Financial Institutions Management A Risk Management Approach The McGraw-Hill/Irwin Series in Finance, Insurance, and Real Estate Stephen A. Ross Franco Modigliani Professor of Finance and Economics Sloan School of Management Massachusetts Institute of Technology Consulting Editor FINANCIAL MANAGEMENT Block, Hirt, and Danielsen Foundations of Financial Management Fifteenth Edition Brealey, Myers, and Allen Principles of Corporate Finance Eleventh Edition Brealey, Myers, and Allen Principles of Corporate Finance, Concise Second Edition Ross, Westerfield, and Jordan Essentials of Corporate Finance Eighth Edition Ross, Westerfield, and Jordan Fundamentals of Corporate Finance Tenth Edition Shefrin Behavioral Corporate Finance: Decisions That Create Value First Edition White Financial Analysis with an Electronic Calculator Sixth Edition INVESTMENTS Brealey, Myers, and Marcus Fundamentals of Corporate Finance Seventh Edition Bodie, Kane, and Marcus Essentials of Investments Ninth Edition Brooks FinGame Online 5.0 Bodie, Kane, and Marcus Investments Tenth Edition Bruner Case Studies in Finance: Managing for Corporate Value Creation Seventh Edition Cornett, Adair, and Nofsinger Finance: Applications and Theory Second Edition DeMello Cases in Finance Second Edition Grinblatt (editor) Stephen A. Ross, Mentor: Influence Through Generations Grinblatt and Titman Financial Markets and Corporate Strategy Second Edition Higgins Analysis for Financial Management Tenth Edition Kellison Theory of Interest Third Edition Ross, Westerfield, and Jaffe Corporate Finance Tenth Edition Ross, Westerfield, Jaffe, and Jordan Corporate Finance: Core Principles and Applications Fourth Edition Hirt and Block Fundamentals of Investment Management Tenth Edition Jordan and Miller Fundamentals of Investments: Valuation and Management Sixth Edition Stewart, Piros, and Heisler Running Money: Professional Portfolio Management First Edition Sundaram and Das Derivatives: Principles and Practice First Edition FINANCIAL INSTITUTIONS AND MARKETS Rose and Hudgins Bank Management and Financial Services Ninth Edition Rose and Marquis Financial Institutions and Markets Eleventh Edition Saunders and Cornett Financial Institutions Management: A Risk Management Approach Eighth Edition Saunders and Cornett Financial Markets and Institutions Fifth Edition INTERNATIONAL FINANCE Eun and Resnick International Financial Management Sixth Edition REAL ESTATE Brueggeman and Fisher Real Estate Finance and Investments Fourteenth Edition Ling and Archer Real Estate Principles: A Value Approach Fourth Edition FINANCIAL PLANNING AND INSURANCE Allen, Melone, Rosenbloom, and Mahoney Retirement Plans: 401(k)s, IRAs, and Other Deferred Compensation Approaches Eleventh Edition Altfest Personal Financial Planning First Edition Harrington and Niehaus Risk Management and Insurance Second Edition Kapoor, Dlabay, and Hughes Focus on Personal Finance: An Active Approach to Help You Develop Successful Financial Skills Fourth Edition Kapoor, Dlabay, and Hughes Personal Finance Tenth Edition Walker and Walker Personal Finance: Building Your Future First Edition Financial Institutions Management A Risk Management Approach Eighth Edition Anthony Saunders John M. Schiff Professor of Finance Salomon Center Stern School of Business New York University Marcia Millon Cornett Professor of Finance Bentley University FINANCIAL INSTITUTIONS MANAGEMENT: A RISK MANAGEMENT APPROACH, EIGHTH EDITION Published by McGraw-Hill Education, 2 Penn Plaza, New York, NY 10121. Copyright © 2014 by McGraw-Hill Education. All rights reserved. Printed in the United States of America. Previous editions © 2011, 2008, and 2006. No part of this publication may be reproduced or distributed in any form or by any means, or stored in a database or retrieval system, without the prior written consent of McGraw-Hill Education, including, but not limited to, in any network or other electronic storage or transmission, or broadcast for distance learning. Some ancillaries, including electronic and print components, may not be available to customers outside the United States. This book is printed on acid-free paper. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 0 QVS/QVS 1 0 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 ISBN 978-0-07-803480-0 MHID 0-07-803480-9 Senior Vice President, Products & Markets: Kurt L. Strand Vice President, Content Production & Technology Services: Kimberly Meriwether David Managing Director: Douglas Reiner Executive Brand Manager: Chuck Synovec Development Editor: Noelle Bathurst Senior Marketing Manager: Melissa Caughlin Director, Content Production: Terri Schiesl Content Project Manager: Judi David Buyer: Susan K. Culbertson Cover Image: Eyewire/Getty Images Compositor: Laserwords Private Limited Typeface: 10/12 Palatino Printer: Quad/Graphics All credits appearing on page or at the end of the book are considered to be an extension of the copyright page. Library of Congress Cataloging-in-Publication Data Saunders, Anthony, 1949Financial institutions management : a risk management approach/Anthony Saunders, John M. Schiff Professor of Finance, Salomon Center, Stern School of Business, New York University, Marcia Millon Cornett, Professor of Finance, Bentley University.—Eighth edition. pages cm ISBN 978-0-07-803480-0 (alk. paper) 1. Financial institutions—United States—Management. 2. Risk management—United States. 3. Financial services industry—United States—Management. I. Cornett, Marcia Millon. II. Title. HG181.S33 2014 332.1068—dc23 2013018782 The Internet addresses listed in the text were accurate at the time of publication. The inclusion of a website does not indicate an endorsement by the authors or McGraw-Hill Education, and McGraw-Hill Education does not guarantee the accuracy of the information presented at these sites. www.mhhe.com To all my co-authors over the years. Anthony Saunders To my parents, Tom and Sue. Marcia Millon Cornett About the Authors Anthony Saunders Anthony Saunders is the John M. Schiff Professor of Finance and the former Chair of the Department of Finance at the Stern School of Business at New York University. Professor Saunders received his PhD from the London School of Economics and has taught both undergraduate- and graduate-level courses at NYU since 1978. Throughout his academic career, his teaching and research have specialized in financial institutions and international banking. He has served as a visiting professor all over the world, including INSEAD, the Stockholm School of Economics, and the University of Melbourne. Professor Saunders has held positions on the Board of Academic Consultants of the Federal Reserve Board of Governors as well as the Council of Research Advisors for the Federal National Mortgage Association. In addition, Dr. Saunders has acted as a visiting scholar at the Comptroller of the Currency and at the Federal Reserve Banks of Philadelphia and New York. Currently, he is an academic consultant for the FDIC. He also held a visiting position in the research department of the International Monetary Fund. He is editor of Financial Markets, Instruments and Institutions. His research has been published in all the major money and banking and finance journals and in several books. In addition, he has authored or coauthored several professional books, the most recent of which is Credit Risk Measurement: New Approaches to Value at Risk and Other Paradigms, 3rd edition, John Wiley and Sons, New York, 2010. In 2008, he was ranked as the most published author in the last 50 years in the top seven journals in finance. Marcia Millon Cornett Marcia Millon Cornett is a Professor of Finance at Bentley University. She received her BS degree in Economics from Knox College in Galesburg, Illinois, and her MBA and PhD degrees in Finance from Indiana University in Bloomington, Indiana. Dr. Cornett has written and published several articles in the areas of bank performance, bank regulation, and corporate finance. Articles authored by Dr. Cornett have appeared in such academic journals as the Journal of Finance, the Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, the Journal of Financial Economics, Financial Management, and the Journal of Banking and Finance. In 2008, she was ranked as the 124th most published author in the last 50 years in the top seven journals in finance. Dr. Cornett served as an Associate Editor of Financial Management and is currently an Associate Editor for the Journal of Banking and Finance, Journal of Financial Services Research, FMA Online, the Multinational Finance Journal, and the Review of Financial Economics. She has served as a member of the Board of Directors, the Executive Committee, and the Finance Committee of the SIU Credit Union. Dr. Cornett has also taught at the University of Colorado, Boston College, Southern Methodist University, and Southern Illinois University at Carbondale. She is a member of the Financial Management Association, the American Finance Association, and the Western Finance Association. vi Preface The last 25 years have been dramatic for the financial services industry. In the 1990s and 2000s boundaries between the traditional industry sectors, such as commercial banking and investment banking, broke down, and competition became increasingly global in nature. Many forces contributed to this breakdown in interindustry and intercountry barriers, including financial innovation, technology, taxation, and regulation. Then in 2008–09, the financial services industry experienced the worst financial crisis since the Great Depression. Even into the mid-2010s, the U.S. and world economies have not recovered from this crisis. It is in this context that this book is written. Although the traditional nature of each sector’s product activity is analyzed, a greater emphasis is placed on new areas of activities such as asset securitization, off-balance-sheet banking, international banking, and on changes occurring as a result of the financial crisis. When the first edition of this text was released in 1994, it was the first to analyze modern financial institutions management from a risk perspective. Thus, the title, Financial Institutions Management: A Modern Perspective. At that time, traditional texts presented an overview of the industry sector by sector, concentrating on balance sheet presentations and overlooking management decision making and risk management. Over the last 20 years other texts have followed this change, such that a risk management approach to analyzing modern financial institutions is now well accepted. Thus, the title: Financial Institutions Management: A Risk Management Approach. The eighth edition of this text takes the same innovative approach taken in the first seven editions and focuses on managing return and risk in modern financial institutions (FIs). Financial Institutions Management’s central theme is that the risks faced by FI managers and the methods and markets through which these risks are managed are similar whether an institution is chartered as a commercial bank, a savings bank, an investment bank, or an insurance company. As in any stockholder-owned corporation, the goal of FI managers should always be to maximize the value of the financial institution. However, pursuit of value maximization does not mean that risk management can be ignored. Indeed, modern FIs are in the risk management business. As we discuss in this book, in a world of perfect and frictionless capital markets, FIs would not exist and individuals would manage their own financial assets and portfolios. But since real-world financial markets are not perfect, FIs provide the positive function of bearing and managing risk on behalf of their customers through the pooling of risks and the sale of their services as risk specialists. INTENDED AUDIENCE Financial Institutions Management: A Risk Management Approach is aimed at upperlevel undergraduate and MBA audiences. Occasionally there are more technical sections. These sections may be included or dropped from the chapter reading, depending on the rigor of the course, without harming the continuity of the chapters. vii viii Preface MAIN FEATURES Throughout the text, special features have been integrated to encourage student interaction with the text and to aid in absorbing the material. Some of these features include: • In-chapter Internet Exercises and references, which detail instructions for accessing important recent financial data online. • International material highlights, which call out material relating to global issues. • In-chapter Examples, which provide numerical demonstrations of the analytics described in various chapters. • Bold key terms and marginal glossary, which highlight and define the main terms and concepts throughout the chapter. • In-chapter Concept Questions, which allow students to test themselves on the main concepts within each major chapter section. • Notable Events from the Financial Crisis, Industry Perspectives, and After the Crisis boxes, which demonstrate the application of chapter material to real current events. ORGANIZATION Since our focus is on return and risk and the sources of that return and risk, this book relates ways in which the managers of modern FIs can expand return with a managed level of risk to achieve the best, or most favorable, return-risk outcome for FI owners. Chapter 1 introduces the special functions of FIs and takes an analytical look at how financial intermediation benefits today’s economy. Chapters 2 through 6 provide an overview describing the key balance sheet and regulatory features of the major sectors of the U.S. financial services industry. We discuss depository institutions in Chapter 2, finance companies in Chapter 3, securities firms and investment banks in Chapter 4, mutual funds and hedge funds in Chapter 5, and insurance institutions in Chapter 6. In Chapter 7 we preview the risk measurement and management sections with an overview of the risks facing a modern FI. We divide the chapters on risk measurement and management into two sections: measuring risk and managing risk. In Chapters 8 and 9, we start the risk measurement section by investigating the net interest margin as a source of profitability and risk, with a focus on the effects of interest rate volatility and the mismatching of asset and liability durations on FI risk exposure. In Chapter 10, we look at the measurement of credit risk on individual loans and bonds and how this risk adversely affects an FI’s profits through losses and provisions against the loan and debt security portfolio. In Chapter 11, we look at the risk of loan (asset) portfolios and the effects of loan concentrations on risk exposure. In addition, as a by-product of the provision of their interest rate and credit intermediation services, FIs face liquidity risk. We analyze the special nature of this risk in Chapter 12. Modern FIs do more than domestic maturity mismatching and credit extensions. They also are increasingly engaging in foreign exchange activities and overseas financial investments (Chapter 13) and engaging in sovereign lending and securities activities (Chapter 14). In Chapter 15, we analyze market risk, a Preface ix risk incurred by FIs in trading assets and liabilities due to changes in interest rates, exchange rates, and other asset prices. In addition, modern FIs do more than generate returns and bear risk through traditional maturity mismatching and credit extensions. They also are increasingly engaging in off-balance-sheet activities to generate fee income (Chapter 16) and making technological investments to reduce costs (Chapter 17). Each of these has implications for the size and variability of an FI’s profits and/or revenues. In Chapter 18 we begin the risk management section by looking at ways in which FIs can insulate themselves from liquidity risk. In Chapter 19 we look at the key role deposit insurance and other guaranty schemes play in reducing liquidity risk. At the core of FI risk insulation is the size and adequacy of the owners’ capital or equity investment in the FI, which is the focus of Chapter 20. Chapter 21 analyzes how and why product and geographic diversification—both domestic and international—can improve an FI’s return-risk performance and the impact of regulation on the diversification opportunity set. Chapters 22 through 26 review various new markets and instruments that have been innovated or engineered to allow FIs to better manage three important types of risk: interest rate risk, credit risk, and foreign exchange risk. These markets and instruments and their strategic use by FIs include futures and forwards (Chapter 22); options, caps, floors, and collars (Chapter 23); swaps (Chapter 24); loan sales (Chapter 25); and securitization (Chapter 26). CHANGES IN THIS EDITION Each chapter in this edition has been revised thoroughly to reflect the most upto-date information available. End-of-chapter questions and problem material have also been expanded and updated to provide a complete selection of testing material. The following are some of the new features of this revision: • Tables and figures in all chapters have been revised to include the most recently available data. • New boxes highlighting significant events occurring “After the Crisis” have been added to chapters throughout the book. • Integrated Minicases have been added to Chapters 9, 13, 16, and 24. • Updates on the major changes proposed for the regulation of financial institutions are included where appropriate throughout the book. • Discussion of how financial institutions continue to recover from the financial crisis has been added throughout the book. Virtually every chapter includes new material detailing how the financial crisis has affected risk management in financial institutions. • Chapters 2, 7, and 14 include discussions of the European debt crisis as it affects the risk and return of financial institutions. • Chapter 2 includes a discussion of Bank Transfer Day, as well as a summary of the new stress tests imposed on large depository institutions. • A section on venture capital services has been added to Chapter 5. Also, the chapter includes a discussion of the LIBOR scandal that broke in late 2012. • Chapter 5 includes a new section on index funds and expanded discussion of ETFs. Further, the chapter includes an update on the regulation of hedge funds. x Preface • An actual interest rate sensitivity report for a depository institution has been added to Chapter 8, and actual duration gap numbers for several banks have been added to Chapter 9. • Detailed discussion and examples of the new international liquidity standards enacted as a result of the financial crisis have been added to Chapter 12. • Chapter 13 includes a discussion of the pegging of the Swiss franc to the euro in September 2011. • Chapter 14 now includes a discussion of the Euromoney Credit Risk measure. This credit risk measure is then used in Chapter 20 as it applies to the new capital standards being phased in at depository institutions. • Chapter 15 includes a discussion and examples of the newest market risk measures enacted as a result of the financial crisis. The chapter also discusses the changes made to market risk measures as a result of Basel 2.5 and Basel III. • Chapter 16 includes a discussion of the losses incurred by J.P. Morgan Chase from derivative trading by the “London Whale.” • Chapter 17 includes a new section on advanced technologies in banking and additional discussion of several recent technology related losses incurred by FIs. • Chapter 18 includes extensive discussion and examples of the new insurance premium system used by depository institutions. • Chapter 20 includes a discussion of Basel III capital adequacy rules. The major changes are described in detail. Many in-chapter and EOC problems have been added to the chapter to illustrate the many and complex changes to capital adequacy calculations. • Chapter 21 includes a new section on shadow banks. The chapter also provides an update on implementation of the Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act enacted as a result of the financial crisis. • Chapter 26 includes a new section on synthetic CDOs. We have retained and updated these features: • The risk approach of Financial Institutions Management has been retained, keeping the first section of the text as an introduction and the last two sections as a risk measurement and risk management summary, respectively. • We again present a detailed look at what is new in each of the different sectors of the financial institutions industry in the first six chapters of the text. We have highlighted the continued international coverage with a global issues icon throughout the text. • Chapter 17 includes material on electronic technology and the Internet’s impact on financial services. Technological changes occurring over the last two decades have changed the way financial institutions offer services to customers, both domestically and overseas. The effect of technology is also referenced in other chapters where relevant. • Coverage of credit risk models (including newer models, such as Moody’s Analytics, CreditMetrics, and CreditRisk) remains in the text. • Coverage in the “Product and Geographic Expansion” chapter explores the increased inroads of banks into the insurance field, the move toward nationwide banking (in the United States), and the rapid growth of foreign banks and other intermediaries in the United States. Preface xi • Numerous highlighted in-chapter Examples remain in the chapters. • Internet references remain throughout each chapter and Internet questions are found after the end-of-chapter questions. • An extensive problem set, including web exercises, can be found at the end of each chapter that allows students to practice a variety of skills using the same data or set of circumstances. ANCILLARIES All supplemental materials for both students and instructors can be found on the McGraw-Hill website for the eighth edition of Financial Institutions Management at www.mhhe.com/saunders8e. Instructor materials are password-protected for your security. Print versions are available by request only—if interested, please contact your McGraw-Hill/Irwin representative. The following supplements are available for the eighth edition. For Students • Multiple-Choice Quizzes for each chapter consist of 10 multiple-choice questions that reflect key concepts from the text. These quizzes have instant grading. • Appendices consist of material that has been removed from previous editions of the print textbook to allow room for new topics. For Instructors • The Test Bank, created by Thomas Secrest of Coastal Carolina University, offers multiple-choice and true/false questions that are designed to apply specifically to this text and this edition’s revisions. The Test Bank is available in Word document format and EZ Test online. • The Instructor’s Manual, created by author Marcia Millon Cornett, contains answers to the text’s Questions and Problems at the end of each chapter and chapter outlines. • The PowerPoint Presentations summarize the main points of each chapter in a step-by-step fashion. These slideshows can be edited by instructors to customize presentations. • The Digital Image Library contains electronic versions of all figures and tables from the seventh edition of the text. CourseSmart is a new way for faculty to find and review eTextbooks. It’s also a great option for students who are interested in accessing their course materials digitally. CourseSmart offers thousands of the most commonly adopted textbooks across hundreds of courses from a wide variety of higher education publishers. It is the only place for faculty to review and compare the full text of a textbook online. At CourseSmart, students can save up to 50 percent off the cost of a print book, reduce their impact on the environment, and gain access to powerful web tools for learning including full text search, notes and highlighting, and email tools for sharing notes between classmates. Your eBook also includes tech support in case you ever need help. Finding your eBook is easy. Visit www.CourseSmart.com and search by title, author, or ISBN. Acknowledgments Finally, we would like to thank the numerous colleagues who assisted with the previous editions of this book. Of great help were the book reviewers whose painstaking comments and advice guided the text through its seven revisions. Jack Aber Boston University Brian J. Adams University of Portland Michael H. Anderson Suffolk University Mounther Barakat University of Houston–Clear Lake Sreedhar Bharath University of Michigan Rita Biswas SUNY–Albany M. E. Bond University of Memphis Qiang Bu Pennsylvania State–Harrisburg Yea-Mow Chen San Francisco State University Jeffrey A. Clark Florida State University Robert A. Clark Butler University S. Steven Cole University of North Texas Douglas Cook University of Mississippi Kenneth Daniels Virginia Commonwealth University Paul Ellinger University of Illinois David Ely San Diego State University Joseph Finnerty University of Illinios Jack Clark Francis Baruch College–CUNY James H. Gilkeson University of Central Florida xii Anurag Gupta Case Western Reserve University John H. Hand Auburn University Yan He San Francisco State University Alan C. Hess University of Washington–Seattle Ray Jackson University of Massachusetts–Dartmouth Kevin Jacques Georgetown University and Office of the Comptroller of the Currency Julapa Jagtiani Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Craig G. Johnson California State University–Hayward Nelson J. Lacey University of Massachusetts at Amherst Robert Lamy Wake Forest University Rick LeCompte Wichita State University Barry Marchman Georgia Institute of Technology Patricia C. Matthews Mount Union College Robert McLeod University of Alabama Jamie McNutt Rutgers–Camden Ardavan Mobasheri Bernard M. Baruch College–CUNY Richard Patterson Indiana University Roberto Perli University of Maryland Acknowledgments Rose M. Prasad Central Michigan University Andreas Rauterkus University of Alabama–Birmingham Kenneth Rhoda LaSalle University Tara Rice Boston College Don Sabbarese Kennesaw State University Daniel Singer Towson University Richard Stolz California State University–Fullerton xiii Michael Toyne Northeastern State University Haluk Unal University of Maryland James A. Verbrugge University of Georgia Hsinrong Wei Baruch College–CUNY Sonya Williams-Stanton University of Michigan–Ann Arbor Robert Wolf University of Wisconsin–La Crosse In addition, we gratefully acknowledge the contributions of the reviewers of the seventh edition: Ethan Cohen-Cole University of Maryland–College Park James Conover University of North Texas Elyas Elyasiani Temple University–Philadelphia Margaret Forster University of Notre Dame Deniz Kebabci Tudor San Francisco State University Elinda Kiss University of Maryland–College Park Richard Patterson Indiana University–Bloomington Joe Peek University of Kentucky–Lexington Marcelo Pinheiro George Mason University Alexander Wilson University of Arizona Shaorong Zhang Marshall University Lina Zhou Augustana College We very much appreciate the contributions of the book team at McGraw-Hill Education: Chuck Synovec, Executive Brand Manager; Noelle Bathurst, Development Editor; Melissa Caughlin, Senior Marketing Manager; and Judi David, Content Project Manager. We are also grateful to our secretaries and assistants, Robyn Vanterpool, Ingrid Persaud, Anand Srinivasan, Brenda Webb, and Sharon Moore. Anthony Saunders Marcia Millon Cornett Brief Contents PART ONE 13 Foreign Exchange Risk Introduction 1 14 Sovereign Risk 1 Why Are Financial Institutions Special? 2 2 Financial Services: Depository Institutions 25 3 Financial Services: Finance Companies 68 4 Financial Services: Securities Brokerage and Investment Banking 84 5 Financial Services: Mutual Funds and Hedge Funds 111 6 Financial Services: Insurance 148 7 Risks of Financial Institutions 173 PART TWO Measuring Risk 9 Interest Rate Risk II 196 226 10 Credit Risk: Individual Loan Risk 274 11 Credit Risk: Loan Portfolio and Concentration Risk 326 12 Liquidity Risk xiv 351 412 438 16 Off-Balance-Sheet Risk 474 17 Technology and Other Operational Risks 503 PART THREE Managing Risk 537 18 Liability and Liquidity Management 538 19 Deposit Insurance and Other Liability Guarantees 568 20 Capital Adequacy 605 21 Product and Geographic Expansion 651 22 Futures and Forwards 195 8 Interest Rate Risk I 15 Market Risk 383 23 Options, Caps, Floors, and Collars 728 24 Swaps 766 25 Loan Sales 796 26 Securitization 812 Index 856 691 Contents PART ONE Other Fee-Generating Activities Regulation 39 Industry Performance 44 INTRODUCTION 1 Savings Institutions Chapter One Why Are Financial Institutions Special? 2 Introduction 2 Financial Institutions’ Specialness FIs Function as Brokers 5 FIs Function as Asset Transformers Information Costs 6 Liquidity and Price Risk 7 Other Special Services 8 Other Aspects of Specialness Credit Unions 4 10 15 15 Appendix 1A The Financial Crisis: The Failure of Financial Services Institution Specialness (www.mhhe.com/saunders8e) Appendix 1B Monetary Policy Tools (www.mhhe.com/saunders8e) 27 Size, Structure, and Composition of the Industry Balance Sheet and Recent Trends 32 Chapter Three Financial Services: Finance Companies 68 Introduction 68 Size, Structure, and Composition of the Industry 68 Balance Sheet and Recent Trends 72 Assets 72 Liabilities and Equity Industry Performance Regulation 80 Global Issues 82 Chapter Two Financial Services: Depository Institutions 25 Introduction 25 Commercial Banks 55 Global Issues: The Financial Crisis 60 Appendix 2A Financial Statement Analysis Using a Return on Equity (ROE) Framework (www.mhhe.com/saunders8e) Appendix 2B Commercial Banks’ Financial Statements and Analysis (www.mhhe.com/saunders8e) Appendix 2C Depository Institutions and Their Regulators (www.mhhe.com/saunders8e) Appendix 2D Technology in Commercial Banking (www.mhhe.com/saunders8e) 8 Safety and Soundness Regulation 11 Monetary Policy Regulation 13 Credit Allocation Regulation 13 Consumer Protection Regulation 13 Investor Protection Regulation 14 Entry Regulation 14 Trends in the United States Global Trends 20 48 55 Size, Structure, and Composition of the Industry Balance Sheet and Recent Trends 57 Regulation 59 Industry Performance 59 5 The Changing Dynamics of Specialness 48 Size, Structure, and Composition of the Industry Balance Sheet and Recent Trends 50 Regulation 52 Industry Performance 52 The Transmission of Monetary Policy 8 Credit Allocation 9 Intergenerational Wealth Transfers or Time Intermediation 9 Payment Services 9 Denomination Intermediation 10 Specialness and Regulation 38 28 77 78 Chapter Four Financial Services: Securities Brokerage and Investment Banking 84 Introduction 84 xv xvi Contents Size, Structure, and Composition of the Industry 86 Balance Sheet and Recent Trends 96 Liquidity Risk 178 Foreign Exchange Risk 180 Country or Sovereign Risk 182 Market Risk 183 Off-Balance-Sheet Risk 185 Technology and Operational Risks 186 Insolvency Risk 188 Other Risks and the Interaction of Risks 189 Recent Trends 96 Balance Sheet 99 Regulation 101 Global Issues 104 Chapter Five Financial Services: Mutual Funds and Hedge Funds 111 PART TWO MEASURING RISK Introduction 111 Size, Structure, and Composition of the Mutual Fund Industry 112 Historical Trends 112 Different Types of Mutual Funds 115 Mutual Fund Objectives 119 Investor Returns from Mutual Fund Ownership Mutual Fund Costs 125 122 Balance Sheet and Recent Trends for the Mutual Fund Industry 128 Money Market Funds 128 Long-Term Funds 130 134 Types of Hedge Funds 138 Fees on Hedge Funds 142 Offshore Hedge Funds 143 Regulation of Hedge Funds 143 Chapter Six Financial Services: Insurance 148 Size, Structure, and Composition of the Industry Balance Sheet and Recent Trends 153 Regulation 156 Rate-Sensitive Assets 201 Rate-Sensitive Liabilities 202 Equal Changes in Rates on RSAs and RSLs 204 Unequal Changes in Rates on RSAs and RSLs 205 168 Chapter Seven Risks of Financial Institutions Market Value Effects 208 Overaggregation 209 The Problem of Runoffs 209 Cash Flows from Off-Balance-Sheet Activities 173 210 219 Chapter Nine Interest Rate Risk II 226 149 157 Size, Structure, and Composition of the Industry Balance Sheet and Recent Trends 159 Regulation 168 Introduction 173 Interest Rate Risk 174 Credit Risk 176 Introduction 196 The Level and Movement of Interest Rates 197 The Repricing Model 199 Appendix 8A The Maturity Model (www.mhhe.com/saunders8e) Appendix 8B Term Structure of Interest Rates Introduction 148 Life Insurance 149 Global Issues 196 Weaknesses of the Repricing Model 208 Regulation of Mutual Funds 131 Global Issues in the Mutual Fund Industry Hedge Funds 136 Property–Casualty Insurance Chapter Eight Interest Rate Risk I 195 157 Introduction 226 Duration: A Simple Introduction 227 A General Formula for Duration 229 The Duration of Interest-Bearing Bonds 231 The Duration of Zero-Coupon Bonds 233 The Duration of Consol Bonds (Perpetuities) 233 Features of Duration 234 Duration and Maturity 234 Duration and Yield 235 Duration and Coupon Interest 235 The Economic Meaning of Duration Semiannual Coupon Bonds 236 240 Duration and Interest Rate Risk 241 Duration and Interest Rate Risk Management on a Single Security 241 Contents xvii Duration and Interest Rate Risk Management on the Whole Balance Sheet of an FI 244 Loan Portfolio Diversification and Modern Portfolio Theory (MPT) 328 Immunization and Regulatory Considerations 251 Difficulties in Applying the Duration Model 252 Duration Matching Can Be Costly 252 Immunization Is a Dynamic Problem 252 Large Interest Rate Changes and Convexity Moody’s Analytics Portfolio Manager Model 331 Partial Applications of Portfolio Theory 335 Regulatory Models 339 Appendix 11A CreditMetrics 345 Appendix 11B CreditRisk 348 253 Appendix 9A The Basics of Bond Valuation (www.mhhe.com/saunders8e) Appendix 9B Incorporating Convexity into the Duration Model 264 Chapter Ten Credit Risk: Individual Loan Risk Introduction 274 Credit Quality Problems Types of Loans 278 Chapter Twelve Liquidity Risk 351 Introduction 351 Causes of Liquidity Risk 352 Liquidity Risk at Depository Institutions 274 276 Commercial and Industrial Loans 278 Real Estate Loans 280 Individual (Consumer) Loans 282 Other Loans 284 Calculating the Return on a Loan 284 The Contractually Promised Return on a Loan The Expected Return on a Loan 288 Retail versus Wholesale Credit Decisions 284 289 Retail 289 Wholesale 289 Measurement of Credit Risk Default Risk Models 292 291 Qualitative Models 292 Quantitative Models 294 Newer Models of Credit Risk Measurement and Pricing 298 Liquidity Risk and Life Insurance Companies 370 Liquidity Risk and Property–Casualty Insurers 370 Investment Funds 371 Appendix 12A Sources and Uses of Funds Statement, Bank of America, March 2012 (www.mhhe.com/saunders8e) Appendix 12B Illustrative Template for the LCR 380 Chapter Thirteen Foreign Exchange Risk 383 Appendix 10A Credit Analysis (www.mhhe.com/saunders8e) Appendix 10B Black–Scholes Option Pricing Model (www.mhhe.com/saunders8e) Introduction 383 Foreign Exchange Rates and Transactions Foreign Exchange Rates 383 Foreign Exchange Transactions 383 384 Sources of Foreign Exchange Risk Exposure 387 Foreign Exchange Rate Volatility and FX Exposure 389 Foreign Currency Trading 390 Chapter Eleven Credit Risk: Loan Portfolio and Concentration Risk 326 Introduction 326 Simple Models of Loan Concentration Risk 352 Liability-Side Liquidity Risk 352 Asset-Side Liquidity Risk 356 Measuring a DI’s Liquidity Risk Exposure 358 New Liquidity Risk Measures Implemented by the Bank for International Settlements 361 Liquidity Risk, Unexpected Deposit Drains, and Bank Runs 368 Bank Runs, the Discount Window, and Deposit Insurance 369 FX Trading Activities 391 Foreign Asset and Liability Positions 392 326 The Return and Risk of Foreign Investments 393 Risk and Hedging 395 Multicurrency Foreign Asset–Liability Positions 399 xviii Contents Interaction of Interest Rates, Inflation, and Exchange Rates 400 Returns and Risks of Off-Balance-Sheet Activities 479 Purchasing Power Parity 401 Interest Rate Parity Theorem 402 Loan Commitments 481 Commercial Letters of Credit and Standby Letters of Credit 485 Derivative Contracts: Futures, Forwards, Swaps, and Options 488 Forward Purchases and Sales of When-Issued Securities 491 Loans Sold 492 Chapter Fourteen Sovereign Risk 412 Introduction 412 Credit Risk versus Sovereign Risk Debt Repudiation versus Debt Rescheduling 416 Country Risk Evaluation 418 416 Non–Schedule L Off-Balance-Sheet Risks Outside Evaluation Models 418 Internal Evaluation Models 420 Using Market Data to Measure Risk: The Secondary Market for LDC and Emerging Market Debt 429 Appendix 14A Mechanisms for Dealing with Sovereign Risk Exposure (www.mhhe.com/saunders8e) Chapter Fifteen Market Risk 438 Introduction 438 Calculating Market Risk Exposure The Risk Metrics Model 441 The Role of OBS Activities in Reducing Risk 495 Appendix 16A A Letter of Credit Transaction (www.mhhe.com/saunders8e) Chapter Seventeen Technology and Other Operational Risks 503 Introduction 503 What are the Sources of Operational Risk? 505 Technological Innovation and Profitability 505 The Impact of Technology on Wholesale and Retail Financial Service Production 508 440 The Market Risk of Fixed-Income Securities Foreign Exchange 445 Equities 446 Portfolio Aggregation 447 442 Historic (Back Simulation) Approach 450 The Historic (Back Simulation) Model versus RiskMetrics 453 The Monte Carlo Simulation Approach 454 Expected Shortfall 458 Regulatory Models: The BIS Standardized Framework 461 Partial Risk Factor Approach 461 Fuller Risk Factor Approach 462 The BIS Regulations and Large-Bank Internal Models 465 Chapter Sixteen Off-Balance-Sheet Risk 493 Settlement Risk 493 Affiliate Risk 494 Wholesale Financial Services 508 Retail Financial Services 509 Advanced Technology Requirements 511 The Effect of Technology on Revenues and Costs 512 Technology and Revenues 514 Technology and Costs 515 Testing for Economies of Scale and Economies of Scope 519 The Production Approach 519 The Intermediation Approach 519 Empirical Findings on Cost Economies of Scale and Scope and Implications for Technology Expenditures 520 Economies of Scale and Scope and X-Inefficiencies 520 Technology and the Evolution of the Payments System 522 474 Introduction 474 Off-Balance-Sheet Activities and FI Solvency 475 Risks That Arise in an Electronic Transfer Payment System 524 Other Operational Risks 529 Regulatory Issues and Technology and Operational Risks 531 Contents PART THREE MANAGING RISK The Causes of the Depository Fund Insolvencies 572 537 Chapter Eighteen Liability and Liquidity Management Introduction 538 Liquid Asset Management The Financial Environment Moral Hazard 573 538 538 Monetary Policy Implementation Reasons 539 Taxation Reasons 539 The Composition of the Liquid Asset Portfolio 540 Return-Risk Trade-Off for Liquid Assets 541 The Liquid Asset Reserve Management Problem for U.S. Depository Institutions 541 Undershooting/Overshooting of the Reserve Target 545 Managing Liquid Assets Other than Cash 549 Liability Management Funding Risk and Cost 550 551 Choice of Liability Structure xix 552 Demand Deposits 552 Interest-Bearing Checking (NOW) Accounts 553 Passbook Savings 554 Money Market Deposit Accounts (MMDAs) 554 Retail Time Deposits and CDs 555 Wholesale CDs 556 Federal Funds 557 Repurchase Agreements (RPs) 558 Other Borrowings 558 Liquidity and Liability Structures for U.S. Depository Institutions 560 Liability and Liquidity Risk Management in Insurance Companies 562 Liability and Liquidity Risk Management in Other Financial Institutions 562 Appendix 18A Federal Reserve Requirement Accounting (www.mhhe.com/saunders8e) Appendix 18B Bankers’ Acceptances and Commercial Paper as Sources of Financing (www.mhhe.com/saunders8e) Chapter Nineteen Deposit Insurance and Other Liability Guarantees 568 Introduction 568 Bank and Thrift Guaranty Funds 572 Panic Prevention versus Moral Hazard 574 Controlling Depository Institution Risk Taking 575 Stockholder Discipline 575 Depositor Discipline 580 Regulatory Discipline 585 Non-U.S. Deposit Insurance Systems The Discount Window 587 586 Deposit Insurance versus the Discount Window The Discount Window 587 Other Guaranty Programs 590 National Credit Union Administration 590 Property–Casualty and Life Insurance Companies 590 The Securities Investor Protection Corporation 591 The Pension Benefit Guaranty Corporation 593 Appendix 19A Calculation of Deposit Insurance Premiums 600 Appendix 19B FDIC Press Release of Bank Failures (www.mhhe.com/saunders8e) Appendix 19C Deposit Insurance Coverage for Commercial Banks in Various Countries (www.mhhe.com/saunders8e) Chapter Twenty Capital Adequacy 605 Introduction 605 Capital and Insolvency Risk 606 Capital 606 The Market Value of Capital 607 The Book Value of Capital 608 The Discrepancy between the Market and Book Values of Equity 609 Arguments against Market Value Accounting 609 Capital Adequacy in the Commercial Banking and Thrift Industry 611 Capital 617 Credit Risk–Adjusted Assets 618 Calculating Risk-Based Capital Ratios 618 Capital Requirements for Other Financial Institutions 636 569 587 Securities Firms 636 Life Insurance 636 Property–Casualty Insurance 638 xx Contents Appendix 20A Internal Ratings-Based Approach to Measuring Credit Risk-Adjusted Assets 648 Appendix 20B Methodology Used to Determine G-SIBs’ Capital Surcharge (www.mhhe.com/saunders8e) Chapter Twenty-One Product and Geographic Expansion 651 Introduction 651 Product Diversification 652 Segmentation in the U.S. Financial Services Industry 653 Commercial and Investment Banking Activities 653 Banking and Insurance 656 Commercial Banking and Commerce 657 Nonbank Financial Service Firms and Banking 658 Nonbank Financial Service Firms and Commerce 660 Activity Restrictions in the United States versus Other Countries 660 Issues Involved in the Diversification of Product Offerings 661 Safety and Soundness Concerns 661 Economies of Scale and Scope 663 Conflicts of Interest 664 Deposit Insurance 665 Regulatory Oversight 666 Competition 666 Cost and Revenue Synergies Affecting Domestic Geographic Expansion by Merger and Acquisition 672 674 Other Market- and Firm-Specific Factors Affecting Domestic Geographic Expansion Decisions 677 Global and International Expansions 678 682 Advantages and Disadvantages of International Expansion 684 Advantages 684 Disadvantages 685 691 Introduction 691 Forward and Futures Contracts 693 Spot Contracts 693 Forward Contracts 693 Futures Contracts 694 Forward Contracts and Hedging Interest Rate Risk 695 Hedging Interest Rate Risk with Futures Contracts 697 Microhedging 697 Macrohedging 697 Routine Hedging versus Selective Hedging Macrohedging with Futures 698 The Problem of Basis Risk 706 Hedging Foreign Exchange Risk 698 708 712 Hedging Credit Risk with Futures and Forwards 715 Insurance Companies 669 Thrifts 669 Commercial Banks 669 U.S. Banks Abroad 679 Foreign Banks in the United States Chapter Twenty-Two Futures and Forwards Forwards 708 Futures 708 Estimating the Hedge Ratio Domestic Geographic Expansion 668 Regulatory Factors Affecting Geographic Expansion 669 Cost Synergies 673 Revenue Synergies 674 Merger Guidelines for Acceptability Appendix 21A EU and G-10 Countries: Regulatory Treatment of the Mixing of Banking, Securities, and Insurance Activities and the Mixing of Banking and Commerce (www.mhhe.com/saunders8e) Credit Forward Contracts and Credit Risk Hedging 716 Futures Contracts and Catastrophe Risk 718 Regulation of Derivative Securities Appendix 22A Microhedging with Futures (www.mhhe.com/saunders8e) 718 Chapter Twenty-Three Options, Caps, Floors, and Collars Introduction 728 Basic Features of Options 728 728 Buying a Call Option on a Bond 729 Writing a Call Option on a Bond 730 Buying a Put Option on a Bond 731 Writing a Put Option on a Bond 731 Writing versus Buying Options 732 Economic Reasons for Not Writing Options Regulatory Reasons 734 Futures versus Options Hedging 734 732 Contents Trends in Loan Sales 800 The Buyers and the Sellers 801 The Mechanics of Hedging a Bond or Bond Portfolio 735 Why Banks and Other FIs Sell Loans Hedging with Bond Options Using the Binomial Model 736 Reserve Requirements Fee Income 807 Capital Costs 807 Liquidity Risk 807 Actual Bond Options 740 Using Options to Hedge Interest Rate Risk on the Balance Sheet 742 Using Options to Hedge Foreign Exchange Risk 747 Hedging Credit Risk with Options 748 Hedging Catastrophe Risk with Call Spread Options 749 Caps, Floors, and Collars 750 Caps 751 Floors 754 Collars 755 Caps, Floors, Collars, and Credit Risk xxi 806 806 Factors Affecting Loan Sales Growth 807 Access to the Commercial Paper Market 807 Customer Relationship Effects 808 Legal Concerns 808 BIS Capital Requirements 808 Market Value Accounting 808 Asset Brokerage and Loan Trading 809 Government Loan Sales 809 Credit Ratings 809 Purchase and Sale of Foreign Bank Loans 809 758 Appendix 23A Microhedging with Options (www.mhhe.com/saunders8e) Chapter Twenty-Six Securitization 812 Chapter Twenty-Four Swaps 766 Introduction 812 Mechanisms Used to Convert On-Balance-Sheet Assets to a Securitized Asset 813 The Pass-Through Security 816 Introduction 766 Swap Markets 767 Interest Rate Swaps 768 Realized Cash Flows on an Interest Rate Swap Macrohedging with Swaps 773 Currency Swaps 772 776 Fixed-Fixed Currency Swaps 776 Fixed-Floating Currency Swaps 778 Credit Swaps 779 Total Return Swaps 781 Pure Credit Swaps 783 CDS Indexes 783 The Collateralized Mortgage Obligation (CMO) 838 Swaps and Credit Risk Concerns 784 Netting and Swaps 786 Payment Flows Are Interest and Not Principal Standby Letters of Credit 786 Appendix 24A Setting Rates on an Interest Rate Swap Chapter Twenty-Five Loan Sales 796 Introduction 796 The Bank Loan Sales Market GNMA 817 FNMA 817 FHLMC 818 The Incentives and Mechanics of Pass-Through Security Creation 818 Prepayment Risk on Pass-Through Securities 824 Prepayment Models 828 Government Sponsorship and Oversight of FNMA and Freddie Mac 836 797 Definition of a Loan Sale 797 Types of Loan Sales 797 Types of Loan Sales Contracts 799 786 792 Creation of CMOs 839 Class A, B, and C Bond Buyers Other CMO Classes 841 841 The Mortgage-Backed Bond (MBB) or Covered Bond 842 Innovations in Securitization 844 Mortgage Pass-Through Strips 844 Securitization of Other Assets 847 Can All Assets Be Securitized? 848 Appendix 26A Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac Balance Sheets (www.mhhe.com/saunders8e) INDEX 856 This page intentionally left blank Part One Introduction 1. Why Are Financial Institutions Special? 2 2. Financial Services: Depository Institutions 28 3. Financial Services: Finance Companies 68 4. Financial Services: Securities Brokerage and Investment Banking 84 5. Financial Services: Mutual Funds and Hedge Funds 111 6. Financial Services: Insurance 148 7. Risks of Financial Institutions 173 Chapter One See Appendices Online at www.mhhe.com/saunders8e • Appendix 1A: The Financial Crisis: The Failure of Financial Institution Specialness • Appendix 1B: Monetary Policy Tools Why Are Financial Institutions Special? INTRODUCTION Over the last 90 years, the financial services industry has come full cycle. Originally, the banking industry operated as a full-service industry, performing directly or indirectly all financial services (commercial banking, investment banking, stock investing services, insurance providers, etc.). In the early 1930s, the economic and industrial collapse resulted in the separation of some of these activities. In the 1970s and 1980s, new, relatively unregulated financial services industries sprang up (mutual funds, brokerage funds, etc.) that separated financial services functions even further. As we entered the 21st century, regulatory barriers, technology, and financial innovation changes were such that a full set of financial services could again be offered by a single financial services firm under the umbrella of a financial services holding company. For example, J.P. Morgan Chase operates a commercial bank, J.P. Morgan Chase Bank, an investment bank, J.P. Morgan Securities (which also sells mutual funds), and an insurance company, J.P. Morgan Insurance Agency. During the financial crisis, this financial services holding company purchased a savings institution, Washington Mutual, and several investment banks, including Bear Stearns. Not only did the boundaries between traditional industry sectors change, but competition became global in nature as well. For example, J.P. Morgan Chase is the world’s eighth largest financial services holding company, operating in 60 countries. Then came the late 2000s when the United States and indeed the world experienced a collapse of financial markets second only to that experienced during the Great Depression. The financial crisis produced a major reshaping of all financial institution (FI) sectors and the end of many major FIs, e.g., Bear Stearns and Lehman Brothers. The result was a call by the Obama administration to again separate activities performed by individual FIs. As the competitive environment changes, attention to profit and, more than ever, risk becomes increasingly important. The major themes of this book are the measurement and management of the risks of financial institutions. Financial institutions (e.g., banks, credit unions, insurance companies, and mutual funds) perform the essential function of channeling funds from those with surplus funds 2 Chapter 1 Why Are Financial Institutions Special? 3 (suppliers of funds) to those with shortages of funds (users of funds). In 2012, U.S. FIs held assets totaling more than $28.68 trillion. In contrast, the U.S. motor vehicle and parts industry (e.g., General Motors and Ford Motor Corp.) held total assets of $0.48 trillion. Although we might categorize or group FIs and the services they perform as life insurance companies, banks, investment banks, and so on, they face many common risks. Specifically, all FIs described in this chapter and Chapters 2 through 6 (1) hold some assets that are potentially subject to default or credit risk and (2) tend to mismatch the maturities of their balance sheet assets and liabilities to a greater or lesser extent and are thus exposed to interest rate risk. Moreover, all FIs are exposed to some degree of liability withdrawal or liquidity risk, depending on the type of claims they have sold to liability holders. In addition, most FIs are exposed to some type of underwriting risk, whether through the sale of securities or the issue of various types of credit guarantees on or off the balance sheet. Finally, all FIs are exposed to operating risks because the production of financial services requires the use of real resources and back-office support systems (labor and technology combined to provide services). Because of these risks and the special role that FIs play in the financial system, FIs are singled out for special regulatory attention. In this chapter, we first examine questions related to this specialness. In particular, what are the special functions that FIs—both depository institutions (banks, savings institutions, and credit unions) and nondepository institutions (insurance companies, securities firms, investment banks, finance companies, and mutual funds)—provide? These functions are summarized in Table 1–1. How do these functions benefit the economy? Second, we investigate what makes some FIs more special than others. Third, we look at how unique and long-lived the special functions of FIs really are. As part of this discussion, we briefly examine how changes in the way FIs deliver services TABLE 1–1 Areas of Financial Intermediaries’ Specialness in the Provision of Services Information costs The aggregation of funds in an FI provides greater incentive to collect information about customers (such as corporations) and to monitor their actions. The relatively large size of the FI allows this collection of information to be accomplished at a lower average cost (so-called economies of scale) than would be the case for individuals. Liquidity and price risk FIs provide financial claims to household savers with superior liquidity attributes and with lower price risk. Transaction cost services Similar to economies of scale in information production costs, an FI’s size can result in economies of scale in transaction costs. Maturity intermediation FIs can better bear the risk of mismatching the maturities of their assets and liabilities. Transmission of monetary supply Depository institutions are the conduit through which monetary policy actions by the country’s central bank (the Federal Reserve) impact the rest of the financial system and the economy. Credit allocation FIs are often viewed as the major, and sometimes only, source of financing for particular sectors of the economy, such as farming, small business, and residential real estate. Intergenerational wealth transfers FIs, especially life insurance companies and pension funds, provide savers with the ability to transfer wealth from one generation to the next. Payment services The efficiency with which depository institutions provide payment services such as check clearing directly benefits the economy. Denomination intermediation FIs, such as mutual funds, allow small investors to overcome constraints to buying assets imposed by large minimum denomination size. 4 Part One Introduction played a major part in the events leading up to the severe financial crisis of the late 2000s. A more detailed discussion of the causes of, major events during, and regulatory and industry changes resulting from the financial crisis is provided in Appendix 1A to the chapter (located at the book’s website, www.mhhe.com/ saunders8e). FINANCIAL INSTITUTIONS’ SPECIALNESS liquidity The ease of converting an asset into cash. price risk The risk that the sale price of an asset will be lower than the purchase price of that asset. To understand the important economic function of FIs, imagine a simple world in which FIs do not exist. In such a world, households generating excess savings by consuming less than they earn would have the basic choice: They could hold cash as an asset or invest in the securities issued by corporations. In general, corporations issue securities to finance their investments in real assets and cover the gap between their investment plans and their internally generated savings such as retained earnings. As shown in Figure 1–1, in such a world, savings would flow from households to corporations. In return, financial claims (equity and debt securities) would flow from corporations to household savers. In an economy without FIs, the level of fund flows between household savers and the corporate sector is likely to be quite low. There are several reasons for this. Once they have lent money to a firm by buying its financial claims, households need to monitor, or check, the actions of that firm. They must be sure that the firm’s management neither absconds with nor wastes the funds on any projects with low or negative net present values. Such monitoring actions are extremely costly for any given household because they require considerable time and expense to collect sufficiently high-quality information relative to the size of the average household saver’s investments. Given this, it is likely that each household would prefer to leave the monitoring to others. In the end, little or no monitoring would be done. The resulting lack of monitoring would reduce the attractiveness and increase the risk of investing in corporate debt and equity. The relatively long-term nature of corporate equity and debt, and the lack of a secondary market in which households can sell these securities, creates a second disincentive for household investors to hold the direct financial claims issued by corporations. Specifically, given the choice between holding cash and holding long-term securities, households may well choose to hold cash for liquidity reasons, especially if they plan to use savings to finance consumption expenditures in the near future. Finally, even if financial markets existed (without FIs to operate them) to provide liquidity services by allowing households to trade corporate debt and equity securities among themselves, investors also face a price risk on sale of securities, and the secondary market trading of securities involves various transaction costs. That is, the price at which household investors can sell securities on secondary markets such as the New York Stock Exchange (NYSE) may well differ from the price they initially paid for the securities. FIGURE 1–1 Flow of Funds in a World without FIs Equity and debt claims Households (net savers) Corporations (net borrowers) Cash Chapter 1 Why Are Financial Institutions Special? 5 Because of (1) monitoring costs, (2) liquidity costs, and (3) price risk, the average household saver may view direct investment in corporate securities as an unattractive proposition and prefer either not to save or to save in the form of cash. However, the economy has developed an alternative and indirect way to channel household savings to the corporate sector. This is to channel savings via FIs. Because of costs of monitoring, liquidity, and price risk, as well as for some other reasons, explained later, savers often prefer to hold the financial claims issued by FIs rather than those issued by corporations. Consider Figure 1–2, which is a closer representation than Figure 1–1 of the world in which we live and the way funds flow in our economy. Notice how financial institutions or intermediaries are standing, or intermediating, between the household and corporate sectors. These intermediaries fulfill two functions; any given FI might specialize in one or the other or might do both simultaneously. FIs Function as Brokers economies of scale The concept that the cost reduction in trading and other transaction services results in increased efficiency when FIs perform these services. asset transformer An FI issues financial claims that are more attractive to household savers than the claims directly issued by corporations. primary securities Securities issued by corporations and backed by the real assets of those corporations. The first function is the brokerage function. When acting as a pure broker, an FI acts as an agent for the saver by providing information and transaction services. For example, full-service securities firms (e.g., Bank of America Merrill Lynch) carry out investment research and make investment recommendations for their retail (or household) clients as well as conduct the purchase or sale of securities for commission or fees. Discount brokers (e.g., Charles Schwab) carry out the purchase or sale of securities at better prices and with greater efficiency than household savers could achieve by trading on their own. This efficiency results in reduced costs of trading, or economies of scale (see Chapter 21 for a detailed discussion). Similarly, independent insurance brokers identify the best types of insurance policies household savers can buy to fit their savings and retirement plans. In fulfilling a brokerage function, the FI plays an extremely important role by reducing transaction and information costs or imperfections between households and corporations. Thus, the FI encourages a higher rate of savings than would otherwise exist. FIs Function as Asset Transformers The second function is the asset-transformation function. In acting as an asset transformer, the FI issues financial claims that are far more attractive to household savers than the claims directly issued by corporations. That is, for many households, the financial claims issued by FIs dominate those issued directly by corporations as a result of lower monitoring costs, lower liquidity costs, and lower price risk. In acting as asset transformers, FIs purchase the financial claims issued by corporations—equities, bonds, and other debt claims called primary securities—and finance these purchases by selling financial claims to household FIGURE 1–2 Flow of Funds in a World with FIs FI (brokers) Households Cash Deposits and insurance policies FI (asset transformers) Corporations Equity and debt Cash 6 Part One Introduction secondary securities Securities issued by FIs and backed by primary securities. investors and other sectors in the form of deposits, insurance policies, and so on. The financial claims of FIs may be considered secondary securities because these assets are backed by the primary securities issued by commercial corporations that in turn invest in real assets. Specifically, FIs are independent market parties that create financial products whose value added to their clients is the transformation of financial risk. How can FIs purchase the direct or primary securities issued by corporations and profitably transform them into secondary securities more attractive to household savers? This question strikes at the very heart of what makes FIs special and important to the economy. The answer lies in the ability of FIs to better resolve the three costs facing a saver who chooses to invest directly in corporate securities. Information Costs agency costs Costs relating to the risk that the owners and managers of firms that receive savers’ funds will take actions with those funds contrary to the best interests of the savers. One problem faced by an average saver directly investing in a commercial firm’s financial claims is the high cost of information collection. Household savers must monitor the actions of firms in a timely and complete fashion after purchasing securities. Failure to monitor exposes investors to agency costs, that is, the risk that the firm’s owners or managers will take actions with the saver’s money contrary to the promises contained in the covenants of its securities contracts. Monitoring costs are part of overall agency costs. That is, agency costs arise whenever economic agents enter into contracts in a world of incomplete information and thus costly information collection. The more difficult and costly it is to collect information, the more likely it is that contracts will be broken. In this case the saver (the so-called principal) could be harmed by the actions taken by the borrowing firm (the so-called agent). FI’s Role as Delegated Monitor delegated monitor An economic agent appointed to act on behalf of smaller agents in collecting information and/or investing funds on their behalf. One solution to this problem is for a large number of small savers to place their funds with a single FI. This FI groups these funds together and invests in the direct or primary financial claims issued by firms. This agglomeration of funds resolves a number of problems. First, the large FI now has a much greater incentive to collect information and monitor actions of the firm because it has far more at stake than does any small individual household. In a sense, small savers have appointed the FI as a delegated monitor to act on their behalf. Not only does the FI have a greater incentive to collect information, the average cost of collecting information is lower. For example, the cost to a small investor of buying a $100 broker’s report may seem inordinately high for a $10,000 investment. For an FI with $10 million under management, however, the cost seems trivial. Such economies of scale of information production and collection tend to enhance the advantages to savers of using FIs rather than directly investing themselves. FI’s Role as Information Producer Second, associated with the greater incentive to monitor and the costs involved in failing to monitor appropriately, FIs may develop new secondary securities that enable them to monitor more effectively. Thus, a richer menu of contracts may improve the monitoring abilities of FIs. Perhaps the classic example of this is the bank loan. Bank loans are generally shorter-term debt contracts than bond contracts. This short-term nature allows the FI to exercise more monitoring power and control over the borrower. In particular, the information the FI generates Chapter 1 Why Are Financial Institutions Special? 7 regarding the firm is frequently updated as its loan renewal decisions are made. When bank loan contracts are sufficiently short term, the banker becomes almost like an insider to the firm regarding informational familiarity with its operations and financial conditions. Indeed, this more frequent monitoring often replaces the need for the relatively inflexible and hard-to-enforce covenants found in bond contracts. Thus, by acting as a delegated monitor and producing better and more timely information, FIs reduce the degree of information imperfection and asymmetry between the ultimate suppliers and users of funds in the economy. Liquidity and Price Risk diversify Reducing risk by holding a number of different securities in a portfolio. In addition to improving the flow and quality of information, FIs provide financial or secondary claims to household and other savers. Often, these claims have superior liquidity attributes compared with those of primary securities such as corporate equity and bonds. For example, depository institutions issue transaction account deposit contracts with a fixed principal value (and often a guaranteed interest rate) that can be withdrawn immediately on demand by household savers. Money market mutual funds issue shares to household savers that allow those savers to enjoy almost fixed principal (depositlike) contracts while often earning interest rates higher than those on bank deposits. Even life insurance companies allow policyholders to borrow against their policies held with the company at very short notice. The real puzzle is how FIs such as depository institutions can offer highly liquid and low price risk contracts to savers on the liability side of their balance sheets while investing in relatively illiquid and higher price risk securities issued by corporations on the asset side. Furthermore, how can FIs be confident enough to guarantee that they can provide liquidity services to investors and savers when they themselves invest in risky asset portfolios? And why should savers and investors believe FIs’ promises regarding the liquidity of their investments? The answers to these questions lie in the ability of FIs to diversify away some but not all of their portfolio risks. The concept of diversification is familiar to all students of finance. Basically, as long as the returns on different investments are not perfectly positively correlated, by exploiting the benefits of size, FIs diversify away significant amounts of portfolio risk—especially the risk specific to the individual firm issuing any given security. Indeed, research has shown that equal investments in as few as 15 securities can bring significant diversification benefits to FIs and portfolio managers. Further, as the number of securities in an FI’s asset portfolio increases beyond 15 securities, portfolio risk falls, albeit at a diminishing rate. What is really going on here is that FIs exploit the law of large numbers in their investments, achieving a significant amount of diversification, whereas because of their small size, many household savers are constrained to holding relatively undiversified portfolios. This risk diversification allows an FI to predict more accurately its expected return on its asset portfolio. A domestically and globally diversified FI may be able to generate an almost risk-free return on its assets. As a result, it can credibly fulfill its promise to households to supply highly liquid claims with little price or capital value risk. A good example of this is the ability of a bank to offer highly liquid demand deposits—with a fixed principal value—as liabilities, while at the same time investing in risky loans as assets. As long as an FI is sufficiently large to gain from diversification and monitoring, its financial claims are likely to be viewed as liquid and attractive to small savers compared with direct investments in the capital market. 8 Part One Introduction Other Special Services The preceding discussion has concentrated on three general or special services provided by FIs: reducing household savers’ monitoring costs, increasing their liquidity, and reducing their price risk exposure. Next, we discuss two other special services provided by FIs: reduced transaction costs and maturity intermediation. Reduced Transaction Costs Just as FIs provide potential economies of scale in information collection, they also provide potential economies of scale in transaction costs. For example, since May 1, 1975, fixed commissions for equity trades on the NYSE have been abolished. As a result, small retail buyers face higher commission charges or transaction costs than do large wholesale buyers. By grouping their assets in FIs that purchase assets in bulk—such as in mutual funds and pension funds— household savers can reduce the transaction costs of their asset purchases. In addition, bid–ask (buy–sell) spreads are normally lower for assets bought and sold in large quantities. Maturity Intermediation An additional dimension of FIs’ ability to reduce risk by diversification is that they can better bear the risk of mismatching the maturities of their assets and liabilities than can small household savers. Thus, FIs offer maturity intermediation services to the rest of the economy. Specifically, through maturity mismatching, FIs can produce long-term contracts, such as long-term, fixed-rate mortgage loans to households, while still raising funds with short-term liability contracts. Further, while such mismatches can subject an FI to interest rate risk (see Chapters 8 and 9), a large FI is better able to manage this risk through its superior access to markets and instruments for hedging such as loan sales and securitization (Chapters 25 and 26); futures (Chapter 22); swaps (Chapter 24); and options, caps, floors, and collars (Chapter 23). Concept Questions 1. What are the three major risks to household savers from direct security purchases? 2. What are two major differences between brokers (such as security brokers) and depository institutions (such as commercial banks)? 3. What are primary securities and secondary securities? 4. What is the link between asset diversification and the liquidity of deposit contracts? OTHER ASPECTS OF SPECIALNESS The theory of the flow of funds points to three principal reasons for believing that FIs are special, along with two other associated reasons. In reality, academics, policymakers, and regulators identify other areas of specialness relating to certain specific functions of FIs or groups of FIs. We discuss these next. The Transmission of Monetary Policy The highly liquid nature of depository institution deposits has resulted in their acceptance by the public as the most widely used medium of exchange in the economy. Indeed, at the core of the two most commonly used definitions of the money Chapter 1 www.federalreserve.gov Why Are Financial Institutions Special? 9 supply—M1 and M21—lie depository institutions’ deposit contracts. Because the liabilities of depository institutions are a significant component of the money supply that impacts the rate of inflation, they play a key role in the transmission of monetary policy from the central bank to the rest of the economy. That is, depository institutions are the conduit through which monetary policy actions impact the rest of the financial sector and the economy in general. Indeed, a major reason the United States and world governments bailed out many depository institutions and increased the deposit insurance limit from $100,000 to $250,000 per person per bank during the financial crisis was so that central banks could implement aggressive monetary policy actions to combat collapsing financial markets. Monetary policy actions include open market operations (the purchase and sale of securities in the U.S. Treasury securities market), setting the discount rate (the rate charged on “lender of last resort” borrowing from the Federal Reserve), and setting reserve requirements (the minimum amount of reserve assets depository institutions must hold to back deposits held as liabilities on their balance sheets). Appendix 1B to the chapter (located at the book’s website, www.mhhe.com/saunders8e) reviews the tools used by the Federal Reserve to implement monetary policy. Credit Allocation A further reason FIs are often viewed as special is that they are the major and sometimes the only source of financing for a particular sector of the economy pre-identified as being in special need of financing. Policymakers in the United States and a number of other countries, such as the United Kingdom, have identified residential real estate as needing special subsidies. This has enhanced the specialness of FIs that most commonly service the needs of that sector. In the United States, savings associations and savings banks have traditionally served the credit needs of the residential real estate sector. In a similar fashion, farming is an especially important area of the economy in terms of the overall social welfare of the population. The U.S. government has even directly encouraged financial institutions to specialize in financing this area of activity through the creation of Federal Farm Credit Banks. Intergenerational Wealth Transfers or Time Intermediation The ability of savers to transfer wealth across generations is also of great importance to the social well-being of a country. Because of this, life insurance and pension funds (see Chapter 6) are often especially encouraged, via special taxation relief and other subsidy mechanisms, to service and accommodate those needs. Payment Services Depository institutions (see Chapter 2) are special in that the efficiency with which they provide payment services directly benefits the economy. Two important payment services are check-clearing and wire transfer services. For example, on any given day, trillions of dollars worth of payments are effected through Fedwire and 1 M1: ($2,418.6 billion outstanding in October 2012) consists of (1) currency outside the U.S. Treasury, Federal Reserve Banks, and the vaults of depository institutions; (2) traveler’s checks of nonbank issuers; (3) demand deposits at all commercial banks other than those owed to depository institutions, the U.S. government, and foreign banks and official institutions, less cash items in the process of collection and Federal Reserve float; and (4) other checkable deposits (OCDs). M2: ($10,221.0 billion outstanding in October 2012) consists of M1 plus (1) savings and small time deposits (time deposits in amounts of less than $100,000) and (2) other nondeposit obligations of depository institutions. 10 Part One Introduction CHIPS, the two large wholesale payment wire networks in the United States (see Chapter 17). Any breakdowns in these systems probably would produce gridlock in the payment system with resulting harmful effects to the economy. Denomination Intermediation Both money market and debt–equity mutual funds are special because they provide services relating to denomination intermediation (see Chapter 5). Because they are sold in very large denominations, many assets are either out of reach of individual savers or would result in savers’ holding highly undiversified asset portfolios. For example, the minimum size of a negotiable certificate of deposit (CD) is $100,000 and commercial paper (short-term corporate debt) is often sold in minimum packages of $250,000 or more. Individually, a saver may be unable to purchase such instruments. However, by buying shares in a money market mutual fund along with other small investors, household savers overcome the constraints to buying assets imposed by large minimum denomination sizes. Such indirect access to these markets may allow small savers to generate higher returns on their portfolios as well. SPECIALNESS AND REGULATION negative externalities Action by an economic agent imposing costs on other economic agents. In the preceding section, FIs were shown to be special because of the various services they provide to sectors of the economy. Failure to provide these services or a breakdown in their efficient provision can be costly to both the ultimate sources (households) and users (firms) of savings. The financial crisis of the late 2000s is a prime example of how such a breakdown in the provision of financial services can cripple financial markets worldwide and bring the world economy into a recession. The negative externalities2 affecting firms and households when something goes wrong in the FI sector of the economy make a case for regulation. That is, FIs are regulated to protect against a disruption in the provision of the services discussed earlier and the costs this would impose on the economy and society at large. For example, bank failures may destroy household savings and at the same time restrict a firm’s access to credit. Insurance company failures may leave households totally exposed in old age to catastrophic illnesses and sudden drops in income on retirement. Further, individual FI failures may create doubts in savers’ minds regarding the stability and solvency of FIs in general and cause panics and even runs on sound institutions. Indeed, this possibility provided the reasoning in 2009 for an increase in the deposit insurance cap to $250,000 per person per bank. At this time, the FDIC was more concerned about the possibility of contagious runs as a few major depository institutions (DIs) (e.g., IndyMac, Washington Mutual) failed or nearly failed. At this point, the FDIC wanted to instill confidence in the banking system and made the change to avoid massive depositor runs from many of the troubled (and even safer) DIs, more DI failures, and an even larger collapse of the financial system. 2 A good example of a negative externality is the costs faced by small businesses in a one-bank town if the local bank fails. These businesses could find it difficult to get financing elsewhere, and their customers could be similarly disadvantaged. As a result, the failure of the bank may have a negative or contagious effect on the economic prospects of the whole community, resulting in lower sales, production, and employment. Chapter 1 net regulatory burden The difference between the private costs of regulations and the private benefits for the producers of financial services. Why Are Financial Institutions Special? 11 Although regulation may be socially beneficial, it also imposes private costs, or a regulatory burden, on individual FI owners and managers. For example, regulations prohibit commercial banks from making loans to individual borrowers that exceed more than 10 percent of their equity capital even though the loans may have a positive net present value to the bank. Consequently, regulation is an attempt to enhance the social welfare benefits and mitigate the social costs of the provision of FI services. The private costs of regulation relative to the private benefits, for the producers of financial services, is called the net regulatory burden. Six types of regulation seek to enhance the net social welfare benefits of financial intermediaries’ services: (1) safety and soundness regulation, (2) monetary policy regulation, (3) credit allocation regulation, (4) consumer protection regulation, (5) investor protection regulation, and (6) entry and chartering regulation. Regulations are imposed differentially on the various types of FIs. For example, depository institutions are the most heavily regulated of the FIs. Finance companies, on the other hand, are subject to many fewer regulations. Regulation can also be imposed at the federal or the state level and occasionally at the international level, as in the case of bank capital requirements (see Chapter 20). Finally, because of the historically segmented nature of the U.S. FI system, many regulations in that system are institution-specific, for example, consumer protection legislation imposed on bank credit allocation to local communities. However, these institution-specific regulations are increasingly being liberalized (see Chapter 21). Safety and Soundness Regulation To protect depositors and borrowers against the risk of FI failure due, for example, to a lack of diversification in asset portfolios, regulators have developed layers of protective mechanisms. These mechanisms are intended to ensure the safety and soundness of the FI and thus to maintain the credibility of the FI in the eyes of its borrowers and lenders. Indeed, even during the worst of the financial crisis deposit runs at banks, savings institutions, and credit unions did not occur. This is because the safety and soundness regulations in place protected virtually all depositors from losing their money. Thus, while depository institution failures increased significantly during the crisis, depositors felt little need to run. In the first layer of protection are requirements encouraging FIs to diversify their assets. Thus, banks are required not to make loans exceeding more than 10 percent of their own equity capital funds to any one company or borrower (see Chapter 10). A bank that has 10 percent of its assets funded by its own capital funds (and therefore 90 percent by deposits) can lend no more than 1 percent of its assets to any one party. The second layer of protection concerns the minimum level of capital or equity funds that the owners of an FI need to contribute to the funding of its operations (see Chapter 20). For example, bank and insurance regulators are concerned with the minimum ratio of capital to (risk) assets. The higher the proportion of capital contributed by owners, the greater the protection against insolvency risk to outside liability claim holders such as depositors and insurance policyholders. This is because losses on the asset portfolio due, for example, to the lack of diversification are legally borne by the equity holders first, and only after equity is totally wiped out by outside liability holders. For example, in 2008 the near failure and subsequent purchase by J.P. Morgan Chase of Washington Mutual left Washington Mutual shareholders with very little. Consequently, by varying the required degree of equity capital, FI regulators can directly affect the degree of 12 Part One Introduction www.fdic.gov www.sipc.org risk exposure faced by nonequity claim holders in FIs. Indeed, part of the TARP program of 2008–2009 (approved by the U.S. Congress in October 2008 as a first response to the financial crisis) was the Capital Purchase Program (CPP). The goal of the CPP was to encourage U.S. financial institutions to build capital to increase the flow of financing to U.S. businesses and consumers and to support the U.S. economy. Further, regulators acted quickly to ensure the largest DIs had sufficient capital to withstand large losses during the financial crisis. In late February 2009, the Obama administration announced that it would conduct a “stress test” of the 19 largest U.S. DIs, which would measure the ability of these DIs to withstand a protracted economic slump: unemployment rate above 10 percent and home prices dropping another 25 percent. Results of the stress test showed that 10 of the 19 DIs needed to raise a total of $74.6 billion in capital. Within a month of the May 7, 2009, release of the results the DIs had raised $149.45 billion of capital. (See Chapter 20 for more discussion on the role of capital in FIs.) The third layer of protection is the provision of guaranty funds such as the Deposit Insurance Fund (DIF) for depository institutions, the Security Inves tors Protection Corporation (SIPC) for securities firms, and the state guaranty funds established (with regulator encouragement) to meet insolvency losses to small claim holders in the life and property–casualty insurance industries (see Chapter 19). By protecting FI claim holders, when an FI fails and owners’ equity or net worth is wiped out, these funds create a demand for regulation of the insured institutions to protect the funds’ resources (see Chapter 19 for more discussion). For example, the FDIC monitors and regulates participants in the DIF. The fourth layer of regulation is monitoring and surveillance itself. Regulators subject all FIs, whether banks, securities firms, or insurance companies, to varying degrees of monitoring and surveillance. This involves on-site examination as well as an FI’s production of accounting statements and reports on a timely basis for off-site evaluation. Just as savers appoint FIs as delegated monitors to evaluate the behavior and actions of ultimate borrowers, society appoints regulators to monitor the behavior and performance of FIs. Many of the regulatory changes proposed in reaction to the financial crisis included significant increases in the monitoring and surveillance of any financial institution whose failure could have serious systemic effects. Finally, note that regulation is not without costs for those regulated. For example, society’s regulators may require FIs to have more equity capital than private owners believe is in their own best interests. Similarly, producing the information requested by regulators is costly for FIs because it involves the time of managers, lawyers, and accountants. Again, the socially optimal amount of information may differ from an FI’s privately optimal amount.3 As noted earlier, the differences between the private benefits to an FI from being regulated—such as insurance fund guarantees—and the private costs it faces from adhering to regulation—such as examinations—is called the net regulatory burden. The higher the net regulatory burden on FIs, the more inefficiently they produce any given set of financial services from a private (FI) owner’s perspective. 3 Also, a social cost rather than social benefit from regulation is the potential risk-increasing behavior (often called moral hazard ) that results if deposit insurance and other guaranty funds provide coverage to FIs and their liability holders at less than the actuarially fair price (see Chapter 19 for further discussion). Chapter 1 Why Are Financial Institutions Special? 13 Monetary Policy Regulation www.federalreserve.gov outside money The part of the money supply directly produced by the government or central bank, such as notes and coin. inside money The part of the money supply produced by the private banking system. Another motivation for regulation concerns the special role banks play in the transmission of monetary policy from the Federal Reserve (the central bank) to the rest of the economy. The problem is that the central bank directly controls only the quantity of notes and coin in the economy—called outside money—whereas the bulk of the money supply consists of deposits—called inside money. In theory, a central bank can vary the quantity of cash or outside money and directly affect a bank’s reserve position as well as the amount of loans and deposits it can create without formally regulating the bank’s portfolio. In practice, regulators have chosen to impose formal controls (these are described in Appendix 1B, located at the book’s website, www.mhhe.com/saunders8e). In most countries, regulators commonly impose a minimum level of required cash reserves to be held against deposits (see Chapter 18). Some argue that imposing such reserve requirements makes the control of the money supply and its transmission more predictable. Such reserves also add to an FI’s net regulatory burden if they are more than the institution believes are necessary for its own liquidity purposes. In general, whether banks or insurance companies, all FIs would choose to hold some cash reserves— even non-interest-bearing—to meet the liquidity and transaction needs of their customers directly. For well-managed FIs, however, this optimal level is normally low, especially if the central bank (or other regulatory body) does not pay interest or pays very little interest on required reserves. As a result, FIs often view required reserves as similar to a tax and as a positive cost of undertaking intermediation. Credit Allocation Regulation Credit allocation regulation supports the FI’s lending to socially important sectors such as housing and farming. These regulations may require an FI to hold a minimum amount of assets in one particular sector of the economy or to set maximum interest rates, prices, or fees to subsidize certain sectors. Examples of asset restrictions include the qualified thrift lender (QTL) test, which requires thrifts (i.e., savings institutions) to hold 65 percent of their assets in residential mortgagerelated assets to retain a thrift charter, and insurance regulations, such as those in New York State that set maximums on the amount of foreign or international assets in which insurance companies can invest. Examples of interest rate restrictions are the usury laws set in many states on the maximum rates that can be charged on mortgages and/or consumer loans and regulations (now abolished) such as the Federal Reserve’s Regulation Q maximums on time and savings deposit interest rates. Such price and quantity restrictions may have justification on social welfare grounds—especially if society has a preference for strong (and subsidized) housing and farming sectors. However, they can also be harmful to FIs that have to bear the private costs of meeting many of these regulations. To the extent that the net private costs of such restrictions are positive, they add to the costs and reduce the efficiency with which FIs undertake intermediation. Consumer Protection Regulation Congress passed the Community Reinvestment Act (CRA) and the Home Mortgage Disclosure Act (HMDA) to prevent discrimination in lending. For example, since 1975, the HMDA has assisted the public in determining whether banks and other mortgage-lending institutions are meeting the needs of their local communities. HMDA is especially concerned about discrimination on the basis of age, race, 14 Part One Introduction www.ffiec.gov www.federalreserve.gov www.fdic.gov www.occ.treas.gov sex, or income. Since 1990, depository institutions have reported to their chief federal regulator on a standardized form the reasons credit was granted or denied. To get some idea of the information production cost of regulatory compliance in this area, consider that the Federal Financial Institutions Examination Council (FFIEC) processed information on more than 14.7 million mortgage transactions from more than 7,632 institutions in 2012. (The council is a federal supervisory body comprising the members of the Federal Reserve, the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC), and the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency.)4 Many analysts believe that community and consumer protection laws are imposing a considerable net regulatory burden on FIs without providing offsetting social benefits that enhance equal access to mortgage and lending markets. However, as deregulation proceeds and the trend toward consolidation and universal banking (see Chapter 2) continues, it is likely that such laws will be extended beyond banks to other financial service providers, such as insurance companies, that are not currently subject to CRA community lending requirements. Indeed, a new Consumer Financial Protection Bureau to protect consumers across the financial sector from unfair, deceptive, and abusive practices was a part of the Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act passed by the U.S. Congress in 2010. Further, a new credit card reform bill, effective in 2010, put unprecedented restrictions on the actions that may be taken by all credit card issuers against credit card holders. Included in the bill were limits on allowable interest rate increases during the first year, limits on fees and penalties credit card companies may charge, protection against arbitrary interest rate increases, provisions giving credit card holders sufficient time to pay their bills, and the abolition of universal default (a practice in which credit card issuers would raise interest rates on customers’ accounts resulting from actions on other accounts, e.g., missing a payment on a utility bill would result in an increase in a credit card rate). Investor Protection Regulation A considerable number of laws protect investors who use investment banks directly to purchase securities and/or indirectly to access securities markets through investing in mutual or pension funds. Various laws protect investors against abuses such as insider trading, lack of disclosure, outright malfeasance, and breach of fiduciary responsibilities (see Chapter 4). Important legislation affecting investment banks and mutual funds includes the Securities Acts of 1933 and 1934, the Investment Company Act of 1940, and the Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act of 2010. As with consumer protection legislation, compliance with these acts can impose a net regulatory burden on FIs. Entry Regulation The entry and activities of FIs are also regulated (e.g., new bank chartering regulations). Increasing or decreasing the cost of entry into a financial sector affects the profitability of firms already competing in that industry. Thus, industries heavily protected against new entrants by high direct costs (e.g., through required equity or capital contributions) and high indirect costs (e.g., by restricting individuals 4 The FFIEC also publishes aggregate statistics and analysis of CRA and HMDA data. The Federal Reserve and other regulators also rate bank compliance. For example, in 2012 the FDIC judged 2.6 percent of the banks examined to be outstanding in CRA compliance, 96.1 percent as satisfactory, and 1.3 percent as needing to improve or as being in noncompliance. Chapter 1 Why Are Financial Institutions Special? 15 who can establish FIs) of entry produce bigger profits for existing firms than those in which entry is relatively easy (see Chapter 21). In addition, regulations (such as the Financial Services Modernization Act of 1999) define the scope of permitted activities under a given charter (see Chapter 21). The broader the set of financial service activities permitted under a given charter, the more valuable that charter is likely to be. Thus, barriers to entry and regulations pertaining to the scope of permitted activities affect the charter value of an FI and the size of its net regulatory burden. Concept Questions 1. Why should more regulation be imposed on FIs than on other types of private corporations? 2. Define the concept of net regulatory burden. 3. What six major types of regulation do FIs face? THE CHANGING DYNAMICS OF SPECIALNESS At any moment in time, each FI supplies a set of financial services (brokerage related, asset transformation related, or both) and is subject to a given net regulatory burden. As the demands for the special features of financial services change as a result of changing preferences, macroeconomic conditions, and technology, one or more areas of the financial services industry become more or less profitable. Similarly, changing regulations can increase or decrease the net regulatory burden faced in supplying financial services in any given area. These demand, cost, and regulatory pressures are reflected in changing market shares in different financial service areas as some contract and others expand. Clearly, an FI seeking to survive and prosper must be flexible enough to move to growing financial service areas and away from those that are contracting. If regulatory activity restrictions inhibit or reduce the flexibility with which FIs can alter their product mix, this will reduce their competitive ability and the efficiency with which financial services are delivered. That is, activity barriers within the financial services industry may reduce the ability to diversify and potentially add to the net regulatory burden faced by FIs. Trends in the United States In Table 1–2 we show the changing shares of total assets in the U.S. financial services industry from 1860 to 2012. A number of important trends are evident: most apparent is the decline in the total share of depository institutions since the Second World War. Specifically, the share of commercial banks declined from 54.5 to 32.9 percent between 1948 and 2012, while the share of thrifts (savings banks, savings associations, and credit unions) fell from 12.0 to 6.9 percent over the same period. Thus, services provided by depository institutions (payment services, transaction costs services, information cost) have become relatively less significant as a portion of all services provided by FIs. Similarly, insurance companies also witnessed a secular decline in their share, from 26.0 to 14.6 percent. The most dramatically increasing trend is the rising share of investment companies (mutual funds and money market mutual funds), increasing their share from 0.3 to 19.8 percent between 1948 and 2012. Investment companies differ from 16 Part One Introduction TABLE 1–2 Percentage Shares of Assets of Financial Institutions in the United States, 1860–2012 Sources: Randall Kroszner, “The Evolution of Universal Banking and Its Regulation in Twentieth Century America,” chap. 3 in Anthony Saunders and Ingo Walter, eds., Universal Banking Financial System Design Reconsidered (Burr Ridge, IL: Irwin, 1996); and Federal Reserve Board, “Flow of Fund Accounts,” various issues. www.federalreserve.gov Commercial banks Thrift institutions Insurance companies Investment companies Pension funds Finance companies Securities brokers and dealers Real estate investment trusts Total (%) Total ($ trillions) 1860 1900 1922 1929 1948 1960 1970 1980 2000 2005 2012 71.4% 62.9% 63.3% 53.7% 54.5% 40.8% 42.6% 40.7% 30.5% 29.3% 32.9% 17.8 18.2 13.9 14.0 12.0 21.0 23.0 25.0 10.1 10.2 6.9 10.7 13.8 16.7 18.6 26.0 24.2 19.0 16.2 15.6 15.0 14.6 — — 0.0 2.4 0.3 0.7 0.7 2.0 15.8 13.7 19.8 — 0.0 0.0 0.7 3.8 7.7 8.0 9.5 8.8 6.2 7.6 — 0.0 0.0 2.0 2.7 5.2 5.7 6.2 6.9 7.3 4.8 0.0 3.8 5.3 8.1 0.7 0.4 0.7 0.3 12.1 17.3 12.1 — 100.0% — 100.0% — 100.0% — 100.0% — 100.0% 0.0 100.0% 0.3 100.0% 0.1 100.0% 0.2 100.0% 1.0 100.0% 1.3 100.0% 0.001 0.016 0.075 0.123 0.218 0.500 1.079 3.140 15.93 23.80 28.68 Chapter 1 Why Are Financial Institutions Special? 17 banks and insurance companies in that they give savers cheaper access to the direct securities markets. They do so by exploiting the comparative advantages of size and diversification, with the transformation of financial claims, such as maturity transformation, a lesser concern. Thus, open-ended mutual funds buy stocks and bonds directly in financial markets and issue savers shares whose value is linked in a direct pro rata fashion to the value of the mutual fund’s asset portfolio. Similarly, money market mutual funds invest in short-term financial assets such as commercial paper, CDs, and Treasury bills and issue shares linked directly to the value of the underlying portfolio. To the extent that these funds efficiently diversify, they also offer price risk protection and liquidity services. The Rise of Financial Services Holding Companies To the extent that the financial services market is efficient and these trends reflect the forces of demand and supply, they indicate a trend: savers increasingly prefer the denomination intermediation and information services provided by mutual funds. These FIs provide investments that closely mimic diversified investments in the direct securities markets over the transformed financial claims offered by traditional FIs. This trend may also indicate that the net regulatory burden on traditional FIs—such as banks and insurance companies—is higher than that on investment companies. Indeed, traditional FIs are unable to produce their services as cost efficiently as they could previously. Recognizing this changing trend, the U.S. Congress passed the Financial Services Modernization (FSM) Act, which repealed the 1933 Glass-Steagall barriers between commercial banking, insurance, and investment banking. The act, promoted as the biggest change in the regulation of financial institutions in 70 years, allowed for the creation of “financial services holding companies” that could engage in banking activities, insurance activities, and securities activities. Thus, after 70 years of partial or complete separation between insurance, investment banking, and commercial banking, the Financial Services Modernization Act of 1999 opened the door for the creation of full-service financial institutions in the United States similar to those that existed before 1933 and that exist in many other countries. As a result, while Table 1–2 lists assets of financial institutions by functional area, the financial services holding company (which combines these activities in a single financial institution) has become the dominant form of financial institution in terms of total assets. The Shift Away from Risk Measurement and Management and the Financial Crisis Certainly, a major event that changed and reshaped the financial services industry was the financial crisis of the late 2000s. As FIs adjusted to regulatory changes brought about by the likes of the FSM Act, one result was a dramatic increase in systemic risk of the financial system, caused in large part by a shift in the banking model from that of “originate and hold” to “originate to distribute.” In the traditional model, banks take short term deposits and other sources of funds and use them to fund longer term loans to businesses and consumers. Banks typically hold these loans to maturity, and thus have an incentive to screen and monitor borrower activities even after a loan is made. However, the traditional banking model exposes the institution to potential liquidity, interest rate, and credit risk. In attempts to avoid these risk exposures and generate improved return–risk trade-offs, banks have shifted to an underwriting model in which they originate or warehouse loans, 18 Part One Introduction and then quickly sell them. Figure 1–3 shows the growth in bank loan secondary market trading from 1991 through the third quarter of 2012. Note the huge growth in bank loan trading even during the financial crisis of 2008–2009. When loans trade, the secondary market produces information that can substitute for the information and monitoring of banks.5 Further, banks may have lower incentives to collect information and monitor borrowers if they sell loans rather than keep them as part of the bank’s portfolio of assets. Indeed, most large banks are organized as financial service holding companies to facilitate these new activities. More recently, activities of shadow banks—nonfinancial service firms that perform banking services—have facilitated the change from the originate and hold model of commercial banking to the originate and distribute banking model. Participants in the shadow banking system include structured investment vehicles (SIVs), special-purpose vehicles (SPVs), asset-backed paper vehicles, credit hedge funds, asset-backed commercial paper (ABCP) conduits, limited-purpose finance companies, money market mutual funds (MMMFs), and credit hedge funds (see Chapter 21 for a detailed discussion of these FIs). In the shadow banking system, savers place their funds with money market mutual6 and similar funds, which invest these funds in the liabilities of other shadow banks. Borrowers get loans and leases from shadow banks such as finance companies rather than from banks. Like the traditional banking system, the shadow banking system intermediates the flow of funds between net savers and net borrowers. However, instead of the bank serving as the middleman, it is the nonbank financial service firm, or shadow bank, that intermediates. Further, unlike the traditional banking system, Trading Volume ($ billion) 600.0 500.0 400.0 300.0 200.0 2011 2012Q3 2010 2009 2008 2007 2006 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 0.0 1993 100.0 1992 Bank Loan Secondary Market Trading, 1991–2012Q3 1991 FIGURE 1–3 5 A. Gande and A. Saunders, “Are Banks Still Special When There Is a Secondary Market for Loans?” Journal of Finance, 2012, pp. 1649–1684, find that equity of borrowers whose bank loans trade on secondary markets for the first time receive positive announcement period returns. Further, announcements by banks of new loans to a borrower after the borrower’s loans begin trading in the secondary markets show positive announcement period returns. 6 Recent regulatory proposals recognize that MMMFs are operating as “banks.” These proposals include requirements that MMMFs maintain capital levels similar to banks and/or that fund shares be backed by a private deposit insurance scheme. Chapter 1 Why Are Financial Institutions Special? 19 where the complete credit intermediation is performed by a single bank, in the shadow banking system it is performed through a series of steps involving many nonbank financial service firms. These innovations remove risk from the balance sheet of financial institutions and shift risk off the balance sheet to other parts of the financial system. Since the FIs, acting as underwriters, are not exposed to the credit, liquidity, and interest rate risks of traditional banking, they have little incentive to screen and monitor activities of borrowers to whom they originate loans. Thus, FIs’ role as specialists in risk measurement and management has been reduced. Adding to FIs’ move away from risk measurement and management was the boom (“bubble”) in the housing markets, which began building in 2001, particularly after the terrorist attacks of 9/11. The immediate response by regulators to the terrorist attacks was to create stability in the financial markets by providing liquidity to FIs. For example, the Federal Reserve lowered the short-term interest rate that banks and other financial institutions pay in the federal funds market and even made lender of last resort funds available to nonbank FIs such as investment banks. Perhaps not surprisingly, low interest rates and the increased liquidity provided by the central banks resulted in a rapid expansion in consumer, mortgage, and corporate debt financing. Demand for residential mortgages and credit card debt rose dramatically. As the demand for mortgage debt grew, especially among those who had previously been excluded from participating in the market because of their poor credit ratings, FIs began lowering their credit quality cut-off points. Moreover, to boost their earnings, in the market now popularly known as the “subprime market,” banks and other mortgage-supplying institutions often offered relatively low “teaser” rates on adjustable rate mortgages (ARMs), i.e., exceptionally low initial interest rates, but, if market rates rose in the future, substantial increases in rates could occur after the initial rate period expired two or three years later. Under the traditional, originate and hold, banking model, banks might have been reluctant to so aggressively pursue low credit quality borrowers for fear that the loans would default. However, under the originate to distribute model of banking, asset securitization and loan syndication allowed banks to retain little or no part of the loans, and hence the default risk on loans that they originated. Thus, as long as the borrower did not default within the first months after a loan’s issuance and the loans were sold or securitized without recourse back to the bank, the issuing bank could ignore longer term credit risk concerns. The result was a deterioration in credit quality, at the same time as there was a dramatic increase in consumer and corporate leverage. Eventually, in 2006, housing prices started to fall. At the same time, the Federal Reserve started to raise interest rates as it began to fear inflation. Since many subprime mortgages originated in the 2001–2005 period had adjustable rates, the cost of meeting mortgage commitments rose to unsustainable levels for many low income households. The confluence of falling house prices, rising interest rates, and rising mortgage costs led to a wave of mortgage defaults in the subprime market and foreclosures that only reinforced the downward trend in house prices. The number of subprime mortgages that were more than 60 days behind on their payments was 17.1 percent in June 2007 and more than 20 percent in August 2007. As this happened, the poor quality of the collateral and credit quality underlying subprime mortgage pools became apparent, with default rates far exceeding those apparently anticipated by the rating agencies in setting their initial subprime mortgage securitizations ratings. In 2007, the 20 Part One Introduction percentage of subprime mortgage-backed securities delinquent by 90 days or more was 10.09 percent, substantially higher than the 5.37 percent rate in May 2005. The financial crisis began. Appendix 1A to the chapter (located at the book’s website, www.mhhe.com/saunders8e) provides a detailed discussion of the causes of, major events during, and regulatory and industry changes resulting from the financial crisis The economy relies on financial institutions to act as specialists in risk measurement and management. The importance of this was demonstrated in the aftermath of the FIs’ failure to perform this critical function during the global financial crisis. The result was a worldwide breakdown in credit markets, as well as an enhanced level of equity market volatility. When FIs failed to perform their critical risk measurement and management functions, the result was a crisis of confidence that disrupted financial markets. Global Trends In addition to these domestic trends, U.S. FIs must now compete not only with other domestic FIs but increasingly with foreign FIs that provide services (such as payment services and denomination intermediation) comparable to those of U.S. FIs. For example, Table 1–3 lists the 10 largest banks in the world, measured by total assets as of October 2012. Notice that only 1 of the top 10 banks is a U.S. bank. Table 1–4 lists foreign versus domestic bank offices’ assets held in the United States from 1992 through 2012. Total foreign bank assets over this period increased £ ¥ :$ TABLE 1–3 The 10 Largest Banks in the World (in millions of dollars) Source: The Banker, February 2012. www.thebanker.com TABLE 1–4 Total Assets Deutsche Bank (Germany) Mitsubishi UFJ Financial Group (Japan) Industrial & Commerce Bank of China (China) HSBC Holdings (United Kingdom) Barclays Bank (United Kingdom) BNP Paribas (France) Japan Post Bank (Japan) J.P. Morgan Chase (United States) Crédit Agricole Groupe (France) Royal Bank of Scotland (United Kingdom) $2,809.9 2,803.4 2,763.6 2,721.1 2,584.3 2,563.0 2,513.2 2,321.3 2,317.1 2,295.8 Domestic versus Foreign Bank Offices’ Assets Held in the United States (in billions of dollars) Source: Federal Reserve Board, “Flow of Fund Accounts,” Statistical Releases, various dates. www.federalreserve.gov Foreign Bank Financial Assets Domestic Bank Financial Assets 1992 1997 1999 2002 2004 2008 2012 $ 510.9 $ 819.1 $ 763.5 $ 823.0 $ 664.1 $ 1,624.5 $ 1,976.7 3,824.4 4,858.5 5,664.4 6,979.1 8,371.8 11,639.0 11,747.6 Chapter 1 Why Are Financial Institutions Special? 21 from $510.9 billion in 1992 to $1,976.7 billion in 2012. This consistently represents over 10 percent (and has been as high as 21.9 percent) of total assets held in the United States. Concept Questions Internet Exercise Summary 1. Is the share of bank and thrift assets growing as a proportion of total FI assets in the United States? 2. What are the fastest growing FIs in the United States? 3. What were the causes of the financial crisis? 4. Describe the global challenges facing U.S. FIs in the early 2000s. Go to the website of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve, and find the latest information available for foreign bank offices’ assets and liabilities held in the United States using the following steps. At www.federalreserve.gov, click on “Economic Research and Data.” Click on “Flow of Funds Accounts of the United States.” Click on the most recent date. Click on “Level Tables.” This will download a file to your computer that will contain the most recent information in Tables L.110 and L.111. This chapter described various factors and forces impacting financial institutions and the specialness of the services they provide. These forces have resulted in FIs, which have historically relied on making profits by performing traditional special functions (such as asset transformation and the provision of liquidity services), expanding into selling financial services that interface with direct security market transactions, such as asset management, insurance, and underwriting services. This is not to say that specialized or niche FIs cannot survive but rather that only the most efficient FIs will prosper as the competitive value of a specialized FI charter declines. The major theme of this book is the measurement and management of FI risks. In particular, although we might categorize or group FIs and label them life insurance companies, banks, finance companies, and so on, in fact, they face risks that are more common than different. Specifically, all the FIs described in this and the next five chapters (1) hold some assets that are potentially subject to default or credit risk and (2) tend to mismatch the maturities of their balance sheets to a greater or lesser extent and are thus exposed to interest rate risk. Moreover, all are exposed to some degree of saver withdrawal or liquidity risk depending on the type of claims sold to liability holders. And most are exposed to some type of underwriting risk, whether through the sale of securities or by issuing various types of credit guarantees on or off the balance sheet. Finally, all are exposed to operating cost risks because the production of financial services requires the use of real resources and back-office support systems. In Chapters 7 through 26 of this textbook, we investigate the ways managers of FIs are measuring and managing this inventory of risks to produce the best returnrisk trade-off for shareholders in an increasingly competitive and contestable market environment. 22 Part One Introduction www.mhhe.com/saunders8e Questions and Problems 1. What are five risks common to all financial institutions? 2. Explain how economic transactions between household savers of funds and corporate users of funds would occur in a world without financial institutions. 3. Identify and explain three economic disincentives that would dampen the flow of funds between household savers of funds and corporate users of funds in an economic world without financial institutions. 4. Identify and explain the two functions FIs perform that would enable the smooth flow of funds from household savers to corporate users. 5. In what sense are the financial claims of FIs considered secondary securities, while the financial claims of commercial corporations are considered primary securities? How does the transformation process, or intermediation, reduce the risk, or economic disincentives, to savers? 6. Explain how financial institutions act as delegated monitors. What secondary benefits often accrue to the entire financial system because of this monitoring process? 7. What are five general areas of FI specialness that are caused by providing various services to sectors of the economy? 8. What are agency costs? How do FIs solve the information and related agency costs experienced when household savers invest directly in securities issued by corporations? 9. How do large FIs solve the problem of high information collection costs for lenders, borrowers, and financial markets? 10. How do FIs alleviate the problem of liquidity risk faced by investors who wish to buy securities issued by corporations? 11. How do financial institutions help individual savers diversify their portfolio risks? Which type of financial institution is best able to achieve this goal? 12. How can financial institutions invest in high-risk assets with funding provided by low-risk liabilities from savers? 13. How can individual savers use financial institutions to reduce the transaction costs of investing in financial assets? 14. What is maturity intermediation? What are some of the ways the risks of maturity intermediation are managed by financial institutions? 15. What are five areas of institution-specific FI specialness and which types of institutions are most likely to be the service providers? 16. How do depository institutions such as commercial banks assist in the implementation and transmission of monetary policy? 17. What is meant by credit allocation regulation? What social benefit is this type of regulation intended to provide? 18. Which intermediaries best fulfill the intergenerational wealth transfer function? What is this wealth transfer process? 19. What are two of the most important payment services provided by financial institutions? To what extent do these services efficiently provide benefits to the economy? 20. What is denomination intermediation? How do FIs assist in this process? 21. What is negative externality? In what ways do the existence of negative externalities justify the extra regulatory attention received by financial institutions? 22. If financial markets operated perfectly and costlessly, would there be a need for financial institutions? 23. Why are FIs among the most regulated sectors in the world? When is the net regulatory burden positive? Chapter 1 Why Are Financial Institutions Special? 23 24. What forms of protection and regulation do the regulators of FIs impose to ensure their safety and soundness? 25. In the transmission of monetary policy, what is the difference between inside money and outside money? How does the Federal Reserve try to control the amount of inside money? How can this regulatory position create a cost for depository institutions? 26. What are some examples of credit allocation regulation? How can this attempt to create social benefits create costs to a private institution? 27. What is the purpose of the Home Mortgage Disclosure Act? What are the social benefits desired from the legislation? How does the implementation of this legislation create a net regulatory burden on financial institutions? 28. What legislation has been passed specifically to protect investors who use investment banks directly or indirectly to purchase securities? Give some examples of the types of abuses for which protection is provided. 29. How do regulations regarding barriers to entry and the scope of permitted activities affect the charter value of financial institutions? 30. What reasons have been given for the growth of investment companies at the expense of “traditional” banks and insurance companies? 31. What events resulted in banks’ shift from the traditional banking model of “originate and hold” to a model of “originate and distribute”? 32. How did the boom in the housing market in the early and mid-2000s exacerbate FIs’ transition away from their role as specialists in risk measurement and management? 33. What are the tools used by the Federal Reserve to implement monetary policy? 34. Suppose the Federal Reserve instructs the Trading Desk to purchase $1 billion of securities. Show the result of this transaction on the balance sheets of the Federal Reserve System and commercial banks. 35. Explain how a decrease in the discount rate affects credit availability and the money supply. 36. What changes did the Fed implement to its discount window lending policy in the early 2000s? 37. Bank Three currently has $600 million in transaction deposits on its balance sheet. The Federal Reserve has currently set the reserve requirement at 10 percent of transaction deposits. a. Suppose the Federal Reserve decreases the reserve requirement to 8 percent. Show the balance sheet of Bank Three and the Federal Reserve System just before and after the full effect of the reserve requirement change. Assume that Bank Three withdraws all excess reserves and gives out loans and that borrowers eventually return all of these funds to Bank Three in the form of transaction deposits. b. Redo part (a) using a 12 percent reserve requirement. 38. Which of the monetary tools available to the Federal Reserve is most often used? Why? 39. Describe how expansionary activities conducted by the Federal Reserve impact credit availability, the money supply, interest rates, and security prices. Do the same for contractionary activities. www.mhhe.com/saunders8e The following questions and problems are based on material in Appendix 1B to the chapter. 24 Part One Introduction Web Questions 40. Go to the Federal Reserve Board’s website at www.federalreserve.gov. Find the latest figures for M1 and M2 using the following steps. Click on “Economic Research and Data.” Click on “View All.” Click on “Money Stock Measures.” This downloads a file onto your computer that contains the relevant data. By what percentage have these measures of the money supply grown over the past year? 41. Go to the Federal Reserve Board’s website at www.federalreserve.gov. Find the latest figures for financial assets outstanding at various types of financial institutions using the following steps. Click on “Economic Research and Data.” Click on “Flow of Funds Accounts of the United States.” Click on the most recent date. Click on “Level tables.” This downloads a file onto your computer that contains the relevant data. How has the percent of financial assets held by commercial banks changed since that listed in Table 1–2 for 2012? Appendix 1A: The Financial Crisis: The Failure of Financial Services Institution Specialness View Appendix 1A at the website for this textbook (www.mhhe.com/saunders8e). Appendix 1B: Monetary Policy Tools www.mhhe.com/saunders8e View Appendix 1B at the website for this textbook (www.mhhe.com/saunders8e). Chapter Two See Appendices Online at www.mhhe.com/saunders8e • Appendix 2A: Financial Statement Analysis Using a Return on Equity (ROE) Framework • Appendix 2B: Commercial Banks’ Financial Statements and Analysis • Appendix 2C: Depository Institutions and Their Regulators • Appendix 2D: Technology in Commercial Banking Financial Services: Depository Institutions INTRODUCTION A theme of this book is that the products sold and the risks faced by modern financial institutions are becoming increasingly similar, as are the techniques used to measure and manage those risks. To illustrate this, Tables 2–1A and 2–1B contrast the products sold by the financial services industry in 1950 with those sold in 2013. In 1999, the U.S. Congress passed the Financial Services Modernization Act (FSMA), which repealed regulations that set barriers between commercial banking, insurance, and investment banking. The bill, promoted as the biggest change in the regulation of financial institutions in nearly 70 years, allowed for the creation of “financial services holding companies” that could engage in banking activities, TABLE 2–1A Products Sold by the U.S. Financial Services Industry, 1950 Function Institution Depository institutions Insurance companies Finance companies Securities firms Pension funds Mutual funds Payment Savings Fiduciary Services Products Services Business Consumer X X X X X X X X X * * Insurance and Risk Management Debt Products Underwriting Issuance of Lending Equity X X X X X * Minor involvement. 25 26 Part One Introduction TABLE 2–1B Products Sold by the U.S. Financial Services Industry, 2013 Function Institution Lending Payment Savings Fiduciary Services Products Services Business Consumer Depository institutions Insurance companies Finance companies Securities firms Pension funds Mutual funds † X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X Underwriting Issuance of Equity Debt X X X X † † X X Insurance and Risk Management Products X X X X X Selective involvement via affiliates. insurance activities, and securities activities. The bill also allowed large banks to place certian activities, including some securities underwriting, in direct bank subsidiaries. Thus, after nearly 70 years of partial or complete separation between the various functions performed by financial institutions, the FSMA opened the door for the creation of full-service financial institutions in the United States. Legislation enacted as a result of the financial crisis, however, represents a partial reversal of this trend. For example, the “Volcker rule” provision of the Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act prohibits bank holding companies from engaging in proprietary trading and limits their investments in hedge funds, private equity, and related vehicles. Despite these most recent changes, many FIs operate in more than one of the industries discussed in the next five chapters. Furthermore, during the financial crisis, several nondepository financial institutions (e.g., investment banks Goldman Sachs and Morgan Stanley and finance company GMAC) requested and were allowed to convert to bank holding companies. The change was recognition that their models of finance and investing had become too risky and the FIs needed the cushion of bank deposits that kept some of the bigger commercial banks like J.P. Morgan Chase relatively safe during the crisis. By becoming bank holding companies, the firms agreed to significantly tighter regulations and much closer supervision by bank examiners from government agencies rather than only the Securities and Exchange Commission. The new charters required the FIs to be subject to more disclosure, hold higher capital reserves, and take less risk. However, the new banks would also have access to the full array of the Federal Reserve lending facilities, something the failed investment bank Lehman Brothers did not have. In this chapter we begin by describing three major FI groups—commercial banks, savings institutions, and credit unions—which are also called depository institutions (DIs) because a significant proportion of their funding comes from customer deposits. Historically, commercial banks have operated as more diversified institutions, having a large concentration of residential mortgage assets but holding commercial loans and consumer loans as well. Savings institutions have concentrated primarily on residential mortgages. Finally, credit unions have historically focused on consumer loans funded with member deposits. In Chapters 3 through 6 other (nondepository) FIs will be described. We focus on four major characteristics of each group: (1) size, structure, and composition of the industry group, (2) balance sheets and recent trends, (3) regulation, and (4) industry performance. Chapter 2 FIGURE 2–1 A Simple Depository Institution Balance Sheet TABLE 2–2 Largest Depository Institutions, 2012 (Banks and Savings Institutions Ranked by Total Assets on September 30, 2012, in billions of dollars) Source: Quarterly reports, 2012. Financial Services: Depository Institutions 27 Depository Institutions Assets Liabilities and Equity Loans Deposits Other assets Other liabilities and equity Company 1. J.P. Morgan Chase 2. Bank of America 3. Citigroup 4. Wells Fargo 5. U.S. Bancorp 6. PNC Financial Services Corp. 7. Bank of New York Mellon 8. State Street Corp. 9. TD Bank 10. HSBC North America Banking Assets Holding Company Assets $1,812.8 1,445.1 1,347.8 1,180.2 342.8 291.8 259.1 197.0 195.9 194.0 $2,321.3 2,168.0 1,931.3 1,374.7 352.3 301.1 340.1 204.1 212.5 320.8 Figure 2–1 presents a very simplified product-based balance sheet for depository institutions. Notice that DIs offer products to their customers on both sides of their balance sheets (loans on the asset side and deposits on the liability side). This joint-product nature of the DI business creates special challenges for management as they deal with the many risks facing these institutions. These risks will be discussed later, in Chapters 7 through 26. Table 2–2 lists the largest U.S. depository institutions in 2012. The ranking is by size of assets devoted to banking services. The table also lists the assets at the holding company level. Many of these large depository institutions (e.g., J.P. Morgan Chase, Bank of America) operate in other financial service areas (e.g., investment banking and security brokerage) as well. Thus, assets held at the holding company level can be much larger than just those devoted to banking services. Several depository institutions manage assets of over $1 trillion which reflects the dramatic trend toward consolidation and mergers among financial service firms in the 1990s and 2000s. The largest bank is J.P. Morgan Chase, created from the merger of J.P. Morgan, Chase Manhattan, Bank One, and Washington Mutual; the second largest is Bank of America, created by the merger of NationsBank BankAmerica, and FleetBoston; and the third largest is Citigroup, created from the merger of Citicorp and Travelers Insurance. COMMERCIAL BANKS commercial bank A bank that accepts deposits and makes consumer, commercial, and real estate loans. Commercial banks make up the largest group of depository institutions measured by asset size. They perform functions similar to those of savings institutions and credit unions. That is, they accept deposits (liabilities) and make loans (assets). However, they differ in their composition of assets and liabilities, which are much more varied. Commercial bank liabilities usually include several types of nondeposit sources of funds, while their loans are broader in range, including consumer, commercial, and real estate loans. Commercial banking activity is also 28 Part One Introduction FIGURE 2–2 Small Banks Breakdown of Loan Portfolios Large Banks C&I 14.30% Credit card 0.33% Source: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, September 2012. www.fdic.gov C&I 21.00% Consumer 4.63% Other 6.65% Real estate 74.09% Credit card 9.85% Real estate 49.09% Consumer 9.11% Other 10.95% Note: Small banks are defined as banks with assets less than $1 billion. Large banks are defined as banks with assets of $1 billion or more. regulated separately from the activities of savings institutions and credit unions. Within the banking industry the structure and composition of assets and liabilities also vary significantly across banks of different asset sizes. For example, as shown in Figure 2–2, small banks make proportionately fewer commercial and industrial (C&I) loans and more real estate loans than do big banks. Size, Structure, and Composition of the Industry In late 2012 the United States had 6,168 commercial banks. Even though this may seem a large number, in fact, the number of banks has been shrinking. For example, in 1985 there were 14,416 banks, and in 1989 there were 12,744. Figure 2–3 illustrates the number of bank mergers, bank failures, and new charters for the period 1980 through 2012. Notice that much of the change in the size, structure, and composition of this industry is the result of mergers and acquisitions. It was FIGURE 2–3 Structural Changes in the Number of Commercial Banks, 1980–2012 Source: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Quarterly Banking Profile, various issues. www.fdic.gov Number 600 Mergers New charters Failures 500 400 300 200 100 0 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 Year Chapter 2 Financial Services: Depository Institutions TABLE 2–3 Number of Subsidiaries of Selected Financial Services Holding Companies Source: D. Avraham, P. Selvaggi, and J.I. Vickery, “A Structural View of U.S. Bank Holding Companies,” FRBNY Economic Policy Review, July 2012. community banks Banks that specialize in retail or consumer banking. Holding Company Rank 1 2 3 4 5 7 10 20 30 40 50 29 Domestic Name Commercial Bank Other Foreign J.P. Morgan Chase Bank of America Citigroup Wells Fargo Goldman Sachs Morgan Stanley Bank of New York Mellon Regions Financial Comerica First Horizon National Webster Financial 4 5 2 5 1 1 3 1 2 1 1 2,936 1,541 935 1,270 1,444 1,593 211 35 72 35 21 451 473 708 91 1,670 1,289 146 4 2 1 0 not until the 1980s and 1990s that regulators (such as the Federal Reserve or state banking authorities) allowed banks to merge with other banks across state lines (interstate mergers), and it has only been since 1994 that Congress has passed legislation (the Riegle-Neal Act) easing branching by banks across state lines. Indeed, the number of branches at U.S. banks has increased from 43,293 in 1985 to 83,209 in 2012. Table 2–3 reports the number of subsidiaries for some of the largest financial services holding companies. Many of the nonbank subsidiaries reported in the table manage trusts and investment funds beyond the traditional banking business. Further, the industry has seen some of the largest mergers and acquisitions ever, such as J.P. Morgan’s acquisition of Chase Manhattan (for $33.6 billion) in September 2000, Bank of America’s acquisition of FleetBoston Financial (for $49.3 billion) in October 2003, J.P. Morgan Chase’s acquisition of Bank One (for $60.0 billion) in January 2004, and Bank of New York’s accuisition of Mellon Financial (for $18.3 billion) in 2007. Thus, while back-office operations are being consolidated, bank customers have an increase in the number of branch locations available to them. Finally, it has only been since 1987 that banks have possessed (limited) powers to underwrite corporate securities. Full authority to enter the investment banking (and insurance) business was received only with the passage of the Financial Services Modernization Act in 1999. Thus, commercial banks may now merge with investment banks (and insurance companies). In subsequent chapters, we discuss the impact that changing regulations as well as technological advances have had on the drop in the number of commercial banks (e.g., technology changes [Chapter 17], regulatory changes [Chapter 21], and competition [Chapter 21]). A comparison of asset concentration by bank size (see Table 2–4) indicates that the consolidations in banking appear to have reduced the asset share of the smallest banks (under $1 billion) from 36.6 percent in 1984 to 9.0 percent in 2012. These smaller or community banks—under $1 billion in asset size—tend to specialize in retail or consumer banking, such as providing residential mortgages and consumer loans and accessing the local deposit base. Clearly, this group of banks is decreasing in both number and importance. 