Faculty Bios Global Executive MBA in Shanghai Dr. Tyrone W. Callahan - Associate Professor of Clinical Finance and Business Economics Finance and Business Economics Tyrone Callahan received his PhD in Finance in 1999 from the University of California, Los Angeles Tyrone has published papers in journals that include The Review of Futures Markets and the Journal of Physical Chemistry. He is an ad-hoc referee at the Journal of Finance, the Journal of Financial Markets, and the International Review of Finance. Tyrone has consulted for Hotchkis and Wiley. Contact Information Phone: (213) 740-6498 Fax: (213) 740-6650 Email: tyrone.callahan@marshall.usc.edu 1 Global Executive MBA in Shanghai Dr. Joseph C. Nunes -- Associate Professor of Marketing Joseph C. Nunes received his Ph.D. in Marketing and Behavioral Decision Research in 1998 from the University of Chicago. He is widely known for his research on loyalty programs, status and luxury goods, pricing and consumer and managerial decision-making. Prof. Nunes has published numerous papers in the top marketing journals which include the Journal of Marketing Research, the Journal of Consumer Research, Marketing Science and the Journal of Marketing. He has alos published in HBR and other publications targeted to practitioners. He currently serves on the Editorial Boards of the Journal of Marketing and Marketing Science. He was the recipient of the Marshall School of Business Dean's Award for Excellence in Research in 2006. Prof. Nunes has consulted for a variety of companies including Southwest Airlines, Kampgrounds of America, Nestlè, Abbott Laboratories, BBDO Advertising, Tribune/Knight Ridder Services Contact Information Phone: (213) 740-5044 Fax: (213) 740-7828 Email: jnunes@marshall.usc.edu 2 Overall Schedule Global Executive MBA in Shanghai GEMBA VIII Theme 3A – Sept.29- Oct. 3 2011, Shanghai JN – Professor Joseph Nunes TC – Professor Ty Callehan Time Thursday September 29 Breakfast Friday September 30 Breakfast Saturday October 1 Breakfast Sunday October 2 Breakfast Monday October 3 Breakfast 8:30-9:45 Mktg 1 JN Mktg 4 JN FIN5 TC FIN 8 TC Mktg 11 JN 9:45-10:00 Break Break Break Break Break 10:00-11:15 Mktg 2 JN Mktg 5 JN FIN 6 TC FIN 9 TC Joint Class TC and JN 11:15-11:30 11:30-12:45 Break Mktg 3 JN Break Mktg 6 JN Break FIN 7 TC Break Mktg 9 JN Break FIN 10 TC 12:45-1:45 Lunch Lunch Lunch Lunch Lunch 1:45-3:00 FIN 1 TC Break FIN 2 TC FIN 3 TC Break FIN4 TC Mktg 7 JN Break Mktg 8 JN Mktg 10 JN Break G7& G8 Joint Session FIN 11 TC Break Summary and Evaluations TC and JN 7:00-8:30 3:00-3:15 3:15-4:30 4:30-4:45 4:45-6:00 In-Class PUB Session Grid for Theme 3A, 29 Sept – 3 Oct 3 Global Executive MBA in Shanghai GEMBA VIII – Theme 3A General Manager as Integrator 29 Sept – 3 Oct 2011, Shanghai Jiao Tong University, Shanghai Professors Ty Callahan (Finance and Business Economics) and Joe Nunes (Marketing) All assigned readings and cases for all the week's sessions need to be read and studied before the first session at SJTU. Focus on reading and being prepared to discuss the cases! Thursday, 29 September 08:30 Marketing Session 1 – Professor Nunes Topic: Course Introduction & Review You should have downloaded and installed the Markstrat Online software before class. This session will include time to ensure software is up and running on all laptops as well as time to form teams for the simulation. Required Reading: Johnson, Richard R. and Ron Mentus: “Marketing Economics”, Darden UV0404 09:45 Break 10:00 Marketing Session 2 – Professor Nunes Topic: Introduction to Markstrat Online Required Reading: You should have read the Markstrat Participant Handbook before arriving on campus. Please review it before class. 10:45 Break 11:30 Marketing Session 3 – Professor Nunes Topic: Using Perceptual Maps Required Reading: Wilcox, Ronald T.: “Methods for Producing Perceptual Maps from Data”, UV0405 Assignment: Exercise 1 – Markstrat Familiarity 12:45 Lunch 13:45 Finance Session 1 – Professor Callahan Topics: Introduction, Growth and Financial Planning We will look at the relation between a company’s growth rate and need for capital. We introduce the concepts of a firm’s internal growth rate and sustainable growth rate and how each is used to anticipate a firm’s need GEMBA VIII, Theme 3A, 29 Sept to 3 Oct, 2011, daily syllabus 4 Page: 1 / 10 Global Executive MBA in Shanghai for capital. Detailed forecasting of (external) funds needed is based on a pro forma analysis of cash flows. Required Reading: RWJ Chapters 3 and 26 Discussion Questions: 1. What is a company’s internal growth rate? What can a company do to improve its internal growth rate? 2. What is a company’s sustainable growth rate? What can a company do to improve its sustainable growth rate? 3. What are the implications for a company that grows at a rate above its internal growth rate? 4. What are the implications for a company that grows at a rate above its sustainable growth rate? To do before this session: - Review readings - Prepare answers to discussion questions Due: Turn in the Pre-Theme Questions 15:00 Break 15:15 Finance Session 2 – Professor Callahan Topic: Growth and Financial Planning – applied We will use the Clarkson Lumber Company case to illustrate how growth implies important changes in the type and amount of financing needed by a firm. This case will also serve as a precursor to our examination of capital structure choices. Required Reading: Clarkson Lumber Company case Discussion Questions: 1. Why has Clarkson Lumber borrowed increasing amounts despite its consistent profitability? 2. Over recent years, how have the financing needs of the company been met? Has the company’s financial strength improved or deteriorated? 3. Assuming projected 1996 sales of $5.5M, do you agree with Mr. Clarkson’s estimate of the company’s loan requirements? 4. Would you advise Mr. Dodge to make the requested loan? GEMBA VIII, Theme 3A, 29 Sept to 3 Oct, 2011, daily syllabus 5 Page: 2 / 10 Global Executive MBA in Shanghai 5. Would you advise Mr. Clarkson to proceed as planned? To do before this session: Prepare the case for discussion Friday, 30 September 08:30 Marketing Session 4 – Professor Nunes Topic: Conjoint Analysis and Product Design Required Reading: Wilcox, Ronald T.: “A Practical Guide to Conjoint Analysis”, UV0406 09:45 Break 10:00 Marketing Session 5 – Professor Nunes Topic: Breakout Sessions This session will include time to complete earlier lectures and ensure comprehension, as well as time to meet as teams with the instructor. 11:15 Break 11:30 Marketing Session 6 – Professor Nunes Topic: Pricing, Cost Curves and Market Price Evolution Required Readings: - Dhebar, Anirudh: “Price-Quantity Determination”, HBS 9-191-093 - Steenburgh, Thomas and Jill Avery: “Marketing Analysis Toolkit: Pricing and Profitability Analysis”, HBS 9-511-028 Due: Exercise 1 – Markstrat Familiarity Assignment: Exercise 2 – Reading Perceptual Maps 12:45 Lunch 13:45 Finance Session 3 – Professor Callahan Topic: Introduction to Capital Structure Choices This session is the first of three sessions in which we examine the concepts, theories, and evidence concerning corporate capital structure (i.e., the debt/equity mix, or amount of leverage, used to finance a firm). We will start by understanding how changes in a firm’s leverage change the allocation of operating cash flows and operating risk among the firm’s debt holders and equity holders. Next we will look at how the tax GEMBA VIII, Theme 3A, 29 Sept to 3 Oct, 2011, daily syllabus 6 Page: 3 / 10 Global Executive MBA in Shanghai deductibility of interest payments to debt holders can increase firm value and decrease a firm’s cost of capital. Required Reading: RWJ Chapters 15 and 16 Discussion Questions: 1. What are the differences in the cash flow rights, control rights, and risk profile of debt versus equity? 2. How does an increase in corporate leverage change the allocation of operating risk between debt and equity? 3. Does US (and most other countries’) corporate tax law favor equity or debt? To do before this session: - Review readings - Prepare answers to discussion questions 15:00 Break 15:15 Finance Session 4 – Professor Callahan Topic: Capital Structure – Additional Considerations In this session we discuss a host of factors that can play a significant role in firms’ capital structure choices. Potential downsides of debt include the risk of bankruptcy and a negative impact on the firm’s relations with customers, employees, and suppliers. Debt can also restrict a firm’s operating flexibility. Excessive debt can create incentives for stockholders to under or overinvest relative to the firm’s optimal investment policy. Potential upsides of debt include its disciplinary effect on managers and the confidence it can project to financial markets. Upsides of equity include maintaining financial flexibility and its use as a form of compensation. Downsides of equity are the potentially negative signal its use sends to financial markets. Required Reading: RWJ Chapters 17 and 30 Discussion Questions: 1. Why are financial distress costs generally considered to be much greater than bankruptcy costs? 2. What are two ways in which equity holders might gain at the expense of debt holders and what mechanisms can debt holders use to try and protect themselves? GEMBA VIII, Theme 3A, 29 Sept to 3 Oct, 2011, daily syllabus 7 Page: 4 / 10 Global Executive MBA in Shanghai 3. How can debt and equity encourage managers to be thrifty and hardworking? 4. What inferences do markets make about firm value when a firm issues debt? When a firm issues equity? To do before this session: - Review readings - Prepare answers to discussion questions 16:30 Break 16:45 In-Class Pub session Saturday, 1 October 08:30 Finance Session 5 – Professor Callahan Topic: Capital Structure Choices – Putting It All Together In this session we will use a case discussion to review and summarize the important tax, risk, information, and agency consequences of a major change in a firm’s capital structure policy. Required Reading: Blaine Kitchenware, Inc.: Capital Structure case Case Discussion Questions: 1. Do you believe Blaine’s capital structure and payout policies are appropriate? Why or why not? 2. Should Dubinski recommend a large share repurchase to Blaine’s board? What are the primary advantages and disadvantages of such a move? 3. Consider the following share repurchase proposal: Blaine will use $209M of cash from its balance sheet and $50M in new interest-bearing debt at a rate of 6.75% to repurchase 14.0M shares at a price of $18.50 per share. How would such a buyback affect Blaine? Consider the impact on, among other things, Blaine’s earnings per share and ROE. 4. As a member of Blaine’s controlling family, would you be in favor of this proposal? Would you be in favor of it as a non-family shareholder? To do before this session: Prepare the case for discussion 09:45 Break 10:00 Finance Session 6 – Professor Callahan GEMBA VIII, Theme 3A, 29 Sept to 3 Oct, 2011, daily syllabus 8 Page: 5 / 10 Global Executive MBA in Shanghai Topic: Leverage and the Cost of Capital for a Firm or Project/Division In this session we will learn how to calculate a firm’s or project’s cost of capital. (They may or may not be the same!) We will discuss the appropriate cost of debt financing, preferred stock financing, and common equity financing and how each is commonly derived. We will also look at the interaction between capital structure choices and the firm’s cost of capital. Required Readings: - RWJ Chapter 13 (review, especially 13.9) - RWJ Chapter 18 (with an emphasis on 18.3, 18.5, and 18.7) Discussion Questions: 1. Intuitively, what does a stock beta represent? 2. What is the difference between a stock beta, a debt beta, and an asset beta? 3. What are three primary determinants of a company’s stock beta (i.e., what determines the relative exposure of a company stock to economy wide fluctuations)? 4. Why might a project beta or division beta differ from a company’s stock beta? Give a real world example of a project with the same beta as the parent company and a real world example of a project with a different beta than the parent company. To do before this session: - Review readings - Prepare answers to the discussion questions 11:15 Break 11:30 Finance Session 7 – Professor Callahan Topic: Estimating the Cost of Capital – An Example In this session we will apply what we have learned in the previous session to the Midland Energy Resources, Inc. case and further refine our financial analysis skills. Required Reading: Midland Energy Resources, Inc.: Cost of Capital Discussion Questions: GEMBA VIII, Theme 3A, 29 Sept to 3 Oct, 2011, daily syllabus 9 Page: 6 / 10 Global Executive MBA in Shanghai 1. How are Mortensen’s estimates of Midland’s cost of capital used? How, if at all, should these anticipated uses affect the calculations? 2. Calculate Midland’s corporate WACC. Be prepared to defend your specific assumptions about the various inputs to the calculations. Is Midland’s choice of EMRP appropriate? If not, what recommendations would you make and why? 3. Should Midland use a single corporate hurdle rate for evaluating investment opportunities in all of its divisions? Why or why not? 4. Compute a separate cost of capital for the E&P and Marketing & Refining divisions. What causes them to differ from one another? 5. How would you compute a cost of capital for the Petrochemical division? To do before this session: Prepare the case for discussion 12:45 Lunch 13:45 Marketing Session 7 – Professor Nunes Topic: Saurer: The China Challenge Required Readings: Saurer: The China Challenge (A) IMD399 Discussion Questions: 1. Should Saurer enter the market for lower functionality twisting machines in China? What are the major advantages and disadvantages to doing this? 2. If Saurer were to introduce the proposed machine, what marketing strategy would you recommend for the product in China? 3. If Saurer were to not introduce the machine, what changes would you recommend for the company’s current strategy in China? Optional Reading: Gadiesh, Orit, Philip Leung and Till Vestring: “The Battle for China’s Good Enough Market”, HBR Reprint R0709E Due: Exercise 2 – Reading Perceptual Maps 15:00 Break 15:15 Marketing Session 8 – Professor Nunes Topic: Breakout Sessions This session will include time to review Exercise 2 before allowing teams to work on their first practice decision. GEMBA VIII, Theme 3A, 29 Sept to 3 Oct, 2011, daily syllabus 10 Page: 7 / 10 Global Executive MBA in Shanghai Assignment: Make Markstrat Practice Decision Sunday, 2 October 08:30 Finance Session 8 – Professor Callahan Topic: Quiz (covering material through Finance session 6) Required Readings and Discussion Questions: None – study for the quiz. To do before this session: Study for the quiz. 09:45 Break 10:00 Finance Session 9 – Professor Callahan Topic: Raising Long-Term Capital This session provides an opportunity to discuss how firms raise external capital, what types of capital are acquired and why, and the comparative costs and benefits of strategic capital acquisition. Topics will include concepts of market efficiency and the process and costs of underwriting common stock and debt. Required Readings: RWJ Chapters 14 and 20 Discussion Questions: 1. Do you believe markets are efficient? Why or why not? 2. What do your views on market efficiency imply about firms’ financial policies? 3. Think about whatever questions you have regarding the institutional details or mechanics of stock or bond issuance. To do before this session: - Review readings - Prepare answers to the discussion questions 11:15 Break 11:30 Marketing Session 9 – Professor Nunes Please review the results of your practice Markstrat Decision. We will discuss and I will answer questions. Topic: Brand Identity & Brand Image Required Readings: Ward, Scott, Larry Light and Jonathan Goldstine: “What High-Tech Managers Need to Know about Brands”, HBR Reprint 994II GEMBA VIII, Theme 3A, 29 Sept to 3 Oct, 2011, daily syllabus 11 Page: 8 / 10 Global Executive MBA in Shanghai 12:45 Lunch 13:45 Marketing Session 10 – Professor Nunes Topic: Pepsi Case Required Readings: Handed out in Class Assignment: Make Decision 1 15:00 Break 15:15 G7 and G8 Joint Session Monday, 3 October 08:30 Marketing Session 11 – Professor Nunes Topic: Mattel Case Required Readings: - Mattel and the Toy Recalls (B) Ivey 908M11 - Donaldson, Thomas “Values in Tension: Ethics Away from Home” HBR Reprint 96502 Discussion Questions: 1. What went wrong with Mattel’s recall strategy? 2. Who are Mattel’s stakeholders? Who did Mattel cater to in the recall? 3. What values did Mattel exhibit during the recall? How did they affect Mattel? 4. What should Mattel do right now (at the point in the case) and in the future? 09:45 Break 10:00 Integrative Session with Professors Nunes and Callahan Topic: TBD 11:15 Break 11:30 Finance Session 10 – Professor Callahan Topic: Returning Value to Shareholders (aka Payout Policy) In recent years, about 40% of firms’ income has been paid out to shareholders via dividends. But it is also true that many firms pay no GEMBA VIII, Theme 3A, 29 Sept to 3 Oct, 2011, daily syllabus 12 Page: 9 / 10 Global Executive MBA in Shanghai dividends at all. What do we know about dividend policy? This session will explore various methods of returning value to shareholders including cash dividends, stock repurchases, and extraordinary dividends. Topics will include dividend policy and personal taxes, factors favoring a high dividend policy, and some empirical regularities about US corporate payout policy. Required Readings: RWJ Chapter 19 Discussion Questions: 1. What are the typical methods used by firms to return cash to shareholders? 2. What role do taxes play in corporate payout policy? 3. What other factors influence corporate payout policy? To do before this session: - Review readings - Prepare answers to the discussion questions 12:45 Lunch 13:45 Finance Session 11 – Professor Callahan Topic: Returning Value to Shareholders – Applied In this session we will use the General Motors Corporation (D) case to review payout policy theory and look at various tradeoffs inherent in choosing a policy. We examine the interaction between payout policy, investment policy, and capital structure policy. Required Reading: The General Motors Corporation (D) case Discussion Questions: 1. What options are Mr. Finnegan and his staff evaluating? 2. What are the pros and cons of each option? 3. What do you recommend General Motors to do? To do before this session: Prepare the case for discussion 15:00 Break 15:15 Summary and Evaluations – Professors Callahan and Nunes GEMBA VIII, Theme 3A, 29 Sept to 3 Oct, 2011, daily syllabus 13 Page: 10 / 10 Thursday, September 29 Global Executive MBA in Shanghai GEMBA VIII – Theme 3A General Manager as Integrator 29 Sept – 3 Oct 2011, Shanghai Jiao Tong University, Shanghai Professors Ty Callahan (Finance and Business Economics) and Joe Nunes (Marketing) All assigned readings and cases for all the week's sessions need to be read and studied before the first session at SJTU. Focus on reading and being prepared to discuss the cases! Thursday, 29 September 08:30 Marketing Session 1 – Professor Nunes Topic: Course Introduction & Review You should have downloaded and installed the Markstrat Online software before class. This session will include time to ensure software is up and running on all laptops as well as time to form teams for the simulation. Required Reading: Johnson, Richard R. and Ron Mentus: “Marketing Economics”, Darden UV0404 09:45 Break 10:00 Marketing Session 2 – Professor Nunes Topic: Introduction to Markstrat Online Required Reading: You should have read the Markstrat Participant Handbook before arriving on campus. Please review it before class. 10:45 Break 11:30 Marketing Session 3 – Professor Nunes Topic: Using Perceptual Maps Required Reading: Wilcox, Ronald T.: “Methods for Producing Perceptual Maps from Data”, UV0405 Assignment: Exercise 1 – Markstrat Familiarity 12:45 Lunch 13:45 Finance Session 1 – Professor Callahan Topics: Introduction, Growth and Financial Planning We will look at the relation between a company’s growth rate and need for capital. We introduce the concepts of a firm’s internal growth rate and sustainable growth rate and how each is used to anticipate a firm’s need GEMBA VIII, Theme 3A, 29 Sept to 3 Oct, 2011, daily syllabus 14 Page: 1 / 3 Global Executive MBA in Shanghai for capital. Detailed forecasting of (external) funds needed is based on a pro forma analysis of cash flows. Required Reading: RWJ Chapters 3 and 26 Discussion Questions: 1. What is a company’s internal growth rate? What can a company do to improve its internal growth rate? 2. What is a company’s sustainable growth rate? What can a company do to improve its sustainable growth rate? 3. What are the implications for a company that grows at a rate above its internal growth rate? 4. What are the implications for a company that grows at a rate above its sustainable growth rate? To do before this session: - Review readings - Prepare answers to discussion questions Due: Turn in the Pre-Theme Questions 15:00 Break 15:15 Finance Session 2 – Professor Callahan Topic: Growth and Financial Planning – applied We will use the Clarkson Lumber Company case to illustrate how growth implies important changes in the type and amount of financing needed by a firm. This case will also serve as a precursor to our examination of capital structure choices. Required Reading: Clarkson Lumber Company case Discussion Questions: 1. Why has Clarkson Lumber borrowed increasing amounts despite its consistent profitability? 2. Over recent years, how have the financing needs of the company been met? Has the company’s financial strength improved or deteriorated? 3. Assuming projected 1996 sales of $5.5M, do you agree with Mr. Clarkson’s estimate of the company’s loan requirements? 4. Would you advise Mr. Dodge to make the requested loan? GEMBA VIII, Theme 3A, 29 Sept to 3 Oct, 2011, daily syllabus 15 Page: 2 / 3 Global Executive MBA in Shanghai 5. Would you advise Mr. Clarkson to proceed as planned? To do before this session: Prepare the case for discussion GEMBA VIII, Theme 3A, 29 Sept to 3 Oct, 2011, daily syllabus 16 Page: 3 / 3 U UV0404 MARKETING ECONOMICS generally associated with the finance and operations functions. Marketing-related decisions often made in conjunction with these calculations include 1) how many units of a product do I have to sell before I begin making a profit 2) how much more do I need to sell to make a particular change in my marketing plan profitable. The purpose of this note is to prepare you for a series of exercises in making Marketing Economics calculations. While the note will give you the basic information on the purpose and structure of various calculations, the note, by itself, will not help you develop a facility for doing these calculations. The series of Exercises in Marketing Economics will help you to become more proficient in performing what will eventually seem to be “simple” calculations. These calculations are not replacements for spreadsheets or more detailed economic calculations such as net present value or return on investment. Rather, they are “back of the envelope” estimates that can easily be communicated to others to buttress your arguments about what a company should or should not do in a decision situation. There are many other situations where these calculations are common. Venture capitalists must determine whether a new business is likely to be profitable. Part of this evaluation necessarily involves calculating costs and the sales volume necessary to cover those costs, a break-even analysis. A company may want to decide whether a new technology designed to streamline the production process and reduce costs is worth the price of acquisition. Again, in integral part of such analysis would be a breakeven. The Note and the Exercises will prepare you for the task of learning how to “see” which calculations are relevant to a particular case. That is a task that needs practicing. The concepts of fixed and variable costs, for example, are simple in theory compared to practice. Deciding what should be treated (assumed) as variable or fixed says a lot about how you intend to manage the business. This note will not make a cost accountant out of you. The goal is to start you on a process of becoming fluent in the practice of marketing economic calculations.1 In the next sections we define different types of costs and provide examples of break-even analysis and contribution margin calculations. We also briefly discuss the impact that selling through channel partners has on such analysis. Costs Costs are often divided into fixed and variable costs. Whereas total fixed costs remain constant despite changes in sales or production volume, the sum total of variable costs changes per unit manufactured or sold. These types of marketing calculations are used both for what we normally think of as marketing-related decisions as well as decisions more Total Costs = Total Variable Costs + Fixed Costs 1 Portions of this note were drawn from Lawrence J. Ring, Derek A. Newton, Neil H. Borden, Jr., and Paul W. Farris, Decisions in Marketing, 2nd Edition, (Homewood, IL: BPI/Irwin, 1989), pp. 941-51. This note was prepared by Richard R. Johnson and Ron Mentus under the supervision of Paul W. Farris, Landmark Communications Professor of Business Administration, Marian C. Moore, Visiting Associate Professor of Business Administration, and Ronald T. Wilcox, Associate Professor of Business Administration. Copyright © 2001 by the University of Virginia Darden School Foundation, Charlottesville, VA. All rights reserved. To order copies, send an e-mail to sales@dardenpublishing.com. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, used in a spreadsheet, or transmitted in any form or by any means—electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording, or otherwise—without the permission of the Darden School Foundation. Rev. 7/02. 17 -2- UV0404 Figure 1: Total Contribution. Variable Costs Variable costs (VC) are costs that vary with volume. VC can be expressed on a per unit basis, as VC per unit; for example, as $3.50 labor and material cost per unit. As more units are manufactured and sold, total VC equals VC per unit times units sold. (Note that selling price, SP, is revenue per unit and is analogous to variable cost per unit. Therefore, as additional units are sold, the relevant effect in terms of a net income of funds into a business is shown by: SP per unit less VC per unit. This residual amount is called contribution to fixed costs and profit, and this concept will be further explained in the following section.) As more units are manufactured and sold, total VC (and revenue) behave as shown in Figure 1. Fixed Costs Note: The vertical distance between the revenue and variable cost lines represents total contribution at a particular sales volume. Contribution per unit (SP – VC per unit) can also be found by dividing total contribution at a particular sales volume by the number of units sold. Fixed costs (FC) do not vary with volume. As more units are manufactured and sold, FC (such as rent and depreciation) remain the same, as shown in Figure 2. Figure 2: Fixed Costs Total Costs Total costs equal FC + total VC (VC per unit times units sold). In Figure 3, if the number of units manufactured and sold were 40, then total costs would be FC = $100 + total VC = $140 (40 times $3.50), for a total of $240. The fixed costs and variable costs categories are usually oversimplifications of most business situations. For example, some costs may be semi-variable, such as certain employee costs. That is, employees may be like a fixed cost in that you do not want to fire them if you do not have 40 hours a week of work for them at all times. However, things may become so slack that employees have to be furloughed, or alternatively, sales may be so good that they will be used overtime. Other costs may seem relatively fixed for existing volume but may go up in large chunks when volume takes a sharp turn. Certain cost situations can be confusing and ambiguous. Notice that our simple graphical interpretation of costs has assumed that the unit cost of production is constant. In other words, for the sake of clear explanation, we have assumed that the first unit a company produces costs them exactly the same as the 1000th unit. There are many instances in which variable costs will decrease, or even increase, as the number of units produced rises. Common reasons for a decrease in variable costs include 1) obtaining better prices on raw materials as the quantity purchased increases (quantity discounts) 2) becoming more efficient at the production process as 18 -3- UV0404 Figure 3: Total Costs By way of introduction, break-even analysis is a general term that refers to an easy way to study, under a number of situations, the interrelationship that exists between: (1) selling price, variable costs, and fixed costs; and (2) volume of sales. The general formula for break-even (BE) is as follows: Break-even point: Total Costs = Total Revenues 500 Total costs ($) 400 300 200 Break - even volume (in units) = 100 0 0 40 80 Units Total Fixed Costs Total Costs Total Variable Costs Total Revenue experience increases. Also, increases can occur because of very practical consideration such as 1) the need to pay employees overtime wages to support an increase in production output and 2) the need to hold additional levels of inventory to serve the ramped-up production process. These are just a few of many possible reasons. Clearly, if variable costs are anticipated to change with different levels of production this needs to factored into your analysis. Breakeven and Target Volume Analysis Break-even analysis is a useful analytical technique to use: (1) when a new product is planned or (2) when a change in the marketing program is considered. Break-even analysis is most useful when it is converted to a percentage of market share, because then the manager will have one more gauge of whether the assumptions required to make a project profitable are reasonable. New product When a new product is planned, the marketer needs to calculate how many units (usually on a per year basis) will need to be sold to break even on all costs. That is, how many units will have to be sold to reach a point where the total revenue just equals the total costs of the product? Fixed costs Unit contribution Unit contribution = Selling price per unit less variable costs per unit Explanations of break-even analysis begin with a consideration of the concept of “contribution,” because break-even analysis is taught to train marketing students to think in terms of contribution – not in terms of sales. Contribution per unit, which is the selling price per unit less variable costs per unit, measures a net income of funds into a business as additional units are sold. That is, as sales of a product are made, revenue flows into the business at a rate that equals selling price (SP) times the unit volume sold. At the same time, other funds – variable costs (VC) – are flowing out of the business with each unit sold. Variable costs (VC) include such variable marketing costs as salesmen’s commissions and shipping, and such variable manufacturing costs as raw materials, direct labor, and the variable portion of factory overhead. Selling price (SP) and variable costs (VC) thus are closely related. Marketers want to sell an additional unit for a certain price, but they also want to know how much it costs to sell that additional unit. “Unit contribution to fixed costs and profit” (or simply “unit contribution”) is calculated as selling price per unit (SP) less variable costs per unit (V). Unit contribution, then, is money that each unit sold “contributes” to paying fixed costs and providing profit. Fixed costs may fall into several categories and usually include such fixed marketing costs as advertising, sales office rent, etc., and such fixed manufacturing costs as property taxes, insurance, and factory depreciation. (For the latter cost, remember that it is yearly depreciation and not total investment that becomes a cost to be subtracted from sales to compute profits for any given year.) When a new 19 -4- product (or other business venture) is planned, there will always be some new fixed costs that will occur regardless of sales volume. Profits are the dollars left over after fixed costs and variable costs have been covered. objective of $6000, then the calculation would be as follows: ($10,000 + $6,000)/($40) = 400 units. Change in the Marketing Program Break-even analysis (or its extension, target volume analysis) can be used for a number of purposes, one of which (used in connection with a new product) has already been demonstrated. Similar analysis can be used to evaluate the economic effect of a change in the marketing program. When a marketing program is changed, it will usually involve a change in one of three things (or combination thereof): (1) a change in selling price (e.g., a “price special”), (2) a change in variable costs (e.g., a more expensive package for the product), and (3) a change in fixed costs (e.g., increased advertising expenditures). Break-even Volume If the analyst’s objective is to make a breakeven calculation that will show how many units will have to be sold to cover all costs, then the formula would be: BE (units) = Fixed Costs Selling price − Var. costs per unit BE = (1) FC SP − VC We have been using an example about a product whose SP = $100, VC = $60, FC = $10,000, and the desired profit is $6,000. Assume that this product comes under a new product manager who wants to cut the price to $90. He also wants to advertise the special price, and this will cost an extra $5,000 for TV advertising. Also, a new package promoting the special price will cost $5 more than the regular package. Yet the manager will still wish, under the new marketing program, to retain the same dollar amount of profit that is currently being made – usually, he would not want to make any change that would reduce his profit, or there would be no point in changing. For example, if the following information applied: SP = $100, VC per unit = $60, and FC = $10,000, then unit contribution would be $100-$60, or $40 per unit. Break-even volume then would be $10,000/$40, or 250 units. (Note: In some cases, such division will yield a fraction. All such fractions in break-even calculations should be rounded-up since the final results are expressed in units, and one cannot sell less than a whole unit.) Target volume More than likely, a marketer wants to do better than simply break even on his costs because at this volume his profits are zero. If the objective is to do a calculation that will show how many units have to be sold to reach break-even on costs and to produce a profit as well, the break-even formula can be expanded into a “target volume” (TV) formula: TV (units) = Fixed costs + Profit Selling price − Var. costs per unit Target volume = UV0404 In this situation there will be a whole new set of numbers to substitute into the target volume formula: TV (units) = ( 2) TV ( units ) = FC + P SP − VC Old FC + New FC + Profit Unit contribution ($10,000 + $5,000) + ($6,000) ($100 − $10) − ($60 + $5) Target volume (in units) = 840 units For example, if the information in the previous example was used in connection with a profit The example above included the current figures as well as the new figures for the changed 20 UV0405 METHODS FOR PRODUCING PERCEPTUAL MAPS FROM DATA Introduction Graphics are instruments for reasoning about quantitative information. If carefully done, graphics can describe and explore complex data in a way that suggests the useful information. We often find that a picture of the data allows greater understanding and helps commit the important features of the data to memory.1 One very common graphic in marketing is a perceptual map. These maps are used to help managers visualize how their product(s) relate to other competitive offerings in the marketplace. Common terms in marketing such as “targeting” and “positioning” implicitly reference the idea that managers are or should be visualizing the perceptual differences between their product(s) and others in the marketplace. Perceptual maps are ubiquitous in marketing presentations to help the audience with visualizations of the competitive landscape. A simple example of a perceptual map is on the next page. It describes the market for sport utility vehicles. 1 E.R. Tufte, The Visual Display of Quantitative Information (Graphics Press, 1983). This note was prepared by Ronald T. Wilcox, Associate Professor of Business Administration, University of Virginia. It was written as a basis for class discussion rather than to illustrate effective or ineffective handling of an administrative situation. Copyright © 2003 by the University of Virginia Darden School Foundation, Charlottesville, VA. All rights reserved. To order copies, send an e-mail to sales@dardenpublishing.com. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, used in a spreadsheet, or transmitted in any form or by any means—electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording, or otherwise—without the permission of the Darden School Foundation. 21 UV0405 -2Figure 1: The Market for Sport Utility Vehicles Prestigious • Cadillac Escalade • • Chevy Tahoe • Nissan Jeep Pathfinder Grand Cherokee • • Not Rugged • Hummer H2 Toyota 4Runner Ford Explorer Rugged • Jeep Cherokee Not Prestigious In the above map we can see that, among other things, Nissan Pathfinder, Toyota 4Runner, and Jeep Grand Cherokee are perceived to be fairly similar. Hummer H2 is perceived to be the most rugged SUV in this group and likewise Cadillac Escalade the most luxurious. Overall, this map allows us to compare each vehicle to all others on the map along the perceptual dimensions listed on the axis. This kind of analysis requires several assumptions. Among the most important of these assumptions are: 1. Consumers evaluate all products in this category using the attributes listed along the axis of the perceptual map. 2. These attributes are the most important of all possible attributes a consumer might use to compare products in this category. 3. The points depicted on the map, representing products, are accurate representations of consumers’ view of the marketplace. We will now discuss how marketing researchers collect and use data on consumers’ perceptions to develop these maps. We will first consider the situation in which the analyst can make an initial hypothesis or guess as to what perceptual attributes consumers may be using to evaluate a product and then move on to a situation in which no such prior hypothesis is possible. 22 UV0405 -3Attribute Ratings Method Constructing the XY plot There are situations in which product managers may have some idea about which perceptual attributes their product(s) and those of their competitors are considered prior to purchase. A good example is the SUV market depicted in Figure 1. Automobiles are very high involvement purchases, usually requiring consumers to make mental trade-offs between price and a number of other attributes of competing products before a purchase decision is made. Over time, automobile manufacturers have developed a reasonably sophisticated understanding, often through marketing research, of the attributes consumers consider in this process. In order to develop a perceptual map, a manager must determine which two of the possible attributes are the most important in the decision process and how consumers’ evaluate each product in the competitive set with respect to these two attributes. The analytics of this method begin by collecting consumer ratings for each product, both the product of interest and other products in the competitive set, for each possible attribute that management believes consumers might reasonably consider. Perceptual attributes are not the same as engineering attributes. For example, “number of miles per gallon” is an engineering attribute. It has a definitive answer. “Fuel efficiency,” while probably highly related to this engineering attribute, is a perceptual attribute. Consumers are not being asked to report the quantitative answer to this question, but are being asked about their overall impression of the vehicle along this dimension. Likewise, “interior space” is an engineering attribute while “roominess” is a perceptual attribute. Measuring consumers’ perceptions is generally accomplished by using a Likert scale survey instrument.2 The general form of this question is: [Insert vehicle name] is a [insert attribute] sport utility vehicle. Strongly Agree ______ Agree ______ Neither Agree nor Disagree Disagree ________ _______ Strongly Disagree _______ For example, for one question we would insert the name “Toyota 4Runner” and the attribute “Rugged.” In general, if the researcher wanted to product a map with N competitive products and was testing M perceptual attributes, he/she would have to ask NxM Likert scale questions. Once a sufficient sample of consumers have provided this information, the researcher can convert this ordinal scale to a cardinal scale by assigning the value “5” to “Strongly Agree,” “4” to “Agree” etc. and compute the arithmetic mean of each attribute score for each vehicle. The output of this process is a matrix that takes the general form: 2 For a more detailed discussion of using a Likert Scale to measure consumers’ perceptions of product attributes, see G. Urban and J. Hauser, Design and Marketing of New Products (Prentice-Hall, 1993), 196–199. 23 -4Table 1: Average Attribute Rating for Each Vehicle Vehicle 1 Vehicle 2 ……….. Attribute 1 Attribute 2 …………. Attribute M UV0405 Vehicle N [average score] In addition to this information, the researcher should also ask a single overall preference question, using the same Likert scale, for each vehicle. The preference question takes the general form: “I believe that [insert vehicle name] is an excellent [insert product category].” So, continuing our example, one question would be “I believe that Toyota 4Runner is an excellent sport utility vehicle.” Thus, the total data set collected by the research includes NxM vehiclesspecific average attribute scores and N overall preference scores. Recall that the researcher now needs to accomplish two tasks. First he/she needs to determine which two of the M possible perceptual dimensions are the most important in the overall evaluation process. Once that is complete, the researcher then needs to place each product in the appropriate position on the map. To determine which attributes should define the axis of the perceptual map, the researcher can estimate a preference regression using a simple linear model. Specifically, the researcher should estimate: Overall Preferencein = α + β1 Attribute1in + β2 Attribute2in + …+βM AttributeMin + εin where Overall Preferencein is the preference of respondent i for product n, Attibute1in is respondent i’s rating on Attribute 1 for product n and so forth. Greek letters represent parameters to be estimated by the regression. To keep things simple, we will assume that εin follows the standard assumptions of the classical linear model so that Ordinary Least Squares, using a software package such as Excel, can be used to estimate this model. Estimating this regression will yield estimates of the parameters (coefficients) with additional information that will allow the researcher to determine whether the parameter estimates are statistically significant.3 From this point, determining the attributes to use to define the axes is straightforward. The researcher should choose the two attributes that have estimated coefficients that are the greatest in absolute value subject to the restriction that are statistically significant. Practically speaking, if either of the two estimated coefficients that are the greatest in absolute value are not 3 A good refresher on the basic linear model and problems that can arise with this model can be found in Darden Technical Notes UVA-QA-0500, Introduction to Least Squares Modeling, and UVA-QA-0416, Problems in Regression, both authored by Phillip E. Pfeifer. 24 -5- UV0405 statistically significant this probably means that: (1) the sample size is not large enough or; (2) the set of attributes tested by the researcher is not capturing the important determinants of product evaluation, and serious consideration should be given to rethinking the data collection from the beginning. The two coefficients that are the greatest in absolute value will indicate which attributes are most important in determining overall preference and hence the most appropriate attributes to define the axes of the perceptual map.4 The use of the absolute value is important because it is possible that some attributes may negatively impact product evaluation. For example, in our SUV example, if one perceptual attribute being tested was “luxurious,” it is entirely possible that the estimated coefficient of this attribute would be negative as some individuals would equate luxury with an SUV that is not sufficiently capable of off-road use. It is also possible that the researcher could define a perceptual attribute as a negative rather than a positive. The perceptual attribute “gas guzzling” would likely show up as a negative influence in the preference regression. Once these two attributes have been determined, the researcher need only to use the average attribute ratings for these two attributes, found in Table 1, to plot each vehicle on an XY axis. It is customary to use the most important attribute as the X axis and the second-most important as the Y axis although it actually makes little difference. Much like Figure 1, positive attributes define the positive portions of each axis, and their negative counterparts define the negative portions. When constructing the actual map itself, it is useful to define the origin, usually the point (0,0) as (3,3) instead. The reason is straightforward. We would like to use the entire space to plot the products. Because perceptual attributes are measured on a one to five scale, defining the origin as (0,0) would force us to plot all products in the first quadrant. This produces a map that is more difficult to interpret than a map that uses the entire space. Thus, centering the map at (3,3) makes the graphic clearer and hence more useful as a decision aid. Here is Figure 1 reproduced with hypothetical average perceptual attributes used as coordinates. 4 It is not generally the case that one can interpret coefficients in a linear regression in this way. However, because all of the independent variables use the exact same scale, we can interpret the magnitude of the estimated coefficient as an indicator of relative importance in determining the dependent variable. 25 UV0405 -6Figure 2: The Market for Sport Utility Vehicles: Attribute Scores Included Prestigious • Cadillac Escalade (1.2, 4.7) • Not Rugged • • Nissan Chevy • Jeep Pathfinder (3.6, 4) Tahoe (1.9, 3.8) Grand Cherokee (2.5, 3 8) • Toyota 4Runner (3.5, 3.3) • Ford Explorer (2.1, 2) • Hummer H2 (4.5, 4.6) Rugged Jeep Cherokee (4, 1.7) Not Prestigious Constructing the ideal vector We have now constructed a perceptual map using perceptual attribute ratings. There is one more potentially valuable piece of information that can be gleaned from the data that has been collected to develop this map. Up to this point, this map contains no information about which product would be preferred by consumers. Some preference information does appear obvious. For example, it appears that, all else equal, Nissan Pathfinder would be preferred by most people to Ford Explorer because it is generally viewed as more rugged and more prestigious. But, it is less obvious whether consumers generally prefer the Jeep Cherokee or the Toyota 4Runner. The Toyota is more prestigious but the Jeep is more rugged. What are the trade-offs consumers are willing to make? This kind of issue becomes even more interesting when different perceptual maps are developed for different potential target audiences. For example, the trade-offs men are willing to make among perceptual attributes may be quite different from those women are willing to make. This kind of information is extremely valuable for product design decisions as well as target selection and marketing communication strategies. Fortunately, the procedure described above already contains enough information to be able to develop stronger statements about consumers’ preferences. This is generally accomplished through the construction of an “ideal vector,” a vector depicted on the perceptual map, which illustrates these trade-offs. To construct the ideal vector, the researcher needs to use the estimated preference regression model. In particular, he/she needs to use the estimated coefficients from the perceptual attributes that define the axes of the map. The ratio of these two 26 UV0405 -7- coefficients will determine the slope of the ideal vector, a vector which originates at the origin of the map. The best way to explain the details of this procedure is through a simple example. Suppose we estimated the preference regression for SUVs, and it yielded the following results for the two most important attributes: Overall Preference = -2.7 + 1.25*Prestige + 2.5*Ruggedness +……….. where Prestige and Ruggedness have been previously determined to be the two most important attributes in the decision process. Following earlier arguments, the estimated coefficients indicate that Ruggedness is more important than Prestige in determining overall preference. In particular, because 2.5 = 2*1.25, we can conclude that Ruggedness is twice as important as Prestige. The ideal vector is constructed as follows: 1. Take the ratio of the coefficient of the second-most important perceptual attribute to the most important. In this case, we would have 1.25/2.5 = ½. 2. Plot a vector with slope defined by this ratio and whose beginning point is at the origin of the graph.5 Figure 3: Constructing the Ideal Vector Prestigious • Cadillac Escalade • • Chevy Tahoe • Nissan Jeep Pathfinder Grand Cherokee • • Not Rugged • Hummer H2 Toyota 4Runner Ford Explorer Rugged • Jeep Cherokee Not Prestigious 5 The one exception to this is if the researcher places the most important attribute on the Y-axis and the secondmost important on the X-axis. In that case, one would want to use the ratio of the most important attribute to the second-most important attribute in determining the slope of the vector. 27 UV0405 -8- Notice that the ideal vector tilts towards the axis defined by the most important attribute. Preference increases as you move out along the vector. Points of equal preference, or what economists would call utility, can be determined by constructing lines that are perpendicular to the ideal vector. Two of these utility lines are depicted in Figure 4. Figure 4: Constructing Linear Utility Functions Prestigious • Cadillac Escalade • • Chevy Tahoe • Nissan Jeep Pathfinder Grand Cherokee • • Not Rugged • Hummer H2 Toyota 4Runner Ford Explorer Rugged • Jeep Cherokee Not Prestigious The answer to the Toyota 4Runner vs. Jeep Cherokee now becomes clear. Because utility lines that intersect the ideal vector further from the origin represent higher levels of preference or utility relative to those that intersect closer to the origin, we can definitely state that, on average, people prefer the Jeep Cherokee to the Toyota 4Runner. We could make similar preference comparisons between any two vehicles in this map and hence order all vehicles in terms of their overall preference. If we constructed separate maps for different segments of the population, we could use the above analysis not only to see how perceptions vary across different groups of people but also to observe how differences in overall preferences relate to these perceptions. Overall Similarity Method For some product categories, it is virtually impossible to determine a priori what attributes consumers might be using to evaluate a product. Consider a movie production company like New Line Cinema, or Hollywood Pictures that is trying to understand how consumers evaluate movies and make decisions on which ones to see at the theatre. What perceptual attributes do consumers use to evaluate a movie? First guesses would include things like amount of action, romance, presence of a particular film star etc. But, movies by their 28 UV0405 -9- nature are not easily described by a precise group of attributes that can be easily specified. For example, the movie About Schmidt is by most accounts an excellent movie. However, unlike the attribute ratings method discussed earlier, it would be very difficult to adequately capture what makes this movie excellent via a list of perceptual attributes. It is simply a more intangible evaluation process than, for example, the evaluation process for sport utility vehicles. For these types of products, the attribute ratings method is a poor way to generate a perceptual map. We must turn to another method, overall similarity, to try to generate a picture of the competitive landscape. Overall Similarity methods work by asking consumers a series of questions designed to determine how similar or dissimilar different pairs of products are to each other. Once the researcher has determined the perceived similarity among all possible products in the competitive set, she can generate a two-dimensional map that graphically reproduces the perceptual distance between and among the products in the set. To see this clearly lets begin with a concrete example focused on current movies. A company like New Line Cinema might begin this process with a list of movies whose preferences they are interested in probing. For the purposes of our example let’s consider the movies About Schmidt, Lord of the Rings: Two Towers, Gangs of New York, Maid in Manhattan, A Guy Thing, and Bowling for Columbine. The researcher would ask an appropriately specified sample of consumers to evaluate how similar each movie is to each other movie. In our example there are six movies and fifteen distinct movie pairs. For each movie pair, say About Schmidt and Bowling for Columbine, there would be a question that reads: About Schmidt and Bowling for Columbine Very Different 1 2 [ ] [ ] 3 [ ] 4 [ ] Very Similar 5 [ ] and a corresponding question for every single product pair. Once this judgment data has been collected, the researcher can simply take the means of the similarity scores and use these means to fill in the perceived similarity matrix. A perceived similarity matrix might look like the following: 29 UV0405 -10Table 2: Movie Similarity Matrix About Schmidt Lord of Rings Gangs of NY Maid in Manhattan A Guy Thing Bowling for Columbine About Lord Schmidt of Rings 5.0 4.2 5.0 3.0 4.0 2.0 1.5 1.0 2.0 3.5 2.5 Gangs Maid in A Guy of NY Manhattan Thing Bowling for Columbine 5.0 1.7 3.4 2.2 5.0 5.0 2.1 1.9 5.0 1.2 These data represent perceptual distances, really the inverse of distances, between the movies. A good perceptual map will reproduce these distances, as closely as possible, in twodimensional space. Reproducing these distances in two-dimensional space is not a simple task. To see this clearly consider the seemingly unrelated analogy of a three-legged stool and a four-legged chair. Which one is more likely to wobble back and forth when you are sitting on it? The answer is obvious, three-legged stools never rocks back and forth but a four-legged chair might. The reason can be tied directly to geometry. Just as it takes two points to define a line, it takes three points (legs) to define a two-dimensional plane (the floor). If you try to match four points (legs) to a two-dimensional plane, there is a chance that they will not all sit perfectly on the surface of any single plane. In mathematics this is called an “overidentified” space. For our purposes, this means that, whenever we have more than three products whose perceptual distances we want to reproduce in two-dimensional space, we are unlikely to be able to do it perfectly. The best we can hope for is to find a solution that reproduces these distances as closely as possible. The process of uncovering this solution is called multidimensional scaling, and because the perceptual data we collect is cardinal rather than ordinal the specific technique presented here is termed metric multidimensional scaling. Much like linear regression, the way metric multidimensional scaling (MMDS) reproduces these perceptual distances is in a way that minimizes the sum of squared errors between the actual distances (given in Table 2) and the distances reproduced on the map. The function that the procedure seeks to minimize is commonly called a “stress function” and is given by the equation: Stress = ∑ i< j (dˆij − d ij ) 2 where d̂ ij are the distances specified on the perceptual map and dij are the actual perceptual distances found in Table 2. The subscripts i and j indicate that the given distance is between product i and j. There are a number of algorithms that MMDS can use to minimize this function, 30 UV0405 -11- but these algorithms are included as easy-to-execute procedures in common statistical software. A discussion of these algorithms is beyond the scope of this technical note. Inserting the data in Table 2 into a MMDS procedure produces the following twodimensional map. MDS for Movie Data Final Configuration, dimension 1 vs. dimension 2 1.0 0.8 MAID BOWL 0.6 Dimension 2 0.4 0.2 SCHMIDT 0.0 -0.2 -0.4 RINGS -0.6 -0.8 -1.0 AGUY NYGANGS -0.6 -0.2 0.2 0.6 1.0 1.4 Dimension 1 Two things stand out from this procedure. First, there are no axes. This is because the procedure only finds distances among the products, not their relationships to any axis. In fact, you can take the above map and turn it upside down, sideways, or rotate it in any way you wish, and it is still the solution to the minimization problem. Second, and as a direct consequence of the first point, this procedure does not identify the perceptual dimensions of the map. So, unlike the attribute-rating method, the researcher must now decide where to draw the axes and what the axes should be named. The most common way to specify the names and position of the axes is for the researcher to use her/his knowledge of the category to define them. This may seem arbitrary, and in some respects it is, but often the position of the products in the space suggests some perceptual dimensions that weren’t obvious to the researcher before the data collection began. We leave it to the reader of this note to speculate about the dimensions of this particular map. 31 -12- UV0405 A Common Theme These two methods for producing perceptual maps, attribute-rating and overall-similarity, both have the ability to depict important relationships among competitive products in twodimensional space. If the researcher believes he/she knows the relevant attributes in consumers’ decision processes, then the attribute-rating method is generally preferred as it leads to a more easily interpretable perceptual map. If the researcher is not willing to specify a group of potentially important perceptual attributes, then the overall-similarity method can be used. The rational behind making a choice between these methods is similar to the trite expression, “pay me now or pay me later.” The attribute-rating method requires more managerial insight and more data collection up-front but has the benefit of an easily interpretably map as an output. The overall-similarity method requires less initial insight and judgment and uses a significantly simpler data collection procedure. The cost of this ease is a map, which management must exercise considerable judgment to interpret. 