Springer Series on Naval Architecture, Marine Engineering, Shipbuilding and Shipping 3 George Adamantios Psarros Energy Efficiency Clauses in Charter Party Agreements Legal and Economic Perspectives and their Application to Ocean Grain Transport Springer Series on Naval Architecture, Marine Engineering, Shipbuilding and Shipping Volume 3 Series editor Nikolas I. Xiros, University of New Orleans, New Orleans, LA, USA The Naval Architecture, Marine Engineering, Shipbuilding and Shipping (NAMESS) series publishes state-of-art research and applications in the fields of design, construction, maintenance and operation of marine vessels and structures. The series publishes monographs, edited books, as well as selected Ph.D. theses and conference proceedings focusing on all theoretical and technical aspects of naval architecture (including naval hydrodynamics, ship design, shipbuilding, shipyards, traditional and non-motorized vessels), marine engineering (including ship propulsion, electric power shipboard, ancillary machinery, marine engines and gas turbines, control systems, unmanned surface and underwater marine vehicles) and shipping (including transport logistics, route-planning as well as legislative and economical aspects). Photo credits: Courtesy of the Vancouver Fraser Port Authority More information about this series at http://www.springer.com/series/10523 George Adamantios Psarros Energy Efficiency Clauses in Charter Party Agreements Legal and Economic Perspectives and their Application to Ocean Grain Transport 123 George Adamantios Psarros DNV GL AS Høvik Norway ISSN 2194-8445 ISSN 2194-8453 (electronic) Springer Series on Naval Architecture, Marine Engineering, Shipbuilding and Shipping ISBN 978-3-319-50264-9 ISBN 978-3-319-50265-6 (eBook) DOI 10.1007/978-3-319-50265-6 Library of Congress Control Number: 2016959248 © Springer International Publishing Switzerland 2017 This work is subject to copyright. All rights are reserved by the Publisher, whether the whole or part of the material is concerned, specifically the rights of translation, reprinting, reuse of illustrations, recitation, broadcasting, reproduction on microfilms or in any other physical way, and transmission or information storage and retrieval, electronic adaptation, computer software, or by similar or dissimilar methodology now known or hereafter developed. The use of general descriptive names, registered names, trademarks, service marks, etc. in this publication does not imply, even in the absence of a specific statement, that such names are exempt from the relevant protective laws and regulations and therefore free for general use. The publisher, the authors and the editors are safe to assume that the advice and information in this book are believed to be true and accurate at the date of publication. Neither the publisher nor the authors or the editors give a warranty, express or implied, with respect to the material contained herein or for any errors or omissions that may have been made. Printed on acid-free paper This Springer imprint is published by Springer Nature The registered company is Springer International Publishing AG The registered company address is: Gewerbestrasse 11, 6330 Cham, Switzerland Αφιεϱώνεται στους γονείς μου Dedicated to my parents Foreword Traditionally, energy efficiency of ships is an area that has been subject to attention from charterers and shipowners. Operational energy efficiency is the sum of so many factors, pointing in different directions. How can anyone “reverse engineer” an observed operational energy efficiency of a ship to understand if it was good or bad? However, we should not forget that all parties share a common interest of optimal performance of the ships they build, operate and charter. These are fundamental aspects that the shipping industry struggles to get their heads around. Is it possible to observe a ship’s operational performance and from that determine if the Master did a good job? Is it possible from the observed operational efficiency of a ship to determine if it is the right one to charter? Ships’ performance has traditionally been referred to in charter contracts as warranties of speed and consumption at some defined loading condition. Such simplistic warranties have worked, probably because they are easy to understand and because it is similarly easy to determine if they are breached. The question if simple speed and consumption warranties are effective and are incentivizing a desired behavior amongst the decision makers in the industry could seem of less importance. A ship’s operational performance is a reflection of so many different parameters. One set of these are a ship’s design characteristics, such as propulsion train design and hull design. Historically, the hull design of a ship was determined by the ship yard designers, taking into account contract design values for speed and consumption at design draught. For some designs these could be complemented by a similar set of ballast draught values. Today, the International Maritime Organization have adopted mandatory design efficiency requirements for the major ship types in the form of Energy Efficiency Design Index (EEDI). The regulation basically specifies an additional loading condition to which it attaches a maximum power/speed correlation. In theory, the EEDI in combination with traditional newbuilding contract specifications should cater for more energy efficient ships across their operating draught ranges. vii viii Foreword A ship’s designed energy efficiency is to some extent reflected in the warranted speed and consumption values that traditionally are used in charter parties, but only to some extent. Warranties reflect the sum of operational behavior, environmental conditions expected to be encountered throughout the voyages and the designed energy efficiency. It is a traditional view that the charter parties of today makes it an implicit obligation to always seek to execute the contracted voyages as efficient as possible. It is also a traditional view that the legal parties to charter arrangements have freedom to agree on any supplemental clauses, including clauses on how to share benefits if so wished. However, it appears that most short term charter parties are currently agreed without such additional provisions. This book makes an effort to suggest ways to separate the designed energy efficiency from the actual operational efficiency to allow shipowners and charterers obtain transparency and henceforth share benefits between the contractual parties. It suggests ways to quantify these benefits and makes legal analysis on how the quantified benefits may be incorporated in charter party terms to obtain the desired behavior. I wish you good reading. Lars Robert Pedersen Deputy Secretary General, The Baltic and International Maritime Council Preface The work reported in this monograph describes the author’s search of excellence and attempt of harvesting knowledge within business, management, sales and marketing related topics. Furthermore, it portrays the author’s orientation to explore new areas of specialization in a more commercial setting, as well as to fulfil the ambition of operating across a range of disciplines beyond own functional specialism. It is admitted that this quest has been challenging not only due to full time job commitments, but also on how to cognitively realize the meaning of leadership. The latter can be encapsulated through Siegel (2008), where the hunger of learning and assimilating facts is a self-governing intellectual ability which is not implied to be displayed or transferred. Nevertheless, the years to come will prove whether the further commitment on such executive education would be rewarding and successful in search of alternative career opportunities, or simply would contribute to adding another postgraduate degree on the shelf. In any case, the reader is cordially tempted to experience the author’s knowledge expedition. The remit of improving maritime industry’s energy efficiency has attracted significant attention not only due to recent regulatory imperatives, but also inconsistencies between demand and supply as well as volatile market behavior. A long-term flexible solution is obtained through nurturing the wider application of innovative energy efficient technologies. This requires the existence of suitable incentives that embrace adoption of new technological solutions and reduce their performance uncertainty. A supporting mechanism to safeguard energy efficient investments can be envisaged through the chartering process (undertaking responsible for a vessel’s employment), its negotiation stages (orchestration of the signatories’ commitment for a successful enterprise) and the charter party agreement (prevailing contract form). Undoubtedly, developing a solid grasp of the regulatory background and gaining a practical insight into the legal, contractual, commercial and economic principles underpinning energy efficiency is a crucial aspect that the buyers and sellers of maritime transportation services need to be aware of in order to reduce impacts on revenue. Hence, the current book proposes a conceptual framework on how to include an incentive mechanism for energy efficiency within the existing charter party ix x Preface contracts. An answer to this call is given by examining key concepts of case law and the generated theoretical proposition is demonstrated for time and voyage charter contracts (book’s qualitative section). Realizing that such development may challenge the traditional business setting of vessel chartering, it is argued how the interests of the contracting parties can be balanced with the use of game theory. This scientific approach is able to solve information problems of strategic behavior. Furthermore, it is believed to be well suited for modeling the chartering negotiations, where the fair investment sharing is perceived by astute price determination. A working example applied to the ocean grain transport is offered to clearly enhance the reader’s understanding and advance an analytical approach during contract negotiation (book’s quantitative section). To the author’s best knowledge, game theoretic applications on such topic have not been exposed to extensive scientific research and the current volume is aimed at filling this gap. Additionally, it is hoped that the contained ideas will trigger additional interest for continued work and will facilitate communication between industry practitioners, as well as set a comprehensive foundation for modernizing the chartering process radically. The views discussed herein are treated with adequate legal as well as mathematical scholarship and the reader is not required to possess sophisticated knowledge for their accumulation. This fascinating book is intended to be attractive to academics (educators, tutors, researchers, scientists) and professionals (shipowners and operators, charterers, cargo owners, shipbrokers, lawyers and insurers, commercial and investment bankers, commodity and energy traders, institutional investors, market analysts and consultants, private equity firms, industry associations) engaged in the maritime industry who wish to sharpen their insights on how to obtain sustainable ocean freight service pricing. It is a valuable asset for enabling the reader to interact across multidisciplinary roles and providing the skills to bargain from a position of strength. The author is confident that the reader will attain a competitive edge and be able to navigate profitably within uncertain markets and an ever demanding shipping environment. Elements of the book’s qualitative section have been prepared as part of the author’s Master of Business Administration dissertation and he would like to express his gratitude to Dr. Lakshmi Narasimhan Vedanthachari, Module Leader Business Transformation Project, Middlesex University, Business School, for accepting his suggested topic. The author is pleased to acknowledge his supervisor Dr. Katerina Konsta, Lloyd’s Maritime Academy, for her valuable comments and constructive feedback on earlier versions of the dissertation. The author’s ambition to quantitatively support the presented ideas of the dissertation equipped him with the desire to extend the work and materialize the current manuscript. Hence, the author is indebted to the editorial team of Springer Series on Naval Architecture, Marine Engineering, Shipbuilding and Shipping, Prof. Nikolaos I. Xiros and Dr. Leontina Di Cecco for their favorable willingness to welcome the book proposal as well as the meaningful guidance during the publication stage. Further, sincere thanks need to be given to Mr. Amer Badawi, Columbia Grain Inc., Ms. Susan Burns, Bunge Limited, Ms. Marion Danneboom, BayWa AG, Ms. Lori Haugh, Cargill Inc., Mr. Jean-Luc Renaudeau, Groupe Sica Atlantique and Preface xi Ms. Megan Sweet, The Vancouver Fraser Port Authority for prominently dealing with the author’s illustration inquiries, sharing the impressive as well as captivating images and granting permission to use the available material from their plentiful media resources. The author is grateful to Mr. Yoji Ito, Japan Ship Exporters’ Association, for providing the requested publication and Prof. Koichiro Tezuka, Nihon University, College of Economics for making available his conference paper. An honor-bound appreciation should be expressed to Mr. Lars Robert Pedersen, The Baltic and International Maritime Council, who despite his tight schedule, accepted the invitation and provided the priceless foreword, which would have not been feasible without Dr. Martin Stopford’s lambent help, Clarkson Research Services Limited. The e-mail correspondence of Mr. Randy Cartmill, Terminal 5 Portland OR, Ms. Alexandra Morgano, Groupe Sica Atlantique and Mrs. Elizabeth Ahlefeldt-Laurvig-Lehn, The Baltic and International Maritime Council is greatly recognized. The indispensable morale support and encouragement from the author’s parents is deeply appreciated. The opinions and beliefs communicated in this book are those of the author and should not be interpreted to reflect the views of his current employer DNV GL AS, any governmental agency, industry association, as well as the acknowledged individuals with their referred organizations. Sandvika, Norway August 2016 George Adamantios Psarros Contents Part I Prologue . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3 3 4 5 5 6 8 2 Literature Review . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2.1 Preamble . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2.2 Design Energy Efficiency Improvements . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2.2.1 Design Energy Efficiency Specification . . . . . . . . . . . . 2.3 Types of Charter Party Agreements . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 2.4 Barriers on Implementing the Design Energy Efficiency Improvements . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 13 13 13 15 17 .... 19 3 Methodology . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3.1 Preamble . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 3.2 Research Design . . . . . . . . . . 3.2.1 Research Method . . . . . . . 23 23 23 27 1 Introduction . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1.1 Preamble . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1.2 Design Energy Efficiency Contracting in Charter Parties . . . . 1.3 Outline of the Book . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1.3.1 Aim and Objectives. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1.3.2 Research Design and Methodology . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 1.3.3 Skeleton of the Book . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Part II Qualitative Part . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . xiii xiv Contents 4 Analysis and Findings . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4.1 Preamble . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4.2 Initial Coding: Themes, Properties and Dimensions . . . . . . . . . . . . 4.2.1 Themes: Time and Voyage Charters . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4.2.2 Properties: Rights and Responsibilities (Obligations) of Shippers or Charterers and Carriers or Ship-Owners . . . . 4.2.3 Dimensions: Breaking Down Groupings Dealing with the Vessel . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4.3 Theory Building: Balancing the Interests for Design Energy Efficiency Improvements. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4.4 Focused Coding: Content Analysis of Charter Party Contracts . . . . 4.4.1 Information Sources . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4.4.2 Content Analysis . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 4.5 Revisiting the Theory from the Initial Coding . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Part III 31 31 32 32 32 34 36 38 38 39 44 Quantitative Part 5 Chartering Negotiations for Energy Efficiency . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5.1 Preamble . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5.2 Theoretical Applications of Games Within Chartering . . . . . . 5.3 Game Theory Model for Sharing Scheme Determination . . . . 5.3.1 Principal—Agent Part . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5.3.2 Bargaining Part . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5.4 Energy Efficiency Investment Appraisal . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 5.5 Conceptualizing the Generated Knowledge . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 49 49 50 51 53 57 59 63 6 Application—Ocean Grain Transportation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6.1 Preamble . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6.2 Trading Grains by Sea . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6.3 Dealing with the Inherent Uncertainties . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6.3.1 Parameter Uncertainties . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6.3.2 Uncertainty Propagation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6.3.3 Parameter Significance of Choice . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6.4 Energy Efficiency Sharing Scheme for Handymax Vessel . . . 6.4.1 Time Charter . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6.4.2 Voyage Charter . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6.4.3 Time Charter Trip . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6.5 Energy Efficiency Sharing Scheme for Panamax Vessel . . . . . 6.5.1 Time Charter . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6.5.2 Voyage Charter . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6.5.3 Time Charter Trip . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 6.6 Commenting Remarks . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 65 65 66 72 72 73 73 74 74 77 83 86 86 89 94 98 Contents Part IV xv Epilogue 7 Conclusions, Limitations and Recommendations. . . . 7.1 Preamble . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7.2 Conclusions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 7.3 Limitations and Suggestions for Further Research 7.4 Recommendations . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 103 103 104 106 108 Appendix A: Generic Bulk Carrier Designs . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 111 Appendix B: Parametric Distribution Fitting to Observed Data . . . . . . . 113 Appendix C: Monte Carlo Simulation . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 115 Appendix D: Parameter Change Interval . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 117 Appendix E: Assigned Parametric Distributions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 119 Appendix F: Simulated Variables . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 121 Appendix G: Milestones of the Book . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 151 Glossary . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 153 References . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 161 Index . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 173 Abbreviations B BIMCO CAPEX CAPM CIHEAM COGSA CRSL ECA(s) EEDI EEISS GHG IACS IEA IEEC IMO JSEA LIBOR L MARPOL MEPC NPV OECD OPEX PTC RFR SEEMP T Vessel’s Length Baltic and International Maritime Council Capital Expenditure Capital Asset Pricing Model Centre International de Hautes Études Agronomiques Méditerranéennes Carriage of Goods by Sea Act Clarkson Research Services Limited Emission Control Area(s) Energy Efficiency Design Index Energy Efficiency Investment Sharing Scheme Green House Gases International Association of Classification Societies International Energy Agency International Energy Efficiency Certificate International Maritime Organization Japan Ship Exporters’ Association London Inter Bank Offered Rate Vessel’s Length International Convention for the Prevention of Pollution from Ships Marine Environment Protection Committee Net Present Value Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development Operating Expenditure Parametric Technology Corporation Required Freight Rate Ship Energy Efficiency Management Plan Vessel’s Draught xvii xviii UNCTAD VC WACC WESTAC Abbreviations United Nations Conference on Trade and Development Voyage Cost Weighted Average Cost of Capital Western Transportation Advisory Council List of Figures Figure 3.1 Figure 3.2 Figure 5.1 Figure 5.2 Figure 5.3 Figure 5.4 Figure 6.1 Figure 6.2 Simple schematic of the adopted sequential exploratory research design. Note the inductive element of theory creation from data and the iteration in the second stage for revisiting the theory. Source Author . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Simple schematic conceptualizing the principal stages of data collection, analysis and comparison. Note that the reciprocal arrows indicate the comparison element (triangulation) between initial and focused coding. Source Author . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Simple schematic illustrating the contract mechanism design for the EEISS. Source Author . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Simple diagram showing the game tree for the principal (B)—agent (S) problem of moral hazard with hidden action between a charterer/shipper B and a ship-owner/carrier S. Source Adapted by Author from Rasmusen (2007) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Simple diagram showing the game tree for the principal (B)—agent (S) problem of adverse selection with screening between a charterer/shipper B and a ship-owner/carrier S. Source Adapted by Author from Rasmusen (2007) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Simple diagram showing the game tree for bargaining between a charterer/shipper B and a ship-owner/carrier S with alternating offers and asymmetric impatience. Source Adapted by Author from Bierman and Fernandez (1998) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Time development of seaborne grain trades. Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016) and World Bank (2016) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . The structure of ocean grain trades. Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. 26 .. 28 .. 52 .. 53 .. 55 .. 58 .. 66 .. 67 xix xx Figure 6.3 Figure 6.4 Figure 6.5 Figure 6.6 Figure 6.7 Figure 6.8 Figure 6.9 Figure 6.10 Figure 6.11 Figure 6.12 Figure 6.13 Figure 6.14 Figure 6.15 Figure 6.16 Figure 6.17 Figure 6.18 Figure 6.19 Figure 6.20 List of Figures Elements of a generic grain logistics network. Source Author’s drawing based on Abis et al. (2014) and WESTAC (1998) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Loading and storage facilities at a grain export terminal with a bulk carrier berthed. Photo credit Courtesy of Bunge Limited . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Cargo hold being loaded and filled with grain by a loading spout. Photo credit Courtesy of Cargill Inc. . . Grain being discharged from a bulk carrier’s cargo hold. Photo credit Courtesy of BayWa AG . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Handymax bulk carrier berthed alongside a grain export terminal and being loaded. Photo credit Courtesy of Columbia Grain Inc. . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Panamax bulk carrier berthed alongside a grain export terminal and being loaded. Photo credit Courtesy of Groupe Sica Atlantique . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Handymax period rates cumulative probability curves. Source Plotted by Author . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Handymax voyage rates cumulative probability curves. Source Plotted by Author . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Handymax voyage rates cumulative probability curves (sensitivity analysis). Source Plotted by Author. . . . . . . . . . Handymax technology investment payback period cumulative probability curves for voyage contracts. Source Plotted by Author . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Handymax time charter trip rates cumulative probability curves. Source Plotted by Author . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Handymax technology investment payback period cumulative probability curves for time charter trip contracts. Source Plotted by Author . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Panamax voyage rates cumulative probability curves. Source Plotted by Author . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Panamax voyage rates cumulative probability curves (sensitivity analysis). Source Plotted by Author. . . . . . . . . . Panamax technology investment payback period cumulative probability curves for voyage contracts. Source Plotted by Author . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Panamax time charter trip rates cumulative probability curves. Source Plotted by Author . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Panamax time charter trip rates cumulative probability curves (sensitivity analysis). Source Plotted by Author . . . . Panamax technology investment payback period cumulative probability curves for time charter trip contracts. Source Plotted by Author . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. 68 .. 69 .. 70 .. 70 .. 71 .. 72 .. 76 .. 79 .. 82 .. 83 .. 84 .. 86 .. 91 .. 93 .. 94 .. 96 .. 97 .. 98 List of Figures Figure A.1 Figure A.2 Figure A.3 Figure F.1 Figure F.2 Figure F.3 Figure F.4 Figure F.5 Figure F.6 xxi Typical cargo hold configuration for a single skin bulk carrier. Note Drawing not in scale. Source Drawn by author and based on IACS (2007) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Generic views of a typical single skin handymax bulk carrier (50,000–65,000 DWT). Average dimensions (m): L × B × T: 200 × 32.26 × 12.9. Note Drawing not in scale. Source Drawn by author and based on JSEA (2016) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Generic views of a typical single skin panamax bulk carrier (70,000–85,000 DWT) Average dimensions (m): L × B × T: 227 × 32.26 × 14.1. Note Drawing not in scale. Source Drawn by author and based on JSEA (2016) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Histogram of effort level for handymax period contract (10,000 repetitions, average = 0.090, standard deviation = 0.242). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . Histogram of agent’s reservation price for handymax period contract (10,000 repetitions, average = 12,193, standard deviation = 3,852). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Histogram of depreciation for handymax vessel (10,000 repetitions, average = 0.064, standard deviation = 0.021). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . Histogram of handymax period surplus fraction for corn and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, principal: average = 0.785, standard deviation = 0.0595, agent: average = 0.215, standard deviation = 0.0602). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . Histogram of handymax equilibrium period contract for corn and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 11,434, standard deviation = 2,684). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Histogram of handymax period surplus fraction for corn and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, principal: average = 0.785, standard deviation = 0.0588, agent: average = 0.215, standard deviation = 0.0594). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . . . 111 . . 112 . . 112 . . 121 . . 122 . . 122 . . 122 . . 123 . . 123 xxii Figure F.7 Figure F.8 Figure F.9 Figure F.10 Figure F.11 Figure F.12 Figure F.13 List of Figures Histogram of handymax equilibrium period contract for corn and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 11,448, standard deviation = 2,670). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . Histogram of handymax period surplus fraction for wheat and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, principal: average = 0.787, standard deviation = 0.058, agent: average = 0.213, standard deviation = 0.0584). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Histogram of handymax equilibrium period contract for wheat and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 11,408, standard deviation = 2,667). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Histogram of handymax period surplus fraction for wheat and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, principal: average = 0.786, standard deviation = 0.0596, agent: average = 0.214, standard deviation = 0.059). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . Histogram of handymax equilibrium period contract for wheat and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 11,446, standard deviation = 2,665). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Histogram of capital cost (10,000 repetitions, average = 10.88, standard deviation = 0.545). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a), OECD (2016) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . Histogram of handymax minimum RFR for period contract and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 11,936, standard deviation = 1,423). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a, b) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 123 . . 124 . . 124 . . 124 . . 125 . . 125 . . 125 List of Figures Figure F.14 Histogram of handymax minimum RFR for period contract and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 12,693, standard deviation = 1,434). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a, b) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . Figure F.15 Histogram of environmental stewardship for handymax voyage contract and corn as cargo (10,000 repetitions, basic technology upgrade and low attribute: average = 0.0013, standard deviation = 0.0033, basic technology upgrade and high attribute: average = 0.0037, standard deviation = 0.0097, advanced technology upgrade and high attribute: average = 0.0033, standard deviation = 0.0113). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Figure F.16 Histogram of environmental stewardship for handymax voyage contract and wheat as cargo (10,000 repetitions, basic technology upgrade and low attribute: average = 0.0018, standard deviation = 0.0047, basic technology upgrade and high attribute: average = 0.0024, standard deviation = 0.0081, advanced technology upgrade and low attribute: average = 0.0019, standard deviation = 0.46, advanced technology upgrade and high attribute: average = 0.0027, standard deviation = 0.0087). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . Figure F.17 Histogram of agent’s reservation price for handymax corn voyage contract and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 38.65, standard deviation = 20.11). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Figure F.18 Histogram of agent’s reservation price for handymax corn voyage contract and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 38.61, standard deviation = 20.12). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . Figure F.19 Histogram of agent’s reservation price for handymax wheat voyage contract and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, Average = 38.43, standard deviation = 19.85). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the Excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . xxiii . . 126 . . 126 . . 127 . . 127 . . 127 . . 128 xxiv List of Figures Figure F.20 Histogram of agent’s reservation price for handymax wheat voyage contract and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 38.70, standard deviation = 20.36). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Figure F.21 Histogram of handymax voyage surplus fraction for corn and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, principal: average = 0.786, standard deviation = 0.0587, agent: average = 0.214, standard deviation = 0.0586). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . Figure F.22 Histogram of handymax equilibrium voyage contract for corn and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 38.42, standard deviation = 20.22). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . Figure F.23 Histogram of handymax voyage surplus fraction for corn and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, principal: average = 0.787, standard deviation = 0.0582, agent: average = 0.213, standard deviation = 0.059). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . Figure F.24 Histogram of handymax equilibrium voyage contract for corn and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 38.48, standard deviation = 20.59). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . Figure F.25 Histogram of handymax voyage surplus fraction for wheat and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, principal: average = 0.787, standard deviation = 0.0588, agent: average = 0.213, standard deviation = 0.0593). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Figure F.26 Histogram of handymax equilibrium voyage contract for wheat and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 38.41, standard deviation = 20.99). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 128 . . 128 . . 129 . . 129 . . 129 . . 130 . . 130 List of Figures Figure F.27 Histogram of handymax voyage surplus fraction for wheat and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, principal: average = 0.786, standard deviation = 0.0592, agent: average = 0.214, standard deviation = 0.0589). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Figure F.28 Histogram of handymax equilibrium voyage contract for wheat and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 38.52, standard deviation = 20.81). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Figure F.29 Histogram of handymax annual grain loadings for voyage contracts (10,000 repetitions, Min = 1, Max = 3). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . Figure F.30 Histogram of handymax spot duration (voyage and time charter trip contracts) (10,000 repetitions, average = 48, standard deviation = 24). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2015) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Figure F.31 Histogram of handymax voyage costs (10,000 repetitions, basic technology upgrade: average = 1.159, standard deviation = 0.94, advanced technology upgrade: average = 1.094, standard deviation = 0.87). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a, b) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Figure F.32 Histogram of handymax voyage RFR for basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 36.51, standard deviation = 5.26). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a, b) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Figure F.33 Histogram of handymax voyage RFR for advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 35.68, standard deviation = 5.02). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a, b) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Figure F.34 Histogram of handymax annual grain loadings for time charter trip contracts (10,000 repetitions, Min = 1, Max = 10). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . xxv . . 130 . . 131 . . 131 . . 131 . . 132 . . 132 . . 132 . . 133 xxvi List of Figures Figure F.35 Histogram of effort level for handymax time charter trip contract (10,000 repetitions, average = 0.128, standard deviation = 0.266). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Figure F.36 Histogram of agent’s reservation price for handymax time charter trip contract (10,000 repetitions, average = 15,478, standard deviation = 8,510). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Figure F.37 Histogram of handymax equilibrium time charter trip contract for corn and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 14,040, standard deviation = 6,829). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . Figure F.38 Histogram of handymax equilibrium time charter trip contract for corn and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 14,083, standard deviation = 6,925). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Figure F.39 Histogram of handymax equilibrium time charter trip contract for wheat and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 14,211, standard deviation = 6,854). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Figure F.40 Histogram of handymax equilibrium time charter trip contract for wheat and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 14,114, standard deviation = 6,904). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Figure F.41 Histogram of handymax RFR for time charter trip contract and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 11,534, standard deviation = 4,358). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a, b) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . Figure F.42 Histogram of handymax RFR for time charter trip contract and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 10,615, standard deviation = 3,162). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a, b) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 133 . . 133 . . 134 . . 134 . . 134 . . 135 . . 135 . . 135 List of Figures Figure F.43 Histogram of effort level for panamax period contract (10,000 repetitions, average = 0.096, standard deviation = 0.231). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Figure F.44 Histogram of agent’s reservation price for panamax period contract (10,000 repetitions, average = 10,541, standard deviation = 3,813). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Figure F.45 Histogram of panamax period surplus fraction for corn and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, principal: average = 0.833, standard deviation = 0.0352, agent: average = 0.167, standard deviation = 0.0354). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . Figure F.46 Histogram of panamax equilibrium period contract for corn and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 9,819, standard deviation = 2,798). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . Figure F.47 Histogram of panamax period surplus fraction for corn and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, principal: average = 0.832, standard deviation = 0.0350, agent: average = 0.168, standard deviation = 0.0355). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . Figure F.48 Histogram of panamax equilibrium period contract for corn and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 9,807, standard deviation = 2,812). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . Figure F.49 Histogram of panamax period surplus fraction for wheat and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, principal: average = 0.833, standard deviation = 0.0350, agent: average = 0.167, standard deviation = 0.0353). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . Figure F.50 Histogram of panamax equilibrium period contract for wheat and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 9,803, standard deviation = 2,812). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . xxvii . . 136 . . 136 . . 136 . . 137 . . 137 . . 137 . . 138 . . 138 xxviii List of Figures Figure F.51 Histogram of panamax period surplus fraction for wheat and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, principal: average = 0.834, standard deviation = 0.0350, agent: average = 0.166, standard deviation = 0.0353). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . Figure F.52 Histogram of panamax equilibrium period contract for wheat and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 9,826, standard deviation = 2,790). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . Figure F.53 Histogram of panamax minimum RFR for period contract and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 14,803, standard deviation = 3,406). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a, b) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . Figure F.54 Histogram of panamax minimum RFR for period contract and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 16,529, standard deviation = 3,821). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a, b) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . Figure F.55 Histogram of environmental stewardship for panamax voyage contract and corn as cargo (10,000 repetitions, basic technology upgrade and low attribute: average = 0.0027, standard deviation = 0.0049, basic technology upgrade and high attribute: average = 0.0020, standard deviation = 0.0031, advanced technology upgrade and high attribute: average = 0.0021, standard deviation = 0.0053). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Figure F.56 Histogram of environmental stewardship for panamax voyage contract and wheat as cargo (10,000 repetitions, basic technology upgrade and low attribute: average = 0.0010, standard deviation = 0.0020, basic technology upgrade and high attribute: average = 0.0012, standard deviation = 0.0024, advanced technology upgrade and high attribute: average = 0.0021, standard deviation = 0.0030). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 138 . . 139 . . 139 . . 139 . . 140 . . 140 List of Figures Figure F.57 Histogram of agent’s reservation price for panamax corn voyage contract and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 34.32, standard deviation = 16.44). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Figure F.58 Histogram of agent’s reservation price for panamax corn voyage contract and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 34.33, standard deviation = 16.87). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Figure F.59 Histogram of agent’s reservation price for panamax wheat voyage contract and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 34.52, standard deviation = 16.63). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Figure F.60 Histogram of agent’s reservation price for panamax wheat voyage contract and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 34.61, standard deviation = 16.71). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Figure F.61 Histogram of panamax voyage surplus fraction for corn and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, principal: average = 0.832, standard deviation = 0.0352, agent: average = 0.168, standard deviation = 0.0351). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . Figure F.62 Histogram of panamax equilibrium voyage contract for corn and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 34.30, standard deviation = 16.58). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . Figure F.63 Histogram of panamax voyage surplus fraction for corn and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, principal: average = 0.831, standard deviation = 0.0351, agent: average = 0.169, standard deviation = 0.0353). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the Excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . xxix . . 140 . . 141 . . 141 . . 141 . . 142 . . 142 . . 142 xxx List of Figures Figure F.64 Histogram of panamax equilibrium voyage contract for corn and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 34.32, standard deviation = 16.85). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . Figure F.65 Histogram of panamax voyage surplus fraction for wheat and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, principal: average = 0.833, standard deviation = 0.0349, agent: average = 0.167, standard deviation = 0.0351). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . Figure F.66 Histogram of panamax equilibrium voyage contract for wheat and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 34.31, standard deviation = 16.58). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . Figure F.67 Histogram of panamax voyage surplus fraction for wheat and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, principal: average = 0.833, standard deviation = 0.0352, agent: average = 0.167, standard deviation = 0.035). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Figure F.68 Histogram of panamax equilibrium voyage contract for wheat and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 34.36, standard deviation = 16.91). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Figure F.69 Histogram of panamax annual grain loadings for voyage contracts (10,000 repetitions, Min = 1, Max = 4). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . Figure F.70 Histogram of panamax spot duration (voyage and time charter trip contracts) (10,000 repetitions, average = 53, standard deviation = 14). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2015) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Figure F.71 Histogram of panamax voyage costs (10,000 repetitions, basic technology upgrade: average = 1.371, standard deviation = 0.879, advanced technology upgrade: average = 1.296, standard deviation = 0.827). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a, b) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . . . 143 . . 143 . . 143 . . 144 . . 144 . . 144 . . 145 . . 145 List of Figures Figure F.72 Histogram of panamax voyage RFR for basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 34.59, standard deviation = 6.55). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a, b) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006). . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Figure F.73 Histogram of panamax voyage RFR for advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 33.67, standard deviation = 6.08). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a, b) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Figure F.74 Histogram of panamax annual grain loadings for time charter trip contracts (10,000 repetitions, Min = 1, Max = 6). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . Figure F.75 Histogram of effort level for panamax time charter trip contract (10,000 repetitions, average = 0.110, standard deviation = 0.284). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Figure F.76 Histogram of agent’s reservation price for panamax time charter trip contract (10,000 repetitions, average = 13,390, standard deviation = 9,554). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Figure F.77 Histogram of panamax equilibrium time charter trip contract for corn and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 12,300, standard deviation = 7,795). