defensive spending? That is, have past counterterrorism measures been effective and worth the cost? Since its inception, the budget of US DHS has risen by 9% annually (Enders & Sandler, 2012: 328). To address such questions requires an unobservable counterfactual, in which benefits in terms of inhibited attacks are ascertained. The cost side of counterterrorism is readily observable. There is only a single study that attempts to compute a counterfactual for post-9/11 counterterrorism spending (Sandler, Arce & Enders, 2011). Though this study is imperfect, these authors found only about a ten cents return on a dollar from post-9/11 defensive spending. Datasets, such as ITERATE, GTD, and RAND, attribute attacks to terrorist groups for the last 40 years. Even though less than half of the recorded attacks are tied to specific groups, there are now sufficient data to investigate the determinants of terrorist group survival. The pioneering article using survival (hazard) analysis is by Blomberg, Engel & Sawyer (2010), with its focus on ‘one hit wonders’ or groups that struck just once. Their study investigated how economic, political, and geographical considerations in the venue country influenced terrorist group longevity. A follow-up study by Blomberg, Gaibulloev & Sandler (2011) included terrorist groups’ ideologies and tactics (e.g. attack diversity and share of transnational attacks). This second study relied on economic, political, and geographical variables but in the terrorist group’s base country. Future analyses need to go a step further to condition the groups’ failure to a cause – i.e. loss of a leader, dissent within the group, accomplishment of its political goal, or defeat by the authorities. Data in a study by Jones & Libicki (2008) can be used to explain specific causes of group failure (Carter, 2012). Suicide terrorism requires further analysis. Benmelech, Berrebi & Klor (2012) established that poor economic conditions may result in terrorist groups recruiting more capable and better educated suicide bombers to attack Israeli targets. As a result, the ‘quality’ of attacks increased in terms of carnage because more qualified suicide bombers can wreak more casualties. This important work should be extended to a global sample. Yet another issue for future research is the study of the factors that promote international cooperation in the fight against international terrorism. For example, INTERPOL can coordinate arrest efforts among countries. The aftermath of 9/11 showed that, under dire threat, nations can cooperate against a common terrorist enemy. For counterterrorism, the role of partial cooperation needs to be investigated. A final direction for future research involves the development of efforts to counter the growing threat of cyber-terrorism in an increasingly electronicdependent world. This article demonstrates that the analytical study of terrorism is a very active research area that has much policy relevance. Event datasets facilitated empirical tests of theoretical propositions, but underscored a real deficiency – i.e. the need for data on governments’ counterterrorism actions. There are a few country-specific coun-terterrorism datasets (see e.g. Dugan & Chenoweth, 2012), but no global counterterrorism dataset. This article also highlights select areas of major new developments, as well as future directions for research. Schweller, Randall L., and Xiaoyu Pu. "After unipolarity: China's visions of international order in an era of US decline." Article overview 1. Why emerging powers will initially attempt to undermine the legitimacy of the hegemon— through cost-imposing measures short of hard balancing—to pave the way for global contestation. 2. Various forms of resistance to hegemonic domination: 3. The discourse and practices of resistance and the strategies of everyday and rightful resistance. 4. China as the most viable contender for a hegemonic challenge, exploring its ambitions and blueprints for a new world order. After the cold war realism was pronounced dead, and the future of international politics became legalized, cosmopolitanized, and network globalized. Since the terrorist attacks of September 11, 2001, the world does not appear so easily transformed, or history so easily escaped. Even unipolarity, which seemed strangely durable only a few years ago, appears today as a “passing moment”—one that most realists predicted. US remains a superpower, but no longer hyperpower. An emergence of multipolarity. order). These issues largely depend on what roles the emerging powers, especially China, decide to play. They may choose to be: (1) supporters, who assume their fair share of the responsibilities associated with co-managing an evolving but essentially unchanged global order, (2) spoilers, who seek to destroy the existing order and replace it with something entirely different, or (3) shirkers, who want the privileges of power but are unwilling to pay for them by contributing to