32 Harvard Business School 9-297-028 Rev. October 29, 1996 Clarkson Lumber Company After a rapid growth in its business during recent years, the Clarkson Lumber Company, in the spring of 1996, anticipated a further substantial increase in sales. Despite good profits, the company had experienced a shortage of cash and had found it necessary to increase its borrowing from the Suburban National Bank to $399,000 in the spring of 1996. The maximum loan that Suburban National would make to any one borrower was $400,000 and Clarkson had been able to stay within this limit only by relying very heavily on trade credit. In addition, Suburban was now asking that Mr. Clarkson guarantee the loan personally. Keith Clarkson, sole owner and president of the Clarkson Lumber Company, was therefore actively looking elsewhere for a new banking relationship where he would be able to negotiate a larger loan that did not require a personal guarantee. Mr. Clarkson had recently been introduced by a friend to George Dodge, an officer of a much larger bank, the Northrup National Bank. The two men had tentatively discussed the possibility that the Northrup bank might extend a line of credit to Clarkson Lumber up to a maximum amount of $750,000. Mr. Clarkson thought that a loan of this size would improve profitability by allowing him to take full advantage of trade discounts. Subsequent to this discussion, Mr. Dodge had arrange for the credit department of the Northrup National Bank to investigate Mr. Clarkson and his company. The Clarkson Lumber Company had been founded in 1981 as a partnership by Mr. Clarkson and his brother-in-law, Henry Holtz. In 1994, Mr. Clarkson bought out Mr. Holtz’s interest for $200,000. Mr. Holtz had taken a note for $200,000, to be paid off in 1995 and 199 6 in order to give Mr. Clarkson time to arrange for the necessary financing. This note carried an interest rate of 11%, and was repayable in semi-annual installments of $50,000, beginning June 30, 1995. The business was located in a growing suburb of a large city in the Pacific Northwest. The company owned land with access to a railroad siding, and four large storage buildings had been erected on this land. The company’s operations were limited to the retail distribution of lumber products in the local area. Typical products included plywood moldings and sash and door products. Quantity discounts and credit terms of net 30 days on open account were usually offered to customers. Sales volume had been built up largely on the basis of successful price competition, made possible by careful control of operating expenses and by quantity purchases of materials at substantial discounts. Most of the moldings and sash and door products, which constituted significant items of sales, were used for repair work. About 55% of total sales were made in the six months from April through September. Annual sales of $2,921,000 in 1993, $3,477,000 in 1994, and $4,51 9,000 in 1995 yielded aftertax profits of $60,000 in 1993, $68,000 in 1994, and $77,000 in 1995. This case was prepared as the basis for class discussion rather than to illustrate either effective or ineffective handling of an administrative situation. Copyright © 1996 by the President and Fellows of Harvard College. To order copies or request permission to reproduce materials, call 1-800-545-7685 or write Harvard Business School Publishing, Boston, MA 02163. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, used in a spreadsheet, or transmitted in any form or by any means—electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording, or otherwise—without the permi ssion of Harvard Business School. 1 33 297-028 Clarkson Lumber Company Operating statements for the years 1993-1995 and for the three months ending March 31, 1996 are given in Exhibit 1. Mr. Clarkson was an energetic man, 49 years of age, who worked long hours on the job. He was helped by an assistant, who in the words of the investigator of the Northrup National Bank, “has been doing and can do about everything that Mr. Clarkson does in the organization.” Other employees numbered 15 in early 1996, 8 of whom worked in the yard and drove trucks, and 7 of whom assisted in the office and in sales. As part of its customary investigation of prospective borrowers, the Northrup National Bank sent inquiries concerning Mr. Clarkson to a number of firms that had business dealings with him. The manager of one of his large suppliers, the Barker Company, wrote in answer: The conservative operation of his business appeals to us. He has not wasted his money in disproportionate plant investment. His operating expenses are as low as they could possibly be. He has personal control over every feature of his business, and he possesses sound judgment and a willingness to work harder than anyone I have ever known. This, with a good personality, gives him a good turnover; and from my personal experience in watching him work, I know that he keeps close check on his own credits. All the other trade letters received by the bank bore out this opinion. In addition to owning the lumber business, which was his major source of income, Mr. Clarkson held jointly with his wife, an equity in their home. The house had cost $72,000 to build in 1979 and was mortgaged for $38,000. He also held a $70,000 life insurance policy, payable to Mrs. Clarkson. Mrs. Clarkson owned independently a half interest in a house worth about $85,000. Otherwise, they had no sizable personal investments. The bank gave particular attention to the debt position and current ratio of the business. It noted the ready market for the company’s products at all times and the fact that sales prospects were favorable. The bank’s investigator reported: “Sales are expected to reach $5.5 million in 1996 and may exceed this level if prices of lumber should rise substantially in the near future.” On the other hand, it was recognized that a general economic downturn might slow down the rate of increase in sales. Clarkson Lumber’s sales, however, were protected to some degree from fluctuations in new housing construction because of the relatively high proportion of its repair business. Projections beyond 1996 were difficult to make, but the prospects appeared good for a continued growth in the volume of Clarkson Lumber’s business over the foreseeable future. The bank also noted the rapid increase in Clarkson Lumber’s accounts and notes payable in the recent past, especially in 1995 and in the spring of 1996. The usual terms of purchase in the trade provided for a discount of 2% for payments made within 10 days of the invoice date. Accounts were due in 30 days at the invoice price, but suppliers ordinarily did not object if payments lagged somewhat behind the due date. During the last two years, Mr. Clarkson had taken very few purchase discounts because of the shortage of funds arising from his purchase of Mr. Holtz’s interest in the business and the additional investments in working capital associated with the company’s increasing sales volume. Trade credit was seriously extended in the spring of 1996 as Mr. Clarkson strove to hold his bank borrowing within the $400,000 ceiling imposed by the Suburban National Bank. Balance sheets at December 31, 1993 through 1995 and March 31, 1996, are presented in Exhibit 2. Statistics for a sample of lumber outlets are provided in Exhibit 3. 2 34 Clarkson Lumber Company 297-028 The tentative discussions between Mr. Dodge and Mr. Clarkson had been in terms of a revolving, secured, 90-day note not to exceed $750,000. The specific details of the loan had not been worked out, but Mr. Dodge had explained that the agreement would involve the standard covenants applying to such a loan. He cited as illustrative provisions the requirement that restrictions on additional borrowing would be imposed; that net working capital would have to be maintained at an agreed level; that additional investments in fixed assets could be made only with the prior approval of the bank; and that limitations would be placed on withdrawals of funds from the business by Mr. Clarkson. Interest would be set on a floating rate basis at 2´ percentage points above the pri me rate. Mr. Dodge indicated that the initial rate to be paid would be approximately 11.0% under conditions in effect in early 1996. Both men also understood that Mr. Clarkson would sever his relationship with the Suburban National Bank if he entered into a loan agreement with the Northrup National Bank. 3 35 297-028 Clarkson Lumber Company Exhibit 1 Operating Expenses for Years Ending December 31, 1993-1995, and for First Quarter 1996 (thousands of dollars) 1994 1995 $2,921 $3,477 $4,519 $1,062 330 2,209 337 2,729 432 3,579 587 819 $2,539 337 $3,066 432 $4,011 587 $1,406 607 $2,202 $2,634 $3,424 $799 Gross profit b Operating expenses 719 622 843 717 1,095 940 263 244 Earnings before interest and taxes Interest expense $97 23 $126 42 $155 56 $19 13 Net income before income taxes c Provision for income taxes $74 14 $84 16 $99 22 $6 1 Net income $60 $68 $77 $5 Net sales Cost of Goods Sold: Beginning inventory Purchases Ending inventory Total Cost of Goods Sold a 1st Quarter 1996 1993 a In the first quarter of 1995, sales were $903,000 and net income was $7,000 b Operating expenses include a cash salary for Mr. Clarkson of $75,000 in 1993; $80,000 in 1994; $85,000 in 1995; and $22,500 in the first quarter of 1996. c Clarkson Lumber was required to estimate its income tax liability for the current tax year and pay four quarterly estimated tax installments during that year. The first $50,000 of pretax profits were taxed at a 15% rate; the next $25,000 were taxed at a 25% rate; the next $25,000 were taxed at a 34% rate; and profits in excess of $100,000 but less than $335,000 were taxed at a 39% rate. 4 36 Clarkson Lumber Company Exhibit 2 297-028 Balance Sheets at December 31, 1993-1995, and March 31, 1996 (thousands of dollars) 1993 $ Current assets Property, net $686 233 $ 895 262 $1,249 388 $1,243 384 Total Assets $919 $1,157 $1,637 $1,627 Notes payable, bank b Note payable to Holtz, current portion Notes payable, trade Accounts payable Accrued expenses c Term loan, current portion $ $ 60 100 -340 45 20 $ 390 100 127 376 75 20 $ 399 100 123 364 67 20 Current liabilities c Term loan b Note payable, Mr. Holtz $275 140 -- $ 565 120 100 $1,088 100 0 $1,073 100 0 Total Liabilities Net worth $415 504 $ 785 372 $1,188 449 $1,173 454 $919 $1,157 $1,637 $1,627 Total Liabilities and Net Worth b $ 56 606 587 1st Quarter 1996 $ 43 306 337 ---213 42 20 52 411 432 1995 Cash Accounts receivable, net Inventory a a 1994 $ 53 583 607 Interest is computed on the average outstanding loan balance at the rate of prime plus 2 ´%. Interest is fixed at 11% times the outstanding balance. c Interest is fixed at 10.0% times the outstanding balance; the term loan is secured by the fixed assets and is repayable in semiannual installments of $10,000. 5 37 297-028 Exhibit 3 Clarkson Lumber Company Selected Statistics on Lumber Outlets Low-Profit a Outlets High-Profit a Outlets Cost of goods 76.9% 75.1% Operating expense 22.0 20.6 Percent of sales: Cash 1.3 1.1 Accounts receivable 13.7 12.4 Inventory 12.0 11.6 Fixed assets, net 12.1 9.2 Total Assets 39.1 34.3 Percent of Total Assets: Current liabilities 52.7% 29.2% Long-term liabilities 34.8 16.0 Equity 12.5 54.8 Current ratio 1.31 2.52 Return on sales (0.7%) 4.3% Return on assets (1.8%) 12.2% Return on equity (14.3%) 22.1% a Defined as the bottom 25% and as the top 25% of all contributors, based on return on sales. 6 38 Friday, September 30 Global Executive MBA in Shanghai GEMBA VIII – Theme 3A General Manager as Integrator 29 Sept – 3 Oct 2011, Shanghai Jiao Tong University, Shanghai Professors Ty Callahan (Finance and Business Economics) and Joe Nunes (Marketing) All assigned readings and cases for all the week's sessions need to be read and studied before the first session at SJTU. Focus on reading and being prepared to discuss the cases! Friday, 30 September 08:30 Marketing Session 4 – Professor Nunes Topic: Conjoint Analysis and Product Design Required Reading: Wilcox, Ronald T.: “A Practical Guide to Conjoint Analysis”, UV0406 09:45 Break 10:00 Marketing Session 5 – Professor Nunes Topic: Breakout Sessions This session will include time to complete earlier lectures and ensure comprehension, as well as time to meet as teams with the instructor. 11:15 Break 11:30 Marketing Session 6 – Professor Nunes Topic: Pricing, Cost Curves and Market Price Evolution Required Readings: - Dhebar, Anirudh: “Price-Quantity Determination”, HBS 9-191-093 - Steenburgh, Thomas and Jill Avery: “Marketing Analysis Toolkit: Pricing and Profitability Analysis”, HBS 9-511-028 Due: Exercise 1 – Markstrat Familiarity Assignment: Exercise 2 – Reading Perceptual Maps 12:45 Lunch 13:45 Finance Session 3 – Professor Callahan Topic: Introduction to Capital Structure Choices This session is the first of three sessions in which we examine the concepts, theories, and evidence concerning corporate capital structure GEMBA VIII, Theme 3A, 29 Sept to 3 Oct, 2011, daily syllabus 39 Page: 1 / 3 Global Executive MBA in Shanghai (i.e., the debt/equity mix, or amount of leverage, used to finance a firm). We will start by understanding how changes in a firm’s leverage change the allocation of operating cash flows and operating risk among the firm’s debt holders and equity holders. Next we will look at how the tax deductibility of interest payments to debt holders can increase firm value and decrease a firm’s cost of capital. Required Reading: RWJ Chapters 15 and 16 Discussion Questions: 1. What are the differences in the cash flow rights, control rights, and risk profile of debt versus equity? 2. How does an increase in corporate leverage change the allocation of operating risk between debt and equity? 3. Does US (and most other countries’) corporate tax law favor equity or debt? To do before this session: - Review readings - Prepare answers to discussion questions 15:00 Break 15:15 Finance Session 4 – Professor Callahan Topic: Capital Structure – Additional Considerations In this session we discuss a host of factors that can play a significant role in firms’ capital structure choices. Potential downsides of debt include the risk of bankruptcy and a negative impact on the firm’s relations with customers, employees, and suppliers. Debt can also restrict a firm’s operating flexibility. Excessive debt can create incentives for stockholders to under or overinvest relative to the firm’s optimal investment policy. Potential upsides of debt include its disciplinary effect on managers and the confidence it can project to financial markets. Upsides of equity include maintaining financial flexibility and its use as a form of compensation. Downsides of equity are the potentially negative signal its use sends to financial markets. Required Reading: RWJ Chapters 17 and 30 Discussion Questions: GEMBA VIII, Theme 3A, 29 Sept to 3 Oct, 2011, daily syllabus 40 Page: 2 / 3 Global Executive MBA in Shanghai 1. Why are financial distress costs generally considered to be much greater than bankruptcy costs? 2. What are two ways in which equity holders might gain at the expense of debt holders and what mechanisms can debt holders use to try and protect themselves? 3. How can debt and equity encourage managers to be thrifty and hardworking? 4. What inferences do markets make about firm value when a firm issues debt? When a firm issues equity? To do before this session: - Review readings - Prepare answers to discussion questions 16:30 Break 16:45 In-Class Pub session GEMBA VIII, Theme 3A, 29 Sept to 3 Oct, 2011, daily syllabus 41 Page: 3 / 3 UV0406 A PRACTICAL GUIDE TO CONJOINT ANALYSIS Introduction Conjoint analysis is a marketing research technique designed to help managers determine the preferences of customers and potential customers. In particular, it seeks to determine how consumers value the different attributes that make up a product and the tradeoffs they are willing to make among the different attributes or features that comprise the product. As such, conjoint analysis is best suited for products that have very tangible attributes that can be easily described or quantified. While the history of conjoint analysis can be traced to early work in mathematical psychology,1 its popularity has grown tremendously over the last few years as access to easy-touse software has allowed its widespread implementation. There have been probably hundreds of applications of conjoint analysis in industrial settings.2 Some of the more important questions modern conjoint analysis is used to analyze are the following: 1. Predicting the market share of a proposed new product, given the current offerings of competitors. 2. Predicting the impact of a new competitive product on the market share of any given product in the marketplace. 3. Determining consumers’ willingness-to-pay for a proposed new product 4. Quantifying the trade-offs customers or potential customers are willing to make among the various attributes or features that are under consideration in the new product design. 1 R.D. Luce and J. W. Tukey, “Simultaneous Conjoint Measurement: A New Type of Fundamental Measurement,” Journal of Mathematical Psychology 1 (February 1964): 1–27. 2 P.E. Green, A.M. Kreiger, and Y. Wind, “Thirty Years of Conjoint Analysis: Reflections and Prospects,” Interfaces 31 (May–June 2001): S56–S73. This technical note was written by Associate Professor Ronald T. Wilcox. Copyright © 2003 by the University of Virginia Darden School Foundation, Charlottesville, VA. All rights reserved. To order copies, send an e-mail to sales@dardenpublishing.com. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, used in a spreadsheet, or transmitted in any form or by any means—electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording, or otherwise—without the permission of the Darden School Foundation. Rev. 11/03. 42 -2- UV0406 The Anatomy of a Conjoint Analysis Literally, conjoint analysis means an analysis of features considered jointly. The idea is that, while it is difficult for consumers to tell us directly how much each feature of a product is worth to them, we can infer the value of an individual feature of a product by experimentally manipulating the features of a product and observing consumers’ ratings for that product or choices among competing products. To fix your intuition here, consider the simple example of a sports car. It would be difficult for the average consumer to tell a market researcher exactly how much more valuable a car with 240 horsepower is to them relative to one with 220. It is possible that a consumer might be able to come up with some dollar value, but that value may not really reflect the way they would make choices if faced with a real marketplace situation. Instead, marketers have found that it is much more accurate to present individuals from the target market with a series of cars, described not only by their horsepower but by other attributes as well (color, price, standard/automatic transmission, etc.) and then ask them to rate each of the cars on a numerical scale. Alternatively, the researcher presents several competing cars with different attributes and asks the consumer to choose one. By repeatedly asking the potential customers to rate the cars or chose a car from a competing set, the researcher can infer the value of each individual attribute. This is the essence of a conjoint analysis; replacing the relatively inaccurate method of asking about each attribute in isolation with a model that allows us to infer the attributes’ values from a series of ratings or choices. The Experimental Design A conjoint analysis begins with an experimental design. This design includes all attributes and the values of the attributes that will be tested. Conjoint analysis distinguishes between attributes and what are generally called “levels.” An attribute is self-explanatory. It could be price, color, horsepower, material used for upholstery, or presence of a sunroof, while a level is the specific value or realization of the attribute. For example, the attribute “color” may have the levels “red,” “blue,” and “yellow,” while the attribute “presence of a sunroof” will have levels “yes” and “no.” Before a researcher begins to collect data, it is important that all the levels of each attribute to be tested are written down. Commercially available software packages require that the user provide these as input. 43 UV0406 -3- Continuing with our car example, an experimental design might look like the information presented in Table 1: Table 1. Example of experimental design. Levels Price $23,000 $25,000 $27,000 $29,000 Brand Toyota Volkswagen Saturn Kia Horsepower 220 HP 250 HP 280 HP Upholstery Cloth Leather Sunroof Yes No This is a very simple design that contains a total of 15 attribute levels. Real designs often contain more attributes and levels than are presented here. When constructing an experimental design, it is important to keep in mind: 1. The more tangible and understandable the levels of each attribute are to the respondents, the more valid the results of the research will be. For example, attribute levels such as “really roomy” are vague, meaning different things to different people and should be avoided. 2. The greater the number of attribute levels to be tested, the more data that will be needed to achieve the same degree of output accuracy. 3. For quantitative variables (price and horsepower in this example), the greater the distance between any two consecutive levels, the harder it will be to get a good idea of how a consumer might evaluate something in between the two (i.e., $24,000). Data Collection Collecting data for a conjoint analysis has been made relatively simple by the advent of dedicated off-the-shelf software. The exact nature of the data collected will be dictated by the type of conjoint analysis that is used. An exhaustive discussion of the benefits and drawbacks of each of the many different types of conjoint analysis now in use is beyond the scope of this technical note. However, those interested are encouraged to read Orme for a good discussion of this topic.3 The state-of-the-art in conjoint data collection involves using personal computers or a Web-based version of the software to guide respondents through an interactive conjoint survey. The software creates the hypothetical product profiles using the experimental design provided by the researcher and estimates the attribute-level utilities from participant ratings or choices. 3 B. Orme, “Which Conjoint Method Should I Use?” Sawtooth Software Technical Paper (2003). Currently, an Acrobat-readable copy of this paper is available at http://www.sawtoothsoftware.com/techabs.shtml#which. 44 UV0406 -4Interpreting Conjoint Results Understanding the basic output The basic results of a conjoint analysis are the estimated attribute level utilities. Keeping with the example in Table 1, conjoint output might look like Table 2: Table 2. Conjoint analysis output. Attribute Price Brand Horsepower Upholstery Sunroof Level $23,000 $25,000 $27,000 $29,000 Toyota Volkswagen Saturn Kia 220 HP 250 HP 280 HP Cloth Leather Yes No Utility (Part-worth) 2.10 1.15 −1.56 −1.69 0.75 0.65 −0.13 −1.27 −2.24 1.06 1.18 −1.60 1.60 0.68 −0.68 t-value 14.00 7.67 10.40 11.27 5.00 4.33 0.87 8.47 14.93 7.07 7.87 10.67 10.67 4.53 4.53 The estimated utilities or part-worths correspond to average consumer preferences for the level of any given attribute. Within a given attribute, the estimated utilities are generally scaled in such a way that they add up to zero. So a negative number does not mean that a given level has “negative utility”; it just means that this level is on average less preferred than a level with an estimated utility that is positive. Conjoint analysis output is also often accompanied by t-values, a standard metric for evaluating statistical significance. Because of the way conjoint utilities are scaled, the standard interpretation of t-values can yield misleading results. For example, the level “Saturn” of the attribute “Brand” has a t-value of 0.87. In general, a t-value of this magnitude would fail a test of statistical significance. However, this t-value is generated because within the attribute “Brand” the level “Saturn” has neither a very high nor very low relative preference. It is basically in the middle in terms of overall preference. Because of the scaling, levels that have more moderate levels of preference within a given attribute are likely to have estimated utilities close to zero, which will tend to produce very low t-values (recall that the t-test is measuring the probability that the true value of a parameter is not different from zero). 45 -5- UV0406 A better way to think about statistical significance in this context is to examine the tvalues of the levels with the highest and lowest preference within a given attribute. An applicable common practice would be if the sum of the absolute value of these two statistics is greater than three, then that given attribute is significant in the overall choice process of consumers. At a practical level, it is rare that an attribute will not be significant, and, if you find one that is, it means that it probably should not have been included in the experimental design in the first place, because respondents are not considering that attribute’s information when they make choices. Conjoint Analysis Applications As mentioned previously, there are many different possible applications of conjoint analysis. We will focus on three very common applications: trade-off analysis, predicting market share, and determining overall attribute importances. Trade-off analysis The utility of any given product that we might consider can be easily computed by simply summing the utilities of its attribute levels. For example, a Toyota with 280 horsepower, leather interior, no sunroof, and a price of $23,000 has a utility of 0.75 + 1.18 + 1.60 − 0.68 + 2.10 = 4.95. If the car with same basic specifications were a Volkswagen, the overall utility would drop to 0.65 + 1.18 + 1.60 − 0.68 + 2.10 = 4.85, a drop of 0.10. This drop can be seen directly by noticing that the difference between the utility for the brand Toyota (0.75) and Volkswagen (0.65) is 0.10 and because nothing else in the profile of the car has changed this will be the exact utility difference between two cars that are the same except for this brand difference. A natural consequence of the above observation is that we use the utilities to analyze what average consumers would be willing to give up on one particular attribute to gain improvements in another. For example, how much money would they be willing to give up (price) if a sunroof was added to the vehicle? We will now look directly at this issue of the hypothetical car detailed in the previous paragraph. Adding a sunroof to the (Toyota) car would yield an overall utility of 0.75 + 1.18 + 1.60 + 0.68 + 2.10 = 6.31. This represents an increase in utility of 6.31 – 4.95 = 1.36 over the identical car without a sunroof. The information above directly implies that we can reduce the utility of price by 1.36, and average consumers would be just as happy as before the sunroof was installed. To find out how much the price can be raised, we must convert the change in utility with a change in price. We do this by first noting how much the original car costs ($23,000) and the utility associated with that figure, 2.10. We know that we can reduce the price utility by 1.36. This is equivalent to saying that we can reduce the price utility to 2.10 – 1.36 = 0.74. By referring to Table 2, we can immediately see that this implies a price between $25,000 and $27,000 because −1.56 < 0.74 < 1.15. In fact, if we assume a linear relationship between price and utility in the range between 46 UV0406 -6- $25,000 and $27,000, we can solve for the exact price by performing a linear interpolation within this range.4 Specifically, the interpolation yields: $25,000 + 1.15 − 0.74 × $2,000 = $25,302.58 1.15 − (−1.56) Utility spread between the two tested price points (25K and 27K). Utility spread between 25K and the target utility. This implies that, if the sunroof is added, the price of the vehicle could be raised from $23,000 to about $25,300, and the average consumer’s attitude would be one of indifference between the two vehicles. Qualitatively, it shows that the value of a sunroof to consumers is very substantial. This same kind of analysis can be performed for other attributes. We could ask how much additional horsepower we would need to add if the interior was changed from leather to cloth. This particular question does present a problem, however. Because the current vehicle under consideration has 280 horsepower, and that is the maximum amount of horsepower tested by the conjoint analysis, it will be impossible to determine how much consumers will value additional horsepower. This leads to an important consideration when constructing the experimental design. That is, if the output is to be used for trade-off analysis, it is important that the range of the levels tested within each attribute span the entire range of that attribute before management would ever consider it as a realistic design alternative. If the experimental design takes this into account, we can perform trade-off analysis between any two attributes in the design. Market share forecasting Another common application is forecasting market share. In order to use conjoint output for this kind of prediction, two conditions must be satisfied: 1. The company must know the other products, besides their own offering, that a consumer is likely to consider when making a selection in the category. 2. Each of these competitive products’ important features must be included in the experimental design. In other words, you must be able to calculate the utility of not only your own product offering but that of the competitive products as well. 4 This is a common way to approximate the relationship between the value of the attribute and its utility for attribute values that were not directly tested by the conjoint analysis. The closer the tested levels are to each other the more accurate this approximation. Also notice that this interpolation can only be performed for quantitative attributes such as price. Interpolating between qualitative attributes, like brand, is nonsensical. 47 UV0406 -7- Market share prediction relies on the use of a multinomial logit model.5 The basic form of the logit model is: Sharei = ∑ eU i n j =1 Uj e where: Ui is the estimated utility of product i Uj is the estimated utility of product j n is the total number of products in the competitive set, including product i. To make things clear, consider the following example. Suppose we are interested in predicting the market share of a car with the following profile: Saturn; $23,000; 220 HP; cloth interior; no sunroof. We believe that when consumers consider our car they will also consider purchasing cars that are currently on the market with the following profiles: 1. $27,000; Toyota; 250 HP; cloth interior; no sunroof 2. $29,000; Volkswagen; 280 HP; leather interior; no sunroof 3. $23,000; Kia; 220 HP; cloth interior; no sunroof For the Saturn and its associated product profile the estimated utility is 2.10 – 0.13 – 2.24 – 1.60 – 0.68 = − 2.55. Similarly, the utilities of the three competing products can be calculated: 1. −1.56 + 0.75 + 1.06 – 1.60 – 0.68 = −2.03 2. −1.69 + 0.65 + 1.18 + 1.60 – 0.68 = 1.06 3. 2.10 – 1.27 – 2.24 – 1.60 – 0.68 = −3.69 With these utilities in hand we can now directly apply the logit model to forecast market share for the Saturn. This is given by: ShareSaturn = e −2.55 = .025 or 2.5% e − 2.55 + e − 2.03 + e1.06 + e − 3.69 This implies that this particular Saturn vehicle will achieve a 2.5% market share within the specified competitive set. The market share of any vehicle that can be described by the experimental design and a set of competitive vehicles, also described by the experimental design, can be found in a similar manner. 5 A good marketing reference to learn about the basics of the logit model is G. Lilien and A. Rangaswamy, Marketing Engineering: Computer-Assisted Marketing Analysis and Planning (2nd Ed.), Englewood Cliffs: Prentice-Hall (2002). Also, most econometrics textbooks will have information on logit models. 48 UV0406 -8Determining attribute importance A researcher may also be interested in determining the importance of any individual attribute in the consumers’ decision processes. Quantifying these attribute importances using the conjoint output is straightforward and can provide both interesting and useful insights into consumer behavior. Intuitively, the variance of the estimated utilities within a given attribute tells you something about how important the attribute is in the choice process. Take, for example, the attributes “Sunroof” and “Upholstery,” both of which have only two levels. If you understand the material up to this point, it should be reasonably clear that “Upholstery” is a more important attribute than “Sunroof.” That is because the utility difference between having a sunroof and not having a sunroof (2 × 0.68 = 1.36) is smaller than the utility difference between having leather versus cloth interior (2 × 1.60 = 3.20). The common metric used to measure attribute importances is: Ii = ∑ Ui −U i n j =1 U j −U j where: Ii = the importance of any given attribute i U = the highest utility level within a given attribute (subscripts indicate which attribute) U = the lowest utility level within a given attribute. This equation is really quite intuitive. In order to calculate the importance of any given attribute, you just take the difference between the highest and lowest utility level of that attribute and divide this by the sum of the differences between the highest and lowest utility level for all attributes (including the one in question). The resulting number will always lie between zero and one and is generally interpreted as the percent decision weight of an attribute in the overall choice process. It also should be clear at this point that this estimated attribute importance depends critically on your experimental design. In particular, if you increase the distance between the most extreme levels of any given attribute you will almost certainly increase the overall attribute importance. For example, if the tested price range was $21K − $31K instead of $23K – $29K (Table 1), this is very likely to increase the estimate attribute importance of price. Let’s now consider a concrete example using the attribute “Horsepower.” The importance of this attribute is calculated as: 49 -9- I Horsepower = UV0406 1.18 + 2.24 = .25 ((2.10 + 1.69) + (0.75 + 1.27) + (1.18 + 2.24) + (1.60 + 1.60) + (0.68 + 0.68) ) In our example, 25% of the overall decision weight is assigned to horsepower. The reader may verify through analogous calculations that the decision weight for “Price” is about 27%, “Brand” about 15%, “Sunroof” about 10%, and “Upholstery” about 23%. The numbers provide a very intuitive metric for thinking about the importance of each attribute in the decision process. Final Thoughts Conjoint analysis has a broad array of possible applications. Many of these applications are variants of the three very common applications presented here. The increasingly widespread availability of conjoint analysis software, both PC and Web-enabled, points to its continued growth as a marketing decision aid. This note has presented what is generally known as “aggregate-level” conjoint analysis. That is, all of the respondents are pooled into one group, and a single set of attribute level utilities are estimated from the ratings or choices provided by the people in this group. Recent advancements in conjoint analysis have enabled researchers to estimate different utilities for different groups of respondents and even, in some cases, for individual respondents. While the mathematics necessary for this procedure is sometimes quite complex, it is now possible to estimate the attribute level utilities and to compute trade-off analyses for each individual respondent. This has some significant advantages over aggregate level analysis particularly when considering marketing segmentation issues. Either way, the data collection and the basic interpretation of the output remains the same. While there is currently no textbook that can provide the reader with answers to all of the questions that might arise when applying this technique in a business setting, there is, as of this writing, a very good and surprisingly comprehensive collection of technical papers located on the site of a company that markets conjoint analysis software (http://www.sawtoothsoftware.com/techpap.shtml). These provide answers to many of the practical implementation questions a user may face. 50 Harvard Business School 9-191-093 Rev. June 23, 1993 Price-Quantity Determination This note examines some of the economic considerations affecting two basic decisions in business: what price should a firm charge for a product, and what quantity of the product should it make? We begin with a discussion of the appropriate decision criterion (Section 1). In Section 2, we consider the demand curve and see how it establishes a linkage between price and quantity. The heart of the analysis is in Section 3, in which we establish the following decision rule: a necessary condition for optimal price and quantity is that marginal revenue must equal marginal cost. Pricequantity determination in the presence of a resource constraint is analyzed in Section 4. Finally, in Section 5, we comment on the competitive case. 1. The Appropriate Decision Criterion What should be the firm’s objective when determining price and quantity?: To maximize market share? To achieve a certain margin on cost? To maximize return on sales? To attain at least a minimum return on capital employed? Let us consider each of these in turn. It is reasonable for a firm to strive to increase market share. However, should it do so by choosing a price so low that it is not profitable to stay in business? “Cost-plus-margin” is a decision rule that eliminates most of the anxiety surrounding the pricing decision, but does it make sense to achieve the same margin on a product of which the firm is the only supplier as on a product for which there are many suppliers? “Maximize return on sales” and “return on capital employed” have at least two weaknesses. First, since they measure ratios rather than absolute amounts, they can be large not only because the numerator is large (which is good), but also because the denominator is small (which is not necessarily good). Second, both measures can be unduly sensitive to the definition of “return.” The example in Table 1 illustrates these weaknesses in the case of “maximize return on sales.” Should the firm choose Alternative C because it promises the highest return on sales? Clearly not: Alternative C has a higher return on sales, not because it results in a large income, but because sales are low (as indicated earlier, a ratio can be high because the numerator is high, the denominator low, or both; here, the denominator is low). Professor Anirudh Dhebar wrote this note as the basis for class discussion rather than to illustrate either effective or ineffective handling of an administrative situation. Copyright © 1990 by the President and Fellows of Harvard College. To order copies or request permission to reproduce materials, call 1-800-545-7685, write Harvard Business School Publishing, Boston, MA 02163, or go to http://www.hbsp.harvard.edu. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, used in a spreadsheet, or transmitted in any form or by any means—electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording, or otherwise—without the permission of Harvard Business School. 1 51 191-093 Table 1 Price-Quantity Determination Maximize Return on Sales? Sales Direct costs Sales less direct costs Allocated costs* Net Income Return on Sales Alternative A Alternative B $95 million $63 million $32 million $19 million $13 million $70 million $42 million $28 million $14 million $14 million 13.7% 20.0% Alternative C $50 million $28 million $22 million $10 million $12 million 24.0% Note: Company practice requires the allocation of 20% of sales towards the recovery of general and administrative expenses incurred by the firm as a whole—expenses that would be incurred whether the firm chooses Alternative A, B, or C. What about Alternative B, which promises the highest return in absolute terms? This alternative is also not the correct choice: “net income” is the highest under the alternative, but net income is calculated after subtracting allocated costs—costs that do not relate to any of the alternatives and would be incurred irrespective of the alternative that is chosen. (Costs that are specific to an alternative are included in the category “direct costs.”) The appropriate decision criterion for the firm should be the following: choose the alternative that maximizes the present value of the net cash flows to the firm. “Net cash flow” is not the same thing as “net income.” In general, net income is calculated after subtracting allocated costs, expenses deferred for tax purposes, depreciation charges (but not capital cost), accrued expenses, etc. On the other hand, net cash flow calculations focus on the actual cash flows arising from the alternative under consideration. These calculations include depreciation tax benefits and capital costs, but exclude allocated costs and costs incurred before the point in time when the decision is being made; they also adjust for the actual receipt of revenues and actual payment of expenses. We will make the following simplifying assumptions in this note: Revenues and costs are not deferred, there is no depreciation, the tax rate is zero, and cash flows occur at the same point in time (and, therefore, their present value is the sum of the cash flows). Given these assumptions, the net cash flow for each alternative is the difference between “sales” and “direct expenses.” Returning to the example in Table 1, the correct choice is Alternative A: it will give the highest net cash flow—$32 million instead of $28 million (Alternative B) or $22 million (Alternative C). Admittedly, the above argument is somewhat simplistic. Depending on the decision context, one can make very valid arguments for the use of decision criteria such as “maximize return on sales,” or “achieve a certain margin on cost,” or “attain at least a minimum return on capital employed.” Ultimately—and over the long run—however, the firm’s choice must result in an acceptable stream of cash flows to the investors. It is this reasoning that motivates the decision criterion in this note. 2. Price, Quantity, and the Demand Curve Suppose the firm is using the appropriate decision criterion and must decide on the price and quantity for one of its products. Does it have complete freedom in this decision? Usually, it does not—because of one or more of the following factors: limited demand, restricted supply, and threatening competition. We consider demand limitations in this section, supply (capacity) constraints in Section 4, and competition in Section 5. To motivate the concept of limited demand, assume the firm has chosen a price for the product under consideration. Consumers learn of this price and decide whether or not to buy the 2 52 Price-Quantity Determination 191-093 product. This decision is made at the level of the individual consumer, and is based on a comparison of the maximum he or she is willing to pay for the product with the price of the product: the consumer will buy the product only if his or her willingness-to-pay is greater than or equal to the product price. (The difference between a consumer’s willingness-to-pay and the price is known as the consumer surplus; only those with a consumer surplus greater than or equal to zero will buy the product.) What determines a consumer’s willingness to pay for a product? Obviously, the product itself is an important determinant: most of us would pay much more for, say, a car than a wristwatch. For a given product category, willingness-to-pay depends on product features, quality, performance, etc. Thus, for a car, we would usually pay a premium for additional power, space, air conditioning, sun roof, etc. In the case of consumable products (which, unlike durable products, are typically purchased repeatedly and consumed in quantities greater than one), willingness-to-pay for each additional unit of the product typically declines as the total quantity consumed increases (the fifth scoop of ice cream is not worth as much as the first scoop; arguably, it might even be bad for the consumer!). Whether the product is a durable product or a consumable product, the willingness-topay depends on the alternatives available to the consumer: it is usually lower if cheaper alternatives are available from competitors or in the form of perfect or imperfect substitutes. Finally, the consumer’s preferences for the product are determined by his or her income, wealth, consumption budget, and tastes. Since a consumer will buy a product only if his or her willingness-to-pay exceeds its price, and since any population of consumers is typically heterogenous in the willingness-to-pay (some consumers value the product a great deal, others somewhat, and others hardly at all), it follows that only a subset of consumers will choose to buy the product. In other words, demand for the product will be limited. In general, the higher the price, the smaller will be the number of consumers with willingness-to-pay greater than or equal to the price, and, therefore, the smaller will be the demand. On the other hand, the lower the price, the larger will be the number of consumers with willingnessto-pay greater than or equal to the price, and the greater will be the demand. This characteristic can be represented graphically with price on the horizontal axis and demand on the vertical axis (see Figure 1). The resulting curve is called the demand curve for the product: it gives the quantity of the product that consumers will demand as a function of its price. Since demand usually decreases as price increases, demand curves are typically downward-sloping. You can think of the demand curve as a constraint on the firm’s price-quantity decision: once a price is chosen, the quantity is automatically determined, and vice versa. Figure 1 Typical Demand Curve D e m a n d Price 3 53 191-093 Price-Quantity Determination The shape of the demand curve plays an important role in the determination of product price and quantity. An important measure in this context is the elasticity of demand: the per cent increase (decrease) in demand that would result from a one per cent decrease (increase) in price. Figure 2 illustrate two extreme cases of demand elasticity. The curve in Figure 2 (a) is a demand curve for a product with highly elastic demand. Demand is said to be highly elastic with respect to price if small changes in price leads to relatively large changes in demand. Demand for luxury items, e.g., Rolls-Royce cars, tends to be highly elastic. Figure 2 (b) illustrates the demand curve for a product with relatively inelastic demand. Demand is said to be inelastic with respect to price if large changes in price lead to relatively small changes in demand. Demand for the basic necessities of life, e.g., essential food items, tends to be relatively inelastic. Figure 2 (a) Demand Curve for Product with Elastic Demand D e m a n d Figure 2 (b) D e m a n d Price 3. Demand Curve for Product with Inelastic Demand Price Determining the Optimal Price and Quantity We saw in Section 1 that the firm’s goal should be to maximize the difference between the revenues and the costs attributable to a product. In this section, we examine how the firm should choose an optimal price-quantity combination using the information in the product’s demand curve. Before beginning with the analysis, however, we should understand that the firm must make a “gono go” decision as well, i.e., it must also decide whether or not to offer the product in the first place. Interestingly, while in real time, the “go-no go” step must occur first, in the analytical sequence, the firm first chooses the price and the quantity, and then decides whether or not to go ahead with the product. Proceeding with the analysis, calculating revenue is simple: it equals price times quantity. As for direct costs, it is useful to distinguish between costs that vary with quantity (variable costs; e.g., cost of raw materials and direct labor) and costs that do not vary with quantity (direct fixed costs; e.g., product launching costs, cost of “indirect” labor and supervisory product management, rent for space obtained specifically for the product under consideration). Since direct fixed costs do not vary with quantity, they cannot have a bearing on the quantity decision; only variable costs are relevant to this decision, and the decision should be based on the maximization of the difference between revenues and variable costs, i.e., contribution. Of course, direct fixed costs are not completely irrelevant. If the maximum contribution is not sufficient to cover these costs, then the firm should stop making the product. In other words, direct fixed costs are relevant to the “go-no go” decision, but not the quantity decision. (Costs that the firm incurs in connection with its other products and businesses and overall corporate administration do not change whatever the firm decides about the product under consideration; they are not relevant to the quantity decision or the go-no go decision.) 4 54 Price-Quantity Determination 191-093 The firm can determine the contribution-maximizing price and quantity by adopting the following procedure (see Figure 3 and Table 2): Start with a price P1 , read the demand D1 from the demand curve, and calculate the contribution for price P1 ; choose a new price P2 , read the demand D2 from the demand curve, and calculate the contribution for price P2 ; choose a new price P3 , read the demand D3 from the demand curve, and calculate the contribution for price P3 ; choose a new price P4 , read the demand D4 from the demand curve, and calculate the contribution for price P4 ;…; stop when a price is chosen such that the total contribution is as large as possible. The greater the number of points along the demand curve that are sampled, the closer to the true optimum the final answer will be. To see how the above procedure works, let us go back to the demand curve (see Figure 4). The decision maker starts with a low price (not lower than the variable cost per unit, however), and increases it by small amounts, always checking if the benefits from doing so outweigh the costs. Let us say the decision maker has reached point A and is considering whether or not to increase the price to point B. At point A, the area (A+C) represents the firm’s total contribution. Similarly, at point B, the area (B+C) represents the total contribution. Should the firm move from point A to point B? Yes, if area (B+C ) exceeds area (A+C), and not, otherwise. Observe that area (B+C) - area (A+C) = area B - area A = “increase in revenue on account of a higher price” - “decrease in contribution because of decreased demand.” Figure 3 Determining Optimal Price and Quantity D1 D e m a n d D2 D3 D4 v (P3-v) Unit Unit Contribution Variable a t Pric e P3 Cost v P1 P2 P3 P4 Price Table 2 Determining Optimal Price and Quantity Price Demand Unit Variable Cost Unit Contribution Total Contribution P1 P2 P3 P4 • D1 D2 D3 D4 • v v v v • [P1 - v] [P2 - v] [P3 - v] [P4 - v] • [P1 - v] x D1 [P2 - v] x D2 [P3 - v] x D3 [P4 - v] x D4 • 5 55 191-093 Figure 4 Price-Quantity Determination Finding Optimal Price and Quantity: "Marginal Analysis" Unit Variable Cost A Demand at Price PA D e m a n d A C Unit Contribution B B Price at Price P 3 The decision maker should go on increasing price by “one cent” (or “one dollar” or “one per cent”) as long as the “increase in revenue on account of a higher price” exceeds the “decrease in contribution on account of decreased demand.” Ultimately, a point will be reached when the two terms are equal. This is the optimal point. For any further increase in price, “increase in revenue on account of a higher price” will fall short of “decrease in contribution on account of decreased demand.” This is what marginal analysis is all about. Once the firm knows the optimal price and quantity, it should check whether or not the resulting total contribution exceeds the direct fixed costs. The above discussion assumed a constant variable cost per unit of the product: the incremental cost to the firm of the 2nd (but not the 1st!) unit of product is the same as that of the 3rd unit, the 4th unit, the 45th unit, the 7363rd unit, etc. In other words, the cost of producing an additional unit of the product is independent of the total quantity that is produced. In practice, this assumption usually only holds over limited ranges of production quantities. Over large quantity ranges, the unit variable cost may increase (because of some production diseconomies) or decrease (because of production economies) as the total production quantity increases. Furthermore, in some situations, for example, those involving joint products and costs, it may be difficult, if not impossible, to determine the unit variable cost at any level of production. In this note, we will restrict the discussion to the case where the unit variable cost does not change with total production quantity.1 Example You are thinking about launching a new high-tech gizmo, a digital AirTime Hogmeter®. The market for the new product is limited: you do not expect anyone other than first-year students to buy the product, and this is going to be a one-time venture (next year, you will be in the second year and, presumably, will have better things to do with your time). You could give the meters away, in which case all 800 students will pick up the freebies. But you would not want to do that: Oisac Corporation, your Napajese supplier from the Pacific rim, is going to charge you $20 for each meter. What should be the selling price for the meter, and how many meters should you order? 1This assumption does not imply that there are no scale economies. If the direct fixed costs are greater than zero, total cost (variable plus direct fixed) per unit (often used to measure scale economies) will decline even if the unit variable cost is constant. 6 56 Price-Quantity Determination 191-093 The first thing you do is conduct some market research: Will anyone buy the meter for a zillion dollars? No way. How about $1000? No: it is cheaper to keep tab of air time consumption using a $16.95 watch, a sheet of paper, and a pencil. $100? There is some interest, but no one has yet said a definite yes. $80? People are about to sign up, but not quite yet. $79? 