30 Part One TABLE 2–4 Introduction U.S. Bank Asset Concentration, 1984 versus 2012 Source: FDIC Quarterly Banking Profile, fourth quarter 1984 and third quarter 2012. www.fdic.gov 2012 Number 6,168 All FDIC-insured commercial banks 1. Under $100 million 2. $100 million– $1 billion 3. $1 billion–$10 billion 4. $10 billion or more 2,034 3,608 437 89 Percent of Total 1984 Assets* 13,069.9 33.0% 58.5 118.0 1,059.2 7.1 1.4 1,133.6 10,759.1 Percent of Total 0.9% 8.1 8.7 82.3 Percent Number of Total 14,483 12,044 2,161 254 24 Assets* $2,508.9 Percent of Total 83.2% 14.9 404.2 513.9 16.1% 20.5 1.7 0.2 725.9 864.8 28.9 34.5 * In billions of dollars. regional or superregional banks Banks that engage in a complete array of wholesale commercial banking activities. federal funds market An interbank market for short-term borrowing and lending of bank reserves. money center banks Banks that have a heavy reliance on nondeposit or borrowed sources of funds. The relative asset share of the largest banks (more than $1 billion in assets), on the other hand, increased from 63.4 percent in 1984 to 91.0 percent in 2012. The majority of banks in the two largest size classes are often either regional or superregional banks. They engage in a more complete array of wholesale commercial banking activities, encompassing consumer and residential lending as well as commercial and industrial lending (C&I loans), both regionally and nationally. In addition, the big banks access markets for purchased funds—such as the interbank or federal funds market—to finance their lending and investment activities. However, some of the very biggest banks often have the separate title money center banks. Currently, five banking organizations constitute the money center bank group: Bank of New York Mellon, Deutsche Bank (through its U.S. acquisition of Bankers Trust), Citigroup, J.P. Morgan Chase, and HSBC Bank USA (formerly Republic NY Corporation).1,2 This number has been declining because of the megamergers, discussed earlier. It is important to note that asset or lending size does not necessarily make a bank a money center bank. Thus, Bank of America Corporation, with $1,445 billion in assets in 2012 (the second-largest U.S. bank organization), is not a money center bank, while Bank of New York Mellon (with only $259 billion in assets) is. What makes a bank a money center bank is partly location3 and partly its heavy reliance on nondeposit or borrowed sources of funds. In fact, because of its extensive retail branch network,4 Bank of America tends to be a net supplier of funds on the interbank market (federal funds market). By contrast, money center banks have few retail branches and rely almost entirely on wholesale and borrowed funds as sources of assets or liabilities. Money center banks are also major particitpants in foreign currency markets and are therefore subject to foreign exchange risk (see Chapter 13). 1 Bankers Trust was purchased by Deutsche Bank (a German bank) in 1998. The Bankers Trust name, however, has been retained for U.S. operations. Republic NY Corporation was purchased by HSBC (a British bank) in 1999. Republic NY Bank has been retained for U.S. operations under the name HSBC Bank USA. 2 These banking organizations are mostly holding companies that own and control the shares of a bank or banks. 3 A money center bank normally is headquartered in New York or Chicago. These are the traditional national and regional centers for correspondent banking services offered to smaller community banks. 4 In 2012 Bank of America had more than 5,700 branches nationwide. Chapter 2 TABLE 2–5 ROA and ROE of Banks by Size, 1990–2012 Source: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Various dates. www.fdic.gov Financial Services: Depository Institutions 31 Percentage Return on Assets (insured commercial banks by consolidated assets) Year All Banks $0ⴚ$100 Million 1990 1995 2000 2001 2003 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2012 0.49% 1.17 1.19 1.16 1.40 1.33 0.95 0.16 0.09 0.66 1.02 0.79% 1.18 1.01 0.91 0.94 0.95 0.82 0.36 0.06 0.36 0.78 $100 Millionⴚ $1 Billion 0.78% 1.25 1.28 1.20 1.27 1.24 1.06 0.38 ⫺0.01 0.34 0.89 $1 Billionⴚ $10 Billion $10 Billionⴙ 0.76% 1.28 1.29 1.31 1.46 1.35 1.08 ⫺0.10 ⫺0.35 0.19 1.25 0.38% 1.10 1.16 1.13 1.42 1.35 0.92 0.16 0.15 0.75 1.01 Percentage Return on Equity (insured commercial banks by consolidated assets) spread The difference between lending and deposit rates. Year All Banks $0ⴚ$100 Million 1990 1995 2000 2001 2003 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2012 7.64% 14.68 14.07 13.10 15.31 13.06 9.29 1.62 0.85 5.99 9.06 9.02% 11.37 9.09 8.07 8.19 7.38 6.00 2.76 0.46 3.06 6.69 $100 Millionⴚ $1 Billion 9.95% 13.48 13.56 12.24 12.80 12.20 10.34 3.68 ⫺0.15 3.35 8.36 $1 Billionⴚ $10 Billion $10 Billionⴙ 10.25% 15.04 14.57 13.77 14.00 12.65 9.47 ⫺0.90 ⫺3.16 1.67 10.66 6.68% 15.60 14.42 13.43 16.37 13.40 9.22 1.70 1.44 6.78 8.97 The bigger banks tend to fund themselves in national markets and lend to larger corporations. This means that their spreads (i.e., the difference between lending and deposit rates) in the past (the 1990s) often were narrower than those of smaller regional banks, which were more sheltered from competition in highly localized markets. As a result, the largest banks’ return on assets (ROA) was below that of smaller banks (see Table 2–5). However, as the barriers to interstate competition and expansion in banking have fallen in recent years and as large banks have focused more on off-balance-sheet activities to generate income (see below), the largest banks’ ROAs as well as returns on equity (ROEs) have often outperformed those of the smallest banks, especially those with assets under $100 million (see Table 2–5). Appendix 2A (located at the book’s website, www.mhhe.com/ saunders8e) shows how a bank’s ROE can be decomposed to examine the different underlying sources of profitability. This decomposition of ROE is often referred to as DuPont analysis. Appendix 2B (also located at the book’s website) contains an overview of the evaluation of bank performance and risk exposure. The U.S. banking system is unique in that it consists of not only very big banks but also a large number of relatively small community banks. This unique banking structure is largely the result of a legal framework that until recently restricted 32 Part One Introduction banks’ abilities to diversify geographically. Over time, with regulatory change (see below) and financial innovation, large banks have become complex organizations engaged in a wide range of activities worldwide. These large banks provide a variety of services to their customers, but often rely on factual financial information, computer models, and centralized decision making as the basis for conducting business. Small banks focus more on relationship banking, often basing decisions on personal knowledge of customers’ creditworthiness and an understanding of business conditions in the communities they serve. As discussed above, with increased merger activity over the last 30 years, the number of community banks (while still large) has declined. Although community banks hold only a small share of the nation’s banking assets, they provide important financial services (such as small-business lending) for which there are few, if any, substitutes. Thus, community banks will likely continue to play an important role in the banking industry even as technology and market conditions change. Balance Sheet and Recent Trends Assets Figure 2–4 shows the broad trends over the 1951–2012 period in the four principal earning asset areas of commercial banks: business loans (or C&I loans), securities, mortgages, and consumer loans. Although business loans were the major asset on bank balance sheets between 1965 and 1987, there has been a drop in their importance (as a proportion of the balance sheet) since 1987. This drop has been mirrored by an offsetting rise in holdings of securities and mortgages. These trends reflect a number of long-term and temporary influences. One important long-term influence has been the growth of the commercial paper market, which has become an alternative funding source for major corporations. Another has been the securitization of mortgages—the pooling and packaging of mortgage loans for sale in the form of bonds (see Chapter 26). A more temporary influence was the so-called FIGURE 2–4 Portfolio Shift: U.S. Commercial Banks’ Financial Assets Source: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Statistics on Depository Institutions. www.fdic.gov Percent of total 50 Securities 40 30 Business loans 20 Mortgages 10 Consumer loans 0 1951 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 Year 1985 1990 1995 2000 2005 2010 Chapter 2 TABLE 2–6 Financial Services: Depository Institutions 33 Assets Balance Sheet (All U.S. Commercial Banks) as of September 30, 2012 (in billions of dollars) Loans and securities Investment securities U.S. government securities Other Total loans Interbank loans Loans excluding interbank Commercial and industrial Real estate Individual All other Less: Reserve for loan losses Total cash assets Other assets Total assets Source: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, September 30, 2012. www.fdic.gov $10,653.2 $3,909.3 $1,705.6 2,203.7 6,743.9 104.6 6,639.3 $1,401.2 3,569.9 1,206.9 619.8 158.5 1,228.4 1,188.3 13,069.9 Liabilities Total deposits Deposits held in foreign offices Deposits held in domestic offices Transaction accounts Nontransaction accounts Borrowings Other liabilities Total liabilities Total equity capital $ 9,622.4 $1,443.9 8,178.5 $1,303.0 6,875.5 1,568.6 378.2 11,569.2 1,500.7 credit crunch and decline in the demand for business loans as a result of the economic downturn and recession in 1989–92 and 2001–02. Further, the financial crisis and the recession of 2007–09 resulted in a reduction in all areas of lending and an increase in the banks’ holdings of less risky securities investments (e.g., Treasury securities, federal funds, and U.S. government agency securities). Look at the detailed balance sheet for all U.S. commercial banks as of September 2012 (Table 2–6). Total loans amount to $6,743.9 billion, or 51.6 percent of total assets, and fall into four broad classes: business or C&I ($1,401.2 billion); commercial and residential real estate ($3,569.9 billion); individual, such as consumer loans for auto purchases and credit card debt ($1,206.9 billion); and all other loans, such as less developed country (LDC) loans ($619.8 billion). In the investment security portfolio of $3,909.3 billion, or 29.9 percent of total assets, U.S. government securities, such as Treasury bonds, constitute $1,705.6 billion, with other securities (in particular, municipal securities and investment-grade corporate bonds) making up the rest.5 A major inference we can draw from this asset structure is that credit or default risk exposure is a major risk faced by modern commercial bank managers (see Chapters 10 and 11). Because commercial banks are highly leveraged and therefore 5 The footnotes to commercial bank balance sheets also distinguish between securities held by banks for trading purposes, normally for less than one year, and those held for longer-term investment purposes. The large money center banks are often active in the secondary market trading of government securities, reflecting their important role as primary dealers in government securities at the time of Treasury security auctions. 34 Part One Introduction hold little equity (see below) compared with total assets, even a relatively small number of loan defaults can wipe out the equity of a bank, leaving it insolvent.6 Liabilities transaction accounts The sum of noninterest-bearing demand deposits and interest-bearing checking accounts. NOW accounts Interest-bearing checking accounts. money market mutual funds Specialized mutual funds that offer depositlike interest bearing claims to savers. negotiable CDs Fixed-maturity interest-bearing deposits with face values over $100,000 that can be resold in the secondary market. Commercial banks have two major sources of funds other than the equity provided by owners: deposits and borrowed or other liability funds. A major difference between banks and other firms is banks’ high leverage. For example, banks had an average ratio of equity to assets of 11.48 percent in 2012. This implies that 88.52 percent of their assets were funded by debt, either deposits or borrowed funds. Note in Table 2–6, the aggregate balance sheet of U.S. banks, that deposits amounted to $9,622.4 billion, or 73.6 percent of total liabilities and equity, and borrowings and other liabilities were $1,568.6 billion and $378.2 billion, respectively. Of the total stock of deposits, transaction accounts constituted 13.5 percent, or $1,303.0 billion. Transaction accounts are checkable deposits that bear no interest (demand deposits) or are interest bearing (most commonly called NOW accounts, or negotiable order of withdrawal accounts). Since their introduction in 1980, interest-bearing checking accounts—especially NOW accounts—have dominated the transaction accounts of banks. However, since limitations are imposed on the ability of corporations to hold such accounts and since there are minimum balance requirements for NOW accounts, non-interest-bearing demand deposits are still held. The second major segment of deposits is retail or household savings and time deposits (also called certificates of deposits or CDs), normally individual account holdings of less than $100,000. Important components of bank retail savings accounts are small nontransaction accounts, which include passbook savings accounts and retail time deposits. Small nontransaction accounts constitute 63.6 percent of total deposits, or $6,123.0 billion. However, this disguises an important trend in the supply of these deposits to banks. Specifically, retail savings and time deposits have been falling in recent years, largely as a result of competition from money market mutual funds. These funds pay a competitive rate of interest based on wholesale money market rates by pooling and investing funds (see Chapter 5) while requiring relatively small-denomination investments by mutual fund investors. The third major source of deposit funds consists of large time deposits (over $100,000), which amounted to $752.5 billion, or approximately 7.8 percent of the stock of deposits, in September 2012. These are primarily negotiable CDs (deposit claims with promised interest rates and fixed maturities of at least 14 days) that can be resold to outside investors in an organized secondary market. As such, they are usually distinguished from retail time deposits by their negotiability and secondary market liquidity. Nondeposit liabilities comprise borrowings and other liabilities that together total 16.8 percent of all bank liabilities, or $1,946.8 billion. These categories include a broad array of instruments, such as purchases of federal funds (bank reserves) on the interbank market and repurchase agreements (temporary swaps of securities for federal funds) at the short end of the maturity spectrum to the issuance of notes and bonds at the longer end.7 6 Losses such as those due to defaults are charged off against the equity (stockholders’ stake) in a bank. Additions to the reserve for loan and lease losses account (and, in turn, the expense account “provisions for losses on loans and leases”) to meet expected defaults reduce retained earnings and, thus, reduce equity of the bank. Unexpected defaults (e.g., due to a sudden major recession) are meant to be written off against the remainder of the bank’s equity (e.g., its retained earnings and funds raised from share offerings). 7 These instruments are explained in greater detail in later chapters, especially Chapter 18. Chapter 2 Financial Services: Depository Institutions 35 Overall, the liability structure of bank balance sheets tends to reflect a shorter maturity structure than does the asset portfolio with relatively more liquid instruments, such as deposits and interbank borrowings, used to fund less liquid assets such as loans. Thus, maturity mismatch or interest rate risk and liquidity risk are key exposure concerns for bank managers (see Chapters 8, 9, 12, and 18). Equity Commercial bank equity capital (11.48 percent of total liabilities and equity in 2012) consists mainly of common and preferred stock (listed at par value), surplus or additional paid-in capital, and retained earnings. Regulators require banks to hold a minimum level of equity capital to act as a buffer against losses from their on- and off-balance-sheet activities (see Chapter 20). Because of the relatively low cost of deposit funding, banks tend to hold equity close to the minimum levels set by regulators. As we discuss in subsequent chapters, this impacts banks’ exposures to risk and their ability to grow—both on and off the balance sheet—over time. Part of the TARP program of 2008–2009 was the Capital Purchase Program intended to encourage U.S. financial institutions to build capital to increase the flow of financing to U.S. businesses and consumers and to support the U.S. economy. Under the program, the Treasury purchased more than $200 billion of senior preferred equity. The senior preferred shares rank senior to common stock should the bank be closed. In addition to capital injections received as part of the Capital Purchase Program, TARP provided additional emergency funding to Citigroup ($25 billion) and Bank of America ($20 billion). Through 2012, $245 billion of TARP capital injections had been allocated to DIs, of which $233.7 billion has been paid back plus a return of $33.9 billion in dividends and assessments to the government. As part of the 2010 Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act, the largest banks are subject to annual stress tests, designed to ensure that the banks are properly capitalized. Scenarios used as part of the stress tests range from mild to calamitous, with the most extreme including a 5 percent decline in gross domestic product, an unemployment rate of 12 percent, and a volatile stock market that loses half its value. The original stress test was announced in late February 2009 when the Obama administration announced that it would conduct a “stress test” of the 19 largest U.S. DIs, which would measure the ability of these DIs to withstand a protracted economic slump: unemployment rate above 10 percent and home prices dropping another 25 percent. Results of this first stress test showed that 10 of the 19 DIs needed to raise a total of $74.6 billion in capital. Within a month of the May 7, 2009, release of the results, the DIs had raised $149.45 billion of capital. As part of the 2013 stress tests, the worst-case scenario includes international events, i.e., the eurozone plunges into recession and a sharp slowdown in China spills into neighboring countries. Internet Exercise Go to the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation website (www.fdic.gov) and find the latest balance sheet information available for commercial banks using the following steps. Click on “Analysts.” Click on “Statistics on Banking.” Click on “Run Report.” This will download a file onto your computer that will contain the most recent balance sheet information for commercial banks. 36 Part One Introduction Off-Balance-Sheet Activities off-balance-sheet asset An item that moves onto the asset side of the balance sheet when a contingent event occurs. off-balance-sheet liability An item that moves onto the liability side of the balance sheet when a contingent event occurs. The balance sheet itself does not reflect the total scope of bank activities. Banks conduct many fee-related activities off the balance sheet. Off-balance-sheet (OBS) activities are important, in terms of their dollar value and the income they generate for banks—especially as the ability of banks to attract high-quality loan applicants and deposits becomes ever more difficult. OBS activities include issuing various types of guarantees (such as letters of credit), which often have a strong insurance underwriting element, and making future commitments to lend. Both services generate additional fee income for banks. Off-balance-sheet activities also involve engaging in derivative transactions—futures, forwards, options, and swaps. Under current accounting standards, such activities are not shown on the current balance sheet. Rather, an item or activity is an off-balance-sheet asset if, when a contingent event occurs, the item or activity moves onto the asset side of the balance sheet or an income item is realized on the income statement. Conversely, an item or activity is an off-balance-sheet liability if, when a contingent event occurs, the item or activity moves onto the liability side of the balance sheet or an expense item is realized on the income statement. By moving activities off the balance sheet, banks hope to earn additional fee income to complement declining margins or spreads on their traditional lending business. At the same time, they can avoid regulatory costs or “taxes” since reserve requirements and deposit insurance premiums are not levied on off-balance-sheet activities (see Chapter 16). Thus, banks have both earnings and regulatory “taxavoidance” incentives to undertake activities off their balance sheets. Off-balance-sheet activities, however, can involve risks that add to the overall insolvency exposure of an FI. Indeed, at the very heart of the financial crisis were losses associated with off-balance-sheet mortgage-backed securities created and held by FIs. Losses resulted in the failure, acquisition, or bailout of some of the largest FIs and a near meltdown of the world’s financial and economic systems. However, off-balance-sheet activities and instruments have both risk-reducing as well as risk-increasing attributes, and, when used appropriately, they can reduce or hedge an FI’s interest rate, credit, and foreign exchange risks. We show the notional, or face, value of bank OBS activities, and their distribution and growth, for 1992 to 2012 in Table 2–7. Notice the relative growth in the notional dollar value of OBS activities in Table 2–7. By September 2012, the notional value of OBS bank activities was $236,945.3 billion compared with the $13,069.9 billion value of on-balance-sheet activities. It should be noted that the notional, or face, value of OBS activities does not accurately reflect the risk to the bank undertaking such activities. The potential for the bank to gain or lose is based on the possible change in the market value over the life of the contract rather than the notional, or face, value of the contract, normally less than 3 percent of the notional value of an OBS contract.8 The use of derivative contracts (futures and forwards, swaps, and options) accelerated during the 1992–2012 period and accounted for much of the growth in OBS activity. Along with the growth in the notional value of OBS activities, banks have seen significant growth in the percentage of their total operating income 8 For example, the market value of a swap (today) is the difference between the present value of the cash flows (expected) to be received minus the present value of cash flows expected to be paid (see Chapter 24). Chapter 2 Financial Services: Depository Institutions 37 TABLE 2–7 Aggregate Volume of Off-Balance-Sheet Commitments and Contingencies by U.S. Commercial Banks, (in billions of dollars) Sources: FDIC, Statistics on Banking, various issues. www.fdic.gov 1992 Commitments to lend Future and forward contracts (exclude FX) On commodities and equities On interest rates Notional amount of credit derivatives Standby contracts and other option contracts Option contracts on interest rates Option contracts on foreign exchange Option contracts on commodities Commitments to buy FX (includes $US), spot, and forward Standby LCs and foreign office guarantees (amount of these items sold to others via participations) Commercial LCs Participations in acceptances Securities borrowed or lent Other significant commitments and contingencies Notional value of all outstanding swaps Total Total assets (on-balance-sheet items) 2003 2007 $ 7,263.9 2009 $ 5,406.3 2012* $ 5,234.6 Distribution 2012 $ 1,272.0 $ 5,398.9 2.2% 26.3 1,738.1 9.6 104.9 7,209.8 1,001.2 251.2 9,116.9 15,862.8 186.2 20,995.8 14,112.3 345.2 30,634.9 13,997.6 0.2 12.9 5.9 1,012.7 12,539.5 20,984.4 27,166.2 26,332.8 11.1 494.8 60.3 1,298.3 767.5 4,024.7 2,715.9 2,714.0 2,001.5 4,480.8 2,539.5 1.9 1.1 3,015.5 4,351.1 10,057.9 9,212.5 15,321.4 6.5 162.5 348.9 1,139.6 1,098.5 1,257.5 0.5 (14.9) 28.1 1.0 107.2 (60.3) 24.2 0.5 852.0 (220.5) 29.7 0.1 2,052.2 (192.1) 22.5 0.0 1,027.3 (302.0) 24.2 0.0 996.7 0.0 0.0 0.4 8.7 2,122.0 $10,075.8 $ 3,476.4 53.3 44,082.7 $78,032.8 $ 7,602.5 173.1 103,091.1 $176,763.5 $ 11,176.1 151.7 139,126.6 $223,221.4 $ 11,822.7 224.3 135,555.8 $236,945.3 $ 13,069.9 0.1 57.2 100.0% FX ⫽ foreign exchange; LC ⫽ letter of credit. * As of September. (interest income plus noninterest income) coming from these non-balance-sheet activities. Indeed, the percentage of noninterest income to total operating income has increased from 22.66 percent in 1979 to 33.73 percent in 2012. As we discuss in detail in Chapters 22 through 24, the significant growth in derivative securities activities by commercial banks has been a direct response to the increased interest rate risk, credit risk, and foreign exchange risk exposures they have faced, both domestically and internationally. In particular, these contracts offer banks a way to hedge these risks without having to make extensive changes on the balance sheet. However, these assets and liabilities also introduce unique risks that must be managed. The failure or near failure of some of the largest U.S. financial institutions during the financial crisis can be attributed to risks associated with OBS activities (e.g., Citigroup). As mortgage borrowers defaulted on their mortgages, financial institutions that held these “toxic” mortgages and “toxic” credit derivatives (in the form of mortgage backed securities) started announcing huge losses on them. Losses from the falling value of OBS securities reached over $1 trillion worldwide through 2009. 38 Part One Introduction The TARP gave the U.S. Treasury funds to buy “toxic” mortgages and other securities from financial institutions. However, the TARP plan was slow to be instituted and not all FIs chose to participate in the program. Better capitalized FIs wanted to hold on to their troubled OBS securities rather than sell them and record losses. Then early 2009 saw a plunge in the market values of financial institutions. Banks such as Citigroup, Bank of America, and J.P. Morgan Chase traded at less than their book value as investors had little confidence in the value of their assets. As a result, a new plan, announced on February 10, 2009, involved a number of initiatives, including offering federal insurance to banks against losses on bad assets and expanding the Fed’s Term Asset-Backed Securities Loan Facility (TALF). Further, the Treasury, working with the Federal Reserve, FDIC, and private investors, created the Public–Private Investment Fund (PPIF) to acquire realestate related OBS assets. By selling to PPIF, financial institutions could reduce balance sheet risk, support new lending, and help improve overall market functioning. The PPIF facility was initially funded at $500 billion with plans to expand the program to up to $1.25 trillion over time. After several months of discussion, in July 2009, the government had selected nine financial firms to manage a scaleddown program; investing $30 billion to start the fund. The selected firms had 12 weeks to raise $500 million of capital each from private investors willing to invest in FI’s toxic assets. The total investment would be matched by the federal government. The purchases of $1.25 trillion in OBS mortgage-backed securities were completed in March 2010. Although the simple notional dollar value of OBS items overestimates their risk exposure amounts, the increase in these activities is still nothing short of phenomenal. Indeed, this phenomenal increase pushed regulators into imposing capital requirements on such activities and explicitly recognizing an FI’s solvency risk exposure from pursuing such activities. We describe these capital requirements in Chapter 20. Further, as a result of the role derivatives played in the financial crisis, in spring 2009, regulators proposed a revamping of the U.S. financial regulatory system that included extending regulatory oversight to unregulated OTC derivative securities (see below). The regulation requires that all over-the-counter derivative contracts be subject to regulation, all derivatives dealers subject to supervision, and regulators be empowered to enforce rules against manipulation and abuse. Other Fee-Generating Activities Commercial banks engage in other fee-generating activities that cannot easily be identified from analyzing their on- and off-balance-sheet accounts. Two of these are trust services and correspondent banking. Trust Services The trust department of a commercial bank holds and manages assets for individuals or corporations. Only the largest banks have sufficient staff to offer trust services. Individual trusts represent about one-half of all trust assets managed by commercial banks. These trusts include estate assets and assets delegated to bank trust departments by less financially sophisticated investors. Pension fund assets are the second largest group of assets managed by the trust departments of commercial banks. The banks manage the pension funds, act as trustees for any bonds held by the pension funds, and act as transfer and disbursement agents for the pension funds. Chapter 2 Financial Services: Depository Institutions 39 Correspondent Banking Correspondent banking is the provision of banking services to other banks that do not have the staff resources to perform the service themselves. These services include check clearing and collection, foreign exchange trading, hedging services, and participation in large loan and security issuances. Correspondent banking services are generally sold as a package of services. Payment for the services is generally in the form of non-interest-bearing deposits held at the bank offering the correspondent services (see Chapter 16). Regulation The Regulators www.fdic.gov Unlike banks in countries that have one or sometimes two regulators, U.S. banks may be subject to the supervision and regulations of up to four separate regulators. The key regulators are the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC), the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency (OCC), the Federal Reserve System (FRS), and state bank regulators. Next, we look at the principal roles played by each regulator. Appendix 2C (located at the book’s website, www.mhhe.com/ saunders8e) lists in greater detail the regulators that oversee the various activities of depository institutions. The FDIC Because of the serious social welfare effects that a contagious run on depository institutions could have, the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC) has established guarantee programs offering deposit holders varying degrees of insurance protection to deter depositor “runs.” While a run on an unhealthy DI is not necessarily a bad thing, there is a risk that runs on bad DIs can become contagious and spread to good or well-run DIs. In a contagious run or panic conditions, liability holders do not bother to distinguish between good and bad DIs but, instead, seek to turn their liabilities into cash or safe securities as quickly as possible. Contagious runs can have a major contractionary effect on the supply of credit as well as the money supply regionally, nationally, or even internationally. Moreover, a contagious run on DIs can have serious social welfare effects. For example, a major run on banks can have an adverse effect on the level of savings in all types of FIs and therefore can inhibit the ability of individuals to transfer wealth through time to protect themselves against major risks such as future ill health and falling income in old age. However, if a deposit holder believes a claim is totally secure, even if the DI is in trouble, the holder has no incentive to run. Thus, FDIC deposit insurance deters runs as well as contagious runs and panics. To see how deposit insurance protects commercial banks from depositor runs, consider the case of Bear Stearns, an investment bank. In the summer of 2007, two Bear Stearns hedge funds suffered heavy losses on investments in the subprime mortgage market. The two funds filed for bankruptcy in the fall of 2007. Bear Stearns’ market value was hurt badly from these losses. The losses became so great that by March 2008 Bear Stearns was struggling to finance its day-to-day operations. Lacking of any kind of federal insurance of its liabilities, rumors of Bear Stearns’ liquidity crisis became a reality as investors began quickly selling their stock and draining what little liquid assets the firm had left; the first major run on a U.S. FI since the Great Depression. In contrast, during the financial crisis investors, looking for a “safer haven” for their money, deposited funds in FDIC-insured depository institutions. 40 Part One Introduction www.occ.treas.gov dual banking system The coexistence of both nationally chartered and state chartered banks in the United States. www.federalreserve.gov In exchange for insuring the deposits of member banks, the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation levies insurance premiums on member banks, manages the deposit insurance fund, and carries out bank examinations. Further, when an insured bank is closed, the FDIC acts as the receiver and liquidator—although the closure decision itself is technically in the hands of the bank chartering or licensing agency, such as the OCC. Because of the problems in the thrift industry and the insolvency of the savings association insurance fund (FSLIC) in 1989, the FDIC managed both the commercial bank insurance fund and the savings association insurance fund. In 2007, the two funds were combined into one, the Deposit Insurance Fund (DIF). The number of FDIC-insured banks and the division between nationally chartered and state chartered banks is shown in Figure 2–5. Office of the Comptroller of the Currency (OCC) The OCC is the oldest bank regulatory agency. Established in 1863, it is a subagency of the U.S. Treasury. Its primary function is to charter so-called national banks as well as to close them. In addition, the OCC examines national banks and has the power to approve or disapprove their merger applications. However, instead of seeking a national charter, banks can be chartered by any of 50 individual state bank regulatory agencies. The choice of being a nationally chartered or state chartered bank lies at the foundation of the dual banking system in the United States. While most large banks, such as Bank of America, choose national charters, this is not always the case. For example, Morgan Guaranty, the money center bank subsidiary of J.P. Morgan Chase, is chartered as a state bank under New York state law. In September 2012, 1,273 banks were nationally chartered and 4,895 were state chartered, with approximately 69 percent and 31 percent of total commercial bank assets, respectively. Federal Reserve System Apart from being concerned with the conduct of monetary policy, as this country’s central bank, the Federal Reserve also has regulatory power over some banks and, when relevant, their holding company parents. All of the 1,273 nationally chartered banks in Figure 2–5 are automatically members of FIGURE 2–5 Insured Commercial Banks (FDIC-DIF) 2012 Bank Regulators $13,069.9 billion in assets Source: FDIC (internal figures), September 2012. www.fdic.gov 6,168 in number 1,273 4,895 Nationally chartered (OCC) State-chartered 833 4,062 Members (FRS) Nonmembers (FDIC) Chapter 2 holding companies Parent companies that own a controlling interest in subsidiary banks or other FIs. Financial Services: Depository Institutions 41 the Federal Reserve system; 833 state-chartered banks also have chosen to become members. Since 1980, all banks have had to meet the same non-interest-bearing reserve requirements whether they are members of the Federal Reserve System (FRS) or not. The primary advantages of FRS membership are direct access to the federal funds wire transfer network for nationwide interbank borrowing and lending of reserves and to the discount window for lender of last resort borrowing of funds. Finally, many banks are often owned and controlled by parent holding companies. For example, Citigroup is the parent holding company of Citibank (a bank). Because the holding company’s management can influence decisions taken by a bank subsidiary and thus influence its risk exposure, the Federal Reserve System regulates and examines bank holding companies as well as banks. Regulations Because of the inherent special nature of banking and banking contracts (see Chapter 1), commercial banks are among the most regulated firms in the U.S. economy. Regulators have imposed numerous restrictions on their product and geographic activities. Table 2–8 lists the major laws from the McFadden Act of 1927 to the Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act of 2010 and briefly describes the key features of each act. TABLE 2–8 Major Bank Laws, Major Features 1927 The McFadden Act 1. Made branching of nationally chartered banks subject to the same branching regulations as state-chartered banks. 2. Liberalized national banks’ securities underwriting activities, which previously had to be conducted through state-chartered affiliates. 1933 The Banking Acts of 1933 1. The Glass-Steagall Act generally prohibited commercial banks from underwriting securities with four exceptions: a. Municipal general obligation bonds. b. U.S. government bonds. c. Private placements. d. Real estate loans. 2. In addition, the acts established the FDIC to insure bank deposits. 3. The Glass-Steagall Act prohibited banks from paying interest on demand deposits. 1956 The Bank Holding Company Act 1. Restricted the banking and nonbanking acquisition activities of multibank holding companies. 2. Empowered the Federal Reserve to regulate multibank holding companies by: a. Determining permissible activities. b. Exercising supervisory authority. c. Exercising chartering authority. d. Conducting bank examinations. 1970 Amendments to the Bank Holding Company Act of 1956 1. Extended the BHC Act of 1956 to one-bank holding companies. 2. Restricted permissible BHC activities to those “closely related to banking.” 1978 International Banking Act 1. Regulated foreign bank branches and agencies in the United States. 2. Subjected foreign banks to the McFadden and Glass-Steagall Acts. 3. Gave foreign banks access to Fedwire, the discount window, and deposit insurance. (continued) 42 Part One TABLE 2–8 (continued) Introduction 1980 Depository Institutions Deregulation and Monetary Control Act (DIDMCA) 1. Set a six-year phaseout for Regulation Q interest rate ceilings on small time and savings deposits. 2. Authorized NOW accounts nationwide. 3. Introduced uniform reserve requirements for state-chartered and nationally chartered banks. 4. Increased the ceiling on deposit insurance coverage from $40,000 to $100,000. 5. Allowed federally chartered thrifts to make consumer and commercial loans (subject to size restrictions). 1982 Garn–St. Germain Depository Institutions Act (DIA) 1. Introduced money market deposit accounts (MMDAs) and super NOW accounts as interest rate–bearing savings accounts with limited check-writing features. 2. Allowed federally chartered thrifts more extensive lending powers and demand deposit– taking powers. 3. Allowed sound commercial banks to acquire failed savings institutions. 4. Reaffirmed limitations on bank powers to underwrite and distribute insurance. 1987 Competitive Equality in Banking Act (CEBA) 1. Redefined the definition of a bank to limit the growth of nonbank banks. 2. Sought to recapitalize the Federal Savings and Loan Insurance Corporation (FSLIC). 1989 Financial Institutions Reform Recovery and Enforcement Act (FIRREA) 1. Limited savings banks’ investments in nonresidential real estate, required divestiture of junk bond holdings (by 1994), and imposed a restrictive asset test for qualifications as a savings institution (the qualified thrift lender [QTL] test). 2. Equalized the capital requirements of thrifts and banks. 3. Replaced the FSLIC with the FDIC-SAIF. 4. Replaced the Federal Home Loan Bank Board as the charterer of federal savings and loans with the Office of Thrift Supervision (OTS), an agency of the Treasury. 5. Created the Resolution Trust Corporation (RTC) to resolve failed and failing savings institutions. 1991 Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation Improvement Act (FDICIA) 1. Introduced prompt corrective action (PCA), requiring mandatory interventions by regulators whenever a bank’s capital falls. 2. Introduced risk-based deposit insurance premiums beginning in 1993. 3. Limited the use of too-big-to-fail bailouts by federal regulators for large banks. 4. Extended federal regulation over foreign bank branches and agencies in the Foreign Bank Supervision and Enhancement Act (FBSEA). 1994 Riegle-Neal Interstate Banking and Branching Efficiency Act 1. Permitted bank holding companies to acquire banks in other states, starting September 1995. 2. Invalidated the laws of states that allowed interstate banking only on a regional or reciprocal basis. 3. Beginning in June 1997, bank holding companies were permitted to convert out-of-state subsidiary banks into branches of a single interstate bank. 4. Newly chartered branches also permitted interstate if allowed by state law. 1999 Financial Services Modernization Act 1. Eliminated restrictions on banks, insurance companies, and securities firms entering into each others’ areas of business. Allowed for the creation of a financial services holding company. 2. Provided for state regulation of insurance. 3. Streamlined bank holding company supervision, with the Federal Reserve as the umbrella holding company supervisor. 4. Prohibited FDIC assistance to affiliates and subsidiaries of banks and savings institutions. 5. Provided for national treatment of foreign banks engaging in activities authorized under the act. (continued) Chapter 2 TABLE 2–8 (continued) nonbank banks Firms that undertake many of the activities of a commercial bank without meeting the legal definition of a bank. financial services holding company A financial institution that engages in banking activities and securities underwriting or any other financial activity. Financial Services: Depository Institutions 43 2010 Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act 1. Created the Financial Services Oversight Council that would look out for systemic risks at large FIs. 2. Gave the government power to break up FIs that provide a systemic risk to the financial system. 3. Created the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau to regulate products such as credit cards and mortgages. 4. Allowed Congress to order the Government Accountability Office to audit Federal Reserve activities. 5. Gave shareholders the right to a nonbinding proxy vote on corporate pay packages. 6. Required some over-the-counter derivatives be traded through clearinghouses to provide transparency of the value of trades. Even though we will go into greater detail about these regulations in later chapters (e.g., product and geographic diversification, Chapter 21), we now note the major objectives of each of these laws. The 1927 McFadden Act sought to restrict interstate bank branching, while the 1933 Glass-Steagall Act sought to separate commercial banking from investment banking by limiting the powers of commercial banks to engage in securities activities. Restrictions on the nonbank activities of commercial banks were strengthened by the Bank Holding Company Act of 1956 and its 1970 amendments, which limited the ability of a bank’s parent holding company to engage in commercial, insurance, and other nonbank financial service activities. The 1978 International Banking Act extended federal regulation, such as the McFadden and Glass-Steagall Acts, to foreign branches and agencies in the United States for the first time, thereby seeking to level the competitive playing field between domestic and foreign banks. The 1980 DIDMCA and the 1982 DIA are mainly deregulation acts in that they eliminated interest ceilings on deposits and gave banks (and thrifts) new liability and asset powers. As we discuss in the next section on thrifts, this deregulation is blamed in part for the thrift crisis that resulted in widespread failures and the insolvency of the FSLIC in 1989. The Competitive Equality in Banking Act (CEBA) of 1987 sought to impose controls over a growing number of nonbank banks that were established to get around interstate banking restrictions and restrictions on nonbank ownership of banks imposed under the 1927 McFadden and the 1956 Bank Holding Company Acts. In 1989 Congress responded to the problems of thrifts and the collapse of the FSLIC with the passage of the FIRREA. In 1991 Congress enacted the FDICIA to deal with a large number of bank failures and the threatened insolvency of the FDIC, the insurance fund for commercial banks. Both the FIRREA and FDICIA sought to pull back from some of the deregulatory elements of the 1980 DIDMCA and the 1982 DIA. In 1994 the Riegle-Neal Act rolled back many of the restrictions on interstate banking imposed by the 1927 McFadden and the 1956 Bank Holding Company Acts. In particular, since June 1997 bank holding companies have been permitted to convert their bank subsidiaries in various states into branches, thus making nationwide branching possible for the first time in 70 years. In 1999 the Financial Services Modernization Act repealed Glass-Steagall barriers between commercial banks and investment banks. The act allowed for the creation of a financial services holding company that could engage in banking activities and securities underwriting. In 2012, more than 750 banks qualified as financial services holding companies. This act also allows 44 Part One Introduction FI customers to opt out of any private information sharing an FI may want to pursue. Thus, FI customers have some control over who will see and have access to their private information. Finally, in 2010, the U.S. Congress passed the 2010 Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act which sought to prevent a repeat of the market meltdown of 2008. Touted as the most extensive proposal for the overhaul of financial rules since the Great Depression, this bill proposed a sweeping overhaul of the nation’s financial system and the rules that govern it. The bill set forth reforms to meet five key objectives: 1. Promote robust supervision and regulation of financial firms by establishing (a) a new Financial Services Oversight Council of financial regulators (chaired by Treasury and including the heads of the principal federal financial regulators as members) to identify emerging systemic risks and improve interagency cooperation, (b) a new authority for the Federal Reserve to supervise all firms that could pose a threat to financial stability, even those that do not own banks, (c) stronger capital and other prudential standards for all financial firms, and even higher standards for large, interconnected firms, (d) a new National Bank Supervisor to supervise all federally chartered banks, (e) the elimination of the federal thrift charter for thrifts not dedicated to mortgage lending and other loopholes that allowed some depository institutions to avoid bank holding company regulation by the Federal Reserve, and (f) the registration of advisers of hedge funds and other private pools of capital with the SEC. 2. Establish comprehensive supervision of financial markets by establishing (a) the regulation of securitization markets, including new requirements for market transparency, stronger regulation of credit rating agencies, and a requirement that issuers and originators retain a financial interest in securitized loans, (b) comprehensive regulation of all over-the-counter derivatives, and (c) new authority for the Federal Reserve to oversee payment, clearing, and settlement systems. 3. Protect consumers and investors from financial abuse by establishing (a) a new Consumer Financial Protection Bureau to protect consumers across the financial sector from unfair, deceptive, and abusive practices, (b) stronger regulations to improve the transparency, fairness, and appropriateness of consumer and investor products and services, and (c) a level playing field and higher standards for providers of consumer financial products and services, whether or not they are part of a bank. 4. Provide the government with the tools it needs to manage financial crises by establishing (a) a new regime to resolve nonbank financial institutions whose failure could have serious systemic effects and (b) revisions to the Federal Reserve’s emergency lending authority to improve accountability. 5. Raise international regulatory standards and improve international cooperation by establishing international reforms to support efforts in the U.S., including strengthening the capital framework; improving oversight of global financial markets; coordinating supervision of internationally active firms; and enhancing crisis management tools. Industry Performance Table 2–9 presents selected performance ratios for the commercial banking industry for various years from 1989 through 2012. With the economic expansion in the U.S. economy and falling interest rates throughout most of the 1990s, U.S. commercial banks flourished for most of that period. In 1999 commercial bank earnings were Chapter 2 TABLE 2–9 Financial Services: Depository Institutions 45 Selected Indicators for U.S. Commercial Banks, 1989 through 2012 Sources: FDIC, Quarterly Banking Profile, various issues; and Historical Statistics, 1989. www.fdic.gov 2012* 2010 2009 2008 2007 Number of institutions 6,168 6,530 6,840 7,086 7,283 Return on assets (%) 1.02 0.65 ⫺0.10 0.13 0.93 Return on equity (%) 9.06 5.86 ⫺0.93 1.33 9.12 Provision for loan losses to total assets (%) 0.30 1.21 1.94 1.30 0.54 Net charge-offs to loans (%) 1.17 2.67 2.60 1.32 0.62 Asset growth rate (%) 4.03 2.05 ⫺3.95 10.15 10.75 Net operating income growth (%) 11.94 1,088.1 ⫺137.98 ⫺80.48 ⫺21.21 Number of failed/ assisted institutions 34 139 120 25 2 2006 2003 2001 2000 1999 1989 7,450 7,769 8,079 8,315 8,580 12,709 1.33 1.40 1.15 1.19 1.31 0.49 13.02 15.34 13.09 14.07 15.31 7.71 0.26 0.47 0.67 0.47 0.38 0.94 0.41 11.63 0.89 7.42 0.95 4.91 0.64 8.79 0.61 5.37 1.16 5.38 11.19 14.92 ⫺1.89 0 3 3 2.02 20.42 ⫺38.70 6 7 206 * Through September. a record $71.6 billion. More than two-thirds of all U.S. banks reported a return on assets (ROA) of 1 percent or higher, and the average ROA for all banks was 1.31 percent, up from 1.19 percent for the year 1998.9 This, despite continued financial problems (or sovereign risk, see Chapter 14) in Southeast Asia, Russia, and South America. With the economic downturn in the early 2000s, however, bank performance deteriorated slightly. For example, commercial banks’ string of eight consecutive years of record earnings ended in 2000 as their net income fell to $71.2 billion. Banks’ provision for loan losses (or credit risk) rose to $9.5 billion in the fourth quarter of 2000, an increase of $3.4 billion (54.7 percent) from the level of a year earlier. This was the largest quarterly loss provision since the fourth quarter of 1991. Finally, the average ROA was 1.19 in 2000, down from 1.31 percent in 1999. This downturn was short-lived, however. In 2001, net income of $74.3 billion easily surpassed the old record of $71.6 billion, and net income rose further, to $106.3 billion, in 2003. Moreover, in 2003, both ROA and ROE (return on equity) reached all-time highs of 1.40 percent and 15.34 percent, respectively. The two main sources of earnings strength in 2003 were higher noninterest income (up $18.9 billion, 10.3 percent) and lower loan loss provisions (down $14.2 billion, or 27.6 percent). The greatest improvement in profitability occurred at large institutions, whose earnings had been depressed in the early 2000s by losses on loans to corporate borrowers and by weakness in market-sensitive noninterest revenue. Only 5.7 percent of all institutions were unprofitable in 2003, the lowest proportion since 1997. Several explanations have been offered for the strong performance of commercial banks during the early 2000s. First, the Federal Reserve cut interest rates 13 times during this period. Lower interest rates made debt cheaper to service and kept many households and small firms borrowing. Second, lower interest rates made home purchasing more affordable. Thus, the housing market boomed throughout the period. Third, the development of new financial instruments, such as credit derivatives and mortgage-backed securities, helped banks shift credit risk from their balance sheets to financial markets and other FIs such as insurance companies. Finally, improved information technology helped banks manage their risk better. 9 ROA is calculated as net income divided by the book value of total assets. It reflects the earnings per dollar of assets for the bank. ROE is calculated as net income divided by common equity of the bank and measures the return to the bank’s common stockholders. 46 Part One Introduction provision for loan losses Bank management’s recognition of expected bad loans for the period. net charge-offs Actual losses on loans and leases. net operating income Income before taxes and extraordinary items. As interest rates rose in the mid-2000s, performance did not deteriorate significantly. Third quarter 2006 earnings represented the second-highest quarterly total ever reported by the industry, and more than half of all banks reported higher earnings in the third quarter of 2006 than in the second quarter. However, increased loan loss provisions, reduced servicing income, and lower trading revenue kept net income reported by commercial banks from setting a new record for the full year. Rising funding costs outstripped increases in asset yields for a majority of banks. Further, mortgage delinquencies, particularly on subprime mortgages, surged in the last quarter of 2006 as homeowners who had stretched themselves financially to buy a home or refinance a mortgage in the early 2000s fell behind on their loan payments. Loan losses at banks in Louisiana, Mississippi, and Texas soared as businesses and consumers hit by Hurricanes Katrina and Rita defaulted on loans. Despite these weaknesses, the industry’s core capital ratio increased to 10.36 percent, the highest level since new, risk-based capital ratios were implemented in 1993. Finally, no FDIC-insured banks failed during 2005 or 2006. Both the number and assets of “problem” banks were at historical lows. The performance of the late 1990s and early and mid-2000s was quite an improvement from the recessionary and high interest rate conditions in which the industry operated in the late 1980s. As reported in Table 2–9, the average ROA and ROE for commercial banks in 2006 were 1.33 percent and 13.02 percent, respectively, compared with 1989 when the ROA and ROE averaged 0.49 percent and 7.71 percent, respectively. Provision for loan losses (bank management’s expectations of losses on the current loan portfolio) to assets ratio and net charge-offs (actual losses on loans and leases) to loans ratio averaged 0.26 percent and 0.41 percent, respectively, in 2006, versus 0.94 percent and 1.16 percent, respectively, in 1989. Net operating income (income before taxes and extraordinary items) grew at an annualized rate of 11.19 percent in 2006 versus a drop of 38.70 percent in 1989. Finally, note that in 2006 no U.S. commercial banks failed, versus 206 failures in 1989. In the late 2000s, the U.S. economy experienced its strongest recession since the Great Depression. Commercial banks’ performance deteriorated along with the economy. For all of 2007, net income was $105.5 billion, a decline of $39.8 billion (27.4 percent) from 2006. Less than half of all institutions (49.2 percent) reported increased earnings in 2007, the first time in 23 years that a majority of institutions had not posted full year earnings increases. The average ROA for the year was 0.93 percent, the lowest yearly average since 1991, and the first time in 15 years that the industry’s annual ROA had been below 1 percent. Sharply higher loss provisions and a very rare decline in noninterest income were primarily responsible for the lower industry profits. Things got even worse in 2008. Net income for all of 2008 was $10.2 billion, a decline of $89.8 billion (89.8 percent) from 2007. This was the lowest annual earnings total since 1989, when the industry earned $10.0 billion. The ROA for the year was 0.13 percent, the lowest since 1987. Almost one in four institutions (23.6 percent) was unprofitable in 2008, and almost two out of every three institutions (62.8 percent) reported lower full-year earnings than in 2007. Total noninterest income declined by $25.6 billion (11 percent) as a result of the industry’s first ever full-year trading loss ($1.8 billion), a $5.8 billion (27.4 percent) decline in securitization income, and a $6.6 billion drop in proceeds from sales of loans, foreclosed properties, and other assets. Net loan and lease charge-offs totaled $38.0 billion in the fourth quarter, an increase of $21.7 billion (132.7 percent) from the fourth quarter of 2007, the highest charge-off rate Chapter 2 net interest margin (NIM) Interest income minus interest expense divided by earning assets. Financial Services: Depository Institutions 47 in the 25 years that institutions have reported quarterly net charge-offs. Twenty commercial banks failed or were assisted during the year, the largest number of failed and assisted institutions in a year since 1993. At year-end, 252 institutions were on the FDIC’s “Problem List,” up from 76 institutions at the end of 2007. As the economy improved in the second half of 2009, so did commercial bank performance. While rising loan-loss provisions continued to dominate industry profitability, growth in operating revenues, combined with appreciation in securities values, helped the industry post an aggregate net profit. Commercial banks earned $2.8 billion in net income in the third quarter of 2009, more than three times the $879 million from 2008. Growth in net interest income, lower realized losses on securities and other assets, higher noninterest income, and lower noninterest expenses, all contributed to the year-over-year increase in net income. The average net interest margin (NIM, i.e., interest income minus interest expense divided by earning assets) in the third quarter was 3.51 percent, the highest quarterly average since the third quarter of 2005. Almost two-thirds of all institutions (62.1 percent) reported higher NIMs than in the second quarter. Realized losses on securities and other assets totaled $4.1 billion, which was $3.8 billion less than the $7.9 billion in losses the industry experienced a year earlier. Noninterest income was $4.0 billion (6.8 percent) higher than 2008 due to net gains on loan sales (up $2.7 billion) and servicing fees (up $1.9 billion). However, the industry was still feeling the effects of the long recession. Provisions for loan and lease losses totaled $62.5 billion, the fourth consecutive quarter that industry provisions had exceeded $60 billion. Net charge-offs continued to rise for an 11th consecutive quarter. Commercial banks charged off $50.8 billion in the quarter, an increase of $22.6 billion (80.5 percent) over the third quarter of 2008. Net charge-offs were higher than 2008 at 60 percent of all institutions. As a result, the full year 2009 ROA and ROE fell to ⫺0.10 and ⫺0.93, respectively. Further, 120 commercial banks failed in 2009. This is the largest number of failures since 1992. The number of commercial banks on the FDIC’s “Problem List” rose from 416 to 552 during the third quarter of 2009, and total assets of “problem” institutions increased from $299.8 billion to $345.9 billion. Both the number and assets of “problem” institutions were at the highest level since the end of 1993. As the economy continued to slowly recover in 2010 through 2012, so did bank performance. The 2010 industry ROA and ROE increased to 0.65 percent and 5.86 percent, respectively, the highest in three years. By 2012, industry ROA and ROE increased to 1.02 percent and 9.06 percent, respectively. In 2012, more than half (57.5 percent) of all institutions reported higher year-over-year net income, and only 10 percent reported negative net income (the lowest level in five years). Provisions for loan losses declined for a third consecutive year, and the amount of loans and leases that were noncurrent (90 days or more past due or in nonaccrual status) declined for 11 consecutive quarters. The number of institutions on the FDIC’s “Problem List” fell from 732 to 694, while assets of “problem” banks declined from $282.4 billion to $262.2 billion. This is the smallest number of “problem” institutions since third-quarter 2009. In addition to a changing economy, also certain to affect the future performance of commercial banks (as well as savings institutions and credit unions) is the extent to which banks adopt the newest technology (see Chapter 17), including the extent to which industry participants embrace the Internet and mobile banking. Appendix 2D (located at the book’s website, www.mhhe.com/saunders8e) provides a short summary of technology-based wholesale and retail services 48 Part One Introduction provided by banks and other FIs. The performance of banks that have invested in Internet banking as a complement to their existing services has been similar to the performance of those without Internet banking, despite relatively high initial technology-related expenses. In particular, banks that offer Internet banking services generally have higher noninterest income (which offsets any increased technology expenses). Further, the risk of banks offering Internet-related banking products appears to be similar to the risk of those banks without Internet banking. Concept Questions 1. What are the major assets held by commercial banks? 2. What are the major sources of funding for commercial banks? 3. Describe the responsibilities of the three federal regulatory agencies in the United States. 4. What are the major regulations that have affected the operations of U.S. commercial banks? 5. What has the trend in ROA and ROE been in the commercial banking industry over the last decade? SAVINGS INSTITUTIONS savings institutions Depository institutions that specialize in residential mortgages mostly backed by short-term deposits and other funds. Savings institutions were first created in the early 1800s in response to commercial banks’ concentration on serving the needs of business (commercial) enterprises rather than the needs of individuals requiring borrowed funds to purchase homes. Thus, the first savings institutions pooled individual savings and invested them mainly in mortgages and other securities. Today’s savings institutions, however, generally perform services similar to those of commercial banks. Savings institutions comprise two different groups of FIs: savings associations (SAs) and savings banks (SBs). They usually are grouped together because they not only provide important mortgage and/or lending services to households but also are important recipients of household savings. Historically, savings associations have concentrated more on residential mortgages, while savings banks have operated as relatively diversified savings institutions that have a large concentration of residential mortgage assets but hold some commercial loans, corporate bonds, and corporate stock as well. In this section, we review these two groups. Size, Structure, and Composition of the Industry Savings associations were historically referred to as savings and loans (S&Ls) associations. However, in the 1980s, federally chartered savings banks appeared in the United States. The term savings association has replaced “S&L association” to capture the resulting change in the structure of the industry.10 These institutions have the same regulators as traditional savings and loans. The savings association industry prospered throughout most of the 20th century. These specialized institutions made long-term residential mortgages backed 10 In 1978, the Federal Home Loan Bank Board (FHLBB), at the time the main regulator of savings associations, began chartering federal savings banks insured by the Federal Savings and Loan Insurance Corporation (FSLIC). In 1982, the FHLBB allowed S&Ls to convert to federal savings banks with bank (rather than S&L) names. As more and more S&Ls converted to savings banks, the title associated with this sector of the thrift industry was revised to reflect this change. Chapter 2 disintermediation Withdrawal of deposits from savings associations and other depository institutions and their reinvestment elsewhere. Regulation Q ceiling An interest ceiling imposed on small savings and time deposits at banks and thrifts until 1986. regulator forbearance A policy of not closing economically insolvent FIs, but allowing them to continue in operation. mutual organizations Savings banks in which the depositors are also the legal owners of the bank. Financial Services: Depository Institutions 49 by short-term savings deposits. At the end of the 1970s, slightly fewer than 4,000 savings associations had assets of approximately $0.6 trillion. Over the period October 1979 to October 1982, however, the Federal Reserve’s restrictive monetary policy action led to a sudden and dramatic surge in interest rates, with rates on T-bills rising as high as 16 percent. This increase in short-term rates and the cost of funds had two effects. First, savings associations faced negative interest spreads or net interest margins in funding much of their fixed-rate long-term residential mortgage portfolios over this period. Second, they had to pay more competitive interest rates on savings deposits to prevent disintermediation and the reinvestment of those funds in money market mutual fund accounts. Their ability to do this was constrained by the Federal Reserve’s Regulation Q ceilings, which limited the rates savings associations could pay on traditional passbook savings account and retail time deposits. In part to overcome the effects of rising rates and disintermediation on the savings association industry, Congress passed two acts, the DIDMCA and the DIA (see Table 2–8). These acts expanded the deposit-taking and asset-investment powers of savings associations. For many savings associations, the new powers created safer and more diversified institutions. For a small but significant group whose earnings and shareholders’ capital were being eroded in traditional lines of business, this created an opportunity to take more risks in an attempt to return to profitability. However, in the mid-1980s, real estate and land prices in Texas and the Southwest collapsed. This was followed by economic downturns in the Northeast and in western states of the United States. Many borrowers with mortgage loans issued by savings associations in these areas defaulted. In other words, the credit or lending risks incurred by savings associations in these areas often failed to pay off. This risk-taking, or moral hazard, behavior was accentuated by the policies of the savings association insurer, the FSLIC. Due to a lack of funds, the FSLIC could not close many of the capital-depleted, economically insolvent savings associations (a policy of regulator forbearance) and maintained deposit insurance premium assessments independent of the risk of the savings institution (see Chapter 19). As a result, there was an increasing number of failures in the 1982–89 period aligned with rapid asset growth of the industry. Thus, savings associations decreased in number from 4,000 in 1980 to 2,600 in 1989, or by 35 percent (however, their assets actually doubled from $600 billion to $1.2 trillion over that period). Traditionally, savings banks were established as mutual organizations (in which the depositors are also legally the owners of the bank) in states that permitted such organizations. These states were largely confined to the East Coast—for example, New York, New Jersey, and the New England states. As a result, savings banks (unlike savings associations) were not as affected by the oil-based economic shocks that impacted Texas and the Southwest in the 1980s. Nevertheless, the crash in New England real estate values in 1990–91 presented equally troubling problems for this group. Indeed, many of the failures of savings institutions in the early 1990s were savings banks rather than savings associations. As a result, savings banks have decreased in both size and number. Figure 2–6 shows the number of failures, mergers, and new charters of savings institutions from 1984 through 2012. Notice the large number of failures from 1987 through 1992 and the decline in the number of new charters. These failures, especially in 1988 and 1989, depleted the resources of the FSLIC to such an extent that by 1989 it was massively insolvent (see Chapter 19). Resulting legislation—the FIRREA of 1989—abolished the FSLIC and created a new insurance fund (SAIF) 50 Part One Introduction FIGURE 2–6 Structural Changes in the Number of Savings Institutions, 1984–2012 Source: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Quarterly Banking Profile, various years. www.fdic.gov Number 300 Failures Mergers New charters 250 200 150 100 50 0 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 Year QTL test Qualified thrift lender test that sets a floor on the mortgage related assets held by thrifts (currently 65 percent). under the management of the FDIC. In addition, the act created the Resolution Trust Corporation (RTC) to close the most insolvent savings associations.11 Further, the FIRREA strengthened the capital requirements of savings institutions and constrained their non-mortgage-related asset-holding powers under a newly imposed qualified thrift lender, or QTL, test. In 1991, Congress enacted the FDICIA. FDICIA introduced risk-based deposit insurance premiums (starting in 1993) in an attempt to limit excess risk taking by savings institutions. It also introduced a prompt corrective action (PCA) policy, such that regulators could close thrifts (and banks) faster (see Chapter 20). In particular, if a savings institution’s ratio of its equity capital to its assets falls below 2 percent, it has to be closed down or recapitalized within three months. As a result of the closing of weak savings institutions and the strengthening of capital requirements, the industry shrunk significantly, both in numbers and in asset size, in the 1990s. Savings institutions decreased in number from 3,677 in 1989 to 2,262 in 1993 (by 38 percent), and assets shrank from $1.427 trillion to $1.001 trillion (by 30 percent) over that same period. Balance Sheet and Recent Trends Even in its new streamlined state, concerns have been raised about the future viability of the savings institution industry in traditional mortgage lending areas. This is partly due to intense competition for mortgages from other financial 11 At the time of its dissolution in 1995, the RTC had resolved or closed more than 700 savings institutions, at an estimated cost of $200 billion to the U.S. taxpayers. Chapter 2 Financial Services: Depository Institutions 51 institutions, such as commercial banks and specialized mortgage bankers. It is also due to the securitization of mortgages into mortgage-backed security pools by government-sponsored enterprises, which we discuss further in Chapter 26.12 In addition, long-term mortgage lending exposes an FI to significant credit, interest rate, and liquidity risks. Table 2–10 shows the balance sheet of savings institutions in 2012. On this balance sheet, mortgages and mortgage-backed securities (securitized pools of mortgages) account for 65.63 percent of total assets. This compares with 27.31 percent in commercial banks. As noted earlier, the FDICIA uses the qualified thrift lender (QTL) test to establish a minimum holding of 65 percent in mortgage-related assets for savings institutions. Reflecting the enhanced lending powers established under the 1980 DIDMCA and the 1982 DIA, commercial loans and consumer loans amounted to 4.66 and 7.65 percent of assets, respectively, in 2012. Finally, savings institutions are required to hold cash and investment securities for liquidity risk purposes and to meet regulator-imposed reserve requirements. In September 2012, cash and U.S. Treasury securities holdings amounted to 10.14 percent of total assets, compared with 22.45 percent at commercial banks. On the liability side of the balance sheet, small time and savings deposits are still the predominant source of funds, with total deposits accounting for 76.48 percent of total liabilities and net worth. The second most important source of funds consists of borrowings from the Federal Home Loan Banks (FHLBs), of which there are 12. These banks in turn are owned by the savings institutions themselves. Because of their size and government-sponsored status, FHLBs have access to wholesale money markets and the capital market for notes and bonds TABLE 2–10 Assets and Liabilities of Savings Institutions, September 30, 2012 Source: FDIC, December 2012. www.fdic.gov Cash and due from U.S. Treasury securities Mortgage loans MBS (includes CMOs, POs, IOs) Bonds, notes, debentures, and other securities Commercial loans Consumer loans Other loans and financing leases Less: Allowance for loan losses and unearned income Other assets Millions of Dollars $ 110,454 6,398 517,525 239,214 59,130 53,730 88,192 17,609 (10,353) 71,181 Percent 9.58% 0.56 44.88 20.75 5.12 4.66 7.65 1.53 (0.90) 6.17 Total assets Total deposits Other borrowings Federal funds and repurchase agreements Other liabilities $1,153,080 $881,859 83,377 30,920 19,861 100.00% 76.48% 7.23 2.68 1.72 1,016,017 137,063 88.11 11.89 Total liabilities Net worth Total liabilities and net worth Number of institutions 12 The major enterprises are GNMA, FNMA, and FHLMC. $1,153,080 100.00% 1,013 52 Part One Introduction and can relend the funds borrowed on these markets to savings institutions at a small markup over wholesale cost. Other borrowed funds include repurchase agreements and direct federal fund borrowings. Finally, net worth, the book value of the equity holders’ capital contribution, amounted to 11.89 percent of total assets in 2012. This compares with 11.48 percent at commercial banks. Regulation The main regulators of savings institutions are the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency (OCC) and the FDIC. www.occ.gov The Office the Comptroller of the Currency In 1989 FIRREA established the Office of Thrift Supervision. This office chartered and examined all federal savings institutions. Further, when savings institutions were held by parent holding companies, the OTS supervised the holding companies as well. During the financial crisis the U.S. Congress determined that savings bank regulators performed relatively weakly compared with commercial bank regulators. Further, a Government Accountability Office report noted that some of the savings institutions regulated by the OTS were primarily operating in areas other than those traditionally engaged by thrifts, i.e., insurance, securities, and commercial activities. To address these concerns, the Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act mandated the consolidation of the Office of Thrift Supervision with the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency. As a result, the OTS became part of the OCC on July 21, 2011, and on October 19, 2011, the OTS ceased to exist. Thus, the OCC now regulates both national banks and federal savings institutions. Additionally, the bill did not eliminate the charter for savings institutions dedicated to mortgage lending, but did subject savings institution holding companies to supervision by the Federal Reserve. www.fdic.gov The FDIC-DIF Fund Also established in 1989 under the FIRREA and in the wake of the FSLIC insolvency, the FDIC oversaw and managed the Savings Association Insurance Fund (SAIF). In 1996, as part of a plan to recapitalize the SAIF, commercial banks were required to pay for part of the burden. In return, Congress promised to eventually merge bank and thrift charters (and hence insurance funds) into one. In January 2007, the FDIC merged the SAIF and the Bank Insurance Fund (BIF) to form the Deposit Insurance Fund (DIF). Thus, thrifts now operate under the same regulatory structure that applies to commercial banks. Other Regulators State-chartered savings institutions (the vast majority) are regulated by state agencies. Savings institutions that adopt federal charters are subject to the regulations of the OTS. Industry Performance Like commercial banks, savings institutions experienced record profits in the midto late-1990s as interest rates (and thus the cost of funds to savings institutions) remained low and the U.S. economy expanded. The result was an increase in the spread between interest income and interest expense for savings institutions and consequently an increase in their net income. In 1999, savings institutions reported $10.7 billion in net income and an annualized ROA of 1.00 percent (this compares Chapter 2 Financial Services: Depository Institutions 53 with an ROA of 1.31 percent over the same period for commercial banks). Only the $10.8 billion of net income reported in 1998 exceeded these results. Asset quality improvements were widespread during 1999, providing the most favorable net operating income that the industry had ever reported. However, as in the commercial banking industry, the downturn in the U.S. economy also resulted in a decline in savings institutions’ profitability in 2000. Specifically, their ROA and ROE ratios fell slightly in 2000 to 0.92 percent and 11.14 percent, respectively, from their 1999 levels. Again, as with commercial banks, despite an economic recession, this downturn was short-lived. Both ROA and ROE increased to record levels each year from 2001 through 2003. The industry’s net interest margins rose: the cost of funding earning assets declined by 2.70 percent while the yield on earning assets declined by only 2.35 percent. However, net charge-offs in 2003 were almost twice those in 2000. A flat yield curve and increased funding costs contributed to decreased margins in the mid-2000s. The average ROA declined to 1.15 percent in 2005 and 0.99 percent in 2006, while ROE decreased to 10.40 percent in 2005 and 8.68 percent in 2006. Table 2–11 presents several performance ratios for the industry for various years from 1989 through 2012. In the late 2000s, as the U.S. economy experienced its strongest recession since the Great Depression, savings institutions’ performance deteriorated. For all of 2007, net income was $6.0 billion, down $11.1 billion from 2006. The average ROA for the year was 0.13 percent, the lowest yearly average since 1989. In 2008, net income was ⫺$8.6 billion. This was the first negative earnings year since 1991. The ROA for the year was ⫺0.72 percent. However, only six savings institutions failed or were assisted during the year. In this group was Washington Mutual the largest savings institution, with over $300 billion in assets. At yearend, 18 savings institutions were on the FDIC’s “Problem List,” up from six institutions at the end of 2007. Like commercial banks, as the economy improved in the second half of 2009 through 2012, so did savings institution performance. Savings institutions earned $1.4 billion in net income in the third quarter of 2009, up from ⫺$18.3 million in the second quarter. This trend continued into 2010 as savings institutions earned $8.3 billion for the year, ROA for the industry was 0.65 percent, and ROE was 5.76 percent—up from 0.14 percent and 1.31 percent, TABLE 2–11 Selected Indicators for U.S. Savings Institutions, 1989 through 2012 Source: FDIC, Quarterly Banking Profile, various issues, and Historical Statistics, 1989. www.fdic.gov 2012* 2010 2009 2008 2007 2006 2005 2003 2001 2000 1999 1989 Number of institutions 1,013 1,128 1,172 1,219 1,251 1,279 1,307 1,413 1,535 1,590 1,642 3,677 Return on assets (%) 1.01 0.65 0.14 ⫺0.72 0.13 0.99 1.15 1.28 1.07 0.92 1.00 ⫺0.39 Return on equity (%) 8.61 5.76 1.31 ⫺7.75 1.08 8.68 10.40 13.66 12.33 11.14 11.73 ⫺8.06 Noncurrent assets plus other real estate owned to assets (%) 2.30 3.04 3.00 2.40 1.46 0.63 0.57 0.62 0.65 0.56 0.58 2.78 Asset growth rate (%) ⫺7.60 ⫺0.84 ⫺17.50 ⫺17.53 4.97 ⫺3.70 8.64 8.49 8.17 6.41 5.60 ⫺11.14 Net operating income growth (%) 35.69 273.16 120.37 ⫺456.80 ⫺81.68 ⫺9.84 8.03 23.07 6.64 3.55 16.70 ⫺58.95 Number of failed/ assisted institutions 9 18 20 6 1 0 0 0 1 1 1 331 * Through September. 54 Part One TABLE 2–12 Introduction U.S. Savings Institution Asset Concentration, 1992 versus 2012 Source: FDIC Quarterly Banking Profile, various issues. www.fdic.gov 2012 All FDIC-insured savings institutions 1. Under $100 million 2. $100 million–$1 billion 3. $1 billion–$10 billion 4. $10 billion or more 1992 Number Percent of Total Assets* Percent of Total 1,013 253 627 105 28 25.0% 61.9 10.4 2.7 $1,153.1 14.3 219.1 218.5 701.1 1.2% 19.0 19.0 60.8 Number 2,391 1,109 1,093 181 8 Percent of Total Assets* Percent of Total 46.4% 45.7 7.6 0.3 $1,035.2 55.9 315.3 479.5 184.5 5.4% 30.5 46.3 17.8 * In billions of dollars. respectively, in 2009. By 2012, the industry ROA was 1.01 percent and ROE was 8.61 percent. Further, 9 savings institutions failed in 2012, down from 20 in 2009 and 18 in 2010. Also like commercial banks, savings institutions experienced substantial consolidation in the 1990s. For example, the 1998 acquisition of H. F. Ahmanson & Co. by Washington Mutual Inc. for almost $10 billion was the fourth-largest bank–thrift merger completed in 1998.13 Washington Mutual was the third-largest savings institutions in the United States early in 1997, while Ahmanson was the largest savings institution. In 1997, Washington Mutual bought Great Western, to become the largest thrift in the country. Then, in March 1998, Washington Mutual bought Ahmanson to combine the two largest U.S. thrifts. However, as mentioned above, Washington Mutual became a victim of the mortgage market meltdown and was seized by regulators in September 2008. The bulk of the institution’s operations were sold to J.P. Morgan Chase. Table 2–12 shows the industry consolidation in number and asset size over the period 1992–2012. Notice that over this period, the biggest savings institutions (over $10 billion in assets) grew in number from 8 to 28 and their control of industry assets grew from 17.8 percent to 60.8 percent. Concept Questions 1. Are savings institutions likely to be more or less exposed to interest rate risk than are banks? Explain your answer. 2. How do adjustable-rate mortgages help savings institutions? 3. Why should savings institutions with little or no equity capital seek to take more risk than well-capitalized savings institutions? 4. Why could it be argued that the QTL test makes savings institutions more rather than less risky? 5. Describe the recent performance of savings institutions. 6. Describe the ways that profit trends for savings institutions have been similar to those of commercial banks in the 1990s through the 2010s. 13 Behind Travelers Group–Citigroup ($74 billion), NationsBank–BankAmerica ($67 billion), and BankOne– First Chicago NBD ($30 billion). Chapter 2 Financial Services: Depository Institutions 55 CREDIT UNIONS credit unions Nonprofit depository institutions, owned by members with a common bond, specializing in small consumer loans. Credit unions (CUs) are nonprofit depository institutions mutually organized and owned by their members (depositors). Credit unions (CUs) were first established in the United States in the early 1900s as self-help organizations intended to alleviate widespread poverty. The first credit unions were organized in the Northeast, initially in Massachusetts. Members paid an entrance fee and invested funds to purchase at least one deposit share in the CU. Members were expected to deposit their savings in the CU, and these funds were lent only to other members. This limit in the customer base of CUs continues today as, unlike commercial banks and savings institutions, CUs are prohibited from serving the general public. Rather, in organizing a credit union, members are required to have a common bond of occupation (e.g., police CUs) or association (e.g., university-affiliated CUs), or to cover a well-defined neighborhood, community, or rural district. CUs may, however, have multiple groups with more than one type of membership. The primary objective of credit unions is to satisfy the depository and lending needs of their members. CU member deposits (shares) are used to provide loans to other members in need of funds. Any earnings from these loans are used to pay higher rates on member deposits, charge lower rates on member loans, or attract new members to the CU. Because credit unions do not issue common stock, the members are legally the owners of a CU. Also, because credit unions are nonprofit organizations, their net income is not taxed and they are not subject to the local investment requirements established under the 1977 Community Reinvestment Act. This tax-exempt status allows CUs to offer higher rates on deposits, and charge lower rates on some types of loans, than do banks and savings institutions. This is shown in Figure 2–7 for the period 1991–2012. Size, Structure, and Composition of the Industry Credit unions are the most numerous of the institutions that make up the depository institutions segment of the FI industry, totaling 7,219 in 2012. Moreover, they were less affected by the crises that impacted commercial banks and savings institutions in the 1980s and late 2000s14 because traditionally, more than 40 percent of their assets have been in the form of small consumer loans, often for amounts less than $10,000. In addition, CUs tend to hold large amounts of government securities (19.9 percent of their assets in 2012) and relatively small amounts of residential mortgages. Their lending activities are funded by savings deposits contributed by more than 95 million members who share some common thread or bond of association, usually geographic or occupational in nature. As a result, in 2008 at the height of the financial crisis, while commercial banks’ and savings institutions’ average ROAs were 0.13 and ⫺0.72 percent, respectively, credit unions saw an average ROA of 0.31 percent. To attract and keep customers, CUs have had to expand their services to compete with those of commercial banks and savings institutions. For example, CUs now offer products and services ranging from mortgages and auto loans (their traditional services) to credit lines and mobile banking. Some credit unions now offer business 14 Credit unions have been covered by federal deposit insurance guarantees since 1971 (under the National Credit Union Share Insurance Fund). The depositor coverage cap of $250,000 is the same as that which currently exists for both commercial banks and savings institutions. 56 Part One Introduction FIGURE 2–7 Credit Union versus Bank Interest Rates Source: National Credit Union Administration, December 2012. www.ncua.gov 12% New Car Loans 10 Banks 8 Credit unions 6 Credit unions 4 Banks 1-Year CDs 2 1991 1993 www.aba.com 1995 1997 1999 2001 Year 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 and commercial loans to their employer groups. For example, in 2012, business loans represented 5.1 percent of the industry’s lending. Because of their tax-exempt status, CUs can charge lower rates on these loans, providing CUs with a cost advantage over banks and savings institutions that is very attractive to customers. As CUs have expanded in number, size, and services, bankers have claimed that CUs are unfairly competing with small banks that have historically been the major lenders in small towns. For example, the American Bankers Association has stated that the tax exemption for CUs gives them the equivalent of a $1 billion per year subsidy. The Credit Union National Association’s (CUNA) response is that any cost to taxpayers from CUs’ tax-exempt status is more than made up in benefits to members and therefore the social good they create. CUNA estimates that the benefits of CU membership can range from $200 to $500 a year per member or, with more than 95 million members, a total benefit of $19 billion to $47.5 billion per year. In 1997 the banking industry filed two lawsuits in its push to narrow the widening membership rules governing credit unions that followed a 1982 legal interpretation of the original 1934 Federal Credit Union Act’s definition of what constitutes a “group having a common bond of occupation or association.” The first lawsuit (filed by four North Carolina banks and the American Bankers Association) challenged the ability of an occupation-based credit union (the AT&T Family Credit Union based in North Carolina) to accept members from companies unrelated to the firm that originally sponsored the CU. In the second lawsuit, the American Bankers Association asked the courts to bar the federal government from letting Chapter 2 Financial Services: Depository Institutions 57 occupation-based credit unions convert to community-based charters. Bankers argued in both lawsuits that such actions, broadening the membership of credit unions under other than occupation-based guidelines, would further exploit an unfair advantage allowed by the credit unions’ tax-exempt status. In February 1998 the Supreme Court sided with banks, stating that credit unions could no longer accept members who did not share the common bond of membership. In April 1998, however, the U.S. House of Representatives overwhelmingly passed a bill that allowed all existing members to keep their credit union accounts. The bill was passed by the Senate in July 1998 and signed into law by the president in August 1998. This legislation allowed CUs not only to keep their existing members but also to accept new groups of members—including small businesses and low income communities—that were not considered part of the “common bond” of membership by the Supreme Court ruling. In another hit to commercial banks, credit unions saw record increases in membership in late 2011 and early 2012, with most of the increase coming from commercial bank customers. For the year ending June 30, 2012, credit union membership increased by nearly 2.2 million new members: almost twice the 1.2 million average annual growth experienced in similar 12-month periods over the previous 10 years and four times greater than the 550,000 new members over that same period the prior year. Much of the growth in membership occurred as a part of nationwide campaigns—such as Bank Transfer Day on November 5, 2011—that encouraged consumers to leave their “big” banks for credit unions and community banks, which tend to incur fewer fees. Among the catalysts for these campaigns was Bank of America’s plan to impose a monthly fee for debit card use. The plan was scrapped after seeing the strong negative reactions from consumers. Balance Sheet and Recent Trends Table 2–13 shows the assets and liabilities for credit unions in June 2012. In that year 7,219 credit unions had assets of $1,012.8 billion. This compares with $155 billion in assets in 1987. Individually, credit unions tend to be very small, with an average size of $140.3 million in 2012 compared with $2,112.8 million for banks. The total assets of all credit unions are less than half the size of those of the largest U.S. banking organization, J.P. Morgan Chase. Given their emphasis on retail or consumer lending, discussed above, 23.8 percent of CU assets are in the form of small consumer loans and another 28.1 percent are in the form of home mortgages. Together, these member loans constitute 51.9 percent of total assets. Because of the common bond requirement on credit union customers, relatively few business or commercial loans are issued by CUs. Credit unions also invest heavily in investment securities (28.3 percent of total assets in 2012). Further, 70.2 percent of the investment portfolios of CUs are in U.S. government Treasury securities or federal agency securities. Their investment portfolio composition, along with their cash holdings (9.5 percent of total assets), allow credit unions ample liquidity to meet their daily cash needs—such as share (deposit) withdrawals. Some CUs have also increased their off-balance-sheet activities. Specifically, unused loan commitments, including credit card limits and home equity lines of credit, totaled more than $152 billion in 2012. Credit union funding comes mainly from member deposits (85.9 percent of total funding in 2012). Figure 2–8 presents the distribution of these deposits in 2012. Regular share draft transaction accounts (similar to NOW accounts at other depository institutions) accounted for 32.3 percent of all CU deposits, followed 58 Part One Introduction TABLE 2–13 Assets and Liabilities of Credit Unions, September 2012 Source: National Credit Union Administration, December 2012. www.ncua.gov Billions of Dollars Assets Cash and equivalents Investment securities: U.S. government securities Treasury Agency Mortgage-backed securities Other investment securities $ 95.7 Percentage 9.5% 11.6 190.0 49.7 35.9 1.1 18.8 4.9 3.5 Total investment securities 287.2 28.3 Loans: Home mortgages Consumer loans Business loans Other (Allowance for loan losses) 285.0 241.4 40.8 23.9 (8.3) 28.1 23.8 4.0 2.4 (0.8) Total loans 582.8 57.5 47.1 Other assets 4.7 Total assets $1,012.8 100.0% Liabilities and Equity Share drafts Small time and savings Large time $ 109.7 687.0 73.0 10.8% 67.9 7.2 Shares/deposits $ 869.7 85.9% Other loans and advances Miscellaneous liabilities 26.3 12.0 2.6 1.2 Total liabilities $ 908.0 89.7% Total ownership shares $ 104.8 10.3% FIGURE 2–8 Composition of Credit Union Deposits, 2012 Regular shares 32.3% CDs 23.2% Source: Credit Union National Association, Credit Union Report Mid-Year 2012. www.cuna.org Money market shares 22.8% IRAs and Keogh accounts 9.1% Share drafts 12.6% by certificates of deposits (23.2 percent of deposits), money market accounts (22.8 percent of deposits) and share drafts (similar to passbook savings accounts at other depository institutions, but so named to designate the deposit holders’ ownership status) (12.6 percent of deposits). Credit unions hold lower levels of Chapter 2 Financial Services: Depository Institutions 59 equity than other depository institutions. Since CUs are not stockholder owned, this equity is basically the accumulation of past profits from CU activities that are “owned” collectively by member depositors. As we will discuss in Chapters 7 and 20, this equity protects a CU against losses on its loan portfolio as well as against other financial and operating risks. However, these risks are generally lower for credit unions than commercial banks and savings institutions. In June 2012, CUs’ capital-to-assets ratio was 10.35 percent compared with 11.89 percent for savings institutions and 11.48 percent for commercial banks. Regulation www.ncua.gov www.cuna.org Like commercial banks and savings institutions, credit unions can be federally or state chartered. As of 2012, 60.5 percent of the 7,219 CUs were federally chartered and subject to National Credit Union Administration (NCUA) regulation, accounting for 54.0 percent of the total credit union membership and 53.5 percent of total assets. In addition, through its insurance fund (the National Credit Union Share Insurance Fund, or NCUSIF), the NCUA provides deposit insurance guarantees of up to $250,000 for insured credit unions. Currently, the NCUSIF covers 98 percent of all credit union deposits. Industry Performance Like other depository institutions, the credit union industry grew in asset size in the 1990s and 2000s. Asset growth from 1999 to 2012 was more than 7.5 percent annually. In addition, CU membership increased from 77.5 million to over 95.3 million over the 1999–2012 period. Asset growth was especially pronounced among the largest CUs (with assets of more than $500 million) as their assets increased by 20 percent annually from 1999 through 2012. Figure 2–9 shows FIGURE 2–9 Return on Assets for Credit Unions, 1993 through 2012 Source: National Credit Union Association, Year-End Statistics, 2013. www.ncua.gov ROA (%) 1.4 1.2 1.0 0.8 0.6 0.4 0.2 0.0 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 Year 60 Part One Introduction the trend in ROA for CUs from 1993 through 2012. The decrease in ROA over the period is mostly attributed to earnings decreases at the smaller CUs. For example, the largest credit unions experienced an ROA of 0.95 percent in the first six months of 2012, while for the smallest CUs (with assets of less than $5 million) the ROA was ⫺0.11 percent. ROA for the whole industry was 0.84 percent. Smaller CUs generally have a smaller customer base with which to issue quality loans and have higher overhead expenses per dollar of assets. Thus, their ROAs have been hurt. Given the mutual-ownership status of this industry, however, growth in ROA (or profits) is not necessarily the primary goal of CUs. Rather, as long as capital or equity levels are sufficient to protect a CU against unexpected losses on its credit portfolio as well as other financial and operational risks, this not-for-profit industry has a primary goal of serving the deposit and lending needs of its members. This contrasts with the emphasis placed on profitability by stockholder-owned commercial banks and savings institutions. Concept Questions 1. How do credit unions differ from commercial banks and savings institutions? 2. Why did credit unions prosper in the 1980s and late 2000s compared with commercial banks and savings institutions? 3. What is the major asset held by credit unions? 4. Why do commercial banks and savings institutions claim that credit unions have an unfair advantage in providing bank services? GLOBAL ISSUES: THE FINANCIAL CRISIS £ ¥ :$ Soon after it hit the United States, the financial crisis spread worldwide. As the crisis quickly spread, banks worldwide saw losses driven by their portfolios of structured finance products and securitized exposures to the subprime mortgage market. Losses were magnified by illiquidity in the markets for those instruments. As with U.S. banks, this led to substantial losses in their marked-to-market valuations. In Europe, the general picture of bank performance in 2008 was similar to that in the United States. That is, net income fell sharply at all banks. The largest banks in the Netherlands, Switzerland, and the United Kingdom had net losses for the year. Banks in Ireland, Spain, and the United Kingdom were especially hard hit as they had large investments in mortgages and mortgage-backed securities, both U.S. and domestic. Because they focused on domestic retail banking, French and Italian banks were less affected by losses on mortgage-backed securities. Continental European banks, in contrast to U.K. banks, partially cushioned losses through an increase in their net interest margins. A number of European banks averted outright bankruptcy thanks to direct support from their central banks and national governments. During the last week of September and first week of October 2008, the German government guaranteed all consumer bank deposits and arranged a bailout of Hypo Real Estate, the country’s second largest commercial property lender. The United Kingdom nationalized mortgage lender Bradford & Bingley (the country’s eighth largest mortgage lender) and raised deposit guarantees from $62,220 to $88,890 per account. Ireland guaranteed deposits and debt of its six major financial institutions. Iceland rescued its third largest bank with an $860 million purchase of 75 percent of the Chapter 2 Financial Services: Depository Institutions 61 bank’s stock and a few days later seized the country’s entire banking system. The Netherlands, Belgium, and Luxembourg central governments together agreed to inject $16.37 billion into Fortis NV (Europe’s first ever cross-border financial services company) to keep it afloat. However, five days later this deal fell apart, and the bank was split up. The Dutch bought all assets located in the Netherlands for approximately $23 billion. The central bank in India stepped in to stop a run on the country’s second largest bank, ICICI Bank, by promising to pump in cash. Central banks in Asia injected cash into their banking systems as banks’ reluctance to lend to each other led the Hong Kong Monetary Authority to inject liquidity into its banking system after rumors led to a run on Bank of East Asia Ltd. South Korean authorities offered loans and debt guarantees to help small and midsize businesses with short-term funding. The United Kingdom, Belgium, Canada, Italy, and Ireland were just a few of the countries to pass an economic stimulus plan and/or bank bailout plan. The Bank of England lowered its target interest rate to a record low of 1 percent, hoping to help the British economy out of a recession. The Bank of Canada, Bank of Japan, and Swiss National Bank also lowered their main interest rate to 1 percent or below. All of these actions were a result of the spread of the U.S. financial market crisis to world financial markets. However, the worldwide economic slowdown experienced in the later stages of the crisis meant that bank losses have become more closely connected to macroeconomic performance. Countries across the world saw companies scrambling for credit and cutting their growth plans. Additionally, consumers worldwide reduced their spending. Even China’s booming economy slowed more than had been predicted, from 10.1 percent in the second quarter of 2008 to 9 percent in the third quarter. This was the first time since 2002 that China’s growth was below 10 percent and dimmed hopes that Chinese demand could help keep world economies growing. In late October, the global crisis hit the Persian Gulf as Kuwait’s central bank intervened to rescue Gulf Bank, the first bank rescue in the oil rich Gulf. Until this time, the area had been relatively immune to the world financial crisis. However, plummeting oil prices (which had dropped over 50 percent between July and October 2008) left the area’s economies vulnerable. In this period, the majority of bank losses were more directly linked to a surge in borrower defaults and to anticipated defaults as evidenced by the increase in the amount and relative importance of loan loss provision expenses. International banks’ balance sheets continued to shrink during the first half of 2009 (although at a much slower pace than in the preceding six months) and, as in the United States, began to recover in the latter half of the year. In the fall of 2009, a steady stream of mostly positive macroeconomic news reassured investors that the global economy had turned around, but investor confidence remained fragile. For example, in late November 2009, security prices worldwide dropped sharply as investors reacted to news that government-owned Dubai World had asked for a delay in some payments on its debt. Further, throughout the spring of 2010, Greece struggled with a severe debt crisis. Early on, some of the healthier European countries tried to step in and assist the debt-ridden country. Specifically, in March 2010, a plan led by Germany and France to bail out Greece with as much as $41 billion in aid began to take shape. However, in late April 2010, Greek bond prices dropped dramatically as traders began betting a debt default was inevitable, even if the country received a massive bailout. The sell-off was the result of still more bad news for Greece, which showed that the 2009 budget deficit was worse than had been previously reported, and as a 62 Part One Introduction result, politicians in Germany began to voice opposition to a Greek bailout. Further, Moody’s Investors Service downgraded Greece’s debt rating and warned that additional cuts could be on the way. Greece’s debt created heavy losses across the Greek banking sector. A run on Greek banks ensued. Initially, between :100 and :500 million per day was being withdrawn from Greek banks. At its peak, the run on Greek banks produced deposit withdrawals of as high as :750 million a day, nearly 0.5 percent of the entire :170 billion deposit base in the Greek banking system. Problems in the Greek banking system then spread to other European nations with fiscal problems, such as Portugal, Spain, and Italy. The risk of a full-blown banking crisis arose in Spain, where the debt rating of 16 banks and four regions were downgraded by Moody’s Investors Service. Throughout Europe, some of the biggest banks announced billions of euros lost from write-downs on Greek loans. In 2011, Crédit Agricole reported a record quarterly net loss of :3.07 billion ($4.06 billion U.S.) after a :220 million charge on its Greek debt. Great Britain’s Royal Bank of Scotland revalued its Greek bonds at a 79 percent loss—or £1.1 billion ($1.7 billion U.S.)—for 2011. Germany’s Commerzbank’s fourth-quarter 2011 earnings decreased by :700 million due to losses on Greek sovereign debt. The bank needed to find :5.3 billion to meet the stricter new capital requirements set by Europe’s banking regulator. Bailed-out Franco-Belgian bank Dexia warned it risked going out of business due to losses of :11.6 billion from its break-up and exposure to Greek debt and other toxic assets such as U.S. mortgage-backed securities. Even U.S. banks were affected by the European crisis. In late 2010, U.S. banks had sovereign risk exposure to Greece totaling $43.1 billion. In addition, exposures to Ireland totaled $113.9 billion, to Portugal totaled $47.1 billion, and to Spain totaled $187.5 billion. Worldwide, bank exposure to these four countries totaled $2,512.3 billion. Default by a small country like Greece cascaded into something that threatened the world’s financial system. Worried about the effect a Greek debt crisis might have on the European Union, other European countries tried to step in and assist Greece. On May 9, 2010, in return for huge budget cuts, Europe’s finance ministers and the International Monetary Fund approved a rescue package worth $147 billion and a “safety net” of $1 trillion aimed at ensuring financial stability across Europe. Through the rest of 2010 and into 2012, eurozone leaders agreed on more measures designed to prevent the collapse of Greece and other member economies. In return, Greece continued to offer additional austerity reforms and agreed to reduce its budget deficits. At times, the extent of these reforms and budget cuts led to worker strikes and protests (some of which turned violent), as well as changes in Greek political leadership. In December 2011, the leaders of France and Germany agreed on a new fiscal pact that they said would help prevent another debt crisis. French President Nicolas Sarkozy outlined the basic elements of the plan to increase budget discipline after meeting with German Chancellor Angela Merkel in Paris. The pact, which involved amending or rewriting the treaties that govern the European Union, was presented in detail at a meeting of European leaders and approved. Efforts by the EU and reforms enacted by the Greek and other European country governments appear to have worked. As of December 18, 2012, Standard & Poor’s raised its rating on Greek debt by six notches to B minus from selective default. S&P cited a strong and clear commitment from members of the eurozone to keep Greece in the common currency bloc as the main reason for the upgrade. Financial Services: Depository Institutions 63 Summary This chapter provided an overview of the major activities of commercial banks, savings institutions, and credit unions. It also described the agencies that regulate these depository institutions. The Federal Reserve System, the FDIC, the OTS, and the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency, in conjunction with state regulators, are the agencies that oversee the activities of these institutions. Each of these institutions relies heavily on deposits to fund its activities, although borrowed funds are becoming increasingly important for the largest institutions. Historically, commercial banks have concentrated on commercial or business lending and on investing in securities, while savings institutions have concentrated on mortgage lending and credit unions have concentrated on consumer lending. These differences are being eroded as a result of competitive forces, regulation, and changing financial and business technology. Questions and Problems 1. What are the differences between community banks, regional banks, and money center banks? Contrast the business activities, location, and markets of each of these bank groups. 2. Use the data in Table 2–5 for banks in the two asset size groups (a) $100 million–$1 billion and (b) more than $10 billion to answer the following questions. a. Why have the ratios for ROA and ROE tended to increase for both groups over the 1990–2006 period, decrease in 2007–2009, and increase in 2010–2012? Identify and discuss the primary variables that affect ROA and ROE as they relate to these two size groups. b. Why is ROA for the smaller banks generally larger than ROA for the large banks? c. Why is the ratio for ROE consistently larger for the large bank group? d. Using the information on ROE decomposition in Appendix 2A, calculate the ratio of equity to total assets for each of the two bank groups for the period 1990–2012. Why has there been such dramatic change in the values over this time period, and why is there a difference in the size of the ratio for the two groups? 3. What factors caused the decrease in loan volume relative to other assets on the balance sheets of commercial banks? How has each of these factors been related to the change and development of the financial services industry during the 1990s and 2000s? What strategic changes have banks implemented to deal with changes in the financial services environment? 4. What are the major uses of funds for commercial banks in the United States? What are the primary risks to a bank caused by each of these? Which of the risks is most critical to the continuing operation of a bank? 5. What are the major sources of funds for commercial banks in the United States? How is the landscape for these funds changing and why? 6. What are the three major segments of deposit funding? How are these segments changing over time? Why? What strategic impact do these changes have on the profitable operation of a bank? 7. How does the liability maturity structure of a bank’s balance sheet compare with the maturity structure of the asset portfolio? What risks are created or intensified by these differences? www.mhhe.com/saunders8e Chapter 2 64 Part One Introduction 8. The following balance sheet accounts (in millions of dollars) have been taken from the annual report for a U.S. bank. Arrange the accounts in balance sheet order and determine the value of total assets. Based on the balance sheet structure, would you classify this bank as a community bank, regional bank, or money center bank? Premises Savings deposits Cash NOW accounts Long-term debt Other assets Intangible assets www.mhhe.com/saunders8e Other time deposits $ 1,078 3,292 2,660 12,816 1,191 1,633 758 2,333 Net loans Short-term borrowing Other liabilities Equity Investment securities Demand deposits Certificates of deposit (under $100,000) Federal funds sold $29,981 2,080 778 3,272 5,334 5,939 9,853 110 9. What types of activities are normally classified as off-balance-sheet (OBS) activities? a. How does an OBS activity move onto the balance sheet as an asset or liability? b. What are the benefits of OBS activities to a bank? c. What are the risks of OBS activities to a bank? 10. Use the data in Table 2–7 to answer the following questions. a. What was the average annual growth rate in OBS total commitments over the period 1992–2012? b. What categories of contingencies have had the highest annual growth rates? c. What factors are credited for the significant growth in derivative securities activities by banks? 11. For each of the following banking organizations, identify which regulatory agencies (OCC, FRB, FDIC, or state banking commission) may have some regulatory supervision responsibility: a. State-chartered, nonmember non–holding company bank. b. State-chartered, nonmember holding company bank. c. State-chartered member bank. d. Nationally chartered non–holding company bank. e. Nationally chartered holding company bank. 12. What are the main features of the Riegle-Neal Interstate Banking and Branching Efficiency Act of 1994? What major impact on commercial banking activity occured from this legislation? 13. What factors normally are given credit for the revitalization of the banking industry during the 1990s? How is Internet banking expected to provide benefits in the future? 14. What factors are given credit for the strong performance of commercial banks in the early and mid-2000s? 15. What factors are given credit for the weak performance of commercial banks in the late 2000s? 16. How do the asset and liability structures of a savings institution compare with the asset and liability structures of a commercial bank? How do these structural differences affect the risks and operating performance of a savings institution? What is the QTL test? Chapter 2 Financial Services: Depository Institutions 65 17. How do savings banks differ from savings associations? Differentiate in terms of risk, operating performance, balance sheet structure, and regulatory responsibility. 18. What happened in 1979 to cause the failure of many savings institutions during the early 1980s? What was the effect of this change on the operating statements of savings institutions? 19. How did two pieces of regulatory legislation—the DIDMCA in 1980 and the DIA in 1982—change the operating profitability of savings institutions in the early 1980s? What impact did these pieces of legislation ultimately have on the risk posture of the savings institutions industry? How did the FSLIC react to this change in operating performance and risk? 20. How did the Financial Institutions Reform, Recovery, and Enforcement Act (FIRREA) of 1989 and the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation Improvement Act of 1991 reverse some of the key features of earlier legislation? 21. What is the “common bond” membership qualification under which credit unions have been formed and operated? How does this qualification affect the operational objective of a credit union? 22. What are the operating advantages of credit unions that have caused concern among commercial bankers? What has been the response of the Credit Union National Association to the banks’ criticism? 23. How does the asset structure of credit unions compare with the asset structure of commercial banks and savings institutions? Refer to Tables 2–6, 2–10, and 2–13 to formulate your answer. 24. Compare and contrast the performance of worldwide depository institutions during and after the financial crisis. The questions and problems that follow refer to Appendix 2B. 25. The financial statements for First National Bank (FNB) are shown below: Assets Cash Demand deposits from other FIs Investments Federal funds sold Loans Reserve for loan losses Premises Total assets $ 450 1,350 4,050 2,025 15,525 (1,125) 1,685 $23,960 Liabilities and Equity Demand deposits Small time deposits Jumbo CDs Federal funds purchased Equity $ 5,510 10,800 3,200 2,250 2,200 Total liabilities/equity $23,960 _______ Income Statement - First National Bank Interest Income Interest expense Provision for loan losses Noninterest income Noninterest expense Taxes $2,600 1,650 180 140 420 90 www.mhhe.com/saunders8e Balance Sheet - First National Bank 66 Part One Introduction a. Calculate the dollar value of FNB’s earning assets. b. Calculate FNB’s ROA. c. Calculate FNB’s asset utilization ratio. d. Calculate FNB’s spread. 26. Megalopolis Bank has the following balance sheet and income statement. Balance Sheet (in millions) Assets Cash and due from banks Investment securities Repurchase agreements Loans Fixed Assets Other assets Total assets $ 9,000 23,000 42,000 90,000 15,000 4,000 $183,000 Liabilities and Equity Demand deposits NOW accounts Retail CDs Debentures Total liabilities Common stock Paid in capital Retained earnings Total liabilities and equity Income Statement www.mhhe.com/saunders8e Interest on fees and loans Interest on investment securities Interest on repurchase agreements Interest on deposits in banks Total interest income Interest on deposits Interest on debentures Total interest expense Operating income Provision for loan losses Other income Other expenses Income before taxes Taxes Net income For Megalopolis, calculate: a. b. c. d. e. f. g. h. i. Return on equity Return on assets Asset utilization Equity multiplier Profit margin Interest expense ratio Provision for loan loss ratio Noninterest expense ratio Tax ratio $ 9,000 4,000 6,000 1,000 $20,000 9,000 2,000 $11,000 $ 9,000 2,000 2,000 1,000 $ 8,000 3,000 $ 5,000 $ 19,000 89,000 28,000 19,000 $155,000 12,000 4,000 12,000 $183,000 Chapter 2 Financial Services: Depository Institutions 67 Web Questions 27. Go to the FDIC website at www.fdic.gov and find the most recent breakdown of U.S. bank asset concentrations using the following steps. Click on “Analysts.” From there click On “FDIC Quarterly Banking Profile” and then click on “Quarterly Banking Profile.” Click on “Commercial Bank Section.” Then click on “TABLE III-A. Full Year (or First XXX Quarters) 20XX, FDICInsured Commercial Banks.” This will bring the files up on your computer that contain the relevant data. How have the number and dollar value of assets held by commercial banks changed since 2012? 28. Go to the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation website at www.fdic.gov and find the latest balance sheet information available for savings institutions using the following steps. Click on “Analysts.” Click on “Statistics on Banking.” Select “Savings Institutions,” then click on “Run Report.” This will download a file on to your computer that will contain the most recent balance sheet information for savings institutions. Using information in this file, update Table 2–10. How have the assets and liabilities of credit unions changed since 2012? 