global governance. Global governance or world governance is a movement towards political cooperation among transnational actors, aimed at negotiating responses to problems that affect more than one state or region. (sounds a lot like world domination or control, lol!) Dramatic structural change rarely happens smoothly or peacefully. The fundamental issue at stake in hegemonic wars is the maintenance or acquisition of prestige, deaned as the reputation for power that serves as the everyday currency of international politics. Robert Gilpin’s theory of hegemonic war and international change is the law of uneven rates of growth among states, which redistributes power in the international system. Economic and military growth (trigger) -> security dilemmas This delegitimation phase, which appears years before the critical inflection point of a power transition, creates the conditions for the emergence of a revisionist counterhegemonic coalition. This phase occurs within the larger cyclical pattern of (1) a stable order, (2) the deconcentration and delegitimation of the hegemon’s power, (3) arms buildups and the formation of alliances, (4) a resolution of the international crisis, often through hegemonic war, and (5) system renewal. The nuclear age makes power transition by means of a deliberately waged hegemonic war unthinkable. This has according to authors permanently broken the hegemonic war cycle. - They argue that the current international system is entering a deconcentration/delegitimation phase. Delegitimation involves two components: 1. a delegitimating rhetoric (the discourse of resistance) and 2. cost-imposing strategies that fall short of full-fledged balancing behavior (the practice of resistance). Sørli, Mirjam E., Nils Petter Gleditsch, and Håvard Strand. "Why is there so much conflict in the Middle East?." Journal of Conflict Resolution 49.1 (2005) Abstract The Middle East is one of the most conflict-proneregions—but why? The Collier-Hoeffler model of civil war provides the starting point for our analysis. In an application to Africa, Collier and Hoeffler found poverty to be the most significant predictor of conflict. For conflict in the Middle East, a more complex picture emerges. Consistent with Collier and Hoeffler, the authors find that economic development and economic growth, in addition to longer periods of peace, generally decrease the likelihood of conflict. They also find that ethnic dominance is significant, while social fractionalization is not. Contrary to Collier and Hoeffler, they find that regime type matters. Variables for the Middle East region, Islamic countries, and oil dependence are not significant. Conflict in the Middle East is quite well explained by a general theory of civil war, and there is no need to invoke a pattern of “Middle Eastern exceptionalism.” Keywords: Middle East; conflict; Collier-Hoeffler model; civil war. This study has found no support for Middle Eastern exceptionalism regarding the causes of conflict. There is nothing mysterious or particular about conflict in the Middle East or in Muslim countries. Conflict is quite well explained by a general model of civil war, although the model underpredicts the probability of conflict in the Middle East. Collier and Hoeffler (2002) conclude that Africa would have seen less conflict if the region had achieved economic development at the world level. The Middle East has enjoyed much greater prosperity than Africa but would undoubtedly benefit from improved economic development. Nevertheless, deciphering the Middle East’s correlates of conflict is a more complex task. In the Middle East and North Africa, abundant access to oil has created a peculiar regional system as well as ties to the international markets and political actors. The failure to modernize and democratize has not led to major internal rebellions in the Middle East. So far, oil money has bought some of the countries enough carrots and sticks to keep their populations quiet. But what will happen when the oil wells run dry? Deteriorating economic conditions and the lack of democracy in the Middle East may well create a fertile base for grievance-based rebellions. Loot-seeking behavior aimed at controlling oil revenue does not characterize civil war in the Middle East, and Collier and Hoeffler’s looting argument appears to be less applicable than in Africa. The concept of the rentier state provides a more fruitful explanation for the current and upcoming economic and political challenges faced by oil producers in the Middle East. These economic and political challenges fit better into the traditional grievance-based perspective on civil war. Lack of economic and political opportunities provides a fruitful base for frustration and opposition. Unless the regimes become increasingly repressive, the future is likely to hold growing political unrest and even civil war in the Gulf area. Sick and Potter (1997, 12) suggest that the Gulf countries are experiencing “a