10 people have indicated that they will buy the meter for $79. You try $70. Now demand is building up: 100 have indicated a willingness to buy (in the population of 800, 100 have a willingness-to-pay greater than or equal to $70). You discover that 200 will buy if you price the meter at $60, 300 at $50, 400 at $40, 500 at $30, 600 at $20, 700 at $10 (of course, you would not want to do that; the meter costs you $20 a piece!), and 800 for free. You plot this information on a sheet of graph paper, and you have a demand curve (see Figure 5). Figure 5 Demand Curve for AirTime Hogmeter 600 D e m a n d 500 400 300 200 100 0 $20 $30 $40 $50 $60 $70 $80 Price You can find the optimal price and quantity using the procedure described earlier. Table 3 reproduces the methodology in Table 2, and Figure 6 presents a graph of total contribution as a function of price. From Table 3 and Figure 6, we see that contribution is maximized at a price of $50 and a quantity equal to 300. The maximum contribution is $9,000. Not bad. Will it cover your product launching costs and your administrative costs? If so, you should go ahead. Table 2 Determining Optimal Price and Quantity for AirTime Hogmeter Price Demand $20 $30 $40 $50 $60 $70 $80 600 500 400 300 200 100 0 Unit Variable Cost $20 $20 $20 $20 $20 $20 $20 Unit Contribution Total Contribution $0 $10 $20 $30 $40 $50 $60 $0 $5,000 $8,000 $9,000 $8,000 $5,000 $0 7 57 191-093 Price-Quantity Determination Figure 6 4. Determining Optimal Price and Quantity for AirTime Hogmeter Price-Quantity Determination with a Resource Constraint In Section 3, we saw how the demand curve acts as a constraint on the firm’s choice of price and quantity. In this section, we consider price-quantity determination in the presence of a resource constraint. Specifically, we examine a case with two products—an existing product, Product A, and a new product, Product B. While the two products are unrelated, they are made with the help of a common resource, only a limited amount of which is available. Suppose the firm is selling Product A for $50. The direct fixed cost of making the product is $15,000 and the variable cost per unit is $10 (the first unit costs the firm $15,010; each additional unit costs an incremental $10). Demand for Product A is very high—demand the firm is unable to meet because of limited manufacturing capacity: it takes four hours to machine each unit of the product, and only 2,000 hours of machine time are available, restricting production to 500 units. At this production level, the firm makes a total contribution of $20,000 (unit contribution $40 times 500 units), and a net cash flow of $5,000 (after paying the $15,000 direct fixed cost for Product A). Consider Product B. The firm must first determine whether it is beneficial to divert any machining capacity from Product A to Product B. Suppose the firm diverts four hours of machining capacity from Product A to Product B. This would result in a drop in the production of Product A by one unit (from 500 to 499 units), and a reduction in total contribution of $40. Clearly, the firm should divert capacity to Product B only if it can manufacture enough Product B in the four hours to offset the contribution loss. Suppose it takes two hours to machine each unit of Product B. Then, in four hours, the firm can machine two units of the product. It follows that Product B should be made only if the contribution realized from the sale of one unit of the product exceeds $20 ($40, the drop in contribution from making one unit less of Product A, divided by the two units of Product B that can be made in the same amount of time). We could repeat the above analysis, now for a diversion of one hour of machine time from Product A to Product B. In that case, the firm would make one-quarter units less of Product A, and the total contribution would go down by $10 (unit contribution of $40 times one-quarter units; assume that the firm can sell fractional units of the product). In the one hour that is freed up, the firm can make one-half units of Product B, from the sale of which it must obtain a contribution of at least $10 for the whole exercise to be worthwhile. We conclude that the “breakeven” contribution for one hour of machine time is $10 ($40, the unit contribution for the existing product, Product A, divided by 4 hours, the machining time for Product A); we call this breakeven value the opportunity cost of the scarce machining resource. The breakeven contribution for Product B is $20 (opportunity cost for the machine constraint times two hours, the machining time for Product B). 8 58 Price-Quantity Determination 191-093 We have seen that the firm should manufacture Product B only if the unit contribution is $20 or greater. Suppose the unit variable cost of Product B is $6 (there is also a direct fixed cost; we will consider it later). Then, machining capacity should be diverted from Product A to Product B only if each unit of the latter can be sold for more than $26. Of course, the firm can charge a higher price. To determine the optimal price, the decision maker should work with the demand curve for Product B and use the procedure described in Section 3. Suppose this price is $36 and the corresponding optimal quantity 600 units. Then, the maximum contribution that the firm can realize from Product B is $18,000 ($36, selling price, minus $6, unit variable cost, times 600, quantity). Making 600 units of Product B will take 1,200 hours of machine time (600 units times two, the machining time per unit). The firm has 2,000 hours of machine time at its disposal. Should it use the balance 800 hours to make more Product B? The answer is “No”: 600 is the optimal production quantity—the level at which contribution is maximized. Should the remaining 800 hours of machine time be used to produce Product A, the demand for which is unlimited? In 800 hours, the firm can machine 200 units of Product A (800 divided by four, the machining time for each unit of the product), and sell these units for a total contribution of $8,000 (200 units times $40, the unit contribution for Product A). Unfortunately, the direct fixed cost for Product A is $15,000. And $8,000 is less than $15000! The conclusion: the firm should not use the balance time to make any Product A. The analysis is not yet complete. We have not answered the basic question: Should the firm make the new product, Product B? Here is where the direct fixed cost for Product B is relevant. Clearly, Product B should not be made if the direct fixed cost for the product exceeds $18,000, the maximum contribution from the product. Suppose the direct fixed cost for Product B is less than $18,000. Should the firm make Product B? It depends. Remember that the firm is already making $20,000 in contribution from Product A, for a net cash flow of $5,000 after paying for its direct fixed cost. Clearly, Product B should only be made if the net cash flow realized from it will exceed $5,000. For this, the direct fixed cost for Product B must be less than $13,000 ($18,000, the contribution from 600 units of the product sold at a price of $36, minus $5,000, the existing cash flow from Product A). It would be worth your while repeating the above analysis with a different set of numbers. Explore alternative scenarios: When should the firm make Product A alone? Product B alone? Both Product A and Product B? The answers to these questions will depend on the machining times for the two products, the total amount of machine time available, the respective variable and fixed costs, Product A’s selling price, and the contribution-maximizing price and quantity for Product B. 5. Competition How does competition affect the firm’s choice of price and quantity? In general, this is a difficult question to answer with any degree of analytical precision. Still, formal—albeit stylized— analysis often helps, offering insight and indicating beneficial courses of action for the firm. To be sure, the competitive decision context is usually quite complex: the different competitors may have different costs, capacities, and market strengths; their products may be differentiated; they may have imperfect information about each other; they may differ in their assessment of consumer demand; and they may be unwilling or unable (for antitrust reasons?) to coordinate their actions. The analysis, interesting (and exasperating!) as it can be in the “singlemove” case (where each competitor decides independently on price and quantity and lives with the decision forever), can get more even complicated in the “multi-move” case (where one firm decides, the other responds, the first firm counter-responds, the second firm counter-counter-responds, and so on and so forth). The multi-move model is particularly interesting because it gives the competitors 9 59 191-093 Price-Quantity Determination repeated opportunities to learn about each other and about each other’s information, costs, strategies, etc.; it also allows competitors to signal to each other—nudging prices up or down, punishing firms for not cooperating, rewarding through cooperative moves, etc. In both the single- and the multimove cases, the firm may need to go through a fair amount of “I-think-that-you-think-that-I-thinkthat-you-think-...” type of analysis when determining price and quantity. Even then, the final outcome might be unpredictable. Our goal is somewhat modest. We will examine an “industry” with two competitors, Firm A and Firm B, offering similar but not identical products (if the products were identical, all the demand would go to the competitor with the lowest price—provided, of course, it has the capacity to meet the demand). The competitors have different variable costs; for simplicity, we assume that neither firm has any fixed costs. Each competitor has adequate capacity to meet total market demand. The two firms have the same objective—to maximize contribution for the firm—and have complete information about each other’s costs and capacities. At what price should each firm offer its product, and what quantity should it expect to sell? The answer to this question depends on two important factors: (1) the dynamics of the industry (Are both firms already in the industry, or is one an incumbent and the other a new entrant? Do both decide at the same time, or does one firm take the leadership, and the other follows? Do the two firms decide only once, or repeatedly in a sequence of moves and countermoves? Et cetera.), and (2) the way in which the two firms share the total demand. We consider the second factor first. The two firms offer somewhat differentiated products. Accordingly, it is reasonable to anticipate that they will not split the total demand equally even if their products are offered at identical prices; indeed, because of product superiority and consumer loyalty, a firm may enjoy a significant market share even if its product is more expensive than its competitor’s product. In the general case, what is the relationship between total demand, market share, and the two firms’ prices? This is usually a very difficult question to answer, and firms expend a lot of resources (money, time, and people) trying to understand how consumers do or will react to price and product differences. For our purpose, let us assume that a total demand-market share-price difference model exists for the products in question. Both firms have access to this model. Let us turn to the first factor, industry dynamics. We begin by considering the case where Firm A is the leader and Firm B the follower. Once the two firms have chosen prices, they must live with their decisions forever. How should each firm set its price? We know that both firms maximize contribution. We also know that each firm is aware of its own variable cost and the variable cost of the competing firm. Finally, each firm knows what the total market demand and its own market share will be given its price and its competitor’s price. In this context, each firm can construct what is called a payoff matrix: a table of contributions for the two firms as a function of their prices. Each row in the table represents a price chosen by Firm A; each column, a price chosen by Firm B. There are two entries in each cell of the table: one for Firm A’s contribution and one for Firm B’s contribution (for the values of Firm A’s and Firm B’s prices to which the cell corresponds). What does Firm A do? It says to itself: “Firm B is not stupid. For any price I choose, Firm B is going to choose a price that maximizes its contribution given my price. Each row of the payoff matrix represents a choice of price on my part, and the different cells in the row give values of my contribution and Firm B’s contribution for each price that Firm B might choose. Firm B is going to choose a price that maximizes its contribution. So, in each row, I should look for the cell in which Firm B’s contribution is maximized. That cell also gives my contribution if I were to choose the price represented by that row and Firm B were to choose its contribution-maximizing price given my price. What price should I choose? I should choose the price that maximizes my contribution given that Firm B chooses a price that maximizes its contribution given my price.” 10 60 Price-Quantity Determination 191-093 An example will help. Let us say Firm A has a variable cost of $1 per unit; Firm B, a variable cost of $2 per unit. The two firms are restricted to only two choices of prices—$5 and $6—and total market demand does not depend on the individual firm’s prices (in reality, overall lower industry prices will stimulate additional consumer demand). The total market demand is 1,000 units. Firm A has a superior product; it expects a 60% market share if it and Firm B offer products at the same price, a 100% share if its price is $5 and Firm B’s price is $6 (i.e., Firm A can expect a share shift from Firm B; the shift comes at a price, however: the unit contribution is diluted because of the lower price), and a 20% share if its price is $6 and Firm B’s price is $5. The payoff matrix is reproduced in Table 4. Table 4 Payoff Matrix for Firm A and Firm B Firm B’s Price $5.00 Firm A’s Price $6.00 $5.00 $2,400; $1,200 $4,000; $0 $6.00 $1,000; $2,400 $3,000; $1,600 Note: The first number in each cell of the “2 x 2” payoff matrix is Firm A’s contribution; the second, Firm B’s contribution. Firm A is the price leader; Firm B, the follower. Firm A says to itself: “If I choose a price of $5, Firm B, which I believe is of sound mind and quite rational, is bound to choose $5 too—because its contribution is higher for a price of $5 than for a price of $6. In that case, my contribution would be $2,400. On the other hand, if I choose $6, Firm B would still choose $5—once again, because its contribution is higher at that price than with a price of $6. In that case, my contribution would be only $1,000, a good deal less than $2,400. Therefore, I should choose a price of $5.” What about Firm B, the follower? If Firm A chooses $5, Firm B maximizes its contribution by also choosing a price of $5. Since both firms choose the same price, Firm A gets a 60% share of the market; Firm B, 40%. Thus, Firm A can expect a demand of 600; Firm B, 400. Given our assumption of the dynamics, the two firms have to live with these decisions forever. What if we allowed Firm A to respond to Firm B’s response to its lead. Now Firm A can examine its alternatives given Firm B’s price ($5) and respond with a price that maximizes contribution. In our example, that price happens to be $5—the price Firm A had chosen in the first place. So, Firm A does not wish to change its price. We have an interesting situation here: Firm A, the leader, is satisfied with its choice given the follower’s response. Since Firm A does not wish to counter-respond, Firm B has no need to counter-counter-respond. In other words, the original prices represent an equilibrium. This need not be the case in general. For different economics and total demand-market shareprice relationships, it is possible that Firm A might have chosen a price other than $5 in a counterresponse to Firm B’s response, and Firm B a price other than $5 in a counter-counter-response. The two players will play a game over time. The game may or may not have an equilibrium. Of course, there is no need to actually play the game to determine the equilibrium—if it exists. In our original leader-follower model, we noted that Firm A chooses a price to maximize its contribution assuming Firm B chooses a price to maximize its contribution given Firm A’s price. In doing so, Firm B was being myopic. Instead, it could have thought about the possibility of Firm A counter-responding to its price, and incorporated that counter-response in its decision. This is fine, expect that Firm A’s counter-response depends on an analysis of Firm B’s counter-counter-response, and the latter hinges on Firm A’s counter-counter-counter-response, and so on and so forth. 11 61 191-093 Price-Quantity Determination Returning to our example, for the [A:$5, B:$5] price pair, Firm A has a contribution of $2,400, and Firm B has a contribution of $1,200. This is rather unfortunate: both firms would prefer the price pair [A:$6, B:$6], where Firm A will have a contribution of $3,000; Firm B, $1,600. The problem, of course, is that it is difficult to get to this price pair: if Firm A chooses a price of $6, Firm B can do better by choosing a price of $5 (its contribution will be $2,400), in which case Firm A is unhappy (its contribution is only $1,000). Similarly, if Firm B chooses a price of $6, Firm A can do better by choosing a price of $5 (its contribution will be $4,000), in which case Firm B is unhappy (its contribution drops to zero). So, the two firms are in a bind. Both prefer the price pair [A:$6, B:$6] over the pair [A:$5, B:$5], but how can they get there? To get there, they need cooperation and credibility (otherwise, each has the incentive to defect—unless the other firm can offer a credible threat to punish the defector). In the microeconomics literature, this situation is often referred to as the prisoner’s dilemma. In this version of the game, there are two prisoners, Prisoner A and Prisoner B, who are suspected of having committed a crime. The prisoners are kept in separate cells and questioned by the local sheriff, who goes first to Prisoner A and asks him to fess up and threatens him with a severe penalty if Prisoner B confesses but Prisoner A does not. Then, the sheriff goes to Prisoner B and asks her to fess up and threatens her with a severe penalty if Prisoner A confesses but Prisoner B does not. If both prisoners confess, they will be thrown into the slammer, but the sentence would not be as severe. Finally, if neither confesses, the sheriff will file some minor charge against them (for the trouble caused!) and the two will receive only a minor reprimand. Draw up the payoff matrix for this case and convince yourself it has the same structure as the matrix in Table 4. Will both prisoners confess? Most probably, yes. All payoff matrices do not have the “prisoner’s dilemma” form; a different set of economics and market sharing rule can result in a matrix with a different structure and a very different set of incentives for the two players. In our example, the total market demand was constant. If we had considered the payoffs, not in terms of contribution, but market shares, we would have observed that Firm A could only benefit at Firm B’s expense: Firm A’s gain of market share is Firm B’s loss of market share. Similarly, Firm B’s gain of share must be accompanied by Firm A’s loss of share. The market share game is, hence, a zero-sum game. The contribution game, on the other hand, is a nonzero-sum game: by charging higher prices, both firms can benefit through cooperation. Who loses in that case? You got it: we, the consumers. 12 62 9-511-028 REV: JULY 26, 2011 THOMAS STEENBURGH JILL AVERY Marketing Analysis Toolkit: Pricing and Profitability Analysis Introduction Pricing is one of the most difficult decisions marketers make and the one with the most direct and immediate impact on the firm’s financial position. Thi s marketing analysis toolkit introduces the fundamental terminology and calculations associated witth pricing and profitability analysis. Determining Demand For most goods, the price of a product determines wh ether customers will buy it; such that as the price goes up, the quantity demanded by customers go oes down, and as the price goes down, the quantity demanded by customers goes up. The re lationship between price and demaand is graphically represented by a demand curve, which is line ar in its most basic form. A demand curve plots customers’ probable purchase quantities at various prices. The slope of a linear demand curve is calculated by the following formu la: Slope of the demand curve (m) = c hange in price change in quantity deemanded The point at which the demand curve crosses the y -axis indicates the price above which any customer will not buy a product because it is too expen sive. This indicates the outer boundary of what customers are willing to pay for the product. If th e firm prices the product at this price, they will sell zero units. The point at which the demand curve crosses the x-aaxis indicates the maximum number of units the firm can sell if the price is zero, the maximum quantiity customers are willing to buy at any price. It is important to remember that a demand curve is only a model of what will happen in the market __________________________________________________ _______________ ______________ __________________________________ Professors Thomas Steenburgh and Jill Avery (Simmons School of Management) p repared this note a s the basis for class discussion. Copyright © 2010, 2011 President and Fellows of Harvard Colleg e e. To order copi es or request perm ission to reproduce materials, call 1--800-5457685, write Harvard Business School Publishing, Boston, MA 02163, or go to ww w.hbsp.harvard.e du/educators. This publication may not be digitized, photocopied, or otherwise reproduced, posted, or transmitted, without t he permission of H arvard Business School. 63 511-028 Marketing Analysis Toolkit: Pricing and Profitability Analysis at different prices, and we should be more willing to trust its predictions for the prices that have been observed in the market than we would for prices that are either extremely high or extremely low. 12,000 maximum reservation price “b” 11,000 10,000 At a price of $9,000, consumers are likely to buy 140 units. Price in Dollars 9,000 8,000 Demand Curve 7,000 6,000 At a price of $5,000, consumers are likely to buy 325 units. 5,000 4,000 3,000 2,000 maximum quantity customers willing to buy at any price 1,000 0 100 200 300 400 500 Quantity Demanded Source: Casewriters. Marketers can graph their demand curves if they have information on how many units customers will buy at two different price points and if they assume that demand is linear. For example, if customers will buy 250 units at a price of $30 and 500 units at a price of $10, then the slope of the demand curve will be: slope = $30-$10 = -0.08 250-500 Once the slope is known, marketers can calculate the y-intercept point using one of the known price/volume relationships using the basic formula for a line: y = m * x + b (where y is the price, x is the quantity demanded, m is the slope of the demand curve, and b is the y-intercept) 30 = (-0.08 * 250) + y-intercept 2 64 Marketing Analysis Toolkit: Pricing and Profitability Analysis 511-028 Rearranging the terms algebraically yields: y-intercept = $50 Given the slope and the y-intercept, the demand curve line can be drawn. In this example, the demand curve equation would be: y = -0.08 * x + $50 This equation can then be used to calculate any price/quantity combination by substituting in any price for y and calculating x to understand how many units will be sold at that price. For example, the maximum quantity consumers are willing to buy at any price (the x-intercept) can be calculated by substituting a zero in for the y value and solving for x. 0 = -0.08 * x + $50 x= 650 Marketers need to understand how responsive, or elastic, customers’ demand for a product is to a change in price at a certain point on the demand curve. The price elasticity of demand ratio helps illuminate this: Price Elasticity = of Demand Percentage change in quantity demanded Percentage change in price The price elasticity of demand measures the percentage change in quantity demanded by consumers as a result of a percentage change in price. Note that this formula usually yields a negative number. The negative sign is traditionally ignored, as the magnitude of the number is the focus for interpretation. Demand is considered “elastic” if consumers’ demand for a product considerably changes when price is changed by a small amount. Demand is considered “inelastic” if consumers’ demand for the product hardly changes when price is changed by a small amount. The price elasticity of demand ratio helps us understand whether our demand is elastic or inelastic. The following chart summarizes the range of elasticities that exist in the marketplace to guide interpretation: Elasticity Ratio Type of Elasticity Description E=∞ Perfectly Elastic Any very small change in price results in a very large change in quantity demanded. 1<E<∞ Relatively Elastic Small changes in price cause large changes in quantity demanded. E=1 Unit Elastic Any change in price is matched by an equal change in quantity. 0<E<1 Relatively Inelastic Large changes in price cause small changes in quantity demanded. E=0 Perfectly Inelastic price is changed. Quantity demanded does not change when 3 65 511-028 Marketing Analysis Toolkit: Pricing and Profitability Analysis Under relatively elastic demand conditions, quantity is very responsive to price. For example, suppose the price elasticity equals 2. A 10% increase in price will lead to a 20% drop in the quantity demanded. Under relatively inelastic demand conditions, the opposite is true, as the quantity demanded is not very responsive to price. For example, suppose the price elasticity is 0.5. In this case, a 10% drop in price will lead to only 5% increase in the quantity demanded. Inelastic demand curves have a steeper slope and are therefore more vertical than elastic demand curves, indicating that the quantity demanded by consumers does not change very much when the price is increased or decreased. 12,000 12,000 10,000 10,000 Price in Dollars 8,000 7,000 6,000 At a price of $5,000, consumers are likely to buy 325 units. 5,000 8,000 7,000 6,000 4,000 3,000 3,000 2,000 2,000 1,000 1,000 100 200 300 400 At a price of $5,000, consumers are likely to buy 210 units. 5,000 4,000 0 At a price of $9,000, consumers are likely to buy 180 units. 9,000 At a price of $9,000, consumers are likely to buy 140 units. 9,000 Price in Dollars Inelastic Demand Curve 11,000 Elastic Demand Curve 11,000 0 500 100 200 300 400 Quantity Demanded Quantity Demanded Source: Casewriters. Marketers can attempt to shift their product’s demand curve outwards (i.e. creating higher levels of quantities demanded at the same price point) by increasing customer preference for the product through branding or other marketing initiatives that increase consumers’ desire for the product. Demand curves can also shift outwards when substitute products offered by competitors become more expensive, or when consumers’ incomes increase. However, demand curves can also shift the other way (i.e. lower quantity demanded at the same price point) if competitors offer compelling substitutes or consumers’ incomes decrease. Technical Note: If we assume that demand for a product is linear (i.e. a straight line with constant slope across all price/quantity combinations, then the price elasticity of demand changes at each price point along the demand curve. As the focal price decreases, the price elasticity of demand gets smaller (in absolute value). An example, which is relatively easy to calculate for a linear demand curve, helps make this idea concrete. Continuing with the previous demand curve, suppose that the product was initially priced at $30. We want to determine the percentage change in demand that occurs following a percentage change in price from $30. The demand curve equation predicts that the company would sell 250 units if the company were to set its price at $30. Furthermore, if the company was to set its price at $20, the demand curve equation predicts that it would sell the following quantity, calculated using the linear demand formula outlined above: 4 66 500 Marketing Analysis Toolkit: Pricing and Profitability Analysis $20 511-028 = -0.08(x) + $50 x = 375 units Given this, the demand model predicts that a 33% drop in price (from $30) would result in a 50% increase in demand. Therefore, the price elasticity of demand at $30 is: Price Elasticity = of Demand (375-250)/250 ($20-$30)/$30 = 50% -33% = -1.5 In contrast, suppose the initial price point was $20 instead of $30. The demand curve equation predicts that the firm would sell 375 units at a price point of.$20 and 500 units at a price point of $10. Therefore, a 50% drop in price (from $20) would result in a 25% increase in demand. Therefore, the price elasticity of demand at $20 is: Price Elasticity = of Demand (500-375)/375 ($10-$20)/$20 = 33% -50% = -0.67 For most demand curves, like the linear demand curve with which we are working, the price elasticity of demand takes different values depending on price. This, however, is not always the case. The constant elasticity demand curve, which is slightly more difficult to work with because it takes the form of an arc, has the same elasticity regardless of price. Calculating Total Revenue Once a manager measures her product’s demand curve and its resulting price elasticity of demand, she can begin to calculate the total revenue the firm will achieve at various price points. Total revenue measures the amount of money coming into the firm from the sale of its products. It is based on the total number of units sold to customers (quantity) and the price at which each unit is sold. Total Revenue = Price per unit * Quantity Sold For firms who sell directly to consumers, the price used in the Total Revenue calculation is the retail price at which the consumer purchases the product. However, for firms who do not sell directly to consumers but rather sell their products through a retailer, the price used in the Total Revenue calculation is the price at which the firm sells its products to its distribution channel partners. Calculating Total Costs A major part of any pricing decision is analyzing the costs of the product. The product’s demand curve sets a ceiling on the price that the firm can charge for its product, and the cost structure of the firm sets a floor. In general, firms want to charge a price that covers its costs of producing, distributing, and selling the product, including a fair return for its effort and risk. There are two types of costs incurred by the firm: fixed costs and variable costs. Fixed costs do not change as the quantity of units produced and sold changes. Fixed costs usually include things like factory and equipment costs, management salaries, and advertising. Variable costs vary as the 5 67 511-028 Marketing Analysis Toolkit: Pricing and Profitability Analysis unit quantity produced and sold changes. Variable costs are directly linked to the quantity produced and include things like direct manufacturing labor and raw materials. Variable costs generally appear in an income statement in the Cost of Good Sold (COGS) line item, while fixed costs generally appear in line items like Property, Plant, and Equipment (PPE), Selling, General, and Administrative (SG&A), and Research and Development (R&D). However, please note that the COGS line item includes variable costs plus a portion of fixed costs associated with making the product. In the U.S., Generally Accepted Accounting Principles (GAAP) requires firms to estimate all product costs (fixed and variable) and allocate them to the number of product units produced. When units are sold, those allocated costs (both fixed and variable) become the cost of goods sold. Total costs measure the amount of money the firm has to spend. Total costs are the combination of fixed and variable costs. Total Costs = Fixed Costs + Variable Cost per unit * Quantity Sold Remember, that total costs change with the unit quantity sold, because of variable costs, so if you are running different quantity scenarios, you need to adjust both Total Revenue and Total Costs. Calculating Profit In general, “profit” or “margin” is the difference between the revenues taken in by the firm and the costs incurred in achieving those revenues. Profit is often calculated as a raw dollar amount and as a percentage of revenue. In marketing, there are four profit measures that are used frequently: contribution margin, gross margin, direct marketing contribution, and net income. Contribution margin is the term used to capture the firm’s top line profitability. Contribution margin is the difference between its total revenue and its variable costs. While contribution margin is calculated as a dollar amount, most firms also calculate a contribution margin percentage, which calculates contribution margin as a percentage of total revenue. Contribution Margin = Total Revenue - (Variable Cost per unit * Quantity Sold) Contribution Margin % = Total Revenue - (Variable Cost per unit * Quantity Sold) Total Revenue Contribution margin may also be calculated on a per unit basis: Contribution margin/unit = Revenue per unit - Variable Cost per unit One can also calculate the firm’s gross margin. Gross margin is the difference between the firm’s total revenue and its cost of goods sold (COGS) and is often reported on the income statement. Gross Margin = Total Revenues - Cost of Goods Sold Gross Margin % = Total Revenues - Cost of Goods Sold Total Revenues Gross margin may also be calculated on a per unit basis: Gross margin/unit = Revenue per unit - COGS per unit 6 68 Marketing Analysis Toolkit: Pricing and Profitability Analysis 511-028 Direct marketing contribution (DMC) includes variable costs plus fixed costs associated with marketing expenditures, such as advertising expense and sales promotion expense. Note that direct marketing contribution generally does not include fixed costs labeled as Selling, General and Administrative (SG&A on an income statement). Again a direct marketing contribution ratio can be calculated. Direct Marketing = Contribution Total Revenue - (Variable Cost per unit *Quantity) - Marketing Expenses Direct Marketing = Contribution % Total Revenue - (Variable Cost per unit *Quantity) - Marketing Expenses Total Revenue Net income is the term used to capture the firm’s bottom line profitability and is often reported on the income statement. Unlike the contribution margin, net income includes fixed costs in addition to variable costs. Again, a net income percentage can be calculated too. Net Income = Total Revenue - Total Costs Net Income % = Total Revenue - Total Costs Total Revenue Retailer Margins and Penny Profit Just like firms, retailers and other distribution channel partners use profit and margin analysis to measure their profitability. A retailer’s “penny profit” calculates the amount of profit a retailer makes in dollars. The “retailer margin” is the ratio of the amount of profit a retailer makes in dollars as a percentage of the retail selling price. The “retail selling price” is the amount of money the retailer receives from a consumer when it sells the item in its store. The “cost to the retailer” is the money that the retailer pays to the manufacturer to purchase the item for resale to the consumer. Hence, the “cost to the retailer” becomes the “revenue per unit” in the firm profit calculations above. Penny Profit = Retail Selling Price - Cost to the Retailer Retailer Margin = Retail Selling Price - Cost to the Retailer Retail Selling Price Notice that penny profit and retailer margin calculations are merely contribution margin/unit calculations from the retailer’s perspective. 7 69 511-028 Marketing Analysis Toolkit: Pricing and Profitability Analysis Using Pricing and Profitability Analysis to Guide Marketing Decision Making It is crucial when making any marketing decision to understand the financial implications of the decision for the firm. Whether you are working in a for-profit or a non-profit organization, profitability matters! Even not-for-profit organizations need to manage their revenues and costs. Managers should assess changes in profitability in the following situations: When recommending a price change, whether permanent or temporary (i.e. a temporary price reduction, coupon promotion, rebate promotion). When recommending a marketing expense. When recommending changes to the product which change its variable cost structure. When recommending changes to the distribution strategy that change the price the firm will receive from its retailer partners or that change the price consumers will pay for the product. When evaluating sales demand from various consumer segments to understand how the varying sales estimates from different customer segments contribute to profitability. Very often, customers who buy lots of unit volume get special pricing, which reduces their profitability to the firm. Customers who buy lower unit quantities but who buy those units at full price are often more profitable. 8 70 Saturday, October 1 Global Executive MBA in Shanghai GEMBA VIII – Theme 3A General Manager as Integrator 29 Sept – 3 Oct 2011, Shanghai Jiao Tong University, Shanghai Professors Ty Callahan (Finance and Business Economics) and Joe Nunes (Marketing) All assigned readings and cases for all the week's sessions need to be read and studied before the first session at SJTU. Focus on reading and being prepared to discuss the cases! Saturday, 1 October 08:30 Finance Session 5 – Professor Callahan Topic: Capital Structure Choices – Putting It All Together In this session we will use a case discussion to review and summarize the important tax, risk, information, and agency consequences of a major change in a firm’s capital structure policy. Required Reading: Blaine Kitchenware, Inc.: Capital Structure case Case Discussion Questions: 1. Do you believe Blaine’s capital structure and payout policies are appropriate? Why or why not? 2. Should Dubinski recommend a large share repurchase to Blaine’s board? What are the primary advantages and disadvantages of such a move? 3. Consider the following share repurchase proposal: Blaine will use $209M of cash from its balance sheet and $50M in new interest-bearing debt at a rate of 6.75% to repurchase 14.0M shares at a price of $18.50 per share. How would such a buyback affect Blaine? Consider the impact on, among other things, Blaine’s earnings per share and ROE. 4. As a member of Blaine’s controlling family, would you be in favor of this proposal? Would you be in favor of it as a non-family shareholder? To do before this session: Prepare the case for discussion 09:45 Break 10:00 Finance Session 6 – Professor Callahan Topic: Leverage and the Cost of Capital for a Firm or Project/Division In this session we will learn how to calculate a firm’s or project’s cost of capital. (They may or may not be the same!) We will discuss the appropriate cost of debt financing, preferred stock financing, and common equity financing and how each is commonly derived. We will GEMBA VIII, Theme 3A, 29 Sept to 3 Oct, 2011, daily syllabus 71 Page: 1 / 3 Global Executive MBA in Shanghai also look at the interaction between capital structure choices and the firm’s cost of capital. Required Readings: - RWJ Chapter 13 (review, especially 13.9) - RWJ Chapter 18 (with an emphasis on 18.3, 18.5, and 18.7) Discussion Questions: 1. Intuitively, what does a stock beta represent? 2. What is the difference between a stock beta, a debt beta, and an asset beta? 3. What are three primary determinants of a company’s stock beta (i.e., what determines the relative exposure of a company stock to economy wide fluctuations)? 4. Why might a project beta or division beta differ from a company’s stock beta? Give a real world example of a project with the same beta as the parent company and a real world example of a project with a different beta than the parent company. To do before this session: - Review readings - Prepare answers to the discussion questions 11:15 Break 11:30 Finance Session 7 – Professor Callahan Topic: Estimating the Cost of Capital – An Example In this session we will apply what we have learned in the previous session to the Midland Energy Resources, Inc. case and further refine our financial analysis skills. Required Reading: Midland Energy Resources, Inc.: Cost of Capital Discussion Questions: 1. How are Mortensen’s estimates of Midland’s cost of capital used? How, if at all, should these anticipated uses affect the calculations? 2. Calculate Midland’s corporate WACC. Be prepared to defend your specific assumptions about the various inputs to the calculations. Is GEMBA VIII, Theme 3A, 29 Sept to 3 Oct, 2011, daily syllabus 72 Page: 2 / 3 Global Executive MBA in Shanghai Midland’s choice of EMRP appropriate? If not, what recommendations would you make and why? 3. Should Midland use a single corporate hurdle rate for evaluating investment opportunities in all of its divisions? Why or why not? 4. Compute a separate cost of capital for the E&P and Marketing & Refining divisions. What causes them to differ from one another? 5. How would you compute a cost of capital for the Petrochemical division? To do before this session: Prepare the case for discussion 12:45 Lunch 13:45 Marketing Session 7 – Professor Nunes Topic: Saurer: The China Challenge Required Readings: Saurer: The China Challenge (A) IMD399 Discussion Questions: 1. Should Saurer enter the market for lower functionality twisting machines in China? What are the major advantages and disadvantages to doing this? 2. If Saurer were to introduce the proposed machine, what marketing strategy would you recommend for the product in China? 3. If Saurer were to not introduce the machine, what changes would you recommend for the company’s current strategy in China? Optional Reading: Gadiesh, Orit, Philip Leung and Till Vestring: “The Battle for China’s Good Enough Market”, HBR Reprint R0709E Due: Exercise 2 – Reading Perceptual Maps 15:00 Break 15:15 Marketing Session 8 – Professor Nunes Topic: Breakout Sessions This session will include time to review Exercise 2 before allowing teams to work on their first practice decision. Assignment: Make Markstrat Practice Decision GEMBA VIII, Theme 3A, 29 Sept to 3 Oct, 2011, daily syllabus 73 Page: 3 / 3 4040 OCTOBER 08, 2009 TIMOTHY LUEHRMAN JOEL HEILPRIN Blaine Kitchenware, Inc.: Capital Structure On April 27, 2007, Victor Dubinski, CEO of Blaine Kitchenware, Inc. (BKI), sat in his office reflecting on a meeting he had had with an investment banker earlier in the week. The banker, whom Dubinski had known for years, asked for the meeting after a group of private equity investors made discreet inquiries about a possible acquisition of Blaine. Although Blaine was a public company, a majority of its shares were controlled by family members descended from the firm’s founders together with various family trusts. Family interests were strongly represented on the board of directors as well. Dubinski knew the family had no current interest in selling—on the contrary, Blaine was interested in acquiring other companies in the kitchen appliances space—so this overture, like a few others before it, would be politely rebuffed. Nevertheless, Dubinski was struck by the banker’s assertion that a private equity buyer could “unlock” value inherent in Blaine’s strong operations and balance sheet. Using cash on Blaine’s balance sheet and new borrowings, a private equity firm could purchase all of Blaine’s outstanding shares at a price higher than $16.25 per share, its current stock price. It would then repay the debt over time using the company’s future earnings. When the banker pointed out that BKI itself could do the same thing—borrow money to buy back its own shares—Dubinski had asked, “But why would we do that?” The banker’s response was blunt: “Because you’re over-liquid and under-levered. Your shareholders are paying a price for that.” In the days since the meeting, Dubinski’s thoughts kept returning to a share repurchase. How many shares could be bought? At what price? Would it sap Blaine’s financial strength? Or prevent it from making future acquisitions? Blaine Kitchenware’s Business Blaine Kitchenware was a mid-sized producer of branded small appliances primarily used in residential kitchens. Originally founded as The Blaine Electrical Apparatus Company in 1927, it produced then-novel electric home appliances, such as irons, vacuum cleaners, waffle irons, and cream separators, which were touted as modern, clean, and easier to use than counterparts fueled by oil, coal, gas, or by hand. By 2006, the company’s products consisted of a wide range of small kitchen appliances used for food and beverage preparation and for cooking, including several branded lines of deep fryers, griddles, waffle irons, toasters, small ovens, blenders, mixers, pressure cookers, steamers, slow cookers, shredders and slicers, and coffee makers. ________________________________________________________________________________________________________________ HBS Professor Timothy A. Luehrman and Illinois Institute of Technology Adjunct Finance Professor Joel L. Heilprin prepared this case solely as a basis for class discussion and not as an endorsement, a source of primary data, or an illustration of effective or ineffective management. This case, though based on real events, is fictionalized, and any resemblance to actual persons or entities is coincidental. There are occasional references to actual companies in the narration. Copyright © 2009 Harvard Business School Publishing. To order copies or request permission to reproduce materials, call 1-800-545-7685, write Harvard Business Publishing, Boston, MA 02163, or go to http://www.hbsp.harvard.edu. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, used in a spreadsheet, or transmitted in any form or by any means—electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording, or otherwise—without the permission of Harvard Business Publishing. Harvard Business Publishing is an affiliate of Harvard Business School. 74 4040 | Blaine Kitchenware, Inc.: Capital Structure Blaine had just under 10% of the $2.3 billion U.S. market for small kitchen appliances. For the period 2003–2006 the industry posted modest annual unit sales growth of 2% despite positive market conditions including a strong housing market, growth in affluent householders, and product innovations. Competition from inexpensive imports and aggressive pricing by mass merchandisers limited industry dollar volume growth to just 3.5% annually over that same period. Historically, the industry had been fragmented, but it had recently experienced some consolidation that many participants expected to continue. In recent years, Blaine had been expanding into foreign markets. Nevertheless in 2006, 65% of its revenue was generated from shipments to U.S. wholesalers and retailers, with the balance coming from sales to Canada, Europe, and Central and South America. The company shipped approximately 14 million units a year. There were three major segments in the small kitchen appliance industry: food preparation appliances, cooking appliances, and beverage-making appliances. Blaine produced product for all three, but the majority of its revenues came from cooking appliances and food preparation appliances. Its market share of beverage-making appliances was only 2%. Most of BKI’s appliances retailed at medium price points, at or just below products offered by the best-known national brands. BKI’s market research consistently showed that the Blaine brand was well-known and well-regarded by consumers. It was associated somewhat with “nostalgia” and the creation of “familiar, wholesome dishes.” Recently, Blaine had introduced some goods with “smart” technology features and sleeker styling, targeting higher-end consumers and intended to compete at higher price points. This strategy was in response to increased competition from Asian imports and private label product. The majority of BKI’s products were distributed via a network of wholesalers, which supplied mass merchandisers and department stores, but its upper-tier products were sold directly to specialty retailers and catalogue companies. Regardless of the distribution channel, BKI offered consumers standard warranty terms of 90 days to one year, depending on the appliance. Blaine’s monthly sales reached a seasonal peak during October and November as retailers increased stock in anticipation of the holiday season. A smaller peak occurred in May and June, coinciding with Mother’s Day, a summer surge in weddings, and the seasonal peak in home purchases. Historically, sales of Blaine appliances had been cyclical as well, tending to track overall macroeconomic activity. This also was the case for the industry as a whole; in particular, changes in appliance sales were correlated with changes in housing sales and in home renovation and household formation. BKI owned and operated a small factory in Minnesota that produced cast iron parts with specialty coatings for certain of its cookware offerings. Otherwise, however, Blaine, like most companies in the appliance industry, outsourced its production. In 2006 BKI had suppliers and contract manufacturers in China, Vietnam, Canada, and Mexico. Victor Dubinski was a great-grandson of one of the founders. An engineer by training, Dubinski served in the U.S. Navy after graduating from college in 1970. After his discharge, he worked for a large aerospace and defense contractor until joining the family business in 1981 as head of operations. He was elected to the board of directors in 1988 and became Blaine’s CEO in 1992, succeeding his uncle. Under Dubinski’s leadership, Blaine operated much as it always had, with three notable exceptions. First, the company completed an IPO in 1994. This provided a measure of liquidity for certain of the founders’ descendants who, collectively, owned 62% of the outstanding shares 2 BRIEFCASES | HARVARD BUSINESS PUBLISHING 75 Blaine Kitchenware, Inc.: Capital Structure | 4040 following the IPO. Second, beginning in the 1990s, Blaine gradually moved its production abroad. The company began by taking advantage of NAFTA, engaging suppliers and performing some manufacturing in Mexico. By 2003, BKI also had established relationships with several Asian manufacturers, and the large majority of its production took place outside the United States. Finally, BKI had undertaken a strategy focused on rounding out and complementing its product offerings by acquiring small independent manufacturers or the kitchen appliance product lines of large diversified manufacturers. The company carefully followed changes in customer purchasing behavior and market trends. Victor Dubinski and the board were eager to continue what they believed had been a fruitful strategy. The company was particularly keen to increase its presence in the beverage appliance segment, which demonstrated the strongest growth and where BKI was weakest. Thus far, all acquisitions had been for cash or BKI stock. Financial Performance During the year ended December 31, 2006, Blaine earned net income of $53.6 million on revenue of $342 million. Exhibits 1 and 2 present the company’s recent financial statements. Approximately 85% of Blaine’s revenue and 80% of its operating income came from the sale of mid-tier products, with the line of higher-end goods accounting for the remainder. The company’s 2006 EBITDA margin of nearly 22% was among the strongest within the peer group shown in Exhibit 3. Despite its recent shift toward higher-end product lines, Blaine’s operating margins had decreased slightly over the last three years. Margins declined due to integration costs and inventory write-downs associated with recent acquisitions. Now that integration activities were completed, BKI executives expected the firm to achieve operating margins at least as high as its historical margins. The U.S. industry as a whole faced considerable pressure from imports and private label products, as well as a shift in consumer purchasing preferences favoring larger, “big box” retailers. In response, some of Blaine’s more aggressive rivals were cutting prices to maintain sales growth. Blaine had not followed suit and its organic revenue growth had suffered in recent years, as some of its core products lost market share. Growth in Blaine’s top line was attributable almost exclusively to acquisitions. Despite the company’s profitability, returns to shareholders had been somewhat below average. Blaine’s return on equity (ROE), shown below, was significantly below that of its publicly traded peers.1 Moreover, its earnings per share had fallen significantly since 2004, partly due to dilutive acquisitions. Companies 2006 ROE Home & Hearth Design AutoTech Appliances XQL Corp. Bunkerhill Incorporated EasyLiving Systems Mean 11.3% 43.1% 19.5% 41.7% 13.9% 25.9% Median 19.5% Blaine 11.0% 1 ROE is computed here as net income divided by end-of-period book equity. HARVARD BUSINESS PUBLISHING | BRIEFCASES 76 3 4040 | Blaine Kitchenware, Inc.: Capital Structure During 2004–2006, compounded annual returns for BKI shareholders, including dividends and stock price appreciation, were approximately 11% per year. This was higher than the S&P 500, which returned approximately 10% per year. However, it was well below the 16% annual compounded return earned by shareholders of Blaine’s peer group during the same period. Financial Policies Blaine’s financial posture was conservative and very much in keeping with BKI’s long-standing practice and, indeed, with its management style generally. Only twice in its history had the company borrowed beyond seasonal working capital needs. The first time was during World War II, when it borrowed from the U.S. government to retool several factories for war production. The second time was during the first oil shock of the 1970s. On both occasions the debt was repaid as quickly as possible. At the end of 2006, Blaine’s balance sheet was the strongest in the industry. Not only was it debtfree, but the company also held $231 million in cash and securities at the end of 2006, down from $286 million two years earlier. Given such substantial liquidity, Blaine had terminated in 2002 a revolving credit agreement designed to provide standby credit for seasonal needs; the CFO argued that the fees were a waste of money and Dubinski agreed. In recent years the company’s largest uses of cash had been common dividends and cash consideration paid in various acquisitions. Dividends per share had risen only modestly during 2004–2006; however, as the company issued new shares in connection with some of its acquisitions, the number of shares outstanding climbed, and the payout ratio rose significantly, to more than 50% in 2006. 2004 Net income Dividends Average shares outstanding Earnings per share Dividend per share Payout ratio $ 53,112 $ 18,589 41,309 $ 1.29 $ 0.45 35.0% 2005 $ 52,435 $ 22,871 48,970 $ 1.07 $ 0.47 43.6% 2006 $ 53,630 $ 28,345 59,052 $ 0.91 $ 0.48 52.9% The next largest use of funds was capital expenditures, which were modest due to Blaine’s extensive outsourcing of its manufacturing. Average capital expenditures during the past three years were just over $10 million per year. While they were expected to remain modest, future expenditures would be driven in part by the extent and nature of Blaine’s future acquisitions. In recent years, after-tax cash generated from operations had been more than four times average capital expenditures and rising, as shown in the table below. EBITDA Less: Taxes After-Tax Operating Cash Flow 4 2004 2005 $ 69,370 24,989 44,380 $ 68,895 24,303 44,592 2006 $ 73,860 23,821 50,039 AVG. 46,337 BRIEFCASES | HARVARD BUSINESS PUBLISHING 77 Blaine Kitchenware, Inc.: Capital Structure | 4040 Reassessing Financial Policies in 2007 In 2007 Blaine planned to continue its policy of holding prices firm in the face of competitive pressures. Consequently, its managers were expecting top line growth of only 3% for fiscal year 2007. However, this growth rate assumed no acquisitions would be made in 2007, unlike the previous two years. While the board remained receptive to opportunities, Dubinski and his team had no target in mind as yet at the end of April. As he reflected on the possibility of repurchasing stock, Dubinski understood that he could consider such a move only in conjunction with all of BKI’s financial policies: its liquidity, capital structure, dividend policy, ownership structure, and acquisition plans. In addition, he wondered about timing. Blaine’s stock price was not far off its all-time high, yet its performance clearly lagged that of its peers. A summary of contemporaneous financial market information is provided in Exhibit 4. Dubinski had begun to suspect that family members on the board would welcome some of the possible effects of a large share repurchase. Assuming that family members held on to their shares, their percentage ownership of Blaine would rise, reversing a downward trend dating from BKI’s IPO. It also would give the board more flexibility in setting future dividends per share. Both Dubinski and the board knew that the recent trend in BKI’s payout ratio was unsustainable and that this concerned some family members. On the other hand, a large repurchase might be unpopular if it forced Blaine to give up its war chest and/or discontinue its acquisition activity. Perhaps even more unsettling, it would cause Blaine to borrow money. The company would be paying significant interest expense for only the third time in its history. As Dubinski turned his chair to face the window, he glanced at the framed photo behind his desk of his great grandfather, Marcus Blaine, demonstrating the company’s first cream separator—its best-selling product during Blaine’s first decade. A real Blaine Electrical Cream Separator sat in a glass case in the corner; the last one had been manufactured in 1949. HARVARD BUSINESS PUBLISHING | BRIEFCASES 78 5 4040 | Blaine Kitchenware, Inc.: Capital Structure Exhibit 1 Blaine Kitchenware, Inc., Income Statements, years ended December 31, ($ in Thousands) Operating Results 2004 2005 2006 $291,940 204,265 $307,964 220,234 $342,251 249,794 Gross Profit Less: Selling, General & Administrative 87,676 25,293 87,731 27,049 92,458 28,512 Operating Income Plus: Depreciation & Amortization 62,383 6,987 60,682 8,213 63,946 9,914 EBITDA 69,370 68,895 73,860 EBIT Plus: Other Income (expense) 62,383 15,719 60,682 16,057 63,946 13,506 Earnings Before Tax Less: Taxes 78,101 24,989 76,738 24,303 77,451 23,821 53,112 $ 18,589 52,435 $ 22,871 53,630 $ 28,345 5.5% 11.1% Revenue Less: Cost of Goods Sold Net Income Dividends Margins Revenue Growth 3.2% Gross Margin 30.0% 28.5% 27.0% EBIT Margin 21.4% 19.7% 18.7% 21.6% EBITDA Margin 23.8% 22.4% Effective Tax Ratea 32.0% 31.7% 30.8% Net Income Margin 15.7% 14.7% 14.2% Dividend payout ratio 35.0% 43.6% 52.9% a. 6 Blaine's future tax rate was expected to rise to the statutory rate of 40%. BRIEFCASES | HARVARD BUSINESS PUBLISHING 79 Blaine Kitchenware, Inc.: Capital Structure | 4040 Exhibit 2 Blaine Kitchenware, Inc. Balance Sheets, December 31, ($ in Thousands) Assets 2004 2005 2006 Cash & Cash Equivalents $ 67,391 $ 70,853 $ 66,557 Marketable Securities 218,403 196,763 164,309 Accounts Receivable 40,709 43,235 48,780 Inventory 47,262 49,728 54,874 Other Current Assets 2,586 3,871 5,157 Total Current Assets 376,351 364,449 339,678 99,402 138,546 174,321 Property, Plant & Equipment 8,134 20,439 38,281 Other Assets Goodwill 13,331 27,394 39,973 Total Assets $497,217 $550,829 $592,253 $ 26,106 $ 28,589 $ 31,936 Liabilities & Shareholders' Equity Accounts Payable Accrued Liabilities 22,605 24,921 27,761 Taxes Payable 14,225 17,196 16,884 Total Current Liabilities 62,935 70,705 76,581 1,794 3,151 4,814 Other liabilities Deferred Taxes 15,111 18,434 22,495 Total Liabilities 79,840 92,290 103,890 Shareholders' Equity Total Liabilities & Shareholders' Equity Note: 417,377 458,538 488,363 $497,217 $550,829 $592,253 Many items in BKI’s historical balance sheets (e.g., Property, Plant & Equipment) have been affected by the firm’s acquisitions. HARVARD BUSINESS PUBLISHING | BRIEFCASES 80 7 81 $ 350,798 372,293 475,377 Net debtb Total debt Book equity 45.18% 31.12% Net Debt/Equity Net Debt/Enterprise Value b. Net debt is total long-term and short-term debt less excess cash. a. Net working capital excludes cash and securities. 