29. Go to the National Credit Union Administration website at www.ncua.gov to collect the most recent information on number of credit unions, assets of credit unions, and membership in credit unions using the following steps. Click on “Regulations, Publications and Reports.” Under “Reports, Plans, & Presentations,” click on “Industry At a Glance (IAG).” Click on the most recent date. This will download a file onto your computer that will contain the necessary data. How have these data changed since 2012? Appendix 2A: Financial Statement Analysis Using a Return on Equity (ROE) Framework View Appendix 2A at the website for this textbook (www.mhhe.com/saunders8e). View Appendix 2B at the website for this textbook (www.mhhe.com/saunders8e). Appendix 2C: Depository Institutions and Their Regulators View Appendix 2C at the website for this textbook (www.mhhe.com/saunders8e). Appendix 2D: Technology in Commercial Banking View Appendix 2D at the website for this textbook (www.mhhe.com/saunders8e). www.mhhe.com/saunders8e Appendix 2B: Commercial Banks’ Financial Statements and Analysis Chapter Three Financial Services: Finance Companies INTRODUCTION Like commercial banks, savings institutions, and credit unions, the main financial service provided by finance companies is lending. That is, the primary function of finance companies is to make loans to both individuals and corporations. The services provided by finance companies include consumer lending, business lending, and mortgage financing. Some of their loans are similar to depository institutions loans, such as consumer and auto loans, but others are more specialized. Finance companies differ from depository institutions in that they do not accept deposits but instead rely on short- and long-term debt as a source of funds. Additionally, finance companies often lend to customers depository institutions find too risky. This difference can lead to losses and even failure if the high risk does not pay off. In this chapter we look at the services provided by finance companies and the competitive and financial situation facing these firms. We discuss the size, structure, and composition of the industry; the services the industry provides; its competitive and financial position; and its regulation. We conclude the chapter with a look at some global issues. From this chapter, the reader should obtain a basic understanding of services provided by finance companies, their performance, and the degree to which they are regulated. SIZE, STRUCTURE, AND COMPOSITION OF THE INDUSTRY www.gecapital.com 68 The first major finance company was originated during the Depression, when General Electric Corp. created General Electric Capital Corp. (GECC) as a means of financing appliance sales to cash-constrained customers who were unable to get installment credit from banks. Installment credit is a loan that is paid back to the lender with periodic payments (installments) consisting of varying amounts of interest and principal (e.g., auto loans, home mortgages, and student loans). By the late 1950s banks were more willing to make installment loans, and so finance companies began looking outside their parent companies for business. GE Capital’s consumer finance and banking businesses today provides millions of customers with loans, including credit card, personal, auto financing, and real estate loans. GE Capital Real Estate’s assets total $73 billion, while GE Energy Financial Chapter 3 www.ally.com Financial Services: Finance Companies 69 Services’ assets total $21 billion. GECC also now performs commercial lending and leasing in a number of industries, from aviation, health care, and energy financing, to fleet, franchise, and middle market corporate finance. In the United States, Canada, and Mexico, GE Capital is a leading provider of business lending and leasing for companies of all sizes in a wide array of industries. In Europe, GE Capital has more than 350,000 customers, while in Asia, GE Capital provides services for more than 15 million businesses and consumers. Services include acquisition finance, inventory and working capital financing, leveraged and sponsor finance, equity capital, equipment leasing, and fleet management. GE Aviation is a world-leading provider of commercial and military jet engines and components. GE Aviation owns and manages more than 1,800 aircraft, for more than 245 customers in 75 countries.1 GE Capital’s exposure to the financial crisis resulted in General Electric Corp.’s market value falling by more than half during 2008 (GE Capital accounted for about half of GE’s sales and profit). The parent company’s stock price fell to $14.58 in November 2008, its lowest level since January 1997. In order to reassure investors and help GE Capital unit compete with banks that already had government protection behind their debt, on November 12, 2008, the FDIC approved GE Capital’s application for designation as an eligible entity under the FDIC’s Temporary Liquidity Guarantee Program (TLGP). Under the TLGP, as much as $139 billion in debt (or 125 percent of total senior unsecured debt outstanding as of September 30, 2008) issued by GE Capital was guaranteed and backed by the full faith and credit of the United States. Granting this finance company access to the FDIC program was possible because GE Capital also owns a federal savings bank and an industrial loan company, both of which qualified for FDIC assistance. The terms of these agreements included, among other things, a requirement that GE and GE Capital reimburse the FDIC for any amounts that the FDIC paid to holders of debt that was guaranteed by the FDIC. In July 2009, GE Capital received approval to exit the TLGP program. Ally Financial (formerly GMAC) is another major finance company, founded in 1919 as the General Motors Acceptance Corporation (GMAC), a provider of financing to automotive customers. Since then, the business has expanded to include insurance, direct banking, mortgage operations, and commercial finance. In November 2006, General Motors sold a 51 percent interest in GMAC to a consortium of investors led by hedge fund Cerberus Capital Management and subsidiaries of Citigroup, Aozora Bank, and PNC Financial. GMAC’s existing management team remained in place, but the finance company assumed a separate and independent credit profile and independent governance by a new board of directors. Under terms of the transaction, General Motors and GMAC entered into a 10-year agreement under which GMAC remained the exclusive provider of GM-sponsored auto finance programs. December 24, 2008, was a key turning point in GMAC’s history when it was approved as a bank holding company by the Federal Reserve Board under the Bank Holding Company Act. GMAC had been hit with huge losses in both its mortgage and auto loan businesses. Its mortgage unit, Residential Capital, had suffered significant losses on home loans it made during the housing boom of the early and mid-2000s. The company lost $8 billion in 2007–2008. In light of the impact GMAC’s losses were having on financial markets, to help ensure the survival of the company, federal regulators permitted the financing arm of General Motors to become a bank holding company. The move allowed GMAC access to as much as $6 billion 1 See GECC’s website, www.gecapital.com. 70 Part One Introduction TABLE 3–1 Assets and Liabilities of U.S. Finance Companies, 2012 Source: Federal Reserve Board, December 2012. www.federalreserve.gov Billions of Dollars Percent of Total Assets Assets Accounts receivable gross Consumer Business Real estate Less reserves for unearned income Less reserves for losses Accounts receivable net All other Total assets $1,300.8 578.3 429.2 293.3 (24.3) (26.5) 74.8% 33.3 24.7 16.8 (1.4) (1.5) $1,250.0 488.0 $1,738.0 71.9% 28.1 100.0% $76.5 61.8 256.6 771.5 322.4 249.2 $1,738.0 4.4% 3.6 14.8 44.4 18.5 14.3 100.0% Liabilities and Capital Bank loans Commercial paper Debt due to parent Debt not elsewhere classified All other liabilities Capital, surplus, and undivided profits Total liabilities and capital in government bailout money. As part of the deal, Cerberus Capital Management was forced to cut its stake in the new bank holding company to less than 15 percent and become a passive investor. Cerberus also stopped providing consulting services to GMAC and the two entities would no longer share executives. Also as a condition of the Federal Reserve’s approval, General Motors had to reduce its ownership stake in GMAC to less than 10 percent, from 49 percent. As of November 2012, the U.S. Treasury owned 73.8 percent of GMAC, followed by General Motors (9.9 percent), Cerberus (8.7 percent), and other third-party investors (7.6 percent). The Federal Reserve’s decision to approve GMAC’s application was particularly controversial. Critics had raised questions about GMAC’s financial strength, its ownership by a private equity firm, and whether it was involved in too many commercial activities to become a bank. GMAC had to make several changes to its structure to alleviate concerns. The Fed, which had been considering the proposal since early November, determined that “emergency conditions” made it imperative that it act quickly. Regulators also wanted to approve GMAC’s application to become a bank so that it could apply for federal funds before a year-end deadline set by the Treasury Department. The company would also be subject to more stringent federal oversight and had to diversify its business beyond loans to car buyers and dealerships. Despite these changes, GMAC still operates and provides financial services mainly as a finance company. Because of the attractive rates they offer on some loans (such as new car loans, see below), their willingness to lend to riskier borrowers than depository institutions, their often direct affiliation with manufacturing firms, and the relatively limited amount of regulation imposed on these firms, finance companies have been among the fastest growing FI groups in recent years. In 2012 their assets stood at $1,738.0 billion (see Table 3–1). Comparing this to assets at the end of 1977 (reported in Table 3–2) of $104.3 billion, this industry has experienced growth of almost 1,566 percent in the last 35 years. Chapter 3 TABLE 3–2 Assets and Liabilities of U.S. Finance Companies on December 31, 1977 Source: Federal Reserve Bulletin, June 1978, p. A39. www.federalreserve.gov www.fordcredit.com www.hfc.com www.aigag.com Financial Services: Finance Companies Billions of Dollars Assets Accounts receivable gross Consumer Business Less reserves for unearned income and losses Accounts receivable net Cash and bank deposit Securities All other $ 99.2 44.0 55.2 (12.7) 71 Percent of Total Assets 95.1% 42.2 52.9 (12.2) $ 86.5 2.6 0.9 14.3 82.9% 2.5 0.9 13.7 Total assets Liabilities and Capital Bank loans Commercial paper Debt Short-term Long-term Other Capital, surplus, and undivided profits $104.3 100.0% Total liabilities and capital $104.3 $ 5.9 29.6 5.7% 28.4 6.2 36.0 11.5 15.1 5.9 34.5 11.0 14.5 100.0% www.cit.com sales finance institutions Institutions that specialize in making loans to the customers of a particular retailer or manufacturer. personal credit institutions Institutions that specialize in making installment and other loans to consumers. business credit institutions Institutions that specialize in making business loans. factoring The process of purchasing accounts receivable from corporations (often at a discount), usually with no recourse to the seller if the receivables go bad. The three major types of finance companies are (1) sales finance institutions, (2) personal credit institutions, and (3) business credit institutions. Sales finance institutions (e.g., Ford Motor Credit and Sears Roebuck Acceptance Corp.) specialize in making loans to the customers of a particular retailer or manufacturer. Because sales finance institutions can frequently process loans faster and more conveniently (generally at the location of purchase) than depository institutions, this sector of the industry competes directly with depository institutions for consumer loans. Personal credit institutions (e.g., HSBC Finance and AIG American General) specialize in making installment and other loans to consumers. Personal credit institutions will make loans to customers that depository institutions find too risky to lend to (due to low income or a bad credit history). These institutions compensate for the additional risk by charging higher interest rates than depository institutions and/or accepting collateral (e.g., used cars) that depository institutions do not find acceptable. Business credit institutions (e.g., CIT Group and U.S. Bancorp Equipment Finance) are companies that provide financing to corporations, especially through equipment leasing and factoring, in which the finance company purchases accounts receivable from corporate customers. These accounts are purchased at a discount from their face value, and the finance company specializes in and assumes the responsibility for collecting the accounts receivable. As a result, the corporate customer no longer has the worry of whether the accounts receivable may or may not be delayed and thus receives cash for sales faster than the time it takes customers to pay their bills. Many finance companies perform more than one of these three services (e.g., GMAC). The industry is quite concentrated, with the largest 20 firms accounting for more than 65 percent of its assets. In addition, many of the largest finance companies, such as Ford Motor Credit Corp., tend to be wholly owned or captive 72 Part One TABLE 3–3 Introduction The Largest Finance Companies Sources: Insurance Information Institute and authors’ research. Total Receivables ($ millions) Company Name General Electric Capital Corporation Capital One Financial 203,132 Sales finance and business credit Personal credit SLM Corp. J.P. Morgan Chase (credit card business) Ally Financial 167,166 124,537 121,259 Personal credit Personal credit Sales finance American Express 117,380 Personal credit Citigroup (credit card business) Bank of America (credit card business) HSBC Finance Corp. Ford Motor Credit Company 108,819 108,659 86,680 71,517 Personal credit Personal credit Personal credit Sales finance captive finance company A finance company that is wholly owned by a parent corporation. Concept Questions $285,395 Type of Finance Company Ownership Captive of GE NYSE-listed independent that also owns Capital One Bank NYSE-listed independent Part of J.P. Morgan Chase Owned by consortium of investors including the U.S. Treasury, Cerberus Capital Management, and GM NYSE-listed independent that also owns American Express Bank Part of Citigroup Part of Bank of America Subsidiary of HSBC Holdings Captive of Ford subsidiaries of major manufacturing companies. A major role of a captive finance company is to provide financing for the purchase of products manufactured by the parent, as Ford Motor Credit Corp. does for cars. In turn, the parent company is often a major source of debt finance for the captive finance company. A benefit of the captive finance subsidiary to the parent company is diversification in revenue streams. For example, as the auto industry suffered from a lack of sales in the mid-2000s, Ford Motor Credit Corp. was producing record profits, as much as 80 percent of the overall profits of Ford Motor Corporation. Table 3–3 lists some of the top finance companies (in terms of total receivables) as of 2012. GECC is the largest with receivables totaling $285.4 billion. Note that 6 of the 10 finance companies are subsidiaries of financial services holding companies such as Citigroup. Thus, while Citibank cannot make high-risk, high-interest rate loans due to bank regulations that restrict credit risk, Citigroup can indirectly make these loans through its finance company subsidiary. 1. What are the three major types of finance companies? What types of customers does each serve? 2. What is a captive finance company? BALANCE SHEET AND RECENT TRENDS Assets As mentioned earlier, finance companies provide three basic lending services: customer lending, consumer lending, and business lending. In Table 3–1 we show the balance sheet of finance companies in 2012. As you can see, business and consumer loans (called accounts receivable) are major assets held by finance Chapter 3 Financial Services: Finance Companies 73 companies, accounting for 58.0 percent of total assets, while real estate loans are 16.8 percent of total assets. Comparing the figures in Table 3–1 to those in Table 3–2 for 1977, we see that 95.1 percent of total assets were consumer and business loans in 1977, yet no real estate loans were listed. Over the last 35 years, finance companies have replaced consumer and business loans with increasing amounts of real estate loans and other assets, although these loans have not become dominant, as is the case with depository institutions. However, like depository institutions, these activities create credit risk, interest rate risk, and liquidity risk that finance company managers must evaluate and manage. The financial crisis was a period that saw the downside of these risks, producing losses in all lending areas for the industry. Table 3–4 shows the breakdown of the industry’s loans in 1995 and 2012 for consumer, real estate, and business lending. In recent years, the fastest-growing areas of asset business have been in the nonconsumer finance areas, especially leasing and business lending. In 2012, consumer loans constituted 58.5 percent of all finance company loans, mortgages represented 12.8 percent, and business loans comprised 28.7 percent. Consumer Loans subprime lender A finance company that lends to high-risk customers. Consumer loans consist of motor vehicle loans and leases, other consumer loans, and securitized loans from each category. Motor vehicle loans and leases are traditionally the major type of consumer loan (53.1 percent of the consumer loan portfolio in 2012). As can be seen from Table 3–5, finance companies historically charged higher rates for automobile loans than did commercial banks. In 1995 and 1996, auto finance companies charged interest rates 1.62 and 0.79 percent, respectively, higher than those of commercial banks. Nevertheless, sometimes these rates get lowered dramatically. For example, because new car sales by U.S. firms in the late 1990s were lower than normal, auto finance companies owned by the major auto manufacturers slashed interest rates on new car loans (some to as low as 0.9 percent). Moreover, after the terrorist attacks in September 2001, the major auto manufacturers lowered rates on many new car loans to 0 percent in an attempt to boost sales. Some of these 0 percent rates continued to be offered into 2005 as the U.S. economy struggled to recover and the general level of interest rates remained low. The financial crisis saw the resurrection of 0 percent car loan rates as auto manufacturers tried to boost slumping car sales. Notice that the difference between new car loans at commercial banks and finance companies continued to widen throughout the early 2000s. By 2002 finance companies were charging more than 3.3 percent less on new car loans than commercial banks, mainly due to the zero interest rates offered by the major auto manufacturers’ captive finance company loans to new car buyers. However, other than for new car loans, these types of low rates are fairly rare. The higher rates finance companies charge for consumer loans are mostly due to the fact that finance companies attract riskier customers than commercial banks. Customers who seek individual (or business) loans from finance companies are often those judged too risky to obtain loans from commercial banks or thrifts.2 It is, in fact, possible for individuals to get a loan from a subprime lender finance company (a finance company that lends to high-risk customers) even with 2 We look at the analysis of borrower (credit) risk in Chapter 10. 74 Part One Introduction TABLE 3–4 Finance Company Loans Outstanding, 1995–2012 (in billions of dollars) Consumer Source: Federal Reserve Board, “Flow of Fund Accounts,” various issues. www.federalreserve.gov 1995 Percent of Total, 1995 2012 Percent of Total, 2012 $285.8 $ 41.5% $ 839.4 58.5% Motor vehicle loans 81.1 11.8 294.6 20.5 Motor vehicle leases 80.8 11.7 139.9 9.7 Revolving1 28.5 4.1 74.2 5.2 42.6 6.2 312.2 21.8 2 Other Securitized assets Motor vehicle loans 34.8 5.1 11.0 0.8 Motor vehicle leases 3.5 0.5 0.0 0.0 Revolving n.a. n.a. 0.0 0.0 Other 14.7 Real estate $ 72.4 2.1 10.5% 7.4 $ 183.5 0.5 12.8% One- to four-family n.a. n.a. 134.0 9.3 Other n.a. n.a. 49.9 3.5 n.a. n.a. 0.0 0.0 Securitized real estate assets3 One- to four-family Other Business Motor vehicles n.a. $331.2 n.a. 48.0% 0.1 $ 411.8 0.0 28.7% 66.5 9.6 127.5 8.9 Retail loans 21.8 3.1 23.7 1.7 Wholesale loans4 36.6 5.3 73.0 5.1 Leases Equipment 8.0 1.2 30.8 2.1 188.0 27.3 202.6 14.1 8.4 Loans 58.6 8.5 120.6 Leases 129.4 18.8 82.0 5.7 47.2 6.8 81.7 5.7 20.6 3.0 0.0 0.0 1.8 0.3 0.0 0.0 18.8 2.7 0.0 0.0 Other business receivables5 Securitized assets3 Motor vehicles Retail loans Wholesale loans Equipment 8.1 1.2 0.0 0.0 Loans 5.3 0.8 0.0 0.0 Leases 2.8 0.4 0.0 0.0 0.8 0.1 0.0 Other business receivables5 Total 1 $689.5 $100.0% $1,434.7 0.0 100.0% Excludes revolving credit reported as held by depository institutions that are subsidiaries of finance companies. Includes personal cash loans, mobile home loans, and loans to purchase other types of consumer goods, such as appliances, apparel, boats, and recreation vehicles. 3 Outstanding balances of pools on which securities have been issued; these balances are no longer carried on the balance sheets of the loan originator. 4 Credit arising from transactions between manufacturers and dealers, that is, floor plan financing. 5 Includes loans on commercial accounts receivable, factored commercial accounts, and receivable dealer capital; small loans used primarily for business or farm purposes; and wholesale and lease paper for mobile homes, campers, and travel trailers. 2 Chapter 3 TABLE 3–5 Financial Services: Finance Companies 75 Consumer Credit Interest Rates, 1995–2012 Source: Federal Reserve Board, “Flow of Fund Accounts,” various dates. www.federalreserve.gov Type Commercial bank new car Auto finance company new car Difference in commercial bank versus finance company rate loan sharks Subprime lenders that charge unfairly exorbitant rates to desperate subprime borrowers. 1995 1996 9.57% 11.19 9.05% 9.84 1.62 0.79 1997 2002 2007 2008 2012 9.02% 7.12 7.62% 4.29 7.77% 4.87 7.02% 5.52 5.73% 4.73 ⫺1.90 ⫺3.33 ⫺2.90 ⫺1.50 ⫺1.00 a bankruptcy on their records. For example, Jayhawk Acceptance Corp., one of a group of finance companies that lent money to used-car buyers with poor or no credit, began marketing loans for tummy tucks, hair transplants, and other procedures that are not usually covered by health insurance. Jayhawk entered into contracts with doctors to lend money to their patients who were seeking cosmetic surgery or some types of dental procedures. Borrowers who paid the loans within a year paid an annual rate of 9.9 percent, while those who repaid within the maximum of two years paid 13.9 percent per year. Left unanswered, however, was what Jayhawk could repossess if a borrower defaulted on a loan. Jayhawk eventually declared bankruptcy. Banks would rarely make these types of risky loans. Most finance companies that offer these types of loans charge rates commensurate with the higher risk, and there are a few loan shark companies that prey on desperate consumers, charging exorbitant rates as high as 30 percent per year or more. Another case of a subprime lender is the payday lender. Payday lenders provide short-term cash advances that are often due when borrowers receive their next paycheck. The payday lending industry originated from check cashing outlets in the early 1990s and has exploded in recent years as demand for short-term loans has risen. A typical borrower takes out a two-week loan and pays $15 for every $100 borrowed, or the equivalent of a 390 percent annual interest rate. The typical customer earns between $25,000 and $50,000 per year. Payday lenders generate approximately $44 billion in loans annually and earned about $10 billion in revenue in 2012. The number of storefronts more than doubled between 2000 and 2012, to roughly 24,000 nationwide and hundreds of websites. As of September 2012, payday lender Cash America International had $256.8 million in payday loans on its balance sheet and charged $558.7 million in interest and fees. Critics claim that rates are exorbitant and often trap financially strapped borrowers in a cycle of paying additional fees to renew the same amount of principal. Lenders argue that the high rates are necessary to cover costs, offset higher default rates, and still earn a profit. The payday loan industry is regulated at the state level. As of 2012, 18 states had effectively banned payday lending. When not explicitly banned, laws that prohibit payday lending are usually in the form of usury limits. Payday lenders have succeeded in getting around usury laws in some states by forming relationships with nationally chartered banks based in a different state with no usury ceiling (such as South Dakota or Delaware). As federal banking regulators became aware of this practice, they began prohibiting these partnerships between commercial banks and payday lenders. The FDIC still allows its member banks to participate in payday lending, but it did issue guidelines in March 2005 that are 76 Part One Introduction meant to discourage long-term debt cycles by transitioning to a longer-term loan after six payday loan renewals. Revolving and other consumer loans include personal cash loans, mobile home loans, and private-label credit card loans (e.g., Discover card) to purchase other types of consumer goods, such as appliances, apparel, general merchandise, and recreational vehicles. In 2012, these loans made up 46.9 percent of the consumer loan portfolio of finance companies. Mortgages securitized mortgage assets Mortgages packaged and used as assets backing secondary market securities. home equity loans Loans that let customers borrow on a line of credit secured with a second mortgage on their home. Residential and commercial mortgages have become a major component in finance company portfolios, although, referring again to Table 3–2, they did not generally deal in mortgages in 1977. However, since finance companies are not subject to as extensive regulations as are banks, they are often willing to issue mortgages to riskier borrowers than commercial banks. They compensate for this additional risk by charging higher interest rates and fees. Mortgages include all loans secured by liens on any type of real estate. Mortgages can be made either directly or as securitized mortgage assets. Securitization of mortgages involves the pooling of a group of mortgages with similar characteristics, the removal of these mortgages from the balance sheet, and the subsequent sale of interests in the pool to secondary market investors. Securitization of mortgages results in the creation of mortgage-backed securities (e.g., government agency securities, collateralized mortgage obligations), which can be traded in secondary mortgage markets.3 While removed from its balance sheet, the finance company that originates the mortgage may still service the mortgage portfolio for a fee.4 The mortgages in the loan portfolio can be first mortgages or second mortgages in the form of home equity loans. Home equity loans allow customers to borrow on a line of credit secured with a second mortgage on their home. Home equity loans have become very profitable for finance companies since the Tax Reform Act of 1986 was passed, disallowing the tax deductibility of consumers’ interest payments other than those on home mortgages. Specifically, interest on (first and second) mortgages secured by residential real estate is tax deductible. Interest on other types of individual loans—such as consumer (e.g., credit card) loans—is not eligible for a tax deduction. Also, the bad debt expense and administrative costs on home equity loans are lower than those on other finance company loans. As discussed below, in 2007–2008 a sharp rise in late payments and defaults by subprime and even relatively strong credit mortgage and home equity loan borrowers caused large losses for mortgage lenders and mortgage-backed securities investors, and ultimately was the root cause of the financial crisis of 2008–2009. Business Loans Business loans represent 28.7 percent of the loan portfolio of finance companies. Finance companies have several advantages over commercial banks in offering services to small business customers. First, as mentioned earlier, they are not subject to regulations that restrict the types of products and services they can offer. Second, 3 We discuss the securitization of mortgages in more detail in Chapter 26. Mortgage servicing is a fee-related business whereby, after mortgages are securitized, the flow of mortgage repayments (interest and principal) has to be collected and passed on (by the mortgage servicer) to investors in either whole mortgage loan packages or securitization vehicles such as pass-through securities (see Chapter 26). In undertaking this intermediation activity, the servicer charges a fee. 4 Chapter 3 Financial Services: Finance Companies 77 because finance companies do not accept deposits, they have no bank-type regulators looking directly over their shoulders.5 Third, being in many cases subsidiaries of corporate-sector holding companies, finance companies often have substantial industry and product expertise. Fourth, as mentioned in regard to consumer loans, finance companies are more willing to accept risky customers than are commercial banks. Fifth, finance companies generally have lower overheads than banks have; for example, they do not need tellers or branches for taking deposits. The major subcategories of business loans are retail and wholesale motor vehicle loans and leases (31.0 percent of all business loans in 2012), equipment loans (49.2 percent), other business loans (19.8 percent), and securitized business assets (0.0 percent). Motor vehicle loans consist of retail loans that assist in transactions between the retail seller of the product and the ultimate consumer (i.e., passenger car fleets and commercial land vehicles for which licenses are required). Wholesale loans are loan agreements between parties other than the companies’ consumers. For example, Ford Motor Credit Corp. (FMCC) provides wholesale financing to Ford dealers for inventory floor plans in which FMCC pays for Ford dealers’ auto inventory received from Ford. FMCC puts a lien on each car on the showroom floor. While the dealer pays periodic interest on the floor plan loan, it is not until the car is sold that the dealer pays for the car. These activities extend to retail and wholesale leasing of motor vehicles as well. Business-lending activities of finance companies also include equipment loans, with the finance company either owning or leasing the equipment directly to its industrial customer or providing the financial backing for a leveraged lease, a working capital loan, or a loan to purchase or remodel the customer’s facility. Finance companies often prefer to lease equipment rather than sell and finance the purchase of equipment. One reason for this is that repossession of the equipment in the event of default is less complicated when the finance company retains its title (by leasing). Further, a lease agreement generally requires no down payment, making a lease more attractive to the business customer. Finally, when the finance company retains ownership of the equipment (by leasing), it receives a tax deduction in the form of depreciation expense on the equipment. Other business loans include loans to businesses to finance accounts receivable, factored commercial accounts, small farm loans, and wholesale and lease paper for mobile homes, campers, and trailers. Liabilities and Equity To finance asset growth, finance companies have relied primarily on short-term commercial paper and other debt (longer-term notes and bonds). Thus, management of liquidity risk is quite different from that in commercial banks that mostly rely on deposits (see Chapter 2). As reported in Table 3–1, in 2012 commercial paper amounted to $61.8 billion (3.6 percent of total assets), while other debt (debt due to parents and debt not elsewhere classified) totaled $1,028.1 billion (59.2 percent) and bank loans totaled $76.5 billion (4.4 percent). Debt due to parent includes all short- and long-term debt owed to the parent company of the finance company, for example, debt Ford Motor Credit Corp. owes to Ford Motor Corp. Debt not elsewhere classified includes all short- and long-term debt (loans, notes, certificates, negotiable paper, or other) owed to external lenders not listed above. If the 5 Finance companies do, of course, have market participants looking over their shoulders and monitoring their activities. 78 Part One Introduction finance company subsidiary has a bad year and cannot make promised payments on its debt, the parent company would be less likely than external fund providers to initiate legal proceedings against the finance company. However, given their large percentage of funding, the parent to a finance company is susceptible to large losses of its own if the finance company subsidiary has a bad year. Comparing these figures with those for 1977 (in Table 3–2), commercial paper was used more in 1977 (28.4 percent of total liabilities and capital), while other debt (short- and long-term) was less significant as a source of financing (40.4 percent). Finance companies also now rely less heavily on bank loans for financing. In 1977, bank loans accounted for 5.7 percent of total financing. Much of the change in funding sources is due to the strong economy and low interest rates in the U.S. long-term debt markets in the early and mid-2000s and the continued low interest rates during the financial crisis of 2008–2009. Finally, in 2012 finance companies’ capital-toassets ratio was 14.3 percent, only slightly lower than the 14.5 percent in 1977. As discussed earlier, unlike banks and thrifts, finance companies cannot issue deposits. Rather, to finance assets, finance companies rely heavily on short-term commercial paper, with many having direct sale programs in which commercial paper is sold directly to mutual funds and other institutional investors on a continuous day-by-day basis. Indeed, finance companies are now the largest issuers in the short-term commercial paper market. Most commercial paper issues have maturities of 30 days or less, although they can be issued with maturities of up to 270 days.6 INDUSTRY PERFORMANCE www.hfc.com In the early 2000s, the outlook for the industry as a whole was bright. Interest rates were at historical lows. Mortgage refinancing grew, and loan demand among lower- and middle-income consumers was strong. Because many of their potential borrowers had very low savings, no major slowdown in the demand for finance company services was expected. The largest finance companies—those that lend to less risky individual and business customers and with few subprime borrowers (e.g., HSBC Finance)—experienced strong profits and loan growth. (The industry’s assets as a whole grew at a rate of almost 8 percent in the early 2000s.) As such, the most successful finance companies became takeover targets for other financial service as well as industrial firms. For example, Citigroup acquired Associates First Capital to create the largest full-service financial institution in the country. In May 2001 American General (the then 13th-largest finance company) was acquired by American International Group (AIG), one of the country’s largest life insurance companies. Finally, in 2003 Household International was acquired by British commercial bank HSBC Holdings for $14.9 billion. This acquisition was one of the largest M&As of any kind in 2003. These are just other examples of integration and consolidation among firms in the financial services sector. Nevertheless, in the mid- and late 2000s problems for industry participants who specialized in loans to relatively lower-quality customers created large losses in the industry and a very big problem for the U.S. economy as a whole. As home prices began to fall in 2005 and 2006 and borrowers faced rising interest rates, 6 Commercial paper issued with a maturity longer than 270 days has to be registered with the SEC (i.e., it is treated the same as publicly placed bonds). Chapter 3 Financial Services: Finance Companies 79 more people defaulted on their mortgages. At the end of 2006, the percentage of subprime mortgage loans on which payments were at least 60 days late was 14 percent, up from 6 percent in early 2005. With delinquencies and defaults by borrowers rising, finance companies started a sharp pullback in subprime lending. Originations of subprime mortgages declined 30 to 35 percent in 2007 from 2006, when they totaled approximately $600 billion, or about one-fifth of the entire mortgage market. The results were sharply lower values for finance companies. For example, shares of New Century Financial, the number-two subprime lender, plunged nearly 79 percent in early March 2007 after the company said it was facing a criminal probe of its practices by the Justice Department and its outside auditor said it believed there was substantial doubt about New Century’s ability to continue as a going concern. On March 13, 2007, the NYSE suspended trading on the company’s stock and began steps to delist the company. Similarly, Fremont General Corp. lost one-third of its value after it announced it would exit the subprime sector due to demands of regulators and market conditions. Countrywide Financial, the country’s leading mortgage lender, lost over half its market value in the summer and fall of 2007 as it announced continued losses in its subprime mortgage portfolio. Only a $2 billion equity investment by Bank of America in 2007 and then an acquisition offer in 2008 kept this finance company alive. However, in March 2008, the FBI announced a probe of Countrywide for possible securities fraud. The inquiry focused on whether company officials made misrepresentations about the company’s financial position and the quality of its mortgage loans in securities filings. Other leaders in the subprime mortgage lending market were units of some of the nation’s biggest financial services holding companies, including HSBC (the number-one subprime mortgage lender, which took a $10.6 million charge for bad loans in 2006), General Electric, Wells Fargo, and Washington Mutual. This crash in the subprime mortgage market led to serious problems in the U.S. and worldwide economies. The housing boom of the early 2000s held defaults to very low levels because borrowers who fell behind on payments could easily sell their homes or refinance into a loan with easier terms. Further, roughly two-thirds of mortgages were packaged into securities and sold to investors worldwide. That and other innovations made credit cheaper and more available, helping more people to afford a home. But as home prices flattened and then dropped in most parts of the country, more borrowers fell behind on their mortgage payments. By the end of 2009 mortgage loan delinquencies increased for the 12th straight quarter, hitting an all-time national average high of 6.89 percent. This rate indicated that more than 7.2 million mortgage loans were behind on payments. As the financial crisis developed and spread, other areas of lending saw increased losses. Small business loan failure rates hit the double digits, at 11.9 percent, in 2009; in 2004, the failure rate was 2.4 percent. In 2009, the national default rate for commercial real estate mortgages rose to 2.25 percent from 1.62 percent in the fourth quarter of 2008. This was the largest quarterly increase since at least 1992. Finance company performance suffered along with these decreases in loan performance. As noted earlier, the crisis resulted in the failure of Countrywide Financial and the forced conversion of GMAC Financial Services to a bank holding company in order to prevent its failure. Another notable failure is that of CIT Group, which filed for Chapter 11 bankruptcy in November 2009. In 2008, CIT was a lender to nearly a million mostly small and midsize businesses and companies. As the financial crisis hit, many of its borrowers became delinquent or defaulted on their loans. While CIT’s failure would not affect financial markets to the same extent as 80 Part One Introduction the failure of a large commercial bank such as Citigroup, it could hurt the flow of credit to many businesses to which banks traditionally did not lend. As a result, in December 2008, the Federal Reserve approved CIT Group’s application to convert to a bank holding company, clearing a key hurdle for the firm to bolster its resources with loans and support from the government’s financial rescue fund. However, as the financial crisis wore on, losses mounted, and CIT was forced to file for bankruptcy protection. At the time of bankruptcy, CIT had assets of $71 billion and liabilities of $65 billion. The bankruptcy eliminated $10 billion of this debt, including $2.3 billion extended to CIT in 2008 as part of the taxpayer bailout of the finance company. The bankruptcy of CIT Group was one of the largest filings ever of a U.S. company—trailing only the likes of Lehman Brothers, Washington Mutual, and General Motors. As was true with depository institutions, as the U.S. economy improved in the late 2000s and early 2010s, the finance company industry improved as well. Employment in the industry increased from 561,700 in 2010 to 562,400 in 2011 (still below the 2007 level of 715,900). Further, in 2011, the median ROE for business credit institutions increased to 9.33 percent from 7.81 percent in 2010. However, the median ROE for personal credit institutions decreased to 13.73 percent in 2011 from 14.12 percent in 2010. Financial crisis issues remained even into 2012. Industry assets totaled $1.74 trillion in 2012 down from $1.75 trillion in 2010 and $2.21 trillion in 2008. Receivables also lagged behind pre-crisis levels. Total receivables dropped from $1.77 trillion in mid-2008 to $1.40 trillion in 2009 and $1.30 trillion in 2012. Concept Questions 1. How have the major assets held by finance companies changed in the last 30 years? 2. How do subprime lender finance company consumer loan customers differ from consumer loan customers at banks? 3. What advantages do finance companies offer over commercial banks to small business customers? REGULATION The Federal Reserve defines a finance company as a firm (other than a depository institution) whose primary assets are loans to individuals and businesses.7 Finance companies, like depository institutions, are financial intermediaries that borrow funds for relending, making a profit on the difference between the interest rate on borrowed funds and the rate charged on the loans. Also like depository institutions, finance companies are subject to any state-imposed usury ceilings on the maximum loan rate assigned to any individual customer and are regulated as to the extent to which they can collect on delinquent loans (e.g., legal mechanisms to be followed). However, because finance companies do not accept deposits, they are not subject to extensive oversight by any specific federal or state regulators as are banks or thrifts—even though they offer services that compete directly with those of depository institutions (e.g., consumer installment loans and mortgages).8 The lack of regulatory oversight for these companies enables them to offer a wide scope of “bank-like” services and yet avoid the expense of regulatory compliance, such 7 8 Whereas a bank is defined as an institution that both accepts deposits and makes loans. Like any corporation, they are subject to SEC disclosure rules. Chapter 3 Financial Services: Finance Companies 81 as that imposed on banks and thrifts by the Community Reinvestment Act of 1977, which requires these institutions to keep and file extensive reports showing that they are not discriminating in their lending practices in their local communities. However, because of the impact that nonbank FIs, including finance companies, had on the U.S. economy during the financial crisis and as a result of the need for the Federal Reserve to rescue several nonbank FIs, regulators proposed that nonbank FIs receive more oversight. Indeed, as discussed earlier, at the height of the financial crisis the Fed stepped in to rescue numerous finance companies, including GMAC, GE Capital, and CIT Group. Credit card lenders American Express and Discover Financial (as well as investment banks Goldman Sachs and Morgan Stanley) also became bank holding companies in 2008. As a result, as part of the 2010 Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act, the federal government was provided with the tools it needs to manage financial crises by establishing (a) a new regime to resolve nonbank financial institutions whose failure could have serious systemic effects and (b) revisions to the Federal Reserve’s emergency lending authority to improve accountability. The bill also proposed robust supervision and regulation of all financial firms by establishing (a) a new Financial Services Oversight Council of financial regulators (chaired by Treasury and including the heads of the principal federal financial regulators as members) to identify emerging systemic risks and improve interagency cooperation; (b) a new authority for the Federal Reserve to supervise all firms that could pose a threat to financial stability, even those that do not own banks; and (c) stronger capital and other prudential standards for all financial firms, and even higher standards for large, interconnected firms. Further, since finance companies are heavy borrowers in the capital markets and do not enjoy the same regulatory “safety net” as banks, they need to signal their solvency and safety to investors.9 Signals of solvency and safety are usually sent by holding higher equity or capital-to-asset ratios—and therefore lower leverage ratios—than banks hold. For example, in 2012 the aggregate balance sheet (Table 3–1) shows a capital-to-assets ratio of 14.3 percent for finance companies. This can be compared to the capital-to-asset ratio for commercial banks of 11.5 percent reported in Table 2–6. Larger, captive finance companies also use default protection guarantees from their parent companies and/or guarantees such as letters of credit or lines of credit purchased for a fee from high-quality commercial or investment banks as additional protection against insolvency risk and as a device to increase their ability to raise additional funds in the capital and money markets. Thus, this group will tend to operate with lower capital-to-asset ratios than smaller finance companies. Given that there is little regulatory oversight of this industry, having sufficient capital and access to financial guarantees are critical to their continued ability to raise funds. Thus, finance companies operate more like nonfinancial, nonregulated companies than other types of financial institutions examined in this text. Concept Questions 1. Since finance companies seem to compete in the same lending markets as banks, why are they not subject to the same regulations as banks? 2. How do finance companies signal solvency and safety to investors? 9 That is, they have no access to the deposit insurance fund or to the Federal Reserve discount window (see Chapter 19). On the other hand, they do not have to pay deposit insurance premiums or meet regulatory imposed minimum capital standards. 82 Part One Introduction GLOBAL ISSUES £ ¥ :$ Summary While commercial banks are the most important source of credit supply in many foreign countries, particularly emerging market economies, nonbank financial institutions (finance companies, credit unions, and building societies) account for a substantial part of the outstanding credit by all financial institutions and their relative importance has been increasing over the past decade. Specialized consumer finance agencies operate throughout western Europe, Canada, Australia, Japan, and some Latin American countries. For example, from the mid-1990s to the late-2000s, the percentage of aggregate credit issued by nonbank financial institutions increased from 22 to 32 percent in Latin America and from 4 to 17 percent in central Europe. In Thailand, nonbank financial institutions, particularly those specializing in credit card lending, gained market share. This trend also occurred in Mexico, where specialized mortgage institutions dominated lowincome mortgage lending. Large sales finance companies specialize in financing purchases of particular commodities and remain closely associated with specific manufacturers. Some also extend credit for wholesale purchases by retail dealers. While the financial crisis affected the operations of finance companies, they still remained a major part of the financial sector in countries worldwide. For example, in New Zealand the financial crisis led to the consolidation, collapse, and restructuring of many of the country’s finance companies. Further, in Russia significant finance company staff reductions occurred during the financial crisis. Because regulations in most foreign countries are not as restrictive as those in the United States, finance companies in foreign countries are generally subsidiaries of commercial banks or industrial firms. For those finance companies owned by commercial banks, as the bank goes, so does the finance company. Some of the major multinational business financing companies include Alliance Leicester Commercial Bank (part of Santander Group, United Kingdom), Commercial Lifeline (United Kingdom), Finance Eai (Australia), Five Arrows Commercial Finance (Australia), Lloyds TSB (United Kingdom), Lombard (United Kingdom), and SME Commercial Finance (Australia). This chapter provided an overview of the finance company industry. This industry competes directly with depository institutions for high-quality (prime) loan customers by specializing in consumer loans, real estate loans, and business loans. The industry also services subprime (high-risk) borrowers deemed too risky for most depository institutions. However, because firms in this industry do not accept deposits, they are not regulated to the same extent as are depository institutions. Because they do not have access to deposits for their funding, finance companies rely heavily on short- and long-term debt, especially commercial paper. Currently, the industry is generally growing and profitable, although the subprime lending sector of the industry is experiencing some financial problems as consumer default rates on loans and credit cards rise. Chapter 3 83 1. What is the primary function of finance companies? How do finance companies differ from depository institution? 2. What are the three major types of finance companies? To which market segments do each of these types of companies provide service? 3. What have been the major changes in the accounts receivable balances of finance companies over the 35-year period 1977–2012? 4. What are the major types of consumer loans? Why are the rates charged by consumer finance companies typically higher than those charged by commercial banks? 5. Why have home equity loans become popular? What are securitized mortgage assets? 6. What advantages do finance companies have over commercial banks in offering services to small business customers? What are the major subcategories of business loans? Which category is the largest? 7. What have been the primary sources of financing for finance companies? 8. How do finance companies make money? What risks does this process entail? How do these risks differ for a finance company versus a commercial bank? 9. Compare Tables 3–1 and 2–6. Which firms have higher ratios of capital to total assets: finance companies or commercial banks? What does this comparison indicate about the relative strengths of these two types of firms? 10. Why do finance companies face less regulation than do commercial banks? How does this advantage translate into performance advantages? What is the major performance disadvantage? Web Question 11. Go to the Federal Reserve’s website at www.federalreserve.gov and get the latest information on finance company consumer, real estate, and business lending using the following steps. Click on “All Statistical Releases.” Under “Business Finance,” click on “Finance Companies.” This downloads a file onto your computer that contains the relevant data. How have these numbers changed since 2012, reported in Table 3–4? www.mhhe.com/saunders8e Questions and Problems Financial Services: Finance Companies Chapter Four Financial Services: Securities Brokerage and Investment Banking INTRODUCTION Securities firms and investment banks primarily help net suppliers of funds (e.g., households) transfer funds to net users of funds (e.g., businesses) at a low cost and with a maximum degree of efficiency. Unlike other types of FIs, securities firms and investment banks do not transform the securities issued by the net users of funds into claims that may be “more” attractive to the net suppliers of funds (e.g., banks and their creation of bank deposits and loans). Rather, they serve as brokers intermediating between fund suppliers and users. Investment banking involves the raising of debt and equity securities for corporations or governments. This includes the origination, underwriting, and placement of securities in money and capital markets for corporate or government issuers. Securities services involve assistance in the trading of securities in the secondary markets (brokerage services and/or market making). Together these services are performed by securities firms and investment banks. The largest companies in this industry perform both sets of services (i.e., underwriting and brokerage services). These full-line firms (e.g., Bank of America Merrill Lynch) are generally called investment banks. Many other firms concentrate their services in one area only (either securities trading or securities underwriting). That is, some firms in the industry specialize in the purchase, sale, and brokerage of existing securities (the retail side of the business) and are called securities firms, while other firms specialize in originating, underwriting, and distributing issues of new securities (the commercial side of the business) and are called investment banks. Investment banking also includes corporate finance activities such as advising on mergers and acquisitions (M&As), as well as advising on the restructuring of existing corporations. Figure 4–1 reports merger activity for the period 1990–2012. Total dollar volume (measured by transaction value) of domestic M&As increased from less than $200 billion in 1990 to $1.83 trillion in 2000 (reflecting 10,864 deals). 84 Chapter 4 Financial Services: Securities Brokerage and Investment Banking 85 FIGURE 4–1 Attracting Partners Source: Thompson Reuters Deals Intelligence, 2013. www.thompsonreuters.com $ 2,000 billion Total value of mergers and acquisitions in the United States (in billions of dollars) 1,900 1,800 1,700 1,600 1,500 1,400 1,300 1,200 1,100 1,000 900 800 700 600 500 400 300 200 100 0 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 This merger wave was not restricted to the United States. For example, in 2000 there were more than 36,700 merger and acquisition deals globally, valued at more than $3.49 trillion. However, reflecting the downturn in the U.S. economy, M&A transactions fell 53 percent in 2001 to $819 billion on only 7,525 deals (the first time since 1995 there were fewer than 10,000 deals). Similarly, worldwide M&As fell to $1.74 trillion in 2001. Domestic M&A activity bottomed out at $458 billion in 2002 (while worldwide activity fell to $1.2 trillion) before recovering (along with the economy), topping $1.7 trillion in the United States (and $4.5 trillion worldwide) 86 Part One Introduction in 2007. During the financial crisis, domestic M&A activity fell to $903 billion, $713 billion, and $687 billion in 2008, 2009, and 2010, respectively, while worldwide M&As fell to $2.9 trillion, $1.7 trillion, and $1.8 trillion, respectively. Note that while this period included the worst financial crisis since the Great Depression, M&A activity remained at higher levels than those experienced in the early 2000s. As the U.S. economy recovered in 2011 and 2012, M&A activity rose as well (to $861 billion and $882 billion, respectively, while worldwide activity increased to $2.33 trillion and $2.04 trillion, respectively). The industry has undergone substantial structural changes in recent years. Some of the most recent consolidations include the acquisition of Bear Stearns by J.P. Morgan Chase, the bankruptcy of Lehman Brothers, and the acquisition of Merrill Lynch by Bank of America. Indeed, as discussed later in the chapter, the investment banking industry has seen the failure or acquisition of all but two of its major firms (Goldman Sachs and Morgan Stanley), and these two firms converted to commercial bank holding companies in 2008. In this chapter we present an overview of (1) the size, structure, and composition of the industry, (2) the balance sheet and recent trends, and (3) the regulation of the industry. After studying the chapter, the reader should have a basic understanding of financial services involving securities brokerage and investment banking, as well as the major trends in the industry. SIZE, STRUCTURE, AND COMPOSITION OF THE INDUSTRY Because of the emphasis on securities trading and underwriting, the size of the industry is usually measured by the equity capital of the firms participating in these financial services. Securities trading and underwriting is a financial service that requires no investment in assets or liability funding (such as the issuance of loans funded through deposits or payments on insurance contracts funded through insurance premiums). Rather, securities trading and underwriting is a profit-generating activity that does not require FIs to actually hold or invest in the securities they trade or issue for their customers, except for very short periods either as part of their trading inventory or during the underwriting period for new issues. Accordingly, asset value is not traditionally a measure of the size of a firm in this industry. Instead, the equity or capital of the FI is used as the most common benchmark of relative size. Equity capital in this industry amounted to $205.9 billion in 2012, supporting total assets of $4.55 trillion. Beginning in 1980 and extending up to the stock market crash of October 19, 1987, the number of firms in the industry expanded dramatically from 5,248 to 9,515. The aftermath of the crash saw a major shakeout, with the number of firms declining to 6,016 by 2006, a decline of 37 percent since 1987. Concentration of business among the largest firms over this period increased dramatically. Some of the significant growth in size came through M&As among the top ranked firms. Table 4–1 lists major U.S. securities industry M&A transactions, many of which involve repeated ownership changes of the same company. Notice from this table that many recent mergers and acquisitions have been interindustry mergers (i.e., insurance companies and investment banks). Recent regulatory changes such as the Financial Services Modernization Act of 1999 (discussed in Chapter 2 and described in more detail in Chapter 21) are a primary cause for such mergers. In fact, note in Table 4–1 that a majority of the securities’ industry mergers Chapter 4 TABLE 4–1 Major U.S. Securities Industry Merger and Acquisition Transactions Sources: Thomson Financial Securities Data; The Wall Street Journal; and authors’ figures. Rank 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 Financial Services: Securities Brokerage and Investment Banking Deal Citicorp merges with Travelers (which owns Smith Barney and Salomon) J.P. Morgan acquires Bank One* Bank of America acquires Merrill Lynch Bank of America acquires FleetBoston* Bank of America acquires Merrill Lynch Chase acquires J.P. Morgan* Bank of America acquires MBNA* Wachovia acquires Golden West Financial* Wachovia acquires Southtrust* BlackRock Inc. acquires Barclays Global UBS acquires Paine Webber Group Credit Suisse First Boston acquires Donaldson Lufkin Jenrette Dean Witter merges with Morgan Stanley† Deutsche Bank acquires Bankers Trust* Region’s Financial acquires AmSouth* CME Group acquires NYMEX Holdings Travelers acquires Salomon Inc. Intercontinental Exchange acquires NYSE Goldman Sachs acquires Spear, Leeds & Kellogg J.P. Morgan acquires Bear Stearns 87 Price ($ billions) Year $83.0 60.0 50.0 49.3 47.1 35.0 35.0 25.5 14.3 13.5 12.0 1998 2004 2008 2003 2008 2000 2005 2006 2004 2009 2000 11.5 10.2 10.1 10.0 9.5 9.0 8.2 6.5 0.2 2000 1997 1998 2006 2008 1997 2012 2000 2008 * These organizations own Section 20 securities subsidiaries and/or are established financial service holding companies under the 1999 Financial Services Modernization Act. † Value of Dean Witter, Discover shares to be exchanged for Morgan Stanley stock, based on closing price of $40.625 on February 5, 1997. broker–dealers Assist in the trading of existing securities. underwriting Assisting in the issue of new securities. and acquisitions occurring in the 2000s include securities firms that are a part of a financial services holding company. The financial crisis resulted in a second major change in the structure of the industry. The five largest investment banks in existence at the beginning of 2008 (Lehman Brothers, Bear Stearns, Merrill Lynch, Goldman Sachs, and Morgan Stanley) were all gone as investment banks by the end of the year. Lehman Brothers failed at the start of the financial crisis, Bear Stearns and Merrill Lynch were acquired by financial services holding companies (J.P. Morgan Chase and Bank of America, respectively), and Goldman Sachs and Morgan Stanley requested and were granted commercial bank charters. As of 2011, commercial bank holding companies’ fee income from securities brokerage topped $40.28 billion, up from $16.47 billion in 2007, and more than 65 percent of the industry total. Table 4–2 lists the top bank holding companies in terms of securities brokerage fee income. Further, the number of securities firms continued to fall to 4,481 by 2012. The investment banking industry was irrevocably changed. In its changed state, firms in the industry can be divided along a number of dimensions. The largest firms, the so-called national full-line firms, service both retail customers (especially in acting as broker–dealers, thus assisting in the trading of existing securities) and corporate customers (such as underwriting, thus assisting in the issue of new securities). With the changes in the past few years, national full-line firms now fall into three subgroups. First are the commercial bank 88 Part One Introduction TABLE 4–2 Bank Holding Company Top Bank Holding Companies in Securities Brokerage Fee Income, 2011 (in billions of dollars) Bank of America Morgan Stanley Wells Fargo Goldman Sachs J.P. Morgan Chase All bank holding companies Securities Brokerage Fee Income $ 9.93 7.47 4.75 3.01 2.75 $36.81 holding companies that are the largest of the full service investment banks. They have extensive domestic and international operations and offer advice, underwriting, brokerage, trading, and asset management services. The largest of these firms include Bank of America (through their acquisition of Merrill Lynch), Morgan Stanley, and J.P. Morgan Chase (through its many acquisitions, including that of Bear Stearns, for $240 million in 2008). Second are the national full-line firms that specialize more in corporate business with customers and are highly active in trading securities. Examples are Goldman Sachs and Salomon Brothers/Smith Barney, the investment banking arm of Citigroup (created from the merger of Travelers and Citicorp in 1998). Third are the large investment banks. These firms maintain more limited branch networks concentrated in major cities operating with predominantly institutional client bases. These firms include Lazard Ltd. and Greenhill & Co. The rest of the industry is comprised of firms that perform a mix of primary and secondary market services for a particular segment of the financial markets: discount brokers Stockbrokers that conduct trades for customers but do not offer investment advice. 1. Regional securities firms that are often subdivided into large, medium, and small categories and concentrate on servicing customers in a particular region, e.g., New York or California (such as Raymond James Financial). 2. Specialized discount brokers that effect trades for customers on- or offline without offering investment advice or tips (such as Charles Schwab). 3. Specialized electronic trading securities firms (such as E*trade) that provide a platform for customers to trade without the use of a broker. Rather, trades are enacted on a computer via the Internet.1 4. Venture capital firms that pool money from individual investors and other FIs (e.g., hedge funds, pension funds, and insurance companies) to fund relatively small and new businesses (e.g., in biotechnology).2 5. Other firms in this industry include research boutiques, floor specialists, companies with large clearing operations, and other firms that do not fit into one of the preceding categories. This would include firms such as Knight Capital Group (a leading firm in off-exchange trading of U.S. equities) and floor specialist LaBranche & Co. Securities firms and investment banks engage in as many as seven key activity areas investment banking, venture capital, market making, trading, investing, 1 Discount brokers and electronic trading securities firms usually charge lower commissions than do fullservice brokers such as Merrill Lynch. 2 Venture capital firms generally play an active management role in the firms in which they invest, often including a seat on the board of directors, and hold significant equity stakes. This differentiates them from traditional banking and securities firms. Chapter 4 Financial Services: Securities Brokerage and Investment Banking TABLE 4–3 Top Underwriters of Global Debt and Equity Source: Thompson Reuters Deals Intelligence, 2013. www.thompsonreuters.com Full Year 2012 Manager J.P. Morgan Deutsche Bank Barclays Capital Citigroup Bank of America Merrill Lynch Top ten Industry total 89 Full Year 2011 Amount (billions) Market Share Amount (billions) Rank Market Share $ 488.6 409.7 384.6 373.6 7.9% 6.6 6.2 6.0 $ 384.8 371.3 365.9 305.6 1 2 3 5 6.9% 6.7 6.6 5.5 339.1 $3,323.2 $6,191.7 5.5 53.6% 100.0% 325.6 $2,958.4 $5,569.7 4 5.9 53.2% 100.0% cash management, mergers and acquisitions, and other service functions. As we describe each of these, note that while each activity is available to a firm’s customers independently, many of these activities can be and are conducted simultaneously (such as mergers and acquisitions financed by new issues of debt and equity underwritten by the M&A advising firm) for a firm’s customers. 1. Investment Banking IPO An initial, or first time, public offering of debt or equity by a corporation. private placement A securities issue placed with one or a few large institutional investors. Investment banking refers to activities related to underwriting and distributing new issues of debt and equity. New issues can be either primary, the first-time issues of companies (sometimes called IPOs [initial public offerings]), or secondary issues (the new issues of seasoned firms whose debt or equity is already trading). In 2012, a total of $6.19 trillion of debt and equity was underwritten. This was up from $4.95 trillion underwritten in 2008 during the financial crisis, but well below the pre-crisis amounts of $7.51 and $7.84 trillion in 2007 and 2006, respectively. Table 4–3 lists the top 5 underwriters of global debt and equity for 2011 and 2012. The top 5 underwriters represented 32.2 percent and the top 10 firms represented more than 50 percent of the industry total, suggesting that the industry is dominated by a handful of top-tier underwriting firms. Top-tier rating and the implied reputation this brings has a huge effect in this business. At times, investment banks have refused to participate in an issue because their name would not be placed where they desired it on the “tombstone” advertisement announcing the issue and its major underwriters. Securities underwritings can be undertaken through either public offerings or private offerings. In a private offering, the investment banker acts as a private placement agent for a fee, placing the securities with one or a few large institutional investors such as life insurance companies. In a public offering, the securities may be underwritten on a best-efforts or a firm commitment basis, and the securities may be offered to the public at large. With best-efforts underwriting, investment bankers act as agents on a fee basis related to their success in placing the issue. In a firm commitment underwriting, the investment banker acts as a principal, purchasing the securities from the issuer at one price and seeking to place them with public investors at a slightly higher price. Finally, in addition to investment banking operations in the corporate securities markets, investment banks may participate as an underwriter (primary dealer) in government, municipal, and asset-backed securities. Table 4–4 shows the top-ranked underwriters for 2012 and 2011 in the different areas of securities underwriting. 90 Part One TABLE 4–4 Introduction Who Is the Lead Underwriter in Each Market? Source: Thompson Reuters Deals Intelligence, 2013. www.thompsonreuters.com Full Year 2012 Full Year 2011 Type Amount (billions) Top-Ranked Manager Amount (billions) Top-Ranked Manager Total debt Convertible debt Investment-grade debt Mortgage-backed securities $5,557.2 64.2 2,655.3 462.0 J.P. Morgan Deutsche Bank J.P. Morgan Deutsche Bank $4,952.2 65.4 2,258.7 521.5 Barclays Capital Goldman Sachs J.P. Morgan Bank of America Merrill Lynch Bank of America Merrill Lynch Goldman Sachs Goldman Sachs J.P. Morgan Asset-backed securities Common stock IPOs Syndicated loans EXAMPLE 4–1 Best Efforts versus Firm Commitment Securities Offering 321.0 566.2 117.4 3,226.8 J.P. Morgan Goldman Sachs Morgan Stanley J.P. Morgan 243.0 551.9 163.8 3,934.0 An investment bank agrees to underwrite an issue of 20 million shares of stock for Murray Construction Corp. on a firm commitment basis. The investment bank pays $15.50 per share to Murray Construction Corp. for the 20 million shares of stock. It then sells those shares to the public for $16.35 per share. How much money does Murray Construction Corp. receive? What is the profit to the investment bank? If the investment bank can sell the shares for only $14.75, how much money does Murray Construction Corp. receive? What is the profit to the investment bank? If the investment bank sells the stock for $16.35 per share, Murray Construction Corp. receives $15.50 ⫻ 20,000,000 shares ⫽ $310,000,000. The profit to the investment bank is ($16.35 ⫺ $15.50) ⫻ 20,000,000 shares ⫽ $17,000,000. The stock price of Murray Construction Corp. is $16.35 since that is what the public agrees to pay. From the perspective of Murray Construction Corp., the $17 million represents the commission that it must pay to issue the stock. If the investment bank sells the stock for $14.75 per share, Murray Construction Corp. still receives $15.50 ⫻ 20,000,000 shares ⫽ $310,000,000. The profit to the investment bank is ($14.75 ⫺ $15.50) ⫻ 20,000,000 shares ⫽ ⫺$15,000,000. The stock price of Murray Construction Corp. is $14.75 since that is what the public agrees to pay. From the perspective of the investment bank, the ⫺$15 million represents a loss for the firm commitment it made to Murray Construction Corp. to issue the stock. Suppose, instead, that the investment bank agrees to underwrite the 20 million shares on a best-efforts basis. The investment bank is able to sell 18.4 million shares for $15.50 per share, and it charges Murray Construction Corp. $0.375 per share sold. How much money does Murray Construction Corp. receive? What is the profit to the investment bank? If the investment bank can sell the shares for only $14.75, how much money does Murray Construction Corp. receive? What is the profit to the investment bank? If the investment bank sells the stock for $15.50 per share, Murray Construction Corp. receives ($15.50 ⫺ $0.375) ⫻ 18,400,000 shares ⫽ $278,300,000, the investment bank’s profit is $0.375 ⫻ 18,400,000 shares ⫽ $6,900,000, and the stock price is $15.50 per share since that is what the public pays. If the investment bank sells the stock for $14.75 per share, Murray Construction Corp. receives ($14.75 ⫺ $0.375) ⫻ 18,400,000 shares ⫽ $264,500,000, the investment bank’s profit is still $0.375 ⫻ 18,400,000 shares ⫽ $6,900,000, and the stock price is $14.75 per share since that is what the public pays. Chapter 4 Financial Services: Securities Brokerage and Investment Banking 91 2. Venture Capital venture capital A professionally managed pool of money used to finance new and often high-risk firms. institutional venture capital firms Business entities whose sole purpose is to find and fund the most promising new firms. angel venture capitalists (or angels) Wealthy individuals who make equity investments. A difficulty for new and small firms in obtaining debt financing from commercial banks (or CBs) is that CBs are generally not willing or able to make loans to new companies with no assets and business history. In this case, new and small firms often turn to investment banks (and other firms) that make venture capital investments to get capital financing as well as advice. Venture capital is a professionally managed pool of money used to finance new and often high-risk firms. Venture capital is generally provided to back an untried company and its managers in return for an equity investment in the firm. Venture capital firms do not make outright loans. Rather, they purchase an equity interest in the firm that gives them the same rights and privileges associated with an equity investment made by the firm’s other owners. The terms venture capital and private equity are often used interchangeably. However, there are distinct differences in the two types of investment institutions. For example, venture capital firms generally, using the pooled investment resources of institutions and wealthy individuals, concern themselves more with startup business concerns. Private equity firms acquire the investment funds they use from sources such as equity securities and non–publicly traded stocks as well as the institutional and individual investment pooling used by venture capital firms. Further, venture capital firms tend to utilize teams of either scientific or business professionals to help identify new and emerging technologies in which to place their money. Private equity firms deal more with existing companies that have already proven themselves in the business field. As a result of the financial crisis, the differences between venture capital firms and private equity firms have become less distinct. With fewer new ventures being brought forth, there has been greater competition between the two types of investment institutions, with both searching for and funding the same types of new and small firms. There are many types of venture capital firms. Institutional venture capital firms are business entities whose sole purpose is to find and fund the most promising new firms. Private sector institutional venture capital firms include venture capital limited partnerships (that are established by professional venture capital firms, acting as general partners in the firm: organizing and managing the firm and eventually liquidating their equity investment), financial venture capital firms (subsidiaries of investment or commercial banks), and corporate venture capital firms (subsidiaries of nonfinancial corporations that generally specialize in making startup investments in high-tech firms). Limited partner venture capital firms dominate the industry. In addition to these private sector institutional venture capital firms, the federal government, through the Small Business Administration (SBA), operates small business investment companies (SBICs). SBICs are privately organized venture capital firms licensed by the SBA that make equity investments (as well as loans) to entrepreneurs for startup activities and expansions. As federally sponsored entities, SBICs have relied on their unique opportunity to obtain investment funds from the U.S. Treasury at very low rates relative to private sector institutional venture capital firms. In contrast to institutional venture capital firms, angel venture capitalists (or angels) are wealthy individuals who make equity investments. Angel venture capitalists have invested much more in new and small firms than institutional venture capital firms. Venture capital firms receive many unsolicited proposals of funding from new and small firms. A majority of these requests are rejected. Venture capital firms look for two things in making their decisions to invest in a firm. The first is a 92 Part One Introduction high return. Venture capital firms are willing to invest in high-risk new and small firms. However, they require high levels of returns (sometimes as high as 700 percent within five to seven years) to take on these risks. The second is an easy exit. Venture capital firms realize a profit on their investments by eventually selling their interests in the firm. They want a quick and easy exit opportunity when it comes time to sell. Basically, venture capital firms provide equity funds to new, unproven, and young firms. This separates venture capital firms from commercial banks, which prefer to invest in existing, financially secure businesses. 3. Market Making Market making involves creating a secondary market in an asset by a securities firm or investment bank. Thus, in addition to being primary dealers in government securities and underwriters of corporate bonds and equities, investment banks make a secondary market in these instruments. Market making can involve either agency or principal transactions. Agency transactions are two-way transactions on behalf of customers, for example, acting as a stockbroker or dealer for a fee or commission. On the NYSE, a market maker in a stock such as IBM may, upon the placement of orders by its customers, buy the stock at $190 from one customer and immediately resell it at $191 to another customer. The $1 difference between the buy and sell price is usually called the bid–ask spread and represents a large portion of the market maker’s profit. In principal transactions, the market maker seeks to profit on the price movements of securities and takes either long or short inventory positions for its own account. (Or an inventory position may be taken to stabilize the market in the securities.) In the example above, the market maker would buy the IBM stock at $190 and hold it in its own portfolio in expectation of a price increase later on. Normally, market making can be a fairly profitable business. However, in periods of market stress or high volatility, these profits can rapidly disappear. For example, on the NYSE, market makers, in return for having monopoly power in market making for individual stocks (e.g., IBM), have an affirmative obligation to buy stocks from sellers even when the market is crashing. This caused a number of actual and near bankruptcies for NYSE market makers at the time of the October 1987 market crash. On NASDAQ, which has a system of competing market makers, liquidity was significantly impaired at the time of the crash and a number of firms had to withdraw from market making. Finally, the recent moves toward decimalization of equities markets in the United States (i.e., expressing quotes in integers of 1 cent [e.g., $50.32] rather than rounding to eighths [e.g., 503/8]) has cut into traders’ profits, as has competition from Internet-based or electronic-based exchanges such as Instinet Group. 4. Trading Trading is closely related to the market-making activities just described, where a trader takes an active net position in an underlying instrument or asset. There are at least six types of trading activities: 1. Position trading involves purchasing large blocks of securities on the expectation of a favorable price move. Position traders maintain long or short positions for intervals of up to several weeks or even months. Rather than attempting to profit from very short-term movements in prices, as day traders do, position traders take relatively longer views of market trends. Such positions also facilitate the smooth functioning of the secondary markets in such securities. Chapter 4 Financial Services: Securities Brokerage and Investment Banking 93 2. Pure arbitrage entails buying an asset in one market at one price and selling it immediately in another market at a higher price. Pure arbitrage “locks in” profits that are available in the market. This profit position usually occurs with no equity investment, the use of only very short-term borrowed funds, and reduced transaction costs for securities firms. Pure arbitrageurs often attempt to profit from price discrepancies that may exist between the spot, or cash, price of a security and its corresponding futures price. Some important theoretical pricing relationships in futures markets should exist with spot markets and prices. When these relationships get out of line, pure arbitrageurs enter the market to exploit them. 3. Risk arbitrage involves buying securities in anticipation of some information release, such as a merger or takeover announcement or a Federal Reserve interest rate announcement. It is termed risk arbitrage because if the event does not actually occur—for example, if a merger does not take place or the Federal Reserve does not change interest rates—the trader stands to lose money. 4. Program trading is defined by the NYSE as the simultaneous buying and selling of a portfolio of at least 15 different stocks valued at more than $1 million, using computer programs to initiate such trades. Program trading is often associated with seeking a risk arbitrage between a cash market price (e.g., the Standard & Poor’s 500 Stock Market Index) and the futures market price of that instrument.3 Because computers are used to continuously monitor stock and futures prices—and can even initiate buy or sell orders—these trades are classified separately as program trading. 5. Stock brokerage involves the trading of securities on behalf of individuals who want to transact in the money or capital markets. To conduct such transactions, individuals contact their broker (such as Merrill Lynch), which then sends the orders to its representative at the exchange to conduct the trades. Large brokerage firms often have several licenses on the floor of a stock exchange (e.g., NYSE), through which their commission brokers trade orders from the firm’s clients or for the firms own account. 6. Electronic brokerage, offered by major brokers, involves direct access, via the Internet, to the trading floor, therefore bypassing traditional brokers. Many securities firms and investment banks offer online trading services to their customers as well as direct access to a client representative (stockbroker). Thus, customers may now conduct trading activities from their homes and offices through their accounts at securities firms. Because services provided by a typical brokerage firm are bypassed, the cost per share is generally lower and the price may be advantageous compared with trading directly on the exchanges. Users of the system can often use the network to discover existing sizes and quotes of offers to buy or sell. Interested parties can then negotiate with each other using the system’s computers. As with many activities of securities firms, such trading can be conducted on behalf of a customer as an agent (or broker), or on behalf of the firm as a principal. When trading at the retail level occurs on behalf of customers, it is often called brokerage (or stock brokering). 3 An example would be buying the cash S&P index and selling futures contracts on the S&P index. Since stocks and futures contracts trade in different markets, their prices are not always equal. Moreover, program trading can occur between futures and cash markets in other assets, e.g., commodities. 94 Part One Introduction 5. Investing Investing involves managing not only pools of assets such as closed- and open end mutual funds but also pension funds in competition with life insurance companies. Securities firms can manage such funds either as agents for other investors or as principals for themselves. The objective in funds management is to choose asset allocations to beat some return–risk performance benchmark such as the S&P 500 index. Since this business generates fees that are based on the size of the pool of assets managed, it tends to produce a more stable flow of income than does either investment banking or trading. 6. Cash Management cash management accounts Money market mutual funds sold by investment banks; most CMAs offer check-writing privileges. Investment banks offer bank deposit-like cash management accounts (CMAs) to individual investors and since the 1999 Financial Services Modernization Act, deposit accounts themselves (Merrill Lynch was the first investment bank to offer a direct deposit account in June 2000, via the two banks it owned). Most of these CMAs allow customers to write checks against some type of mutual fund account (e.g., money market mutual fund). These accounts, when issued in association with commercial banks and thrifts, can even be covered by federal deposit insurance from the FDIC. CMAs were adopted by other security firms under various names (e.g., house account) and spread rapidly. Many of these accounts offer ATM services and debit cards. As a result of CMAs, the distinction between commercial banks and investment banks became blurred. However, the advantage of brokerage firm CMAs over commercial bank deposit accounts is that they make it easier to buy and sell securities. The broker can take funds out of the CMA account when an investor buys a security and deposit funds back into the CMA when the investor sells securities. CMAs were instrumental in the securities industry’s efforts to provide commercial banking services prior to the 1999 Financial Services Modernization Act. Since the passage of this regulation, securities firms are allowed to make loans, offer credit and debit cards, provide ATM services, and, most importantly, sell securities. 7. Mergers and Acquisitions Investment banks are frequently involved in providing advice or assisting in mergers and acquisitions. For example, they will assist in finding merger partners, underwriting new securities to be issued by the merged firms, assessing the value of target firms, recommending terms of the merger agreement, and even helping target firms prevent a merger (e.g., seeing that poison-pill provisions are written into a potential target firm’s securities contracts). As noted in the introduction to this chapter, U.S. merger and acquisition activity stood at $882 billion in 2012. Panel A of Table 4–5 lists the top 10 investment bank merger advisors ranked by dollar volume of domestic mergers in which they were involved. Panel B of Table 4–5 lists the top 10 investment banks ranked by dollar volume of worldwide M&A activity. Notice that many of the top U.S.-ranked investment banks reported in panel A of Table 4–5 are also top-ranked for worldwide activity in panel B. 8. Back-Office and Other Service Functions These functions include custody and escrow services, clearance and settlement services, and research and other advisory services—for example, giving advice on divestitures and asset sales. In addition, investment banks are making increasing inroads into traditional bank service areas such as small business lending and the Chapter 4 TABLE 4–5 Ten Largest Merger and Acquisition Firms Ranked by Value of Mergers, 2012 Source: Thompson Reuters Deals Intelligence, 2013. www.thompsonreuters.com Financial Services: Securities Brokerage and Investment Banking 95 Panel A: Mergers Completed in U.S. Rank 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Investment Bank Goldman Sachs J.P. Morgan Barclays Capital Credit Suisse Morgan Stanley Evercore Partners Citigroup Bank of America Merrill Lynch Lazard Deutsche Bank Industry total Value ($ billions) $299.8 241.5 229.9 216.7 175.2 140.9 134.1 131.5 124.8 101.3 $882.1 Number of Deals 140 114 120 86 95 65 72 91 91 66 6,951 Panel B: Worldwide Mergers Rank 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Investment Bank Goldman Sachs J.P. Morgan Morgan Stanley Credit Suisse Barclays Capital Bank of America Merrill Lynch Deutsche Bank Citigroup Lazard Rothschild Industry total Credit Lent ($ billions) $ 570.2 406.4 379.4 354.5 321.6 274.2 265.0 238.1 220.0 164.6 $2,040.6 Number of Deals 352 247 320 231 235 192 216 184 223 234 28,454 trading of loans (see Chapter 21). In performing these functions, an investment bank normally acts as an agent for a fee. As mentioned above, fees charged are often based on the total bundle of services performed for the client by the firm. The portion of the fee or commission allocated to research and advisory services is called soft dollars. When one area in the firm, such as an investment advisor, uses client commissions to buy research from another area in the firm, it receives a benefit because it is relieved from the need to produce and pay for the research itself. Thus, the advisor using soft dollars faces a conflict of interest between the need to obtain research and the client’s interest in paying the lowest commission rate available. Because of the conflict of interest that exists, the SEC (the primary regulator of investment banks and securities firms) requires these firms to disclose soft dollar arrangements to their clients. Nevertheless, in the early and mid-2000s tremendous publicity was generated concerning conflicts of interest in a number of investment banks between analysts’ research recommendations on stocks to buy or not buy and whether the firm played a role in underwriting the securities of the firm the analysts were recommending. After an investigation by the New York State Attorney General, Merrill 96 Part One Introduction Lynch agreed to pay a fine of $100 million and to follow procedures more clearly separating analysts’ recommendations (and their compensation) from the underwriting activities of the firm. A number of other major Wall Street firms were also placed under investigation (discussed later). The investigation was triggered by the dramatic collapse of many new technology stocks while analysts were still making recommendations to buy or hold them. Concept Questions 1. Describe the difference between brokerage services and underwriting services. 2. What are the key areas of activities for securities firms and investment banks? 3. Describe the difference between a best-efforts offering and a firm commitment offering. 4. What are the trading activities performed by securities firms and investment banks? BALANCE SHEET AND RECENT TRENDS Recent Trends In this section, we look at the balance sheet and trends in the securities firm and investment banking industry. Trends in this industry depend heavily on the state of the stock market. For example, a major effect of the 1987 stock market crash was a sharp decline in stock market trading volume and thus in brokerage commissions earned by securities firms over the 1987–91 period. The overall decline in brokerage commissions actually began more than 35 years ago, in 1977. The decline is reflective of a long-term fall in the importance of commission income, as a percentage of revenues, for securities firms as a result of the abolition of fixed commissions on securities trades imposed by the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) in May 1975 and the fierce competition for wholesale commissions and trades that followed (see Figure 4–2). Commission income began to stabilize and recover only after 1992, with record equity trading volumes being achieved in 1995–2000 when the Dow Jones and S&P indexes hit new highs. Improvements in the U.S. economy in the mid-2000s resulted in even greater increases in stock market values and trading and thus commission income. However, rising oil prices and the subprime mortgage market collapse and the eventual full market crash in 2008–09 pushed stock market values down. As a result, commission income in the securities industry declined as well. As the economy and the stock market recovered in the early 2010s, commission income again rose to almost 20 percent of total revenues. Also affecting the profitability of the securities industry was the decline in new equity issues over the 1987–90 period as well as a decline in bond and equity underwriting in general (see Table 4–6). This was due partly to the stock market crash, partly to a decline in mergers and acquisitions, partly to a general economic recession, and partly to investor concerns about the high-risk junk-bond market, which crashed during this period. Between 1991 and 2001, however, the securities industry showed a resurgence in profitability. For example, domestic underwriting activity over the 1990–2001 period grew from $192.7 billion in 1990 to $1,623.9 billion in 2001 (see Table 4–6). The principal reasons for this were enhanced trading profits and increased growth in new issue underwritings. In particular, corporate debt issues became highly attractive to corporate treasurers because of relatively low long-term interest rates. Moreover, growth in the asset-backed Chapter 4 FIGURE 4–2 Financial Services: Securities Brokerage and Investment Banking 97 Commission Income as a Percentage of Total Revenues Sources: Securities and Exchange Commission, Standard & Poor’s Industry Surveys, and Securities Industry and Financial Markets Association. 45% 40 35 30 25 20 15 10 1977 TABLE 4–6 1980 1985 1990 1995 Year 2000 2005 2010 U.S. Corporate Underwriting Activity (in billions of dollars) Source: Securities Industry and Financial Markets Association. www.sifma.com Straight ConAssetNon Corporate vertible Backed agency Debt Debt Debt MBS 1986 134.9 9.8 1987 108.5 10.3 1990 76.5 5.5 1995 279.8 12.0 2000 587.5 49.6 2001 776.1 78.3 2002 635.4 30.5 2005 752.8 30.1 2006 1,058.9 62.8 2007 1,128.3 76.4 2008 707.2 42.0 2009 901.9 33.0 2010 1,062.8 29.1 2011 1,012.1 20.7 2012 1,354.5 19.7 % Change 33.8% ⫺5.1% (YTD 2011 to YTD 2012) 10.0 8.9 43.6 113.1 337.0 383.3 496.2 753.5 753.9 509.7 163.3 150.9 107.5 124.8 199.4 59.8% 62.2 83.3 43.2 36.5 102.1 216.5 263.9 901.2 917.4 773.9 45.0 32.4 19.0 22.9 39.3 71.1% Total Debt 216.9 211.0 168.8 441.4 1,076.2 1,454.2 1,399.0 2,437.6 2,793.0 2,488.2 957.4 1,118.2 1,218.4 1,180.5 1,612.9 36.6% Common Preferred Total Stock Stock Equity 43.2 41.5 19.2 82.0 189.1 128.4 116.4 160.5 157.2 187.5 164.9 254.6 239.5 185.1 245.1 32.4% 13.9 11.4 4.7 15.1 15.4 41.3 37.6 29.9 33.4 60.0 77.3 9.6 22.2 13.3 32.5 144.4% 57.1 52.9 23.9 97.1 204.5 169.7 154.0 190.4 190.5 247.5 242.3 264.2 261.7 198.4 277.6 39.9% All IPOs 22.3 24.0 10.1 30.2 76.1 40.8 41.2 62.6 57.9 91.1 11.0 26.9 52.0 47.8 55.4 15.7% Total Underwriting 274.0 263.9 192.7 538.5 1,280.7 1,623.9 1,553.0 2,628.0 2,983.5 2,735.7 1,199.7 1,382.4 1,480.0 1,378.9 1,890.5 37.1% Note: High-yield bonds represent a subset of straight corporate debt. IPOs are a subset of common stock; true and closed-end fund IPOs are subsets of all IPOs. 98 Part One FIGURE 4–3 Introduction Securities Industry Pretax Profits, 1990–2012 Source: Securities Industry and Financial Markets Association, various years. www.sifma.com Billlons $75 65 55 45 35 25 15 5 −51990 Year 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 −15 −25 −35 securities market as a result of increased securitization of mortgages (and growth of mortgage debt) added to the value of underwriting.4 As a result of enhanced trading profits and growth in new issue underwriting, pretax net income for the industry topped $9 billion each year over the 1996–2000 period (see Figure 4–3). This is despite the collapse of the Russian ruble and bond markets, economic turmoil in Asia, and political uncertainty in Washington during this period. Possibly more surprising is that despite a downturn in the U.S. economy toward the end of 2000, pretax profits soared to an all-time high of $31.6 billion in 2000. The continued slowdown of the U.S. economy in 2001 and the terrorist attacks on the World Trade Center (which housed offices of many securities firms and investment banks) in September 2001, however, brought an end to these record profits. Industry pretax profits for the year 2001 fell 24 percent, to $16 billion. The Bank of New York alone estimated costs associated with the terrorist attacks were $125 million. Citigroup estimated it lost $100–$200 million in business from branches that were closed and because of the four days the stock market did not trade. Morgan Stanley, the largest commercial tenant in the World Trade Center, said the cost of property damage and relocation of its employees was $150 million. Also impacting profit, the securities industry was rocked by several allegations of securities law violations as well as a loss of investor confidence in Wall Street and corporate America as a result of a number of corporate governance failures and accounting scandals involving Enron, Merck, WorldCom, and other major U.S. corporations. With the recovery of the U.S. economy in the mid-2000s, the U.S. securities industry again earned record profits as revenue growth strengthened and became 4 Another sign of the resurgence in this industry during the 1990s appears in employment figures. Annual U.S. securities industry employment increased by 72 percent (from 486,000 jobs in 1992 to 837,000 in 2000 [peaking at 840,900 in March 2001]). Chapter 4 Financial Services: Securities Brokerage and Investment Banking 99 more broadly based. Domestic underwriting surged to $2,983.5 billion in 2006, from $1,553.0 billion in 2002 (see Table 4–6). Further, the industry increased its profitability through deep cuts in expenses. Total expenses fell 10.4 percent from 2002 levels, largely due to lower interest expenses. Interest expense fell an estimated 22.5 percent from $48.4 billion in 2002 to $37.5 billion in 2003. The results for 2003 were a surge in pretax profits to $24.1 billion (see Figure 4–3). Interest rate increases in 2005 caused interest expense incurred by the securities industry to increase. The result was that, while gross revenues remained high, the increased interest expense caused pretax profits to fall to $17.6 billion in 2005. A surge in revenues from trading gains and corporate advisory services caused pretax profits to bounce back to a record level of $33.1 billion for 2006. Signs of the impending financial crisis arose in 2007. The industry began 2007 on a strong note but, hit by the subprime mortgage market meltdown that began in the summer of 2007, ended the year with pretax profits of just $0.78 billion. Many revenue lines showed solid growth in 2007, and total revenues reached a record high of $474.2 billion. However, trading and investment account losses were large, totaling a loss of $6 billion in 2007 compared with a gain of $43 billion in 2006. Further, expenses grew faster than revenues, to a record $473.4 billion in 2007. The worst of the financial crisis hit in 2008 as the industry reported a record loss for the year of $34.1 billion. Revenues were $290.5 billion, down 38.7 percent from 2007. Nearly all revenue lines decreased from 2007 levels, with trading and investment account losses being the largest (⫺$65.0 billion in 2008). As quickly as industry profits plunged during the financial crisis, they recovered in 2009. Pretax profits were a record $61.4 billion. Revenues totaled $288.1 billion for the year. Commission and fee income was $49.0 billion of the total, reflecting improved trading volume. Trading revenues, which had been negative for six consecutive quarters, grew to $45.3 billion. Industry expenses for 2009 were $212.4 billion, 33.7 percent below 2008 levels. Of this, interest expense fell to just $21.9 billion, 82.2 percent below 2008 levels. While still in a fragile state, the industry seemed to be recovering along with the economy. The U.S. and world economies grew very slowly after the financial crisis. While interest rates remained at historic lows, concerns about the health of eurozone economies and the U.S. fiscal cliff kept economic growth at a standstill. Memories of the financial crisis were still fresh in the minds of investors. Events such as the May 2010 “flash crash,” the October 2011 collapse of MF Global Holdings, and the August 2012 trading glitch at Knight Capital caused individual and institutional investors to limit capital market activity. Industry pretax profits fell to $34.8 billion, $10.6 billion, and $12.4 billion in 2010, 2011, and 2012, respectively. Balance Sheet The consolidated balance sheet for the industry is shown in Table 4–7. Note the current importance of securities trading and underwriting in the consolidated balance sheet of all securities firms. Looking at the asset portfolio, we can see that reverse repurchase agreements—securities purchased under agreements to resell (i.e., the broker gives a short-term loan to the repurchase agreement seller)— accounted for 34.7 percent, receivables from other broker–dealers accounted for 27.9 percent, and long positions in securities and commodities accounted for 23.6 percent of assets. Because of the extent to which this industry’s balance sheet consists of financial market securities, the industry is subjected to particularly high levels of market risk (see Chapter 15) and interest rate risk (see Chapters 8 and 9). 100 Part One Introduction TABLE 4–7 Assets and Liabilities of Broker–Dealers as of 2012 (in billions of dollars) Source: Focus Report, Office of Economic Analysis, U.S. Securities and Exchange Commission, 2013. www.sec.gov Percent of Total Assets Assets Cash Receivables from other broker–dealers Receivables from customers Receivables from noncustomers Long positions in securities and commodities Securities and investments not readily marketable Securities purchased under agreements to resell Exchange membership Other assets Total assets Liabilities Bank loans payable Payables to other broker–dealers Payables to noncustomers Payables to customers Short positions in securities and commodities Securities sold under repurchase agreements Other nonsubordinated liabilities Subordinated liabilities Total liabilities Capital Equity capital Total capital (equity capital and subordinate liabilities) Number of firms $ 117.2 1,267.6 192.5 47.0 1,074.6 19.7 1,577.4 0.2 254.1 $4,550.3 2.6% 27.9 4.2 1.0 23.6 0.4 34.7 0.0 5.6 $ 45.0 621.1 71.0 681.3 381.6 2,065.6 356.9 121.9 $4,344.4 1.0% 13.6 1.6 15.0 8.4 45.4 2.7 2.7 95.5% $ 205.9 4.5% 327.8 4,481 7.2% Further, to the extent that many of these securities are foreign issued securities, FI managers must also be concerned with foreign exchange risk (see Chapter 13) and sovereign risk (see Chapter 14). With respect to liabilities, repurchase agreements were the major source of funds; these are securities temporarily lent in exchange for cash received. Repurchase agreements—securities sold under agreements to repurchase—amounted to 45.4 percent of total liabilities and equity. The other major sources of funds were payables to customers, payables to other broker–dealers, and securities and commodities sold short for future delivery. Equity capital amounted to only 4.5 percent of total assets, while total capital (equity capital plus subordinated liabilities) accounted for 7.2 percent of total assets. These levels are well below those we saw for depository institutions in Chapter 2 (11.48 percent for commercial banks, 11.89 percent for savings institutions, and 10.35 percent for credit unions). One reason for lower capital levels is that securities firms’ balance sheets contain mostly tradable (liquid) securities compared with the relatively illiquid loans that constitute a significant proportion of depository institutions’ asset portfolios. Securities firms are required to maintain a net worth (capital) to assets ratio in excess of 2 percent (see Chapter 20). Chapter 4 Financial Services: Securities Brokerage and Investment Banking Concept Questions 101 1. Describe the trend in profitability in the securities industry over the past 10 years. 2. What are the major assets held by broker–dealers? 3. Why do broker–dealers tend to hold less equity capital than do commercial banks and thrifts? REGULATION www.sec.gov www.finra.org The primary regulator of the securities industry is the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC), established in 1934 largely in response to abuses by securities firms that many at the time felt were partly responsible for the economic problems in the United States. The primary role of the SEC includes administration of securities laws, review and evaluation of registrations of new securities offerings (ensuring that all relevant information is revealed to potential investors), review and evaluation of annual and semiannual reports summarizing the financial status of all publicly held corporations, and the prohibition of any form of security market manipulation. The National Securities Markets Improvement Act (NSMIA) of 1996 reaffirmed the significance of the SEC as the primary regulator of securities firms. According to the NSMIA, states are no longer allowed to require federally registered securities firms to be registered in a state as well. States are also now prohibited from requiring registration of securities firms’ transactions and from imposing substantive requirements on private placements. Prior to the NSMIA, most securities firms were subject to regulation from the SEC and from each state in which they operated. While the NSMIA provides that states may still require securities firms to pay fees and file documents to be submitted to the SEC, most of the regulatory burden imposed by states has been removed. Thus, the NSMIA effectively gives the SEC the exclusive regulatory jurisdiction over securities firms. The early 2000s saw a reversal of this trend toward the dominance of the SEC, with states—especially their attorneys general—increasingly intervening through securities-related investigations. Several highly publicized securities violations resulted in criminal cases brought against securities law violators by mainly state and some federal prosecutors. For example, the New York State attorney general forced Merrill Lynch to pay a $100 million penalty because of allegations that Merrill Lynch brokers gave investors overly optimistic reports about the stock of its investment banking clients. In the spring of 2003 the issue culminated in an agreement between regulators and 10 of the nation’s largest securities firms to pay a record $1.4 billion in penalties to settle charges involving investor abuse. The long-awaited settlement centered on charges that securities firms routinely issued overly optimistic stock research to investors in order to gain favor with corporate clients and win their investment banking business. The agreement also settled charges that at least two big firms, Citigroup and Credit Suisse First Boston, improperly allocated initial public offering (IPO) shares to corporate executives to win banking business from their firms. The SEC and other regulators, including the Financial Industry Regulatory Authority (FINRA) and state regulators, unveiled multiple examples of how Wall Street stock analysts tailored their research reports and ratings to win investment banking business. The agreement forced brokerage companies to make structural 102 Part One Introduction changes in the way they handle research—preventing analysts, for example, from attending certain investment banking meetings with bankers. The agreement also required securities firms to have separate reporting and supervisory structures for their research and banking operations. Additionally, it required that analysts’ pay be tied to the quality and accuracy of their research, rather than the amount of investment banking business they generate. Table 4–8 lists the 10 firms involved in the settlement and the penalties assessed. Subsequent to these investigations, the SEC instituted rules requiring Wall Street analysts to vouch that their stock picks are not influenced by investment banking colleagues and that analysts disclose details of their compensation that would flag investors to any possible conflicts. If evidence surfaces that analysts have falsely attested to the independence of their work, it could be used to bring enforcement actions. Violators could face a wide array of sanctions, including fines and other penalties, such as a suspension or a bar from the securities industry. In addition, the SEC now requires that top officials from all public companies sign off on financial statements. Despite all of these changes, in December 2012, Morgan Stanley agreed to pay $5 million to settle allegations that one of its senior investment bankers tried to improperly influence research analysts in the days before Facebook went public in May 2012. Allegations involved in the charge that the senior investment banker arranged phone calls from Facebook to analysts in a way that favored large investors over small investors and that violated restrictions on investment bankers’ role in the IPO process. While the SEC sets the overall regulatory standards for the industry, the Financial Industry Regulatory Authority (FINRA) is involved in the day-to-day regulation of trading practices. The FINRA monitors trading abuses (such as insider trading) trading rule violations, and securities firms’ capital (solvency) positions. For example, in January 2013, FINRA announced that it is expanding its oversight of dark pool trading. Dark pools are trades created by institutional orders away from central exchanges. The details of the trades are unavailable to the public. As of 2013, nearly 15 percent of all stock trades in the United States occurred through dark pools, up from 3 percent in 2007. As more financial trading has occurred in dark pools, regulators and investors are concerned that firms are placing orders on exchanges and in dark pools at the same time to move stock prices to their advantage. FINRA’s expanded oversight is intended to monitor and determine TABLE 4–8 Securities Firm Penalties Assessed for Trading Abuses Source: Authors’ research, 2004. Firm Citigroup Credit Suisse First Boston Merrill Lynch Morgan Stanley Goldman Sachs Bear Stearns J.P. Morgan Chase Lehman Brothers UBS Warburg Piper Jaffray Penalty ($ millions) $400 200 200 125 110 80 80 80 80 32 Chapter 4 Financial Services: Securities Brokerage and Investment Banking 103 whether orders placed in dark pools are indeed attempts at moving stock prices. FINRA also announced that it is increasing its surveillance of high-speed trading and rapid-fire trading across exchanges. Also overseeing this industry at the federal level is the U.S. Congress. For example, along with changes instituted by the SEC, the U.S. Congress passed the Sarbanes-Oxley Act in July 2002. This act created an independent auditing oversight board under the SEC, increased penalties for corporate wrongdoers, forced faster and more extensive financial disclosure, and created avenues of recourse for aggrieved shareholders. The goal of the legislation was to prevent deceptive accounting and management practices and to bring stability to jittery stock markets battered in the summer of 2002 by corporate governance scandals of Enron, Global Crossings, Tyco, WorldCom, and others. More recently, the U.S. Senate Permanent Subcommittee on Investigations was created with the broad mandate to determine whether any changes are required in U.S. law to better protect the public. In the spring of 2010, a subcommittee hearing focused on the role of investment banks in contributing to the financial crisis. Investment banks such as Goldman Sachs bundled toxic mortgages into complex financial instruments, many of which were rated AAA by credit rating agencies, and sold them to investors. Goldman Sachs, in an attempt to manage its own risk on these securities, shorted the mortgage market, setting itself up for gains that would offset losses on the mortgage securities. The subcommittee brought up evidence and internal Goldman documents that showed Goldman knew the housing market was on the brink of collapse but continued to sell mortgage-backed securities to investors. All the while, Goldman allegedly bet against the securities it built and sold with the knowledge that the housing market’s collapse would bring the firm a sizable payday. The 2010 Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act, passed in response to the financial crisis, set forth many changes in the way securities firms and investment banks are regulated. The bill’s Financial Services Oversight Council of financial regulators was given oversight of the industry in its charge to identify emerging systemic risks. Also under the act, effective July 21, 2011, the dollar threshold for determining whether an investment advisor must register under federal or state law increased. Specifically, all advisors with assets under management of less than $100 million must register with state regulators and those with more than $100 million under management must register with the SEC. Prior to that date, only advisors with assets under management of less than $25 million registered with a state regulator. The bill also gave new authority for the Federal Reserve to supervise all firms that could pose a threat to financial stability and called for stronger capital and other prudential standards for all financial firms, and even higher standards for large, interconnected firms. Investment banks also saw stricter oversight as the bill called for the regulation of securitization markets, stronger regulation of credit rating agencies, a requirement that issuers and originators retain a financial interest in securitized loans, comprehensive regulation of all over-the-counter derivatives, and new authority for the Federal Reserve to oversee payment, clearing, and settlement systems. Finally, the bill gave authority to the government to resolve nonbank financial institutions whose failure could have serious systemic effects and revised the Federal Reserve’s emergency lending authority to improve accountability. One of the most publicized “missteps” by securities firms and investment banks over the course of the financial crisis was related to executive compensation. Top 104 Part One Introduction www.sipc.org Concept Questions executives received millions of dollars in bonuses for taking risks that in some cases paid off and in others cases left taxpayers to bailout the firms. As a result, the Obama administration proposed compensation rule changes for all financial institutions. Specifically, the administration called for stronger assurances that compensation committees are independent from senior management. It also proposed regulations that gave shareholders at all publicly traded companies a nonbinding vote on executive compensation packages. Finally, at FIs receiving government support, the administration’s “pay czar,” Kenneth Feinberg, was given a say over compensation packages given to top executives. While meant to curb what was seen by many as excessive pay, others argued that these restrictions would make it difficult to attract and retain talent sufficient to keep domestic FIs on a competitive footing with their global peers. Securities firms and investment banks have historically been strongly supportive of efforts to combat money laundering, and the industry has been subject to federal laws that impose extensive reporting and record-keeping requirements. However, the USA Patriot Act, passed in response to the September 11 terrorist attacks, included additional provisions that financial services firms must implement. The new rules, which took effect on October 1, 2003, imposed three requirements on firms in the industry. First, firms must verify the identity of any person seeking to open an account. Second, firms must maintain records of the information used to verify the person’s identity. Third, firms must determine whether a person opening an account appears on any list of known or suspected terrorists or terrorist organizations. The rules are intended to deter money laundering without imposing undue burdens that would constrain the ability of firms to serve their customers. Finally, the Securities Investor Protection Corporation (SIPC) protects investors against losses of up to $500,000 caused by securities firm failures. This guaranty fund was created after the passage of the Securities Investor Protection Act in 1970 and is funded with premium contributions from member firms. The fund protects investor accounts against the possibility of a member broker–dealer not being able to meet its financial obligations to customers. The fund does not, however, protect against losses on a customer’s account due to poor investment choices that reduce the value of a portfolio. 1. What is the major result of the NSMIA? 2. What regulatory changes resulted from the financial crisis? GLOBAL ISSUES £ ¥ :$ Much more so than other sectors of the financial institutions industry, securities firms and investment banks operate globally. Both U.S. and European investment banks compete for business worldwide. This can be seen in Table 4–3, as three of the top 5 (and 5 of the top 10) underwriters of global debt and equity are U.S. investment banks (e.g., J.P. Morgan Chase, Bank of America Merrill Lynch) and the rest European banks (e.g., Barclays Capital, Credit Suisse). In 2012, in M&A deals involving U.S. targets, 7 of the top 10 advisors were U.S. investment banks Chapter 4 Financial Services: Securities Brokerage and Investment Banking 105 (e.g., Morgan Stanley, Goldman Sachs) and 3 were European banks (e.g., Barclays Capital, Deutsche Bank). Further, U.S. investment banks held 6 of the top 10 spots on M&A deals in Europe and held five of the top spots on deals in Asia. As domestic securities trading and underwriting have grown in the 1990s and 2000s, so have foreign securities trading and underwriting. Tables 4–9 and 4–10 show foreign transactions in U.S. securities and U.S. transactions in foreign securities from 1991–2012. For example, foreign investors’ transactions involving U.S. stocks increased from $211.2 billion in 1991 to $12,037.9 billion in 2008 (an increase of 5,600 percent) before falling to $6,654.0 in 2009, during the financial crisis. As of 2012, stock transactions had increased to only $7,048.6 billion. Similarly, U.S. investors’ transactions involving stocks listed on foreign exchanges grew from $152.6 billion in 1991 to $5,423.0 billion in 2008 (an increase of 3,454 percent), before falling to $3,228.9 in 2009 and recovering only slightly to $3,455.2 billion in 2012. Table 4–11 reports the total dollar value of international security offerings from 1995–2012. Over this period, total offerings increased from $570.5 billion to $6,547.2 billion in 2009, then decreased to $5,503.5 billion in 2011. Of the amounts in 2011, U.S. security issuers offered $2,558.2 billion in international markets, up from $184.7 billion in 1995. One result of the financial crisis in the late 2000s was that large investment banks around the world became more concerned than ever with capital, liquidity, and leverage. However, they did not want to lose ground in the global competition for clients. The result was that global investment banks looked for strategic alliances that would allow them to compete in foreign markets or they exited foreign markets altogether. For example, in 2008, Morgan Stanley, in need of capital to bolster its balance sheet, sold a 21 percent stake in the firm to Japanese financial TABLE 4–9 Foreign Transactions in U.S. Securities Markets (in billions of dollars) Source: Treasury Bulletin, U.S. Treasury, various dates. www.ustreas.gov TABLE 4–10 U.S. Transactions in Foreign Securities Markets (in billions of dollars) Source: Treasury Bulletin, U.S. Treasury, various dates. www.ustreas.gov Year 1991 1995 2000 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 Corporate Stock Transactions $ 211.2 451.7 3,605.2 6,868.6 10,639.3 12,037.9 6,654.0 6,747.2 7,720.3 7,048.6 Corporate Bond Transactions $ 85.9 168.1 479.5 1,678.5 1,913.3 1,467.0 1,189.4 971.2 996.1 937.6 Year Corporate Stock Transactions Corporate Bond Transactions 1991 1995 2000 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 $ 152.6 395.8 1,815.3 3,742.6 5,311.1 5,423.0 3,228.9 3,734.3 4,040.2 3,455.2 $ 345.1 927.9 963.0 2,024.2 3,105.7 2,217.7 2,079.4 3,704.8 3,583.4 3,686.8 106 Part One Introduction TABLE 4–11 Value of International Security Offerings (in billions of dollars) Source: Quarterly Review: International Banking and Financial Market Developments, Bank for International Settlements, various issues. www.bis.org 1995 2001 2002 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012* Total International Offerings Floating-rate debt $103.0 $ 642.7 $ 603.3 $1,470.7 $2,063.9 $2,008.1 $2,249.9 $1,451.6 $1,158.8 $1,252.5 $ 675.1 Straight debt 394.8 1,590.3 1,454.6 2,323.9 2,763.9 3,301.6 3,040.9 4,261.7 3,689.9 3,698.1 2,673.3 Convertible debt 18.1 72.2 42.7 41.7 51.2 100.9 74.6 100.7 91.3 70.3 45.2 Equity 54.6 149.4 102.3 307.5 371.3 499.1 392.2 733.2 701.1 482.6 352.2 Total offerings $570.5 $2,454.6 $2,202.9 $4,143.8 $5,250.3 $5,909.7 $5,802.6 $6,547.2 $5,641.1 $5,503.5 $3,745.8 International Offerings by U.S. Issuers Floating-rate debt $ 50.9 $ 262.3 $ 214.4 $ 602.4 $ 708.8 $ 653.3 $ 509.4 $ 537.2 $ 296.3 $ 441.1 $ 182.8 Straight debt 115.3 836.1 755.0 1,454.0 1,202.0 1,482.0 1,294.8 1,866.1 2,002.6 1,899.7 1,310.1 Convertible debt 8.5 32.9 16.5 42.8 17.4 100.9 74.6 56.8 63.8 39.0 24.0 Equity 10.0 24.8 1.2 5.7 16.3 12.9 99.0 245.5 212.3 178.4 168.4 Total offerings $184.7 $1,156.1 $ 987.1 $2,104.9 $1,944.5 $2,249.1 $1,977.8 $2,705.6 $2,575.0 $2,558.2 $1,685.3 * Through three quarters. institution, Mitsubishi UFJ. In March 2009, the two announced plans to form a joint venture that combined each firm’s Japan-based securities business. Morgan Stanley took 40 percent ownership and managerial control of the institutional business, and Mitsubishi took the remaining ownership and control of the retail operations. This kind of arrangement provides U.S.-based investment banks with a foothold alongside a domestic firm in the foreign market. In contrast to the type of strategic alliance as that between Morgan Stanley and Mitsubishi UFJ is Citigroup, which during the financial crisis had to deal with growing U.S. government ownership, a deteriorating credit environment, and an unwieldy structure. Rather than try to compete globally in this environment, Citigroup decided to abandon several foreign markets. Citigroup sold its Japanese domestic securities unit, and its Japanese asset management unit, Nikko Asset Management, to subsidiaries of Sumitomo Mitsui Financial Group. It also sold NikkoCiti Trust and Banking Corp. to Nomura Trust & Banking Co. Moves such as the sale of international properties, originally acquired to allow the investment bank to expand globally, will likely continue to play a part in the reshaping of the global investment banking industry. One of the more grievous actions by some global investment banks during the financial crisis was the manipulation of the LIBOR (London Interbank Offered Rate) interest rate. LIBOR is the interest rate at which banks can borrow from each other. It is also used to price, among other things, mortgage and business loans and derivative securities. LIBOR is the average of the interest rates submitted by major banks in the United States, Europe, and the United Kingdom in a variety of major currencies such as the dollar, euro, and yen. The scandal arose when it was discovered that banks had been manipulating the LIBOR rate so as to make either profits on its derivative positions (such as interest rate swaps) or to make the bank look stronger for reputational reasons. It is estimated that the banks involved made at least $75 billion on the manipulations. The After the Crisis box summarizes the allegations that several large banks tried to manipulate the LIBOR rate during the financial crisis. The scandal became widely public in June 2012 when British investment bank Barclays agreed to pay $450 million to settle allegations by U.S. and British authorities that some of its traders attempted to manipulate LIBOR rates to increase the bank’s profits and reduce concerns about its stability during the financial crisis. Chapter 4 Financial Services: Securities Brokerage and Investment Banking After the Crisis 107 Traders Manipulated Key Rate, Bank Says A group of traders and brokers successfully managed to manipulate an interest rate that affects loans around the world, one of the banks being investigated has told regulators. In a court filing in Ottawa, Canada’s Competition Bureau said a bank it didn’t identify has told the agency’s investigators that people involved in the alleged scheme “were able to move” interest rates . . . The Canadian regulator also sets out clearly for the first time how its investigators believe bank employees may have managed to game a system used to set costs for financial products around the world, with the alleged aim of increasing their trading profits. The yen London Interbank Offered Rate, or Libor, is calculated by Thomson Reuters under the auspices of the British Bankers’ Association and is based on data submitted daily by a 16-bank panel. Around 11 a.m. London time every day, each bank submits estimates of what rates it would pay to borrow from other banks for different time periods. The top four and bottom four quotes are then discarded, and Libor is calculated using an average of the middle eight quotes. The Canadian watchdog said lawyers acting for the cooperating bank had told it that traders at six banks on the yen Libor panel… “entered into agreements to submit artificially high or artificially low” quotes, according to the court documents. The traders used emails and instant messages to tell each other whether they wanted “to see a higher or lower yen Libor [rate] to aid their trading position(s),” according to a court filing. Each of the traders would then “communicate internally” with the person at their bank who was responsible for submitting the Libor quote, before letting each other know if this attempt to influence the quote had worked. “Not all attempts to affect Libor submissions were successful,” the regulator said in the court filing. The Canadian regulator said it is investigating whether the traders also “conspired” with individuals at interdealer broker firms, according to the documents. These brokers act as go-betweens for the different banks, advising them on the interbank borrowing rates on which Libor quotes are based. The brokers were asked by the traders “to use their influence with yen Libor submitters to affect what rates were submitted by other yen Libor panel banks,” including banks that were part of the alleged conspiracy, according to a court filing . . . The BBA has made some tweaks to how Libor is calculated, such as increasing the size of the U.S. dollar panel, since concerns about the integrity of the system were raised following the financial crisis. But the fundamental approach of calculating rates based on estimates submitted by banks remains unchanged, despite the intensifying global probe. Source: The Wall Street Journal, February 17, 2012, by Jean Eaglesham, Paul Vieira, and David Enrich. Reprinted by permission of The Wall Street Journal. © 2012 Dow Jones & Company, Inc. All Rights Reserved Worldwide. www.wsj.com Concerns were also raised about the failure of British and U.S. regulators to stop the manipulation of LIBOR when there was evidence that both were aware of it. In July 2012, a former trader stated that LIBOR manipulation had been occurring since at least 1991. In July 2012, the Federal Reserve Bank of New York released documents dated as far back as 2007 showing that they knew that banks were misreporting their borrowing costs when setting LIBOR. Yet, no action was taken. Similarly, documents from the Bank of England indicated that the bank knew as early as November 2007 that the LIBOR rate was being manipulated. It was not until June 2012 that Barclays became the first bank to agree to settle LIBOR manipulation allegations. In December 2012, UBS agreed to pay about $1.5 billion to settle charges that it manipulated LIBOR. In February 2013, the Royal Bank of Scotland also decided to settle at a cost of $610 million. Also in early 2013, Deutsche Bank stated that it had set aside money to cover potential fines associated with its role in the manipulation of the LIBOR. 108 Part One Introduction www.mhhe.com/saunders8e Concept Questions 1. What have been the trends in foreign transactions in U.S. securities and U.S. transactions in foreign securities in the 1990s and 2000s? 2. What have been the trends in international securities offerings in the late 1990s and 2000s? 3. Why do foreign banks operating in the United States compete with both U.S. commercial banks and investment banks? Summary This chapter presented an overview of security firms (which offer largely retail services to investors) and investment banking firms (which offer largely wholesale services to corporate customers). Firms in this industry assist in getting new issues of debt and equity to the markets. Additionally, this industry facilitates trading and market making of securities after they are issued as well as corporate mergers and restructurings. We looked at the structure of the industry and changes in the degree of concentration in firm size in the industry over the last decade. We also analyzed balance sheet information which highlighted the major assets and liabilities of firms in the industry. Overall, the industry is in a period of consolidation and globalization as the array and scope of its activities expand. Questions and Problems 1. Explain how securities firms differ from investment banks. In what ways are they financial intermediaries? 2. In what ways have changes in the investment banking industry mirrored changes in the commercial banking industry? 3. What are the different types of firms in the securities industry and how does each type differ from the others? 4. What are the key activity areas for investment banks and securities firms? How does each activity area assist in the generation of profits and what are the major risks for each area? 5. What is the difference between an IPO and a secondary issue? 6. What is the difference between a private placement and a public offering? 7. What are the risk implications to an investment bank from underwriting on a best-efforts basis versus a firm commitment basis? If you operated a company issuing stock for the first time, which type of underwriting would you prefer? Why? What factors might cause you to choose the alternative? 8. An investment bank agrees to underwrite an issue of 15 million shares of stock for Looney Landscaping Corp. a. If the investment bank underwrites the stock on a firm commitment basis, it agrees to pay $12.50 per share to Looney Landscaping Corp. for the 15 million shares of stock. It can then sell those shares to the public for $13.25 per share. How much money does Looney receive? What is the profit to the investment bank? If the investment bank can sell the shares for only $11.95, how much money does Looney receive? What is the profit to the investment bank? b. Suppose, instead, that the investment bank agrees to underwrite the 15 million shares on a best-efforts basis. The investment bank is able to sell 13.6 million shares for $12.50 per share, and it charges Looney Landscaping Corp. $0.275 per share sold. How much money does Looney receive? What is the 9. 10. 11. 12. 13. 14. 15. 16. 17. 18. 19. 20. 21. 22. 109 profit to the investment bank? If the investment bank can sell the shares for only $11.95, how much money does Looney receive? What is the profit to the investment bank? An investment bank agrees to underwrite a $500 million, 10-year, 8 percent semiannual bond issue for KDO Corporation on a firm commitment basis. The investment bank pays KDO on Thursday and plans to begin a public sale on Friday. What type of interest rate movement does the investment bank fear while holding these securities? If interest rates rise 0.05 percent, or five basis points, overnight, what will be the impact on the profits of the investment bank? What if the market interest rate falls five basis points? An investment bank pays $23.50 per share for 4 million shares of JCN Company. It then sells those shares to the public for $25 per share. How much money does JCN receive? What is the profit to the investment bank? What is the stock price of JCN? XYZ Inc. has issued 10 million new shares of stock. An investment bank agrees to underwrite these shares on a best-efforts basis. The investment bank is able to sell 8.4 million shares for $27 per share, and it charges XYZ $0.675 per share sold. How much money does XYZ receive? What is the profit to the investment bank? What is the stock price of XYZ? What is venture capital? What are the different types of venture capital firms? How do institutional venture capital firms differ from angel venture capital firms? What are the advantages and disadvantages to a new or small firm of getting capital funding from a venture capital firm? How do agency transactions differ from principal transactions for market makers? One of the major activity areas of securities firms is trading. a. What is the difference between pure arbitrage and risk arbitrage? b. What is the difference between position trading and program trading? If an investor observes that the price of a stock trading in one exchange is different from the price in another exchange, what form of arbitrage is applicable, and how can the investor participate in that arbitrage? An investor notices that an ounce of gold is priced at $1,518 in London and $1,525 in New York. a. What action could the investor take to try to profit from the price discrepancy? b. Under which of the four trading activities would this action be classified? c. If the investor is correct in identifying the discrepancy, what pattern should the two prices take in the short term? d. What may be some impediments to the success of this transaction? What three factors are given credit for the steady decline in brokerage commissions as a percentage of total revenues over the period beginning in 1977 and ending in 1991? What factors are given credit for the resurgence of profitability in the securities industry beginning in 1991? Are firms that trade in fixed-income securities more or less likely to have volatile profits? Why? Using Table 4–6, which type of security accounts for most underwriting in the United States? Which is likely to be more costly to underwrite: corporate debt or equity? Why? How did the financial crisis affect the performance of securities firms and investment banks? www.mhhe.com/saunders8e Chapter 4 Financial Services: Securities Brokerage and Investment Banking 110 Part One Introduction 23. How do the operating activities, and thus the balance sheet structures, of securities firms differ from the operating activities of depository institutions? How are the balance sheet structures of securities firms similar to depository institutions? 