crisis in slow motion.” The economic and political effects of oil—corruption, slow growth, and authoritarianism—create a basis for grievancebased conflict. The growth of political Islam is, to a large extent, a result of these forces. The regime change strategy in Iraq is not likely to dramatically change the Middle East’s status quo in which the region’s authoritarian regimes have remained in power to a large extent due to external (particularly U.S.) support. These regimes have little legitimacy and put the West in an awkward light in many Arab eyes. Although the authoritarian regimes so far have been successful in quelling serious political and domestic armed conflict, they have not successfully constructed solid economic and social platforms for the future. The incumbent regimes face serious challenges to provide food and jobs to their populations (UNDP 2002). Ensuring diversified economic development remains the key to preventing future conflicts. Improved management of resources, natural as well as human, and the development of more transparent and legitimate, if not democratic, regimes provide the most efficient means toward preventing new conflicts—in the Middle East as in other developing regions. Tannenwald, Nina. "The nuclear taboo: The United States and the normative basis of nuclear non-use." Deterrence theory and MAD cannot fully explain the non-use: 1. Cases with no fear of retaliation, and still nuclear weapons were not used • First ten years of nuclear era, the US in Vietnam and 1991 Persian Gulf war, the UK in the Falkland war, Soviet in Afghanistan. 2. Cases when non-nuclear states attacked nuclear states without fear of nuclear retaliation China attacked the US in Korean War, North Vietnam attacked the US in Vietnam War, Argentina attacked Britain in Falkland War, Iraq attacked U.S. forces and Israel in 1991 Gulf War. 3. Non-nuclear states do not seem very scared of nuclear states There is a norm in the global system against the use of nuclear weapons – the use of nuclear weapons is stigmatized. Non-nuclear powers feel safer because they know their enemies are hesitant of using nuclear powers. Valbjørn, Morten. “International Relations Theory and the New Middle East: Three Levels of a Debate.” The Arab uprisings have not only impacted the Arab world but also scholarship about Arab politics. Valbjørn identifies three clusters of debate: The first cluster, which operates at a more empirical level, concerns the question of how Middle East international relations have been affected by the Arab uprisings and relates to the debate about the “newness” of the “new Middle East.” Halliday once remarked—in the context of September 11, 2001—that, “there are two predictable, and nearly always mistaken, responses to any great international upheaval: one is to say that everything has changed; the other is to say that nothing has changed,” The second cluster, which operates at a first-order theoretical level, is about how insights on and studies of the “new Middle East” can contribute to the academic field of IR and enrich our general understanding of the international relations. This kind of engagement can take a number of forms. One variant will be to use the Middle East as a “most/least likely” case to test allegedly universal IR theories. As Halliday once noted, one should ask of any theory what it can contribute to the study of Middle East international relations, and if it cannot help to explain this region then it cannot fly as an IR theory of general scope. Lastly, a third and final cluster concerns a range of questions of a more meta-theoretical second-order nature. The first of these questions takes its point of departure in the classic universalism/particularism debate. As Halliday explained, this relates to a “very fundamental issue much debated in contemporary social thought on whether it is possible, or desirable, to analyze and evaluate different parts of the world on the basis of similar criteria, or whether we should accept that they are marked by different and distinct dynamics precluding any universalist ‘narratives,’ maybe necessitating a spatial and temporal differentiation of a plurality of concepts and logics. Walt, Stephen M. (1998). “International Relations: One World, Many Theories,” Foreign Policy (110) Abstract Is NATO expansion an effort to extend Western influence at Russia's expense or to support nascent democracies? The answer depends on whether you are a "realist" or "liberal" thinker. Find out where you fall on the theoretical spectrum and how ideas can become self-fulfilling realities. Conclusion // Tomorrow’s conceptual toolbox While these debates reflect the diversity of contemporary scholarship on international affairs, there are also obvious signs of convergence. Most realists recognize that nationalism, militarism, ethnicity, and other domestic factors are important; liberals acknowledge that power is central to international behavior; and some constructivists admit