1.91x 10.56x 9.46x 1.63x 1.03 LTM Trading Multiples MVIC/Revenue MVIC/EBIT MVIC/EBITDA Market/Book equity Equity beta 776,427 $1,127,226 $ 21,495 54,316 900,803 $ 976,613 Cash & securities Net working capitala Net fixed assets Total assets Market capitalization Enterprise value (MVIC) $ 589,747 106,763 119,190 $ 53,698 Home & Hearth Design 31.74% 24.10% 1.02x 7.35x 6.03x 4.26x 1.24 13,978,375 $18,415,689 $4,437,314 4,973,413 3,283,000 $ 536,099 1,247,520 7,463,564 $9,247,183 $18,080,000 2,505,200 3,055,200 $1,416,012 AutoTech Appliances 17.97% 15.23% 1.45x 8.65x 7.84x 2.51x 0.96 5,290,145 $6,240,947 $ 950,802 972,227 2,109,400 $ 21,425 353,691 3,322,837 $3,697,952 $4,313,300 721,297 796,497 $ 412,307 XQL Corp. 6.01% 5.67% 1.14x 7.42x 6.88x 4.93x 0.92 3,962,780 $4,200,836 $ 238,056 391,736 804,400 $ 153,680 334,804 815,304 $1,303,788 $3,671,100 566,099 610,399 $ 335,073 Bunkerhill, Inc. -15.47% -18.31% 1.87x 18.05x 15.15x 4.41x 0.67 418,749 $ 353,949 $ (64,800) 177,302 94,919 $ 242,102 21,220 68,788 $ 332,110 $ 188,955 19,613 23,356 $ 13,173 EasyLiving Systems Selected Operating and Financial Data for Public Kitchenware Producers, 12 months ended December 31, 2006, ($ in Thousands) Revenue EBIT EBITDA Net income Exhibit 3 -24.06% -31.68% 2.13x 11.40x 9.87x 1.96x 0.56 959,596 $ 728,730 $(230,866) 488,363 $ 230,866 32,231 174,321 $ 592,253 $ 342,251 63,946 73,860 $ 53,630 Blaine Kitchenware 4040 -8- Blaine Kitchenware, Inc.: Capital Structure | 4040 Exhibit 4 Contemporaneous Capital Market Data (April 21, 2007) Yields on U.S. Treasury Securities Maturity 30 days 60 days 90 days 1 year 5 years 10 years 20 years 30 years 4.55% 4.73% 4.91% 4.90% 4.91% 5.02% 5.26% 5.10% Seasoned corporate bond yields Moody's Aaa 5.88% Aa 6.04% A 6.35% Baa 6.72% Ba 7.88% B 8.94% Default spread 0.86% 1.02% 1.33% 1.70% 2.86% 3.92% HARVARD BUSINESS PUBLISHING | BRIEFCASES 82 9 4129 JUNE 19, 2009 TIMOTHY A. LUEHRMAN JOEL L. HEILPRIN Midland Energy Resources, Inc.: Cost of Capital In late January 2007, Janet Mortensen, senior vice president of project finance for Midland Energy Resources, was preparing her annual cost of capital estimates for Midland and each of its three divisions. Midland was a global energy company with operations in oil and gas exploration and production (E&P), refining and marketing (R&M), and petrochemicals. On a consolidated basis, the firm had 2006 operating revenue and operating income of $248.5 billion and $42.2 billion, respectively. Estimates of the cost of capital were used in many analyses within Midland, including asset appraisals for both capital budgeting and financial accounting, performance assessments, M&A proposals, and stock repurchase decisions. Some of these analyses were performed at the division or business unit level, while others were executed at the corporate level. Midland’s corporate treasury staff had begun preparing annual cost of capital estimates for the corporation and each division in the early 1980s. The estimates produced by treasury were often criticized, and Midland’s division presidents and controllers sometimes challenged specific assumptions and inputs. In 2002, Mortensen, then a senior analyst reporting to the CFO, was asked to estimate Midland’s cost of capital in connection with a large proposed share repurchase. Six months later she was asked to calculate corporate and divisional costs of capital that the executive and compensation committees of the board could incorporate in planned performance evaluations. Since then, Mortensen had undertaken a similar exercise each year and her estimates had become widely circulated de facto standards in many analyses throughout the company, even ones in which they were not formally required. By 2007 Mortensen was aware that her calculations had become influential and she devoted ever more time and care to their preparation. Lately she wondered whether they were actually appropriate for all applications and she was considering appending a sort of “user’s guide” to the 2007 set of calculations. Midland’s Operations Midland Energy Resources had been incorporated more than 120 years previously and in 2007 had more than 80,000 employees. Exhibits 1 and 2 present Midland’s most recent consolidated financial statements. Exhibit 3 presents selected business segment data for the period 2004-06. ________________________________________________________________________________________________________________ HBS Professor Timothy A. Luehrman and Illinois Institute of Technology Adjunct Finance Professor Joel L. Heilprin prepared this case specifically for the Harvard Business Publishing Brief Case Collection. Though inspired by real events, the case does not represent a specific situation at an existing company, and any resemblance to actual persons or entities is unintended. Cases are developed solely as the basis for class discussion and are not intended to serve as endorsements, sources of primary data, or illustrations of effective or ineffective management. Copyright © 2009 Harvard Business Publishing. To order copies or request permission to reproduce materials, call 1-800-545-7685 or go to www.hbsp.harvard.edu/educators. This publication may not be digitized, photocopied, or otherwise reproduced, posted, or transmitted, without the permission of Harvard Business Publishing. Harvard Business Publishing is an affiliate of Harvard Business School. 83 4129 | Midland Energy Resources, Inc.: Cost of Capital Exploration & Production Midland engaged in all phases of exploration, development, and production, though the last of these, production, dominated the E&P division’s reported operating results. During 2006, Midland extracted approximately 2.10 million barrels of oil per day—a 6.3% increase over 2005 production— and roughly 7.28 billion cubic feet of natural gas per day—an increase of slightly less than 1% over 2005. This represented $22.4 billion of revenue and after-tax earnings of $12.6 billion. E&P was Midland’s most profitable business, and its net margin over the previous five years was among the highest in the industry. Midland expected continued global population and economic growth to result in rising demand for its products for the foreseeable future. Nevertheless, the fraction of production coming from nontraditional sources such as deepwater drilling, heavy oil recovery, liquefied natural gas (LNG), and arctic technology was expected to increase. Further, the geographic composition of output was shifting, marked by increases from places such as the Middle East, Central Asia, Russia, and West Africa. With oil prices at historic highs in early 2007, Midland anticipated continued heavy investment in acquisitions of promising properties, in development of its proved undeveloped reserves, and in expanding production. In particular, continued high prices underlay plans to boost investment in sophisticated extraction methods that extended the lives of older fields and marginal properties. Capital spending in E&P was expected to exceed $8 billion in 2007 and 2008. Refining and Marketing Midland had ownership interests in 40 refineries around the world with distillation capacity of 5.0 million barrels a day. Measured by revenue, Midland’s refining and marketing business was the company’s largest. Global revenue for 2006 was $203.0 billion—a slight decrease of approximately 1.8% over 2005. The division faced stiff competition, as its products were highly commoditized. After-tax earnings for refining and marketing totaled only $4.0 billion. The relatively small margin was consistent with a long-term trend in the industry; margins had declined steadily over the previous 20 years. Though most of Midland’s refinery output was gasoline and was sold as fuel for automobiles, the company also had manufacturing capacity to produce approximately 120,000 barrels of base-stock lubricants per day. Midland believed its capacity was as technologically advanced as any in the industry. Advanced technology and vertical integration combined to make Midland a market leader in this business. Midland projected capital spending in refining and marketing would remain stable, without substantial growth in 2007-08. This reflected both the historical trends of low and shrinking margins and the difficulty of obtaining the myriad approvals necessary to expand or to build and operate a new refinery. However, most analysts projected a longer-term global shortage of refining capacity that would eventually spur investment in this segment. Petrochemicals Petrochemicals was Midland’s smallest division, but was a substantial business nonetheless. Midland owned outright or had equity interests in 25 manufacturing facilities and five research centers in eight countries around the world. The company’s chemical products included polyethylene, polypropylene, styrene and polystyrene as well as olefins, 1-hexene, aromatics, and 2 BRIEFCASES | HARVARD BUSINESS PUBLISHING 84 Midland Energy Resources, Inc.: Cost of Capital | 4129 fuel and lubricant additives. In 2006, revenue and after-tax earnings were $23.2 billion and $2.1 billion, respectively. Capital spending in petrochemicals was expected to grow in the near-term as several older facilities were sold or retired and replaced by newer, more efficient capacity. Much of the new investment would be undertaken by joint ventures outside the United States in which Midland’s Petrochemicals Division owned a substantial minority interest. Midland’s Financial and Investment Policies Midland’s financial strategy in 2007 was founded on four pillars: (1) to fund significant overseas growth; (2) to invest in value-creating projects across all divisions; (3) to optimize its capital structure; and (4) to opportunistically repurchase undervalued shares. Overseas Growth The most easily exploited domestic resources had been put into production decades previously. Consequently, overseas investments were the main engine of growth for most large U.S. producers, and Midland was no exception. Midland usually invested in foreign projects alongside either a foreign government or a local business as partner. Often, these investments had specialized financial and contractual arrangements similar in many respects to project financing. In most cases, Midland acted as the lead developer of the project, for which it collected a management fee or royalty. Midland and its foreign partner shared the equity interest, with the foreign partner generally receiving at least 50% plus a preferred return. Despite the fact that the investments were located abroad, Midland analyzed and evaluated them in U.S. dollars by converting foreign currency cash flows to dollars and applying U.S. dollar discount rates. In 2006, Midland had earnings from equity affiliates of approximately $4.75 billion. The majority of these earnings, 77.7%, came from non-US investments. Value-creating Investments Midland used discounted cash flow methodologies to evaluate most prospective investments. Midland’s DCF methods typically involved debt-free cash flows and a hurdle rate equal to or derived from the WACC for the project or division. However, Midland’s interests in some overseas projects were instead analyzed as streams of future equity cash flows and discounted at a rate based on the cost of equity. The performance of a business or division over a given historical period was measured in two main ways. The first was performance against plan over 1- , 3- , and 5-year periods. The second was based on “economic value added” (EVA), in which debt-free cash flows1 were reduced by a capital charge, and expressed in dollars.2 The capital charge was computed as the WACC for the business or division times the amount of capital it employed during the period. 1 For purposes of EVA calculations, the company defined debt-free cash flows as net operating profit after taxes (NOPAT), which is EBIT(1-t). 2The basic EVA equation employed by Midland was EVA = NOPAT – (r HARVARD BUSINESS PUBLISHING | BRIEFCASES 85 wacc )(Invested Capital). 3 4129 | Midland Energy Resources, Inc.: Cost of Capital Optimal Capital Structure Midland optimized its capital structure in large part by prudently exploiting the borrowing capacity inherent in its energy reserves and in long-lived productive assets such as refining facilities. Debt levels were regularly reevaluated and long-term targets set accordingly. In particular, changes in energy price levels were correlated with changes in Midland’s stock price, and necessitated regular reassessments of optimal borrowing. In 2007 both oil prices and Midland’s stock price were at historic highs, which—all else equal—increased the company’s borrowing capacity. This in turn represented an opportunity to shield additional profits from taxes. Each of Midland’s divisions had its own target debt ratio. Targets were set based on considerations involving each division’s annual operating cash flow and the collateral value of its identifiable assets. Targets themselves tended to be “sticky,” but changes in the market value of specific collateral, such as oil reserves, or the market capitalization of the company as a whole could drive actual debt ratios away from corresponding targets. Mortensen’s team did not set targets—they were set in consultations among division and corporate executives and the board—but Mortensen did estimate a debt rating for each division based on its target, and a corresponding spread over treasury bonds to estimate divisional and corporate costs of debt.3 Mortensen’s preliminary estimates for 2007 are shown below in Table 1. Table 1 Business Segment: Consolidated Credit Rating A+ Exploration & Production Refining & Marketing Petrochemicals A+ BBB AA- Debt/ Spread to Value Treasury 42.2% 1.62% 46.0% 31.0% 40.0% 1.60% 1.80% 1.35% Note: Debt/Value is based on market values. At December 31, 2006, the company’s debt was rated A+ by Standard & Poor’s. Table 2 gives yields to maturity for U.S. Treasury bonds in January 2007. Table 2 Maturity: 1-Year 10-Year 30-Year Rate: 4.54% 4.66% 4.98% Finally, although prudent use of Midland’s debt capacity was a primary determinant of capital structure, other considerations played important roles as well. In particular, the strength of Midland’s consolidated balance sheet and its access to global financial and commodity markets sometimes presented attractive opportunities to trade securities and commodities. Midland was conservative compared to some of its large competitors, but it did have a group of traders in-house 3 The spread to Treasury refers to the amount the borrower will have to pay in interest cost above U.S. Treasury securities of a similar maturity. 4 BRIEFCASES | HARVARD BUSINESS PUBLISHING 86 Midland Energy Resources, Inc.: Cost of Capital | 4129 who actively managed currency, interest rate, and commodity risks within a set of guidelines approved by the board. The desire to manage certain risks, or to take advantage of private information or unusual pricing relationships, was an additional reason that the actual capital structure sometimes departed, temporarily, from planned targets. Stock Repurchases In the past, Midland had repurchased its own shares on occasion, and had stated that it would do so again whenever attractive opportunities arose. Consequently, the company regularly estimated the intrinsic value of its shares by subtracting the market value of its debt from the fundamental value of the enterprise and dividing the result by the number of shares outstanding. The fundamental value of the consolidated enterprise was estimated using DCF analyses and a comparison of the company’s trading multiples with those of its peers. When the stock price fell below the stock’s intrinsic value, Midland considered repurchasing its shares. Small numbers of shares could be purchased on the open market; larger blocks would be bought via self-tenders. Midland had not repurchased shares in large numbers since 2002 and no large purchases were anticipated by analysts in the near future, given the company’s high stock price. Nevertheless, Midland executives pointed out that the mere fact that the stock price had risen did not mean the shares were not undervalued – intrinsic value had clearly risen as well, and Midland remained committed to repurchasing shares when they were undervalued. Exhibit 4 shows Midland’s historical stock prices, dividends per share, and selected financial data for the period 2001-06. Estimating the Cost of Capital Mortensen’s primary calculations were based on the formula for WACC shown below. In this expression, D and E are the market values of the debt and equity respectively, and V is the firm’s or division’s enterprise value (V = D + E). Similarly, rd and re are the costs of debt and equity, respectively, and t is the tax rate. ⎛D⎞ ⎛E⎞ WACC = rd ⎜ ⎟(1 − t ) + re ⎜ ⎟ ⎝V ⎠ ⎝V ⎠ Cost of Debt Mortensen computed the cost of debt for each division by adding a premium, or spread, over U.S. Treasury securities of a similar maturity. The spread depended on a variety of factors, including the division’s cash flow from operations, the collateral value of the division’s assets, and overall credit market conditions. For some of Midland’s operations, long-term expected cash flow and collateral value were affected by political risk. This risk was most apparent, for example, in the exploration and production division. A significant fraction of E&P’s productive assets and proven reserves were located in politically volatile countries in which the risk of nationalization or a forced renegotiation of production rights was significant. All else equal, such properties supported less borrowing than might otherwise be expected. HARVARD BUSINESS PUBLISHING | BRIEFCASES 87 5 4129 | Midland Energy Resources, Inc.: Cost of Capital Cost of Equity To estimate the cost of equity, Mortensen used the Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM), shown below, in which rf denotes the risk-free rate of return, β is a measure of systematic risk, and EMRP denotes the equity market risk premium, that is, the amount by which the return on a broadly diversified portfolio of risky assets is expected to exceed the risk-free return over a specific holding period. re = rf + β(EMRP) Mortensen was aware that betas were measured, with error, from regressions of individual stock returns on market returns. She and her team used betas published in commercially available databases, rather than running their own regressions. Midland’s beta was 1.25, for example. However, betas for Midland’s divisions were not observable, since the divisions did not have traded shares of stock. To estimate betas for the divisions, Mortensen relied on published betas for publicly traded companies she deemed comparable to each division’s business. A selection of these, along with related financial data, is presented in Exhibit 5. In 2006 Midland used an equity market risk premium of 5.0%, but higher EMRPs—6.0% to 6.5%— had been used by Midland at various times in the past. Historical data on stock returns and bond yields, such as those presented in Exhibit 6, supported the higher estimates of the EMRP. Other data, such as the survey results shown in Exhibit 6, suggested lower figures. Midland adopted its current estimate of 5.0% after a review of recent research and in consultation with its professional advisors— primarily its bankers and auditors—as well as Wall Street analysts covering the industry. 6 BRIEFCASES | HARVARD BUSINESS PUBLISHING 88 Midland Energy Resources, Inc.: Cost of Capital | 4129 Exhibit 1 Midland Income Statements, Years ended December 31 ($ in millions) Operating Results: Operating Revenues Plus: Other Income Total Revenue & Other Income Less: Crude Oil & Product Purchases Less: Production & Manufacturing Less: Selling, General & Administrative Less: Depreciation & Depletion Less: Exploration Expense Less: Sales-Based Taxes Less: Other Taxes & Duties Operating Income Less: Interest Expense Less: Other Non-Operating Expenses Income Before Taxes Less: Taxes Net Income HARVARD BUSINESS PUBLISHING | BRIEFCASES 89 2004 2005 2006 $201,425 $249,246 $248,518 2,817 3,524 1,239 202,664 252,062 252,042 94,672 125,949 124,131 15,793 18,237 20,079 9,417 9,793 9,706 6,642 6,972 7,763 747 656 803 18,539 20,905 20,659 27,849 28,257 26,658 29,005 41,294 42,243 10,568 8,028 11,081 528 543 715 17,910 32,723 30,447 7,414 12,830 11,747 $10,496 $19,893 $18,701 7 4129 | Midland Energy Resources, Inc.: Cost of Capital Exhibit 2 Midland Balance Sheets, at December 31 ($ in millions) Assets: Cash & Cash equivalents Restricted Cash Notes Receivable Inventory Prepaid Expenses Total Current Assets 2005 $16,707 3,131 18,689 6,338 2,218 47,083 2006 $19,206 3,131 19,681 7,286 2,226 51,528 Investments & Advances Net Property, Plant & Equipment Other Assets Total Assets 30,140 156,630 10,818 244,671 34,205 167,350 9,294 262,378 Liabilities & Owners' Equity: Accounts Payable & Accrued Liabilities Current Portion of Long-Term Debt Taxes Payable Total Current Liabilities 24,562 26,534 5,723 56,819 26,576 20,767 5,462 52,805 Long-Term Debt Post Retirement Benefit Obligations Accrued Liabilities Deferred Taxes Other Long-Term Liabilities 82,414 6,950 4,375 14,197 2,423 81,078 9,473 4,839 14,179 2,725 Total Shareholders' Equity Total Liabilities & Owners' Equity 8 97,280 77,493 $244,671 $262,378 BRIEFCASES | HARVARD BUSINESS PUBLISHING 90 Midland Energy Resources, Inc.: Cost of Capital | 4129 Exhibit 3 Midland Segment Data ($ in millions) Exploration & Production: Operating Revenue After-Tax Earnings 2004 $15,931 6,781 Capital Expenditures Depreciation Total Assets 6,000 7,180 7,940 4,444 4,790 5,525 $76,866 $125,042 $140,100 Refining & Marketing: Operating Revenue After-Tax Earnings 2005 $20,870 13,349 2006 $22,357 12,556 2004 2005 2006 $166,280 $206,719 $202,971 2,320 4,382 4,047 Capital Expenditures Depreciation Total Assets 1,455 1,620 $60,688 1,550 1,591 $91,629 1,683 1,596 $93,829 Petrochemicals: Operating Revenue After-Tax Earnings 2004 $19,215 1,394 2005 $21,657 2,162 2006 $23,189 2,097 Capital Expenditures Depreciation Total Assets 305 578 $19,943 330 591 $28,000 436 642 $28,450 HARVARD BUSINESS PUBLISHING | BRIEFCASES 91 9 4129 | Midland Energy Resources, Inc.: Cost of Capital Exhibit 4 Stock Prices, Dividends and Selected Financial Data Stock Prices: Fourth Quarter Third Quarter Second Quarter First Quarter Dividends Per Share: Fourth Quarter Third Quarter Second Quarter First Quarter Annual Dividend Selected Financial Data: Net income ($ in millions) Shares Outstanding EPS Payout Ratio DPS 2001 $27.16 $27.90 $28.33 $24.13 2002 $31.29 $30.41 $27.80 $26.85 2003 $32.59 $29.42 $32.45 $31.57 2004 $34.37 $35.78 $36.98 $31.28 2005 $38.32 $40.29 $37.52 $34.58 2006 $44.11 $39.75 $46.32 $38.81 $0.28 $0.28 $0.28 $0.28 $1.11 $0.29 $0.29 $0.29 $0.29 $1.14 $0.30 $0.29 $0.29 $0.29 $1.17 $0.31 $0.31 $0.31 $0.31 $1.24 $0.34 $0.34 $0.34 $0.34 $1.35 $0.36 $0.36 $0.36 $0.36 $1.46 $15,303 2,049 7.47 14.8% $1.11 $11,448 2,025 5.65 20.2% $1.14 $11,848 2,035 5.82 19.9% $1.16 $10,496 2,055 5.11 24.2% $1.24 $19,893 2,945 6.75 20.0% $1.35 $18,701 2,951 6.34 23.0% $1.46 Note: Results have not been adjusted for a divestiture at the end of 2001 and an acquisition at the beginning of 2005. 10 BRIEFCASES | HARVARD BUSINESS PUBLISHING 92 Midland Energy Resources, Inc.: Cost of Capital | 4129 Exhibit 5 Comparable Company Information ($ in millions) Exploration & Production: Jackson Energy, Inc. Wide Plain Petroleum Corsicana Energy Corp. Worthington Petroleum Average Refining & Marketing: Bexar Energy, Inc. Kirk Corp. White Point Energy Petrarch Fuel Services Arkana Petroleum Corp. Beaumont Energy, Inc. Dameron Fuel Services Average Midland Energy Resources Equity Market Value $57,931 46,089 42,263 27,591 60,356 15,567 9,204 2,460 18,363 32,662 48,796 $134,114 Net Debt $6,480 39,375 6,442 13,098 6,200 3,017 1,925 (296) 5,931 6,743 24,525 $79,508 D/E 11.2% 85.4% 15.2% 47.5% 39.8% Equity Beta 0.89 1.21 1.11 1.39 1.15 LTM LTM Revenue Earnings $18,512 $4,981 17,827 8,495 14,505 4,467 12,820 3,506 10.3% 19.4% 20.9% -12.0% 32.3% 20.6% 50.3% 20.3% 1.70 0.94 1.78 0.24 1.25 1.04 1.42 1.20 160,708 67,751 31,682 18,874 49,117 59,989 58,750 9,560 1,713 1,402 112 3,353 1,467 4,646 59.3% 1.25 $251,003 $18,888 Market values are based on 12/31/06 closing prices. The average stock price for MIDLAND during 2006 was $42.31, and the average shares outstanding were 2,951 million. HARVARD BUSINESS PUBLISHING | BRIEFCASES 93 11 4129 | Midland Energy Resources, Inc.: Cost of Capital Exhibit 6 The Equity Market Risk Premium—Selected Data and Studies A. Selected historical data on U.S. stock returns minus Treasury bond yields Period Average excess return US Equities – T-Bonds Standard error 1987-2006 6.4% 3.7% 1967-2006 4.8% 2.6% 1926-2006 7.1% 2.2% 1900-2006 6.8% 1.9% 1872-2006 5.9% 1.6% 1798-2006 5.1% 1.2% Source: Pratt & Grabowski, Cost of Capital, Applications and Examples, John Wiley & Sons, 2008. Data are extracted from Exhibit 9.1, p. 95. B. Selected market risk premium survey results Researcher Survey Subjects Dates Respondents’ Risk Premia Welcha 500+ finance & economics professors 2001 Median: 3.6% ~400 U. S. CFOs Quarterly 2000-2006 Range: 2.5% - 4.7% 2006 Range: 2% - 4% Graham & Harveyb c Greenwich Associates US pension fund managers Interquartile range: 2.6%-5.6% Most recent survey (4Q2006): 3.3% Notes: a. Ivo Welch, “The Equity Premium Consensus Forecast Revisited,” Cowles Foundation Discussion Paper No. 1325, September 2001. b. John Graham & Campbell Harvey, “The Equity Risk Premium in 2006: Evidence from the Global CFO Outlook Survey,” downloaded at http://www.duke.edu/~charvey. c. Greenwich Associates, “Market Trends, Actuarial Assumptions, Funding, and Solvency Ratios,” Fall 2006. 12 BRIEFCASES | HARVARD BUSINESS PUBLISHING 94 IMD399 v. 20.07.2006 INTERNATIONAL SAURER: THE CHINA CHALLENGE (A) Professor Adrian Ryans prepared this case as a basis for class discussion rather than to illustrate either effective or ineffective handling of a business situation. Cost, market share and margin data have been changed to protect confidentiality. KREFELD, GERMANY: In December 2003 the management team at Saurer Twisting Systems was facing a series of difficult choices with respect to its machine business. The market for twisting machines had migrated rapidly to Asia, particularly China. The global market for these machines was in recession and Volkmann, one of the two brands in Saurer Twisting Systems, was seeing a significant decline in sales of machines for making staple yarn for apparel. Volkmann was the global leader in the high end of the market, but saw few opportunities to grow its business in that segment by taking market share away from its Japanese and European competitors. The lower end segment of the market had grown rapidly in recent years. In the critically important Chinese market, Volkmann’s lowest cost twisting machine, which was made in China, was about twice the price of the machines produced by its local Chinese competitors. In addition, Rifa, its major Chinese competitor, was investing in research and development and was rapidly upgrading its machines. Dr Dirk Burger, the CEO, and Wolfgang Leupers, the executive vice president, of Saurer Twisting, along with their management team and managers from Saurer China, were considering the introduction of a lower cost machine targeted at Chinese and Asian customers who could not afford their high-end solution. Margins on the new product were likely to be significantly lower than those on their existing products, even if they managed to achieve some very aggressive cost targets. In addition, the new machine could significantly cannibalize their existing high-end machine. If they did decide to introduce the new product, they would have to make some very difficult decisions about positioning, pricing, naming the product, and sales strategy. It was also not clear how the Chinese competitors would react to the launch of the new product. Copyright © 2005 by IMD - International Institute for Management Development, Lausanne, Switzerland. Not to be used or reproduced without written permission directly from IMD. 95 -2- IMD-5-0688 INTERNATIONAL Saurer Franz Saurer founded Saurer in 1853. The business began as a small foundry and engineering workshop. About 15 years later Saurer began manufacturing embroidery machines in Arbon in eastern Switzerland. Over the next one hundred years it diversified into a variety of industries. In the late 1980s, after significant financial difficulties and restructuring, it refocused, largely on the textile industry. Over the next decade Saurer made a series of acquisitions, many in textile machinery. Among the companies acquired were Hamel, Volkmann, Allma, Schlafhorst, Melco and Zinser. In 1999 Saurer purchased Barmag and Neumag, leading global players in machines for producing and finishing chemical fibers (as opposed to natural fibers, like cotton or wool). Most of the acquired companies were based in Germany. In 2003 Saurer was expected to have revenues of about €1.7 billion and net profit of over €45 million (refer to Exhibit 1 for some key financial data). About 73% of Saurer’s revenues were generated by Saurer Textile Solutions (STS). Saurer Textile Solutions STS was comprised of Saurer’s nine textile strategic business units. In 2002 the business units were placed under one management structure reporting to Henry Fischer, the CEO of Saurer. The business units shared centralized resources for marketing and sales, technology, and administration and human resources. STS’s mission was “to be the undebated market leader for full service solutions in textile engineering and set continuously new benchmarks for efficient production.” In line with this mission statement, STS was putting increasing emphasis on providing total solutions for customers in selected textile markets (refer to Exhibit 2 for ad). A Saurer total solutions package included the textile manufacturing equipment, project finance, turnkey plant and process support (including plant design, process integration, plant/machine start-up, and production support), local service, Internet support and marketing support. In early 2002 STS began the Tempus program--which aimed to radically reengineer business processes and the corporate culture--to enhance customer satisfaction and reduce fixed costs by at least €50 million by 2005. During 2003 STS completed a major program to outsource parts manufacturing. Some production was relocated to the Czech Republic and China. These moves gave it a much greater ability to weather the highly volatile cycles in the textile machinery industry and to adjust more rapidly to any changes in market demand. STS had a number of important strengths. Many of its business units had industryleading products, which incorporated state-of-the-art engineering. In the early years many of the STS predecessor companies had developed a deep understanding of textile production from their very close contact and working relationships with their European customers, who were often the leaders in their industries. Saurer’s stable of brands, such as Barmag, Volkmann and Schlafhorst, was very strong and highly regarded by many customers all over the world. Saurer also had a welldeveloped local sales and service presence around the world. The Tempus program had helped Saurer develop quite a flexible supply chain, so that STS had the best capital turns in the textile machinery industry. Fischer was still concerned that the company was not as customer focused and responsive to customer needs as it 96 -3- IMD-5-0688 INTERNATIONAL might be, and he believed there were still opportunities to drive more costs out of the business and to improve the company’s responsiveness. Textiles and the Textile Machinery Industry As shown in Exhibit 3, the textile industry can be broadly thought of as having four major value-added steps: fibers, yarns, fabrics, and apparel and made-up textile articles. Fibers come from two sources: natural and manmade. The yarns made from fibers are then made into fabrics, which are converted or incorporated into a variety of products, such as apparel, home textiles, vehicle tires, carpets, disposable clothing, baby diapers and luggage. Worldwide fiber consumption was growing by 2% to 3% per year, with manmade fibers, such as polyester and acrylic, growing at about 5% per year and natural fibers, such as wool, cotton and silk, showing little or no growth. The production of textile raw materials was increasingly concentrated in Asia. Over 50% of the world’s cotton was produced in Asia, with almost 25% in China alone. The only major producers outside of Asia were the United States and Brazil. In manmade fibers the situation was similar. In the case of polyester fiber, 83% of global manufacturing was done in Asia, with almost 50% of global manufacturing in China alone. Asian countries accounted for 85% of global exports of textiles and apparel in 2001. China and India also had huge domestic markets. China was expected to account for about 25% of the global textile industry in 2004. Some industry observers believed that this might rise to 50% by 2010 as a result of the elimination of quotas on China’s exports to North America and the European Union in January 2005. STS was the largest manufacturer of textile machinery in the world with a major presence in many steps of the textile value-added chain (refer to Exhibit 4). In most of the markets in which it competed, the Saurer business units had the leading market share (refer to Exhibit 5). Strategic Importance of China The globalization of the textile industry accelerated in the early 1990s. Decisions about where to locate new textile production facilities depended not only on the raw materials available in a geographic area, but also on the growth potential of the area and labor costs. Turkey, India and particularly China became growth markets for textile machinery. These new customers had different requirements than traditional Western customers. The latest technology and automation were no longer key choice factors. More emphasis was placed on simple and productionproven equipment and low prices. Given that China was a major source of textile raw materials, had a large domestic market and a large and growing position in textile exports, success in China was crucial for Saurer. Some steps in the textile manufacturing process, such as weaving and sewing, were still very labor intensive. Labor costs in the textile industry in China were between $0.40 and $0.70 per hour, versus about $15 per hour in the United States and over $20 per hour in Germany. Also the Chinese infrastructure, labor markets and productivity were better than those in other developing countries. It was theoretically cheaper to manufacture yarn, a highly 97 -4- IMD-5-0688 INTERNATIONAL automated part of the textile value chain, in the United States due to lower energy costs and cost of capital. However, since there were very few customers for yarn left in the United States, yarn manufacturing had also moved to Asia, and particularly to China. Historically, the textile machinery business was about one-third in Europe, onethird in North and South America and one-third in Asia. However, by 2003, more than 70% of textile manufacturing investments were being made in Asia, with about half of those in China. As a result of these developments, Saurer was increasingly dependent on Asian markets, especially China, for its sales (refer to Exhibit 6). This trend was expected to continue. Saurer in China Some of Saurer’s business units (or predecessor companies) were early participants in the Chinese market. Barmag had established a wholly owned sales subsidiary in Hong Kong in 1973, and for a period of time was the only company allowed to export machines for spinning manmade fibers to China. Service was provided out of Hong Kong. In 1984 Barmag began technical cooperation agreements with Shanghai Enfangi Company in Shanghai and with Wuxi Hong Yuan in Wuxi. During this period it had representatives in China, but all contracts had to be signed in Hong Kong. It also began to add service engineers in China, opening a service center in Beijing in 1985. In 1992 it established a joint venture (JV) in Beijing (initially 25% Barmag-owned, but later this was increased to 60%). In 1995 and 1996 Barmag established JVs with its Chinese partners in Shanghai (51% Barmag-owned) and Wuxi (53% Barmag-owned). These JVs were successful in further developing the Chinese market and were profitable. However, they were not without problems. JV partners set up parallel companies to develop their own products based on the knowledge they had gained from Barmag, and they even hired key personnel from the JV for the wholly owned company. Some of the parts supplied by the JV partners were of inferior quality, which impacted the image of the products. The partners often had a conflict of interest in making the best decisions for the joint companies. While Barmag nominally had the controlling interest in the JVs, the Chinese partners had the relationships that were so essential to business success in China in the 1990s. By 2000 it was clear that this approach, although successful in many respects, was not allowing Barmag to fully capitalize on the Chinese market opportunity. When China made a decision to allow wholly owned foreign subsidiaries in the late 1990s, Barmag established Barmag Textile Machinery (Suzhou) in 2001. It then proceeded to liquidate its Shanghai JV and took over the one in Wuxi. Taking over certain assets of the Wuxi JV was highly contentious, but ultimately successful. At the same time as two of Barmag’s JVs were being wound up, Saurer corporately decided to focus on establishing a direct presence for most of its business units in China. The joint ventures and other forms of cooperation with Chinese companies had helped create strong new Chinese competitors, which was viewed by Fischer as a “cost of learning about the Chinese market.” By late 2003 Saurer had about 1,000 employees in China with significant operations in Beijing, Suzhou and Wuxi. Over the previous two or three years, 98 -5- IMD-5-0688 INTERNATIONAL Saurer had developed an extensive sales and service organization in China. In 2005 Saurer planned to build a major new facility in Suzhou that would allow it to consolidate in one location much of its procurement activities, machine assembly and administration for all the business units operating in China. Saurer Volkmann History of Volkmann Volkmann was founded in 1904 in Krefeld, Germany by two Volkmann brothers. Initially, Volkmann manufactured textile machinery for the local silk and velvet industry. After World War II, Volkmann began producing twisting machines for the manufacture of yarns. Twisting is a mechanical finishing process for two or more spinning threads which are twisted around a common axis. The twisted yarn is higher quality with higher density and greater strength than single fibers; it has a noticeable twist structure that improves the appearance of woven and knitted goods. In 1954 Volkmann developed the breakthrough “Two-for-One” twisting machine, which resulted in one turn of the spindle inserting two turns in the yarn. This machine was significantly more productive and cost effective than conventional twisting machines. This gave the company a technological lead over its competitors. Largely as a result of this breakthrough, sales grew to over DM 10 million in the early 1960s. Over the next two decades, Volkmann expanded globally. By the end of the 1980s, Volkmann had evolved into a healthy, mid-sized enterprise, but felt that it needed to be part of a larger textile machinery company if it was to continue to be successful. This led to the merger with Saurer in 1990. Volkmann and Allma became Saurer Twisting Systems, but the two brands were retained. After the merger Volkmann’s activities were focused on twisting systems for staple fiber yarn production (mostly cotton, cotton blends, wool and wool blends) and carpet yarn twisting. In 1994 Volkmann introduced a new machine generation of Two-for-One twisters called the CompactTwister, which was designed to meet the requirements of customers in the new emerging textile markets (refer to Exhibit 7). The machine dramatically lowered customer costs. The benefits of the CompactTwister were also valued by customers in many Western markets, particularly Italy, and most of the initial sales were outside Asia. The machines were produced in Krefeld. The design of the product was also imitated by several of Volkmann’s competitors. Project “Dragon” Although the CompactTwister enjoyed some success in China, it only succeeded in capturing about 20% of the market (in units) for twisting machines in 1996 (refer to Exhibit 8). In early 1997 planning began for the production of CompactTwister in Asia (ultimately called Project “Dragon”). Volkmann set up a plant in Suzhou, a city in Jiangsu Province west of Shanghai. The product was initially targeted at the Chinese market, but, over time, the plan was to export it to 99 -6- IMD-5-0688 INTERNATIONAL other markets in the Far East. The plant was to have a capacity of 48,000 spindles per year (equivalent to 240 machines).1 The machines would be identical to those produced in Germany, but fewer options would be offered, thus reducing the complexity of the manufacturing and sourcing processes. The goal was to produce machines of the same quality as those made in Krefeld. The initial investment was about €3 million.2 After detailed analysis of the likely production costs, the management team estimated that by 2002 total product cost per spindle in China would be 25% lower than in Germany. The bulk of the parts for the Chinese machine would be sourced in China, but some key components would continue to come from Germany. In addition, as Volkmann developed component suppliers in China, some of them would be used to supply the Krefeld plant, replacing the more costly parts made in Germany. Project Dragon was not without risks. Among them were the political risks of investing in China, cost inflation in China, productivity levels in the Chinese plant, potential loss of the Volkmann quality image in Europe and North America, loss of intellectual property to Chinese competitors, and the impact on the cost structure in the Krefeld plant of the transfer of production volume to China. The reaction of the German work force to the loss of jobs to China was also an issue. As a result of Project Dragon, Twisting Systems was the first Saurer business unit to establish its own manufacturing operation in China. It began producing the CompactTwister in May 1998. It was priced in renmimbi and sold at a price about 15% below that of a German-built machine. The product was sold on the basis of superior German engineering, high quality and excellent performance. Sales grew rapidly from 1998 to 2002, when Volkmann sold over 40,000 spindles in China, accounting for about 40% of its global CompactTwister sales. Sales worldwide were down in 2003, but Chinese CompactTwister sales accounted for almost 50% of global sales. By 2003 it had succeeded in capturing about 15% of the Chinese market in terms of machine market share, but about 30% of the Chinese market in value terms.3 The market was much larger than had been projected in 1997, with about 1,000 machines expected to be sold in 2004 rather than the 550 anticipated in the 1997 business plan. The price realized and the degree of the CompactTwister’s success were pleasant surprises for Saurer management. As Fischer remarked: We were pleasantly surprised at how well such an expensive machine sold in China, and we realized that part of its success was due to the fact that it was priced in local currency, so that customers did not have to acquire foreign currency to make the purchase. 1 Since twisting machines varied in the number of spindles, number of spindles was a standard way of measuring market sizes and unit market shares. 2 Most figures are stated in euro or renmimbi (RMB) to simplify the presentation. The exchange rate in late 2003 was about €1 = RMB 10. 3 Volkmann tended to sell machines with more spindles than average. The combination of higher prices per spindle and more spindles per machine explains the difference between unit and RMB market shares. 100 -7- IMD-5-0688 INTERNATIONAL In some cases customers had to get a license from the government to import a machine, and this barrier was obviously removed when the machine was made in China. Volkmann global sales in 2003 were expected to be about €50 million, with just over half of that in staple yarn twisting machines and parts sold under the Volkmann brand. Gross margins on machine sales were typically about 35%. Market in China Volkmann’s Customers One of the challenges that Volkmann management faced was understanding the needs of the local Chinese customers. Until the late 1990s all textile companies had been state-owned. Some of these state-owned companies were very large, vertically integrated textile companies with thousands of employees; many of them provided social services such as education and health care for the workers and their families. There were two major segments of state-owned companies: those that produced for export markets and those that produced for the local Chinese market. The export-oriented firms were typically able to get licenses from the ministry responsible for textiles to buy imported textile machines. As stateowned companies began to be restructured in the 1990s, private, more entrepreneurial, companies were allowed to produce textile products. These companies tended to be much smaller, with 50--or fewer--to perhaps 500 employees. This led to a dramatic increase in the number of potential customers, with many of them initially buying one or two machines. Volkmann estimated that by 2003 there were perhaps 1,000 to 1,500 potential customers for staple fiber twisting machines in China, of which it had relationships with 250. The private companies paid much less attention than Western customers to total cost of ownership; rather, they were very focused on how long it would take a machine to pay for itself (“When will I get my money back?”). They felt that this would reduce their financial risk and give them the flexibility to redeploy their capital to a totally different industry if a better opportunity came up in a couple of years. In some cases, Chinese companies had to buy Western or Japanese equipment to meet their customers’ quality requirements. However, as soon as a local manufacturer could meet these standards and provide a faster payback, the companies tended to switch to the lower cost local manufacturer. Customers often ordered new machines only after they had received yarn orders. They then wanted quick delivery of the machines. Connections and relationships were still very important in many suppliercustomer interactions in China, as in the rest of Asia. In addition, given the low labor costs and the ease of replacing workers, most Chinese companies had little interest in machine ergonomics and automation, areas that were important to Western customers. However, the old attitudes were starting to change as more and more Chinese managers began to appreciate the efficiency of the machines and the quality of the products they produced, which would enable them to increase revenue and make more money. The attitude of most Chinese customers to after-sales service and support was also different. In North America and Europe, customers wanted no unplanned 101 -8- IMD-5-0688 INTERNATIONAL downtime. They invested in preventative maintenance and had planned annual shutdowns for maintenance. Customers sometimes contracted with Saurer to do this annual maintenance to minimize machine downtime. These service contracts, consumables and spare parts were a profitable business. In China, there was little interest in preventative maintenance or annual contracts. Some Saurer executives believed that this attitude was rooted in the old state-owned enterprise mentality of basing mill managers’ bonuses more on minimizing outside cash expenditures on spare parts than on machine uptime and efficiency. This was deeply ingrained in the mindset of some of the older managers, who had often worked for stateowned companies for most of their careers. The attitude was to repair the machine when it broke down and only to replace a part when it failed. This resulted in a need for quick replacement when a machine did come to a halt. Many of the parts could be fabricated very quickly in local machine shops close to the customers’ factories, although some of the electronic controls and higher technology parts still had to be bought from the original equipment manufacturer. The result of these attitudes and behaviors was that Saurer’s after-sales spare parts and service revenues per machine in China were only about one-third the level achieved in Western countries. This was very worrying to Fischer and other senior Saurer managers, since after sales-service and support were not only profitable but also a powerful way to develop close relationships with customers, identify new sales opportunities and gain a deep understanding of their evolving needs. Volkmann’s Competition in China Volkmann faced two major traditional twisting machine competitors in China, Muratec from Japan and Savio from Italy. Muratec was a diversified Japanese company with total revenues of less than €1 billion. It had traditionally been Volkmann’s strongest competitor in China, with almost twice the market share of Volkmann in the mid-1990s. Savio’s market share in the mid-1990s was slightly smaller than Volkmann’s. With the introduction of the Chinese-made CompactTwister, Volkmann became the market leader in China, although Muratec remained a significant player. The domestic Chinese competitors had become an increasingly important factor in the textile machinery market, and the twisting machine market was no exception to this trend. They had a dominant position in the lower end of the market and showed little respect for the intellectual property of Western and Japanese manufacturers. In the mid-1990s most of the locally made twisting machines in China were copies of either the Murata or Volkmann machines. After the introduction and success of the Volkmann CompactTwister, it was the one that was most imitated. In some cases even the colors of the machines and the brochures were reproduced (including printing errors). The copying was increasingly sophisticated. One of Saurer’s business units had delivered a new, state-of-the-art machine to one of its Chinese customers. A month later, the Saurer salesperson asked how the machine was performing and was told that the customer was not using it for production yet, since a team of engineers from a textile technology institute had taken the machine apart and were making computer-aided design (CAD) drawings of all the parts, so that they could be made available to Chinese manufacturers. Fischer had become philosophical about the inability to protect intellectual property in China, saying: “For the 102 -9- IMD-5-0688 INTERNATIONAL moment, it is a cost of doing business in China, just as dealing with the tort system is a cost of doing business in the US.” Some Chinese competitors were surprised that Western companies were so upset by the copying of intellectual property and responded with remarks such as: “You should be proud that we copy your machines--we only copy the best!” and “Every great painter starts by copying the great masters before developing a style of his own.” By 2003, there were three major Chinese competitors in the twisting market, with another 10 to 15 local companies in the market at any one time. Rifa Textile Machines, a private company, was the largest of the three. Rifa was founded in 1993 and by 2003 it had five subsidiary companies producing different types of textile machines. It was part of a large holding company. Rifa had originally copied Murata twisting machines, but partly in response to the demands of its own customers, it had steadily upgraded its machines--often using principles from the CompactTwister--and was now incorporating its own technology. It had recently invested in a 7,000 square meter research and development center, and was highly efficient from a production perspective. Rifa had a relatively large sales force with good coverage all over China. Taitan, the second Chinese competitor, was smaller than Rifa but followed a similar strategy. Wanli, the third major local competitor, was viewed as less of a threat by Volkmann management. Volkmann’s Chinese competitors were very focused on winning contracts, even if margins were very low. They seemed to be driven primarily by revenue growth rather than profit growth. The situation in India was similar to that in China. A strong local competitor, Veejay Lakshmi, had emerged and was following a strategy very similar to Rifa’s. It had captured about 70% market share in the Indian market and was exporting its twisting machines to some other developing countries, particularly those with expatriate Indian business people in the textile business. Muratec and Savio were also active in India. In Pakistan, Muratec had the dominant market share, but Rifa was beginning to gain some. Volkmann had very low market shares in both countries. Responding to the Local Chinese Challenge Although the CompactTwister was the clear market leader in the high end of the Chinese market, the product did not meet the needs of the lower-end customers in China and other Asian countries, who bought twisting machines from local competitors. Volkmann managers took some comfort from the fact that a few Chinese customers were attempting to compete in higher-end markets where better-quality and high-performance yarns were key and where the capabilities and flexibility of the CompactTwister were important. However, at the same time the quality and capabilities of the Rifa and Taitan machines were improving rapidly. Rifa was starting to supply twisting machines for some of the coarser wool and wool-blend yarns, a market which Volkmann and the other high-end competitors had traditionally owned. While the cotton and cotton blend market was still showing good growth in Asia, the wool and wool blend market was stagnant. After a trip to China in September 2003, Burger sent a memo to members of his management team which said in part: 103 - 10 - IMD-5-0688 INTERNATIONAL Besides the market slowdown in China, competition is getting worse and worse. Local competitors have reduced their prices by 30% per spindle. Machines from local competitors have less performance, but they are doing the job for counts lower than Ne 80.4 Our sales price is twice as much… It will be difficult to hold onto our market share with our existing pricing strategy… Therefore, it seems absolutely necessary to develop a new product for cotton that is less than Ne 80. A team with members from both Germany and China, under the leadership of Burger and Leupers, began investigating the opportunity. The team had had one face-to-face meeting in Krefeld to exchange information and do some preliminary planning. They attempted to quantify the size of the opportunity in the low end, customer requirements and price levels. They concluded that the CompactTwister, although well suited to wool and very fine cotton yarns, was over-engineered for less demanding segments. They estimated that the market size for the next few years would average about 1,000 machines (with 150 spindles per machine) per year, with about 300 in the high end and 700 in the low end. The market in the rest of Asia was expected to be almost as large. From their research the team put together the preliminary specification for a new twisting machine that would meet the needs of many lower-end customers making cotton and cotton blend yarns with medium and fine yarn counts. On some specifications, such as spindle speed, the proposed machine was higher than Rifa and the other local Chinese competitors, matched Muratec, but was lower than CompactTwister. On other specifications it was lower than all competitors, and on some other features that were standard on competitive machines, it offered the feature as an option for an additional charge. Overall, the team believed that the proposed product was superior to all of the products made by its Chinese competitors. They believed that the key elements of the value proposition for customers would be about 20% higher productivity, globally competitive yarn quality, lower energy and spare parts consumption, easy maintenance and high reliability. However, convincing the customers of the value of these benefits would take effective selling. The CompactTwister would continue to be the machine of choice for wool and wool blends, as well as very fine cotton yarn. The variable manufacturing cost per spindle for the proposed machine was estimated to be 25 to 30% lower than the CompactTwister in 2005, and that cost was expected to be reduced by about 3% per year. Other variable costs, including sales, installation and warranty, were expected to be about 15% of the sales price. VAT was 17%. In addition, there were fixed production and administration costs that had to be covered. Normally, these additional costs were about 8% of sales. Decision Time As they prepared for the crucial decision meeting on December 8, Burger and Leupers reviewed the arguments for and against the launch of the new product. They also looked at implementation issues the Volkmann and Saurer China team would have to resolve if the product was to be a profitable addition to the Volkmann product line. 4 The higher the count the finer was the yarn. Ne 80-count yarn was fine, but some Volkmann twisters could handle extremely fine yarn with counts as high as Ne 200. 