24. Based on the data in Table 4–7, what were the largest single asset and the largest single liability of securities firms in 2012? Are these asset and liability categories related? Exactly how does a repurchase agreement work? 25. How did the National Securities Markets Improvement Act of 1996 (NSMIA) change the regulatory structure of the securities industry? 26. Identify the major regulatory organizations that are involved in the daily operations of the investment securities industry, and explain their role in providing smoothly operating markets. 27. What are the three requirements of the USA Patriot Act that financial service firms must implement after October 1, 2003? Web Questions www.mhhe.com/saunders8e 28. Go to the Securities Industry and Financial Markets Association website at www.sifma.org and find the most recent data on U.S. corporate underwriting activity using the following steps. Click on “Research.” Click “Statistics and Data.” Click on “US Key Stats.” This will download an Excel file to your computer that contains the relevant data, on the page “Corporate.” How has the distribution of underwriting activity changed since 2012, as reported in Table 4–6? 29. Go to the U.S. Treasury website at www.ustreas.gov and find the most recent data on foreign transactions in U.S. securities and U.S. transactions in foreign securities using the following steps. Under “Bureaus,” click on “Financial Management Services.” Under “Publications,” click on “Treasury Bulletin.” Click on “Capital Movements Tables (Section IV).” This will download a file onto your computer that will contain the most recent information on foreign transactions. How have these number changed since 2012, as reported in Tables 4–9 and 4–10? Chapter Five Financial Services: Mutual Funds and Hedge Funds INTRODUCTION Mutual funds and hedge funds are financial institutions that pool the financial resources of individuals and companies and invest in diversified portfolios of assets. An open-ended mutual fund (the major type of mutual fund) continuously stands ready to sell new shares to investors and to redeem outstanding shares on demand at their fair market value. Thus, these funds provide opportunities for small investors to invest in financial securities and diversify risk. Mutual funds are also able to generate greater economies of scale by incurring lower transaction costs and commissions than are incurred when individual investors buy securities directly. As a result of the tremendous increase in the market value of financial assets, such as equities, in the 1990s (for example, the S&P 500 index saw a return of more than 25 percent in 1997 and 1998) and the relatively low-cost opportunity mutual funds provide to investors (particularly small investors) who want to hold such assets (through either direct mutual fund purchases or contributions to retirement funds sponsored by employers and managed by mutual funds), the mutual fund industry boomed in size and customers in the 1990s. The early 2000s and a slowdown in the U.S. economy brought an end to such a rapid pace of growth and the more severe financial crisis of 2008–09 resulted in the largest ever drop in the value of industry assets. During 2008, mutual fund losses on investments in financial securities and liquidation of mutual fund shares by investors resulted in a drop in industry assets of $2.4 trillion (or 20 percent). Further, allegations of trading abuses resulted in a loss of confidence in several mutual fund managers. Despite these issues, in 2012 more than 7,000 different stock and bond mutual companies held total assets of $10.26 trillion. If we add money market mutual funds, the number of funds rises to more than 7,600 and the 2012 value of assets under management rises to $12.87 trillion. Hedge funds are a type of investment pool that solicit funds from (wealthy) individuals and other investors (e.g., commercial banks) and invest these funds on their behalf. Hedge funds are similar to mutual funds in that they are pooled investment vehicles that accept investors’ money and generally invest it on a collective basis. Investments in hedge funds, however, are restricted to more wealthy clients. 111 112 Part One Introduction In this chapter we first provide an overview of the services offered by mutual funds and highlight their rapid growth over the last twenty-five years. We look at the size, structure, and composition of the industry, highlighting historical trends in the industry, the different types of mutual funds, mutual fund objectives, investor returns from mutual fund ownership, and mutual fund costs. We also look at the industry’s balance sheets and recent trends, the regulations and regulators governing the industry, and global issues for this industry. We then discuss investment pools organized as hedge funds. Because hedge funds limit investors to only the wealthiest individuals, they are examined separately from mutual funds discussed elsewhere in the chapter. Another difference between mutual funds and hedge funds is that, prior to 2010, hedge funds were generally unregulated. However, as a result of some very publicized hedge fund failures and near failures (the result of fraud by fund managers, e.g., Bernard L. Madoff Investment Securities and the financial crisis, e.g., Bear Stearns High Grade Structured Credit Strategies Fund), in 2010 federal regulators increased the oversight of hedge funds. Specifically, regulations now require that hedge funds with assets under management exceeding some threshold should be required to register with the SEC under the Investment Advisers Act of 1940 in a similar fashion to that required for mutual funds. Similarly, fund advisors are required to report financial information on the funds they manage that is sufficient to assess whether any fund poses a threat to the financial system. SIZE, STRUCTURE, AND COMPOSITION OF THE MUTUAL FUND INDUSTRY Historical Trends The first mutual fund was founded in Boston in 1924. The industry grew very slowly at first; by 1970, 361 funds held about $50 billion in assets. Since then the number of mutual funds and the asset size of the industry have increased dramatically. This growth is attributed to the advent of money market mutual funds in 1972 (as investors looked for ways to earn market rates on short-term funds when bank deposit rates were constrained by regulatory ceilings), to tax-exempt money market mutual funds first established in 1979, and to an explosion of special-purpose equity, bond, emerging market, and derivative funds (as capital market values soared in the 1990s). Table 5–1 documents the tremendous increase from 1940 though 2007 of mutual funds. For example, total assets invested in mutual funds grew from $0.5 billion in 1940 to $12,001.46 billion in 2007 (of which $8,916.5 billion was invested in long-term funds). In addition, the number of mutual fund accounts increased from 296,000 in 1940 to 292.6 million in 2007 (253.5 million of which were long-term fund accounts), and the number of mutual funds increased from 68 in 1940 to 8,026 in 2007. The majority of this growth occurred during the bull market run in the 1990s (total assets in 1990 were $1,065.2 billion). The financial crisis and the collapse in stock and other security prices produced a sharp drop in mutual fund activity. At the end of 2008, total assets fell to $9,603.6 billion and the number of accounts to 264.6 million (of this, $5,771.3 billion and 226.5 million accounts were long-term funds). Investor demand for certain types of mutual funds plummeted, driven in large part by deteriorating financial market conditions. Equity funds suffered substantial outflows, while the inflow to U.S. government money market funds reached record highs. As the economy recovered starting in 2009, so did Chapter 5 TABLE 5–1 Financial Services: Mutual Funds and Hedge Funds 113 Growth of Mutual Fund Industry, 1940–2012 Sources: Investment Company Institute, 2006 Investment Company Fact Book (Washington, DC: Investment Company Institute, May 2006) and Trends in Mutual Fund Investing, various issues. www.ici.org Year Total Net Assets (billions) Gross Sales (billions) Redemptions (billions) Net Sales (billions) Accounts (thousands) Number of Funds 2012 2010 2009 2008 2007 2005 2000 1995 1990 1980 1970 1960 1950 1940 $13,045.2 11,831.9 11,113.0 9,603.6 12,001.5 8,904.8 6,964.6 2,811.3 1,065.2 134.8 47.6 17.0 2.5 0.5 $17,020.90 18,207.5 20,680.0 26,346.7 23,471.7 14,042.5 11,109.4 3,600.6 1,564.8 247.4 4.6 2.1 0.5 N/A $16,618.7 18,319.1 20,680.2 25,725.8 22,353.4 13,648.4 10,586.6 3,314.9 1,470.8 216.1 3.0 0.8 0.3 N/A $402.2 ⫺111.6 ⫺0.2 620.9 1,118.3 394.1 522.8 285.7 94.0 31.3 1.6 1.3 0.2 N/A 264,131 291,299 269,450 264,599 292,555 275,479 244,706 131,219 61,948 12,088 10,690 4,898 939 296 7,596 7,580 7,684 8,022 8,026 7,975 8,155 5,725 3,079 564 361 161 98 68 Note: Data include money market funds. Institute “gross sales” figures include the proceeds of initial fund underwritings prior to 1970. assets invested in mutual funds, growing to $11,113.0 billion by the end of the year and to $13,045.2 billion in 2012 (finally surpassing 2007 levels). Of this, $10,351.7 billion were invested in long-term funds. Additionally, growth has been the result of the rise in retirement funds under management by mutual funds. The retirement fund market has increased from $4 trillion in 1990 to almost $20.0 trillion in 2012. Mutual funds manage approximately one-quarter of this market and have experienced the growth along with it. Many of these retirement funds are institutional funds. Institutional funds are mutual funds that manage retirement plans for an institution’s employees. Institutions arrange these retirement (mutual) funds for the benefit of their members. Wealthy individuals also often use institutional funds. In total, about 80 percent of all retirement plan investments are in institutional funds. Institutional funds are managed by the same companies that run mutual funds: banks, insurance companies, brokers, and mutual fund advisory companies. Costs of institutional funds are very low because there are no additional distribution fees and because the retirement plan can use its bargaining power to get the best deals. Unlike the case with traditional mutual funds, retirement plan sponsors can set out how much risk an institutional fund can take in trying to beat the market. As can be seen in Figure 5–1, in terms of asset size, the mutual fund industry is larger than the insurance industry, but smaller than the commercial banking industry. This makes mutual funds the second most important FI group in the United States as measured by asset size. The tremendous growth in this area of FI services has not gone unnoticed by commercial banks as they have sought to directly compete by either buying existing mutual fund groups or managing mutual fund assets for a fee. Banks’ share of all mutual fund assets managed was about 7 percent in 2012. Much of this growth has occurred through banks buying mutual fund companies, for example, Mellon buying Dreyfus, as well as converting internally 114 Part One Introduction FIGURE 5–1 Assets of Major Financial Intermediaries, 1990, 2007, and 2012 (in trillions of dollars) Source: Federal Reserve Board, “Flow of Fund Accounts,” various years. www.federalreserve.gov 14.8 15 14 13 12.4 11.8 12 10.9 11 10 9 8 7.0 7 6.3 6.4 6.6 1990 2007 2012 6 5 4.5 4 3.23.1 3 1.9 2 1.9 1.6 1.6 1.1 1 0 0.7 Depository institutions Mutual Funds MutualFunds Funds Mutual Mutual funds Insurance companies Private Pention Fund pension funds State and local government pension funds 0.6 Finance companies managed trust funds into open-end mutual funds. Insurance companies are also beginning to enter this booming industry. In March 2001, for example, State Farm began offering a family of 10 mutual funds nationwide. The funds are available from more than 9,000 registered State Farm agents, on the Internet, or by application sent in response to phone requests made to a toll-free number. As of 2012, insurance companies managed 5 percent of the mutual fund industry’s assets. Low barriers to entry in the U.S. mutual fund industry have allowed new entrants to offer funds to compete for investor attention and has kept the industry from being increasingly concentrated. As a result, the share of industry assets held by the largest mutual fund sponsors has changed little since 1990. For example, the largest 25 companies that sponsor mutual funds managed 73 percent of the industry’s assets in 2012, compared to 25 percent in 1990. The composition of the Chapter 5 Financial Services: Mutual Funds and Hedge Funds 115 list of the 25 largest fund sponsors, however, has changed, with 12 of the largest fund companies in 2012 not among the largest in 1990. Different Types of Mutual Funds equity funds Funds that contain common and preferred stock securities. bond funds Funds that contain fixed-income capital market debt securities. hybrid funds Funds that contain bond and stock securities. money market mutual funds Funds that contain various mixtures of money market securities. The mutual fund industry is usually divided into two sectors: short-term funds and long-term funds. Long-term funds include equity funds (comprised of common and preferred stock securities), bond funds (comprised of fixed-income securities with a maturity of longer than one year), and hybrid funds (comprised of both bond and stock securities). Short-term funds include taxable money market mutual funds (MMMFs) and tax-exempt money market mutual funds. Table 5–2 shows how the mix of stock, bond, hybrid, and money market fund assets changed between 1980 and 2012. As can be seen, there was a strong trend toward investing in equity mutual funds, reflecting the rise in share values during the 1990s. As a result, in 1999, 74.3 percent of all mutual fund assets were in long-term funds while the remaining funds, or 25.7 percent, were in money market mutual funds. The proportion invested in longterm versus short-term funds can vary considerably over time. For example, the share of money market funds was 44.8 percent in 1990 compared to 25.7 percent in 1999. The decline in the growth rate of short-term funds and the increase in the growth rate of long-term funds reflect the increase in equity returns during the period 1992–99 and the generally low level of short-term interest rates over the period. Notice that in the early 2000s, as interest rates rose, the U.S. economy declined, and equity returns fell, the growth in money market funds outpaced the growth in long-term funds. In 2002, the share of long-term funds fell to 62.1 percent and money market funds grew to 37.9 percent. However, in the mid-2000s, as the U.S. economy grew and stock values increased, the share of long-term funds grew (to 72.1 percent of all funds in 2007), while money market funds decreased (to 27.9 percent in 2007). The 2008–2009 financial crisis and the collapse in stock prices produced a sharp drop in long-term mutual fund activity. Equity funds suffered substantial outflows, while inflows to U.S. government money market funds reached record highs. At the end of 2008, the share of long-term equity and bond funds plunged to 59.1 percent of all funds, while money market funds increased to 40.9 percent. As discussed below, part of the move to money market funds was the fact that during the worst of the financial crisis, the U.S. Treasury extended government insurance to all money market mutual fund accounts on a temporary basis. In 2009, as the economy and the stock market recovered, the share of long-term equity and bond funds increased back to 68.1 percent of all funds, while money market funds fell to 31.9 percent. By 2012, the share of long-term equity and bond funds was 78.7 percent of all funds, while money market funds decreased to 21.3 percent. Money market mutual funds provide an alternative investment to interestbearing deposits at commercial banks, which may explain the growth in MMMFs in the 1980s and late 1990s, when the spread earned on MMMF investments relative to deposits was mostly positive (see Figure 5–2). Both investments are relatively safe and earn short-term returns. The major difference between the two is that interest-bearing deposits (below $250,000 in size) are fully insured by the FDIC but due to bank regulatory costs (such as reserve requirements, capital requirements, and deposit insurance premiums) generally offer lower returns than do noninsured MMMFs.1 Thus, the net gain in switching to MMMFs is higher returns 1 Some mutual funds are covered by private insurance and/or by implicit or explicit guarantees from mutual fund management companies. 116 TABLE 5–2 Growth in Long-Term versus Short-Term Mutual Funds, 1980–2012 (in billions of dollars) Source: Federal Reserve Bulletin, “Flow of Fund Accounts,” various issues. www.federalreserve.gov 1980 1990 1999 2000 2002 2004 2007 2008 2009 2012 Panel A: Equity, Hybrid, and Bond Mutual Funds Holdings at market value $61.8 $608.4 $4,538.5 $4,433.1 $3,638.4 $5,436.3 $7,829.0 $5,435.3 $6,961.6 $9,262.4 Household sector 52.1 511.6 2,894.9 2,704.3 2,218.3 3,417.6 4,832.0 3,442.6 4,161.1 5,542.9 Nonfinancial corporate business 1.5 9.7 127.0 121.9 95.8 140.5 217.5 143.3 161.9 171.4 State and local governments 0.0 4.8 33.4 30.8 24.3 27.5 34.5 29.8 37.5 37.1 Commercial banking 0.0 1.9 12.4 15.0 19.6 18.1 29.6 19.6 46.1 52.8 Credit unions 0.0 1.4 2.5 2.2 3.5 3.1 2.1 2.0 1.3 2.1 Insurance companies 1.1 30.7 101.4 99.9 79.6 119.6 195.2 125.4 146.1 165.1 Private pension funds 7.1 40.5 1,056.5 1,131.7 931.9 1,278.2 1,848.2 1,229.5 1,817.3 2,370.5 State and local government retirement funds 0.0 7.8 140.9 178.3 167.4 235.9 296.4 181.1 226.7 274.6 Rest of world 0.0 0.0 169.5 149.0 98.0 195.8 373.5 262.0 363.6 645.9 Panel B: Money Market Mutual Funds Total assets $76.4 $493.3 $1,579.6 $1,812.1 $2,223.9 $1,879.8 $3,033.1 $3,757.3 $3,258.3 $2,506.9 Household sector 64.3 389.4 774.2 937.3 1,071.7 904.1 1,346.6 1,581.9 1,313.1 1,044.5 Nonfinancial corporate business 7.0 19.7 196.8 213.9 319.7 299.6 548.5 710.6 641.7 427.2 Nonfinancial noncorporate business 0.0 6.7 40.7 49.4 61.3 66.5 74.3 75.4 73.7 70.6 State and local governments 0.0 0.0 51.2 53.9 58.7 78.6 116.6 113.3 122.0 126.5 Insurance companies 1.9 19.1 19.4 23.1 27.6 30.5 42.3 71.9 63.3 55.9 Private pension funds 2.6 17.8 76.9 81.1 84.5 84.9 93.5 95.7 96.4 96.1 State and local government retirement funds 0.0 2.8 11.8 13.2 15.5 11.6 12.4 14.3 14.3 15.1 Funding corporations 0.6 36.6 400.5 429.0 568.6 381.1 752.8 1,024.5 857.1 607.5 Rest of world 0.0 1.2 8.1 11.2 16.3 22.9 46.0 69.7 76.9 63.5 Chapter 5 FIGURE 5–2 Financial Services: Mutual Funds and Hedge Funds 117 Interest Rate Spread and Net New Cash Flow to Retail Money Market Funds, 1985–2012 Source: Investment Company Institute, Investment Company Fact Book (Washington, DC: Investment Company Institute, various issues). www.ici.org Percent 5 Percent of total assets 4 Interest rate spread 4 3 3 2 2 1 1 0 0 −1 −1 Net new cash flow −2 −3 −2 1985 1987 1989 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 2011 −3 Note: Net new cash flow is a percentage of retail money market fund assets and is shown as a six-month moving average. The interest rate spread is the difference between the taxable money market fund yield and the average interest rate on savings deposits; the series is plotted with a six-month lag. in exchange for the loss of deposit insurance coverage. Many investors appeared willing to give up insurance coverage to obtain additional returns in the 1980s and late 1990s (through 2001). An exception occurred during the financial crisis of 2008–09. In September 2008, Reserve Primary Fund a large and reputedly conservative money market fund, had holdings of $785 million in commercial paper issued by Lehman Brothers. As a result of Lehman’s failure, shares in Reserve Primary Fund “broke the buck” (i.e., fell below $1), meaning that its investors lost part of their principal investment. This was the first ever incidence of a share price dipping below a dollar for any money market mutual fund open to the general public. This type of fund had built a reputation for safe investment. Hence, exposure to Lehman’s failure scared investors, leading to a broad run on all money market mutual funds. Within a few days more than $200 billion had flowed out of these funds. The U.S. Treasury stopped the run by extending government insurance to all money market mutual fund accounts held in participating money market funds as of the close of business on September 19, 2008. The insurance coverage lasted for one year (through September 18, 2009). As seen in Figure 5–2, this action is associated with a change in trend from net outflows to net inflows of funds into money market mutual funds. Table 5–3 reports the growth in the mutual fund industry based on the number of funds in existense from 1980 through 2012. All categories of funds have generally increased in number in this time period, from a total of 564 in 1980 to 8,026 in 2007. Tax-exempt money market funds first became available in 1979. This was 118 Part One Introduction TABLE 5–3 Number of Mutual Funds, 1980–2012 Source: Investment Company Institute, Investment Company Fact Book, various years (Washington DC: Investment Company Institute). www.ici.org Year Equity Hybrid Bond Taxable Money Market 1980* 1990 2000 2002 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 288 1,099 4,385 4,747 4,763 4,802 4,616 4,547 4,581 4,527 N/A 193 523 473 489 483 471 475 495 532 170 1,046 2,208 2,035 1,969 1,954 1,893 1,906 1,929 1,959 96 506 703 679 546 534 476 442 431 405 Tax-Exempt Money Market Total 10 235 336 310 259 249 228 210 201 189 564 3,079 8,155 8,244 8,026 8,022 7,684 7,580 7,637 7,612 * The definition of equity, hybrid, and bond funds was reclassified in 1984. Thus, 1980 data are not directly comparable to data for other years. the major reason for their relatively small number (10 funds) in 1980. Also, the number of equity funds has boomed, mainly in the 1990s. Equity funds numbered 4,763 in 2007, up from 1,099 in 1990, while bond funds numbered 1,969 in 2007, up from 1,046 in 1990. But again, the 2008–09 financial crisis and the collapse in financial markets produced a significant drop in the number of mutual funds. The number of equity funds fell to 4,616 and bond funds fell to 1,893 by the end of 2009. The total number of funds dropped below 8,000 for the first time since 1999. In terms of the number of funds, the industry has still not recovered from the crisis. As of 2012, the number of equity funds had fallen to 4,527 and the total number of mutual funds stood at 7,612. Notice that in Table 5–2 households (i.e., small investors) own the majority of both long- and short-term funds: 59.8 percent for long-term mutual funds and 41.7 percent for short-term mutual funds in 2012. This is to be expected, given that the rationale for the existence of mutual funds is to achieve superior diversification through fund and risk pooling compared to what individual small investors can achieve on their own. Consider that wholesale CDs sell in minimum denominations of $100,000 each and often pay higher interest rates than passbook savings accounts or small time deposits offered by depository institutions. By pooling funds in a money market mutual fund, small investors can gain access to wholesale money markets and instruments and, therefore, to potentially higher interest rates and returns. Internet Exercise Go to the Federal Reserve Board’s website at www.federalreserve.gov. Find the latest figures for the dollar value of money market and long-term mutual funds and the distribution of mutual fund investment by ownership using the following steps. Click on “Flow of Funds— Z.1.” Click on the most recent date. Click on “Level tables.” This downloads a file onto your computer that contains the relevant data, in Tables L.206 and L.214. As of 2012, 53.8 million (44.4 percent of) U.S. households owned mutual funds. This was down from 56.3 million (52 percent) in 2001. Table 5–4 lists some characteristics of household mutual fund owners as of 2012 and 1995. Most are long-term owners, with 38 percent making their first purchases before 1990. While mutual fund Chapter 5 Financial Services: Mutual Funds and Hedge Funds TABLE 5–4 Selected Characteristics of Household Owners of Mutual Funds* Source: Investment Company Institute, Profile of Mutual Fund Shareholders, various years (Washington, DC: Investment Company Institute). www.ici.org 119 2012 1995 51 years $ 80,000 $200,000 44 years $ 60,000 $ 50,000 75.0 72.0 48.0 71.0 80.0 58.0 48.0 36.0 69.0 17.0 68.0 28.3 $120,000 4 $ 18,000 3 79 50 44 66 73 49 N/A 52 Demographic Characteristics: Median age Median household income Median household financial assets Percent: Married or living with a partner Employed Four-year college degree or more Household financial assets invested in mutual funds Owning fund inside employer-sponsored retirement funds Owning fund outside employer-sponsored retirement funds Mutual Fund Ownership Characteristics: Median mutual fund assets Median number of funds owned Fund Types Owned (percent): Equity Bond Hybrid Money market * Characteristics of primary financial decision maker in the household. investors come from all age groups, ownership is concentrated among individuals in their prime saving and investing years. Two-thirds of households owning mutual funds in 2012 were headed by individuals between the ages of 35 and 64. Interestingly, the number of families headed by a person with less than a college degree investing in mutual funds is 52 percent. The bull markets of the 1990s, the low transaction costs of purchasing mutual funds shares, as well as the diversification benefits achievable through mutual fund investments are again the likely reasons for these trends. The typical fund-owning household had $120,000 invested in a median number of four mutual funds. Finally, 21 percent of investors who conducted equity fund transactions used the Internet for some or all of these transactions. This compares to 6 percent in 1998. Notice, from Table 5–4, that compared to 1995, 2012 has seen an increase in the median age of mutual fund holders (from 44 to 51 years) and a large increase in median household financial assets owned (from $50,000 to $200,000) and median mutual fund assets owned (from $18,000 to $120,000). Further, holdings of equity funds have increased from 73 to 79 percent of all households. Mutual Fund Objectives Regulations require that mutual fund managers specify the investment objectives of their funds in a prospectus available to potential investors. This prospectus should include a list of the securities that the fund holds. The aggregate figures for long-term equity, bond, and hybrid funds tend to obscure the fact that there are many different funds in these groups. Every mutual fund sponsor offers multiple 120 Part One Introduction TABLE 5–5 Total Net Asset Value of Equity, Hybrid, and Bond Funds by Investment Classification Source: Investment Company Institute, 2012 Investment Company Fact Book (Washington, DC: Investment Company Institute, 2012). www.ici.org Classification of Fund Combined Assets ($ billions) Percent of Total Total net assets $11,621.58 100.0% Capital appreciation World equity Total return Total equity funds 2,355.66 1,359.35 1,490.09 $ 5,205.10 20.3 11.7 12.8 44.8% Total hybrid funds $838.70 7.2% Corporate bond High-yield bond World bond Government bond Strategic income State municipal National municipal Total bond funds 452.60 212.12 259.51 261.09 1,204.14 158.91 337.99 $ 2,886.36 3.9 1.8 2.2 2.2 10.4 1.4 2.9 24.8% Taxable money market funds Tax-exempt money market funds Total money market funds 2,399.72 291.70 $ 2,691.42 20.7 2.5 23.2% funds of each type (e.g., long-term equity), differentiated by the securities held in the particular mutual fund as defined by the fund’s objective. Table 5–5 classifies 13 major categories of investment objectives (or classifications) for mutual funds. These objectives are shown along with the assets allocated to each major category. A fund objective provides general information about the types of securities a mutual fund will hold as assets. For example, “capital appreciation” funds hold securities (mainly equities) of high-growth, high-risk firms. Again, within each of these 13 categories of mutual funds are a multitude of different funds offered by mutual fund companies (see also the mutual fund quote section below). Historically, mutual funds have had to send out lengthy prospectuses describing their objectives and investments. In 1998, the SEC adopted a new procedure in which key sections of all funds’ prospectuses must be written in “plain” English instead of legal boilerplate. The idea is to increase the ability of investors to understand the risks related to the investment objectives or profile of a fund. Internet Exercise Go to the Vanguard Group’s website at www.vanguard.com. Find the latest prospectus for the Vanguard 500 Index Admiral Fund using the following steps. Click on “Go to the Personal Investors site.” In the box “Find a fund,” enter “Vanguard 500 Index Fund Admiral Shares,” and click on “Go.” Click on “View prospectus and reports.” Click on “Statutory Prospectus.” This downloads a file onto your computer that contains the prospectus. What is listed as the primary investment objective for this fund? It should be noted that, prior to 1998, the risk of returns [e.g., the fund’s total return risk or even its “beta” (or systematic risk)] was rarely mentioned in prospectuses or advertisements. In 1998, the SEC adopted an initiative requiring mutual funds to disclose more information about their return risk as well as the returns Chapter 5 TABLE 5–6 Financial Services: Mutual Funds and Hedge Funds 121 Largest Mutual Funds by Assets Managed Sources: The Wall Street Journal Online, January 18, 2013 and authors’ research. Reprinted by permission of The Wall Street Journal © 2013 Dow Jones & Company, Inc. All Rights Reserved Worldwide. www.wsj.com Name of Fund Vanguard Tot Stk Inx;Inv Vangaurd Instl Indx:Inst Vanguard Tot Stk Idx; Adm Vanguard 500 Index; Adm Fidelity Contrafund American Funds CIB;A American Funds Inc;A American Funds Growth;A Vanguard Instl Index; InsP American Funds CWGI;A American Funds InvCoA Franklin Cust;Inc;A Dodge & Cox Intl Stock Dodge & Cox Stock American Funds Wash;A Vanguard T StMk Idx; Inst Vanguard Wellington;Adm Vanguard Tot I Stk; Inv American Funds Bal;A American Funds FInv;A www.americanfunds.com www.vanguard.com www.fidelity.com Objective Growth/Income S&P 500 Index Growth/Income S&P 500 Index Growth Income Income Growth S&P 500 Index Global Growth/Income Income International Growth/Income Growth/Income Growth/Income Balanced International Balanced Growth/Income Total Assets (in millions) $78,936 68,055 59,771 59,749 58,819 58,079 57,661 55,970 49,286 46,651 44,501 42,511 40,556 39,841 39,823 39,367 37,959 37,659 34,272 32,568 Total Return 12 month 17.40% 17.08 17.54 17.06 17.09 13.66 13.41 20.07 17.10 19.69 16.50 15.12 22.75 23.16 13.58 17.54 13.41 17.94 14.72 17.58 5 year 5.10% 4.46 5.22 4.45 4.95 2.54 4.86 3.54 4.48 1.45 3.14 5.66 0.75 2.55 4.02 5.22 5.93 ⫺0.56 5.44 3.77 10 year 8.03% 7.25 8.13 7.23 10.06 7.91 7.94 8.33 7.28 10.26 6.81 8.81 11.65 7.54 6.77 8.15 8.51 9.59 7.17 9.33 NAV $37.12 135.64 37.13 136.52 80.20 53.74 18.48 35.61 135.65 38.33 31.28 2.28 35.90 128.06 32.21 37.13 60.16 15.39 21.00 42.37 Initial Fees 0.00% 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 5.75 5.75 5.75 0.00 5.75 5.75 4.25 0.00 0.00 5.75 0.00 0.00 0.00 5.75 5.75 themselves. The SEC’s rule was intended to better enable investors to compare return-risk trade-offs from investing in different mutual funds. Table 5–6 lists the largest (in total assets held) 20 mutual funds available in January 2013, including the fund’s objective; total assets; 12-month, 5-year, and 10-year returns; net asset value (discussed below); and any initial fees (discussed below). Vanguard’s Total Stock Market Index Fund, Investor Class Shares (which seeks to track the performance of a benchmark index that measures the investment return of the overall stock market), was the largest fund at the time. American Funds, Vanguard, and Fidelity offered 17 of the top 20 funds measured by asset size. Many of the top funds list either growth or growth and income as the fund objective, and all of the top 20 funds performed well in 2012 as the stock market saw high returns as the economy recovered from the financial crisis. Despite a relatively small downturn in the U.S. economy from 2001 through 2002 and a severe financial crisis in 2008–09, all of the top 20 funds earned positive annual returns over the period 2002–12. Over the three time periods (12 months, 5 years, and 10 years), the S&P 500 index saw annual returns of 13.59 percent, 2.32 percent, and 5.12 percent, respectively. Of the top mutual funds, 17 outperformed the S&P 500 index over the 12-month period, 17 outperformed it over the 5-year period, and all 20 funds outperformed the S&P 500 index over the 10-year period. A growing number of the long-term mutual funds are index funds in which fund managers buy securities in proportions similar to those included in a specified 122 Part One Introduction major stock index (such as the S&P 500 index). Thus, index funds are designed to match the performance of a stock index. In 2012, 383 index funds managed total net assets of $1.1 trillion. Because little research or aggressive management is necessary for index funds, management fees (discussed later) are lower. However, returns are often higher than more actively managed funds. The difference in returns between actively managed funds and passively managed index funds can be explained. For example, from data analyzed by Morningstar and Forbes over the period 2007–2010, it was found that 18 percent of actively managed funds outperformed index fund portfolios. The overachieving, actively managed portfolios had a median outperformance of 0.4 percent annualized, while the 82 percent underperforming portfolios fell short by 1.0 percent annually.2 Further, the average amount of expenses that an actively managed fund charges its shareholders every year is approximately 1.3 percent. Conversely, the Vanguard S&P 500 expense ratio is 0.19 percent. Finally, actively managed funds turn over their holdings rapidly. This turnover occurs at an average rate as high as 85 percent per year. The transaction costs involved in buying and selling so many shares every year result in an additional 0.7 percent of return disappearing every year. Investor Returns from Mutual Fund Ownership marked-to-market Adjusting asset and balance sheet values to reflect current market prices. NAV The net asset value of a mutual fund; equal to the market value of the assets in the mutual fund portfolio divided by the number of shares outstanding. EXAMPLE 5–1 Impact of Capital Appreciation on NAV The return an investor gets from investing in mutual fund shares reflects three aspects of the underlying portfolio of mutual fund assets. First, income and dividends are earned on those assets. Second, capital gains occur when assets are sold by a mutual fund at prices higher than the purchase price. Third, capital appreciation in the underlying values of the assets held in a fund’s portfolio add to the value of mutual fund shares. With respect to capital appreciation, mutual fund assets are normally marked-to-market daily. This means that the managers of the fund calculate the current value of each mutual fund share by computing the daily market value of the fund’s total asset portfolio and then dividing this amount by the number of mutual fund shares outstanding. The resulting value is called the net asset value (NAV) of the fund. This is the price the investor gets when selling shares back to the fund that day or buying any new shares in the fund on that day. Suppose a mutual fund contains 2,000 shares of Sears, Roebuck currently trading at $45.50, 1,000 shares of Exxon/Mobil currently trading at $91.25, and 1,500 shares of AT&T currently trading at $33.75. The mutual fund currently has 15,000 shares outstanding held by investors. Thus, today, the NAV of the fund is calculated as: NAV ⫽ [(2,000 ⫻ $45.50) ⫹ (1,000 ⫻ $91.25) ⫹ (1,500 ⫻ $33.75)] ⫼ 15,000 ⫽ $15.525 If next month Sears shares increase to $50, Exxon/Mobil shares increase to $95, and AT&T shares increase to $45, the NAV (assuming the same number of shares outstanding) would increase to: NAV ⫽ [(2,000 ⫻ $50) ⫹ (1,000 ⫻ $95) ⫹ (1,500 ⫻ $45)] ⫼ 15,000 ⫽ $17.50 2 The Power of Passive Investing: More Wealth with Less Work, Richard A. Ferri, 2011. John Wiley & Sons, Inc. Hoboken, NJ. Chapter 5 open-end mutual fund The supply of shares in the fund is not fixed but can increase or decrease daily with purchases and redemptions of shares. EXAMPLE 5–2 Impact of Investment Size on NAV Financial Services: Mutual Funds and Hedge Funds 123 Most mutual funds are open-end in that the number of shares outstanding fluctuates up and down daily with the amount of share redemptions and new purchases. With open-end mutual funds, investors buy and sell shares from and to the mutual fund company. Thus, the demand for shares determines the number outstanding and the NAV of shares is determined solely by the market value of the underlying securities held in the mutual fund divided by the number of shareholders outstanding. Consider the mutual fund in Example 5–1, but suppose that today 1,000 additional investors buy into the mutual fund at the current NAV of $15.525. This means that the fund manager now has $15,525 in additional funds to invest. Suppose the fund manager decides to use these additional funds to buy additional shares in AT&T. At today’s market price he or she can buy $15,525 ⫼ $33.75 ⫽ 460 additional shares of AT&T. Thus, the mutual fund’s new portfolio of shares would be 2,000 in Sears, 1,000 in Exxon/Mobil, and 1,960 in AT&T. At the end of the month the NAV of the portfolio would be: NAV ⫽ [(2,000 ⫻ $50) ⫹ (1,000 ⫻ $95) ⫹ (1,960 ⫻ $45)] ⫼ 16,000 ⫽ $17.70 given the appreciation in value of all three stocks over the month. Note that the fund’s value changed over the month due to both capital appreciation and investment size. A comparison of the NAV in Example 5–1 with the one in this example indicates that the additional shares alone enabled the fund to gain a slightly higher NAV than had the number of shares remained static ($17.70 versus $17.50). closed-end investment companies Specialized investment companies that invest in securities and assets of other firms but have a fixed supply of shares outstanding themselves. REIT A real estate investment trust. A closedend investment company that specializes in investing in mortgages, property, or real estate company shares. Open-end mutual funds can be compared to most regular corporations traded on stock exchanges and to closed-end investment companies, both of which have a fixed number of shares outstanding at any given time. For example, real estate investment trusts (REITs) are closed-end investment companies that specialize in investment in real estate company shares and/or in buying mortgages.3 With closed-end funds, investors must buy and sell the investment company’s shares on a stock exchange similar to the trading of corporate stock. Since the number of shares available for purchase at any moment in time is fixed, the NAV of the fund’s shares is determined not only by the value of the underlying shares but also by the demand for the investment company’s shares themselves. When demand is high, the shares can trade at more than the NAV of the securities held in the fund. In this case, the fund is said to be trading at a premium, that is, at more than the fair market value of the securities held. When the value of the closed-end fund’s shares are less than the NAV of its assets, its shares are said to be trading at a discount, that is, at less than the fair market value of the securities held. 3 The total market value of funds invested in closed-end funds was $261.3 billion at the end of 2012. This compares to $12,871.9 billion invested in open-end funds at that time. 124 Part One Introduction EXAMPLE 5–3 Market Value of Closed-End Mutual Fund Shares Because of high demand for a closed-end investment company’s shares, the 50 shares (NS) are trading at $20 per share (PS). The market value of the equity-type securities in the fund’s asset portfolio, however, is $800, or $16 ($800 ⫼ 50) per share. The market value balance sheet of the fund is shown below: Assets Liabilities and Equity Market value of asset portfolio $800 Premium $200 Market value of closed-end fund shares (PS ⫻ NS) $1,000 The fund’s shares are trading at a premium of $4 (200 ⫼ 50) per share. Because of low demand for a second closed-end fund, the 100 shares outstanding are trading at $25 per share. The market value of the securities in this fund’s portfolio is $3,000, or each share has a NAV of $30 per share. The market value balance sheet of this fund is: Assets Liabilities and Equity Market value of asset portfolio $3,000 Discount ⫺$500 Market value of closed-end fund shares (100 ⫻ $25) $2,500 Exchange Traded Funds Similar to closed-end funds in that a fixed number of shares are outstanding at any point in time, an exchange-traded fund (ETF) is an investment company with shares that trade intraday on stock exchanges at market-determined prices. ETFs may be bought or sold through a broker or in a brokerage account, like trading shares of any publicly traded company. While ETFs are registered with the SEC as investment companies, they differ from traditional mutual funds both in how their shares are issued and redeemed and in how their shares or units are traded. Specifically, ETF shares are created by an institutional investor’s depositing of a specified block of securities with the ETF. In return for this deposit, the institutional investor receives a fixed amount of ETF shares, some or all of which may then be sold on a stock exchange. The institutional investor may obtain its deposited securities by redeeming the same number of ETF shares it received from the ETF. Individual investors can buy and sell the ETF shares only when they are listed on an exchange. Unlike an institutional investor, a retail investor cannot purchase or redeem shares directly from the ETF, as with a traditional mutual fund. Assets invested in the 1,193 ETFs in existence in 2012 totaled $1.29 trillion, up from $66 billion invested in a total of 80 funds in 2000. Most ETFs are long-term mutual funds that are designed to replicate a particular stock market index.4 ETFs include funds such as SPDRs and Vanguard’s Large-Cap VIPERs funds.5 Like 4 However, in February 2008 the SEC gave approval for the first actively managed ETF. SPDRs, Standard & Poor’s Depository Receipts, hold a portfolio of the equity securities that comprise the Standard & Poor’s 500 Composite Stock Price Index. SPDRs seek investment results that, before expenses, generally correspond to the price and yield performance of the Standard & Poor’s 500 Composite Stock Price Index. Vanguard Large-Cap Index Participation Equity Receipts (VIPERs) seek to track the performance of a benchmark index that measures the investment return of large-capitalization stocks. 5 Chapter 5 Financial Services: Mutual Funds and Hedge Funds 125 index funds, the share price of an ETF changes over time in response to a change in the stock prices underlying a stock index. Further, like index funds, most ETFs are intended to track a specific index, management of the funds is relatively simple, and management fees are lower than those for actively managed mutual funds. Unlike index funds, however, ETFs can be traded during the day, they can be purchased on margin, and they can be sold short by an investor who expects a drop in the underlying index value. Because ETFs behave like stocks, investors are subject to capital gains taxes only when they sell their shares. Thus, ETF investors can defer capital gains for as long as they hold the ETF. www.morningstar.com www.lipperweb.com Mutual fund investors can get information on the performance of mutual funds from several places. For example, for a comprehensive analysis of mutual funds, Morningstar, Inc., offers information on more than 10,000 open-end and closedend funds. Morningstar does not own, operate, or hold an interest in any mutual fund. Similarly, Lipper Analytical services, a subsidiary of Reuters, tracks the performance of more than 115,000 funds worldwide. Mutual Fund Costs Mutual funds charge shareholders a price or fee for the services they provide (i.e., management of a diversified portfolio of financial securities). Two types of fees are incurred by investors: sales loads and fund operating expenses. We discuss these next. The total cost to the shareholder of investing in a mutual fund is the sum of the annualized sales load and other fees charged. Load versus No-Load Funds load fund A mutual fund with an up-front sales or commission charge that has to be paid by the investor. no-load fund A mutual fund that does not charge upfront fees or commission charges on the sale of mutual fund shares to investors. An investor who buys a mutual fund share may be subject to a sales charge, sometimes as high as 5.75 percent. In this case, the fund is called a load fund.6 Other funds that directly market shares to investors do not use sales agents working for commissions and have no up-front commission charges. These are called no-load funds. The argument in favor of load funds is that their managers provide investors with more personal attention and advice than managers of no-load funds. However, the cost of this increased attention may not be worthwhile. For example, the last column in Table 5–6 lists initial fees for the largest U.S. stock funds in 2012. Notice that only American Funds group and Franklin Templeton Custodian Funds (Franklin Cust:Inc;A) assess a load fee on mutual fund share purchases. After adjusting for this fee, the 12-month returns on the 10 American Funds mutual funds fall from 20.07 percent to 13.41 percent (among the highest returns earned by the largest funds) to 14.32 percent to 7.66 percent (among the lowest of the returns on these funds). As Figure 5–3 indicates, investors increasingly recognized this cost disadvantage for load funds in the 1990s as stock market values increased broadly and dramatically. In 1985, load funds represented almost 70 percent of equity mutual fund sales, and no-load funds represented just over 30 percent. By 1998 new sales of no-load mutual fund shares exceeded that of load fund shares, and by 2002 total assets invested in no-load funds far exceeded those invested in load funds. Of course, because the load fee is a one-time charge, it must be converted to an annualized charge incurred by the shareholder over the life of the 6 Another kind of load, called a back-end load, is sometimes charged when mutual fund shares are sold by investors. Back-end loads, also referred to as deferred sales charges, are an alternative way to compensate the fund managers or sales force for their services. 126 Part One Introduction FIGURE 5–3 Load versus No-Load Fund Assets as a Share of Fund Assets (percent) Source: Investment Company Institute, Investment Company Fact Book (Washington, DC: Investment Company Institute, various issues). www.ici.org Equity funds (%) 100 90 80 70 Load 60 50 40 30 20 No-Load 10 0 Year 1984 1986 1988 1990 1992 1994 1996 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 2008 2010 2012 investment. If the shareholder’s investment horizon is long term, the annualized load fee can end up being quite small. If the investment horizon is short, however, the load fee can leave the shareholder with little profit. The demand for no-load funds by mutual fund investors has not gone unnoticed. Many companies, particularly discount brokers, now offer mutual fund supermarkets through which investors can buy and sell mutual fund shares, offered by several different mutual fund sponsors, through a single broker. The most important feature of a fund supermarket is its non–transaction fee program, whereby an investor may purchase mutual funds with no transaction fees from a large number of fund companies. The broker is generally paid for services from the fund’s 12b–1 fees (see below). The non–transaction fee offerings at a discount broker often number in the thousands, providing an investor the convenience of purchasing no-load funds from different families at a single location. Fund Operating Expenses 12b–1 fees Fees relating to the distribution and other operating costs of mutual fund shares. In contrast to one-time up-front load charges on the initial investment in a mutual fund, annual fees are charged to cover all fund level expenses experienced as a percent of the fund assets. One type of fee (called a management fee) is charged to meet operating costs (such as administration and shareholder services). In addition, mutual funds generally require a small percentage (or fee) of investable funds to meet fund level marketing and distribution costs. Such annual fees are known as 12b–1 fees after the SEC rule covering such charges. These annual fees cannot exceed 1 percent of a fund’s average net assets per year. Marketing and servicing costs are capped at 0.25 percent per year, while management fees are capped at 0.75 percent per year, for a total maximum 12b-1 charge of 1 percent per year. Because these fees, charged to cover fund operating expenses, are paid out of the fund’s assets, investors indirectly bear these expenses. These fees are generally expressed as a percentage of the average net assets invested in the fund. Chapter 5 EXAMPLE 5–4 Calculation of Mutual Fund Costs Financial Services: Mutual Funds and Hedge Funds 127 The cost of mutual fund investing to a shareholder includes both the one-time sales load and any annual fees charged. Because the sales load is a one-time charge, it must be converted to an annualized payment incurred by the shareholder over the life of his or her investment. With this conversion, the total shareholder cost of investing in a fund is the sum of the annualized sales load plus any annual fees. For example, suppose an investor purchases fund shares with a 4 percent front-end load and expects to hold the shares for 10 years. The annualized sales load7 incurred by the investor is: 4%/10 years ⫽ 0.4% per year Further, suppose the fund has a total fund expense ratio (including 12b–1 fees) of 1 percent per year. The annual total shareholder cost for this fund is calculated as 0.4% ⫹ 1% ⫽ 1.4% per year Funds sold through financial professionals such as brokers have recently adopted alternative payment methods. These typically include an annual 12b–1 fee based on asset values that also may be combined with a front-end or back-end sales charge. In many cases, funds offer several different share classes (all of which invest in the same underlying portfolio of assets), but each share class may offer investors different methods of paying for broker services. Indeed, in 2010, approximately two-thirds of all mutual funds had two or more share classes, compared to 1980 when all funds had only one share class. Most funds sold in multiple classes offer investors three payment plans through three share classes (A, B, and C), each having different mixes of sales loads and management and 12b–1 fees. Class A shares represent the traditional means for paying for investment advice. That is, class A shares carry a front-end load that is charged at the time of purchase as a percent of the sales price. The front-end load on class A shares is charged on new sales and is not generally incurred when class A shares are exchanged for another mutual fund within the same fund family. In addition to the front-end load, class A shares usually have annual management and 12b–1 fees that are used to compensate brokers and sales professionals for ongoing assistance and service provided to fund shareholders. The management and 12b–1 fees for class A shares are typically between 25 and 35 basis points of the portfolio’s assets. Unlike class A shares, class B shares are offered for sale at the NAV without a front-end load. Class B share investors pay for advice and assistance from brokers through a combination of annual management and 12b–1 fees (usually 1 percent) and a back-end load. The back-end load is charged when shares are redeemed (sold) and is typically based on the lesser of the original cost of the shares or the market value at the time of sale. After six to eight years, class B shares typically convert to class A shares, lowering the level of the annual management and 12b–1 fees from 1 percent to that of A shares. Class C shares are offered at the NAV with no front-end load, and they typically recover distribution costs through a combination of annual management and 12b–1 fees of 1 percent and a back-end load, set at 1 percent in the first year of purchase. After the first year, no back-end load is charged on redemption. Class C shares usually do not convert to class A shares, and thus the annual 7 Convention in the industry is to annualize the sales load without adjusting for the time value of money. 128 Part One Introduction 1 percent payment to the broker continues throughout the period of time that the shares are held. As discussed below, the lack of complete disclosure and the inability of most mutual fund investors to understand the different fees charged for various classes of mutual fund shares came under scrutiny in the early 2000s. Indeed, the potential for overcharging fees to various classes of mutual fund shareholders led to the SEC creating new rules pertaining to these charges. Possibly as a result of these scandals and new rules, more than 850 mutual funds decreased their management fees in 2005, and over 700 lowered their fees in 2006. The average fees and expenses paid by mutual fund investors continue to fall. Investors paid 0.79 percent on the average stock fund in 2012, down from 1.98 percent in 1990 and 1.18 percent in 2004. Bond fund investors paid an average of 0.62 percent in 2009, down from 1.89 percent in 1990 and 0.92 percent in 2004. Concept Questions 1. 2. 3. 4. Where do mutual funds rank in terms of asset size among all FI industries? Describe the difference between short-term and long-term mutual funds. What have been the trends in the number of mutual funds since 1980? What are the three biggest mutual fund companies? How have their funds performed in recent years? 5. Describe the difference between open-end and closed-end mutual funds. BALANCE SHEET AND RECENT TRENDS FOR THE MUTUAL FUND INDUSTRY Money Market Funds The distribution of assets of money market mutual funds from 1990 through 2012 is shown in Table 5–7. As you can see, in 2012, $2,076.9 billion (82.8 percent of total assets) was invested in short-term financial securities such as foreign deposits, domestic checkable deposits and currency, time and savings deposits, repurchase agreements (RPs), open market paper (mostly commercial paper), and U.S. government securities. This is up from 2007 (at the start of the financial crisis) when $2,094.4 billion (or 69.0 percent) of financial assets were invested in short-term securities. As financial markets tumbled in 2008, money market mutual funds moved investments out of corporate and foreign bonds (12.4 percent of the total in 2007 and 6.1 percent in 2008) into safer securities such as U.S. government securities (13.6 percent of the total investments in 2007 and 35.5 percent in 2008). Shortmaturity asset holdings reflect the objective of these funds to retain the depositlike nature of the share liabilities they issue. In fact, most money market mutual fund shares have their values fixed at $1. Asset value fluctuations due to interest rate changes and capital gains or losses on assets are adjusted for by increasing or reducing the number of $1 shares owned by the investor. In addition to these typical risks faced by fund mangers, money market mutual funds experienced unusual liquidity risk at the start of the financial crisis. On September 16, 2008 (one day after Lehman Brothers filed for bankruptcy), Reserve Primary Fund, the oldest money market fund in the United States, saw its shares fall to an equivalent of 97 cents (below the $1.00 book value) after writing off debt Chapter 5 TABLE 5–7 Financial Services: Mutual Funds and Hedge Funds 129 Distribution of Assets in Money Market Mutual Funds, 1990–2012 (in billions of dollars) Source: Federal Reserve Board, “Flow of Fund Accounts,” various issues. www.federalreserve.gov 1990 1995 2000 2005 2007 2008 2010 2012 Total financial assets $493.3 $745.3 $1,812.1 $2,006.9 $3,033.1 $3,757.3 $2,755.3 $2,506.9 Foreign deposits 26.7 19.7 91.1 94.7 127.3 129.3 105.9 40.2 Checkable deposits and currency 11.2 ⫺3.5 2.2 ⫺0.9 1.9 7.5 14.2 11.3 Time and savings deposits 21.9 52.3 142.4 183.0 270.7 355.2 468.0 405.3 Security RPs 58.2 87.8 183.0 346.0 605.9 542.4 479.3 513.1 Credit market instruments 371.3 545.5 1,290.9 1,340.8 1,936.4 2,675.0 1,621.0 1,471.6 Open market paper 204.0 235.5 608.6 492.2 674.6 618.5 394.2 319.4 Treasury 44.9 70.0 90.4 88.6 178.1 577.7 335.4 456.3 Agency 36.4 90.8 185.2 160.1 235.9 756.2 402.8 331.3 Municipal securities 84.0 127.7 244.7 336.7 471.0 494.6 334.4 271.6 Corporate and foreign bonds 2.0 21.5 161.9 263.2 376.8 228.0 154.2 93.0 Miscellaneous assets 4.0 43.4 102.5 43.3 90.9 47.9 66.9 65.4 Percent of Total, 2012 100.0% 1.6 0.5 16.2 20.5 58.6 12.7 18.2 13.2 10.8 3.7 2.6 issued by Lehman Brothers. Resulting investor anxiety about Reserve Primary Fund spread to other funds, and investors industrywide liquidated their MMMF shares. In just one week investors liquidated over $200 billion of the industry total $4 trillion invested in MMMFs. In response, on September 19 the federal government took steps to restore confidence in the MMMF industry. Specifically, the Department of Treasury opened the Temporary Guarantee Program for MMMFs, which provided up to $50 billion in coverage to MMMF shareholders for amounts they held in the funds as of close of business that day. The guarantee was triggered if a participating fund’s net asset value fell below $0.995. The program was designed to address the severe liquidity strains in the industry and immediately stabilized the industry and stopped the outflows. EXAMPLE 5–5 Calculation of Number of Shares Outstanding in a Money Market Mutual Fund Due to a drop in interest rates, the market value of the assets held by a particular MMMF increases from $100 to $110. The market value balance sheet for the mutual fund before and after the drop in interest rates is: Assets Liabilities and Equity (a) Before the interest rate drop: Market value of MMMF assets $100 Market value of MMMF fund shares (100 shares ⫻ $1) $100 (b) After the interest rate drop: Market value of MMMF assets 110 Market value of MMMF fund shares (110 shares ⫻ $1) 110 The interest rate drop results in 10 (110 ⫺ 100) new equity-type shares that are held by investors in the MMMF, reflecting the increase in the market value of the MMMF’s assets of $10 (i.e., 10 new shares of $1 each). 130 Part One TABLE 5–8 Introduction Distribution of Assets in Bond, Equity, and Hybrid Mutual Funds, 1990–2012 (in billions of dollars) Source: Federal Reserve Board, “Flow of Fund Accounts,” various issues. www.federalreserve.gov 1990 1995 2000 2005 2007 2008 2010 2012 Percent of Total, 2012 Total financial assets $608.4 $1,852.8 $4,434.6 $6,048.9 $7,829.0 $5,435.3 $7,934.5 $9,262.4 100.0% Security RPs 6.1 50.2 106.4 115.4 132.2 124.7 137.5 222.7 2.4 Credit market instruments 360.1 771.3 1,097.8 1,747.1 2,203.1 2,276.5 3,031.4 4,035.5 43.6 Open market paper 28.5 50.2 106.4 97.1 114.1 51.6 66.3 131.1 1.4 Treasury 111.1 205.3 123.7 155.7 179.2 187.9 297.4 427.6 4.6 Agency 48.6 109.9 275.3 483.4 565.2 592.7 791.1 1,066.6 11.5 Municipal securities 112.6 210.2 230.5 311.7 372.2 389.6 526.6 612.8 6.6 Corporate and foreign bonds 59.3 185.5 337.6 662.7 889.9 959.9 1,275.4 1,701.9 18.4 Other loans and advances 0.0 10.2 24.3 36.5 82.5 94.8 74.6 95.5 1.1 Corporate equities 233.2 1,024.9 3,226.9 4,175.7 5,476.9 3,014.1 4,762.7 5,004.2 54.0 Miscellaneous assets 8.9 6.3 3.5 10.7 16.8 20.0 2.9 0.0 0.0 Long-Term Funds Note the asset composition of long-term mutual funds shown in Table 5–8. As might be expected, it reflects the popularity of different types of bond or equity funds at any point in time. For example, underscoring the attractiveness of equity funds in 2007 was the fact that stocks comprised over 70.0 percent of total longterm mutual fund asset portfolios. Credit market instruments were the next most popular assets (28.1 percent of the asset portfolio). In contrast, look at the distribution of assets in 2008, when the equity markets were plummeting. Equities made up only 55.5 percent of the long-term mutual fund portfolios and credit market instruments were 41.9 percent of total assets. Note too that total financial assets fell from $7,829.0 billion in 2007 (before the start of the financial crisis) to just $5,435.3 billion in 2008 (at the height of the crisis), a drop of 30.6 percent. As the economy and financial markets recovered (in 2010), financial assets held by long-term mutual funds increased to $7,934.5 billion, of which only 60.0 percent were corporate equities. In 2012, long-term funds held financial assets totaling $9,262.4 billion, of which 54.0 percent were corporate equities. Thus, even four years after the start of the financial crisis, long-term funds had not switched their holdings of corporate equities back to pre-crisis levels. Concept Questions 1. Describe the major assets held by mutual funds in the 1990s and 2000s. 2. How does the asset distribution differ between money market mutual funds and long-term mutual funds? Chapter 5 Financial Services: Mutual Funds and Hedge Funds 131 REGULATION OF MUTUAL FUNDS www.sec.gov www.nasd.com Because mutual funds manage and invest small investors’ savings, this industry is heavily regulated. Indeed, many regulations have been enacted to protect investors against possible abuses by managers of mutual funds. The SEC is the primary regulator of mutual funds. Specifically, the Securities Act of 1933 requires a mutual fund to file a registration statement with the SEC and sets rules and procedures regarding the fund’s prospectus sent to investors. In addition, the Securities Exchange Act of 1934 makes the purchase and sale of mutual fund shares subject to various antifraud provisions. This regulation requires that a mutual fund furnish full and accurate information on all financial and corporate matters to prospective fund purchasers. The 1934 act also appointed the National Association of Securities Dealers (NASD) to supervise mutual fund share distributions. In 1940 Congress passed the Investment Advisers Act and the Investment Company Act. The Investment Advisers Act regulates the activities of mutual fund advisors. The Investment Company Act sets out rules to prevent conflicts of interest, fraud, and excessive fees or charges for fund shares. More recently, the passage of the Insider Trading and Securities Fraud Enforcement Act of 1988 has required mutual funds to develop mechanisms and procedures to avoid insider trading abuses. In addition, the Market Reform Act of 1990, passed in the wake of the 1987 stock market crash, allows the SEC to introduce circuit breakers to halt trading on exchanges and to restrict program trading when it deems necessary. Finally, the National Securities Markets Improvement Act (NSMIA) of 1996 also applies to mutual fund companies. Specifically, the NSMIA exempts mutual fund sellers from oversight by state securities regulators, thus reducing their regulatory burden. Despite the many regulations imposed on mutual fund companies, several allegations of trading abuses and improper assignment of fees were revealed and prosecuted in the early 2000s. The abusive activities fell into four general categories: market timing, late trading, directed brokerage, and improper assessment of fees to investors. Market timing involves short-term trading of mutual funds that seeks to take advantage of short-term discrepancies between the price of a mutual fund’s shares and out-of-date values on the securities in the fund’s portfolio. It is especially common in international funds as traders can exploit differences in time zones. Typically, market timers hold a fund for only a few days. For example, when Asian markets close with losses, but are expected to rebound the following day, market timers can buy a U.S. mutual fund, investing in Asian securities after the loss on that day and then sell the shares for a profit the next day. This singleday investment dilutes the profits of the fund’s long-term investors, while market timers profit without much risk. Late trading allegations involved cases in which some investors were able to buy or sell mutual fund shares long after the price had been set at 4 pm eastern time each day (i.e., after the close of the NYSE and NASDAQ). Under existing rules, investors had to place an order with their broker or another FI by 4 pm. But the mutual fund company may not have received the order until much later, sometimes as late as 9 pm. However, because of this time delay, some large investors had been able to call their broker back after the market closed and alter or cancel their order. 132 Part One Introduction Directed brokerage involves arrangements between mutual fund companies and brokerage houses and whether those agreements improperly influenced which funds brokers recommended to investors. The investigation examined whether some mutual fund companies agreed to direct orders for stock and bond purchases and sales to brokerage houses that agreed to promote sales of the mutual fund company’s products. Finally, regulators claimed that the disclosure of 12b–1 fees allowed some brokers to trick investors into believing they were buying no-load funds. Before 12b–1 fees, all funds sold through brokers carried front-end load fees. As discussed above, with 12b–1 fees, fund companies introduced share classes, some of which carried back-end loads that declined over time and others that charged annual fees of up to 1 percent of asset values. Funds classes that charged annual 12b–1 fees would see performance decrease by that amount and thus not perform as well as an identical fund that carried a lower 12b–1 fee. The shareholder, however, saw only the fund’s raw return (before annual fees) and not the dollar amount of the fee paid. Further, regulators discovered in late 2002 that brokers often overcharged customers by failing to provide discounts to fund investors who qualified to receive them. Since discount policies differ from fund to fund, brokers did not always realize which customers qualified for them. The result of these illegal and abusive activities was new rules and regulations imposed (in 2004 and 2005) on mutual fund companies. The rules were intended to give investors more information about conflicts of interest, improve fund governance, and close legal loopholes that some fund managers had abused. Many of these new rules involve changes to the way mutual funds operate, including requirements that funds have an independent board headed by an independent chairman. Specifically, the SEC required an increase in the percentage of independent board members to 75 percent from the previous level of 50 percent and required mutual fund companies to have independent board chairs (a move that would displace the sitting chairmen at about 80 percent of the nations mutual funds). The SEC saw independent directors as those who better serve as watchdogs guarding investors’ interests. Further, the Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002 requires public companies, including mutual fund companies, to make sure their boards’ audit committees have at least one individual who is familiar with generally accepted accounting principles and has experience with internal auditing controls, preparing or auditing financial statements of “generally comparable issuers,” and applying GAAP principles for estimates, accruals, and reserves. The SEC also took steps to close a loophole that allowed improper trading to go unnoticed at some mutual funds. Prior to the new rules, the SEC required that funds report trading by senior employees in individual stocks but not in shares of mutual funds they manage. The SEC now requires portfolio managers to report trading in funds they manage. Investment advisors also have to protect information about stock selections and client holding and transactions. The SEC and other regulators had found that advisory personnel revealed confidential information about fund portfolio holdings so that others could exploit the funds. To address the problem of market timing, the SEC now requires funds to provide expanded disclosure of the risks of frequent trading in fund shares and of their policies and procedures regarding such activities. Mutual funds also now have to be more open about their use of fair value pricing (a practice of estimating the value of rarely traded securities or updating the values of non-U.S. securities that last traded many hours before U.S. funds calculate their share prices each day) Chapter 5 Financial Services: Mutual Funds and Hedge Funds 133 to guard against stale share prices that could produce profits for market timers. The market timing provisions also require mutual funds to explain when they use fair value pricing. Fair value pricing is one of the most effective ways of combating the market timing that was most common in some mutual funds holding nonU.S. stocks. Many mutual funds had rarely used fair value pricing. Further, new SEC rules require brokers to tell investors about any payments, compensation, or other incentives they receive from fund companies including whether they are paid more to sell a certain fund. Conflicts would have to be disclosed before the sale is completed. To ensure that the required rule changes take place, starting October 5, 2004, the SEC required that mutual funds hire chief compliance officers to monitor whether the mutual fund company follows the rules. The chief compliance officer reports directly to mutual fund directors, and not to executives of the fund management company. To further insulate the chief compliance officer from being bullied into keeping quiet about improper behavior, only the fund board can fire the compliance officer. Duties of the compliance officer include policing personal trading by fund managers, ensuring accuracy of information provided to regulators and investors, reviewing fund business practices such as allocating trading commissions, and reporting any wrongdoing directly to fund directors. Finally, the new SEC rules call for shareholder reports to include the fees shareholders pay during any period covered, as well as management’s discussion of the fund’s performance over that period. As of September 1, 2004, mutual fund companies must provide clear information to investors on brokerage commissions and discounts, including improved disclosure on up-front sales charges for broker-sold mutual funds. Investors now get a document showing the amount they paid for a fund, the amount their broker was paid, and how the fund compares with industry averages based on fees, sales loads, and brokerage commissions. As of December 2004, mutual funds must provide to investors summary information in a fund prospectus on eligibility for breakpoint discounts and explain what records investors may need to show brokers to demonstrate they qualify for discounts. The SEC also proposed that mutual funds or their agents receive all trading orders by 4 pm eastern time, when the fund’s daily price is calculated. This “hard closing,” which would require fund orders to be in the hands of the mutual fund companies by 4 pm, is intended to halt late trading abuses. In March 2009, the SEC adopted amendments to the form used by mutual funds to register under the Investment Company Act of 1940 and to offer their securities under the Securities Act of 1933 in order to enhance the disclosures that are provided to mutual fund investors. The amendments (first proposed in November 2007) require key information to appear in plain English in a standardized order at the front of the mutual fund statutory prospectus. The amendment also includes a new option for satisfying prospectus delivery obligations with respect to mutual fund securities under the Securities Act. Under the option, key information is sent or given to investors in the form of a summary prospectus and the statutory prospectus is provided on an Internet website. The improved disclosure framework was intended to provide investors with information that is easier to use and more readily accessible, while retaining the comprehensive quality of the information that was previously available. Finally, in a February 2013 letter sent to the Financial Stability Oversight Council (FSOC) (set up as a result of the Wall Street Reform and Consumer 134 Part One Introduction Protection Act to oversee the financial system), the leaders of all 12 regional Federal Reserve banks called for a significant overhaul of the money market industry. The letter stated that even four years after the financial crisis, without reform money, market mutual fund activities could spread the risk of significant credit problems from the funds to banks to the broader financial system. New York Fed president William Dudley stated that the risk of a run on money market funds was potentially higher in 2013 than before the crisis because banks increasingly used these funds as a source of financing and because Congress blocked the Fed and Treasury from using certain emergency tools that could stabilize the funds during a market panic. A proposal released in November 2012 by the FSOC included a requirement for money market mutual funds to let fund prices adjust to changes in the net asset value of the funds’ holdings, rather than fixing values at $1 a share. The logic behind the proposal is that with a floating value, investors would be less likely to rush to pull their cash out of the funds before share values “break the buck,” as happened during the 2008 crisis (discussed earlier). However, little action followed the release of the proposal. The joint letter by the Fed presidents was intended to serve as impetus to renew the push for reform. Concept Questions 1. Who is the primary regulator of mutual fund companies? 2. How did the NSMIA affect mutual funds? GLOBAL ISSUES IN THE MUTUAL FUND INDUSTRY £ ¥ :$ As discussed throughout the chapter, mutual funds have been the fastest-growing sector in the U.S. financial institutions industry throughout the 1990s and into the 2000s. Only the worldwide financial crisis and the worst worldwide recession since the Great Depression curtailed the growth in this industry. Worldwide investment in mutual funds is shown in Table 5–9. Combined assets invested in non-U.S. mutual funds are approximately equal to that invested in U.S. mutual funds alone. However, recent growth in non-U.S. funds has exceeded that in U.S. funds. Worldwide (other than in the United States), investments in mutual funds have increased more than 211 percent, from $4.545 trillion in 1999 to $14.130 trillion in 2007. This compares with growth of 75 percent in U.S. funds. Likewise, non-U.S. mutual funds experienced bigger losses in total assets during the financial crisis. Worldwide funds fell to $9.316 trillion (34.1 percent) in 2008, while U.S. funds fell to $9.601 trillion (20.1 percent). By 2012, as worldwide economies improved, worldwide investments in mutual funds increased to $13.291 trillion (an increase of 42.7 percent from 2008), while U.S. investments increased to $12.754 trillion (an increase of 32.8 percent). In addition, as this industry developed in countries throughout the world, the number of mutual funds worldwide (other than in the United States) increased 46.4 percent, from 44,955 in 1999 to 65,795 in 2012. Much more established in the United States, the number of U.S. mutual funds decreased by almost 3 percent over this period. In 2012, of the total amount invested in mutual funds outside the United States, 35 percent was in equity funds, 16 percent in bond funds, 19 percent in hybrid funds, 22 percent in money market funds, and 8 percent in other funds. TABLE 5–9 Worldwide Assets of Open-End Investment Companies* (in millions of dollars) Source: Investment Company Institute, Investment Company Fact Book (Washington, DC: Investment Company Institute, various issues). www.ici.org Non-U.S. Countries 1999 6,990 N/A 56,254 65,461 117,758 N/A 269,825 4,091 N/A N/A 1,473 27,558 10,318 656,132 237,312 36,397 182,265 1,725 13,065 95,174 475,661 502,752 167,177 N/A 661,084 N/A 19,468 94,539 8,502 15,107 N/A 117 762 19,704 N/A 177 N/A N/A 18,235 207,603 83,250 82,512 31,153 N/A N/A 375,199 2002 $ 1,021 356,304 66,877 74,983 96,729 N/A 248,979 6,705 N/A 1,738 3,297 40,153 16,516 845,147 209,168 26,621 164,322 3,992 20,364 250,116 378,259 303,191 149,544 3,847 803,869 N/A 30,759 84,211 7,505 15,471 N/A 474 5,468 19,969 27 372 N/A N/A 20,983 179,133 57,992 82,622 62,153 N/A 6,002 288,887 2007 $ 6,789 1,192,992 138,709 149,842 615,365 N/A 698,397 24,444 434,063 1,203 7,595 104,082 81,136 1,989,690 372,072 29,807 818,421 12,577 108,582 951,371 419,687 713,998 329,979 25,103 2,685,065 N/A 75,428 113,759 14,924 74,709 4,956 2,090 45,542 29,732 390 7,175 4,762 4,219 95,221 396,354 194,955 176,282 58,323 N/A 22,609 897,460 2008 $ 3,867 841,133 93,269 105,057 479,321 226 416,031 17,587 276,303 1,098 5,260 65,182 48,750 1,591,082 237,986 12,189 N/A 9,188 62,805 720,486 263,588 575,327 221,992 20,489 1,860,763 N/A 60,435 77,379 10,612 41,157 1,985 1,263 17,782 13,572 326 2,026 3,841 2,067 69,417 270,983 113,331 135,052 46,116 N/A 15,404 504,681 2012† 2010 Argentina Australia Austria Belgium Brazil Bulgaria Canada Chile China Costa Rica Czech Republic Denmark‡ Finland France Germany Greece Hong Kong Hungary India Ireland Italy Japan Korea Liechtenstein Luxembourg Malta Mexico Netherlands New Zealand Norway Pakistan Philippines Poland Portugal Romania Russia Slovakia Slovenia South Africa Spain Sweden Switzerland Taiwan Trinidad & Tobago Turkey United Kingdom $ $ Total non-U.S. $ 4,544,799 $ 4,933,771 $14,130,041 $ 9,316,409 $12,878,305 $13,290,983 Total U.S. Total world $ 6,846,339 $11,391,138 $ 6,390,360 $11,324,131 $12,020,895 $26,150,936 $ 9,601,090 $18,917,499 $11,820,865 $24,699,170 $12,754,273 $26,045,256 * Funds of funds are not included. Data include home-domiciled funds, except for Hong Kong, Korea, and New Zealand. † As of end of the third quarter. ‡ Before 2003, data include special funds reserved for institutional investors. Note: Components may not add to total because of rounding. 5,179 1,455,850 94,670 96,288 5,179 302 636,947 38,243 364,985 1,470 5,508 89,800 71,210 1,617,176 333,713 8,627 N/A 11,532 111,421 1,014,104 234,313 785,504 266,495 35,387 2,512,874 N/A 98,094 85,924 19,562 84,505 2,290 2,184 25,595 11,004 1,713 3,917 4,349 2,663 141,615 216,915 205,449 261,893 59,032 5,812 19,545 854,413 $ 8,571 1,610,190 85,288 82,499 8,571 296 840,890 35,040 373,519 1,651 4,657 98,525 70,483 1,439,987 314,040 5,001 N/A 8,082 110,021 1,216,670 176,227 753,552 255,419 32,459 2,510,001 3,002 109,481 70,634 30,020 93,890 3,214 3,210 22,554 6,987 2,400 N/A 2,882 2,340 138,283 188,660 199,454 310,504 57,282 6,388 15,862 938,832 135 136 Part One Introduction As may be expected, the worldwide mutual fund market is most active in those countries with the most sophisticated securities markets (e.g., Japan, France, Australia, and the United Kingdom). However, in the late 1990s and early 2000s, the faltering Japanese economy resulted in a decrease in both the assets invested in and the number of mutual funds. Assets invested in Japanese mutual funds fell from $502.7 billion in 1999 to $303.2 billion in 2002 (a drop of 39.7 percent) and the number of funds fell from 3,444 to 2,718 (21.1 percent) over the period. Some U.S. FIs saw this decline in the Japanese market as an opportunity. U.S. FIs such as Paine Webber Group (teaming up with Yasuda Life Insurance Co.) and Merrill Lynch (buying the assets of failed Japanese brokerage firm Yamaichi Securities) entered the Japanese mutual fund market in the late 1990s and early 2000s. The U.S. FIs saw Japan as a profitable market for mutual fund sales, noting that about 60 percent of Japan’s savings was in low-yielding bank deposits or governmentrun institutions. Although U.S. mutual fund companies sponsor funds abroad, barriers to entry overseas are typically higher than in the United States. The U.S. mutual fund industry has worked to lower the barriers that prevent U.S. mutual fund firms from marketing their services more widely and to improve competition in the often diverse fund markets around the world. The U.S. mutual fund industry, for example, has worked to achieve a true cross-border market for mutual fund companies in Europe and to ensure that publicly offered mutual fund companies can be used as funding vehicles in the retirement fund market in Europe and Japan. The industry also has sought to reduce barriers for U.S. mutual fund sponsors seeking to offer mutual fund company products in China and other Asian countries. Concept Question 1. What have been the trends in the assets invested in worldwide mutual funds from the 1990s through the 2000s? HEDGE FUNDS Hedge funds are a type of investment pool that solicits funds from (wealthy) individuals and other investors (e.g., commercial banks) and invests these funds on their behalf. Hedge funds are similar to mutual funds in that they are pooled investment vehicles that accept investors’ money and generally invest it on a collective basis. Hedge funds are, however, not subject to the numerous regulations that apply to mutual funds for the protection of individuals, such as regulations requiring a certain degree of liquidity, regulations requiring that mutual fund shares be redeemable at any time, regulations protecting against conflicts of interest, regulations to ensure fairness in the pricing of funds shares, disclosure regulations, and regulations limiting the use of leverage. Further, hedge funds do not have to disclose their full activities to third parties. Thus, they offer a high degree of privacy for their investors. Until 2010, hedge funds were not required to register with the SEC. Thus, they were subject to virtually no regulatory oversight (e.g., by the SEC under the Securities Act and Investment Advisers Act) and generally took significant risk. Even after 2010, hedge funds offered in the United States avoid regulations by limiting the asset size of the fund (see below). Chapter 5 Financial Services: Mutual Funds and Hedge Funds 137 Historically, hedge funds avoided regulations by limiting the number of investors to less than 100 individuals (below that required for SEC registration), who must be deemed “accredited investors.” To be accredited, an investor must have a net worth of more than $1 million or have an annual income of at least $200,000 ($300,000 if married). These stiff financial requirements allowed hedge funds to avoid regulation under the theory that individuals with such wealth should be able to evaluate the risk and return on their investments. According to the SEC, these types of investors should be expected to make more informed decisions and take on higher levels of risk. However, as a result of some heavily publicized hedge fund failures and near failures (the result of fraud by fund managers, e.g., Bernard L. Madoff Investment Securities, and the financial crisis, e.g., Bear Stearns High Grade Structured Credit Strategies Fund), in 2010 federal regulators increased the oversight of hedge funds (see below). Even with this increased oversight, because hedge funds remain exempt from many of the rules and regulations governing mutual funds, they can use aggressive strategies that are unavailable to mutual funds, including short selling, leveraging, program trading, arbitrage, and derivatives trading. Further, since hedge funds that do not exceed $100 million in assets under management do not register with the SEC, their actual data cannot be independently tracked. Therefore, much hedge fund data are self-reported. It is estimated that in 2013 there were more than 8,000 hedge funds in the world, with managed assets estimated at $2.25 trillion. Table 5–10 lists the 10 largest hedge funds by total assets managed in 2013. Hedge funds grew in popularity in the 1990s as investors saw returns of more than 40 percent after management fees (often more than 25 percent of the fund’s profits). They came to the forefront of the news in the late 1990s when one large hedge fund, Long-Term Capital Management (LTCM), nearly collapsed. The near collapse of LTCM not only hurt its investors, but arguably came close to damaging the world’s financial system. So great was the potential impact of the failure of LTCM that the Federal Reserve felt it was necessary to intervene by brokering a $3.6 billion bailout of LTCM by a consortium of some of the world’s largest financial institutions. Some hedge funds take positions (using sophisticated computer models) speculating that some prices will rise faster than others. For example, a hedge fund may buy (take a long position in) a bond expecting that its price will rise. At the TABLE 5–10 Largest Hedge Fund Firms by Assets Managed Source: Institutional Investor, January 2013. www.institutionalinvestor.com Name of Fund Country Bridgewater Associates J.P. Morgan Asset Management Man Group Brevan Howard Asset Management Winton Capital Management Och-Ziff Capital Management Group BlackRock BlueCrest Capital Management Baupost Group AQR Capital Management United States United States United Kingdom United Kingdom United Kingdom United States United States United Kingdom United States United States Total Assets (in billions) $76.1 53.6 38.5 34.2 30.0 28.8 28.8 28.6 25.2 23.2 138 Part One Introduction same time the fund will borrow (taking a short position) in another bond and sell it, promising to return the borrowed bond in the future. Generally, bond prices tend to move up and down together. Thus, if prices go up as expected, the hedge fund will gain on the bond it purchased while losing money on the bond it borrowed. The hedge fund will make a profit if the gain on the bond it purchased is larger than the loss on the bond it borrowed. If, contrary to expectations, bond prices fall, the hedge fund will make a profit if the gains on the bond it borrowed are greater than the losses on the bond it bought. Thus, regardless of the change in prices, the simultaneous long and short positions in bonds will minimize the risk of overall losses for the hedge fund. Types of Hedge Funds Most hedge funds are highly specialized, relying on the specific expertise of the fund manager(s) to produce a profit. Hedge fund managers follow a variety of investment strategies, some of which use leverage and derivatives, while others use more conservative strategies and involve little or no leverage. Generally, hedge funds are set up with specific parameters so that investors can forecast a risk-return profile. Figure 5–4 shows the general categories of hedge funds by risk classification. More risky funds are the most aggressive and may produce profits in many types of market environments. Funds in this group are classified by objectives such as aggressive growth, emerging markets, macro, market timing, and short selling. Aggressive growth funds invest in equities expected to experience acceleration in growth of earnings per share. Generally, high price-to-earnings ratio, low or no dividend companies are included. These funds hedge by shorting equities where earnings disappointment is expected or by shorting stock indexes. Emerging market funds invest in equity or debt securities of emerging markets, which tend to have higher inflation and volatile growth. Macro funds aim to profit from changes in global economies, typically brought about by shifts in government policy that impact interest rates. These funds include investments in equities, bonds, currencies, and commodities. They use leverage and derivatives to accentuate the impact of market moves. Market timing funds allocate assets among different asset classes depending on the manager’s view of the economic or market outlook. Thus, portfolio emphasis may swing widely between asset classes. The unpredictability of FIGURE 5–4 Classification of Hedge Funds More Risky Market directional—These funds seek high returns using leverage, typically investing based on anticipated events. Moderate Risk Market neutral or value orientation—These funds have moderate exposure to market risk, typically favoring a longer-term investment strategy. Risk Avoidance Market neutral—These funds strive for moderate, consistent returns with low risk. Chapter 5 Financial Services: Mutual Funds and Hedge Funds 139 market movements and the difficulty of timing entry and exit from markets add significant risk to this strategy. Short-selling funds sell securities in anticipation of being able to buy them back in the future at a lower price based on the manager’s assessment of the overvaluation of the securities or in anticipation of earnings disappointments. Moderate risk funds are more traditional funds, similar to mutual funds, with only a portion of the portfolio being hedged. Funds in this group are classified by objectives such as distressed securities, fund of funds, opportunistic, multistrategy, and special situations. Distressed securities funds buy equity, debt, or trade claims, at deep discounts, of companies in or facing bankruptcy or reorganization. Profit opportunities come from the market’s lack of understanding of the true value of these deep-discount securities and from the fact that the majority of institutional investors cannot own below-investment-grade securities. Funds of funds mix hedge funds and other pooled investment vehicles. This blending of different strategies and asset classes aims to provide a more stable long-term investment return than any of the individual funds. Returns and risk can be controlled by the mix of underlying strategies and funds. Capital preservation is generally an important consideration for these funds. Opportunistic funds change their investment strategy as opportunities arise to profit from events such as IPOs, sudden price changes resulting from a disappointing earnings announcement, and hostile takeover bids. These funds may utilize several investing styles at any point in time and are not restricted to any particular investment approach or asset class. Multistrategy funds take a diversified investment approach by implementing various strategies simultaneously to realize short- and long-term gains. This style of investment allows the manager to overweight or underweight different strategies to best capitalize on current investment opportunities. Special-situation funds invest in event-driven situations such as mergers, hostile takeovers, reorganizations, or leveraged buyouts. These funds may undertake the simultaneous purchase of stock in a company being acquired and sale of stock in its bidder, hoping to profit from the spread between the current market price and the final purchase price of the company. Risk-avoidance funds are also more traditional funds, emphasizing consistent but moderate returns while avoiding risk. Funds in this group are classified by objectives such as income, market neutral–arbitrage, market neutral–securities hedging, and value. Income funds invest with the primary focus on yield or current income rather than solely on capital gains. These funds use leverage to buy bonds and some fixed-income derivatives, profiting from principal appreciation and interest income. Market neutral–arbitrage funds attempt to hedge market risk by taking offsetting positions, often in different securities of the same issuer, for example, long convertible bonds and short the firm’s equity. Their focus is on obtaining returns with low or no correlation to both equity and bond markets. Market neutral–securities hedging funds invest equally in long and short equity portfolios in particular market sectors. Market risk is reduced, but effective stock analysis is critical to obtaining a profit. These funds use leverage to magnify their returns. They also sometimes use market index futures to hedge systematic risk. Value funds invest in securities perceived to be selling at deep discounts relative to their intrinsic values. Securities include those that may be out of favor or underfollowed by analysts. Using traditional risk-adjusted measures of performance (such as Sharpe ratios), the performance of hedge funds has been very strong compared to that 140 Part One Introduction TABLE 5–11 Largest Hedge Funds by Fund Earnings, 2008–2009 Source: Bloomberg, 2009. www.bloomberg.com Fund, Manager Name(s) Fund Company Appaloosa Investment I, David Tepper Redwood Capital Master, Jonathan Kolatch Glenview Institutional Partners, Larry Robbins PARS IV, Changhong Zhu Tennenbaum Opportunities V, TCP Investment Committee Kensington Global Strategies, Kenneth Griffin BlueGold Global, Pierre Andurand, Dennis Crema Waterstone Market Neutral Master, Shawn Bergerson Canyon Value Realization, Mitchell Julis, Joshua Friedman Discovery Global Opportunity, Robert Citrone Appaloosa Mgmt. Redwood Captial Mgmt. Glenview Capital Mgmt. Pacific Investment Mgmt. Tennenbaum Capital Partners 2009 Return 2008 Return 117.3% 69.1 67.1 61.0 58.5 ⫺26.7% ⫺33.0 ⫺49.0 ⫺17.0 ⫺51.2 Citadel Investment Group BlueGold Capital Mgmt. 57.0 54.6 ⫺55.0 209.4 Waterstone Capital Mgmt. 50.3 12.0 Canyon Partners 49.6 ⫺29.0 Discovery Capital Mgmt. 47.9 ⫺31.0 of traditional financial investments like stocks and bonds.8 Many hedge funds posted strong returns during the early 2000s even as stock returns were plummeting. A few hedge funds even performed well during the financial crisis. Table 5–11 lists the top hedge fund managers and their hedge fund company by 2009 earnings. The average hedge fund lost 15.7 percent in 2008, the worst performance on record. Nearly three-quarters of all hedge funds experienced losses. Nevertheless, many funds outperformed many of the underlying markets such as the S&P 500 index. Note that two of the hedge funds listed in Table 5–11 earned positive returns for 2008 as well as 2009 and one, BlueGold Global Fund, earned 209.4 percent in 2008, a year where the S&P 500 index earned a return of ⫺37.0 percent. Indeed, only three of the listed hedge funds performed worse during the beginning of the financial crisis than the S&P 500 index. Performance improved significantly in 2009 with the average fund earning more than 20 percent for the year, the highest level since 2003 and the second best return in 10 years. However, the 2009 return on the S&P 500 index was 26.46 percent. Note that while mutual fund performance is generally measured by returns relative to some benchmark (and therefore can perform “well” even by losing 10 percent if the benchmark loses 10.5 percent), performance of hedge funds is measured by the growth in total assets managed. Assets under management in the hedge fund industry fell by nearly 30 percent (to $1.5 trillion) in 2008. The decline was the largest on record and was attributed to a combination of negative performance, a surge in redemptions, and liquidations of funds. Hedge fund performance continued to lag into the 2010s. In 2010, the average hedge fund earned 10.3 percent. In 2011 the average was 5.0 percent, and in 2012 8 However, data deficiencies in the reporting and collection of hedge fund returns somewhat reduce confidence in all measures of hedge fund performance. Further, the inability to explain returns of individual hedge funds with standard multifactor risk models leaves open the possibility that it is not possible to properly measure the risk associated with at least some hedge fund strategies. If so, risk-adjusted returns earned by hedge funds may be overstated. Chapter 5 Financial Services: Mutual Funds and Hedge Funds 141 TABLE 5–12 Largest Hedge Funds by Fund Earnings, 2011–2012 Source: Bloomberg, 2013, www.bloomberg.com Fund, Manager Name(s) Fund Company Metacapital Mortgage Opportunities, Deepak Narula Pine River Fixed Income, Steve Kuhn CQS Directional Opportunities, Michael Hintze Pine River Liquid Mortgage, Steve Kuhn/Jiayi Chen Omega Overseas Partners A, Leon Cooperman Odey Europen, Crispin Odey Marathon Securitized Credit, Bruce Richards/ Louis Hanover Palomino, David Tepper BTG Pactual GEMM, Team managed Metacapital Management 37.8% Pine River Capital Management CQS Pine River Capital Management Omega Advisors Odey Asset Management Marathon Asset Management 32.9 28.9 28.0 24.4 24.1 24.0 4.8 ⫺10.4 7.2 ⫺1.4 ⫺20.3 ⫺4.2 Appaloosa Management BTG Pactual Global Asset Management Third Point 24.0 23.1 ⫺3.5 3.4 22.1 ⫺2.3 Third Point Ultra, Daniel Loeb 2012 Return* 2011 Return 23.6% * Through three quarters. the average was 6.2 percent. The returns on the S&P 500 Index for these three years were 15.1 percent, 2.0 percent, and 14.5 percent, respectively. As discussed later, hedge funds generally charge fees of 2 percent of the money they manage (compared to 1 percent for mutual funds) whether the fund makes money or not. Further, managers may take up to 20 percent of any profit the hedge fund earns. With performance as seen in the last four years, the question for the industry is whether investors will start to lose faith in hedge funds and start liquidating their sizable investments in these funds. In 2012, the industry saw net outflows of funds invested of $31 billion. In August 2012, Reuters reported that one hedge fund administrator’s redemption indicator hit its second-highest level of the year. Also, major investors in John Paulson’s prominent but struggling hedge funds (e.g., Citigroup’s private bank) had requested to redeem hundreds of millions of dollars. Man Group, the world’s biggest publicly traded hedge fund, has seen its stock drop by 40 percent through mid-2012 after its assets under management fell by almost a third. Table 5–12 lists the top hedge fund managers and their hedge fund company for 2012. Despite their name, hedge funds do not always “hedge” their investments to protect the fund and its investors against market price declines and other risks. For example, while bond prices generally move in the same direction, the risk in hedge funds is that bond prices may unexpectedly move faster in some markets than others. For example, in 1997 and 1998 computer models used by LTCM detected a price discrepancy between U.S. Treasury markets and other bonds (including high yield corporate bonds, mortgaged-backed securities, and European government bonds). LTCM consequently shorted U.S. Treasury securities (betting their prices would fall) and took long positions in other types of bonds (betting their prices would rise). However, unexpectedly, in 1998 large drops in many foreign stock markets caused money to pour into the U.S. Treasury markets, driving Treasury security prices up and yields down. This drop in U.S. Treasury yields drove rates on mortgages down, which pushed down the prices of many 142 Part One Introduction mortgage-backed securities. Further, the flight to U.S. Treasury security markets meant a drop in funds flowing into European bond markets and high-yield corporate bond markets. With all of their positions going wrong, LTCM experienced huge losses.9 Similarly, the failures of two of Bear Stearns hedge funds (Bear Stearns HighGrade Structured Credit Fund and Bear Stearns High-Grade Structured Credit Enhanced Leveraged Fund) were the result of managers’ failure to accurately predict how the subprime bond market would behave under extreme circumstances. The market moved against them, and their investors lost $1.6 billion when the funds, heavily invested in mortgage securities, collapsed in the summer of 2007. The failures were the first sign of the upcoming financial crisis that would eventually cripple financial markets and the overall economy. The strategy employed by the Bear Stearns funds was quite simple. Specifically, the funds purchased collateralized debt obligations (CDOs) that paid an interest rate over and above the cost of borrowing. Thus, every incremental unit of leverage added to the hedge funds’ total expected return. To capitalize on this, fund managers used as much leverage as they could raise. Because the use of leverage increased the portfolio’s exposure, fund managers purchased insurance on movements in credit markets. The insurance instruments, called credit default swaps (CDSs), were designed to cover losses during times when credit concerns cause the bonds to fall in value, effectively hedging away some of the risk. In instances when credit markets (or the underling bonds’ prices) remained relatively stable, or even when they behaved in line with historically based expectations, this strategy generated consistent, positive returns with very little deviation. Unfortunately, as the problems with subprime debt began to unravel, the subprime mortgage-backed securities market behaved well outside of what the portfolio managers expected. This started a chain of events that imploded the funds. The subprime mortgage market began to see substantial increases in delinquencies from homeowners, which caused sharp decreases in the market values of these types of bonds. Since the Bear Stearns hedge fund managers failed to expect these sorts of extreme price movements, they failed to purchase sufficient credit insurance to protect against these losses. Because they had leveraged their positions substantially, the funds began to experience large losses. The large losses made the creditors who provided the debt financing uneasy. The lenders required Bear Stearns to provide additional cash on their loans because the collateral (subprime bonds) was rapidly falling in value. However, the funds had no cash holdings. Thus, fund managers needed to sell bonds in order to generate cash. Quickly, it became public knowledge that Bear Stearns was in trouble, and competing funds moved to drive the prices of subprime bonds lower to force Bear Stearns’ into an asset fire-sale. As prices on bonds fell, the fund experienced losses, which caused it to sell more bonds, which lowered the prices of the bonds, which caused them to sell more bonds. It did not take long before the funds had experienced a complete loss of capital. Fees on Hedge Funds Hedge fund managers generally charge two type of fees: management fees and performance fees. As with mutual funds, the management fee is computed as a 9 A major reason for LTCM’s large loss was that it was so highly leveraged compared to other funds. LTCM was two to four times more leveraged than the typical fund. Chapter 5 Financial Services: Mutual Funds and Hedge Funds 143 percentage of the total assets under management and typically runs between 1.5 and 2.0 percent. Performance fees are unique to hedge funds. Performance fees give the fund manager a share of any positive returns on a hedge fund. The average performance fee on hedge funds is approximately 20 percent but varies widely. For example, Steven Cohen’s SAC Capital Partners charges a performance fee of 50 percent. Performance fees are paid to the hedge fund manager before returns are paid to the fund investors. Hedge funds often specify a hurdle rate, which is a minimum annualized performance benchmark that must be realized before a performance fee can be assessed. Further, a high-water mark is usually used for hedge funds in which the manager does not receive a performance fee unless the value of the fund exceeds the highest net asset value it has previously achieved. High-water marks are used to link the fund manager’s incentives more closely to those of the fund investors and to reduce the manager’s incentive to increase the risk of trades. Offshore Hedge Funds Hedge funds that are organized in the United States are designated as domestic hedge funds. These funds require investors to pay income taxes on all earnings from the hedge fund. Funds located outside the United States and structured under foreign laws are designated as offshore hedge funds. Many offshore financial centers encourage hedge funds to locate in their countries. The major centers include the Cayman Islands, Bermuda, Dublin, and Luxembourg. The Cayman Islands is estimated to be the location of approximately 75 percent of all hedge funds. Offshore hedge funds are regulated in that they must obey the rules of the host country. However, the rules in most of these countries are not generally burdensome and provide anonymity to fund investors. Further, offshore hedge funds are not subject to U.S. income taxes on distributions of profit or to U.S. estate taxes on fund shares. When compared to domestic hedge funds, offshore hedge funds have been found to trade more intensely, due to the low or zero capital gains tax for offshore funds. Further, offshore hedge funds tend to engage less often in positive feedback trading (rushing to buy when the market is booming and rushing to sell when the market is declining) than domestic hedge funds. Finally, offshore hedge funds have been found to herd (mimic each other’s behavior when trading while ignoring information about the fundamentals of valuation) less than domestic hedge funds. Many hedge fund managers maintain both domestic and offshore hedge funds. Given the needs of their client investors, hedge fund managers want to have both types of funds to attract all types of investors. Regulation of Hedge Funds While mutual funds are very highly regulated, hedge funds have generally been unregulated. Mutual funds in the United States are required to be registered with the SEC. Although hedge funds fall within the same statutory category as mutual funds, they operate under two exemptions from registration requirements as set forth in the Investment Company Act of 1940. First, funds are exempt if they have less than 100 investors. Second, funds are exempt if the investors are “accredited.” To comply with SEC exemptions, hedge funds are also sold only via private placements. Thus, hedge funds may not be offered or advertised to the general investing public. In 2010, the Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act required hedge fund advisors with private pools of capital exceeding $100 million in assets to 144 Part One Introduction register with the SEC as investment advisors and become subject to all rules which apply to registered advisors by July 2011. Thus, previous exemptions from registration provided under the Investment Company Act of 1940 no longer apply to most hedge fund advisors. Under the act, hedge fund managers who have less than $100 million in assets under management will be overseen by the state where the manager is domiciled and become subject to state regulation. This registration subjects the hedge funds to periodic inspections by SEC examiners. Further, hedge funds are required to report information to the SEC about their trades and portfolios that is “necessary for the purpose of assessing systemic risk posed by a private fund.” The data is kept confidential, and can be shared only with the Financial Stability Oversight Council that the legislation set up to monitor potential shocks to the economic system. Finally, should the government determine a hedge fund has grown too large or risky, the hedge fund is placed under the supervision of the Federal Reserve. Thus, while the act requires large hedge funds to be registered with the SEC, the regulations imposed on hedge funds continue to be much less onerous than those imposed on mutual funds. Nevertheless, hedge funds are prohibited from abusive trading practices and a number got mixed up in the scandals plaguing the mutual fund industry in the 2000s. For example, Canary Capital Partners and its managers agreed to pay $30 million from its illicit profits as well as a $10 million penalty to the SEC to settle allegations that it engaged in illegal trading practices with mutual fund companies, including making deals after the market had closed and promising to make substantial investments in various funds managed by the mutual funds. In March 2007, the SEC charged 14 defendants in a scheme involving insiders at UBS Securities, Morgan Stanley, and several hedge funds and hedge fund managers. The SEC claimed that the defendants made $15 million in illicit profits through thousands of illegal trades, using inside information misappropriated from UBS. Just two months prior to this announcement, regulators announced an investigation of UBS and other banks that leased office space to hedge fund traders. Regulators stated a concern about the relationship between the banks and their hedge fund “hotel guests,” looking at whether the banks might be using the real estate relationships as a way to entice hedge funds to do business with them, possibly at the expense of the funds’ investors. Specifically, there was an investigation into whether hedge funds located in bank buildings were paying higher than normal trading fees to banks to compensate them for the office space and failing to disclose this expense to investors. More recently, the late 2000s saw two highly publicized scandals associated with hedge funds. The first was that of Bernard L. Madoff Investment Securities. The Madoff investment scandal occurred after the discovery that the asset management business of former NASDAQ chairman Bernard Madoff was actually a giant “Ponzi” scheme. According to a federal criminal complaint, client statements showing $65 billion in stock holdings were fictitious, and there was no indication that any stocks were purchased since the mid-1990s. Alerted by his sons, federal authorities arrested Madoff on December 11, 2008. The firm was placed in liquidation and a trustee was appointed on December 15, 2008, after Bernard Madoff confessed to having stolen customer property over a period of many years. On March 12, 2009, Madoff pled guilty to 11 felonies and admitted to operating what has been called the largest investor fraud ever committed by an individual. On June 29, 2009, he was sentenced to 150 years in prison with restitution of $170 billion. Although Madoff did not operate as a hedge fund, he operated through various funds of hedge funds. Chapter 5 Financial Services: Mutual Funds and Hedge Funds 145 Second is the case of Galleon Group LLC, one of the largest hedge fund management firms in the world before announcing its closure in October 2009. The firm was at the center of a 2009 insider trading scandal that resulted in investors pulling capital from the firm rapidly. Twenty people, including Galleon Group LLC co-founder Raj Rajaratnam, were criminally charged in what federal authorities called the biggest prosecution of alleged hedge fund insider trading in the United States. Prosecutors said they had evidence from wiretaps, trading records, and cooperating witnesses to prove widespread trafficking in illegal insider information, including an insider trading operation that paid sources for nonpublic information, that netted the hedge fund more than $20 million. 1. What is the difference between a mutual fund and a hedge fund? 2. What are the performance fees charged by hedge funds? 3. How is the regulatory status of hedge funds changing? Summary This chapter provided an overview of the mutual fund and hedge fund industries. Mutual funds and hedge funds pool funds from individuals and corporations and invest in diversified asset portfolios. Given the tremendous growth in the market values of financial assets—such as equities—from 1992 through 2007 and the costeffective way in which these funds allow investors to participate in these markets, mutual funds and hedge funds have grown tremendously in size, number of funds, and number of shareholders. Questions and Problems 1. What is a mutual fund? In what sense is it a financial institution? 2. What are money market mutual funds? In what assets do these funds typically invest? What factors have caused the strong growth in this type of fund since the late 1970s? 3. What are long-term mutual funds? In what assets do these funds usually invest? What factors caused the strong growth in this type of fund from 1992 through 2007, the slowdown in growth in 2007, 2008, and the return to growth after 2008? 4. Using the data in Table 5–2, discuss the growth and ownership holdings over the last 32 years of long-term funds versus short-term funds. 5. Why did the proportion of equities in long-term funds increase from 38.3 percent in 1990 to more than 70 percent by 2000 and then decrease to 54 percent in 2012? How might an investor’s preference for a mutual funds objective change over time? 6. How does the risk of short-term funds differ from the risk of long-term funds? 7. What are the economic reasons for the existence of mutual funds; that is, what benefits do mutual funds provide for investors? Why do individuals rather than corporations hold most mutual funds shares? 8. What are the principal demographics of household owners who own mutual funds? What are the primary reasons why household owners invest in mutual funds? 9. What change in regulatory guidelines occurred in 2009 that had the primary purpose of giving investors a better understanding of the risks and objectives of a fund? www.mhhe.com/saunders8e Concept Questions www.mhhe.com/saunders8e 146 Part One Introduction 10. What are the three possible components reflected in the return an investor receives from a mutual fund? 11. How is the net asset value (NAV) of a mutual fund determined? What is meant by the term marked-to-market daily? 12. Suppose today a mutual fund contains 2,000 shares of J.P. Morgan Chase, currently trading at $46.75; 1,000 shares of Walmart, currently trading at $70.10; and 2,500 shares of Pfizer, currently trading at $27.50. The mutual fund has no liabilities and 10,000 shares outstanding held by investors. a. What is the NAV of the fund? b. Calculate the change in the NAV of the fund if tomorrow J.P. Morgan’s shares increase to $50, Walmart’s shares increase to $73, and Pfizer’s shares increase to $30. c. Suppose that today 1,000 additional investors buy one share each of the mutual fund at the NAV of $23.235. This means that the fund manager has $23,235 additional funds to invest. The fund manager decides to use these additional funds to buy additional shares in J.P. Morgan Chase. Calculate tomorrow’s NAV given the same rise in share values as assumed in part (b). 13. A mutual fund owns 300 shares of General Electric, currently trading at $22, and 400 shares of Microsoft Inc., currently trading at $28. The fund has 1,000 shares outstanding. a. What is the net asset value (NAV) of the fund? b. If investors expect the price of General Electric shares to increase to $26 and the price of Microsoft shares to decrease to $20 by the end of the year, what is the expected NAV at the end of the year? c. Assume that the expected price of the General Electric shares is realized at $26. What is the maximum price decrease that can occur to the Microsoft shares to realize an end-of-year NAV equal to the NAV estimated in part (a)? 14. What is the difference between open-end and closed-end mutual funds? Which type of fund tends to be more specialized in asset selection? How does a closed-end fund provide another source of return from which an investor may either gain or lose? 15. Open-end fund A owns 165 shares of AT&T valued at $35 each and 50 shares of Toro valued at $45 each. Closed-end fund B owns 75 shares of AT&T and 120 shares of Toro. Each fund has 1,000 shares of stock outstanding. a. What are the NAVs of both funds using these prices? b. Assume that in one month the price of AT&T stock has increased to $36.25 and the price of Toro stock has decreased to $43.375. How do these changes impact the NAV of both funds? If the funds were purchased at the NAV prices in part (a) and sold at month end, what would be the realized returns on the investments? c. Assume that another 155 shares of AT&T are added to fund A. The funds needed to buy the new shares are obtained by selling 676 more shares in fund A. What is the effect on fund A’s NAV if the stock prices remain unchanged from the original prices? 16. What is the difference between a load fund and a no-load fund? Is the argument that load funds are more closely managed and therefore have higher returns supported by the evidence presented in Table 5–6? 17. What is a 12b–1 fee? Suppose you have a choice between a load fund with no annual 12b–1 fee and a no-load fund with an annual 12b–1 fee of 25 basis points. How would the length of your expected investment horizon, or holding period, influence your choice between these two funds? Chapter 5 Financial Services: Mutual Funds and Hedge Funds 147 18. Suppose an individual invests $10,000 in a load mutual fund for two years. The load fee entails an up-front commission charge of 4 percent of the amount invested and is deducted from the original funds invested. In addition, annual fund operating expenses (or 12b–1 fees) are 0.85 percent. The annual fees are charged on the average net asset value invested in the fund and are recorded at the end of each year. Investments in the fund return 5 percent each year paid on the last day of the year. If the investor reinvests the annual returns paid on the investment, calculate the annual return on the mutual fund over the two-year investment period. 19. Who are the primary regulators of the mutual fund industry? How do their regulatory goals differ from those of other types of financial institutions? 20. What is a hedge fund and how is it different from a mutual fund? 21. What are the different categories of hedge funds? 22. What types of fees do hedge funds charge? 23. What is the difference between domestic hedge funds and offshore hedge funds? Describe the advantages of offshore hedge funds over domestic hedge funds. Web Questions www.mhhe.com/saunders8e 24. Go to the Fidelity Investments website and look up the annual 1-, 5-, and 10-year returns on Fidelity Select Biotechnology Fund using the following steps. The website is www.fidelity.com. Click on “Investment Products.” Click on “Mutual Funds.” Click on “Fidelity Funds.” Click on “Browse all Fidelity Funds.” Click on “S.” Click on “Select Biotechnology Portfolio.” This will bring the file onto your computer that contains the relevant data. 25. Go to the Investment Company Institute website and look up the most recent data on the asset values and number of short-term and long-term mutual funds using the following steps. The website is www.ici.org. Click on “Publications.” Click on “Fact Books.” Click on the most recent year for “XXXX Investment Company Fact Book.” Go to “Data Tables.” This section contains the relevant data. The data on asset values and number of mutual funds are among the first few pages. How have these values increased since those for 2012 reported in Table 5–1? Chapter Six Financial Services: Insurance INTRODUCTION www.metlife.com www.allstate.com www.aig.com 148 Insurance services offered by FIs protect individuals and corporations (policyholders) from adverse events. By accepting premiums, FIs that offer insurance services promise policyholders compensation if certain specified events occur. These policies represent financial liabilities to the insurance company. With the premiums collected, insurance companies invest in financial securities such as corporate bonds and stocks. Insurance services are classified into two major groups: life and property–casualty. Life insurance provides protection against the possibility of untimely death, illnesses, and retirement. Property–casualty insurance protects against personal injury and liability such as accidents, theft, and fire. Many FIs (e.g., MetLife and Allstate) offer both life and property–casualty services. Further, many FIs that offer insurance services also sell a variety of investment products in a similar fashion to other financial service firms, such as mutual funds (Chapter 5) and banking services (Chapter 2). The financial crisis showed just how much risk insurance companies can present to FIs and the global financial system. Specifically, as the subprime mortgage market began to fail in the summer of 2008, subprime mortgage pools, and the securities written on them, ended up falling precipitously in value as foreclosures and defaults rose on the underlying mortgage pools. Many credit default swaps (CDSs) were written on these subprime mortgage securities. CDS contracts offer credit protection (insurance) against default on the mortgage securities. As mortgage security losses started to rise, buyers of the CDS contracts wanted to be paid for these losses. AIG was a major writer of these CDS securities. When mortgage-backed securities started to fall in value, AIG had to make good on billions of dollars of credit default swaps. Soon it became clear that AIG was not going to be able to cover its credit default swap market losses. The result was a significant increase in the risk exposure of banks, investment banks, and insurance companies that had purchased AIG CDS insurance contracts. Indeed, the reason the federal government stepped in and bailed out AIG was that the insurer was a dominant player in the CDS market. Had AIG defaulted, every FI that had bought a CDS contract from the company would have suffered substantial losses. In this chapter we describe the main features of life insurance and property– casualty insurance companies, concentrating on (1) the size, structure, and composition of the industry in which they operate, (2) balance sheets and recent Chapter 6 Financial Services: Insurance 149 trends, and (3) regulations for each. We also look at global competition and trends in this industry. LIFE INSURANCE Life insurance allows individuals and their beneficiaries to protect against losses in income through premature death or retirement. By pooling risks, life insurance transfers income-related uncertainties from the insured individual to a group. Size, Structure, and Composition of the Industry In the 2010s, the United States had approximately 1,000 life insurance companies compared with more than 2,300 in 1988. The aggregate assets of life insurance companies were $5.6 trillion in 2012, compared with $1.1 trillion in 1988. The four largest life insurance companies, in terms of total assets (listed in Table 6–1) wrote 27 percent of the industry’s $676.4 billion new life insurance premium business in 2011. Interestingly, many of these insurance policies were sold through commercial banks. For example, in 2012 commercial banks sold 12.8 percent of all fixed annuity insurance contracts and 12.3 percent of all variable rate insurance contracts. Although not to the extent seen in the banking industry, the life insurance industry has seen some major mergers in recent years (e.g., SunAmerica and AIG, Prudential and Cigna, and MetLife and American Life Insurance) as competition within the industry and from other FIs has increased. In addition, many of the largest insurance companies, such as Metropolitan and Prudential, have converted to stockholder-controlled companies. In so doing, they gain access to the equity markets in order to realize additional capital for future business expansions and to compete with the rapidly consolidating banking industry. Since a mutual company is owned by its policyholders, the existing capital and reserves (equal to accumulated past profits) have to be distributed to the insurer’s policyholders. Table 6–1 lists the form of ownership for the top 10 life insurers in the United States, while Figure 6–1 illustrates the difference between a mutual insurer and a stock insurance company. While life insurance may be the core activity area, modern life insurance companies also sell annuity contracts, manage pension plans, and provide accident and health insurance (Figure 6–2 shows the distribution of premiums written for the various lines of insurance in 2011). We discuss these different activity lines in the following sections. TABLE 6–1 Biggest Life Insurers Sources: Best’s Review, July 2012; and authors’ research. www.ambest.com Rank 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Insurance Company Metropolitan Life Prudential of America Manulife Financial SunAmerica Financial Group Teachers Insurance and Annuity New York Life Hartford Life Northwestern Mutual ING Group Aegon USA Inc. Form of Ownership Assets (billions) Stock Stock Stock Stock Stock Mutual Stock Mutual Stock Stock $612.8 424.1 243.3 233.9 229.8 228.3 218.5 189.7 181.7 180.2 150 Part One Introduction FIGURE 6–1 Mutual Insurer Mutual versus Stock Insurance Companies Stock Insurer Accumulated profits owned by stockholders s right rship Stockholders wne Accumulated profits owned by policyholders Mutual Insurance Company O Policy and ownership rights Policy dividends Stock Insurance Company Policyholders k Stoc ends divid Policy rights Policyholders One problem that naturally faces life insurance companies (as well as property– casualty insurers) is the so-called adverse selection problem. Adverse selection is a problem in that customers who apply for insurance policies are more likely to be those most in need of insurance (i.e., someone with chronic health problems is more likely to purchase a life insurance policy than someone in perfect health). Thus, in calculating the probability of having to pay out on an insurance contract and, in turn, determining the insurance premium to charge, insurance companies’ use of health (and other) statistics representing the overall population may not be appropriate (since the insurance company’s pool of customers is more prone to health problems than the overall population). Insurance companies deal with the adverse selection problem by establishing different pools of the population based on health and related characteristics (such as income). By altering the pool used to determine the probability of losses to a particular customer’s health characteristics, the insurance company can more accurately determine the probability of having to pay out on a policy and can adjust the insurance premium accordingly. As the various types of insurance policies and services offered are described below, notice that some policies (such as universal life policies and annuities) provide not only insurance features but also savings components. For example, universal life policy payouts are a function of the interest earned on the investment of the policyholder’s premiums. Types of Life Insurance The four basic classes or lines of life insurance are distinguished by the manner in which they are sold or marketed to purchasers. These classes are (1) ordinary life, (2) group life, (3) industrial life, and (4) credit life. Among the life insurance FIGURE 6–2 Distribution of Life Insurance Premiums Written Source: Best’s Review, September 2012. www.ambest.com Other* 0.2% Group life 4.7% Ordinary life 19.3% Accident and health 26.3% *Includes credit life and industrial life Group annuities 18.1% Ordinary annuities 31.4% Chapter 6 Financial Services: Insurance 151 policies in force in the United States, ordinary life accounted for approximately 79.9 percent, group life for 19.2 percent, and industrial life and credit life together for less than 1 percent of the $163.8 billion in contracts written in 2011. Ordinary Life Ordinary life insurance involves policies marketed on an individual basis, usually in units of $1,000, on which policyholders make periodic premium payments. Despite the enormous variety of contractual forms, there are essentially five basic contractual types. The first three are traditional forms of ordinary life insurance, and the last two are newer contracts that originated in the 1970s and 1980s as a result of increased competition for savings from other segments of the financial services industry. The three traditional contractual forms are term life, whole life, and endowment life. The two newer forms are variable life and universal life. The key features of each of these contractual forms are as follows: • Term life. A term life policy is the closest to pure life insurance, with no savings element attached. Essentially, the individual receives a payout contingent on death during the coverage period. The term of coverage can vary from as little as 1 year to 40 years or more. • Whole life. A whole life policy protects the individual over an entire lifetime. In return for periodic or level premiums, the individual’s beneficiaries receive the face value of the life insurance contract on death. Thus, there is certainty that if the policyholder continues to make premium payments, the insurance company will make a payment—unlike term insurance. As a result, whole life has a savings element as well as a pure insurance element. • Endowment life. An endowment life policy combines a pure (term) insurance element with a savings element. It guarantees a payout to the beneficiaries of the policy if death occurs during some endowment period (e.g., prior to reaching retirement age). An insured person who lives to the endowment date receives the face amount of the policy. • Variable life. Unlike traditional policies that promise to pay the insured the fixed or face amount of a policy if a contingency arises, variable life insurance invests fixed premium payments in mutual funds of stocks, bonds, and money market instruments. Usually, policyholders can choose mutual fund investments to reflect their risk preferences. Thus, variable life provides an alternative way to build savings compared with the more traditional policies such as whole life because the value of the policy increases or decreases with the asset returns of the mutual fund in which the premiums are invested. • Universal life and variable universal life. Universal life allows both the premium amounts and the maturity of the life contract to be changed by the insured, unlike traditional policies that maintain premiums at a given level over a fixed contract period. In addition, for some contracts, insurers invest premiums in money, equity, or bond mutual funds—as in variable life insurance—so that the savings or investment component of the contract reflects market returns. In this case, the policy is called variable universal life. Group Life Insurance Group life insurance covers a large number of insured persons under a single policy. Usually issued to corporate employers, these policies may be either contributory (where both the employer and employee cover a share of the employee’s cost of the insurance) or noncontributory (where the employee does not contribute to the cost of the insurance) for the employees. Cost economies represent the principal advantage of group life over ordinary life policies. 