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Figure F.78 Histogram of panamax equilibrium time charter trip contract for corn and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 12,361, standard deviation = 7,865). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . Figure F.79 Histogram of panamax equilibrium time charter trip contract for wheat and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 12,266, standard deviation = 7,822). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . Figure F.80 Histogram of panamax equilibrium time charter trip contract for wheat and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 12,341, standard deviation = 7,883). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . xxxi . . 145 . . 146 . . 146 . . 146 . . 147 . . 147 . . 147 . . 148 . . 148 xxxii List of Figures Figure F.81 Histogram of panamax RFR for time charter trip contract and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 11,489, standard deviation = 2,394). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a, b) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . 148 Figure F.82 Histogram of panamax RFR for time charter trip contract and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 11,924, standard deviation = 2,589). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a, b) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) . . . . . . . 149 List of Tables Table 2.1 Table 2.2 Table 4.1 Table 4.2 Table 4.3 Table 4.4 Table 4.5 Table 6.1 Table 6.2 Table 6.3 Table 6.4 Table 6.5 Table 6.6 Table 6.7 Table 6.8 Table 6.9 Upper bound of the fuel savings that may result from the implementation of different measures . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Allocation of costs and responsibilities under voyage and time charters . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Examples of defects in the technical condition of a vessel or her equipment rendering her unseaworthy . . . . . . . . . . . . Standardized charter party forms to be surveyed . . . . . . . . . . List of common Clauses contained in the standard charter party forms . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Coding sub categories for vessel energy efficiency in time charter parties . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Coding sub categories for vessel energy efficiency in voyage charter parties . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Surplus fractions and equilibrium prices for handymax period contracts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Parameters for evaluating the significance of change for handymax period contracts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Surplus fractions and equilibrium prices for handymax period contracts (sensitivity analysis) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Agent’s preference characteristics and reservation prices for handymax voyage contracts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Surplus fractions and equilibrium prices for handymax voyage contracts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Parameters for evaluating the significance of change for handymax voyage contracts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Agent’s preference characteristics and reservation prices for handymax voyage contracts (sensitivity analysis) . . . . . . Surplus fractions and equilibrium prices for handymax voyage contracts (sensitivity analysis) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Surplus fractions and equilibrium prices for handymax time charter trips . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. 16 .. 18 .. .. 35 40 .. 41 .. 42 .. 43 .. 75 .. 76 .. 77 .. 78 .. 78 .. 80 .. 81 .. 81 .. 84 xxxiii xxxiv List of Tables Table 6.10 Parameters for evaluating the significance of change for handymax time charter trip contracts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Table 6.11 Surplus fractions and equilibrium prices for handymax time charter trip contracts (sensitivity analysis) . . . . . . . . . . . Table 6.12 Surplus fractions and equilibrium prices for panamax period contracts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Table 6.13 Parameters for evaluating the significance of change for panamax period contracts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Table 6.14 Surplus fractions and equilibrium prices for panamax period contracts (sensitivity analysis) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Table 6.15 Agent’s preference characteristics and reservation prices for panamax voyage contracts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Table 6.16 Surplus fractions and equilibrium prices for panamax voyage contracts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Table 6.17 Parameters for evaluating the significance of change for panamax voyage contracts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Table 6.18 Agent’s preference characteristics and reservation prices for panamax voyage contracts (sensitivity analysis) . . . . . . . Table 6.19 Surplus fractions and equilibrium prices for panamax voyage contracts (sensitivity analysis) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Table 6.20 Surplus fractions and equilibrium prices for panamax time charter trip contracts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Table 6.21 Parameters for evaluating the significance of change for panamax time charter trip contracts . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Table 6.22 Surplus fractions and equilibrium prices for panamax time charter trip contracts (sensitivity analysis) . . . . . . . . . . . Table 6.23 Summary of results from the game theoretical analysis (average values) . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Table E.1 Input data for entertaining the probabilistic models . . . . . . . . Table E.2 Legend—explanations for the parameters of the statistical distributions . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . Table G.3 Work plan . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . . .. 85 .. 85 .. 87 .. 88 .. 88 .. 89 .. 90 .. 92 .. 92 .. 92 .. 95 .. 96 .. 97 .. 99 . . 119 . . 120 . . 151 Executive Summary Regulatory imperatives stipulate that shipping needs to improve its environmental performance and the agreed framework for reducing its air emissions is composed of three pillars. The first pillar contains operational measures, such as slow steaming, propeller and hull cleaning, weather routing and voyage planning, etc. The second pillar includes design measures, such as air lubrication, bulbous bow, waste heat recovery, hull optimization, propeller nozzles, diesel-electric drives, counter-rotating propellers, etc. The third pillar refers to market based measures, such as emissions trading scheme and a levy/fuel charge. It is recognized that the first two pillars offer greater flexibility since the industrial players are free to select the optimum combination of measures. Ultimately, a long-term solution is attained through the improvement of the vessel’s design energy efficiency. Accepting that any new technology to be installed on-board a vessel encompasses uncertainty with respect to its energy saving potential, certain mechanisms are deemed appropriate for inducing confidence and facilitating wider application of energy saving technologies. A relevant mechanism that can foster on the ability to systematically address energy efficiency could be facilitated within the contractual structure of the charter party agreement. This book is an attempt to explore this call and to provide supporting premise for putting money into the most energy efficient vessel, rather than giving merit to the standard design. Such provision holds implications on the manner that chartering practice has traditionally been arranged. First, the expectations and interests of the parties involved in investing in energy efficient equipment need to be identified. Second, greater emphasis on monitoring as well as on verifying the vessel’s efficiency is given. Third, any potential conflicting issues with respect to the freight rate negotiation have to be clarified. To this end, the current book is focused on the contractual considerations associated with design energy efficiency improvements without taking into account the technical aspects of the energy efficient technology investments. Thus, having set the background of the subject available in the published literature, the aim of the present book is to construct a theoretical proposition on incorporating design energy efficiency improvements in charter party contracts. xxxv xxxvi Executive Summary Essential element for shedding light on this topic is the observation of commercial contracts for the use of the vessel as well as legal instruments for the carriage of goods by sea. To the author’s best effort and belief, this book has effectively addressed the following qualitative research objectives: • Examine if the legal instruments permit the inclusion of clauses into the existing charter party contracts that can clarify the investment responsibility and obligation of design energy efficiency improvements; • Identify if any clauses included in the charter party contracts are accounting for design energy efficiency improvements; • Determine which vessel design parameters incorporated in the charter party contract clauses are associated with the topic under investigation; • Propose any amendments or additions to the relevant charter party contract clauses that could contain the vessel’s energy efficiency specification; Furthermore, the following quantitative research objectives have been prominently tackled: • Suggest a mechanism design of the energy efficiency sharing scheme and its connection to the chartering procedure; • Demonstrate the practicality of the designed mechanism within the dry bulk shipping sector and a specific commodity. The book’s qualitative research objectives are met by adopting a qualitative, inductive and exploratory approach where coherence is achieved through the grounded theory method, a formalized strategy to collect and analyze data (observed premises) which is composed of two sequential stages. The process begins first with the initial coding (first stage) of legal instruments on the carriage of goods by sea. The purpose of this activity is to investigate if it is permitted to regulate the rights and responsibilities of design energy efficiency improvements. In addition, it seeks to identify any wedge for incorporating such term in the charter party contract through the relevant academic literature. Second, the analysis of the relationship of the contracted parties with respect to energy efficiency specification clauses indicates the type of cases (voyage and time charters) to select for further data collection. Consequently, since the research is concentrated around these two types of contracts, the focused coding (second stage) is supported by sufficient sampling of the standard agreement forms. In this stage, content analysis is employed for uncovering themes within the clauses by objectively and systematically searching for certain subjects within the text (i.e., energy efficiency specification). Furthermore, it is determined which themes are associated with the vessel’s design parameters. This process continues until additional data collation does not contribute to the coding of the topic under investigation and any new theoretical lines of enquiry are not possible to be offered. The latter are reflected by proposing any amendments or additions to the relevant themes (charter party contract clauses) that could contain the vessel’s energy efficiency specification. Delving into the quantitative research objectives, game theory is chosen to model the interplay dynamics of the chartering negotiations between a shipowner Executive Summary xxxvii (carrier) and a charterer (shipper). Hence, the game participants are two. Depending on the type of contract (voyage and time charter), game theory can be adjusted to appropriately represent the incentive mixture for energy efficiency (mechanism design). The process is composed of two stages. First, the principal–agent problem is utilized for determining the difference between the two players’ reservation prices (hire for time and freight for voyage charter) as well as their information asymmetry related to energy efficiency. This forms the basis where the negotiations can begin. Second, the two players are given the opportunity to split the difference between them with alternating offers which resembles a bargaining game and results to the contracted price. Then, for the given vessel revenue performance, discounted cash flow analysis is performed to investigate whether the EEISS is profitable and the expense can be justified. Tantamount to proving the practical validity of the outlined mathematical concepts, an illustrative case study contributes to their clear demonstration. The working example is focused on seaborne grain transport since it is acknowledged that grain is one of the most important commodities around the world for human as well as animal feed. Briefly, the work reported in this book points out that the current legal instruments do not inhibit any constraint for including a rider-clause related to design energy efficiency improvements within the charter party contracts. Furthermore, the time and voyage charter party contracts content analysis indicates that reference to design energy efficiency improvements is not made explicit, whereas they are indirectly linked to the vessel’s performance (fuel consumption) which is emphasized only on the former. The quantitative analysis results and through the case study within the grain ocean transportation, show that the mechanism design endorses strongly the time charter rather than the voyage contracts. This finding is attributed to the latter contract’s functionality, i.e., transport is bought on a lump sum basis covering all the incurred costs. Additionally, given the current dry bulk (grain) freight market conditions and a fixed investment horizon (15 years), only the basic technology expenditure ($1.5 million) for the smaller vessels (handymax) can be recovered. Most notably, the models presented in this book need to be populated when the market conditions improve, so that new areas of thought and investigation are revealed. In the best sense, it is expected that by encouraging the incorporation of a standard rider-clause related to the vessel’s design energy efficiency specification, the responsibility between the involved parties for a sustainable supply chain will be clarified. Remarkably, an incentive will be created for implementing and investing in design energy efficiency improvements in both time as well as voyage charters. Part I Prologue Chapter 1 Introduction Abstract In addition to regulatory compliance and to irradiate environmental stewardship across the maritime industry, appropriate mechanisms need to be in place so that the ocean freight service is delivered in an energy efficient manner. This chapter is aimed at explaining the book’s motivation, the adopted research approach which is distinguished between qualitative as well as quantitative, and it offers an outline of the embodied content. 1.1 Preamble Although shipping is considered to be a small contributor to atmospheric emissions— approximately 3.1–2.8% of annual global CO2 and GHG respectively, Smith et al. (2014)—in comparison to other transportation modes and public utilities such as power stations, due to more stringent regulatory requirements its environmental performance needs to be improved (IMO 2012c). Albeit to the expected growth of world economy and associated transport demand, in the long term, it is made clear that shipping should be engaged to a reduction target of at least 50% by 2050 compared to 2010 levels (Pachauri et al. 2014). This emissions’ reduction potential can be attained through a pathway consisting of three pillars, with an indicated value as estimated by Strand (2011). Accordingly, the first pillar is related to business as usual or operational efficiency improvements (i.e. slow steaming, propeller and hull cleaning, weather routing and voyage planning, etc.) leading to 14% decrease. The second one is associated with the introduction by IMO of the EEDI that encourages design improvements for new vessels (i.e. air lubrication, bulbous bow, waste heat recovery, hull optimization, propeller nozzles, diesel-electric drives, counter-rotating propellers, etc.) yielding 12% reduction. The third one corresponds to market based measures, it is currently under development and the discussions within IMO are concentrated on two aspects: emissions trading scheme and a levy (fuel charge) with anticipated outcome of 32%. The abatement of the remaining 43% emissions will depend on the impact of the successful implementation of the aforementioned measures (Strand 2011). © Springer International Publishing Switzerland 2017 G.A. Psarros, Energy Efficiency Clauses in Charter Party Agreements, Springer Series on Naval Architecture, Marine Engineering, Shipbuilding and Shipping 3, DOI 10.1007/978-3-319-50265-6_1 3 4 1.2 1 Introduction Design Energy Efficiency Contracting in Charter Parties The documents containing all the terms and conditions of the contract between a charterer or shipper and a ship-owner or carrier are defined as charter party agreements. These documents encompass various clauses setting out the rights and responsibilities of both parties in relation to freight or hire payment and contingencies for strikes, general, average and war. They also contain details such as amount of freight, lay time, demurrage, the vessel’s construction, speed and consumption, without any reference to the vessel’s energy efficiency specification (Brodie 2015; Gorton et al. 2009; Panayides 2014). In general, energy efficiency is associated with reduced fuel consumption for a vessel’s propulsion and power generation systems and this entails benefits for the company charged with the fuel bill (Psaraftis and Kontovas 2014). As long as the fuel efficiency is monitored and verified, the provision of evidence of compliance to the shipping emissions’ regulations adopted by IMO enhances the environmental friendly performance of the carriage of goods by sea and the supply chain to a larger degree (Lai et al. 2013; Azevedo et al. 2011). To obtain the energy efficiency gain, design alterations are required implying additional cost conferred on the ship-owner’s shoulder. However, the current contracts do not include any clauses for investing in energy efficient technologies and thus providing details on the vessel’s energy efficiency specification (Gorton et al. 2009), an incentive that could expedite the successful implementation of EEDI. To further reap the effectiveness of the global shipping community’s efforts for greener performance, it has been argued by Johnson and Andersson (2016) as well as Psarros and Mestl (2015) that the contractual structure of the charter party agreements should foster on the ability to systematically address energy efficiency. In this sense, supporting premise for investing into the most energy efficient vessel could be provided, rather than giving merit to the standard design. Moreover, the clauses included in the charter party agreements are associated with bunkers, performance, speed and consumption, but no reference to the energy efficiency specification of the vessel is made explicit (Hill 2003). Such provision could firstly identify the expectations of the parties involved in investing in energy efficient equipment. Secondly, it could give greater emphasis on monitoring and verifying the vessel’s efficiency. Thirdly, it could clarify any potential conflicting issues with respect to the freight rate negotiation. Indeed, it has been advocated by Lun et al. (2015) who were inspired by the contribution of Rai et al. (2012) on contractual flexibility, that contractual agreements specifying the vessel’s energy efficiency can become the core mechanism for enhancing environmental performance. In addition, the rights, duties and responsibilities between the business signatories can provide a mutual understanding of the common obligation for adopting greener shipping practices. Thus, the wider acceptance of energy efficiency clauses will strongly depend upon recognizing that such incentive is strongly connected with social corporate responsibility goals (Locke 1968). These elements are already embraced 1.2 Design Energy Efficiency … 5 to every organization’s strategic objectives and the possible adoption is anticipated to depend on how change processes are usually implemented, where the pattern could be either incremental (slow and steady) or abrupt (sudden and immediate) (Dacin et al. 2002). The inclusion of energy efficiency within the charter party agreements would be expected to entail compliance with environmental regulations (i.e. reduction of shipping emissions) and contribute to environmentally sustainable shipping operations (Lun et al. 2015). Unfortunately, detailed research on this aspect is rather limited, with the exemption of the studies by Lindholm (2014) as well as Rehmatulla and Smith (2015a), where operational efficiency improvements have been investigated. It has been argued in their work that the clauses for operational efficiency (i.e. “slow steaming”, “virtual arrival”) have been drafted mainly for resolving the uncertainties regarding the goal of delivery (cargo/vessel) in each voyage leg. Moreover, these clauses are not concentrated on the implementation effectiveness of speed reduction as a measure for dealing with the shipping emissions’ issue. However, touching the rigidity and incompleteness of charter party agreements with respect to design efficiency improvements is a topic that has not attracted research interest so far. Therefore, the current book attempts to propose any necessary changes or additions to the relevant clauses so that energy efficiency is adequately addressed from a design point of view. 1.3 Outline of the Book The project work conducted in the present book is focused on the contractual considerations associated with design energy efficiency improvements without taking into account the technical aspects of the energy efficient technology investments. In the following subsections, the statements that the research sets out to achieve are mentioned together with the project’s main beneficiaries. Furthermore, details on the research design and the type of data used are also included and finally the project’s structure is offered. 1.3.1 Aim and Objectives The aim of the work reported herein is to investigate whether the aspect of design energy efficiency improvements is made explicit in the charter party agreements. Additionally, the means that would clarify the investment responsibility between the involved parties are explored besides with the proposition of a suitable incentive mechanism. In this context, the objectives of the proposed research can be distinguished into qualitative and quantitative. The qualitative research objectives can be underlined as follows: 6 1 Introduction • Examine if the legal instruments permit the inclusion of clauses into the existing charter party contracts that can clarify the investment responsibility and obligation of design energy efficiency improvements; • Identify if any clauses included in the charter party contracts are accounting for design energy efficiency improvements; • Determine which vessel design parameters incorporated in the charter party contract clauses are associated with the topic under investigation; • Propose any amendments or additions to the relevant charter party contract clauses that could contain the vessel’s energy efficiency specification (design energy efficiency improvements); Furthermore, the quantitative research objectives can be accentuated along the following: • Suggest a mechanism design of the energy efficiency sharing scheme and its connection to the chartering procedure; • Demonstrate the practicality of the designed mechanism within the dry bulk shipping sector and a specific commodity. 1.3.2 Research Design and Methodology As mentioned already in the previous subsections, the proposed topic has not been touched upon and therefore exploratory research is utilized in the current book. This means that an inductive approach is adopted due to the lack of published research and lack of knowledge with the purpose to develop a better insight into the aforementioned qualitative research objectives (Wilson 2014). In addition, the study is largely qualitative since the intent is to explore the complex set of factors surrounding the proposed topic and present the varied beneficiaries perspectives (charterer or shipper and ship-owner or carrier). Thus, the literature is used to frame the problem (i.e. contractual considerations associated with design energy efficiency improvements) and to understand the beneficiaries’ relationship (i.e. their responsibilities and obligations) (Creswell 2009; Saunders et al. 2012). The problem’s theoretical ideas are emerged out of the collection and analysis of data, frequently cited as grounded theory method. The purpose of utilizing the grounded theory method is based on the fact that the process is comprised of two sequential stages. Firstly, the initial coding with reference to the legal regimes for the carriage of goods by sea is intended to explore and generate properties as well as dimensions related to design energy efficiency improvements. In this respect, the first research objective of examining if the legal instruments permit the inclusion of clauses into the existing charter party contracts that can clarify the investment responsibility and obligation of design energy efficiency improvements is met. Whilst, the second stage known as focused coding, builds on the first stage findings and through the analysis of the standard (generic) charter party forms available from the website of BIMCO. Hence, the previous set of findings is not only 1.3 Outline of the Book 7 complemented, but also expanded (i.e. identifying if any clauses included in the charter party forms are accounting for design energy efficiency improvements and determining which vessel design parameters incorporated in the charter party clauses are associated with design energy efficiency improvements). At this point, the course of the study has demonstrated that the second and third objectives have been achieved. For the latter stage, content analysis of the contracts is employed as a technique for identifying subjects, terms as well as attributes within the contract clauses and seeking contrasts under certain data component parts (i.e. vessel description) from which a theoretical elaboration can begin to emerge. The resulting theory for the work conducted in this book is the fourth research objective, the proposal of any amendments or additions to the relevant charter party contract clauses that could contain the vessel’s energy efficiency specification. This operation continues until a point is reached where the collation of new data no further illuminates any theoretical concept and has been supported by the combination of the findings of the two stages (initial and focused coding), giving harmonizing strength of the result (Bryman 2012). Having set the theoretical foundation of elaborating clauses related to the vessel’s energy efficiency specification within the charter party agreements, the reader is now prepared to tackle the quantitative research objectives utilizing game theory as the main tool. It is noted that this book is not intended to exhaust all possible contributions that have ripened within the scientific domain of game theory. Instead, the goal is to provide initial clues of designing an incentive mechanism (an area which has thrived in the context of game theory) and offer its methodological adaptation to chartering negotiations. Initially, the analysis is focused on aligning the shipper’s (charterer’s or principal’s) profit maximization objectives when delegating the task of ocean transportation to a carrier (ship-owner or agent). The agent possesses information (i.e. vessel’s energy efficiency) that either their actions can be unobserved by the principal (moral hazard), or their valuation can be ignored by the principal (adverse selection). The former situation resembles the time charter, whilst the latter reminds the voyage charter contract. These information problems impose costs to the principal, so that the informed agent is motivated to reveal as well as credibly communicate their private knowledge and an efficient contract is designed. Hence, the incentive mechanism is aimed at defining the principal’s desirable allocative expenses that need to be implemented in order to diminish the impact of information costs (Laffont and Martimort 2002). Consequently, with the preferences between the principal and the agent being assigned, it is inescapable to establish how the two parties could possibly cooperate under favorable terms. The negotiation process involves a series of alternating offers between the bargainers who are concerned about the time at which an agreement is reached. This entails that delay costs are incurred by both players. The player with the longest patience to conclude the negotiation and complete the vessel’s fixture is understood to enjoy the strongest bargaining power. As a result, the gains from the cooperation are divided between the players in a share equivalent to their bargaining power (Osborne and Rubinstein 1990). The numerical solutions 8 1 Introduction to the adapted game models originate from CRSL fixtures sample which contains data associated with freight, cargo type and quantity, as well as hire rate and period. Given the fact that the literature on the addressed issue is non-existent (the inclusion of energy efficiency specification clauses in charter party contracts) and although no conclusive answers will be provided, at least some direction for further research can be drawn. Furthermore, it is expected that the conducted work in this book is accurate enough and the material presented herein is supported by multiple sources of evidence/references, hence the reader will be convinced for its scientific merit (Wilson 2014). Indeed, Sugden (2011) states that for any sequence of actual observations of the real world, there is infinity of different patterns where that sequence fits. Then, inductive inferences can be grounded albeit to prior selection of a small subset of patterns which are conforming to prior expectations about the world and its regularities (i.e. environmental performance). In turn, this implies that despite the fact that very little is known or understood about the mechanism for projecting this pattern, reasonable confidence has been built from what has been already observed (Sugden 2011). 1.3.3 Skeleton of the Book The current work is divided into seven chapters, which are structured as follows: the first chapter, Introduction, sets the landscape for the topic under investigation (design energy efficiency improvements) and addresses the motivation to conduct the research study (environmental awareness and regulatory compliance). In addition, it presents the aim as well as objectives of the study and gives an overview of the selected research design together with the corresponding research method. The first part of the book forms the qualitative section (Chaps. 2 through 4), and expose the reader to the qualitative study. There, the intent is to exhibit the principles that allow the elaboration of energy efficiency specification clauses within the charter party agreements. As a start, the second chapter, Literature review, is devoted to present the connection of design energy efficiency improvements to the maritime regulatory framework. Then, the types of charter party agreements that are commonly used within shipping are described, the parties’ duties are outlined and a short discussion on the barriers that could inhibit the introduction of the vessel’s design energy efficiency improvements follows. In the third chapter of the present work, Methodology, the framework of the conducted research is described, where essential element is the grounded theory method. Grounded theory is a formalized strategy to collect and analyze data (observed premises) which enables to answer the particular research questions and meet the study’s objective. This entails that a qualitative inductive and exploratory approach is adopted for seeking a theoretical generalization in a sense that there is a gap in supporting the logic argument for including the element of design energy efficiency improvements in the charter party agreements. Furthermore, the methods for data collation and analysis are explained, followed by arguments and evidence 1.3 Outline of the Book 9 embracing their choice. Nevertheless, despite the fact that the study is based on desk research, the findings are emerging from two sequential stages which not only complement each other, but also strengthen their validity. The fourth chapter, Analysis and findings, is concerned with presenting how the application of the grounded theory method is carried out. For the first stage, the analysis and its results are grounded on the initial coding of the legal instruments on the carriage of goods by sea in order to categorize dimensions as well as properties relevant for design energy efficiency improvements. Additionally, it seeks to identify if it is permitted to regulate the rights and responsibilities of design energy efficiency improvements. This formulation sets the premise for the second stage, which is the content analysis of the existing standard charter party contract forms. In a nutshell, the sequential work intends to determine any clauses associated with design energy efficiency improvements and propose any revisions that could incorporate the vessel’s energy efficiency specification. The second part of the book constitutes the quantitative section (Chaps. 5 and 6) which drives the reader to the quantitative study. Essentially, the effort is put towards designing an incentive mechanism for energy efficiency and testing its profundity through a case. The core ingredients of the mechanism are revealed at chapter five, Chartering negotiations for energy efficiency, which consist of the principal-agent and bargaining models, together with investment appraisal techniques. The mathematical expressions are kept as simple as possible, so that the reader does not have to invoke any advanced game theory as well as economic and financial concepts. Yet, to the author’s best knowledge, the synthesis is sufficiently powerful that clearly demonstrates how the existing chartering practice can be revolutionized. In Chap. 6, Application to ocean grain transportation, the reader is invited to navigate with data through the repertoire of approaches outlined in the previous chapter. The integration of such insight streams from the exhibited material is so immanent, that any residual hesitation on the successful implementation of the proposed incentive mechanism would have been removed. This achievement is translated into a satisfaction for retaining the book’s targeted and promised research objectives. The last chapter, Conclusions, limitations and recommendations, is dedicated for concluding the performed work, addressing suggestions for further research and making recommendations drawn upon the second chapter’s literature review. Ultimately, it should be stressed that while the book concludes, the presented topics have been investigated with a humble perception. At the same time, the matter should not be interpreted as complete or final and undoubtedly is open to improvement. Supplementary material supporting the quantitative section is contained in the Appendices. Part II Qualitative Part Chapter 2 Literature Review Abstract In the book’s second chapter, a background related to design energy efficiency improvements and their connection to the maritime regulatory framework is presented. Consequently, a subsection is devoted to the types of charter party agreements that are commonly used within shipping and a brief on the parties’ duties is provided. Then, a short discussion on the barriers that could inhibit the introduction of the design energy efficiency improvements is given. 2.1 Preamble Although the energy saving potential of new technologies would be higher than the one offered by existing ones, the substitution of the latter by the former could be delayed albeit to proven results. The adoption of new energy efficient technologies is followed by further competence building entailing that previous expertise becomes obsolete and familiarization efforts are required (Mulder 2005). Moreover, the acceptance of new technologies is governed by each user’s risk perception on performance. These obstacles could be overwhelmed when the regulations are shaped towards addressing not only safety, security and environmental protection standards, but also nurturing innovation, growth and advancement needs (Herzenstein et al. 2007). 2.2 Design Energy Efficiency Improvements In response to tackling the climate change in maritime transport, amendments to the MARPOL Convention were adopted in July 2011 and were entered into force in January 2013. To this end, a new chapter containing regulations aimed at improving the energy efficiency of vessels was added on Annex VI, the dedicated part of the Convention related to the prevention of air pollution from vessels. These changes made mandatory the introduction of the EEDI for new vessels which is concerned © Springer International Publishing Switzerland 2017 G.A. Psarros, Energy Efficiency Clauses in Charter Party Agreements, Springer Series on Naval Architecture, Marine Engineering, Shipbuilding and Shipping 3, DOI 10.1007/978-3-319-50265-6_2 13 14 2 Literature Review with design improvements. Furthermore, they stipulated the establishment of a mechanism for all vessels (SEEMP) in order to use operating measures that improve the energy efficiency of the vessel and requirements for survey and certification, including the format for IEEC (IMO 2012a). During the EEDI’s development, conducted research (Kristensen and Lützen 2012; Ozaki et al. 2010) was associated with this regulation’s thorough analysis and such technical detail will not be covered herein. The EEDI regulation is believed to be a proactive performance based mechanism designed to induce technical measures for improving the energy efficiency of vessels and represents an expression of CO2 emissions per ton-mile of transport work. Its non-prescriptive nature is attributed to the fact that the industry players are free to choose the optimum combination of energy saving technologies, as long as the required energy efficiency level is attained and compliance with the regulation is obtained (Otsubo 2015). In defense of this view, Chang (2012) and Smith (2012) concluded that for a long term solution to the issue of shipping emissions, the regulations need to address energy efficiency in the design of vessel engines and hulls. Besides, the effects of the application of the new technologies need to be taken into consideration without affecting basic vessel design parameters such as deadweight capacity and speed (Chang 2012; Smith 2012). Intuitively, these parameters are vessel and trade specific, thus embrace distinctive characteristics of an ocean freight service. Hence, through the EEDI, it should be attempted to thrust ship-owners to invest in vessels that have state of the art technologies for reducing fuel (energy) consumption and should not be interpreted to penalize vessels with higher installed power. Then, the operation of the vessel is affected by the SEEMP which supplements EEDI and impacts the fuel (energy) consumption (Stevens et al. 2015). Additionally, it is asserted that with the input of industrial stakeholders (equipment manufacturers, shipbuilders, ship-owners, verifiers, etc.), technology roadmaps for exploring potential benefits and challenges of radical new developments or retrofit options can be identified for different types of vessels (Gilbert 2014; Vergara et al. 2012). It is also recognized that such flexibility, sets the requirements and inherently specifications for future vessel designs albeit to the feedback from new vessels allowing a dynamic change on the required EEDI and thus stringent control (Ančić and Šestan 2015). The latter will be facilitated through the need to demonstrate the performance of each technology in terms of (reduced) energy usage for a given vessel under a range of operational scenarios and environmental conditions (Calleya et al. 2015). Further lines of argument have been urged by Devanney (2011) to design vessels that are capable of attaining the contracted speed (albeit to the allowable margin) during market peaks, including heavy weather and without reaching the engine’s limits in order to avoid any machinery failures. Reference is given to vessels with large propeller diameter (hence increased propulsion efficiency) due to a combination of large bore size (translated into higher power per cylinder), lower rotational speeds and greater fuel economy (Devanney 2011). 2.2 Design Energy Efficiency Improvements 2.2.1 15 Design Energy Efficiency Specification Energy efficient technologies concerned with the vessel’s design can be categorized depending on their characteristics and effects on EEDI, i.e. reduction of main engine and auxiliary power in terms of fuel consumption (IMO 2013): 1. Reduction of main engine power: • Cannot be separated from overall performance of the vessel; – – – – Low friction coating, Bare optimization, Rudder resistance, Propeller design. • Can be treated separately from the overall performance of the vessel; – Hull air lubrication system (an air carpet is created beneath the vessel’s hull via air injection to reduce frictional resistance—it can be switched-off), – Wind assistance (sails, Flettner Rotors, kites—subjected to wind condition). 2. Reduction of auxiliary power: • Effective at all time; – Waste heat recovery system (exhaust gas heat recovery and conversion to electric power). • Depending on ambient environment; – Photovoltaic cells. Although the reader may argue that the aforementioned technologies are farfetched, recent research in conjunction with simulated experiments as well as full scale trials provides evidence that some of them can be adopted in short term, while others need refinements and adjustment of production capacity to lower their costs. For instance, this is quite relevant for hull air lubrication where up to 13% of net energy savings have been recorded (Fukuda et al. 2000; Mizokami et al. 2013; Kawakita et al. 2015; Kumagai et al. 2015). However, a lower energy saving potential has been observed (4%) for other technical improvements such as propeller design and hull coating (Armstrong 2013). This result coincides with the duct (Kim et al. 2015) as well as rudder with bulb and fins appendages (Hai-long et al. 2016) predicted propulsive efficiency from simulated calculations. With respect to the other technologies, only desk studies have been published and it is worth pointing out the efforts of Fujiwara et al. (2005), Luyu et al. (2010), Traut et al. (2014), Viola et al. (2015) for wind assisted propulsion, Lindstad et al. (2013), Marzi and Gatchell (2012) for hull optimization, Livanos et al. (2014) for waste heat recovery and Glykas et al. (2010) for photovoltaic cells. 16 Table 2.1 Upper bound of the fuel savings that may result from the implementation of different measures 2 Literature Review Technology/design improvement Low friction coating Bare optimization Rudder resistance Propeller design Air lubrication Wind assistance Waste heat recovery Photovoltaic cells Source Fulton et al. (2009) Fuel efficiency gain (%) <5 <9 <4 <4 <15 <25 <10 <4 Description of the energy saving equipment is contained in the EEDI technical file, where the potential energy saving (i.e. reduced percentage of fuel consumption) is indicated for modifying the design of existing installations, replacing existing equipment or adding new equipment and modifying the operating conditions of an existing installation (IMO 2012b). Admittedly, it is challenging to track the energy saving potential and in the absence of any tangible results the following tentative values can be realized as shown in Table 2.1. It is claimed that when these measures are combined, an overall up to 20–30% reduction in CO2 emissions on average from the existing fleet can be anticipated (Fulton et al. 2009). It should be emphasized that this uncertainty nurtures the need for transparent monitoring of efficient vessel operations where the collation of real time data can be fed up into bottom up models for quantifying more accurately the energy usage on-board vessels (Gilbert and Bows 2012). There is indeed evidence to support the latter statement by the initiative of industrial players to equip vessels with data acquisition systems installed within the machinery and navigation systems. The purpose is firstly to monitor the performance of their fleets along various routes and verify the simulated results during the vessel’s design phase as well as provide a cornerstone to comply with the requirements of the SEEMP (Marty et al. 2012; Baldi et al. 2014; Perera et al. 2015; Fun-sang and Caprace 2015; Bialystocki and Konovessis 2016; Deligiannis 2016). Secondly, to develop a methodology for benchmarking and analyzing real time measurements based on probabilistic methods (Petersen et al. 2012; Sasa et al. 2015; Trodden et al. 2015; Bocchetti et al. 2015; Meng et al. 2016; Kakuta et al. 2016; Orihara et al. 2016). As a matter of fact, much more visibility, clarity and scrutiny than ever before can be immortalized by such evolvement, and with no exaggeration, simple regulatory compliance will not be adequate in the future. Essentially, in turn this may acquaint the business and economic benefits (i.e. enforce performance guarantee and energy efficiency specification clauses) of design improvements between charterers and owners as well as facilitate better communication of the financial benefits which can be expected from installing energy efficient technologies (Rehmatulla and Smith 2015a). 