104 - 11 - IMD-5-0688 INTERNATIONAL They could see several reasons for not moving ahead with the value solution. Volkmann’s name was synonymous with leading-edge engineering, and it had always positioned itself as the technology leader in twisting systems. If Volkmann introduced a value solution, it would almost certainly lead to some cannibalization of CompactTwister sales. Since Volkmann had historically focused on customers with high-end needs, its sales force had almost no contact with the target customers for the new machine, and it was used to selling the CompactTwister against low-end solutions. In fact, it would be quite difficult to identify the potential customers. A quick analysis had suggested that about 85% of the potential demand for the new machine would be in 6 of China’s 22 provinces. These six provinces had a population of almost 400 million. The biggest challenge would be making the low-end business a profitable one for Volkmann. Even at relatively high prices for the new machine and with an aggressive cost reduction program, the contribution margin was likely to be a fraction of that for CompactTwister. There was also the issue of how Rifa and the other Chinese and foreign competitors would react to Volkmann’s entry into this segment. Would they drop their prices in response? Rifa, in particular, was more vertically integrated than Volkmann and this might give it a cost advantage. In some cases, Volkmann used higher-quality components that resulted in higher costs. Volkmann spindle bearings were designed to last for 100,000 hours, and some had now been in machines for 15 years with no failures. If Volkmann decided to introduce the new product, it needed to develop a comprehensive marketing strategy. Among the major issues that needed to be addressed was the exact value proposition that would be communicated to the target customers, the pricing of the new product, the branding and naming of the product and the sales and marketing communications strategy. The pricing of the CompactTwister and competitive machines in late 2003 is shown in Exhibit 9. Some small local players had even lower prices than Taitan. Several names for the new product were also under consideration, including VolkTwister, CottonTwister and E-Twister (E for easy or economical). Volkmann currently had four regional managers, who also acted as sales representatives, together with three additional sales representatives to cover all of China. These sales representatives were paid a fixed salary and a commission based on the sales revenue the individual generated. Typically, about two-thirds of the representative’s total compensation came from the fixed salary. Saurer’s Suzhou organization would be responsible for installing and commissioning new machines and providing spare parts support. An obvious opportunity to launch the new machine was at the biannual CITME (China International Textile Machinery Exhibition), which was to be held in October 2004 in Beijing. At the 2002 CITME, the exhibition space occupied 50,000 square meters and attracted 850 exhibitors and 120,000 visitors. If a decision was made quickly and product development moved very quickly, a prototype could probably be built by mid2004 and the first regular production machines could be assembled and ready before CITME. 105 106 INTERNATIONAL 47 Net profit (loss) 671 580 142 468 Current assets Non-current assets Third-party loans Shareholders’ equity Source: Company information Capital expenditures 51 10.7% 1,251 Total assets Return on equity (ROE) 2003 Balance Sheet 125 88 EBIT Cash flow (from op. activities) 166 1,746 Sales EBITDA 2003 Income Statement 50 7.7% 431 206 630 671 1,301 2003 145 33 69 149 1,697 2002 Exhibit 1 Selected Financial Data (€ million) - 12 - 64 -12.3% 415 342 692 695 1,386 2001 117 -51 -36 100 1,593 2001 74 9.4% 470 276 688 646 1,334 2000 110 44 77 151 1,426 2000 IMD-5-0688 107 Source: Company information INTERNATIONAL Exhibit 2 Saurer Total Solutions Ad - 13 IMD-5-0688 108 Filament ƒ $UWLILFLDO 5D\RQ $FHWDWH ƒ 6\QWKHWLF 3RO\HVWHU 1\ORQ $FU\OLF Chemical industry (manmade fibers) ƒ 7RZHOV ƒ 6KHHWVSLOORZFDVHV ƒ &XUWDLQVDQGGUDSHV Home textiles ƒ 6KLUWVDQGEORXVHV ƒ 7URXVHUVDQGVKRUWV ƒ 6NLUWVDQGGUHVVHV ƒ 8QGHUZHDU Apparel Apparel and Made-up Textile Articles ƒ /XJJDJH ƒ 7HQWV ƒ %DJV Other made-ups Industrial fabrics Carpets and rugs Nonwoven Knit ƒ &RWWRQ PDQPDGH ILEHUV ƒ :RRODQGILQHDQLPDO KDLU ƒ 0DQPDGHILEHUV ƒ 6LON ƒ 'HQLP ƒ 3ULQWFORWK ƒ %URDGFORWK ƒ 6KHHWLQJ Spun Agricultural sector (natural) ƒ &RWWRQ ƒ :RRODQGILQHDQLPDOKDLU ƒ 6LON ƒ 5DPLH Woven Yarns Fabrics Exhibit 3 Textile Industry Value-Added Steps - 14 - Fibers Source: US International Trade Commission INTERNATIONAL IMD-5-0688 109 Source: Company information INTERNATIONAL 6DXUHU Neumag Nonwoven Schlafhorst Open-end Spinning Barmag Staple Fiber Spinning Spinning Preparation Zinser Ring Spinning Schlafhorst Winding Allma & Volkmann Twisting Weaving/Knitting Finishing/Printing/Dyeing Melco Saurer Embroidery Final Consumer Market Air-Jet Spinning Exhibit 4 Saurer’s Participation in the Textiles Value-Added Chain - 15 - POY Preparation Barmag & Neumag Filament Spinning Barmag Texturizing IMD-5-0688 110 Neumag Saurer Melco Allma, Hamel, Volkmann 30% 40% 40% 35% 38% 60% 25% Market Share 400-600 1 1 1 1 1 1,2 1 2,1 Saurer Pos. 10-50% 3 300-500 50% (excl. multihead) 500-750 650-1000 200-400 350-500 500-800 400-800 500-1000 Market Volume in CHF m Note: 1 Swiss Franc (CHF) was approximately € 0.63 Airlaid/Spunbond NONWOVENS Embroidery Systems EMBROIDERY Twisting Systems TWISTING Filament Spinning Synth. Staple fiber Texturing Barmag Neumag Barmag Schlafhorst Schlafhorst Winding Rotor Spinning Brands Zinser FILAMENT - 16 - Reifenhäuser, Fleissner Lässer, Tajima, Barudan Murata, Rieter, Leewa Savio TMT, Rieter Lurgi Zimmer, HILLS, Fare TMT, Rieter Rieter, Toyoda, Marzoli, LMW Murata, Savio Rieter, Savio Main Competitors Exhibit 5 Saurer’s Position in the Textile Value-Added Steps (2003) Ringspinning SPINNING Source: Company information INTERNATIONAL IMD-5-0688 111 Percentage of total sales 0% 10% 20% 30% 40% 50% 60% 70% 80% Source: Company information INTERNATIONAL 2001 2000 Asia 2002 2001 2000 Region America 2003 1995 2003 2002 Exhibit 6 Percentage of Saurer Textile Solution’s Sales by Region - 17 - 2001 2000 Europe 2003 2002 1995 1995 IMD-5-0688 112 Source: Company information INTERNATIONAL Exhibit 7 CompactTwister - 18 IMD-5-0688 113 $FWXDO 3URMHFWHG $VVXPHVWKDWVWDSOHILEHU PDUNHWJURZVDWSHU\HDU Saurer Germany Saurer China Muratec Savio Other Second hand Exhibit 8 Actual and Projected Sales of Staple Fiber Twisting Machines in China - 19 - 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 0 100 200 300 400 500 600 Source: Company information INTERNATIONAL Machines per year IMD-5-0688 114 :DQOL 5LID 7DLWDQ 9RONPDQQ &RPSDFW7ZLVWHU 0XUDWHF Price per spindle (in RMB) Source: Company information Exhibit 9 Approximate Pricing in China in Late 2003 - 20 - Manufacturer 1RWH$OOSULFHVLQFOXGH9$7 INTERNATIONAL IMD-5-0688 www.hbrreprints.org Multinationals and local firms for the first time are squaring off in China’s rapidly growing middle market—a critical staging ground for global expansion and the segment from which worldbeating companies will emerge. The Battle for China’s Good-Enough Market by Orit Gadiesh, Philip Leung, and Till Vestring Included with this full-text Harvard Business Review article: 1 Article Summary The Idea in Brief—the core idea The Idea in Practice—putting the idea to work 2 The Battle for China’s Good-Enough Market 12 Further Reading A list of related materials, with annotations to guide further exploration of the article’s ideas and applications Reprint R0709E 115 The Battle for China’s Good-Enough Market The Idea in Brief The Idea in Practice Between now and 2030, China will account for one-third of the world’s GDP growth. Yet many multinationals are losing share in this critical market. That’s because local businesses are targeting China’s ballooning cohort of midlevel consumers with reliable, low-cost products that are displacing multinationals’ premium offerings. And the regional upstarts making these “good enough” products plan to use the same strategy to challenge incumbents in other emerging markets. Gadiesh, Leung, and Vestring offer these guidelines for entering China’s goodenough space: COPYRIGHT © 2007 HARVARD BUSINESS SCHOOL PUBLISHING CORPORATION. ALL RIGHTS RESERVED. To defend your China position and prevent local competitors from becoming global threats, say Gadiesh, Leung, and Vestring, consider entering China’s good-enough space. For instance, attack the competition from above by lowering your costs and distributing simplified, reasonable-quality offerings. If you can’t reduce your costs quickly, use acquisitions to gain a toehold in this space. By managing the risks and opportunities inherent in China’s middle market, you’ll claim your share of this pivotal market. And you’ll strengthen your competitive position elsewhere around the globe. ATTACK FROM ABOVE Moving to the good-enough segment in China is risky if you’re already thriving in the premium space. For instance, your new offerings could cannibalize your high-end products. To mitigate the risks: • Analyze the differences between China’s premium and good-enough segments. You may discover strong geographic distinctions you can capitalize on. Example: GE Healthcare expanded sales of its MRI equipment in China by creating a line of simplified machines targeted at hospitals in China’s remote and financially constrained second- and third-tier cities. • Determine which capabilities and resources you’ll need to seize opportunities in the good-enough space. Example: GE Healthcare assigned a special team to observe target hospitals’ operations. Members also talked with administrators and physicians to determine the kinds of medical equipment they wanted, features they needed, possible price points, and required distribution and services. GE then reconfigured its existing networks of sales, distribution, and services to serve this new market. • Stake claims in the good-enough space to box out emerging local players and global competitors that might be eyeing the same target market. By entering this space ahead of the pack, GE Healthcare defended its position against local upstarts, capturing 52% of the $238 million market in 2004. USE ACQUISITIONS If you can’t alter your cost structure or business processes quickly enough to compete with local players, consider mergers and acquisitions. Example: Anheuser-Busch owned 27% of Tsingtao Brewery, one of China’s largest brewers. It outbid competitor SABMiller to acquire Harbin, the fourth-largest brewer in China. The acquisition enabled Anheuser-Busch to reach the masses while preventing Harbin from swimming upstream. Note, though, that non-Chinese acquirers are facing tougher M&A approval processes. To increase your chances of gaining regulatory and political approval: • Draft a compelling business case for the acquisition, citing benefits for local companies and authorities. • Be willing to adjust the structure, terms, and conditions of the deal. • Engage in heavy-duty relationship building, to woo critical players. Also, to ensure that each acquisition delivers the maximum possible value: • Select a target company that offers cost and distribution synergies with your firm and whose products won’t cannibalize your premium brands. • Overinvest in the due diligence process. • Take a systematic approach to postmerger integration. page 1 116 Multinationals and local firms for the first time are squaring off in China’s rapidly growing middle market—a critical staging ground for global expansion and the segment from which world-beating companies will emerge. The Battle for China’s Good-Enough Market COPYRIGHT © 2007 HARVARD BUSINESS SCHOOL PUBLISHING CORPORATION. ALL RIGHTS RESERVED. by Orit Gadiesh, Philip Leung, and Till Vestring Caterpillar, the world leader in construction equipment, is having trouble making deeper tracks in China. The U.S.-based manufacturer of tractors, backhoes, road graders, and other devices began selling equipment in China in 1975, a year before the death of Chairman Mao. As the Chinese government invested massively in infrastructure, Caterpillar helped pave the way, literally, for economic growth and modernization in the world’s fastestgrowing market for construction equipment. Like many foreign players in any number of industries, Caterpillar got its start in China by selling goods to the Chinese government— the only possible customer before the era of economic reform—and then began selling high-quality equipment to the private sector as a premium segment of the market emerged. But it never broadened its focus to include other segments, and by the early 2000s, Komatsu, Hitachi, Daewoo, and other competitors from Japan and Korea were in the middle market with tools and equipment that cost less but were still reliable. Mean- harvard business review • september 2007 while, a tranche of local manufacturers that had previously been focused only on the low end of the market were burrowing up to battle the established players, designing and releasing their own products targeted squarely at middle-market consumers. As the experiences of Caterpillar and other multinationals suggest, a critical new battleground is emerging for companies seeking to establish, sustain, or expand their presence in China: It’s the “good-enough” market segment, home of reliable-enough products at low-enough prices to attract the cream of China’s fast-growing cohort of midlevel consumers. Harvard professor Clay Christensen, author of The Innovator’s Dilemma, has used the phrase “good enough” to suggest that start-up companies developing and releasing new products and services don’t necessarily need to aim for perfection to make inroads against established players. The phrase can be similarly applied to middle-market players in China that have been able to steal a march on page 2 117 The Battle for China’s Good-Enough Market incumbents by developing and releasing good-enough products that are displacing premium ones. These forward-thinking companies (multinational and domestic firms alike) are doing more than just seizing share of wallet and share of mind in China’s rapidly expanding middle market—in and of itself a major achievement. They are conditioning themselves for worldwide competition tomorrow: They’re building the scale, expertise, and business capabilities they’ll need to export their China offerings to other large emerging markets (India and Brazil, for instance) and, ultimately, to the developed markets. Given China’s share of global market growth (Goldman Sachs estimates that China will account for 36% of the world’s incremental GDP between 2000 and 2030) and the country’s role in preparing companies to pursue opportunities in other developing regions, it’s becoming clear that businesses wanting to succeed globally will need to win in China first. In the following pages, we’ll explore the importance of China as a lead market. We’ll describe the surge of activity in China’s middle market; when (and whether) multinationals and Chinese companies should enter this vibrant arena for growth; and, most important, how they can compete effectively in the good-enough segment. As Caterpillar and other foreign players have learned, achieving leadership in China’s middle market isn’t easy. An Evolving Opportunity Orit Gadiesh (orit.gadiesh@bain.com) is the chairman of Bain & Company in Boston. Philip Leung (philip.leung@ bain.com), a Bain partner in Shanghai, leads the firm’s Greater China health care practice. Till Vestring (till.vestring@ bain.com), a Bain partner based in Singapore, leads the firm’s Asia-Pacific industrial practice. Historically, there has been a simple structure to China’s markets: at the top, a small premium segment served by foreign companies realizing solid margins and rapid growth; at the bottom, a large low-end segment served by local companies offering lowquality, undifferentiated products (typically 40% to 90% cheaper than premium ones) that often lose money—when producers do their accounting right. Between the two is the rapidly expanding good-enough segment. (For an example of how one market sector breaks out, see the exhibit “The Structure of China’s Market for Televisions.”) The good-enough space in China is growing for many reasons, not the least of which are recent shifts in consumer buying patterns harvard business review • september 2007 and preferences. These shifts are coming from two directions: Consumers with rising incomes are trading up from the low-end products they previously purchased. At the same time, higher-income consumers are moving away from pricey foreign brands and accepting less expensive, locally produced alternatives of reasonable quality. The same holds true on the B2B front. Consequently, China’s middle market is growing faster than both the premium and low-end segments. In some categories, the good-enough space already accounts for nearly half of all revenues. Eight out of every ten washing machines and televisions now sold in China are good-enough brands. It should come as no surprise, then, that China—and, in particular, its opportunityrich middle market—is increasingly capturing multinational executives’ resources and attention. As Mark Bernhard, chief financial officer of General Motors’ Shanghai-based GM China Group, recently told the Detroit News: “For GM to remain a global industry leader, we must also be a leader in China.” The automaker’s strategy in China embodies that belief. GM had traditionally been an underperformer in the market for small cars. However, its acquisition of Korea’s ailing Daewoo Motor in 2002 enabled it to compete and ultimately take a leadership position in China. The deal allowed GM to develop new models for half what it would cost the company to develop them in the West. Daewoodesigned cars now make up more than 50% of GM’s sales in China, currently its second biggest market. What’s more, GM is using these vehicles to compete against Asian automakers and sell small cars in more than 150 markets around the world, from India to the United States. Colgate-Palmolive made similar moves in China. It entered into a joint venture in the early 1990s with one of China’s largest toothpaste producers, and it acquired China’s market leader for toothbrushes a decade later, allowing it to scale up and then leverage its production processes to compete in other parts of the world. As a result, Colgate more than doubled its oral hygiene revenues in China between 1998 and 2005, and it now exports its China products to 70 countries. Local Chinese competitors pose the biggest challenge to multinationals seeking to capi- page 3 118 The Battle for China’s Good-Enough Market talize on their business ventures in China and beyond. In the auto industry, for instance, domestic carmakers like Geely and Chery have eaten away at Western companies’ market share in China by introducing good-enough cars for local consumption. Several of these automakers have started exhibiting vehicles at car shows in the United States and Europe, buying available Western brands, and exporting vehicles to other emerging markets. True, these players face enormous challenges in meeting safety and emissions standards and in building up the required distribution networks to compete in Europe and North America. But no Western company should underestimate the determination of Chinese firms to figure out how to meet international quality standards and make their global mark. European and North American companies producing major appliances, microwaves, and televisions know this all too well. They abdicated China to low-cost local competitors in the 1990s and now find themselves struggling to compete globally against those same Chinese companies. Haier, which started making refrigerators in 1984, went on to become one of China’s best-known brands and then used its hard-won scale advantages and manufacturing skills to crack, and then dominate, foreign markets. Today, it is one of the largest refrigerator companies in the world, controlling 8.3% of the highly fragmented global market. The company sells products in more than 100 markets, including the United States, Africa, and Pakistan. Obviously, the stakes in China have changed. Local companies are using booming domestic markets to hone their strategies at home before taking on the world. Multinationals, therefore, need to defend their positions in China not only to profit from the economic growth in that country but also to prevent local competitors from becoming global threats. The good-enough space is where multinationals and Chinese firms are going head-to-head—and it’s the market segment from which the world’s leading companies will emerge. Making an Entrance It’s one thing to recognize the importance of China’s middle market; it’s another thing entirely to turn that awareness into action. The first step in winning the battle for China’s good-enough market is determining when— or when not—to enter the fray. That will depend on the attractiveness of the premium segment: Is it still growing? Are companies still achieving high returns or are returns eroding? Another consideration is your company’s market position: Are you a leader or a niche player? (See the exhibit “Should You Enter the Middle Market?”) Foreign companies grappling with the goodenough decision in China will need to consider these factors and perform thorough market and competitor analyses, along with careful The Structure of China’s Market for Televisions Premium (Narrow) Good-Enough (Rapidly Expanding) Low-End (Evolving Base) Definition: High-end products purchased by discerning customers with significant purchasing power. Definition: Products of good quality, produced by local companies for a rapidly expanding group of value-seeking consumers with midlevel incomes. Leading Vendors: Panasonic, Philips, Sony Leading Vendors: Hisense, Skyworth, TCL Definition: Products of lower quality, meeting basic needs, produced by local firms for a large group of consumers with low incomes. Product Features: LCD and plasma screens, many stateof-the art user features, priced according to their status as international brands. Product Features: LCD, plasma, and large cathode-ray tube screens, with limited user features, priced to undercut foreign brands. Product Features: Cathode-ray tube screens with basic standard user features and low-cost components, priced to sell. Share of Market in 2005: 13% Share of Market in 2005: 62% Share of Market in 2005: 25% harvard business review • september 2007 Leading Vendor: Konka page 4 119 The Battle for China’s Good-Enough Market customer segmentation and needs analyses— classic strategy tools, of course, but applied in the context of a rapidly changing economy that may lack historical data on market share, prices, and the like. Senior managers will need to establish the factors that are key to success in everything from branding to pricing to distribution. This knowledge will inform important decisions about whether companies should expand organically into the middle market, acquire an existing player in that space, or find a good-enough partner. Generally speaking, competing in the goodenough space is neither necessary nor wise for multinationals operating in stable premium segments. These companies should instead focus on lowering their costs and innovating to maintain their premium or niche positions and to sustain their margins. We studied one large manufacturer of automation equipment, for example, that wisely decided to stand pat in the premium segment. Market research suggested that its customers were still willing to pay more for reliability, even with a variety of lower-cost choices out there. The company continued to invest in R&D, hoping to further differentiate its products from those of local players; it expanded its distribution and service networks to improve its responsiveness to customers; and it cut costs by taking advantage of local production resources. Few multinationals find themselves in such a fortunate position, however. If growth in the premium segment is slowing and returns are eroding, multinational corporations will need to enter the good-enough space. Even those companies that because of their strong competitive position initially abstain from entering the middle market should revisit their decision frequently to guard against emerging competitive threats. For their part, Chinese companies will need to move upmarket as the lower-end segment becomes increasingly competitive. Our research and experience indicate that companies contemplating a move into the good-enough space go about it in one of three basic ways: Leading multinationals in the premium segment attack from above. The goal for Should You Enter the Middle Market? Multinationals deciding whether to move into China’s middle market need to first consider the attractiveness of the premium segment and their current market position. If conditions warrant, they can attack aggressively from above. Chinese firms can burrow up from below. Both can acquire their way into the good-enough space. STATE OF THE PREMIUM MARKET SEGMENT STRONG WEAK OR ERODING Maintain strong premium status Attack from above or buy your way in Hold off on entering the goodenough segment of the market— Premium players employ an for now. Drop prices as required to remain competitive; lower costs and innovate to defend premium enter the middle market. That is, they enter the good-enough segment in order to defend against the status and sustain margin. rise of local competitors and the erosion of the premium segment. Regularly reevaluate the decision not to enter. WEAK OR ERODING COMPANIES’ COMPETITIVE POSITION STRONG offensive-defense approach to Innovate to maintain current premium status Burrow up from below or buy your way in Hold off on entering the goodenough segment of the market— Value players enter the goodenough segment using a break- for now. Increase innovation efforts to capture a niche position in the premium segment. through approach—with a merger, for instance, or by developing China-specific products or busi- Regularly reevaluate the decision not to enter. harvard business review • september 2007 ness models—to steal share from incumbents and attain market leadership. page 5 120 The Battle for China’s Good-Enough Market these organizations is to lower their manufacturing costs, introduce simplified products or services, and broaden their distribution networks while maintaining reasonable quality. Meanwhile, Chinese challengers in the low-end segment tend to burrow up from below. These companies aim to take the legs out from under established players by providing new offerings that ratchet up quality but cost consumers much less than the premium products do. And, finally, multinationals that can’t reduce their costs fast enough, and domestic players looking for more skills, technology, and talent, buy their way in. Each of these moves comes with its own set of traps. The challenge, then, for companies eyeing the middle market is to understand why those that went before them failed in this space—and how to sidestep the pitfalls they encountered. Let’s take a closer look at these three approaches. Attacking from Above Whether they’re selling toothpaste or power transmission equipment, multinational companies dominate China’s small but highmargin premium segment—the only one in which foreign players have traditionally been able to compete successfully. So a move toward the middle certainly holds a fair amount of risk for those already thriving in the premium space. A chief concern is cannibalization. After all, selling to consumers in less-than-premium segments could negatively affect sales of highend products. These companies also run the risk of fueling gray markets for their wares. If, say, a business sells a T-shirt for $10 in China but $20 in the United States, there’s a good chance an enterprising distributor will find a way to buy that T-shirt in China and export it to the United States for sale there. Multinational managers, therefore, need to conduct careful market analyses to understand the differences between China’s premium and good-enough segments. There may be, for instance, strong geographic distinctions a company can capitalize on. Consider the strategy GE Healthcare employed to expand sales of its MRI equipment in China. The company created a line of simplified machines targeted at hospitals in China’s remote and financially constrained second- and third-tier cities— places like Hefei and Lanzhou, where other multinationals rarely ventured. That good- harvard business review • september 2007 enough territory had all the right conditions: It was a fast-growing market whose customers’ purchasing criteria weren’t likely to change soon. GE’s cost structure allowed it to compete with other middle-market players in the industry. And there was little risk that the company would cannibalize its premium line of diagnostic machines; large city hospitals were not keen on downgrading their MRI equipment. Markets are dynamic, and there’s no place on the planet where they are shifting as quickly or as dramatically as in China. So multinational executives also need to think about the degree to which the premium and good-enough segments will converge over time. Managers can use traditional forecasting methods (scenario planning, war gaming, consultations with leading-edge customers, and so on) to pick up on emerging threats and impending opportunities. Which brings us back to GE Healthcare’s MRI expansion plans: The company’s long-held commitment to health care development in China meshed perfectly with Chinese leaders’ publicly stated desire to improve health services in less-privileged areas of the country. Given the government’s aims, GE Healthcare understood there would eventually be some overlap of the premium, middle, and lowend markets—and profitable opportunities in the good-enough space. After weighing the risks that cannibalization and dynamic markets pose to their company’s premium positioning, managers in multinationals need to consider their possible opportunities in the good-enough space: Can they take advantage of their lower purchasing costs, greater manufacturing scale, and distribution synergies? Then they have to determine which capabilities they may need to develop: How adept is their organization at designing products, services, brands, and sales approaches that will attract customers in the middle market without diminishing their company’s position in the premium space? They may need to convene teams dedicated solely to studying the opportunities and resources required in the good-enough segment, as GE Healthcare did. (See the sidebar, “Penetrating the GoodEnough Market, One County Hospital at a Time.”) They may also want to recruit local management talent—individuals with experience competing in the middle space— page 6 121 The Battle for China’s Good-Enough Market or purchase local companies to gain new technologies or expertise. Those multinationals that decide to enter the middle market tend to employ an “offensivedefense” strategy—aggressively staking claims in the good-enough space to box out emerging local players and established global competitors seeking to gain their own scale advantages. By entering the good-enough space ahead of the pack, for instance, GE Healthcare was able to defend its position against local upstarts, including Mindray, Wandong, and Anke. The company is still trying to develop the optimal product portfolio and is addressing such issues as how best to service the equipment. Even so, GE captured 52% of the $238 million market in 2004, generating roughly $120 million in sales. Having honed its approach to the goodenough space, GE is replicating the strategy in new markets in several developing countries, including India. Multinationals are bound to find it tough to jump in from above. Apart from the risks of cannibalization and all the challenges always associated with going down-market, companies will need to adapt fast, as customers’ preferences change and competitors react. And they will probably need to tear apart the cost structure of their good-enough competitors to understand how those firms make money while charging such low prices. Just switching to local sourcing, for instance, may not be sufficient for large multinationals to match the lower production costs of their domestic competitors. Burrowing Up from Below Multinationals for years underestimated the ability and desire of local players in the low end of the market to move up and compete— a miscalculation that may now be coming home to roost. Recent developments have strengthened local competition in China and facilitated Chinese companies’ moves upmarket and beyond. Let’s start with consolidation. For years, there were often hundreds of companies in a single industry catering primarily to customers in the low end of the market and typically focusing on regional needs. Many of those companies operated unprofitably— think of Red Star Appliances or Wuhan Xi Dao Industrial Stock. Because of China’s free-market reforms, however, the weakest of those competitors are folding, and industries are experiencing waves of consolidation. Red Star, Wuhan Xi Dao, and 16 other money-losing concerns shifted and reshifted throughout the 1990s to form appliance maker Haier. A competent player or two, like Haier, have risen in each industry, often benefiting from national support. China’s booming economy has enabled these survivors to build scale and develop market capabilities such as R&D and branding. As we Penetrating the Good-Enough Market, One County Hospital at a Time GE Healthcare already had a successful business selling high-end medical equipment in China when the Chinese government set a goal for the next decade of improving the health care available in less-privileged locales. To support the government’s efforts and also to break out of the high end of the market, GE developed a business case for manufacturing and selling medical devices for China’s goodenough market. CEO Jeff Immelt’s visits and conversations with Chinese leaders motivated the company to pursue the opportunity. In the end, GE’s research and analysis identified a substantial demand from thousands of midtier and low-end Chinese hospitals in less affluent provinces that were not served by multinationals. GE knew that it could design new products and business models to serve this market. GE also knew that by using techniques like Six Sigma to eliminate manufacturing waste, it could make its costs competitive. A team was charged with observing operations in the target hospitals and meeting with the hospital administrators and physicians to help determine what sort of medical equipment customers wanted, the specific features they needed, possible price points, and the kinds of distribution and services that would be required. Armed with this information, the fact-finding team considered stripping out some of the expensive equipment features and adding others that these target customers valued more. For instance, doctors in China’s high-end hospitals preferred to program the harvard business review • september 2007 medical equipment themselves, whereas physicians in the midlevel and low-end hospitals, who considered themselves less computer savvy, preferred preprogrammed machines. The team worked with staffers in GE’s R&D and manufacturing groups to build the right products at the right price points for the good-enough market. Because GE’s existing sales, distribution, and service systems were not geared to the target customers, the company also had to reconfigure its networks of existing representatives and recruit new ones. This middle-market initiative is still a work in progress, but GE Healthcare has taken an enormous first step in establishing itself—and defending itself against rivals—in the good-enough segment. page 7 122 The Battle for China’s Good-Enough Market Chinese customers are becoming less willing to shell out 70% to 100% premiums for international products. At most they may pay 20% to 30% more for world-class brands. have seen, over time, several of these emerging domestic champions have become direct challengers to global companies in a variety of industries. Next, look at the rapidly expanding customer base in the middle space. Chinese customers—whether individual consumers, businesses, or government agencies—are becoming less willing to shell out 70% to 100% premiums for international products. At most, they may pay 20% to 30% more for world-class brands. The Italian dairy giant Parmalat discovered exactly that when it tried selling fruit-flavored yogurt for the equivalent of 24 cents a cup. Instead, consumers went with local brands at half the price. It seemed that brand, innovation, and quality—the hallmarks of multinationals in China—were no longer critical points of differentiation in customers’ minds. This price sensitivity is opening up new ground for ambitious Chinese companies traditionally focused on the low end. These firms are designing and releasing good-enough products that overcome buyers’ skepticism about quality at much lower prices, which generate higher margins than their low-end products. The often brutal competitive dynamics in the lowend segment also serve as a huge incentive for the better-managed local companies to move up. Until consumer demand began to explode in China, however, there really wasn’t anywhere for these firms to go. Now there is. The journey from low end to good-enough to global usually takes a decade and then some—but more and more Chinese companies are embarking on it. For instance, Lenovo, founded in 1984, entered the goodenough segment via a joint venture, flourished in the middle market, and then went on to establish its international brand with the purchase of IBM’s PC division in 2005 for $1.75 billion. It is currently the world’s third-largest PC maker. Similarly, Huawei Technologies has grown since 1988 to the point where 31 of the first 50 firms on Standard & Poor’s ranking of the world’s top telecom companies are clients of the Chinese maker of mobile and fixed telecommunications networks. Just as foreign players approaching the market from above come face-to-face with their shortcomings—high costs, limited distribution capabilities, and the possibility of harvard business review • september 2007 cannibalizing their own products—local companies moving up encounter their own limitations. Foremost is the shortage of managerial talent, especially for international businesses. Growing numbers of Chinese students are pursuing MBAs and studying abroad. They are slowly distinguishing themselves from the large cohort of current Chinese managers, whose command-and-control leadership style dominates local manufacturing houses. But catching up remains difficult, as China’s surging economic growth outpaces the country’s ability to educate and apprentice twenty-first-century managers. Another obstacle for Chinese companies is their inability to compete with global players through innovation or by establishing a strong brand because of their limited size and their lack of management tools and experience. A question like “How much should we spend on advertising?” can stymie local managers looking at expansion. Long used to competing solely on price, they have little experience in understanding and addressing segmentspecific needs, linking those needs to R&D and brand-building efforts, and creating the required infrastructure in sales and distribution. Consider the early successes enjoyed by Chinese handset manufacturer Ningbo Bird. It was among a group of small, local companies that took 20% to 30% of the telecom market between 2000 and 2002 from the likes of Nokia and Motorola. Ningbo Bird prevailed by competing on price. But its success was short-lived, its march toward global expansion thwarted. The company just didn’t have the expertise and resources the foreign corporations had in customer segmentation, R&D, innovation, and distribution. By contrast, Huawei has been able to successfully navigate such roadblocks. Initially established as a network equipment distributor, Huawei has built and acquired the technical and managerial capabilities it needed to rise up from the low end of the market. From its inception, Huawei invested 10% of its sales in R&D. It developed its own products to penetrate new segments in China and forged technical alliances to further broaden its product mix. With government support, Huawei prompted consolidation in the domestic market, gaining massive scale in the process. The company now controls 14% of the local market for telecom networks. page 8 123 The Battle for China’s Good-Enough Market Firmly established in the good-enough space at home, Huawei built brands to meet the requirements of global customers. It established 12 R&D centers around the world, pioneering next-generation technologies (customized communication networks and voice access systems) and partnering with global brands such as 3Com to build customer awareness of its own brands. Huawei has broadened its reach in stages over 14 years. The company first focused on establishing itself in developing regions of China, where multinationals had less incentive to compete. It then penetrated countries with emerging economies, such as Russia and Brazil. Finally, it attacked the developed countries. It has expanded internationally through aggressive sales and marketing, by taking advantage of low-cost China-based R&D, and by leveraging its ability to outsource some of its manufacturing processes to other players in China. A little more than a decade ago, Huawei was a regional company in a local market that few multinationals considered important. With 2005 revenues of $8.2 billion, it is now second only to Cisco, according to InfoTech Trends’ ranking of the networking hardware industry. It could never have ascended the way it has without using China’s good-enough segment as a springboard for growth. Buying Your Way In For multinational companies that can’t alter their costs or processes quickly enough to compete with local players, and for Chinese firms that lack the production scale, R&D mechanisms, and customer-facing capabilities to compete with foreign players, there is still a breakthrough option for entering the middle market—mergers and acquisitions. China’s entry into the World Trade Organization in 2001 fueled a surge in M&A activity. Now, however, foreign acquirers are facing tougher approval processes. China’s public commitment to open markets remains strong, but several high-profile deals have gotten stuck at the provincial or ministerial level, owing to increasing public concerns about selling out to foreign firms. For instance, in its bid to buy Xugong Group Construction Machinery, China’s largest construction machinery manufacturer and distributor, the U.S. private equity firm Carlyle Group met with unexpected resis- harvard business review • september 2007 tance from the government and ended up twice reducing its stake, ultimately to 45%. In rejecting successive Carlyle bids, officials in Beijing insisted the nation’s construction equipment industry should be controlled by “domestic hands.” As the Carlyle Group learned, gaining regulatory and political approval for M&As in China is a major undertaking. Foreign companies seeking such approval may need to draft (and redraft) a compelling business case for the acquisition, one that cites up front the benefits for local companies and authorities. Like Carlyle, they must be willing to adjust (and readjust) the structure, terms, and conditions of a deal to gain government support. They may also need to engage in heavy-duty relationship building, investing the time and resources required to woo critical players in the deal. As is always the case with M&As the world over, it’s all about fit: There should be cost and distribution synergies between the multinational and its target and little chance that the local company’s products will cannibalize the multinational’s premium brands. Successful acquirers in China—multinationals and Chinese firms alike—use a clear strategic rationale to select the right target. They overinvest in the due diligence process. They take a systematic approach to postmerger integration. That was the game plan behind Gillette’s 2003 acquisition of Nanfu, then China’s leading battery manufacturer. Gillette’s Duracell division throughout the 1990s was losing market share in China to lower-priced competitors. By 2002, Duracell’s share of the Chinese domestic battery market was 6.5%. By contrast, Nanfu controlled more than half the market. After careful analysis, Gillette’s management team recognized that its Duracell unit was at a cost disadvantage compared with its rivals and concluded it would be difficult to broaden the brand’s market penetration. Facing such odds, Gillette decided to buy into the good-enough market, acquiring a majority stake in Nanfu. But Gillette was extremely careful to protect both Duracell’s and Nanfu’s brands in their respective segments. Gillette continues to sell premium batteries in China under the Duracell brand and has maintained Nanfu as the leading national brand for the mass market. The dual branding, cost synergies, sales growth, broadened product portfolio, economies of page 9 124 The Battle for China’s Good-Enough Market Many Chinese companies believe they must forge ahead and buy established Western brands and distribution systems whether or not they have the experience and management tools to handle them. scale, and distribution to more than 3 million retail outlets in China have paid off for Gillette, which has seen significant increases in its operating margins in China. Buying into the good-enough segment also worked for consumer-goods giants Danone, L’Oréal, and Anheuser-Busch—companies that saw the vast potential in China but couldn’t get their costs low enough to compete. For instance, in 2004, Anheuser-Busch outbid its competitor SABMiller to acquire Harbin, the fourth-largest brewer in China. That acquisition allowed Anheuser-Busch to reach the masses while preventing Harbin from swimming upstream. The next year, it increased its stake in Tsingtao Brewery, from 9.9% to 27%. Both moves enabled the global brewer to rapidly increase its share among China’s drinkers of less-than-premium beer. Chinese companies are also wrapping their arms around acquisition strategies, attempting to establish their presence in the middle market by purchasing brands, talent, and other resources from target companies in Europe and North America. To date, they’ve met with mixed results. On the one hand, Lenovo’s acquisition of IBM’s PC division turned the Chinese computer maker into the world’s third-largest PC company. On the other hand, the acquisition experiences of TCL, a major Chinese consumer electronics manufacturer, have been less successful. TCL built a strong position in the Chinese market by producing and distributing basic cathode-ray tube TVs at astonishingly low prices. It also engaged in contract and privatelabel manufacturing for the U.S. and European markets. But TCL realized it would need a strong brand to rise up from the low end of the China market and that growing organically in a mature industry like TV manufacturing would be prohibitively expensive. So TCL acquired French firm Thomson, which owned a number of well-known brands, including RCA. Unfortunately, Thomson also owned some high-cost and unproductive manufacturing facilities in France. TCL has struggled since acquiring Thomson, as the market for TVs has shifted from cathode-ray to plasma and LCD technologies. In 2006, the company lost $351 million from operations. Many Chinese companies believe that in order to play in the global arena, they must simply forge ahead, buying established harvard business review • september 2007 Western brands and distribution systems— whether or not they have the experience and management tools to handle such acquisitions. But, as TCL’s story suggests, executing such a plan is hardly cut-and-dried. ••• In the 1960s and 1970s, the mantra for many organizations was “Capture U.S. market share, capture the world.” Today, China—and its middle market in particular—has become the object of multinationals’ ardent pursuit. The enormous market potential of the country’s population, the formidable growth of the economy, and China’s established position in low-cost sourcing and manufacturing are providing competitive advantages for many companies—benefits these organizations are then leveraging both inside and outside the nation. Local Chinese companies know their futures depend on entering the good-enough space and attacking global leaders (and their premium positioning) by offering low-cost products of reasonable quality that they can eventually take to the world. Multinationals are beginning to recognize that ceding the middle space to Chinese firms may breed competitors that will ultimately challenge them on a global scale. Ironically, Chinese companies that have already gone global are on the defensive as well. A recent Forbes Asia article reported that as Haier has attacked international markets and won share abroad, both local companies and multinationals have been nibbling away at its share of China’s middle market—which fell from 29% in 2004 to 25% last year. The stakes are high. All the more reason, then, for companies that have stumbled in China in the past to redouble their efforts. Danone’s high product costs thwarted its early attempts to sell dairy products in China’s middle market. But that obstacle was removed when the firm reengaged in the fight, lowering its costs by buying a local dairy. Likewise, Caterpillar hasn’t diverted its focus away from China and the importance of the good-enough space. The company plans to triple its sales by 2010, opening more manufacturing plants and dealerships and forming more joint ventures with local companies. “Operational and sales success in China is critical for the company’s long- page 10 125 The Battle for China’s Good-Enough Market term growth and profitability,” said Rich Lavin, vice president of Caterpillar’s Asia Pacific Operations Division, in November 2006. Shortly thereafter, the company moved its divisional headquarters—from Tokyo to Beijing. Reprint R0709E To order, see the next page or call 800-988-0886 or 617-783-7500 or go to www.hbrreprints.org harvard business review • september 2007 page 11 126 The Battle for China’s Good-Enough Market Further Reading HBR ARTICLE COLLECTION Winning in the World’s Emerging Markets by Tarun Khanna, Krishna G. Palepu, Jayant Sinha, Ming Zeng, and Peter J. Williamson Harvard Business Review October 2006 Product no. 1455 This collection provides additional ideas for entering China’s good-enough space. In “Strategies That Fit Emerging Markets,” Tarun Khanna, Krishna G. Palepu, and Jayant Sinha recommend assessing market institutions in the parts of China where you’re considering introducing new offerings. For instance, how strong are transportation infrastructures? Then, decide whether altering your business model will help you compensate for any weak institutions. Dell Computer, for example, decided to sell its products in China through local distributors and systems integrators after discovering that Chinese consumers don’t buy over the Internet. To Order For Harvard Business Review reprints and subscriptions, call 800-988-0886 or 617-783-7500. Go to www.hbrreprints.org For customized and quantity orders of Harvard Business Review article reprints, call 617-783-7626, or e-mai customizations@hbsp.harvard.edu specialized, high-value products (such as refrigerated containers). 3) Competitive networks comprise hundreds of local entrepreneurial companies that achieve scale and reduce cost by using the same suppliers, labor, and distribution channels. 4) Technology upstarts are state-owned research institutions that commercialize their technologies and spawn new firms. In “Emerging Giants: Building World-Class Companies in Developing Countries,” Khanna and Palepu advise analyzing Chinese upstarts’ best practices to better position your firm to compete in China’s good-enough space. For example, Chinese enterprises exploit their knowledge of local consumers. They leverage familiarity with local talent and capital markets to cost-effectively serve customers at home and abroad. And some treat lack of market institutions as business opportunities, providing new banking, insurance, and product-rating services that turn into big companies. In “The Hidden Dragons,” Ming Zeng and Peter J. Williamson suggest that, to compete against new rivals from China, you need to gain familiarity with four types of local contenders: 1) National champions identify and serve market segments that global giants have missed. 2) Dedicated exporters develop expertise with crucial technologies to export page 12 127 Sunday, October 2 Global Executive MBA in Shanghai GEMBA VIII – Theme 3A General Manager as Integrator 29 Sept – 3 Oct 2011, Shanghai Jiao Tong University, Shanghai Professors Ty Callahan (Finance and Business Economics) and Joe Nunes (Marketing) All assigned readings and cases for all the week's sessions need to be read and studied before the first session at SJTU. Focus on reading and being prepared to discuss the cases! Sunday, 2 October 08:30 Finance Session 8 – Professor Callahan Topic: Quiz (covering material through Finance session 6) Required Readings and Discussion Questions: None – study for the quiz. To do before this session: Study for the quiz. 09:45 Break 10:00 Finance Session 9 – Professor Callahan Topic: Raising Long-Term Capital This session provides an opportunity to discuss how firms raise external capital, what types of capital are acquired and why, and the comparative costs and benefits of strategic capital acquisition. Topics will include concepts of market efficiency and the process and costs of underwriting common stock and debt. Required Readings: RWJ Chapters 14 and 20 Discussion Questions: 1. Do you believe markets are efficient? Why or why not? 2. What do your views on market efficiency imply about firms’ financial policies? 3. Think about whatever questions you have regarding the institutional details or mechanics of stock or bond issuance. To do before this session: - Review readings - Prepare answers to the discussion questions 11:15 Break 11:30 Marketing Session 9 – Professor Nunes GEMBA VIII, Theme 3A, 29 Sept to 3 Oct, 2011, daily syllabus 128 Page: 1 / 2 Global Executive MBA in Shanghai Please review the results of your practice Markstrat Decision. We will discuss and I will answer questions. Topic: Brand Identity & Brand Image Required Readings: Ward, Scott, Larry Light and Jonathan Goldstine: “What High-Tech Managers Need to Know about Brands”, HBR Reprint 994II 12:45 Lunch 13:45 Marketing Session 10 – Professor Nunes Topic: Pepsi Case Required Readings: Handed out in Class Assignment: Make Decision 1 15:00 Break 15:15 G7 and G8 Joint Session GEMBA VIII, Theme 3A, 29 Sept to 3 Oct, 2011, daily syllabus 129 Page: 2 / 2 What High-Tech Managers Need to Know About Brands by Scott Ward, Larry Light, and Jonathan Goldstine Reprint 99411 130 JULY– AUGUST 1999 Reprint Number Jim Collins TURNING GOALS INTO RESULTS: THE POWER OF CATALYTIC MECHANISMS 99401 Scot t Ward, L arry Light, and Jonathan Goldstine WHAT HIGH-TECH MANAGERS NEED TO KNOW ABOUT BRANDS 99411 Peter Frost and sandr a Robinson THE TOXIC HANDLER: ORGANIZATIONAL HERO – AND CASUALTY 99406 Cl audio FernA ndez-ArAoz HIRING WITHOUT FIRING 99403 Tarun Khanna and Krishna Palepu THE RIGHT WAY TO RESTRUCTURE CONGLOMERATES IN EMERGING MARKETS 99407 Robert G. Eccles, Kersten L . Lanes, and Thom a s C. Wilson ARE YOU PAYING TOO MUCH FOR THAT ACQUISITION? 