152 Part One Introduction Cost economies result from mass administration of plans, lower costs for evaluating individuals through medical screening and other rating systems, and reduced selling and commission costs. Industrial Life Industrial life insurance currently represents a very small area of coverage. Industrial life usually involves weekly payments directly collected by representatives of the companies. To a large extent, the growth of group life insurance has led to the demise of industrial life as a major activity class. Credit Life Credit life insurance is sold to protect lenders against a borrower’s death prior to the repayment of a debt contract such as a mortgage or car loan. Usually, the face amount of the insurance policy reflects the outstanding principal and interest on the loan. Other Life Insurer Activities Three other major activities of life insurance companies involve the sale of annuities, private pension plans, and accident and health insurance. Annuities Annuities represent the reverse of life insurance activities. Whereas life insurance involves different contractual methods of building up a fund, annuities involve different methods of liquidating a fund, such as paying out a fund’s proceeds. As with life insurance contracts, many different types of annuity contracts have been developed. Specifically, they can be sold to an individual or a group and on a fixed or a variable basis by being linked to the return on some underlying investment portfolio. Individuals can purchase annuities with a single payment or with payments spread over a number of years. The annuity builds up a fund whose returns are tax deferred. That is, they are not subject to capital gains taxes on their investments. Payments may be structured to start immediately, or they can be deferred (at which time taxes are paid based on the income tax rate of the annuity receiver). These payments may cease on death or continue to be paid to beneficiaries for a number of years after death. While the traditional life insurance products described remain an important part of life insurance firm business, these lines (whether measured by premium income or by assets) are no longer the primary business of many companies in the life insurance industry. Rather, the major area of business for life insurance companies has shifted to annuities. Annuity sales in 2011 topped $334.8 billion ($212.4 billion of which were ordinary annuities), compared with $26 billion in 1996. Further, this is more than twice the $163.8 billion in sales for the traditional life insurance lines. Private Pension Plans Insurance companies offer many alternative pension plans to private employers in an effort to attract this business from other financial service companies, such as commercial banks and securities firms. Some of their innovative pension plans are based on guaranteed investment contracts (GICs). This means the insurer guarantees not only the rate of interest credited to a pension plan over a given period—for example, five years—but also the annuity rates on beneficiaries’ contracts. Other plans include immediate participation and separate account plans that follow more aggressive investment strategies than traditional life insurance, such as investing premiums in special-purpose equity mutual funds. In 2012, life insurance companies were managing more than $2.6 trillion in pension plan assets, equal to approximately 40 percent of all private pension plans. Accident and Health Insurance While life insurance protects against mortality risk, accident and health insurance protect against morbidity, or ill health, risk. More than $177.8 billion in premiums were written by life and health companies Chapter 6 Financial Services: Insurance 153 in the accident–health area in 2011. The major activity line is group insurance, providing health insurance coverage to corporate employees. Life insurance companies write more than 50 percent of all health insurance premiums. Balance Sheet and Recent Trends Assets policy loans Loans made by an insurance company to its policyholders using their policies as collateral. TABLE 6–2 Because of the long-term nature of their liabilities (as a result of the long-term nature of life insurance policyholders’ claims) and the need to generate competitive returns on the savings elements of life insurance products, life insurance companies concentrate their asset investments at the longer end of the maturity spectrum (e.g., bonds, equities, and government securities). Look at Table 6–2, where we show the distribution of life insurance companies’ assets. As you can see, in 2012, 11.7 percent of assets were invested in government securities, 68.9 percent in corporate bonds and stocks, and 6.2 percent in mortgages, with other loans—including policy loans (loans made to policyholders using their policies as collateral)—making up the balance. While commercial banks are the major issuers of new mortgages (sometimes keeping the mortgages on their books and sometimes selling them to secondary market investors), insurance companies hold mortgages as investment securities. That is, they purchase many mortgages in the secondary markets (see Chapters 25 and 26). The major trends have been a long-term increase in the proportion of bonds and equities1 and a decline in the Distribution of Assets of U.S. Life Insurance Companies Sources: American Council of Life Insurance, Life Insurance Fact Book, 1994; Best’s Review, October 1996; and Federal Reserve Bulletin, various issues. www.federalreserve.gov Year 1917 1920 1930 1940 1950 1960 1970 1980 1990 1995 2000 2005 2007 2008 2009 2010 2012 Total Assets (billions) $ Government Securities 5.9 7.3 18.9 30.8 64.0 119.6 207.3 479.2 1,408.2 2,131.9 3,133.9 4,350.7 4,949.7 4,515.5 4,749.4 5,176.3 5,561.6 9.6% 18.4 8.0 27.5 25.2 9.9 5.3 6.9 15.0 18.6 9.3 10.6 10.0 11.5 11.5 12.5 11.7 Corporate Securities Bonds Stocks Mortgages Policy Loans Miscellaneous U.S. Assets 33.2% 26.7 26.0 28.1 36.3 39.1 35.3 37.5 41.4 41.4 39.1 44.0 37.6 40.3 40.2 39.2 38.6 1.4% 1.0 2.8 2.0 3.3 4.2 7.4 9.9 9.1 17.4 31.5 29.2 33.4 24.9 27.2 30.1 30.3 34.0% 33.4 40.2 19.4 25.1 34.9 35.9 27.4 19.2 9.9 7.5 6.6 6.6 7.6 7.0 6.1 6.2 13.6% 11.7 14.9 10.0 3.8 4.4 7.8 8.6 4.4 4.5 3.2 2.5 2.9 3.6 3.5 2.7 2.6 5.2% 6.5 5.2 6.3 4.1 4.4 5.3 6.6 7.8 6.3 9.4 7.1 9.5 12.1 10.6 9.4 10.6 Note: Beginning with 1962, these data include the assets of separate accounts. 1 The bull market of the 1980s and 1990s probably constitutes a major reason for the large percentage of assets invested in equities. Conversely, the large drop in equity prices during the financial crisis explains the reduction in the percentage of stocks held by insurance companies in the late 2000s. 154 Part One Introduction TABLE 6–3 Life Insurance Industry Balance Sheet, 2012 (in billions of dollars) Percent of Total Assets Assets Source: Reprinted with permission from Best’s Aggregates & Averages, Life-Health, 2012, p. 2. www.ambest.com Bonds Preferred stock Common stock Mortgage loans Real estate Contract loans Cash and short-term investments Other invested assets Premiums due Accrued investment income Separate account assets Other assets $2,611.5 8.5 73.5 332.9 20.9 128.8 99.0 184.2 24.8 35.1 1,849.4 114.3 47.6% 0.2 1.3 6.1 0.4 2.3 1.8 3.4 0.5 0.6 33.7 2.1 Total assets $5,482.9 100.0% Net policy reserves Deposit-type contracts Policy claims Other liabilities Separate account business Total capital and surplus $2,609.3 275.3 43.6 390.2 1,854.4 319.1 47.6% 5.0 0.8 7.1 33.7 5.8 Total liabilities and capital/surplus $5,482.9 100.0% Liabilities and Capital/Surplus proportion of mortgages in the balance sheet. Thus, insurance company managers must be able to measure and manage the credit risk, interest rate risk, and other risks associated with these securities. Liabilities policy reserves A liability item for insurers that reflects their expected payment commitment on existing policy contracts. surrender value of a policy The cash value of a policy received from the insurer if a policyholder surrenders the policy before maturity. The cash surrender value is normally only a portion of the contract’s face value. The aggregate balance sheet for the life insurance industry at the beginning of 2012 is shown in Table 6–3. Looking at the liability side of the balance sheet, we see that $2.609 trillion, or 47.6 percent, of total liabilities and capital are net policy reserves (the expected payment commitment on existing policy contracts). These reserves are based on actuarial assumptions regarding the insurers’ expected future liability commitments to pay out on present contracts, including death benefits, matured endowments (lump sum or otherwise), and the cash surrender values of policies (the cash value paid to the policyholder if the policy is surrendered before it matures). Even though the actuarial assumptions underlying policy reserves are normally very conservative, unexpected fluctuations in future required payouts can occur; thus, underwriting life insurance is risky. For example, mortality rates—and life insurance payouts—might unexpectedly increase above those defined by historically based mortality tables as a result of a catastrophic epidemic illness such as AIDS or widespread influenza. To meet unexpected future losses, the life insurer holds a capital and surplus reserve fund with which to meet such losses (and reduce insolvency risk). The capital and surplus reserves of life insurers in 2012 were $319.1 billion, or 5.8 percent of total assets.2 2 An additional line of defense against unexpected underwriting losses is the insurer’s investment income from its asset portfolio plus any new premium income flows. Chapter 6 separate accounts Annuity programs sponsored by life insurance companies in which the payoff on the policy is linked to the assets in which policy premiums are invested. Financial Services: Insurance 155 Separate account business represented 33.7 percent of total liabilities and capital in 2012. A separate account is a fund established and held separately from the insurance company’s other funds. These funds may be invested without regard to the usual diversification restrictions; that is, they may be invested in all stocks, all bonds, and so forth. Note that these assets are also listed separately on the asset side of the balance sheet. Separate account assets are 33.7 percent of total assets. The payoff on the life insurance policy thus depends on the return on the funds in the separate account. Another important life insurer liability, GICs (5.0 percent of total liabilities and capital), are short- and medium-term debt instruments sold by insurance companies to fund their pension plan business (see deposit-type contracts in Table 6–3). Recent Trends The life insurance industry was very profitable in the early and mid-2000s, with over $500 billion in premiums and annuities recorded annually in 2004 through 2009. Net income topped $34 billion in 2006, up 6.5 percent from 2005. Credit markets continued to be strong, and capital levels for the industry remained strong. However, the financial crisis took a toll on this industry. The value of stocks and bonds in insurers’ asset portfolios dropped as financial markets deteriorated. Further, losses were experienced on life insurers’ positions in commercial mortgagebacked securities, commercial loans, and lower-grade corporate debt as bond default rates increased and mortgage markets froze. Lower equity market values also reduced asset-based fees earned from balances on equity-linked products, such as variable annuities. As a result, life insurers with large proportions of separate-account assets were particularly hard hit with declining earnings from equities. Furthermore, as investors fled to the safety of government bonds during the financial crisis, government bond yields (which are generally a significant source of investment income for life insurers) fell. Additionally, historically low short-term interest rates prevented life insurers from lowering minimum rates on new policies, which encouraged higher surrender rates on existing policies that were already at minimum credit rates. The results were huge losses in 2008 for the industry. Realized and unrealized capital losses from bonds, preferred stocks, and common stocks topped $35 billion, representing more than an 875 percent drop from 2007. Net investment income also fell by 3.5 percent in 2008 from 2007. The result was that net after-tax income for the year was ⫺$51.8 billion, $83.7 billion less than in 2007. The large drop in the value of stocks and bonds that the insurers held made it harder for the companies to pay out money due to their policyholders. In late 2008/early 2009, insurance company reserves began to dwindle to dangerous levels. Further, the falling value of their assets made it harder for the insurers’ to raise capital. As a result, the Treasury Department decided to extend bailout funds to a number of struggling life insurance companies, the most notable being $127 billion to AIG (including $45 billion from TARP, $77 billion to purchase collateralized debt and mortgage backed securities, and a $44 billion bridge loan). Other life insurers receiving TARP funds included Hartford Financial Services Group, Prudential Financial, Lincoln National, and Allstate. Events associated with the financial crisis continued to be felt in 2009. Premium income fell by $120 billion (19 percent) from 2008 levels, while net realized capital for the industry fell by $28.7 billion. However, late 2009 saw some improvements for the industry. Overall, the industry saw an increase in total assets of more than $200 billion and net 156 Part One Introduction income returned to a positive $21.1 billion. Further, the industry continued to pay dividends of $15.0 billion in 2009. Premiums continued to recover in 2010 and 2011 as annuity and most types of life insurance premiums increased. The 2011 premiums of $676.4 billion fell just short of the pre-crisis (2007) level, $677.2 billion. Further, net income increased to $28.0 billion in 2010 before dropping to $14.4 billion in 2011. The 2011 drop was the result of accounting changes and a number of one-time events involving specific companies rather than industry weakness. However, challenges remain for the industry. Interest rates remain at historical lows, which increases the risk of spread compression for existing contracts and hampers the sale of new fixed annuity and universal life insurance contracts. Further, equity markets remain volatile and new regulations (see below) could adversely affect profits. Regulation McCarran-Ferguson Act of 1945 Legislation confirming the primacy of state over federal regulation of insurance companies. www.naic.org insurance guarantee funds Funds consisting of required contributions from within state insurance companies to compensate insurance company policyholders if there is a failure. An important legislation affecting the regulation of life insurance companies is the McCarran-Ferguson Act of 1945, which confirms the primacy of state over federal regulation of insurance companies. Thus, unlike the depository institutions we discussed in Chapter 2, which can be chartered either at the federal or the state level, chartering of life insurers is done entirely at the state level. In addition to chartering, state insurance commissions supervise and examine insurance companies by using a coordinated examination system developed by the National Association of Insurance Commissioners (NAIC). In 2009, the U.S. Congress considered establishing an optional federal insurance charter. The move behind such a charter picked up steam following the failure of the existing state by state regulatory system to act in preventing the problems at insurance giant AIG from becoming a systemic risk to the national economy. Those in favor of an optional federal insurance charter noted that under the current state by state system, insurers face obstacles such as inconsistent regulations, barriers to innovation, conflicting agent licensing, and education requirements. While the House version of the 2010 Financial Services Regulatory Overhaul Bill (approved in December 2009) contained no provision for federal regulation of insurance companies, Financial Services Chairman Barney Frank stated that this would still be a possibility as the bill moved through the regulatory process toward final passage. The final version of the overhaul bill, the Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act of 2010, established the Federal Insurance Office (FIO) that reports to Congress and the president on matters pertaining to the insurance industry. While the industry’s main regulator continues to be the states in which firms operate, the FIO has the authority to monitor the insurance industry, identify regulatory gaps or systemic risk, deal with international insurance matters, and monitor the extent to which underserved communities have access to affordable insurance products. The Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act also called for the establishment of the Financial Stability Oversight Council (FSOC), which is charged with designating any financial institution (including insurance companies) that presents a systemic risk to the economy and subjecting them to greater regulation. In addition to supervision and examination, states promote life insurance guarantee funds. Unlike banks and thrifts, life insurers have no access to a federal guarantee fund (although, as mentioned above, during the financial crisis the federal government took the unprecedented step of bailing out several major insurance companies). These state guarantee funds differ in a number of important Chapter 6 www.ins.state.ny.us Concept Questions Financial Services: Insurance 157 ways from deposit insurance. First, although these programs are sponsored by state insurance regulators, they are actually run and administered by the (private) insurance companies themselves. Second, unlike DIF, in which the FDIC has established a permanent reserve fund by requiring banks to pay annual premiums in excess of payouts to resolve failures (see Chapter 19), no such permanent guarantee fund exists for the insurance industry—with the sole exception of the PC and life guarantee funds in the state of New York. This means that contributions are paid into the guarantee fund by surviving firms in a state only after an insurance company has actually failed. Third, the size of the required contributions that surviving insurers make to protect policyholders in failed insurance companies differs widely from state to state. In those states that have guarantee funds, each surviving insurer is normally levied a pro rata amount, according to the size of its statewide premium income. This amount either helps pay off small policyholders after the assets of the failed insurer have been liquidated or acts as a cash injection to make the acquisition of a failed insurer attractive. The definition of small policyholders varies among states in the range of holding policies from $100,000 to $500,000. Finally, because no permanent fund exists and the annual pro rata payments to meet payouts to failed insurer policyholders are often legally capped, a delay usually occurs before small policyholders receive the cash surrender values of their policies or other payment obligations from the guarantee fund. This contrasts with deposit insurance, which normally provides insured depositors immediate coverage of their claims up to $250,000. 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. What is the difference between a life insurance contract and an annuity contract? Describe the different forms of ordinary life insurance. Why do life insurance companies invest in long-term assets? What is the major source of life insurance underwriting risk? Who are the main regulators of the life insurance industry? Why is traditional life insurance in decline? PROPERTY–CASUALTY INSURANCE Property insurance involves insurance coverages related to the loss of real and personal property. Casualty—or, perhaps more accurately, liability—insurance concerns protection against legal liability exposures. However, the distinctions between the two broad areas of property and liability insurance are increasingly becoming blurred. This is due to the tendency of property–casualty (PC) insurers to offer multiple-activity line coverages combining features of property and liability insurance into single policy packages, for example, homeowners multiple-peril insurance. Size, Structure, and Composition of the Industry Currently, some 2,700 companies sell property–casualty insurance, with approximately half of these firms writing PC business in all or most of the United States. The total assets of the PC industry in 2012 were $1.6 trillion, or approximately 30 percent of the life insurance industry’s assets. The U.S. PC insurance industry is 158 Part One Introduction quite concentrated. Collectively, the top 10 firms have a 50 percent share of the overall PC market measured by premiums written, and the top 200 firms made up 95 percent of the industry premiums written. In 2012, the top firm (State Farm) wrote 10.5 percent of all PC insurance premiums, while the second-ranked insurer (Liberty Mutual) wrote 5.3 percent (i.e., a joint total of 15.8 percent of premiums written). In contrast, in 1985, the top two firms wrote 14.5 percent of the total industry insurance premiums. Thus, the industry leaders appear to be increasing their share of this financial service sector. As with banks, much of this consolidation is coming through mergers and acquisitions. Types of Property–Casualty Insurance In this section we describe the key features of the main PC lines. Note, however, that some PC activity lines are marketed as different products to both individuals and commercial firms (e.g., auto insurance), while other lines are marketed to one specific group (e.g., boiler and machinery insurance targeted at commercial purchasers). To understand the importance of each line in terms of premium income and losses incurred, look at Table 6–4. The following data show the changing TABLE 6–4 Property and Casualty Insurance Industry Underwriting by Lines, 2011 Source: BestWeek, August 2012. Net Premiums Written* Losses Incurred† Fire $ 13.38 44.6% Allied lines 11.72 73.3 Farm owners multiple peril (MP) 3.18 87.6 Multiple peril crop 12.36 87.6 Homeowners MP 74.57 76.0 Commercial MP 33.92 62.5 Mortgage guaranty 4.57 194.6 Ocean marine 4.10 42.0 Inland marine 14.09 49.9 Financial guaranty 1.06 136.6 Medical professional liability 10.30 35.5 Earthquake 2.77 9.4 Group accident and health 4.72 62.2 Individual accident and health 3.80 70.6 Workers’ compensation 43.99 70.7 Other liability 46.93 48.4 Products liability 2.88 63.7 Private passenger auto liability 103.73 69.7 Commercial auto liability 18.62 56.9 Private passenger auto physical damage (PD) 65.51 64.7 Commercial auto PD 5.46 68.3 Aircraft 1.80 50.2 Fidelity 1.17 46.0 Surety 5.15 13.2 Burglary and theft 0.22 23.8 Boiler and machinery 1.41 35.9 Credit 2.36 27.3 Warranty 2.81 68.5 Flood 2.80 62.4 Other lines 2.18 47.1 Total * In billions of dollars. † To premiums earned. $501.56 65.5% Chapter 6 net premiums written The entire amount of premiums written on insurance contracts. Financial Services: Insurance 159 composition in net premiums written (NPW) (the entire amount of premiums on insurance contracts written) for major PC lines over the 1960–2011 period. Important PC lines include the following: • Fire insurance and allied lines. Protects against the perils of fire, lightning, and removal of property damaged in a fire (2.7 percent of all premiums written in 2011; 16.6 percent in 1960). • Homeowners multiple-peril (MP) insurance. Protects against multiple perils of damage to a personal dwelling and personal property as well as provides liability coverage against the financial consequences of legal liability due to injury done to others. Thus, it combines features of both property and liability insurance (14.9 percent of all premiums written in 2011; 5.2 percent in 1960). • Commercial multiple-peril insurance. Protects commercial firms against perils; similar to homeowners multiple-peril insurance (6.8 percent of all premiums written in 2011; 0.4 percent in 1960). • Automobile liability and physical damage (PD) insurance. Provides protection against (1) losses resulting from legal liability due to the ownership or use of the vehicle (auto liability) and (2) theft of or damage to vehicles (auto physical damage) (38.5 percent of all premiums written in 2011; 43.0 percent in 1960). • Liability insurance (other than auto). Provides either individuals or commercial firms with protection against non-automobile-related legal liability. For commercial firms, this includes protection against liabilities relating to their business operations (other than personal injury to employees covered by workers’ compensation insurance) and product liability hazards (12.0 percent of all premiums written in 2011; 6.6 percent in 1960). Balance Sheet and Recent Trends The Balance Sheet and Underwriting Risk unearned premiums Reserve set-aside that contains the portion of a premium that has been paid before insurance coverage has been provided. The balance sheet of PC firms at the beginning of 2012 is shown in Table 6–5. Similar to life insurance companies, PC insurers invest the majority of their assets in long-term securities, thus subjecting them to credit and interest rate risks. Bonds ($931.1 billion), preferred stock ($11.6 billion), and common stock ($228.8 billion) constituted 72.0 percent of total assets in 2012. PC insurers hold mainly long-term securities for two reasons. First, PC insurers, like life insurers, hold long-term assets to match the maturity of their longer-term contractual liabilities. Second, PC insurers, unlike life insurers, have more uncertain payouts on their insurance contracts (i.e., they incur greater levels of liquidity risk). Thus, their asset structure includes many assets with relatively fixed returns that can be liquidated easily and at low cost. Looking at their liabilities, we can see the major component is the loss reserve and loss adjustment expenses ($632.4 billion) set aside to meet expected losses from underwriting and administrative expenses associated with the PC lines just described. This item constitutes 38.9 percent of total liabilities and capital. Unearned premiums (a reserve set-aside that contains the portion of a premium that has been paid before insurance coverage has been provided) are also a major liability, representing 15.4 percent of total liabilities and capital. To understand how and why a loss reserve on the liability side of the balance sheet is established, we need to understand the risks of underwriting PC insurance. In particular, PC underwriting risk results when the premiums generated on a given insurance line are insufficient to cover (1) the claims (losses) incurred 160 Part One Introduction TABLE 6–5 Balance Sheet for the Property– Casualty Industry, 2012 (in billions of dollars) Source: Reprinted with permission from A.M. Best’s Aggregates and Averages, property–casualty, 2012, p. 1. www.ambest.com Percent of Total Assets Assets Unaffiliated investments Bonds Preferred stocks Common stocks Real estate investments Cash and short-term investments Other invested assets Net deferred taxes Reinsurance Premium balances Accrued interest Other assets $1,374.0 $931.1 11.6 228.8 15.4 76.3 110.8 84.5% 57.2% 0.7 14.1 1.0 4.7 6.8 29.1 43.1 128.7 10.6 41.1 Total assets 1.8 2.6 7.9 0.7 2.5 $1,626.6 100.0% Loss reserve and loss adjustment expenses Unearned premiums Other liabilities $ 632.4 251.4 168.4 38.9% 15.4 10.4 Total liabilities Policyholders surplus Capital and assigned surplus Surplus notes Unassigned surplus $1,052.2 $ 574.4 64.7% 35.3% Liabilities and Capital/Surplus Total liabilities and capital/surplus $248.0 15.2 311.2 15.3% 0.9 19.1 $1,626.6 100.0% insuring against the peril and (2) the administrative expenses of providing that insurance (legal expenses, commissions, taxes, etc.) after taking into account (3) the investment income generated between the time premiums are received and the time claims are paid. Thus, underwriting risk may result from (1) unexpected increases in loss rates, (2) unexpected increases in expenses, and/or (3) unexpected decreases in investment yields or returns. Next, we look more carefully at each of these three areas of PC underwriting risk. Loss Risk The key feature of claims loss exposure is the actuarial predictability of losses relative to premiums earned. This predictability depends on a number of characteristics or features of the perils insured, specifically: • Property versus liability. In general, the maximum levels of losses are more predictable for property lines than for liability lines. For example, the monetary value of the loss of, or damage to, an auto is relatively easy to calculate, while the upper limit to the losses an insurer might be exposed to in a product liability line—for example, asbestos damage to workers’ health under other liability insurance—may be difficult, if not impossible, to estimate. • Severity versus frequency. In general, loss rates are more predictable on low severity, high-frequency lines than they are on high-severity, low-frequency lines. For example, losses in fire, auto, and homeowners peril lines tend to involve events expected to occur with a high frequency and to be independently distributed across any pool of the insured. Furthermore, the dollar loss on each event in the insured pool tends to be relatively small. Applying the law of large Chapter 6 frequency of loss The probability that a loss will occur. severity of loss The size of the loss. long-tail loss A claim that is made some time after a policy was written. Financial Services: Insurance 161 numbers, insurers can estimate the expected loss potential of such lines—the frequency of loss times the size of the loss (severity of loss)—within quite small probability bounds. Other lines, such as earthquake, hurricane, and financial guaranty insurance, tend to insure very low-probability (frequency) events. Here the probabilities are not always stationary, the individual risks in the insured pool are not independent, and the severity of the loss could be enormous. This means that estimating expected loss rates (frequency times severity) is extremely difficult in these coverage areas. For example, even with the new federal terrorism insurance program introduced in 2002, coverage for highprofile buildings in big cities, as well as other properties considered potential targets, remains expensive. Under the 2002 federal program, the government is responsible for 90 percent of insurance industry losses that arise from any future terrorist incidents that exceed a minimum amount. The government’s losses are capped at $100 billion per year. Each insurer has a maximum amount it would pay before federal aid kicks in. In 2012, the amount was 15 percent of each company’s commercial property–casualty premiums. The result is that in some cases, the cost of terrorism insurance has been reduced significantly since the new law took effect. But those buildings viewed as target risks will continue to have much higher premiums than properties outside of major cities. This higher uncertainty of losses forces PC firms to invest in more short-term assets and hold a larger percentage of capital and reserves than life insurance firms hold. • Long tail versus short tail. Some liability lines suffer from a long-tail risk exposure phenomenon that makes the estimation of expected losses difficult. This long-tail loss arises in policies in which the insured event occurs during a coverage period but a claim is not filed or reported until many years later. The delay in filing of a claim is in accordance with the terms of the insurance contract and often occurs because the detrimental consequences of the event are not known for a period of time after the event actually occurs. Losses incurred but not reported have caused insurers significant problems in lines such as medical malpractice and other liability insurance where product damage suits (e.g., the Dalkon shield case and asbestos cases) have mushroomed many years after the event occurred and the coverage period expired.3 For example, in 2002 Halliburton, a major U.S. corporation, agreed to pay $4 billion in cash and stock, and to seek bankruptcy protection for a subsidiary, to settle more than 300,000 asbestos claims. To resolve its growing asbestos liability, Halliburton considered a novel step that put one of its biggest subsidiaries into bankruptcy courts, while allowing Halliburton to hold on to the rest of its businesses. Questions still remain about how much insurance companies will be required to reimburse Halliburton for the cost of asbestos case settlements and when. The company had only $1.6 billion of expected insurance on its books for asbestos claims. If Halliburton is successful in putting just one of its subsidiaries (and not the entire firm) into bankruptcy, it could set a precedent for many companies, such as Honeywell International and Dow Chemical, which were also trying to contain their asbestos risk in subsidiaries. • Product inflation versus social inflation. Loss rates on all PC property policies are adversely affected by unexpected increases in inflation. Such increases were 3 In some product liability cases, such as those involving asbestos, the nature of the risk being covered was not fully understood at the time many of the policies were written. 162 Part One Introduction triggered, for example, by the oil price shocks of 1973, 1978, and 2008. However, in addition to a systematic unexpected inflation risk in each line, there may be line-specific inflation risks. The inflation risk of property lines is likely to reflect the approximate underlying inflation risk of the economy. Liability lines may be subject to social inflation, as reflected in juries’ willingness to award punitive and other liability damages at rates far above the underlying rate of inflation. Such social inflation has been particularly prevalent in commercial liability and medical malpractice insurance and has been directly attributed by some analysts to faults in the U.S. civil litigation system. Reinsurance An alternative to managing risk on a PC insurer’s balance sheet is to purchase reinsurance from a reinsurance company. Reinsurance is essentially insurance for insurance companies. Note from Table 6–5 that reinsurance (the payments that may be collected under reinsurance contracts) represented 2.6 percent of total assets in 2012. Reinsurance is a way for primary insurance companies to protect against unforeseen or extraordinary losses. Depending on the contract, reinsurance can enable the insurer to improve its capital position, expand its business, limit losses, and stabilize cash flows, among other things. In addition, the reinsurer, drawing information from many primary insurers, will usually have a far larger pool of data for assessing risks. Reinsurance takes a variety of forms. It may represent a layer of risk, such as losses within certain limits, say, $5 million to $10 million, that will be paid by the reinsurer to the primary insurance company for which a premium is paid, or a sharing of both losses and profits for certain types of business. Reinsurance is an international business. About 75 percent of the reinsurance business that comes from U.S. insurance companies is written by non-U.S. reinsurers such as Munich Re. Some investment banks are now setting up reinsurers as part of a move to develop alternative risk financing deals such as catastrophe bonds. Insurers and reinsurers also typically issue catastrophe bonds. The bonds pay high interest rates and diversify an investor’s portfolio because natural disasters occur randomly and are not associated with (independent of) economic factors. Depending on how the bond is structured, if losses reach the threshold specified in the bond offering, the investor may lose all or part of the principal or interest. For example, a deep-discount or zero-coupon catastrophe bond would pay 100(1 ⫺ ␣) on maturity, where ␣ is the loss rate due to the catastrophe. Thus, Munich Re issued a $250 million catastrophe bond in 2012 where ␣ (the loss rate) reflected losses incurred on all reinsurer policies over a 24-hour period should an event (such as a flood or hurricane) occur and losses exceed a certain threshold. The required yield on these bonds reflected the risk-free rate plus a premium reflecting investors’ expectations regarding the probability of the event’s occurring. loss ratio Ratio that measures pure losses incurred to premiums earned. premiums earned Premiums received and earned on insurance contracts because time has passed with no claim being filed. Measuring Loss Risk The loss ratio measures the actual losses incurred on a line. It measures the ratio of losses incurred to premiums earned (premiums received and earned on insurance contracts because time has passed with no claim being filed). Thus, a loss ratio less than 100 means that premiums earned were sufficient to cover losses incurred on that line. Aggregate loss ratios for the period 1951–2012 are shown in Table 6–6. Notice the steady increase in industry loss ratios over the period, increasing from the 60 percent range in the 1950s to the 70 and 80 percent range in the 1980s into the 2010s. For example, in 2011, the aggregate loss ratio on all PC lines was 79.4. This includes, however, loss adjustment expenses (LAE)— see below—as well as (pure) losses. The (pure) loss ratio, net of LAE, in 2011 was 65.5 (see Table 6–4). Chapter 6 TABLE 6–6 Industry Underwriting Ratios Source: Best’s Review, various issues. www.ambest.com Financial Services: Insurance 163 Year Loss Ratio* Expense Ratio† Combined Ratio Dividends to Policyholders‡ Combined Ratio after Dividends 1951 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 1997 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 60.3 63.8 70.3 70.8 79.3 74.9 88.7 82.3 78.8 72.8 81.4 88.4 81.1 74.7 73.3 74.8 66.2 68.0 77.4 73.2 73.5 79.4 73.9 34.0 32.2 30.4 27.6 27.3 26.5 25.9 26.0 26.2 27.1 27.8 26.9 25.6 24.9 25.0 25.5 25.4 27.1 27.2 27.3 28.4 28.4 29.8 94.3 96.0 100.7 98.4 106.6 101.4 114.6 108.3 105.0 99.9 109.2 115.3 106.7 99.6 98.3 100.3 91.6 95.1 104.6 100.5 101.9 107.8 103.7 2.6 2.2 1.9 1.7 1.3 1.7 1.6 1.2 1.4 1.7 1.3 0.7 0.5 0.5 0.4 0.6 0.8 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.5 0.4 0.3 96.9 98.2 102.6 100.1 107.9 103.1 116.2 109.6 106.4 101.6 110.5 116.0 107.2 100.1 98.7 100.9 92.4 95.6 105.1 101.0 102.4 108.2 104.0 * Losses and adjustment expenses incurred to premiums earned. † Expenses incurred (before federal income taxes) to premiums written. ‡ Dividends to policyholders to premiums earned. combined ratio Ratio that measures the overall underwriting profitability of a line; it is equal to the loss ratio plus the ratios of loss adjustment expenses to premiums earned and commission and other acquisition costs to premiums written plus any dividends paid to policyholders as a proportion of premiums earned. Expense Risk The two major sources of expense risk to PC insurers are (1) loss adjustment expenses (LAE) and (2) commissions and other expenses. Loss adjustment expenses relate to the costs surrounding the loss settlement process; for example, many PC insurers employ adjusters who determine the liability of the insurer and the size of the adjustment or settlement to be made. The other major area of expense occurs in the commission costs paid to insurance brokers and sales agents and other expenses related to the acquisition of business. As mentioned above, the loss ratio reported in Table 6–6 includes LAE. The expense ratio reported in Table 6–6 reflects commissions and other (non-LAE) expenses for PC insurers over the 1951–2012 period. In contrast to the increasing trend in the loss ratio, the expense ratio generally decreased over the period shown. Expenses can account for significant portions of the overall costs of operations. In 2011, for example, expenses—other than LAE—amounted to 28.4 percent of premiums written. Clearly, sharp rises in insurance broker commissions and other operating costs can rapidly render an insurance line unprofitable. One of the reasons for the secular decline in the expense ratio has been the switch in the way PC insurance has been distributed. Specifically, rather than relying on independent brokers to sell policies (the American agency method of distribution), large insurance companies are increasingly selling insurance to the public directly through their own brokers (the direct writer method of distribution). A common measure of the overall underwriting profitability of a line, which includes both loss and expense experience, is the combined ratio. Technically, the combined ratio is equal to the loss ratio plus the ratios of LAE to premiums earned, commissions and other acquisition costs and general expense costs to 164 Part One Introduction premiums written, plus any dividends paid to policyholders as a proportion of premiums earned. The combined ratio after dividends adds any dividends paid to policyholders as a proportion of premiums earned to the combined ratio. If the combined ratio is less than 100, premiums alone are sufficient to cover both losses and expenses related to the line. If premiums are insufficient and the combined ratio exceeds 100, the PC insurer must rely on investment income earned on premiums for overall profitability. For example, in 2001 the combined ratio before dividend payments was 116.0, indicating that premiums alone were insufficient to cover the costs of both losses and expenses related to writing PC insurance. Table 6–6 presents the combined ratio and its components for the PC industry for the years 1951–2012. We see that, over this period, premiums have often been unable to cover losses and expenses (i.e., combined ratios have generally been greater than 100). operating ratio A measure of the overall profitability of a PC insurer; it equals the combined ratio minus the investment yield. Investment Yield/Return Risk As discussed above, when the combined ratio is more than 100, overall profitability can be ensured only by a sufficient investment return on premiums earned. That is, PC firms invest premiums in assets between the time they are received and the time they are paid out to meet claims. For example, in 2012 net investment income to premiums earned (or the PC insurers’ investment yield) was 10.5 percent. As a result, the overall average profitability (or operating ratio) of PC insurers was 93.5. It was equal to the combined ratio after dividends (104.0) minus the investment yield 10.5. Since the operating ratio was less than 100, PC insurers were profitable in 2012. However, lower net returns on investments (e.g., 3.5 percent rather than 10.5 percent) would have meant that underwriting PC insurance was marginally unprofitable (i.e., the operating ratio of insurers in this case would have been 100.5). Thus, the effect of interest rates and default rates on PC insurers’ investments is crucial to PC insurers’ overall profitability. That is, measuring and managing credit and interest rate risk are key concerns of PC managers. Consider the following example. Suppose an insurance company’s projected loss ratio is 79.8 percent, its expense ratio is 27.9 percent, and it pays 2 percent of its premiums earned to policyholders as dividends. The combined ratio (after dividends) for this insurance company is equal to: Loss ratio ⫹ Expense ratio ⫹ Dividend ratio ⫽ Combined ratio after dividends 79.8 ⫹ 27.9 ⫹ 2.0 ⫽ 109.7 Thus, expected losses on all PC lines, expenses, and dividends exceeded premiums earned by 9.7 percent. If the company’s investment portfolio, however, yielded 12 percent, the operating ratio and overall profitability of the PC insurer would be: Operating ratio ⫽ Combined ratio after dividends ⫺ Investment yield ⫽ ⫽ 109.7 97.7 percent ⫺ and Overall profitability ⫽ 100 ⫺ Operating ratio ⫽ 100 ⫺ 97.7 ⫽ 2.3 percent 12.0 Chapter 6 Financial Services: Insurance 165 As can be seen, the high investment returns (12 percent) make the PC insurer profitable overall. Given the importance of investment returns to PC insurers’ profitability, we can see from the balance sheet in Table 6–5 that bonds—both Treasury and corporate— dominated the asset portfolios of PC insurers. Bonds constituted 57.2 percent of total assets and 67.8 percent of financial assets (so-called unaffiliated investments) in 2012. Finally, if losses, expenses, and other costs are higher and investment yields are lower than expected so that operating losses are incurred, PC insurers carry a significant amount of surplus reserves (policyholder surplus) to reduce the risk of insolvency. In 2012, the ratio of policyholder surplus to assets was 35.3 percent. Recent Trends underwriting cycle The tendency of profits in the PC industry to follow a cyclical pattern. www.iso.com While catastrophes should be random, the period 1985–2012 was characterized by a number of catastrophes of historically high severity, as shown in Figure 6–3. In the terminology of PC insurers, the industry experienced troughs of an underwriting cycle, or underwriting conditions were hard. These cycles are characterized by periods of rising premiums leading to increased profitability. Following a period of solid but not spectacular rates of returns, the industry enters a down phase in which premiums soften as the supply of insurance products increases. As a result, most of the period 1985–2012 was not very profitable for the PC industry. In particular, the combined ratio (the measure of loss plus expense risk) was 116.2 in 1987, 115.7 in 1992, and 116.0 in 2001. (Remember that a combined ratio higher than 100 is bad in that it means that losses, expenses, and dividends totaled more than premiums earned.) The major reason for these losses was a succession of catastrophes from Hurricane Hugo in 1989, the San Francisco earthquake in 1991, the Oakland fires of 1991, and the almost $20 billion in losses incurred in Florida as a result of Hurricane Andrew in 1991. In 1993 the industry showed signs of improvement, with the combined ratio falling to 106.9. However, in 1994 that ratio rose again to 108.4, partly as a result of the Northridge earthquake with estimated losses of $7 billion to $10 billion. The industry ratio fell back down to 101.6 in 1997. However, major losses associated with El Niño (e.g., Hurricane Georges and Midwest storms) drove the combined ratio back up to 105.6 in 1998. The combined ratio increased even further to 107.9 in 1999 and 110.5 in 2000. Part of these increases is attributable to an increase in amounts paid on asbestos claims. In 1999, $3.4 billion was paid out on these claims, the largest payouts ever. The Insurance Services Office Inc. estimates that the combined ratio for 1999, 107.9, would have been one percentage point lower without these claims. The year 2001 saw yet another blow to the insurance industry and the world with the terrorist attacks on the World Trade Center and the Pentagon. Early estimates of the costs of these attacks to insurance companies were as high as $40 billion. It was estimated that only 10 percent of the September 11 losses were reported in 2001, and yet the losses attributed to the terrorist attacks added an estimated 4 percentage points to the combined ratio after dividends of 116.0. Because of the tremendous impact these attacks had on the health of the U.S. insurance industry, the Bush administration proposed that the U.S. government pay the majority of the losses of the insurance industry due to the attacks. The proposal capped insurers’ 2002 liabilities at $12 billion, 2003 liabilities at $23 billion, and 2004 liabilities at $36 billion. Despite this bailout of the industry, many insurers did not survive and those that did were forced to increase premiums significantly. 166 Part One Introduction FIGURE 6–3 U.S. Catastrophes, 1949–2012 Sources: Richard L. Sandor, Center Financial Products, 1949–1994; authors’ research,1995–2012. $50 $45 $66,000 2001 2012 2004 1992 2012 2011 2008 2005 1994 2005 1989 2003 1998 1965 1995 1996 1992 1993 1999 40,000 25,000 25,000 19,900 16,000 14,200 12,500 10,300 7,200 5,627 4,939 3,100 2,900 2,346 2,100 2,000 1,646 1,625 1,600 Catastrophe Year Hurricane Fran Hurricane Frederic Wind, hail, tornadoes Minnesota storms Freeze Oakland fire Hurricane Cecelia Wind California earthquake Midwest drought Texas hailstorm Midwest storms Hurricane Isabel Hurricane Alicia L.A. riots 1995 1979 1974 1998 1983 1991 1970 1950 1989 2000 1995 1998 2003 1983 1992 $1,600 1,575 1,395 1,300 1,280 1,273 1,169 1,136 1,130 1,100 1,100 1,000 1,000 983 797 Terrorists attacks on WTC $40 Amount ($ millions) $35 $30 Hurricane Sandy $55 2005 Hurricane Katrina $60 Year Hurricane Katrina Terrorist attacks on WTC and Pentagon Hurricane Sandy Florida Hurricanes Hurricane Andrew Midwest drought Midwest tornadoes Hurricane Ike Hurricane Wilma Northridge earthquake Hurricane Rita Hurricane Hugo Midwest tornadoes Hurricane Georges Hurricane Betsy Hurricane Opal Blizzard of 1996 Hurricane Iniki Blizzard of 1993 Hurricane Floyd Florida hurricanes $65 Amount ($ millions) Catastrophe and Pentagon $70 $0 Hurricane Ike Hurricane Wilma Hurricane Rita Midwest tornadoes Hurricane Isabel Minnesota storms Hurricane Georges Midwest storms Hurricane Floyd Midwest drought Northridge earthquake Texas hailstorm Hurricane Opal Hurricane Fran Blizzard Hurricane Iniki Blizzard Oakland fires L.A. riots Hurricane Hugo California earthquake Hurricane Alicia Freeze Hurricane Frederic Wind $5 Tornadoes Hurricane Betsy $10 Hurricane Cecelia $15 Hurricane Andrew $20 Midwest tornadoes Midwest drought $25 1949 1956 1961 1966 1969 1973 1975 1977 1979 1980 1982 1984 1986 1988 1989 1991 1992 1994 1995 1996 1998 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 Year Chapter 6 Financial Services: Insurance 167 After several tumultuous years, 2003 saw profitability in the PC industry improve. The combined ratio after dividends was 100.1, down sharply from 107.2 in 2002, and much better than most analysts and industry experts expected. The 2003 results were the best since 1979, when the combined ratio was 100.6. In 2004, Florida and the East coast were hit with several major hurricanes including Hurricanes Charley, Frances, Ivan, and Jeanne (the estimated losses from these four hurricanes were $25 billion). Yet, these were the only major catastrophes to occur in 2004. As a result, the industry saw its first overall profitable year since the 1960s. The combined ratio in 2004 was 98.7. In 2005 the PC industry reported a combined ratio of 100.9. The losses resulted from $57.7 billion in catastrophe losses primarily resulting from the record-breaking hurricane season, which included losses from Hurricanes Katrina, Wilma, and Rita. These losses added an estimated 8 points to the industry’s combined ratio. If catastrophe losses are excluded, the combined ratios for 2005 and 2004 would have been 92.9 and 94.5, respectively. Losses from the record 2005 hurricane season prompted both Allstate and State Farm to stop writing new homeowner policies and drop some existing customers altogether. In 2006 and 2007 a small level of catastrophic losses, combined with a strong performance in virtually all other major lines of PC insurance, resulted in combined ratios of 92.4 (the best underwriting performance since 1936) and 95.6, respectively. Losses rose significantly in 2008 through 2012 due to jumps in catastrophe losses (including $12.5 billion from Hurricane Ike, $25.0 billion from Hurricane Sandy, and $14.2 billion from the Midwest tornadoes) and losses in the mortgage and financial guarantee segments associated with the financial crisis. Note from Table 6–4 that these two segments experienced losses of 194.6 and 136.6 percent of premiums written, respectively, in 2012, down from 214.6 and 416.9 percent of premiums written, respectively, in 2008 at the height of the financial crisis. These losses pushed the 2008 combined ratio to 105.1 (up 9.5 points from 2007). Excluding losses from these two sectors, the industry’s combined ratio would have been 101.0 for the year. Significantly, lower catastrophe losses and a recovering economy resulted in an industry combined ratio of 101.0 in 2009 and 102.4 in 2010. While 2009 saw the third straight year of negative premium growth (the first since the Great Depression), premiums written in 2010 began to recover. Further, few major catastrophes occurred during these two years. As a result, the combined ratio in 2009 and 2010 fell to 101.0 and 102.4, respectively. The United States experienced one of the worst years ever in terms of catastrophes in 2011. Insured catastrophe losses totaled $33.6 billion, the fifth most expensive year on record for insured catastrophe losses on an inflation-adjusted basis. Overall net income after taxes fell 46 percent to $19.2 billion from $35.2 billion in 2010. Such high catastrophe losses, along with high underwriting losses in key non-catastrophe-exposed lines such as workers’ compensation, pushed the industry’s combined ratio to 108.2 (its highest level since 2001). As a result of large decreases in catastrophe losses and a marked acceleration in premium growth, profitability in the PC insurance industry rebounded sharply during the first nine months of 2012. Catastrophe losses fell to $16.2 billion in the first nine months of 2012 from $32.8 billion in the first nine months of 2011. However, catastrophe losses from Hurricane Sandy, which made landfall in the northeast United States in late October, totaled $25.0 billion. As a result, the industry’s combined ratio fell to 100.9 in the first nine months, to 104.0 for the full year. The federal government has gradually increased the role of providing compensation and reconstruction assistance following a variety of natural disasters such as the terrorist attacks of 9/11. Although the insurance industry has been stressed 168 Part One Introduction by major catastrophes, it has argued that government involvement in the market for catastrophe insurance should be minimized to avoid crowding out more efficient private market solutions, such as catastrophe bonds. Regulation www.naic.org Concept Questions As with life insurance companies, PC insurers are chartered by states and regulated by state commissions. In addition, state guaranty funds provide some protection to policyholders if an insurance company fails. The National Association of Insurance Commissioners (NAIC) also provides various services to state regulatory commissions. These services include a standardized examination system called IRIS (Insurance Regulatory Information System) to identify insurers with loss, combined, and other ratios outside the normal ranges. An additional burden that PC insurers face in some activity lines—especially auto insurance and workers’ compensation insurance—is rate regulation. That is, given the public utility nature of some insurance lines, state commissioners set ceilings on premiums and premium increases, usually based on specific cost of capital and line risk exposure formulas for the insurance suppliers. This had led some insurers to leave states such as New Jersey, Florida, and California, which have the most restrictive regulations. Further, the industry came under attack for the way it handled homeowners’ claims associated with Hurricane Katrina. Homeowners policies excluded damage caused by flooding. Insurers insisted the storm surge from Hurricane Katrina was classified as a flood and that damage therefore was excluded from coverage under policy forms that had been reviewed by regulators in each state and in force for years. Lawyers for policyholders of State Farm Insurance Company claimed that insurers were trying to avoid paying out on their homeowners policies by claiming the cause was a flood when it was a combination of hurricane winds and a storm surge. They claimed that the storm surge was not a flood but a direct result of the hurricane’s winds, which is a covered risk. Policyholders claimed that State Farm and other insurance companies used “deceptive” sales practices to sell those hurricane policies and collected extra premiums from them. A verdict in January 2007 not only held State Farm responsible for policy limits that totaled more than $220,000 on each loss deemed to be due to storm-surge flooding but also held the company liable for punitive damages. 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. Why do PC insurers hold more capital and reserves than do life insurers? Why are life insurers’ assets, on average, longer in maturity than those of PC insurers? Describe the main lines of insurance offered by PC insurers. What are the components of the combined ratio? How does the operating ratio differ from the combined ratio? Why does the combined ratio tend to behave cyclically? GLOBAL ISSUES £ ¥ :$ Like the other sectors of the financial institutions industry, the insurance sector is becoming increasingly global. Table 6–7 lists the top 10 countries in terms of total premiums written in 2011 (in U.S. dollars) and their percentage share of the world market. Table 6–8 lists the top 10 insurance companies worldwide by total Chapter 6 TABLE 6–7 Financial Services: Insurance 169 The World’s Top Countries in Terms of Insurance Premiums Written Source: Swiss Re, sigma No 3/2012. Rank Country Life Premiums Written (US$ billions) 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 United States Japan United Kingdom France Germany China Italy South Korea Canada Netherlands $537.6 524.7 210.1 174.8 113.9 134.5 105.1 79.2 52.2 31.2 Property–Casualty Premiums Written (US$ billions) Total Premiums Written (US$ billions) Share of World Market $667.1 103.7 109.5 98.3 131.3 87.3 55.4 51.2 69.0 79.7 $1,204.7 655.4 319.6 273.1 245.2 221.8 160.5 130.4 121.2 110.9 26.2% 14.3 7.0 5.9 5.3 4.8 3.5 2.8 2.6 2.4 TABLE 6–8 World’s Largest Insurance Companies by Total Revenues Source: Insurance Information Institute website, 2012. www.iii.org Rank Company Revenues (US$ billions) Home Country $211.0 142.7 112.6 90.8 77.5 70.6 67.3 62.5 61.8 58.5 Japan France Italy Japan Japan United States China Japan United Kingdom United Kingdom $143.7 134.2 90.1 71.7 64.3 53.0 47.7 43.3 36.5 35.3 United States Germany Germany United States United States Switzerland Japan Japan China Japan Panel A: Life Insurers 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Japan Post Holdings AXA Group Assicurazioni Generali Nippon Life Insurance Meiji Yasuda Life MetLife China Life Insurance Dai-ichi Mutual Life Aviva Prudential Panel B: Property–Casualty Insurers 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Berkshire Hathaway Allianz Munich Re Group American International Group State Farm Insurance Zurich Financial Services MS&AD Insurance Group Tokio Marine People’s Insurance Co. of China NKSJ Holdings revenues. While the United States, Japan, and western Europe dominate the global market, all regions are engaged in the insurance business and many insurers are engaged internationally. Worldwide, 2011 was a bad year for life and PC insurers. Catastrophe losses were the worst on record. Japan’s earthquake and tsunami (with insured losses of $40 billion), earthquakes in New Zealand (with insured losses of $13 billion), 170 Part One Introduction www.mhhe.com/saunders8e floods in Thailand (insured losses of $10 billion), and a series of severe tornadoes in the United States ($14.2 billion) all contributed to $350 billion in disaster losses. Insurance losses from these disasters would have been far greater had the central governments in these countries not picked up a large portion of the loss coverage. Worldwide insured losses in 2012 were 36 percent higher than the 10-year average ($72 billion versus $53 billion), mainly due to events in the United States (discussed above). However, except for the earthquake in Italy (with insured losses topping $1.6 billion), no major catastrophes occurred outside the United States. Insured losses in Europe, Asia, and Canada were far below their 10-year averages. Summary This chapter examined the activities and regulation of insurance companies. The first part of the chapter described the various classes of life insurance and recent trends. The second part covered property–casualty companies. The various lines that make up property–casualty insurance are becoming increasingly blurred as multiple-activity line coverages are offered. Both life and property–casualty insurance companies are regulated at the state rather than the federal level. In addition, both are coming under threat from other financial service firms that offer similar or competitive products. Questions and Problems 1. What is the primary function of an insurance company? How does this function compare with the primary function of a depository institution? 2. What is the adverse selection problem? How does adverse selection affect the profitable management of an insurance company? 3. What are the similarities and differences among the four basic lines of life insurance products? 4. Explain how annuity activities represent the reverse of life insurance activities. 5. Explain how life insurance and annuity products can be used to create a steady stream of cash disbursements and payments to avoid paying or receiving a single lump-sum cash amount. 6. a. Calculate the annual cash flows from a $1 million, 20-year fixed-payment annuity earning a guaranteed 10 percent per year if payments are to begin at the end of the current year. b. Calculate the annual cash flows from a $1 million, 20-year fixed-payment annuity earning a guaranteed 10 percent per year if payments are to begin at the end of year 5. c. What is the amount of the annuity purchase required if you wish to receive a fixed payment of $200,000 for 20 years? Assume that the annuity will earn 10 percent per year. 7. You deposit $10,000 annually into a life insurance fund for the next 10 years, after which time you plan to retire. a. If the deposits are made at the beginning of the year and earn an interest rate of 8 percent, what will be the amount of retirement funds at the end of year 10? b. Instead of a lump sum, you wish to receive annuities for the next 20 years (years 11 through 30). What is the constant annual payment you expect to 8. 9. 10. 11. 12. 13. 14. 15. 16. 17. 18. 19. 20. 21. 22. Financial Services: Insurance 171 receive at the beginning of each year if you assume an interest rate of 8 percent during the distribution period? c. Repeat parts (a) and (b) above assuming earning rates of 7 percent and 9 percent during the deposit period and earning rates of 7 percent and 9 percent during the distribution period. During which period does the change in the earning rate have the greatest impact? You deposit $12,000 annually into a life insurance fund for the next 10 years, at which time you plan to retire. Instead of a lump sum, you wish to receive annuities for the next 20 years. What is the annual payment you expect to receive beginning in year 11 if you assume an interest rate of 6 percent for the whole time period? a. Suppose a 65-year-old person wants to purchase an annuity from an insurance company that would pay $20,000 per year until the end of that person’s life. The insurance company expects this person to live for 15 more years and would be willing to pay 6 percent on the annuity. How much should the insurance company ask this person to pay for the annuity? b. A second 65-year-old person wants the same $20,000 annuity, but this person is much healthier and is expected to live for 20 years. If the same 6 percent interest rate applies, how much should this healthier person be charged for the annuity? c. In each case, what is the difference in the purchase price of the annuity if the distribution payments are made at the beginning of the year? Contrast the balance sheet of a life insurance company (Table 6–3) with the balance sheet of a commercial bank (Table 2–6) and with that of a savings institution (Table 2–10). Explain the balance sheet differences in terms of the differences in the primary functions of the three organizations. Using the data in Table 6–2, how has the composition of assets of U.S. life insurance companies changed over time? How do life insurance companies earn a profit? How would the balance sheet of a life insurance company change if it offered to run a private pension fund for another company? How does the regulation of insurance companies differ from the regulation of depository institutions? What are the major pieces of life insurance regulatory legislation? How do state guarantee funds for life insurance companies compare with deposit insurance for depository institutions? What are the two major activity lines of property–casualty insurance firms? How have the product lines of property–casualty insurance companies changed over time? Contrast the balance sheet of a property–casualty insurance company (Table 6–5) with the balance sheet of a commercial bank (Table 2–6). Explain the balance sheet differences in terms of the differences in the primary functions of the two organizations. What are the three sources of underwriting risk in the property–casualty insurance industry? How do unexpected increases in inflation affect property–casualty insurers? Identify the four characteristics or features of the perils insured against by property–casualty insurance. Rank the features in terms of actuarial predictability and total loss potential. Insurance companies will charge a higher premium for which of the insurance lines listed below? Why? www.mhhe.com/saunders8e Chapter 6 172 Part One Introduction 23. 24. 25. 26. 27. 28. 29. 30. www.mhhe.com/saunders8e 31. a. Low-severity, high-frequency lines versus high-severity, low-frequency lines. b. Long-tail lines versus short-tail lines. What does the loss ratio measure? What has been the long-term trend of the loss ratio? Why? What does the expense ratio measure? Identify and explain the two major sources of expense risk to a property–casualty insurer. Why has the long-term trend in this ratio been decreasing? How is the combined ratio defined? What does it measure? What is the investment yield on premiums earned? Why has this ratio become so important to property–casualty insurers? Consider the data in Table 6–6. Since 1980, what has been the necessary investment yield for the industry to enable the operating ratio to be less than 100 in each year? How is this requirement related to the interest rate risk and credit risk faced by a property–casualty insurer? a. What is the combined ratio for a property insurer that has a loss ratio of 73 percent, a loss adjustment expense of 12.5 percent, and a ratio of commissions and other acquisition expenses of 18 percent? b. What is the combined ratio adjusted for investment yield if the company earns an investment yield of 8 percent? An insurance company’s projected loss ratio is 77.5 percent and its loss adjustment expense ratio is 12.9 percent. The company estimates that commission payments and dividends to policyholders will be 16 percent. What must be the minimum yield on investments to achieve a positive operating ratio? An insurance company collected $3.6 million in premiums and disbursed $1.96 million in losses. Loss adjustment expenses amounted to 6.6 percent and dividends paid to policyholders totaled 1.2 percent. The total income generated from the company’s investments was $170,000 after all expenses were paid. What is the net profitability in dollars? A property-casualty insurer brings in $6.25 million in premiums on its homeowners’ multiple peril line of insurance. The line’s losses amount to $4,343,750, expenses are $1,593,750, and dividends are $156,250. The insurer earns $218,750 on the investment of its premiums. Calculate the line’s loss ratio, expense ratio, dividend ratio, combined ratio, investment ratio, operating ratio, and overall profitability. Web Questions 32. Go to the Federal Reserve Board’s website at www.federalreserve.gov and find the most recent distribution of life insurance industry assets for Table 6–2. Click on “Economic Research and Data.” Click on “Flow of Fund Accounts of the United States.” Click on the most recent date. Click on “Level tables.” This will bring the file (Table L.115) onto your computer that contains the relevant data. How have the values of government securities, corporate securities, mortgages, and policy loans changed since 2012? 33. Go to the Insurance Information Institute’s website at www.iii.org and use the following steps to find the most recent data on the largest life insurance companies by total revenue. Click on “Facts & Statistics.” Click on “Life Insurance.” This will bring the file onto your computer that contains the relevant data. What are total revenues and assets of the top 10 life insurance companies? Chapter Seven Risks of Financial Institutions INTRODUCTION A major objective of FI management is to increase the FI’s returns for its owners. This often comes, however, at the cost of increased risk. This chapter overviews the various risks facing FIs: interest rate risk, credit risk, liquidity risk, foreign exchange risk, country or sovereign risk, market risk, off-balance-sheet risk, technology and operational risk, and insolvency risk. Table 7–1 presents a brief definition of each of these risks. By the end of this chapter, you will have a basic understanding of the variety and complexity of the risks facing managers of modern FIs. In the remaining chapters of the text, we look at the measurement and management of the most important of these risks in more detail. As will become TABLE 7–1 Risks Faced by Financial Intermediaries Interest rate risk The risk incurred by an FI when the maturities of its assets and liabilities are mismatched. Credit risk The risk that promised cash flows from loans and securities held by FIs may not be paid in full. Liquidity risk The risk that a sudden surge in liability withdrawals may require an FI to liquidate assets in a very short period of time and at less than fair market prices. Foreign exchange risk The risk that exchange rate changes can affect the value of an FI’s assets and liabilities denominated in nondomestic currencies. Country or sovereign risk The risk that repayments from foreign borrowers may be interrupted because of restrictions, intervention, or interference from foreign governments. Market risk The risk incurred from assets and liabilities in an FI’s trading book due to changes in interest rates, exchange rates, and other prices. Off-balance-sheet risk The risk incurred by an FI as the result of activities related to its contingent assets and liabilities held off the balance sheet. Technology risk The risk incurred by an FI when its technological investments do not produce anticipated cost savings. Operational risk The risk that existing technology, auditing, monitoring, and other support systems may malfunction or break down. Insolvency risk The risk that an FI may not have enough capital to offset a sudden decline in the value of its assets. 173 174 Part One Introduction clear, the effective management of these risks is central to an FIs performance. Indeed, it can be argued that the main business of FIs is to manage these risks.1 While over the past decade, U.S. financial institution profitability has generally been robust, the risks of financial intermediation have increased as the U.S. and overseas economies have become more integrated. For example, weakening economic conditions inside and outside the United States—especially in Greece, Italy, Spain, and Portugal—have presented great risks for those FIs that operate in and lend to foreign markets and customers. Even those FIs that do not have foreign customers can be exposed to foreign exchange and sovereign risk if their domestic customers have business dealings with foreign countries. As a result, FI managers must devote significant time to understanding and managing the various risks to which their FIs are exposed. INTEREST RATE RISK interest rate risk The risk incurred by an FI when the maturities of its assets and liabilities are mismatched. EXAMPLE 7–1 Impact of an Interest Rate Increase on an FI’s Profits When the Maturity of Its Assets Exceeds the Maturity of Its Liabilities Chapter 1 discussed asset transformation as a key special function of FIs. Asset transformation involves an FI’s buying primary securities or assets and issuing secondary securities or liabilities to fund asset purchases. The primary securities purchased by FIs often have maturity and liquidity characteristics different from those of the secondary securities FIs sell. In mismatching the maturities of assets and liabilities as part of their asset-transformation function, FIs potentially expose themselves to interest rate risk. Consider an FI that issues $100 million of liabilities of one-year maturity to finance the purchase of $100 million of assets with a two-year maturity. We show this situation in the following time lines: 0 0 Liabilities ($100 million) 1 1 Assets ($100 million) 2 In these time lines the FI can be viewed as being “short-funded.” That is, the maturity of its liabilities is less than the maturity of its assets. Suppose the cost of funds (liabilities) for the FI is 9 percent per year and the return on assets is 10 percent per year. Over the first year the FI can lock in a profit spread of 1 percent (10 percent ⫺ 9 percent) times $100 million by borrowing short term (for one year) and lending long term (for two years). Thus, its profit is $1 million (0.01 ⫻ $100 m). However, its profits for the second year are uncertain. If the level of interest rates does not change, the FI can refinance its liabilities at 9 percent and lock in a 1 percent, or $1 million, profit for the second year as well. There is always a risk, however, that interest rates will change between years 1 and 2. If interest rates were to rise and the FI can borrow new one-year liabilities only at 11 percent in the second year, its profit spread in the second year 1 Recall that Appendix 2B at the book’s website (www.mhhe.com/saunders8e) contains an overview of the evaluation of FI performance and risk exposure (“Commercial Banks’ Financial Statements and Analysis”). Included are several accounting ratio–based measures of risk. Chapter 7 refinancing risk The risk that the cost of rolling over or reborrowing funds will rise above the returns being earned on asset investments. EXAMPLE 7–2 Impact of an Interest Rate Decrease When the Maturity of an FI’s Liabilities Exceeds the Maturity of Its Assets reinvestment risk 175 would actually be negative; that is, 10 percent ⫺ 11 percent ⫽ ⫺1 percent, or the FI’s loss is $1 million (⫺0.01 ⫻ $100 m). The positive spread earned in the first year by the FI from holding assets with a longer maturity than its liabilities would be offset by a negative spread in the second year. Note that if interest rates were to rise by more than 1 percent in the second year, the FI would stand to take losses over the two-year period as a whole. As a result, when an FI holds longer-term assets relative to liabilities, it potentially exposes itself to refinancing risk. This is the risk that the cost of rolling over or reborrowing funds could be more than the return earned on asset investments. The classic example of this type of mismatch was demonstrated by U.S. savings institutions during the 1980s (see Chapter 2). An alternative balance sheet structure would have the FI borrowing $100 million for a longer term than the $100 million of assets in which it invests. In the time lines below the FI is “longfunded.” The maturity of its liabilities is longer than the maturity of its assets. Using a similar example, suppose the FI borrows funds at 9 percent per year for two years and invests the funds in assets that yield 10 percent for one year. This situation is shown as follows: 1 Liabilities ($100 million) 0 0 The risk that the return on funds to be reinvested will fall below the cost of funds. Risks of Financial Institutions Assets ($100 million) 2 1 In this case, the FI is also exposed to an interest rate risk; by holding shorter-term assets relative to liabilities, it faces uncertainty about the interest rate at which it can reinvest funds in the second period. As before, the FI locks in a one-year profit spread of 1 percent, or $1 million. At the end of the first year, the assets mature and the funds that have been borrowed for two years have to be reinvested. Suppose interest rates fall between the first and second years so that in the second year the return on $100 million invested in new one-year assets is 8 percent. The FI would face a loss, or negative spread, in the second year of 1 percent (that is, 8 percent asset return minus 9 percent cost of funds), or the FI loses $1 million (⫺0.01 ⫻ $100 m). The positive spread earned in the first year by the FI from holding assets with a shorter maturity than its liabilities is offset by a negative spread in the second year. Thus, the FI is exposed to reinvestment risk; by holding shorter-term assets relative to liabilities, it faces uncertainty about the interest rate at which it can reinvest funds borrowed for a longer period. As interest rates fell in the 2000s, good examples of this exposure were provided by banks that borrowed fixed-rate deposits while investing in floatingrate loans, that is, loans whose interest rates changed or adjusted frequently. In addition to a potential refinancing or reinvestment risk that occurs when interest rates change, an FI faces market value risk as well. Remember that the market (or fair) value of an asset or liability is conceptually equal to the present value of current and future cash flows from that asset or liability. Therefore, rising interest rates increase the discount rate on those cash flows and reduce the market value of that asset or liability. Conversely, falling interest rates increase the market values of assets and liabilities. Moreover, mismatching maturities by holding longer-term assets than liabilities means that when interest rates rise, the market 176 Part One Introduction value of the FI’s assets falls by a greater amount than its liabilities. This exposes the FI to the risk of economic loss and, potentially, the risk of insolvency. If holding assets and liabilities with mismatched maturities exposes FIs to reinvestment (or refinancing) and market value risks, FIs can seek to hedge, or protect against, interest rate risk by matching the maturity of their assets and liabilities.2 This has resulted in the general philosophy that matching maturities is somehow the best policy to hedge interest rate risk for FIs that are averse to risk. Note, however, that matching maturities is not necessarily consistent with an active assettransformation function for FIs. That is, FIs cannot be asset transformers (e.g., transforming short-term deposits into long-term loans) and direct balance sheet matchers or hedgers at the same time. While reducing exposure to interest rate risk, matching maturities may also reduce the FI’s profitability because returns from acting as specialized risk-bearing asset transformers are reduced. As a result, some FIs emphasize asset–liability maturity mismatching more than others. For example, depository institutions traditionally hold longer-term assets than liabilities, whereas life insurers tend to match the long-term nature of their liabilities with long-term assets. Finally, matching maturities hedges interest rate risk only in a very approximate rather than complete fashion. The reasons for this are technical, relating to the difference between the average life (or duration) and maturity of an asset or liability and whether the FI partly funds its assets with equity capital as well as liabilities. In the preceding simple examples, the FI financed its assets completely with borrowed funds. In the real world, FIs use a mix of liabilities and stockholders’ equity to finance asset purchases. When assets and liabilities are not equal, hedging risk (i.e., insulating FI’s stockholders’ equity values) may be achieved by not exactly matching the maturities (or average lives) of assets and liabilities. We discuss the causes of interest rate risk and methods used to measure interest rate risk in detail in Chapters 8 and 9. We discuss the methods and instruments used to hedge interest rate risk in Chapters 22 through 24. Concept Questions 1. What is refinancing risk? 2. Why does a rise in the level of interest rates adversely affect the market value of both assets and liabilities? 3. Explain the concept of maturity matching. CREDIT RISK credit risk The risk that the promised cash flows from loans and securities held by FIs may not be paid in full. Credit risk arises because of the possibility that promised cash flows on financial claims held by FIs, such as loans or bonds, will not be paid in full. Virtually all types of FIs face this risk. However, in general, FIs that make loans or buy bonds with long maturities are more exposed than are FIs that make loans or buy bonds with short maturities. This means, for example, that depository institutions and life 2 This assumes that FIs can directly “control” the maturities of their assets and liabilities. As interest rates fall, many mortgage borrowers seek to “prepay” their existing loans and refinance at a lower rate. This prepayment risk—which is directly related to interest rate movements—can be viewed as a further interest rate–related risk. Prepayment risk is discussed in detail in Chapter 26. Chapter 7 Risks of Financial Institutions 177 insurers are more exposed to credit risk than are money market mutual funds and property–casualty insurers. If the principal on all financial claims held by FIs was paid in full on maturity and interest payments were made on the promised dates, FIs would always receive back the original principal lent plus an interest return. That is, they would face no credit risk. If a borrower defaults, however, both the principal loaned and the interest payments expected to be received are at risk. As a result, many financial claims issued by corporations and held by FIs promise a limited or fixed upside return (principal and interest payments to the lender) with a high probability and a large downside risk (loss of loan principal and promised interest) with a much smaller probability. Good examples of financial claims issued with these return-risk trade-offs are fixed-income coupon bonds issued by corporations and bank loans. In both cases, an FI holding these claims as assets earns the coupon on the bond or the interest promised on the loan if no borrower default occurs. In the event of default, however, the FI earns zero interest on the asset and may lose all or part of the principal lent, depending on its ability to lay claim to some of the borrower’s assets through legal bankruptcy and insolvency proceedings. Accordingly, a key role of FIs involves screening and monitoring loan applicants to ensure that FIs fund the most creditworthy loans (see Chapter 10). The effects of credit risk are evident in Figure 7–1, which shows commercial bank charge-off (or write-off) rates for various types of loans between 1984 and 2012. Notice, in particular, the high rate of charge-offs experienced on credit card loans throughout this period. Indeed, credit card charge-offs by commercial banks increased persistently from the mid-1980s until 1993 and again from 1995 through early 1998. By 1998, charge-offs leveled off, and they even declined after 1998. FIGURE 7–1 Charge-Off Rates for Commercial Bank Lending Activities, 1984–2012 Source: FDIC, Quarterly Banking Profile, various issues. www.fdic.gov Net charge-off rate (%) 14.0 13.0 12.0 11.0 10.0 9.0 C&I loans Real estate loans Credit card loans 8.0 7.0 6.0 5.0 4.0 3.0 2.0 1.0 0.0 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 178 Part One Introduction firm-specific credit risk The risk of default of the borrowing firm associated with the specific types of project risk taken by that firm. systematic credit risk The risk of default associated with general economywide or macro conditions affecting all borrowers. Concept Questions However, a weak economy and change in bankruptcy laws3 resulted in a surge in credit card charge-offs in the early 2000s and during the recession from 2007–2010. Despite these losses, credit card loans extended by commercial banks (including unused balances) continued to grow, from $1.856 trillion in March 1997 to $4.367 trillion in September 2008. With the financial crisis, total credit card loans had fallen to $3.626 trillion in March 2009, and they remained relatively low for several years as the U.S. economy failed to show any robust growth. In March 2012, credit card loans extended by commercial banks totaled $3.289 trillion. The potential loss an FI can experience from lending suggests that FIs need to monitor and collect information about borrowers whose assets are in their portfolios and to monitor those borrowers over time. Thus, managerial monitoring efficiency and credit risk management strategies directly affect the return and risks of the loan portfolio. Moreover, one of the advantages FIs have over individual household investors is the ability to diversify some credit risk from a single asset away by exploiting the law of large numbers in their asset investment portfolios (see Chapter 1). Diversification across assets, such as loans exposed to credit risk, reduces the overall credit risk in the asset portfolio and thus increases the probability of partial or full repayment of principal and/or interest. FIs earn the maximum dollar return when all bonds and loans pay off interest and principal in full. In reality, some loans or bonds default on interest payments, principal payments, or both. Thus, the mean return on the asset portfolio would be less than the maximum possible. The effect of risk diversification is to truncate or limit the probabilities of the bad outcomes in the portfolio. In effect, diversification reduces individual firm-specific credit risk, such as the risk specific to holding the bonds or loans of General Motors, while leaving the FI still exposed to systematic credit risk, such as factors that simultaneously increase the default risk of all firms in the economy (e.g., an economic recession). We describe methods to measure the default risk of individual corporate claims such as bonds and loans in Chapter 10. In Chapter 11, we investigate methods of measuring the risk in portfolios of such claims. Chapter 25 discusses various methods—for example, loan sales, reschedulings, and a good bank–bad bank structure—to manage and control credit risk exposures better, while Chapters 22, 23, 24, and 26 discuss the role of the credit derivative markets in hedging credit risk. 1. Why does credit risk exist for FIs? 2. How does diversification affect an FI’s credit risk exposure? LIQUIDITY RISK liquidity risk The risk that a sudden surge in liability withdrawals may leave an FI in a position of having to liquidate assets in a very short period of time and at low prices. Liquidity risk arises when an FI’s liability holders, such as depositors or insurance policyholders, demand immediate cash for the financial claims they hold with an FI or when holders of off-balance-sheet loan commitments (or credit lines) suddenly exercise their right to borrow (draw down their loan commitments). For example, when liability holders demand cash immediacy—that is, “put” their financial claims back to the FI—the FI must either borrow additional funds or sell assets to meet the demand for the withdrawal of funds. The most liquid asset of 3 In the early 2000s, the U.S. Congress considered and passed legislation that made it more difficult for individuals to declare bankruptcy. This congressional activity brought about a rise in bankruptcy filings before changes took effect. Chapter 7 www.fdic.gov EXAMPLE 7–3 Impact of Liquidity Risk on an FI’s Equity Value Risks of Financial Institutions 179 all is cash, which FIs can use to directly meet liability holders’ demands to withdraw funds. Although FIs limit their cash asset holdings because cash earns no interest, low cash holdings are usually not a problem. Day-to-day withdrawals by liability holders are generally predictable, and FIs can normally expect to borrow additional funds to meet any sudden shortfalls of cash on the money and financial markets. However, there are times when an FI can face a liquidity crisis. Because of a lack of confidence by liability holders in the FI or some unexpected need for cash, liability holders may demand larger withdrawals than normal. When all, or many, FIs face abnormally large cash demands, the cost of additional purchased or borrowed funds rises and the supply of such funds becomes restricted. As a consequence, FIs may have to sell some of their less liquid assets to meet the withdrawal demands of liability holders. This results in a more serious liquidity risk, especially as some assets with “thin” markets generate lower prices when the asset sale is immediate than when the FI has more time to negotiate the sale of an asset. As a result, the liquidation of some assets at low or fire-sale prices (the price an FI receives if an asset must be liquidated immediately at less than its fair market value) could threaten an FI’s profitability and solvency. For example, in the summer of 2008 IndyMac bank failed, in part due to a bank run that continued for several days, even after being taken over by the FDIC. The bank had announced on July 7 that, due to its deteriorating capital position, its mortgage operations would stop and it would operate only as a retail bank. News reports over the weekend highlighted the possibility that IndyMac would become the largest bank failure in over 20 years. Worried that they would not have access to their money, bank depositors rushed to withdraw money from IndyMac even though their deposits were insured up to $100,000 by the FDIC.4 The run was so large that within a week of the original announcement, the FDIC had to step in and take over the bank. Consider the simple FI balance sheet in Table 7–2. Before deposit withdrawals, the FI has $10 million in cash assets and $90 million in nonliquid assets (such as small business loans). These assets were funded with $90 million in deposits and $10 million in owner’s equity. Suppose that depositors unexpectedly withdrew $15 million in deposits (perhaps due to the release of negative news about the profits of the FI) and the FI receives no new deposits to replace them. To meet these deposit withdrawals, the FI first uses the $10 million it has in cash assets and then seeks to sell some of its nonliquid assets to raise an additional $5 million in cash. Assume that the FI cannot borrow any more funds in the short-term money markets, and because it cannot wait to get better prices for its assets in the future (as it needs the cash now to meet immediate depositor withdrawals), the FI has to sell any nonliquid assets at 50 cents on the dollar. Thus, to cover the remaining $5 million in deposit withdrawals, the FI must sell $10 million in nonliquid assets, incurring a loss of $5 million from the face value of those assets. The FI must then write off any such losses against its capital or equity funds. Because its capital was only $10 million before the deposit withdrawal, the loss on the firesale of assets of $5 million leaves the FI with only $5 million in equity. 4 One reason is that, although deposits were insured up to $100,000 (since increased to $250,000), it may take some days to transfer deposits to the bank of an acquirer. IndyMac was eventually acquired by OneWest Bank Group. 180 Part One Introduction TABLE 7–2 Adjusting to a Deposit Withdrawal Using Asset Sales (in millions) Before the Withdrawal Assets Cash assets Nonliquid assets After the Withdrawal Liabilities/Equity $ 10 90 $100 Deposit Equity $ 90 10 $100 Assets Cash assets Nonliquid assets Liabilities/Equity $ 0 80 Deposits Equity $80 $ 75 5 $ 80 We examine the nature of normal, abnormal, and run-type liquidity risks and their impact on FIs in more detail in Chapter 12. In addition, we look at ways an FI can better manage liquidity and liability risk exposures in Chapter 18. Chapter 19 discusses the roles of deposit insurance and other liability guarantee schemes in deterring deposit (liability) runs. Concept Questions 1. Why might an FI face a sudden liquidity crisis? 2. What circumstances might lead an FI to liquidate assets at fire-sale prices? FOREIGN EXCHANGE RISK £ ¥ :$ foreign exchange risk The risk that exchange rate changes can affect the value of an FI’s assets and liabilities denominated in foreign currencies. Increasingly, FIs have recognized that both direct foreign investment and foreign portfolio investments can extend the operational and financial benefits available from purely domestic investments. Thus, U.S. pension funds that held approximately 5 percent of their assets in foreign securities in the early 1990s now hold over 12 percent of their assets in foreign securities. At the same time, many large U.S. banks, investment banks, and mutual funds have become more global in their orientation. To the extent that the returns on domestic and foreign investments are imperfectly correlated, there are potential gains for an FI that expands its asset holdings and liability funding beyond the domestic borders. The returns on domestic and foreign direct investing and portfolio investments are not perfectly correlated for two reasons. The first is that the underlying technologies of various economies differ, as do the firms in those economies. For example, one economy may be based on agriculture while another is industry based. Given different economic infrastructures, one economy could be expanding while another is contracting. In the early 2010s, for example, the U.S. economy was expanding while the European economy was recessionary. The second reason is that exchange rate changes are not perfectly correlated across countries. This means the dollar–euro exchange rate may be appreciating while the dollar–yen exchange rate may be falling. One potential benefit from an FI’s becoming increasingly global in its outlook is an ability to expand abroad directly through branching or acquisitions or by developing a financial asset portfolio that includes foreign securities as well as domestic securities. Even so, foreign investment exposes an FI to foreign exchange risk. Foreign exchange risk is the risk that exchange rate changes can adversely affect the value of an FI’s assets and liabilities denominated in foreign currencies. Chapter 7 Risks of Financial Institutions 181 To understand how foreign exchange risk arises, suppose that a U.S. FI makes a loan to a British company in pounds (£). Should the British pound depreciate in value relative to the U.S. dollar, the principal and interest payments received by U.S. investors would be devalued in dollar terms. Indeed, were the British pound to fall far enough over the investment period, when cash flows are converted back into dollars, the overall return could be negative. That is, on the conversion of principal and interest payments from pounds into dollars, foreign exchange losses can offset the promised value of local currency interest payments at the original exchange rate at which the investment occurred. In general, an FI can hold assets denominated in a foreign currency and/or issue foreign liabilities. Consider a U.S. FI that holds £100 million in pound loans as assets and funds £80 million of them with pound certificates of deposit. The difference between the £100 million in pound loans and £80 million in pound CDs is funded by dollar CDs (i.e., £20 million worth of dollar CDs). See Figure 7–2. In this case, the U.S. FI is net long £20 million in pound assets; that is, it holds more foreign assets than liabilities. The U.S. FI suffers losses if the exchange rate for pounds falls or depreciates against the dollar over this period. In dollar terms, the value of the pound loan assets falls or decreases in value by more than the pound CD liabilities do. That is, the FI is exposed to the risk that its net foreign assets may have to be liquidated at an exchange rate lower than the one that existed when the FI entered into the foreign asset–liability position. Instead, the FI could have £20 million more pound liabilities than assets; in this case, it would be holding a net short position in pound assets, as shown in Figure 7–3. Under this circumstance, the FI is exposed to foreign exchange risk if the pound appreciates against the dollar over the investment period. This occurs because the value of its pound liabilities in dollar terms rose faster than the return on its pound assets. Consequently, to be approximately hedged, the FI must match its assets and liabilities in each foreign currency. Note that the FI is fully hedged only if we assume that it holds foreign assets and liabilities of exactly the same maturity.5 Consider what happens if the FI matches the size of its foreign currency book (Pound assets ⫽ Pound liabilities ⫽ £100 million in that currency) but mismatches the maturities so that the pound assets are of FIGURE 7–2 The Foreign Asset and Liability Position: Net Long Asset Position in Pounds 0 Foreign assets £100 million 0 Foreign liabilities £80 million 0 Foreign assets £80 million FIGURE 7–3 The Foreign Asset and Liability Position: Net Short Asset Position in Pounds 0 5 Foreign liabilities £100 million Technically speaking, hedging requires matching the durations (average lives of assets and liabilities) rather than simple maturities (see Chapter 9). 182 Part One Introduction six-month maturity and the liabilities are of three-month maturity. The FI would then be exposed to foreign interest rate risk—the risk that British interest rates would rise when it has to roll over its £100 million in pound CD liabilities at the end of the third month. Consequently, an FI that matches both the size and maturities of its exposure in assets and liabilities of a given currency is hedged, or immunized, against foreign currency and foreign interest rate risk. To the extent that FIs mismatch their portfolio and maturity exposures in different currency assets and liabilities, they face both foreign currency and foreign interest rate risks. As already noted, if foreign exchange rate and interest rate changes are not perfectly correlated across countries, an FI can diversify away part, if not all, of its foreign currency risk. We discuss the measurement and evaluation of an FI’s foreign currency risk exposure in depth in Chapter 13. Concept Questions 1. Explain why the returns on domestic and foreign portfolio investments are not, in general, perfectly correlated. 2. A U.S. bank is net long in European assets. If the euro appreciates against the dollar, will the bank gain or lose? COUNTRY OR SOVEREIGN RISK £ ¥ :$ country or sovereign risk The risk that repayments from foreign borrowers may be interrupted because of interference from foreign governments. As we noted in the previous section, a globally oriented FI that mismatches the size and maturities of its foreign assets and liabilities is exposed to foreign currency and foreign interest rate risks. Even beyond these risks, and even when investing in dollars, holding assets in a foreign country can expose an FI to an additional type of foreign investment risk called country or sovereign risk. Country or sovereign risk is a different type of credit risk that is faced by an FI that purchases assets such as the bonds and loans of foreign corporations. For example, when a domestic corporation is unable or unwilling to repay a loan, an FI usually has recourse to the domestic bankruptcy courts and eventually may recoup at least a portion of its original investment when the assets of the defaulted firm are liquidated or restructured. By comparison, a foreign corporation may be unable to repay the principal or interest on a loan even if it would like to. Most commonly, the government of the country in which the corporation is headquartered may prohibit or limit debt payments because of foreign currency shortages and adverse political reasons. For example, in 2001, the government of Argentina, which had pegged its peso to the dollar on a one-to-one basis since the early 1990s, had to default on its government debt largely because of an overvalued peso and the adverse effect this had on its exports and foreign currency earnings. In December 2001, Argentina ended up defaulting on $130 billion in government-issued debt and, in 2002, passed legislation that led to defaults on $30 billion of corporate debt owed to foreign creditors. Argentina’s economic problems continued into the mid-2000s. In September 2003 it defaulted on a $3 billion loan repayment to the IMF and in 2005 Argentina announced that it was offering its creditors about 30 cents on the dollar from its 2001 debt restructuring of $103 billion. More recently, despite massive injections of bailout funds by the eurozone and the International Monetary Fund, Chapter 7 Risks of Financial Institutions 183 in March 2012, Greek government debtholders lost 53.5 percent of their $265 billion investment as Greece restructured much of its sovereign debt. The restructuring produced the largest-ever sovereign debt default. In the event of such restrictions, reschedulings, or outright prohibitions on the payment of debt obligations by sovereign governments, the FI claimholder has little, if any, recourse to the local bankruptcy courts or an international civil claims court. The major leverage available to an FI to ensure or increase repayment probabilities and amounts is its control over the future supply of loans or funds to the country concerned. However, such leverage may be very weak in the face of a country’s collapsing currency and government. Chapter 14 discusses how country or sovereign risk is measured and considers possible financial market solutions to the country risk exposure problems of a globally oriented FI. Concept Questions 1. Can an FI be subject to sovereign risk if it lends only to the highest-quality foreign corporations? 2. What is one major way an FI can discipline a country that threatens not to repay its loans? MARKET RISK market risk The risk incurred in the trading of assets and liabilities due to changes in interest rates, exchange rates, and other asset prices. Market risk arises when FIs actively trade assets and liabilities (and derivatives) rather than hold them for longer-term investment, funding, or hedging purposes. Market risk is closely related to interest rate risk, credit risk, and foreign exchange risk in that as these risks increase or decrease, the overall risk of the FI is affected. However, market risk adds another dimension resulting from its trading activity. Market risk is the incremental risk incurred by an FI when interest rate, foreign exchange, and credit risks are combined with an active trading strategy, especially one that involves short trading horizons such as a day. Conceptually, an FI’s trading portfolio can be differentiated from its investment portfolio on the basis of time horizon and secondary market liquidity. The trading portfolio contains assets, liabilities, and derivative contracts that can be quickly bought or sold on organized financial markets. The investment portfolio (or in the case of banks, the so-called banking book) contains assets and liabilities that are relatively illiquid and held for longer holding periods. Table 7–3 shows a hypothetical breakdown TABLE 7–3 The Investment (Banking) Book and Trading Book of a Commercial Bank Banking book Trading book Assets Cash Loans Premises and equipment Other illiquid assets Liabilities Deposits Other illiquid borrowed funds Capital Bonds (long) Commodities (long) FX (long) Equities (long) Bonds (short) Commodities (short) FX (short) Equities (short) Derivatives* (long) Derivatives* (short) *Derivatives are off-balance-sheet items (as discussed in Chapter 16). 184 Part One Introduction between banking book and trading book assets and liabilities. As can be seen, the banking book contains the majority of loans and deposits plus other illiquid assets. The trading book contains long and short positions in instruments such as bonds, commodities, foreign exchange (FX), equities, and derivatives. With the increasing securitization of bank loans (e.g., mortgages), more and more assets have become liquid and tradable. Of course, with time, every asset and liability can be sold. While bank regulators have normally viewed tradable assets as those being held for horizons of less than one year, private FIs take an even shorter-term view. In particular, FIs are concerned about the fluctuation in the value of their trading account assets and liabilities for periods as short as one day especially if such fluctuations pose a threat to their solvency. An extreme case of the type of risk involved in active trading is, of course, the market meltdown of 2008–2009. As mortgage borrowers defaulted on their mortgages, financial institutions that held these mortgages and mortgage-backed securities started announcing huge losses on them. It is these securitized loans, and particularly securitized subprime mortgage loans, that led to huge financial losses resulting from market risk. Investment banks and securities firms were major purchasers of mortgage originators in the early 2000s, which allowed them to increase their business of packaging the loans as securities. As mortgage borrowers defaulted on their mortgages, the securitized mortgage market froze up and FIs were left to hold these “toxic” assets at deeply reduced market values. Investment banks were particularly hard hit with huge losses on the mortgages and securities backing them. On Monday, September 15, Lehman Brothers (the 158-year-old investment bank) filed for bankruptcy, Merrill Lynch was bought by Bank of America, AIG (one of the world’s largest insurance companies) met with federal regulators to raise desperately needed cash, and Washington Mutual (the largest savings institution in the United States) was acquired by J.P. Morgan Chase. A sense of foreboding gripped Wall Street. The Dow fell more than 500 points, the largest drop in over seven years. World stock markets saw huge swings in value as investors tried to sort out who might survive (markets from Russia to Europe were forced to suspend trading as stock prices plunged). By mid-September, financial markets froze and banks stopped lending to each other at anything but exorbitantly high rates. Banks that were active traders faced extreme market risk. The financial market crisis illustrates that market, or trading, risk is present whenever an FI takes an open or unhedged long (buy) or sell (short) position in bonds, equities, foreign exchange, and derivative products, and prices change in a direction opposite to that expected. As a result, the more volatile are asset prices in the markets in which these instruments trade, the greater are the market risks faced by FIs that adopt open trading positions. This requires FI management (and regulators) to establish controls to limit positions taken by traders as well as to develop models to measure the market risk exposure of an FI on a day-to-day basis. These market risk measurement models are discussed in Chapter 15. Concept Questions 1. What is market, or trading, risk? 2. What modern conditions have led to an increase in this particular type of risk for FIs? Chapter 7 Risks of Financial Institutions 185 OFF-BALANCE-SHEET RISK off-balance-sheet risk The risk incurred by an FI due to activities related to contingent assets and liabilities. letter of credit A credit guarantee issued by an FI for a fee on which payment is contingent on some future event occurring. One of the most striking trends for many modern FIs has been the growth in their off-balance-sheet activities and thus their off-balance-sheet risk. While all FIs to some extent engage in off-balance-sheet activities, most attention has been drawn to the activities of banks, especially large banks, who invest heavily in off-balance-sheet assets and liabilities, particularly derivative securities. By contrast, off-balance-sheet activities have been less of a concern to smaller depository institutions and many insurance companies, who hold relatively few off-balance-sheet securities. An off-balance-sheet activity, by definition, does not appear on an FI’s current balance sheet since it does not involve holding a current primary claim (asset) or the issuance of a current secondary claim (liability). Instead, off-balance-sheet activities affect the future shape of an FI’s balance sheet in that they involve the creation of contingent assets and liabilities that give rise to their potential (future) placement on the balance sheet. Thus, accountants place them “below the bottom line” of an FI’s asset and liability balance sheet. A good example of an off-balance-sheet activity is the issuance of standby letter of credit guarantees by insurance companies and banks to back the issuance of municipal bonds. Many state and local governments could not issue such securities without bank or insurance company letter of credit guarantees that promise principal and interest payments to investors should the municipality default on its future obligations. Thus, the letter of credit guarantees payment should a municipal government (e.g., New York State) face financial problems in paying the promised interest payments and/or the principal on the bonds it issues. If a municipal government’s cash flow is sufficiently strong so as to pay off the principal and interest on the debt it issues, the letter of credit guarantee issued by the FI expires unused. Nothing appears on the FI’s balance sheet today or in the future. However, the fee earned for issuing the letter of credit guarantee appears on the FI’s income statement. As a result, the ability to earn fee income while not loading up or expanding the balance sheet has become an important motivation for FIs to pursue off-balancesheet business. Unfortunately, this activity is not risk free. Suppose the municipal government defaults on its bond interest and principal payments. Then the contingent liability or guaranty the FI issued becomes an actual liability that appears on the FI’s balance sheet. That is, the FI has to use its own equity to compensate investors in municipal bonds. Letters of credit are just one example of off-balance-sheet activities. Others include loan commitments by banks, mortgage servicing contracts by depository institutions, and positions in forwards, futures, swaps, and other derivative securities by almost all large FIs. While some of these activities are structured to reduce an FI’s exposure to credit, interest rate, or foreign exchange risks, mismanagement or speculative use of these instruments can result in major losses to FIs. Indeed, as seen during the financial crisis of 2008–2009, significant losses in off-balance-sheet activities (e.g., credit default swaps) can cause an FI to fail, just as major losses due to balance sheet default and interest rate risks can cause an FI to fail. We detail the specific nature of the risks of off-balance-sheet activities more fully in Chapter 16. We look at how some of these instruments (forwards, futures, options, and swaps) can be used to manage risks in Chapters 22, 23, 24, and 26. 186 Part One Introduction EXAMPLE 7–4 Impact of OffBalance-Sheet Risk on an FI’s Equity Value Consider Table 7–4. In Panel A, the value of the FI’s net worth (E ) is calculated in the traditional way as the difference between the market values of its on-balance-sheet assets (A) and liabilities (L): E⫽A⫺L 10 ⫽ 100 ⫺ 90 Under this calculation, the market value of the stockholders’ equity stake in the FI is 10 and the ratio of the FI’s capital to assets is 10 percent. Regulators and FIs often use the latter ratio as a simple measure of solvency (see Chapter 20 for more details). A more accurate picture of the FI’s economic solvency should consider the market values of both its on-balance-sheet and OBS activities (Panel B of Table 7–4). Specifically, the FI manager should value contingent or future asset and liability claims as well as current assets and liabilities. In our example, the current market value of the FI’s contingent assets (CA) is 50; the current market value of its contingent liabilities (CL) is 55. Since CL exceed CA by 5, this difference is an additional obligation, or claim, on the FI’s net worth. That is, stockholders’ true net worth (E) is really: E ⫽ (A ⫺ L) ⫹ (CA ⫺ CL) ⫽ (100 ⫺ 90) ⫹ (50 ⫺ 55) ⫽ 5 rather than 10 when we ignored off-balance-sheet activities. Thus, economically speaking, contingent assets and liabilities are contractual claims that directly impact the economic value of the equity holders’ stake in an FI. Indeed, from both the stockholders’ and regulators’ perspectives, large increases in the value of OBS liabilities can render the FI economically insolvent just as effectively as losses due to mismatched interest rate gaps and default or credit losses from on-balance-sheet activities. TABLE 7–4 Valuation of an FI’s Net Worth with and without Consideration of Off-Balance-Sheet Activities Panel A: Traditional Valuation of an FI’s Net Worth Market value of assets (A) Market value of liabilities (L) Net worth (E ) 100 90 10 100 Panel B: Valuation of an FI’s Net Worth with On- and Off-Balance-Sheet Activities Valued Market value of assets (A) Market value of contingent assets (CA) Concept Questions 100 100 50 150 Market value of liabilities (L) Net worth (E ) Market value of contingent liabilities (CL) 90 5 55 150 1. Why are letter of credit guarantees an off-balance-sheet item? 2. Why are FIs motivated to pursue off-balance-sheet business? What are the risks? TECHNOLOGY AND OPERATIONAL RISKS www.bis.org Technology and operational risks are closely related and in recent years have caused great concern to FI managers and regulators alike. The Bank for International Settlements (BIS), the principal organization of central banks in the major economies Chapter 7 economies of scale The degree to which an FI’s average unit costs of producing financial services fall as its outputs of services increase. economies of scope The degree to which an FI can generate cost synergies by producing multiple financial service products. technology risk The risk incurred by an FI when technological investments do not produce the cost savings anticipated. operational risk The risk that existing technology or support systems may malfunction or break down. Risks of Financial Institutions 187 of the world, defines operational risk (inclusive of technological risk) as “the risk of loss resulting from inadequate or failed internal processes, people, and systems or from external events.”6 A number of FIs add reputational risk and strategic risk (e.g., due to a failed merger) as part of a broader definition of operational risk. Technological innovation was a major growth area of FIs in the 1990s and 2000s. Banks, insurance companies, and investment companies all sought to improve operational efficiency with major investments in internal and external communications, computers, and an expanded technological infrastructure. For example, most banks provide depositors with the capabilities to check account balances, transfer funds between accounts, manage finances, pay bills, and perform other functions from their home personal computers. At the wholesale level, electronic transfer of funds through automated clearing houses (ACH) and wire transfer payment networks such as the Clearing House Interbank Payments Systems (CHIPS) have been developed. Indeed, the global financial services firm Citigroup has operations in more than 100 countries connected in real time by a proprietaryowned satellite system. The major objectives of technological expansion are to lower operating costs, increase profits, and capture new markets for the FI. In current terminology, the objective is to allow the FI to exploit, to the fullest extent possible, better potential economies of scale and economies of scope in selling its products. Economies of scale refer to an FI’s ability to lower its average costs of operations by expanding its output of financial services. Economies of scope refer to an FI’s ability to generate cost synergies by producing more than one output with the same inputs. For example, an FI could use the same information on the quality of customers stored in its computers to expand the sale of both loan products and insurance products. That is, the same information (e.g., age, job, size of family, income) can identify both potential loan and life insurance customers. Technology risk occurs when technological investments do not produce the anticipated cost savings in the form of economies of either scale or scope. Diseconomies of scale, for example, arise because of excess capacity, redundant technology, and/ or organizational and bureaucratic inefficiencies that become worse as an FI grows in size. Diseconomies of scope arise when an FI fails to generate perceived synergies or cost savings through major new technological investments. We describe the measurement and evidence of economies of scale and scope in FIs in Chapter 17. Technological risk can result in major losses in the competitive efficiency of an FI and, ultimately, in its long-term failure. Similarly, gains from technological investments can produce performance superior to an FI’s rivals as well as allow it to develop new and innovative products, enhancing its long-term survival chances. Operational risk is partly related to technology risk and can arise whenever existing technology malfunctions or back-office support systems break down. For example, the biggest known theft of credit card numbers was discovered in May 2007, when, over a two-year period, as many as 200 million card numbers were stolen from TJX Company—parent company to such retail stores as Marshalls and TJ Maxx. The retailer’s wireless network reportedly had less security than most home networks. Even though such computer breakdowns are rare, their occurrence can cause major dislocations in the FIs involved and potentially disrupt the financial system in general. 6 See Basel Committee on Bank Supervision, “Sound Practices for the Management and Supervision of Operational Risk,” July 2002, p. 2, Basel, Switzerland. 188 Part One Introduction Operational risk is not exclusively the result of technological failure. For example, employee fraud and errors constitute a type of operational risk that often negatively affects the reputation of an FI (see Chapter 17). A good example involves $2 billion in trading losses incurred by J.P. Morgan Chase’s trader, Bruno Iksil, also known as “the London Whale,” who had taken large credit default swap (CDS) positions in expectation that the financial crisis in Europe would cause anxiety in financial markets. Instead, bailouts, austerity measures, and interventions prevented any major events in Europe. To maintain the proper balance and deal with expiring contracts, Iksil needed to continually make new trades. But the CDS market was too small and the amounts Iksil was trading were too large to let J.P. Morgan operate in secrecy. Once the story got out, hedge funds traders took positions designed to gain from the trades that Iksil had to make to keep the position going. That activity negatively altered prices on the CDSs that Iksil needed. Eventually, the only choice was to close the CDS position and take the loss. These activities by employees of FIs result in an overall loss of reputation and, in turn, business for the FI employers. Concept Questions 1. What is the difference between economies of scale and economies of scope? 2. How is operational risk related to technology risk? 3. How does technological expansion help an FI better exploit economies of scale and economies of scope? When might technology risk interfere with these goals? INSOLVENCY RISK insolvency risk The risk that an FI may not have enough capital to offset a sudden decline in the value of its assets relative to its liabilities. Insolvency risk is a consequence or outcome of one or more of the risks described above: interest rate, credit, liquidity, foreign exchange, sovereign, market, offbalance-sheet, and technology risks. Technically, insolvency occurs when the capital or equity resources of an FI’s owners are driven to, or near to, zero because of losses incurred as the result of one or more of the risks described above. Consider the case of Washington Mutual (WaMu), which incurred heavy losses from its on- and off-balance-sheet holdings during the financial crisis. By early September 2008, WaMu’s market capital was worth only $3.5 billion, down from $43 billion at the end of 2006. In September 2008, the bank was taken over by the FDIC and sold to J.P. Morgan Chase. In contrast, in March 2009, Citigroup’s stock price fell to below $1 per share, and the once largest bank in the United States was near failure. Proving that some banks are too big to fail, Citigroup received a substantial government guarantee against losses (up to $306 billion) and a $20 billion injection of cash to prevent failure. Indeed, through December 2009 more than 700 banks had received a total of $205 billion in federal government funds (through the Capital Purchase Program) in an effort to prop up capital and support lending. In general, the more equity capital to borrowed funds an FI has—that is, the lower its leverage—the better able it is to withstand losses, whether due to adverse interest rate changes, unexpected credit losses, or other reasons. Thus, both management and regulators of FIs focus on an FI’s capital (and adequacy) as a key measure of its ability to remain solvent and grow in the face of a multitude of risk exposures. The issue of what is an adequate level of capital to manage an FI’s overall risk exposure is discussed in Chapter 20. Chapter 7 Concept Questions Risks of Financial Institutions 189 1. When does insolvency risk occur? 2. How is insolvency risk related to the other risks discussed in this chapter? OTHER RISKS AND THE INTERACTION OF RISKS In this chapter we have concentrated on 10 major risks continuously affecting an FI manager’s decision-making process and risk management strategies. These risks were interest rate risk, credit risk, liquidity risk, foreign exchange risk, country or sovereign risk, market risk, off-balance-sheet risk, technology and operational risk, and insolvency risk. Even though the discussion generally described each independently, in reality, these risks are often interdependent. For example, when interest rates rise, corporations and consumers find maintaining promised payments on their debt more difficult. Thus, over some range of interest rate movements, credit, interest rate, and off-balance-sheet risks are positively correlated. Furthermore, the FI may have been counting on the funds from promised payments on its loans for liquidity management purposes. Thus, liquidity risk is also correlated with interest rate and credit risks. The inability of a customer to make promised payments also affects the FI’s income and profits and, consequently, its equity or capital position. Thus, each risk and its interaction with other risks ultimately affects insolvency risk. Similarly, foreign exchange rate changes and interest rate changes are also highly correlated. When the Federal Reserve changes a key interest rate (such as the Fed funds rate) through its monetary policy actions, exchange rates are also likely to change. Various other risks, often of a more discrete or event type, also impact an FI’s profitability and risk exposure, although, as noted earlier, many view discrete or event risks as part of operational risks. Discrete risks might include events external to the FI, such as a sudden change in regulation policy. These include lifting the regulatory barriers to lending or to entry or on products offered (see Chapter 21). The 1994 regulatory change allowing interstate branching after 1997 is one example, as are the 1999 Financial Services Modernization Act and the Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act of 2010. Other discrete or event risks involve sudden and unexpected changes in financial market conditions due to war, revolution, or sudden market collapse, such as the 1929 and 2008 stock market crashes or the September 2001 terrorist attacks in the United States. These can have a major impact on an FI’s risk exposure. Other event risks include fraud, theft, earthquakes, storms, malfeasance, and breach of fiduciary trust; all of these can ultimately cause an FI to fail or be severely harmed. Yet each is difficult to model and predict. Finally, more general macroeconomic or systematic risks, such as increased inflation, inflation volatility, and unemployment, can directly and indirectly impact an FI’s level of interest rate, credit, and liquidity risk exposure. For example, the U.S. unemployment rate was greater than 10 percent in the fall of 2009, the highest level since September 1992. Since December 2007 (as the recession began) the U.S. economy lost some 8 million jobs, most of which were lost in the period November 2008 through June 2009. With so many people out of work, credit risk exposure of FIs increased dramatically as borrowers had trouble keeping up with their loan payments after losing their jobs. Concept Questions 1. What is meant by the term event risk? 2. What are some examples of event and general macroeconomic risks that impact FIs? www.mhhe.com/saunders8e 190 Part One Introduction Summary This chapter provided an introductory view of 10 major risks faced by modern FIs. They face interest rate risk when the maturities of their assets and liabilities are mismatched. They face credit risk or default risk if their clients default on their loans and other obligations. They encounter liquidity risk as a result of excessive withdrawals or problems in refinancing liabilities. If FIs conduct foreign business, they are subject to additional risks, namely, foreign exchange and sovereign risks. They incur market risk on their trading assets and liabilities if adverse movements in interest rates, exchange rates, or other asset prices occur. Modern-day FIs also engage in significant off-balance-sheet activities that expose them to off-balancesheet risks: contingent asset and liability risks. The advent of sophisticated technology and automation exposes FIs to both technological and operational risks. FI’s face insolvency risk when their capital is insufficient to withstand the losses that they incur as a result of such risks. The interaction of the various risks means that FI managers face making trade-offs among them. As they take actions in an attempt to affect one type of risk, FI managers must consider the possible impact on other risks. The effective management of these risks determines a modern FI’s success or failure. The chapters that follow analyze each of these risks in greater detail. Questions and Problems 1. What is the process of asset transformation performed by a financial institution? Why does this process often lead to the creation of interest rate risk? What is interest rate risk? 2. What is refinancing risk? How is refinancing risk part of interest rate risk? If an FI funds long-term assets with short-term liabilities, what will be the impact on earnings of an increase in the rate of interest? A decrease in the rate of interest? 