that ideas will have greater impact when backed by powerful states and reinforced by enduring material forces. The boundaries of each paradigm are somewhat perme- able, and there is ample opportunity for intellectual arbitrage. Which of these broad perspectives sheds the most light on contemporary international affairs, and which should policymakers keep most firmly in mind when charting our course into the next century? Although many academics (and more than a few policymakers) are loathe to admit it, realism remains the most compelling general framework for understanding international relations. States continue to pay close attention to the balance of power and to worry about the possibility of major conflict. Among other things, this enduring preoccupation with power and security explains why many Asians and Europeans are now eager to preserve-and possibly expand-the U.S. military presence in their regions. As Czech president Vaiclav Havel has warned, if NATO fails to expand, "we might be heading for a new glob- al catastrophe ... [which] could cost us all much more than the two world wars." These are not the words of a man who believes that great power rivalry has been banished forever. As for the United States, the past decade has shown how much it likes being "number one" and how determined it is to remain in a predominant position. The United States has taken advantage of its current superiori- ty to impose its preferences wherever possible, even at the risk of irritating many of its long-standing allies. It has forced a series of one-sided arms control agreements on Russia, dominated the problematic peace effort in Bosnia, taken steps to expand NATO into Russia's backyard, and become increasingly concerned about the rising power of China. It has called repeatedly for greater reliance on multilateralism and a larger role for international institutions, but has treated agencies such as the United Nations and the World Trade Organization with disdain whenever their actions did not conform to U.S. interests. It refused to join the rest of the world in outlawing the production of landmines and was politely uncooperative at the Kyoto environmental summit. Although U.S. leaders are adept at cloaking their actions in the lofty rhetoric of "world order," naked self-interest lies behind most of them. Thus, the end of the Cold War did not bring the end of power politics, and realism is likely to remain the sin- gle most useful instrument in our intellectual toolbox. Yet realism does not explain everything, and a wise leader would also keep insights from the rival paradigms in mind. Liberal theories identify the instruments that states can use to achieve shared inter- ests, highlight the powerful economic forces with which states and societies must now contend, and help us understand why states may differ in their basic preferences. Paradoxically, because U.S. protec- tion reduces the danger of regional rivalries and reinforces the "liber- al peace" that emerged after 1945, these factors may become relatively more important, as long as the United States continues to provide security and stability in many parts of the world. Meanwhile, constructivist theories are best suited to the analysis of how identities and interests can change over time, thereby producing subtle shifts in the behavior of states and occasionally triggering far- reaching but unexpected shifts in international affairs. It matters if political identity in Europe continues to shift from the nation-state to more local regions or to a broader sense of European identity, just as it matters if nationalism is gradually supplanted by the sort of "civilizational" affinities emphasized by Huntington. Realism has little to say about these prospects, and policymakers could be blind-sided by change if they ignore these possibilities entirely. In short, each of these competing perspectives captures important aspects of world politics. Our understanding would be impoverished were our thinking confined to only one of them. The "compleat diplomat" of the future should remain cognizant of realism's emphasis on the inescapable role of power, keep liberalism's awareness of domestic forces in mind, and occasionally reflect on constructivism's vision of change. Walt, Stephen M. "ISIS as Revolutionary State." Foreign Affairs. Vol 94 (2015): 42 (in progress) Walter Barbara F. The Extremist’s Advantage in Civil Wars. International Security, Vol. 42, No. 2 (Fall 2017) Abstract / Introduction One of the puzzles of the current wave of civil wars is that rebel groups espousing extremist ideologies—especially Salaª jihadism—have thrived in ways that moderate rebels have not.1 Groups such as Jabhat al-Nusra and the Islamic State (also known by the acronym ISIS) have attracted more recruits, foreign soldiers, and ªnancing than corresponding moderate groups such as the Free Syrian Army, Ahlu Sunna Waljamaa, or Jaysh Rijaal al-Tariqa al-Naqshbandia (JRTN).2 The proliferation