99402 Forest L . Reinhardt BRINGING THE ENVIRONMENT DOWN TO EARTH 99408 R ay Friedm an THE CASE OF THE RELIGIOUS NETWORK GROUP D onald N. Sull WHY GOOD COMPANIES GO BAD HBR CASE STUDY 99405 thinking about… 99410 so cial enterprise Larry Fondation, Peter Tufano, and Patricia Walker COLLABORATING WITH CONGREGATIONS: OPPORTUNITIES FOR FINANCIAL SERVICES IN THE INNER CITY 99404 perspectives Introduction by Regina Fa zio M aruca RETAILING: CONFRONTING THE CHALLENGES THAT FACE BRICKS-AND-MORTAR STORES Peter Sealey HOW E-COMMERCE WILL TRUMP BRAND MANAGEMENT 99412 bo oks in review 131 99409 What High-Tech Managers Need to Know About Brands Brands are not just names slapped on products by the marketing department; they embody the value those products have for your customers. That may be more true for high-tech products than it is for soap. by Scott Ward, Larry Light, and Jonathan Goldstine M any managers in high-tech companies believe that market success depends primarily on the price-performance ratio. At the same time, however, most would acknowledge that the bulk of their offerings are fast becoming commodities (if they are not already). Products and services are highly similar – printers print and computers compute. And if one manufacturer boasts of more “feeds and speeds” today, competitors will catch up tomorrow. Price and performance are just the ante to get into the game. art work by michael klein Copyright © 1999 by the President and Fellows of Harvard College. All rights reserved. 132 b r a n d s f o r h i g h - t e c h m a n ag e r s What, then, can make the difference between a successful high-tech venture and an unsuccessful one? One critical factor is brand management. The problem is that many of the people leading hightech companies – managers who have grown up through the technical side of the business – do not truly understand what good brand management involves and what it can do for their companies. Most think of marketing as merely selling, and branding as an advertising campaign or a slogan – necessary evils that are costly, difficult to assess, and antithetical to a business model built on delivering the highest performance at the lowest price. The idea of developing and maintaining a strong brand in the fullest sense – conceiving of a promise of value for customers and then ensuring that the promise is kept through the way the product is developed, produced, sold, serviced, and advertised – simply does not resonate as it should. What’s needed is a sea change in managerial attitudes from a product-centric to a promise-centric business model. Successful brand management helps attract and keep customers. It can also be a strong foundation from which to launch new products, improve relationships with channel partners, foster good communication among employees within and across business functions, and help a company better focus its resources. Changing long-held beliefs isn’t easy. But our experience suggests that the first step toward doing so is to recognize the barriers that may be impeding the change. In that spirit, we’ll first address what we feel are the two most prevalent misconceptions about brands in high-tech markets. Then we’ll elaborate on our definition of a brand and related concepts that are particularly important in high-tech businesses. Finally, we’ll suggest some specific steps senior managers can take to move their companies from a product-centric to a promise-centric, brand-driven business. Two Misconceptions About Branding Most technically trained managers reflexively reject the idea that their businesses could be focused around brand management, and they base that judgment on these two assumptions: n Brands and brand images are relevant only when purchase decisions are “irrational” or “emotional,” which is fine for detergents, automobiles, and fashions. But they have nothing to do with markets populated by highly sophisticated and experienced customers, nothing to do with purchase decisions based on benchmarking studies and objective performance data. Brand management is best left to the marketing or sales departments; it’s not central to the technical direction of the company. A brand is just a logo, trademark, slogan, or ad campaign, and marketing handles those things. Let’s tackle the first assumption first. It is true that most of our knowledge about brand strategies comes from the accumulated experience of consumer-packaged-goods companies like Procter & Gamble, Nabisco, and Nestlé. Such companies invented brand management – and a wealth of enduring and highly profitable brands. But just because a concept evolved in the consumer goods markets is no reason to reject it in business-to-business markets in general or in high-technology markets in particular. A successful brand in any business commands enduring premium profits because substantial numbers of customers view it as a promise of receiving a certain type and level of value. Real value is at the heart of strong relationships with customers. And value need not be defined narrowly in terms of features and performance. Value in hightech markets, as in other markets, is a much more complex concept. “Price” and “performance,” for example, may mean different things to different people. Does price mean initial cost or life cycle cost? Does performance mean microprocessor speed, the product’s ability to keep pace with a company’s growth, or a vendor’s ability to deal effectively with a multiplatform environment? Does performance include presale and postsale service and support? Most customers’ evaluations of price and performance include multiple definitions and dimensions, and the trade-offs individuals make in their buying decisions reflect different definitions of value and different needs. Through strong brands, high-tech companies can make it clear exactly which aspects of their offerings’ price and performance benefit their customers. We acknowledge that an individual’s decision to buy a certain brand of soap may be more emotional or irrational than his or her decision to buy a particular phone or than a company’s decision to go with a certain line of fax machines, at least as those terms are popularly defined and understood. Consumers may buy a certain brand of cosmetic or clothing to express a particular lifestyle, something that many people think shouldn’t apply to hightech purchases. But we argue that in markets such as personal computers, the line between a high-tech product and a consumer product is becoming increasingly fuzzy. And parallel kinds of motives exist even in n 86 harvard business review 133 July–August 1999 b r a n d s f o r h i g h - t e c h m a n ag e r s High-Technology Brands: Misconceptions Versus Realities MISCONCEPTIONS REALITIES Technology products are bought on the basis of the price-performance ratio, period. Price and performance are important, but other factors may also be highly influential. Additionally, the people involved in purchase decisions may weigh various performance factors differently. High switching costs associated with a large installed base are the key to profitability. True for a while, but customers don’t like to feel trapped, and competitors are dedicated to offering seamless transitions, along with better performance and functionality. Brand management is used when product differentiation is difficult or impossible. By then it’s too late. A brand’s promise of value is the core element of differentiation, not an alternative to it. Branding is something the marketing department does, and as such, it means advertising, trade shows, and sales literature. The results are hard to measure. The promise of value must be reflected in every aspect of the complete product offering in tangible and measurable ways. Even psychological rewards among brand users, like trust, can be measured and related to business performance. business-to-business high-tech purchases. Consider the following: n Many hard-nosed M.B.A. students purchase a relatively costly Hewlett-Packard calculator instead of a less expensive brand that performs just as well to signal their proficiency with technology to themselves and to others. n The vast majority of people who use personal computers would not recognize the microprocessor in their PCs if the machine were disassembled and the parts arrayed in front of them. However, Intel’s success in establishing a strong brand has arguably influenced consumers’ purchasing decisions, effectively shifting some brand equity its way from PC manufacturers. n When managers of information technology weigh the merits of a vendor’s bid, they may be thinking not only about how well the vendor’s products and services will complement their own company’s business and technological environment but also about how the purchase decision will look to others. That is, IT managers may be just as concerned with the image of the product – and with how the purchase decision will reflect on them – as they are with the technical strengths or weaknesses of the vendor’s offering. harvard business review How many people do you know once claimed that they would be the last Apple buyer? Even at its lowest point, Apple still enjoyed considerable brand loyalty from a devoted group of followers for whom that brand was synonymous with the Apple’s simplicity and its utility for their particular needs. And witness the enormous popularity of the iMac, the result of Steve Jobs’s thus-far-successful efforts to refocus the company’s marketing and productdevelopment strategies. In short, a rational decision means one that maximizes value, but value can be based on objective or subjective data. As for the second assumption, consider this: It’s true that creating logos and advertising campaigns are a part of marketing. But those activities will fall short of their intended goals if they are devel- n Scott Ward is a professor of marketing at the University of Pennsylvania’s Wharton School in Philadelphia. Larry Light is president of Arcature, a brand-strategy consulting company in Stamford, Connecticut. Jonathan Goldstine is program director for AIX strategy in the Server Group of IBM in Somers, New York. 87 July–August 1999 134 b r a n d s f o r h i g h - t e c h m a n ag e r s oped and implemented without some sort of unifying foundation. The foundation for all marketing activities should be creating and nurturing a promise of value to customers. A promise of value (the brand) – and delivery on that promise – is critical if a company is going to differentiate itself from its competitors and stake a solid claim in its intended market. If all functions in an organization are not helping to create and nurture a single promise of value, customers will be, at best, confused and, at worst, angry. It’s true that building and positioning a promise of value for a high-tech product or service often begins with a prototype core offering that may be understood and purchased initially by only a tiny cadre of technophiles, so the importance of the promise of value may not be widely apparent right away. But for that product to achieve some degree of broader market acceptance, the product will likely need to attract not only a broader base of customers but also a network of ancillary products and services. For example, a server’s prowess in accommodating ever-increasing workloads, its scalability, is of little value if it lacks supporting applications written by independent software vendors. A company cannot expect to build that broader acceptance simply by making a promise of value in advertising. It must first know what promise to make and to whom. That requires the ability to assess the potential of relevant technologies and to anticipate its customers’ current and future needs – even before customers can articulate those needs. It must also ensure that the promise of value is understood and fulfilled as the company manages complex networks of value-adding partners, ranging from consulting firms to systems integrators, from independent software vendors to resellers. Gateway Computer Systems is a good example of a company that understands the importance of marketing as a companywide function. Gateway differentiates itself from other mail-order PC companies through folksy advertisements in otherwise terse and dense catalogs. But the company knows that its marketing message – in essence, a promise of friendly service – must be backed up by efficient Any high-tech company attempting to build a brand must pay for the mistakes other companies have made. help lines and effective order and service fulfillment to ensure that its promise of value is consistently kept. If these arguments aren’t enough to dispel the misconceptions, consider one more thing: some high-tech companies enjoy considerable brand equity, or financial value, that can be attributed to a brand name. Essentially, a brand’s value is derived by multiplying its annual net after-tax profits, adjusted to exclude the earnings expected for an equivalent generic product, by a discount rate that reflects the brand’s strength as defined by such factors as the brand’s ability to influence the market, the stability of its customer franchise, the ability to sustain demand in the face of technological change, and the strength of supporting communications. Calculated according to that methodology, the world’s most valuable brands include IBM, Microsoft, Intel, and Hewlett-Packard.1 Fine-Tuning the Definition of a Brand Brands are often confused with logos or trademarks. A trademark is a distinguishing name, sign, symbol, or design, or some combination of them, that identifies the goods or services of one seller. A brand is a distinctive identity that differentiates a relevant, enduring, and credible promise of value associated with a product, service, or organization and indicates the source of that promise. Emphasis can be placed at the corporate level or at the level of a subbrand. For high-tech brands, the emphasis is often at the corporate level because specific offerings are generally configured for specific clients, so identifying a subbrand isn’t feasible. IBM does not have subbrands for its e-business offerings, for example, since its solutions are unique to each of its servers and include software, service, and support provided by business partners. By contrast, Lotus shares brand equity with its subbrand Domino. Just as a trademark must be seen and recognized by customers in order to perform its identification function, so too must a brand’s promise of value be tangible and predictably manifested in a company’s business behavior and, ultimately, in its products and services. Brands can be built around many different promises of value. We’ve said that performance is the price of admission in high-tech markets; nevertheless, for some high-tech companies, the promise of value can center around the related idea that they offer cutting edge products and services. Lucent Technologies’ current brand-building effort is a case in point. Lucent’s message is, in effect, “We know competitors will match us, but look to us to be the first with the newest technology.” By con- 88 harvard business review 135 July–August 1999 b r a n d s f o r h i g h - t e c h m a n ag e r s trast, IBM is not often first to market with the latest technology; instead, its promise of value is built on its long tradition of superior service and support. The president of one of its major European customers told one IBM senior executive, “As long as IBM is in the general price range of competitors, we’ll always buy IBM for the service and support you deliver.” Of course, the promise of value must be relevant to the people or businesses a company wants to have as its customers; no business can promise everything for everyone. But it is possible to tailor a promise to meet the desires of a specific subgroup of customers, as long as that promise can be kept and as long as it doesn’t confuse anyone. That’s why a company must consider its own capabilities and its target customer segments before developing its brand message. Consider how IBM tweaks its brand message for application development tools. Traditionally, target customers for the tools were IT managers in large organizations. Those managers valued service, support, and reliability. However, a new breed of customer has emerged in recent years. These customers are young, sophisticated, highly competent, and comfortable with technologies. They care less about IBM’s tradition of service and support than they do about being able to work with so-called bleeding edge technologies. Some even look forward to the hassles of working with new technologies for the intellectual and technical challenges they pose. Accordingly, IBM’s promise of value for this group emphasizes technical prowess, layered on top of its traditional message of solid service and support. EMC, a manufacturer of data storage systems, knows the importance of choosing a particular type of customer before defining the promise of value. Attempting to avoid the price wars that resulted from marketing to technically sophisticated buyers in IT departments, EMC instead tailored its promise for senior managers who could dictate purchasing decisions. In a series of advertisements in publications like the Wall Street Journal, EMC raised relevant issues for senior executives, such as the role of data storage in securing competitive advantage. EMC realized that in IT departments, purchasing decisions are often narrowly based on price, but for senior executives, any decision reflects broader considerations. As luck would have it, EMC’s decision to create its promise of value for senior executives, and to market to them, may have bought the company some time in the mid- to late 1980s, when the company faced critical product quality issues. It is hard to imagine any credible promise of value that EMC could have made to IT harvard business review professionals and other technical customers who were directly affected by the company’s quality problems at that time. Under Michael C. Ruettgers, who became EMC’s CEO in 1992, the quality problems have been solved, and profits have climbed from $30 million in that year to an expected $1 billion in 1999. Managers in high-tech businesses face many of the same problems as managers in other businesses in formulating distinctive and credible promises of value. But in high-technology markets, offering a distinctive value proposition is especially difficult since, with lightning speed, competitors match one another ’s clearly defined performance characteristics (modem speed, microprocessor capacity, and the like). What’s more, many buyers have been burned by both new and established companies that promised much but delivered little – and often delivered late, to boot. There are almost as many business failures as there are start-ups in the high-tech arena in a given year; any high-tech company attempting to build a brand must pay for the mistakes other high-tech companies have made along the way. There isn’t a great deal of trust between customers and companies in high-tech markets simply because there are many and frequent new entrants, and most have not had the time or the wisdom to build a promise of value that goes beyond price-performance. Building trust is a worthy goal, however. The credibility of a company’s promise of value results from persistence and consistency. It would be difficult, for example, for a new entrant, or even an established one, to claim that it could fulfill phone or Internet orders for personal computers better than Dell does. And Apple’s devotion to simple, easy-touse computer systems continually shores up its distinctive promise of value. On the other hand, consider that Netscape had little competition for quite some time for its Internet browser. Microsoft’s inroads into that company’s once-dominant position in the browser market may be due to Netscape’s failure to articulate clearly a distinctive and credible promise of value as much as to Microsoft’s bundling of its browser into Windows software. Lacking any loyalty to Netscape, many consumers elected to “switch rather than fight.” Netscape The credibility of a company’s promise of value results from persistence and consistency. 89 July–August 1999 136 b r a n d s f o r h i g h - t e c h m a n ag e r s might have preempted Microsoft by giving customers tangible reasons to stick with its browser. Even after Microsoft’s entry, Netscape could have questioned customers who defected and those who stuck with Netscape to determine where its implicit promise of value was being fulfilled and where it was not. With that knowledge, Netscape might have emphasized the salient dimensions of its value proposition in its advertising and modified certain technical aspects of its offering along those same lines as well. Powerful brands make promises that are enduring. Making a promise is serious business, and, as in personal life, making too many promises, or changing them frequently, raises uncertainty in the people to whom the promises are made. Making and keeping a promise, and keeping it consistently, can be a powerful source of competitive advantage. Studies of the U.S. consumer-packagedgoods industry show that many brands that were market leaders half a century ago are still market leaders today, despite inroads from cheaper privatelabel brands and generic products. While being the market leader half a century ago does not guarantee leadership, or even survival, today (Remember Schlitz, Woolworth’s, and PanAm?), there’s a higher probability that truly strong brands will continue to be leaders because they make and keep a promise of value over successive generations of technologies. No doubt IBM’s reputation for solid products and for great service and support has helped its Server Group catch up to a radically changed environment for buying large computers. IBM realizes that it can no longer be profitable if it just sells “the box,” so the Server Group is aggressively pursuing new partners to provide a wider array of software applications, technical features, service, and support. Time will tell if IBM’s past leadership in the mainframe market will continue in the new, and very different, server market. True, newer technologies can eclipse older ones; electromechanical calculating machines never had a chance against electronic ones. But an enduring promise of value can buy time for a brand in the face of new technology or, as we suggested earlier in the discussion of EMC’s products, in the face of serious lapses in product quality. Monopoly power built on overwhelming market share is not, in the end, a promise of value. Consider the devotion of scientists and engineers to Hewlett-Packard. If a competitor introduces a superior product, HP’s brand equity gives the company a chance to at least match its competitor. Tide’s brand equity allowed Procter & Gamble to plan an orderly progression of products to respond to competitors’ scented offerings, liquid detergents, and proliferation of package sizes. The Novell brand –and its promise of leadership in superior and secure networking software – has bought that company time in the face of competitive inroads from Microsoft NT and Netscape Calendar. Recently, Novell unbundled its powerful Novell Directory Services (NDS) from its flagship NetWare operating system software and continued to fulfill its leadership promise with a new version, Scalable Directory Services, or SCADS. Managers in high-tech companies may fail to think about the different promises their products could fulfill because their instincts and training tell them that good, cost-effective high-tech products and services will succeed as long as they perform as promised, satisfy customers’ needs, and garner a large installed base that will withstand any upstart brand. But such product-centric thinking is highly dangerous because customers do not necessarily experience a company’s promise of value just because its products enjoy wide acceptance. (Remember WordPerfect?) There is a tendency among managers to believe that a product’s success is ensured once a large installed base is secured, since switching costs pose a barrier to buying from other suppliers. Witness the practice by high-tech vendors of giving away software and hardware products in order to penetrate a market rapidly. However, sheer presence and satisfactory performance do not ensure that users will become loyal customers – that is to say, customers who are eager to buy products, not just customers who feel compelled to buy them. No customers like to feel trapped by the pervasiveness of a company’s hardware or software. Sooner or later, customers will defect. Monopoly power built on overwhelming market share is not, in the end, a promise of value. People will buy because they feel they have to buy, but they will not become loyal customers. Building a Powerful Brand Powerful high-tech brands build equity through a process we illustrate in our brand pyramid, which is based on materials developed by Larry Light. (See the exhibit “How High-Tech Brands Build Equity.”) The pyramid’s bottom level represents the core product – the tangible, verifiable product character- 90 harvard business review 137 July–August 1999 b r a n d s f o r h i g h - t e c h m a n ag e r s istics. Many high-tech managers are most comfortable in this space, and, unfortunately, it is where many high-tech products reside. Increasingly, however, high-tech purchases involve not just technologists but also business managers and end users, who are far more interested in what a technology product does for them than in how it works. As high-tech managers come to understand this, many start changing the way they speak of their offerings. Instead of selling “products,” they sell “solutions” or “benefits.” Such a shift in thinking and in language marks a step in the right direction; in fact, it represents the second level of the pyramid. But it is not enough. The first two levels of the pyramid still embody the elements of product competition, not those of brand competition. Competitors can continually match and leapfrog over one another by offering better and more features and by identifying the benefits of their products for customers. For instance, two manufacturers make Unix-based servers that not only perform similarly but also produce the same benefits for customers –the ability to run data-mining applications, executive information systems, and the like. The third level of the pyramid is where a company can truly differentiate itself from competitors by providing emotional rewards for its business. How do customers feel when experiencing the functional benefits of the offering? How do customers feel when experiencing the benefits of the brand? Do they feel confident? Productive? Innovative? Caring? Responsible? Successful? It is exceedingly difficult for many high-tech managers to acknowledge, much less embrace, the idea that emotions can be so important to a company’s success. But goods and services that reside in that third level are indeed developed and positioned as a way of fulfilling a promise of value to selected customers, not simply as technologies in search of a market. In this regard, Apple comes to mind and also IBM’s venerable Customer Information Control System (or CICS). Eckhard Pfeiffer, the former CEO of Compaq, illustrated the important differences between the bottom and the top of the pyramid this way: “Consumers don’t go shopping for a 24-valve, six-cylinder, 200-horsepower, fuel-injected engine. They shop for a Taurus, a Lexus, a BMW, a Jeep Cherokee, a Hummer, whatever. They shop for well-known, trusted brands.”2 While some may question the validity of that assertion, given Compaq’s disappointing recent earnings and Pfeiffer’s subsequent departure from the company, the fact remains that Compaq did enjoy considerable success in the PC market for many How High-Tech Brands Build Equity To build a strong high-tech brand, managers need to answer the following questions: LEVEL 5 What does “value” mean for the typical loyal customer? LEVEL 4 LEVEL 3 LEVEL 2 LEVEL 1 What is the essential nature and character of the brand? What psychological rewards or emotional benefits do customers receive by using this brand’s products? How does the customer feel? What benefits to the customer or solutions result from the brand’s features? What are the tangible, verifiable, objective, measurable characteristics of products, services, ingredients, or components that carry this brand name? harvard business review 91 July–August 1999 138 b r a n d s f o r h i g h - t e c h m a n ag e r s years. Declining profit margins in the business as a whole, fueled by such strategies as companies actually giving PCs away to encourage end users to get on the Internet, have left the PC market barren of strong brands. Compaq is currently pinning its hopes on translating its promise of value for higherend technology applications. The company’s ads boast of its entrance into the enterprise-computing arena, pointing out that 17 of the 20 largest stock exchanges in the world run on its systems and claiming that Compaq “out integrates” the top IT integrators. Time will tell if Compaq can leverage its promise of value in this very different market. The top two levels of the pyramid illustrate the concept that powerful brands attract and hold customers with their particular promises of value. At the top level of the pyramid is the personality of the brand. It’s the characteristics the brand would have if it had human qualities: friendly, warm, caring, confident, decisive, aggressive, or the like. The next level of the pyramid describes the deeper values that the brand reflects. We are particularly interested in reflecting values of the target customer that will create and reinforce brand loyalty. By “values,” we mean such things as conservative values, family values, achievement-oriented values, and so on. Taken together, these two levels of the pyramid define the relevant and differentiating character of the brand. In the end, powerful brands enable customers to fill in the blank in the following sentence with ease: “Oh yes, [brand name]; that’s the company that .” Focusing a company around brand management – getting from the bottom two basic levels of the pyramid to levels three, four, and five – does not mean tearing up the organization chart, forming yet another set of teams to explore a new initiative, or instituting a gaggle of new processes. Business-planning processes and topics are the same in a promise-centric company as they are in a product-centric organization. A brand plan is a business plan. The fundamental difference between a product-centric and a brand-centric company lies in the attitudes of the people throughout the organization – not just in the marketing department – in their understanding of what it means to shift from Focusing a company around brand management does not mean tearing up the organization chart. selling products or services to selling a promise of value. How can senior managers help the process along? By doing the following: Figure out what the company’s current promise of value seems to be. What do customers think of the company and its offerings? Do they see offerings as brands or merely as technology products? How do customers feel about the total experience of buying and using the company’s products? We are not suggesting that taking this step is as simple as sending out a survey that asks, “What emotional rewards do you get from using this product?” Rather, it is a matter of probing and listening. Consider, for example, the experience of one manufacturer of Unix-based servers. In a very competitive marketplace – where nearly equivalent boxes are produced by HP, IBM, Silicon Graphics, and Sun – managers at one of these companies conducted a series of focus groups with server buyers and users around the world. They found that those people had many and complex perceptions of the competitors, the offerings, and the promises they felt the competitors made. In other words, they had a lot to say. The most intriguing data were about the kinds of promises of value the customers wanted but felt some vendors did not or could not deliver. Armed with the data, the company formulated several alternative promises of value and tested them out in a second round of research. Once the promise is clear, think about how that promise relates to the company’s strengths and employees’ impressions of what the company is offering. Do the internal and external impressions match? If not, how do they differ? Refine the promise of value. This step requires managers to make three crucial decisions. First, they must understand how the potential customer markets are segmented and choose the segments they wish to serve. Second, they must determine what type of promises are feasible to offer. Third, they must set a branding policy – that is, they must decide whether and how much the equity of any one subbrand will be shared with other subbrands and with the parent brand. Older, established hightech companies like IBM can generally rest a great deal of equity at the parent-brand level. But at times the parent may wish to allow a subbrand to build an identity of its own. Such branding decisions must be handled with care. The trick is to enhance the promise of value for selected customer segments without jeopardizing or diluting the core promise. In some cases, of course, the company will want to maintain a strong connection between its parent brand and a given subbrand. GroupWise, NetWare, 92 harvard business review 139 July–August 1999 b r a n d s f o r h i g h - t e c h m a n ag e r s ManageWise, and BorderManager, for example, are all Novell subbrands, but it is not clear how much customers associate those products with the parent company or whether Novell could be building stronger brand equity if it made the connection between the subbrands and the parent more explicit. Determine what the company’s various business functions must do to make good on the promise of value. It may help at this point to try to distill the promise of value to its essence. For example, if the promise boils down to superior service and support, then those capabilities must be fully developed, maintained, and monitored. Resources should be directed not only at creating a team of fully qualified service technicians for postsale service but also at developing Web-based service capabilities. Service and support should also be built into technology offerings in the first place. To make sure it could keep its promise, for instance, the server vendor hammered out its value proposition – which centered around providing tailored solutions to help buyers achieve sustained competitive advantage – with managers and employees from every business function within the company. Those people suggested instituting specific objectives and measures to make the promise clear and to make it work. For example, to deliver on the promise of providing tailored solutions, the company’s manufacturing operation needed to recruit and closely collaborate with the independent software vendors that would tailor applications to each buyer’s needs. To deliver on the promise to help a buyer achieve competitive advantage, the company needed to go beyond selling boxes to understanding a customer’s business. In some instances, the changes were minor – but meaningful for customers. For example, the company instituted changes in its order fulfillment processes. Previously, customers were told only when their computer would be shipped. But customers in Asia wanted to know when their computers would arrive, so the company changed its procedures to take into account the delivery time to offshore destinations. Delivering on a promise of service and support need not be costly – in fact, it can cut costs and produce profits. Customers, channel partners, and technology vendors can all win. For example, consider Support Pack, which Hewlett-Packard offers to customers buying its low-end, high-volume line of printers, PCs, plotters, fax machines, and the like. Support Pack is a service package in a box designed for computer superstores and other resellers that distribute HP’s products. Previously, a customer would be offered the opportunity to purchase harvard business review a postsale service contract immediately after purchasing an HP product. But channel partners are much better at selling physical products than services, so HP set out to make after-sale service profitable, both for the company and for its channel partners. Support Pack is an actual box, displayed next to HP products. It’s designed to be easy for customers to buy and channel partners to sell and earn significant margins on: Support Pack sells for 10% to 20% of the price of the corresponding hardware product. It contains a “Dear Customer” letter with instructions for registering as a Support Pack customer, a mail-in registration card, information about service terms and conditions, and options for obtaining service. With this service product, HP cuts down on incoming service calls, dealers get a product they can sell at a good profit, and customers are reassured that they will get service and support if they need them. Institute measures of brand performance. Begin to develop the algorithms that relate those measures to business performance. For example, it’s important to track how customers perceive the brand relative to its competition over time. It’s also important to monitor the health of key dimensions of a brand’s promise of value. Managers should try to modify research on customer satisfaction levels to determine if satisfaction is leading to loyalty or if satisfaction levels are simply high or low for all players in the market. The company should try to gather information that reveals which customers are true brand loyalists and why others defect. These data can be extremely useful as managers try to decide where to place resources and how the business might more extensively change its activities to fulfill its promises. Business planning is the same in a promise-centric company as it is in a productcentric company. A brand plan is a business plan. The Rewards of Brand Management As we’ve suggested throughout, high-tech businesses that actively manage their brands stand to gain a great deal. For example, as we’ve discussed, allocating resources becomes a more direct process 93 July–August 1999 140 b r a n d s f o r h i g h - t e c h m a n ag e r s What Lies Between Your Brand and Your Customers? One of the difficulties in maintaining a powerful brand in high-tech markets stems from the involvement of numerous partners in the production, distribution, and support of complete technology products. Many high-tech products contain components from several suppliers and are sold through a variety of channels. For example, a server such as IBM’s AS/400 contains components manufactured by several suppliers, and it may be bundled for sale with software written by independent software vendors and sold by systems integrators, computer resellers, or some other value-adding entity that makes and maintains contact with customers. Can IBM make, deliver, and control a relevant, distinctive, and enduring promise of value to the end user through so many filters? Companies in many industries use numerous sources for their product components. However, the brand name indicates where the buck stops. If a buyer of a Ford Mustang has a problem with wheel bearings made in Mexico or engine mounts manufactured in eastern Europe, the problem must be resolved by Ford, through one of its dealers, or ultimately in Dearborn. Because of the relatively great need for service and support associated with many high-tech products, the issue of who, exactly, is the seller is critical. To use a well-known example, the “Intel Inside” microprocessor may fail, but the computer company that installed the part is responsible to the customer. The computer manufacturer may deal with Intel, but that’s of no concern to the consumer. There are variations on this scenario, but the theme is the same – customers don’t want to buy a basket of hardware and software; they want to buy a complete offering, and they want reassurance from somebody. That somebody is the creator and owner of the brand. Many companies also use multiple routes to distribute products to customers. They’re responding to the growth in distribution channels to serve segments of customers who want and get alternate ways to buy products and the need all companies have to reduce the high costs associated with direct sales forces. The complexity of high-tech products and their market when a company is focused on filling one value proposition across all business functions. In fact, brand management can become a powerful unifying force throughout the company. High-tech companies usually contain various camps of people from very different backgrounds. Product developers with strictly technical backgrounds may have little exposure to marketing, production, or other business functions. Conversely, M.B.A.’s in sales applications requires distributors to do much more than simply resell products. They may install, upgrade, and service new products. They may train customers to use the new products. They may integrate new products with existing systems. The term “valueadded reseller” is apt. Because of VARs’ importance, managers in high-tech businesses may begin to feel that they are customers. Moreover, buyers may believe that their most important contact is with the VAR, not with the manufacturer. But that state of affairs is a recipe for dilution of a powerful brand. Managers of high-tech brands must understand that the promise of value is made to the end user, not to the reseller. The promise of value is inherently a “pull” marketing concept, in which demand is driven more by customers who pull the product through reseller channels, than it is a “push” concept, in which the company offers resellers high margins and other incentives to push the goods out to end users. Pull marketing is common in the consumer-packaged-goods arena, where manufacturers advertise heavily to end users. Cosmetics and detergents are among the most intensively advertised consumer packaged goods, and they enjoy considerable levels of customer loyalty. Push marketing is traditionally more associated with business-to-business products in that a higher proportion of the money spent on marketing is devoted to direct sales forces and to distributors, which push the product for the manufacturer to end users. We argue that successful brands – in both consumer goods and technology products – are more likely to result from generating consumer desire –the desire to pull –as a result of a brand’s promise of value, than from attempting to push products through resellers, which are likely to be much more interested in high margins than in reinforcing a manufacturer’s promise of value. Hightech managers must try to ensure that VARs understand the brand’s promise of value and precisely what they must do to fulfill and reinforce that promise. Companies should consider instituting performance measurements to monitor their VARs’ success in delivering on the promise of value. and marketing may have scant understanding of their industry’s core technologies and sufficient, but not extraordinary, knowledge of their company’s own technology products. Brand management concepts provide a common denominator and a common language to bridge these different thought worlds. Externally, strong brand management helps breed loyal customers – customers the company under- 94 harvard business review 141 July–August 1999 b r a n d s f o r h i g h - t e c h m a n ag e r s stands and knows how to work with. Similarly, brand management can improve the relationships a company has with its suppliers and distributors. It’s fashionable to refer to those relationships as “partnerships,” characterized by cooperation and communication, but some are really naked power struggles. (See the insert “What Lies Between Your Brand and Your Customers?”) If a company’s promise of value to customers is well understood internally, then its managers can evaluate and select partners based on their ability and willingness to support the promise. What’s more, a well-articulated promise forms a solid basis for clearly and consistently defining the roles of, and allocating tasks between, a company and its partners. Finally, high-tech companies that manage their brands effectively are well positioned to increase their profits. In general, marketing high-tech products and services costs less than marketing consumer packaged goods. High-tech markets are often more segmented, focused, and granular. For business-to-business customers, advertising is a less important ingredient of the promotion mix than more cost-effective ways of approaching customers such as trade shows, the Internet, and user groups – all powerful vehicles for reaching highly targeted customers. Moreover, targeting customers means that expenditures for product development and promotion can be tightly focused and efficiently allocated. On the revenue side, strong technology brands harvard business review can increase customers’ willingness to buy related products and services and pay price premiums. Launching new products may also be less costly for powerful brands because of their loyal customer base and the increased willingness of potential customers to deal with a well-known brand. Our experience indicates that many managers in high-tech businesses find brand management concepts interesting but are loathe to move from a product-centric to a brand-centric business model. The “it doesn’t apply here” argument is often based on what are believed to be unique characteristics of high-tech products and markets, especially the volatility of the industry caused by swiftly changing technology and high levels of uncertainty among buyers. We argue, however, that it is precisely those volatile conditions that make the brand concept especially pertinent. When things change quickly, and when buyers face great uncertainty, they want to deal with a company they perceive has a vision of their needs and interests that goes beyond price and performance. They want to deal with a company they feel they can trust. 1. For more information on measuring brand equity, see the case note “Brand Valuation Methodology: A Simple Example,” Harvard Business School Publishing 596092. 2. “Mission Impossible: Winning the Computer Advertising Wars,” Upside, September 1996. Reprint 99411 To place an order, call 1-800-988-0886. 95 July–August 1999 142 CASE STUDIES AND HARVARD BUSINESS REVIEW ARTICLE REPRINTS Many readers have asked for an easy way to order case studies and article reprints or to obtain permission to copy. In response, we have established a Customer Service Team to grant permission, send rush copies in paper form, deliver files in Acrobat (PDF) format electronically (Harvard Business Review articles only), or customize collections. Please contact the Customer Service Team: Phone: 617-496-1449 United States and Canada: 800-668-6780 (8 A.M. to 6 P.M. weekdays; voice mail after hours) Fax: 617-496-1029 (24 hours, 7 days a week) E-mail: custserv@hbsp.harvard.edu (24 hours, 7 days a week) Web Site: http://www.hbsp.harvard.edu Prices (minimum order, $10): Harvard Business Review Reprints (Discounts apply to multiple copies of the same article.) 1–9 copies 10–49 50–79 80–99 100–499 Electronic HARVARD BUSINESS REVIEW SUBSCRIPTION SERVICE United States and Canada Phone: 800-274-3214 Rates per year: United States, $95; Canada, U.S.$105 International and Mexico Phone: 44-1858-435324 Fax: 44-1858-468969 Rates per year: international, U.S.$145; Mexico, U.S.$105 Orders, inquiries, and address changes: Harvard Business Review Tower House, Sovereign Park Lathkill Street, Market Harborough Leicestershire le16 9ef England International customer service e-mail address: harvard@subscription.co.uk Payments accepted: Visa, MasterCard, American Express; checks at current exchange rate payable to Harvard Business Review. Bills and other receipts may be issued. CATALOGS $5.50 each $5.00 $4.50 $4.00 $3.50 $5.50 each Harvard Business School Publishing Media Catalog This 32-page, full-color catalog features more than 40 management development video and interactive CD-ROM programs. Harvard Business School Case Studies $5.50 each For quantity estimates or quotes on customized products, call Frank Tamoshunas at 617-495-6198. Fax: 617-496-8866 PERMISSIONS For information on permission to quote or translate Harvard Business School Publishing material, contact: Customer Service Department Harvard Business School Publishing Corporation 60 Harvard Way Boston, MA 02163 Phone: 617-496-1449 United States and Canada: 800-668-6780 Fax: 617-495-6985 E-mail: custserv@hbsp.harvard.edu 143 Harvard Business School Press This latest full-color catalog features books for the fast-paced business world where you live and work. Harvard Business School Publishing Catalog of Best-Selling Teaching Materials This collection of teaching materials contains those items most requested by our customers. Harvard Business School Publishing Catalog of New Teaching Materials Designed for individuals looking for the latest materials in case method teaching. Monday, October 3 Global Executive MBA in Shanghai GEMBA VIII – Theme 3A General Manager as Integrator 29 Sept – 3 Oct 2011, Shanghai Jiao Tong University, Shanghai Professors Ty Callahan (Finance and Business Economics) and Joe Nunes (Marketing) All assigned readings and cases for all the week's sessions need to be read and studied before the first session at SJTU. Focus on reading and being prepared to discuss the cases! Monday, 3 October 08:30 Marketing Session 11 – Professor Nunes Topic: Mattel Case Required Readings: - Mattel and the Toy Recalls (B) Ivey 908M11 - Donaldson, Thomas “Values in Tension: Ethics Away from Home” HBR Reprint 96502 Discussion Questions: 1. What went wrong with Mattel’s recall strategy? 2. Who are Mattel’s stakeholders? Who did Mattel cater to in the recall? 3. What values did Mattel exhibit during the recall? How did they affect Mattel? 4. What should Mattel do right now (at the point in the case) and in the future? 09:45 Break 10:00 Integrative Session with Professors Nunes and Callahan Topic: TBD 11:15 Break 11:30 Finance Session 10 – Professor Callahan Topic: Returning Value to Shareholders (aka Payout Policy) In recent years, about 40% of firms’ income has been paid out to shareholders via dividends. But it is also true that many firms pay no dividends at all. What do we know about dividend policy? This session will explore various methods of returning value to shareholders including GEMBA VIII, Theme 3A, 29 Sept to 3 Oct, 2011, daily syllabus 144 Page: 1 / 2 Global Executive MBA in Shanghai cash dividends, stock repurchases, and extraordinary dividends. Topics will include dividend policy and personal taxes, factors favoring a high dividend policy, and some empirical regularities about US corporate payout policy. Required Readings: RWJ Chapter 19 Discussion Questions: 1. What are the typical methods used by firms to return cash to shareholders? 2. What role do taxes play in corporate payout policy? 3. What other factors influence corporate payout policy? To do before this session: - Review readings - Prepare answers to the discussion questions 12:45 Lunch 13:45 Finance Session 11 – Professor Callahan Topic: Returning Value to Shareholders – Applied In this session we will use the General Motors Corporation (D) case to review payout policy theory and look at various tradeoffs inherent in choosing a policy. We examine the interaction between payout policy, investment policy, and capital structure policy. Required Reading: The General Motors Corporation (D) case Discussion Questions: 1. What options are Mr. Finnegan and his staff evaluating? 2. What are the pros and cons of each option? 3. What do you recommend General Motors to do? To do before this session: Prepare the case for discussion 15:00 Break 15:15 Summary and Evaluations – Professors Callahan and Nunes GEMBA VIII, Theme 3A, 29 Sept to 3 Oct, 2011, daily syllabus 145 Page: 2 / 2 S w 908M11 MATTEL AND THE TOY RECALLS (B)1 Professors Hari Bapuji and Paul Beamish wrote this case solely to provide material for class discussion. The authors do not intend to illustrate either effective or ineffective handling of a managerial situation. The authors may have disguised certain names and other identifying information to protect confidentiality. Ivey Management Services prohibits any form of reproduction, storage or transmittal without its written permission. Reproduction of this material is not covered under authorization by any reproduction rights organization. To order copies or request permission to reproduce materials, contact Ivey Publishing, Ivey Management Services, c/o Richard Ivey School of Business, The University of Western Ontario, London, Ontario, Canada, N6A 3K7; phone (519) 661-3208; fax (519) 661-3882; e-mail cases@ivey.uwo.ca. Copyright © 2008, Ivey Management Services Version: (A) 2008-02-21 China is now issuing two types of toys: leaded and un-leaded. – Jay Leno, U.S. Talk Show Host On August 14, 2007, the U.S. Consumer Product Safety Commission (CPSC) in cooperation with Mattel announced five different recalls of Mattel’s toys. See Exhibit 1 for excerpts of the CPSC recall notices. On the same day, Mattel issued a press release (see Exhibit 2) and held a press conference. Bob Eckert, CEO of Mattel, made a five minute briefing and answered the questions posed by the reporters. Following are some excerpts from Eckert’s address.2 As you know today Mattel announced in cooperation with the U.S. Consumer Product Safety Commission voluntary recalls on two issues, a product recalled for impermissible levels of lead and an expansion of the November 2006 magnet recall. We’ve already put measures in place to address these issues, and I will talk about those in a moment. Obviously we don’t wanna have recalls, but in acting responsibly we won’t hesitate to take action to correct issues to assure the safety of our products and the safety of children. I want to underscore that Mattel has extremely rigorous testing and quality procedures in place and we will continue to be vigilant in enforcing quality and safety. First Mattel has voluntarily recalled one toy from the Cars die cast vehicle line, manufactured between May 2007 and July 2007 containing impermissible levels of lead. The recall of the ‘Sarge Toy’ results from Mattel’s on going testing procedures. The Cars toy was produced by Early Light Industrial Company, one of Mattel’s contract manufacturing facilities in China, which subcontracted the painting of parts of the toy to another vendor named Hong Li Da, also in China. While the painting subcontractor was required to utilize certified paint supplied directly from Early Light, he had instead violated Mattel standards and utilized paint from a non-authorized third party supplier. To address this issue we have 1 This case has been written on the basis of published sources. Consequently, the interpretations and perspectives presented are not necessarily those of Mattel and other organizations represented in this case or any of their employees. 2 Transcript of Eckert’s address to reporters. 146 Page 2 9B08M011 immediately implemented a strengthened three point check system…. (details of the system) Additionally Mattel is voluntarily recalling certain toys with magnets manufactured between January 2002 and January 31st, 2007 that may release small powerful magnets. The recall expands upon Mattel’s voluntary recall of 8 toys in November 2006 and is based on a thorough internal review of all of our brands that have toys with magnets and analyzed the ways in which magnets may come loose. Since January, 2007 all magnets used in our toys have been locked into the toy with sturdy material holding in the edges around the exposed face of the magnet or completely covering the magnet. We now believe it is prudent to recall our older toys with magnets that do not meet our latest retention system requirements. This means we are recalling 72 toys that were distributed in prior years. The safety of children is our main concern and we’re confident that our new requirements work based on our continued testing and consumer experience. The risk of magnets are swallowed is serious and we believe that all our toys with magnets should have the safety benefit of our new standards. The news of the recall spread like wildfire all over the world. The media coverage it received was unprecedented, with TV channels running the story through the day. Several analysts pointed to the previous recalls of Chinese-made goods and demanded that the U.S. and Chinese governments must act. The recall of Mattel toys was quickly followed by several other recalls of Chinese-made goods. About 40 different products, most made in China, were recalled for excess lead. Mattel announced three more recalls on September 4 in which an additional 773,900 toys made in China were recalled for excess lead. The spate of recalls severely eroded consumer confidence. In a poll conducted by Reuters/Zogby,3 the majority of people (close to 80 per cent) reported that they were apprehensive about buying goods made in China. Nearly two-thirds (63 per cent) of the respondents reported that they were likely to participate in a boycott of Chinese goods until the Chinese government improved the regulations governing the safety of the goods exported to the United States. Several other opinion polls conducted by news agencies and market research firms revealed similar sentiments. The governments in the West quickly responded to the crisis of confidence. At a summit of North American political leaders in Canada, the heads of governments of Canada, the United States, and Mexico decided to crack down on unsafe goods, particularly those designed for children. Using the Mattel recalls case, EU Consumer Commissioner Meglena Kuneva, initiated an extensive review of the strengths and weaknesses of the consumer product safety mechanisms in Europe. The review had involved extensive work with national surveillance authorities, the Chinese authorities, the U.S. authorities, the European toy industry, retailers, as well as consultations with the European Parliament. The government of Brazil decided to halt the import of toys by Mattel until the lead issue was resolved. The U.S. Senate as well as the House of Commons held hearings on the safety of imported products and Bob Eckert was summoned to testify in both the hearings. In those hearings, Eckert asserted:4 “a few vendors, either deliberately or out of carelessness, circumvented our long-established safety standards and procedures.” 