3. What is reinvestment risk? How is reinvestment risk part of interest rate risk? If an FI funds short-term assets with long-term liabilities, what will be the impact on earnings of a decrease in the rate of interest? An increase in the rate of interest? 4. The sales literature of a mutual fund claims that the fund has no risk exposure since it invests exclusively in federal government securities which are free of default risk. Is this claim true? Explain why or why not. 5. How can interest rate risk adversely affect the economic or market value of an FI? 6. Consider an FI that issues $100 million of liabilities with one year to maturity to finance the purchase of $100 million of assets with a two-year maturity. Suppose that the cost of funds (liabilities) for the FI is 5 percent per year and the interest return on the assets is 8 percent per year. a. Calculate the FI’s profit spread and dollar value of profit in year 1. b. Calculate the profit spread and dollar value of profit in year 2 if the FI can refinance its liabilities at 5 percent. c. If interest rates rise and the FI can borrow new one-year liabilities at 9 percent in the second year, calculate the FI’s profit spread and dollar value of profit in year 2. d. If interest rates fall and the FI can borrow new one-year liabilities at 3 percent in the second year, calculate the FI’s profit spread and dollar value of profit in year 2. Chapter 7 Risks of Financial Institutions 191 7. Consider an FI that issues $200 million of liabilities with two years to maturity to finance the purchase of $200 million of assets with a one year maturity. Suppose that the cost of funds (liabilities) for the FI is 5 percent per year and the interest return on the assets is 9 percent per year. a. Calculate the FI’s profit spread and dollar value of profit in year 1. b. Calculate the profit spread and dollar value of profit in year 2 if the FI can reinvest its assets at 9 percent. c. If interest rates fall and the FI can invest in one-year assets at 6 percent in the second year, calculate the FI’s profit spread and dollar value of profit in year 2. d. If interest rates rise and the FI can invest in one-year assets at 11 percent in the second year, calculate the FI’s profit spread and dollar value of profit in year 2. 8. A financial institution has the following market value balance sheet structure: Cash Bond Total assets Liabilities and Equity $ 1,000 10,000 $11,000 Certificate of deposit Equity Total liabilities and equity $10,000 1,000 $11,000 a. The bond has a 10-year maturity, a fixed-rate coupon of 10 percent paid at the end of each year, and a par value of $10,000. The certificate of deposit has a 1-year maturity and a 6 percent fixed rate of interest. The FI expects no additional asset growth. What will be the net interest income at the end of the first year? Note: Net interest income equals interest income minus interest expense. b. If at the end of year 1, market interest rates have increased 100 basis points (1 percent), what will be the net interest income for the second year? Is this result caused by reinvestment risk or refinancing risk? c. Assuming that market interest rates increase 1 percent, the bond will have a value of $9,446 at the end of year 1. What will be the market value of equity for the FI? Assume that all of the NII in part (a) is used to cover operating expenses or dividends. d. If market interest rates had decreased 100 basis points by the end of year 1, would the market value of equity be higher or lower than $1,000? Why? e. What factors have caused the changes in operating performance and market value for this firm? 9. How does a policy of matching the maturities of assets and liabilities work (a) to minimize interest rate risk and (b) against the asset-transformation function of FIs? 10. Corporate bonds usually pay interest semiannually. If a company decided to change from semiannual to annual interest payments, how would this affect the bond’s interest rate risk? 11. Two 10-year bonds are being considered for an investment that may have to be liquidated before the maturity of the bonds. The first bond is a 10-year premium bond with a coupon rate higher than its required rate of return, and the second bond is a zero-coupon bond that pays only a lump-sum payment after 10 years with no interest over its life. Which bond would have more interest rate risk? That is, which bond’s price would change by a larger amount for a given change in interest rates? Explain your answer. www.mhhe.com/saunders8e Assets 192 Part One Introduction 12. Consider again the two bonds in problem 11. If the investment goal is to leave the assets untouched until maturity, such as for a child’s education or for one’s retirement, which of the two bonds has more interest rate risk? What is the source of this risk? 13. A money market mutual fund bought $1 million of two-year Treasury notes six months ago. During this time, the value of the securities has increased, but for tax reasons the mutual fund wants to postpone any sale for two more months. What type of risk does the mutual fund face for the next two months? 14. A bank invested $50 million in a two-year asset paying 10 percent interest per year and simultaneously issued a $50 million, one-year liability paying 8 percent interest per year. The liability will be rolled over after one year at the current market rate. What will be the impact on the bank’s net interest income if at the end of the first year all interest rates have increased by 1 percent (100 basis points)? 15. What is credit risk? Which types of FIs are more susceptible to this type of risk? Why? 16. What is the difference between firm-specific credit risk and systematic credit risk? How can an FI alleviate firm-specific credit risk? 17. Many banks and savings institutions that failed in the 1980s had made loans to oil companies in Louisiana, Texas, and Oklahoma. When oil prices fell, these companies, the regional economy, and the banks and savings institutions all experienced financial problems. What types of risk were inherent in the loans that were made by these banks and savings institutions? 18. What is liquidity risk? What routine operating factors allow FIs to deal with this risk in times of normal economic activity? What market reality can create severe financial difficulty for an FI in times of extreme liquidity crises? 19. Consider the simple FI balance sheet below (in millions of dollars). Before the Withdrawal Assets Cash assets Nonliquid Assets Liabilities/Equity $ 20 155 www.mhhe.com/saunders8e $175 Deposit Equity $150 25 $175 Suppose that depositors unexpectedly withdraw $50 million in deposits and the FI receives no new deposits to replace them. Assume that the FI cannot borrow any more funds in the short-term money markets, and because it cannot wait to get better prices for its assets in the future (as it needs the cash now to meet immediate depositor withdrawals), the FI has to sell any nonliquid assets at 75 cents on the dollar. Show the FI’s balance sheet after adjustments are made for the $50 million of deposit withdrawals. 20. What two factors provide potential benefits to FIs that expand their asset holdings and liability funding sources beyond their domestic borders? 21. What is foreign exchange risk? What does it mean for an FI to be net long in foreign assets? What does it mean for an FI to be net short in foreign assets? In each case, what must happen to the foreign exchange rate to cause the FI to suffer losses? Risks of Financial Institutions 193 22. If the Swiss franc is expected to depreciate in the near future, would a U.S.-based FI in Bern City prefer to be net long or net short in its asset positions? Discuss. 23. If international capital markets are well integrated and operate efficiently, will FIs be exposed to foreign exchange risk? What are the sources of foreign exchange risk for FIs? 24. If an FI has the same amount of foreign assets and foreign liabilities in the same currency, has that FI necessarily reduced the risk involved in these international transactions to zero? Explain. 25. A U.S. insurance company invests $1,000,000 in a private placement of British bonds. Each bond pays £300 in interest per year for 20 years. If the current exchange rate is £1.564/$, what is the nature of the insurance company’s exchange rate risk? Specifically, what type of exchange rate movement concerns this insurance company? 26. Assume that a bank has assets located in London that are worth £150 million on which it earns an average of 8 percent per year. The bank has £100 million in liabilities on which it pays an average of 6 percent per year. The current spot exchange rate is £1.50/$. a. If the exchange rate at the end of the year is £2.00/$, will the dollar have appreciated or depreciated against the pound? b. Given the change in the exchange rate, what is the effect in dollars on the net interest income from the foreign assets and liabilities? Note: The net interest income is interest income minus interest expense. c. What is the effect of the exchange rate change on the value of assets and liabilities in dollars? 27. Six months ago, Qualitybank issued a $100 million, one-year maturity CD denominated in euros. On the same date, $60 million was invested in a :-denominated loan and $40 million was invested in a U.S. Treasury bill. The exchange rate on this date was :1.5675/$. Assume no repayment of principal and an exchange rate today of :1.2540/$. a. What is the current value of the CD principal (in euros and dollars)? b. What is the current value of the euro-denominated loan principal (in dollars and euros)? c. What is the current value of the U.S. Treasury bill (in euros and dollars)? d. What is Qualitybank’s profit/loss from this transaction (in euros and dollars)? 28. Suppose you purchase a 10-year, AAA-rated Swiss bond for par that is paying an annual coupon of 6 percent. The bond has a face value of 1,000 Swiss francs (SF). The spot rate at the time of purchase is SF1.15/$. At the end of the year, the bond is downgraded to AA and the yield increases to 8 percent. In addition, the SF appreciates to SF1.05/$. a. What is the loss or gain to a Swiss investor who holds this bond for a year? What portion of this loss or gain is due to foreign exchange risk? What portion is due to interest rate risk? b. What is the loss or gain to a U.S. investor who holds this bond for a year? What portion of this loss or gain is due to foreign exchange risk? What portion is due to interest rate risk? 29. What is country or sovereign risk? What remedy does an FI realistically have in the event of a collapsing country or currency? 30. What is market risk? How does this risk affect the operating performance of financial institutions? What actions can be taken by an FI’s management to minimize the effects of this risk? www.mhhe.com/saunders8e Chapter 7 www.mhhe.com/saunders8e 194 Part One Introduction 31. What is the nature of an off-balance-sheet activity? How does an FI benefit from such activities? Identify the various risks that these activities generate for an FI, and explain how these risks can create varying degrees of financial stress for the FI at a later time. 32. What is technology risk? What is the difference between economies of scale and economies of scope? How can these economies create benefits for an FI? How can these economies prove harmful to an FI? 33. What is the difference between technology risk and operational risk? How does internationalizing the payments system among banks increase operational risk? 34. Why can insolvency risk be classified as a consequence or outcome of any or all of the other types of risks? 35. Discuss the interrelationships among the different sources of FI risk exposure. Why would the construction of an FI risk management model to measure and manage only one type of risk be incomplete? 36. Characterize the risk exposure(s) of the following FI transactions by choosing one or more of the risk types listed below: a. Interest rate risk b. Credit risk c. Off-balance-sheet risk d. Technology risk e. Foreign exchange risk f. Country or sovereign risk (1) A bank finances a $10 million, six-year fixed-rate commercial loan by selling one-year certificates of deposit. (2) An insurance company invests its policy premiums in a long-term municipal bond portfolio. (3) A French bank sells two-year fixed-rate notes to finance a two-year fixed-rate loan to a British entrepreneur. (4) A Japanese bank acquires an Austrian bank to facilitate clearing operations. (5) A mutual fund completely hedges its interest rate risk exposure by using forward contingent contracts. (6) A bond dealer uses his own equity to buy Mexican debt on the less developed country (LDC) bond market. (7) A securities firm sells a package of mortgage loans as mortgage-backed securities. 37. Consider these four types of risks: credit, foreign exchange, market, and sovereign. These risks can be separated into two pairs of risk types in which each pair consists of two related risk types, with one being a subset of the other. How would you pair off the risk types, and which risk type could be considered a subset of the other type in the pair? Part Two Measuring Risk 8. Interest Rate Risk I 196 9. Interest Rate Risk II 226 10. Credit Risk: Individual Loan Risk 274 11. Credit Risk: Loan Portfolio and Concentration Risk 326 12. Liquidity Risk 351 13. Foreign Exchange Risk 383 14. Sovereign Risk 412 15. Market Risk 438 16. Off-Balance-Sheet Risk 474 17. Technology and Other Operational Risks 503 Chapter Eight See Appendices Online at www.mhhe.com/saunders8e • Appendix 8A: The Maturity Model Interest Rate Risk I INTRODUCTION net worth The value of an FI to its owners; this is equal to the difference between the market value of assets and that of liabilities. www.federalreserve.gov www.bis.org 196 In Chapter 7 we established that while performing their asset-transformation functions, FIs often mismatch the maturities of their assets and liabilities. In so doing, they expose themselves to interest rate risk. For example, in the 1980s a large number of thrifts suffered economic insolvency (i.e., the net worth or equity of their owners was eradicated) when interest rates unexpectedly increased. All FIs tend to mismatch their balance sheet maturities to some degree. However, measuring interest rate risk exposure by looking only at the size of the maturity mismatch can be misleading. The next two chapters present techniques used by FIs to measure their interest rate risk exposures. This chapter begins with a discussion of the Federal Reserve’s monetary policy, which is a key determinant of interest rate risk. As we discuss later, in 2008–2014, the Fed, in an effort to address the severe financial crisis and the slowly improving economy afterward, dropped its target fed funds rate to a range between zero and a quarter of 1 percent and lowered its discount window rate to half a percent. Thus, at this time interest rate risk at FIs may be relatively low. However, as the economy recovers and/or inflation arises, interest rate risk will again become a significant risk for FIs to manage. The chapter also analyzes the simpler method used to measure an FI’s interest rate risk: the repricing model. The repricing, or funding gap, model concentrates on the impact of interest rate changes on an FI’s net interest income (NII), which is the difference between an FI’s interest income and interest expense. Because of its simplicity, smaller depository institutions (the vast majority of DIs) still use this model as their primary measure of interest rate risk. Until recently, U.S. bank regulators had been content to base their evaluations of bank interest rate risk exposures on the repricing model. As explained later in this chapter, however, the repricing model has some serious weaknesses. Appendix 8A, at the book’s website (www.mhhe.com/saunders8e), compares and contrasts this model with the market value–based maturity model. While rarely used anymore by FIs, the maturity model was a first attempt to include the impact of interest rate changes on the overall market value of an FI’s assets and liabilities and, ultimately, its net worth. In the early 2000s, the Bank for International Settlements Chapter 8 www.bis.org Interest Rate Risk I 197 (the organization of the world’s major Central Banks) issued a consultative document1 suggesting a standardized model be used by regulators in evaluating a bank’s interest rate risk exposure. The approach suggested is firmly based on market value accounting and the duration model (see Chapter 9). As regulators move to adopt these models, bigger banks (which hold the vast majority of total assets in the banking industry) have adopted them as their primary measure of interest rate risk. Moreover, where relevant, banks may be allowed to use their own market-value-based models (see Chapter 15) to assess the interest rate risk of the banking book. Appendix 8B, at the end of this chapter, looks at the term structure of interest rates that compares the market yields or interest rates on securities, assuming that all characteristics except maturity are the same. This topic is generally covered in introductory finance courses. For students needing a review, Appendix 8B is encouraged introductory reading. THE LEVEL AND MOVEMENT OF INTEREST RATES www.federalreserve.gov While many factors influence the level and movement of interest rates, it is the central bank’s monetary policy strategy that most directly underlies the level and movement of interest rates that, in turn, affect an FI’s cost of funds and return on assets. The central bank in the United States is the Federal Reserve (the Fed). Through its daily open market operations, such as buying and selling Treasury bonds and Treasury bills, the Fed seeks to influence the money supply, inflation, and the level of interest rates (particularly short-term interest rates). In turn, changing interest rates impact economic decisions, such as whether to consume or save. When the Fed finds it necessary to slow down the economy, it tightens monetary policy by raising interest rates. The normal result is a decrease in business and household spending (especially that financed by credit or borrowing). Conversely, if business and household spending declines to the extent that the Fed finds it necessary to stimulate the economy, it allows interest rates to fall (an expansionary monetary policy). The drop in rates promotes borrowing and spending. For example, in December 2008, as the U.S. economy fell into its deepest depression since the Great Depression, the Fed, in a historic move, unexpectedly announced that it would drop its target fed funds rate to a range between zero and a quarter of one percent and lower its discount window rate to a half a percent, the lowest level since the 1940s. Even through January 2012, because of the economy’s continued weakness, the Fed announced that it expected to keep fed fund rates below 1 percent until late 2014. Figure 8–1 shows the interest rate on U.S. threemonth T-bills for the period 1965–2012. While Federal Reserve actions are targeted mostly at short-term rates (especially the federal funds rate), changes in shortterm rates usually feed through to the whole term structure of interest rates. The linkages between short-term rates and long-term rates and theories of the term structure of interest rates are discussed in Appendix 8B to this chapter. 1 See Basel Committee on Banking Supervision, “Principles for the Management and Supervision of Interest Rate Risk,” Bank for International Settlements, Basel, Switzerland, January 2001. 198 Part Two Measuring Risk FIGURE 8–1 Interest Rate on U.S. 91-Day Treasury Bills, 1965–2012 Source: Federal Reserve Board website, various dates. www.federalreserve.gov Interest rate (%) 17 T-bill 16 15 14 13 12 11 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 Internet Exercise 1/1/11 1/1/09 1/1/07 1/1/05 1/1/03 1/1/01 1/1/99 1/1/97 1/1/95 1/1/93 1/1/91 1/1/89 1/1/87 1/1/85 1/1/83 1/1/81 1/1/79 1/1/77 1/1/75 1/1/73 1/1/71 1/1/69 1/1/67 1/1/65 0 Year Go to the Federal Reserve Board’s website at www.federalreserve.gov to find the latest information available on three-month Treasury bill rates using the following steps. Click on “Economic Research and Data.” Click on “Selected Interest Rates—H.15.” Click on “Current Release.” This will download the data onto your computer that will contain the most recent information on Treasury bill rates. In addition to the Fed’s impact on interest rates via its monetary policy strategy, the increased level of financial market integration over the last decade has also affected interest rates. Financial market integration increases the speed with which interest rate changes and associated volatility are transmitted among countries, making the control of U.S. interest rates by the Federal Reserve more difficult and less certain than before. The increased globalization of financial market flows in recent years has made the measurement and management of interest rate risk a prominent concern facing many modern FI managers. For example, investors across the world carefully evaluate the statements made by Ben Bernanke (chairman of the Federal Reserve Board of Governors) before Congress. Even hints of Chapter 8 Interest Rate Risk I 199 changes in U.S. interest rates may have a major effect on world interest rates (as well as foreign exchange rates and stock prices). The level and volatility of interest rates and the increase in worldwide financial market integration make the measurement and management of interest rate risk one of the key issues facing FI managers. Further, the Bank for International Settlements requires depository institutions (DIs) to have interest rate risk measurement systems that assess the effects of interest rate changes on both earnings and economic value. These systems should provide meaningful measures of a DI’s current levels of interest rate risk exposure and should be capable of identifying any excessive exposures that might arise (see Chapter 20). In this chapter and in Chapter 9, we analyze the different ways an FI might measure the exposure it faces in running a mismatched maturity book (or gap) between its assets and its liabilities in a world of interest rate volatility. In particular, we concentrate on three ways, or models, of measuring the asset– liability gap exposure of an FI: The repricing (or funding gap) model (in Chapter 8). The maturity model (in Appendix 8A at www.mhhe.com/saunders8e). The duration model (in Chapter 9). Concept Questions 1. How is the Federal Reserve’s monetary policy linked to the degree of interest rate uncertainty faced by FIs? 2. How has financial market integration affected interest rate movements? THE REPRICING MODEL repricing gap The difference between assets whose interest rates will be repriced or changed over some future period (rate-sensitive assets) and liabilities whose interest rates will be repriced or changed over some future period (ratesensitive liabilities). The repricing, or funding gap, model is a simple model used by small (thus most) FIs in the United States. This model is essentially a book value accounting cash flow analysis of the repricing gap between the interest income earned on an FI’s assets and the interest expense paid on its liabilities (or its net interest income) over a particular period of time. This contrasts with the market value–based maturity and duration models discussed in the appendix to this chapter and in Chapter 9. Under the repricing gap approach, commercial banks report quarterly on their call reports, interest-rate sensitivity reports which show the repricing gaps for assets and liabilities with various maturities: For example, rate-sensitive asset or liability 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. One day. More than one day to three months. More than three months to six months. More than six months to twelve months. More than one year to five years. More than five years. An asset or liability that is repriced at or near current market interest rates within a maturity bucket. A bank reports the gaps in each maturity bucket by calculating the rate sensitivity of each asset (RSA) and each liability (RSL) on its balance sheet. Rate sensitivity here means that the asset or liability is repriced at or near current market interest rates within a certain time horizon (or maturity bucket). Repricing can be the 200 Part Two Measuring Risk TABLE 8–1 Repricing Gap (in millions of dollars) 1. One day 2. More than one day–three months 3. More than three months–six months 4. More than six months–twelve months 5. More than one year–five years 6. Over five years refinancing risk The risk that the cost of rolling over or reborrowing funds will rise above the returns being earned on asset investments. reinvestment risk The risk that the returns on funds to be reinvested will fall below the cost of the funds. (1) (2) (3) Assets Liabilities Gaps (4) Cumulative Gap $ 20 30 70 90 40 10 $260 $ 30 40 85 70 30 5 $260 $10 10 15 20 10 5 $10 20 35 15 5 0 result of a rollover of an asset or liability (e.g., a loan is paid off at or prior to maturity and the funds are used to issue a new loan at current market rates), or it can occur because the asset or liability is a variable-rate instrument (e.g., a variable-rate mortgage whose interest rate is reset every quarter based on movements in a prime rate). Table 8–1 presents a simple interest rate sensitivity report showing the asset and liability repricing gaps of an FI, categorized into each of the six previously defined maturity buckets. The advantage of the repricing model lies in its information value and its simplicity in pointing to an FI’s net interest income exposure (or profit exposure) to interest rate changes in different maturity buckets. For example, suppose that an FI has a negative $10 million difference between its assets and liabilities being repriced in one day (one-day bucket). Assets and liabilities that are repriced each day are likely to be interbank borrowings on the federal funds or repurchase agreement market (see Chapter 2). Thus, a negative gap (RSA RSL) exposes the FI to refinancing risk, in that a rise in these short-term rates would lower the FI’s net interest income since the FI has more rate-sensitive liabilities than assets in this bucket. In other words, assuming equal changes in interest rates on RSAs and RSLs, interest expense will increase by more than interest revenue. Conversely, if the FI has a positive $20 million difference between its assets and liabilities being repriced in 6 months to 12 months, it has a positive gap (RSA RSL) for this period and is exposed to reinvestment risk, in that a drop in rates over this period would lower the FI’s net interest income; that is, interest income will decrease by more than interest expense. Specifically, let: NII i = Change in net interest income in maturity bucket i GAPi = Dollar size of the gap between the book value of rate-sensitive assets and rate-sensitive liabilities in maturity bucket i Ri = Change in the level of interest rates impacting assets and liabilities in the ith bucket Then: NII i (GAPi ) Ri (RSAi RSLi ) Ri In this first bucket, if the gap is negative $10 million and short-term interest rates (such as fed fund and/or repo rates) rise 1 percent, the annualized change in the FI’s future net interest income is: NII i ($10 million) 0.01 $100, 000 Chapter 8 Interest Rate Risk I 201 That is, the negative gap and associated refinancing risk results in a loss of $100,000 in net interest income for the FI. This approach is very simple and intuitive. Remember, however, from Chapter 7 and our overview of interest rate risk that capital or market value losses also occur when rates rise. The capital loss effect that is measured by both the maturity and duration models developed in Appendix A to this chapter and in Chapter 9 is not accounted for in the repricing model. The reason is that in the book value accounting world of the repricing model, asset and liability values are reported at their historic values or costs. Thus, interest rate changes affect only current interest income or interest expense—that is, net interest income on the FI’s income statement—rather than the market value of assets and liabilities on the balance sheet.2 The FI manager can also estimate cumulative gaps (CGAPs) over various repricing categories or buckets. A common cumulative gap of interest is the oneyear repricing gap estimated from Table 8–1 as: CGAP ($10) ($10) ($15) $20 $15 million If ΔRi is the average interest rate change affecting assets and liabilities that can be repriced within a year, the cumulative effect on the bank’s net interest income is:3 NII i (CGAP) Ri ($15 million) (0.01) $150, 000 (1) We can now look at how an FI manager would calculate the cumulative oneyear gap from a balance sheet. Remember that the manager asks: Will or can this asset or liability have its interest rate changed within the next year? If the answer is yes, it is a rate-sensitive asset or liability. If the answer is no, it is not rate sensitive. Consider the simplified balance sheet facing the FI manager in Table 8–2. Instead of the original maturities, the maturities are those remaining on different assets and liabilities at the time the repricing gap is estimated. Rate-Sensitive Assets Looking down the asset side of the balance sheet in Table 8–2, we see the following one-year rate-sensitive assets (RSAs): 1. Short-term consumer loans: $50 million. These are repriced at the end of the year and just make the one-year cutoff. 2. Three-month T-bills: $30 million. These are repriced on maturity (rollover) every three months. 3. Six-month T-notes: $35 million. These are repriced on maturity (rollover) every six months. 4. 30-year floating-rate mortgages: $40 million. These are repriced (i.e., the mortgage rate is reset) every nine months. Thus, these long-term assets are rate-sensitive assets in the context of the repricing model with a one-year repricing horizon. 2 For example, a 30-year bond purchased 10 years ago when rates were 13 percent would be reported as having the same book (accounting) value as when rates are 7 percent. Using market value, gains and losses to asset and liability values would be reflected in the balance sheet as rates change. 3 Note that a change in the dollar value and mix of rate-sensitive assets and liabilities (or a change in CGAP) also affects the FI’s net income. 202 Part Two Measuring Risk TABLE 8–2 Assets Simple FI Balance Sheet (in millions of dollars) 1. Short-term consumer loans (one-year maturity) 2. Long-term consumer loans (two-year maturity) 3. Three-month Treasury bills 4. Six-month Treasury notes 5. Three-year Treasury bonds 6. 10-year, fixed-rate mortgages 7. 30-year, floating-rate mortgages (rate adjusted every nine months) Liabilities $ 50 1. Equity capital (fixed) $ 20 25 2. Demand deposits 40 30 35 70 20 3. Passbook savings 4. Three-month CDs 5. Three-month bankers acceptances 6. Six-month commercial paper 7. One-year time deposits 30 40 20 60 20 40 8. Two-year time deposits $270 40 $270 Summing these four items produces total one-year rate-sensitive assets (RSAs) of $155 million. The remaining $115 million of assets are not rate sensitive over the one-year repricing horizon—that is, a change in the level of interest rates will not affect the size of the interest income generated by these assets over the next year.4 Although the $115 million in long-term consumer loans, 3-year Treasury bonds, and 10-year, fixed-rate mortgages generate interest income, the size of income generated will not change over the next year, since the interest rates on these assets are not expected to change (i.e., they are fixed over the next year). Rate-Sensitive Liabilities Looking down the liability side of the balance sheet in Table 8–2, we see the following liability items clearly fit the one-year rate or repricing sensitivity test: 1. Three-month CDs: $40 million. These mature in three months and are repriced on rollover. 2. Three-month bankers acceptances: $20 million. These also mature in three months and are repriced on rollover. 3. Six-month commercial paper: $60 million. These mature and are repriced every six months. 4. One-year time deposits: $20 million. These get repriced right at the end of the oneyear gap horizon. Summing these four items produces one-year rate-sensitive liabilities (RSLs) of $140 million. The remaining $130 million is not rate sensitive over the one-year period. The $20 million in equity capital and $40 million in demand deposits (see the following discussion) do not pay interest and are therefore classified as noninterest-paying. The $30 million in passbook savings (see the following discussion) and $40 million in two-year time deposits generate interest expense over the next year, but the level of the interest expense generated will not change if the general level of interest rates changes. Thus, we classify these items as rateinsensitive liabilities. 4 We are assuming that the assets are noncallable over the year and that there will be no prepayments (runoffs, see below) on the mortgages within a year. Chapter 8 Interest Rate Risk I 203 Note that demand deposits (or transaction accounts in general) are not included as RSLs. We can make strong arguments for and against their inclusion as ratesensitive liabilities. Against Inclusion core deposits Those deposits that act as an FI’s longterm sources of funds. The explicit interest rate on demand deposits is zero by regulation. Further, although explicit interest is paid on transaction accounts such as NOW accounts, the rates paid by FIs do not fluctuate directly with changes in the general level of interest rates (particularly when the general level of rates is rising). Moreover, many demand deposits act as core deposits for FIs, meaning they are a long-term source of funds. For Inclusion Even though they pay no explicit interest, demand deposits pay implicit interest because FIs do not charge fees that fully cover their costs for checking services. Further, if interest rates rise, individuals draw down (or run off) their demand deposits, forcing the bank to replace them with higher yielding, interest bearing, rate-sensitive funds. This is most likely to occur when the interest rates on alternative instruments are high. In such an environment, the opportunity cost of holding funds in demand deposit accounts is likely to be larger than it is in a low–interest rate environment. Similar arguments for and against inclusion of retail passbook savings accounts can be made. Although Federal Reserve Regulation Q ceilings on the maximum rates to be charged for these accounts were abolished in March 1986, banks still adjust these rates only infrequently. However, savers tend to withdraw funds from these accounts when rates rise, forcing banks into more expensive fund substitutions.5 The four repriced liabilities ($40 $20 $60 $20) sum to $140 million, and the four repriced assets ($50 $30 $35 $40) sum to $155 million. Given this, the cumulative one-year repricing gap (CGAP) for the bank is: CGAP One-year rate-sensitive assets One-year rate-sensitive liabilities RSA RSL $155 million $140 million $15 million Often FIs express interest rate sensitivity as a percentage of assets (A): CGAP $15 million 0.056 5.6% A $270 million Expressing the repricing gap in this way is useful since it tells us (1) the direction of the interest rate risk exposure (positive or negative CGAP) and (2) the scale of that exposure as indicated by dividing the gap by the asset size of the institution. In our example the FI has 5.6 percent more RSAs than RSLs in one-year-andless buckets as a percentage of total assets. Alternatively, FIs calculate a gap ratio defined as rate-sensitive assets divided by rate-sensitive liabilities. A gap ratio 5 The Federal Reserve’s repricing report has traditionally viewed transaction accounts and passbook savings accounts as rate-insensitive liabilities, as we have done in this example. However, with the growth of the Internet and competition from money market mutual funds, the mobility of these funds is highly sensitive to (relative) rates paid by banks versus other nonbank FIs (such as money market mutual funds). 204 Part Two Measuring Risk greater than 1 indicates that there are more rate sensitive assets than liabilities (similar to a gap 0). Thus, the FI is set to see increases in net interest income when interest rates increase. A gap ratio less than 1 indicates that there are more rate sensitive liabilities than assets (similar to a gap 0). Thus, the FI is set to see increases in net interest income when interest rates decrease. In our example, the gap ratio is 1.107 meaning that in the one-year-and-less time bucket, the FI has $1.107 of RSAs for every $1 of RSLs. Table 8–3 shows an interest rate sensitivity report for Harleysville Savings Financial Corp. (headquartered in Harleysville, Pennsylvania) for 2011. In this report, Harleysville reports the repricing gap for periods ranging from one to five years. The choice of time horizon used to measure interest rate risk is critical to managing this risk. An excessively long repricing period includes many securities that are repriced at different times within the repricing period. That is, it overstates the rate sensitivity of the balance sheet and leaves the FI exposed to interest rate risk. For example, consider a bank that measures interest rate risk exposure over a oneyear time horizon only and has a repricing gap of $0 over the one year. However, if the bank has $50 million more RSAs than RSLs that are repriced in the first six months of the year and $50 million more liabilities than assets that are repriced over the last six months, it would be exposed to changes in interest rates occurring within the year. In its gap analysis, the bank would show a zero repricing gap for the year [50 (50) 0]. But the bank’s assets and liabilities are mismatched within the bucket, and therefore, the bank is exposed to interest rate risk. Clearly, the shorter the range over which bucket gaps are calculated, the smaller is this problem. Conversely, an excessively short repricing period omits consideration of the interest rate risk exposure of assets and liabilities are that repriced in the period immediately following the end of the repricing period. That is, it understates the rate sensitivity of the balance sheet. Equal Changes in Rates on RSAs and RSLs The CGAP provides a measure of an FI’s interest rate sensitivity. Table 8–4 highlights the relation between CGAP and changes in NII when interest rate changes for RSAs are equal to interest rate changes for RSLs. For example, when CGAP is positive (or the FI has more RSAs than RSLs), NII will rise when interest rates rise (row 1, Table 8–4), since interest income increases more than interest expense does. EXAMPLE 8–1 Impact of Rate Changes on Net Interest Income When CGAP Is Positive Suppose that, for the FI depicted in Table 8–2, interest rates rise by 1 percent on both RSAs and RSLs. The CGAP would project the expected annual change in net interest income (∆NII) of the FI as: NII (RSA R ) (RSL R ) CGAP R ($155 million 0.01) ($140 million 0.01) ($15 million) 0.01 ($1.55 million $1.40 million) $150,000 Similarly, if interest rates fall equally for RSAs and RSLs (row 2, Table 8–4), NII will fall when CGAP is positive. As rates fall, interest income falls by more than interest expense. Thus, NII falls. Suppose that for our FI, rates fall by 1 percent. The CGAP predicts that NII will fall by: NII ($155 million ( 0.01)) ($140 million ( 0.01)) $15 million 0.01 $1.55 million ($1.40 million) $150,000 Chapter 8 TABLE 8–3 Interest Rate Risk I 205 Harleysville Savings Financial Corp., Interest Rate Sensitivity Report, 2011 Source: Harleysville Savings Financial, Form 10-K, 2011. 1 Year or less 1 to 3 Years 3 to 5 Years Over 5 Years Total (In Thousands) Interest-earning assets: Mortgage loans Commercial loans Mortgage-backed securities Consumer and other loans Investment securities and other investments $ 56,557 49,658 55,908 68,042 80,462 $ 59,050 17,216 41,406 9,690 23,846 $ 46,569 14,329 23,289 4,552 21,445 $180,021 16,144 29,944 4,373 5,806 $342,197 97,347 150,547 86,657 131,559 Total interest-earning assets 310,627 151,208 110,184 236,288 808,307 Interest-bearing liabilities: Passbook and Club accounts NOW and interest-bearing checking accounts Consumer Money Market Deposit accounts Business Money Market Deposit accounts Certificate accounts Borrowed money 401 6,931 53,172 17,563 126,177 57,708 — — — — 124,560 59,253 — — — — 44,713 26,389 3,793 62,379 58,021 5,855 — 106,844 4,194 69,310 111,193 23,418 295,450 250,194 236,892 753,759 Total interest-bearing liabilities 261,952 183,813 71,102 Repricing GAP during the period $ 48,675 $(32,605) $ 39,082 $ Cumulative GAP (604) $ 54,548 $ 48,675 $ 16,070 $ 55,152 $ 54,548 Ratio of GAP during the period to total assets 5.82% 3.90% 4.68% 0.07% Ratio of cumulative GAP to total assets 5.82% 1.92% 6.60% 6.53% CGAP effects The relations between changes in interest rates and changes in net interest income. It is evident from this equation that the larger the absolute value of CGAP, the larger the expected change in NII (i.e., the larger the increase or decrease in the FI’s interest income relative to interest expense). In general, when CGAP is positive, the change in NII is positively related to the change in interest rates. Thus, an FI would want its CGAP to be positive when interest rates are expected to rise. Conversely, when CGAP is negative, if interest rates rise by equal amounts for RSAs and RSLs (row 3, Table 8–4), NII will fall (since the FI has more RSLs than RSAs). If interest rates fall equally for RSAs and RSLs (row 4, Table 8–4), NII will increase when CGAP is negative. As rates fall, interest expense decreases by more than interest income. In general then, when CGAP is negative, the change in NII is negatively related to the change in interest rates. Thus, an FI would want its CGAP to be negative when interest rates are expected to fall. We refer to these relationships as CGAP effects. Unequal Changes in Rates on RSAs and RSLs The previous section considered changes in net interest income as interest rates changed, assuming that the change in rates on RSAs was exactly equal to the change in rates on RSLs (in other words, assuming the interest rate spread between rates on RSAs and RSLs remained unchanged). This is not often the case. Rather, rate changes on RSAs generally differ from those on RSLs (i.e., the spread between interest rates on assets and liabilities change along with the levels of these rates). See Figure 8–2, 206 Part Two Measuring Risk TABLE 8–4 Impact of CGAP on the Relation between Changes in Interest Rates and Changes in Net Interest Income, Assuming Rate Changes for RSAs Equal Rate Changes and RSLs spread effect The effect that a change in the spread between rates on RSAs and RSLs has on net interest income as interest rates change. EXAMPLE 8–2 Impact of Spread Effect on Net Interest Income Row CGAP Change in Interest Rates Change in Interest Income Change in Interest Expense Change in NII 1 2 0 0 ⇑ ⇓ ⇑ ⇓ ⇑ ⇓ ⇑ ⇓ 3 4 0 0 ⇑ ⇓ ⇑ ⇓ ⇑ ⇓ ⇓ ⇑ which plots quarterly CD rates (liabilities) and prime lending rates (assets) for the period 1990–2012. Notice that although the rates generally move in the same direction, they are not perfectly correlated. In this case, as we consider the impact of rate changes on NII, we have a spread effect in addition to the CGAP effect. If the spread between the rate on RSAs and RSLs increases, when interest rates rise (fall), interest income increases (decreases) by more (less) than interest expense. The result is an increase in NII. Conversely, if the spread between the rates on RSAs and RSLs decreases, when interest rates rise (fall), interest income increases (decreases) less (more) than interest expense, and NII decreases. In general, the spread effect is such that, regardless of the direction of the change in interest rates, a positive relation exists between changes in the spread (between rates on RSAs and RSLs) and changes in NII. Whenever the spread increases (decreases), NII increases (decreases). To understand spread effect, assume for a moment that RSAs equal RSLs equal $155 million. Suppose that rates rise by 1.2 percent on RSAs and by 1 percent on RSLs (i.e., the spread between the rates on RSAs and RSLs increases by 1.2 percent 1 percent 0.2 percent). The resulting change in NII is calculated as: NII (RSA RRSA ) (RSL RRSL ) Interest revenue Interest expense ($155 million 1.2%) ($155 million 1.0%) $155 million (1.2% 1.0%) $310,000 (2) See Table 8–5 for various combinations of CGAP and spread changes and their effects on NII. The first four rows in Table 8–5 consider an FI with a positive CGAP; the last four rows consider an FI with a negative CGAP. Notice in Table 8–5 that both the CGAP and spread effects can have the same effect on NII. For example, in row 6 of Table 8–5, if CGAP is negative and interest rates increase, the CGAP effect says NII will decrease. If, at the same time, the spread between RSAs and RSLs decreases as interest rates increase, the spread effect also says NII will decrease. In these cases, FI managers can accurately predict the direction of the change in NII as interest rates change. When the two work in opposite directions, however, the change in NII cannot be predicted without knowing the size of the CGAP and expected change in the spread. For example, in row 5 of Table 8–5, if CGAP is negative and interest rates increase, the CGAP effect says NII will decrease. If, at the same time, the spread between RSAs and RSLs increases as interest rates increase, the spread effect says NII will increase. Chapter 8 FIGURE 8–2 Yield (%) Three-Month CD Rates versus Prime Rates for 1990–2012 12 Source: Federal Reserve Bulletin, various issues. www.federalreserve.gov Interest Rate Risk I 207 Prime (RSA) CD (RSL) 10 8 6 4 2 Impact of CGAP on the Relation between Changes in Interest Rates and Changes in Net Interest Income, Allowing for Different Rate Changes for RSAs and RSLs EXAMPLE 8–3 Combined Impact of CGAP and Spread Effect on Net Interest Income -1 2 Year Ja n 8 -1 0 Ja n -0 6 Ja n Ja n -0 -0 4 2 Ja n 0 -0 Ja n 8 -0 Ja n -9 6 TABLE 8–5 Ja n 4 -9 Ja n 2 -9 Ja n -9 Ja n Ja n -9 0 0 Change in Interest Rates Change in Spread NII 0 0 0 0 ⇑ ⇑ ⇓ ⇓ ⇑ ⇓ ⇑ ⇓ ⇑ ⇑⇓ ⇑⇓ ⇓ 0 0 0 0 ⇑ ⇑ ⇓ ⇓ ⇑ ⇓ ⇑ ⇓ ⇑⇓ ⇓ ⇑ ⇑⇓ Row CGAP 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 Suppose that for the FI in Table 8–2, interest rates fall by 1 percent on RSAs and by 1.2 percent on RSLs. Now the change in NII is calculated as: NII [$155 million (0.01)] [$140 million (0.012)] $1.55 million ($1.68 million) $0.13 million or $130,000 Even though the CGAP effect (i.e., RSA RSL) is putting negative pressure on NII (in Example 8–1, the CGAP effect of a 1 percent decrease in the rate on both RSAs and RSLs produced a decrease in NII of $150,000), the increase in the spread, and the resulting spread effect, is so big that NII increases by $130,000. Some FIs accept quite large interest rate exposures relative to their asset sizes. For example, the one-year repricing gap to total assets ratio of Harleysville Savings Financial Corporation (Harleysville, Pennsylvania) was 5.82 percent at the end of 2011 and the five-year gap to total assets ratio was 6.60 percent (i.e., it had more RSAs than RSLs). If interest rates rose in 2012, Harleysville Savings was set up to see net interest income increases due to the repricing of its large amount of 208 Part Two Measuring Risk RSAs (relative to RSLs) at higher rates. Thus, Harleysville’s management set its balance sheet up in expectation of interest rate increases over the next five years. Conversely, HopFed Bancorp (headquartered in Hopkinsville, Kentucky) reported a one-year repricing gap to total assets ratio of 5.69 percent and a five-year ratio of 6.98 percent. Thus, HopFed was set up to see net interest income increases at lower interest rates. That is, HopFed’s management set its balance sheet up in expectation of interest rate decreases over the next five years. The repricing gap is the measure of interest rate risk historically used by FIs, and it is still the main measure of interest rate risk used by small community banks and thrifts. In contrast to the market value–based models of interest rate risk discussed in Appendix A to this chapter and in Chapter 9, the repricing gap model is conceptually easy to understand and can easily be used to forecast changes in profitability for a given change in interest rates. The repricing gap can be used to allow an FI to structure its assets and liabilities or to go off the balance sheet to take advantage of a projected interest rate change. However, the repricing gap model has some major weaknesses that have resulted in regulators’ calling for the use of more comprehensive models (e.g., the duration gap model) to measure interest rate risk. We next discuss some of the major weaknesses of the repricing model. Concept Questions 1. Summarize the case for and against the inclusion of demand deposits as a ratesensitive liability. 2. How can FIs change the size and the direction of their repricing gap? 3. Why is it useful to express the repricing gap in terms of a percentage of assets? What specific information does this provide? WEAKNESSES OF THE REPRICING MODEL Despite the fact that this model of interest rate risk is used by the vast majority of depository institutions in the United States, the repricing model has four major shortcomings: (1) It ignores market value effects of interest rate changes, (2) it is overaggregative, (3) it fails to deal with the problem of rate-insensitive asset and liability runoffs and prepayments, and (4) it ignores cash flows from off-balancesheet activities. In this section we discuss each of these weaknesses in more detail. Market Value Effects As was discussed in the overview of FI risks (Chapter 7), interest rate changes have a market value effect in addition to an income effect on asset and liability values. That is, the present values of the cash flows on assets and liabilities change, in addition to the immediate interest received or paid on them, as interest rates change. In fact, the present values (and where relevant, the market prices) of virtually all assets and liabilities on an FI’s balance sheet change as interest rates change. The repricing model ignores the market value effect—implicitly assuming a book value accounting approach. As such, the repricing gap is only a partial measure of the true interest rate risk exposure of an FI. As we discuss the market value–based measures of interest rate risk (in Appendix A and in Chapter 9), we highlight the impact that ignoring the market value effect has on the ability to accurately measure the overall interest rate risk of an FI. Chapter 8 Interest Rate Risk I 209 Overaggregation The problem of defining buckets over a range of maturities ignores information regarding the distribution of assets and liabilities within those buckets. For example, the dollar values of RSAs and RSLs within any maturity bucket range may be equal. However, on average, liabilities may be repriced toward the end of the bucket’s range, while assets may be repriced toward the beginning, in which case a change in interest rates will have an effect on asset and liability cash flows that will not be accurately measured by the repricing gap approach. Look at the simple example for the three-month to six-month bucket in Figure 8–3. Note that $50 million more RSAs than RSLs are repriced between months 3 and 4, while $50 million more RSLs than RSAs are repriced between months 5 and 6. The FI in its interest rate sensitivity report would show a zero repricing gap for the threemonth to six-month bucket [50 (50) 0]. But as you can easily see, the FI’s assets and liabilities are mismatched within the bucket. Clearly, the shorter the range over which bucket gaps are calculated, the smaller this problem is. If an FI manager calculated one-day bucket gaps out into the future, this would give a more accurate picture of the net interest income exposure to rate changes. Reportedly, many large FIs have internal systems that indicate their repricing gaps on any given day in the future (252 days’ time, 1,329 days’ time, etc.). This suggests that although regulators examine the reporting of repricing gaps over only relatively wide maturity bucket ranges, FI managers could set in place internal information systems to report the daily future patterns of such gaps. The Problem of Runoffs In the simple repricing model discussed earlier, we assumed that all consumer loans matured in 1 year or that all conventional mortgages matured in 30 years. In reality, the FI continuously originates and retires consumer and mortgage loans as it creates and retires deposits. For example, today, some 30-year original maturity mortgages may have only 1 year left before they mature; that is, they are in their 29th year. In addition, these loans may be listed as 30-year mortgages (and included as not rate sensitive), yet they will sometimes be prepaid early as mortgage holders refinance their mortgages and/or sell their houses. Thus, the resulting proceeds will be reinvested at current market rates within the year. In addition, even if an FIGURE 8–3 The Overaggregation Problem: The Three-Month to SixMonth Bucket RSA-RSL 150 0 1 250 RSA-RSL 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Months 210 Part Two Measuring Risk runoff Periodic cash flow of interest and principal amortization payments on long-term assets, such as conventional mortgages, that can be reinvested at market rates. asset or liability is rate insensitive, virtually all assets and liabilities (e.g., long-term mortgages) pay some principal and/or interest back to the FI in any given year. As a result, the FI receives a runoff cash flow from its rate-insensitive portfolio that can be reinvested at current market rates. That is, this runoff cash flow component of a rate-insensitive asset or liability is itself rate sensitive. The FI manager can deal easily with this in the repricing model by identifying for each asset and liability item the estimated dollar cash flow that will run off within the next year and adding these amounts to the value of rate sensitive assets and liabilities. Cash Flows from Off-Balance-Sheet Activities The RSAs and RSLs used in the repricing model generally include only the assets and liabilities listed on the balance sheet. Changes in interest rates will affect the cash flows on many off-balance-sheet instruments as well. For example, an FI might have hedged its interest rate risk with an interest rate futures contract (see Chapter 22). As interest rates change, these futures contracts—as part of the marking-to-market process—produce a daily cash flow (either positive or negative) for the FI that may offset any on-balance-sheet gap exposure. These offsetting cash flows from futures contracts are ignored by the simple repricing model and should (and could) be included in the model. www.mhhe.com/saunders8e Concept Questions 1. What are four major weaknesses of the repricing model? 2. What does runoff mean? Summary This chapter introduced a method of measuring an FI’s interest rate risk exposure: the repricing model. The repricing model looks at the difference, or gap, between an FI’s rate-sensitive assets and rate-sensitive liabilities to measure interest rate risk. The chapter showed that the repricing model has difficulty in accurately measuring the interest rate risk of an FI. In particular, the repricing model ignores the market value effects of interest rate changes. More complete and accurate measures of an FI’s exposure are duration and the duration gap, which are explained in the next chapter. Questions and Problems 1. How do monetary policy actions made by the Federal Reserve impact interest rates? 2. How has the increased level of financial market integration affected interest rates? 3. What is the repricing gap? In using this model to evaluate interest rate risk, what is meant by rate sensitivity? On what financial performance variable does the repricing model focus? Explain. 4. What is a maturity bucket in the repricing model? Why is the length of time selected for repricing assets and liabilities important in using the repricing model? 5. What is the CGAP effect? According to the CGAP effect, what is the relation between changes in interest rates and changes in net interest income when CGAP is positive? When CGAP is negative? 6. Which of the following is an appropriate change to make on a bank’s balance sheet when GAP is negative, spread is expected to remain unchanged, and interest rates are expected to rise? a. Replace fixed-rate loans with rate-sensitive loans. b. Replace marketable securities with fixed-rate loans. Chapter 8 Interest Rate Risk I 211 c. Replace fixed-rate CDs with rate-sensitive CDs. d. Replace equity with demand deposits. e. Replace vault cash with marketable securities. 7. If a bank manager was quite certain that interest rates were going to rise within the next six months, how should the bank manager adjust the bank’s six-month repricing gap to take advantage of this anticipated rise? What if the manager believed rates would fall in the next six months? 8. Consider the following balance sheet positions for a financial institution: • Rate-sensitive assets $200 million Rate-sensitive liabilities $100 million • Rate-sensitive assets $100 million Rate-sensitive liabilities $150 million • Rate-sensitive assets $150 million Rate-sensitive liabilities $140 million a. Calculate the repricing gap and the impact on net interest income of a 1 percent increase in interest rates for each position. b. Calculate the impact on net interest income of each of the above situations, assuming a 1 percent decrease in interest rates. c. What conclusion can you draw about the repricing model from these results? 9. Consider the following balance sheet for MMC Bancorp (in millions of dollars): 1. Cash and due from 2. Short-term consumer loans (one-year maturity) 3. Long-term consumer loans (two-year maturity) 4. Three-month T-bills 5. Six-month T-notes 6. Three-year T-bonds 7. 10-year, fixed-rate mortgages 8. 30-year, floating-rate mortgages 9. Premises Liabilities $ 6.25 62.50 31.25 37.50 43.75 75.00 25.00 50.00 6.25 $337.50 1. Equity capital (fixed) $ 25.00 2. Demand deposits 50.00 3. Passbook savings 4. Three-month CDs 5. Three-month bankers’ acceptances 6. Six-month commercial paper 7. One-year time deposits 8. Two-year time deposits 37.50 50.00 25.00 75.00 25.00 50.00 $337.50 a. Calculate the value of MMC’s rate-sensitive assets, rate-sensitive liabilities, and repricing gap over the next year. b. Calculate the expected change in the net interest income for the bank if interest rates rise by 1 percent on both RSAs and RSLs. If interest rates fall by 1 percent on both RSAs and RSLs. c. Calculate the expected change in the net interest income for the bank if interest rates rise by 1.2 percent on RSAs and by 1 percent on RSLs. If interest rates fall by 1.2 percent on RSAs and by 1 percent on RSLs. 10. What are the reasons for not including demand deposits as rate-sensitive liabilities in the repricing analysis for a commercial bank? What is the subtle but potentially strong reason for including demand deposits in the total of rate sensitive liabilities? Can the same argument be made for passbook savings accounts? www.mhhe.com/saunders8e Assets 212 Part Two Measuring Risk 11. What is the gap to total assets ratio? What is the value of this ratio to interest rate risk managers and regulators? 12. Which of the following assets or liabilities fit the one-year rate or repricing sensitivity test? 3-month U.S. Treasury bills 1-year U.S. Treasury notes 20-year U.S. Treasury bonds 20-year floating-rate corporate bonds with annual repricing 30-year floating-rate mortgages with repricing every two years 30-year floating-rate mortgages with repricing every six months Overnight fed funds 9-month fixed-rate CDs 1-year fixed-rate CDs 5-year floating-rate CDs with annual repricing Common stock 13. What is the spread effect? 14. A bank manager is quite certain that interest rates are going to fall within the next six months. How should the bank manager adjust the bank’s six-month repricing gap and spread to take advantage of this anticipated rise? What if the manager believes rates will rise in the next six months? 15. Consider the following balance sheet for WatchoverU Savings Inc. (in millions): Assets Floating-rate mortgages (currently 10% annually) 30-year fixed-rate loans (currently 7% annually) www.mhhe.com/saunders8e Total assets Liabilities and Equity $ 50 50 $100 1-year time deposits (currently 6% annually) 3-year time deposits (currently 7% annually) Equity Total liabilities and equity $ 70 20 10 $100 a. What is WatchoverU’s expected net interest income at year-end? b. What will net interest income be at year-end if interest rates rise 2 percent? c. Using the cumulative repricing gap model, what is the expected net interest income for a 2 percent increase in interest rates? d. What will net interest income be at year-end if interest rates on RSAs increase by 2 percent but interest rates on RSLs increase by 1 percent? Is it reasonable for changes in interest rates on RSAs and RSLs to differ? Why? 16. Use the following information about a hypothetical government security dealer named M. P. Jorgan. Market yields are in parentheses, and amounts are in millions. Assets Cash 1-month T-bills (7.05%) 3-month T-bills (7.25%) 2-year T-notes (7.50%) 8-year T-notes (8.96%) 5-year munis (floating rate) (8.20% reset every 6 months) Total assets Liabilities and Equity $ 10 75 75 50 100 Overnight repos Subordinated debt 7-year fixed rate (8.55%) $170 150 25 $335 Equity Total liabilities and equity 15 $335 Chapter 8 Interest Rate Risk I 213 a. What is the repricing gap if the planning period is 30 days? 3 months? 2 years? Recall that cash is a non-interest-earning asset. b. What is the impact over the next 30 days on net interest income if interest rates increase 50 basis points? Decrease 75 basis points? c. The following one-year runoffs are expected: $10 million for two-year T-notes and $20 million for eight-year T-notes. What is the one-year repricing gap? d. If runoffs are considered, what is the effect on net interest income at year end if interest rates increase 50 basis points? Decrease 75 basis points? 17. A bank has the following balance sheet: Assets Rate sensitive Fixed rate Nonearning Total $ 550,000 755,000 265,000 $1,570,000 Avg. Rate 7.75% 8.75 Liabilities/Equity Rate sensitive Fixed rate Nonpaying Total $ 375,000 805,000 390,000 $1,570,000 Avg. Rate 6.25% 7.50 Suppose interest rates rise such that the average yield on rate-sensitive assets increases by 45 basis points and the average yield on rate-sensitive liabilities increases by 35 basis points. a. Calculate the bank’s CGAP, gap to total assets ratio, and gap ratio. b. Assuming the bank does not change the composition of its balance sheet, calculate the resulting change in the bank’s interest income, interest expense, and net interest income. c. Explain how the CGAP and spread effects influenced the change in net interest income. 18. A bank has the following balance sheet: Rate sensitive Fixed rate Nonearning Total $ 550,000 755,000 265,000 $1,570,000 Avg. Rate 7.75% 8.75 Liabilities/Equity Rate sensitive Fixed rate Nonpaying Total $ 575,000 605,000 390,000 $1,570,000 Avg. Rate 6.25% 7.50 Suppose interest rates fall such that the average yield on rate-sensitive assets decreases by 15 basis points and the average yield on rate-sensitive liabilities decreases by 5 basis points. a. Calculate the bank’s CGAP, gap to total assets ratio, and gap ratio. b. Assuming the bank does not change the composition of its balance sheet, calculate the resulting change in the bank’s interest income, interest expense, and net interest income. c. The bank’s CGAP is negative and interest rates decreased, yet net interest income decreased. Explain how the CGAP and spread effects influenced this decrease in net interest income. www.mhhe.com/saunders8e Assets 214 Part Two Measuring Risk 19. The balance sheet of A. G. Fredwards, a government security dealer, is listed below. Market yields are in parentheses, and amounts are in millions. Assets Cash 1-month T-bills (7.05%) 3-month T-bills (7.25%) 2-year T-notes (7.50%) 8-year T-notes (8.96%) 5-year munis (floating rate) (8.20% reset every 6 months) Total assets Liabilities and Equity $ 20 150 150 100 200 Overnight repos Subordinated debt 7-year fixed rate (8.55%) $340 50 $670 Equity Total liabilities and equity 30 $670 300 a. What is the repricing gap if the planning period is 30 days? 3 months? 2 years? b. What is the impact over the next three months on net interest income if interest rates on RSAs increase 50 basis points and on RSLs increase 60 basis points? c. What is the impact over the next two years on net interest income if interest rates on RSAs increase 50 basis points and on RSLs increase 75 basis points? d. Explain the difference in your answers to parts (b) and (c). Why is one answer a negative change in NII, while the other is positive? 20. A bank has the following balance sheet: Assets www.mhhe.com/saunders8e Rate sensitive Fixed rate Nonearning Total Avg. Rate $225,000 550,000 120,000 $895,000 6.35% 7.55 Liabilities/Equity Rate sensitive Fixed rate Nonpaying Total $300,000 505,000 90,000 $895,000 Avg. Rate 4.25% 6.15 Suppose interest rates rise such that the average yield on rate-sensitive assets increases by 45 basis points and the average yield on rate-sensitive liabilities increases by 35 basis points. a. Calculate the bank’s repricing GAP. b. Assuming the bank does not change the composition of its balance sheet, calculate the net interest income for the bank before and after the interest rate changes. What is the resulting change in net interest income? c. Explain how the CGAP and spread effects influenced this increase in net interest income. 21. What are some of the weaknesses of the repricing model? How have large banks solved the problem of choosing the optimal time period for repricing? What is runoff cash flow, and how does this amount affect the repricing model’s analysis? The following questions and problems are based on material in Appendix 8A, located on the website (www.mhhe.com/saunders8e). 22. What is a maturity gap? How can the maturity model be used to immunize an FI’s portfolio? What is the critical requirement that allows maturity matching to have some success in immunizing the balance sheet of an FI? Chapter 8 Interest Rate Risk I 215 23. Nearby Bank has the following balance sheet (in millions): Assets Cash 5-year Treasury notes 30-year mortgages Total assets Liabilities and Equity $ 60 60 200 $320 Demand deposits 1-year certificates of deposit Equity Total liabilities and equity $140 160 20 $320 What is the maturity gap for Nearby Bank? Is Nearby Bank more exposed to an increase or a decrease in interest rates? Explain why. 24. County Bank has the following market value balance sheet (in millions, all interest at annual rates). All securities are selling at par equal to book value. Liabilities and Equity Cash 15-year commercial loan at 10% interest, balloon payment 30-year mortgages at 8% interest, balloon payment $ 20 Total assets $480 160 300 Demand deposits 5-year CDs at 6% interest, balloon payment 20-year debentures at 7% interest, balloon payment Equity Total liabilities and equity $100 210 120 50 $480 a. What is the maturity gap for County Bank? b. What will be the maturity gap if the interest rates on all assets and liabilities increase 1 percent? c. What will happen to the market value of the equity? 25. If a bank manager is certain that interest rates are going to increase within the next six months, how should the bank manager adjust the bank’s maturity gap to take advantage of this anticipated increase? What if the manager believes rates will fall? Would your suggested adjustments be difficult or easy to achieve? 26. An insurance company has invested in the following fixed-income securities: (a) $10,000,000 of five-year Treasury notes paying 5 percent interest and selling at par value, (b) $5,800,000 of 10-year bonds paying 7 percent interest with a par value of $6,000,000, and (c) $6,200,000 of 20-year subordinated debentures paying 9 percent interest with a par value of $6,000,000. a. What is the weighted-average maturity of this portfolio of assets? b. If interest rates change so that the yields on all the securities decrease 1 percent, how does the weighted-average maturity of the portfolio change? c. Explain the changes in the maturity values if the yields increase 1 percent. d. Assume that the insurance company has no other assets. What will be the effect on the market value of the company’s equity if the interest rate changes in (b) and (c) occur? 27. The following is a simplified FI balance sheet: Assets Liabilities and Equity Loans $1,000 Total assets $1,000 Deposits Equity Total liabilities and equity $ 850 150 $1,000 www.mhhe.com/saunders8e Assets 216 Part Two Measuring Risk The average maturity of loans is four years and the average maturity of deposits is two years. Assume that loan and deposit balances are reported as book value, zero-coupon items. a. Assume that the interest rate on both loans and deposits is 9 percent. What is the market value of equity? b. What must be the interest rate on deposits to force the market value of equity to be zero? What economic market conditions must exist to make this situation possible? c. Assume that the interest rate on both loans and deposits is 9 percent. What must be the average maturity of deposits for the market value of equity to be zero? 28. Gunnison Insurance has reported the following balance sheet (in thousands): www.mhhe.com/saunders8e Assets Liabilities and Equity 2-year Treasury note 15-year munis $175 165 Total assets $340 1-year commercial paper 5-year note Equity Total liabilities and equity $135 160 45 $340 All securities are selling at par equal to book value. The two-year notes are yielding 5 percent, and the 15-year munis are yielding 9 percent. The one-year commercial paper pays 4.5 percent, and the five-year notes pay 8 percent. All instruments pay interest annually. a. What is the weighted-average maturity of the assets for Gunnison? b. What is the weighted-average maturity of the liabilities for Gunnison? c. What is the maturity gap for Gunnison? d. What does your answer to part (c) imply about the interest rate risk exposure of Gunnison Insurance? e. Calculate the values of all four securities on Gunnison Insurance’s balance sheet assuming that all interest rates increase 2 percent. What is the dollar change in the total asset and total liability values? What is the percentage change in these values? f. What is the dollar impact on the market value of equity for Gunnison? What is the percentage change in the value of the equity? g. What would be the impact on Gunnison’s market value of equity if the liabilities paid interest semiannually instead of annually? 29. Scandia Bank has issued a one-year, $1 million CD paying 5.75 percent to fund a one-year loan paying an interest rate of 6 percent. The principal of the loan will be paid in two installments: $500,000 in six months and the balance at the end of the year. a. What is the maturity gap of Scandia Bank? According to the maturity model, what does this maturity gap imply about the interest rate risk exposure faced by Scandia Bank? b. Assuming no change in interest rates over the year, what is the expected net interest income at the end of the year? c. What would be the effect on annual net interest income of a 2 percent interest rate increase that occurred immediately after the loan was made? What would be the effect of a 2 percent decrease in rates? d. What do these results indicate about the ability of the maturity model to immunize portfolios against interest rate exposure? Chapter 8 Interest Rate Risk I 217 30. EDF Bank has a very simple balance sheet. Assets consist of a two-year, $1 million loan that pays an interest rate of LIBOR plus 4 percent annually. The loan is funded with a two-year deposit on which the bank pays LIBOR plus 3.5 percent interest annually. LIBOR currently is 4 percent, and both the loan and the deposit principal will be paid at maturity. a. What is the maturity gap of this balance sheet? b. What is the expected net interest income in year 1 and year 2? c. Immediately prior to the beginning of year 2, LIBOR rates increase to 6 percent. What is the expected net interest income in year 2? What would be the effect on net interest income of a 2 percent decrease in LIBOR? d. What do the answers to parts (b) and (c) of this question suggest about the use of maturity gap to immunize an FI against interest rate risk? 31. What are the weaknesses of the maturity gap model? The following questions and problems are based on material in Appendix 8B to the chapter. 32. Suppose that the current one-year rate (one-year spot rate) and expected oneyear T-bill rates over the following three years (i.e., years 2, 3, and 4, respectively) are as follows: 33. 34. 35. 36. 37. 6% E(2 r1 ) 7% E(3 r1 ) 7.5% E( 4 r1 ) 7.85% Using the unbiased expectations theory, calculate the current (long-term) rates for one-, two-, three-, and four-year-maturity Treasury securities. Plot the resulting yield curve. The current one-year Treasury bill rate is 5.2 percent, and the expected one-year rate 12 months from now is 5.8 percent. According to the unbiased expectations theory, what should be the current rate for a two-year Treasury security? The Wall Street Journal reported interest rates of 6 percent, 6.35 percent, 6.65 percent, and 6.75 percent for three-year, four-year, five-year, and six-year Treasury notes, respectively. According to the unbiased expectations theory, what are the expected one-year rates for years 4, 5, and 6? The Wall Street Journal reports that the rate on three-year Treasury securities is 5.60 percent and the rate on four-year Treasury securities is 5.65 percent. According to the unbiased expectations hypothesis, what does the market expect the one-year Treasury rate to be in year 4, E(4r1)? How does the liquidity premium theory of the term structure of interest rates differ from the unbiased expectations theory? In a normal economic environment, that is, an upward-sloping yield curve, what is the relationship of liquidity premiums for successive years into the future? Why? Based on economists’ forecasts and analysis, one-year Treasury bill rates and liquidity premiums for the next four years are expected to be as follows: 1 R1 5.65% E(2 r1 ) 6.75% L2 0.05% E( 3 r1 ) 6.85% L3 0.10% E( 4 r1 ) 7.15% L4 0.12% Using the liquidity premium hypothesis, plot the current yield curve. Make sure you label the axes on the graph and identify the four annual rates on the curve both on the axes and on the yield curve itself. www.mhhe.com/saunders8e 1 R1 218 Part Two Measuring Risk 38. The Wall Street Journal reports that the rate on three-year Treasury securities is 5.25 percent and the rate on four-year Treasury securities is 5.50 percent. The one-year interest rate expected in year four, E(4r1), is 6.10 percent. According to the liquidity premium hypothesis, what is the liquidity premium on the four-year Treasury security, L4? 39. You note the following yield curve in The Wall Street Journal. According to the unbiased expectations hypothesis, what is the one-year forward rate for the period beginning two years from today, 2 f1? Maturity Yield One day One year Two years Three years 2.00% 5.50 6.50 9.00 Integrated Mini Case CALCULATING AND USING THE REPRICING GAP State Bank’s balance sheet is listed below. Market yields are in parentheses, and amounts are in millions. www.mhhe.com/saunders8e Assets Liabilities and Equity Cash Fed funds (5.05%) 3-month T-bills (5.25%) 2-year T-notes (6.50%) 8-year T-bonds (7.50%) 5-year munis (floating rate) (8.20%, repriced @ 6 months) 6-month consumer loans (6%) 1-year consumer loans (5.8%) 5-year car loans (7%) 7-month C&I loans (5.8%) 2-year C&I loans (floating rate) (5.15%, repriced @ 6 months) 15-year variable-rate mortgages (5.8%, repriced @ 6 months) 15-year variable-rate mortgages (6.1%, repriced @ year) 15-year fixed-rate mortgages (7.85%) 30-year variable-rate mortgages (6.3%, repriced @ quarter) 30-year variable-rate mortgages (6.4%, repriced @ month) 30-year fixed-rate mortgages (8.2%) Premises and equipment $ 20 150 150 100 200 Total assets $3,945 50 250 300 350 200 275 200 400 300 Demand deposits Savings accounts (1.5%) MMDAs (4.5%) (no minimum balance requirement) 3-month CDs (4.2%) 6-month CDs (4.3%) 1-year CDs (4.5%) 2-year CDs (5%) 4-year CDs (5.5%) 5-year CDs (6%) Fed funds (5%) Overnight repos (5%) 6-month commercial paper (5.05%) Subordinate notes: 3-year fixed rate (6.55%) Subordinated debt: 7-year fixed rate (7.25%) Total liabilities $ 250 20 Equity Total liabilities and equity 400 $3,945 340 120 220 375 425 330 350 225 290 300 200 100 $3,545 225 355 400 20 1. What is the repricing gap if the planning period is 30 days? 6 months? 1 year? 2 years? 5 years? 2. What is the impact over the next six months on net interest income if interest rates on RSAs increase 60 basis points and on RSLs increase 40 basis points? Interest Rate Risk I 219 3. What is the impact over the next year on net interest income if interest rates on RSAs increase 60 basis points and on RSLs increase 40 basis points? Appendix 8A: The Maturity Model View Appendix 8A at the website for this textbook (www.mhhe.com/saunders8e). Appendix 8B Term Structure of Interest Rates To explain the process of estimating the impact of an unexpected shock in short-term interest rates on the entire term structure of interest rates, FIs use the theory of the term structure of interest rates or the yield curve. The term structure of interest rates compares the market yields or interest rates on securities, assuming that all characteristics (default risk, coupon rate, etc.) except maturity are the same. The change in required interest rates as the maturity of a security changes is called the maturity premium (MP). The MP, or the difference between the required yield on longand short-term securities of the same characteristics except maturity, can be positive, negative, or zero. The yield curve for U.S. Treasury securities is the most commonly reported and analyzed yield curve. The shape of the yield curve on Treasury securities has taken many forms over the years, but the three most common shapes are shown in Figure 8B–1. In graph (a), the yield curve on May 29, 2012, yields rise steadily with maturity when the yield curve is upward sloping. This is the most common yield curve, so on average the MP is positive. Graph (b) shows an inverted or downward-sloping yield curve, reported on November 24, 2000, for which yields decline as maturity increases. Inverted yield curves do not generally last very long. Finally, graph (c) shows a flat yield curve, reported on June 4, 2007, in which the yield to maturity is virtually unaffected by the term to maturity. Note that these yield curves may reflect factors other than investors’ preferences for the maturity of a security, since in reality there may be liquidity differences among the securities traded at different points along the yield curve. For example, newly issued 20-year Treasury bonds offer a rate of return less than (seasoned issues) 10-year Treasury bonds if investors prefer new (“on the run”) securities to previously issued (“off the run”) securities. Specifically, since the Treasury (historically) issues new 10-year notes and 20-year bonds only at the long end of the maturity spectrum, an existing 10-year Treasury bond would have to have been issued 10 years previously (i.e., it was originally a 20-year bond when it was issued 10 years previously). The increased demand for the newly issued “liquid” 20-year Treasury bonds relative to the less liquid 10-year Treasury bonds can be large enough to push the equilibrium interest rate on the www.mhhe.com/saunders8e Chapter 8 220 Part Two FIGURE 8B–1 Measuring Risk Treasury Yield Curves Source: U.S. Treasury, “Daily Treasury Rates.” www.ustreas.gov (a) Yield Curve, May 29, 2012 Yield 3.00 to maturity 2.00 1.00 Time to maturity 0.00 1-month 3-month 6-month 1-year Yield 7.00 to maturity 2-year 3-year 5-year 7-year 10-year 20-year 30-year (b) Yield Curve, November 24, 2000 6.00 Time to maturity 5.00 3-month 6-month 1-year 2-year 3-year 5-year 7-year 10-year 20-year 30-year (c) Yield Curve, June 4, 2007 Yield 5.50 to maturity 5.00 4.50 Time to maturity 4.00 3-month 6-month 1-year 2-year 3-year 5-year 7-year 20-year Treasury bonds below that on the 10-year Treasury bonds and even below short-term rates. Explanations for the shape of the yield curve fall predominantly into three theories: the unbiased expectations theory, the liquidity premium theory, and the market segmentation theory. 10-year 20-year 30-year UNBIASED EXPECTATIONS THEORY According to the unbiased expectations theory for the term structure of interest rates, at a given point in time the yield curve reflects the market’s Chapter 8 FIGURE 8B–2 221 Unbiased Expectations Theory of the Term Structure of Interest Rates (1+1R1) [1+E(2r1)] [1+E(3r1)] [1+E(4r1)] Buy 4 one-year bonds (1 + 1R4)4 0 Interest Rate Risk I 1 2 Buy a four-year bond 3 current expectations of future short-term rates. Thus, an upward-sloping yield curve reflects the market’s expectation that short-term rates will rise throughout the relevant time period (e.g., the Federal Reserve is expected to tighten monetary policy in the future). Similarly, a flat yield curve reflects the expectation that short-term rates will remain constant over the relevant time period. As illustrated in Figure 8B–2, the intuition behind the unbiased expectations theory is that if investors have a 4-year investment horizon, they either could buy a current 4-year bond and earn the current yield on a 4-year bond each year (1R4, if held to maturity) or could invest in 4 successive one-year bonds (of which they know only the current one-year rate, 1R1, but form expectations of the unknown future one-year rates). In equilibrium, the return to holding a 4-year bond to maturity should equal the expected return to investing in 4 successive one-year bonds. Similarly, the return on a 3-year bond should equal the expected return on investing in 3 successive oneyear bonds. If future one-year rates are expected to rise each successive year into the future, then the yield curve will slope upward. Specifically, the current 4-year T-bond rate or return will exceed the 3-year bond rate, which will exceed the 2-year bond rate, and so on. Similarly, if future one-year rates are expected to remain constant each successive year into the future, then the 4-year bond rate will be equal to the 3-year bond rate. That is, the term structure of interest rates will remain constant over the relevant time period. Specifically, the unbiased expectations theory posits that long-term rates are a geometric average of current and expected short-term interest rates. That is, the interest rate that equates the return on a series of short-term security investments with the return on a long-term security with an equivalent maturity reflects the market’s forecast of future interest 4 Year rates. The mathematical equation representing this relationship is: (1 1 RN )N (1 1 R1 ) [1 E( 2 r1 )] ... [1 E( N r1 )] where 1 RN Actual N -period rate N Term to maturity Current one-year rate 1 R1 E( t r1 ) Expected one-year (forward) yield during period t Notice that uppercase interest rate terms, 1Rt, are the actual current interest rates on securities purchased today with a maturity of t years. Lowercase interest rate terms, tr1, are estimates of future one-year interest rates starting t years into the future. For example, suppose the current oneyear spot rate and expected one-year Treasury bill rates over the following three years (i.e., years 2, 3, and 4, respectively) are as follows: 2.94% E( 2 r1 ) 4.00% E( 3 r1 ) 4.74% E( 4 r1 ) 5.10% 1 R1 This would be consistent with the market’s expecting the Federal Reserve to increasingly tighten monetary policy. With the unbiased expectations theory, current long-term rates for one-, two-, three-, and four-year maturity Treasury securities should be: 1 R1 2.940% 1 R2 [(1 0.0294)(1 0.04)]1/2 1 3.47% 1 R3 1/3 [(1 0.0294)(1 0.04)(1 0.0474)] 1 3.89% 1 R4 [(1 0.0294)(1 0.04)(1 0.0474) (1 0.051)]1/ 4 1 4.19% 222 Part Two Measuring Risk And the yield curve should look like this: Yield to maturity (%) 4.19 3.89 3.47 2.94 0 1 2 3 4 Term to maturity (years) Thus, the upward-sloping yield curve reflects the market’s expectation of consistently rising oneyear (short-term) interest rates in the future. LIQUIDITY PREMIUM THEORY The unbiased expectations theory has the shortcoming that it neglects to recognize that forward rates are not perfect predictors of future interest rates. If forward rates were perfect predictors of future interest rates, future prices of Treasury securities would be known with certainty. The return over any investment period would be certain and independent of the maturity of the instrument initially purchased and of the time at which the investor needs to liquidate the security. However, with uncertainty about future interest rates (and future monetary policy actions) and hence about future security prices, these instruments become risky in the sense that the return over a future investment period is unknown. In other words, because of future uncertainty of returns, there is a risk in holding long-term securities, and that risk increases with the security’s maturity. The liquidity premium theory of the term structure of interest rates allows for this future uncertainty. It is based on the idea that investors will hold long-term maturities only if they are offered a premium to compensate for the future uncertainty in a security’s value, which increases with an asset’s maturity. Specifically, in a world of uncertainty, short-term securities provide greater marketability (due to their more active secondary market) and have less price risk (due to smaller price fluctuations for a given change in interest rates) than long-term securities. As a result, investors prefer to hold shorter-term securities because they can be converted into cash with little risk of a capital loss, that is, a fall in the price of the security below its original purchase price. Thus, investors must be offered a liquidity premium to buy longer-term securities that have higher risk of capital losses. This difference in price or liquidity risk can be directly related to the fact that longer-term securities are more sensitive to interest rate changes in the market than are shorterterm securities—see Appendix 9A for a discussion on bond interest rate sensitivity and the link to a bond’s maturity. Because the longer the maturity on a security the greater its risk, the liquidity premium increases as maturity increases. The liquidity premium theory states that longterm rates are equal to the geometric average of current and expected short-term rates (as with the unbiased expectations theory) plus a liquidity or risk premium that increases with the maturity of the security. Figure 8B–3 illustrates the difference in the shape of the yield curve under the unbiased expectations theory versus the liquidity premium theory. For example, according to the liquidity premium theory, an upward-sloping yield curve may reflect the investor’s expectations that future short-term rates will rise, be flat, or fall, but because the liquidity premium increases with maturity, the yield curve will nevertheless increase with the term to maturity. The liquidity premium theory may be mathematically represented as: 1 RN {(1 1 R1 )[1 E( 2 r1 ) L2 ]...[1 E( N r1 ) LN ]}1/ N 1 where Lt liquidity premium for a period t and L 2 L3 . . . LN . For example, suppose that the current one-year rate (one-year spot rate) and expected one-year T-bill rates over the following three years (i.e., years 2, 3, and 4, respectively) are as follows: 1 R1 2.94% E( 2 r1 ) 4.00% E( 3 r1 ) 4.74% E( 4 r1 ) 5.10% Chapter 8 FIGURE 8B–3 Interest Rate Risk I 223 Yield Curve under the Unbiased Expectations Theory (UET) versus the Liquidity Premium Theory (LPT) (a) Upward-sloping yield to maturity (b) Inverted or downward-sloping yield to maturity LPT LPT UET UET Time to maturity Time to maturity (c) Flat yield to maturity LPT UET Time to maturity In addition, investors charge a liquidity premium on longer-term securities such that: L2 0.10% L3 0.20% L4 0.30% Using the liquidity premium theory, current rates for one-, two-, three-, and four-year-maturity Treasury securities should be: 1 R1 = 2.94% 1 R2 = [(1 + 0.0294)(1 + 0.04 + 0.001)] 1 R3 = [(1 + 0.0294)(1 + 0.04 + 0.001)(1 + 0.0474 1 2 − 1 = 3.52% + 0.002)]1 3 − 1 = 3.99% 1 R4 = [(1 + 0.0294)(1 + 0.04 + 0.001)(1 + 0.0474 + 0.002)(1 + 0.051 + 0.003)]1 4 − 1 = 4.34% and the current yield to maturity curve will be upward sloping as shown: Yield to maturity (%) 4.34 3.99 3.52 2.94 0 1 2 3 4 Term to maturity (years) Comparing the yield curves in the example above (using the unbiased expectations hypothesis) and here, notice that the liquidity premium in year 2 (L2 0.10%) produces a 0.05 percent premium on the yield to maturity on a two-year T-note, the liquidity premium for year 3 (L3 0.20%) produces a 0.10 percent premium on the yield to maturity on the three-year T-note, and the liquidity premium for year 4 (L4 0.30%) produces a 0.15 percent premium on the yield to maturity on the four-year T-note. MARKET SEGMENTATION THEORY Market segmentation theory argues that individual investors have specific maturity preferences. Accordingly, securities with different maturities are not seen as perfect substitutes under the market segmentation theory. Instead, individual investors have preferred investment horizons dictated by the nature of the assets and liabilities they hold. For example, banks might prefer to hold relatively short-term U.S. Treasury bills because of the short-term nature of their deposit liabilities, while insurance companies might prefer to 224 Part Two FIGURE 8B–4 Yield percent rS SS Measuring Risk Market Segmentation and Determination of the Slope of the Yield Curve Yield percent rL DS Yield percent SL DL Yield curve Short-term securities Yield percent rS SS Long-term securities Yield percent rL DS S L Time to maturity Yield percent SL DL Yield curve Short-term securities Long-term securities hold long-term U.S. Treasury bonds because of the long-term nature of their life insurance contractual liabilities. As a result, interest rates are determined by distinct supply and demand conditions within a particular maturity bucket or market segment (e.g., the short end and the long end of the market). The market segmentation theory assumes that neither investors nor borrowers are willing to shift from one maturity sector to another to take advantage of opportunities arising from changes in yields. Figure 8B–4 demonstrates how changes in the supply curve for short-versus long-term bonds result in changes in the shape of the yield curve. Such a change may occur if the U.S. Treasury decides to issue fewer short-term bonds and more long-term bonds (i.e., to lengthen the average maturity of government debt outstanding). Specifically in Figure 8B–4, the higher the yield on securities, the higher the demand for them. Thus, as the supply of securities decreases in the short-term market and increases in the longterm market, the slope of the yield curve becomes steeper. If the supply of short-term securities had increased while the supply of long-term S L Time to maturity securities had decreased, the yield curve would have become flatter (and may even have sloped downward). Indeed, the large-scale repurchases of long-term Treasury bonds (i.e., reductions in supply) by the U.S. Treasury in 2000 have been viewed as the major cause of the inverted yield curve that appeared in 2000. More recently, in 2011 the Federal Reserve announced its Operation Twist in which the Fed purchased $400 billion of 15- and 20-year Treasury bonds, and at the same time, sold $400 billion of its short-term securities. The name of the plan came from what the Fed hoped the plan would do to the yield curve: flip it around, or at least flatten the curve, so that longterm rates go down and short-term rates rise. In June 2012, the Fed announced an extension of Operation Twist involving a swap of $267 billion short-term for long-term securities. Both moves did immediately flatten the yield curve. Federal Reserve Bank of San Francisco estimated that the first round of Operation Twist, lowered long-term yields by 15 basis points relative to short-term yields. With the second round of Operation Twist, the spread between long- and short-term rates fell another 11 basis points. Chapter 8 FORECASTING INTEREST RATES As interest rates change, so do the values of financial securities. Accordingly, the ability to predict or forecast interest rates is critical to the profitability of FIs. For example, if interest rates rise, the value of investment portfolios of FIs will fall, resulting in a loss of wealth. Thus, interest rate forecasts are extremely important for the financial wealth of FIs. The discussion of the unbiased expectations theory above indicates that the shape of the yield curve is determined by the market’s current expectations of future short-term interest rates. For example, an upward-sloping yield curve suggests that the market expects future short-term interest rates to increase. Given that the yield curve represents the market’s current expectations of future short-term interest rates, the unbiased expectations theory can be used to forecast (short-term) interest rates in the future (i.e., forward one-year interest rates). A forward rate is an expected or implied rate on a short-term security that is to be originated at some point in the future. With the equations representing the unbiased expectations theory, the market’s expectation of forward rates can be derived directly from existing or actual rates on securities currently traded in the spot market. To find an implied forward rate on a one-year security to be issued one year from today, we can rewrite the unbiased expectation theory equation as follows: 1 R2 {(1 1 R1 )[1 ( 2 f1 )]} 1 2 1 where 2 f1 Expected one-year rate for year 2, or the implied forward one-year rate for next year Interest Rate Risk I 225 Therefore, 2f1 is the market’s estimate of the expected one-year rate for year 2. Solving for 2f1, we get: 2 f1 {(1 1 R2 )2 / [1 ( 1 R1 )]} 1 In general, we can find the one-year forward rate for any year, N years into the future, using the following equation: N f1 {(1 1 RN )N / [1 ( 1 RN 1 )]N 1 } 1 For example, on May 29, 2012, the existing or current (spot) one-year, two-year, three-year, and four-year zero-coupon Treasury security rates were as follows: 0.203% 1 R3 0.439% 1 R1 0.304% 1 R4 0.604% 1 R2 With the unbiased expectations theory, one-year forward rates on zero-coupon Treasury bonds for years 2, 3, and 4 as of May 29, 2012, were: 2 f1 [(1.00304)2 / (1.00203)] 1 1.004% 3 f1 [(1.00439)3 / (1.00304)2 ] 1 1.007% 4 f1 [(1.00604)4 / (1.00439)3 ] 1 1.011% Thus, the expected one-year rate one year into the future was 1.004 percent; the expected one-year rate two years into the future was 1.007 percent; and the expected one-year rate three years into the future was 1.011 percent. Chapter Nine See Appendices Online at www.mhhe.com/saunders8e • Appendix 9A: The Basics of Bond Valuation Interest Rate Risk II INTRODUCTION book value accounting Accounting method in which the assets and liabilities of the FI are recorded at historic values. market value accounting Accounting method in which the assets and liabilities of the FI are revalued according to the current level of interest rates. mark to market Valuing securities at their current market price. As mentioned in Chapter 8, a weakness of the repricing model is its reliance on book values rather than market values of assets and liabilities. Indeed, in most countries, FIs report their balance sheets by using book value accounting. This method records the historic values of securities purchased, loans made, and liabilities sold. For example, for U.S. banks, investment assets (i.e., those expected to be held to maturity) are recorded at book values, while those assets expected to be used for trading (trading securities or available-for-sale securities) are reported according to market value.1 The recording of market values means that assets and liabilities are revalued to reflect current market conditions. Thus, if a fixed-coupon bond had been purchased at $100 per $100 of face value in a low-interest rate environment, a rise in current market rates reduces the present value of the cash flows from the bond to the investor. Such a rise also reduces the price—say to $97—at which the bond could be sold in the secondary market today. That is, the market value accounting approach reflects economic reality, or the true values of assets and liabilities if the FI’s portfolio were to be liquidated at today’s securities prices rather than at the prices when the assets and liabilities were originally purchased or sold. This practice of valuing securities at their market value is referred to as marking to market. We discuss book value versus market value accounting and the impact that the use of the alternate methods has in measuring the value of an FI in more detail in Chapter 20. Appendix 9A, located at the book’s website (www.mhhe.com/saunders8e), presents a review of bond pricing and price volatility. This topic is generally covered in introductory finance courses. For students needing a review, Appendix 9A is encouraged reading. In this second chapter on measuring interest rate risk, we present a market value–based model of managing interest rate risk: the duration gap model. We explain the concept of duration and see that duration and the duration gap are more accurate measures of an FI’s interest rate risk exposure than is the repricing gap model described in Chapter 8. Unlike the repricing gap model, duration 1 More accurately, they are reported at the lower of cost or current market value (LOCOM). However, both the SEC and the Financial Accounting Standards Board (FASB) have strongly advocated that FIs switch to full market value accounting in the near future. Currently, FASB 115 requires FIs to value certain bonds at market prices but not loans. 226 Chapter 9 Interest Rate Risk II 227 gap considers market values and the maturity distributions of an FI’s assets and liabilities. Further, duration gap considers the degree of leverage on an FI’s balance sheet as well as the timing of the payment or arrival of cash flows on assets and liabilities. Thus, duration gap is a more comprehensive measure of an FI’s interest rate risk. As a result, regulators are increasingly focusing on this model in determining an appropriate level of capital reserves for an FI exposed to interest rate risk (see Chapter 20). We begin the chapter by presenting the basic arithmetic needed to calculate the duration of an asset or liability. Then we analyze the economic meaning of the number we calculate for duration. This number, which measures the average life of an asset or liability, also has economic meaning as the interest rate sensitivity (or interest elasticity) of that asset or liability’s value. Next, we show how the duration measure can be used to protect an FI against interest rate risk. Finally, we examine some problems in applying the duration measure to real-world FIs’ balance sheets. The more advanced issues associated with these problems are presented in Appendix 9B at the end of the chapter. DURATION: A SIMPLE INTRODUCTION Duration is a more complete measure of an asset or liability’s interest rate sensitivity than is maturity because duration takes into account the time of arrival (or payment) of all cash flows as well as the asset’s (or liability’s) maturity. Consider a loan with a 15 percent interest rate and required repayment of half the $100 in principal at the end of six months and the other half at the end of the year. The loan is financed with a one-year CD paying 15 percent interest per year. The promised cash flows (CF) received by the FI from the loan at the end of one-half year and at the end of the year appear in Figure 9–1. CF1/2 is the $50 promised repayment of principal plus the $7.50 promised interest payment ($100 ½ 15%) received after six months. CF1 is the promised cash flow at the end of the year and is equal to the second $50 promised principal repayment plus $3.75 promised interest ($50 ½ 15%). To compare the relative sizes of these two cash flows, we should put them in the same dimensions. This is the case because $1 of principal or interest received at the end of a year is worth less to the FI in terms of the time value of money than $1 of principal or interest received at the end of six months. Assuming that the current required interest rates are 15 percent per year, we calculate the present values (PV) of the two cash flows (CF) shown in Figure 9–2 as: CF1/2 $57.50 PV1/2 $57.5/(1.075) $53.49 CF1 $53.75 PV1 $53.75/(1.075)2 $46.51 CF1/2 CF1 $111.25 PV1/2 PV1 $100.00 Note that since CF1/2, the cash flows received at the end of one-half year, are received earlier, they are discounted at (1 ½R), where R is the current annual CF1/2 = $57.50 FIGURE 9–1 Promised Cash Flows on the OneYear Loan 0 1/2 year CF1 = $53.75 1 year 228 Part Two Measuring Risk FIGURE 9–2 PV of the Cash Flows from the Loan PV1 = $46.51 PV1/2 = $53.49 1/2 0 duration The weighted-average time to maturity on an investment. CF1 = $53.75 CF1/2 = $57.50 1 year year interest rate on the loan. This is smaller than the discount rate on the cash flow received at the end of the year (1 ½R)2. Figure 9–2 summarizes the PVs of the cash flows from the loan. Technically speaking, duration is the weighted-average time to maturity on the loan using the relative present values of the cash flows as weights. On a time value of money basis, duration measures the weighted average of when cash flows are received on the loan. As Figure 9–2 shows, the FI receives some cash flows at one-half year and some at one year. Duration analysis weights the time at which cash flows are received by the relative importance in present value terms of the cash flows arriving at each point in time. In present value terms, the relative importance of the cash flows arriving at time t ½ year and time t 1 year are as follows: Time (t) 1/2 year Weight (x) X 1/ 2 PV1/2 53.49 0.5349 53.49% PV1/2 PV1 100.00 X1 PV1 46.51 0.4651 46.51% PV1/ 2 PV1 100.00 1 year 1.0 100% That is, in present value terms, the FI receives 53.49 percent of cash flows on the loan with the first payment at the end of six months (t ½) and 46.51 percent with the second payment at the end of the year (t 1). By definition, the sum of the (present value) cash flow weights must equal 1: X 1/2 X 1 1 0.5349 0.4651 1 We can now calculate the duration (D), or the weighted-average time to maturity, of the loan using the present value of its cash flows as weights: D1 X 1/2 ( 1 2) X 1 (1) 0.5349( 1 2) 0.4651(1) 0.7326 years Thus, while the maturity of the loan is one year, its duration, or average life in a cash flow sense, is only 0.7326 years. The duration is less than the maturity of the loan because in present value terms 53.49 percent of the cash flows are received at the end of one-half year. Note that duration is measured in years since we weight the time (t) at which cash flows are received by the relative present value importance of cash flows (X1/2, X1, etc.). We next calculate the duration of the one-year, $100, 15 percent interest certificate of deposit. The FI promises to make only one cash payment to depositors at Chapter 9 FIGURE 9–3 PV1 = $100 PV of the Cash Flows of the Deposit Interest Rate Risk II 229 CF1 = $115 1 year 0 the end of the year; that is, CF1 $115, which is the promised principal ($100) and interest repayment ($15) to the depositor. Since weights are calculated in present value terms: CF1 $115, and PV1 $115/1.15 $100 We show this in Figure 9–3. Because all cash flows are received in one payment at the end of the year, X1 PV1/PV1 1, the duration of the deposit is: DD X 1 1 DD 1 1 1 year Thus, only when all cash flows are limited to one payment at the end of the period with no intervening cash flows does duration equal maturity. This example also illustrates that while the maturities on the loan and the deposit are both one year (and thus the difference or gap in maturities is zero), the duration gap is negative: ML MD 1 1 0 DL DD 0.7326 1 0.2674 years As will become clearer, to measure and to hedge interest rate risk, the FI needs to manage its duration gap rather than its maturity gap. Concept Questions 1. Why is duration considered a more complete measure of an asset or liability’s interest rate sensitivity than maturity? 2. When is the duration of an asset equal to its maturity? A GENERAL FORMULA FOR DURATION You can calculate the duration (or Macaulay’s duration2) for any fixed-income security that pays interest annually using the following general formula: N D ∑ CFt DFt t t 1 N ∑ CFt DFt t 1 2 N ∑ PVt t t 1 N ∑ PVt t 1 Named after an economist who was among the first to develop the duration concept. (1) 230 Part Two Measuring Risk where D Duration measured in years CFt Cash flow received on the security at end of period t N Last period in which the cash flow is received DFt Discount factor 1/(1 R)t, where R is the annual yield or current level of interest rates in the market N Summation sign for addition of all terms from t 1 to t N ∑ t1 PVt Present value of the cash flow at the end of the period t, which equals CFt DFt For bonds that pay interest semiannually, the duration equation becomes:3 CFt t 2t t 1 2 (1 R 2) N ∑ D N CF ∑ (1 Rt 2)2t t 1 2 (2) where t ½, 1, 1½, . . . , N. A key assumption of the simple Macaulay duration model is that the yield curve or the term structure of interest rates is flat and that when rates change, the yield curve shifts in a parallel fashion. Further, the simple duration equation assumes that the issuer of a security or the borrower of a loan pays the interest and principal as promised. That is, the equation assumes no default risk. As we go through the theory and analysis of the duration model and interest rate risk in the body of the chapter, we use the simple Macaulay duration model and these assumptions. In Appendix 9B, we relax these assumptions, allowing for something other than a flat yield curve and default risk. Relaxing these assumptions changes the formulas in the body of the chapter slightly. However, the intuition and general trends remain the same as those seen in the body of the chapter. Notice that the denominator of the duration equation is the present value of the cash flows on the security (which in an efficient market will be equal to the current market price). The numerator is the present value of each cash flow received on the security multiplied or weighted by the length of time required to receive the cash flow. To help you fully understand this formula, we next look at some examples. Table 9–1 summarizes duration and its features, which we illustrate in the examples. 3 In general, the duration equation is written as: N D ∑ t 1/ m N ∑ t 1/ m CFt t (1 R / m)mt CFt (1 R / m)mt where m number of times per year interest is paid. Chapter 9 TABLE 9–1 Duration: Definition and Features Interest Rate Risk II 231 Definition of Duration 1. The weighted-average time to maturity on a security. 2. The interest elasticity of a security’s price to small interest rate changes. Features of Duration 1. Duration increases with the maturity of a fixed-income security, but at a decreasing rate. 2. Duration decreases as the yield on a security increases. 3. Duration decreases as the coupon or interest payment increases. Risk Management with Duration 1. Duration is equal to the maturity of an immunized security. 2. Duration gap is used by FIs to measure and manage the interest rate risk of an overall balance sheet. The Duration of Interest-Bearing Bonds EXAMPLE 9–1 The Duration of a Six-Year Eurobond TABLE 9–2 Duration of a SixYear Eurobond with 8 Percent Coupon and Yield Eurobonds pay coupons annually. Suppose a Eurobond matures in 6 years, the annual coupon is 8 percent, the face value of the bond is $1,000, and the current yield to maturity (R) is also 8 percent. We show the calculation of its duration in Table 9–2. Column 1 lists the time period (in years) in which a cash flow (CF) is received. Column 2 lists the CF received in time period t. Column 3 lists the discount factor used to convert a future value to a present value. Column 4 is the present value of the CF received in each period t (Column 2 times Column 3). The sum of Column 4 is the present value of the bond: the denominator of the duration equation. Column 5 is the present value of the CF received each period times the time it takes to receive the CF (Column 4 times Column 1). The sum of Column 5 is the time weighted present value of the bond: the numerator of the duration equation. As the calculation indicates, the duration or weighted-average time to maturity on this bond is 4.993 years. t CFt DFt 1 2 3 4 5 6 80 80 80 80 80 1,080 0.9259 0.8573 0.7938 0.7350 0.6806 0.6302 D = CFt ⴛ DFt CFt ⴛ DFt ⴛ t 74.07 68.59 63.51 58.80 54.45 680.58 74.07 137.18 190.53 235.20 272.25 4,083.48 1,000.00 4,992.71 4, 992.71 = 4.993 years 1, 000 232 Part Two Measuring Risk EXAMPLE 9–2 The Duration of a Two-Year U.S. Treasury Bond U.S. Treasury bonds pay coupon interest semiannually. Suppose a Treasury bond matures in two years, the annual coupon rate is 8 percent, the face value is $1,000, and the annual yield to maturity (R) is 12 percent. See Table 9–3 for the calculation of the duration of this bond. As the calculation indicates, the duration, or weighted-average time to maturity, on this bond is 1.883 years. Table 9–4 shows that if the annual coupon rate is lowered to 6 percent, duration rises to 1.909 years. Since 6 percent coupon payments are lower than 8 percent, it takes longer to recover the initial investment in the bond. In Table 9–5 duration is calculated for the original 8 percent bond, assuming that the yield to maturity increases to 16 percent. Now duration falls from 1.883 years (in Table 9–3) to 1.878 years. The higher the yield to maturity on the bond, the more the investor earns on reinvested coupons and the shorter the time to recover the initial investment. Finally, when the maturity on a bond decreases to 1 year (see Table 9–6), its duration falls to 0.980 year. Thus, the shorter the maturity on the bond, the more quickly the initial investment is recovered. TABLE 9–3 Duration of a TwoYear U.S. Treasury Bond with 8 Percent Coupon and 12 Percent Yield t CFt DFt CFt ⴛ DFt CFt ⴛ DFt ⴛ t ½ 1 1½ 2 40 40 40 1,040 0.9434 0.8900 0.8396 0.7921 37.74 35.60 33.58 823.78 930.70 18.87 35.60 50.37 1,647.56 1,752.40 D TABLE 9–4 Duration of a TwoYear U.S. Treasury Bond with 6 Percent Coupon and 12 Percent Yield t ½ 1 1½ 2 CFt DFt CFt ⴛ DFt CFt ⴛ DFt ⴛ t 30 30 30 1,030 0.9434 0.8900 0.8396 0.7921 28.30 26.70 25.19 815.86 14.15 26.70 37.78 1,631.71 896.05 1,710.34 D TABLE 9–5 Duration of a TwoYear U.S. Treasury Bond with 8 Percent Coupon and 16 Percent Yield t ½ 1 1½ 2 1,752.40 1.883 years 930.70 1,710.34 1.909 years 896.05 CFt DFt CFt ⴛ DFt CFt ⴛ DFt ⴛ t 40 40 40 1,040 0.9259 0.8573 0.7938 0.7350 37.04 34.29 31.75 764.43 18.52 34.29 47.63 1,528.86 867.51 1,629.30 D 1,629.30 1.878 years 867.51 Chapter 9 TABLE 9–6 Duration of a OneYear U.S. Treasury Bond with 8 Percent Coupon and 12 Percent Yield t ½ 1 CFt DFt CFt ⴛ DFt 40 1,040 0.9434 0.8900 37.74 925.60 963.34 D Interest Rate Risk II 233 CFt ⴛ DFt ⴛ t 18.87 925.60 944.47 944.47 0.980 year 963.34 Next, we look at two other types of bonds that are useful in understanding duration. The Duration of Zero-Coupon Bonds The U.S. Treasury has created zero-coupon bonds that allow securities firms and other investors to strip individual coupons and the principal from regular Treasury bonds and sell them to investors as separate securities. Elsewhere, such as in the corporate bond markets, corporations have issued discount or zero-coupon bonds directly. U.S. T-bills and commercial paper usually are issued on a discount basis and are additional examples of discount bonds. These bonds sell at a discount from face value on issue, pay the face value (e.g., $1,000) on maturity, and have no intervening cash flows, such as coupon payments, between issue and maturity. The current price an investor is willing to pay for such a bond is equal to the present value of the single, fixed (face value) payment on the bond that is received on maturity (here, $1,000), or: P 1,000 (1 R)N where R is the required annually compounded yield to maturity, N is the number of years to maturity, and P is the price. Because there are no intervening cash flows such as coupons between issue and maturity, the following must be true: DB MB That is, the duration of a zero-coupon bond equals its maturity. Note that only for zero-coupon bonds are duration and maturity equal. Indeed, for any bond that pays some cash flows prior to maturity, its duration will always be less than its maturity. The Duration of Consol Bonds (Perpetuities) consol bond A bond that pays a fixed coupon each year forever. Although consol bonds have yet to be issued in the United States, they are of theoretical interest in exploring the differences between maturity and duration. A consol bond pays a fixed coupon each year. The novel feature of this bond is that it never matures; that is, it is a perpetuity: Mc 234 Part Two Measuring Risk In fact, consol bonds that were issued by the British government in the 1890s to finance the Boer Wars in South Africa are still outstanding. However, while its maturity is theoretically infinity, the formula for the duration of a consol bond is: Dc 1 1 R where R is the required yield to maturity. Suppose that the yield curve implies R 5 percent annually. Then the duration of the consol bond would be: Dc 1 1 21 years 0.05 Thus, while maturity is infinite, duration is finite. Moreover, as interest rates rise, the duration of the consol bond falls. Consider the 1979–82 period, when some yields rose to around 20 percent on long-term government bonds. Then: Dc 1 Concept Questions 1 6 years 0.2 1. What does the denominator of the duration equation measure? 2. What does the numerator of the duration equation measure? 3. Calculate the duration of a one-year, 8 percent coupon, 10 percent yield bond that pays coupons quarterly. 4. What is the duration of a zero-coupon bond? 5. What feature is unique about a consol bond compared with other bonds? FEATURES OF DURATION From the preceding examples, we derive three important features of duration relating to the maturity, yield, and coupon interest of the security being analyzed. Duration and Maturity A comparison of Tables 9–6, 9–3, and 9–7 indicates that duration increases with the maturity of a fixed-income asset or liability, but at a decreasing rate:4 ∂D 0 ∂M ∂2 D 0 ∂M2 To see this, look at Figure 9–4, where we plot duration against maturity for a three-year, a two-year, and a one-year U.S. Treasury bond using the same yield of 4 This is the case for the vast majority of securities. It needs to be noted, however, that for bonds selling below par, duration increases at a decreasing rate up to a point. At long maturities (e.g., 50 years) duration starts to decline. Few bonds in the market have a maturity long enough to see this decline. Chapter 9 TABLE 9–7 Duration of a Three-Year U.S. Treasury Bond with 8 Percent Coupon and 12 Percent Yield (Coupon Interest Paid Semiannually) t ½ 1 1½ 2 2½ 3 CFt DFt CFt ⴛ DFt CFt ⴛ DFt ⴛ t 40 40 40 40 40 1,040 0.9434 0.8900 0.8396 0.7921 0.7473 0.7050 37.04 35.60 33.58 31.68 29.89 733.16 18.87 35.60 50.37 63.36 74.72 2,199.48 901.65 2,442.40 D FIGURE 9–4 Interest Rate Risk II 235 2,442.40 2.709 years 901.65 Duration Duration versus Maturity 2.709 years 1.883 years 0.980 year 1 year 2 years 3 years Maturity ∞ 12 percent for all three and assuming an annual coupon of 8 percent (with semiannual payments of 4 percent) on each bond. As the maturity of the bond increases from one year to two years (Tables 9–6 and 9–3), duration increases by 0.903 year, from 0.980 year to 1.883 years. Increasing maturity an additional year, from two years to three years (Tables 9–3 and 9–7), increases duration by 0.826, from 1.883 years to 2.709 years. Duration and Yield A comparison of Tables 9–3 and 9–5 indicates that duration decreases as yield increases: ∂D 0 ∂R As the yield on the Treasury bond increases from 12 percent to 16 percent (Tables 9–3 and 9–5), the duration on the bond decreases from 1.883 years to 1.878 years. This makes sense intuitively because higher yields discount later cash flows more heavily and the relative importance, or weights, of those later cash flows decline when compared with earlier cash flows on an asset or liability. Duration and Coupon Interest A comparison of Tables 9–4 and 9–3 indicates that the higher the coupon or promised interest payment on the security, the lower its duration: ∂D 0 ∂C 236 Part Two Measuring Risk As the coupon rate on the U.S. Treasury bond increases from 6 percent to 8 percent in Tables 9–4 and 9–3, the duration on the bond decreases from 1.909 years to 1.883 years. This is due to the fact that the larger the coupons or promised interest payments, the more quickly cash flows are received by investors and the higher are the present value weights of those cash flows in the duration calculation. On a time value of money basis, the investor recoups the initial investment faster when coupon payments are larger. Concept Questions 1. Which has the longest duration, a 30-year, 8 percent, zero-coupon or discount bond or an 8 percent infinite maturity consol bond? 2. What is the relationship between duration and yield to maturity on a financial security? 3. Do high-coupon bonds have high or low durations? THE ECONOMIC MEANING OF DURATION So far we have calculated duration for a number of different fixed-income assets and liabilities. Now we are ready to make the direct link between the number measured in years we call duration and the interest rate sensitivity of an asset or liability or of an FI’s entire portfolio. In addition to being a measure of the average life, in a cash flow sense, of an asset or liability, duration is also a direct measure of the interest rate sensitivity, or elasticity, of an asset or liability. In other words, the larger the numerical value of D, the more sensitive is the price of that asset or liability to changes or shocks in interest rates. Consider the following equation showing that the current price of a bond that pays interest annually is equal to the present value of the coupons and principal payment on the bond: P C C CF … (1 R) (1 R)2 (1 R)N (3) where P Price on the bond C Coupon or interest payment (annual) R Yield to maturity N Number of periods to maturity F Face value of the bond We want to find out how the price of the bond (P) changes when yields (R) rise. We know that bond prices fall, but we want to derive a direct measure of the size of this fall (i.e., its degree of price sensitivity). Chapter 9 Interest Rate Risk II 237 Taking the derivative of the bond’s price (P) with respect to the yield to maturity (R), we can show that:5 1 dP ( P D) 1R dR By cross multiplying: dP 1R D dR P or, alternatively, and recognizing that interest rate changes tend to be discrete:6 P P D R 1R interest elasticity The percentage change in the price of a bond for any given change in interest rates. (4) The economic interpretation of equation (4) is that the number D is the interest elasticity, or sensitivity, of the security’s price to small interest rate changes. That is, D 5 The first derivative of the bond’s price in equation (3) with respect to the yield to maturity (R) is: dP C 2C N (C F ) … dR (1 R )2 (1 R )3 (1 R )N 1 By rearranging, we get: 1 ⎡ C 2C dP N (C F ) ⎤ … 1 R ⎢⎣ (1 R ) dR (1 R )2 (1 R )N ⎥⎦ (A) We have shown that duration (D) is the weighted-average time to maturity using the present value of cash flows as weights; that is, by definition: D 1 C C (C F ) 2 … N (1 R ) (1 R )2 (1 R )N C C (C F ) … (1 R ) (1 R )2 (1 R )N Since the denominator of the duration equation is simply the price (P) of the bond that is equal to the present value of the cash flows on the bond, then: D 1 C C (C F ) 2 … N (1 R ) (1 R )2 (1 R )N P Multiplying both sides of this equation by P, we get: P D 1 C C C F 2 … N (1 R ) (1 R )2 (1 R )N (B) The term on the right side of equation (B) is the same term as that in square brackets in equation (A). Substituting equation (B) into equation (A), we get: dP 1 [P D ] dR 1 R 6 In what follows, we use the ∆ (change) notation instead of d (derivative notation) to recognize that interest rate changes tend to be discrete rather than infinitesimally small. For example, in real-world financial markets, the smallest observed rate change is usually one basis point, or 1/100th of 1 percent. 238 Part Two Measuring Risk describes the percentage price fall of the bond (ΔP/P) for any given (present value) increase in required interest rate or yield (ΔR/(1 R)). Equation (4) can be rearranged in another useful way for interpretation regarding interest rate sensitivity. That is, the percentage change in the price of a bond for a change in interest rates can be written as: P ⎡ R ⎤ D ⎢ P ⎣ 1 R ⎥⎦ modified duration Duration divided by 1 plus the interest rate. (5) Equation (5) shows that for small changes in interest rates, bond prices move in an inversely proportional fashion according to the size of D. Clearly, for any given change in interest rates, long duration securities suffer a larger capital loss (or receive a higher capital gain) should interest rates rise (fall) than do short-duration securities. By implication, gains and losses under the duration model are symmetric. That is, if we repeat the above examples but allow interest rates to decrease by one basis point annually (or 1/2 basis point semiannually), the percentage increase in the price of the bond (ΔP/P) would be proportionate with D. Further, the capital gains would be a mirror image of the capital losses for an equal (small) increase in interest rates. The duration equation can be rearranged, combining D and (1 R) into a single variable D/(1 R), to produce what practitioners call modified duration (MD). For annual compounding of interest: P MD dR P where MD dollar duration The dollar value change in a security’s price to a 1 percent change in the return on the security. D 1R This form is more intuitive because we multiply MD by the simple change in interest rates rather than the discounted change in interest rates as in the general duration equation. Duration is a measure of the percentage change in the price of a security for a 1 percent change in the return on the security. Dollar duration is the dollar value change in the price of a security to a 1 percent change in the return on the security. The dollar duration is defined as the modified duration times the price of a security: Dollar duration MD P Thus, the total dollar value of a security will change by an amount equal to the dollar duration times the change in the return on the security: P Dollar duration R Like the modified duration, the dollar duration is intuitively appealing in that we multiply the dollar duration by the change in the interest rate to get the actual Chapter 9 Interest Rate Risk II 239 dollar change in the value of a security to a change in interest rates.7 Next, we use duration to measure the interest sensitivity of an asset or liability. EXAMPLE 9–3 The Six-Year Eurobond Consider Example 9–1 for the six-year Eurobond with an 8 percent coupon and 8 percent yield. We determined in Table 9–2 that its duration was approximately D 4.993 years. The modified duration is: MD D/(1 R) 4.993/1.08 4.623 That is, the price of the bond will increase by 4.623 percent for a 1 percent decrease in the interest rate on the bond. Further, the dollar duration is: Dollar duration 4.623 $1,000 4,623 or a 1 percent (or 100 basis points) change in the return on the bond would result a change of $46.23 in the price of the bond. To see this, suppose that yields were to rise by one basis point (1/100th of 1 percent) from 8 to 8.01 percent. Then: P ⎡ 0.0001 ⎤ (4.993) ⎢ P ⎣ 1.08 ⎥⎦ 0.000462 or 0.0462% The bond price had been $1,000, which was the present value of a six-year bond with 8 percent coupons and 8 percent yield. The duration model, and specifically dollar duration, predicts that the price of the bond would fall to $999.5377 after the increase in yield by one basis point. That is, the price would change by: P Dollar duration R 4623 0.0001 $0.463 EXAMPLE 9–4 The Consol Bond Consider a consol bond with an 8 percent coupon paid annually, an 8 percent yield, and a calculated duration of 13.5 years (Dc 1 1/0.08 13.5). Thus, for a one-basis-point change in the yield (from 8 percent to 8.01 percent): P ⎡ 0.0001 ⎤ (13.5) ⎢ P ⎣ 1.08 ⎥⎦ 0.00125 or 0.125% 7 Another measure of interest sensitivity is spread duration. Spread duration is the sensitivity of the price of a bond to a change in its option-adjusted spread (OAS). OAS, discussed in Chapter 26, is the required interest spread of a pass-through or mortgage-backed security over a Treasury rate when prepayment risk is taken into account. Since mortgage payers tend to exercise their right to prepay when it is favorable for them, buying a pass-through or mortgage-backed security partly involves selling an option. This is the source of the option-adjusted spread. Thus, spread duration is the price sensitivity of the pass-through or mortgage-backed security to a change in the OAS. A change in the OAS of a pass-through or mortgagebacked security does not affect the cash flows that the security pays to the investor. Thus, spread duration is the impact of these cash flows at varying interest rates. We discuss this in more detail in Chapter 26. 