2.3 Types of Charter Party Agreements 2.3 17 Types of Charter Party Agreements From a functional point of view (i.e. volume of cargo to be transported from one location to another or the need for an extra vessel for a period of time) the freight market has two different types of transaction. One is the freight contract (voyage charter) in which the shipper or charterer buys transport from the ship-owner at a fixed price per ton of cargo. The second is the time charter (contract) under which the vessel is hired by the day with the length of the hire taken to complete a single voyage (trip charter) or a period of months or years (period charter) (Gorton et al. 2009; Stopford 2009). The freight contract suits players who prefer to pay an agreed sum and leave the management of the transport, hence commercial risk to the ship-owner (spot market). The time charter is for experienced ship operators who prefer to manage the transport themselves and it creates the business of industrial shipping based upon the charterers’ decision to carry the commercial risk (Stopford 2009). There are other types of contracts such as contract of affreightment or consecutive voyages which correspond to a hybrid form of voyage charter; whereas the bareboat or demise charter amounts to the lease of the vessel from the owner to the charterer. The latter is really a financing arrangement and it is not related to the use of the vessel for transporting cargoes (Gorton et al. 2009; Stopford 2009). To this end, it is not unreasonable to suggest only two types of contracts for the carriage of goods by sea since from the inaugural work of Pirrong (1993) it is reported that long term contracting is interchanged between spot deployments. In addition, the contractual specificities depend on the characteristics of the cargo flows, the nature of the markets for the transported commodity, the geographic dispersion of supply sources and the characteristics of the vessels employed in that trade. For instance, there is little incentive to haggle over the services of an obsolete vessel when her contract expires because the quasi gains are trivial (Pirrong 1993). Similarly, it is advocated by Nomikos and Giamouzi (2013) as well as Fagerholt et al. (2010) that vessels are allocated by considering the best performing contract (whether a spot or a period arrangement will be signed or extended) not only in terms of profitability and avoidance of significant freight rate risks, but also accounting for strategic positioning aspects. For example, during a market upturn, ship-owners prefer chartering their vessels under (short) voyage contracts as opposed to time charter contracts (thus maintaining resource flexibility). Though at the same time, charterers switch to hire vessels under (lengthy) time charter contracts as opposed to voyage contracts (preferring thus resource commitment) (Axarloglou et al. 2013). What is really remarkable however, is that, fuel consumption as perceived to be correlated to technology advancements, was found to be completely unrelated to time charter rates during buoyant market conditions. Thus, different consumption rates impacting on charterers’ costs mattered only marginally for contract rates (Köhn and Thanopoulou 2011). The commercial operation of a vessel always involves certain costs and responsibilities which are allocated in a slightly different way under the type of charter, as shown in Table 2.2. Under a voyage charter, the ship-owner contracts to 18 2 Literature Review Table 2.2 Allocation of costs and responsibilities under voyage and time charters Voyage charter ($/t) Voyage costs Despatch/demurrage Costs that may be shared in Loading/discharging different ways Stevedoring/trimming Certain costs to be paid by Port charges, fees charterer Cleaning holds Costs of the owner Cargo claims Canal transit dues Bunker fuel Other voyage expenses Operating Wages costs Provisions Maintenance Repairs Stores and supplies Lube oil Water Insurance (Hull, War, P&I) Overheads Capital Capital repayment costs Interest on own and borrowed capital Depreciation on invested capital Brokerage Source Gorton et al. (2009) and Stopford (2009) Time charter ($/day) Costs of the charterer Costs of the owner carry a specific cargo in a specific vessel for a negotiated price per ton which covers all the expenses incurred during the voyage, such as voyage (including cargo handling and port/canal charges) costs, operating costs and capital costs. The time charter is an agreement between owner and charterer to hire a vessel, complete with crew, for a fee per day, month or year. In this case, the ship-owner is responsible for the capital and operating costs, whereas the charterer pays all incurred expenses associated with the voyage (Gorton et al. 2009; Stopford 2009). In an attempt to balance the interests of the ship-owner and charterer, as well as the fact that sea trade is performed internationally albeit to special and hazardous conditions, where it is practically impossible for one party to supervise the work of the other daily, legal regimes (i.e. Hague-Visby Rules, Hamburg Rules, Rotterdam Rules) were enacted to govern the contracts for the carriage of goods by sea (i.e. bills of lading). This development introduced a set of contractual duties which was to be used as a base for performance (Dockray and Thomas 2007; Singh 2011). The implied duties cover seaworthiness, care for the cargo, deviation, reasonable dispatch and not to ship dangerous cargo, whilst for the first three exempting liability must be transparently attained. The suitable incorporation of the Rules into the charter party is secured by a clause paramount, or setting out sections of the Rules 2.3 Types of Charter Party Agreements 19 in the charter party, or the provision that any set of Rules that applies to any bill of lading issued under the charter party shall also apply (Baatz 2014; Todd 2016). 2.4 Barriers on Implementing the Design Energy Efficiency Improvements As it has been shown from Table 2.2, due to the different responsibilities and costs allocated in voyage and time charters, the carrier or ship-owner (agent) and the shipper or charterer (principal) are not provoked into a steady implementation of design energy efficiency improvements. In essence, this can be explained by the fact that the two players have different profit maximization goals from the trade-off between the cost of energy efficiency and the cost of measuring the performance. Moreover, assessing the vessel’s performance accurately within a practical amount of time (i.e. contract’s duration) insurmountably creates uncertainty for curbing any varying levels of cost sharing (Eisenhardt 1989; Jensen and Meckling 1976). To further elaborate on this point, it is asserted by Sorrell et al. (2004) as well as Fleiter and Plötz (2013) that owning to constraints on time, attention and the lack of ability to process information that may lead to cost effective opportunities, the players do not make decisions in the manner assumed in economic models (i.e. life cycle cost consideration). As a consequence, additional costs related to management overheads, information collation and analysis may not be accounted for, thus implying uncertainty and lack of confidence (bounded rationality). In turn, the players may neglect energy efficiency opportunities, even when given good information and appropriate incentives are available or even known (Sorrell et al. 2004; Fleiter and Plötz 2013). The latter constitute an important reason why energy efficiency improvements can be hampered. The most prominent example of split incentives is the investor— agent/user—principal dilemma, where the carrier or ship-owner—agent is responsible for building the vessel, but the shipper or charterer—principal under a time charter contract receives the benefit in the form of lower energy bills. In this case, the agent would not receive a financial reward for the expensive energy efficiency improvements. On the other hand, the principal, who would receive the benefit and thus have an incentive to install energy efficient equipment, does not own the vessel and cannot install it (Sorrell et al. 2004; Fleiter and Plötz 2013). Convergence of such inconsistent objectives would create agency costs being translated into incentives, whereas a premium (remuneration) would be required to compensate for these additional costs (Arnold 2010; Watson and Head 2013). To attach more credibility in bounded rationality and split incentives, the works of Balland et al. (2015), Jafarzadeh and Utne (2014) as well as Rojon and Dieperink (2014) were based on interviews with shipping experts, where it was concluded that the absence of objective and verified data in combination with the harsh economic climate were inherently forcing short term survivability. Hence, such behavior 20 2 Literature Review clearly inhibits any motivation for investing in design energy efficient improvements. Similarly, Lun et al. (2014) and Agnolucci et al. (2014) concur that the emphasis on operational efficiency in the current charter party agreements for enforcing warranties and legal legitimacy weaken the promotion of information monitoring systems as well as the cooperation between principals and agents concerning energy efficient equipment. However, from the perspective of contractual complexity, agreements encompassing only performance measures may induce the agent to engage in dysfunctional action, i.e. maximize own margins and dampen the incentive of paid bunkers, which is not necessarily in line with the principal’s objective of minimizing transport cost (Baker 1992). Armstrong and Banks (2015) suggest that although the industry is acquainted with such information systems, still the lack of shared goals and objectives between commercial and technical stakeholders (principals and agents) prevents the realization of energy efficiency. In this respect, reference is given to the misconception of performance monitoring. Voyage performance has more “commercial” nature related to voyage cost minimization, revenue maximization and efficient vessel utilization. Whereas, vessel performance has more “technical” nature and is associated with hull and propeller condition so as to plan the appropriate maintenance activities (Armstrong and Banks 2015). Additionally, energy efficient technologies are impeded with the information from performance monitoring equipment remaining imperfect due to absence of any reliable benchmark for crediting the energy saving potential (Poulsen and Sornn-Friese 2015). Therefore, it is plausible that the technologies will be selected based on the trade-off between bunker price and equipment cost, rather than their energy saving potential (Stevens et al. 2015). In general, any agent would like to reimburse the energy efficiency investment expenditure, but such effort can be obstructed by the commercial imperatives of the observed chartering practice (see Sect. 2.3). It is not rare that costly technologies cannot be implemented to some types of charter contracts either due to short duration, or lack of control over operations. Moreover, the negotiated price does not mirror the economic benefit of the claimed fuel efficiency, even if the vessel is resold (Rehmatulla and Smith 2015b). To further reflect on that, the advantages granted by trading on the spot market (flexible employment) do not allow acute recognition of energy efficiency. Admittedly, the realization of fuel savings is a time consuming process which can take years of assessment and evaluation, whilst such charters usually expire long before these effects can be genuinely diagnosed. By contrast, vessels trading under long term contractual relationships (bareboat and long period charters); have experienced tremendous energy efficient performance (Poulsen and Johnson 2016). Though, the latter is attributed more on operational initiatives rather on implementing design measures where the principal may not be willing to share the cost with the agent. Instead, the agent may not be directly rewarded for energy efficiency, but at least it is likely to improve the possibility of winning a charter and obtain better fleet utilization. Nevertheless, principals gradually have given emphasis on the agent’s energy efficiency and in some cases have influenced the vessel’s design (installed wind assistance and air lubrication system). 2.4 Barriers on Implementing the Design Energy Efficiency Improvements 21 However, the time charter duration is too short (usually half to one year) for recouping the investment which may require a longer payback period (Rehmatulla et al. 2015). Knowing that long term contracts (time charters) are fit for incentive screening through their performance clauses and short term contracts (voyage charters) allow a better matching between the abilities of agents and the needs of principals (Macho-Stadler et al. 2014), it is necessary to provide a mechanism that specifies in detail the agent’s characteristics (energy efficiency specification and costs). This should be subject to the available evidence (energy reduction potential) and their relationship is not only emerged through profit maximization (incentive compatibility), but also is blended with general utility aspects, i.e. greener lifecycle performance (Page 1991; Ochs and Roth 1989). The extent to which such undertaking (i.e. inclusion of clauses related to the design energy efficiency equipment specification of the vessel and investment sharing) is plausible will be argued in the fourth chapter. Chapter 3 Methodology Abstract This chapter is aimed at presenting the framework of the conducted qualitative research. Essential element is the observation of commercial contracts for the use of the vessel (charter party) as well as legal instruments for the carriage of goods by sea with the result being a theory generalization. This entails that a qualitative inductive and exploratory approach is adopted in a sense that there is a gap in the logic argument between the conclusion and the observations being made. The coherence for this reasoning is achieved through the grounded theory method, a formalized strategy to collect and analyze data (observed premises) which enables to answer the particular research objectives and meet the book’s aim. 3.1 Preamble It is recognized that in social, physical or mathematical sciences knowledge is evolved from the reciprocal analysis of theory (modeling) and research, where data can be collated either by a sample survey or a literature review. During such endeavor, different decisions are made, merely subjective, with respect to variables, levels of detail and sample space. The inferred ideas and hypotheses furnished by the analysis may then need to be tuned so that either the model is harmonized with the data to illustrate the state of affairs, or the model is modified to better describe the data. This creative iteration between theory and research adds objectivity with the aim to converge as soon and reliable as possible (Box 1980). 3.2 Research Design The formulation of clauses in the commercial contract for the use of a vessel between a carrier or ship-owner and a shipper or charterer is quite complex and tailored to the specific trade. This means that subject to the book’s qualitative research objectives, the examination of the legal instruments will allow to © Springer International Publishing Switzerland 2017 G.A. Psarros, Energy Efficiency Clauses in Charter Party Agreements, Springer Series on Naval Architecture, Marine Engineering, Shipbuilding and Shipping 3, DOI 10.1007/978-3-319-50265-6_3 23 24 3 Methodology understand the two parties’ obligations and render under which set of circumstances the inclusion of clauses that can clarify the responsibility of design energy efficiency improvements is permitted. Thus, it is of concern to explore the way in which the two parties’ commercial affairs are regulated and offer suggestions as to how they may be improved within the existing and present practice of the two parties’ business roles. Furthermore, the investigation of the standardized charter forms is paramount in determining if design energy efficiency improvements are included as a subject term in the contractual clauses and which vessel parameters already incorporated in the clauses can be related to design energy efficiency. Essentially, such research objectives are hard to tackle without seeking insights from published interpretations of the legal instruments (secondary data) and an in depth inquiry of standardized charter forms (primary data). This interpretive philosophy is associated with qualitative research and is aimed at establishing trust, access to meanings and informed understanding of the addressed topic, i.e. design energy efficiency improvements within the charter part clauses. This research is inductively built from objective interpretations of the meanings of collected data and honors a style that portrays the importance of recognizing the complexity of the investigated situation. It means that the researcher is the protagonist during the whole process of delving into new layers of information into a sequential and iterative fashion (Creswell 2009; Saunders et al. 2012). Its procedural regimen is aimed at firstly achieving a level of understanding that transcends the results and secondly at identifying matured areas as well as areas where more knowledge and practice recommendations need to be developed. Its universal applicability of systematic synthesis of research findings to accumulate, organize and interpret information is demonstrated by contributions from multiple disciplines, i.e. entrepreneurship (Rauch et al. 2014), family research (Goldberg and Allen 2015), health psychology (Bishop 2015), corporate governance (McNulty et al. 2013), policy making (Ritz 2011), economics (Starr 2014), as well as management research (Klag and Langley 2013). Commonly to these studies, the main investigated issues of design energy efficiency as mentioned previously, need to be exposed from a critical realism perspective with the descriptive findings based on verbal data rather than numbers or statistics and being generalized at a later stage, aspects that can be effectively delineated through qualitative rigor. An inductive approach is employed to develop a richer theoretical perspective since the investigation of the inclusion of energy efficiency specification clauses in charter party contracts is relatively new and is not covered in the existing academic literature, as discussed in the introduction. To this end, albeit to the shortage of published research and the absence of a theory supporting the view that design energy efficiency improvements shall be included in the charter forms, an inductive procedure allows to deal with the book’s qualitative research objectives. Furthermore, it allows a good fit to address the aforementioned knowledge gap between the commercial roles and implied obligations of the involved parties as well as gain familiarity with that topic of which is little currently understood. Consequently, the developed theoretical proposition needs to be tested and verified through the detailed investigation of standardized charter forms for drawing 3.2 Research Design 25 conclusions (i.e. how design energy efficiency improvements can be incorporated in the charter clauses). Hence, as argued by Saunders et al. (2012), the whole process is based on the extensive collection of verbal data which is simultaneously explored for building a theory to guide the subsequent work. Because of the interactive nature of the verbal data collection and analysis, the theory emerges as a result of the research process (Saunders et al. 2012). Such approach can be iterative since once the phase of theoretical reflection on a set of verbal data has been carried out, further verbal data may be collected in order to establish the conditions in which a theory will and will not hold. This weaving back and forth between the theory which is created from the legal instruments interpretations (secondary data) and the research of the standard charter forms (primary data) contains a deductive element too. Inherently, this feature is particularly evident in grounded theory (Bryman 2012) a formalized strategy of collecting and analyzing data, as it will be explained in the following subsection. Briefly, the literature is analyzed further during the secondary data analysis, whilst the findings are expanded by the primary data. By sequence, the process has to identify any verbal characteristics in the charter forms that account for design energy efficiency improvements, as well as the determination of which vessel parameters incorporated in the charter clauses are of relevance. Although admittedly a bulk of desk research is performed, the findings are emerging from two sequential stages (i.e. legal instruments and charter forms analyses) which not only complement each other, but also strengthen their validity. It is this logical, as well as rational and scientific inference of observations that enables the creation of new forms of knowledge (obligations and responsibilities of the charterer or shipper and the ship-owner or carrier). In addition, the innovative creation of new possibilities for objectively reconstructing themes, categories and patterns in the data (related to design energy efficiency) could bring forth deeper reflections on the observed information (the proposal or not of amendments in the charter clauses) (Bendassolli 2013). Furthermore, the primary purpose of the inductive approach is to allow research findings to emerge from the frequent, dominant, or significant themes, categories and patterns inherent in raw verbal data, without the restraints imposed by structured methodologies in which it is not possible to revisit the developed theory (Thomas 2006). This iterative criterion is evident in the current study where verbal data is collected from the interpretations of legal instruments. Then, a theory generalization upon design energy efficiency improvements is drawn. Successively, more verbal data is collected from the standard charter forms (i.e. obligations and responsibilities of the charterer or shipper and the ship-owner or carrier) and is analyzed further. Next, the theory is re-examined again, until an acceptable conclusion between theory and data is accomplished. The book’s objectives pose exploratory research since they are open and seek to discover what is happening in practice about the implied obligations and responsibilities of the charterer or shipper and the ship-owner or carrier. Moreover, the book’s objectives have the purpose to gain insight concerning the inclusion of energy efficiency specification clauses within charter party agreements due to the 26 3 Methodology scarcity of the conducted research on this topic, as it has already been pointed out. This type of research is a valuable way to clarify the understanding of this book’s particular study and is performed through document search of journal articles, standard charter contracts and interpretations of legal instruments. In this respect, a diverse set of data is used to examine meanings that may not have been considered when the written material was firstly produced. It is mainly desk research where cost effectiveness can be achieved with the minimum expense. Additionally, the time intensive nature of document search and collection has the advantage of being flexible and adaptable to change as a result of new verbal data that appear; hence new insights are occurred than those originally anticipated (Saunders et al. 2012; Wilson 2014). This characteristic is applied to the study documented in the current book, where the initial verbal data collection from the interpretation of legal instruments and journal articles is followed by a second verbal data collection of standard charter forms. The purpose is to explore the existing coverage of design energy efficiency and then generalize the proposition (i.e. incorporation of design energy efficiency improvements in the charter clauses). The adopted sequential exploratory design is illustrated at Fig. 3.1, where it involves a first stage of secondary data collection (interpretation of legal instruments) and a theory building augmented with evidence from journal articles. Afterwards, a second stage of primary data collection is carried out from a sample of more than 50 standardized charter forms. The intent of the second stage is that the results from the first analysis (theory building) can help to inform the survey of the standardized forms and consequently the latter findings are fed into the theory developed initially. st 1 Stage: Interpretation of legal instruments Theory building: Design energy efficiency in charter clauses nd 2 Stage: Standardized charter forms sample Findings Evidence: Journal articles Fig. 3.1 Simple schematic of the adopted sequential exploratory research design. Note the inductive element of theory creation from data and the iteration in the second stage for revisiting the theory. Source Author 3.2 Research Design 3.2.1 27 Research Method In connection with the previous discussion, it is believed that the adoption of a qualitative inductive and sequential exploratory research design requires a method of data collection, analysis, and comparison from different sources. Such adoption leads to insightful conclusions as well as it provides the necessary consolidated and validated outcome. The fact that multiple data resources are used (journal articles, contracts and legal instruments) and their subsequent analysis provides a stronger foundation for theory building which is also referred to as grounded theory method (Creswell 2009; Bryman 2012). It is a strategy of inquiry where a general theory is derived grounded in multiple stages of data collection, refinement and connection of categories of information for maximizing the associated similarities and differences. In order to obtain convergence of research findings (the inclusion of design energy efficiency improvements within the charter contracts), triangulation by sources of data permits the researcher to clarify the perceived meanings and verify the interpreted information (Creswell 2009; Bryman 2012). For instance, the findings from the legal instruments (first source) and journal articles (second source) are elaborated and confirmed by examining evidence from different types of standardized charter forms (third source). To this end, triangulation from these three sources is utilized to build a coherent justification for establishing patterns that are based on converging perspectives. This process can be claimed as adding to the validity of the current book’s study (Creswell 2009; Bryman 2012). Reliability is ensured by the method’s application consistency across different disciplines and projects, for instance family research (LaRossa 2005), legal studies (Outhwaite et al. 2007), data analytics (Urquhart et al. 2010), education and learning (Thomas and James 2006), artificial intelligence (Castellani et al. 2003), nursing research (Engward and Davis 2015), human resource capital (Storberg-Walker 2007), logistics management (Mello and Flint 2009), managerial action (Partington 2000), as well as consumer research (Stall-Meadows and Hyle 2010). In a similar point of view, the method adapted to the current book’s study is unique in appraising the flexible nature of the wide range of evidence from multiple sources that is required to address and to acquire a deeper understanding of design energy efficiency improvements as a contractual term. The process of data collection, analysis and comparison consists of two principal stages: initial coding of legal instruments as well as journal articles and focused coding supported by sufficient sampling of contracts, which is illustrated at Fig. 3.2. During the initial coding, the analysis of the relationship of the contracted parties with respect to energy efficiency specification clauses indicates the type of cases (voyage and time charters) to select for further data collection. This coding involves recording of identifiable subjects (properties or dimensions), where similar subjects are grouped together (see Fig. 3.2 for the developed labels). This purposive sampling continues until theoretical saturation is achieved and occurs when the data collection ceases to reveal any new relevant observations as well as the relationship between the parties has been verified (Bryman 2012; Saunders et al. 2012). Since 28 3 Methodology “seaworthiness” is identified as a core subject around which research is concentrated, a particular focus is provided (focused coding of standardized charter forms) from which new data is collected and analyzed to pursue theoretical lines of enquiry. For the examination of charter party contracts, content analysis is selected as the technique for uncovering generic categories within the clauses by objectively and systematically searching for certain ideas within the text (i.e. vessel description, bunkers). The text is coded in terms of certain subjects and themes so that the categorization of the topic under investigation is sought, understanding is increased and knowledge is accumulated. At the next level, sub categories (see Fig. 3.2) within similar concepts are classified together (i.e. energy saving devices, fuel consumption, etc.) and the recording continues as long as it is reasonable and possible. The categorization within the focused coding not only registers observations that are similar or related, but also allows a comparison between the Initial Coding: Interpretation of legal instruments and journal articles Themes: Time & Voyage charters Properties: Charterer’s/ Shipper’s & Shipowner’s/ Carrier’s obligations Dimensions: Seaworthiness Due care & despatch Safe port Cargo Freight Focused Coding: Sampling of standardized charter forms Sub Categories: Energy saving devices Fuel Consumption Speed Bunkers Generic Categories: Vessel description Bunkers Main Categories: Seaworthiness Fig. 3.2 Simple schematic conceptualizing the principal stages of data collection, analysis and comparison. Note that the reciprocal arrows indicate the comparison element (triangulation) between initial and focused coding. Source Author 3.2 Research Design 29 observations unfolded during the initial coding. In this respect, it is implied that data is analyzed and simplified to form categories that are relevant to the topic under investigation i.e. design energy efficiency improvements as a term included in the charter clauses (Bryman 2012). As shown in Fig. 3.2, the initial and focused coding scheme and the affiliated sampling procedure can be clearly set out so that replications and follow up studies are feasible. It is this transparency that often causes content analysis to be referred to as an objective technique of analysis. Furthermore, it is highly flexible that it can be applied to a wide variety of different kinds of documents and can allow information to be generated that is ambiguously hidden in the text (Bryman 2012). Published examples in academic research using content analysis and affirming its applicability can be found in nursing and health research (Elo and Kyngäs 2007), as well as social sciences literature (Zhang et al. 2013). In a maritime context, Rehmatulla and Smith (2015a) have employed this method to evaluate the influence of implementing speed reduction measures within the charter party contracts. However, it should be made crystal clear that their research was focused on operational measures and not on design energy efficiency improvements which is the subject matter investigated in the current book (see Sect. 1.2). By using these elements it is asserted that the process of data collection and analysis becomes increasingly focused, leading to the generation of a contextually based theoretical explanation. It is emphasized that the analysis is interactive, flexible and less prescriptive; it develops from constantly comparing data to codes and codes to data in order to construct higher levels of abstraction and is shaped by the objective interpretation of these constant comparisons. Thus, two central features of grounded theory are that, firstly it is concerned with the development of theory out of the collated data. Whereas secondly, the approach is iterative, or recursive, as it is sometimes called, meaning that data collection and analysis proceed in tandem, repeatedly referring back to each other (Bryman 2012; Saunders et al. 2012). Chapter 4 Analysis and Findings Abstract This chapter is concerned with reporting the results grounded on the methodology outlined in the previous chapter. In this respect, firstly the initial coding of legal instrument interpretations on the carriage of goods by sea investigates if it is permitted to regulate the rights and responsibilities of design energy efficiency improvements. Furthermore, it seeks to identify any wedge for incorporating such term in the charter party contract through the relevant law literature. Secondly, since the research is concentrated around voyage and time charters, the focused coding is supported by sufficient sampling of the standard agreement forms. To this end, content analysis is employed for uncovering themes within the clauses by objectively and systematically searching for certain subjects within the text (i.e. energy efficiency specification). Moreover, it is determined which themes are associated with vessel design parameters. This process continues until additional data collation does not contribute to the coding of the topic under investigation and any new theoretical lines of enquiry are not possible to be offered. 4.1 Preamble A theory on how to support the view that design energy improvements can be included in the charter party agreements has been already emerged and the reader is disposed to witness its applicability. It is formulated by analyzing the possible and thinkable moral reasons for the conclusion that such proposal is acceptable. Further, a richer conclusion is derived from the coherent and consistent set of legal premises, where the inclusion of a clause specifying the design energy efficiency obligation is justifiable and rational. This follows the logical expectation that within the juristic paradigm a morally and legally reasonable responsibility is created by the taken for granted principle of pollution prevention (Peczenik 1988). © Springer International Publishing Switzerland 2017 G.A. Psarros, Energy Efficiency Clauses in Charter Party Agreements, Springer Series on Naval Architecture, Marine Engineering, Shipbuilding and Shipping 3, DOI 10.1007/978-3-319-50265-6_4 31 32 4.2 4 Analysis and Findings Initial Coding: Themes, Properties and Dimensions This part seeks to indicate the type of charter parties as well as categories (similar subjects grouped together) to select for further data collection. Consequently, the relationship of the contracted parties with respect to the energy efficiency specification is determined. The latter is reflected by proposing any amendments or additions to the relevant themes (charter party contract clauses) that could contain the vessel’s energy efficiency specification. 4.2.1 Themes: Time and Voyage Charters The transactions for the services for transporting cargoes by sea are distinguished into two types. The freight contract (voyage charter); where the shipper or charterer buys transport from the ship-owner at a fixed price per ton of cargo and it is suited for those who prefer to pay an agreed sum for the service whilst the management of the transport is left to the ship-owner. The time charter; where the vessel is hired by the day and it is appropriate for experienced ship operators who prefer to manage the transport themselves (Gorton et al. 2009; Stopford 2009). There are other types of contracts such as contract of affreightment or consecutive voyages which correspond to a hybrid form of voyage charter. Whereas the bareboat or demise charter amounts to the lease of the vessel from the owner to the charterer, which is really a financing arrangement and it is not related to the use of the vessel for transporting cargoes (Gorton et al. 2009; Stopford 2009). 4.2.2 Properties: Rights and Responsibilities (Obligations) of Shippers or Charterers and Carriers or Ship-Owners Since from a theoretical perspective the charter parties are classified as a contract for the use of the vessel, they are not subject firstly to the statutory assignment contained in the COGSA 1992 and secondly to the mandatory application of the Hague and Hague-Visby Rules which are associated with contracts for the carriage of goods such as the bill of lading. The provisions of these regulations however can be incorporated in the contract if it is chosen by the signatory parties. For instance, the inclusion by virtue of a clause in charters linking contractually the carrier or ship-owner with the bills of lading holder on the terms of the charter party, which is incorporated into the bill of lading, provided that the regulations effect the necessary statutory or mandatory assignments (Baughen 2010). 4.2 Initial Coding: Themes, Properties and Dimensions 33 Without dealing here with all details, under common law, the shipper or charterer has the obligation to nominate a safe port, not to ship dangerous cargoes, to provide cargo and pay for the bought service. Whilst under the international conventions, the shipper or charterer has the duty to provide accurate information about the transported goods (Hague-Visby Rules Art. III, r. 5/Art. IV r. 3 and 6). Furthermore, the Hamburg Rules [Art. 17(1), 12 and 13] have the potential to cover a wider scope of information i.e. relevant information as to the dangerous nature of the goods, as well as the necessary precautions to be taken in transporting the goods. In addition, the Rotterdam Rules [Art. 27, 28, 29(1), 30, 31, 32] state goods that are likely to become a danger to persons, property or the environment and the notification as to the nature of the goods shall be done in accordance with any law, regulations or other requirements of public authorities that apply during any stage of the intended carriage of the goods (Singh 2011; Todd 2016). As far as the obligations of the carrier or ship-owner under common law, these can be summarized as follows (Singh 2011; Baatz 2014; Todd 2016). The provision of a seaworthy vessel (i.e. fit for receiving the assigned cargo and performing the intended voyage in terms of her physical condition and equipment, competence/ efficiency of her master and crew, adequacy of stores and documentation). Additionally, the cargo is carried to the designated port without deviating from the agreed route albeit to any lawful justifications for doing so and that the carrier’s or ship-owner’s contractual obligations are conducted with reasonable dispatch. The international conventions stipulate that a bill of lading is issued as a receipt for the goods received (Hague-Visby Rules Art. III, r. 3), the exercise of due diligence to make the vessel seaworthy, the vessel is properly manned and equipped, the holds and other parts of the vessel for which goods are carried are fit for the purpose (Hague-Visby Rules Art. III, r. 1). Further, the cargo is carefully and properly loaded, handled, stowed, carried, kept, cared for and discharged (Hague-Visby Rules Art. III, r. 2) and a wider range of permissible deviations is offered (Hague-Visby Rules Art. IV, r. 4). The Hamburg Rules do not give the carrier or ship-owner as many exceptions from liability as the Hague and Hague-Visby Rules. In particular, the carrier or ship-owner is not exonerated from liability arising from negligence in navigation or management of the vessel. The Rotterdam Rules cover a wider range of persons associated with the transport of goods, the period of carrier’s or ship-owner’s liability is extended to a door to door service (i.e. under the custody of a port terminal), include the duty to receive the goods for transport and to deliver them to the consignee at destination (Singh 2011; Baatz 2014; Todd 2016). The importance of the aforementioned lies in the fact that the shipper or charterer is responsible for the nature of the goods loaded on the vessel with the technical specification of the vessel ultimately considered as the obligation of the carrier or ship-owner and not the shipper’s or charterer’s. 34 4.2.3 4 Analysis and Findings Dimensions: Breaking Down Groupings Dealing with the Vessel Depending on the type of contract, the vessel may have a more or less central position in the charter party agreement. In time charters the vessel is a central factor whereas in voyage charters the vessel is not as essential and the agreements are concluded before it is known what vessel will be used. Since during a voyage charter the vessel’s performance is at the carrier’s or ship-owner’s risk, the only parameter of the vessel’s description is her cargo capacity. Other details or qualities such as principal dimensions, air draught, cargo handling equipment, number of hatches an their dimensions need to be specified in advance for the economical and practical planning of the loading, carrying and discharging of a cargo (Gorton et al. 2009; Wilson 2010). The efficiency of the chartered vessel is paramount to the time charterer because the success of the commercial enterprise may depend on it. Therefore, the specifications of the vessel are set in detail, the most important of which are normally those relating to speed, loading capacity and fuel consumption. Charterers or shippers require that they have correct and sufficient information about the vessel not only because it is necessary to form an opinion about her commercial value, but also due to the fact that cargoes to be loaded and ports to be visited are not known beforehand. In addition, when the vessel is chartered for a long period, a more detailed description is needed and the shippers or charterers get copies of the general arrangement plan as well as other plans that give information about the vessel and her construction (Gorton et al. 2009; Wilson 2010). Of these points, it is usually stated in any charter party that the vessel shall be kept in a seaworthy condition. The concept of seaworthiness can be described as having three aspects: (i) seaworthiness from the technical point of view, (ii) cargoworthiness, and (iii) seaworthiness for the intended voyage. The design energy efficiency improvements are of interest to the first issue which includes the vessel’s design and condition in hull and machinery, and also her stability. In addition, the vessel must be technically equipped and furnished with certificates necessary for her to be able to call at a certain port or a certain country without risk of delay as well as being kept in good order and condition during the charter period (Gorton et al. 2009). It is well to note that such undertaking reflects technology advancements which are matter of construction and relatively depend on the charter’s character. By the same token, if the vessel is not classed as represented, she may be enunciated as a handicap to maritime commerce and either the charterer is compelled to pay extra insurance premiums to protect the shipped cargo, or refuse to load the vessel (Vandeventer 1975). Until now, case examples or rulings related to design energy efficiency improvements (see Table 2.1 for an explanation of vessel related technologies) rendering technical unseaworthiness do not exist (see Table 4.1 for relevant 4.2 Initial Coding: Themes, Properties and Dimensions 35 Table 4.1 Examples of defects in the technical condition of a vessel or her equipment rendering her unseaworthy Defect Case Leaking hull Hull fracture Lyon v Mells [1805] 1 KB 697 Danske Sukkerfabrikker v Bajamar Compania Naviera, The Torenia [1983] 2 Lloyd’s Rep 211 Itoh & Co Ltd v Atlantska Plovidba, The Gundulic [1981] 2 Lloyd’s Rep 511 McFadden v Blue Star Line [1905] 1 KB 697 Steel v State Line; Dobell v Steamship Rossmore Co [1905] 2 QB 408 Havelock v Geddes (1809) 10 East 555 The Glenfruin (1885) 10 PD 103 SNIA v Suzuki (1924) 29 Com Cas 284 Project Asia Line Inc v Shone, The Pride of Donegal [2002] EWHC 24; [2002] 1 Lloyd’s Rep 659 Guinomar of Conakry v Samsung Fire & Marine Insurance Co Ltd, The Kamsar Voyager [2002] 2 Lloyd’s Rep 57 Fyffes Group Ltd and Caribbean Gold Ltd v Reefer Express Lines Pty Ltd & Reefkrit Shipping Inc, The Kriti Rex [1996] 2 Lloyd’s Rep 373 The Vortigern [1899] P 140 Island Tug and Barge v Makedonia, The Makedonia [1962] P 190 Vinmar v Theresa [2001] 2 Lloyd’s Rep 1 Rey Banano del Pacifico Co v Transportes Navieros Ecuatorianos, The Isla Fernandina [2000] 2 Lloyd’s Rep 15 Maori King v Hughes [1895] 2 QB 550 Leaking hatch covers Leaking sea valve Porthole not capable of being closed at sea Neglecting to put in a nail Crankshaft with flaw in weld Defective propeller Insufficient spare parts Unsuitable spare parts Sludge in lubricating oil Insufficient supply of fuel Contaminated fuel Contaminated cargo tanks and lines Inadequate charts and navigation aids Defective refrigerating machinery where the cargo was frozen meat Ship with no dunnage mats to protect dry cargo Pumps inadequate for cargo Source Dockray and Thomas (2007) Hogarth v Walker [1899] 2 QB 401 Stanton v Richardson (1872) LR 7 CP 421 examples regarding the vessel’s technical condition according to the common law doctrine), meaning that the parties signing the charter agreement are free to adopt a solution making their wishes clear (Dockray and Thomas 2007). However, the ground for any voluntary contractual inclusion of a design energy efficiency improvement clause that also exemplifies a sharing scheme of the incurred cost will be discussed in the next sub-section. 