3 http://www.signonsandiego.com/news/nation/20070919-0400-usa-foodsafety-poll.html Testimony of Robert Eckert, CEO, Mattel, to the Sub-committee on Commerce, Trade, and Consumer Protection of the Committee on Energy and Commerce. September 19, 2007. 4 147 Page 3 9B08M011 The recalls catapulted consumer product safety to the center of debate. Questions were raised about whether the CPSC had enough resources to ensure product safety. Consumer advocates and some politicians pointed to the steady budget and staffing cuts the CPSC faced; with 420 employees in 2007, the CPSC was half its size of the 1980s. Many wondered if that number was adequate to monitor 15,000 consumer products in a market valued at US$614 billion. It was pointed out that CPSC had only one employee devoted to testing the safety of toys. Also, only 15 CPSC inspectors were available to check all the U.S. ports where import shipments were received.5 Given the limited resources of the CPSC, it was easy for unscrupulous companies to “play truant.” And, the CPSC “lacked the teeth” to check it. For example, the maximum penalty the CPSC could impose on companies for violations was $1.8 million. Imposing penalties was never easy because the burden of proof rested with the CPSC. Additionally, the CPSC could not even make public its concerns or investigations about companies. It was required by law to take prior approval of the companies whose names were being divulged.6 The role of Mattel in ensuring product safety was also under scrutiny. Some observers pointed that Mattel had not informed the CPSC within the stipulated time. In the past, Mattel was fined twice by the CPSC for not informing the latter about product hazards in a timely manner. If the alleged delay by managers was indeed true, then it was possible that shareholders might sue the directors and senior executives of the company for the delays and exposing the company to risk. In an interview with the Wall Street Journal, Eckert felt that the CPSC requirement of immediately reporting the incidents was unreasonable and that Mattel had the freedom to investigate the incidents before providing the information to the CPSC. When asked by the media about the time Mattel took to recall, Eckert said that the company asked the CPSC to initiate a fast-track recall and they acted as fast as they could. Some observers criticized Mattel for being unapologetic about the recalls. Efforts by several reporters to reach Mattel after August 14 were in vain. Mattel’s customers were livid about the recalls and wondered if the company had any control and monitoring systems at all because they were recalling toys sold over the previous three years. Some wondered if Mattel had any quality systems to test the manufactured toys for safety. As the recalls were announced, parents found it difficult to empty the toy baskets of their children without “breaking their hearts.” Some families filed class-action lawsuits, asking Mattel to pay for tests to determine if children were exposed to lead. More lawsuits were expected to follow. The recalls made the licensors of brands to Mattel, such as Disney and Sesame Workshop, very nervous. They feared the erosion of their brand value because of the lead paint issue. Disney announced independent testing of the toys it made with Disney brand names. One of the largest toy retailers, Toys’R’Us also began to conduct its own lead testing of toys on its shelves.7 The continued attention to the issue of recall and particularly Mattel’s role began to affect the image of all toys sold in the United States. The toys made by every company were being scrutinized and consumers were looking more carefully at the toys to find out where they were made. Many consumers rushed in search of toys made in the United States or other developed countries, but they were hard to find. Not to be discouraged, some enthusiasts set up websites to inform shoppers about where to buy American toys 5 Stephen Labaton. Bigger budget? No, responds safety agency. New York Times, Oct. 30, 2007. Felcher M. 2001. It's No Accident: How Corporations Sell Dangerous Baby Products. Common Courage Press: Monroe, ME 7 http://www.reuters.com/article/domesticNews/idUSN1040588720070910 6 148 Page 4 9B08M011 (www.howtobuyamerican.com) and others set up businesses that sold toys not made in China, aptly named NMC Toys (Not Made in China Toys www.nmctoys.com). A few companies, such as Little Tykes, which manufactured some of their toys in the United States began to prominently display Made in USA labels on their toys. Some analysts argued that the suppliers in China and elsewhere were compromising on safety to meet the ever increasing pressure of the Western toy companies to supply toys and other products at a cheaper cost, even in the face of increasing raw material and wage costs. This resulted in a double-squeeze for the toy suppliers. Some consumer advocates asserted that companies like Mattel which brought the toys into the United States had the primary responsibility for ensuring the safety of products — that no matter where in the global supply chain, the problem might have occurred. The suppliers in China faced pressures from large toy companies, who in turn faced pressures from large retailers, to cut down costs. Additionally, the economic growth enjoyed by China resulted in rising wages, and a general increase in the cost of doing business. Within China, toy-making is clustered in Guangdong province. The Nominal Wage Rate Index (NWRI) in Guangdong increased to 545 in 2003 from a base of 100 in 1991. The increase was much higher than the national average of 450 in 2003, and was fifth largest within China. The average Consumer Price Index (CPI) in China rose from 100 in 1992 to 202 in 2004. The rise in CPI was less stark for Guangdong province, reaching 189.8 The suppliers in China faced another problem: the rising value of the yuan when compared to other Asian currencies. For example, since 1997 the Chinese yuan has appreciated nearly four fold against the Indonesian rupiah, doubled in value against the Philippine peso, and increased in value by at least 1.5 times against the South Korean won, the Malaysian ringgit and the Thai baht. As a result, these destinations were becoming increasingly attractive for manufacturing and the advantage of operating in China was eroding.9 As a result of the increased wages, cost of living and the value of the yuan, the pattern of economic activity in China underwent a rapid change. Industrial activity had shifted to higher-value industries which could absorb the rising costs. Exhibit 3 presents the changes in industry concentration by region in China. From being dominant in only one region in 1990, electronic equipment was the most dominant industrial activity in four regions in 2006.10 The shift in industrial activity was best captured in the words of the Mattel CEO: Wage rates are going up in southern China, and it’s harder for us to find employees in southern China. You know, next to a toy factory 20 years ago, there was empty land. Today next to every toy factory, I think you can look to your left and see a cell phone plant or some sort of electronics plant. You might be able to look to your right and see an auto manufacturer. The effect of recalls began to take a toll on the already besieged toy suppliers in China. On August 11, 2007, Cheng Shu-hung, who directly managed the operations of Lee Der, committed suicide. He was 48, single, and lived in a 250 square foot room in one of Lee Der’s offices. He was considered to be kind to the factory workers and was credited with the better working conditions that prevailed in the three factories of Lee Der. Shop floor salaries for a 10-hour, six-day week in Lee Der factories ranged between US$120 and 180 a month, higher than the local average of $130 a month for seven-day week schedules that often ran 8 Delios A, Beamish P, Zhao X. 2008. The evolution of Japanese investment in China: From toys to textiles to business process outsourcing. Asia Pacific Business Review (forthcoming). 9 Ibid. 10 Ibid. 149 Page 5 9B08M011 14-hours a day. Also, employees received overtime pay when the shift exceeded 10 hours. One of the last things Cheng Shu-hung did was to sell his factories and pay wages to his employees.11 Following the recalls, Chinese employees in Lee Der and other factories became jobless. The conditions of workers became an issue of discussion. Some observers wondered what the effect of lead was on the employees who painted lead on the toys, and thus ingested it, every day of the week. The recalls began to severely erode “Brand China” and the Chinese government quickly set up a taskforce under the leadership of Chinese Vice Premier Wu Yi to ensure product safety. This taskforce intensified the inspection of Chinese plants and suspended or revoked the export licenses of hundreds of companies. Some suppliers named in the recalls were jailed. Faced with intense pressure from all quarters, the Chinese authorities asserted that the majority of products made in China were safe and that Western companies were unduly blaming China. Several suppliers who worked with big companies and were forced to close factories or lay off workers asserted that Mattel and other large companies were making them scapegoats. In what appeared to be a counter-offensive, China rejected North American imports such as frozen pig kidneys imported from the United States and frozen pork spareribs from Canada. These products were found to contain residues of ractopamine, forbidden for use as veterinary medicine in China.12 Also, China rejected shipments of U.S.-made orange pulp and dried apricots containing high levels of bacteria and preservatives.13 In an effort aimed at enhancing product safety, the CPSC and its Chinese-counterpart AQSIQ met in Washington on September 11-12, 2007. This meeting culminated in agreement to ban the use of lead in toys made in China. At the meeting, in his address, the AQSIQ chief asserted that the West was blaming China for the problems created by its toy companies. In support of his assertion, he mentioned a recent Canadian study which found that the majority of toy recalls in the U.S. were due to design flaws. According to a report in the New York Times on September 12, 2007, two Canadian business school researchers, after analyzing the toy recalls in the United States over the previous 20 years, found that 76 per cent of the recalls were due to design flaws such as sharp edges, easily detachable small parts, and long strings. In contrast, only 10 per cent were due to manufacturing flaws such as using poor material, incorrect assembly, and use of unacceptable material like lead paint. The researchers argued that China should not be blamed for most of the recalls, when a vast majority of the problems were because of the designs made in the corporate headquarters of toy companies. Mattel had considerable interests in China. Five of its factories were located in China and a very large number of factories made toys for Mattel, directly or indirectly. The Chinese news agencies began to report that Chinese suppliers were being made a scapegoat by Mattel, despite the fact that 90 per cent of the toys recalled on August 14 were due to magnets detaching, which was a design problem for which Mattel was responsible. The loss of reputation for China as a result of the recalls was huge and Mattel seemed like the floodgate that had opened it. 11 http://www.ckgsb.edu.cn:8080/article/600/3051.aspx http://www.cbc.ca/consumer/story/2007/09/17/china-exports.html 13 http://www.cbc.ca/consumer/story/2007/06/26/china-trade.html 12 150 Page 6 9B08M011 Exhibit 1 CPSC RECALL NOTICES FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE August 14, 2007 Release #07-273 Firm's Recall Hotline: (888) 597-6597 CPSC Recall Hotline: (800) 638-2772 CPSC Media Contact: (301) 504-7908 Additional Reports of Magnets Detaching from Polly Pocket Play Sets Prompts Expanded Recall by Mattel WASHINGTON, D.C. - The U.S. Consumer Product Safety Commission, in cooperation with the firm named below, today announced a voluntary recall of the following consumer product. Consumers should stop using recalled products immediately unless otherwise instructed. Name of Products: Various Polly Pocket dolls and accessories with magnets Units: About 7.3 million play sets (about 2.4 million play sets were recalled on November 21, 2006) Importer: Mattel Inc., of El Segundo, Calif. Hazard: Small magnets inside the dolls and accessories can come loose. The magnets can be found by young children and swallowed or aspirated. If more than one magnet is swallowed, the magnets can attract each other and cause intestinal perforation or blockage, which can be fatal. Incidents/Injuries: Since the previous recall announcement, Mattel has received more than 400 additional reports of magnets coming loose. CPSC was aware in the first recall announcement of 170 reports of the magnets coming out of the recalled toys. There had been three reports of serious injuries to children who swallowed more than one magnet. All three suffered intestinal perforations that required surgery. Description: The recalled Polly Pocket play sets contain plastic dolls and accessories that have small magnets. The magnets measure 1/8 inch in diameter and are embedded in the hands and feet of some dolls, and in the plastic clothing, hairpieces and other accessories to help the pieces attach to the doll or to the doll’s house. The model number is printed on the bottom of the largest pieces on some of the play sets. Products manufactured after November 1, 2006 and are currently on store shelves are not included in this recall. Contact Mattel if you cannot find a model number on your product to determine if it is part of the recall. Sold at: Toy stores and various other retailers from May 2003 through November 2006 for between $15 and $30. Manufactured in: China Remedy: Consumers should immediately take these recalled toys away from children and contact Mattel to receive a voucher for a replacement toy of the customer’s choice, up to the value of the returned product. ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~ Mattel Recalls Doggie Day Care™ Magnetic Toys Due to Magnets Coming Loose Name of Product: Doggie Day Care™ play sets Units: About 1 million Importer: Mattel Inc., of El Segundo, Calif. Hazard: Small magnets inside the toys can fall out. Magnets found by young children can be swallowed or aspirated. If more than one magnet is swallowed, the magnets can attract each other and cause intestinal perforation or blockage, which can be fatal. Incidents/Injuries: The firm has received two reports of magnets coming loose. No injuries have been reported. Description: The recalled Doggie Day Care play sets have various figures and accessories that contain small magnets. Sold at: Toy stores and various other retailers nationwide from July 2004 to August 2007 for between $4 and $20. Manufactured in: China Remedy: Consumers should immediately take the recalled toys away from children and contact Mattel to receive a free replacement toy. ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~ Mattel Recalls Barbie and Tanner™ Magnetic Toys Due to Magnets Coming Loose Name of Product: Barbie and Tanner™ play sets Units: About 683,000 Importer: Mattel Inc., of El Segundo, Calif. Hazard: A small magnet inside the “scooper” accessory can come loose. Magnets found by young children can be swallowed or aspirated. If more than one magnet is swallowed, the magnets can attract each other and cause intestinal perforation or blockage, which can be fatal. Incidents/Injuries: The firm has received three reports of magnets coming loose. No injuries have been reported. 151 Page 7 9B08M011 Exhibit 1 (continued) Description: The recall involves Barbie and Tanner™ play sets -- model numbers J9472 and J9560. The toys include a “scooper” accessory with a magnetic end. Recalled scoopers have a visible, silver-colored, disc-shaped magnet on the end of the scooper. Scoopers with a white material covering the magnet and products manufactured after January 31, 2007 are not recalled. Sold at: Toy stores and various other retailers nationwide May 2006 to August 2007 for about $16. Manufactured in: China Remedy: Consumers should immediately take the recalled toys away from children and contact Mattel to receive a free replacement toy. ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~ Mattel Recalls “Sarge” Die Cast Toy Cars Due To Violation of Lead Safety Standard Name of Product: “Sarge” die cast toy cars Units: About 253,000 Importer: Mattel Inc., of El Segundo, Calif. Hazard: Surface paints on the toys could contain lead levels in excess of federal standards. Lead is toxic if ingested by young children and can cause adverse health effects. Incidents/Injuries: None reported. Description: The recall involves die cast “Sarge” 2 ½ inch toy cars. The toy looks like a military jeep and measures about 2 ½ inches long by 1 inch high by 1 inch wide. The recalled toy has the markings “7EA” and “China” on the bottom. The “Sarge” toy car is sold alone or in a package of two, and may have the product number M1253 (for single cars) and K5925 (for cars sold as a set) printed on the packaging. The cars marked “Thailand” are not included in this recall. Sold at: Retail stores nationwide from May 2007 through August 2007 for between $7 and $20 (depending on whether they were sold individually or in sets). Manufactured in: China Remedy: Consumers should immediately take the recalled toys away from children and contact Mattel. Consumers will need to return the product to receive a replacement toy. ~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~~ Mattel Recalls Batman™ and One Piece™ Magnetic Action Figure Sets Due To Magnets Coming Loose Name of Product: Batman™ and One Piece™ magnetic action figure sets Units: About 345,000 Importer: Mattel Inc., of El Segundo, Calif. Hazard: Small, powerful magnets inside the accessories of the toy figures can fall out and be swallowed or aspirated by young children. If more than one magnet is swallowed, they can attract inside the body and cause intestinal perforation, infection or blockage which can be fatal. Incidents/Injuries: The firm is aware of 21 incidents where a magnet fell out of the toy figure, including a case of a 3year-old boy who was found with a magnet in his mouth. The boy did not swallow the magnet and no injuries have been reported to Mattel and CPSC. Description: The recalled Batman™ toys include: • The Batman™ Magna Battle Armor™ Batman™ figure with model number J1944, • The Batman™ Magna Fight Wing™ Batman™ figure with model number J1946, • The Batman™ Secret ID™ figure with model number J5114, and • The Batman™ Flying Fox™ figure with model number J5115. The seven inch tall action figures include the Batman logo on the front and include magnetic accessories. The model number is located on the lower right corner of the tag which is sewn to the figure. The recalled One Piece™ toy is: • One Piece™ Triple Slash Zolo Roronoa™ figure with model number J4142. The 5 ½ inch tall action figure has green hair, black pants, and has magnets in his hands which connect to magnets on various swords that the figure can hold. The model number is printed on the back of the action figure’s left leg. Sold at: Discount department stores and toy stores nationwide from June 2006 through June 2007 for about $11. Manufactured in: China Remedy: Consumers should immediately stop using the toy and contact Mattel for instructions on how to return it to receive a free replacement toy. 152 Page 8 9B08M011 Exhibit 2 MATTEL PRESS RELEASE - MATTEL ANNOUNCES EXPANDED RECALL OF TOYS One product recalled for impermissible levels of lead November 2006 magnet recall expanded EL SEGUNDO, Calif., August 14, 2007 – Mattel, Inc. announced today that the company has voluntarily recalled one toy from the “CARS” die-cast vehicle line (“Sarge” character), manufactured between May 2007 and July 2007, containing impermissible levels of lead. The recalled vehicles include 436,000 total toys, including 253,000 in the U.S. and 183,000 outside of the U.S. The recall of the Sarge toy results from Mattel’s increased investigation and ongoing testing procedures following the recall of select Fisher-Price toys on August 1, 2007. The toy was produced by Early Light Industrial Co., Ltd (Early Light), one of Mattel’s contract manufacturing facilities in China, which subcontracted the painting of parts of the toy to another vendor, Hong Li Da (HLD), also in China. While the painting subcontractor, HLD, was required to utilize paint supplied directly from Early Light, it instead violated Mattel’s standards and utilized paint from a non-authorized third-party supplier. “We have immediately implemented a strengthened three-point check system: First, we’re requiring that only paint from certified suppliers be used and requiring every single batch of paint at every single vendor to be tested. If it doesn’t pass, it doesn’t get used. Second, we are tightening controls throughout the production process at vendor facilities and increasing unannounced random inspections. Third, we’re testing every production run of finished toys to ensure compliance before they reach our customers. We’ve met with vendors to ensure they understand our tightened procedures and our absolute requirement of strict adherence to them,” said Jim Walter, senior vice president of Worldwide Quality Assurance, Mattel. Additionally, Mattel announced the voluntary recall of magnetic toys manufactured between January 2002 and January 31, 2007, including certain dolls, figures, play sets and accessories that may release small, powerful magnets. The recall expands upon Mattel’s voluntary recall of eight toys in November 2006 and is based on a thorough internal review of all Mattel’s brands. Mattel is recalling 18.2 million magnetic toys globally (9.5 million in the U.S.); however, the majority of the toys are no longer at retail. Beginning in January 2007, Mattel implemented enhanced magnet retention systems in its toys across all brands. “Since our November 2006 magnet-related recall, we have implemented more robust magnet retention systems and more rigorous testing. We are exercising caution and have expanded the list of recalled magnetic toys due to potential safety risks associated with toys that might have loose magnets,” said Walter. “The safety of children is our primary concern, and we are deeply apologetic to everyone affected,” said Robert A. Eckert, chairman and chief executive officer, Mattel. “Mattel has rigorous procedures, and we will continue to be vigilant and unforgiving in enforcing quality and safety. We don’t want to have recalls, but we don’t hesitate to take quick and effective action to correct issues as soon as we’ve identified them to ensure the safety of our products and the safety of children.” Issues Safety Alert to Consumers Mattel is working in cooperation with the U.S. Consumer Product Safety Commission and other regulatory agencies worldwide. Mattel is also working with retailers worldwide to identify and remove affected products from retail shelves. Details of the recall are as follows: Mattel voluntarily recalled 63 magnetic toys sold at retail prior to January 2007. Magnetic toys recalled within the U.S. include 44 Polly Pocket™ toys, 11 Doggie Day Care® toys, 4 Batman™ toys, 1 One Piece™ toy, and the accessory part of 2 Barbie® toys. For additional information regarding the magnetic toy recall, contact Mattel at (888) 597-6597, or visit the company’s Web site at www.service.mattel.com. The Sarge toy from the “CARS” die-cast vehicle line was manufactured between May 2007 and August 2007. For additional information regarding the Sarge toy recall, contact Mattel at (800) 916-4997, or visit the company’s Web site at www.service.mattel.com. A full list of products is published on the company’s Web site at www.mattel.com, as well as by the Consumer Products Safety Commission. Consumers should immediately take these products away from children and contact Mattel to arrange return and to receive a voucher for a replacement toy of the consumer’s choice, up to the value of the returned product. Source: Mattel Website 153 Page 9 9B08M011 Exhibit 3 INDUSTRY CONCENTRATION BY REGION IN CHINA (1990 - 2006) Region Industry (1990) Conc. Industry (2000) Conc. Industry (2006) Conc. North Industrial Machinery 16% Industrial Machinery 17% Electronic Equipment 17% Northeast Apparel 20% Industrial Machinery 17% Electronic Equipment 19% East Apparel 27% Apparel 16% Electronic Equipment 19% Mid-South Electronic Equipment 26% Electronic Equipment 28% Electronic Equipment 30% Southwest Food Products 50% Transportation Equipment 49% Transportation Equipment 47% Northwest Food Products 25% Industrial Machinery 41% Industrial Machinery 32% Note: North = Beijing, Tianjin, Hebei, Shanxi, Inner Mongolia Northeast = Liaoning, Jilin, Heilongjiang East = Shanghai, Jiangsu, Zhejiang, Anhui, Fujian, Jiangxi, Shandong Mid-South = Henan, Hubei, Hunan, Guangdong, Guangxi, Hainan Southwest = Chongqing, Sichuan, Guizhou, Yunnan, Tibet Northwest = Shaanxi, Gansu, Qinghai, Ningxia, Xinjiang Source: Delios A, Beamish P, Zhao X. 2008. The evolution of Japanese investment in China: From toys to textiles to business process outsourcing. Asia Pacific Business Review (forthcoming). 154 Values in Tension: Ethics Away from Home by Thomas Donaldson Harvard Business Review Reprint 96502 155 Harvard Business Review HBR Subscriptions Harvard Business Review U.S. and Canada Subscription Service P.O. Box 52623 Boulder, CO 80322-2623 Telephone: (800) 274-3214 Fax: (617) 496-8145 Outside U.S. and Canada Tower House Sovereign Park Lathkill Street Market Harborough Leicestershire LE16 9EF Telephone: 44-85-846-8888 Fax: 44-85-843-4958 American Express, MasterCard, VISA accepted. Billing available. HBR Article Reprints HBR Index and Other Catalogs HBS Cases HBS Press Books Harvard Business School Publishing Customer Service - Box 230-5 60 Harvard Way Boston, MA 02163 Telephone: U.S. and Canada (800) 545-7685 Outside U.S. and Canada: (617) 495-6117 or 495-6192 Fax: (617) 495-6985 Internet address: custserv@cchbspub.harvard.edu HBS Management Productions Videos Harvard Business School Management Productions videos are produced by award winning documentary filmmakers. You’ll find them lively, engaging, and informative. HBR Custom Reprints Please inquire about HBR’s custom service and quantity discounts. We will print your company’s logo on the cover of reprints, collections, or books in black and white, two color, or four color. The process is easy, cost effective, and quick. Telephone: (617) 495-6198 or Fax: (617) 496-8866 Permissions For permission to quote or reprint on a one-time basis: Telephone: (800) 545-7685 or Fax: (617) 495-6985 For permission to re-publish please write or call: Permissions Editor Harvard Business School Publishing Box 230-5 60 Harvard Way Boston, MA 02163 Telephone: (617) 495-6849 156 HarvardBusinessReview SEPTEMBER-OCTOBER 1996 Reprint Number JAMES C. COLLINS AND JERRY I. PORRAS BUILDING YOUR COMPANY’S VISION 96501 DAVID A. THOMAS AND ROBIN J. ELY MAKING DIFFERENCES MATTER: A NEW PARADIGM FOR MANAGING DIVERSITY 96510 ANN MAJCHRZAK AND QIANWEI WANG BREAKING THE FUNCTIONAL MIND-SET IN PROCESS ORGANIZATIONS 96505 N. CRAIG SMITH, ROBERT J. THOMAS, AND JOHN A. QUELCH A STRATEGIC APPROACH TO MANAGING PRODUCT RECALLS 96506 RICHARD B. FREEMAN TOWARD AN APARTHEID ECONOMY? 96503 WITH COMMENTARIES BY: ROBERT B. REICH, JOSH S. WESTON, JOHN SWEENEY, WILLIAM J. MCDONOUGH, AND JOHN MUELLER GEORGE STALK, JR., DAVID K. PECAUT, AND BENJAMIN BURNETT BREAKING COMPROMISES, BREAKAWAY GROWTH 96507 JOHN STRAHINICH HBR CASE STUDY THE PITFALLS OF PARENTING MATURE COMPANIES 96508 BARBARA E. TAYLOR, RICHARD P. CHAIT, AND THOMAS P. HOLLAND SOCIAL ENTERPRISE THE NEW WORK OF THE NONPROFIT BOARD 96509 THOMAS DONALDSON WORLD VIEW VALUES IN TENSION: ETHICS AWAY FROM HOME 96502 JAMES P. WOMACK AND DANIEL T. JONES IDEAS AT WORK BEYOND TOYOTA: HOW TO ROOT OUT WASTE AND PURSUE PERFECTION MARC LEVINSON BOOKS IN REVIEW CAPITALISM WITH A SAFETY NET? 157 96511 96504 W O R L D V I E W When is different just different, and when is different wrong? with people from the home country, whose standards should prevail? Even the best-informed, bestintentioned executives must rethink their assumptions about business practice in foreign settings. What works in a company’s home country can fail in a country with different standards of ethical conduct. Such difficulties are unavoidable for businesspeople who live and work abroad. But how can managers resolve the problems? What are the principles that can help them work through the maze of cultural differences and establish codes of conduct for globally ethical business practice? How can companies answer the toughest question in global business ethics: What happens when a host country’s ethical standards seem lower than the home country’s? ple in Denmark or Singapore who refuse to offer or accept bribes. Likewise, if Belgians fail to find insider trading morally repugnant, who cares? Not enforcing insider-trading laws is no more or less ethical than enforcing such laws. The cultural relativist’s creed – When in Rome, do as the Romans do – is tempting, especially when failing to do as the locals do means forfeiting business opportunities. The inadequacy of cultural relativism, however, becomes apparent when the practices in question are more damaging than petty bribery or insider trading. In the late 1980s, some European tanneries and pharmaceutical companies were looking for cheap wastedumping sites. They approached virtually every country on Africa’s west coast from Morocco to the Congo. Values in Tension: by Thomas Donaldson When we leave home and cross our nation’s boundaries, moral clarity often blurs. Without a backdrop of shared attitudes, and without familiar laws and judicial procedures that define standards of ethical conduct, certainty is elusive. Should a company invest in a foreign country where civil and political rights are violated? Should a company go along with a host country’s discriminatory employment practices? If companies in developed countries shift facilities to developing nations that lack strict environmental and health regulations, or if those companies choose to fill management and other top-level positions in a host nation Competing Answers One answer is as old as philosophical discourse. According to cultural relativism, no culture’s ethics are better than any other’s; therefore there are no international rights and wrongs. If the people of Indonesia tolerate the bribery of their public officials, so what? Their attitude is no better or worse than that of peo- Copyright © 1996 by the President and Fellows of Harvard College. All rights reserved. 158 Nigeria agreed to take highly toxic polychlorinated biphenyls. Unprotected local workers, wearing thongs and shorts, unloaded barrels of PCBs and placed them near a residential area. Neither the residents nor the workers knew that the barrels contained toxic waste. We may denounce governments that permit such abuses, but many countries are unable to police transnational corporations adequately even if they want to. And in many countries, the combination of ineffective enforcement and inadequate regulations leads to behavior by unscrupulous companies that is clearly wrong. A few years ago, for example, a group of investors became interested in restoring the SS United States, once a luxurious ocean liner. Before the actual restoration could begin, the ship had to be stripped of its asbestos lining. A bid from a U.S. company, based on U.S. standards for asbestos removal, priced the job DRAWINGS BY MICHAEL REAGAN W O R L D at more than $100 million. A company in the Ukranian city of Sevastopol offered to do the work for less than $2 million. In October 1993, the ship was towed to Sevastopol. A cultural relativist would have no problem with that outcome, but I do. A country has the right to establish its own health and safety regulations, but in the case described above, the standards and the terms of the contract could not possibly have protected workers in Sevastopol from known health risks. Even if the contract met Ukranian standards, ethical businesspeople must object. Cultural relativism is morally blind. There are fundamental values that cross cultures, and companies must uphold them. (For an economic argument against cultural relativism, see the insert “The Culture and Ethics of Software Piracy.”) V I E W they had used with U.S. managers: the participants were asked to discuss a case in which a manager makes sexually explicit remarks to a new female employee over drinks in a bar. The instructors failed to consider how the exercise would work in a culture with strict conventions governing relationships between men and women. As a result, the training sessions were ludicrous. They baffled and offended the Saudi participants, and the message to avoid coercion and sexual discrimination was lost. The theory behind ethical imperialism is absolutism, which is based on three problematic principles. Absolutists believe that there is a single list of truths, that they can be expressed only with one set of concepts, and that they call for exactly the same behavior around the world. Ethics Away from Home At the other end of the spectrum from cultural relativism is ethical imperialism, which directs people to do everywhere exactly as they do at home. Again, an understandably appealing approach but one that is clearly inadequate. Consider the large U.S. computer-products company that in 1993 introduced a course on sexual harassment in its Saudi Arabian facility. Under the banner of global consistency, instructors used the same approach to train Saudi Arabian managers that The first claim clashes with many people’s belief that different cultural traditions must be respected. In some cultures, loyalty to a community – family, organization, or society – is the foundation of all ethical behavior. The Japanese, for example, define business ethics in terms of Thomas Donaldson is a professor at the Wharton School of the University of Pennsylvania in Philadelphia, where he teaches business ethics. He wrote The Ethics of International Business (Oxford University Press, 1989) and is the coauthor, with Thomas W. Dunfee, of Business Ethics as Social Contracts, to be published by the Harvard Business School Press in the fall of 1997. HARVARD BUSINESS REVIEW September-October 1996 159 loyalty to their companies, their business networks, and their nation. Americans place a higher value on liberty than on loyalty; the U.S. tradition of rights emphasizes equality, fairness, and individual freedom. It is hard to conclude that truth lies on one side or the other, but an absolutist would have us select just one. The second problem with absolutism is the presumption that people must express moral truth using only one set of concepts. For instance, some absolutists insist that the language of basic rights provide the framework for any discussion of W O R L D V I E W The Culture and Ethics of Software Piracy Before jumping on the cultural relativism bandwagon, stop and consider the potential economic consequences of a when-in-Rome attitude toward business ethics. Take a look at the current statistics on software piracy: In the United States, pirated software is estimated to be 35% of the total software market, and industry losses are estimated at $2.3 billion per year. The piracy rate is 57% in Germany and 80% in Italy and Japan; the rates in most Asian countries are estimated to be nearly 100%. There are similar laws against software piracy in those countries. What, then, accounts for the differences? Although a country’s level of economic development plays a large part, culture, including ethical attitudes, may be a more crucial factor. The 1995 annual report of the Software Publishers Association connects software piracy directly to culture and attitude. It describes Italy and Hong Kong as having “‘first world’ per capita incomes, along with ‘third world’ rates of piracy.” When asked whether one should use software without paying for it, most people, including people in Italy and Hong Kong, ethics. That means, though, that entire cultural traditions must be ignored. The notion of a right evolved with the rise of democracy in postRenaissance Europe and the United States, but the term is not found in either Confucian or Buddhist traditions. We all learn ethics in the context of our particular cultures, and the power in the principles is deeply tied to the way in which they are expressed. Internationally accepted lists of moral principles, such as the United Nations’ Universal Declaration of Human Rights, draw on say no. But people in some countries regard the practice as less unethical than people in other countries do. Confucian culture, for example, stresses that individuals should share what they create with society. That may be, in part, what prompts the Chinese and other Asians to view the concept of intellectual property as a means for the West to monopolize its technological superiority. What happens if ethical attitudes around the world permit large-scale software piracy? Software companies won’t want to invest as much in developing new products, because they cannot expect any return on their investment in certain parts of the world. When ethics fail to support technological creativity, there are consequences that go beyond statistics – jobs are lost and livelihoods jeopardized. Companies must do more than lobby foreign governments for tougher enforcement of piracy laws. They must cooperate with other companies and with local organizations to help citizens understand the consequences of piracy and to encourage the evolution of a different ethic toward the practice. many cultural and religious traditions. As philosopher Michael Walzer has noted, “There is no Esperanto of global ethics.” The third problem with absolutism is the belief in a global standard of ethical behavior. Context must shape ethical practice. Very low wages, for example, may be considered unethical in rich, advanced countries, but developing nations may be acting ethically if they encourage investment and improve living standards by accepting low wages. Likewise, when people are 6 malnourished or starving, a government may be wise to use more fertilizer in order to improve crop yields, even though that means settling for relatively high levels of thermal water pollution. When cultures have different standards of ethical behavior – and different ways of handling unethical behavior – a company that takes an absolutist approach may find itself making a disastrous mistake. When a manager at a large U.S. specialtyproducts company in China caught an employee stealing, she followed the company’s practice and turned the employee over to the provincial authorities, who executed him. Managers cannot operate in another culture without being aware of that culture’s attitudes toward ethics. If companies can neither adopt a host country’s ethics nor extend the home country’s standards, what is the answer? Even the traditional litmus test – What would people think of your actions if they were written up on the front page of the newspaper? – is an unreliable guide, for there is no international consensus on standards of business conduct. Balancing the Extremes: Three Guiding Principles Companies must help managers distinguish between practices that are merely different and those that are wrong. For relativists, nothing is sacred and nothing is wrong. For absolutists, many things that are different are wrong. Neither extreme illuminates the real world of business decision making. The answer lies somewhere in between. When it comes to shaping ethical behavior, companies must be guided by three principles. 䡺 Respect for core human values, which determine the absolute moral threshold for all business activities. 䡺 Respect for local traditions. 䡺 The belief that context matters when deciding what is right and what is wrong. Consider those principles in action. In Japan, people doing business together often exchange gifts – sometimes expensive ones – in keeping with long-standing Japanese tradition. When U.S. and European com- HARVARD BUSINESS REVIEW 160 September-October 1996 W O R L D panies started doing a lot of business in Japan, many Western businesspeople thought that the practice of gift giving might be wrong rather than simply different. To them, accepting a gift felt like accepting a bribe. As Western companies have become more familiar with Japanese traditions, however, most have come to tolerate the practice and to set different limits on gift giving in Japan than they do elsewhere. Respecting differences is a crucial ethical practice. Research shows that management ethics differ among cultures; respecting those differences means recognizing that some cultures have obvious weaknesses – as well as hidden strengths. Managers in Hong Kong, for example, have a higher tolerance for some forms of bribery than their Western counterparts, but they have a much lower tolerance for the failure to acknowledge a subordinate’s work. In some parts of the Far East, stealing credit from a subordinate is nearly an unpardonable sin. People often equate respect for local traditions with cultural rela- V I E W tivism. That is incorrect. Some practices are clearly wrong. Union Carbide’s tragic experience in Bhopal, India, provides one example. The company’s executives seriously underestimated how much on-site management involvement was needed at the Bhopal plant to compensate for the country’s poor infrastructure and regulatory capabilities. In the after math of the disastrous gas leak, the lesson is clear: companies using sophisticated technology in a developing country must evaluate that country’s ability to oversee its safe use. Since the incident at Bhopal, Union Carbide has become a leader in advising companies on using hazardous technologies safely in developing countries. Some activities are wrong no matter where they take place. But some practices that are unethical in one setting may be acceptable in another. For instance, the chemical EDB, a soil fungicide, is banned for use in the United States. In hot climates, however, it quickly becomes harmless through exposure to intense solar radiation and high soil tempera- What Do These Values Have in Common? Non-Western Western Kyosei (Japanese): Living and working together for the common good. Individual liberty Dharma (Hindu): The fulfillment of inherited duty. Egalitarianism Santutthi (Buddhist): The importance of limited desires. Political participation Zakat (Muslim): The duty to give alms to the Muslim poor. Human rights HARVARD BUSINESS REVIEW tures. As long as the chemical is monitored, companies may be able to use EDB ethically in certain parts of the world. Defining the Ethical Threshold: Core Values Few ethical questions are easy for managers to answer. But there are some hard truths that must guide managers’ actions, a set of what I call core human values, which define minimum ethical standards for all companies. 1 The right to good health and the right to economic advancement and an improved standard of living are two core human values. Another is what Westerners call the Golden Rule, which is recognizable in every major religious and ethical tradition around the world. In Book 15 of his Analects, for instance, Confucius counsels people to maintain reciprocity, or not to do to others what they do not want done to themselves. Although no single list would satisfy every scholar, I believe it is possible to articulate three core values that incorporate the work of scores of theologians and philosophers around the world. To be broadly relevant, these values must include elements found in both Western and non-Western cultural and religious traditions. Consider the examples of values in the insert “What Do These Values Have in Common?” At first glance, the values expressed in the two lists seem quite different. Nonetheless, in the spirit of what philosopher John Rawls calls overlapping consensus, one can see that the seemingly divergent values converge at key points. Despite important differences between Western and non-Western cultural and religious traditions, both express shared attitudes about what it means to be human. First, individuals must not treat others simply as tools; in other words, they must recognize a person’s value as a human being. Next, individuals and communities must treat people in ways that respect people’s basic rights. Finally, members of a community must work together to support and improve the institutions on which the community depends. I call those 7 September-October 1996 161 W O R L D three values respect for human dignity, respect for basic rights, and good citizenship. Those values must be the starting point for all companies as they formulate and evaluate standards of ethical conduct at home and abroad. But they are only a starting point. Companies need much more specific guidelines, and the first step to developing those is to translate the core human values into core values for business. What does it mean, for example, for a company to respect human dignity? How can a company be a good citizen? I believe that companies can respect human dignity by creating and sustaining a corporate culture in which employees, customers, and suppliers are treated not as means to an end but as people whose intrinsic value must be acknowledged, and by producing safe products and services in a safe workplace. Companies can respect basic rights by acting in ways that support and protect the individual rights of employees, customers, and surrounding communities, and by avoiding relationships that vio- V I E W late human beings’ rights to health, education, safety, and an adequate standard of living. And companies can be good citizens by supporting essential social institutions, such as the economic system and the education system, and by working with host governments and other organizations to protect the environment. The core values establish a moral compass for business practice. They can help companies identify practices that are acceptable and those that are intolerable – even if the practices are compatible with a host country’s norms and laws. Dumping pollutants near people’s homes and accepting inadequate standards for handling hazardous materials are two examples of actions that violate core values. Similarly, if employing children prevents them from receiving a basic education, the practice is intolerable. Lying about product specifications in the act of selling may not affect human lives directly, but it too is intolerable because it violates the trust that is needed to sustain a corporate culture in which customers are respected. Sometimes it is not a company’s actions but those of a supplier or customer that pose problems. Take Many companies don’t do anything with their codes of conduct; they simply paste them on the wall. the case of the Tan family, a large supplier for Levi Strauss. The Tans were allegedly forcing 1,200 Chinese and Filipino women to work 74 hours per week in guarded compounds on the Mariana Islands. In 1992, after repeated warnings to the Tans, Levi Strauss broke off business relations with them. Creating an Ethical Corporate Culture The core values for business that I have enumerated can help companies begin to exercise ethical judgment and think about how to operate ethically in foreign cultures, but they are not specific enough to guide managers through actual ethical dilemmas. Levi Strauss relied on a written code of conduct when figuring out how to deal with the Tan family. The company’s Global Sourcing and Operating Guidelines, formerly called the Business Partner Terms of Engagement, state that Levi Strauss will “seek to identify and utilize business partners who aspire as individuals and in the conduct of all their businesses to a set of ethical standards not incompatible with our own.” Whenever intolerable business situations arise, managers should be guided by precise statements that spell out the behavior and operating practices that the company demands. Ninety percent of all Fortune 500 companies have codes of conduct, and 70% have statements of vision and values. In Europe and the Far East, the percentages are lower but 8 HARVARD BUSINESS REVIEW 162 September-October 1996 W O R L D are increasing rapidly. Does that mean that most companies have what they need? Hardly. Even though most large U.S. companies have both statements of values and codes of conduct, many might be better off if they didn’t. Too many companies don’t do anything with the documents; they simply paste them on the wall to impress employees, customers, suppliers, and the public. As a result, the senior managers who drafted the statements lose credibility by proclaiming values and not living up to them. Companies such as Johnson & Johnson, Levi Strauss, Motorola, Texas Instruments, and Lockheed Martin, however, do a great deal to make the words meaningful. Johnson & Johnson, for example, has become well known for its Credo Challenge sessions, in which managers discuss ethics in the context of their current business problems and are invited to criticize the company’s credo and make suggestions for changes. The participants’ ideas are passed on to the company’s senior managers. Lockheed Martin has created an innovative site on the World Wide Web and on its local network that gives employees, customers, and suppliers access to the company’s ethical code and the chance to voice complaints. Codes of conduct must provide clear direction about ethical behavior when the temptation to behave unethically is strongest. The pronouncement in a code of conduct that bribery is unacceptable is useless unless accompanied by guide- The company’s code of conduct, however, is explicit about actual business practice. With respect to bribery, for example, the code states that the “funds and assets of Motorola shall not be used, directly or indirectly, for illegal payments of any kind.” It is unambiguous about what sort of payment is illegal: “the payment of a bribe to a public official or the kickback of funds to an employee of a customer....” The code goes on to prescribe specific procedures for handling commissions to intermediaries, issuing sales invoices, and disclosing confidential information in a sales transaction – all situations in which employees might have an opportunity to accept or offer bribes. Codes of conduct must be explicit to be useful, but they must also leave room for a manager to use his or her judgment in situations requiring cultural sensitivity. Hostcountry employees shouldn’t be forced to adopt all home-country Many activities are neither good nor bad but exist in moral free space. lines for gift giving, payments to get goods through customs, and “requests” from intermediaries who are hired to ask for bribes. Motorola’s values are stated very simply as “How we will always act: [with] constant respect for people [and] uncompromising integrity.” HARVARD BUSINESS REVIEW V I E W values and renounce their own. Again, Motorola’s code is exemplary. First, it gives clear direction: “Employees of Motorola will respect the laws, customs, and traditions of each country in which they operate, but will, at the same time, engage in no course of conduct which, even if legal, customary, and accepted in any such country, could be deemed to be in violation of the accepted business ethics of Motorola or the laws of the United States relating to business ethics.” After laying down such absolutes, Motorola’s code then makes clear when individual judgment will be necessary. For example, employees may sometimes accept certain kinds of small gifts “in rare circumstances, where the refusal to accept a gift” would injure Motorola’s “legitimate business interests.” Under certain circumstances, such gifts “may be accepted so long as the gift inures to the benefit of Motorola” and not “to the benefit of the Motorola employee.” Striking the appropriate balance between providing clear direction and leaving room for individual 9 September-October 1996 163 W O R L D judgment makes crafting corporate values statements and ethics codes one of the hardest tasks that executives confront. The words are only a start. A company’s leaders need to refer often to their organization’s credo and code and must themselves be credible, committed, and consistent. If senior managers act as though ethics don’t matter, the rest of the company’s employees won’t think they do, either. Conflicts of Development and Conflicts of Tradition Managers living and working abroad who are not prepared to grapple with moral ambiguity and tension should pack their bags and come home. The view that all business practices can be categorized as either ethical or unethical is too simple. As Einstein is reported to have said, “Things should be as simple as possible – but no simpler.” Many business practices that are considered unethical in one setting may be ethical in another. Such activities are neither black nor white but exist in what Thomas Dunfee and I have called moral free space.2 In this gray zone, there are no tight prescriptions for a company’s behavior. Managers must chart their own courses – as long as they do not violate core human values. Consider the following example. Some successful Indian companies offer employees the opportunity for one of their children to gain a job with the company once the child has completed a certain level in school. The companies honor this commitment even when other applicants are more qualified than an employee’s child. The perk is extremely valuable in a country where jobs are hard to find, and it reflects the Indian culture’s belief that the West has gone too far in allowing economic opportunities to break up families. Not surprisingly, the perk is among the most cherished by employees, but in most Western countries, it would be branded unacceptable nepotism. In the United States, for example, the ethical principle of equal opportunity holds that jobs should go to the applicants with the best qualifications. If a U.S. com- V I E W pany made such promises to its employees, it would violate regulations established by the Equal Employment Opportunity Commission. Given this difference in ethical attitudes, how should U.S. managers react to Indian nepotism? Should they condemn the Indian companies, refusing to accept them as partners or suppliers until they agree to clean up their act? Despite the obvious tension be- tween nepotism and principles of equal opportunity, I cannot condemn the practice for Indians. In a country, such as India, that emphasizes clan and family relationships and has catastrophic levels of unemployment, the practice must be viewed in moral free space. The decision to allow a special perk for employees and their children is not necessarily wrong – at least for members of that country. The Problem with Bribery Bribery is widespread and insidious. Managers in transnational companies routinely confront bribery even though most countries have laws against it. The fact is that officials in many developing countries wink at the practice, and the salaries of local bureaucrats are so low that many consider bribes a form of remuneration. The U.S. Foreign Corrupt Practices Act defines allowable limits on petty bribery in the form of routine payments required to move goods through customs. But demands for bribes often exceed those limits, and there is seldom a good solution. Bribery disrupts distribution channels when goods languish on docks until local handlers are paid off, and it destroys incentives to compete on quality and cost when purchasing decisions are based on who pays what under the table. Refusing to acquiesce is often tantamount to giving business to unscrupulous companies. I believe that even routine bribery is intolerable. Bribery undermines market efficiency and predictability, thus ultimately denying people their right to a minimal standard of living. Some degree of ethical commitment – some sense that everyone will play by the rules – is necessary for a sound economy. Without an ability to predict outcomes, who would be willing to invest? 