240 Part Two Measuring Risk As you can see, for any given change in yields, long-duration securities suffer a greater capital loss or receive a greater capital gain than do short-duration securities. Semiannual Coupon Bonds For fixed-income assets or liabilities whose interest payments are received semiannually or more frequently than annually, the formula in equation (5) has to be modified slightly. For semiannual payments the percentage change in the price of a bond for a change in interest rates is: P R ⎤ ⎡ D ⎢ ⎥ P ⎣ 1 12 R ⎦ (6) The only difference between equation (6) and equation (5) is the introduction of a ½ in the discount rate term 1 ½R to take into account the semiannual payments of interest. EXAMPLE 9–5 Semiannual Coupon, TwoYear Maturity Treasury Bonds Recall from Example 9–2 the two-year T-bond with semiannual coupons whose duration we derived in Table 9–3 as 1.883 years when annual yields were 12 percent. The modified duration is: MD D/(1 R) 1.883/1.06 1.776 That is, the price of the bond will increase by 1.776 percent for a 1 percent decrease in the interest rate on the bond. Further, the dollar duration is: Dollar duration 1.776 $930.70 1,653 or a 1 percent (or 100 basis points) change in the return on the bond would result a change of $16.53 in the price of the bond. Thus, a one-basis-point rise in interest rates would have the following predicted effect on price: P ⎡ 0.0001 ⎤ 1.883 ⎢ P ⎣ 1.06 ⎥⎦ 0.0001776 or the price of the bond would fall by 0.01776 percent from $930.6979 to $930.5326. That is, P Dollar duration R $16.53 0.0001 $0.1653 Concept Questions 1. What is the relation between the duration of a bond and the interest elasticity of a bond? 2. How would the formula in equation (6) have to be modified to take into account quarterly coupon payments and monthly coupon payments? Chapter 9 Interest Rate Risk II 241 DURATION AND INTEREST RATE RISK So far, you have learned how to calculate duration and you understand that the duration measure has economic meaning because it indicates the interest sensitivity, or elasticity, of an asset or liability’s value. For FIs, the major relevance of duration is as a measure for managing interest rate risk exposure. Also important is the role of duration in allowing the FI to reduce and even eliminate interest rate risk on its balance sheet or some subset of that balance sheet. In the following sections we consider two examples of how FIs can use the duration measure to manage interest rate risk. The first is its use by insurance company and pension fund managers to help meet promised cash flow payments to policyholders or beneficiaries at a particular time in the future. The second is its use to reduce or immunize the whole balance sheet of an FI against interest rate risk. Duration and Interest Rate Risk Management on a Single Security Frequently, pension fund and life insurance company managers face the problem of structuring their asset investments so they can pay out a given cash amount to policyholders in some future period. The classic example of this is an insurance policy that pays the holder some lump sum on reaching retirement age. The risk to the life insurance company manager is that interest rates on the funds generated from investing the holder’s premiums could fall. Thus, the accumulated returns on the premiums invested could not meet the target or promised amount. In effect, the insurance company would be forced to draw down its reserves and net worth to meet its payout commitments. (See Chapter 6 for a discussion of this risk.) Suppose that we are in 2016 and the insurer has to make a guaranteed payment to a policyholder in five years, 2021. For simplicity, we assume that this target guaranteed payment is $1,469, a lump-sum policy payout on retirement, equivalent to investing $1,000 at an annually compounded rate of 8 percent over five years. Of course, realistically, this payment would be much larger, but the underlying principles of the example do not change by scaling up or down the payout amount. To immunize, or protect, itself against interest rate risk, the insurer needs to determine which investments would produce a cash flow of exactly $1,469 in five years regardless of what happens to interest rates in the immediate future. The FI investing either in a five-year maturity and duration zero-coupon bond or in a coupon bond with a five-year duration would produce a $1,469 cash flow in five years no matter what happened to interest rates in the immediate future. Next, we consider the two strategies: buying five-year maturity (and duration) deepdiscount bonds and buying five-year duration coupon bonds. Buy Five-Year Maturity Discount Bonds Given a $1,000 face value, an 8 percent yield, and assuming annual compounding, the current price per five-year discount bond would be $680.58 per bond: P 680.58 1,000 (1.08)5 If the insurer bought 1.469 of these bonds at a total cost of $1,000 in 2016, these investments would produce exactly $1,469 on maturity in five years ($1,000 (1.08)5 $1,469). The reason is that the duration of this bond portfolio 242 Part Two Measuring Risk exactly matches the target horizon for the insurer’s future liability to its policyholder. Intuitively, since no intervening cash flows or coupons are paid by the issuer of the zero-coupon discount bonds, future changes in interest rates have no reinvestment income effect. Thus, the return would be unaffected by intervening interest rate changes. Buy a Five-Year Duration Coupon Bond Suppose no five-year discount bonds exist. Then the portfolio manager may seek to invest in appropriate duration coupon bonds to hedge interest rate risk. In this example the appropriate investment would be in five-year duration coupon bearing bonds. We demonstrated earlier in Table 9–2 that a six-year maturity Eurobond paying 8 percent coupons with an 8 percent yield to maturity had a duration of 4.993 years, or approximately five years. If we buy this six-year maturity, fiveyear duration bond in 2016 and hold it for five years, until 2021, the term exactly matches the target horizon of the insurer. The cash flows generated at the end of five years will be $1,469 whether interest rates stay at 8 percent or instantaneously (immediately) rise to 9 percent or fall to 7 percent. Thus, buying a coupon bond whose duration exactly matches the time horizon of the insurer also immunizes the insurer against interest rate changes. EXAMPLE 9–6 Interest Rates Remain at 8 Percent The cash flows received by the insurer on the bond if interest rates stay at 8 percent throughout the five years would be 1. Coupons, 5 $80 2. Reinvestment income 3. Proceeds from sale of bond at end of fifth year $ 400 69 1,000 $1,469 We calculate each of the three components of the insurer’s income from the bond investment as follows: 1. Coupons. The $400 from coupons is simply the annual coupon of $80 received in each of the five years. 2. Reinvestment income. Because the coupons are received annually, they can be reinvested at 8 percent as they are received, generating an additional cash flow of $69.8 8 Receiving annual coupons of $80 is equivalent to receiving an annuity of $80. The appropriate terminal value of receiving $1 a year for five years and reinvesting at 8 percent can be determined from the future value of an annuity (FVA) formula: ⎡ (1 R )n 1 ⎤ FVAn, R ⎢ ⎥ R ⎦ ⎣ In our example: FVA 5, 8% ⎡ (1 0.08)5 1 ⎤ ⎥ 5.867 ⎢ 0.08 ⎦ ⎣ Thus, the reinvestment income for $80 of coupons per year is: Reinvestment income (80 5.867) 400 469 400 69 Note that we take away $400 since we have already counted the simple coupon income (5 $80). Chapter 9 Interest Rate Risk II 243 3. Bond sale proceeds. The proceeds from the sale are calculated by recognizing that the six year bond has just one year left to maturity when it is sold by the insurance company at the end of the fifth year. That is: ↓ Sell $1,080 Year 5 (2021) Year 6 (2022) What fair market price can the insurer expect to get when selling the bond at the end of the fifth year with one year left to maturity? A buyer would be willing to pay the present value of the $1,080—final coupon plus face value—to be received at the end of the one remaining year (i.e., in 2022), or: P5 1, 080 $1, 000 1.08 Thus, the insurer would be able to sell the one remaining cash flow of $1,080, to be received in the bond’s final year, for $1,000. Next, we show that since this bond has a duration of five years, matching the insurer’s target period, even if interest rates were to instantaneously fall to 7 percent or rise to 9 percent, the expected cash flows from the bond would still exactly sum to $1,469. That is, the coupons reinvestment income principal at the end of the fifth year would be immunized. In other words, the cash flows on the bond are protected against interest rate changes. EXAMPLE 9–7 Interest Rates Fall to 7 Percent In this example with falling interest rates, the cash flows over the five years would be: 1. Coupons, 5 $80 2. Reinvestment income 3. Bond sale proceeds $ 400 60 1,009 $1,469 The total proceeds over the five years are unchanged from what they were when interest rates were 8 percent. To see why this occurs, consider what happens to the three parts of the cash flow when rates fall to 7 percent: 1. Coupons. Are unchanged since the insurer still gets five annual coupons of $80 $400. 2. Reinvestment income. The coupons can now be reinvested only at the lower rate of 7 percent. Reinvestment income is only $60, which is $9 less than it was when rates were 8 percent.9 9 This reinvestment income is calculated as follows. FVA 5, 7% ⎡ (1 0.07)5 1 ⎤ ⎥ 5.751 ⎢ 0.07 ⎦ ⎣ Reinvestment income (5.751 80) 400 60. 244 Part Two Measuring Risk 3. Bond sale proceeds. When the six-year maturity bond is sold at the end of the fifth year with one cash flow of $1,080 remaining, investors are now willing to pay more: P5 1,080 1,009 1.07 That is, the bond can be sold for $9 more than it could have when rates were 8 percent. The reason for this is that investors can get only 7 percent on newly issued bonds, while this older bond was issued with a higher coupon of 8 percent. A comparison of reinvestment income with bond sale proceeds indicates that the fall in rates has produced a gain on the bond sale proceeds of $9. This exactly offsets the loss of reinvestment income of $9 due to reinvesting at a lower interest rate. Thus, total cash flows remain unchanged at $1,469. EXAMPLE 9–8 Interest Rates Rise to 9 Percent In this example with rising interest rates, the proceeds from the bond investment are: 1. Coupons, 5 $80 2. Reinvestment income [(5.985 80) 400] 3. Bond sale proceeds (1,080/1.09) $ 400 78 991 $1,469 Notice that the rise in interest rates from 8 percent to 9 percent leaves the final terminal cash flow unaffected at $1,469. The rise in rates has generated $9 extra reinvestment income ($78 $69), but the price at which the bond can be sold at the end of the fifth year has declined from $1,000 to $991, equal to a capital loss of $9. Thus, the gain in reinvestment income is exactly offset by the capital loss on the sale of the bond. These examples demonstrate that matching the duration of a coupon bond— or any other fixed–interest rate instrument, such as a loan or mortgage—to the FI’s target or investment horizon immunizes the FI against instantaneous shocks to interest rates. The gains or losses on reinvestment income that result from an interest rate change are exactly offset by losses or gains from the bond proceeds on sale. Duration and Interest Rate Risk Management on the Whole Balance Sheet of an FI duration gap A measure of overall interest rate risk exposure for an FI. So far we have looked at the durations of individual instruments and ways to select individual fixed-income securities to protect FIs such as life insurance companies and pensions funds with precommitted liabilities such as future pension plan payouts. The duration model can also evaluate the overall interest rate exposure for an FI, that is, measure the duration gap on its balance sheet. The Duration Gap for a Financial Institution To estimate the overall duration gap of an FI, we determine first the duration of an FI’s asset portfolio (A) and the duration of its liability portfolio (L). These can be calculated as: DA X 1 A D1A X 2 A D2A ... X nA DnA Chapter 9 Interest Rate Risk II 245 and DL X 1L D1L X 2 L D2L ... X nL DnL where X 1 j X 2 j ... X nj 1 and j A, L The Xij’s in the equation are the market value proportions of each asset or liability held in the respective asset and liability portfolios. Thus, if new 30-year Treasury bonds were 1 percent of a life insurer’s portfolio and D1A (the duration of those bonds) was equal to 9.25 years, then X 1 A D1A 0.01(9.25) 0.0925. More simply, the duration of a portfolio of assets or liabilities is a market value weighted average of the individual durations of the assets or liabilities on the FI’s balance sheet. Consider an FI’s simplified market value balance sheet: Assets ($) Liabilities ($) A 100 L 90 E 10 100 100 From the balance sheet: A LE and A L E or E A L That is, when interest rates change, the change in the FI’s equity or net worth (E) is equal to the difference between the change in the market values of assets and liabilities on each side of the balance sheet. Since ΔE ΔA ΔL, we need to determine how ΔA and ΔL—the changes in the market values of assets and liabilities on the balance sheet—are related to duration. From the duration model (assuming annual compounding of interest): A R DA (1 R) A L R DL (1 R) L Here we have simply substituted ΔA/A or ΔL/L, the percentage change in the market values of assets or liabilities, for ΔP/P, the percentage change in any single bond’s price and DA or DL, the duration of the FI’s asset or liability portfolio, for D, the duration on any given bond, deposit, or loan. The term ΔR/(1 R) reflects the shock to interest rates as before.10 These equations can be rewritten to show the dollar changes in assets and liabilities on an FI’s balance sheet: R (7) A DA A (1 R) and L DL L R (1 R) (8) 246 Part Two Measuring Risk We can substitute these two expressions into the equation ΔE ΔA ΔL. Rearranging and combining this equation results in a measure of the change in the market value of equity on an FI’s balance sheet for a change in interest rates: E [DA DL k ] A R 1R (9) where k L/A is a measure of the FI’s leverage, that is, the amount of borrowed funds or liabilities rather than owners’ equity used to fund its asset portfolio.11 The effect of interest rate changes on the market value of an FI’s equity or net worth (ΔE) breaks down into three effects: 1. The leverage adjusted duration gap [DA DLk]. This gap is measured in years and reflects the degree of duration mismatch in an FI’s balance sheet. Specifically, the larger this gap is in absolute terms, the more exposed the FI is to interest rate shocks. 2. The size of the FI. The term A measures the size of the FI’s assets. The larger the scale of the FI, the larger the dollar size of the potential net worth exposure from any given interest rate shock. 3. The size of the interest rate shock ΔR/(1 R). The larger the shock, the greater the FI’s exposure. Given this, we express the exposure of the net worth of the FI as: E [Leverage adjusted duration gap] Asset size Interest rate shock Interest rate shocks are largely external to the FI and often result from changes in the Federal Reserve’s monetary policy (as discussed in the first section of Chapter 8). The size of the duration gap and the size of the FI, however, are under the control of management. The Industry Perspectives box reports the duration gaps and the estimated changes in equity value for three financial institutions during the first quarter of 2012. Note that all three institutions had average duration gaps that were negative 10 We assume that the level of rates and the expected shock to interest rates are the same for both assets and liabilities, which means that the FI’s spread (the difference between the rate on earning assets and interest-bearing liabilities) is zero. However, as long as the FI has more earning assets than interest bearing liabilities, it will have a positive level for net interest income. This assumption is standard in Macaulay duration analysis. While restrictive, this assumption can be relaxed. However, if this is done, the duration measure changes, as is discussed later in Appendix 9B to this chapter. 11 We do this as follows: R ⎤ R ⎤ ⎡ ⎡ ⎢ DL L E ⎢ DA A (1 R ) ⎥⎦ (1 R ) ⎥⎦ ⎣ ⎣ Assuming that the level of rates and the expected shock to interest rates are the same for both assets and liabilities: R E [DA A DLL] (1 R ) or E [DA A DLL] R (1 R ) To rearrange the equation in a slightly more intuitive fashion, we multiply and divide both DAA and DLL by A (assets): A L⎤ R ⎡ E ⎢ DA DL ⎥ A A (1 R ) A⎦ ⎣ R or E [DA DLk ] A (1 R ) Chapter 9 Interest Rate Risk II 247 or zero. However, Fannie Mae’s duration gaps ranged between 0.9 month and 0.4 month, while Freddie Mac’s ranged between 0.3 month and 0.6 month. Even these small fluctuations exposed Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac to as much as $200 million and $379 million, respectively, in equity value losses. Industry Perspectives Duration GAP for Various Financial Institutions, March 2012 PRINCIPAL FINANCIAL GROUP March 31, 2012 Risk Management Strategy Value of total assets Duration of assets Net duration gap Net fair value change Primary duration-managed Duration-monitored Non-duration-managed Total (in millions) $26,074.4 25,566.4 5,253.9 $56,894.7 3.73 4.28 4.19 (0.12) (3.44) N/A (in millions) $31.3 879.9 N/A $911.2 Net fair value change is based on a 100 basis point immediate, parallel increase in interest rates increases. Duration-Managed Our exposure to interest rate risk stems largely from our substantial holdings of guaranteed fixed rate liabilities in our Retirement and Investor Services segment. We actively manage the duration of assets and liabilities in these products by minimizing the difference between the two. Non-Duration-Managed We also have a block of participating general account pension business that passes most of the actual investment performance of the assets to the customer. The investment strategy of this block is to maximize investment return to the customer on a “best efforts” basis, and there is little or no attempt to manage the duration of this portfolio since there is little or no interest rate risk. Duration-Monitored For products such as whole life insurance and term life insurance that are less sensitive to interest rate risk, and for other products such as individual fixed deferred annuities, we manage interest rate risk based on a modeling process that considers the target average life, maturities, crediting rates, and assumptions of policyholder behavior. FANNIE MAE The duration gap for the three months ended March 31, 2012, averaged zero months, which is similar to the results for the three months ended March 31, 2011. Rate Slope Shock measures the change in the value of the equity for the stated change in interest rates. For the Three Months Ended March 31, 2012 Duration Gap Rate Slope Shock 25 Bps Rate Level Shock 50 Bps Exposure (in months) Average. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Minimum . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Maximum . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Standard deviation. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . (0.1) (0.9) 0.4 0.3 (dollars in billions) $— — 0.1 — $— — 0.2 0.1 continued 248 Part Two Measuring Risk Industry Perspectives continued For the Three Months Ended March 31, 2011 Duration Gap Rate Slope Shock 25 Bps Rate Level Shock 50 Bps Exposure (in months) Average. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Minimum . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Maximum . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Standard deviation. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . (dollars in billions) 0.4 (0.4) 0.8 0.2 $0.1 — 0.2 — $0.2 0.1 0.4 0.1 FREDDIE MAC Three Months Ended March 31, 2012 Duration Gap (in months) Average. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Minimum . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Maximum . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Standard deviation. . . . . . . . . . . . . 0.0 (0.3) 0.6 0.2 * PMVS measures the change in the value of the equity for the stated change in interest rates. PMVS* 25 bps 2011 PMVS 50 bps (dollars in millions) $16 $ 1 $57 $12 $223 $130 $379 $ 47 Duration Gap PMVS 25 bps PMVS 50 bps (in months) (dollars in millions) (0.3) (1.0) 0.4 0.3 $21 $— $51 $13 $448 $280 $721 $101 Sources: Principal Financial Group, Form 10-Q, March 31, 2012; Fannie Mae, Form 10-Q, March 31, 2012; Freddie Mac, Form 10-Q, March 31, 2012. Equation (9) and the duration model provide an FI manager with a benchmark measure of the FI’s performance for various interest rate changes and therefore the extent to which the FI is exposed to interest rate risk. If, for an expected change in interest rates, managers find the change in equity will be small or negative, the duration model can be used to identify changes needed on or off the FI’s balance sheet to reduce or even immunize the FI against interest rate risk. Using an example, the next section explains how a manager can use information on an FI’s duration gap to restructure the balance sheet to limit losses and even immunize stockholders’ net worth against interest rate risk (i.e., to set the balance sheet up before a change in interest rates, so that ΔE is nonnegative for an expected change in interest rates). Chapters 22, 23, and 24 look at ways a manager can use the duration gap to take off-balance-sheet positions in derivative securities to reduce or immunize the FI against interest rate risk. Chapter 9 EXAMPLE 9–9 Duration Gap Measurement and Exposure Interest Rate Risk II 249 Suppose the FI manager calculates that: DA 5 years DL 3 years Then the manager learns from an economic forecasting unit that rates are expected to rise from 10 percent to 11 percent in the immediate future; that is: R 1% 0.01 1 R 1.10 The FI’s initial balance sheet is assumed to be: Assets ($ millions) Liabilities ($ millions) A 100 L 90 E 10 100 100 The FI’s manager calculates the potential loss to equity holders’ net worth (E) if the forecast of rising rates proves true as follows: E ( DA kDL ) A R (1 R ) (5 (0.9)(3)) $100 million 0.01 $2.09 million 1.10 The FI could lose $2.09 million in net worth if rates rise 1 percent. Since the FI started with $10 million in equity, the loss of $2.09 million is almost 21 percent of its initial net worth. The market value balance sheet after the rise in rates by 1 percent would look like this:12 Assets ($ millions) Liabilities ($ millions) A 95.45 L 87.54 E 7.91 95.45 95.45 12 These values are calculated as follows: A A 5(0.01 1.10) 0.04545 4.545% 100 ( 0.04545)100 95.45 and L L 3(0.01 1.10) 0.02727 2.727% 90 ( 0.02727)90 87.54 250 Part Two Measuring Risk Even though the rise in interest rates would not push the FI into economic insolvency, it reduces the FI’s net worth-to-assets ratio from 10 (10/100) to 8.29 (7.91/95.45) percent. To counter this effect, the manager might reduce the FI’s duration gap. In an extreme case, the gap might be reduced to zero: E [0] A R (1 R) 0 To do this, the FI should not directly set DA DL, which ignores the fact that the FI’s assets (A) do not equal its borrowed liabilities (L) and that k (which reflects the ratio L/A) is not equal to 1. To see the importance of factoring in leverage, suppose the manager increased the duration of the FI’s liabilities to five years, the same as DA. Then: E [5 (0.9)(5)] $100 million (0.01/1.10) $0.45 million The FI is still exposed to a loss of $0.45 million if rates rise by 1 percent. An appropriate strategy would involve changing DL until: DA kDL 5 years For example, E [5 (0.9) 5.55] $100 million (0.01/1.10) 0 In this case the FI manager sets DL 5.55 years, or slightly longer than DA 5 years, to compensate for the fact that only 90 percent of assets are funded by borrowed liabilities, with the other 10 percent funded by equity. Note that the FI manager has at least three other ways to reduce the duration gap to zero: 1. Reduce DA. Reduce DA from 5 years to 2.7 years [equal to kDL or (0.9)3] such that: [DA kDL ] [2.7 (0.9)(3)] 0 2. Reduce DA and increase DL. Shorten the duration of assets and lengthen the duration of liabilities at the same time. One possibility would be to reduce DA to 4 years and to increase DL to 4.44 years such that: [DA kDL ] [4 (0.9)(4.44)] 0 3. Change k and DL. Increase k (leverage) from 0.9 to 0.95 and increase DL from 3 years to 5.26 years such that: [DA kDL ] [5 (0.95)(5.26)] 0 Concept Questions 1. Refer to the example of the insurer in Examples 9–6 through 9–8. Suppose rates fell to 6 percent. Would the FI’s portfolio still be immunized? What if rates rose to 10 percent? 2. How is the overall duration gap for an FI calculated? 3. How can a manager use information on an FI’s duration gap to restructure, and thereby immunize, the balance sheet against interest rate risk? 4. Suppose DA 3 years, DL 6 years, k 0.8, and A $100 million. What is the effect on owners’ net worth if ∆R/(1 R) rises 1 percent? (∆E $1,800,000) Chapter 9 Interest Rate Risk II 251 IMMUNIZATION AND REGULATORY CONSIDERATIONS In the above section we assumed that the FI manager wants to structure the duration of assets and liabilities to immunize the equity or net worth (E) of the FI’s equity owners from interest rate shocks. However, regulators periodically monitor the solvency or capital position of FIs. As we discuss in greater detail in Chapter 20 on capital adequacy, regulators set minimum target ratios for an FI’s capital (or net worth) to assets. The simplest is the ratio of FI capital to its assets, or: E Capital (net worth ) ratio A www.sec.gov While this target has normally been formulated in book value accounting terms for depository institutions, it is evaluated in a market value context for investment banks. Also, the SEC has long advocated a capital ratio based on market value accounting for U.S. depository institutions. Given these regulations imposed on the minimum level of the capital ratio, if an FI’s asset levels change significantly through time, FI managers may be most interested in immunizing against changes in the capital ratio (Δ(E/A)) due to interest rate risk rather than changes in the level of capital (ΔE). For example, suppose the FI manager is close to the minimum regulatory required E/A (or capital) ratio (e.g., 4.5 percent for depository institutions) and wants to immunize the FI against any fall in this ratio if interest rates rise.13 That is, the immunization target is no longer ΔE 0 when rates change but Δ(E/A) 0. Obviously, immunizing ΔE against interest rate risk cannot result in the same management strategy as immunizing Δ(E/A). A portfolio constructed to immunize ΔE would have a different duration match from that required to immunize Δ(E/A). Or, more simply, the manager could satisfy either the FI’s stockholders or the regulators but not both simultaneously. More specifically, when the objective is to immunize equity capital against interest rate risk, that is, to set ΔE 0, the FI manager should structure the balance sheet so that the leverage adjusted duration gap is zero: E 0 DA kDL or set DA kDL By comparison, to immunize the capital ratio, that is, to set Δ(E/A) 0 the manager needs to set: DA DL In this scenario, the leverage adjustment effect (k) drops out. If DA 5, then immunizing the capital ratio would require setting DL 5. Concept Question 1. Is immunizing a bank’s net worth the same as immunizing its net worth-to-assets ratio? If not, why not? 13 In actuality, depository institutions face three required minimum capital ratios. The 4.5 percent rule used in this example is for the common equity capital ratio (see Chapter 20 for more details). 252 Part Two Measuring Risk In the next section, we analyze weaknesses of the duration model. Specifically, there are several practical problems in estimating duration and duration gap for real-world FIs. DIFFICULTIES IN APPLYING THE DURATION MODEL www.bis.org Critics of the duration model have often claimed that it is difficult to apply in real world situations. However, duration measures and immunization strategies are useful in most real-world situations. In fact, the model used by the Bank for International Settlements to monitor bank interest rate risk taking is based heavily on the duration model. In this section, we look at the various criticisms of the duration model and discuss ways that an FI manager would deal with them in practice. In Appendix 9B to the chapter, we present some of the more advanced issues associated with these weaknesses. Duration Matching Can Be Costly Critics charge that although in principle an FI manager can change DA and DL to immunize the FI against interest rate risk, restructuring the balance sheet of a large and complex FI can be both time-consuming and costly. While this argument may have been true historically, the growth of purchased funds, asset securitization, and loan sales markets has considerably eased the speed and lowered the transaction costs of major balance sheet restructurings. (See Chapters 25 and 26 for a discussion of these strategies.) Moreover, an FI manager could still manage risk exposure using the duration model by employing techniques other than direct portfolio rebalancing to immunize against interest rate risk. Managers can get many of the same results of direct duration matching by taking hedging positions in the markets for derivative securities, such as futures and forwards (Chapter 22); options, caps, floors, and collars (Chapter 23); and swaps (Chapter 24). Immunization Is a Dynamic Problem Immunization is an aspect of the duration model that is not well understood. Let’s go back to the earlier immunization example in which an insurer sought to buy bonds to provide an accumulated cash flow of $1,469 in five years no matter what happened to interest rates. We showed that buying a six-year maturity, 8 percent coupon bond with a five-year duration immunizes the insurer against an instantaneous change in interest rates. The word instantaneous is very important here; it means a change in interest rates immediately after purchasing the bond. However, interest rates can change at any time over the holding period. Further, the duration of a bond changes as time passes, that is, as it approaches maturity or the target horizon date. In addition, duration changes at a different rate than does real or calendar time. To understand this time effect, consider the initially hedged position in which the insurer bought the five-year duration (six-year maturity), 8 percent coupon bond in 2016 to match its cash flow target of $1,469 in 2021. Suppose the FI manager puts the bond in the bottom drawer of a desk and does not think about it for a year, believing that the insurance company’s position is fully hedged. After one Chapter 9 Interest Rate Risk II 253 year has passed (in 2017), suppose interest rates (yields) have fallen from 8 percent to 7 percent and the manager opens the drawer of the desk and finds the bond. Knowing the target date is now only four years away, the manager recalculates the duration of the bond. Imagine the manager’s shock on finding that the same 8 percent coupon bond with a 7 percent yield and only five years left to maturity has a duration of 4.33 years. This means the insurance company is no longer hedged; the 4.33-year duration of this bond portfolio exceeds the investment horizon of four years. As a result, the manager has to restructure the bond portfolio to remain immunized. One way to do this is to sell some of the five-year bonds (4.33-year duration) and buy some bonds of shorter duration so that the overall duration of the investment portfolio is four years. For example, suppose the insurer sold 50 percent of the five-year bonds with a 4.33-year duration and invested the proceeds in 3.67-year duration and maturity zero-coupon bonds. Because duration and maturity are the same for discount bonds, the duration of the asset portfolio is: DA [4.33 0.5] [3.67 0.5] 4 years This simple example demonstrates that immunization based on duration is a dynamic strategy. In theory, the strategy requires the portfolio manager to rebalance the portfolio continuously to ensure that the duration of the investment portfolio exactly matches the investment horizon (i.e., the duration of liabilities). Because continuous rebalancing may not be easy to do and involves costly transaction fees, most portfolio managers seek to be only approximately dynamically immunized against interest rate changes by rebalancing at discrete intervals, such as quarterly. That is, there is a trade-off between being perfectly immunized and the transaction costs of maintaining an immunized balance sheet dynamically. Large Interest Rate Changes and Convexity Duration accurately measures the price sensitivity of fixed-income securities for small changes in interest rates of the order of one basis point. But suppose interest rate shocks are much larger, of the order of 2 percent, or 200 basis points. Then duration becomes a less accurate predictor of how much the prices of securities will change and therefore a less accurate measure of interest rate sensitivity. Looking at Figure 9–5, you can see the reason for this. Note first the change in a bond’s price due to yield changes according to the duration model and second, the true relationship, as calculated directly, using the exact present value calculation for bond valuation. The duration model predicts that the relationship between interest rate shocks and bond price changes will be proportional to D (duration). However, by precisely calculating the true change in bond prices, we would find that for large interest rate increases, duration overpredicts the fall in bond prices, while for large interest rate decreases, it underpredicts the increase in bond prices. That is, the duration model predicts symmetric effects for rate increases and decreases on bond prices. As Figure 9–5 shows, in actuality, for rate increases, the capital loss effect tends to be smaller than the capital gain effect is for rate decreases. This is the result of the bond price–yield relationship exhibiting a property called convexity rather than linearity, as assumed by the basic duration model. 254 Part Two Measuring Risk + ΔP/P FIGURE 9–5 Duration versus True Relationship Error + − 0 −D ΔR 1+R True relationship Error Duration model − convexity The degree of curvature of the price–yield curve around some interest rate level. Note that convexity is a desirable feature for an FI manager to capture in a portfolio of assets. Buying a bond or a portfolio of assets that exhibits a lot of convexity, or curvature, in the price–yield curve relationship is similar to buying partial interest rate risk insurance. Specifically, high convexity means that for equally large changes of interest rates up and down (e.g., plus or minus 2 percent), the capital gain effect of a rate decrease more than offsets the capital loss effect of a rate increase. As we show in Appendix 9B to the chapter, all fixed-income assets or liabilities exhibit some convexity in their price–yield relationships. To see the importance of accounting for the effects of convexity in assessing the impact of large rate changes on an FI’s portfolio, consider the six-year Eurobond with an 8 percent coupon and yield. According to Table 9–2, its duration is 4.993 years, and its current price P0 is $1,000 at a yield of 8 percent: P0 80 80 80 (1.08) (1.08)2 (1.08)3 80 80 1, 080 $1, 000 (1.08)4 (1.08)5 (1.08)6 This is point A on the price–yield curve in Figure 9–6. If rates rise from 8 to 10 percent, the duration model predicts that the bond price will fall by 9.2463 percent; that is: P 0.02 ⎤ 4.993 ⎡⎢ 9.2463% P ⎣ 1.08 ⎥⎦ or, from a price of $1,000 to $907.537 (see point B in Figure 9–6). However, calculating the exact change in the bond’s price after a rise in yield to 10 percent, we find that its true value is: P0 80 80 80 2 (1.10) (1.10) (1.10)3 80 80 1, 080 $912.895 (1.10)4 (1.10)5 (1.10)6 Chapter 9 FIGURE 9–6 The Price–Yield Curve for the SixYear Eurobond Interest Rate Risk II 255 Price (P) E 1,098.347 Error 1,092.463 D A 1,000 912.895 C 907.537 B 6% 8% 10% Error Yield (R ) This is point C in Figure 9–6. As you can see, the true or actual fall in price is less than the predicted fall by $5.358. This means that there is over a 0.5 percent error using the duration model. The reason for this is the natural convexity to the price– yield curve as yields rise. Reversing the experiment reveals that the duration model would predict the bond’s price to rise by 9.2463 percent if yields fell from 8 to 6 percent, resulting in a predicted price of $1,092.463 (see point D in Figure 9–6). By comparison, the true or actual change in price can be computed as $1,098.347 by estimating the present value of the bond’s coupons and its face value with a 6 percent yield (see point E in Figure 9–6). The duration model has underpredicted the bond price increase by $5.884, or by over 0.5 percent of the true price increase. An important question for the FI manager is whether a 0.5 percent error is big enough to be concerned about. This depends on the size of the interest rate change and the size of the portfolio under management. Clearly, 0.5 percent of a large number will still be a large number! Summary This chapter analyzed the duration gap model approach to measuring interest rate risk. The duration gap model is superior to the simple repricing gap model in that it incorporates the timing of cash flows as well as maturity effects into a simple measure of interest rate risk. The duration gap measure could be used to immunize a particular liability as well as the whole FI balance sheet. However, as the concluding section of the chapter indicates, a number of potential problems exist in applying the duration gap model in real-world scenarios. Despite these weaknesses, the duration gap model is fairly robust and can deal with a large number of real-world complexities, such as credit risk, convexity, floating interest rates, and uncertain maturities. 256 Part Two Measuring Risk www.mhhe.com/saunders8e Questions and Problems 1. What is the difference between book value accounting and market value accounting? How do interest rate changes affect the value of bank assets and liabilities under the two methods? What is marking to market? 2. What are the two different general interpretations of the concept of duration, and what is the technical definition of this term? How does duration differ from maturity? 3. A one-year, $100,000 loan carries a coupon rate and a market interest rate of 12 percent. The loan requires payment of accrued interest and one-half of the principal at the end of six months. The remaining principal and the accrued interest are due at the end of the year. a. What will be the cash flows at the end of six months and at the end of the year? b. What is the present value of each cash flow discounted at the market rate? What is the total present value? c. What proportion of the total present value of cash flows occurs at the end of six months? What proportion occurs at the end of the year? d. What is the duration of this loan? 4. Two bonds are available for purchase in the financial markets. The first bond is a two-year, $1,000 bond that pays an annual coupon of 10 percent. The second bond is a two-year, $1,000 zero-coupon bond. a. What is the duration of the coupon bond if the current yield to maturity (R) is 8 percent? 10 percent? 12 percent? (Hint: You may wish to create a spreadsheet program to assist in the calculations.) b. How does the change in the yield to maturity affect the duration of this coupon bond? c. Calculate the duration of the zero-coupon bond with a yield to maturity of 8 percent, 10 percent, and 12 percent. d. How does the change in the yield to maturity affect the duration of the zero coupon bond? e. Why does the change in the yield to maturity affect the coupon bond differently than it affects the zero-coupon bond? 5. What is the duration of a five-year, $1,000 Treasury bond with a 10 percent semiannual coupon selling at par? Selling with a yield to maturity of 12 percent? 14 percent? What can you conclude about the relationship between duration and yield to maturity? Plot the relationship. Why does this relationship exist? 6. Consider three Treasury bonds each of which has a 10 percent semiannual coupon and trades at par. a. Calculate the duration for a bond that has a maturity of four years, three years, and two years. b. What conclusions can you reach about the relationship between duration and the time to maturity? Plot the relationship. 7. A six-year, $10,000 CD pays 6 percent interest annually and has a 6 percent yield to maturity. What is the duration of the CD? What would be the duration if interest were paid semiannually? What is the relationship of duration to the relative frequency of interest payments? 8. What is a consol bond? What is the duration of a consol bond that sells at a yield to maturity of 8 percent? 10 percent? 12 percent? Would a consol trading at a yield to maturity of 10 percent have a greater duration than a 20-year zerocoupon bond trading at the same yield to maturity? Why? Interest Rate Risk II 257 9. Maximum Pension Fund is attempting to manage one of the bond portfolios under its management. The fund has identified three bonds that have five year maturities and trade at a yield to maturity of 9 percent. The bonds differ only in that the coupons are 7 percent, 9 percent, and 11 percent. a. What is the duration for each bond? b. What is the relationship between duration and the amount of coupon interest that is paid? Plot the relationship. 10. An insurance company is analyzing three bonds and is using duration as the measure of interest rate risk. All three bonds trade at a yield to maturity of 10 percent, have $10,000 par values, and have five years to maturity. The bonds differ only in the amount of annual coupon interest they pay: 8, 10, and 12 percent. a. What is the duration for each five-year bond? b. What is the relationship between duration and the amount of coupon interest that is paid? 11. You can obtain a loan of $100,000 at a rate of 10 percent for two years. You have a choice of (i) paying the interest (10 percent) each year and the total principal at the end of the second year or (ii) amortizing the loan, that is, paying interest (10 percent) and principal in equal payments each year. The loan is priced at par. a. What is the duration of the loan under both methods of payment? b. Explain the difference in the two results. 12. How is duration related to the interest elasticity of a fixed-income security? What is the relationship between duration and the price of the fixed-income security? 13. You have discovered that the price of a bond rose from $975 to $995 when the yield to maturity fell from 9.75 percent to 9.25 percent. What is the duration of the bond? 14. A 10-year, 10 percent annual coupon, $1,000 bond trades at a yield to maturity of 8 percent. The bond has a duration of 6.994 years. What is the modified duration of this bond? What is the practical value of calculating modified duration? Does modified duration change the result of using the duration relationship to estimate price sensitivity? 15. What is dollar duration? How is dollar duration different from duration? 16. Calculate the duration of a two-year, $1,000 bond that pays an annual coupon of 10 percent and trades at a yield of 14 percent. What is the expected change in the price of the bond if interest rates fall by 0.50 percent (50 basis points)? 17. The duration of an 11-year, $1,000 Treasury bond paying a 10 percent semiannual coupon and selling at par has been estimated at 6.763 years. a. What is the modified duration of the bond? What is the dollar duration of the bond? b. What will be the estimated price change on the bond if interest rates increase 0.10 percent (10 basis points)? If rates decrease 0.20 percent (20 basis points)? c. What would the actual price of the bond be under each rate change situation in part (b) using the traditional present value bond pricing techniques? What is the amount of error in each case? 18. Suppose you purchase a six-year, 8 percent coupon bond (paid annually) that is priced to yield 9 percent. The face value of the bond is $1,000. a. Show that the duration of this bond is equal to five years. www.mhhe.com/saunders8e Chapter 9 258 Part Two Measuring Risk 19. 20. www.mhhe.com/saunders8e 21. 22. 23. b. Show that if interest rates rise to 10 percent within the next year and your investment horizon is five years from today, you will still earn a 9 percent yield on your investment. c. Show that a 9 percent yield also will be earned if interest rates fall next year to 8 percent. Suppose you purchase a five-year, 15 percent coupon bond (paid annually) that is priced to yield 9 percent. The face value of the bond is $1,000. a. Show that the duration of this bond is equal to four years. b. Show that if interest rates rise to 10 percent within the next year and your investment horizon is four years from today, you will still earn a 9 percent yield on your investment. c. Show that a 9 percent yield also will be earned if interest rates fall next year to 8 percent. Consider the case in which an investor holds a bond for a period of time longer than the duration of the bond, that is, longer than the original investment horizon. a. If interest rates rise, will the return that is earned exceed or fall short of the original required rate of return? Explain. b. What will happen to the realized return if interest rates decrease? Explain. c. Recalculate parts (b) and (c) of problem 19 above, assuming that the bond is held for all five years, to verify your answers to parts (a) and (b) of this problem. d. If either calculation in part (c) is greater than the original required rate of return, why would an investor ever try to match the duration of an asset with his or her investment horizon? Two banks are being examined by regulators to determine the interest rate sensitivity of their balance sheets. Bank A has assets composed solely of a 10-year $1 million loan with a coupon rate and yield of 12 percent. The loan is financed with a 10-year $1 million CD with a coupon rate and yield of 10 percent. Bank B has assets composed solely of a 7-year, 12 percent zero-coupon bond with a current (market) value of $894,006.20 and a maturity (principal) value of $1,976,362.88. The bond is financed with a 10-year, 8.275 percent coupon $1,000,000 face value CD with a yield to maturity of 10 percent. The loan and the CDs pay interest annually, with principal due at maturity. a. If market interest rates increase 1 percent (100 basis points), how do the market values of the assets and liabilities of each bank change? That is, what will be the net effect on the market value of the equity for each bank? b. What accounts for the differences in the changes in the market value of equity between the two banks? c. Verify your results above by calculating the duration for the assets and liabilities of each bank, and estimate the changes in value for the expected change in interest rates. Summarize your results. If an FI uses only duration to immunize its portfolio, what three factors affect changes in the net worth of the FI when interest rates change? Financial Institution XY has assets of $1 million invested in a 30-year, 10 percent semiannual coupon Treasury bond selling at par. The duration of this bond has been estimated at 9.94 years. The assets are financed with equity and a $900,000, two-year, 7.25 percent semiannual coupon capital note selling at par. a. What is the leverage adjusted duration gap of Financial Institution XY? Chapter 9 Interest Rate Risk II 259 b. What is the impact on equity value if the relative change in all market interest rates is a decrease of 20 basis points? Note: The relative change in interest rates is ΔR/(1 R/2) 0.0020. c. Using the information in parts (a) and (b), what can be said about the desired duration gap for the financial institution if interest rates are expected to increase or decrease. d. Verify your answer to part (c) by calculating the change in the market value of equity assuming that the relative change in all market interest rates is an increase of 30 basis points. e. What would the duration of the assets need to be to immunize the equity from changes in market interest rates? 24. The balance sheet for Gotbucks Bank Inc. (GBI) is presented below ($ millions). Assets Liabilities and Equity Cash Federal funds Loans (floating) Loans (fixed) $ 30 20 105 65 Core deposits Federal funds Euro CDs Equity $ 20 50 130 20 Total assets $220 Total liabilities and equity $220 a. What is the duration of the fixed-rate loan portfolio of Gotbucks Bank? b. If the duration of the floating-rate loans and fed funds is 0.36 year, what is the duration of GBI’s assets? c. What is the duration of the core deposits if they are priced at par? d. If the duration of the Euro CDs and fed funds liabilities is 0.401 year, what is the duration of GBI’s liabilities? e. What is GBI’s duration gap? What is its interest rate risk exposure? f. What is the impact on the market value of equity if the relative change in all interest rates is an increase of 1 percent (100 basis points)? Note that the relative change in interest rates is ΔR/(1 R) 0.01. g. What is the impact on the market value of equity if the relative change in all interest rates is a decrease of 0.5 percent (50 basis points)? h. What variables are available to GBI to immunize the bank? How much would each variable need to change to get DGAP to equal zero? 25. Hands Insurance Company issued a $90 million, one-year note at 8 percent add-on annual interest (paying one coupon at the end of the year) or with an 8 percent yield. The proceeds were used to fund a $100 million, two-year commercial loan with a 10 percent coupon rate and a 10 percent yield. Immediately after these transactions were simultaneously closed, all market interest rates increased 1.5 percent (150 basis points). a. What is the true market value of the loan investment and the liability after the change in interest rates? b. What impact did these changes in market value have on the market value of the FI’s equity? www.mhhe.com/saunders8e Notes to the balance sheet: The fed funds rate is 8.5 percent, the floating loan rate is LIBOR 4 percent, and currently LIBOR is 11 percent. Fixed-rate loans have five-year maturities, are priced at par, and pay 12 percent annual interest. The principal is repaid at maturity. Core deposits are fixed rate for two years at 8 percent paid annually. The principal is repaid at maturity. Euro CDs currently yield 9 percent. 260 Part Two Measuring Risk c. What was the duration of the loan investment and the liability at the time of issuance? d. Use these duration values to calculate the expected change in the value of the loan and the liability for the predicted increase of 1.5 percent in interest rates. e. What is the duration gap of Hands Insurance Company after the issuance of the asset and note? f. What is the change in equity value forecasted by this duration gap for the predicted increase in interest rates of 1.5 percent? g. If the interest rate prediction had been available during the time period in which the loan and the liability were being negotiated, what suggestions would you have offered to reduce the possible effect on the equity of the company? What are the difficulties in implementing your ideas? 26. The following balance sheet information is available (amounts in thousands of dollars and duration in years) for a financial institution: Amount www.mhhe.com/saunders8e T-bills T-notes T-bonds Loans Deposits Federal funds Equity $ 90 55 176 2,724 2,092 238 715 Duration 0.50 0.90 x 7.00 1.00 0.01 Treasury bonds are five-year maturities paying 6 percent semiannually and selling at par. a. What is the duration of the T-bond portfolio? b. What is the average duration of all the assets? c. What is the average duration of all the liabilities? d. What is the leverage adjusted duration gap? What is the interest rate risk exposure? e. What is the forecasted impact on the market value of equity caused by a relative upward shift in the entire yield curve of 0.5 percent [i.e., ΔR/(1 R) 0.0050]? f. If the yield curve shifts downward 0.25 percent [i.e., ΔR/(1 R) 0.0025], what is the forecasted impact on the market value of equity? g. What variables are available to the financial institution to immunize the balance sheet? How much would each variable need to change to get DGAP to equal 0? 27. Assume that a goal of the regulatory agencies of financial institutions is to immunize the ratio of equity to total assets, that is, Δ(E/A) 0. Explain how this goal changes the desired duration gap for the institution. Why does this differ from the duration gap necessary to immunize the total equity? How would your answers to part (h) in problem 24 and part (g) in problem 26 change if immunizing equity to total assets was the goal? 28. Identify and discuss three criticisms of using the duration gap model to immunize the portfolio of a financial institution. 29. In general, what changes have occurred in the financial markets that would allow financial institutions to restructure their balance sheets more rapidly and efficiently to meet desired goals? Why is it critical for an FI manager who Chapter 9 Interest Rate Risk II 261 has a portfolio immunized to match a desired investment horizon to rebalance the portfolio periodically? What is convexity? Why is convexity a desirable feature to capture in a portfolio of assets? 30. A financial institution has an investment horizon of two years 9.33 months (or 2.777 years). The institution has converted all assets into a portfolio of 8 percent, $1,000 three-year bonds that are trading at a yield to maturity of 10 percent. The bonds pay interest annually. The portfolio manager believes that the assets are immunized against interest rate changes. a. Is the portfolio immunized at the time of the bond purchase? What is the duration of the bonds? b. Will the portfolio be immunized one year later? c. Assume that one-year, 8 percent zero-coupon bonds are available in one year. What proportion of the original portfolio should be placed in these bonds to rebalance the portfolio? The following questions and problems are based on material in Appendix 9A, at the book’s website (www.mhhe.com/saunders8e). Change N Coupon Rate 8 9 10% 10 YTM 9% 9 10 10 10 10 10 10 9 10 11 11 12 10 10 11 11 Price $ Change in Price from Par % Change in Price from Par www.mhhe.com/saunders8e 31. Consider a 12-year, 12 percent annual coupon bond with a required return of 10 percent. The bond has a face value of $1,000. a. What is the price of the bond? b. If interest rates rise to 11 percent, what is the price of the bond? c. What has been the percentage change in price? d. Repeat parts (a), (b), and (c) for a 16-year bond. e. What do the respective changes in bond prices indicate? 32. Consider a five-year, 15 percent annual coupon bond with a face value of $1,000. The bond is trading at a yield to maturity of 12 percent. a. What is the price of the bond? b. If the yield to maturity increases 1 percent, what will be the bond’s new price? c. Using your answers to parts (a) and (b), what is the percentage change in the bond’s price as a result of the 1 percent increase in interest rates? d. Repeat parts (b) and (c) assuming a 1 percent decrease in interest rates. e. What do the differences in your answers indicate about the interest rate– price relationships of fixed-rate assets? 33. Consider a $1,000 bond with a fixed-rate 10 percent annual coupon rate and a maturity (N) of 10 years. The bond currently is trading at a yield to maturity (YTM) of 10 percent. a. Complete the following table: 262 Part Two Measuring Risk b. Use this information to verify the principles of interest rate–price relationships for fixed-rate financial assets. Rule 1. Interest rates and prices of fixed-rate financial assets move inversely. Rule 2. The longer is the maturity of a fixed-income financial asset, the greater is the change in price for a given change in interest rates. Rule 3. The change in value of longer-term fixed-rate financial assets increases at a decreasing rate. Rule 4. Although not mentioned in Appendix 9A, for a given percentage ( ) change in interest rates, the increase in price for a decrease in rates is greater than the decrease in value for an increase in rates. The following questions and problems are based on material in Appendix 9B to the chapter. 34. MLK Bank has an asset portfolio that consists of $100 million of 30-year, 8 percent coupon, $1,000 bonds that sell at par. a. What will be the bonds’ new prices if market yields change immediately by / 0.10 percent? What will be the new prices if market yields change immediately by / 2.00 percent? b. The duration of these bonds is 12.1608 years. What are the predicted bond prices in each of the four cases using the duration rule? What is the amount of error between the duration prediction and the actual market values? c. Given that convexity is 212.4, what are the bond price predictions in each of the four cases using the duration plus convexity relationship? What is the amount of error in these predictions? d. Diagram and label clearly the results in parts (a), (b), and (c). 35. Estimate the convexity for each of the following three bonds, all of which trade at a yield to maturity of 8 percent and have face values of $1,000. A 7-year, zero-coupon bond. A 7-year, 10 percent annual coupon bond. A 10-year, 10 percent annual coupon bond that has a duration value of 6.994 years (i.e., approximately 7 years). www.mhhe.com/saunders8e Rank the bonds in terms of convexity, and express the convexity relationship between zeros and coupon bonds in terms of maturity and duration equivalencies. Integrated Mini Case CALCULATING AND USING DURATION GAP State Bank’s balance sheet is listed below. Market yields and durations (in years) are in parenthesis, and amounts are in millions. Assets Cash Fed funds (5.05%, 0.02) T-bills (5.25%, 0.22) T-bonds (7.50%, 7.55) Liabilities and Equity $ 20 150 300 200 Demand deposits MMDAs (4.5%, 0.50) (no minimum balance requirement) CDs (4.3%, 0.48) $ 250 360 715 Chapter 9 Assets Interest Rate Risk II 263 Liabilities and Equity 900 475 1,200 Consumer loans (6%, 2.50) C&I loans (5.8%, 6.58) Fixed-rate mortgages (7.85%, 19.50) Variable-rate mortgages, repriced @ quarter (6.3%, 0.25) Premises and equipment 580 120 Total assets $3,945 a. What is State Bank’s duration gap? b. Use these duration values to calculate the expected change in the value of the assets and liabilities of State Bank for a predicted increase of 1.5 percent in interest rates. CDs (6%, 4.45) Fed funds (5%, 0.02) Commercial paper (5.05%, 0.45) Subordinated debt: Fixed-rate (7.25%, 6.65) Total liabilities Equity Total liabilities and equity 1,105 515 400 200 $3,545 400 $3,945 c. What is the change in equity value forecasted from the duration values for a predicted increase in interest rates of 1.5 percent? Integrated Mini Case: Chapters 8 and 9 CALCULATING AND USING REPRICING AND DURATION GAP State Bank’s balance sheet is listed below. Market yields and durations (in years) are in parenthesis, and amounts are in millions. Cash Fed funds (2.05%, 0.02) 3-month T-bills (3.25%, 0.22) 8-year T-bonds (6.50%, 7.55) 5-year munis (7.20%, 4.25) 6-month consumer loans (5%, 0.42) 5-year car loans (6%, 3.78) 7-month C&I loans (4.8%, 0.55) 2-year C&I loans (4.15%, 1.65) Fixed-rate mortgages (5.10%, 0.48) (maturing in 5 months) Fixed-rate mortgages (6.85%, 0.85) (maturing in 1 year) Fixed-rate mortgages (5.30%, 4.45) (maturing in 5 years) Fixed-rate mortgages (5.40%, 18.25) (maturing in 20 years) Premises and equipment Total assets Liabilities and Equity $ 31 150 200 250 50 250 350 200 275 450 300 275 355 20 $3,156 $ 253 50 Demand deposits Savings accounts (0.5%, 1.25) MMDAs (3.5%, 0.50) (no minimum balance requirement) 3-month CDs (3.2%, 0.20) 1-year CDs (3.5%, 0.95) 5-year CDs (5%, 4.85) Fed funds (2%, 0.02) Repos (2%, 0.05) 6-month commercial paper (4.05%, 0.55) Subordinate notes: 1-year fixed rate (5.55%, 0.92) Subordinated debt: 7-year fixed rate (6.25%, 6.65) Total liabilities $2,778 Equity Total liabilities and equity 3078 $3,156 460 175 375 350 225 290 300 200 100 www.mhhe.com/saunders8e Assets www.mhhe.com/saunders8e 264 Part Two Measuring Risk a. What is State Bank’s repricing gap if the planning period is six months? one year? b. What is State Bank’s duration gap? c. What is the impact over the next six months on net interest income if interest rates on RSAs increase 50 basis points and on RSLs increase 35 basis points? Explain the results. d. What is the impact over the next year on net interest income if interest rates on RSAs decrease (increase) 35 basis points and on RSLs decrease (increase) 50 basis points? Explain the results. e. Use these duration values to calculate the expected change in the value of the assets and liabilities of State Bank for a predicted decrease of 0.35 percent in interest rates on assets and 0.50 percent on liabilities. f. What is the change in equity value forecasted from the duration values for decrease of 0.35 percent in interest rates on assets and 0.50 percent on liabilities? g. Use the duration gap model to calculate the change in equity value if the relative change in all market interest rates is a decrease of 50 basis points. Appendix 9A: The Basics of Bond Valuation View Appendix 9A at the website for this textbook (www.mhhe.com/saunders8e). Appendix 9B Incorporating Convexity into the Duration Model In the main body of the chapter, we established these three characteristics of convexity: 1. Convexity is desirable. The greater the convexity of a security or a portfolio of securities, the more insurance or interest rate protection an FI manager has against interest rate increases and the greater the potential gains after interest rate decreases. 2. Convexity and duration. The larger the interest rate changes and the more convex a fixed income security or portfolio, the greater the error the FI manager faces in using just duration (and duration matching) to immunize exposure to interest rate shocks. 3. All fixed-income securities are convex.1 To see this, we can take the six-year, 8 percent coupon, 8 percent yield bond and look at two extreme price–yield scenarios. What is the price on the 1 This applies to fixed-income securities without special option features such as calls and puts. bond if yields falls to zero, and what is its price if yields rise to some very large number, such as infinity? When R 0: P 80 1, 080 ... $1, 480 (1 0) (1 0)6 The price is just the simple undiscounted sum of the coupon values and the face value. Since yields can never go below zero, $1,480 is the maximum possible price for the bond. When R : P 80 1, 080 ... ⯝ 0 (1 + ∞) (1 + ∞)6 As the yield goes to infinity, the bond price falls asymptotically toward zero, but by definition a bond’s price can never be negative. Thus, zero must be the minimum bond price (see Figure 9B–1). Chapter 9 FIGURE 9B–1 Price The Natural Convexity of Bonds 1,480 Interest Rate Risk II 265 Price–yield curve convexity ∞ Yield (R ) 0 Since convexity is a desirable feature for assets, the FI manager might ask: Can we measure convexity? And can we incorporate this measurement in the duration model to adjust for or offset the error in prediction due to its presence? The answer to both questions is yes. Theoretically speaking, duration is the slope of the price–yield curve, and convexity, or curvature, is the change in the slope of the price–yield curve. Consider the total effect of a change in interest rates on a bond’s price as being broken into a number of separate effects. The precise mathematical derivation of these separate effects is based on a Taylor series expansion that you might remember from your math classes. Essentially, the first-order effect (dP/dR) of an interest rate change on the bond’s price is the price–yield curve slope effect, which is measured by duration. The second-order effect (dP2/d2R) measures the change in the slope of the price–yield curve. This is the curvature, or convexity, effect. There are also third-, fourth-, and higher-order effects from the Taylor series expansion, but for all practical purposes these effects can be ignored. We have noted that overlooking the curvature of the price–yield curve may cause errors in predicting the interest rate sensitivity of a portfolio of assets and liabilities, especially when yields change by large amounts. We can adjust for this by explicitly recognizing the second-order effect of yield changes by measuring the change in the slope of the price–yield curve around a given point. Just as D (duration) measures the slope effect (dP/dR), we introduce a new parameter (CX) to measure the curvature effect (dP2/d2R) of the price–yield curve. The resulting equation, predicting the change in a security’s price (ΔP/P), is: P 1 R D CX ( R)2 P (1 R) 2 (1) or: P 1 MD R CX ( R)2 P 2 (2) The first term in equation (1) is the simple duration model that over- or underpredicts price changes for large changes in interest rates. The second term is the second-order effect of interest rate changes, that is, the convexity or curvature adjustment. In equation (1), the first term D can be divided by 1 R to produce what we called earlier modified duration (MD). You can see this in equation (2). In the convexity term, the number 1/2 and (ΔR)2 result from the fact that the convexity effect is the second-order effect of interest rate changes, while duration is the first-order effect. The parameter CX reflects the degree of curvature in the price–yield curve at the current yield level; that is, the degree to which the capital gain effect exceeds the capital loss effect for an equal change in yields up or down. At best, the FI manager can only approximate the curvature effect by using a parametric measure of CX. Even though calculus is based on infinitesimally small changes, in financial markets the smallest change in yields normally observed is one basis point, or a 1/100th of 1 percent change. One possible way to measure CX is introduced next. As just discussed, the convexity effect is the degree to which the capital gain effect more than offsets the capital loss effect for an equal increase and decrease in interest rates at the current interest rate level. In Figure 9B–2 we depict yields changing upward by one basis point (R 0.01%) and downward by one basis point (R 0.01%). Because convexity measures the curvature of the price–yield curve around the rate level R percent, it intuitively measures the degree to which the capital gain effect of a small yield decrease exceeds 266 Part Two Measuring Risk FIGURE 9B–2 Price Convexity and the Price–Yield Curve P+ Capital gain P Capital loss P– R –0.01% R % the capital loss effect of a small yield increase. Definitionally, the CX parameter equals: ⎡ Capital Capital ⎢ gain from a ⎢ loss from a Scaling ⎢ one-basis-point one-basis-point CX factor ⎢ ⎢ rise in yield fall in yield ⎢ (negative effect) (positive effect) ⎢⎣ ⎤ ⎥ ⎥ ⎥ ⎥ ⎥ ⎥ ⎥⎦ The sum of the two terms in the brackets reflects the degree to which the capital gain effect exceeds the capital loss effect for a small onebasis-point interest rate change down and up. The scaling factor normalizes this measure to account for a larger 1 percent change in rates. Remember, when interest rates change by a large amount, the convexity effect is important to measure. A commonly used scaling factor is 108 so that:2 ⎡ P CX 108 ⎢ ⎣ P P ⎤ P ⎥⎦ Calculation of CX To calculate the convexity of the 8 percent coupon, 8 percent yield, six-year maturity Eurobond that had a price of $1,000:3 2 This is consistent with the effect of a 1 percent (100 basis points) change in rates. 3 You can easily check that $999.53785 is the price of the sixyear bond when rates are 8.01 percent and $1,000.46243 is the price of the bond when rates fall to 7.99 percent. Since we are dealing in small numbers and convexity is sensitive to the number of decimal places assumed, we use at least five decimal places in calculating the capital gain or loss. In fact, the more decimal places used, the greater the accuracy of the CX measure. R +0.01% CX 10 8 Yield ⎡ 999.53785 ⎢⎣ 1, 000 Capital loss from a one-basis-point increase in rates 1, 000 1, 000.46243 1, 000 ⎤ 1, 000 ⎥⎦ Capital gain from a one-basis-point decrease in rates 8 CX 10 [0.00000028] CX 28 This value for CX can be inserted into the bond price prediction equation (2) with the convexity adjustment: P 1 MD R (28) R 2 P 2 Assuming a 2 percent increase in R (from 8 to 10 percent), 4.993 ⎤ P 1 ⎡⎢ 0.02 (28)(0.02)2 P 2 ⎣ 1.08 ⎥⎦ 0.0925 0.0056 0.0869 or 8.69% The simple duration model (the first term) predicts that a 2 percent rise in interest rates will cause the bond’s price to fall 9.25 percent. However, for large changes in yields, the duration model overpredicts the price fall. The duration model with the second-order convexity adjustment predicts a price fall of 8.69 percent; it adds back 0.56 percent because of the convexity effect. This is much closer to the true fall in the six-year, 8 percent coupon bond’s price if we calculate this using 10 percent to discount the coupon and face value cash flows on the bond. The true value of Chapter 9 Interest Rate Risk II 267 TABLE 9B–1 Properties of Convexity 2. Convexity Varies with Coupon 1. Convexity Increases with Bond Maturity Example Example Example A B C A B A B N6 R 8% C 8% D5 CX 28 N 18 R 8% C 8% D 10.12 CX 130 N R 8% C 8% D 13.5 CX 312 N6 R 8% C 8% D5 CX 28 N6 R 8% C 0% D6 CX 36 N6 R 8% C 8% D5 CX 28 N5 R 8% C 0% D5 CX 25.72 the bond price fall is 8.71 percent. That is, using the convexity adjustment reduces the error between predicted value and true value to just a few basis points.4 In Table 9B–1 we calculate various properties of convexity, where N Time to maturity R Yield to maturity C Annual coupon D Duration CX Convexity Part 1 of Table 9B–1 shows that as the bond’s maturity (N) increases, so does its convexity (CX). As a result, long-term bonds have more convexity— which is a desirable property—than do short-term bonds. This property is similar to that possessed by duration.5 Part 2 of Table 9B–1 shows that coupon bonds of the same maturity (N) have less convexity than do zero-coupon bonds. However, for coupon bonds 4 3. Same Duration, Zero-Coupon Bonds Are Less Convex Than Coupon Bonds It is possible to use the third moment of the Taylor series expansion to reduce this small error (8.71 percent versus 8.69 percent) even further. In practice, few FIs do this. 5 Note that the CX measure differs according to the level of interest rates. For example, we are measuring CX in Table 9B–1 when yields are 8 percent. If yields were 12 percent, the CX number would change. This is intuitively reasonable, as the curvature of the price–yield curve differs at each point on the price–yield curve. Note that duration also changes with the level of interest rates. and discount or zero-coupon bonds of the same duration, part 3 of the table shows that the coupon bond has more convexity. We depict the convexity of both in Figure 9B–3. Finally, before leaving convexity, we might look at one important use of the concept by managers of insurance companies, pension funds, and mutual funds. Remembering that convexity is a desirable form of interest rate risk insurance, FI managers could structure an asset portfolio to maximize its desirable effects. Consider a pension fund manager with a 15-year payout horizon. To immunize the risk of interest rate changes, the manager purchases bonds with a 15-year duration. Consider two alternative strategies to achieve this: Strategy 1: Invest 100 percent of resources in a 15-year deep-discount bond with an 8 percent yield. Strategy 2: Invest 50 percent in the very shortterm money market (Federal funds)6 and 50 percent in 30-year deepdiscount bonds with an 8 percent yield. The duration (D) and convexities (CX) of these two asset portfolios are: Strategy 1: D 15, CX 206 Strategy 2: D ½(0) ½(30) 15, CX ½(0) ½(797) 398.5 6 The duration and convexity of one-day federal funds are approximately zero. 268 Part Two Measuring Risk + ΔP/P FIGURE 9B–3 Convexity of a Coupon versus a Discount Bond with the Same Duration – –MD = –D 1+R 0 + ΔR Coupon bond = –4.62 Discount bond – Strategies 1 and 2 have the same durations, but strategy 2 has a greater convexity. Strategy 2 is often called a barbell portfolio, as shown in Figure 9B–4 by the shaded bars.7 Strategy 1 is the unshaded bar. To the extent that the market does not price (or fully price) convexity, the barbell strategy dominates the direct duration-matching strategy (strategy 1).8 More commonly, an FI manager may seek to attain greater convexity in the asset portfolio than in the liability portfolio, as shown in Figure 9B–5. As a result, both positive and negative shocks to interest rates would have beneficial effects on the FI’s net worth.9 7 This is called a barbell because the weights are equally loaded at the extreme ends of the duration range, or bar, as in weight lifting. 8 In a world in which convexity is priced, the long-term 30-year bond’s price would rise to reflect the competition among buyers to include this more convex bond in their barbell asset portfolios. Thus, buying bond insurance—in the form of the barbell portfolio—would involve an additional cost to the FI manager. In addition, for the FI to be hedged in both a duration sense and a convexity sense, the manager should not choose the convexity of the asset portfolio without seeking to match it to the convexity of the liability portfolio. 9 Another strategy would be for the FI to issue callable bonds as liabilities. Callable bonds have limited upside capital gains because if rates fall to a low level, then the issuer calls the bond in early (and reissues new lower coupon bonds). The effect of limited upside potential for callable bond prices is that the price–yield curve for such bonds exhibits negative convexity. Thus, if asset investments have positive convexity and liabilities negative convexity, then yield shocks (whether positive or negative) are likely to produce net worth gains for the FI. THE PROBLEM OF THE FLAT TERM STRUCTURE We have been calculating the simple, or Macaulay, duration. A key assumption of the simple duration model is that the yield curve or term structure of interest rates is flat and that when rates change, the yield curve shifts in a parallel fashion. In the real world, the yield curve can take many shapes and at best may only approximate a flat yield curve. If the yield curve is not flat, using simple duration could be a potential source of error in predicting asset and liability interest rate sensitivities. Many models can deal with this problem. These models differ according to the shapes and shocks to the yield curve that are assumed. Suppose the yield curve is not flat but shifts in such a manner that the yields on different maturity discount bonds change in a proportional fashion.10 Consider calculating the duration of the six-year Eurobond when the yield curve is not flat at 8 percent. Instead, the yield curve looks like the one in Figure 9B–6. Suppose the yield on one-year discount bonds rises. Assume also that the discounted changes in longer-maturity discount bond yields are just 10 We are interested in the yield curve on discount bonds because these yields reflect the time value of money for single payments at different maturity dates. Thus, we can use these yields as discount rates for cash flows on a security to calculate appropriate present values of its cash flows and its duration. Chapter 9 FIGURE 9B–4 Interest Rate Risk II Percent of portfolio Barbell Strategy 100 50 0 FIGURE 9B–5 Assets Are More Convex Than Liabilities Asset, liability, equity value ($) 15 30 Equity { } Equity R22% FIGURE 9B–6 Nonflat Yield Curve Duration R% } Equity R +2% Assets Liabilities Interest rates Discount bond yield curve Yield (%) 10.3 10.2 9.8 9.4 8.8 8.0 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 Maturity 269 270 Part Two Measuring Risk TABLE 9B–2 Duration with an Upward-Sloping Yield Curve t CF CF ⴛ DF DF CF ⴛ DF ⴛ t 1 80 1 0.9259 (1.08) 74.07 74. 07 2 80 1 0.8448 (1.088)2 67.58 135.16 3 80 1 0.7637 (1.094)3 61.10 183.30 4 80 1 0.6880 (1.098)4 55.04 220.16 5 80 1 0.6153 (1.102)5 49.22 246.10 6 1,080 1 0.5553 (1.103)6 599.75 3,598.50 906.76 4,457.29 D* proportional to the change in the one-year discount bond yield: R6 R1 R2 ... 1 R1 1 R2 1 R6 Given this quite restrictive assumption, it can be proved that the appropriate duration measure of the bond—call it D*—can be derived by discounting the coupons and principal value of the bond by the discount rates or yields on appropriate maturity zero-coupon bonds. Given the discount bond yield curve plotted in Figure 9B–6, D* is calculated in Table 9B–2. Notice that D* is 4.916 years, while the simple Macaulay duration (with an assumed flat 8 percent yield curve) is 4.993 years. D* and D differ because, by taking into account the upward-sloping yield curve in Figure 9B–6, the later cash flows are discounted at higher rates than they are under the flat yield curve assumption underlying Macaulay’s measure D. With respect to the FI manager’s problem, choosing to use D* instead of D does not change the basic problem except for a concern with the gap between the D* on assets and leverage-weighted liabilities: 4, 457.29 4.91562 906.76 DA* kDL* However, remember that the D* was calculated under very restrictive assumptions about the yield curve. If we change these assumptions in any way, the measure of D* changes. THE PROBLEM OF DEFAULT RISK The models and the duration calculations we have looked at assume that the issuer of bonds or the borrower of a loan pays the promised interest and principal with a probabilitity of 1; we assume no default or delay in the payment of cash flows. In the real world, problems with principal and interest payments are common and lead to restructuring and workouts on debt contracts as bankers and bond trustees renegotiate with borrowers; that is, the borrower reschedules or recontracts interest and principal payments rather than defaulting outright. If we view default risk as synonymous with the rescheduling of cash flows to a later date, this is quite easy to deal with in duration models. Consider the six-year, 8 percent coupon, 8 percent yield Eurobond. Suppose the issuer gets into difficulty and cannot pay the first coupon. Instead, the borrower and the FI agree that the Chapter 9 TABLE 9B–3 Duration and Rescheduling t CF DF CF ⴛ DF CF ⴛ DF ⴛ t 1 2 3 4 5 6 0 160 80 80 80 1,080 0.9259 0.8573 0.7938 0.7350 0.6806 0.6302 0 137.17 63.51 58.80 54.45 680.58 994.51 0 274.34 190.53 235.21 272.25 4,083.48 5,055.81 D unpaid interest can be paid in year 2. This alleviates part of the cash flow pressure on the borrower while lengthening the duration of the bond from the FI’s perspective (see Table 9B–3). The effect of rescheduling the first interest payment is to increase duration from approximately 5 years to 5.08 years. More commonly, an FI manager unsure of the future cash flows because of future default risk might multiply the promised cash flow (CFt) by the probability of repayment (pt) in year t to generate expected cash flows in year t—E(CFt). E(CFt ) pt CFt Chapter 10 suggests a number of ways to generate these repayment probabilities. Once the cash flows have been adjusted for default risk, a duration measure can be directly calculated in the same manner as the Macaulay formula (or D*) except that E(CFt) replaces CFt.11 FLOATING-RATE LOANS AND BONDS The duration models we have looked at assume that the interest rates on loans or the coupons on bonds are fixed at issue and remain unchanged until maturity. However, many bonds and loans carry floating interest rates. Examples include loan rates indexed to LIBOR (London Interbank 11 Interest Rate Risk II Alternatively, the promised cash flow could be discounted by the appropriate discount yield on a risk-free Treasury security plus an appropriate credit-risk spread; that is, CFt /(1 dt St)t, where CFt is the promised cash flow in year t, dt is the yield on a t-period zero-coupon Treasury bond, and St is a credit-risk premium. 5,055.81 994.51 271 5.0837 years Offered Rate) and adjustable-rate mortgages (ARMs) whose rates can be indexed to Treasury or other securities yields. Moreover, in the 1980s, many banks and security firms either issued or underwrote perpetual floating-rate notes (FRNs). These are like consol bonds in that they never mature. Unlike consols, their coupons fluctuate with market rates. The FI manager, who wants to analyze overall gap exposure, may ask: What are the durations of such floating-rate securities? The duration of a floating-rate instrument is generally the time interval between the purchase of the security and the time when the next coupon or interest payment is readjusted to reflect current interest rate conditions. We call this the time to repricing of the instrument. For example, suppose the investor bought a perpetual floating-rate note. These floating-rate notes never mature. At the beginning of each year, the FI sets the coupon rate, which is paid at the end of that year. Suppose the investor buys the bond in the middle of the first year (t ½) rather than at the beginning (see Figure 9B–7). The present value of the bond from time of purchase is: C1 C2 1 1 (1 2 R) (1 2 R)(1 R) C3 C4 2 1 1 (1 2 R)(1 R) (1 2 R)(1 R)3 C5 ... 1 (1 2 R)(1 R)4 C 1 (1 2 R)(1 R)1 P 272 Part Two Measuring Risk FIGURE 9B–7 Floating-Rate Note Set C1 Pay C1 Set C2 0 1 Buy bond 1 at t = /2 Pay C2 Set C3 Pay C3 Set C4 Pay C4 Set C5 Pay C5 Set C6 2 3 4 5 Note three important aspects of this present value equation. First, the investor has to wait only a half year to get the first coupon payment—hence, the discount rate is (1 ½R). Second, the investor knows with certainty only the size of the first coupon C1, which was preset at the beginning of the first coupon period to reflect interest rates at that time. The FI set the first coupon rate six months before the investor bought the bond. Third, the other coupons on the bond, C2, C3, C4, C5, . . . C, are unknown at the time the bond is purchased because they depend on the level of interest rates at the time they are reset (see Figure 9B–7). To derive the duration of the bond, rewrite the cash flows at one-half year onward as: 1 C1 P 1 (1 2 R) (1 1 2 R) C3 C4 ⎡ C2 ⎢ (1 R) (1 R)2 (1 R)3 ⎣ C5 C∞ ⎤ ... ∞ 1 ⎥ 4 (1 R) (1 R) ⎦ where P is the present value of the bond (the bond price) at one-half year, the time of purchase. The term in brackets is the present value or fair price (P1) of the bond if it were sold at the end of year 1, the beginning of the second coupon period. As long as the variable coupons exactly match fluctuations in yields or interest rates, the present value of the cash flow in the square brackets is unaffected by interest rate changes. Thus, P C1 P1 (1 1 2 R) (1 1 2 R) Since C1 is a fixed cash flow preset before the investor bought the bond and P1 is a fixed cash flow in present value terms, buying this bond is similar to buying two single-payment deep-discount bonds each with a maturity of six months. Because the duration of a deep-discount bond is the same as its maturity, this floating rate bond has: D 1 2 year As indicated earlier, a half year is exactly the interval between the time when the bond was purchased and the time when it was first repriced. DEMAND DEPOSITS AND PASSBOOK SAVINGS Many banks and thrifts hold large amounts of checking and passbook savings account liabilities. This is especially true for smaller banks. The problem in assessing the duration of such claims is that their maturities are open-ended and many demand deposit accounts do not turn over very frequently. Although demand deposits allow holders to demand cash immediately— suggesting a very short maturity—many customers tend to retain demand deposit balances for lengthy periods. In the parlance of banking, they behave as if they were a bank’s core deposits. One way for an FI manager to get around this problem is to analyze the runoff, or the turnover characteristics, of the FI’s demand and passbook savings account deposits. For example, suppose the manager learns that on average each dollar in demand deposit accounts turns over five times a year. This suggests an average turnover or maturity per dollar of around 73 days, (i.e., 365 days/5). A second method is to consider demand deposits as bonds that can be instantaneously put back to the bank in return for cash. As instantaneously putable bonds, the duration of demand deposits is approximately zero. Chapter 9 A third approach is more directly in line with the idea of duration as a measure of interest rate sensitivity. It looks at the percentage change of demand deposits (ΔDD/DD) to interest rate changes (ΔR). Because demand deposits and, to a lesser extent, passbook savings deposits pay either low explicit or implicit interest—where implicit interest takes forms such as subsidized checking fees—there tend to be enhanced withdrawals and switching into higher-yielding instruments as rates rise. You can use a number of quantitative techniques to test this sensitivity, including linear and nonlinear time series regression analysis. A fourth approach is to use simulation analysis. This is based on forecasts of future interest rates and the net withdrawals by depositors from their accounts over some future time period. Taking the discounted present values of these cash flows allows a duration measure to be calculated. MORTGAGES AND MORTGAGEBACKED SECURITIES Calculating the durations of mortgages and mortgage-backed securities is difficult because of prepayment risk. Essentially, as the level of interest rates falls, mortgage holders have the option Interest Rate Risk II 273 to prepay their old mortgages and refinance with a new mortgage at a lower interest rate. In the terminology of finance, fixed-rate mortgages and mortgage-backed securities contain an embedded option. Calculating duration requires projecting the future cash flows on an asset. Consequently, to calculate the duration of mortgages, we need to model the prepayment behavior of mortgage holders. Possible ways to do this are left to Chapter 26 on mortgage asset securitization. FUTURES, OPTIONS, SWAPS, CAPS, AND OTHER CONTINGENT CLAIMS When interest rates change, so do the values of (off-balance-sheet) derivative instruments such as futures, options, swaps, and caps (see Chapter 16). Market value gains and losses on these instruments can also have an impact on the net worth (E) of an FI. The calculation of the durations of these instruments is left to Chapters 22, 23, and 24. However, it should be noted that a fully fledged duration gap model of an FI should take into account the durations of its derivatives portfolio as well as the duration of its on-balance-sheet assets and liabilities. This is especially so today as more and more FIs take positions in derivative contracts. Chapter Ten See Appendices Online at www.mhhe.com/saunders8e • Appendix 10A: Credit Analysis • Appendix 10B: Black–Scholes Option Pricing Model Credit Risk: Individual Loan Risk INTRODUCTION As discussed in Chapter 1, financial institutions (FIs) are special because of their ability to efficiently transform financial claims of household savers into claims issued to corporations, individuals, and governments. An FI’s ability to evaluate information and to control and monitor borrowers allows it to transform these claims at the lowest possible cost to all parties. One of the specific types of financial claim transformation discussed in Chapter 1 is credit allocation. That is, FIs transform claims of household savers (in the form of deposits) into loans issued to corporations, individuals, and governments. The FI accepts the credit risk on these loans in exchange for a fair return sufficient to cover the cost of funding (e.g., covering the costs of borrowing, or issuing deposits) to household savers and the credit risk involved in lending. In this chapter, the first of two chapters on credit risk, we discuss various approaches to analyzing and measuring the credit or default risk on individual loans (and bonds). In the next chapter, we consider methods for evaluating the risk of the overall loan portfolio, or loan concentration risk. Methods for hedging and managing an FI’s credit risk, such as the use of credit derivative swaps, are left to Chapters 22 through 26. Measurement of the credit risk on individual loans or bonds is crucial if an FI manager is to (1) price a loan or value a bond correctly and (2) set appropriate limits on the amount of credit extended to any one borrower or the loss exposure it accepts from any particular counterparty. Indeed, the default of one major borrower can have a significant impact on the value and reputation of many FIs. For example, total exposure of U.S. banks to WorldCom at the time of its bankruptcy in 2002 was over $700 million. Losses from this single failure resulted in a drop in earnings per share at J.P. Morgan Chase of 5 cents (or nearly 2 percent), at then Bank One (Bank One is now a part of J.P. Morgan Chase), of 3 cents (or 1 percent), and at Bank of America of 5 cents (or 1 percent). Similarly, a single major economic event can cause losses to many FIs’ loan portfolios. For example, in 2005 Hurricanes Katrina and Rita resulted in over $1.3 billion in bad loans for major banks operating in areas hit by the 274 Chapter 10 Credit Risk: Individual Loan Risk 275 storm. And, of course, the financial market crisis of the late 2000s resulted in the largest ever credit risk-related losses for U.S. financial institutions. Losses from the falling value of on- and off-balance-sheet credit instruments (e.g., mortgages, mortgage-backed securities, credit cards) topped $2.3 trillion worldwide, with $1.6 trillion coming from loans and assets originated at U.S. financial institutions. In just the first quarter of 2009, the annualized net charge-off rate on total loans and leases at U.S. banks was 1.94 percent, slightly below the 1.95 percent rate in the fourth quarter of 2008 (that was the highest quarterly net chargeoff rate in the 25 years that insured institutions have reported these data). The year-over-year rise in charge-offs was led by loans to commercial and industrial (C&I) borrowers, where charge-offs increased by $4.2 billion (170 percent), then credit cards (up $3.4 billion, or 68.9 percent), real estate construction loans (up $2.9 billion, or 161.7 percent), and 1–4 family residential real estate loans (up $2.7 billion, or 64.9 percent). Many financial institutions were unable to survive the mortgage crisis. For example, Countrywide Financial, the country’s largest mortgage issuer, nearly failed in the summer of 2007 due to defaults by its subprime mortgage borrowers. Only a $2 billion equity investment by Bank of America in 2007 and then an acquisition by Bank of America in 2008 kept this thrift alive. IndyMac Bank, the ninth largest mortgage lender in the U.S. in 2007, was seized by the FDIC in July 2008. At a cost to the FDIC of between $4 billion and $8 billion, IndyMac represented the largest bank failure in more than 20 years. Overall, in 2008–2010, 322 U.S. banks failed, compared to 3 in 2005–2007. Further, the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation reported that it had 884 banks on its list of troubled institutions at year end 2010, up from 90 in the first quarter of 2008. Most recently, bank loan portfolios were exposed to losses from the European debt crisis. In early 2012, U.S. banks had virtually no exposure to Greek debt, approximately $5.8 billion. Despite this relatively insignificant amount, the risks posed to U.S. banks and the banking system system from a Greek debt default and a contagion crisis in other Eurozone countries were huge. U.S. banks had more than $50 billion worth of debt exposure to both Spain and Ireland, $6.6 billion to Portugal, and more than $66 billion to Italy, all countries in risk of debt default in the event of a continued economic slowdown. Further, U.S. banks had even larger exposures to the larger countries in Europe and to European banks. These seemingly unending creditrelated events stress that FIs need to manage their loan portfolios to protect the overall FI from failure due to credit risk. We begin this chapter with a look at the types of loans (commercial and industrial [C&I], real estate, individual (consumer), and others) as well as the characteristics of those loans made by U.S. FIs. We then look at how both interest and fees are incorporated to calculate the return on a loan. This is followed by a discussion of how the return on a loan versus the quantity of credit made available for lending is used by FIs to make decisions on wholesale (C&I) versus retail (consumer) lending. Finally, we examine various models used to measure credit risk, including qualitative and quantitative models (credit scoring models and newer models of credit risk measurement). Indeed, technological advances have been at least one driving force behind the advances and new models of credit risk measurement and management in recent years. Appendix 10A, located at the book’s website (www.mhhe.com/saunders8e), discusses cash flow and financial ratio analysis widely used in the credit analysis process for mortgage, consumer, and commercial loans. 276 Part Two Measuring Risk CREDIT QUALITY PROBLEMS junk bonds Bonds rated as speculative or less than investment grade by bond-rating agencies such as Moody’s. www.moodys.com www.standardandpoors.com FIGURE 10–1 Over the past three decades the credit quality of many FIs’ lending and investment decisions has attracted a great deal of attention. In the 1980s there were tremendous problems with bank loans to less developed countries (LDCs) as well as with thrift and bank residential and farm mortgage loans. In the early 1990s attention switched to the problems of commercial real estate loans (to which banks, thrifts, and insurance companies were all exposed) as well as junk bonds (rated as speculative or less than investment grade securities by bond-rating agencies such as Moody’s or Standard & Poors). In the late 1990s concerns shifted to the rapid growth in low-quality auto loans and credit cards as well as the declining quality in commercial lending standards as loan delinquencies started to increase. In the late 1990s and early 2000s, attention focused on problems with telecommunication companies, new technology companies, and a variety of sovereign countries including at various times Argentina, Brazil, Russia, and South Korea. Despite these credit concerns, the credit quality of most FIs improved throughout the 1990s. For example, for FDIC-insured commercial banks, the ratio of nonperforming loans to assets declined significantly from 1992 through 2000 (see Figure 10–1).1 The recession in the U.S. economy in the early 2000s led to a reversal in this trend as nonperforming loan rates increased, particularly on commercial and industrial (C&I) loans. However, the nonperformance of loans in all categories was still below that of the early 1990s. As the U.S. economy improved in the mid2000s, nonperforming loan rates fell. However, mortgage delinquencies, particularly on subprime mortgages, surged in the last quarter of 2006 and all of 2007 as home owners who stretched themselves financially to buy a home or refinance Nonperforming Asset Ratio for U.S. Commercial Banks Source: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Quarterly Banking Profile, various issues. www.fdic.gov Percentage of loans 10 Total real estate Commercial and industrial Loans to individuals All other loans 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 Year 0 84 85 86 87 88 89 90 91 92 93 94 95 96 97 98 99 00 01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 1 Nonperforming loans are loans that are 90 days or more past due or are not accruing interest. Chapter 10 Credit Risk: Individual Loan Risk 277 a mortgage in the early 2000s fell behind on their loan payments. Trouble in the mortgage markets continued to escalate as the number of foreclosures hit a record 1.5 million in the first six months of 2009. Nonperforming real estate loans reached levels higher than those seen in the 1980s. Problems in the mortgage markets spread to other sectors as well. In 2008 consumer bankruptcy filings rose to 1.06 million, up from 801,840 in 2007 and 602,000 in 2006. Business loan losses grew as well. For example, when Chrysler went into bankruptcy in May 2009, it owed banks, including Citigroup and J.P. Morgan Chase, $6.9 billion. President Obama’s plan for Chrysler’s bankruptcy cut that to $1 billion for a loss to banks of $5.9 billion. The banks ended up realizing 33 cents on the dollar for these loans, a loss of $4.6 billion. As the U.S. economy slowly recovered in 2010–2012, nonperforming loans rates edged downward but still remained at levels higher than those seen throughout most of the 30-year period. Internet Exercise Go to the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation website and find the latest information available for nonperforming loans at commercial banks in the United States, using the following steps: Go to the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation website at www.fdic.gov. Click on “Analysts.” Click on “FDIC Quarterly Banking Profile.” Click on “Quarterly Banking Profile.” Click on the most recent date and “Commercial Bank Section.” Click on “TABLE V-A. Loan Performance.” This will download a file on to your computer that will contain the most recent information as “Percent of Loans Noncurrent: Total Loans and Leases.” Credit quality problems, in the worst case, can cause an FI to become insolvent or can result in such a significant drain on capital2 and net worth that they adversely affect its growth prospects and ability to compete with other domestic and international FIs. However, credit risk does not apply only to traditional areas of lending and bond investing. As banks and other FIs have expanded into credit guarantees and other off-balance-sheet activities (see Chapter 16), new types of credit risk exposure have arisen, causing concern among managers and regulators. Thus, credit risk analysis is now important for a whole variety of contractual agreements between FIs and counterparties.3 Concept Questions 1. What are some of the credit quality problems faced by FIs over the last three decades? 2. What are some of the newer, nontraditional activities that create credit risk for today’s FIs? 2 Losses drain capital through the income statement item “provision for loan losses.” The provision for loan losses is a noncash, tax-deductible expense representing the FI management’s prediction of loans at risk of default for the current period. As credit quality problems arise, the FI recognizes its expected bad loans by recording this expense, which reduces net income and, in turn, the FI’s capital. The provision for loan losses is then allocated to the allowance for loan losses listed on the balance sheet. The allowance for loan and lease losses is a cumulative estimate by the FI’s management of the gross loans (and leases) that will not be repaid to the FI. Actual losses are then deducted from, and recoveries are added to (referred to as net write-offs), their accumulated loans and lease loss reserve balance. See Appendix 2A, “Commercial Banks’ Financial Statements and Analysis” (located at the book’s website, www.mhhe.com/ saunders8e) for a more detailed discussion of these items. 3 This is one of the reasons for bank regulators’ setting capital requirements against credit risk (see Chapter 20). 278 Part Two Measuring Risk TYPES OF LOANS Although most FIs make loans, the types of loans made and the characteristics of those loans differ considerably. This section analyzes the major types of loans made by U.S. financial institutions. Table 10–1 shows a recent breakdown of the aggregate loan portfolio of U.S. commercial banks into four broad classes: commercial and industrial (19.6 percent of all commercial bank loans), real estate (52.9 percent), individual (17.5 percent), and all others (10.0 percent). We look briefly at each of these loan classes in turn. Commercial and Industrial Loans syndicated loan A loan provided by a group of FIs as opposed to a single lender. secured loan A loan that is backed by a first claim on certain assets (collateral) of the borrower if default occurs. unsecured loan A loan that has only a general claim to the assets of the borrower if default occurs. The figures in Table 10–1 disguise a great deal of heterogeneity in the commercial and industrial loan portfolio. Indeed, commercial loans can be made for periods as short as a few weeks to as long as eight years or more. Traditionally, short-term commercial loans (those with an original maturity of one year or less) are used to finance firms’ working capital needs and other short-term funding needs, while long-term commercial loans are used to finance credit needs that extend beyond one year, such as the purchase of real assets (machinery), new venture start-up costs, and permanent increases in working capital. They can be made in quite small amounts, such as $100,000, to small businesses or in packages as large as $10 million or more to major corporations. Large C&I loans are often syndicated. A syndicated loan is provided by a group of FIs as opposed to a single lender. A syndicated loan is structured by the lead FI (or agent) and the borrower. Once the terms (rates, fees, and covenants) are set, pieces of the loan are sold to other FIs. In addition, C&I loans can be secured or unsecured. A secured loan (or assetbacked loan) is backed by specific assets of the borrower. If the borrower defaults, the lender has a first lien or claim on those assets. Secured debt is senior to an unsecured loan (or junior debt) that has only a general claim on the assets of the borrower if default occurs. As we explain later in this chapter, there is normally a trade-off between the security or collateral backing of a loan and the loan interest rate or risk premium charged by the lender on a loan. In addition, commercial loans can be made at either fixed or floating rates of interest. A fixed-rate loan has the rate of interest set at the beginning of the contract period. This rate remains in force over the loan contract period no matter what happens to market rates. Suppose, for example, IBM borrowed $10 million at a fixed rate of 10 percent for one year, but the FI’s cost of funds rose over the course of the year. Because this is a fixed-rate loan the FI bears all the interest rate risk. This is why many loans have floating-rate contractual terms; that is, IBM borrows $10 million at a floating rate, e.g., LIBOR 5 percent, for one year. The loan rate can be periodically adjusted according to a formula so that the interest rate risk is TABLE 10–1 Types of U.S. Bank Loans (in billions of dollars) Source: Federal Reserve Board, Assets and Liabilities of Commercial Banks, June 2012. www.federalreserve.gov Total loans* C&I Real estate Individual Other Amount Percent $6,739.8 1,322.1 3,562.3 1,183.0 672.4 100.0% 19.6 52.9 17.5 10.0 *Excluding interbank loans. Chapter 10 spot loan The loan amount is withdrawn by the borrower immediately. loan commitment A credit facility with a maximum size and a maximum period of time over which the borrower can withdraw funds; a line of credit. commercial paper Unsecured shortterm debt instrument issued by corporations. Credit Risk: Individual Loan Risk 279 transferred in large part from the FI to the borrower. As might be expected, longerterm loans are more likely to be made under floating-rate contracts than are relatively short-term loans.4 Finally, loans can be made either spot or under commitment. A spot loan is made by the FI, and the borrower uses or takes down the entire loan amount immediately. With a loan commitment, or line of credit, the lender makes an amount of credit available, such as $10 million. The borrower has the option to take down any amount up to the $10 million at any time over the commitment period. In a fixedrate loan commitment, the interest rate to be paid on any takedown is established when the loan commitment contract originates. In a floating-rate commitment, the borrower pays the loan rate in force when the loan is actually taken down. For example, suppose the $10 million floating-rate IBM loan was made under a oneyear loan commitment. When the loan commitment was originated (say, January 2015), IBM borrows nothing. Instead, it waits until six months have passed (say, July 2015) before it takes down the entire $10 million. Since this is a floating-rate loan commitment, IBM pays the loan rate in force as of July 2015. We discuss the special features of loan commitments more fully in Chapter 16. To determine the basic characteristics of C&I loans, the Federal Reserve surveys more than 400 banks each quarter. Table 10–2 shows the major characteristics in a recent lending survey. As you can see, more short-term (under one year) C&I loans ($62.27 billion) than long-term loans ($3.36 billion) were reported. Also, short-term loans are less likely to be backed or secured by collateral (ranging from 27.1 percent for daily loans to 67.9 percent for zero loans) than long-term loans (80.7 percent). Finally, as we noted in Chapter 2, commercial loans are declining in importance in bank loan portfolios. The major reason for this has been the rise in nonbank loan substitutes, especially commercial paper. Commercial paper is an unsecured short-term debt instrument issued by corporations either directly or via an underwriter to purchasers in the financial markets, such as money market mutual funds. TABLE 10–2 Characteristics of Commercial Loan Portfolios, March 2012 Source: Federal Reserve Board website, June 2012. www.federalreserve.gov Long-Term Loans Amount outstanding ($ billions) Average size of loan ($ thousands) Percent of which made under commitment Percent of loans secured by collateral Short-Term Loans Zero* Daily 2 to 30 days 31 to 365 days $3.36 $355 88.8% $17.96 $294 95.9% $17.34 $2,282 31.9% $20.87 $501 83.5% $6.10 $713 89.7% 80.7% 67.9% 27.1% 39.9% 54.6% *Floating-rate loans that are subject to repricing at any time. 4 However, floating-rate loans are more credit risky than fixed-rate loans, holding all other contractual features the same. This is because floating-rate loans pass the risk of all interest rate changes onto borrowers. Thus, in rising interest rate environments, floating-rate borrowers may find themselves unable to pay the interest on their loans and may be forced to default. This is what happened in the mortgage markets in the late 2000s and ignited the financial crisis. The benefit of floating-rate loans to lenders is that they better enable FIs to hedge the cost of rising interest rates on liabilities (such as deposits). This suggests that controlling interest rate risk may be at the expense of enhanced credit risk. 280 Part Two Measuring Risk By using commercial paper, a corporation can sidestep banks and the loan market to raise funds often at rates below those banks charge. As of June 2012, the total commercial paper outstanding in the United States was $1,007.1 billion compared with C&I loans of $1,322.1 billion. Prior to the financial crisis, in December 2007 commercial paper outstanding was $1,788.1 billion compared to $1,445.8 billion in bank loans. Moreover, since only the largest corporations can tap the commercial paper market, banks are often left with a pool of increasingly smaller and riskier borrowers in the C&I loan market. For example, as the U.S. economy slowed in the early 2000s, noncurrent (loans that are 90 days or more past due or are not accruing interest) C&I loans increased from $14 billion (in the fourth quarter of 1999) to almost $24 billion (in the second quarter of 2003). As the economy strengthened in the mid-2000s, this amount decreased to $2.4 billion. The recession and financial crisis in the late 2000s saw noncurrent C&I loans grow again; to a high of $45 billion in the third quarter of 2009. The commercial paper market was also hard hit by the financial crisis, but not because of nonperformance issues related to the commercial paper issuing firms. At the height of the crisis, in September 2008, money market mutual fund withdrawals skyrocketed. Fund investors pulled out a record $144.5 billion during the week ending Wednesday, September 17 (redemptions during the week of September 10 totaled just $7.1 billion), as investors worried about the safety of even these safest investments. Money market mutual funds participated heavily in the $1.7 trillion commercial paper market, which provided a bulk of the short-term funds to corporations. As investors pulled their money from these funds, the commercial paper market shrank by $52.1 billion for the week (through Wednesday). These outflows severely undermined the stability of short-term funding markets, upon which many large corporations rely heavily to meet their short-term borrowing needs. In response, businesses that had them drew down their loan commitments at FIs. Thus, C&I loans issued by commercial banks increased as the commercial paper market decreased in size. Real Estate Loans Real estate loans are primarily mortgage loans and some revolving home equity loans (approximately 13 percent of the real estate loan portfolio in March 2012).5 We show the distribution of mortgage debt for U.S. banks in 2012 in Table 10–3. For banks (as well as thrifts), residential mortgages are still the largest component of the real estate loan portfolio (63.5 percent in 2012). TABLE 10–3 Percent Distribution of U.S. Commercial Bank Real Estate Mortgage Debt One- to four-family residences Multifamily residences Commercial Farm Source: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation website, June 2012. www.fdic.gov 63.5% 5.1 29.3 2.1 100.0% 5 Under home equity loans, borrowers use the equity they have in their homes as collateral backing for loans. Chapter 10 FIGURE 10–2 Credit Risk: Individual Loan Risk 281 ARMs’ Share of Total Loans Closed, 1987–2012 Sources: Federal Housing Finance Agency website, www.fhfa.gov, and Federal Reserve Board website, www.federalreserve.gov. 70 ARMs’ share (%) 12 ARMs’ share(%) 30-year mortgage rate (%) 11 60 10 50 9 40 8 30 7 20 6 10 5 0 1987 1989 adjustable-rate mortgage (ARM) A mortgage whose interest rate adjusts with movements in an underlying market index interest rate. 1991 1993 1995 1997 1999 2001 2003 2005 2007 2009 30-year mortgage rates (%) 80 4 2011 Year As with C&I loans, the characteristics of residential mortgage loans differ widely. These characteristics include the size of the loan, the ratio of the loan to the property’s price (the loan price or loan value ratio), and the maturity of the mortgage. Other important characteristics are the mortgage interest (or commitment) rate and fees and charges on the loan, such as commissions, discounts, and points paid by the borrower or the seller to obtain the loan.6 In addition, the mortgage rate differs according to whether the mortgage has a fixed rate or a floating rate, also called an adjustable rate. Adjustable-rate mortgages (ARMs) have their contractual rates periodically adjusted to some underlying index, such as the oneyear T-bill rate. The proportion of fixed-rate mortgages to ARMs in FI portfolios varies with the interest rate cycle. In low–interest rate periods, borrowers prefer fixed-rate to adjustable-rate mortgages. As a result, the proportion of ARMs to fixed-rate mortgages can vary considerably over the rate cycle. In Figure 10–2, note the behavior of ARMs over one recent interest rate cycle—1999 to 2007— when interest rates (and ARMs) rose, then fell, and then rose and fell again. Note also that ARMs were virtually nonexistent in late 2008 and 2009 as the federal government, in an effort to stimulate the devasted housing market, took actions that lowered fixed mortgage rates to historic lows. Table 10–4 presents a summary of the major contractual terms on conventional fixed-rate mortgages as of 2012. TABLE 10–4 Purchase price ($ thousands) Amount of loan ($ thousands) Loan-to-value ratio (percent) Maturity (years) Fees and charges (percent of loan amount) Contract rate (percent) Contractual Terms on Conventional New Home Mortgages Source: Federal Housing Finance Agency, Mortgage Interest Rates, June 2012. www.fhfa.gov 6 $349.2 $256.2 75.3% 27.3 0.90% 3.93% Points are a certain percentage of the face value of the loan paid up front, as a fee, by the borrower to the lender. 282 Part Two Measuring Risk Home buyers raised an average of 75.3 percent of the value of their new homes by borrowing through mortgage loans. Rates charged on the average loan remained at historical lows (3.93 percent), and mortgage lenders charged an additional 0.9 percent in fees for processing the mortgages. Residential mortgages are very long-term loans with an average maturity of 29 years. To the extent that house prices can fall below the amount of the loan outstanding—that is, the loan-to-value ratio rises—the residential mortgage portfolio can also be susceptible to default risk. For example, during the collapse in real estate prices in the late 2000s, many house prices actually fell below the prices of the mid-2000s. This led to a dramatic surge in the level of mortgage defaults and eventually foreclosures by banks and thrifts. Individual (Consumer) Loans revolving loan A credit line on which a borrower can both draw and repay many times over the life of the loan contract. Another major type of loan is the individual, or consumer, loan, such as personal and auto loans. Commercial banks, finance companies, retailers, savings institutions, credit unions, and oil companies also provide consumer loan financing through credit cards, such as Visa, MasterCard, and proprietary credit cards issued by, for example, Sears and AT&T. Credit card transactions typically must be authorized by the cardholder’s bank. Thus, verification of satisfactory credit quality occurs with each transaction. The five largest credit card issuers and their outstanding balances in 2011 are shown in Table 10–5. Together, these five credit card issuers hold more than 66 percent of all outstanding balances. In Table 10–6 are the two major classes of consumer loans at U.S. banks. The largest class of loans is nonrevolving consumer loans (66.2 percent), which include new and used automobile loans, mobile home loans, and fixed-term consumer loans such as 24-month personal loans. The other major class of consumer loans is revolving loans (33.8 percent), such as credit card debt. With a revolving loan, the borrower has a credit line on which to draw as well as to repay, up to some maximum over the life of the credit contract. In recent years, bank’s have faced chargeoff rates between 4 and 8 percent on their credit card loans outstanding. Note particularly that in October 2005, the Bankruptcy Reform Act was signed into law. TABLE 10–5 Biggest Credit Card Issuers Source: The Nilson Report, February 2012. Card Issuer J.P. Morgan Chase Bank of America Citigroup American Express Capital One Financial TABLE 10–6 Types of Consumer Loans at Commercial Banks Source: Federal Reserve Board website, Consumer Credit, June 2012. www.federalreserve.gov Total Outstanding Balances ($ billions) Market Share, 2011 Market Share, 2010 $130.02 112.62 92.33 80.25 50.88 18.23% 15.79 12.94 11.92 7.13 18.64% 17.19 13.34 11.28 7.05 Percent Revolving Nonrevolving 33.8% 66.2 100.0% Chapter 10 FIGURE 10–3 Credit Risk: Individual Loan Risk 283 Annual Net Charge-Off Rates on Loans Source: Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, Quarterly Banking Profile, various issues. www.fdic.gov Number of bankruptcies (thousands) Percent of loans 14 1100 13 1000 12 900 11 Personal bankruptcy filings Credit card charge-offs C&I charge-offs 10 9 800 700 8 7 600 6 500 5 400 4 3 300 2 200 1 0 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2012 2012 usury ceilings National-, state-, or city-imposed ceilings on the maximum rate FIs can charge on consumer and mortgage debt. This act made it more difficult for consumers to declare bankruptcy. As a result, there was a surge in bankruptcy filings in the summer and early fall of 2005, just before the new rules went into effect. Consequently, banks saw a surge in credit card charge-offs. These charge-off rates were significantly higher than those on commercial loans (see Figure 10–3). Note also that the level of credit card charge offs rose sharply during the financial crisis (to over 13 percent), which is significantly higher than that seen on commercial loan charge offs (which peaked at 8.7 percent). Such relatively high default rates again point to the importance of risk evaluation prior to the credit decision. In Table 10–7 we show indicative interest rates on car (5.07 percent), personal (10.88 percent), and credit card (12.34 percent) loans as of February 2012. These rates differ widely depending on features such as collateral backing, maturity, default rate experience, and non–interest rate fees. In addition, competitive conditions in each market as well as regulations such as national-, state-, or city-imposed usury ceilings (maximum rates FIs can charge on consumer and mortgage debt) all affect the rate structure for consumer loans. For example, in 2012 federally chartered credit unions were prohibited from charging more than 18 percent on any loan. TABLE 10–7 Interest Rate Terms on Consumer Loans Source: Federal Reserve Board website, Consumer Credit, June 2012. www.federalreserve.gov Percent 48-month car loan 24-month personal loan Credit card 5.07% 10.88 12.34 284 Part Two Measuring Risk Other Loans The “other loans” category can include a wide variety of borrowers and types, including farmers, other banks, nonbank financial institutions such as broker margin loans (loans financing a percentage of an individual investment portfolio), state and local governments, foreign banks, and sovereign governments. We discuss sovereign loans in Chapter 14. Concept Questions 1. What are the four major types of loans made by U.S. commercial banks? What are the basic distinguishing characteristics of each type of loan? 2. Will more ARMs be originated in high- or low-interest-rate environments? Explain your answer. 3. In Table 10–7, explain why credit card loan rates are much higher than car loan rates. CALCULATING THE RETURN ON A LOAN An important element in the credit management process, once the decision to make a loan has been made, is its pricing. This includes adjustments for the perceived credit risk or default risk of the borrower as well as any fees and collateral backing the loan.7 This section demonstrates one method used to calculate the return on a loan: the traditional return on assets approach. Although we demonstrate the return calculations using examples of commercial and industrial loans, the techniques can be used to calculate the return on other loans (such as credit card or mortgage loans) as well. The Contractually Promised Return on a Loan The previous description of loans makes it clear that a number of factors impact the promised return an FI achieves on any given dollar loan (asset) amount. These factors include the following: 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. The interest rate on the loan. Any fees relating to the loan. The credit risk premium on the loan. The collateral backing of the loan. Other nonprice terms (especially compensating balances and reserve requirements). First, let us consider an example of how to calculate the promised return on a C&I loan. Suppose that an FI makes a spot one-year, $1 million loan. The loan rate is set as follows: Base lending rate (BR) 12% Credit risk premium or margin ( ) 2% BR 14% 7 FIs have developed relationship pricing programs, which offer discounts on interest rates for customers based on the total amount of fee-based services used and investments held at the FI. Relationship pricing is in contrast to (the more traditional) transaction pricing, in which customers pay a stated rate for a service regardless of the total amount of other (nonloan) business conducted with the FI. Chapter 10 LIBOR The London Interbank Offered Rate, which is the rate for interbank dollar loans of a given maturity in the offshore or Eurodollar market. prime lending rate The base lending rate periodically set by banks. compensating balance A percentage of a loan that a borrower is required to hold on deposit at the lending institution. Credit Risk: Individual Loan Risk 285 The base lending rate (BR) could reflect the FI’s weighted-average cost of capital or its marginal cost of funds, such as the commercial paper rate, the federal funds rate, or LIBOR—the London Interbank Offered Rate, which is the rate for interbank dollar loans of a given maturity in the Eurodollar market. The center of the Eurodollar market is London. Initially, most variable-rate business loans were tied to the U.S. fed funds rate. However, the tremendous growth of the Eurodollar market has resulted in the LIBOR becoming the standard rate by which these loan rates are now priced. For example, the commercial paper market in the United States now quotes rates as a spread over the LIBOR rate rather than over the Treatsury bill rate. Higher LIBOR rates result in higher borrowing costs for businesses while lower rates can make FIs hesitant to lend. In addition to business loans, some bonds and interest rate swaps also use LIBOR as their benchmark. The After the Crisis box looks at allegations that several large banks tried to manipulate the LIBOR rate during the financial crisis. Because of the extensive use of LIBOR as a base rate on business loans, and even mortgages and credit card rates, even a small bit of manipulation can cause massive redistribution of resources. In addition to the Canadian government, the U.S. Justice Department as well as officials in Switzerland and the United Kingdom are involved in the investigation. As stated in the box, in June 2012, the British bank Barclays agreed to pay $453 million to U.S. and British authorities to settle allegations that it manipulated the LIBOR. The Barclays settlement put increasing pressure on other banks to cooperate in the probe that could cost the financial industry billions of dollars and brought to question the use of LIBOR as the benchmark loan rate. Alternatively, the base lending rate could reflect the prime lending rate. The prime rate is most commonly used in pricing longer-term loans, while the fed funds rate and LIBOR rate are most commonly used in pricing short-term loans. Traditionally, the prime rate has been the rate charged to the FI’s lowest-risk customers. Now, it is more of a base rate to which positive or negative risk premiums (f) can be added. In other words, the best and largest borrowers now commonly pay below prime rate to be competitive with the commercial paper market. Direct and indirect fees and charges relating to a loan generally fall into three categories: 1. A loan origination fee (of ) charged to the borrower for processing the application. 2. A compensating balance requirement (b) to be held as (generally non-interestbearing demand) deposits. Compensating balances are a percentage of a loan that a borrower cannot actively use for expenditures. Instead, these balances must be kept on deposit at the FI. For example, a borrower facing a 10 percent compensating balance requirement on a $100 loan would have to place $10 on deposit (traditionally on demand deposit) with the FI and could use only $90 of the $100 borrowed. This requirement raises the effective cost of loans for the borrower since less than the full loan amount ($90 in this case) can actually be used by the borrower and the deposit rate earned on compensating balances is less than the borrowing rate. Thus, compensating balance requirements act as an additional source of return on lending for an FI.8 3. A reserve requirement (RR) imposed by the Federal Reserve on the FI’s (specifically depository institution’s) demand deposits, including any compensating balances. 8 They also create a more stable supply of deposits and thus mitigate liquidity problems. Further, compensating balances are sometimes used as an offset to fees charged on the loan. That is, loans with a compensating balance requirement often have lower fees than loans without a compensating balance. In this case, the additional revenue from the compensating balances is offset by the loss in fee income. 286 Part Two Measuring Risk After the Crisis Interest Rate Probe Escalates: Barclays Agrees to Pay Record Fine; Emails Show Traders Tried to Manipulate Libor Barclays agreed to pay $453 million in fines after admitting that traders and executives tried to manipulate benchmark interest rates tied to loans and contracts around the world . . . A series of Wall Street Journal articles in 2008 raised questions about whether global banks were manipulating the process by low-balling a key interest rate to avoid looking desperate for cash amid the financial crisis. Emails and instant messages disclosed in the bank’s settlement show how Barclays’s traders tried to manipulate rates to benefit their own trading positions. “This is the way you pull off deals like this chicken,” one trader told another trader in March 2007, according to the U.K. regulator. “Don’t tell ANYBODY.”. . . The unusually steep punishment reflected what officials said were serious and widespread efforts by traders and senior managers at Barclays to manipulate the London Interbank Offered Rate, or Libor, and the Euro Interbank Offered Rate, or Euribor. The rates are used globally to help set the price of many types of loans, from home mortgages to commercial borrowing. The bank’s $200 million fine with the Commodity Futures Trading Commission was the U.S. agency’s largest penalty ever . . . Other banks that have disclosed they are under investigation include Citigroup Inc., HSBC Holdings, J.P. Morgan Chase, Lloyds Banking Group, and Royal Bank of Scotland Group PLC. None of these banks have been charged with any wrongdoing in the matter by U.S. or U.K. regulators. The CFTC filing said the wrongful conduct at Barclays lasted at least four years and “at times occurred on an almost daily basis.” In an October 2006 email quoted by the U.K. regulator, an employee at another bank told a Barclays trader to try to get the benchmark rate lower, saying: “If it comes in unchanged I’m a dead man.” Hours later he offered a bottle of Bollinger as thanks for the attempted manipulation: “Dude. I owe you big time!”. . . Libor is set each day in London based on estimates submitted by a panel of banks. The banks are supposed to say how much it would cost them to borrow from each other in different currencies over different time periods. The CFTC said the rates affect “enormous volumes” of financial transactions, including $360 trillion of swaps and loans, as well as futures traded on the Chicago Mercantile Exchange with a notional value in 2011 of more than $564 trillion . . . In its filing, the CFTC alleged that a senior manager at Barclays warned the bankers’ association in a phone call in 2008 that the bank hadn’t been submitting accurate Libor rates. Source: The Wall Street Journal, June 28, 2012, by Jean Eaglesham and Max Colchester. Reprinted by permission of The Wall Street Journal. © 2012 Dow Jones & Company, Inc. All rights Reserved Worldwide. www.wsj.com While credit risk may be the most important factor ultimately affecting the return on a loan, these other factors should not be ignored by FI managers in evaluating loan profitability and risk. Indeed, FIs can compensate for high credit risk in a number of ways other than charging a higher explicit interest rate or risk premium on a loan or restricting the amount of credit available. In particular, higher fees, high compensating balances, and increased collateral backing all offer implicit and indirect methods of compensating an FI for lending risk. The contractually promised gross return on the loan, k, per dollar lent—or ROA per dollar lent—equals:9 1k 1 of (BR ) 1 [b(1 RR)] This formula may need some explanation. The numerator is the promised gross cash inflow to the FI per dollar lent, reflecting direct fees (of ) plus the loan interest 9 This formula ignores present value aspects that could easily be incorporated. For example, fees are earned in up-front undiscounted dollars while interest payments and risk premiums are normally paid on loan maturity and thus should be discounted by the FI’s cost of funds. Chapter 10 Credit Risk: Individual Loan Risk 287 rate (BR f). In the denominator, for every $1 the FI lends, it retains b as noninterest-bearing compensating balances. Thus, 1 b is the net proceeds of each $1 of loans received by the borrower from the FI, ignoring reserve requirements. However, since b (the compensating balance) is held by the borrower at the FI in a demand deposit account, the Federal Reserve requires depository institutions to hold non- (or low) interest-bearing reserves at the rate RR against the compensating balance. Thus, the FI’s net benefit from requiring compensating balances must consider the cost of holding additional reserve requirements. The net outflow by the FI per $1 of loans is 1 [b(1 RR)], or 1 minus the reserve adjusted compensating balance requirement. EXAMPLE 10–1 Calculation of ROA on a Loan Suppose a bank does the following: 1. Sets the loan rate on a prospective loan at 10 percent (where BR 6% and f 4%). 2. Charges a 1/8 percent (or 0.125 percent) loan origination fee to the borrower. 3. Imposes a 8 percent compensating balance requirement to be held as non-interest-bearing demand deposits. 