36 4.3 4 Analysis and Findings Theory Building: Balancing the Interests for Design Energy Efficiency Improvements It has been already reported that the existing legal instruments and contractual charter party practices assign the duty and responsibility of the vessel’s construction (hence design energy efficiency improvements) to the carrier or ship-owner. However, it is true to say that socially responsible behavior nurtured through improved environmental risk management (i.e. a reduction in emissions and pollutants) decreases the probability of environmental crises that can negatively affect a firm’s expected cash flows (i.e. lawsuits, clean-up costs of environmental accidents, fines, reputation damage). Hence, investing in energy efficient technologies demonstrates environmental commitment and creates “moral capital”, or goodwill which provides insurance-like protection in the occurrences of negative events or crises. In addition, stakeholders including shippers or charterers and consignees are requiring carriers to adopt promulgated environmental policies striving for minimum environmental damage when handling their shipments (Drobetz et al. 2014a; Lai et al. 2011). The aforementioned statements can be supported by Lys et al. (2015) who found that corporate social responsibility activities (i.e. reduction of environmental impact) are considered as investments which are positively associated with economic returns. Such investments within a wide range of industries including transportation, utilities, agriculture, communications, minerals, retailers among others, have generated at least 7% increase in the operating cash flows difference between two consecutive years. Also, it is suggested by the results of Clarkson et al. (2013) and Plumlee et al. (2015) that industries with high environmental expenditures (i.e. oil and gas, metals and mining, chemicals, pharmaceuticals, utilities, food and beverage) have lowered their cost of capital and equity by 17 and 6.5% respectively. Although these studies are not referred to the shipping industry per se, it can be argued that initiatives to improve the energy efficiency of a fleet and reduce its greenhouse gas emissions can enhance the stakeholder value of any company. The efforts shaping the achievement of environmental and thus sustainable legitimacy in the society should be also coerced by those who have exercised pervasive control over the carrier’s activities, such as budgeting, commercial contracts, voyage instructions and port assignment (Anderson and Rue 2001). Thus, under the negligence theory (doctrine) of common law, if a time or voyage charterer breached a duty of care which proximately caused pollution damage to third parties, the charterer would be held liable for such damage. By virtue, the above issue was raised only in one recorded case (The American Trader oil spill); where the court declined to dismiss the action against entities of cargo owner and charterer, see for example Slaven v. BP America Inc. [786 F. Supp. 853, 1993 AMC 455 (C.D. Cal. 1992)] as well as Holifield v. BP America Inc. [786 F. Supp. 840, 842, 1992 AMC 456, 457 (C.D. Cal. 1991)] (Anderson and Rue 2001). This entails that time or voyage charterers would of course remain responsible for contractual obligations 4.3 Theory Building: Balancing the Interests for Design Energy … 37 arising out of cargo operations and vessel movement directions as well as for their own independent negligence causing damage or injury to third parties. Nevertheless, the exercise of these rights is not inconsistent with the vessel owner’s control of the vessel and her crew (Anderson and Rue 2001). Although the aforementioned apply to oil pollution, there is a clear moral basis that such utterance can be chosen to express a single shared meaning of the contracting parties’ common intention for socially responsible performance. Ultimately, this reflects the value of decreasing their environmental footprint in terms of air emissions and thus creating rights and obligations which increase the abilities of the parties to plan and facilitate commerce in a sustainable manner (Leggatt 2015). By instinct, the promotion of environmental stewardship in charter party contracts can be traced in one respect through the infusion of a sub-clause in the charter party agreements referring to the use of performance monitoring systems provided by the charterers, upon mutual agreement between the parties beforehand. This provision is intended not to place any additional burden on the owners, but merely to indicate that if the use of such equipment aids has been agreed by the parties, then the owners are also under the obligation to use them optimally (Hunter 2012). The corollary of this is that under the common purpose of air emissions reduction, both parties have the duty to carry on negotiations in good faith for pursuing the inclusion of a sharing scheme for the incurred costs of design energy efficiency improvements. Entering the bona fides point and in view of the facts known, it would be expected that the parties act in honest as well as reasonable grounds to conclude their bargaining (Tetley 2004). In this way, to advance own interest, that party is entitled, if the co-operative regime for negotiation could not appropriately serve long term benefits, to threaten to withdraw from further negotiations, in the hope that the opposite party may seek to reopen the negotiations by offering better terms (Hoskins 2014). Hence, such good will clauses may provide agreements with valuable flexibility, allowing a contractual venture to continue in changed circumstances (i.e. extension). The formation of legally binding relations of economic significance justifies a robust approach to determine susceptible enforceable provisions in construing the terms of their agreement, identifying its boundaries and distinct obligations (Hoskins 2014). From a general contract law perspective, when establishing the necessary elements for the formation of a charter party (fixture), the name and characteristics of the vessel constitute among others, the essential terms consented to by owner and charterer in order to constitute agreement on the use of the vessel (Andreu 2001; Anderson 2001). Pursuant to the fixture, the parties negotiate and fine tune the particulars of the essential terms (details), which can also involve deciding specifics on energy efficiency and associated costs. The negotiations conclude upon concurrence of remaining particularities and the contract is deemed binding (Andreu 2001; Anderson 2001). Upon acceptance, the success of the prospective commercial enterprise is assured by declaring commitment to what has been agreed, thus promised and the self-imposed obligation that a return is expected for keeping the promised premises intact (Fried 1981). In line with the touchstone of contract law, the charter party cannot be disintegrated upon disagreement to minor details, since 38 4 Analysis and Findings all terms are equally important. At the same time, it could be argued that “details” are not considered as an acknowledgement of the intent to continue negotiations, but a condition subsequent which satisfies the contract. As discussed previously, details under the common purpose of environmental stewardship can be introduced as an essential term for the conduct of the voyage or inaugurated as a main term at the onset of negotiations and there should be an agreement between the parties before the charter party is “fixed” (Andreu 2001; Anderson 2001). It should be noted that design energy efficiency as a term should have compensatory nature in defining the willingness and ability of the two parties to bear risk (cost). Apparently, such element requires that the size of awards be modified so as to share the risk according to their respective degrees of risk aversion or approximating Pareto efficiency, i.e. the most important risks are separated from the trivial ones (Trimarchi 1991). On this reason, it is important to establish a legal rule (charter clause) that is based on a consideration of the effects deriving from the performance of the energy efficient equipment, where areas for a concerted effort (sharing scheme) are identified. Contracting in advance is necessary because of the very nature of the equipment performance which requires time to be fulfilled (i.e. in realizing the benefits of design energy efficiency improvements). Essentially, an efficient cost allocation is achieved so that the contract is performed as long as the incurred cost is less than the obtained profit (Pareto efficiency). Yet, the implication of this legal rule is to provide an incentive which reasonably aims at solving effectively the energy efficiency sharing scheme by influencing the behavior of the parties at the time they negotiate the contract (Trimarchi 1991). 4.4 Focused Coding: Content Analysis of Charter Party Contracts The theory elaborated through the initial coding is now refined by a more detailed analysis of predetermined subjects as collated from the available charter party forms. It is an iterative process aimed at providing validity of the previous proposal that the vessel’s energy efficiency specification could be contained as a theme by amending or adding relevant clauses. 4.4.1 Information Sources Charter parties are commonly drafted using highly standardized forms specific to the particular trades and business needs of the parties which are available from BIMCO website (BIMCO 2015). It is because the shipping industry is unique in the fact that such contracts are negotiated within a few days or even hours; hence these forms have been established to facilitate the process efficiently. To cater both parties’ needs, these forms are being amended so that good chartering practice is 4.4 Focused Coding: Content Analysis of Charter Party Contracts 39 captured and the evolved market dynamics (bargaining power and balance between the charterer and the owner) are reflected (Collins 2000; Humphries 2014). A list of the 56 analyzed contracts is summarized on Table 4.2, where they are categorized according to market (dry and wet bulk, liner and general) and the themes from the initial coding (time and voyage charters, see Fig. 3.2). 4.4.2 Content Analysis The method for data collection and analysis was presented and explained in the previous chapter and bringing in mind the conceptual schematic of Fig. 3.2, the purpose of content analysis is to organize the qualitative data under higher order headings and group them by creating categories. As shown from Table 4.2, more than fifty standard forms are currently in use, most of which are voyage charter parties covering various trades (i.e. coal, iron ore, fertilizer, timber, minerals and sands, chemicals, liquefied natural gas, crude oil and products). There are also standard forms for tanker charter parties, partly because of the specific characteristics of this type of carriage and partly reflecting the relatively stronger bargaining power of tanker charterers (oil major companies). In addition, some very large charterers (dry bulk) have their own forms of charter parties, whilst general standardized forms as well as for the liner markets exist. 4.4.2.1 Qualitative Data Organization: Main Category The standard forms are supplemented by a myriad of additional clauses (so-called “rider-clauses”), some of which have attained standardized wording themselves and many which are drafted on an ad hoc basis (UNCTAD 1990). An overview of the normal clauses observed in the surveyed standard charter parties is given at Table 4.3, that by no means can be considered as exhaustive. This can be explained by the fact that firstly the various trades have different characteristics of carriage as well as clients’ expectations. Secondly, large companies and charterers also prepare their own private (“in-house”) tailor-made contracts which are not publicly available. From the initial coding, the subject of “seaworthiness” from a technical point of view was identified as a dimension that reflects the fitness of the vessel to withstand the expected hazards of the contemplated voyage laden with cargo. This entails that the vessel shall be equipped and be maintained in a thoroughly efficient state throughout the duration of the charter. 4.4.2.2 Qualitative Data Organization: Generic Categories There are clauses in charter parties referring to the vessel’s dimensions and capabilities, that are important as far as trading is concerned: the vessel’s capacity to 40 4 Analysis and Findings Table 4.2 Standardized charter party forms to be surveyed Market Time charters Voyage charters Dry bulk ASBATIME BALTIME BHPBTIME GENTIME NYPE Wet bulk BIMCHEMTIME BPTIME EXXONMOBILTIME GASTIME INTERTANKTIME SHELLLNGTIME SHELLTIME BOXTIME ROPAXTIME AMWELSH AUSTWHEAT BHPBVOY BLACKSEAWOOD CEMENTVOY COAL-OREVOY FERTICON FERTISOV FERTIVOY GRAINCON HYDROCHARTER MUNTAJATCHARTER MURMAPATIT NANYOZAI NIPPONCOAL BIMCHEMVOY BISCOILVOY BPVOY EXXONMOBILVOY GASVOY Liner General NIPPONORE NORGRAIN NUBALTWOOD PANSTONE POLCOALVOY QAFOCHARTER RIODOCEORE RUSWOOD SCANCON SOVCOAL SOVCONROUND SOVORECON SYNACOMEX WORLDFOOD YARACHARTER GIIGNLLNGVOY INTERCONSEC SHELLVOY TANKERVOY CRUISEVOY GENCON NUVOY Source BIMCO (2015) carry cargo, the vessel’s ability to enter a port and be berthed, the basis on which dues are calculated. With respect to time charters, there are clauses specifying the vessel’s performance as well as the amount of fuel and diesel required to be on-board at the time of delivery and redelivery. The bunker clause in voyage charters allows the ship-owner to proceed to any port on or off the route to take on bunkers. These observations have also been documented by Brodie (2015). 4.4.2.3 Qualitative Data Organization: Sub Categories The clauses referring to the vessel’s description and performance are considered to be related to the vessel’s energy efficiency design specification, whilst their qualitative data systemization and interpretation provide a sound ground for comparison, as shown in Tables 4.4 and 4.5. The results indicate that the focus of the time charter contracts on the vessel’s performance (coded by the vessel’s parameters fuel consumption and speed) is around protecting the commercial relationship between the two parties. Moreover, no merit is given to the vessel’s design energy efficiency 4.4 Focused Coding: Content Analysis of Charter Party Contracts Table 4.3 List of common clauses contained in the standard charter party forms Time charter party Preamble Vessel description Duration of period/description of trip(s) Trading intentions/limits Cargo intentions/exclusions Vessel condition Owner’s responsibilities Charterer’s responsibilities Delivery and redelivery Bunkers Segregated ballastb Hire Off-hire Vessel performance Vessel maintenance Cargo claims Masters and officers Logbooks Supercargo/victualling Pollution Oil major acceptabilityb Emergency responseb Salvage Laying-up Arbitration Lien Assignment Exceptions ITOPFb Requisitions Bills of lading Stevedore damagea Stevedores, pilots, tugs Commissions Loss of vessel Protecting clauses Signatures Voyage charter party Preamble Name and brief description of the vessel Condition of the vessel Cargo quantity and description Loading place Loading port orders/rotation Discharging places and port orders/rotation Laydays and cancelling Freight Cost of loading/discharging Berthing, pumping and mooringb Notice of readiness/time counting Loading/discharging rates Excepted periods Demurrage/dispatch Notices Vessel’s gear Grab discharge/stevedore damagea Overtime Shifting seaworthy trim Cleaning/gradesb Clean ballastb Inert gasb Crude oil washingb Cargo separations and tallying Dues and taxes Port agents Bills of lading Lightening General average ITOPFb Strikes Exceptions Commissions Protecting clauses Lien and cesser Ice War risks Signatures a Common only to the dry bulk market/bCommon only to the wet bulk market Source Compiled by the Author from BIMCO (2015) 41 42 4 Analysis and Findings Table 4.4 Coding sub categories for vessel energy efficiency in time charter parties Market Contract form Bunkers Fuel consumption Energy saving devices Speed Dry bulk ASBATIME BALTIME BHPBTIME GENTIME NYPE BIMCHEMTIME ✓ Fuel oil Grades Grades ✓ Sulphur content and grades ✓ Grades ✓ Grades Sulphur content and grades Grades Sulphur content and grades Sulphur content and grades ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ X X X X X X ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ X X X X X ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ X X ✓ ✓ ✓ X ✓ Wet bulk BPTIME EXXONMOBILTIME GASTIME INTERTANKTIME SHELLLNGTIME Liner SHELLTIME BOXTIME ROPAXTIME Source Developed by the Author specification, despite the fact that fuel consumption is inherently connected to the vessel’s energy efficiency. In addition, reference to the bunkers’ quality is associated with the charterer avoiding any claims and indemnities arising from engine damages (Gorton et al. 2009; Plomaritou 2014). By contrast, in voyage charter contracts, the bunkers and speed interpretation embrace the ship-owner’s or carrier’s right when bunker prices have risen and it has sometimes become difficult to find bunkers. This is in accord to deviate for the purpose of getting bunkers or to proceed at reduced speed so that to get a lower bunker consumption (Gorton et al. 2009). Since the vessel’s owner is responsible for the voyage costs, fuel consumption and thus the vessel’s performance is not taken into account, yielding that design energy efficiency is not negotiated as a term when fixing the vessel. However, in a very limited number of voyage contracts and particularly for wet bulk, a reward as increased freight is allocated when sailing at higher speed, hence emphasizing on fuel consumption (Table 4.5). 4.4 Focused Coding: Content Analysis of Charter Party Contracts 43 Table 4.5 Coding sub categories for vessel energy efficiency in voyage charter parties Market Contract form Bunkers Fuel consumption Energy saving devices Speed Dry bulk AMWELSH AUSTWHEAT BHPBVOY BLACKSEAWOOD CEMENTVOY COAL-OREVOY FERTICON FERTISOV FERTIVOY GRAINCON HYDROCHARTER MUNTAJATCHARTER ✓ X ✓ X ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ X Sulphur content X X ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ X ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ X X X X ✓ X ✓ ✓ X ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ X X X X ✓ X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X ✓ X ✓ X ✓ X X X ✓ X X ✓ X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X ✓ ✓ X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X X ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ X X X ✓ X X X X X X ✓ ✓ X X ✓ ✓ X ✓ ✓ ✓ ✓ Wet bulk MURMAPATIT NANYOZAI NIPPONCOAL NIPPONORE NORGRAIN NUBALTWOOD PANSTONE POLCOALVOY QAFOCHARTER RIODOCEORE RUSWOOD SCANCON SOVCOAL SOVCONROUND SOVORECON SYNACOMEX WORLDFOOD YARACHARTER BIMCHEMVOY BISCOILVOY BPVOY EXXONMOBILVOY GASVOY GIIGNLLNGVOY INTERCONSEC SHELLVOY TANKERVOY (continued) 44 4 Analysis and Findings Table 4.5 (continued) Market Contract form Liner General CRUISEVOY GENCON NUVOY Source Developed by the Author 4.5 Bunkers Fuel consumption Energy saving devices Speed ✓ X X X X X X X X X X ✓ Revisiting the Theory from the Initial Coding The previous subsection provided evidence that the incorporation of the vessel’s design energy efficiency improvements (i.e. installed energy saving devices) has not received attention when preparing the charter party contract, due to the established functional and commercial use of the vessel. It is encouraging though to note that reference to the bunkers’ sulphur content and grades (for time charters in particular) can be from one hand translated as an indication on behalf of the shippers or charterers to transport their goods without any disruption. Hence, by necessity comply with Regulation 14 of MARPOL’s Annex VI on Emission Control Areas (IMO 2012a). From the other hand, it could be argued that this is related to a protecting strategy minimizing the commercial risk arising from the vessel’s operation. In this point, it should be stressed that the promotion of environmental stewardship strengthens the corporate social responsibility image of both charterers or shippers and ship-owners or carriers. Given the need for increased transparency and reporting, such attribute shall not be pursued by adhering only to operational measures (i.e. bunkers, slow steaming, etc.). Further improvement in reducing the environmental footprint of shipping can be additionally attained by the consideration of design energy efficiency measures or devices (see Sect. 2.2.1) that could be included in the contract as a sub-clause referring to the vessel’s design energy efficiency specification. Having design energy efficiency as a negotiated term from the initial stages of the chartering process is expected to provide an incentive supporting both parties’ environmental commitment. Additionally, it furnishes a means for clarifying the costs’ and rewards’ distribution of the will to invest in design energy efficiency measures. These parameters can represent the substantive (technical and economic) constituent of negotiations. What is more, an activity is sketched where the two parties with diverging interests search for agreement despite a difference in their points of view as well as traditional behavior emanating from agency theory (Pannebakker 2013). This is illustrated by the charterer or shipper who would like to minimize the transportation cost, whilst the ship-owner or carrier would like to maximize income (see Sect. 2.4). Indeed, such clause can be instrumental in firstly having the capacity to enable both parties and empower them for advancing the collective interest of environmental stewardship. Secondly, it stimulates the continuous improvement of the vessel’s energy efficiency and emulates the reinvestment into efficiency upgrades. Thirdly, it determines the legal status of the 4.5 Revisiting the Theory from the Initial Coding 45 obligation to comply with air emissions regulations. This constructive tailoring can also be interpreted as a form of control restraining the traditional behavior of both charterers or shippers and ship-owners or carriers by changing the principles that govern their long established relationship (Messenger 2016). Another argument put forward for the implicit reasoning of design energy efficiency as a rider-clause becoming legally operative, is the consideration of close analogies within the doctrine of precedent in oil and air pollution (see Sect. 4.3). These are concerned with an intelligible rationale nested within the wider body of law used to help resolve unsettled issues. The conjecture by reliance depends on an intuitive appreciation of the similarity between previous rulings on relevant cases and the case at hand. On an orthodox understanding, the ruling holds that given the facts (i.e. vessel movements and a duty of care breach) certain legal consequences follow (liability to pay damages to third parties arising from pollution) (Lamond 2014). Hence, the binding of rulings and the rationales for those rulings creates a close regard for internal doctrinal coherence between analogy and precedence. Because at a higher level of generality air pollution as a novel context is comparable to oil pollution, the view is taken that the outcome of the latter cases should be followed unless the facts of the air pollution case provide some basis for reaching a different conclusion (Lamond 2014). This cornerstone of common law reasoning constitutes a good rational canon for incorporating a vessel design energy efficiency specification rider-clause pointing the desirability to eliminate the legal consequences. Part III Quantitative Part Chapter 5 Chartering Negotiations for Energy Efficiency Abstract The fifth chapter introduces the reader to the quantitative part, which is devoted to answering the fundamental question how to design the energy efficiency sharing scheme mechanism and its connection to the chartering procedure. In this respect, game theory offers a wide range of models that can be adjusted to appropriately represent the incentive mixture for energy efficiency. Firstly, the principal-agent problem is utilized for determining the difference between the two players’ reservation prices (hire for time and freight for voyage charter) as well as their information asymmetry related to energy efficiency. This forms the basis where the negotiations can begin. Secondly, the two players are given the opportunity to split the difference between them with alternating offers which resembles a bargaining game and results to the contracted price. Then, for the given vessel revenue performance, discounted cash flow analysis is performed to investigate whether the EEISS is profitable and the expense can be justified. 5.1 Preamble Since the empirics of chartering are so complex, it is not attempted to develop any theoretical models, but instead apply well established concepts and approaches. The chartering negotiations between a ship-owner/carrier and a charterer/shipper are aimed at inaugurating consensus. Thus, the entailed interplay dynamics is modeled through game theory, a mathematical study of strategic decision making between intelligent and rational players. It treats the general principles that prescribe how each participant within a social or trade exchange behaves in every situation which may conceivably arise. For each specific alternative, the participant attaches a quantity (utility) that describes own fulfilment of needs and wishes about certain aspects of the world (i.e. compensation). Consequently, every participant is influenced by the anticipated reactions of the others to the participant’s own utilities and choices and they in turn reflect the other participant’s expectation of that participant’s own actions. This characterizes rational behavior, where in concrete © Springer International Publishing Switzerland 2017 G.A. Psarros, Energy Efficiency Clauses in Charter Party Agreements, Springer Series on Naval Architecture, Marine Engineering, Shipbuilding and Shipping 3, DOI 10.1007/978-3-319-50265-6_5 49 50 5 Chartering Negotiations for Energy Efficiency instances a choice between various alternatives has to be made (i.e. agency costs, accept offer or counteroffer) by either one of the participants, or by some device subject to chance denoted as nature (Von Neumann and Morgenstern 2004). 5.2 Theoretical Applications of Games Within Chartering In recent years, game theory has gained an increased focus on capturing key aspects of maritime commerce such as the interactions of shippers and carriers, supply chain integration, fleet deployment, route implementation, chartering and freight decisions (Yang et al. 2010; Shi and Voß 2011). When arranging the employment of a vessel, the charterer or shipper would like to minimize the transportation cost, whereas the ship-owner or carrier would like to maximize income, thus the two players have opposite goals. Due to the possibility to bid for cargoes and on realizing that the lowest offer will win, the latter (ship-owners or carriers) are price takers since they accept the freight rate offered in the market as given (McConville 1999). The power for reaching an agreement is not uniform, as some charterers may have stronger power than others and similarly some owners may have more power than others. For example, weak owners will opt for lower rates from stronger parties, whilst charterers not fixing cargoes on unknown numerous intermediaries or to owners not perceived to be weak will pay higher rate. Hence, the freight rate over a particular cargo is the outcome of iterated negotiations that happen at the same or approximately the same time in different places, balancing expectations of overall demand and supply in a particular market segment or the entire market. The process thus consists of a game where the two players negotiate over a known market price until the charter contract rate is achieved (equilibrium) and both parties are satisfied (Karakitsos and Varnavides 2014). This novel approach on determining the price for the shipping service (freight) as well as modeling the contracting procedure has not attracted yet the meticulous attention of academic research, though very few studies have been published. The value of information in terms of vessel quality while negotiating for a voyage charter has been investigated by Bergantino and Veenstra (2002), whilst the effect of contractual variation in vessel speed and fuel consumption as translated through an underperformance claim during a time charter has been explored by Veenstra and van Dalen (2011). The division of the equilibrium freight rate’s payoff (profit or loss) between the charterer and the ship-owner during the pre-fixture process (reservation vs market price) of a voyage charter has been determined by Suh and Park (2010). Tezuka and Ishii (2008) examine the formation of the equilibrium freight rates in the spot market; whereas later this work is extended further by incorporating the behavior of ship-owners who wish to balance the supply of shipping services (Tezuka and Ishii 2011). Tezuka et al. (2012) address how to utilize shipping derivatives to describe the risk attitudes of ship-owners and charterers, whilst Ishizaka et al. (2012) augment their study with the impact of the market’s volatility on the shares of listed shipping companies. The strategic 5.2 Theoretical Applications of Games Within Chartering 51 decisions of two competing ship-owners on investing in fleet expansion through the influence of freight rates on vessel speed and bunker is analyzed by Kou and Luo (2016). With respect to contract performance, the game theoretical analysis conducted by Zhou (2010) investigated the seller’s (charterer’s) payoff when repudiation to the charter party occurs due to own decision to breach the agreement subject to a cancellation clause. Anderlini et al. (2007) modeled the magnitude of the effects of unforeseen contingencies (i.e. force majeure) on profit maximization by excusing performance of the contract between a risk neutral buyer (shipper) and a risk averse seller (carrier). The selection (matching) of cargoes by carriers and vessels by shippers through a price game considering also the time where the vessel is available to satisfy the transportation demand was studied by Peng et al. (2016). Their work focused on how the non-dominant market players manage to gain bigger surplus by adjusting the bidding time charter hire until advantageous pairing is achieved and the equilibrium price is settled. In the following, it is demonstrated how game theory can be applied within charter contracts to allocate the investment sharing scheme of design energy efficiency improvements. 5.3 Game Theory Model for Sharing Scheme Determination Game theory is understood to provide valuable insights into the mechanisms that may encourage viewing design energy efficiency improvements as a way of obtaining competitive advantage through a differentiation focus, rather than simply regulatory compliance where only a license to operate is assigned. Intuitively, the investment in innovative technologies achieves environmental friendliness that is sufficiently valued by both buyers and sellers of ocean freight to allow a price premium, increases commitment to service and can improve brand recognition as well as customer loyalty (Johnson et al. 2011). By placing a weighting on the freight rate it is possible to perceive the optimum reward for energy efficiency which determines a fair service payment and resolves the level of contribution between the contractual parties. The magnitude of ratios governs the sharing scheme and it is proportional to the strength of motivation and thus bargaining power to reduce or remove inequity, an unpleasant experience causing tension (Mullins et al. 2013). The initial bid from a ship-owner/carrier (agent) might specify the vessel’s name, deadweight, the date and place when she is open, possible voyage and an idea of the rate required (agent’s reservation price). A charterer/shipper (principal) would state the size and type of the cargo, readiness and laycan dates, voyage and also the rate sought (expected market price—principal’s reservation price). Once a potential match is found between a vessel and a cargo, the agent is able to estimate the costs of the proposed voyage and the exchange of correspondence becomes more 52 5 Chartering Negotiations for Energy Efficiency detailed. Since the rate is subject to the market’s behavior (trough: low rates or peak: high rates) as well as the availability of other committed cargoes and vessels in the area, it is possible that the rate may change when the agent makes a bid at a later stage (Brodie 2015). From a practical point of view, negotiating the sharing scheme for energy efficiency investments within a charter contract can fall under the standard routine of any chartering procedure (Gorton et al. 2009; Panayides 2014; Collins 2000). To put things into perspective, it contains the establishment of a stipend component, plus a series of “offers” and “counter offers” albeit to the obligation that each party has to respond within a fixed time limit. It consists of two parts, firstly determination of the ship-owner’s/carrier’s reservation price and secondly bargaining for splitting the surplus (difference in reservation prices). The former can be analyzed in the context of a principal—agent relationship, since both parties may not be equally aware of the energy efficiency performance. Hence the two players possess asymmetric information. For instance, the principal (charterer/shipper) is less- or un-informed, due to coarser information; whilst the agent (ship-owner/carrier) is better- or well-informed, due to finer information (Rasmusen 2007). When the parties are in agreement, further consultations take place about the details and the wording of the respective clause (sharing scheme). A diagrammatic representation of the mechanism design is depicted in Fig. 5.1, with each part described in the subsequent sections. Principal – Agent energy efficiency investment information asymmetry for the reserved freight rate Charterer / Shipper (Principal) Charter Party Contract with EEISS clause Ship-owner / Carrier (Agent) Bargaining the energy efficiency investment equilibrium freight rate Fig. 5.1 Simple schematic illustrating the contract mechanism design for the EEISS. Source Author 5.3 Game Theory Model for Sharing Scheme Determination 5.3.1 53 Principal—Agent Part The energy efficiency investment clause implies that the buyer—B (charterer/ shipper—principal) pays a fixed proportion of the installed technology cost (incentive contract) so that the seller—S (ship-owner/carrier—agent) can appropriate the return. Hence, the seller’s reservation price should account for the energy efficiency expenditure during the initial bid and form the basis of a good negotiable point. In order to design the optimal response, the buyer’s difficulties in monitoring and observing the seller’s character (i.e. energy efficiency performance) shall be considered. Such setting falls under the general family of principal-agent problems and of interest are two categories. The first one is when the principal (buyer) has complete information concerning the agent’s (seller’s) character, without being able to control it (moral hazard with hidden action). The second one is when the principal has incomplete information about the character of the agent, who has to be induced to sincerely report details (adverse selection with screening) (Levin 2003). Bearing in mind that there are two types of transactions for the services for transporting cargoes by sea (Gorton et al. 2009; Stopford 2009), the aforementioned principal-agent problem applications are outlined hereunder. 5.3.1.1 Time Charter In the time charter, the charterer/shipper (principal) hires per day a ship-owner’s/ carrier’s (agent’s) vessel for satisfying own transport needs. The price reflects the market’s behavior and is denoted as FRM. The agent’s task is to determine the customized premium accounting for energy efficiency that will form the basis for the negotiations. The principal cares for and knows the vessel’s performance (fuel consumption), but is not aware of the agent’s effort level (cost for improved energy efficiency). This situation resembles the moral hazard problem with hidden action and is portrayed by the simple game tree in Fig. 5.2. It is assumed that the principal (B) offers the agent (S) a contract and an effort level π (high or low) has been chosen by the agent. The result of the decided effort level is stated as “Nature—N” (Rasmusen 2007). accept contract B S Market freight rate: FRM effort, π S1 N Forming the basis of negotiations Reserved freight rate: FR RT Fig. 5.2 Simple diagram showing the game tree for the principal (B)—agent (S) problem of moral hazard with hidden action between a charterer/shipper B and a ship-owner/carrier S. Source Adapted by Author from Rasmusen (2007) 54 5 Chartering Negotiations for Energy Efficiency Then, it is necessary to strike the best possible effort level π (percentage of FRM) that balances the interests of both contracted parties. The model utilized here builds on Holmström (1979) with the analytical solution presented in Bolton and Dewatripont (2005). The agent’s effort level affects the principal’s gains from trade [commodity price (cp: $/t) × commodity quantity (cq: t)] in terms of reduced bunker fuel expenses [contract duration (d: days) × bunker price (bp: $/t) × bunker consumption (bc: t/day)] in comparison to the standard vessel. The vessel with design energy efficiency improvements is a costly decision to the agent; hence the principal has to compensate the agent for the incurred investment. The compensation level C(π) should be as appropriate as to induce the agent to maintain the contract with the greater possible return to the principal. In this respect, the principal expects to earn a higher residual profit when the compensation level strictly increases with high technology cost (tc: $) but at a decreasing rate (Miller and Whitford 2007). The charterer’s/shipper’s [B(π)] and ship-owner’s/carrier’s [S(π)] utility functions as well as the compensation level can be given as: BðpÞ ¼ cp cq d bp bc d FRM d FRM e1p ð5:1Þ S(pÞ ¼ d FRM þ d FRM e1p tc ð5:2Þ C(pÞ ¼ d FRM þ d FRM e1p ð5:3Þ The best possible effort level π can be derived from Bolton and Dewatripont (2005): C0 ðpÞ ¼ B00 ðpÞ k S00 ðpÞ þ B00 ðpÞ ð5:4Þ B0 ðpjFRH Þ S0 ðpjFRH Þ ð5:5Þ with: k¼ where FRH is associated with the historical development of freight rates and it represents the agent’s outside option (i.e. keep the vessel running). Equations (5.4) and (5.5) cannot be solved analytically and the computer program Mathcad (PTC 2014) will be utilized to find the best possible effort level π. In conclusion, the agent’s reserved freight rate FRRT yields: FRRT ¼ FRM ð1 þ pÞ 5.3.1.2 ð5:6Þ Voyage Charter In the voyage charter, the charterer/shipper (principal) buys transport from the ship-owner/carrier (agent) with the freight rate agreed on a lump sum basis per ton of 5.3 Game Theory Model for Sharing Scheme Determination 55 cargo. This amount covers all the incurred expenses for the contract’s duration, such as voyage, operating and capital costs (Gorton et al. 2009; Stopford 2009). The price reflects the market’s behavior and is denoted as FRM. The agent’s task is to determine the customized premium accounting for energy efficiency that will form the basis for the negotiations. Admittedly, the agent is selected for enhancing the principal’s corporate responsibility disclosure in terms of environmental stewardship. The principal does not know the agent’s environmental stewardship attributes, since the agent is privately informed on the investment expenditure with cost tc ($). In response to that, the agent provides credentials with the anticipation to obtain a premium for the vessel’s design energy efficiency improvements. This state of affairs can be highlighted by the adverse selection problem with screening and is rendered by the simple game tree in Fig. 5.3. “Nature—N” is defined as the decision to invest in environmental stewardship, π (high or low). The principal (B) as an uninformed player, offers the agent (S) a contract that might depend on the agent’s environmental stewardship attribute, which is communicated as a cue (installed technologies described in SEEMP) and is an observable characteristic (Rasmusen 2007). The prime concern is to derive the best, i.e. profit maximizing value of π (percentage of FRM) that the agent will be able to induce the principal to choose. Thus, the agent is accorded an “informational rent” from the principal so that the private information on environmental stewardship is elicited. The analysis of this problem had been credited to Mirrlees (1971), which is rigorously explored by Bolton and Dewatripont (2005) and the model reported herein is inspired by their work. The principal has to offer for all types of agent’s environmental stewardship (low and high) the same menu of options, being reflected with preference characteristics σL and σH respectively (σL < σH): rL ¼ e tcL cq cp ð5:7Þ tcH cq rH ¼ e cp ð5:8Þ where tci: technology cost i 2 {L: Low, H: High } ($), cp: commodity price ($/t) and cq: commodity quantity (t). The agent is of type σL with probability β 2 [0, 1] and of type σH with probability (1 − β). The probability β can also be interpreted as high, π N B low, π contract S1 Market freight rate: FRM accept S2 Forming the basis of negotiations Reserved freight rate: FRRV Fig. 5.3 Simple diagram showing the game tree for the principal (B)—agent (S) problem of adverse selection with screening between a charterer/shipper B and a ship-owner/carrier S. Source Adapted by Author from Rasmusen (2007) 56 5 Chartering Negotiations for Energy Efficiency the proportion of agents of type σL which can be obtained through vetting, for instance RightShip (2016). If the agent has attained environmental certification (publicly available), the principal can infer that boosting corporate responsibility is not too difficult and will consequently want to reduce the informational rent on environmental stewardship. This directly implies that the commitment to partial disclosure (i.e. SEEMP) is ex-ante incentive compatible and individually rational for both parties. The principal’s ex-post information rent can be eliminated because the value of misrepresenting ex-post information is diminished. Thus, revealing less information in the first period of the negotiations is beneficial to the agent and reduces the principal’s informational rents at a decreasing rate (Krähmer and Strausz 2015). The principal’s preferences can be expressed by the utility function: cp B ðpÞ ¼ ri cp cq pi e1FRM pi cq FRM ð1 þ pi Þ |fflffli{zfflffl} ð5:9Þ i2fL; H g Assuming that the agent’s marginal cost (technology cost (tc, $)/cargo quantity (cq, t)) is given by mc, the profit from transporting the cargo can be evaluated by: Si ðpÞ ¼ cq FRM ð1 þ pi Þ cq mc |ffl{zffl} ð5:10Þ i2fL; H g The optimum pair value of π (πL < πH) can be entertained from (Bolton and Dewatripont 2005): cp 1FRcp pH M rH cp cq e pH e ¼ mc ð5:11Þ FRM cp mc 1FRcp pL 1FRcp pL M M [ mc rL cp cq e pL e ¼ 1b rH rL FRM 1 b rL 1FRcp pH M ð5:12Þ If the denominator in (5.12) is not positive, the optimum solution involves πL = 0, while the other agent’s type remains determined by (5.11) (Bolton and Dewatripont 2005). Equations (5.11) and (5.12) cannot be solved analytically and the computer program Mathcad (PTC 2014) will be utilized to estimate the best possible rent pair π. In conclusion, the reserved freight rate yields: FRRV ¼ FRM ð1 þ b pL þ ð1 bÞ ½pH ðpH pL Þ pL Þ ð5:13Þ 5.3 Game Theory Model for Sharing Scheme Determination 5.3.2 57 Bargaining Part In this subsection, the equilibrium freight rate is determined accounting for the negotiations related to offsetting the expectations of energy efficiency. The model is based on the bargaining work of alternating offers from Rubinstein (1982) as exemplified by Bierman and Fernandez (1998). Let’s consider a charterer/shipper (buyer—B) and a ship-owner/carrier (seller—S) who are bargaining over the division of a surplus q (difference of their reservation prices QB = FRM and QS = FRRT/V respectively, QB < QS) with alternate offers. The delay in reaching an agreement imposes a cost on the negotiations which is associated with the discounting of future trade gains relative to present trade gains and is referred to as discount factor (impatience). It is admitted that the energy efficiency investment sharing will not be the same for the contract parties (asymmetric impatience), implying that their discount factors δB and δS are not necessarily equal, though are strictly positive and no greater than one (Bierman and Fernandez 1998). Certainly, the delay cost hurts more the ship-owner/carrier rather than the charterer/shipper (δB < δS) due to the assigned capital. This entails that the ship-owner/ carrier can expect less generous share (θB > θS) since the charterer/shipper has the incentive to reduce its partition, partly reflecting own relatively stronger bargaining power. Hence, it may be better for the charterer/shipper to wait for a larger expected share (translated into soared gain) than to increase the probability of settling early with a smaller expected share. As an outcome, it will be the weaker party’s (ship-owner/carrier) negotiation flexibility to accept the other party’s proposal (Ellingsen and Miettinen 2014). Then, there is a unique perfect equilibrium freight rate agreed after an infinite number of rounds (Fig. 5.4), where each party’s fraction (weight) of the surplus is Bierman and Fernandez (1998): 1 dS 1 d S dB ð5:14Þ dS ð1 dB Þ 1 dS dB ð5:15Þ hB ¼ hS ¼ The discount factors can be calculated as the reduction of gains per day from trade for each party, normalized by the technology investment and vessel cost per day. In the case of charterer/shipper, the delay is associated with holding physical stocks of the commodity (cargo to be transported) over the negotiation period and is defined as cost of carry (Pindyck 2001): dB ¼ icpcq 365 þ sc tc þ vp 365 ð5:16Þ With i: the interest rate, cp: commodity price ($/t), cq: commodity quantity (t), sc: storage cost ($/day), tc: technology cost ($) and vp: vessel price ($). The storage 58 5 Chartering Negotiations for Energy Efficiency Negotiations begin: QB , QS Round 0: B δB|0 , δS|0 , FRE|0 offer S Round 1: accept δB|1 , δS|1 , FRE|1 counteroffer End: Fixture confirmed, main terms & freight rate agreed End: Fixture confirmed, main terms & freight rate agreed accept B Round 2: δB|2 , δS|2 , FRE|2 counteroffer S accept counteroffer ……… End: Fixture confirmed, main terms & freight rate agreed ……… Round n∞: δB| n∞ , δS| n∞ , FRE| n∞ counteroffer End: Negotiations terminated reject S accept End: Fixture confirmed, main terms & freight rate agreed Fig. 5.4 Simple diagram showing the game tree for bargaining between a charterer/shipper B and a ship-owner/carrier S with alternating offers and asymmetric impatience. Source Adapted by Author from Bierman and Fernandez (1998) cost can be provided as a percentage of the commodity cost, where the coefficient ω has been estimated in Symeonidis et al. (2012) and Frankel (2014): sc ¼ 1 ex cp cq 365 100 ð5:17Þ For the ship-owner/carrier, the delay is due to the lost earnings le ($/day) and depreciation cost dc ($/day): 5.3 Game Theory Model for Sharing Scheme Determination dS ¼ le þ dc tc þ vp 365 59 ð5:18Þ The declining balance depreciation is chosen because it is impossible to reduce the vessel’s value to zero at the end of her expected useful life. Under this method, the depreciation amount charged every year is an amount less than the previous year; hence a fixed rate is applied to an annually changing vessel value. This entails that larger amounts are appropriated during the initial years of the vessel’s life. So, the depreciation rate rdep per annum basis can be given from Liapis and Kantianis (2015): rdep ¼ 1 rv 1n ac ð5:19Þ where rv: vessel’s residual value ($), for instance resale (second hand) or scrap price, ac: vessel’s acquisition cost ($) and n: vessel’s expected useful life (operational horizon). It follows from the aforementioned discussion, as supported by the influential work of Akerlof (1982) that the negotiated (equilibrium) freight rate (FRET/V) the charterer/shipper is agreeing to pay is more than the minimum market freight rate FRM. However, the ship-owner/carrier is accepting a fixture not as much as the reservation price and is less than the maximum rate at which the transportation service can be sold (hence opt for the smaller surplus fraction): FRET=V ¼ FRM þ hS q ð5:20Þ To ensure that the contractual freight rate has been drawn-up accordingly, hence the sharing scheme clause will perform as expected; it is necessary to investigate how the energy efficiency premium affects the revenues of the vessel. This aspect is dealt with in the subsequent section. 