and success of extremist groups is particularly surprising given that their goals are far more radical than those of the populations they seek to represent.3 Salaª jihadists aim to establish a transnational caliphate using military force, an objective the vast majority of Muslims do not support.4 Why have so many extremist groups emerged in countries experiencing civil wars since 2003, and why have they thrived in ways that moderate groups have not? Conclusion This article helps to explain one of the major international phenomena of our time: the rise of Sala jihadist groups in civil wars in the Muslim world. It began with the observation that the number of Salaª jihadist groups ªghting in civil wars has grown and, in many cases, these groups have outperformed and outlasted more moderate groups. By 2016, Sala jihadist groups accounted for most of the militant groups in Syria, half of all such groups in Somalia, and a third of all militant groups in Iraq. Currently, the scholarly literature has no theory for why rebel groups would embrace an extreme ideology or why more extreme groups would perform better than more moderate groups in war. The academic literature has tended to ignore the role of ideology in civil war.99 Instead, scholars have assumed that the core features of rebel groups— their identity, goals, and beliefs—were exogenous to the war in which they were ªghting and not part of an ongoing strategy of the war itself. This article has attempted to ªll this gap. It has argued that the choice of ideology, especially the level of extremism, is likely to be endogenous to speciªc features of a civil war: the level of competition, a group’s local support network, and the institutional constraints on state power. When competition is high, information poor, and institutional constraints weak, an extremist ideology could help rebel groups mitigate difªcult collective-action, principalagent, and commitment problems. An extremist ideology, therefore, can give rebel entrepreneurs an organizational advantage under certain conditions. All three of these conditions were present in the post-2003 civil wars in Muslim countries, and all help explain the emergence and growth of Salaª jihadist groups. This theory challenges a number of assumptions about extremist ideology and its adherents. The popular press is ªlled with stories about the increasing radicalization of Muslims around the world. The assumption is that Salaª jihadism has grown in popular support and strength because the number of true believers has grown. This article offers a different interpretation of the rise of these groups. Muslims need not believe in an extreme version of Islam to sympathize and support groups that embrace such a vision. They need only operate in a world where political power is heavily contested and the quality and commitment of competing rebel groups is uncertain. An extremist ideology will always attract citizens who believe in the ideology, but during times of uncertainty and insecurity it will attract more moderate citizens as well. Finally, the popular press often portrays individuals who join or collaborate with extremist groups as either true believers or hapless victims. The formation of so many Salaª jihadist groups and the ability of groups such as Jabhat al-Nusra, ISIS, and al-Qaida to capture and administer territory suggests a deeper level of local support than many Westerners have been willing to acknowledge. This article reveals the very practical incentives that moderate citizens might have to support such groups in environments of uncertainty, competition, and state abuse of power. The seeming popularity of Salaª jihadist groups, therefore, may have less to do with the ideas Salaª jihadism promotes than with the security and assurances it offers. The framework reveals the role that an extreme ideology can play in organizing a rebel group and ªghting a war. It suggests that many rebel leaders may have embraced Salaª jihadism because this particular ideology allowed them to use cheap inducements and punishments to attract supporters. The extreme nature of the ideology helped them recruit a core group of particularly tough ªghters— zealots—who elevated the quality of the ªghting force and helped enlist additional soldiers attracted to the success of the group. Salaª jihadism then allowed rebel elites to reassure Muslims that they would remain true to the rule of Islam and avoid aligning with the West, making them additionally attractive to a more mainstream audience. Al-Baghdadi and alZarqawi effectively used these advantages to outcompete other Sunni groups. This article is the ªrst step in understanding the role that ideology, especially extremist ideology, plays in civil war. It reveals the incentives that individuals may have to promote an extreme ideology even if they do not believe in its ideals. Much more work needs to be done. On the theoretical side, signiªcantly more analysis is needed on the societal bases