4. Sets aside reserves, at a rate of 10 percent of deposits, held at the Federal Reserve (i.e., the Fed’s cash-to-deposit reserve ratio is 10 percent). Plugging the numbers from our example into the return formula, we have:10 0.00125 (0.06 0.04) 1 [(0.08)(0.9)] 0.10125 1 k 1 0.928 1 k 1.1091 or k 10.91% 1 k 1 This is, of course, greater than the simple promised interest return on the loan, BR f 10%. In the special case where fees (of ) are zero and the compensating balance (b) is zero: of 0 b 0 the contractually promised return formula reduces to: 1 k 1 (BR ) That is, the credit risk premium or margin (f) is the fundamental factor driving the promised return on a loan once the base rate on the loan is set. Note that as commercial lending markets have become more competitive, both origination fees (of ) and compensating balances (b) are becoming less important. For example, where compensating balances are still charged, the FI may now allow them to be held as time deposits, and they earn interest. As a result, borrowers’ opportunity losses from compensating balances have been reduced to 10 If we take into account the present value effects on the fees and the interest payments and assume that the bank’s discount rate (d ) was 10.5 percent, then the BR f term needs to be discounted by 1 d 1.105, while fees (as up-front payments) are undiscounted. In this case, k is 9.89 percent. 288 Part Two Measuring Risk the difference between the loan rate and the compensating balance time-deposit rate.11 Further, compensating balance requirements are very rare on international loans such as Eurodollar loans. Finally, note that for a given promised gross return on a loan, k, FI managers can use the pricing formula to find various combinations of fees, compensating balances, and risk premiums they may offer their customers that generate the same returns. The Expected Return on a Loan default risk The risk that the borrower is unable or unwilling to fulfill the terms promised under the loan contract. The promised return on the loan (1 k) that the borrower and lender contractually agree on includes both the loan interest rate and non–interest rate features such as fees. The promised return on the loan, however, may well differ from the expected and, indeed, actual return on a loan because of default risk. Default risk is the risk that the borrower is unable or unwilling to fulfill the terms promised under the loan contract. Default risk is usually present to some degree in all loans. Thus, at the time the loan is made, the expected return [E(r)] per dollar lent is related to the promised return as follows: 1 E(r ) p(1 k ) (1 p)0 where p is the probability of complete repayment of the loan (such that the FI receives the principal and interest as promised) and (1 p) is the probability of default (in which the FI receives nothing, i.e., 0). Rearranging this equation, we get: E(r ) p (1 k ) 1 To the extent that p is less than 1, default risk is present. This means the FI manager must (1) set the risk premium (f) sufficiently high to compensate for this risk and (2) recognize that setting high risk premiums as well as high fees and base rates may actually reduce the probability of repayment (p). That is, k and p are not independent. Indeed, over some range, as fees and loan rates increase, the probability that the borrower pays the promised return may decrease (i.e., k and p may be negatively related). As a result, FIs usually have to control for credit risk along two dimensions: the price or promised return dimension (1 k) and the quantity or credit availability dimension. Further, even after adjusting the loan rate for the default risk of the borrower (by increasing the risk premium on the loan), there is no guarantee that the FI will actually receive the promised payments. The measurement and pricing approaches discussed in the chapter consider credit risk based on probabilities of receiving promised payments on the loan. The actual payment or default on a loan once it is issued may vary from the probability expected. In general, compared with wholesale (e.g., C&I) loans, the quantity dimension controls credit risk differences on retail (e.g., consumer) loans more than the price dimension does. We discuss the reasons for this in the next section. That is followed by a section that evaluates various ways FI managers can assess the appropriate size of f, the risk premium on a loan. This is the key to pricing wholesale loan and debt risk exposures correctly. 11 If compensating balances held as deposits paid interest at 2 percent (rd 2%), then the numerator (cash flow) of the bank in the example would be reduced by b rd, where rd 0.02 and b 0.08. In this case, the k 10.74 percent. This assumes that the reserve requirement on compensating balances held as time deposits (RR) is 10 percent. However, while currently reserve requirements on demand deposits are 10 percent, the reserve requirement on time deposits is 0 percent (zero). Recalculating but assuming RR 0 and interest of 2 percent on compensating balances, we find k 10.83 percent. Chapter 10 Concept Questions Credit Risk: Individual Loan Risk 289 1. Calculate the promised return (k) on a loan if the base rate is 13 percent, the risk premium is 2 percent, the compensating balance requirement is 5 percent, fees are ½ percent, and reserve requirements are 10 percent. (16.23%) 2. What is the expected return on this loan if the probability of default is 5 percent? (10.42%) RETAIL VERSUS WHOLESALE CREDIT DECISIONS Retail credit rationing Restricting the quantity of loans made available to individual borrowers. Because of the small dollar size of the loans in the context of an FI’s overall asset portfolio and the higher costs of collecting information on household borrowers (consumer loans), most loan decisions made at the retail level tend to be accept or reject decisions. Regardless of their credit risk, borrowers who are accepted are often charged the same rate of interest and by implication the same credit risk premium. For example, a wealthy individual borrowing from a credit union to finance the purchase of a Rolls-Royce is likely to be charged the same auto loan rate as a less wealthy individual borrowing from that credit union to finance the purchase of a Honda. In the terminology of finance, retail customers (consumer loans) are more likely to be sorted or rationed by loan quantity restrictions than by price or interest rate differences.12 That is, at the retail level an FI controls its credit risks by credit rationing rather than by using a range of interest rates or prices. Thus, the FI may offer the wealthy individual a loan of up to $80,000, while the same FI may offer the less wealthy individual a loan of up to $20,000, both at the same interest rate. Residential mortgage loans provide another good example. While two borrowers may be accepted for mortgage loans, an FI discriminates between them according to the loan-to-value ratio—the amount the FI is willing to lend relative to the market value of the house being acquired—rather than by setting different mortgage rates. Wholesale In contrast to the retail level, at the wholesale (C&I) level FIs use both interest rates and credit quantity to control credit risk. Thus, when FIs quote a prime lending rate (BR) to C&I borrowers, lower-risk borrowers may be charged a lending rate below the prime lending rate (i.e., f 0). Higher-risk borrowers are charged a markup on the prime rate, or a credit (default) risk premium (i.e., f 0), to compensate the FI for the additional credit risk involved. As long as they are compensated with sufficiently high interest rates (or credit risk premiums), over some range of credit demand, FIs may be willing to lend funds to high-risk wholesale borrowers. However, as discussed earlier, increasing loan interest rates (k) may decrease the probability (p) that a borrower will pay the promised return. For example, a borrower who is charged 15 percent for a loan—a prime rate of 6 percent plus a credit risk premium of 9 percent—may be able to make the promised payments on the loan only by using the funds to invest in high-risk investments with some small chance of a big payoff. However, 12 This does not mean that rates cannot vary across FIs. For example, finance companies associated with car manufacturers (e.g., GMAC) offered 0.0 percent financing on car loans for much of the 2000s. Unrecognized by many car buyers, the lenders’ costs of funds were incorporated into an increased price for the car. Depository institutions, not able to recover their costs of funds in this manner, offered varying rates in an attempt to compete with finance companies. However, for a given FI, the rate offered on car loans would be the same for all borrowers. 290 Part Two Measuring Risk by definition, high-risk projects have relatively high probabilities that they will fail to realize the big payoff. If the big payoff does not materialize, the borrower may have to default on the loan. In an extreme case, the FI receives neither the promised interest and fees on the loan nor the original principal lent. This suggests that very high contractual interest rate charges on loans may actually reduce an FI’s expected return on loans because high interest rates induce the borrower to invest in risky projects.13 Alternatively, only borrowers that intend to use the borrowed funds to invest in high-risk projects (high-risk borrowers) may be interested in borrowing from FIs at high interest rates. Low-risk borrowers drop out of the potential borrowing pool at high-rate levels. This lowers the average quality of the pool of potential borrowers. We show these effects in Figure 10–4. At very low contractually promised interest rates (k), borrowers do not need to take high risks in their use of funds and those with relatively safe investment projects use FI financing. As interest rates increase, borrowers with fairly lowrisk, low-return projects no longer think it is profitable to borrow from FIs and drop out of the pool of potential borrowers. Alternatively, borrowers may switch their use of the borrowed funds to high-risk investment projects to have a (small) chance of being able to pay off the loan. In terms of Figure 10–4, when interest rates rise above k* (8 percent), the additional expected return earned by the FI through higher contractually promised interest rates (k) is increasingly offset by a lower probability of repayment on the loan (p). In other words, because of the potential increase in the probability of default when contractually promised loan rates are high, an FI charging wholesale borrowers loan rates in the 9 to 14 percent region can earn a lower expected return than will an FI charging 8 percent. This relationship between contractually promised interest rates and the expected returns on loans suggests that beyond some interest rate level, it may be best for the FI to credit ration its wholesale loans, that is, to not make loans or to FIGURE 10–4 Relationship between the Promised Loan Rate and the Expected Return on the Loan Expected return on loan [p(1 + k ) – 1] percent 14 13 12 11 10 9 8 7 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 k* 13 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 Contractually promised loan rate (k) percent In the context of the previous section, a high k on the loan reflecting a high base rate (BR) and risk premium (f) can lead to a lower probability of repayment (p) and thus a lower E(r) on the loan, where E(r) p(1 k) 1. Indeed, for very high k, the expected return on the loan can become negative. Chapter 10 Credit Risk: Individual Loan Risk 291 make fewer loans. Rather than seeking to ration by price (by charging higher and higher risk premiums to borrowers), the FI can establish an upper ceiling on the amounts it is willing to lend to maximize its expected returns on lending. In the context of Figure 10–4, borrowers may be charged interest rates up to 8 percent, with the most risky borrowers also facing more restrictive limits or ceilings on the amounts they can borrow at any given interest rate. Concept Questions 1. Can an FI’s expected return on its loan portfolio increase if it cuts its loan rates? 2. What might happen to the expected return on a wholesale loan if an FI eliminates its fees and compensating balances in a low–interest rate environment? MEASUREMENT OF CREDIT RISK covenants Restrictions written into bond and loan contracts either limiting or encouraging the borrower’s actions that affect the probability of repayment. To calibrate the default risk exposure of credit and investment decisions as well as to assess the credit risk exposure in off-balance-sheet contractual arrangements such as loan commitments, an FI manager needs to measure the probability of borrower default. The ability to do this depends largely on the amount of information the FI has about the borrower. At the retail level, much of the information needs to be collected internally or purchased from external credit agencies. At the wholesale level, these information sources are bolstered by publicly available information, such as certified accounting statements, stock and bond prices, and analysts’ reports. Thus, for a publicly traded company, more information is produced and is available to an FI than is available for a small, single-proprietor corner store. The availability of more information, along with the lower average cost of collecting such information, allows FIs to use more sophisticated and usually more quantitative methods in assessing default probabilities for large borrowers compared with small borrowers. However, advances in technology and information collection are making quantitative assessments of even smaller borrowers increasingly feasible and less costly. The simpler details (such as cash flow and ratio analysis) associated with the measurement of credit risk at the retail and the wholesale levels are discussed in Appendix 10A, located at the book’s website (www.mhhe.com/saunders8e). In principle, FIs can use very similar methods and models to assess the probabilities of default on both bonds and loans. Even though loans tend to involve fewer lenders to any single borrower as opposed to multiple bondholders, in essence, both loans and bonds are contracts that promise fixed (or indexed) payments at regular intervals in the future. Loans and bonds stand ahead of the borrowing firm’s equity holders in terms of the priority of their claims if things go wrong. Also, bonds, like loans, include covenants restricting or encouraging various actions to enhance the probability of repayment. Covenants can include limits on the type and amount of new debt, investments, and asset sales the borrower may undertake while the loan or bonds are outstanding. Financial covenants are also often imposed restricting changes in the borrower’s financial ratios such as its leverage ratio or current ratio. For example, a common restrictive covenant included in many bond and loan contracts limits the amount of dividends a firm can pay to its equity holders. Clearly, for any given cash flow, a high dividend payout to stockholders means that less is available for repayments to bondholders and lenders. Moreover, bond yields, like wholesale loan rates, usually reflect risk premiums that vary with the perceived 292 Part Two Measuring Risk credit quality of the borrower and the collateral or security backing of the debt. Given this, FIs can use many of the following models that analyze default risk probabilities either in making lending decisions or when considering investing in corporate bonds offered either publicly or privately. Concept Questions 1. Is it more costly for an FI manager to assess the default risk exposure of a publicly traded company or a small, single-proprietor firm? Explain your answer. 2. How do loan covenants help protect an FI against default risk? DEFAULT RISK MODELS Economists, analysts, and FI managers have employed many different models to assess the default risk on loans and bonds. These vary from relatively qualitative to the highly quantitative models. Further, these models are not mutually exclusive; an FI manager may use more than one model to reach a credit pricing or loan quantity rationing decision. As will be discussed below in more detail, a great deal of time and effort has recently been expended by FIs in building highly technical credit risk evaluation models. Many of these models use ideas and techniques similar to the market risk models discussed in Chapter 15. We analyze a number of models in two broad groups: qualitative models and quantitative models. Qualitative Models In the absence of publicly available information on the quality of borrowers, the FI manager has to assemble information from private sources—such as credit and deposit files—and/or purchase such information from external sources—such as credit rating agencies. This information helps a manager make an informed judgment on the probability of default of the borrower and price the loan or debt correctly. In general, the amount of information assembled varies with the size of the potential debt exposure and the costs of collection. However, a number of key factors enter into the credit decision. These include (1) borrower-specific factors, which are idiosyncratic to the individual borrower, and (2) market-specific factors, which have an impact on all borrowers at the time of the credit decision. The FI manager then weights these factors subjectively to come to an overall credit decision. Because of their reliance on the subjective judgment of the FI manager, these models are often called expert systems. Commonly used borrower-specific and market-specific factors are discussed next. Borrower-Specific Factors implicit contract Long-term customer relationship between a borrower and lender based on reputation. Reputation The borrower’s reputation involves the borrowing–lending history of the credit applicant. If, over time, the borrower has established a reputation for prompt and timely repayment, this enhances the applicant’s attractiveness to the FI. A long-term customer relationship between a borrower and lender forms an implicit contract regarding borrowing and repayment that extends beyond the formal explicit legal contract on which borrower–lender relationships are based. The importance of reputation, which can be established only over time through repayment and observed behavior, works to the disadvantage of small, newer borrowers. This is one of the reasons initial public offerings of debt securities by small firms often require higher yields than do offerings of older, more seasoned firms. Chapter 10 leverage The ratio of a borrower’s debt to equity. Credit Risk: Individual Loan Risk 293 Leverage A borrower’s leverage or capital structure—the ratio of debt to equity— affects the probability of its default because large amounts of debt, such as bonds and loans, increase the borrower’s interest charges and pose a significant claim on its cash flows. As shown in Figure 10–5, relatively low debt–equity ratios may not significantly impact the probability of debt repayment. Yet beyond some point, the risk of bankruptcy increases, as does the probability of some loss of interest or principal for the lender. Thus, highly leveraged firms may find it necessary to pay higher risk premiums on their borrowings if they are not rationed in the first place. Volatility of Earnings As with leverage, a highly volatile earnings stream increases the probability that the borrower cannot meet fixed interest and principal charges for any given capital structure. Consequently, newer firms or firms in high-tech industries with a high earnings variance over time are less attractive credit risks than are those with long and more stable earnings histories. Collateral As discussed earlier, a key feature in any lending and loan-pricing decision is the degree of collateral, or assets backing the security of the loan. Many loans and bonds are backed by specific assets should a borrower default on repayment obligations. Mortgage bonds give the bondholder first claim to some specific piece of property of the borrower, normally machinery or buildings; debentures give a bondholder a more general and more risky claim to the borrower’s assets. Subordinated debentures are even riskier because their claims to the assets of a defaulting borrower are junior to those of both mortgage bondholders and debenture bondholders. Similarly, loans can be either secured (collateralized) or unsecured (uncollateralized).14 Market-Specific Factors The Business Cycle The position of the economy in the business cycle phase is enormously important to an FI in assessing the probability of borrower default. For example, during recessions, firms in the consumer durable goods sector that produce autos, refrigerators, or houses do badly compared with those in the nondurable goods sector producing clothing and foods. People cut back on luxuries FIGURE 10–5 Relationship between the Cost of Debt, the Probability of Default, and Leverage Probability of default 0 D/E* Leverage 100% (debt–equity ratio) 14 However, collateralized loans are still subject to some default risk unless these loans are significantly overcollateralized; that is, assets are pledged with market values exceeding the face value of the debt instrument. There is also some controversy as to whether posting collateral signifies a high- or low-risk borrower. Arguably, the best borrowers do not need to post collateral since they are good credit risks, whereas only more risky borrowers need to post collateral. That is, posting collateral may be a signal of more rather than less credit risk. 294 Part Two Measuring Risk www.federalreserve.gov www.rmahq.org Concept Questions during a recession, but are less likely to cut back on necessities such as food. Thus, corporate borrowers in the consumer durable goods sector of the economy are especially prone to default risk. Because of cyclical concerns, FIs are more likely to increase the relative degree of credit rationing in recessionary phases. This has especially adverse consequences for smaller borrowers with limited or no access to alternative credit markets such as the commercial paper market. The Level of Interest Rates High interest rates indicate restrictive monetary policy actions by the Federal Reserve. FIs not only find funds to finance their lending decisions scarcer and more expensive, but also must recognize that high interest rates are correlated with higher credit risk in general. As discussed earlier, high interest rate levels may encourage borrowers to take excessive risks and/or encourage only the most risky customers to borrow. So far, we have delineated just a few of the qualitative borrower- and economyspecific factors an FI manager may take into account in deciding on the probability of default on any loan or bond.15 Rather than letting such factors enter into the decision process in a purely subjective fashion, the FI manager may weight these factors in a more objective or quantitative manner. We discuss quantitative models used to measure credit risk next. One frequently used source of much of this information is the Risk Management Association (RMA). RMA has become a standard reference for thousands of commercial lenders by providing average balance sheet and income data for more than 400 industries, common ratios computed for each size group and industry, five-year trend data, and financial statement data for more than 100,000 commercial borrowers. 1. Make a list of key borrower characteristics you would assess before making a mortgage loan. 2. How should the risk premium on a loan be affected if there is a reduction in a borrower’s leverage? Quantitative Models Credit Scoring Models credit scoring models Mathematical models that use observed loan applicant’s characteristics either to calculate a score representing the applicant’s probability of default or to sort borrowers into different default risk classes. Credit scoring models are quantitative models that use observed borrower characteristics either to calculate a score representing the applicant’s probability of default or to sort borrowers into different default risk classes. By selecting and combining different economic and financial borrower characteristics, an FI manager may be able to: 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. Numerically establish which factors are important in explaining default risk. Evaluate the relative degree or importance of these factors. Improve the pricing of default risk. Be better able to screen out bad loan applicants. Be in a better position to calculate any reserves needed to meet expected future loan losses. The primary benefit from credit scoring is that credit lenders can more accurately predict a borrower’s performance without having to use more resources. 15 More generally, five Cs of credit that should be included in any subjective (qualitative) credit analysis include character (willingness to pay), capacity (cash flow), capital (wealth), collateral (security), and conditions (economic conditions). See Appendix 10A, located at the book’s website (www.mhhe.com/saunders8e). Chapter 10 Credit Risk: Individual Loan Risk 295 Using these models means fewer defaults and write-offs for lenders. Indeed, many FIs are implementing credit scoring models as a way to come in accordance with the Sarbanes–Oxley Act of 2002, which sets guidelines for corporate governance in several areas, including risk management and control assessment. To use credit scoring models, the manager must identify objective economic and financial measures of risk for any particular class of borrower. For consumer debt, the objective characteristics in a credit scoring model might include income, assets, age, occupation, and location. For commercial debt, cash flow information and financial ratios such as the debt–equity ratio are usually key factors. After data are identified, a statistical technique quantifies, or scores, the default risk probability or default risk classification. Credit scoring models include these three broad types: (1) linear probability models, (2) logit models, and (3) linear discriminant analysis. Appendix 10A to the chapter (located at the book’s website, www.mhhe.com/saunders8e) looks at credit scoring models used to evaluate mortgages and consumer loans. In this section we look at credit scoring models used to evaluate commercial loans. Linear Probability Model and Logit Model The linear probability model uses past data, such as financial ratios, as inputs into a model to explain repayment experience on old loans. The relative importance of the factors used in explaining past repayment performance then forecasts repayment probabilities on new loans. That is, factors explaining past repayment performance can be used for assessing p, the probability of repayment discussed earlier in this chapter (a key input in setting the credit premium on a loan or determining the amount to be lent) and the probability of default (PD). Briefly, we divide old loans into two observational groups: those that defaulted (PDi 1) and those that did not default (PDi 0). Then we relate these observations by linear regression to a set of j causal variables (Xij) that reflect quantitative information about the ith borrower, such as leverage or earnings. We estimate the model by linear regression of this form: PDi n ∑ β j Xij error j1 where j is the estimated importance of the jth variable (e.g., leverage) in explaining past repayment experience. If we then take these estimated js and multiply them by the observed Xij for a prospective borrower, we can derive an expected value of PDi for the prospective borrower. That value can be interpreted as the probability of default for the borrower: E(PDi) (1 pi) expected probability of default, where pi is the probability of repayment on the loan. EXAMPLE 10–2 Estimating the Probability of Repayment on a Loan Using Linear Probability Credit Scoring Models Suppose there were two factors influencing the past default behavior of borrowers: the leverage or debt–equity ratio (D/E) and the sales–asset ratio (S/A). Based on past default (repayment) experience, the linear probability model is estimated as: PDi 0.5( D/Ei ) 0.0525( S / Ai ) Assume a prospective borrower has a D/E 0.3 and an S/A 2.0. Its expected probability of default (PDi) can then be estimated as: PDi 0.5(0.3) 0.0525(2.0) 0.045 or 4.5% 296 Part Two Measuring Risk While this technique is straightforward as long as current information on the Xij is available for the borrower, its major weakness is that the estimated probabilities of default can often lie outside the interval 0 to 1. The logit model overcomes this weakness by restricting the estimated range of default probabilities from the linear regression model to lie between 0 and 1. Essentially this is done by plugging the estimated value of PDi from the linear probability model (in our example, PDi 0.045) into the following formula: F( PDi ) 1 1 ePDi where e is exponential (equal to 2.718) and F(PDi) is the logistically transformed value of PDi. Linear Discriminant Models While linear probability and logit models project a value for the expected probability of default if a loan is made, discriminant models divide borrowers into high or low default risk classes contingent on their observed characteristics (Xj). Similar to linear probability models, linear discriminant models use past data as inputs into a model to explain repayment experience on old loans. The relative importance of the factors used in explaining past repayment performance then forecasts whether the loan falls into the high or low default class. Consider the discriminant analysis model developed by E. I. Altman for publicly traded manufacturing firms in the United States. The indicator variable Z is an overall measure of the default risk classification of a commercial borrower.16 This in turn depends on the values of various financial ratios of the borrower (Xj) and the weighted importance of these ratios based on the past observed experience of defaulting versus nondefaulting borrowers derived from a discriminant analysis model.17 Altman’s discriminant function (credit-classification model) takes the form: Z 1.2X 1 1.4X 2 3.3X 3 0.6X 4 1.0X 5 where X1 Working capital18/total assets ratio X2 Retained earnings/total assets ratio X3 Earnings before interest and taxes/total assets ratio X4 Market value of equity/book value of long-term debt ratio X5 Sales/total assets ratio According to Altman’s credit scoring model, any firm with a Z score of less than 1.81 should be considered a high default risk firm; between 1.81 and 2.99, an indeterminant default risk firm; and greater than 2.99, a low default risk firm. 16 The Z score is a default indicator and is not a direct probability of default (PD) measure. E. I. Altman, “Managing the Commercial Lending Process,” in Handbook of Banking Strategy, eds. R. C. Aspinwall and R. A. Eisenbeis (New York: John Wiley & Sons, 1985), pp. 473–510. 18 Working capital is current assets minus current liabilities. 17 Chapter 10 EXAMPLE 10–3 Calculation of Altman’s Z Score Credit Risk: Individual Loan Risk 297 Suppose that the financial ratios of a potential borrowing firm take the following values: X1 0.2 X2 0 X3 0.20 X4 0.10 X5 2.0 The ratio X2 is zero and X3 is negative, indicating that the firm has had negative earnings or losses in recent periods. Also, X4 indicates that the borrower is highly leveraged. However, the working capital ratio (X1) and the sales/assets ratio (X5) indicate that the firm is reasonably liquid and is maintaining its sales volume. The Z score provides an overall score or indicator of the borrower’s credit risk since it combines and weights these five factors according to their past importance in explaining borrower default. For the borrower in question: Z 1.2(0.2) 1.4(0) 3.3(0.20) 0.6(0.10) 1.0(2.0) 0.24 0 0.66 0.06 2.0 1.64 With a Z score less than 1.81 (i.e., in the high default risk region), the FI should not make a loan to this borrower until it improves its earnings. There are a number of problems in using the discriminant analysis model to make credit risk evaluations.19 The first problem is that these models usually discriminate only between two extreme cases of borrower behavior: no default and default. As discussed in Chapter 7, in the real world various gradations of default exist, from nonpayment or delay of interest payments (nonperforming assets) to outright default on all promised interest and principal payments. This problem suggests that a more accurate or finely calibrated sorting among borrowers may require defining more classes in the discriminant analysis model. The second problem is that there is no obvious economic reason to expect that the weights in the discriminant function—or, more generally, the weights in any credit scoring model—will be constant over any but very short periods. The same concern also applies to the variables (Xj). Specifically, because of changing real and financial market conditions, other borrower-specific financial ratios may come to be increasingly relevant in explaining default risk probabilities. Moreover, the linear discriminant model assumes that the Xj variables are independent of one another. The third problem is that these models ignore important, hard-to-quantify factors that may play a crucial role in the default or no default decision. For example, reputation of the borrower and the nature of long-term borrower–lender relationship could be important borrower-specific characteristics, as could macrofactors such as the phase of the business cycle. These variables are often ignored in credit scoring models. Moreover, traditional credit scoring models rarely use publicly available information, such as the prices of outstanding public debt and equity of the borrower. A fourth problem relates to default records kept by FIs. Currently, no centralized database on defaulted business loans for proprietary and other reasons exists. 19 Most of these criticisms also apply to the linear probability and logit models. 298 Part Two Measuring Risk Some task forces set up by consortiums of commercial banks, insurance companies, and consulting firms are currently seeking to construct such databases largely in response to reforms to bank capital requirements (see Chapter 20). However, it may well be many years before they are developed. This constrains the ability of many FIs to use traditional credit scoring models (and quantitative models in general) for larger business loans—although their use for smaller consumer loans, such as credit card loans, where much better centralized databases exist, is well established. Concept Questions 1. Suppose an estimated linear probability model looked as follows: Z 0.03X1 0.01X2 error, where X1 Debt − equity ratio X 2 Total assets Working capital ratio Suppose, for a prospective borrower, X1 1.5 and X2 3.0. What is the projected probability of default for the borrower? (7.5%) 2. Suppose X3 0.5 in Example 103. Show how this would change the default risk classification of the borrower. (Z 3.95) 3. What are two problems in using discriminant analysis to evaluate credit risk? Newer credit risk models use financial theory and more widely available financial market data to make inferences about default probabilities on debt and loan instruments. Consequently, these models are most relevant in evaluating loans to larger borrowers in the corporate sector. This is the area in which a great deal of current research is taking place by FIs, as noted in Appendixes 11A and 11B. We next consider a number of these newer approaches or models of credit risk, including: 1. 2. 3. 4. Term structure of credit risk approach (also called reduced-form models). Mortality rate approach. RAROC models. Option models (also called structural models since they are based on an economic model of why firms default). While some of these models focus on different aspects of credit risk, they are all linked by a strong reliance on modern financial theory and financial market data.20 Newer Models of Credit Risk Measurement and Pricing Term Structure Derivation of Credit Risk www.standardandpoors.com One market-based method of assessing credit risk exposure and default probabilities is to analyze the risk premiums inherent in the current structure of yields on corporate debt or loans to similar risk-rated borrowers. Rating agencies such as Standard & Poor’s (S&P) categorize corporate bond issuers into at 20 For further details on these newer models, see A. Saunders and L. Allen, Credit Risk Management: In and Out of the Financial Crisis, 3rd ed. (New York: John Wiley and Sons, 2010). Chapter 10 FIGURE 10–6 Corporate and Treasury Discount Bond Yield Curves Credit Risk: Individual Loan Risk 299 Corporate bonds (grade B) Yield (%) 13% Treasury strips 10.80% 6% 5.05% 1 www.occ.treas.gov Treasury strips and zero-coupon corporate bonds Bonds that are created or issued bearing no coupons and only a face value to be paid on maturity. As such, they are issued at a large discount from face value. (Also called deep-discount bonds.) 2 Maturity (years) least seven major classes according to perceived credit quality.21 The first four quality ratings—AAA, AA, A, and BBB—indicate investment-quality borrowers. The Office of the Comptroller of the Currency, which regulates national banks, restricts the ability of banks to purchase securities rated outside these classes. By comparison, insurance company regulators have permitted these FIs to purchase noninvestment-grade securities with ratings such as BB, B, and CCC, but with restrictions on the aggregate amounts they can include in their portfolios. These three classes are known as high-yield or junk bonds. Different quality ratings are reflected in the degree to which corporate bond yields exceed those implied by the Treasury (credit risk–free) yield curve. Look at the spreads shown in Figure 10–6 for zero-coupon corporate (grade B) bonds over similar maturity zero-coupon Treasuries (called Treasury strips). Because Treasury strips and zero-coupon corporate bonds are single-payment discount bonds, it is possible to extract required credit risk premiums and implied probabilities of default from actual market data on interest rates. That is, the spreads between risk-free discount bonds issued by the Treasury and discount bonds issued by corporate borrowers of differing quality reflect perceived credit risk exposures of corporate borrowers for single payments at different times in the future. FIs can use these credit risk probabilities on existing debt to decide whether or not to issue additional debt to a particular credit risk borrower. Note that in market-based models of assessing default risk, FIs use information on credit quality processed by rating agencies rather than by the FI itself. Thus, the use of market-based models abstracts the FI’s role as an information processor. Rather, the unique role played by the FI is to process market-based information to assess default probabilities. 21 Rating agencies consider several factors in determining and assigning credit ratings on bond issues. For example, a financial analysis is conducted of the issuer’s operations and its needs, its position in the industry, and its overall financial strength and ability to pay the required interest and principal on the bonds. Rating agencies analyze the issuer’s liquidity, profitability, debt capacity, and, more recently, corporate governance structure (following the passage of the Sarbanes–Oxley Act in 2002). Then for each particular issue, rating agencies evaluate the nature and provisions of the debt issue (e.g., covenants and callability of the bond) and the protection afforded by, and relative position of, the debt issue in the event of bankruptcy, reorganization, or other arrangements under the laws of bankruptcy and other laws affecting creditors’ rights. 300 Part Two Measuring Risk Next, we look at the simplest case of extracting an implied probability of default for an FI considering buying one-year bonds from or making one-year loans to a risky borrower. Then, we consider multiyear loans and bonds. In each case, we show that we can extract a market view of the credit risk—the expected probability of default—of an individual borrower. Probability of Default on a One-Period Debt Instrument Assume that the FI requires an expected return on a one-year (zero-coupon) corporate debt security equal to at least the risk-free return on one-year (zero-coupon) Treasury strips. Let p be the probability that the corporate debt will be repaid in full; therefore, 1 p is the probability of default. If the borrower defaults, the FI is (for now) assumed to get nothing (i.e., the recovery rate is zero or the loss given default is 100 percent).22 By denoting the contractually promised return on the one-year corporate debt strip as 1 k and on the credit risk–free one-year Treasury strip as 1 i, the FI manager would just be indifferent between corporate and Treasury securities when:23 p (1 k ) 1 i or, the expected return on corporate securities is equal to the risk-free rate. EXAMPLE 10–4 Calculating the Probability of Default on a One-Year Bond (Loan) Using Term Structure Derivation of Credit Risk Suppose, as shown in Figure 10–6, the interest rates in the market for one-year, zero-coupon Treasury strips and for one-year, zero-coupon grade B corporate bonds are, respectively: i 5.05% and k 10.80% This implies that the probability of repayment on the security as perceived by the market is: p 1 i 1.0505 0.948 1 k 1.1080 If the probability of repayment is 0.948, this implies a probability of default (1 p) equal to 0.052. Thus, in this simple one-period framework, a probability of default of 5.2 percent on the corporate bond (loan) requires the FI to set a risk premium (f) of 5.75 percent.24 k i 5.75% Clearly, as the probability of repayment (p) falls and the probability of default (1 p) increases, the required spread f between k and i increases. 22 This is a key assumption. If the recovery rate is nonzero (which in reality is true, since in recent years banks have recovered, on average, over 80 percent of a defaulted loan and 60 percent of a senior secured bond), then the spread between the corporate bond return and the Treasury security return will reflect both the probability of default (PD) as well as the loss given default (the latter is equal to 1 minus the recovery rate). To disentangle the probability of default from the loss given default, we need to make assumptions about the size of the loss given default (LGD) or the statistical process that either the PD and/or the LGD follow, such as the Poisson process. One simple case assuming LGD is known is discussed later in this chapter. 23 This assumes that the FI manager is not risk averse; that is, this is a risk-neutral valuation method and the probabilities so derived are called risk-neutral probabilities. In general these will differ from probabilities estimated from historic data on defaults. See Saunders and Allen, Credit Risk Management, chap. 5. 24 In the real world an FI could partially capture this required spread in higher fees and compensating balances rather than only in the risk premium. In this simple example, we are assuming away compensating balances and fees. However, they could easily be built into the model. Chapter 10 TABLE 10–8 Recovery Rates (RR) on Defaulted Debt Source: E. I. Altman, “Default Recovery Rates and LGD in Credit Risk Modeling and Practice,” Working Paper, New York University Salomon Center, January 2012. Type of Debt Bank debt Revolving loans Term loans Senior secured bonds Senior unsecured bonds Senior subordinated bonds Subordinated bonds Credit Risk: Individual Loan Risk 301 Recovery Rate Number of Observations 82.24% 85.63 56.34 62.00 43.80 30.50 28.80 1,156 1,034 122 320 863 489 399 This analysis can easily be extended to the more realistic case in which the FI does not expect to lose all interest and all principal if the corporate borrower defaults. Realistically, the FI lender can expect to receive some partial repayment even if the borrower goes into bankruptcy. For example, Altman estimated that when firms defaulted on their bonds in 2011, the investor lost on average 63.3 cents on the dollar (i.e., recovered around 36.7 cents on the dollar).25 Table 10–8 gives recovery rates on defaulted debt by type of debt from 1988 to 2010. As discussed earlier in this chapter, many loans and bonds are secured or collateralized by first liens on various pieces of property or real assets should a borrower default. Note that secured loans experienced the highest recovery rates among the corporate bonds listed (62.00 percent). Let be the proportion of the loan’s principal and interest that is collectible on default, where in general is positive. The FI manager would set the expected return on the loan to equal the risk-free rate in the following manner: [(1 p)γ (1 k )] [ p(1 k )] 1 i The new term here is (1 p) (1 k); this is the payoff the FI expects to get if the borrower defaults. As might be expected, if the loan has collateral backing such that 0, the required risk premium on the loan will be less for any given default risk probability (1 p). Collateral requirements are a method of controlling default risk. They act as a direct substitute for risk premiums in setting required loan rates. To see this, solve for the risk premium f between k (the required yield on risky corporate debt) and i (the risk-free rate of interest): ki (1 i) (1 i) ( γ p pγ ) If i 5.05 percent and p 0.948 as before but the FI can expect to collect 90 percent of the promised proceeds if default occurs ( 0.9), then the required risk premium f 0.55 percent. Interestingly, in this simple framework, and p are perfect substitutes for each other. That is, a bond or loan with collateral backing of 0.95 and p 0.9 would have the same required risk premium as one with 0.9 and p 0.95. An increase in collateral is a direct substitute for an increase in default risk (i.e., a decline in p). 25 E. I. Altman, “Current Conditions and Outlook on Global Sovereign and Corporate Credit Markets,” Working Paper, New York University Salomon Center, February 2012. 302 Part Two Measuring Risk marginal default probability The probability that a borrower will default in any given year. cumulative default probability The probability that a borrower will default over a specified multiyear period. Probability of Default on a Multiperiod Debt Instrument We can extend this type of analysis to derive the credit risk or default probabilities occurring in the market for longer-term loans or bonds (i.e., two-year bonds). To do this, the manager must estimate the probability that the bond will default in the second year conditional on the probability that it does not default in the first year. The probability that a bond will default in any given year is clearly conditional on the fact that the default has not occurred earlier. The probability that a bond will default in any given year, t, is the marginal default probability for that year, 1 pt. However, for, say, a two-year loan, the marginal probability of default in the second year (1 p2) can differ from the marginal probability of default in the first year (1 p1). If we use these marginal default probabilities, the cumulative default probability at some time between now and the end of year 2 is: Cp 1 [( p1 )( p2 )] EXAMPLE 10–5 Calculating the Probability of Default on a Multiperiod Bond Suppose the FI manager wants to find out the probability of default on a two-year loan. For the one-year loan, 1 p1 0.05 is the marginal and total or cumulative probability (Cp) of default in year 1. Later in this chapter we discuss ways in which p2 can be estimated by the FI manager, but for the moment suppose that 1 p2 0.07. Then: 1 p1 .05 marginal probability of default in year 1 1 p2 .07 marginal probability of default in year 2 The probability of the borrower surviving—not defaulting at any time between now (time 0) and the end of period 2—is p1 p2 (0.95)(0.93) 0.8835. Cp 1 [(0.95)(0.93)] 0.1165 There is an 11.65 percent probability of default over this period. no arbitrage The inability to make a profit without taking risk. forward rate A one-period rate of interest expected on a bond issued at some date in the future. We have seen how to derive the one-year probability of default from yield spreads on one-year bonds. We now want to derive the probability of default in year 2, year 3, and so on. Look at Figure 10–6; as you can see, yield curves are rising for both Treasury issues and corporate bond issues. We want to extract from these yield curves the market’s expectation of the multiperiod default rates for corporate borrowers classified in the grade B rating class.26 Look first at the Treasury yield curve. The condition of efficient markets and thus no arbitrage profits by investors requires that the return on buying and holding the two-year Treasury strip (T-strip) to maturity just equals the expected return from investing in the current one-year discount T-strip and reinvesting the principal and interest in a new one-year discount T-strip at the end of the first year at the expected one-year forward rate. That is: (1 i2 )2 (1 i1 )(1 f1 ) 26 (1) To use this model, one has to place borrowers in a rating class. One way to do this for unrated firms would be to use the Z score model to calculate a Z ratio for this firm. E. I. Altman has shown that there is a high correlation between Z scores and Standard & Poor’s and Moody’s bond ratings. Once a firm is placed in a bond rating group (e.g., B) by the Z score model, the term structure model can be used to infer the expected (implied) probabilities of default for the borrower at different times in the future. Chapter 10 Credit Risk: Individual Loan Risk 303 The term on the left side is the return from holding the two-year Treasury strip to maturity. The term on the right side results from investing in two successive oneyear T-strips, where i1 is the current one-year T-strips rate and f1 is the expected one-year T-strip rate or forward rate next year. Since we can observe directly from the T-strip yield curve the current required yields on one- and two-year Treasuries, we can directly infer the market’s expectation of the one-year Treasury strip rate next period or the one-year forward rate, f1: 1 f1 (1 i2 )2 (1 i1 ) (2) We can use the same type of analysis with the corporate bond yield curve to infer the one-year forward rate on corporate bonds (grade B in this example). The one-year rate expected on corporate securities (c1) one year into the future reflects the market’s default risk expectations for this class of borrower as well as the more general time value factors also affecting f1: 1 c1 (1 k2 )2 (1 k1 ) (3) The expected rates on one-year bonds can generate an estimate of the expected probability of repayment on one-year corporate bonds in one year’s time, or what we have called p2. Since: p2 (1 c1 ) 1 f1 then: ⎡ 1 f1 ⎤ p2 ⎢ ⎥ ⎣ 1 c1 ⎦ (4) Thus, the expected probability of default in year 2 is: 1 p2 (5) In a similar fashion, the one-year rates expected in two years’ time can be derived from the Treasury and corporate term structures so as to derive p3, and so on. EXAMPLE 10–6 Calculating the Probability of Default on a Multiperiod Bond Using Term Structure Derivation of Credit Risk From the Treasury strip yield curve in Figure 10–6, the current required yields on one- and twoyear Treasuries are i1 5.05 percent and i2 6 percent, respectively. If we use equation (2), the one-year forward rate, f1, is: 1 f1 (1.06)2 1.0696 (1.0505) or f1 6.96% The expected rise in one-year rates from 5.05 percent (i1) this year to 6.96 percent (f1) next year reflects investors’ perceptions regarding inflation and other factors that directly affect the time value of money. 304 Part Two Measuring Risk Further, the current yield curve, in Figure 10–6, indicates that appropriate one-year discount bonds are yielding k1 10.80 percent and two-year bonds are yielding k2 13 percent. Thus, if we use equation (3), the one-year rate expected on corporate securities, c1, is: 1 c1 (1.13)2 1.1524 (1.1080) or c 1 15.24% We summarize these calculations in Table 10–9. As you can see, the expected spread between one-year corporate bonds and Treasuries in one year’s time is higher than the spread for current one-year bonds. Thus, the default risk premium increases with the maturity on the corporate (risky) bond. From these expected rates on one-year bonds, if we use equations (4) and (5), the expected probability of repayment on one-year corporate bonds in one year’s time, p2, is: p2 [1.0696] 0.9281 [1.1524] and the expected probability of default in year 2 is: 1 p2 1 0.9281 0.0719 or 7.19% The probabilities we have estimated are marginal probabilities conditional on default not occurring in a prior period. We also discussed the concept of the cumulative probability of default that would tell the FI the probability of a loan or bond investment defaulting over a particular time period. In the example developed earlier, the cumulative probability that corporate grade B bonds would default over the next two years is: Cp 1 [(p1 )(p2 )] Cp 1 [(0.948)(0.9281)] 12.02% As with the credit scoring approach, this model creates some potential problems. Its principal advantages are that it is clearly forward-looking and based on market expectations. Moreover, if there are liquid markets for Treasury and corporate discount bonds—Treasury strips and corporate zero-coupon bonds—then we can easily estimate expected future default rates and use them to value and price loans. However, while the market for Treasury strips is now quite deep, the market for corporate discount bonds is quite small. Although a discount yield curve TABLE 10–9 Treasury and Corporate Rates and Rate Spreads Current One-Year Rate Treasury Corporate (B) Spread 5.05% 10.80 5.75 Expected One-Year Rate 6.96% 15.24 8.28 Chapter 10 Credit Risk: Individual Loan Risk 305 for corporate bonds could be extracted mathematically from the corporate bond coupon yield curve, these bonds often are not very actively traded and prices are not very transparent. Given this, the FI manager might have to consider an alternative way to use bond or loan data to extract default rate probabilities for all but the very largest corporate borrowers. We consider a possible alternative next. Concept Questions 1. What is the difference between the marginal default probability and the cumulative default probability? 2. How should the posting of collateral by a borrower affect the risk premium on a loan? Mortality Rate Derivation of Credit Risk mortality rate Historic default rate experience of a bond or loan. marginal mortality rate The probability of a bond or loan defaulting in any given year after issue. FIGURE 10–7 Hypothetical Marginal Mortality Rate Curve for Grade B Corporate Bonds Rather than extracting expected default rates from the current term structure of interest rates, the FI manager may analyze the historic or past default risk experience, the mortality rates, of bonds and loans of a similar quality. Consider calculating p1 and p2 using the mortality rate model. Here p1 is the probability of a grade B bond or loan surviving the first year of its issue; thus 1 p1 is the marginal mortality rate, or the probability of the bond or loan defaulting in the first year of issue. While p2 is the probability of the loan surviving in the second year given that default has not occurred during the first year, 1 p2 is the marginal mortality rate for the second year. Thus, for each grade of corporate borrower quality, a marginal mortality rate (MMR) curve can show the historical default rate experience of bonds in any specific quality class in each year after issue on the bond or loan. Note in Figure 10–7 that as grade B bonds age, their probability of default increases in each successive year. Of course, in reality, any shape to the mortality curve is possible. It is possible that MMRs can be flat, decline over time, or show a more complex functional form. These marginal mortality rates can be estimated from actual data on bond and loan defaults. Specifically, for grade B quality bonds (loans): MMR1 Total value of grade B bonds defaulting in year 1 of issue Total value of grade B bonds outstanding in year 1 of issue MMR2 Total value of grade B bonds defaulting in year 2 of issue Total value of grade B bonds outstanding in year 2 of issue adjusted for defaults, calls, sinking fund redemptions, and maturities in the prior year Marginal mortality rate (MMR) MMR5 MMR4 MMR3 MMR2 MMR1 0 1 2 3 4 5 Years since issue 306 Part Two Measuring Risk TABLE 10–10 Mortality Rates by Original Rating—All Rated* Corporate Bonds, 1971–2011 Source: E. I. Altman and B. J. Kuehne, “Special Report on Default and Returns in the High-Yield Bond and Distressed Debt Market: The Year 2011 in Review and Outlook,” New York University Salomon Center, February 2012. Years after Issuance AAA Marginal Cumulative AA Marginal Cumulative A Marginal Cumulative BBB Marginal Cumulative BB Marginal Cumulative B Marginal Cumulative CCC Marginal Cumulative 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.02% 0.02% 0.01% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.00% 0.02% 0.04% 0.05% 0.05% 0.05% 0.05% 0.00% 0.00% 0.25% 0.11% 0.02% 0.02% 0.01% 0.01% 0.03% 0.01% 0.00% 0.00% 0.25% 0.36% 0.38% 0.40% 0.41% 0.42% 0.45% 0.46% 0.01% 0.06% 0.16% 0.17% 0.14% 0.10% 0.04% 0.30% 0.11% 0.07% 0.01% 0.07% 0.23% 0.40% 0.54% 0.64% 0.68% 0.98% 1.09% 1.15% 0.38% 2.49% 1.37% 1.05% 0.58% 0.27% 0.30% 0.17% 0.16% 0.36% 0.38% 2.86% 4.19% 5.20% 5.75% 6.00% 6.28% 6.44% 6.59% 6.93% 1.01% 2.07% 3.95% 2.00% 2.42% 1.47% 1.51% 1.10% 1.50% 3.20% 1.01% 3.06% 6.89% 8.75% 10.96% 12.27% 13.59% 14.54% 15.82% 18.52% 2.96% 7.86% 7.95% 7.93% 5.84% 4.58% 3.66% 2.15% 1.83% 0.82% 2.96% 10.59% 17.70% 24.22% 28.65% 31.92% 34.41% 35.82% 36.99% 37.51% 8.30% 12.65% 18.28% 16.35% 4.82% 11.78% 5.45% 4.95% 0.70% 4.41% 8.30% 19.90% 34.54% 45.24% 47.88% 54.02% 56.53% 58.68% 58.97% 60.78% *Rated by S&P at issuance. Based on 2,644 issues. Table 10–10 shows the estimated mortality and cumulative default rates for samples of 2,644 rated corporate bonds over the 1971–2011 period. From Table 10–10 it can be seen that mortality rates are higher the lower the rating of the bond. For example, between 1971 and 2011, there was a 1.15 percent probability that A-rated bonds would default over the 10 years after issue and a 37.51 percent probability that B-rated bonds would default over the 10 years after issue. The mortality rate approach has a number of conceptual and applicability problems. Probably the most important of these is that, like the credit scoring model, it produces historic, or backward-looking, measures. Also, the estimates of default rates and therefore implied future default probabilities tend to be highly sensitive to the period over which the FI manager calculates the MMRs. For example, WorldCom had an S&P rating of BBB just prior to its defaulting on its debt in 2002. Note in Table 10–10 the second year’s marginal mortality rate for BBB bonds (2.49 percent) is much higher than those of years 3 and 4 (1.37 percent and 1.05 percent, respectively) and is even higher than that of the second-year mortality rate for BB bonds (2.07 percent). This is primarily due to the default of WorldCom in 2002. In addition, the estimates tend to be sensitive to the number of issues and the relative size of issues in each investment grade.27 Concept Questions 1. In Table 10–10, the CMR over 3 years for CCC-rated corporate bonds is 34.54 percent. Check this calculation using the individual year MMRs. 2. Why would any FI manager buy loans that have a CMR of 34.54 percent? Explain your answer. 27 For example, even though the estimates in Table 10–10 are based on 2,644 observations of bonds, these estimates still have quite wide confidence bands. See Saunders and Allen, Credit Risk Management. Chapter 10 Credit Risk: Individual Loan Risk 307 RAROC Models RAROC Risk-adjusted return on capital. An increasingly popular model used to evaluate (and price) credit risk based on market data is the RAROC model. The RAROC (risk-adjusted return on capital) was pioneered by Bankers Trust (acquired by Deutsche Bank in 1998) and has now been adopted by virtually all the large banks in the United States and Europe, although with some significant proprietary differences between them. The essential idea behind RAROC is that rather than evaluating the actual or contractually promised annual ROA on a loan, as earlier in the chapter (that is, net interest and fees divided by the amount lent), the lending officer balances expected interest and fee income less the cost of funds against the loan’s expected risk. Thus, the numerator of the RAROC equation is net income (accounting for the cost of funding the loan) on the loan. Further, rather than dividing annual loan income by assets lent, it is divided by some measure of asset (loan) risk or what is often called capital at risk, since (unexpected) loan losses have to be written off against an FI’s capital:28 RAROC One year net income on a loan Loan (asset) risk or capital at risk A loan is approved only if RAROC is sufficiently high relative to a benchmark return on capital (ROE) for the FI, where ROE measures the return stockholders require on their equity investment in the FI. The idea here is that a loan should be made only if the risk-adjusted return on the loan adds to the FI’s equity value as measured by the ROE required by the FI’s stockholders. Thus, for example, if an FI’s ROE is 10 percent, a loan should be made only if the estimated RAROC is higher than the 10 percent required by the FI’s stockholders as a reward for their investment in the FI. Alternatively, if the RAROC on an existing loan falls below an FI’s RAROC benchmark, the lending officer should seek to adjust the loan’s terms to make it “profitable” again. Therefore, RAROC serves as both a credit risk measure and a loan pricing tool for the FI manager. The numerator of the RAROC equation is relatively straightforward to estimate. Specifically, One year net income on loan (Spread Fees) Dollar value of the loan outstanding FIs may deduct any overhead and tax expenses as well to get the one year net income on the loan. However, a more difficult problem in estimating RAROC is the measurement of loan risk (the denominator in the RAROC equation). Two methods of estimating loan risk involve the use of a duration model and the use of loan default rates. Using Duration to Estimate Loan Risk Chapter 9 on duration showed that the percentage change in the market value of an asset such as a loan (ΔLN/LN) is related to the duration of the loan and the size of the interest rate shock (ΔR/(1 R)), where R is the base rate, BR, plus the credit risk premium, f: LN R DLN 1R LN 28 Traditionally, expected loan losses are covered by an FI’s loss reserve (or provisions), while unexpected or extreme loan losses are being met by an FI’s capital reserves. 308 Part Two Measuring Risk The same concept is applied here, except that (assuming that the base rate remains constant) interest rate shocks are the consequence of credit quality (or credit risk premium) shocks (i.e., shocks to f). We can thus rewrite the duration equation with the following interpretation to estimate the loan risk or capital at risk on the loan: LN (dollar capital risk exposure or loss amount) EXAMPLE 10–7 Calculation of RAROC on a Loan DLN (duration of the loan) LN (risk amount or size of loan) ( R/(1 R)) (expected maximum change in the loan rate due to a change in the credit risk premium ( ) or risk factor on the loan) Suppose an FI wants to evaluate the credit risk of a $1 million loan with a duration of 2.7 years to a AAA borrower. Assume there are currently 400 publicly traded bonds in that class (i.e., bonds issued by firms of a rating type similar to that of the borrower). The first step is to evaluate the actual changes in the credit risk premiums (Ri RG) on each of these bonds for the past year (in this example, the year 2015). These (hypothetical) changes are plotted in the frequency curve of Figure 10–8. They range from a fall in the risk premiums of negative 2 percent to an increase of 3.5 percent. Since the largest increase may be a very extreme (unrepresentative) number, the 99 percent worst-case scenario is chosen (i.e., only 4 bonds out of 400 had risk premium increases exceeding the 99 percent worst case). For the example shown in Figure 10–8 this is equal to 1.1 percent. The estimate of loan (or capital) risk, assuming that the current average level of rates (R) on AAA bonds is 5 percent, is: R 1+ R ⎛ 0.011⎞ (2.7)($1million) ⎜ ⎝ 1.05 ⎟⎠ LN DLN × LN × $28,286 While the market value of the loan amount is $1 million, the risk amount, or change in the loan’s market value due to a decline in its credit quality, is $28,286. Thus, the denominator of the RAROC equation is this possible loss, or $28,286. To determine whether the loan is worth making, the estimated loan risk is compared with the loan’s income (spread over the FI’s cost of funds plus fees on the loan). Suppose the projected (one-year) spread plus fees is as follows: Spread 0.2% $1 million $2, 000 Fees 0.1% $1 million $1, 000 $3, 000 The loan’s RAROC is: RAROC One year net income on loan $3,000 = 10.61% Loan risk (or capital risk)( LN ) $28,286 Note that RAROC can be either forward looking, comparing the projected income over the next year on the loan with ΔLN, or backward looking, comparing the actual income generated on the loan over the past year with ΔLN. If the 10.61 Chapter 10 FIGURE 10–8 Credit Risk: Individual Loan Risk 309 Frequency Hypothetical Frequency Distribution of Yield Spread Changes for All AAA Bonds in 2015 1% of all AAA bonds – Risk – 2% premium 0 +1.1% +3.5% + Risk premium percent exceeds the FI’s internal RAROC benchmark (based on its cost of capital, or ROE), the loan will be approved. If it is less, the loan will be rejected outright or the borrower will be asked to pay higher fees and/or a higher spread to increase the RAROC to acceptable levels. While the loan’s duration (2.7 years in our example) and the loan amount ($1 million) are easily estimated, it is more difficult to estimate the maximum change in the credit risk premium on the loan over the next year. Since publicly available data on loan risk premiums are scarce, we turn to publicly available corporate bond market data to estimate premiums. First, an S&P credit rating (AAA, AA, A, and so on) is assigned to a borrower. Thereafter, the available risk premium changes of all the bonds traded in that particular rating class over the last year are analyzed. The ΔR in the RAROC equation equals: R Max [ (Ri RG ) 0] where Δ(Ri RG) is the change in the yield spread between corporate bonds of credit rating class i (Ri) and matched duration Treasury security (RG) over the last year. In order to consider only the worst-case scenario, a maximum change in yield spread is chosen, as opposed to the average change. In general, it is common to pick the 1 percent worst case or 99th percentile of credit risk changes. Using Loan Default Rates to Estimate Loan Risk Other FIs have adopted different ways of calculating ΔLN in their versions of RAROC. Some FIs, usually the largest ones with very good loan default databases, divide one-year income by the product of an unexpected loss rate and the proportion of the loan lost on default, also called the loss given default. Thus: RAROC One-year net income per dollar loaned Unexpected default rate Proportion of loan lost on default (loss given default) Suppose expected income per dollar lent is 0.3 cents, or 0.003. The 99th percentile historic (extreme case) default rate for borrowers of this type is 4 percent, 310 Part Two Measuring Risk and the dollar proportion of loans of this type that cannot be recaptured is 80 percent. Then:29 RAROC Concept Question 0.003 0.003 9.375% (0.04)(0.8) (0.032) 1. Describe the basic concept behind RAROC models. Option Models of Default Risk Theoretical Framework In recent years, following the pioneering work of Nobel Prize winners Merton, Black, and Scholes, we now recognize that when a firm raises funds by issuing bonds or increasing its bank loans, it holds a very valuable default or repayment option.30 That is, if a borrower’s investment projects fail so that it cannot repay the bondholder or the bank, it has the option of defaulting on its debt repayment and turning any remaining assets over to the debtholder. Because of limited liability for equity holders, the borrower’s loss is limited on the downside by the amount of equity invested in the firm. On the other hand, if things go well, the borrower can keep most of the upside returns on asset investments after the promised principal and interest on the debt have been paid. The KMV Corporation (which was purchased by Moody’s in 2002 and is now part of Moody’s Analytics Enterprise Risk Solutions) turned this relatively simple idea into a credit monitoring model. Many of the largest U.S. FIs are now using this model to determine the expected default risk frequency (EDF) of large corporations.31 Before we look at the Moody’s Analytics Credit Monitor model, we will take a closer look at the theory underlying the option approach to default risk estimation. Appendix 10B, located at the book’s website (www.mhhe.com/ saunders8e), reviews the Black–Scholes option pricing model. The Borrower’s Payoff from Loans Look at the payoff function for the borrower in Figure 10–9, where S is the size of the initial equity investment in the firm, B is the value of outstanding bonds or loans (assumed for simplicity to be issued on a discount basis), and A is the market value of the assets of the firm. If the investments in Figure 10–9 turn out badly such that the firm’s assets are valued at point A1, the limited-liability stockholder–owners of the firm will default on the firm’s debt, turn its assets (such as A1) over to the debt holders, and lose only their initial stake in the firm (S). By contrast, if the firm does well and the 29 Calculating the unexpected default rate commonly involves calculating the standard derivation ( ) of annual default rates on loans of this type and then multiplying by a factor such that 99 percent (or higher) of defaults are covered by capital. For example, if the loss distribution was normally distributed, then the of default rates would be multiplied by 2.33 to get the extreme 99 percent default rate. For many FIs, default rates are skewed to the right and have fat tails suggesting a multiplier much larger than 2.33. For example, to get coverage of 99.97 percent of defaults, Bank of America has historically used a multiplier of 6. Finally, the denominator can also be adjusted for the degree of correlation of the loan with the rest of the FI’s portfolio. 30 R. C. Merton, “On the Pricing of Corporate Debt: The Risk Structure of Interest Rates,” Journal of Finance 29 (1974), pp. 449–70; and F. Black and M. Scholes, “The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities,” Journal of Political Economy 81 (1973), pp. 637–59. 31 See KMV Corporation Credit Monitor, KMV Corporation, San Francisco, 1994; and Saunders and Allen, Credit Risk Measurement, chap. 4. Chapter 10 FIGURE 10–9 Payoff Function to Corporate Borrowers (Stockholders) Credit Risk: Individual Loan Risk 311 Payoff to stockholders 0 A1 B (debt) A2 Assets (A) –S assets of the firm are valued highly (A2), the firm’s stockholders will pay off the firm’s debt and keep the difference (A2 B). Clearly, the higher A2 is relative to B, the better off are the firm’s stockholders. Given that borrowers face only a limited downside risk of loss of their equity investment, but a very large potential upside return if things turn out well, equity is analogous to buying a call option on the assets of the firm (see also Chapter 23 on options). The Debt Holder’s Payoff from Loans Consider the same loan or bond issue from the perspective of the FI or bondholder. The maximum amount the FI or bondholder can get back is B, the promised payment. However, the borrower who possesses the default or repayment option would rationally repay the loan only if A B, that is, if the market value of assets exceeds the value of promised debt repayments. A borrower whose asset value falls below B would default and turn over any remaining assets to the debt holders. The payoff function to the debt holder is shown in Figure 10–10. After investment of the borrowed funds has taken place, if the value of the firm’s assets lies to the right of B, the face value of the debt—such as A2—the debt holder or FI will be paid off in full and receive B. On the other hand, if asset values fall in the region to the left of B—such as A1—the debt holder will receive back only those assets remaining as collateral, thereby losing B A1. Thus, the value of the loan from the perspective of the lender is always the minimum of B or A, or min [B, A]. That is, the payoff function to the debt holder is similar to writing a put option on the value of the borrower’s assets with B, the face value of debt, as the exercise price. If A B, the loan is repaid and the debt holder earns a small fixed return (similar to the premium on a put option), which is the interest rate implicit in the discount FIGURE 10–10 Payoff Function to the Debt Holder (the FI) from a Loan Payoff to debt holders B 0 A1 B (debt) A2 Assets (A) 312 Part Two Measuring Risk bond. If A B, the borrower defaults and the debt holder stands to lose both interest and principal. In the limit, default for a firm with no assets left results in debt holders’ losing all their principal and interest. In actuality, if there are also costs of bankruptcy, the debt holder can potentially lose even more than this. Applying the Option Valuation Model to the Calculation of Default Risk Premiums Merton has shown that in the context of the preceding options framework, it is quite straightforward to express the market value of a risky loan made by a lender to a borrower as:32 F(τ) Beiτ [(1/ d)N ( h1 ) N ( h2 )] (6) where Length of time remaining to loan maturity; that is, T t, where T is the maturity date and time t is today. d Borrower’s leverage ratio measured as Bei /A, where the market value of debt is valued at the rate i, the risk-free rate of interest. N(h) Value computed from the standardized normal distribution statistical tables. This value reflects the probability that a deviation exceeding the calculated value of h will occur. 2 h1 ⎡⎣( 1 2 ) 2 ln(d) ⎤⎦ / h2 ⎡⎣( 1 2 ) 2 ln(d) ⎤⎦ / Measures the asset risk of the borrower. Technically, it is the variance of the rate of change in the value of the underlying assets of the borrower. Written in terms of a yield spread, , this equation reflects an equilibrium default risk premium that the borrower should be charged: k( ) i (1/ ) ln[ N ( h2 ) (1/ d)N ( h1 )] where k( ) Required yield on risky debt (the contractually promised return from earlier) ln Natural logarithm i Risk-free rate on debt of equivalent maturity (here, one period) Thus, Merton has shown that the lender should adjust the required risk premium as d and 2 change, that is, as leverage and asset risk change. EXAMPLE 10–8 Calculating the Value of and Interest Rate on a Loan Using the Option Model Suppose that: B $100,000 1 year i 5% d 90% or 0.9 12% 32 See Merton, “On the Pricing of Corporate Debt.” Chapter 10 Credit Risk: Individual Loan Risk 313 That is, suppose we can measure the market value of a firm’s assets (and thus d Bei /A) as well as the volatility of those assets ( ). Then, substituting these values into the equations for h1 and h2 and solving for the areas under the standardized normal distribution, we find that: N (h1) 0.174120 N (h2 ) 0.793323 where h1 [ 12 (0.12)2 (1) ln(0.9)] 0.938 0.12 and h2 [ 1 2 (0.12)2 (1) ln(0.9)] 0.818 0.12 The current market value of the loan is: L(t ) Bei [N (h2 ) (1/d )N (h1)] $100,000 [0.793323 (1.1111)(0.17412)] 1.05127 $100,000 [0.986788] 1.05127 $93,866.18 and the required risk spread or premium, , is: ⎛ 1⎞ k ( ) i ⎜ ⎟⎠ ln[N (h2 ) (1/d )N (h1)] ⎝ ( 1)ln[0.986788] 1.33% Thus, the risky loan rate k( ) should be set at 6.33 percent when the risk-free rate (i) is 5 percent. www.moodysanalytics.com Theoretically, this model is an elegant tool for extracting premiums and default probabilities. It also has important conceptual implications regarding which variables to focus on in credit risk evaluation [e.g., the firm’s market value of assets (A) and asset risk ( 2)]. Even so, this model has a number of real-world implementation problems. Probably the most significant is the fact that neither the market value of a firm’s assets (A) nor the volatility of the firm’s assets ( 2) is directly observed. The Moody’s Analytics Option Model and Expected Default Frequency The Moody’s Analytics model in fact recognizes this problem by using an option pricing model (OPM) approach to extract the implied market value of assets (A) and the asset volatility of a given firm’s assets ( 2). The Moody’s Analytics model uses the value of equity in a firm (from a stockholder’s perspective) as equivalent to holding a call option on the assets of the firm (with the amount of debt borrowed acting similarly to the exercise price of the option). From this approach, and the link between the volatility of the market value of the firm’s equity and that of its assets, it is possible to derive the asset volatility (risk) of any given firm ( ) and 314 Part Two Measuring Risk FIGURE 10–11 $ Frequency distribution of asset values at time 1 Expected Default Frequency Using the Moody’s Analytics Model Source: Moody’s Analytics. www.moodysanalytics.com +s Asset market value (A) 2s Distance from default Probability of default (EDF) B Contractual amount of current obligations (default point) 0 1 Time the market value of the firm’s assets (A).33 Using the implied value of for assets and A, the market value of assets, the likely distribution of possible asset values of the firm relative to its current debt obligations can be calculated over the next year. As shown in Figure 10–11, the expected default frequency (EDF) that is calculated reflects the probability that the market value of the firm’s assets (A) will fall below the promised repayments on its short-term debt liabilities (B) in one year. If the value of a firm’s assets falls below its debt liabilities, it can be viewed as being economically insolvent. Suppose the value of the firm’s assets (A) at the time zero is $100 million and the value of its short-term debt is $80 million. Suppose also that the implied volatility ( ) of asset values is estimated at $12.12 million, and it is assumed that assetvalue changes are normally distributed. The firm becomes distressed only if the value of its assets falls to $80 million or below (falls by $20 million). Such a fall is equal to 1.65 , i.e., 1.65 $12.12 million $20 million. From statistics, we know that the area of the normal distribution (in each tail) lying 1.65 from the mean is theoretically 5 percent. Thus, the Moody’s Analytics model would suggest a theoretical 5 percent probability of the firm’s going into distress over the next year (by time 1). However, Moody’s Analytics calculates empirical EDFs, since we do not know the true distribution of asset values (A) over time. Essentially, it asks this question: In practice, how many firms that started the year with asset values 1.65 distance from default (see Figure 10–11) actually defaulted by the end of the year? This value may or may not equal 5 percent. 33 More specifically, it does this by using the equity (stock market) value of the firm’s shares (E) and the volatility of the value of the firm’s shares ( E). Since equity can be viewed as a call option on the firm’s assets and the volatility of a firm’s equity value will reflect the leverage adjusted volatility of its underlying assets, we have in general form: E f ( A, , B, r , ) and E g( ) where the bars denote values that are directly measurable. Since we have two equations and two unknowns (A, ), we can directly solve for both A and and use these, along with the firm’s outstanding short-term liabilities or current liabilities, to calculate the EDF (expected default frequency). Chapter 10 FIGURE 10–12 Credit Risk: Individual Loan Risk 315 Moody’s Analytics EDF, Moody’s, and S&P Ratings for AMR Corporation Source: Moody’s Analytics. www.moodysanalytics.com S&P Default Date: 11/29/2011 Moody’s C EDF % 38.00 36.00 AMR Corporation 34.00 CCC+ 32.00 EDF Ca 30.00 28.00 26.00 Caa3 24.00 22.00 Moody’s rating Caa2 20.00 18.00 Caa1 16.00 S&P rating B– 14.00 B3 12/11/10 1/16/11 2/21/11 3/29/11 5/4/11 6/9/11 7/15/11 8/20/11 9/25/11 10/31/11 Simulations by Moody’s Analytics have shown that EDF models outperform both Z score–type models and S&P rating changes as predictors of corporate failure and distress.34 An example for AMR Corp., which filed for Chapter 11 bankruptcy protection on November 29, 2011, is shown in Figure 10–12. Note that the Moody’s Analytics EDF score (expected default frequency) is rising earlier than the rating agencies are downgrading the firm’s debt. Indeed, the rating agency ratings are very slow to react to, if not totally insensitive to, the increase in AMR Corp. risk. The Moody’s Analytics EDF score starts to rise almost a year prior to AMR Corp. bankruptcy and suggests a C rating by July 2011. Thus, the Moody’s Analytics EDF score gives a better early warning of impending default. In an effort to get control over credit rating firms, that give high-quality ratings to highrisk firms, such as AMR, in April 2009 the Credit Rating Agency Reform Act was passed. This act gave the SEC regulatory authority over credit rating firms and was intended to increase competition and oversight of credit rating firms. Concept Questions 1. Which is the only credit risk model discussed in this section that is really forward looking? 2. How should the risk premium on a loan be affected if there is a reduction in a borrower’s leverage and the underlying volatility of its earnings? 3. What is the link between the implied volatility of a firm’s assets and its expected default frequency? 34 The Moody’s Analytics database contains 30 years of information on more than 6,000 public and 220,000 private company default events for a total of 60,000 public and 2.8 million private companies, healthy and distressed, around the world. 316 Part Two Measuring Risk Summary www.mhhe.com/saunders8e Questions and Problems This chapter discussed different approaches to measuring credit or default risk on individual loans (bonds). The different types of loans made by FIs and some of their basic characteristics were first examined. The expected return on a loan was shown to depend on factors such as origination fees, compensating balances, interest rates, and maturity. The various models to assess default risk include both qualitative and quantitative models. The qualitative models usually contain both firm-specific factors, such as reputation and leverage, and market-specific factors, such as the business cycle and the level of interest rates. Quantitative models, such as the linear probability model, the logit model, and the linear discriminant model, were shown to provide credit scores that can rank or classify loans by expected default risk. The more rigorous of the quantitative models make use of both financial theory and financial data. These include the term structure and mortality rate models as well as the RAROC (risk-adjusted return on capital) and option-based models. In the next chapter we look at methods to evaluate the risk of loan portfolios, or loan concentration risk. 1. Why is credit risk analysis an important component of FI risk management? What recent activities by FIs have made the task of credit risk assessment more difficult for both FI managers and regulators? 2. Differentiate between a secured loan and an unsecured loan. Who bears most of the risk in a fixed-rate loan? Why would FI managers prefer to charge floating rates, especially for longer-maturity loans? 3. How does a spot loan differ from a loan commitment? What are the advantages and disadvantages of borrowing through a loan commitment? 4. Why is commercial lending declining in importance in the United States? What effect does this decline have on overall commercial lending activities? 5. What are the primary characteristics of residential mortgage loans? Why does the ratio of adjustable-rate mortgages to fixed-rate mortgages in the economy vary over an interest rate cycle? When would the ratio be highest? 6. What are the two major classes of consumer loans at U.S. banks? How do revolving loans differ from nonrevolving loans? 7. Why are rates on credit cards generally higher than rates on car loans? 8. What are compensating balances? What is the relationship between the amount of compensating balance requirement and the return on the loan to the FI? 9. Suppose that a bank does the following: a. Sets a loan rate on a prospective loan at 8 percent (where BR 5% and 3%). b. Charges a 1 10 percent (or 0.10 percent) loan origination fee to the borrower. c. Imposes a 5 percent compensating balance requirement to be held as noninterestbearing demand deposits. d. Holds reserve requirements of 10 percent imposed by the Federal Reserve on the bank’s demand deposits. Calculate the bank’s ROA on this loan. 10. County Bank offers one-year loans with a stated rate of 9 percent but requires a compensating balance of 10 percent. What is the true cost of this loan to the borrower? How does the cost change if the compensating balance is 15 percent? If the compensating balance is 20 percent? In each case, assume origination fees and the reserve requirement are zero. Chapter 10 Credit Risk: Individual Loan Risk 317 PDi 0.105(D/Ai ) 0.35(PMi ) Prospective borrower A has a D/A 0.65 and a PM 5%, and prospective borrower B has a D/A 0.45 and a PM 1%. Calculate the prospective borrowers’ expected probabilities of default (PDi). Which borrower is the better loan candidate? Explain your answer. 20. Suppose the estimated linear probability model used by an FI to predict business loan applicant default probabilities is PD 0.03X1 0.02X2 0.05X3 error, where X1 is the borrower’s debt/equity ratio, X2 is the volatility of borrower earnings, and X3 is the borrower’s profit ratio. For a particular loan applicant, X1 0.75, X2 0.25, and X3 0.10. a. What is the projected probability of default for the borrower? b. What is the projected probability of repayment if the debt/equity ratio is 2.5? c. What is a major weakness of the linear probability model? www.mhhe.com/saunders8e 11. Metrobank offers one-year loans with a 9 percent stated or base rate, charges a 0.25 percent loan origination fee, imposes a 10 percent compensating balance requirement, and must hold a 6 percent reserve requirement at the Federal Reserve. The loans typically are repaid at maturity. a. If the risk premium for a given customer is 2.5 percent, what is the simple promised interest return on the loan? b. What is the contractually promised gross return on the loan per dollar lent? c. Which of the fee items has the greatest impact on the gross return? 12. Why are most retail borrowers charged the same rate of interest, implying the same risk premium or class? What is credit rationing? How is it used to control credit risks with respect to retail and wholesale loans? 13. Why could a lender’s expected return be lower when the risk premium is increased on a loan? In addition to the risk premium, how can a lender increase the expected return on a wholesale loan? A retail loan? 14. What are covenants in a loan agreement? What are the objectives of covenants? How can these covenants be negative? Positive? 15. Identify and define the borrower-specific and market-specific factors that enter into the credit decision. What is the impact of each type of factor on the risk premium? a. Which of these factors is more likely to adversely affect small businesses rather than large businesses in the credit assessment process by lenders? b. How does the existence of a high debt ratio typically affect the risk of the borrower? c. Why is the volatility of the earnings stream of a borrower important to a lender? 16. Why is the degree of collateral as specified in the loan agreement of importance to a lender? If the book value of the collateral is greater than or equal to the amount of the loan, is the credit risk of a lender fully covered? Why or why not? 17. Why are FIs consistently interested in the expected level of economic activity in the markets in which they operate? Why is monetary policy of the Federal Reserve System important to FIs? 18. What are the purposes of credit scoring models? How do these models assist an FI manager in better administering credit? 19. Suppose there were two factors influencing the past default behavior of borrowers: the leverage or debt–assets ratio (D/A) and the profit margin ratio (PM). Based on past default (repayment) experience, the linear probability model is estimated as: 318 Part Two Measuring Risk 21. Describe how a linear discriminant analysis model works. Identify and discuss the criticisms which have been made regarding the use of this type of model to make credit risk evaluations. 22. Suppose that the financial ratios of a potential borrowing firm take the following values: Working capital/total assets ratio (X1) 0.75 Retained earnings/total assets ratio (X2) 0.10 Earnings before interest and taxes/total assets ratio (X3) 0.05 Market value of equity/book value of long-term debt ratio (X4) 0.10 Sales/total assets ratio (X5) 0.65 Calculate the Altman’s Z-score for the borrower in question. How is this number a sign of the borrower’s default risk? 23. MNO Inc., a publicly traded manufacturing firm in the United States, has provided the following financial information in its application for a loan. All numbers are in thousands of dollars. Assets Cash Accounts receivable Inventory $ 20 90 90 Plant and equipment 500 Total assets www.mhhe.com/saunders8e Liabilities and Equity $700 Accounts payable Notes payable Accruals Long-term debt Equity (retained earnings $22) $ 30 90 30 150 400 Total liabilities and equity $700 Also assume sales $500,000; cost of goods sold $360,000; and the market value of equity is equal to the book value. a. What is the Altman discriminant function value for MNO Inc.? Recall that: Net working capital Current assets Current liabilities. Current assets Cash Accounts receivable Inventories. Current liabilities Accounts payable Accruals Notes payable. EBIT Revenues Cost of goods sold. b. Based on the Altman’s Z score only, should you approve MNO Inc.’s application to your bank for a $500,000 capital expansion loan? c. If sales for MNO were $300,000, the market value of equity was only half of book value, and all other values are unchanged, would your credit decision change? d. Would the discriminant function change for firms in different industries? Would the function be different for manufacturing firms in different geographic sections of the country? What are the implications for the use of these types of models by FIs? 24. Consider the coefficients of Altman’s Z score. Can you tell by the size of the coefficients which ratio appears most important in assessing creditworthiness of a loan applicant? Explain. Credit Risk: Individual Loan Risk 319 25. If the rate on one-year Treasury strips currently is 6 percent, what is the repayment probability for each of the following two securities? Assume that if the loan is defaulted, no payments are expected. What is the marketdetermined risk premium for the corresponding probability of default for each security? a. One-year AA-rated zero-coupon bond yielding 9.5 percent. b. One-year BB-rated zero-coupon bond yielding 13.5 percent. 26. A bank has made a loan charging a base lending rate of 10 percent. It expects a probability of default of 5 percent. If the loan is defaulted, the bank expects to recover 50 percent of its money through the sale of its collateral. What is the expected return on this loan? 27. Assume that a one-year Treasury strip is currently yielding 5.5 percent and an AAA-rated discount bond with similar maturity is yielding 8.5 percent. a. If the expected recovery from collateral in the event of default is 50 percent of principal and interest, what is the probability of repayment of the AAArated bond? What is the probability of default? b. What is the probability of repayment of the AAA-rated bond if the expected recovery from collateral in the case of default is 94.47 percent of principal and interest? What is the probability of default? c. What is the relationship between the probability of default and the proportion of principal and interest that may be recovered in case of default on the loan? 28. What is meant by the phrase marginal default probability? How does this term differ from cumulative default probability? How are the two terms related? 29. Suppose an FI manager wants to find the probability of default on a two-year loan. For the one-year loan, 1 p1 0.03 is the marginal and total or cumulative probability (Cp) of default in year 1. For the second year, suppose that 1 p2 0.05. Calculate the cumulative probability of default over the next two years. 30. From the Treasury strip yield curve, the current required yields on one- and twoyear Treasuries are i1 4.65 percent and i2 5.50 percent, respectively. Further, the current yield curve indicates that appropriate one-year discount bonds are yielding k1 8.5 percent, and two-year bonds are yielding k2 10.25 percent. a. Calculate the one-year forward rate on the Treasuries and the corporate bond. b. Using the current and forward one-year rates, calculate the marginal probability of repayment on the corporate bond in years 1 and 2, respectively. c. Calculate the cumulative probability of default on the corporate bond over the next two years. 31. Calculate the term structure of default probabilities over three years using the following spot rates from the Treasury strip and corporate bond (pure discount) yield curves. Be sure to calculate both the annual marginal and the cumulative default probabilities. Spot 1 Year Treasury strip BBB-rated bonds 5.0% 7.0 Spot 2 Year 6.1% 8.2 Spot 3 Year 7.0% 9.3 www.mhhe.com/saunders8e Chapter 10 320 Part Two Measuring Risk 32. The bond equivalent yields for U.S. Treasury and A-rated corporate bonds with maturities of 93 and 175 days are given below: 93 Days 175 Days Treasury strip A-rated corporate 8.07% 8.42 8.11% 8.66 Spread 0.35 0.55 a. What are the implied forward rates for both an 82-day Treasury and an 82-day A-rated bond beginning in 93 days? Use daily compounding on a 365-day year basis. b. What is the implied probability of default on A-rated bonds over the next 93 days? Over 175 days? c. What is the implied default probability on an 82-day, A-rated bond to be issued in 93 days? 33. What is the mortality rate of a bond or loan? What are some of the problems with using a mortality rate approach to determine the probability of default of a given bond issue? 34. The following is a schedule of historical defaults (yearly and cumulative) experienced by an FI manager on a portfolio of commercial and mortgage loans. Years after Issuance Loan Type www.mhhe.com/saunders8e Commercial: Annual default Cumulative default Mortgage: Annual default Cumulative default 1 Year 2 Years 3 Years 4 Years 5 Years 0.00% ______ ______ 0.10% 0.50% ______ ______ 0.80% 0.30% ______ 0.10% ______ 0.25% ______ 0.60% ______ ______ 1.64% 0.80% ______ a. Complete the blank spaces in the table. b. What are the probabilities that each type of loan will not be in default after five years? c. What is the measured difference between the cumulative default (mortality) rates for commercial and mortgage loans after four years? 35. The table below shows the dollar amounts of outstanding bonds and corresponding default amounts for every year over the past five years. Note that the default figures are in millions, while those outstanding are in billions. The outstanding figures reflect default amounts and bond redemptions. Years after Issuance Loan Type A-rated: Annual default (millions) Outstanding (billions) B-rated: Annual default (millions) Outstanding (billions) C-rated: Annual default (millions) Outstanding (billions) 1 Year 2 Years 3 Years 4 Years 5 Years 0 $100 0 $100 $ 1 $100 0 $95 $ 1 $94 $ 3 $97 0 $93 $ 2 $92 $ 5 $90 $ 1 $91 $ 3 $89 $ 5 $85 $ 2 $88 $ 4 $85 $ 6 $79 What are the annual and cumulative default rates of the above bonds? Chapter 10 Credit Risk: Individual Loan Risk 321 Face value of loan (B) $500,000 Length of time remaining to loan maturity ( ) 4 years Risk-free rate (i) 4% Borrower’s leverage ratio (d) 60% Standard deviation of the rate of change in the value of the underlying assets 15% 40. A firm is issuing a two-year loan in the amount of $200,000. The current market value of the borrower’s assets is $300,000. The risk-free rate is 4 percent and the standard deviation of the rate of change in the underlying assets of the borrower is 20 percent. Using an options framework, determine the following: a. The current market value of the loan. b. The risk premium to be charged on the loan. 41. A firm has assets of $200,000 and total debts of $175,000. With an option pricing model, the implied volatility of the value of the firm’s assets is estimated at $10,730. Under the Moody’s Analytic method, what is the expected default frequency (assuming a normal distribution for assets)? 42. Carman County Bank (CCB) has a $5 million face value outstanding adjustablerate loan to a company that has a leverage ratio of 80 percent. The current riskfree rate is 6 percent and the time to maturity on the loan is exactly ½ year. The asset risk of the borrower, as measured by the standard deviation of the rate of change in the value of the underlying assets, is 12 percent. The normal density function values are given below. www.mhhe.com/saunders8e 36. What is RAROC? How does this model use the concept of duration to measure the risk exposure of a loan? How is the expected change in the credit risk premium measured? What precisely is ΔLN in the RAROC equation? 37. An FI wants to evaluate the credit risk of a $5 million loan with a duration of 4.3 years to a AAA borrower. There are currently 500 publicly traded bonds in that class (i.e., bonds issued by firms with a AAA rating). The current average level of rates (R) on AAA bonds is 8 percent. The largest increase in credit risk premiums on AAA loans, the 99 percent worst-case scenario, over the last year was equal to 1.2 percent (i.e., only 6 bonds out of 500 had risk premium increases exceeding the 99 percent worst case). The projected (oneyear) spread on the loan is 0.3 percent and the FI charges 0.25 percent of the face value of the loan in fees. Calculate the capital at risk and the RAROC on this loan. 38. A bank is planning to make a loan of $5,000,000 to a firm in the steel industry. It expects to charge a servicing fee of 50 basis points. The loan has a maturity of 8 years with a duration of 7.5 years. The cost of funds (the RAROC benchmark) for the bank is 10 percent. The bank has estimated the maximum change in the risk premium on the steel manufacturing sector to be approximately 4.2 percent, based on two years of historical data. The current market interest rate for loans in this sector is 12 percent. a. Using the RAROC model, determine whether the bank should make the loan. b. What should be the duration in order for this loan to be approved? c. Assuming that the duration cannot be changed, how much additional interest and fee income will be necessary to make the loan acceptable? d. Given the proposed income stream and the negotiated duration, what adjustment in the loan rate would be necessary to make the loan acceptable? 39. Calculate the value of and interest rate on a loan using the option model and the following information. 322 Part Two Measuring Risk h N(h) h N(h) 2.55 2.60 2.65 2.70 2.75 0.0054 0.0047 0.0040 0.0035 0.0030 2.50 2.55 2.60 2.65 2.70 0.9938 0.9946 0.9953 0.9960 0.9965 a. Use the Merton option valuation model to determine the market value of the loan. b. What should be the interest rate for the last six months of the loan? The questions and problems that follow refer to Appendix 10A. 43. Suppose you are a loan officer at Carbondale Local Bank. Joan Doe listed the following information on her mortgage application. Characteristic Annual gross income TDS Relations with FI Major credit cards Age Residence Length of residence Job stability Credit history Value $45,000 10% Checking account 5 27 Own/mortgage 2½ years 5½ years Missed 2 payments 1 year ago Use the information below to determine whether or not Joan Doe should be approved for a mortgage from your bank. www.mhhe.com/saunders8e Characteristic Characteristic Values and Weights Annual gross $25,000–$50,000 $50,000–$100,000 $100,000 $10,000 $10,000–$25,000 income Score 0 10 20 35 60 TDS 35%–50% 15%–35% 5%–15% 50% 5% Score 0 20 40 60 10 Relations with FI None Checking account Savings account Both Score 0 10 10 20 Major credit cards None Between 1 and 4 5 or more Score 0 20 10 Age 25–60 25 60 Score 5 25 35 Residence Rent Own with mortgage Own outright Score 5 20 50 Length of 1–5 years 1 year 5 years residence Score 0 25 40 Job stability 1–5 years 1 year 5 years Score 0 25 50 Credit history No record Missed a payment in last 5 years Met all payments Score 0 40 15 Chapter 10 Credit Risk: Individual Loan Risk 323 The loan is automatically rejected if the applicant’s total score is less than or equal to 120; the loan is automatically approved if the total score is greater than or equal to 190. A score between 120 and 190 (noninclusive) is reviewed by a loan committee for a final decision. 44. What are some of the special risks and considerations when lending to small businesses rather than large businesses? 45. How does ratio analysis help to answer questions about the production, management, and marketing capabilities of a prospective borrower? 46. Consider the following company balance sheet and income statement. Balance Sheet Assets Cash Accounts receivable Inventory Total current assets Fixed assets Total assets Liabilities and Equity $ 4,000 52,000 40,000 96,000 44,000 $140,000 Accounts payable Notes payable Total current liabilities Long-term debt Equity Total liabilities and equity $ 30,000 12,000 42,000 36,000 62,000 $140,000 Income Statement $200,000 130,000 70,000 20,000 8,000 42,000 4,800 37,200 11,160 $ 26,040 For this company, calculate the following: a. Current ratio. b. Number of days’ sales in receivables. c. Sales to total assets. d. Number of days in inventory. e. Debt to assets ratio. f. Cash flow to debt ratio. g. Return on assets. h. Return on equity. 47. Industrial Corporation has an income to sales (profit margin) ratio of 0.03, a sales to assets (asset utilization) ratio of 1.5, and a debt to asset ratio of 0.66. What is Industrial’s return on equity? Web Questions 48. Go to the Federal Reserve Board’s website at www.federalreserve.gov and update the data in Table 10–1 using the following steps. Click on “All Statistical Releases.” Click on “Assets and Liabilities of Commercial Banks in the www.mhhe.com/saunders8e Sales (all on credit) Cost of goods sold Gross margin Selling and administrative expenses Depreciation EBIT Interest expense Earning before tax Taxes Net income 324 Part Two Measuring Risk U.S.” This downloads a file onto your computer that contains the relevant data. How has the data changed since that reported in Table 10–1 for 2012? 49. Go to the Federal Housing Finance Agency’s website at www.fhfa.gov and find the most recent data on the percentage of conventional single-family mortgages with adjustable rates using the following steps. Under “Research & Analysis,” then “Market Data,” and then “Monthly Interest Rate Survey Data,” click on “Historical Summary Tables.” Click on “Annual, All Homes, 1963–20XX.” This downloads a file onto your computer that contains the relevant data. How has this data changed since 2012? 50. Go to the Federal Reserve Board’s website at www.federalreserve.gov and update Table 10–7 using the following steps. Click on “All Statistical Releases.” Click on “Consumer Credit.” This downloads a file onto your computer that contains the relevant data. How have consumer loan rates changed since 2012 as reported in Table 10–7? Integrated Mini Case LOAN ANALYSIS As a senior loan officer at MC Bancorp, you have the following loan applications waiting for review. The bank uses Altman’s Z score, default probabilities, mortality rates, and RAROC to assess loan acceptability. The bank’s cost of equity (the RAROC benchmark) is 9 percent. The bank’s loan policy states that the maximum probability of default for loans by type is as follows: Loan Type and Maturity Maximum Allowable Default Probability www.mhhe.com/saunders8e AAA-rated A-rated 0.50% 1.25 Which loans should be approved and which rejected? Assets 1. An AAA-rated, one-year C&I loan from a firm with a liquidity ratio of 2.15, a debt-to-asset ratio of 45 percent, volatility in earnings of 0.13, and a profit margin of 12 percent. MC Bancorp uses a linear probability model to evaluate AAA-rated loans as follows: PD 0.08X 1 0.15X 2 1.25X 3 0.45 X 4 where X1 Liquidity ratio X2 Debt-to-asset ratio X3 Volatility in earnings X4 Profit margin 2. An AA-rated, one-year C&I loan from a firm with the following financial statement information (in millions of dollars): Liabilities and Equity Cash Accounts receivables Inventory $ 40 120 210 Plant and equipment Total assets 1,100 $1,470 Also assume sales $1,250 m, cost of goods sold $930 m, and the market value of equity is equal Accounts payable Notes payable Accruals Long-term debt Equity (ret. earnings $200) Total liabilities and equity $ 55 60 70 550 735 $1,470 to 2.2 times the book value. MC Bancorp uses the Altman’s Z score model to evaluate AA-rated loans. Chapter 10 3. An A-rated corporate loan with a maturity of three years. A-rated corporate loans are evaluated using the mortality rate approach. Credit Risk: Individual Loan Risk 325 A schedule of historical defaults (annual and cumulative) experienced by the bank on its A-rated corporate loans is as follows: Years after Issuance 1 year 2 years 3 years 4 years 0.10% 0.10 0.25% 0.325 0.40% 0.595 0.65% 1.858 4. A $2 million, five-year loan to a BBB-rated corporation in the computer parts industry. MC Bancorp charges a servicing fee of 75 basis points. The duration on the loan is 4.5 years. The cost of funds for the bank is 8 percent. Based on four years of historical data, the bank has estimated the maximum change in the risk premium on the computer parts industry to be approximately 5.5 percent. The current market rate for loans in this industry is 10 percent. Appendix 10A: Credit Analysis View Appendix 10A at the website for this textbook (www.mhhe.com/saunders8e). Appendix 10B: Black–Scholes Option Pricing Model View Appendix 10B at the website for this textbook (www.mhhe.com/saunders8e). www.mhhe.com/saunders8e Loan type A-rated corporate loans Annual default Cumulative default Chapter Eleven Credit Risk: Loan Portfolio and Concentration Risk INTRODUCTION www.naic.org The models discussed in the previous chapter describe alternative ways by which an FI manager can measure the default risks on individual debt instruments such as loans and bonds. Rather than looking at credit risk one loan at a time, this chapter concentrates on the ability of an FI manager to measure credit risk in a loan (asset) portfolio context and the benefit from loan (asset) portfolio diversification. We discuss and illustrate several models that are used by FI managers to assess the risk of the overall loan portfolio. The risk-return characteristics of each loan in the portfolio are a concern for the FI, but the risk-return of the overall loan portfolio, with some of the risk of the individual loans diversified, affects an FI’s overall credit risk exposure. Additionally, we look at the potential use of loan portfolio models in setting maximum concentration (borrowing) limits for certain business or borrowing sectors (e.g., sectors identified by their Standard Industrial Classification [SIC] codes). This chapter also discusses regulatory methods for measuring default risk of a portfolio. In particular, the FDIC Improvement Act of 1991 required bank regulators to incorporate credit concentration risk into their evaluation of bank insolvency risk. Moreover, a debate currently is being conducted among bankers and regulators about how this can be done. Some banks are allowed to use their own internal models, such as CreditMetrics and CreditRisk (discussed in the Appendices to this chapter) and Moody’s Analytics Portfolio Manager (discussed later in this chapter), to calculate their capital requirements against insolvency risk from excessive loan concentrations. Further, the National Association of Insurance Commissioners (NAIC) has developed limits for different types of assets and borrowers in insurers’ portfolios—a so-called pigeonhole approach. SIMPLE MODELS OF LOAN CONCENTRATION RISK FIs widely employ two simple models to measure credit risk concentration in the loan portfolio beyond the purely subjective model of “We have already lent too 326 Chapter 11 TABLE 11–1 A Hypothetical Rating Migration, or Transition, Matrix Credit Risk: Loan Portfolio and Concentration Risk 327 Risk Rating at End of Year Risk Rating at Beginning of Year AAA-A BBB-B CCC-C AAA-A 0.85 0.12 0.03 BBB-B 0.10 0.83 0.13 CCC-C 0.04 0.03 0.80 D* 0.01 0.02 0.04 *D default. migration analysis A method to measure loan concentration risk by tracking credit ratings of firms in a particular sector or ratings class for unusual declines. www.standardandpoors.com www.moodys.com loan migration matrix A measure of the probability of a loan being upgraded, downgraded, or defaulting over some period. concentration limits External limits set on the maximum loan size that can be made to an individual borrower. much to this borrower.” The first is migration analysis, where lending officers track S&P, Moody’s, or their own internal credit ratings of certain pools of loans or certain sectors—for example, machine tools. If the credit ratings of a number of firms in a sector or rating class decline faster than has been historically experienced, FIs curtail lending to that sector or class. A loan migration matrix (or transition matrix) seeks to reflect the historic experience of a pool of loans in terms of their credit rating migration over time. As such, it can be used as a benchmark against which the credit migration patterns of any new pool of loans can be compared. Table 11–1 shows a hypothetical credit migration matrix, or table, in which loans are assigned to one of three rating classes (most FIs use 10 to 13 rating classes). The rows in Table 11–1 list the S&P rating at which the portfolio of loans began the year and the columns list the rating at which the portfolio ended the year. The numbers in the table are called transition probabilities, reflecting the average experience (proportions) of loans that began the year, say, as rating BB remaining rating BB at the end of the year, being upgraded to an AA, being downgraded to a CC, or defaulting (D). For example, for loans that began the year at rating BBB-B, historically (on average) 12 percent have been upgraded to AAA-A, 83 percent have remained at BBB-B, 3 percent have been downgraded to CCC-C, and 2 percent have defaulted by the end of the year. Suppose that the FI is evaluating the credit risk of its current portfolio of loans of borrowers rated BBB-B and that over the last few years a much higher percentage (say, 5 percent) of loans has been downgraded to CCC-C and a higher percentage (say, 3 percent) has defaulted than is implied by the historic transition matrix. The FI may then seek to restrict its supply of lower-quality loans (e.g., those rated BBB-B and CCC-C), concentrating more of its portfolio on grade AAA-A loans. At the very least, the FI should seek higher credit risk premiums on lower-quality (rated) loans. Not only is migration analysis used to evaluate commercial loan portfolios, it is widely used to analyze credit card portfolios and consumer loans as well. The second simple model requires management to set some firm external limit on the maximum amount of loans that will be made to an individual borrower or sector. The FI determines concentration limits on the proportion of the loan portfolio that can go to any single customer by assessing the borrower’s current portfolio, its operating unit’s business plans, its economists’ economic projections, and its strategic plans. Typically, FIs set concentration limits to reduce exposures to certain industries and increase exposures to others. When two industry groups’ performances are highly correlated, an FI may set an aggregate limit of less than the sum of the two individual industry limits. FIs also typically set geographic limits. They may set aggregate portfolio limits or combinations of industry and geographic limits. Bank regulators in recent years have limited loan concentrations to individual borrowers to a maximum of 10 percent of a bank’s capital. 328 Part Two Measuring Risk EXAMPLE 11–1 Calculating Concentration Limits for a Loan Portfolio Suppose management is unwilling to permit losses exceeding 10 percent of an FI’s capital to a particular sector. If management estimates that the amount lost per dollar of defaulted loans in this sector is 40 cents, the maximum loans to a single sector as a percent of capital, defined as the concentration limit, is: Concentration limit Maximum loss as a percent of capital 1 Loss rate 10% (1/0.4) 25% Concept Questions 1. In Example 11–1, what would the concentration limit be if the loss rate on bad loans is 25 cents on the dollar? (40%) 2. In Example 11–1, what would the concentration limit be if the maximum loss (as a percent of capital) is 15 percent instead of 10 percent? (60%) Next we look at the use of more sophisticated portfolio theory–based models to set concentration limits. While these models have a great deal of potential, data availability and other implementation problems have, until recently, hindered their use. The basic idea is to select the portfolio of loans that maximizes the return on the loan portfolio for any given level of risk (or that minimizes the degree of portfolio risk for any given level of returns). LOAN PORTFOLIO DIVERSIFICATION AND MODERN PORTFOLIO THEORY (MPT) To the extent that an FI manager holds widely traded loans and bonds as assets or, alternatively, can calculate loan or bond returns, portfolio diversification models can be used to measure and control the FI’s aggregate credit risk exposure. Suppose the manager can estimate the expected return of each loan or bond (Ri ) in the FI’s portfolio. After calculating the individual security return series, the FI manager can compute the expected return (Rp) on a portfolio of assets as: Rp N ∑ Xi Ri (1) i 1 In addition, the variance of returns or risk of the portfolio ( i2 ) can be calculated as: n n n ∑ Xi2 i2 ∑ p2 i 1 ∑ Xi X j ij (2) i 1 j 1 i≠ j or p2 n n n ∑ Xi2 i2 ∑ ∑ Xi X jρij i j i=1 i 1 j 1 i j (3) Chapter 11 Credit Risk: Loan Portfolio and Concentration Risk 329 where Rp Expected or mean return on the asset portfolio Summation sign Ri return on the ith asset in the portfolio Xi Proportion of the asset portfolio invested in the ith asset (the desired concentration amount) i2 = of returns on the ith asset ij Covariance of returns between the ith and jth assets ij Correlation between the returns on the ith and jth assets1 The fundamental lesson of modern portfolio theory (MPT) is that by taking advantage of its size, an FI can diversify considerable amounts of credit risk as long as the returns on different assets are imperfectly correlated with respect to their default risk adjusted returns.2 Consider the p2 in equation (3). If many loans have negative correlations of returns (ij are negative)—that is, when one borrower’s loans do badly and another’s do well—then combining loans to both borrowers may reduce the FI’s overall credit risk exposure. That is, if there is negative correlation across borrower default probabilities, then a portfolio of loans may have less risk than an individual loan, all else equal. Thus, the sum of the individual credit risks of loans viewed independently overestimates the risk of the whole portfolio. Because correlation is constrained to lie between plus and minus one, we can evaluate the effect of a change in ij on asset portfolio risk. For example, in the two-asset case, if ij is negative, the second term in equation (3) will also be negative and will offset the first term, which will always be positive. By appropriately exploiting correlation relationships among assets, an FI can significantly reduce risk in the asset portfolio and improve the portfolio’s risk-return trade-off. This is what we meant in Chapter 1 when we stated that by pooling funds, FIs can reduce risk by taking advantage of the law of large numbers in their investment decisions. EXAMPLE 11–2 Calculation of Return and Risk on a Two-Asset Portfolio Suppose that an FI holds two loans with the following characteristics:3 1 Loan i Xi Ri i i2 1 2 0.40 0.60 10% 12 0.0857 0.0980 0.007344 0.009604 12 0.84 12 0.0070548 The correlation coefficient reflects the joint movement of asset returns, or default risks in the case of loans, and lies between the values 1 1, where is the correlation coefficient. As can be seen from equations (2) and (3), the covariance between any two assets (ij) is related to the correlation coefficient (ij) by ij ijij. 2 One objection to using modern portfolio theory for loans is that the returns on individual loans are not normally or symmetrically distributed. In particular, most loans have limited upside returns and long-tail downside risks; see Appendix 11A and Chapter 9 in Saunders and Allen, Credit Risk Management: In and Out of the Financial Crisis, 3rd ed. (New York: John Wiley & Sons, 2010). Also, concerns about maintaining relationships with traditional customers may limit the ability of an FI to diversify. The relationship limit on diversification has been called the “paradox of credit.” That is, leading institutions specialize in monitoring and generating information about their key customers (see Chapter 1), yet such monitoring specialization may lead to a highly concentrated loan portfolio. Relationship concerns may inhibit the loan portfolio’s being managed in a fashion similar to a mutual fund’s management of an equity portfolio. 3 Note that variance (2) is measured in percent squared; standard deviation () is measured in percent. 330 Part Two Measuring Risk The return on the loan portfolio is: Rp 0.4(10%) 0.6(12%) 11.2% while the risk of the portfolio is: 2 2 2 σ p (0.4) (0.007344) (0.6) (0.009604) 2(0.4)(0.6)( 0.84)(0.0857)(0.0980) 0.0012462 thus, σ p 0.0012462 0.0353 3.53% Notice that the risk (or standard deviation of returns) of the portfolio, p (3.53 percent), is less than the risk of either individual asset (8.57 percent and 9.80 percent, respectively). The negative correlation between the returns of the two loans ( 0.84) results in an overall reduction of risk when they are put together in an FI’s portfolio. minimum risk portfolio Combination of assets that reduces the risk of portfolio returns to the lowest feasible level. FIGURE 11–1 FI Portfolio Diversification To see more generally the advantages of diversification, consider Figure 11–1. Note that A is an undiversified portfolio with heavy investment concentration in just a few loans or bonds. By fully exploiting diversification potential with bonds or loans whose returns are negatively correlated or that have a low positive correlation with those in the existing portfolio, the FI manager can lower the credit risk on the portfolio from pA to pB while earning the same expected return. That is, portfolio B is the efficient (lowest-risk) portfolio associated with portfolio return level Rp. By varying the proportion of the asset portfolio invested in each asset (in other words, by varying the required portfolio return level Rp up and down), the manager can identify an entire frontier of efficient portfolio mixes (weights) of loans and bonds. Each portfolio mix is efficient in the sense that it offers the lowest risk level to the FI manager at each possible level of portfolio returns. However, as you can see in Figure 11–1, of all possible efficient portfolios that can be generated, portfolio B produces the lowest possible risk level for the FI manager. That is, it maximizes the gains from diversifying across all available loans and bonds so that the manager cannot reduce the risk of the portfolio below pB. For this reason, pB is usually labeled the minimum risk portfolio. Even though B is clearly the minimum risk portfolio, it does not generate the highest returns. Consequently, portfolio B may be chosen only by the most Rp (return) C B Rp 0 A σpB σpA σp(risk) Chapter 11 Credit Risk: Loan Portfolio and Concentration Risk 331 risk-averse FI managers, whose sole objective is to minimize portfolio risk regardless of the portfolio’s return. Most portfolio managers have some desired return-risk trade-off in mind; they are willing to accept more risk if they are compensated with higher expected returns. One such possibility would be portfolio C in Figure 11–1. This is an efficient portfolio in that the FI manager has selected loan proportions (Xi) to produce a portfolio risk level that is a minimum for that higher expected return level. This portfolio dominates all other portfolios that can produce the same expected return level.4 Portfolio theory is a highly attractive tool. Still, over and above the intuitive concept that diversification is generally good, a question arises as to its applicability for banks, insurance companies, and thrifts. These FIs often hold significant amounts of regionally specific nontraded or infrequently traded loans and bonds. Concept Questions www.moodysanalytics.com Moody’s Analytics Portfolio Manager A model that applies modern portfolio theory to the loan portfolio. 1. What is the main point in using MPT for loan portfolio risk? 2. Why would an FI not always choose to operate with a minimum risk portfolio? Moody’s Analytics Portfolio Manager Model Despite the nontraded aspect of many loans, a great deal of recent research has gone into developing modern portfolio theory models for loans. Below we look at one approach developed by KMV Corporation (now owned and operated by Moody’s Analytics) called Portfolio Manager.5 We will see that Moody’s Analytics Portfolio Manager model differs from MPT in that it does not require loan returns to be normally distributed. Further, Moody’s Analytics has developed a proprietary model to estimate the value of infrequently traded loans. Thus, the Moody’s Analytics model is unique in the way it estimates the return, risk, and correlations between loans in an FI’s loan portfolio. Once these variables are estimated in the Moody’s Analytics Portfolio Manager model, they are then incorporated into the standard MPT equations to get an estimate of the risk and return of the FI’s loan portfolio. The Moody’s Analytics Credit Monitor model examines Moody’s Analytics’ method of evaluating default risk on an individual loan (so-called expected default frequency, or EDF). The Moody’s Analytics Portfolio Manager model, examined in this chapter, uses the default probability on each loan in a portfolio to identify the overall risk of the portfolio. Any model that seeks to estimate an efficient frontier for loans, as in Figure 11–1, and thus the optimal or best proportions (Xi) in which to hold loans made to different borrowers, needs to determine and measure three things [see equations (1), (2), and (3)]: the expected return on a loan to borrower i (Ri), the risk of a loan to borrower i (i), and the correlation of default risks between loans made to borrowers i and j (ij). Specifically, in the Moody’s Analytics Portfolio Manager model 4 Rather than selecting a point on the loan efficient frontier that reflects managerial risk aversion, as in Figure 11–1, point C, the FI manager would pick a point that maximizes firm value. This would be the point where the return of the portfolio minus the risk-free rate divided by the standard deviation of portfolio returns is maximized, that is, the maximum of [(Rp Rf)/p)]. In MPT this is often called the Sharpe ratio. Diagramatically, this is a point on the efficient frontier where a straight line drawn from the vertical axis, from a point equal to Rf, is just tangential to the efficient frontier. At this tangency point, it is impossible to improve upon the risk-return trade-off. 5 Other portfolio models have been developed, including CreditMetrics, CreditRisk, and Credit Portfolio View (McKinsey and Company). See Saunders and Allen, Credit Risk Management. 332 Part Two Measuring Risk portfolio return and risk are a function of the extent to which loan (exposure) values can change over a one-year horizon and how these value changes move together across different loans in the loan portfolio (correlations). Changes in loan values are determined by changes in the borrower’s credit quality (measured as the expected default frequency [EDF], discussed in Chapter 10) and the amount of the loan not recovered (i.e., the loss given default [LGD] on the loan). To calculate correlations, Moody’s Analytics considers the joint impact of 120 different systematic factors, which reflect the global economy, region, industry, and country. In its simplest form, Moody’s Analytics measures each of these as follows: Ri AISi E(Li ) AISi i ULi Di LGDi [EDFi LGDi ] EDFi (1 EDFi ) LGDi ij Correlation between the systematic return components of the asset returns of borrower i and borrower j (4) (5) Each of these needs some explanation. Return on the Loan (Ri) The return on a loan is measured by the so-called annual all-in-spread (AIS), which measures annual fees earned on the loan by the FI plus the annual spread between the loan rate paid by the borrower and the FI’s cost of funds. Deducted from this is the expected loss on the loan [E(Li)]. This expected loss is equal to the product of the expected probability of the borrower defaulting over the next year, or its expected default frequency (EDFi)—as discussed in Chapter 10—times the amount lost by the FI if the borrower defaults (the loss given default, or LGDi). Also, if desired, the return on the loan can be expressed in excess return form by deducting the risk-free rate on a security of equivalent maturity. We looked at Altman’s estimates of recovery rates (1–LGD) on defaulted bonds in Chapter 10. Altman’s research consistently finds that approximately 90 percent of bond recovery rates can be explained and estimated using regressions that include default rates on bonds, one-year changes in bond default rates, and the amount of high yield bonds outstanding in a particular year (which represents the potential supply of defaulted bonds). Macroeconomic factors are found to be insignificant in explaining recovery rates on defaulted bonds (much of this effect is captured in bonds default rates).6 Different types of debt instruments have different recovery rates. For example, more senior securities tend to have higher recovery rates than subordinated securities, all else equal. Moody’s Analytics research has found that the highest (lowest) LGD is for preferred stock and junior subordinated bonds (industrial revenue bonds, senior secured bonds, and senior secured loans). The Basel Committee assessed a fixed 45 percent LGD on secured loans if fully secured by physical, non-real estate collateral and 40 percent if fully secured by receivables. However, there is evidence suggesting that these fixed LGD rates may be too high for bank loans. Risk of the Loan (i) The risk of the loan reflects the volatility of the loan’s default rate (Di) around its expected value times the amount lost given default (LGDi). The product of 6 See E. Altman, “Loss Given Default: The Link between Default and Recovery Rates, Recovery Ratings and Recent Empirical Evidence,” New York University Salomon Center Working Paper, May 2008. Chapter 11 Credit Risk: Loan Portfolio and Concentration Risk FIGURE 11–2 333 Firm risk Moody’s Analytics Asset Level Correlation Systematic risk Industry risk Industry specific risk Global economic risk Firm specific risk Country risk Regional risk Industrial specific risk Country specific risk the volatility of the default rate and the LGD is called the unexpected loss on the loan (ULi) and is a measure of the loan’s risk, or i. To measure the volatility of the default rate, assume that loans can either default or repay (no default). Then defaults are binomially distributed, and the standard deviation of the default rate for the ith borrower (Di) is equal to the square root of the probability of default times 1 minus the probability of default [ (EDF )(1 EDF )]. Correlation (ij) To measure the unobservable default risk correlation between any two borrowers, the Moody’s Analytics Portfolio Manager model uses the systematic asset return components of the two borrowers—as discussed i