5.4 Energy Efficiency Investment Appraisal To assure that the aforementioned EEISS justifies the capital expenditure and leads to the greatest increase in the value of the ship-owner/carrier, it is necessary to consider the magnitude of expected cash flows, their timing (through discounting) and their associated risk (through the selected discounting rate). To this end, the NPV method of investment appraisal is considered appropriate since it results in a discounted stream of cash in-/out-flows and its foundation is attributed to Hirshleifer (1958). Reasons supporting its wider applicability cover: (i) changes in the discount rate can be easily incorporated, (ii) cash flows of different sign in successive periods can be accommodated, (iii) mutually exclusive investments can be selected and (iv) it is assumed that the generated cash flows can be reinvested 60 5 Chartering Negotiations for Energy Efficiency elsewhere at a rate equal to the cost of capital. Cash flows occurring during a time period are assumed to occur at the end of the period, whilst the initial investment occurs at the start of the first period. Intuitively, a positive value indicates that the investment is expected to provide a return in excess of the cost of capital (target rate of return to discount the relevant cash flows) (Watson and Head 2013). The generic algebraic formula for NPV can be represented as: NPV ¼ I0 þ C1 C2 C3 Cn þ þ þ...þ 2 3 ð1 þ r Þ ð1 þ r Þ ð1 þ r Þn ð1 þ r Þ ð5:21Þ where I0 is the initial investment, C1, C2, C3, …, Cn are the cash flows generated in years 1, 2, 3,…, n and r is the cost of capital or required rate of return (Watson and Head 2013). It is generally accepted that in the investment appraisal, a WACC should be used as the discount rate, since it provides an indication of ‘financial gearing’ or ‘leverage’ between the main components of finance: debt (FD) and equity (FE) capital (Modigliani and Miller 1958). Debt reflects the borrowed capital, whereas equity represents own capital and thus ownership stake in the business (Ross et al. 2013). Each of these components is supplied at a cost, which are then combined (Brigham and Houston 2013): rWACC ¼ FD FE rD ð1 T Þ þ ðrRF þ bS RPM Þ FD þ FE FD þ FE ð5:22Þ where: rD (1 − T) is the tax adjusted cost of debt since interest on debt is tax deductible, and rRF + βS RPM is the equity cost component equal to the risk free rate (average investment return) plus a market risk premium RPM (usually estimated by government securities) scaled up or down by a coefficient βS to reflect the systematic risk (economic growth, inflation and exchange rates changes) (Brigham and Houston 2013). By way of reference, the equity cost component is estimated by the CAPM and is based on the ground breaking work of Sharpe (1964). It is an equilibrium asset pricing theory showing that the equilibrium expected return on all risky assets is a function of their covariance with the market portfolio (Ross et al. 2013). It should be borne in mind that the choice of the appropriate risk premium as well as systematic risk, financial gearing level and risk free rate has attracted a wide range of academic research (see Mason et al. 2016 for a review) and these issues are considered out of the current book’s scope. Though, it is emphasized that knowing where informed judgement has been employed in the cost of capital calculation and what is reasonable range, are more important aspects than scientific precision (Arnold 2010). From (5.22), it is evident that shipping companies (common to any borrower) would like to minimize the cost of capital by asking the highest leverage (debt to value) possible, since debt is cheaper than equity, i.e. 4–8%, whereas creditors will seek a premium on higher debt to value ratios (Brauner and Illingworth 2009). Indeed, it was recently reported (Albertijn et al. 2011) that shipping companies have 5.4 Energy Efficiency Investment Appraisal 61 traditionally operated with fairly leveraged capital structures which are accompanied with lower operating leverage albeit to market volatility. This entails that the companies are exposed to larger operational risk which sets constraints in the companies’ debt capacity and restricting their access to the public debt market (i.e. bonds). Hence, in order to avoid facing higher financial distress costs, the more flexible but nominally more expensive bank debt is preferred in a sense that is more efficient in rewriting debt contracts with banks than with bondholders. Although the banks are becoming increasingly risk averse, asset-backed securities that contain shipping loans remain attractive since generally good collateral is provided and thus debt capacity is increased (Albertijn et al. 2011). The loan proposal can be placed at 65% of the vessel’s current market value with 1% arrangement fee charged in the first year, a tenor of 7 years and repayment in equal annual instalments. With 600 basis points (6.0%) the bank’s funding rate (Germany et al. 2014), the cost of debt can be made at a ‘spread’ over the bank’s funding rate, for example LIBOR, plus 200 basis points (2.0%) (Stopford 2009). For realizing the tax benefit, the OECD values on corporate tax can be used (OECD 2016). As far as the equity component cost parameters, the average investment return of shipping companies has been reported in Stopford (2009), the systematic risk for shipping has been estimated by Drobetz et al. (2014b) and the risk premium can be obtained from Dimson et al. (2015). The RFR (FRR) is a criterion for investment appraisal within shipping and is a variation of the NPV formula. By setting NPV = 0 it provides information on the cost level that needs to be covered by freight revenue (break-even point). Furthermore, it can be used to determine whether the contracted freight rate as estimated by (5.13) and (5.20) is profitable. The algebraic formula for obtaining FRR can be expressed in the following way (Schinas and Kewitsch 2015): NPV ¼ 0 ! n X d ½FRR ð1 bf Þ Xt CapExt OpExt VCt ðrWACC þ 1Þn t¼1 ð5:23Þ where: δ is a coefficient reflecting the annual number of commodity loadings, Xt is the expected payload in year t (voyage charter) or the expected hire period (time charter), bf is the brokerage fee (2.5% on average), CapExt, OpExt and VCt (only for voyage charter) are the expected costs in year t, rWACC the cost of capital used for discounting and n the vessel’s expected life (operational horizon). Only relevant cash flow components in (5.23) need to be included, with a typical classification constituting of capital costs—CapEx (loan principal and interest, arrangement fee and depreciation), operating costs—OpEx (manning, insurance, repairs and maintenance, stores, spares and supplies, management and administration) and voyage costs—VC (bunkers, cargo handling, port charges and canal dues) (Stopford 2009; Gorton et al. 2009). The latter costs are quite challenging to be estimated, since voyage details are unknown. To deal with this obstacle, it is claimed by Stopford (2009) that bunkers account for the majority of the voyage costs (3/4) with the remaining quarter 62 5 Chartering Negotiations for Energy Efficiency associated with the other constituents. Hence, for a known bunker cost, it can be argued that the voyage costs could be estimated from the bunker costs, multiplied by a factor of 4/3. The bunker costs are a function of the vessel’s fuel consumption which in turn is approximately proportional to the third power of vessel’s speed. This cubic relationship has been accepted as reasonable assumption for relating changes in speed Vi and consumption bci to the vessel’s design speed V0 and consumption bc0 (Alderton 1981; Ronen 1982). Common practice allows a reasonable margin for the time charter contract speed (Collins 2000; Gorton et al. 2009) which has been reported by Veenstra and van Dalen (2011) to be in the range of 0.3—0.5 knots (depending on vessel type) and a deviation of 0.3 knots. It is argued then that the adjusted fuel consumption can be estimated as: Vi bci ¼ bc0 V0 3 ð5:24Þ The vessel over her expected investment life wears out in equal proportions; hence this cost should be deducted from the revenues each year [reference (5.19)]. Apparently, a longer investment horizon results into less annual depreciation (Stopford 2009). An indication of whether the energy efficiency sharing scheme increases the value (wealth) of the agent (carrier or ship-owner) has been given by (5.23). Since there is great deal of uncertainty about future cash flows, it is appropriate to investigate their risk related to the time distance from the scheme’s implementation date as associated with the incurred technology cost (project). Hence, for those cases where the contracted (equilibrium) freight rate is larger than the minimum required freight value, it is worthy to determine the number of years it is expected to take to recover the cost expenditure from the forecasted net discounted cash flows resulting from a capital investment project. This estimated timeframe is defined as payback period which provides information about a company’s liquidity and risk. It can be argued that the shorter the payback, the greater the project’s liquidity and the lesser the company’s exposure to risk. Furthermore, in situations of capital shortage (limited funds) there is an advantage in receiving a return earlier than later since reinvestment in other profitable opportunities is allowed (Arnold 2010; Watson and Head 2013). For a given annual cash flow output at time t yielding NPVt, the payback period TPB can be estimated as (Kim et al. 2013): TPB ¼ t NPVt NPVt þ 1 NPVt ð5:25Þ where t* is the last year that the NPV has a negative value and t* + 1 is the first year that the NPV becomes positive and remains positive. Due to the inherent uncertainty of the forecasted discounted cash flows and to include the random variation, it is assumed that the payback period is normally distributed (Weingartner 1969). 5.5 Conceptualizing the Generated Knowledge 5.5 63 Conceptualizing the Generated Knowledge The ancillary clause inclusion is created by the parties’ asymmetric information on a variety of issues (investment cost, vessel performance, environmental attributes) in addition to bargaining power. Under this view, game theory is useful in structuring the contractual provisions of the EEISS since not only the potential gains from trade are realized, but also the fiduciary obligations of the parties are specified. Thus, the contractual equilibrium is produced through an immutable rule set in a manner that the parties’ welfare is enhanced and their private information is optimally allocated (Ayres and Gertner 1992). Accordingly, the incentive mechanism designed through game theory is established bona fide since it generates value for both players as well as it allows pre-commitment to intrinsically plain and unequivocal language. On this conjecture, any player who has institutionalized a reputation of honesty will have a competitive advantage by being offered more attractive contracts. Nevertheless, it is transcended from common sense that when writing down extra few sincere sentences while negotiating the main terms of the charter party agreement, adds little to the cost (economies of scale) (Rasmusen 2001). In this setting, it is conventional wisdom for the many players participating regularly in the market that the mechanism is standardized in some fashion. Certainly, it is recognized by the contracting parties that such ‘boilerplate’ leaves blank space to be filled with the essential economic terms. Besides, the intention is to provide well-defined and successful ways of dividing the trade surplus, to reduce the social costs of the parties’ strategic behavior, to promote an ongoing cooperation and to encourage the desire to maintain goodwill (Katz 1990). This emphasis has been sustained through the game models outlined in the current chapter, which can usefully guide the development of a rider clause related to the vessel’s design energy efficiency improvements. Under the auspices of such clause, it is then possible to predict how aware the players are of the extent to which they are ignorant about the vessel’s energy efficiency. From the analysis portrayed in the current chapter, the reader is persuaded that this regime has been comprehensively treated. Given that sellers (ship-owners or carriers) are bearing the cost of the (innovative) technology installed onboard, it is to their interest to provide a level of energy efficiency beyond the minimum and to alert buyers (charterers or shippers) to the fact they have done so. Once the effort and attributes are learned, the insights gained the game model presented herein can help highlight the incentive mechanism design and illuminate the terms in which the parties choose to contract. Understandably, during the course of negotiation, a norm is imposed that is subject to the players’ protection against unusually oppressive terms and commercial reasonableness (Katz 1990). Explicitly, the aforementioned lines of argument while bargaining the EEISS clause stipulate that evidence shall be provided with respect to the vessel’s performance, taking into account the data available from the vessel’s condition monitoring systems. The contractual provisions can be detailed with the 64 5 Chartering Negotiations for Energy Efficiency indispensable guidance of BIMCO’s distilled experience on chartering aspects (BIMCO 2016). For example, the wording of the clause shall be formulated by considering how slow steaming influences the operation of the installed energy efficiency equipment (technical and safety recommendations published by the manufacturer/designer). Furthermore, subject to the Master’s obligation to ensure the safety of the vessel, her crew, cargo and protection of the marine environment, due diligence shall be exercised to prevent contradiction with other clauses (i.e. utmost and/or due dispatch). Additionally, the contracted parties shall establish the elements to comply with (basis of measurement, means of verification and term of application) and the remedies for violation which constitute a breach of the contract. Such protection measures and controls shall be clearly stated so that the charter party contract is mutually maintained and the rise of any claim leading to costly and unpredictable arbitration awards is avoided (BIMCO 2016). The most important merit of the energy efficiency clause is that both parties have ownership of environmental stewardship, thus achieving brand recognition. It is also a proactive approach (industry mediated standard) which can ensure that technological innovations can be realized. Chapter 6 Application—Ocean Grain Transportation Abstract Having outlined the principal-agent and bargaining games as foundation tools for modeling the chartering negotiations inclusive of the EEISS appraisal, we are now in position to appreciate the capabilities of this approach. The forthcoming developments in the text indicate how informed decision making can be realized when these models are entertained with data. By necessity, this chapter is concentrated on demonstrating the practical viability of the suggested techniques through an illustrative case study, where the material is presented in a gradual quest for problem solving. The working example is focused on seaborne grain transport since it is acknowledged that grain is one of the most important commodities around the world. 6.1 Preamble The difficulty of understanding the feasibility of alternatives or searching for the next alternative involves additional procedural features beyond those captured by the utilized cognitive processes and the finer the collated information is filtered. Decisions are made rationally when a strict preference relation over the various sets of alternatives exists and depends on the identity (classification) of the best alternative encountered so far. Therefore, maximization of the expected utility is used as a measure of performance when a choice is made that satisfies the necessary requirements for pursuing a fair and honest determination of EEISS (Salant 2011). The latter is evidently treated through the selected case study where, as acclaimed by Thomson (1883), when any entity is measured and quantified, then, it is possible for anyone to be acquainted with its meanings as well as properties, and this is considered the starting point of systematically studying its structure. © Springer International Publishing Switzerland 2017 G.A. Psarros, Energy Efficiency Clauses in Charter Party Agreements, Springer Series on Naval Architecture, Marine Engineering, Shipbuilding and Shipping 3, DOI 10.1007/978-3-319-50265-6_6 65 66 6.2 6 Application—Ocean Grain Transportation Trading Grains by Sea Grains are grasses cultivated for their grains or seeds; constitute the third largest commodity transported by sea (Fig. 6.1a) and they provide food energy to humans as well as animals. Grains are categorized in cereal (wheat, corn/maize, rice, barley, oats, sorghum and rye), soya beans and coarse used for animal feedstuff, oils and fats. Of these, corn/maize and wheat are the most important. Although the transported volumes follow the overall trend of world population (subject to many fluctuations), they are more closely related to the income (Fig. 6.1b). Countries with low income per capita rely more on grains for direct human consumption. As the income per capita is increasing, consumers can afford to switch from rice to wheat, which is a staple part of a diet and is treated as luxury. When the income is higher, the demand slowly turns to more expensive foods like meat and dairy products, implying a more extensive use of grains for livestock feeds (Tamvakis 2007). The main suppliers and receivers of seaborne grain trades are illustrated in Fig. 6.2 together with their growth potential. Asia represents 32% of total deliveries (a) Growth of five major bulk commodities (b) Growth of grain shipments Fig. 6.1 Time development of seaborne grain trades. Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016) and World Bank (2016) 6.2 Trading Grains by Sea 67 (a) Major exporters (b) Major importers Fig. 6.2 The structure of ocean grain trades. Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016) and is by far the largest import region. Africa, the Middle East, Europe and Latin America are the second tier importers with 21, 14, 11 and 9% market share respectively. Europe has the highest import growth, followed by the increasing role of Asia, Africa, the Middle East and Latin America, albeit to the aforementioned commentary. On the export side, the Americas (both North and South) dominate with about 60% of total exports, whilst Brazil is increasingly contributing after 2006, hence explaining the wide spread. As can be seen, the United States and Brazil are playing steadily increasing, but diagonally opposite roles. Europe and Australia are the second tier exporters with a market share close to 10% each. The higher growth of Europe as an exporter can be explained by its self-sufficiency in grains and thus its transformation into a frequent exporter albeit to a revised agricultural policy. For Australia, the agricultural sector although it is still important, it has lost its position as the country’s top export income earner, giving place to manufacturing and mining (Tamvakis 2007). 68 6 Application—Ocean Grain Transportation The seaborne trades in grains naturally follow in the short term seasonal variations in different parts of the world such as harvests, with crop failures being the main source of unexpected trough trade flows. Additionally, grain trading emphasis is being periodically switched between a number of highly scattered and dispersed import markets that generate considerable requirements among shippers and traders for eminently flexible vessel selection policies. Since these fluctuations are not predictable, planning the transport is very difficult and complex, with shippers relying more on the spot market (Stopford 2009). It is estimated that 60% of seaborne grain trade is transported under voyage and trip charters, whilst the remainder are shipped on relatively short time charters (Pirrong 1993; Jonnala et al. 2002). In the longer term, the grain trade is influenced by income, prices and yields’ performance. Hence, the grain logistics system is designed so that its elements work together as efficiently as possible, whereas the sea transport is just one stage in the supply chain moving bulk grain between producers and consumers (Stopford 2009). Figure 6.3 shows a typical scenario of a bulk grain supply chain. Seeds are bought by farmers from a seed company. After crop production, grains are harvested and moved from the field to a storage bin. During high harvests or when demand is low, these storage facilities may become inadequate and any available covered storage is handled by elevator companies. Grain elevators market bulk commodities against generic grade standards, thus grains are commingled to meet buyer specifications and to maximize profit. The grains are either directly sold to a processor, or are shipped for overseas export. The infrastructure commonly used for storing grains usually has tall and cylindrical shape. From the storage elevator, the grains are fed to railcars, trucks or barges and shipped to a terminal. Then, the grains are transferred into an elevator where they await to be loaded on a bulk Fig. 6.3 Elements of a generic grain logistics network. Source Author’s drawing based on Abis et al. (2014) and WESTAC (1998) 6.2 Trading Grains by Sea 69 Fig. 6.4 Loading and storage facilities at a grain export terminal with a bulk carrier berthed. Photo credit Courtesy of Bunge Limited carrier (see Fig. 6.4). Naturally, the elevator must hold enough grain to fill the vessel (Stopford 2009; Thakur and Hurburgh 2009). It is noted that the grain when carried in bulk by sea, is subjected to the vessel’s movements and is liable to shift transversely across the cargo holds. To eliminate such behavior characteristic, the cargo holds are filled and trimmed to feed as much grain as possible, reaching their highest level (see Fig. 6.5). This levelling (trimming) provides stable stowage during the vessel’s sea passage (House 2005). At the end of the voyage, the process is reversed: the grains are offloaded from the vessel either with grab (see Fig. 6.6) or pneumatic or mechanical systems and moved to storage elevators (silos). From the silos, the grains are shipped into a flour mill, grinding facility or feed compounder. At the processing plant, grains are either processed into a final product with the addition of other ingredients, or are mixed with other products while undergoing many processing steps. The finished product (i.e. flour) is either packaged for the consumer market, or shipped in bulk by rail and truck to bakeries, other large industrial users or farmers (Stopford 2009; Thakur and Hurburgh 2009). It is emphasized that storage bins contain grains from many different sources and elevator companies buy grain from the farmers with different quality characteristics (i.e. moisture, test weight, foreign material, etc.). When in storage, a part or entire content of an elevator’s silo can be transferred to other silos in order to avoid spoilage due to environmental conditions, usually increased temperature. Finally, the grains for the outgoing shipments are blended from several bins so that the customer specifications for quality are met and the finished product for consignment 70 6 Application—Ocean Grain Transportation Fig. 6.5 Cargo hold being loaded and filled with grain by a loading spout. Photo credit Courtesy of Cargill Inc. Fig. 6.6 Grain being discharged from a bulk carrier’s cargo hold. Photo credit Courtesy of BayWa AG 6.2 Trading Grains by Sea 71 Fig. 6.7 Handymax bulk carrier berthed alongside a grain export terminal and being loaded. Photo credit Courtesy of Columbia Grain Inc. is prepared (Thakur et al. 2010). In this respect, the arrangement of ocean grain transport requires careful scheduling from different sources and involves the avoidance of any penalties for faulty consignments as well as demurrage charges, which grow rapidly with large cargoes. For this reason, it is more difficult to introduce large vessels into the grain trade than into the iron ore and coal trades and there is often congestion (Stopford 2009). As mentioned earlier, bulk carriers are heavily employed in the grain seaborne trade with the individual consignments (parcel sizes) clustered in two ranges. The first one is around 25,000–45,000 tones with handymax bulk carriers (see Fig. 6.7) the main source for transport, and the second one is around 50,000–70,000 tones which is carried in panamax bulk carriers (see Fig. 6.8) (Stopford 2009). For the interested reader, generic vessel designs are exhibited in Appendix A. The panamax vessel reflects the cargo quantity where economies of scale can be reached for obtaining the minimum ocean transport cost (Jonnala et al. 2002; Park and Koo 2004). Besides, the attainment of even larger scale economies has introduced the ultramax and kamsarmax types which belong to the handymax and panamax range, though with increased cargo capacity (JSEA 2016). In view of the two grain parcel sizes, the application of the models described in the previous chapter refers to these two vessel sizes. 72 6 Application—Ocean Grain Transportation Fig. 6.8 Panamax bulk carrier berthed alongside a grain export terminal and being loaded. Photo credit Courtesy of Groupe Sica Atlantique 6.3 Dealing with the Inherent Uncertainties The utilized data (i.e. quantities to populate the game theoretical models) are transformed into information with the expression of frequency estimates, out of which knowledge is derived about their properties. A measure of how much confidence is known about the data and thus a measure of the attached uncertainty is the use of probability (Modarres 2006). It is realized that the critical component in these probabilistic characterizations are the choices made in selecting the fitted probability distributions. Moreover, these approximations represent a simplification of the real world, which do not necessarily describe the natural complexity. However, it is believed that the logical derivations are useful in terms of encapsulating knowledge with practical reality (Box 1976) and the following subparagraphs describe how uncertainty is handled. 6.3.1 Parameter Uncertainties Parameter uncertainties are those associated with the values of the quantities of interest and are due to unknowns about correct input. These involve limited data and information, inaccuracies in the assumptions used to infer the actual quantity of interest from the observed readings, estimation of parameters through small and/or 6.3 Dealing with the Inherent Uncertainties 73 non-representative samples. As stated earlier, they are typically characterized by establishing probability distributions on the parameter values (Modarres 2006). In this respect, the uncertainty for all monetary parameters (commodity prices, time and voyage charter rates, bunker and vessel prices, depreciation, lost earnings, operational and voyage costs) is represented by the log-normal distribution. The reason for choosing this probabilistic characterization is not only because the distribution is defined for positive values (Forbes et al. 2011), but also salient features of price behavior can be captured (i.e. extreme outcomes occur more frequently) which is quite important within shipping (Pirrong 2015). Following Psarros and Vassalos (2009), Gaussian distributions are used for capturing the uncertainties of interest rates. The vessel’s speed and bunker consumption are manifested by a Weibull distribution (Aldous et al. 2015), since decreasing, constant, or increasing levels can be portrayed (Forbes et al. 2011). The vessel’s voyage as well as hire duration are depicted by a Gamma distribution (Chen et al. 2011) due to its positive space and shape flexibility (Forbes et al. 2011). Gaussian distributions are assigned to the vessel’s bale capacity, principal dimensions (Diez and Peri 2010) as well as commodity quantity and density (Chen et al. 2011) because most values are expected to cluster closely around a central mean (Bury 1999). Vessel calls and inherently number of voyages are assumed to follow the Poisson distribution which occur randomly at a normally distributed constant rate (Bury 1999; Vose 2009) and are in consistency with Alvarez et al. (2010). The approach outlined in Vose (2009) is employed for estimating the parameters of the chosen distributions (see Appendix B). 6.3.2 Uncertainty Propagation The probabilistic characterization of the utilized data allows finding the distribution characteristics (mean and variance) of a function (i.e. the game theoretical as well as investment appraisal models) by treating the dependent and independent elements as random variables. Such technique to perform the uncertainty propagation is based on Monte Carlo simulation and involves the random sampling of each independent variable’s probability distribution within the model to produce many trials of the dependent variable’s distribution. The reconstructed distribution’s shape is procured from calculated values for the model outcome and therefore reflects the probability of the values that could occur (Modarres 2006; Vose 2009). A procedure for Monte Carlo simulation is given in Appendix C. 6.3.3 Parameter Significance of Choice The probabilistic characterizations and the uncertainty propagation from which the game theoretical as well as investment appraisal models are entertained entail that 74 6 Application—Ocean Grain Transportation their parameters’ significance of choice should be determined. Thus, the objective of a sensitivity analysis is to identify and rank the parameters in the acceptable range which are mostly responsible for realizing the models’ target output (Saltelli et al. 2006). The effects of input variables such as charter rates are measured by modifying them by several folds, factors, or even one or more order of magnitudes one at a time, and measure relative changes observed in the model’s results. This process is repeated using different values for the same parameter until those parameters whose change leads to the highest impact in the final model’s values are determined. As an outcome, attention is focused to those parameters that need better characterization of uncertainty which in turn strengthens the quality and validity of the performed calculations (Modarres 2006). The specification of the amount of change to be applied to each parameter is outlined in Appendix D. 6.4 Energy Efficiency Sharing Scheme for Handymax Vessel The models outlined in the previous chapter are populated with data from CRSL (2016a, b). It is assumed that the investment horizon is fifteen years since the vessel is sold to new owners at the end of the period. The calculations are considering the transport of corn and the more expensive wheat, as well as the options of basic and advanced technological upgrades. 6.4.1 Time Charter The charterer’s or shipper’s (principal’s) reservation price can be determined through a sample of handymax period fixtures from CRSL (2016a) between August 2012 and December 2015. For that period, out of a sample of 364 transactions, 49 fixtures were related to the carriage of grains with a rate of FRM = 11,228 $/d (see Appendix E for the distribution parameters). This value represents also the market price. 6.4.1.1 Principal—Agent Part By applying (5.4) and (5.5), the optimum effort level is 9%, whereas from (5.6) the ship-owner’s or carrier’s (agent’s) reservation price accounting also for the energy efficiency effort is FRRP = 12,193 $/d (see Appendix F for the simulated result, Figs. F.1 and F.2). 6.4 Energy Efficiency Sharing Scheme for Handymax Vessel 75 Table 6.1 Surplus fractions and equilibrium prices for handymax period contracts Commodity: corn Basic technology upgrade Advanced technology upgrade Commodity: wheat Basic technology upgrade Advanced technology upgrade Source Calculated by Author 6.4.1.2 θΒ (%) θS (%) FRE ($/d) 78.5 78.5 21.5 21.5 11,434 11,448 78.7 78.6 21.3 21.4 11,408 11,446 Bargaining Part As per (5.14) and (5.15), the surplus between the principal’s and agent’s reservation prices is split by the respective percentages shown in Table 6.1 (see Appendix F for the simulated result). From (5.20), the equilibrium rate is also shown in Table 6.1 (see Appendix F for the simulated result, Figs. F.4, F.5, F.6, F.7, F.8, F.9, F.10 and F.11). It is observed that the surplus fraction and equilibrium rate are indifferent (inelastic) to the commodity prices and technology costs. For the sake of consistency, the inventory interest rate is assumed to be 5.35% (Dunsby et al. 2008) whilst the inventory holding coefficient ω has been estimated as −0.062 for corn and −0.254 for wheat (Symeonidis et al. 2012; Frankel 2014). Data from CRSL (2016) are used for the estimation of commodity prices, vessel prices, earnings and grain capacity (see Appendix E for distribution parameters). The values for the cargo’s density are considered from Sewell (1999) (see Appendix E for distribution parameters) and the vessel’s depreciation is estimated from (5.19) (see Appendix F for the simulated results, Fig. F.3). The basic technology upgrade (i.e. low friction coating or bare optimization or appendages or a combination of these) is assumed to cost around $1.5 million, whereas the advanced upgrade (basic plus air lubrication or wind solutions) is assumed to cost around $4 million (Eason 2015). 6.4.1.3 Investment Appraisal The simulated results of (5.22) provide a capital cost of 10.9% (see Appendix F, Fig. F.12), whereas the operating costs are in the range of 5,181 $/d (Gardiner et al. 2009) (see Appendix E for distribution parameters). Furthermore, the operating costs are assumed to escalate by 2.5% on an annual basis, with an anticipated increase of 5% to current levels during the tenth year (Gardiner 2014, 2015). By applying (5.23), the minimum RFR for basic and advanced technology upgrade is 11,936 and 12,693 $/d respectively (see Appendix F for simulated results, Figs. F.13 and F.14). Comparing these values with those from Table 6.1 it is obvious that the equilibrium freight rate is not profitable for the basic and advanced technology expenditure with probability 66 and 86% respectively. It is worthwhile 76 6 Application—Ocean Grain Transportation Fig. 6.9 Handymax period rates cumulative probability curves. Source Plotted by Author noting that the agent’s (ship-owner’s) reservation price (Sect. 6.4.1.1) can justify only the cost of the basic technology upgrade by 55% (Fig. 6.9). 6.4.1.4 Sensitivity Analysis The peculiar results of the previous paragraph deserve the further investigation of the equilibrium freight rate subject to the volatility of the market charter rates. For lower prices it is straightforward that the EEISS would still not be profitable. Though, the models could be entertained by considering an increase on the prices with the technique outlined in Appendix D. The new values are shown in Table 6.2. Upon these changes, the optimum effort level is 9.7% and the agent’s reservation price yields FRRP = 12,762 $/d. The surplus fraction percentages between the Table 6.2 Parameters for evaluating the significance of change for handymax period contracts Variable Corn price ($/t) Wheat price ($/t) Period rate ($/d) Newbuilding price ($ 106) 15 years price ($ 106) Earnings ($/d) Source Calculated by Author Model Distribution Parameters Mean Variance Lognormal Lognormal Lognormal Lognormal Lognormal Lognormal m m m m m m = = = = = = 257 328 11,563 25.9 10.6 11,598 s2 s2 s2 s2 s2 s2 = = = = = = 582 562 5,5552 1.542 4.172 3,3342 6.4 Energy Efficiency Sharing Scheme for Handymax Vessel 77 Table 6.3 Surplus fractions and equilibrium prices for handymax period contracts (sensitivity analysis) Commodity: corn Basic technology upgrade Advanced technology upgrade Commodity: wheat Basic technology upgrade Advanced technology upgrade Source Calculated by Author θΒ (%) θS (%) FRE ($/d) 78.4 78.3 21.6 21.7 11,853 11,810 78.4 78.4 21.6 21.6 11,854 11,837 principal’s and agent’s reservation prices as well as the equilibrium rate are shown in Table 6.3. Again, it is observed that the surplus fraction and equilibrium rate are indifferent (inelastic) to the commodity prices and technology costs. The fraction percentages are almost similar to those estimated previously, whilst, the rate values have been moderately increased. The minimum RFR for basic and advanced technology upgrade is 11,647 $/d (standard deviation = 1,241) and 12,222 $/d (standard deviation = 1,527) respectively. From a first instance it could be claimed that the basic technology upgrade EEISS can be justified. However, considering the variation, it can be concluded that only from a marginal point of view the cost is covered. As far as the advanced technology upgrade is concerned, even with slightly improved freight market, still the energy efficiency sharing scheme is not profitable. 6.4.2 Voyage Charter The charterer’s or shipper’s (principal’s) reservation price can be determined through a sample of handymax voyage fixtures from CRSL (2016a) between August 2012 and December 2015. For that period, out of a sample of 169 transactions, 79 fixtures were related to the carriage of grains with a rate of FRM = 38.4 $/t and transported cargo quantity of 52,883 t (see Appendix E for the distribution parameters). This value represents also the market price. 6.4.2.1 Principal—Agent Part Before determining the ship-owner’s or carrier’s (agent’s) reservation price, it is necessary to estimate the agent’s preference characteristics, which are obtained by applying (5.7) and (5.8) and are shown in Table 6.4. The assigned values reflect different commodity prices as well as basic and advanced technology upgrade. The probability β of the agent’s preference type is assumed to be 24% (Cargill 2016). 78 6 Application—Ocean Grain Transportation Table 6.4 Agent’s preference characteristics and reservation prices for handymax voyage contracts σL (−) σH (−) Basic technology upgrade 1.034 1.145 0.658 0.13 0.37 38.65 Advanced technology upgrade 1.095 1.444 −0.013 0 0.33 38.61 Basic technology upgrade 1.026 1.107 0.749 0.18 0.24 38.43 Advanced technology upgrade 1.070 1.313 0.274 0.19 0.27 38.70 Den (−) πL (%) πH (%) FRRV ($/t) Commodity: corn Commodity: wheat Source Calculated by Author Prior to continuing, it is important to explore the denominator’s sign of the right part of (5.12) ðDen ¼ 1 ððð1 bÞ=bÞ ððrH rL Þ=rL ÞÞÞ. Furthermore, in the absence of relevant information, an agent of low preference σL is assumed to spend 25% of the cost needed for basic and advanced technology upgrades respectively. The negative value only for the advanced technology upgrade with corn transported as cargo stipulates that πL = 0. The environmental stewardship can be evaluated from (5.11) and (5.12) (see Appendix F for the simulated results, Figs. F.15, F.16, F.17, F.18, F.19 and F.20). It can be observed that the values differ marginally from the principal’s reservation price, which coincides with the freight contract’s functionality, i.e. transport is bought from the agent on a lump sum basis and covers all the incurred costs (see Sect. 2.3). 6.4.2.2 Bargaining Part As per (5.14) and (5.15), the surplus between the principal’s and agent’s reservation prices is split by the respective percentages shown in Table 6.5 (see Appendix F for the simulated result). From (5.20), the equilibrium rate is also shown in Table 6.5 (see Appendix F for the simulated result, Figs. F.21, F.22, F.23, F.24, F.25, F.26, F.27, F.28). It is observed that the surplus fraction and equilibrium rate are indifferent (inelastic) to the commodity prices and technology costs. Additionally, the Table 6.5 Surplus fractions and equilibrium prices for handymax voyage contracts Commodity: corn Basic technology upgrade Advanced technology upgrade Commodity: wheat Basic technology upgrade Advanced technology upgrade Source Calculated by Author θΒ (%) θS (%) FRE ($/t) 78.6 78.7 21.4 21.3 38.42 38.48 78.7 78.6 21.3 21.4 38.41 38.52 6.4 Energy Efficiency Sharing Scheme for Handymax Vessel 79 surplus fractions are similar to those of Table 6.1. For the sake of consistency, the same assumptions concerning the inventory interest rate and holding coefficient, technology upgrades and vessel’s depreciation hold. 6.4.2.3 Investment Appraisal The number of voyages per year of a handymax vessel is assumed to be ten (10) (Psarros 2009) with a factor of 0.4 related to grain cargoes and an average voyage duration of 48 days (CRSL 2015, 2016a) (see Appendix E for distribution parameters and Appendix F for simulated results, Figs. F.29 and F.30). The voyage costs are determined indirectly from (5.24) with data from CRSL (2016a, b), taking fuel cost in the range of 584 $/t, speed in the range of 14.4 knots (considering in addition the margin of 0.5 ± 0.3 knots, see Sect. 5.4) and fuel consumption in the range of 31.7 t/d (see Appendix E for the distribution parameters) accounting also for the fuel efficiency gains. It is acknowledged that the fuel savings are vessel, weather and route specific, so based on the values of Table 2.1 and Eason (2015), it is conservatively assumed that 10 and 15% fuel consumption efficiency can be obtained for the basic and advanced technology upgrade respectively (see Appendix F for the simulated results, Fig. F.31). Furthermore, the previous assumptions concerning the capital and operating costs hold here as well. By applying (5.23), the minimum RFR for basic and advanced technology upgrade is 36.5 and 35.7 $/t respectively (see Appendix F for simulated results, Figs. F.32 and F.33). Comparing these values with those from Table 6.5 it is obvious that the equilibrium freight rate is profitable for the technology expenditure. However, the variability can create some concerns and by plotting the cumulative probability graphs of the equilibrium and RFRs (Fig. 6.10) the comparison can be interpreted directly. As shown, the probability of the RFR Fig. 6.10 Handymax voyage rates cumulative probability curves. Source Plotted by Author 80 6 Application—Ocean Grain Transportation being larger than the equilibrium prices is around 42–46%. This entails that the cost of basic and advanced technology upgrades can be justified only by a range between 54 and 58%. 6.4.2.4 Sensitivity Analysis The peculiar results of the previous paragraph deserve the further investigation of the equilibrium freight rate subject to the volatility of the market voyage rates. Lower and higher prices are considered for evaluating the significance of change on the RFR and exploring whether the EEISS would still be profitable. Therefore, the models are entertained by considering different prices with the technique outlined in Appendix D. The new values are shown in Table 6.6. Upon these changes, the agent’s preference characteristics and environmental stewardship together with the reserved prices are shown in Table 6.7. It is evident that the values differ marginally from the market prices, entailing that this observation coincides with the freight contract’s functionality as commented in Sect. 6.4.2.1. The surplus fraction percentages between the principal’s and agent’s reservation prices as well as the equilibrium rate are shown in Table 6.8. Again, it is observed that the surplus fraction and equilibrium rate are indifferent (inelastic) to the commodity prices and technology costs. The minimum RFR for basic and advanced technology upgrade with low prices is 35.18 $/t (standard deviation = 3.8) and 35.18 $/t (standard deviation = 4.5) respectively. By contrast, the minimum RFR for basic and advanced technology upgrade with high prices is 37.91 $/t (standard deviation = 4.1) and 37.85 $/t (standard deviation = 4.4) respectively. In order to check whether the EEISS could be justified, the cumulative probability graphs are plotted together (Fig. 6.11). Vis á vis, for low and high prices the probability of RFR being larger than the equilibrium prices is between 44 and 46%. This indicates that the cost of basic and advanced Table 6.6 Parameters for evaluating the significance of change for handymax voyage contracts Variable Model Distribution parameters Mean Corn price ($/t) Lognormal Wheat price ($/t) Lognormal Voyage rate ($/t) Lognormal 6 Newbuilding price ($ 10 ) 15 years price ($ 106) Lognormal Lognormal Variance Lower Upper Lower m = 211 m = 257 s2 = 812 m = 277 m = 37 m = 25.1 m = 9.2 m = 328 m = 39.8 m = 25.9 m = 10.6 Upper 2 2 2 2 s = 79 s = 11 s2 = 582 s2 = 562 s2 = 152 2 2 s2 = 1.542 2 2 s2 = 4.172 s = 1.09 s = 2.96 Earnings ($/d) Lognormal m = 9,900 m = 11,598 s2 = 4,6952 s2 = 3,3342 Bunker price ($/t) Lognormal m = 537 m = 632 s2 = 2592 s2 = 3652 Source Calculated by Author 6.4 Energy Efficiency Sharing Scheme for Handymax Vessel 81 Table 6.7 Agent’s preference characteristics and reservation prices for handymax voyage contracts (sensitivity analysis) σL (−) σH (−) Basic technology upgrade 1.035 1.150 0.656 0.20 0.04 37.04 Advanced technology upgrade 1.098 1.454 −0.030 0 0.24 37.03 Basic technology upgrade 1.029 1.122 0.717 0.05 0.40 39.86 Advanced technology upgrade 1.079 1.358 0.276 0.08 0.09 39.85 Basic technology upgrade 1.027 1.112 0.736 0.02 0.29 37.05 Advanced technology upgrade 1.073 1.329 0.254 0.09 0.01 37.04 Basic technology upgrade 1.023 1.094 0.775 0.14 0.06 39.83 Advanced technology upgrade 1.061 1.271 0.379 0.05 0.36 39.85 Den (−) πL (%) πH (%) FRRV ($/t) Commodity: corn—low price Commodity: corn—high price Commodity: wheat—low price Commodity: wheat—high price Source Calculated by Author Table 6.8 Surplus fractions and equilibrium prices for handymax voyage contracts (sensitivity analysis) Commodity: corn—low price Basic technology upgrade Advanced technology upgrade Commodity: corn—high price Basic technology upgrade Advanced technology upgrade Commodity: wheat—low price Basic technology upgrade Advanced technology upgrade Commodity: wheat—high price Basic technology upgrade Advanced technology upgrade Source Calculated by Author θΒ (%) θS (%) FRE ($/t) 79.4 79.4 20.6 20.6 37.03 37.02 78.4 78.2 21.6 21.8 39.86 39.82 79.6 79.6 20.4 20.4 37.04 37.03 78.5 78.4 21.5 21.6 39.81 39.82 technology upgrades can be justified by 54–56%, which is slightly reduced than the previous estimation, but it still provides robust result. 6.4.2.5 Investment Recovery By applying (5.25), the payback period is estimated as 12.4 years (standard deviation 3.1 years) for the basic technology upgrade and 20.6 years (standard 82 6 Application—Ocean Grain Transportation (a) Low prices (b) High prices Fig. 6.11 Handymax voyage rates cumulative probability curves (sensitivity analysis). Source Plotted by Author deviation 7.2 years) for the advanced technology upgrade. From Fig. 6.12 it is illustrated that for the vessel’s expected operational horizon (15 years), the cost expenditure can be recovered up to 80% for the basic, whilst up to 22% for the advanced technology upgrade. 6.4 Energy Efficiency Sharing Scheme for Handymax Vessel 83 Fig. 6.12 Handymax technology investment payback period cumulative probability curves for voyage contracts. Source Plotted by Author 6.4.3 Time Charter Trip The charterer’s or shipper’s (principal’s) reservation price can be determined through a sample of handymax time charter trip fixtures CRSL (2016a) between August 2012 and December 2015. For that period, out of a sample of 3,317 transactions, 324 fixtures were related to the carriage of grains with a rate of FRM = 13,692 $/d (see Appendix E for the distribution parameters). This value represents also the market price. 