of ideology and on the initial choice of ideology by rebel entrepreneurs. Why do certain ideas resonate more with some societies than others? Additional theorizing is also needed on the strategic choices made by individual citizens and the conditions under which their support for one ideology over another may change and evolve over time. On the empirical side, this framework lends itself to rigorous testing. The theory proposes a number of conditions purported to encourage the emergence of extremist rebel groups. These include periods of heavy political competition, low information, and weak political institutions. It also identiªes additional factors that could cause elites and citizens to embrace an extreme ideology, including rapid social change, lengthy civil wars, and powerful Salaª jihadist networks. At the macro level, data could be collected on each of these variables to determine whether extremist groups are more likely to emerge under any of these conditions. At the meso level, data could be collected to determine whether the ideology of rebel groups ªghting in a civil war changes as conditions on the ground change. Do rebel groups shift to more extreme ideologies if the number of rebel groups increases over time, or if ªnancing from radical organizations suddenly becomes available? Finally, at the micro level, data could be collected to determine whether moderate citizens are strategic, shifting their support to more radical groups based on certain predicted conditions on the ground. Do moderate individuals behave as the theory predicts or are they more heavily inºuenced by other factors? It is my hope that this article triggers a larger research program on ideology and civil war that addresses many of these theoretical and empirical issues. The theory, if correct, could have three potentially important implications for policymakers seeking to counter the rise of radical Islamist groups around the world. The most important concerns the sources of support for extremist groups, especially from local populations. The type of counterstrategy the United States pursues will depend heavily on whether U.S. leaders assume that Muslim citizens support Salaª jihadist groups because they truly believe in a seemingly “medieval” and fringe interpretation of Islam, or because they believe these groups are more likely to deliver justice and reform in countries where both characteristics are missing. This article reveals the incentives that moderate citizens may have to support extreme groups and the conditions under which these incentives are likely to be strong and weak. It also reveals the parts of an extremist strategy that are designed to appeal to more moderate citizens. Dissuading true believers from joining these movements will be a huge challenge, but convincing more moderates to defect might not. This article suggests three ways in which moderate support for these movements might be undercut. The ªrst involves the competitive nature of these wars and the collectiveaction problems this creates for rebels. Wars with multiple competing rebel factions create incentives for rebel entrepreneurs to go to the ideological extreme, but this competition also creates opportunities for outsiders to bolster less extreme groups. This can be done by helping moderate groups build high-quality ªghting units that would then attract the support of a larger percentage of moderate citizens. The second has to do with agency problems. Outsiders can also help to reveal the fraudulent nature of extremist elites and their claims. Religious authorities of a more moderate persuasion (often tribal leaders), for example, can use the politics of religious legitimacy as a check against radical leaders who attempt to use their religiosity as a costly signal of principle and devotion. Finally, outsiders can address the commitment problems that encourage extremism by helping to reform state institutions and refusing to support and sustain corrupt regimes. Scholars can no longer close their eyes to the role of ideology in civil war. The rise of Salaª jihadist groups, with their global aims and their condemnation of the United States and its allies, has become one of the biggest security threats in the world today. To date, the United States has not been particularly effective at reducing their number. Indeed, these groups are growing over time. This growth suggests an underlying level of support from Muslim communities around the world that we do not yet understand. Only by analyzing the ways in which an extreme ideology may beneªt both elites and more moderate citizens in civil war can we begin to understand how it might be strategically used, and the conditions under which it is likely to attract support. This article is a first step in that direction. Wohlforth, W., De Carvalho, B., Leira, H., & Neumann, I. (2018). Moral authority and status in International Relations: Good states and the social dimension of status seeking. (in progress)