10 There was a U.S. company whose shipping crates were regularly pilfered by handlers on the docks of Rio de Janeiro. The handlers would take about 10% of the contents of the crates, but the company was never sure which 10% it would be. In a partial solution, the company began sending two crates – the first with 90% of the merchandise, the second with 10%. The handlers learned to take the second crate and leave the first untouched. From the company’s perspective, at least knowing which goods it would lose was an improvement. Bribery does more than destroy predictability; it undermines essential social and economic systems. That truth is not lost on businesspeople in countries where the practice is woven into the social fabric. CEOs in India admit that their companies engage constantly in bribery, and they say that they have considerable disgust for the practice. They blame government policies in part, but Indian executives also know that their country’s business practices perpetuate corrupt behavior. Anyone walking the streets of Calcutta, where it is clear that even a dramatic redistribution of wealth would still leave most of India’s inhabitants in dire poverty, comes face-toface with the devastating effects of corruption. HARVARD BUSINESS REVIEW 164 September-October 1996 W O R L D How can managers discover the limits of moral free space? That is, how can they learn to distinguish a value in tension with their own from one that is intolerable? Helping managers develop good ethical judgment requires companies to be clear about their core values and codes of conduct. But even the most explicit set of guidelines cannot always provide answers. That is especially true in the thorniest ethical dilemmas, in which the host country’s ethical standards not only are different but also seem lower than the home following question: Would the practice be acceptable at home if my country were in a similar stage of economic development? Consider the difference between wage and safety standards in the United States and in Angola, where citizens accept lower standards on both counts. If a U.S. oil company is hiring Angolans to work on an offshore Angolan oil rig, can the company pay them lower wages than it pays U.S. workers in the Gulf of Mexico? Reasonable people have to answer yes if the alternative for Angola is the loss of both the foreign investment and the jobs. Consider, too, differences in regulatory environments. In the 1980s, the government of India fought hard to be able to import Ciba-Geigy’s Entero Vioform, a drug known to be enormously effective in fighting dysentery but one that had been banned in the United States because some users experienced side effects. Although dysentery was not a big problem in the United States, in India, poor public sanitation was contributing to epidemic levels of the disease. Was it unethical to make the drug available in India after it had been banned in the United States? On the contrary, rational people should consider it unethical not to do so. Apply our test: Would the United States, at an earlier stage of development, have used this drug despite its side effects? The answer is clearly yes. But there are many instances when the answer to similar questions is no. Sometimes a host country’s standards are inadequate at any level of economic development. If a country’s pollution standards are so low that working on an oil rig would considerably increase a person’s risk of developing cancer, foreign oil companies must refuse to do business there. Likewise, if the dangerous side effects of a drug treatment outweigh its benefits, managers should not accept health standards that ignore the risks. When relative economic conditions do not drive tensions, there is If a company declared all gift giving unethical, it wouldn’t be able to do business in Japan. country’s. Managers must recognize that when countries have different ethical standards, there are two types of conflict that commonly arise. Each type requires its own line of reasoning. In the first type of conflict, which I call a conflict of relative development, ethical standards conflict because of the countries’ different levels of economic development. As mentioned before, developing countries may accept wage rates that seem inhumane to more advanced countries in order to attract investment. As economic conditions in a developing country improve, the incidence of that sort of conflict usually decreases. The second type of conflict is a conflict of cultural tradition. For example, Saudi Arabia, unlike most other countries, does not allow women to serve as corporate managers. Instead, women may work in only a few professions, such as education and health care. The prohibition stems from strongly held religious and cultural beliefs; any increase in the country’s level of economic development, which is already quite high, is not likely to change the rules. To resolve a conflict of relative development, a manager must ask the HARVARD BUSINESS REVIEW V I E W a more objective test for resolving ethical problems. Managers should deem a practice permissible only if they can answer no to both of the following questions: Is it possible to conduct business successfully in the host country without undertaking the practice? and Is the practice a violation of a core human value? Japanese gift giving is a perfect example of a conflict of cultural tradition. Most experienced businesspeople, Japanese and non-Japanese alike, would agree that doing business in Japan would be virtually impossible without adopting the practice. Does gift giving violate a core human value? I cannot identify one that it violates. As a result, gift giving may be permissible for foreign companies in Japan even if it conflicts with ethical attitudes at home. In fact, that conclusion is widely accepted, even by companies such as Texas Instruments and IBM, which are outspoken against bribery. Does it follow that all nonmonetary gifts are acceptable or that bribes are generally acceptable in countries where they are common? Not at all. (See the insert “The Problem with Bribery.”) What makes the routine practice of gift giving acceptable in Japan are the limits in its scope and intention. When gift giving moves outside those limits, it soon collides with core human values. For example, when Carl Kotchian, president of Lockheed in the 1970s, carried suitcases full of cash to Japanese politicians, he went beyond the nor ms established by Japanese tradition. That incident galvanized opinion in the United States Congress and helped lead to passage of the Foreign Corrupt Practices Act. Likewise, Roh Tae Woo went beyond the norms established by Korean cultural tradition when he accepted $635.4 million in bribes as president of the Republic of Korea between 1988 and 1993. Guidelines for Ethical Leadership Learning to spot intolerable practices and to exercise good judgment when ethical conflicts arise requires practice. Creating a company culture that rewards ethical behavior is 11 September-October 1996 165 W O R L D essential. The following guidelines for developing a global ethical perspective among managers can help. Treat corporate values and formal standards of conduct as absolutes. Whatever ethical standards a company chooses, it cannot waver on its principles either at home or abroad. Consider what has become part of company lore at Motorola. Around 1950, a senior executive was negotiating with officials of a South American government on a $10 million sale that would have increased the company’s annual net profits by nearly 25%. As the negotiations neared completion, however, the executive walked away from the deal because the officials were asking for $1 million for “fees.” CEO Robert Galvin not only supported the executive’s decision but also made it clear that Motorola would neither accept the sale on any terms nor do business with those government officials again. Retold over the decades, this story demonstrating Galvin’s resolve has helped cement a culture of ethics for thousands of employees at Motorola. Design and implement conditions of engagement for suppliers and customers. Will your company do business with any customer or supplier? What if a customer or supplier uses child labor? What if it has strong links with organized crime? What if it pressures your company to break a host country’s laws? Such issues are best not left for spur-of-themoment decisions. Some companies have realized that. Sears, for instance, has developed a policy of not contracting production to companies that use prison labor or infringe on workers’ rights to health and safety. And BankAmerica has specified as a condition for many of its loans to developing countries that environmental standards and human rights must be observed. Allow foreign business units to help formulate ethical standards and interpret ethical issues. The French pharmaceutical company Rhône- V I E W Poulenc Rorer has allowed foreign subsidiaries to augment lists of corporate ethical principles with their own suggestions. Texas Instruments has paid special attention to issues of international business ethics by creating the Global Business Practices Council, which is made up of managers from countries in which the company operates. With the overarching intent to create a “global ethics strategy, locally deployed,” the council’s mandate is to provide ethics education and create local processes that will help managers in the company’s foreign business units resolve ethical conflicts. In host countries, support efforts to decrease institutional corruption. Individual managers will not be able to wipe out corruption in a host country, no matter how many bribes they turn down. When a host country’s tax system, import and export procedures, and procurement practices favor unethical players, companies must take action. Many companies have begun to participate in reforming host-country institutions. General Electric, for example, has taken a strong stand in India, using the media to make repeated condemnations of bribery in business and government. General Electric and others have found, however, that a single company usually cannot drive out entrenched corruption. Transparency International, an organization based in Germany, has been effective in helping coalitions of companies, government officials, and others work to reform briberyridden bureaucracies in Russia, Bangladesh, and elsewhere. Exercise moral imagination. Using moral imagination means resolving tensions responsibly and creatively. Coca-Cola, for instance, has consistently turned down requests for bribes from Egyptian officials but has managed to gain political support and public trust by sponsoring a project to plant fruit trees. And take the example of Levi Strauss, which discovered in the early 1990s that 12 two of its suppliers in Bangladesh were employing children under the age of 14–a practice that violated the company’s principles but was tolerated in Bangladesh. Forcing the suppliers to fire the children would not have ensured that the children received an education, and it would have caused serious hardship for the families depending on the children’s wages. In a creative arrangement, the suppliers agreed to pay the children’s regular wages while they attended school and to offer each child a job at age 14. Levi Strauss, in turn, agreed to pay the children’s tuition and provide books and uniforms. That arrangement allowed Levi Strauss to uphold its principles and provide long-term benefits to its host country. Many people think of values as soft; to some they are usually unspoken. A South Seas island society uses the word mokita, which means, “the truth that everybody knows but nobody speaks.” However difficult they are to articulate, values affect how we all behave. In a global business environment, values in tension are the rule rather than the exception. Without a company’s commitment, statements of values and codes of ethics end up as empty platitudes that provide managers with no foundation for behaving ethically. Employees need and deserve more, and responsible members of the global business community can set examples for others to follow. The dark consequences of incidents such as Union Carbide’s disaster in Bhopal remind us how high the stakes can be. 1. In other writings, Thomas W. Dunfee and I have used the term hypernorm instead of core human value. 2. Thomas Donaldson and Thomas W. Dunfee, “Toward a Unified Conception of Business Ethics: Integrative Social Contracts Theory,” Academy of Management Review, April 1994; and “Integrative Social Contracts Theory: A Communitarian Conception of Economic Ethics,” Economics and Philosophy, spring 1995. Reprint 96502 To place an order, call 1-800-545-7685. HARVARD BUSINESS REVIEW 166 September-October 1996 Harvard Business School 9-299-009 August 11, 1998 The General Motors Corporation (D) 1993-1996 In December 1996, John D. Finnegan and his staff were preparing for an upcoming meeting of the Board of Directors of the General Motors Corporation (GM) that was scheduled for January 27, 1997. Finnegan, the Treasurer of GM, was responsible for developing a plan to address a cash surplus identified in GM’s most recent five year plan. The Board would consider whether GM should hold excess cash, increase the firm’s dividend, or repurchase shares. If the firm were to proceed with a stock buy-back, Finnegan and his group would need to recommend how to proceed with the details of its execution and whether to incorporate the use of puts or an Accelerated Share Repurchase structure. These decisions would be made in light of GM’s financial policies, its recent history, and its projections of future needs. Rebuilding General Motors’ Balance Sheet GM’s new management team inherited a difficult position when they took over at the end of 1992. Having maintained solvency through the most difficult part of a downturn in the auto industry and having raised sufficient capital to begin the company’s rebuilding process, the new management next provided an internal mandate to “clean up” the company’s balance sheet. Specifically, the Treasury staff was given until the end of 1994 to accomplish the following objectives: • Determine cash balances necessary to survive the next automotive downturn; • Determine the debt-to-total capital ratio that moves the corporation to its optimal WACC, work with the rating agencies on communicating a plan necessary to improve the credit rating, and make the changes to the capital structure that are necessary to meet the target; • Determine a sustainable dividend level and dividend yield and regain investor confidence through an achievable and well communicated dividend policy; and Charles M. Williams Fellow Markus F. Mullarkey and William J. Wildern, IV, MBA 1997 prepared this case under the supervision of Professor Peter Tufano as the basis for class discussion rather than to illustrate either effective or ineffective handling of an administrative situation. It is part of a four-part General Motors Corporation case series including HBS Cases #299-006 through #299-009. Copyright © 1998 by the President and Fellows of Harvard College. To order copies or request permission to reproduce materials, call 1-800-545-7685 or write Harvard Business School Publishing, Boston, MA 02163. No part of this publication may be reproduced, stored in a retrieval system, used in a spreadsheet, or transmitted in any form or by any means—electronic, mechanical, photocopying, recording, or otherwise—without the permission of Harvard Business School. 1 167 299-009 The General Motors Corporation (D) • Fully fund the pension plan. The key financial targets that the Group recommended are described in the General Motors Corporation (B) case. The return to profitability Between 1993 and 1996, U.S. automotive sales began to rebound from the slump in 1990-1992. By 1996, retail sales of passenger cars and light trucks were expected to approach 17 million units, up 13% from 1992. While GM’s market share fell from 33.1% in 1992 to 31.0% in 1996, total GM units sold in the U.S. rose 6% in this period, and revenues rose 24%. Coupled with an improvement in reduction in cost of goods sold, this generated a turnaround in pre-tax income from negative $3.3 billion in 1992 to a profit of $6.7 billion in 1996 (see Exhibit 1). The improvement in GM’s auto business significantly relaxed the cash difficulties the company had been facing, generating an estimated operating cash flow of $18.7 billion in 1996, over three times its operating cash flow of $5.9 billion in 1991. This allowed the company to re-establish its investment program, and between 1994 and 1996, the company dedicated $27.2 billion in cash flow to investing activities, 28% above 1992 spending levels. In addition, stronger results allowed GM to resume contributions to its corporate pension plans, reducing GM’s underfunded pension liability from $22.3 billion to $4.6 billion between 1993 and 1996.1 As a result of its improved performance, GM’s stock price improved over the 1992-1996 time period, despite a slight recession in 1994 that affected all auto manufacturers (see Exhibit 2). Increasing the dividend As a result of the improved performance, in the second quarter of 1995, GM’s Board of Directors voted to increase the company’s quarterly dividend from $0.20 per quarter to $0.30 per quarter. This was done primarily to keep GM’s dividend yield on par with those of the other major U.S. automakers, both of whom had been increasing their dividends recently and were expected to do so again in the second quarter of 1995 (see Exhibit 3). In addition, executives recognized that, “a lot of work had been done and people wanted to send a signal to the market that GM was on track again.”2 The dividend was increased to $.40 per quarter nine months later in the first quarter of 1996, still well below the $0.75 per quarter GM paid prior to the dividend cut in 1991. 3 These dividend increases were intended as a signal of GM’s confidence in its future earnings potential. 1 See Harvard University Kennedy School of Government Cases #C108-97-1385.0 and #C108-97-1386.0, Protecting Pension Benefits: The Pension Benefit Guarantee Corporation Meets General Motors: Parts A and B, for more information on the history and details of GM’s pension actions during this period. 2 However, despite an initial 1.0% increase in GM’s stock price over the two days following the dividend announcement, GM’s share price fell 1.4% over the three week period following the dividend increase (see Exhibit 4). In the comparable two-day and three-week periods, the S&P 500 index rose 1.7% and 3.8% respectively. 3 The immediate market reaction to the 1996 dividend announcement was strong. GM’s share price increased 2.3% in the two days following the announcement, while the S&P 500 index was up 0.7%. In addition, over three weeks following the announcement GM’s share price increased further, gaining a total of 7.6% (see Exhibit 4). 2 168 The General Motors Corporation (D) 299-009 Cleaning up the balance sheet As a result of GM’s improving operating performance, the finance staff was able to undertake a number of programs in an effort to reconfigure the company’s balance sheet, to reduce leverage, to upgrade the company’s rating, and to simplify the structure of its equity claims. Paying down debt By 1993, GM’s total debt-to-total capital (book) ratio had exceeded 58.3%. In addition, throughout the 1990-1992 period, GM’s EBIT-to-interest expense ratio was negative, reflecting the company’s operating losses, and even its ratio of EBITDA to interest expense dropped below 1.00 in 1991. Between 1992 and 1994, however, GM began decreasing its debt outstanding in an effort to reduce the company’s debt-to-total capital ratios. As a result, by the end of 1996, the company was expected to meet its leverage targets, with a debt-to-total capital ratio of 22% and an EBIT-to-interest coverage ratio of 6.2. Converting the PERCS In 1991, GM had issued 17.8 million shares of Preference Equity Redemption Cumulative Stock, which paid $.83 per quarter. In essence the PERCS were a form of common stock with capped appreciation. June 1994, the PERCS were converted into GM common stock on a one-for-one basis, reducing its preferred dividend payments and lowering overall dividend payments. GM had the option to pay $53.79 per share in cash between May 1 and July 1, 1994 to force conversion prior to the mandatory one-for-one stock conversion date of July 1, 1994. With common stock trading between $50 and $55 per share in the three months prior to mandatory conversion, the company announced that it would convert all outstanding PERCS on a one-for-one basis into GM common as of the closing price on June 17, 1994. The stock closed at $53-7/8 and all outstanding PERCS were converted. The conversion was covered by issuing 17.8 million new shares (increasing the total number of outstanding GM common shares by that number). Tendering the Preference Stocks GM also sought to eliminate a substantial amount of its outstanding preference stock. This stock, which had been issued in the early 1990’s, when GM was under financial stress, carried an average dividend coupon of 8.9%. This was very inefficient in comparison to debt financing because the dividend coupon (unlike an interest coupon on a debt security) was not tax deductible. As a result, GM sought to tender for the shares, thereby reducing the after-tax coupon it paid, cleaning-up the company’s balance sheet, and improving the efficiency of its financing. In May, 1995, GM successfully tendered 57% of the Series B, D, and G preferred stock with an outlay of $1.3 billion in cash. GM also considered the use of a number of other innovative structures to maximize shareholder value. One such structure, Trust Originated Preferred Shares (TOPrS), was being considered in late1996 for implementation in 1997. In essence, the structure replaced the preference stock that remained after the May 1995 tender offer with subordinated debentures through the use of an innovative trust structure. While the resulting structure was economically quite similar to the original structure, it was far more efficient financially because of the significant tax advantage it created as GM deducted interest payments on the debentures for tax purposes. However, with respect to the economics of the transaction and the accounting by GM, TOPrS would retain many attractive features of equity. GM’s 1996 Balance Sheet Review Thus, by the end of 1996, the company was largely restored to financial health as measured by the policy targets it had set in the early 1990s. The company was projected by the end of the year to achieve its leverage target (20%-25% debt-to-total capital on a book basis) and to have fully funded its pension liability when measured on an economic basis. At the same time, the company was working with rating agencies to restore its debt rating to a credible single-A level, and was expecting 3 169 299-009 The General Motors Corporation (D) action in that regard by the middle of 1997. Lastly, for the first time since the financial crisis, the company was projecting a substantial cash surplus over the target cash balances to which it had committed itself at the time of its crisis in 1992 ($13 billion), thereby prompting a review of the company’s future cash needs. The first step in determining the appropriate cash balances for the company going forward was to update the company’s 1993 analysis of its likely cash needs over the coming 5 year business plan. GM’s capital planning group initiated the process by putting together financial projections which incorporated not only the company’s budgets and strategic plans, but also the market conditions the company was expected to face. The casewriters’ estimates of these projections indicated that GM could be expected to generate approximately $4.9 billion in excess cash (beyond the target level) by 1997 and $15 billion in cash over the next five years (see Exhibit 5).4 Realizing that the company would post cash balances well above its $13 billion cash target by the end of 1996, many investors had begun to speculate openly about the company’s response. In October 1996 one analyst forecasted, “a large dividend hike [and] a share buyback program.” Similarly, another analyst stated that, “in addition to dividend increases, we would also attach a high probability to a share repurchase authorization being passed within the next 24 months.” As a result, the Treasury staff was asked to provide a recommendation about the disposition of the company’s cash balances to be discussed in early 1997 with the President’s Council composed of the seven top executives of the corporation.5 If approved, the recommendation would be discussed at the January 27, 1997 meeting of the firm’s Board of Directors. In the meantime, the Treasury staff would work with the company’s Chief Financial Officer, J. Michael Losh, to generate and evaluate alternatives. Given GM’s recent history, Finnegan was sure the matter would receive an unusually high level of attention and scrutiny. As one executive noted, “you have to remember, a lot of these people had the unpleasant experience of living through that tumultuous period when they had to defend their actions day-in and day-out. Now that GM was out of trouble, many of them saw a chance to put forth a policy that enabled them to fulfill their past promises.” The finance team knew the importance of the task, and the visibility it would receive, both inside and outside GM. GM’s Alternatives Broadly speaking, there were four main alternatives GM needed to consider moving forward: spending the money on investments beyond the company’s current five year investment plan, holding the money as an additional cash buffer against future downturns, reducing the firm’s leverage, or returning cash to investors in the form of dividends (either a one-time special dividend or a common stock dividend increase) or a share repurchase program. 4 Estimates of GM’s future cash balances are made by the casewriters and based on historical trends and economic and automotive market estimates. They are for illustrative purposes only and do not necessarily represent the company’s actual expectations of its future cash position. 5 In January 1997, the President’s Council consisted of: John F. Smith, Jr., Chairman, CEO, and President; J. Michael Losh, CFO; G. Richard Wagoner, President North American Operations; Louis R. Hughes, President International Operations; Harry J. Pearce, Vice Chairman; C. Michael Armstrong, CEO Hughes Electronics Corporation; and J. T. Battenberg, III, President of Delphi Automotive Systems. 4 170 The General Motors Corporation (D) 299-009 Incremental spending One potential use of the surplus cash balance was for GM to find incremental spending opportunities that would enhance shareholder value, or to accelerate its currently planned investment program. A number of alternatives were considered such as the following: Investments Executives at GM had analyzed the potential for incremental growth or globalization initiatives, and appreciated the importance of maintaining the flexibility to take advantage of strategic opportunities that might arise. As a result, the Treasury staff felt that the allocation of some funds to cover such contingencies was an attractive proposition. These opportunities might require as much as $500 million in investment in any given year, though it was too late in 1996 to begin any initiatives in that calendar year. Pension Contributions Despite having virtually eliminated its large underfunded pension liability, GM could still make incremental contributions to its pension programs as a buffer against potential poor investment returns, future increased labor settlements, or changes in the discount rate at which future obligations would be calculated. However, the company did not foresee a significant risk of falling below the regulatory constraints on their pension funding given the contributions that were already planned. Holding the Cash GM could hold onto the cash and boost its cash balances. Given the large impact an economic downturn could have on GM’s profitability and cash flows (see Exhibit 6), there were some on the Board of Directors that felt that erring on the conservative side was appropriate. They were also concerned by the projected slowdown in automotive sector performance that was expected to occur during 1997, and were aware of the difficulties a number of firms in the automotive industry had faced in periods where cash became constrained. Finnegan realized, however, that conservatism was not without its costs. Because cash balances earned considerably lower returns than capital invested in a profitable business, Finnegan did not want GM to be more conservative than was realistically necessary to ensure the company could continue making profitable investments as opportunities arose. Beyond that point, however, more cash would be a drain on GM’s return on equity. Other costs of large cash balances involved increasing the likelihood of shareholder criticism and activism against GM management. In evaluating this alternative, Finnegan would rely on the 1993 analysis by the Planning Group that had been recently revised. The analysis, which examined the company’s possible usage of cash under potentially severe economic scenarios, recommended a cash balance of $13 billion would provide ample insurance against a worst-case scenario. Reducing debt Excess cash can be thought of as negative leverage, which gives rise to taxable interest income and additional earnings. Rather than hold more cash, GM could reduce its leverage by repurchasing outstanding debt in the marketplace. Given recent declines in interest rates and the recent improvements in GM’s credit quality, however, the debt would have to be repurchased at prices above par, giving rise to negative earnings charges as the company took an immediate extinguishment of debt charge (the full loss would be recognized immediately, not amortized over future periods). However, the loss would also generate a positive tax impact by accelerating the recognition of the write-down for tax purposes. The alternative of reducing the debt balance would have to be evaluated within the context of the company’s stated total debt-to-total capital targets, which specified a 20-25% debt-to-total capital ratio and an A rating or higher. 5 171 299-009 The General Motors Corporation (D) Returning the cash to shareholders Rather than spending the cash, holding on to it, or using it to reduce leverage, GM could return the cash to investors. This was a contentious issue among some key Board of Directors members. For example, some felt that investment advisors would consider returning cash to shareholders as an indication that the company was “out of good ideas,” and that would be a poor reflection on its management as well as its Board of Directors. However, as one very well known investor had remarked to GM executives, “As a mature company in a cyclical industry, you shouldn’t be getting capital from the market, you should be giving it back.” This critique resonated with many senior executives and Board members. Cash could be returned to shareholders via dividends or share repurchases, each of which is treated in more detail below: Dividends In analyzing potential dividend increases, the company referred to the dividend policy which had been set following the dividend cuts in the early 1990s.6 The policy indicated that GM’s dividend decisions should be guided by an analysis of and comparison to competitors’ dividend yields, an ability to maintain a reasonable average payout ratio throughout the business cycle, and an ability to sustain dividend payments over the long-term. Analysis of Chrysler and Ford’s dividends indicated that GM’s dividend yield (its annual dividend as a percentage of common stock price) was somewhat lower than its competitors (see Exhibit 3). Whereas Ford and Chrysler currently delivered 4.5% dividend yields, GM’s current quarterly dividend of $0.40 per share resulted in a dividend yield of only 3.0%.7 Many felt this was a problem as it would place GM at a disadvantage vis-à-vis other auto companies with respect to their ability to attract yield-oriented investors who were interested in holding auto stocks. In addition, this yield was much lower than GM’s historical dividend yield which had ranged from 5.5% to 8.0% between 1987 and 1990. The Treasury staff had also performed an analysis of GM’s dividend payout ratio. Lastly, the Treasurer’s Office took the cash forecast prepared by the Capital Planning group and estimated the level of dividend that could be sustained over the following 5 years. Casewriters’ estimates indicate that an annual dividend increase of $0.30 per quarter, while feasible in good times, would leave the company with little flexibility. A large economic downturn might force GM to decide among a dividend cut, a cut in planned investment, or an increase in external financing. This is precisely the sort of situation GM was seeking to avoid, and the reason GM had created its stated financial policies after the financial crisis in the early 1990’s. One way to mitigate the risk of future dividend cuts while still announcing a large dividend was to simply announce a “special dividend.” If labeled in this way, investors would understand that the dividend was not expected to be repeated on a quarterly basis, and would not be disappointed if the dividend could not be maintained. In fact, this was exactly how GM used to manage its dividend payout in the 1970’s, when second and fourth quarter special dividends came to be an expected part of GM stock ownership. In years when the company was producing strong results, the special dividend would be large, whereas in slower years, it would shrink or disappear altogether. While this seemed to avert the risk of announcing a strong dividend, there was some question as to whether it had any impact on the company’s stock price. As CFO J. Michael Losh put it, “We were doing then what we now know is exactly the wrong thing. When you use special dividends, you get no credit from investors for the dividend, because they know they can’t count on it in the future.” 6 See HBS Case #299-007, The General Motors Corporation (B) for more details on GM’s dividend policy decisions. 7 The average dividend yield of stocks in the S&P 500 index at the end of 1996 was approximately 2.0%. 6 172 The General Motors Corporation (D) 299-009 Share repurchase programs Another option to address the cash surplus was a share repurchase program. This had a number of potential benefits as compared with a dividend increase or special dividend. For example, it was considered more tax efficient from the standpoint of taxable investors because the maximum federal income tax rate on dividend income was higher than that on capital gains income (39.6% to the highest taxed investor versus a 28% long-term capital gains tax8). Moreover, a share repurchase program would have a positive EPS benefit compared to a dividend increase due to an unchanged net income being applied to a reduced number of shares outstanding upon completion of the program. While it was unclear whether this EPS boost would be perceived by the market as advantageous, some reasoned that if the P/E multiple for GM remained in the then current 8 to 9 range for an automotive company, GM’s stock price would naturally rise due to increasing EPS. Additionally, if it were possible to consistently and predictably boost EPS through the use of repurchases, the stock might even eventually enjoy a higher P/E multiple as a result. There were also potential signaling benefits of announcing a stock buyback program. Research from academics and Wall Street analysts showed that companies that announced share repurchases had been shown to enjoy an average stock price boost anywhere from 2%-15% around the time of the announcement (see Exhibit 7). Some studies documented the persistence of these excess returns for longer periods of time after the announcement.9 Implementing a repurchase If GM decided to pursue a repurchase program, there were three primary ways to execute it: through an open market purchase, a fixed-price tender offer, or a Dutch auction style tender offer. Exhibit 8 provides a description of each method. Open market repurchases Of the three primary forms of share repurchases, open market repurchase programs were the most widely used, accounting for roughly 90% of repurchase programs initiated between 1989 and 1996.10 In an open market repurchase, a company simply repurchased shares through brokers on the open market. The overall size of the repurchase program would be announced to shareholders, though specific repurchases would not need to be reported individually. The primary advantage of such a program was its flexibility with respect to timing, purchase price, and number of shares purchased. In addition, since GM could speed up or slow down the rate at which it repurchased shares over time, it could maintain flexibility to match its seasonal cash flows. In addition, opportunistic purchases of large blocks at attractive pricing could speed up completion of the program while minimizing its cost. Lastly, no pre-set premium was anticipated on the shares, and skillful broker execution could actually lead to an average repurchase price somewhat below market prices (reportedly as much as 5%). The major drawbacks to the program were the risk of price appreciation of GM’s shares (which would increase the average repurchase price) and the restriction on the company’s ability to execute the program quickly. For example, SEC Rule 10(b)-18 limited the shares of its own stock a company 8 US tax rates in effect in December 1996. 9 Samuel Stewert, Jr., for example, documents a 5-20% excess annual return over the five years subsequent to a repurchase program (see “Should a Corporation Repurchase its Own Stock?,” The Journal Of Finance, June 1976), while Ikenbrery, Lakonishok, and Vermaelen document a 12.6% average excess returns over the four years following repurchase announcements (see “Market Underreaction to Open Market Share Repurchases,” Working Paper No. 106, Rice University, July 1994). 10 Reported by Chris Innes, Peter B. Blanton, Nomo Nomo-Ongolo, and Cindy Sieden, “Stock Buybacks – Strategy and Tactics,” Salomon Brothers, February 1997 using data from Securities Data Company. 7 173 299-009 The General Motors Corporation (D) could repurchase to approximately 25% of the company’s daily trading volume.11 As a result, open market repurchases usually took longer to complete than other means of repurchasing shares. Fixed-price tender offer Fixed-price tender offers were less common than open market repurchases, accounting for 6.5% of all programs between 1989 and 1996. Under a fixed-price tender offer, GM would announce the proposed tender offer including the number of shares it sought to repurchase and the fixed price at which it offered to purchase them. It would then file with the SEC and mail tender documents to shareholders. This alternative had a number of advantages including the rapid timing (within seven to nine weeks) and known costs of the program. It also provided the ability for management to describe the rationale for the program in the offering documentation mailed to shareholders. The drawbacks, however, included its inflexibility and the higher costs of the program as compared with other alternatives. For example, once announced, GM would not be able to change the price of the tender offer as the market price of its shares moved. Nor could the number of shares which would be repurchased be altered. Also, the tender was typically carried out at a significant premium (often as large as 15% above the then prevailing market price of the shares). Dutch-auction style tender offer Dutch-auction style tender offers accounted for 3.8% of all announced share repurchase programs. Under this type of program, a company would announce the number of shares it sought to repurchase and an expiration date for the offer, but instead of announcing a tender price, it would announce a minimum and maximum repurchase price. Tendering shareholders would then offer to sell their shares at prices within the range announced by the company. At the expiration of the offer, the price required to repurchase all of the shares sought by the company would be set and shareholders tendering at that price or lower would sell their shares at the tender price. Shareholders who tendered at higher prices would not be bought out. The primary advantage of this alternative as compared with a fixed-price tender is that it decreased the risk of significant over- or under-pricing of the repurchase (because the eventual tender price was effectively set by the market and flexible over the timeframe of the offer). The primary drawback was that the complexity of the process might reduce the likelihood of small shareholders tendering shares, and therefore increase the risk that the offer would go only partially subscribed. In addition to determining the method of repurchase, GM would also have to consider what size program to attempt. GM had approached a number of the company’s bankers, who had advised the company that a share repurchase needed to target at least 5% of the company’s outstanding shares (about 37 million shares in GM’s case) for it to be considered a credible signal of the undervalued status of the company’s stock. This was supported by research findings which indicated that open market share repurchase programs accounting for 5% or more of a company’s outstanding shares generated a 2.2% three day excess return, while those accounting for less than 5% only generated a 0.6% excess return.12 Beyond 5%, there was disagreement whether incremental size would have an impact. Tender offers (fixed-price or dutch-auction), however, were usually only undertaken in instances where the company was repurchasing 10% or more of its outstanding shares.13 11 Rule 10(b)-18 was intended to help prevent a corporation from artificially boosting its stock price through market intervention. Basically, a firm can only be represented by one broker on any given treading day, and that broker can not participate in the first trade of the day, the last half hour of the day, or on any bid where the last bid was lower than the current bid (an uptick). 12 See Chris Innes, Peter B. Blanton, Nomo Nomo-Ongolo, and Cindy Sieden, “Stock Buybacks – Strategy and Tactics,” Salomon Brothers, February 1997. 13 Similar to the above study with respect to open market repurchase plans, a study quoted in the publication mentioned above indicated that fixed price tender offer programs accounting for 10% or more of a company’s outstanding shares generated a 8.2% three day excess return, while those accounting for less than 10% only 8 174 The General Motors Corporation (D) 299-009 Alternative repurchase structures In conjunction with the three share repurchase methods outlined above, there were a number of other ways GM could complete a share repurchase program and generate tax and/or accounting benefits not available under traditional repurchase methods. Exhibit 8 provides a description of each method. Put writing While put options were not considered a substitute for a share repurchase program, a number of banks had proposed that GM consider writing puts to supplement its repurchase program. A put option gives the holder the right to sell stock at a fixed exercise price. As the writer (or seller) of the puts, GM would give others the right to sell GM stock to the company at a fixed exercise price. GM could write put options equivalent to a portion of the number of shares it intended to repurchase and receive the premium for the sale of these options. Over time, GM would carry out open market repurchase program as outlined above (at currently prevailing market prices). Upon expiration of the put options, if the options were out of the money (i.e., GM stock rose in price above the exercise price), they would not be exercised, and GM would continue with the open-market repurchase. If, however, the options were in the money, they would be exercised, and the put holders would deliver the shares to GM at the exercise price of the puts, and GM would buy fewer shares in the open market. In either case, GM would still receive the up-front, tax-free premium from the put options it sold (Exhibit 9 and 10 provide financial markets data as of the time of the case). Bankers suggested that the potential advantages of this program would be the overall reduction in cost for repurchasing the stock which resulted from the put premium GM received, the tax-free nature of the put premium, and the signal that purchasing puts provides (implying that GM expects its stock price to rise). The drawbacks include the placement of a floor on GM’s repurchase price, the increase in short positions in GM’s stock that result from the put buyer’s efforts to dynamically hedge their put positions, and the potential additional disclosure problems related to the limitation that GM cannot be in possession of any material inside information when entering into the put contract. In conjunction with writing puts on its stock, GM could also buy call options and create a collar. With a cashless collar, GM could use the premium from the written puts to fund the purchase of the call options, with no net inflow or outflow at the initiation of the contract.14 By using a collar position, GM would effectively lock in a price range within which they could repurchase stock. Accelerated share repurchases A second derivative-based repurchase enhancement was what was referred to as an Accelerated Share Repurchase program (ASR). This type of program was intended to allow a company to purchase and retire a targeted number of shares immediately with the final price of the shares determined by the market price of the shares over a fixed period of time in the future. To execute such a program GM would enter into an agreement with an investment bank under which the bank would borrow the company’s shares from investors and sell them to GM immediately at the current market price. The bank would then buyback the shares in the market over a pre-specified period of time at the then-current market prices and return the borrowed shares to the lenders. At the end of the period, the bank would then charge or pay GM the difference between the average generated a 0.8% excess return. Dutch-auction style programs appeared less size sensitive, with programs accounting for 10% or more of a company’s outstanding shares generating a 7.4% three day excess return, while those accounting for less than 10% only generated a 6.2% excess return. 14 Additionally, it is possible to synthetically create a forward contract, or a commitment to repurchase the shares at a fixed price at a certain point in the future, by selling puts and buying an equal amount of calls with the same expiration date and strike price. 9 175 299-009 The General Motors Corporation (D) purchase price of the shares and the initial price paid by GM, so that GM’s ultimate price for the shares would closely match the average market price of the shares over the period. Bankers stated that a primary benefit of this transaction would be that GM would receive the EPS accounting benefit of an immediate share repurchase without the pressure of being forced to complete the repurchase immediately. ASRs disconnect the timing of the accounting impact of a share repurchase from the market implementation, and outsource the execution of the repurchase program to the bank. However, the ASR constituted an irrevocable commitment to purchase the stock; if the stock price appreciated rapidly, the company would not be able to terminate or decelerate the program as it could a traditional open market purchase program. Lastly, an ASR program would result in an increase in reported short interest as the investment bank would have to borrow shares at the beginning of the program. The Decisions The range of decisions available to GM was quite large. Finnegan realized that it would be critical not only to consider the simple dollars and cents of each choice, but to consider the impact each might have on the perceptions of investors and analysts. In particular, Finnegan was acutely aware of the benefits of consistency and stability; analysts and investors looked for patterns and trends in a company’s actions. For example, if the company had declared dividend increases every 3 to 5 quarters for a number of years, not declaring one could prove to be as powerful a signal as cutting a dividend was otherwise. Finnegan was eager to build what he considered a “consistent track record” with the investment community. Because the Board of Directors would have the ultimate decision to approve the recommendations, understanding the group’s dynamics would be important as well. A number of Directors had not been present during the financial crisis of the early 1990’s and the Board was divided. Some felt that erring on the conservative side by holding the excess cash was appropriate, while others questioned the need for the planned $13 billion in cash holdings. One thing they had in common, however, was an appreciation of the visibility their decisions would have both inside and outside the company. 10 176 The General Motors Corporation (D) 299-009 GM financial results 1992-1996 —data in $ billions unless otherwise noted Exhibit 1 Financial Results 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 U.S. market size - millions of units 15.0 16.0 17.3 16.5 17.0 U.S. GM unit sales - millions of units 5.0 5.2 5.6 5.3 5.3 33.1% 32.5% 32.3% 32.3% 31.0% U.S. share of market - % Worldwide revenues 132.2 138.2 148.5 160.3 164.1 Cost of goods sold - % of revenues 79.6% 77.0% 76.5% 75.7% 75.5% Research & development spending 5.9 6.0 7.0 8.2 8.9 Pre-tax income (3.3) 2.6 7.1 8.3 6.7 Net income (before extraordinary items) (2.6) 2.5 4.9 6.0 5.0 Net income (after extraordinary items) (23.5) 2.5 4.9 6.9 5.0 Total cash flow from operations Capital expenditures Total cash flow from investing activities Net increase/(decrease) in debt 1 9.8 14.7 11.1 16.5 18.7 6.6 6.5 7.2 10.1 9.9 1.8 0.4 (16.2) (22.1) (17.7) 0.4 (0.4) (0.2) (1.9) 1.1 (21.1) (0.6) 7.2 10.5 0.1 1.4 1.1 1.1 1.3 1.5 (6.9) (12.5) 2.0 5.3 2.6 8.0 10.5 11.0 10.2 17.0 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 Long-term debt/equity 110.1% 111.1% 47.4% 17.6% 22.2% Total debt/total capital 55.6% 58.3% 36.0% 21.7% 22.0% EBIT/interest expense -1.4 1.8 6.1 19.3 6.2 BBB+ BBB+ A- Net increase/(decrease) in equity 1 Cash dividend payments Total cash flow from financing activities Year-end cash balance Leverage Measures 2 1 Senior bond rating ABBB+ Source: GM financial statements 1 Data reported with GMAC accounted for on an equity basis. 2 Includes cash and marketable securities 1 Exhibit 2 Monthly stock and index prices scaled relative to GM’s price as of December, 1992 $70 $70 $60 $60 $50 $50 $40 $40 $30 $30 GM $20 $20 Ford Chr y sler $10 $10 S&P 500 index 1 Dec-96 Sep-96 Jun-96 Mar-96 Dec-95 Sep-95 Jun-95 Mar-95 Dec-94 Jun-94 Sep-94 Mar-94 Dec-93 Sep-93 Jun-93 Mar-93 $0 Dec-92 $0 As of December 1996, GM’s common stock price was $52.59 per share. 11 177 299-009 The General Motors Corporation (D) Quarterly dividends of the major U.S. automakers Exhibit 3a Recesssion Rebuilding $0.80 GM $0.70 Ford $0.60 Chry sler $0.50 $0.40 $0.30 $0.20 $0.10 Exhibit 3b 1996:1 1995:2 1994:3 1993:4 1993:1 1992:2 1991:3 1990:4 1990:1 1989:2 1988:3 1987:4 1987:1 $0.00 Dividend yields of the major U.S. automakers Recesssion 14.0% Rebuilding GM 12.0% Ford Chr y sler 10.0% 8.0% 6.0% 4.0% 2.0% Exhibit 4 Event 4/28/95 2/2/96 Dividend increase 3 weeks following announcement Change in GM Price Change in S&P 500 Excess 1 Returns Change in GM Price Change in S&P 500 Excess 1 Returns 1.0% 1.7% -0.7% -1.4% 3.8% -5.2% 7.6% 3.5% +4.1% Dividend 2.3% 0.7% +1.6% increase Source: Calculated by casewriters using data from Datastream 1 1996:1 Impact of dividend increases on GM stock price 2 days following announcement Date 1995:2 1994:3 1993:4 1993:1 1992:2 1991:3 1990:4 1990:1 1989:2 1988:3 1987:4 1987:1 0.0% Based on GM’s equity beta versus the S&P 500 index over the prior 250 day period. 12 178 The General Motors Corporation (D) 299-009 GM capital projections 1996-2000 (as of 1996) Exhibit 5 $ Billions 1996 1997 1998-2000 17.0 18.9 28.0 13.0 13.0 13.0 4.0 5.9 15.0 4.0 1.9 9.1 0.0 (0.5) (1.5) (0.5) (0.5) (1.5) 0.0 0.0 0.0 Cash Forecast Ending cash balance Cash reserve required 2 Ending excess cash Forecast Excess Cash Generation 1 3 Potential Uses of Excess Cash Growth/Globalization Spending Other contingencies Additional Pension Funding Adjusted Excess Cash Generation 3.5 0.9 6.1 Source: Casewriters’ estimates based on historical trends and economic and auto industry forecasts 1 2 3 Approximate year end balances in 1998 and 1999 were estimated to be $22 billion and $25 billion, respectively. $13 billion was the company’s previously-stated cash balance target, and was based on the amount of cash GM was expected to need to weather a significant downturn in automotive sales. Excess cash generation between 1998 and 2000 was estimated at approximately $3.0 billion per year. Effects of cyclical auto sales on GM's profitability and cash flow Exhibit 6 $20,000 20,000 18,000 16,000 $15,000 14,000 12,000 10,000 $ millions 8,000 6,000 $5,000 4,000 2,000 $0 Units (,000's) $10,000 0 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 -2,000 -4,000 -$5,000 -6,000 -8,000 Unit sales GM Pre-tax income -$10,000 GM Operating Cash Flow s -10,000 13 179 299-009 The General Motors Corporation (D) Results of academic studies on the stock price impact of stock repurchases by U.S. firms Exhibit 7 Sample Size Time Period Excess Return Open Market Repurchases Vermaelen 243 1970-1978 3.4% 1239 1980-1990 3.5% Comment and Jarrell 1197 1985-1988 2.3% Salomon Brothers, Inc. 1794 1991-1996 1.9% Ikenberry, Lakonishok, and Vermaelen 1 Tender Offers Vermaelen 131 1962-1977 14.1% Dann 143 1962-1976 15.4% Masulis 199 1963-1978 16.9% Fixed-price 68 1984-1989 11.0% Dutch-auction 64 1984-1989 7.9% 129 1989-1996 3.7% 77 1989-1996 6.7% Comment and Jarrell Salomon Brothers, Inc. Fixed-price Dutch-auction Source: 1 Chris Innes, Peter B. Blanton, Nomo Nomo-Ongolo, and Cindy Sieden, “Stock Buybacks – Strategy and Tactics,” Salomon Brothers, February 1997. These figures represent the market reaction over a relatively short time interval (i.e., two or three days) to announcements of repurchase programs . The authors also document an additional average 12.6% excess return over the four years following the announcement date of an open market repurchase program. 14 180 181 Source: GM documents. • Company must issue a press release announcing the size of the repurchase program but does not announce any individual repurchases • Not all shareholders have an equal chance to participate. Holders of large blocks are usually targeted • In practice virtually unlimited for liquid stocks • Daily limit: 25% of the average daily trading volume for the last four weeks plus any blocks of 5,000 shares or more • Market price at time of repurchase (unknown in advance) • Skillful broker execution could lead to average repurchase prices below market prices (as much as 5%) • Company is exposed to the risk of a rising stock price • Per share commission (roughly $0.02 - $0.04/share) Open Market Repurchase • A tender offer document must be distributed to all shareholders, and notification must be made in the press • Offer must remain open for at least 20 business days and for 10 business days if terms are modified • Generally done in conjunction with open market activities, and a company’s share repurchase announcement is sufficient disclosure • If put repurchase obligation exceeds 3% of shareholders’ equity, additional disclosure may be required • Purchaser of put warrants is a large financial institution • Purchaser of put warrants buys stock in a manner similar to open market repurchase program • If the puts are exercised, net repurchase price equals the strike price less upfront put premium • If the puts expire out of the money, net repurchase price equals the open market repurchase price less upfront put premium received • Minimal legal fees, if any • No execution costs • Company receives tax-free cash premium for selling put warrants • Fixed Price: Fixed, predetermined price at a premium to market (as high as 15%) • Dutch Auction: A set price within a specified range. Determined by bid at a premium to market (typically 5%-10%) • Broker/Dealer fees • Legal, printing, advertising, depository and information agent fees • Roughly 1.0% total • Fixed Price: Every shareholder has an equal and pro rata chance to participate • Dutch Auction: Every shareholder has an equal chance to participate • In practice, a company may have aggregate puts outstanding equal to 5-10 days of trading volume Sale of Put Options • Not limited by regulation • Typically at least 10% of outstanding shares Self-Tender (Fixed-Price/Dutch Auction) Overview of share repurchase program alternatives SEC Requirements and Disclosure Participation Costs Share Repurchase Price Size of Program Exhibit 8 299-009 • Bank’s hedging activity is generally targeted at non-block, “retail size” trades • Company may purchase additional blocks of stock through the bank during the ASR • Generally, a company’s share repurchase announcement is sufficient disclosure • If settlement amount at maturity is likely to exceed 3% of shareholders’ equity, additional disclosure may be required • Per share commission (roughly $0.02 - $0.04/share) • Final price is equal to the average market price over a fixed period of time • Company is exposed to the risk of a rising stock price • Size limited by bank’s ability to borrow shares at the commencement of an ASR Accelerated Share Repurchase 15 The General Motors Corporation (D) -15- 299-009 The General Motors Corporation (D) Historical volatility of GM common equity returns — June 1990 - December 1996 1 45% 40% 35% 30% 25% 20% 15% 10% 5% Source: Casewriter calculations based on data from Datastream 1 Based on the annualized standard deviation of daily returns over the prior 100 day period. As of December 31, 1996, GM’s prior 100 day volatility was 21.4% Exhibit 9b Implied volatility of GM common equity returns — March 1994 - December 1996 40% Annual Volatility 35% 30% 25% 20% 15% 10% 5% 11/29/96 9/30/96 7/31/96 5/31/96 3/29/96 1/31/96 11/30/95 9/29/95 7/31/95 5/31/95 3/31/95 1/31/95 11/30/94 9/30/94 7/29/94 5/31/94 3/31/94 0% Source: Compiled from Bloomberg which reports implied volatilities from call options using either the Black-Scholes or binomial model. As of December 31, 1996, implied volatility on call options was 22.6%. 16 182 12/31/96 8/13/96 3/26/96 11/7/95 6/20/95 1/31/95 9/13/94 4/26/94 12/7/93 7/20/93 3/2/93 10/13/92 5/26/92 1/7/92 8/20/91 4/2/91 11/13/90 0% 6/26/90 Annualized Standard Deviation of Daily Returns Exhibit 9a The General Motors Corporation (D) Exhibit 10 299-009 Term structure of U.S. Treasury STRIPS - December 1996 Maturity Bond Equivalent Yield 3 month 5.31% 6 month 5.36% 1 year 5.63% 2 year 5.89% 3 year 6.04% 5 year 6.18% 10 year 6.49% 20 year 6.74% 30 year 6.69% Source: Bloomberg 17 183