6.4.3.1 Principal—Agent Part The assumptions of Sect. 6.4.2.3 related to a handymax vessel’s annual number of trips and average trip duration also hold herein. A factor of 0.1 is allocated for grain trips per year (CRSL 2016a) (see Appendix E for distribution parameters and Appendix F for simulated results, Fig. F.34). By applying (5.4) and (5.5), the optimum effort level is 12.8%, whereas from (5.6) the ship-owner’s or carrier’s (agent’s) reservation price accounting also for the energy efficiency effort is FRRP = 15,478 $/d (see Appendix F for the simulated result, Figs. F.35 and F.36). 6.4.3.2 Bargaining Part As per (5.14) and (5.15), the surplus between the principal’s and agent’s reservation prices is split by the respective percentages shown in Table 6.9, which are similar to the fraction values presented in Table 6.1. From (5.20), the equilibrium rate is also shown in Table 6.9 (see Appendix F for the simulated result, Figs. F.37, F.38, F.39 and F.40). Again, it is observed that the surplus fraction and equilibrium rate are indifferent (inelastic) to the commodity prices and technology costs. The assumptions of Sect. 6.4.1.2 related to the inventory holding and interest rate, cargo density, technology upgrades, vessel earnings, prices and grain capacity also hold. 84 6 Application—Ocean Grain Transportation Table 6.9 Surplus fractions and equilibrium prices for handymax time charter trips Commodity: corn Basic technology upgrade Advanced technology upgrade Commodity: wheat Basic technology upgrade Advanced technology upgrade Source Calculated by Author 6.4.3.3 θΒ (%) θS (%) FRE ($/d) 78.5 78.5 21.5 21.5 14,040 14,083 78.6 78.5 21.4 21.5 14,211 14,114 Investment Appraisal The capital and operating costs are assumed to be the same as in Sect. 6.4.1.3, whereas the number of grain trips and their respective duration are in consistency with the values in Sect. 6.4.3.1. By applying (5.23), the minimum RFR for basic and advanced technology upgrade is 11,534 and 10,615 $/d respectively (see Appendix F for simulated results, Figs. F.41 and F.42). Comparing these values with those from Table 6.9 it is obvious that the equilibrium freight rate is profitable for the basic and advanced technology expenditure. However, to remove any doubts, by comparing the rate cumulative probability plots the results can be elucidated outspokenly. As indicated by Fig. 6.13, the probability of the equilibrium time charter trip rates being larger than the minimum required values for basic and advanced technology upgrades is between 82 and 84%. Fig. 6.13 Handymax time charter trip rates cumulative probability curves. Source Plotted by Author 6.4 Energy Efficiency Sharing Scheme for Handymax Vessel 6.4.3.4 85 Sensitivity Analysis It is straightforward that for higher prices the EEISS would still be profitable. Though, to investigate the significance of change in the price volatility, the models could be entertained by considering a price reduction with the technique outlined in Appendix D. The new values are shown in Table 6.10. Upon these changes, the optimum effort level is 11.2% and the agent’s reservation price yields FRRP = 14,546 $/d. The surplus fraction percentages between the principal’s and agent’s reservation prices as well as the equilibrium rate are shown in Table 6.11. Again, it is observed that the surplus fraction and equilibrium rate are indifferent (inelastic) to the commodity prices and technology costs. The fraction percentages are almost similar to those estimated previously, whilst, the rate values have been decreased. The minimum RFR for basic and advanced technology upgrade is 10,744 $/d (standard deviation = 2,876) and 11,008 $/d (standard deviation = 2,928) respectively. With these values, it could be claimed that the basic technology upgrade EEISS can be justified. From the cumulative probability curves it can be interpreted that the equilibrium time charter trip rates can be higher than the minimum required values by 93–95%, which validates even further the investment appraisal’s result. Table 6.10 Parameters for evaluating the significance of change for handymax time charter trip contracts Variable Corn price ($/t) Wheat price ($/t) Trip rate ($/d) Newbuilding price ($ 106) 15 years price ($ 106) Earnings ($/d) Source Calculated by Author Model Distribution Parameters Mean Variance Lognormal Lognormal Lognormal Lognormal Lognormal Lognormal m m m m m m = = = = = = 211 277 13,087 25.1 9.2 9,900 s2 s2 s2 s2 s2 s2 = = = = = = 812 792 63402 1.092 2.962 4,6952 Table 6.11 Surplus fractions and equilibrium prices for handymax time charter trip contracts (sensitivity analysis) Commodity: corn Basic technology upgrade Advanced technology upgrade Commodity: wheat Basic technology upgrade Advanced technology upgrade Source Calculated by Author θΒ (%) θS (%) FRE ($/d) 79.5 79.5 20.5 20.5 13,455 13,416 79.6 79.6 20.4 20.4 13,398 13,510 86 6 Application—Ocean Grain Transportation Fig. 6.14 Handymax technology investment payback period cumulative probability curves for time charter trip contracts. Source Plotted by Author 6.4.3.5 Investment Recovery By applying (5.25), the payback period is estimated as 12.1 years (standard deviation 2.7 years) for the basic technology upgrade and 20.6 years (standard deviation 12.2 years) for the advanced technology upgrade. From Fig. 6.14 it is illustrated that for the vessel’s expected operational horizon (15 years), the cost expenditure can be recovered up to 86% for the basic, whilst up to 32% for the advanced technology upgrade. 6.5 Energy Efficiency Sharing Scheme for Panamax Vessel The models outlined in the previous chapter are populated with data from CRSL (2016a, b). Similarly to the handymax vessel case, it is assumed that the investment horizon is fifteen years since the vessel is sold to new owners at the end of the period. The calculations are considering the transport of corn and the more expensive wheat, as well as the options of basic and advanced technological upgrades. 6.5.1 Time Charter The charterer’s or shipper’s (principal’s) reservation price can be determined through a sample of panamax period fixtures from CRSL (2016a) between August 2012 and December 2015. For that period, out of a sample of 851 transactions, 132 fixtures were related to the carriage of grains with a rate of FRM = 9,635 $/d (see Appendix E for the distribution parameters). This value represents also the market price. 6.5 Energy Efficiency Sharing Scheme for Panamax Vessel 6.5.1.1 87 Principal—Agent Part By applying (5.4) and (5.5), the optimum effort level is 9.6%, whereas from (5.6) the ship-owner’s or carrier’s (agent’s) reservation price accounting also for the energy efficiency effort is FRRP = 10,541 $/d (see Appendix F for the simulated result, Figs. F.43 and F.44). 6.5.1.2 Bargaining Part As per (5.14) and (5.15), the surplus between the principal’s and agent’s reservation prices is split by the respective percentages shown in Table 6.12 (see Appendix F for the simulated result). From (5.20), the equilibrium rate is also shown in Table 6. 12 (see Appendix F for the simulated result, Figs. F.45, F.46, F.47, F.48, F.49, F. 50, F.51 and F.52). It is observed that the surplus fraction and equilibrium rate are indifferent (inelastic) to the commodity prices and technology costs. For the sake of consistency, the assumptions of Sect. 6.4.1.2 associated with the inventory interest rate, holding coefficient, vessel depreciation, technology upgrade costs and cargo density also hold herein. Data from CRSL (2016a) are used for the estimation of commodity prices, vessel prices, earnings and grain capacity (see Appendix E for distribution parameters). 6.5.1.3 Investment Appraisal Similarly to the previous application, a capital cost of 10.9% (see figure X of Appendix F) is utilized, whereas the operating costs are in the range of 6,324 $/d (Gardiner et al. 2009) (see Appendix E for distribution parameters) and assumed escalation as in Sect. 6.4.1.3. By applying (5.23), the minimum RFR for basic and advanced technology upgrade is 14,803 and 16,529 $/d respectively (see Appendix F for simulated results, Figs. F.53 and F.54). Comparing these values with those from Table 6.12 it is obvious that the equilibrium freight rate is not profitable for the basic and advanced technology expenditure. Table 6.12 Surplus fractions and equilibrium prices for panamax period contracts Commodity: corn Basic technology upgrade Advanced technology upgrade Commodity: wheat Basic technology upgrade Advanced technology upgrade Source Calculated by Author θΒ (%) θS (%) FRE ($/d) 83.3 83.2 16.7 16.8 9,819 9,807 83.3 83.4 16.7 16.6 9,803 9,826 88 6.5.1.4 6 Application—Ocean Grain Transportation Sensitivity Analysis For lower prices it is straightforward that the EEISS would still not be profitable. Though, the models could be entertained by considering an increase on the prices with the technique outlined in Appendix D. The new values are shown in Table 6.13. Upon these changes, the optimum effort level is 12.4% and the agent’s reservation price yields FRRP = 11,058 $/d. The surplus fraction percentages between the principal’s and agent’s reservation prices as well as the equilibrium rate are shown in Table 6.14. Again, it is observed that the surplus fraction and equilibrium rate are indifferent (inelastic) to the commodity prices and technology costs. The fraction percentages are almost similar to those estimated previously, whilst, the rate values have been moderately increased. The minimum RFR for basic and advanced technology upgrade is 14,808 $/d (standard deviation = 2,191) and 16,513 $/d (standard deviation = 4020) respectively. From these values it is indicated that the basic as well as advanced technology upgrade EEISSs are not profitable and cannot be justified. Table 6.13 Parameters for evaluating the significance of change for panamax period contracts Variable Corn price ($/t) Wheat price ($/t) Period rate ($/d) Newbuilding price ($ 106) 15 years price ($ 106) Earnings ($/d) Source Calculated by Author Model Distribution Parameters Mean Variance Lognormal Lognormal Lognormal Lognormal Lognormal Lognormal m m m m m m = = = = = = 257 328 9,799 27.7 10.9 8,428 s2 s2 s2 s2 s2 s2 = = = = = = 582 562 3,6572 1.952 4.092 2,5372 Table 6.14 Surplus fractions and equilibrium prices for panamax period contracts (sensitivity analysis) Commodity: corn Basic technology upgrade Advanced technology upgrade Commodity: wheat Basic technology upgrade Advanced technology upgrade Source Calculated by Author θΒ (%) θS (%) FRE ($/d) 83.3 83.3 16.7 16.7 10,110 10,100 83.4 83.4 16.6 16.6 10,026 10,058 6.5 Energy Efficiency Sharing Scheme for Panamax Vessel 6.5.2 89 Voyage Charter The charterer’s or shipper’s (principal’s) reservation price can be determined through a sample of panamax voyage fixtures from CRSL (2016a) between August 2012 and December 2015. For that period, out of a sample of 1,197 transactions, 218 fixtures were related to the carriage of grains with a rate of FRM = 34.3 $/t and transported cargo quantity of 59,507 t (see Appendix E for the distribution parameters). This value represents also the market price. 6.5.2.1 Principal—Agent Part Before determining the ship-owner’s or carrier’s (agent’s) reservation price, it is necessary to estimate the agent’s preference characteristics, which are obtained by applying (5.7) and (5.8) and are shown in Table 6.15. The assigned values reflect different commodity prices as well as basic and advanced technology upgrade. The probability β of the agent’s preference type is assumed to be 14% (Cargill 2016). Prior to continuing, it is important to explore the denominator’s sign of the right part of (5.112) ðDen ¼ 1 ððð1 bÞ=bÞ ððrH rL Þ=rL ÞÞÞ. In a similar way to Sect. 6.4.2.1, an agent of low preference σL is assumed to spend 25% of the cost needed for basic and advanced technology upgrades respectively. The negative value for the advanced technology upgrade with corn and wheat transported as cargo stipulates that πL = 0. The environmental stewardship can be evaluated from (5.11) and (5.12) (see Appendix F for the simulated results, Figs. F.55, F.56, F.57, F.58, F.59 and F.60). It can be observed that the values differ marginally from the principal’s reservation price, which coincides with the freight contract’s functionality, i.e. transport is bought from the agent on a lump sum basis and covers all the incurred costs (see Sect. 2.3). 6.5.2.2 Bargaining Part As per (5.14) and (5.15), the surplus between the principal’s and agent’s reservation prices is split by the respective percentages shown in Table 6.16 (see Appendix F for Table 6.15 Agent’s preference characteristics and reservation prices for panamax voyage contracts σL (−) σH (−) Basic technology upgrade 1.029 1.124 0.435 0.27 0.20 34.32 Advanced technology upgrade 1.083 1.369 −0.624 0 0.21 34.33 Basic technology upgrade 1.022 1.091 0.583 0.10 0.12 34.52 Advanced technology upgrade 1.060 1.263 −0.180 0 0.21 34.61 Den (−) πL (%) πH (%) FRRV ($/t) Commodity: corn Commodity: wheat Source Calculated by Author 90 6 Application—Ocean Grain Transportation Table 6.16 Surplus fractions and equilibrium prices for panamax voyage contracts Commodity: corn Basic technology upgrade Advanced technology upgrade Commodity: wheat Basic technology upgrade Advanced technology upgrade Source Calculated by Author θΒ (%) θS (%) FRE ($/t) 83.2 83.1 16.8 16.9 34.30 34.32 83.3 83.3 16.7 16.7 34.31 34.36 the simulated result). From (5.20), the equilibrium rate is also shown in Table 6.16 (see Appendix F for the simulated result, Figs. F.61, F.62, F.63, F.64, F.65, F.66, F.67 and F.68). It is observed that the surplus fraction and equilibrium rate are indifferent (inelastic) to the commodity prices and technology costs. Additionally, the surplus fractions are similar to those of Table 6.14. For the sake of consistency, the same assumptions concerning the inventory interest rate and holding coefficient, technology upgrades and vessel’s depreciation hold. 6.5.2.3 Investment Appraisal The number of voyages per year of a panamax vessel is assumed to be eight (8) (Psarros 2009) with a factor of 0.2 related to grain cargoes and an average voyage duration of 53 days (CRSL 2015, 2016a) (see Appendix E for distribution parameters and Appendix F for simulated results, Figs. F.69 and F.70). The voyage costs are determined indirectly from (5.24) with data from CRSL (2016a, b), taking fuel cost in the range of 584 $/t, speed in the range of 14.4 knots (considering in addition the margin of 0.3 ± 0.3 knots, see Sect. 5.4) and fuel consumption in the range of 35.9 t/d (see Appendix E for the distribution parameters) accounting also for the fuel efficiency gains. It is acknowledged that the fuel savings are vessel, weather and route specific, so based on the values of Table 2.1 and Eason (2015), it is conservatively assumed that 10 and 15% fuel efficiency can be obtained for the basic and advanced technology upgrade respectively (see Appendix F for the simulated results, Fig. F.71). Furthermore, the previous assumptions concerning the capital and operating costs hold here as well. By applying (5.23), the minimum RFR for basic and advanced technology upgrade is 34.6 and 33.7 $/t respectively (see Appendix F for simulated results, Figs. F.72 and F.73). Comparing these values with those from Table 6.16 it is obvious that the equilibrium freight rate is not profitable for the technology expenditure. However, the variability can doubt the previous observation and by plotting the cumulative probability graphs of the equilibrium and RFRs (Fig. 6.15) the comparison can be interpreted directly. As shown, the probability of the RFR being larger than the equilibrium prices is around 50–52%. This entails 6.5 Energy Efficiency Sharing Scheme for Panamax Vessel 91 Fig. 6.15 Panamax voyage rates cumulative probability curves. Source Plotted by Author that the cost of basic and advanced technology upgrades can be justified only by a range between 48 and 50%. 6.5.2.4 Sensitivity Analysis The peculiar results of the previous paragraph deserve the further investigation of the equilibrium freight rate subject to the volatility of the market voyage rates. Lower and higher prices are considered for evaluating the significance of change on the RFR and exploring whether the EEISS would still be profitable. Therefore, the models are entertained by considering different prices with the technique outlined in Appendix D. The new values are shown in Table 6.17. Upon these changes, the agent’s preference characteristics and environmental stewardship together with the reserved prices are shown in Table 6.18. It is evident that the values differ marginally from the market prices, entailing that this observation coincides with the freight contract’s functionality as commented in Sect. 6.5.2.1. The surplus fraction percentages between the principal’s and agent’s reservation prices as well as the equilibrium rate are shown in Table 6.19. Again, it is observed that the surplus fraction and equilibrium rate are indifferent (inelastic) to the commodity prices and technology costs. The minimum RFR for basic and advanced technology upgrade with low prices is 31.81 $/t (standard deviation = 6.16) and 32.72 $/t (standard deviation = 4.47) respectively. By contrast, the minimum RFR for basic and advanced technology upgrade with high prices is 35.39 $/t (standard deviation = 7.2) and 35.06 $/t (standard deviation = 6.7) respectively. In order to check whether the EEISS could be justified, the cumulative probability graphs are plotted together (Fig. 6.16). Vis á 92 6 Application—Ocean Grain Transportation Table 6.17 Parameters for evaluating the significance of change for panamax voyage contracts Variable Model Distribution parameters Mean Variance Lower Upper Corn price ($/t) Lognormal m = 211 m = 257 s2 = 812 s2 = 582 Wheat price ($/t) Lognormal m = 277 m = 328 s2 = 792 s2 = 562 Voyage rate ($/t) Lognormal 6 Lower Upper m = 33.7 m = 34.8 2 s = 11 2 2 s2 = 122 2 s2 = 1.952 Newbuilding price ($ 10 ) Lognormal m = 26.8 m = 27.7 s = 1.39 15 years price ($ 106) Lognormal m = 9.5 m = 10.97 s2 = 2.912 s2 = 4.092 Earnings ($/d) Lognormal m = 7,319 m = 8,428 s2 = 1,8012 s2 = 2,5372 Bunker price ($/t) Lognormal m = 537 2 m = 632 s = 259 2 s2 = 3652 Source Calculated by Author Table 6.18 Agent’s preference characteristics and reservation prices for panamax voyage contracts (sensitivity analysis) σL (−) σH (−) Basic technology upgrade 1.030 1.128 0.422 0.10 0.25 33.70 Advanced technology upgrade 1.085 1.376 −0.660 0 0.20 33.75 Basic technology upgrade 1.025 1.104 0.530 0.05 0.03 34.86 Advanced technology upgrade 1.069 1.301 −0.325 0 0.20 34.85 Basic technology upgrade 1.023 1.096 0.564 0.11 0.20 33.75 Advanced technology upgrade 1.064 1.276 −0.223 0 0.10 33.73 Basic technology upgrade 1.019 1.080 0.633 0.13 0.03 34.85 Advanced technology upgrade 1.054 1.229 −0.018 0 0.10 34.87 Den (−) πL (%) πH (%) FRRV ($/t) Commodity: corn—low price Commodity: corn—high price Commodity: wheat—low price Commodity: wheat—high price Source Calculated by Author Table 6.19 Surplus fractions and equilibrium prices for panamax voyage contracts (sensitivity analysis) Commodity: corn—low price Basic technology upgrade Advanced technology upgrade Commodity: corn—high price Basic technology upgrade Advanced technology upgrade Commodity: wheat—low price Basic technology upgrade Advanced technology upgrade Commodity: wheat—high price Basic technology upgrade Advanced technology upgrade Source Calculated by Author θΒ (%) θS (%) FRE ($/t) 83.7 83.6 16.3 16.4 33.70 33.75 83.2 83.2 16.8 16.8 34.86 34.85 83.8 83.7 16.2 16.3 33.74 33.71 83.4 83.4 16.6 16.6 34.84 34.86 6.5 Energy Efficiency Sharing Scheme for Panamax Vessel 93 vis, for low prices, the probability of the equilibrium prices being larger than the required freight is between 60 and 64%, thus the energy efficiency scheme may be considered as reasonable. However, for high prices, the probability of the required freight being larger than the equilibrium freight ranges between 51 and 54%. This indicates that the cost of basic and advanced technology upgrades can be justified by 46–49%, which is slightly reduced than the previous estimation, but it still provides robust result. (a) Low prices (b) High prices Fig. 6.16 Panamax voyage rates cumulative probability curves (sensitivity analysis). Source Plotted by Author 94 6 Application—Ocean Grain Transportation Fig. 6.17 Panamax technology investment payback period cumulative probability curves for voyage contracts. Source Plotted by Author 6.5.2.5 Investment Recovery By applying (5.25), the payback period is estimated as 19.7 years (standard deviation 10.5 years) for the basic technology upgrade and 24.4 years (standard deviation 15.1 years) for the advanced technology upgrade. From Fig. 6.17 it is illustrated that for the vessel’s expected operational horizon (15 years), the cost expenditure can be recovered up to 33% for the basic, whilst up to 27% for the advanced technology upgrade. 6.5.3 Time Charter Trip The charterer’s or shipper’s (principal’s) reservation price can be determined through a sample of panamax time charter trip fixtures from CRSL (2016a) between August 2012 and December 2015. For that period, out of a sample of 6,086 transactions, 1,576 fixtures were related to the carriage of grains with a rate of FRM = 12,059 $/d (see Appendix E for the distribution parameters). This value represents also the market price. 6.5.3.1 Principal—Agent Part The assumptions of Sect. 6.5.2.3 related to a panamax vessel’s annual number of trips and average trip duration also hold herein. A factor of 0.25 is allocated for grain trips per year (CRSL 2016a) (see Appendix E for distribution parameters and Appendix F for simulated results, Fig. F.74). By applying (5.4) and (5.5), the optimum effort level is 11%, whereas from (5.6) the ship-owner’s or carrier’s (agent’s) reservation price accounting also for the energy efficiency effort is FRRP = 13,390 $/d (see Appendix F for the simulated result, Figs. F.75 and F.76). 6.5 Energy Efficiency Sharing Scheme for Panamax Vessel 95 Table 6.20 Surplus fractions and equilibrium prices for panamax time charter trip contracts Commodity: corn Basic technology upgrade Advanced technology upgrade Commodity: wheat Basic technology upgrade Advanced technology upgrade Source Calculated by Author 6.5.3.2 θΒ (%) θS (%) FRE ($/d) 83.2 83.1 16.8 16.9 12,300 12,361 83.4 83.4 16.6 16.6 12,266 12,341 Bargaining Part As per (5.14) and (5.15), the surplus between the principal’s and agent’s reservation prices is split by the respective percentages shown in Table 6.20, which are similar to the fraction values presented in Table 6.12. From (5.20), the equilibrium rate is also shown in Table 6.20 (see Appendix F for the simulated result, Figs. F.77, F.78, F.79 and F.80). Again, it is observed that the surplus fraction and equilibrium rate are indifferent (inelastic) to the commodity prices and technology costs. The assumptions of Sect. 6.5.1.2 related to the inventory holding and interest rate, cargo density, technology upgrades, vessel earnings, prices and grain capacity also hold. 6.5.3.3 Investment Appraisal The capital and operating costs are assumed to be the same as in Sect. 6.5.1.3, whereas the number of grain trips and their respective duration are in consistency with the values in Sect. 6.5.3.1. By applying (5.23), the minimum RFR for basic and advanced technology upgrade is 11,489 and 11,924 $/d respectively (see Appendix F for simulated results, Figs. F.81 and F.82). Juxtaposing these values with those from Table 6.20 it is obvious that the equilibrium freight rate is profitable for the basic and advanced technology expenditure. However, to remove any doubts, by comparing the rate cumulative probability plots the results can be elucidated outspokenly. As indicated by Fig. 6.18, the probability of the minimum required time charter trip rates being larger than the equilibrium values for basic and advanced technology upgrades is between 44 and 48%. This entails that the EEISS can be justified by a probability in the range of 52–56%. 6.5.3.4 Sensitivity Analysis It is straightforward that for higher prices the EEISS would still be profitable. Though, to investigate the significance of change in the price volatility, the models could be entertained by considering a price reduction with the technique outlined in Appendix D. The new values are shown in Table 6.21. 96 6 Application—Ocean Grain Transportation Fig. 6.18 Panamax time charter trip rates cumulative probability curves. Source Plotted by Author Table 6.21 Parameters for evaluating the significance of change for panamax time charter trip contracts Variable Corn price ($/t) Wheat price ($/t) Trip rate ($/d) Newbuilding price ($ 106) 15 years price ($ 106) Earnings ($/d) Source Calculated by Author Model Distribution Parameters Mean Variance Lognormal Lognormal Lognormal Lognormal Lognormal Lognormal m m m m m m = = = = = = 211 277 11,762 26.8 9.5 7,319 s2 s2 s2 s2 s2 s2 = = = = = = 812 792 5,8352 1.392 2.912 1,8012 Upon these changes, the optimum effort level is 10.6% and the agent’s reservation price yields FRRP = 13,036 $/d. The surplus fraction percentages between the principal’s and agent’s reservation prices as well as the equilibrium rate are shown in Table 6.22. Again, it is observed that the surplus fraction and equilibrium rate are indifferent (inelastic) to the commodity prices and technology costs. The fraction percentages are almost similar to those estimated previously, whilst, the rate values have been moderately decreased. The minimum RFR for basic and advanced technology upgrade is 12,028 $/d (standard deviation = 2,661) and 12,571 $/d (standard deviation = 2,745) respectively. With these values, it could be claimed that the basic technology upgrade EEISS can be marginally justified. From the cumulative probability curves (Fig. 6.19) it can be interpreted that the minimum required time charter trip rates can be higher than the equilibrium prices by 39–51%. Hence, it can be depicted that 6.5 Energy Efficiency Sharing Scheme for Panamax Vessel 97 Table 6.22 Surplus fractions and equilibrium prices for panamax time charter trip contracts (sensitivity analysis) Commodity: corn Basic technology upgrade Advanced technology upgrade Commodity: wheat Basic technology upgrade Advanced technology upgrade Source Calculated by Author θΒ (%) θS (%) FRE ($/d) 83.7 83.7 16.3 16.3 12,037 12,021 83.8 83.8 16.2 16.2 12,023 12,059 Fig. 6.19 Panamax time charter trip rates cumulative probability curves (sensitivity analysis). Source Plotted by Author the investment expenditure could be justified by a probability in the range of 49–51%. Although this value is moderately reduced than the previous estimation, it is consistent with the investment appraisal’s result. 6.5.3.5 Investment Recovery By applying (5.25), the payback period is estimated as 20.3 years (standard deviation 16.1 years) for the basic technology upgrade and 27.4 years (standard deviation 18.2 years) for the advanced technology upgrade. From Fig. 6.20 it is illustrated that for the vessel’s expected operational horizon (15 years), the cost expenditure can be recovered up to 37% for the basic, whilst up to 25% for the advanced technology upgrade. 98 6 Application—Ocean Grain Transportation Fig. 6.20 Panamax technology investment payback period cumulative probability curves for time charter trip contracts. Source Plotted by Author 6.6 Commenting Remarks It is noted that the surplus fractions for the selected commodity (i.e. grains), are in favor of the charterer/shipper (principal/buyer) and this provides strong evidence that the arguments put in Sect. 5.3.2 are correct. Moreover, further support is accorded through the work of Ådland et al. (2016) who investigated the fixture buyer-seller characteristics. From their work, a degree of charterers’ market (bargaining) power over the ship-owner/carrier (agent/seller) was observed. Thus, it is understood that the former are large contributors to the determination of the contract price. Consequently, the risk for not reaching an agreement during the negotiations is greater for the owner than it is for the charterer. In this sense, there is more pressure on the owner’s side to settle since the charterer may be willing to give up more than the owner and fix the cargo with another owner. Even in booming market conditions, the owner may not be willing to pursue own reservation price because is fully aware that any final agreement will necessarily benefit the side with the higher surplus (Fisher et al. 2010). The previous analysis has also indicated that the EEISS endorses strongly the time charter rather than the voyage contracts (see Table 6.23 for a summary). As noted earlier, the effect of energy efficiency on voyage freight rates is insignificant because of the freight contract’s functionality, i.e. transport is bought from the agent on a lump sum basis and covers all the incurred costs (see Sect. 2.3). The estimated premium for energy efficiency in the time charter, taking into account the market condition from August 2012 until December 2015, is around 1.8–3.0% of the equilibrium (contract) price, which might be viewed as skimpy. As claimed by Poulsen et al. (2016), although cargo owners (charterers/buyers) have shaped their corporate social responsibility agenda to meet their sustainability concerns and are important potential incubators of promoting environmental behavior, inertia factors exist that inhibit greener performance. Dry bulk and inherently grain sea transportation is characterized by low consumer visibility (the raw material is considerably processed before the final product is made), emphasis is given on price and environmental performance into the procurement of shipping services has been 6.6 Commenting Remarks 99 Table 6.23 Summary of results from the game theoretical analysis (average values) Vessel/contract type Handymax Period Spot Voyage Time charter trip Panamax Period Spot Voyage Time charter trip Source Calculated by Author Energy efficiency premium $/d $/t % of equilibrium price 206 1.8 420 0.06 0.16 3.0 179 1.8 0.03 258 0.09 2.1 integrated by very few players. On the other hand, carriers (ship-owners/sellers) encounter increasing pressure from their clients to improve their environmental performance and in order to provide evidence of the achieved gains; they voluntarily participate in a confusing set of industry and stakeholder initiatives for benchmarking. Moreover, the lack of a consistent framework for collecting data, verification methodology of energy efficient technologies, standardized ranking and rating scheme creates uncertainty among carriers that stalls commitment to environmental stewardship (Poulsen et al. 2016). Yet, this premium percentage is expected to become higher albeit to the anticipation of increasing grain shipments (doubled by 2050 in comparison to current levels) to satisfy rising consumer expectations in developing countries. Additionally, supply chain strategies will be greatly influenced by sustainability aspects, bunker cost minimization motives, raised awareness of climate change and the impact of shipping on atmospheric emissions. Besides, the all-embracing implementation of EEDI measures to ensure a supply of low carbon bulk carriers needs also to be considered (Dinwoodie et al. 2014). Nevertheless, efforts to reduce the carbon footprint of the grain supply chain should contemplate improvements in transportation together with the resultant changes in emissions from production modifications, with the latter comprising the largest component (O’Donnell et al. 2009). However, it is equitable to say that any adjustment will also strongly depend on how the freight rates will respond to the return and volatility of commodity markets as well as the cycles of world economy and commodity consumption (Kavussanos et al. 2010; Geman and Smith 2012). Table 6.23 results coincide with the work of Smith et al. (2013) where the impact of energy efficiency on time charter prices was within the same range and was quantified as being in the region of 200 $/d. 100 6 Application—Ocean Grain Transportation The asymmetric behavior of the energy efficiency premium between period and spot time charter contracts can be explained by the fact that period earnings are lower than spot earnings as well as contain less uncertainty (less than half standard deviation in comparison to the spot). This is because the latter involve unemployment risk (the vessel could be unoccupied for a time), relocation cost (incurred expense when the vessel is relocated after being fixed with different spot contracts) and due to temporal high demand for shipping services combined with an inelastic supply of tonnage (Alizadeh and Nomikos 2011). External factors like port conditions and the different trading patterns of each region play also a role for the observed asymmetry. Besides, as far as the spot market is concerned (trip and voyage charter), voyage contracts are more volatile, hence higher profit is expected and the vessel is preferred to be fixed more on such market (Tsioumas and Papadimitriou 2015). In this respect and under the current market condition, the result that the energy efficiency sharing scheme is not profitable for the period but it can be justified for the spot contracts is reasonable. Outspokenly, basic technology solutions (i.e. low friction coating or bare optimization or appendages or a combination of these) have been also identified by Tsereklas-Zafeirakis et al. (2016) as preferable due to their profitability and technological maturity. Hence, it could be argued that the results of the current book’s chapter can vividly be supported as valid. Furthermore, for the expected investment horizon and the investigated commodity (i.e. grains), only the basic technology upgrade for the handymax vessel is possible to be recovered. Such an observation is not surprising since this is related to the flexibility of smaller vessels to operate in different routes as well as their versatility to perform better in poor market conditions, whilst the operation of larger vessels is more rigid and to secure soaring employment is not easy. Apparently, optimizing the portfolio of period and spot contracts in order a fleet to be fully utilized is part of any shipping company’s risk management policy. For example within a tactical planning context, the possibilities to charter in additional vessels or to charter out the subset of available vessels to other companies (even considering vessel lay-up) is decided so that transportation demand can be met (Nomikos et al. 2013; Pantuso et al. 2014). Though, it should be pointed out that if an owner is risk averse, a stable income even with a lower average value will be accepted than a higher variable income. Similarly, the owner is opting for an energy efficiency premium that balances own needs for secured vessel employment versus the charterer’s needs to have the commodity transported (Fisher et al. 2010). Part IV Epilogue Chapter 7 Conclusions, Limitations and Recommendations Abstract The research objectives posed the necessity to adapt a qualitative approach using exploratory document search from which a theory is developed to examine if it is appropriate to include design energy efficiency improvement clause in charter party contracts. Subsequently, the book’s work proceeded with the quantitative research objectives, where game theory is employed to suggest a suitable incentive mechanism design that may support the pricing aspects of the clause. The developed conceptual framework is demonstrated through a case study within seaborne grain transport. In this respect, the book’s current and final chapter is aimed at concluding the performed research by outlining the results of the analysis as well as the contribution to the body of knowledge on charter party contracts. In confidence that academic and industry interest may be generated, this chapter has also the purpose to address the book’s limitations and to make recommendations drawn upon the book’s second chapter’s literature review. 7.1 Preamble The maritime industry’s approach to minimizing its emissions’ impact can go beyond the already adapted operational measures and become more strategically oriented by exploiting opportunities induced through regulations. Companies can embrace a proactive approach that improves their commercial positioning to competitors by the ability to invest largely in technology and reconfigure their fleets. The competitive advantage produced by a company’s energy efficient vessels can outperform rivals lacking the scope of energy saving performance beyond the standard requirements (Porter and Reinhardt 2007). This is related to innovative technologies that initially may look financially unattractive and cannot make a valid contribution to corporate growth. However, many of these technologies are valued only in new applications which are not in the forefront of the rapidly growing needs of existing markets. Once these innovations are established within their emerging markets and followed by steep progress, then the next generation market needs can be satisfied more or better. The cost structure securing investment and funneling © Springer International Publishing Switzerland 2017 G.A. Psarros, Energy Efficiency Clauses in Charter Party Agreements, Springer Series on Naval Architecture, Marine Engineering, Shipbuilding and Shipping 3, DOI 10.1007/978-3-319-50265-6_7 103 104 7 Conclusions, Limitations and Recommendations resources for these technologies plays a critical role in pursuing the effort required for their acceptance (Bower and Christensen 1995). 7.2 Conclusions Forthcoming stringent maritime environmental regulations as well as those that have recently been in force imply the importance of adopting a life cycle approach to environmental stewardship by investing in the installation of energy efficient equipment. The argument put forward is not only viewed from an operational perspective, but also sets actions during the vessel’s design phase. Essentially, an efficient way of achieving this target is through the creation of incentives, so that the long established business attitude between charterers or shippers and ship-owners or carriers is influenced and ultimately changed. In this study therefore, an attempt has been made to shed light on this challenge by assembling a qualitative and exploratory research study where the conclusions are grounded on the simultaneous analyses of data (legal instruments and literature as well as charter party contracts) and a body of theoretical knowledge is emerged from the observed phenomena. Thus, to negotiate design energy efficiency improvements from a position of strength and gain a competitive edge, it is important to grasp a solid understanding of the relevant commercial, regulatory, legal and contractual principles. It is explored how the prevailing multi-faceted commercial challenges of the charter party signatories can be resolved through the international regulatory context on pollution prevention which underpins maritime law. Moreover, it is clearly demonstrated how the corresponding framework of reference under case law comes into play within the governing legal landscape in order to appreciate and provide wise contract safeguards surrounding environmental protection. The value to transforming the existing chartering practice and its contractual structure is incisively addressed with a conceptualization commentary. To this end, it is argued that the book’s aim and objectives have been met, since the main contribution of the conducted qualitative research has been twofold, firstly it is related to the development of the methodology itself. Secondly, due to the lack of academic work and relevant literature, a theoretical proposition on incorporating design energy efficiency improvements in charter party contracts is described. On attaining this contribution, answers to the following qualitative research objectives need to be obtained from the current book: • Examine if the legal instruments permit the inclusion of clauses into the existing charter party contracts that can clarify the investment responsibility and obligation of design energy efficiency improvements; • Identify if any clauses included in the charter party contracts are accounting for design energy efficiency improvements; • Determine which vessel design parameters incorporated in the charter party contract clauses are associated with the topic under investigation; 7.2 Conclusions 105 • Propose any amendments or additions to the relevant charter party contract clauses that could contain the vessel’s energy efficiency specification. It is believed that the book’s qualitative part provides answers to the aforementioned that are guided by an inductive sequential exploratory research using qualitative data extracted from documents, where each objective is addressed through several stages. The whole procedure is based on grounded theory which helped to establish the framework for promoting the inclusion of design energy efficiency improvements in charter party contracts. The first objective is answered by the initial coding of the legal instruments interpretations (first stage—see Sect. 4.2). The documentary sources augmented with evidence from journal articles enabled the author (researcher) to acquire an enhanced understanding of the complex nature of the charter party contracts with respect to the vessel’s energy efficiency specification. More specifically, the conducted work allows firstly pointing out that the current legal instruments do not inhibit any constraint for including a rider-clause related to design energy efficiency improvements within the charter party contracts. The focused coding (second stage—see Sect. 4.4) of the standardized charter forms provides input to the second and third objectives. It identifies the areas where the vessel’s design energy efficiency improvements can be supported as a subject term of a charter’s rider-clause. This finding is drawn upon the time and voyage charter party contracts content analysis, which indicated that reference to design energy efficiency improvements is not made explicit. It is observed that energy efficiency is indirectly linked to the vessel’s performance (fuel consumption) which is emphasized only on the former (time charters). The answer to the last qualitative objective is grounded on the performed research and advances a clear view of the theoretical proposition on incorporating design energy efficiency improvements in charter party contracts (see Sects. 4.3 and 4.5). It is expected that such initiative will clarify the responsibility between the involved parties and will create an incentive for implementing and investing in design energy efficiency improvements in both time as well as voyage charters. To increase the book’s intellectual gravity, the work dwells in the quantitative part which is an economic inquiry process of the theoretical proposition, i.e. rider-clause on design energy efficiency improvements. For this purpose, the book is tasked to satisfy the following quantitative research objectives: • Suggest a mechanism design of the energy efficiency sharing scheme and its connection to the chartering procedure; • Demonstrate the practicality of the designed mechanism within the dry bulk shipping sector and a specific commodity. In tribute of the first, the well-established game theory mathematical models on principal-agent and bargaining are adapted to portray the business attitude between the charterer (shipper or buyer) and ship-owner (carrier or seller) (see Sect. 5.3). The work is also supplemented with investment appraisal techniques to foster justification of the proposed energy efficiency sharing scheme, as specified in a 106 7 Conclusions, Limitations and Recommendations prospective rider-clause. On this foundation, it is anticipated that such rule is grounded on commercial reasonableness, the parties’ interests are secured and inevitably the maritime industry’s environmental commitment is not only conserved, but also recognized. The illustrative case study is concentrated on seaborne grain trade and treats the last quantitative research objective (see Sects. 6.4 and 6.5). The results clearly discern the charterer’s bargaining power over the ship-owner with the surplus fraction (gains from trade) favoring the former. This affirms that the technical arguments displayed in Sect. 5.3 are correct. The energy efficiency sharing scheme’s mastery is prominently noticed on the time charter contracts. By contrast, for the voyage contracts the contribution is trivial due to their functionality, i.e. transport is bought from the agent on a lump sum basis and covers all the incurred costs (see Sect. 2.3). Furthermore, the higher energy efficiency premium for the spot time charters signals their intricate purpose since more employment risk is availed. As far as the technology investment is concerned, given the current grain market situation and the fixed operational horizon (15 years), it suffices to say that only the basic expenditure ($1.5 million) for the handymax bulk carrier can be recovered. Such finding confers a thorough indication of the smaller vessel’s resource capability to perform satisfactorily under a challenging freight market. In this spirit, the game theory approach applied to chartering and as outlined in the current book’s quantitative part can provide an all-encompassing insight of the parties’ information needs when negotiating the contract. Incredibly, a new ground is offered to make understandable the incentive mechanism for investing in the vessel’s design energy efficiency improvements. 7.3 Limitations and Suggestions for Further Research Common to any research study, the conducted work in this book recognizes a number of limitations which need to be mentioned. The inductive nature of the book’s qualitative part has facilitated the creation of a theory related to the incorporation of design energy efficiency improvements in charter party contracts and an instrumental element is the reliance on document search. Although the qualitative research objectives have been addressed, a third stage could be added in the research method examining the industry’s opinion on this aspect. This could be materialized through the organization of questionnaires as well as interviews with major stakeholders such as ship-owners or carriers, charterers or shippers, ship builders, brokers, lawyers, shipping associations, etc. To this end, using multiple data collection methods will strengthen the triangulation of data sources during the previous two stages (see Sect. 3.2.1). However, it should be stressed that in the present work, only the theoretical foundations for supporting the existence of a rider-clause associated with design energy efficiency improvements in time and voyage charters are formed. The difficulty of the negotiations in determining the details of the sharing scheme (costs, risks and rewards) between the two parties should not be underestimated and 7.3 Limitations and Suggestions for Further Research 107 relies on a thorough quantification. Accordingly, given the fact that the investigated topic poses challenges into the traditional concept of the commercial enterprise between the charterers or shippers and ship-owners or carriers, the validity and practicality of their respective changing financial responsibilities can be elaborated with the consideration of brokers. In this respect, the rigorous mathematical framework of game theory provides an excellent premise to extend the models in Sect. 5.3, see for example Rubinstein and Wolinsky (1987) as well as Biglaiser (1993). Certainly, the adapted mathematical models could be also specified for other possible states, for instance competition or pooling between ship-owners and selection from a menu of charterers or when the ship-owners are able to exercise market power. Initial thoughts on how to analyze the strategic interaction and valuate the contract can be pursued from Roger (2016) and Blume et al. (2009) respectively. Another element that requires closer examination is the quantification of the agent’s environmental attributes (see Sect. 5.3.2.2) which is a complex topic by itself. Moreover, the intention of the current book is to introduce game theory reasoning when negotiating the charter party contract and orchestrate additional activity in this area. Appreciating the caveat of reflecting the real world by mathematical models, the prevailing assumptions in the NPV calculations need to be refined. In order to get an accurate description for the vessel’s operational profile, backhaul opportunities of other major dry bulk commodities (as well as the minor bulks) need to be accommodated. However, this may diverge from the book’s research objectives since this issue may fall upon drawing inferences on the optimal mix of transported cargoes and is out of the book’s scope (see Stålhane et al. 2014 as well as Laake and Zhang (2016) for more information). Without adding unnecessary difficulty, the inclusion of different values of parameter δ in (5.23) and the relevant changes in the commodity values as well as freight and hire rates (the principal-agent and bargaining models have to be updated), can solve this aspect. Yet, by investigating a set of commodities, the models could govern the general principles on how to select contracts that can recover faster the design energy efficiency investment. The depicted economic evaluations were concerned only for newbuilding vessels, thus, valuable insights of the EEISS within the second-hand market could be obtained when these calculations are also performed for the old tonnage. Furthermore, the topics discussed herein could be implemented in the capesize sector as well as in the seaborne oil transportation. Recognizing that during the last four decades the fuel consumption per transported unit has been reduced by 1.5% on an annual basis (Chen et al. 2010), the conservative assignment of energy efficiency gains could be relaxed (i.e. 5% increase of the assumed values). In addition, the impact of trading within ECAs could be added by considering two different bunkers (heavy fuel and marine gas oil), although such formulation is not expected to influence the findings. In any case, the vessel will choose to sail longer distances to avoid or reduce the time spent within ECAs, hence use less of the more expensive fuel (Fagerholt et al. 2015). Variable vessel speeds and voyage duration have already been utilized and this element can be incorporated by increasing the standard deviation of the 108 7 Conclusions, Limitations and Recommendations distributions. Nevertheless, the aforementioned stemming appeals seem to painstakingly correspond to the author’s best effort in providing useful insights that can justify the investment sharing between the charter contract’s signatories. This is a subject of some controversy as accorded to the existing business setting between charterers or shippers and ship-owners or carriers. 7.4 Recommendations Given the lack of a theory supporting the view that design energy efficiency improvements shall be included in the charter forms; the qualitative stages as described in the current book, need to be supplemented by a succeeding action stage that informs the qualitative findings. This requires the collation of primary data through interviews, questionnaires as well as discussions to obtain the perceptions of the market (industrial players) and gain insight into their motivations as well as actions regarding design energy efficiency improvements. Such a comprehensive study will offer an understanding whether the promotion of environmental stewardship across the value chain for both charterers or shippers and ship-owners or carriers should be reflected in the charter party agreements. In this way, the compliance of the EEDI regulation for improving the energy efficiency of vessels will be driven by the industrial players, confirming the regulation’s non-prescriptive nature. Judged by the aforementioned, the EEDI regulation as a proactive performance based mechanism designed to induce technical measures for improving the energy efficiency of vessels, gives the industry players the privilege to choose the optimum combination of energy saving technologies, as long as the required energy efficiency level is attained and compliance with the regulation is obtained. In order to transform the traditional concept of the commercial enterprise between the charterers or shippers and ship-owners or carriers and to encourage better implementation of the design energy saving improvements, it is suggested that a standardized rider-clause within the ordinary contracts will ensure the interest protection of both parties and overcome the agency formation tendency. All in all, shipping circles (Ballou 2015; Rust 2015) have raised concerns over the current standardized charter agreements and a better solution that would improve the business would be overhauling the agreement, in which outdated clauses are replaced with new terms that motivate taking advantage of technology innovations. Having said that, and conferring the book’s findings from the quantitative framework of contract theory, the uncertainties emanating through the varying levels of cost, information sharing as well as the trade-off between energy efficiency and performance have been clarified. To this end, the book’s material can be viewed as a pathway towards forming or amending charter contracts where commercial reasonableness guides a fair negotiation. As shown from the conducted content analysis of time and voyage charters, as well as the observations identified by the literature (for instance see the relevant theory on design energy efficiency improvements in Sect. 4.3), the consideration of 7.4 Recommendations 109 the bunkers’ quality in addition to the installed systems for monitoring the vessel’s performance (fuel consumption) paves the way for the inclusion of new negotiated terms, for instance the vessel’s design energy efficiency specification when arranging her employment. Such provision is intended to indicate that design energy efficiency improvements have been agreed by the parties and there is implied obligation on the equipment’s optimal utilization. The corollary of this is that, both parties have the duty to carry on negotiations in good faith for pursuing the inclusion of a sharing scheme for the incurred costs of design energy efficiency improvements, since their goals of profit maximization are different. Ultimately the human element is paramount to the overall effectiveness of the chartering process and as argued by Kitada and Ölҫer (2015) humans need to be equipped with satisfactory knowledge and awareness of selecting as well as implementing appropriate energy efficiency measures. It should be noted that the contractual flexibility achieved by the inclusion of clauses in the charter party forms specifying the vessel’s energy efficiency clarifies the rights, duties and responsibilities between the business signatories concerning design energy efficiency improvements. Furthermore, it provides a mutual understanding of the common obligation for adopting greener shipping practices and it is the core mechanism for enhancing environmental performance. In coincidence with Lister et al. (2015) stakeholders along the maritime value chain have moved towards a more proactive stance by voluntarily participating in various ‘green shipping’ initiatives. Definitely environmentally sustainable shipping operations are given merit, but with these schemes different shipping segments are targeted and the evaluations rely on self-assessment, therefore a consistent framework for data collection and verification methodology is lacking (Lister et al. 2015). Although this entails progress and thus compliance with environmental regulations (i.e. reduction of shipping emissions), it is inefficient to effectively motivate the implementation of design energy efficiency improvements. It is believed that the obtained competitive advantages of enhanced corporate social responsibility and a focus on sustainability through design energy efficiency will be realized when the widely used operational measures (i.e. slow steaming, virtual arrival) have already delivered their emission abatement potential. Consequently, to the author’s ambition this book could be regarded as a starting point to fill the gap on how to support design measures. Appendix A Generic Bulk Carrier Designs The bulk carrier is a merchant vessel designed for the carriage of cargoes in homogeneous mass, usually without packaging of any kind and is engaged in various trades (i.e. iron ore, coal, grains, fertilizers, minerals, etc.) lacking a regular itinerary. This ocean transportation service is known as tramp shipping. Apart from achieving economies of scale which in turn facilitated the growth in vessel size, the increasing popularity of the bulk carrier is attributed to her cargo hold configuration (see Fig. A.1). As shown, the hatch opening is wide to ease cargo handling, the hatch is extended above deck to accept more cargo (grain in particular) and the need for shifting boards is eliminated due to the slopped wing and hopper tanks that can carry ballast. These tanks are the key, since they result in a self-trimming hold, which means that the cargoes follow their natural gradient when loaded into the hold and thereby reducing the expensive stevedore costs for trimming the cargo (Wijnolst and Wergeland 2009). Bulk carriers employed in the grain trade are of Fig. A.1 Typical cargo hold configuration for a single skin bulk carrier. Note Drawing not in scale. Source Drawn by author and based on IACS (2007) © Springer International Publishing Switzerland 2017 G.A. Psarros, Energy Efficiency Clauses in Charter Party Agreements, Springer Series on Naval Architecture, Marine Engineering, Shipbuilding and Shipping 3, DOI 10.1007/978-3-319-50265-6 111 112 Appendix A: Generic Bulk Carrier Designs Fig. A.2 Generic views of a typical single skin handymax bulk carrier (50,000–65,000 DWT). Average dimensions (m): L B T: 200 32.26 12.9. Note Drawing not in scale. Source Drawn by author and based on JSEA (2016) Fig. A.3 Generic views of a typical single skin panamax bulk carrier (70,000–85,000 DWT) Average dimensions (m): L B T: 227 32.26 14.1. Note Drawing not in scale. Source Drawn by author and based on JSEA (2016) two types: handymax and panamax (see Figs. A.2 and A.3 respectively). It is observed that the handymax vessel is equipped with cranes (usually grab fitted) and her cargo space is divided into five holds. Whereas, the panamax vessel is gearless and her cargo space is divided into seven holds. Appendix B Parametric Distribution Fitting to Observed Data The most common and flexible technique of finding a theoretical (parametric) distribution that best fits the observed data is the maximum likelihood estimation. The estimators of the distribution are the parameters that maximize the joint probability density (likelihood function) and usually an optimizer is exploited (like Microsoft Excel Solver) to find the most suitable combination of parameter values. The likelihood function of a sample x1, x2, x3, …, xn from the probability density f (X, h) of random variable X, with parameter vector h = (h1, …, hm) can be given as (Vose 2009): Lðx1 ; x2 ; . . .; xn jh1 ; . . .; hm Þ ¼ max n Y f ðxi jhÞ ðB:1Þ i¼1 Due to the multiplicative form of (B.1) and because the logarithmic transformation is monotonous, it is more convenient to maximize the logarithm of the likelihood function (Vose 2009): lðx1 ; x2 ; . . .; xn jh1 ; . . .; hm Þ ¼ max n X logðf ðxi jhÞÞ ðB:2Þ i¼1 Upon fitting the theoretical distribution, it is necessary to determine whether the sample belongs to the parametric distribution (goodness of fit statistic). The chi-square (v2) statistic measures how well the expected frequency E(i) of the fitted distribution compares with the observed frequency O(i) of a k-interval histogram of the observed data and is calculated as follows (Vose 2009): v2 ¼ k X ½OðiÞ E ðiÞ2 i¼1 E ðiÞ ðB:3Þ Given that m parameters have been estimated from the sample, the result of (B.3) shall be smaller than the critical value of v21a ðk m 1Þ, i.e. the (1 − a)100 © Springer International Publishing Switzerland 2017 G.A. Psarros, Energy Efficiency Clauses in Charter Party Agreements, Springer Series on Naval Architecture, Marine Engineering, Shipbuilding and Shipping 3, DOI 10.1007/978-3-319-50265-6 113 114 Appendix B: Parametric Distribution Fitting to Observed Data percentile of the chi-square distribution with k – m − 1 degrees of freedom. In this respect, chances are greater than 1 in (100 − a%)−1 that the observed data correspond to the theoretical distribution, which implies that the distribution should not be rejected (Vose 2009). Appendix C Monte Carlo Simulation Let us consider a general estimation model M which is a function of uncertain quantities x1, …, xn and is described as (Modarres 2006; Vose 2009): M ¼ f ðx1 ; . . .; xn Þ ðC:1Þ Knowing that the uncertainties of the quantities xi have been characterized and analyzed through the fitted distributions from the observed data, we want to determine the distribution of M on the basis of some information about the joint distribution of x1, …, xn. Apparently, information is available about the marginal distributions of x1, …, xn which are regarded as random variables, are treated separately and are considered uncorrelated (independent) from each other. It is the concept of inverse function gi(fi(xi)) that is employed to generate random samples from each distribution. Naturally, the generated random number ri is acquired from a uniform (0, 1) distribution to provide equal opportunity of an xk value being produced in any percentile range. The result is then fed into the equation to determine the value to be generated for the distribution (Modarres 2006; Vose 2009): gi ðfi ðxi ÞÞ ¼ ri ) gi ðri Þ ¼ xk ðC:2Þ Hence, we are able to calculate the uncertainty characteristics of M by also treating it as a random variable. For each xi, a value is selected from its respective distribution with the assistance of statistical sampling techniques, where each set of data values is used to find one estimate of M. This is repeated for a large number of times, i.e. 10,000 (or more to achieve the required level of precision), in order to obtain many estimate instances of the M’s distribution. Consequently, these values are used for determining the distribution of M (Modarres 2006; Vose 2009): © Springer International Publishing Switzerland 2017 G.A. Psarros, Energy Efficiency Clauses in Charter Party Agreements, Springer Series on Naval Architecture, Marine Engineering, Shipbuilding and Shipping 3, DOI 10.1007/978-3-319-50265-6 115 116 Appendix C: Monte Carlo Simulation g11 ðr1 Þ; . . .; g1n ðrn Þ ) M1 ¼ f x1k ... ... ... ... ... gl1 ðr1 Þ; . . .; gln ðrn Þ ... ) M ¼ f xlk ðC:3Þ l It is noted that the performed Monte Carlo simulations are run with the Microsoft Excel add-in created by Barreto and Howland (2006) and packaged in their book. Appendix D Parameter Change Interval Given a sample of observable quantities y1, y2, …, yn, we would like to draw conclusions about the population’s location (mean h) and scale (variance r) parameters which are assumed to be independent. The joint posterior distribution of h and r can be regarded as being built up from a series of a class of distributions each centered at y, each of which represents the conditional distribution pðhjr; yÞ of h for some given r, multiplied by pðrjsÞ, the marginal posterior distribution of r which has the form of an inverted gamma function (where s2 is the sample’s variance). It is known that the parent distribution is a member of a class of symmetric distributions which is stipulated by a parameter b. In particular, when b = 0 the normal distribution is chosen, b = 1 the double exponential distribution is included and b = −1 the uniform distribution is disposed. The posterior distribution of h can thus be derived supposing a fixed value b0 (Box and Tiao 1962): " ðn þ 1Þ pðh; rjy,b0 Þ ¼ kr 2=ð1 þ b0 Þ # 1 X yi h exp 2 i r ðD:1Þ where k is an appropriate normalization coefficient. After taking the logarithms and upon integration of (D.1), the subsequent conclusions are drawn (Box and Tiao 1965, 1968): Pn pffiffiffiffi 2 yÞ2 and • It is observed that r is distributed as vsv1 v where vs ¼ i¼1 ðyi v = n − 1 degrees of freedom. The limits of the 95% interval can be obtained from tables of the double tailed chi-squared distribution corresponding to a = 0.05 and v = n − 1 degrees of freedom. Thus, the lower and upper limits of r are respectively: r20 ¼ vs2 v2 ð v Þ and r21 ¼ vs2 v2 ð v Þ © Springer International Publishing Switzerland 2017 G.A. Psarros, Energy Efficiency Clauses in Charter Party Agreements, Springer Series on Naval Architecture, Marine Engineering, Shipbuilding and Shipping 3, DOI 10.1007/978-3-319-50265-6 ðD:2Þ 117 118 Appendix D: Parameter Change Interval • It is shown that h follows Student’s t distribution with v = n − 1 degrees of pffiffiffi freedom, which is symmetric and centered at y with scaling factor s= n. Further, the limits of the (1 − a) intervals of tðy; s2 =n; vÞ are given by: s y pffiffiffi tðaÞ ðvÞ n 2 ðD:3Þ An illustrative example that demonstrates in a practical way how the aforementioned propositions can be applied is offered by Box and Tiao (1992). Appendix E Assigned Parametric Distributions See Tables E.1 and E.2. Table E.1 Input data for entertaining the probabilistic models Variable Model Distribution parameters Test statistic Corn price ($/t) Wheat price ($/t) Grain densitya (t/m3) Bunker price ($/t) Handymax vessel Period rate ($/d) Period duration (d) Newbuilding price ($106) 15 years price ($106) Earnings ($/d) Grain capacity (m3) Operating costsb ($/d) Voyage rate ($/t) Cargo quantity (t) Grain voyages (%) Spot duration (d) Speed (kn) Fuel consumption (t/d) Time charter trip ($/d) Grain trips (%) Panamax vessel Period rate ($/d) Period duration (d) Lognormal Lognormal Normal Lognormal m = 234 m = 302 l = 0.7227 m = 584 s2 = 662 s2 = 642 r2 = 0.0952 s2 = 2962 0.45 0.33 0.04 1.33 36.415 36.415 24.996 36.415 Lognormal Gamma Lognormal m = 11,228 a = 20.3 m = 25.5 s2 = 2,4882 b = 6.6 s2 = 1.252 0.52 1.29 0.57 36.415 36.415 36.415 Lognormal Lognormal Normal Lognormal Lognormal Normal Normal Gamma Weibull Weibull Lognormal Normal m = 9.9 m = 10,749 l = 68,785 m = 5,181 m = 38.4 l = 52,883 l = 40 a = 3.95 a = 32.9 a = 11 m = 13,962 l = 10 s2 = 3.382 s2 = 3,8112 r2 = 9,5512 s2 = 1,4662 s2 = 19.92 r2 = 8,8972 r 2 = 52 b = 12.21 b = 14.4 b = 31.7 s2 = 6,7272 r2 = 0.52 0.51 0.23 11.9 0.21 0.51 0.05 0.84 0.06 2.72 19.13 1.39 0.16 36.415 36.415 124.342 22.362 55.758 55.758 30.144 9.488 124.342 124.342 79.082 30.144 Lognormal Gamma m = 9,635 a = 3.5 s2 = 2,7622 b = 75.5 0.67 2.66 © Springer International Publishing Switzerland 2017 G.A. Psarros, Energy Efficiency Clauses in Charter Party Agreements, Springer Series on Naval Architecture, Marine Engineering, Shipbuilding and Shipping 3, DOI 10.1007/978-3-319-50265-6 Critical value 79.082 79.082 (continued) 119 120 Appendix E: Assigned Parametric Distributions Table E.1 (continued) Variable Model Distribution parameters Lognormal m = 27.3 Newbuilding price ($106) Lognormal m = 10.2 15 years price ($106) Earnings ($/d) Lognormal m = 7,873 Normal l = 93,687 Grain capacity (m3) Lognormal m = 6,324 Operating costsb ($/d) Voyage rate ($/t) Lognormal m = 34.3 Cargo quantity (t) Normal l = 59,508 Grain voyages (%) Normal l = 20 Spot duration (d) Gamma a = 15.09 Speed (kn) Weibull a = 34.6 Fuel consumption (t/d) Weibull a = 11 Time charter trip ($/d) Lognormal m = 12,059 Grain trips (%) Normal l = 25 Source Author’s calculations using data from CRSL b Gardiner et al. (2009) s2 = 1.592 Test statistic 0.56 Critical value 36.415 s2 = 3.322 0.22 36.415 0.07 36.415 s2 = 2,0592 r2 = 6,7332 11.88 124.342 s2 = 1,7522 0.21 22.362 1.16 79.082 s2 = 16.62 79.082 r2 = 2,8682 17.11 0.08 30.144 r 2 = 32 b = 3.48 0.79 21.026 b = 14.4 22.07 124.342 b = 35.9 3.72 124.342 124.342 s2 = 7,7002 19.47 0.15 30.144 r2 = 0.92 (2016a, b) except from: aSewell (1999) and Table E.2 Legend—explanations for the parameters of the statistical distributions Parameter l r m s a b a b Mean of the normal distribution (location parameter) Standard deviation of the normal distribution (scale parameter) Mean of the lognormal distribution (scale parameter) Standard deviation of the lognormal distribution (shape parameter) Shape parameter of the Gamma distribution Scale parameter of the Gamma distribution Shape parameter (Weibull distribution) Characteristic value (scale parameter of Weibull distribution) Appendix F Simulated Variables See Figs. F.1, F.2, F.3, F.4, F.5, F.6, F.7, F.8, F.9, F.10, F.11, F.12, F.13, F.15, F.16, F.17, F.18, F.19, F.20, F.21, F.22, F.23, F.24, F.25, F.26, F.27, F.29, F.30, F.31, F.32, F.33, F.34, F.35, F.36, F.37, F.38, F.39, F.40, F.41, F.43, F.44, F.45, F.46, F.47, F.48, F.49, F.50, F.51, F.52, F.53, F.54, F.55, F.57, F.58, F.59, F.60, F.61, F.62, F.63, F.64, F.65, F.66, F.67, F.68, F.69, F.71, F.72, F.73, F.74, F.75, F.76, F.77, F.78, F.79, F.80, F.81 and F.82. F.14, F.28, F.42, F.56, F.70, Fig. F.1 Histogram of effort level for handymax period contract (10,000 repetitions, average = 0.090, standard deviation = 0.242). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) © Springer International Publishing Switzerland 2017 G.A. Psarros, Energy Efficiency Clauses in Charter Party Agreements, Springer Series on Naval Architecture, Marine Engineering, Shipbuilding and Shipping 3, DOI 10.1007/978-3-319-50265-6 121 122 Appendix F: Simulated Variables Fig. F.2 Histogram of agent’s reservation price for handymax period contract (10,000 repetitions, average = 12,193, standard deviation = 3,852). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.3 Histogram of depreciation for handymax vessel (10,000 repetitions, average = 0.064, standard deviation = 0.021). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.4 Histogram of handymax period surplus fraction for corn and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, principal: average = 0.785, standard deviation = 0.0595, agent: average = 0.215, standard deviation = 0.0602). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Appendix F: Simulated Variables 123 Fig. F.5 Histogram of handymax equilibrium period contract for corn and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 11,434, standard deviation = 2,684). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.6 Histogram of handymax period surplus fraction for corn and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, principal: average = 0.785, standard deviation = 0.0588, agent: average = 0.215, standard deviation = 0.0594). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.7 Histogram of handymax equilibrium period contract for corn and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 11,448, standard deviation = 2,670). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) 124 Appendix F: Simulated Variables Fig. F.8 Histogram of handymax period surplus fraction for wheat and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, principal: average = 0.787, standard deviation = 0.058, agent: average = 0.213, standard deviation = 0.0584). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.9 Histogram of handymax equilibrium period contract for wheat and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 11,408, standard deviation = 2,667). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.10 Histogram of handymax period surplus fraction for wheat and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, principal: average = 0.786, standard deviation = 0.0596, agent: average = 0.214, standard deviation = 0.059). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Appendix F: Simulated Variables 125 Fig. F.11 Histogram of handymax equilibrium period contract for wheat and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 11,446, standard deviation = 2,665). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.12 Histogram of capital cost (10,000 repetitions, average = 10.88, standard deviation = 0.545). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a), OECD (2016) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.13 Histogram of handymax minimum RFR for period contract and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 11,936, standard deviation = 1,423). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a, b) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) 126 Appendix F: Simulated Variables Fig. F.14 Histogram of handymax minimum RFR for period contract and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 12,693, standard deviation = 1,434). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a, b) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.15 Histogram of environmental stewardship for handymax voyage contract and corn as cargo (10,000 repetitions, basic technology upgrade and low attribute: average = 0.0013, standard deviation = 0.0033, basic technology upgrade and high attribute: average = 0.0037, standard deviation = 0.0097, advanced technology upgrade and high attribute: average = 0.0033, standard deviation = 0.0113). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Appendix F: Simulated Variables 127 Fig. F.16 Histogram of environmental stewardship for handymax voyage contract and wheat as cargo (10,000 repetitions, basic technology upgrade and low attribute: average = 0.0018, standard deviation = 0.0047, basic technology upgrade and high attribute: average = 0.0024, standard deviation = 0.0081, advanced technology upgrade and low attribute: average = 0.0019, standard deviation = 0.46, advanced technology upgrade and high attribute: average = 0.0027, standard deviation = 0.0087). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.17 Histogram of agent’s reservation price for handymax corn voyage contract and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 38.65, standard deviation = 20.11). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.18 Histogram of agent’s reservation price for handymax corn voyage contract and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 38.61, standard deviation = 20.12). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) 128 Appendix F: Simulated Variables Fig. F.19 Histogram of agent’s reservation price for handymax wheat voyage contract and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 38.43, standard deviation = 19.85). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the Excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.20 Histogram of agent’s reservation price for handymax wheat voyage contract and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 38.70, standard deviation = 20.36). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.21 Histogram of handymax voyage surplus fraction for corn and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, principal: average = 0.786, standard deviation = 0.0587, agent: average = 0.214, standard deviation = 0.0586). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Appendix F: Simulated Variables 129 Fig. F.22 Histogram of handymax equilibrium voyage contract for corn and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 38.42, standard deviation = 20.22). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.23 Histogram of handymax voyage surplus fraction for corn and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, principal: average = 0.787, standard deviation = 0.0582, agent: average = 0.213, standard deviation = 0.059). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.24 Histogram of handymax equilibrium voyage contract for corn and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 38.48, standard deviation = 20.59). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) 130 Appendix F: Simulated Variables Fig. F.25 Histogram of handymax voyage surplus fraction for wheat and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, principal: average = 0.787, standard deviation = 0.0588, agent: average = 0.213, standard deviation = 0.0593). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.26 Histogram of handymax equilibrium voyage contract for wheat and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 38.41, standard deviation = 20.99). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.27 Histogram of handymax voyage surplus fraction for wheat and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, principal: average = 0.786, standard deviation = 0.0592, agent: average = 0.214, standard deviation = 0.0589). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Appendix F: Simulated Variables 131 Fig. F.28 Histogram of handymax equilibrium voyage contract for wheat and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 38.52, standard deviation = 20.81). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.29 Histogram of handymax annual grain loadings for voyage contracts (10,000 repetitions, Min = 1, Max = 3). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.30 Histogram of handymax spot duration (voyage and time charter trip contracts) (10,000 repetitions, average = 48, standard deviation = 24). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2015) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) 132 Appendix F: Simulated Variables Fig. F.31 Histogram of handymax voyage costs (10,000 repetitions, basic technology upgrade: average = 1.159, standard deviation = 0.94, advanced technology upgrade: average = 1.094, standard deviation = 0.87). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a, b) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.32 Histogram of handymax voyage RFR for basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 36.51, standard deviation = 5.26). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a, b) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.33 Histogram of handymax voyage RFR for advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 35.68, standard deviation = 5.02). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a, b) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Appendix F: Simulated Variables 133 Fig. F.34 Histogram of handymax annual grain loadings for time charter trip contracts (10,000 repetitions, Min = 1, Max = 10). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.35 Histogram of effort level for handymax time charter trip contract (10,000 repetitions, average = 0.128, standard deviation = 0.266). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.36 Histogram of agent’s reservation price for handymax time charter trip contract (10,000 repetitions, average = 15,478, standard deviation = 8,510). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) 134 Appendix F: Simulated Variables Fig. F.37 Histogram of handymax equilibrium time charter trip contract for corn and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 14,040, standard deviation = 6,829). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.38 Histogram of handymax equilibrium time charter trip contract for corn and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 14,083, standard deviation = 6,925). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.39 Histogram of handymax equilibrium time charter trip contract for wheat and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 14,211, standard deviation = 6,854). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Appendix F: Simulated Variables 135 Fig. F.40 Histogram of handymax equilibrium time charter trip contract for wheat and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 14,114, standard deviation = 6,904). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.41 Histogram of handymax RFR for time charter trip contract and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 11,534, standard deviation = 4,358). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a, b) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.42 Histogram of handymax RFR for time charter trip contract and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 10,615, standard deviation = 3,162). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a, b) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) 136 Appendix F: Simulated Variables Fig. F.43 Histogram of effort level for panamax period contract (10,000 repetitions, average = 0.096, standard deviation = 0.231). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.44 Histogram of agent’s reservation price for panamax period contract (10,000 repetitions, average = 10,541, standard deviation = 3813). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.45 Histogram of panamax period surplus fraction for corn and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, principal: average = 0.833, standard deviation = 0.0352, agent: average = 0.167, standard deviation = 0.0354). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Appendix F: Simulated Variables 137 Fig. F.46 Histogram of panamax equilibrium period contract for corn and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 9,819, standard deviation = 2,798). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.47 Histogram of panamax period surplus fraction for corn and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, principal: average = 0.832, standard deviation = 0.0350, agent: average = 0.168, standard deviation = 0.0355). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.48 Histogram of panamax equilibrium period contract for corn and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 9,807, standard deviation = 2,812). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) 138 Appendix F: Simulated Variables Fig. F.49 Histogram of panamax period surplus fraction for wheat and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, principal: average = 0.833, standard deviation = 0.0350, agent: average = 0.167, standard deviation = 0.0353). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.50 Histogram of panamax equilibrium period contract for wheat and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 9,803, standard deviation = 2,812). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.51 Histogram of panamax period surplus fraction for wheat and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, principal: average = 0.834, standard deviation = 0.0350, agent: average = 0.166, standard deviation = 0.0353). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Appendix F: Simulated Variables 139 Fig. F.52 Histogram of panamax equilibrium period contract for wheat and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 9,826, standard deviation = 2,790). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.53 Histogram of panamax minimum RFR for period contract and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 14,803, standard deviation = 3,406). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a, b) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.54 Histogram of panamax minimum RFR for period contract and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 16,529, standard deviation = 3,821). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a, b) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) 140 Appendix F: Simulated Variables Fig. F.55 Histogram of environmental stewardship for panamax voyage contract and corn as cargo (10,000 repetitions, basic technology upgrade and low attribute: average = 0.0027, standard deviation = 0.0049, basic technology upgrade and high attribute: average = 0.0020, standard deviation = 0.0031, advanced technology upgrade and high attribute: average = 0.0021, standard deviation = 0.0053). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.56 Histogram of environmental stewardship for panamax voyage contract and wheat as cargo (10,000 repetitions, basic technology upgrade and low attribute: average = 0.0010, standard deviation = 0.0020, basic technology upgrade and high attribute: average = 0.0012, standard deviation = 0.0024, advanced technology upgrade and high attribute: average = 0.0021, standard deviation = 0.0030). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.57 Histogram of agent’s reservation price for panamax corn voyage contract and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 34.32, standard deviation = 16.44). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Appendix F: Simulated Variables 141 Fig. F.58 Histogram of agent’s reservation price for panamax corn voyage contract and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 34.33, standard deviation = 16.87). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.59 Histogram of agent’s reservation price for panamax wheat voyage contract and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 34.52, standard deviation = 16.63). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.60 Histogram of agent’s reservation price for panamax wheat voyage contract and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 34.61, standard deviation = 16.71). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) 142 Appendix F: Simulated Variables Fig. F.61 Histogram of panamax voyage surplus fraction for corn and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, principal: average = 0.832, standard deviation = 0.0352, agent: average = 0.168, standard deviation = 0.0351). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.62 Histogram of panamax equilibrium voyage contract for corn and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 34.30, standard deviation = 16.58). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.63 Histogram of panamax voyage surplus fraction for corn and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, principal: average = 0.831, standard deviation = 0.0351, agent: average = 0.169, standard deviation = 0.0353). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the Excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Appendix F: Simulated Variables 143 Fig. F.64 Histogram of panamax equilibrium voyage contract for corn and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 34.32, standard deviation = 16.85). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.65 Histogram of panamax voyage surplus fraction for wheat and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, principal: average = 0.833, standard deviation = 0.0349, agent: average = 0.167, standard deviation = 0.0351). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.66 Histogram of panamax equilibrium voyage contract for wheat and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 34.31, standard deviation = 16.58). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) 144 Appendix F: Simulated Variables Fig. F.67 Histogram of panamax voyage surplus fraction for wheat and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, principal: average = 0.833, standard deviation = 0.0352, agent: average = 0.167, standard deviation = 0.035). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.68 Histogram of panamax equilibrium voyage contract for wheat and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 34.36, standard deviation = 16.91). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.69 Histogram of panamax annual grain loadings for voyage contracts (10,000 repetitions, Min = 1, Max = 4). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Appendix F: Simulated Variables 145 Fig. F.70 Histogram of panamax spot duration (voyage and time charter trip contracts) (10,000 repetitions, average = 53, standard deviation = 14). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2015) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.71 Histogram of panamax voyage costs (10,000 repetitions, basic technology upgrade: average = 1.371, standard deviation = 0.879, advanced technology upgrade: average = 1.296, standard deviation = 0.827). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a, b) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.72 Histogram of panamax voyage RFR for basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 34.59, standard deviation = 6.55). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a, b) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) 146 Appendix F: Simulated Variables Fig. F.73 Histogram of panamax voyage RFR for advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 33.67, standard deviation = 6.08). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a, b) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.74 Histogram of panamax annual grain loadings for time charter trip contracts (10,000 repetitions, Min = 1, Max = 6). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.75 Histogram of effort level for panamax time charter trip contract (10,000 repetitions, average = 0.110, standard deviation = 0.284). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Appendix F: Simulated Variables 147 Fig. F.76 Histogram of agent’s reservation price for panamax time charter trip contract (10,000 repetitions, average = 13,390, standard deviation = 9554). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.77 Histogram of panamax equilibrium time charter trip contract for corn and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 12,300, standard deviation = 7,795). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.78 Histogram of panamax equilibrium time charter trip contract for corn and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 12,361, standard deviation = 7,865). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) 148 Appendix F: Simulated Variables Fig. F.79 Histogram of panamax equilibrium time charter trip contract for wheat and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 12,266, standard deviation = 7,822). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.80 Histogram of panamax equilibrium time charter trip contract for wheat and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 12,341, standard deviation = 7,883). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Fig. F.81 Histogram of panamax RFR for time charter trip contract and basic technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 11,489, standard deviation = 2,394). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a, b) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Appendix F: Simulated Variables 149 Fig. F.82 Histogram of panamax RFR for time charter trip contract and advanced technology upgrade (10,000 repetitions, average = 11,924, standard deviation = 2,589). Source Author’s plot using data from CRSL (2016a, b) and the excel add-in by Barreto and Howland (2006) Appendix G Milestones of the Book See Table G.1. Table G.1 Work plan Event Key date Choosing topic Literature on strategy Literature on leadership Literature on innovative technologies and marketing Literature on finance Topic refinement Qualitative part Book proposal Quantitative part Synthesis Draft manuscript available Foreword received Draft book complete Review comments Book production December 2013–January 2014 March 2014–April 2014 July 2014–August 2014 December 2014–January 2015 March 2015–April 2015 February 2015–June 2015 July 2015–October 2015 November 2015 December 2015–April 2016 May 2016–July 2016 August 2016 September 2016 September 2016 October 2016 November 2016 © Springer International Publishing Switzerland 2017 G.A. Psarros, Energy Efficiency Clauses in Charter Party Agreements, Springer Series on Naval Architecture, Marine Engineering, Shipbuilding and Shipping 3, DOI 10.1007/978-3-319-50265-6 151 Glossary Adverse selection Principal-agent problem in which the agent has private information about a parameter of his optimization problem (Laffont and Martimort 2002) Agency cost Cost of preventing agents pursuing their own interests at the expense of their principals (Arnold 2010) Agent Player who has the finer information partition (informed player) (Rasmusen 2007) Asymmetric information Information partition that is different and not worse than another player’s, hence the useful private information possessed by a player (Rasmusen 2007) Bargaining Game situation in which the participants have the possibility of concluding a mutually beneficial agreement albeit to balancing their interests. The agreement is considered binding upon each participant’s approved acceptance (Osborne and Rubinstein 1990) Bill of lading Document issued by a ship-owner to a shipper where it serves four purposes: (i) a receipt for the goods, (ii) evidence of the contract of carriage, (iii) document of title, (iv) transfer of constructive possession (Baughen 2010) Bulk cargo Homogeneous unpacked dry cargo (Brodie 2015) Bulk carrier Sea going self-propelled vessel which is constructed generally with single deck, double bottom, hopper side tanks, and top side tanks and with single or double side skin construction in cargo length area and is intended primarily to carry dry cargoes in bulk (IACS 2006) Bunker Vessel’s fuel distinguished into four general categories: (i) marine gas oil, (ii) marine diesel oil, (iii) intermediate fuel oil, (iv) heavy fuel oil (Brodie 2015) Buyer Party entering into a sales transaction in return for the contract goods or service (Baughen 2010) © Springer International Publishing Switzerland 2017 G.A. Psarros, Energy Efficiency Clauses in Charter Party Agreements, Springer Series on Naval Architecture, Marine Engineering, Shipbuilding and Shipping 3, DOI 10.1007/978-3-319-50265-6 153 154 Glossary Capital Funding for a business—can be equity only or equity plus debt (Arnold 2010) Cargo Goods carried in or on a vessel (Brodie 2015) Carrier Party who enters into a contract with a charterer or shipper, as the case may be, for the carriage of cargo (Brodie 2015) Charter in To hire a vessel from a ship-owner (Brodie 2015) Charter out To hire a vessel out to a charterer (Brodie 2015) Charter party agreement Document containing all the terms and conditions of the contract between a ship-owner and a charterer (Brodie 2015) Charterer Person or company who hires a vessel from a ship-owner for a period of time (time charterer) or who reserves the entire cargo space of a vessel for the carriage of goods from a port or ports of loading to a port or ports of discharge (voyage charterer) (Brodie 2015) Chartering negotiation Exchange of correspondence between a ship-owner and a charterer, often by means of intermediaries acting for each, respectively owner’s broker and chartering agent, leading to the chartering of a vessel (Brodie 2015) Clauses Contractual provisions contained in a charter party setting out the rights and responsibilities of both parties in relation to such matters as payment of freight or hire and contingencies for strikes, general average and war (Brodie 2015) Commodity Large quantity of a product moving between two locations on a regular basis, such as raw materials and foodstuffs, i.e. major and minor bulks (Arnold 2010; Bowersox et al. 2013) Consignee Person named in the bill of lading, or waybill, as the person to whom delivery of the goods loaded thereunder is to be made, usually the buyer (Baughen 2010; Singh 2011) Consignor Person entitled to possession of goods at the time that they are loaded onto a vessel. The bill of lading should be issued to this party even if another party has made the contract of carriage with the ship-owner, for example a free on board buyer (Baughen 2010) Content analysis Approach to the analysis of documents and texts that seeks to quantify content in terms of predetermined categories and in a systematic and replicable manner. The term is sometimes used in connection with qualitative research as well (Bryman 2012) Cost of capital The rate of return that a company has to offer finance providers to induce them to buy and hold a financial security (Arnold 2010) Counteroffer Response to an offer which in some way varies the terms or conditions of that offer (Brodie 2015) Glossary 155 Deadweight Measurement of a merchant vessel’s earning capacity and includes the weight of all cargo, oil bunkers, fresh and feed water, stores and effects (Rawson and Tupper 2001) Debt Obligation to pay (Arnold 2010) Discharge To unload a vessel (Brodie 2015) Discount rate The rate applied to cash flows used to change future values into present values (Watson and Head 2013) Energy efficiency Way of managing and restraining the growth in energy consumption. Something is more energy efficient if it delivers more services for the same energy input, or the same services for less energy input (IEA 2016) Equity Ownership interest in a firm (Ross et al. 2013) Firm offer Offer which is not conditional in any way and is binding on the party making it, provided that it is accepted in full and within any time limit specified in it (Brodie 2015) Fixture The conclusion of a contract that results to chartering the vessel (Brodie 2015) Freight Amount of money paid to a ship-owner or shipping line for the carriage of cargo (Brodie 2015) Game The totality of the absolute commands that prescribe how each participant of social or trade exchange behaves in every economic situation that may conceivably arise (Von Neumann and Morgenstern 2004) Game theory The mathematical treatment of economic activities of participants within a social or trade exchange who behave rationally (Von Neumann and Morgenstern 2004) Geared vessel Vessel which is equipped with her own crane(s) or derrick(s) (Brodie 2015) Gearless vessel Vessel which is not equipped with her own crane(s) or derrick(s) (Brodie 2015) Goods Raw materials as well as (semi)manufactured products (Singh 2011) Grains Fruits of relatively simple plants in the grass family (Tamvakis 2007) Grounded theory Iterative approach to the analysis of qualitative data that aims to generate theory out of research data by achieving a close fit between the two (Bryman 2012) Hague, Hague-Visby Rules Mandatory codes governing the contractual terms applicable to bill of lading contracts (Baughen 2010) Hamburg Rules See Hague, Hague-Visby Rules 156 Glossary Handymax vessel Bulk carrier of 35,000–50,000 tons deadweight (Brodie 2015) Hidden action Type of agent’s private information where the agent can take an action unobserved by the principal (Laffont and Martimort 2002) Hidden knowledge Type of agent’s private information where the agent’s cost or valuation is ignored by the principal (Laffont and Martimort 2002) Hire Money paid by a charterer to a ship-owner for the hire of a vessel taken on time charter (Brodie 2015) Hold Compartment of the vessel’s structure used for carrying cargo (IACS 2006) Incentive Setting attached to aligning the objectives of a firm’s various members with the firm’s ownership profit maximization (Laffont and Martimort 2002) Information partition Collection of a player’s set of different points in the game, but on different action sets, at which some player or Nature takes an action or the game ends (Rasmusen 2007) Information rent Cost attached to the principal for eliciting the agent’s private information (Laffont and Martimort 2002) Interest rate Price paid for borrowing money (Ross et al. 2013) Major bulks The five commodities such as iron ore, coal, grain, bauxite/alumina and phosphate rock (Asariotis et al. 2015) Minor bulks Commodities such as agribulks, metals and minerals and manufactures (Asariotis et al. 2015) Moral hazard Principal-agent problem where the principal may also choose actions that affect the value of trade or, more generally, the agent’s performance (Laffont and Martimort 2002) Nature Pseudo-player who takes random actions at specified points in the game with specified probabilities (Rasmusen 2007) Net present value Present value of the expected cash flows associated with a project after discounting at a rate that reflects the value of the alternative use of the funds (Arnold 2010) Ocean freight Element of the freight consisting of the ocean part of a voyage. Often used to denote the service itself (Brodie 2015) Offer Chartering proposal that starts the firm negotiations (Gorton et al. 2009) Operate a vessel To run a vessel (Brodie 2015) Panamax vessel Bulk carrier of 60,000–70,000 tons deadweight capable of transiting the Panama Canal (Brodie 2015) Payback Period of time it takes to recover the initial cash put into a project (Arnold 2010) Glossary 157 Period Freight market’s sector where seaborne transport is traded for a defined duration (Stopford 2009) Player Individual who makes decisions and participates in a game. Each player’s goal is to maximize own utility by choice of actions (Rasmusen 2007) Population True nature of the measured phenomenon is known when all possible measurements on a variable are on hand, thus the possession of complete information (Bury 1999) Present value Current worth of future cash flows when discounted (Arnold 2010) Principal Player who has the coarser information partition (uninformed player) (Rasmusen 2007) Principal-agent problem Game situation of delegating a task to an agent with private information who does not act in the best interests of the principal (Arnold 2010; Laffont and Martimort 2002) Probability Positive measurement of all possible fields of mathematical expectation of a set of precise premises which could take place upon realization of established conditions which could make it possible (Kolmogorov 1933) Probability distribution Density of probability for a random variable’s possible values over its sample space, thus the uncertainty of occurrence of a random variable’s particular value (Bury 1999) Qualitative content analysis Approach to documents that emphasizes the role of the investigator in the construction of the meaning of and in texts (Bryman 2012) Qualitative research Emphasis is given on words rather than quantification in the collection and analysis of data (Bryman 2012) Quantitative research Emphasis is given on quantification in the collection and analysis of data (Bryman 2012) Random variable Unknown values of repeated measurements on a quantity of interest (Bury 1999) Rational behavior Fact that every player is influenced by the anticipated reactions of the others to the player’s own measures and volitions and they in turn reflect the other players’ expectation of that player’s own actions (Von Neumann and Morgenstern 2004) Research design Framework for the collection and analysis of data (Bryman 2012) Research method Technique for collecting data (Bryman 2012) Research strategy General orientation to the conduct of research (Bryman 2012) Risk Potential for realization of unwanted, negative consequences of an event under conditions of uncertainty (Rowe 1988) 158 Glossary Sample Limited set of actual observations on hand, thus the representation of incomplete information on the population (Bury 1999) Screening Adverse selection situation where the uninformed party makes the contract offers and it must attempt to assess the different pieces of information the informed party has (Bolton and Dewatripont 2005) Seller Party entering into a sales transaction in return for the contract price (Baughen 2010) Ship management Technical operation aspects that include crewing and supplying the vessel, keeping her machinery and equipment in working order which, in turn, means arranging the necessary surveys, keeping her certificates up to date, and stowing cargoes safely and efficiently (Brodie 2015) Ship operation Commercial operation aspects that are concerned more with finding cargoes, negotiating freight rates and bunker prices and appointing ship’s agents at the ports of call (Brodie 2015) Ship-owner Person or company who owns vessel(s) (Brodie 2015) Shipbroker Person who negotiates the terms for the charter of a vessel on behalf of a charterer or ship-owner (Brodie 2015) Shipper Person who makes the initial contract of carriage with the carrier. However, it may also be used to refer to the consignor. This person may not always have made the initial contract of carriage, as is the case with most free on board contracts (Baughen 2010) Signaling Adverse selection situation where the informed party makes the contract offers and it may attempt to indicate to the other party what it knows through the type of contract it offers or other actions (Bolton and Dewatripont 2005) Spot Freight market’s sector where seaborne transport is traded for a single voyage or trip (Stopford 2009) Subject details Term qualifying an offer or counteroffer for the charter of a ship which denotes that only minor details remain to be agreed (Brodie 2015) Subjects Conditions attached to offers (Brodie 2015) Terms Commercially important elements when involved in a chartering negotiation (Collins 2000) Time charter The hire of a vessel for a period of time (Brodie 2015) Time charter party Document containing the terms and conditions of a contract between a charterer and a ship-owner for the hire of a vessel for a period of time (Brodie 2015) Glossary 159 Tramp shipping Maritime transport concerned with vessels which will call at any port to carry whatever cargoes, most commonly bulk cargoes, are available (Brodie 2015) Trip charter Time charter of a vessel for a specific trip, rather for a period of time (Brodie 2015) Uncertainty The absence of information, that which is unknown (Rowe 1988) Utility Quantity attached to certain aspects of the physical world, thus the satisfaction of a rational economic human’s wants and desires, as expressed on a scale (Von Neumann and Morgenstern 2004; Rowe 1988) Vessel Ship or boat (Brodie 2015) Voyage Journey by sea specified via loading and discharging ports and up to the position where the ship is expected to start her next employment, that is, so that a possible passage in ballast should also be included (Gorton et al. 2009) Voyage charter The use of a vessel’s cargo space for one, or sometimes more than one, voyage (Brodie 2015) Voyage charter party Document containing the terms and conditions of a contract between a charterer and a ship-owner for the use of a vessel’s cargo space for one, or more than one, voyage (Brodie 2015) Weighted average cost of capital Discount rate calculated by weighting the cost of debt and equity in proportion to their contributions to the total capital of the firm (Arnold 2010) References Abis S, Luguenot F, Rayé P (2014) Trade and logistics: the case of the grains sector. In: Lacirignola C (ed) Mediterra: logistics and agro-food trade—a challenge for the Mediterranean. CIHEAM, Paris, pp 133–148 Ådland R, Cariou P, Wolff F-C (2016) The influence of charterers and owners on bulk shipping freight rates. Transp Res Part E 86:69–82 Agnolucci P, Smith T, Rehmatulla N (2014) Energy efficiency and time charter rates: energy efficiency savings recovered by ship owners in the Panamax market. Transp Res Part A 66:173–184 Akerlof GA (1982) Labor contracts as partial gift exchange. Q J Econ 97:543–569 Albertijn S, Bessler W, Drobetz W (2011) Financing shipping companies and shipping operations: a risk-management perspective. J Appl Corp Finan 23:70–82 Alderton PM (1981) The optimum speed of ships. J Navig 34:341–355 Aldous L, Smith T, Bucknall R, Thompson P (2015) Uncertainty analysis in ship performance monitoring. Ocean Eng 110:29–38 Alizadeh AH, Nomikos NK (2011) Dynamics of the term structure and volatility of shipping freight rates. J Transp Econ Policy 45:105–128 Alvarez JF, Longva T, Engebrethsen ES (2010) A methodology to assess vessel berthing and speed optimization policies. Marit Econ Logistics 12:327–346 Ančić I, Šestan A (2015) Influence of the required EEDI reduction factor on the CO2 emission from bulk carriers. Energy Policy 84:107–116 Anderlini L, Felli L, Postlewaite A (2007) Courts of law and unforeseen contingencies. J Law Econ Organ 23:662–684 Anderson CB, Cdl Rue (2001) Liability of charterers and cargo owners for pollution from ships. Tulane Marit Law J 26:1–60 Anderson HE III (2001) “Subject to details” and charter party negotiations. Tulane Marit Law J 26:61–69 Andreu LM (2001) Comments: a comparative analysis of charter party agreements “subject to” respective American and British laws and decisions … it’s all in the details. Tulane Marit Law J 26:291–319 Armstrong VN (2013) Vessel optimisation for low carbon shipping. Ocean Eng 73:195–207 Armstrong VN, Banks C (2015) Integrated approach to vessel energy efficiency. Ocean Eng 110:39–48 Arnold G (2010) Financial times handbook of corporate finance, 2nd edn. Pearson Education Limited, Harlow Asariotis R, Benamara H, Hoffmann J, Premti A, Sanchez R, Valentine V, Wilmsmeier G, Youssef F (2015) Review of maritime transport 2015. UNCTAD, Geneva Axarloglou K, Visvikis I, Zarkos S (2013) The time dimension and value of flexibility in resource allocation: the case of the maritime industry. Transp Res Part E 52:35–48 © Springer International Publishing Switzerland 2017 G.A. Psarros, Energy Efficiency Clauses in Charter Party Agreements, Springer Series on Naval Architecture, Marine Engineering, Shipbuilding and Shipping 3, DOI 10.1007/978-3-319-50265-6 161 162 References Ayres I, Gertner R (1992) Strategic contractual inefficiency and the optimal choice of legal rules. Yale Law J 101:729–773 Azevedo SG, Carvalho H, Cruz Machado V (2011) The influence of green practices on supply chain performance: a case study approach. Transp Res Part E 47:850–871 Baatz Y (2014) Chapter 4: charter parties. In: Baatz Y (ed) Maritime law, 3rd edn. Informa Law from Routledge, Oxon, pp 117–177 Baldi F, Johnson H, Gabrieli C, Andersson K (2014) Energy analysis of ship energy systems—the case of a chemical tanker. Energy Procedia 61:1732–1735 Ballou PJ (2015) An examination of social factors that impact vessel efficiency. Paper presented at the SNAME world maritime technology conference (WMTC2015), Paper ID: WMTC-013-2015, Providence RI, 3–7 Nov 2015 Baker GP (1992) Incentive contracts and performance measurement. J Polit Econ 100:598–614 Balland O, Girard C, Erikstad SO, Fagerholt K (2015) Optimized selection of vessel air emission controls—moving beyond cost-efficiency. Marit Policy Manage 42:362–376 Barreto H, Howland FM (2006) Introductory econometrics—using Monte Carlo simulation with microsoft excel. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge Baughen S (2010) Shipping law, reprinted 4th edn. Routledge-Cavendish, Oxon Bendassolli PF (2013) Theory building in qualitative research: reconsidering the problem of induction. Forum Qualitative Sozialforschung/Forum: Qualitative Social Research 14, Art. 25. Available via: http://nbn-resolving.de/urn:nbn:de:0114-fqs1301258. Accessed 10 Aug 2015 Bergantino AS, Veenstra AW (2002) Principal agent problems in shipping—an investigation into the formation of charter contracts. Paper presented at the international association of maritime economists conference (IAME2002), Panama City, 13–15 Nov Bialystocki N, Konovessis D (2016) On the estimation of ship’s fuel consumption and speed curve: a statistical approach. J Ocean Eng Sci 1:157–166 Bierman HS, Fernandez L (1998) Game Theory with economic applications, 2nd edn. Addison-Wesley Publishing Company Inc., Reading Biglaiser G (1993) Middlemen as experts. Rand J Econ 24:212–223 BIMCO (2015) Time and voyage charter parties documents. Available via: https://www.Bimco. org/Chartering/Clauses_and_Documents/Documents.aspx. Accessed 20 July 2015 BIMCO (2016) BIMCO clauses. Available via: https://www.bimco.org/Chartering/Clauses_and_ Documents/Clauses.aspx. Accessed 1 Feb 2016 Bishop FL (2015) Using mixed methods research designs in health psychology: an illustrated discussion from a pragmatist perspective. Br J Health Psychol 20:5–20 Blume LE, Easley D, Kleinberg J, Tardos É (2009) Trading networks with price-setting agents. Games Econ Behav 67:36–50 Bocchetti D, Lepore A, Palumbo B, Vitiello L (2015) A statistical approach to ship fuel consumption monitoring. J Ship Res 59:162–171 Bolton P, Dewatripont M (2005) Contract theory. The MIT Press, Cambridge Bower JL, Christensen CM (1995) Disruptive technologies: catching the wave. Harvard Bus Rev 73:43–53 Bowersox DJ, Closs DJ, Cooper MB, Bowersox JC (2013) Supply chain logistics management, 4th edn. McGraw-Hill Education Asia, Singapore Box GEP (1976) Science and statistics. J Am Stat Assoc 71:791–799 Box GEP (1980) Sampling and Bayes’ inference in scientific modelling and robustness. J Roy Stat Soc Ser A 143:383–430 Box GEP, Tiao GC (1962) A further look at robustness Via Bayes’ theorem. Biometrika 49:419–432 Box GEP, Tiao GC (1965) Multiparameter problems from a Bayesian point of view. Ann Math Stat 36:1468–1482 Box GEP, Tiao GC (1968) A Bayesian approach to some outlier problems. Biometrika 55:119–129 Box GEP, Tiao GC (1992) Bayesian inference in statistical analysis, 2nd edn. Wiley, Toronto References 163 Brauner A, Illingworth P (2009) The banker’s perspective. In: French L, Ward J (eds) Shipping finance. Euromoney Institutional Investor Plc, London, pp 67–92 Brigham EF, Houston JF (2013) Fundamentals of financial management, 13th edn. South-Western Cengage Learning, Mason Brodie P (2015) Commercial shipping handbook, 3rd edn. Informa Law from Routledge, Oxon Bryman A (2012) Social research methods, 4th edn. Oxford University Press Inc., New York Bury K (1999) Statistical distributions in engineering. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge Calleya J, Pawling R, Greig A (2015) Ship impact model for technical assessment and selection of carbon dioxide reducing technologies (CRTs). Ocean Engineering 97:82–89 Cargill (2016) Ocean transportation: our fleet—dry bulk carriers. Available via: http://www.cargill. com/products/ocean-transportation/fleet/index.jsp. Accessed 28 Feb 2016 Castellani B, Castellani J, Spray SL (2003) Grounded neural networking: modeling complex quantitative data. Symbolic Interact 26:577–589 Chang C-C (2012) Marine energy consumption, national economic activity, and greenhouse gas emissions from international shipping. Energy Policy 41:843–848 Chen S, Frouws K, Van de Voorde E (2010) Technical changes and impacts on economic performance of dry bulk vessels. Marit Policy Manage 37:305–327 Chen S, Frouws K, Van de Voorde E (2011) Simulation-based optimization of ship design for dry bulk vessels. Marit Econ Logistics 13:190–212 Clarkson PM, Fang X, Li Y, Richardson G (2013) The relevance of environmental disclosures: Are such disclosures incrementally informative? J Account Public Policy 32:410–431 CRSL (2015) Sources and methods for the shipping intelligence weekly. CRSL, London CRSL (2016a) Shipping intelligence network 2015. Available via: https://sin.clarksons.net/. Accessed 8 Jan 2016 CRSL (2016b) World fleet register. Available via: https://www.clarksons.net/wfr/. Accessed 8 Jan 2016 Collins N (2000) The essential guide to chartering and the dry freight market. Clarkson Research Studies, London Creswell JW (2009) Research design—qualitative, quantitative, and mixed methods approaches, 3rd edn. SAGE Publications Inc., Thousand Oaks Dacin MT, Goodstein J, Scott WR (2002) Institutional theory and institutional change: introduction to the special research forum. Acad Manage J 45:45–57 Deligiannis P (2016) Ship performance indicator. Marine Policy. doi:10.1016/j.marpol.2016. 02.027 Devanney J (2011) The impact of the energy efficiency design index on very large crude carrier design and CO2 emissions. Ships Offshore Struct 6:355–368 Diez M, Peri D (2010) Robust optimization for ship conceptual design. Ocean Eng 37:966–977 Dimson E, Marsh P, Staunton M (2015) Credit Suisse global investment returns yearbook 2015. Credit Suisse AG, Zurich Dinwoodie J, Landamore M, Rigot-Muller P (2014) Dry bulk shipping flows to 2050: delphi perceptions of early career specialists. Technol Forecast Soc Change 88:64–75 Dockray M, Thomas KR (2007) Cases and materials on the carriage of goods by sea, 3rd edn. Digital printing. Routledge-Cavendish, Oxon Drobetz W, Merikas A, Merika A, Tsionas MG (2014) Corporate social responsibility disclosure: the case of international shipping. Transp Res Part E 71:18–44 Drobetz W, Menzel C, Schröder H (2014b). Beta estimation and the cost of equity for listed shipping companies. Paper presented at the Baltic exchange’s shipping risk management symposium, University of Hamburg, Hamburg, 9 Oct 2014 Dunsby A, Eckstein J, Gaspar J, Mulholland S (2008) Commodity investing—maximizing returns through fundamentals analysis. Wiley, Hoboken Eason C (2015) Special report—maximising ship efficiency: ending the debate. Lloyd’s List, London Eisenhardt KM (1989) Agency theory: an assessment and review. Acad Manage Rev 14:57–74 164 References Ellingsen T, Miettinen T (2014) Tough negotiations: bilateral bargaining with durable commitments. Games Econ Behav 87:353–366 Elo S, Kyngäs H (2007) The qualitative content analysis process. J Adv Nurs 62:107–115 Engward H, Davis G (2015) Being reflexive in qualitative grounded theory: discussion and application of a model of reflexivity. J Adv Nurs 71:1530–1538 Fagerholt K, Christiansen M, Hvattum LM, Johnsen TAV, Vabø TJ (2010) A decision support methodology for strategic planning in maritime transportation. Omega 38:465–474 Fagerholt K, Gausel NT, Rakke JG, Psaraftis HN (2015) Maritime routing and speed optimization with emission control areas. Transp Res Part C 52:57–73 Fisher TCG, Prentice D, Waschik R (2010) Managerial economics: a strategic approach, 2nd edn. Routledge, Oxon Fleiter T, Plötz P (2013) Diffusion of energy-efficient technologies. In: Shogren JF (ed) Encyclopedia of energy, natural resource, and environmental economics—volume 1: energy. Elsevier Inc., Waltham, pp 63–73 Forbes C, Evans M, Hastings N, Peacock B (2011) Statistical distributions, 4th edn. Wiley, Hoboken Frankel JA (2014) Effects of speculation and interest rates in a “carry trade” model of commodity prices. J Int Money Finance 42:88–112 Fried C (1981) Contract as promise: a theory of contractual obligation. Harvard University Press, Cambridge Fujiwara T, Hearn GE, Kitamura F, Ueno M, Minami Y (2005) Steady sailing performance of a hybrid-sail assisted bulk carrier. J Mar Sci Technol 10:131–146 Fukuda K, Tokunaga J, Nobunaga T, Nakatani T, Iwasaki T, Kunitake Y (2000) Frictional drag reduction with air lubricant over a super-water-repellent surface. J Mar Sci Technol 5:123–130 Fulton L, Cazzola P, Cuenot F, Kojima K, Onoda T, Staub J, Taylor M, Crist P, McKinnon A, Piecyk M, Tam C, Gül T, Dowling P, Eisentraut A, Taamallah S (2009) Transport energy and CO2—moving toward sustainability. IEA /OECD, Paris Fun-sang MA, Caprace JD (2015) Improving ship fleet performance using a non-parametric model. Paper presented at the SNAME world maritime technology conference (WMTC2015), Paper ID: WMTC-182-2015, Providence RI, 3–7 Nov 2015 Gardiner N, Neylan P, Jupe M (2009) Ship operating costs | 2009–2010: annual review and forecast. Drewry Shipping Consultants Ltd., London Gardiner N (2014). Ship operating costs under sustained pressure. Available via: http://www. drewry.co.uk/news.php?id=260. Accessed 28 Feb 2016 Gardiner N (2015) Ship operating costs to rise over next two years. Available via: http://www. drewry.co.uk/news.php?id=420. Accessed 28 Feb 2016 Geman H, Smith WO (2012) Shipping markets and freight rates: an analysis of the Baltic Dry Index. J Altern Investments 15:98–109 Germany D, Prucyk BR, Price TM, Nordenfelt N, Susser P (2014) Bank loans: time to focus on quality. Wells Capital Management, San Francisco Gilbert P (2014) From reductionism to systems thinking: how the shipping sector can address sulphur regulation and tackle climate change. Mar Policy 43:376–378 Gilbert P, Bows A (2012) Exploring the scope for complementary sub-global policy to mitigate CO2 from shipping. Energy Policy 50:613–622 Glykas A, Papaioannou G, Perissakis S (2010) Application and cost-benefit analysis of solar hybrid power installation on merchant marine vessels. Ocean Eng 37:592–602 Goldberg AE, Allen KR (2015) Communicating qualitative research: some practical guideposts for scholars. J Marriage and Fam 77:3–22 Gorton L, Hillenius P, Ihre R, Sandevärn A (2009) Shipbroking and chartering practice, 7th edn. Informa, London Hai-long S, Obwogi EO, Yu-min S (2016) Scale effects for rudder bulb thrust fin on propulsive efficiency based on computational fluid dynamics. Ocean Eng 117:199–209 References 165 Herzenstein M, Posavac SS, Brakus JJ (2007) Adoption of new and really new products: the effects of self-regulation systems and risk salience. J Mark Res 44:251–260 Hill C (2003) Maritime law, 6th edn. Informa, London Hirshleifer J (1958) On the theory of optimal investment decision. J Polit Econ 66:329–352 Holmström B (1979) Moral hazard and observability. Bell J Econ 10:74–91 Hoskins H (2014) Contractual obligations to negotiate in good faith: faithfulness to the agreed common purpose. Law Q Rev 130:131–159 House DJ (2005) Cargo work: for maritime operations, 7th edn. Elsevier Butterworth-Heinemann, Oxford Humphries ADW (2014) Dry cargo chartering. Institute of Chartered Shipbrokers, London Hunter G (2012) BIMCO slow steaming clause for time charter parties. Paper presented at the London Shipping Law Centre Maritime Business Forum, Ince & Co., London, 10 May 2012 IACS (2006) Common structural rules for bulk carriers. IACS. Available via http://www.iacs.org. uk/document/public/Publications/Common_rules/PDF/CSR_Bulk_Carrier_Consolidated_PDF_ File_pdf774.pdf. Accessed 11 June 2016 IACS (2007) IACS guidelines for surveys, assessment and repair of hull structure—bulk carriers. Available via: http://www.iacs.org.uk/document/public/Publications/Guidelines_and_ recommendations/PDF/REC_76_pdf216.pdf. Accessed 7 Feb 2016 IEA (2016) Topics–energy efficiency. Available via: http://www.iea.org/topics/energyefficiency/. Accessed 12 June 2016 IMO (2012a) International convention for the prevention of pollution from ships, 1973, as modified by the protocol of 1978—MARPOL consolidated edition 2011. Sales No: ID520E. IMO, London IMO (2012b) 2012 Guidelines on survey and certification of the energy efficiency design index (EEDI). IMO Resolution MEPC. 214(63), London IMO (2012c) International shipping facts and figures—information resources on trade, safety, security, environment. Maritime Knowledge Centre, London IMO (2013) 2013 guidance on treatment of innovative energy efficiency technologies for calculation and verification of the attained EEDI. IMO MEPC.1/Circ.815, London Ishizaka M, Ishii M, Tezuka K (2012) Assessing the risk attitudes in shipping freight markets. Paper presented at the international association of maritime economists conference (IAME2012), Paper ID: SMK-303, Taipei, 6–8 Sept 2012 Jafarzadeh S, Utne IB (2014) A framework to bridge the energy efficiency gap in shipping. Energy 69:603–612 Jensen MC, Meckling WH (1976) Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure. J Financ Econ 3:305–360 Johnson G, Whitthington R, Scholes K (2011) Exploring strategy—text & cases, 9th edn. Pearson Education Limited, Harlow Johnson H, Andersson K (2016) Barriers to energy efficiency in shipping. WMU J Marit Affairs 15:79–96 Jonnala S, Fuller S, Bessler D (2002) A GARCH approach to modelling ocean grain freight rates. Marit Econ Logistics 4:103–125 JSEA (2016) Shipbuilding and Marine Engineering in Japan. Japan Ship Exporters’ Association, Tokyo Kakuta R, Ando H, Yonezawa T (2016) Utilization of vessel performance management system in a shipping company. In: Bertram V (ed) Proceedings of the 1st hull performance and insight conference, Castello di Pavone, Torino, 13–15 Apr 2016, pp 96–105. Karakitsos E, Varnavides L (2014) Maritime economics—a macroeconomic approach. Palgrave Macmillan, Basingstoke Katz A (1990) The strategic structure of offer and acceptance: game theory and the law of contract formation. Mich Law Rev 89:215–295 Kavussanos M, Visvikis I, Dimitrakopoulos D (2010) Information linkages between Panamax freight derivatives and commodity derivatives markets. Marit Econ Logistics 12:91–110 166 References Kawakita C, Sato S, Okimoto T (2015) Application of simulation technology to mitsubishi air lubrication system. Mitsubishi Heavy Ind Tech Rev 52:50–56 Kim B-C, Shim E, Reinschmidt KF (2013) Probability distribution of the project payback period using the equivalent cash flow decomposition. Eng Econ 58:112–136 Kim J-H, Choi J-E, Choi B-J, Chung S-H, Seo H-W (2015) Development of energy-saving devices for a full slow-speed ship through improving propulsion performance. Int J Naval Archit Ocean Eng 7:390–398 Kitada M, Ölҫer A (2015) Managing people and technology: the challenges in CSR and energy efficient shipping. Res Transp Bus Manage 17:36–40 Klag M, Langley A (2013) Approaching the conceptual leap in qualitative research. Int J Manage Rev 15:149–166 Kolmogorov AN (1933) Foundations of the theory of probability. 2nd English edition (trans: Morrison N (1956)). Chelsea Publishing Company, New York Kou Y, Luo M (2016) Strategic capacity competition and overcapacity in shipping. Marit Policy Manage 43:389–406 Köhn S, Thanopoulou H (2011) A gam assessment of quality premia in the dry bulk time—charter market. Transp Res Part E 47:709–721 Krähmer D, Strausz R (2015) Ex post information rents in sequential screening. Games Econ Behav 90:257–273 Kristensen HOH, Lützen M (2012) Existing design trends for tankers and bulk carriers—design changes for improvement of the EEDI in the future. In: Proceedings volume 2 of the 11th international marine design conference (IMDC2012), University of Strathclyde, Glasgow, 11– 14 June 2012, pp 379–393 Kumagai I, Takahashi Y, Murai Y (2015) Power-saving device for air bubble generation using a hydrofoil to reduce ship drag: theory, experiments, and application to ships. Ocean Eng 95:183–194 Laake J, Zhang A (2016) Joint optimization of strategic fleet planning and contract analysis in tramp shipping. Appl Econ 48:203–211 Laffont J-J, Martimort D (2002) The theory of incentives: the principal-agent model. Princeton University Press, Princeton Lai K-H, Lun VYH, Wong CWY, Cheng TCE (2011) Green shipping practices in the shipping industry: conceptualization, adoption, and implications. Resour Conserv Recycl 55:631–638 Lai K-H, Wong CWY, Lun YHV, Cheng TCE (2013) Shipping design for compliance and the performance contingencies for shipping firms. Transp Res Part E 55:74–83 Lamond G (2014) Analogical reasoning in the common law. Oxford J Legal Stud 34:567–588 LaRossa R (2005) Grounded theory methods and qualitative family research. J Marriage Fam 67:837–857 Leggatt G (2015) Making sense of contracts: the rational choice theory. Law Q Rev 131:454–475 Levin J (2003) Relational incentive contracts. Am Econ Rev 93:835–857 Liapis KJ, Kantianis DD (2015) Depreciation methods and life-cycle costing (LCC) methodology. Procedia Econ Finan 19:314–324 Lindholm EMS (2014) Efficient charter parties—notice of readiness, slow steaming and virtual arrival agreements, MSc thesis. University of Oslo, Faculty of Law, Oslo Lindstad H, Jullumstrø E, Sandaas I (2013) Reductions in cost and greenhouse gas emissions with new bulk ship designs enabled by the Panama Canal expansion. Energy Policy 59:341–349 Lister J, Poulsen RT, Ponte S (2015) Orchestrating transnational environmental governance in maritime shipping. Global Environ Change 34:185–195 Livanos GA, Theotokatos G, Pagonis D-N (2014) Techno-economic investigation of alternative propulsion plants for Ferries and RoRo ships. Energy Convers Manage 79:640–651 Locke EA (1968) Toward a theory of task motivation and incentives. Organ Behav Hum Perform 3:157–189 Lun YHV, Lai K-H, Wong CWY, Cheng TCE (2014) Green shipping practices and firm performance. Marit Policy Manage 41:134–148 References 167 Lun YHV, Lai K-H, Wong CWY, Cheng TCE (2015) Environmental governance mechanisms in shipping firms and their environmental performance. Transp Res Part E 78:82–92 Luyu C, Shunhuai C, Yigong W (2010) Analysis on sail selection and energy conservation of a panamax bulk carrier. In: Proceedings of the 2010 international conference on advances in energy engineering (ICAEE), IEEE, New York, NY, 19–20 June 2010, Beijing, pp 182–185 Lys T, Naughton JP, Wang C (2015) Signaling through corporate accountability reporting. J Acc Econ 60:56–72 Macho-Stadler I, Pérez-Castrillo D, Porteiro N (2014) Coexistence of long-term and short-term contracts. Games Econ Behav 86:145–164 Marty P, Corrignan P, Gondet A, Chenouard R, Hétet J-F (2012) Modelling of energy flows and fuel consumption on board ships: application to a large modern cruise vessel and comparison with sea monitoring data. In: Proceedings volume 2 of the 11th international marine design conference (IMDC2012), University of Strathclyde, Glasgow, 11–14 June 2012, pp 545–563 Marzi J, Gatchell S (2012) Towards the ship of least energy consumption. In: Proceedings volume 2 of the 11th international marine design conference (IMDC2012), University of Strathclyde, Glasgow, 11–14 June 2012, pp 365–378 Mason A, Agyei-Ampomah S, Skinner F (2016) Realism, skill, and incentives: current and future trends in investment management and investment performance. Int Rev Financ Anal 43:31–40 McConville J (1999) Economics of maritime transport—theory and practice. Witherby & Co., Ltd., London McNulty T, Zattoni A, Douglas T (2013) Developing corporate governance research through qualitative methods: a review of previous studies. Corp Gov Int Rev 21:183–198 Mello J, Flint DJ (2009) A refined view of grounded theory and its application to logistics research. J Bus Logistics 30:107–125 Meng Q, Du Y, Wang Y (2016) Shipping log data based container ship fuel efficiency modeling. Transp Res Part B 83:207–229 Messenger G (2016) The development of international law and the role of causal language. Oxford J Legal Stud 36:110–134 Miller GJ, Whitford AB (2007) The principal’s moral hazard: constraints on the use of incentives in hierarchy. J Public Adm Res Theory 17:213–233 Mirrlees JA (1971) An exploration in the theory of optimum income taxation. Rev Econ Stud 38:175–208 Mizokami S, Kawakado M, Kawano M, Hasegawa T, Hirakawa I (2013) Implementation of ship energy-saving operations with Mitsubishi air lubrication system. Mitsubishi Heavy Ind Tech Rev 50:44–49 Modarres M (2006) Risk analysis in engineering—techniques, tools, and trends. Taylor & Francis Group, Boca Raton Modigliani F, Miller MH (1958) The cost of capital, corporation finance and the theory of investment. Am Econ Rev 48:261–297 Mulder P (2005) The economics of technology diffusion and energy efficiency. Edward Elgar Publishing Limited, Cheltenham Glos Mullins LJ, Christy G, Scott P (2013) Management and organisational behaviour, 10th edn. Pearson Education Limited, Harlow Nomikos NK, Kyriakou I, Papapostolou NC, Pouliasis PK (2013) Freight options: price modelling and empirical analysis. Transp Res Part E 51:82–94 Nomikos N, Giamouzi M (2013) Investigating the profitability of ship chartering strategies in the dry-bulk shipping market using market timing rules. Paper presented at the international association of maritime economists conference (IAME2013), Paper ID: 303, 3–5 July 2013, Marseille Ochs J, Roth AE (1989) An experimental study of sequential bargaining. Am Econ Rev 79:355–384 168 References O’Donnell B, Goodchild A, Cooper J, Ozawa T (2009) The relative contribution of transportation to supply chain greenhouse gas emissions: a case study of American wheat. Transp Res Part D 14:487–492 OECD (2016) Query database—public sector, taxation and market regulation: table II.1. Corporate income tax rate. Available via: https://stats.oecd.org/Index.aspx?DataSetCode=TABLE_II1. Accessed 24 Jan 2016 Orihara H, Yoshida H, Amaya I (2016) Evaluation of full-scale performance of large merchant ships by means of onboard performance monitoring. In: Chung JS, Young Hong S, Schreier S, Yan S, Wan D (eds) Proceedings of the 26th international ocean and polar engineering conference, Rhodes Hellas, 26 June–1 July. International Society of Offshore and Polar Engineers (ISOPE), vol 3, Cupertino CA, pp 553–560 Osborne MJ, Rubinstein A (1990) Bargaining and markets. Emerald Group Publishing Limited, Bingley Bradford Otsubo S (2015) EEDI, other regulations to come, and their implications for ship design. In: Proceedings volume 1 of the 12th international marine design conference (IMDC2015), JASNAOE, Tokyo, 11–14 May 2015, pp 1–23 Outhwaite O, Black R, Laycock A (2007) The pursuit of grounded theory in agricultural and environmental regulation: a suggested approach to empirical legal study in biosecurity. Law Policy 29:493–528 Ozaki Y, Larkin J, Tikka K, Michel K (2010) An evaluation of the energy efficiency design index (EEDI) baseline for tankers, containerships, and LNG carriers. Paper presented at the SNAME & marine board symposium climate change and ships: increasing energy efficiency, 16–17 Feb 2010, Linthicum MD Pachauri RK, Allen MR, Barros VR, Broome J, Cramer W, Christ R, Church JA, Clarke L, Dahe Q, Dasgupta P, Dubash N, Edenhofer O, Elgizouli I, Field CB, Forster P, Friedlingstein P, Fuglestvedt J, Gomez-Echeverri L, Hallegatte S, Hegerl G, Howden M, Jiang K, Cisneros BJ, Kattsov V, Lee H, Mach KJ, Marotzke J, Mastrandrea MD, Meyer L, Minx J, Mulugetta Y, O’Brien K, Oppenheimer M, Pereira JJ, Pichs-Madruga R, Plattner GK, Pörtner HO, Power SB, Preston B, Ravindranath NH, Reisinger A, Riahi K, Rusticucci M, Scholes R, Seyboth K, Sokona Y, Stavins R, Stocker TF, Tschakert P, Vuuren Dv, Ypersele JPv (2014) Climate change 2014 synthesis report—contribution of working groups I, II and III to the fifth assessment report of the intergovernmental panel on climate change. IPCC, Geneva Page FH Jr (1991) Optimal contract mechanisms for principal-agent problems with moral hazard and adverse selection. Econ Theory 1:323–338 Panayides PM (2014) Principles of chartering. Create Space Publications, New York Pannebakker E (2013) Offer and acceptance and the dynamics of negotiations: arguments for contract theory from negotiation studies. Erasmus Law Rev 6:131–141 Pantuso G, Fagerholt K, Hvattum LM (2014) A survey on maritime fleet size and mix problems. Eur J Oper Res 235:341–349 Park JJ, Koo WW (2004) An econometric analysis of ocean freight rates for grain shipments from the United States to major importing countries. J Transp Res Forum 43:85–100 Partington D (2000) Building grounded theories of management action. Br J Manage 11:91–102 Peczenik A (1988) Legal reasoning as a special case of moral reasoning. Ratio Juris 1:123–136 Peng Z, Shan W, Guan F, Yu B (2016) Stable vessel-cargo matching in dry bulk shipping market with price game mechanism. Transp Res Part E 95:76–94 Perera LP, Mo B, Kristjánsson LA, Jønvik PC, Svardal JØ (2015) Evaluations on ship performance under varying operational conditions. Paper presented at the ASME 2015 34th international conference on ocean, offshore and arctic engineering (OMAE2015), Paper ID: OMAE2015-41793, 31 May–5 June, St. John’s NL Petersen JP, Jacobsen DJ, Winther O (2012) Statistical modelling for ship propulsion efficiency. J Marine Sci Technol 17:30–39 Pindyck RS (2001) The dynamics of commodity spot and futures markets: a primer. Energy J 22:1–29 References 169 Pirrong SC (1993) Contracting practices in bulk shipping markets: a transactions cost explanation. J Law Econ 36:937–976 Pirrong C (2015) Risk management by commodity trading firms: the case of trafigura. J Appl Corp Finan 27:19–26 Plomaritou E (2014) A review of shipowner’s & charterer’s obligations in various types of charter. J Shipping Ocean Eng 4:307–321 Plumlee M, Brown D, Hayes RM, Marshall RS (2015) Voluntary environmental disclosure quality and firm value: further evidence. J Account Public Policy 34:336–361 Porter ME, Reinhardt FL (2007) A strategic approach to climate. Harvard Bus Rev 85:22–26 Poulsen RT, Sornn-Friese H (2015) Achieving energy efficient ship operations under third party management: how do ship management models influence energy efficiency? Res Transp Bus Manage 17:41–52 Poulsen RT, Johnson H (2016) The logic of business vs. the logic of energy management practice: understanding the choices and effects of energy consumption monitoring systems in shipping companies. J Cleaner Prod 112:3785–3797 Poulsen RT, Ponte S, Lister J (2016) Buyer-driven greening? Cargo-owners and environmental upgrading in maritime shipping. Geoforum 68:57–68 Psaraftis HN, Kontovas CA (2014) Ship speed optimization: concepts, models and combined speed-routing scenarios. Transp Res Part C 44:52–69 Psarros GA, Vassalos D (2009) Effectiveness of corrosion measures to bulk carriers with life cycle cost analysis. Int Shipbuilding Prog 56:95–118 Psarros GA (2009) Operational risk management in maritime transport: tools, trends, methodology and application to dry bulk shipping. Lambert Academic Publishing AG & Co. KG., Saarbrücken Psarros GA, Mestl T (2015) Towards understanding the stepwise dissemination of shipping technologies. WMU J Marit Affairs 15:7–24 PTC Inc. (2014) Parametric technology corporation mathcad prime 3.0. Needham, MA Rai A, Keil M, Hornyak R, Wüllenweber K (2012) Hybrid relational-contractual governance for business process outsourcing. J Manage Inf Syst 29:213–256 Rawson KJ, Tupper EC (2001) Basic ship theory—volume 2, 5th edn. Butterworth-Heinemann, Oxford Rasmusen EB (2001) Explaining incomplete contracts as the result of contract–reading costs. B.E. J Econ Anal Policy. doi:10.2202/1538-0637.1000 Rasmusen E (2007) Games and information: an introduction to game theory, 4th edn. Blackwell Publishing Ltd., Oxford Rauch A, Rv Doorn, Hulsink W (2014) A qualitative approach to evidence-based entrepreneurship: theoretical considerations and an example involving business clusters. Entrepreneurship Theory Pract 38:333–368 Rehmatulla N, Smith T (2015) Barriers to energy efficiency in shipping: a triangulated approach to investigate the principal agent problem. Energy Policy 84:44–57 Rehmatulla N, Smith T (2015b) Barriers to energy efficient and low carbon shipping. Ocean Eng 110:102–112 Rehmatulla N, Parker S, Smith T, Stulgis V (2015) Wind technologies: opportunities and barriers to a low carbon shipping industry. Mar Policy. doi:10.1016/j.marpol.2015.12.021 RightShip (2016) Ship vetting information system (SVIS™). Available via: http://site.rightship. com/products/svis™/. Accessed 23 Jan 2016 Ritz A (2011) Attraction to public policy-making: a qualitative inquiry into improvements in PSM measurement. Public Adm 89:1128–1147 Roger G (2016) Participation in moral hazard problems. Games Econ Behav 95:10–24 Rojon I, Dieperink C (2014) Blowin’ in the wind? Drivers and barriers for the uptake of wind propulsion in international shipping. Energy Policy 67:394–402 Ronen D (1982) The effect of oil price on the optimal speed of ships. J Oper Res Soc 33:1035–1040 170 References Ross SA, Westerfield RW, Jaffe J (2013) Corporate finance, 10th edn. McGraw-Hill/Irwin, New York Rowe WD (1988) An anatomy of risk. In: Robert E (ed) Krieger Publishing Company, Malabar Rubinstein A (1982) Perfect equilibrium in a bargaining model. Econometrica 50:97–109 Rubinstein A, Wolinsky A (1987) Middlemen. Q J Econ 102:581–594 Rust B (2015) Standard charter-party forms should be binned. TradeWinds, Friday 23 Oct 2015, p 18 Salant Y (2011) Procedural analysis of choice rules with applications to bounded rationality. Am Econ Rev 101:724–748 Saltelli A, Ratto M, Tarantola S, Campolongo F (2006) Sensitivity analysis practices: strategies for model-based inference. Reliab Eng Syst Saf 91:1109–1125 Sasa K, Terada D, Shiotani S, Wakabayashi N, Ikebuchi T, Chen C, Takayama A, Uchida M (2015) Evaluation of ship performance in international maritime transportation using onboard measurement system—in case of a bulk carrier in international voyages. Ocean Eng 104:294–309 Saunders M, Lewis P, Thornhill A (2012) Research methods for business students, 6th edn. Pearson Education Limited, Harlow Schinas O, Kewitsch S (2015) Loans and risk management considerations. In: Schinas O, Grau C, Johns M (eds) HSBA handbook on ship finance. Springer, Heidelberg, pp 33–54 Sewell T (1999) Grain: carriage by sea. LLP Reference Publishing, London Sharpe WF (1964) Capital asset prices: A theory of market equilibrium under conditions of risk. J Finan 19:425–442 Shi X, Voß S (2011) Game theoretical aspects in modelling and analyzing the shipping industry. In: Böse JW, Hu H, Jahn C, Shi X, Stahlbock R, Voß S (eds) Computational logistics—second international conference, ICCL 2011 proceedings, Hamburg, 19–22 Sept 2011. Lecture notes in computer science, vol 6971. Springer, Heidelberg, pp 302–320 Siegel L (2008) Against the machine: being human in the age of the electronic mob. Serpent’s Tail, London Singh L (2011) The law of carriage of goods by sea. Bloomsbury Professional Ltd., Haywards Heath Smith TWP (2012) Technical energy efficiency, its interaction with optimal operating speeds and the implications for the management of shipping’s carbon emissions. Carbon Manage 3:589–600 Smith T, O’Keeffe E, Aldous L, Agnolucci P (2013) Assessment of shipping’s efficiency using satellite AIS data. UCL Energy Institute, London Smith TWP, Jalkanen JP, Anderson BA, Corbett JJ, Faber J, Hanayama S, O’Keeffe E, Parker S, Johansson L, Aldous L, Raucci C, Traut M, Ettinger S, Nelissen D, Lee DS, Ng S, Agrawal A, Winebrake JJ, Hoen M, Chesworth S, Pandey A (2014) Reduction of GHG emissions from Ships: third IMO GHG study 2014—final report. IMO MEPC 67/INF.3, London Sorrell S, O’Malley E, Schleich J, Scott S (2004) The economics of energy efficiency: barriers to cost-effective investment. Edward Elgar Publishing Limited, Cheltenham Stall-Meadows C, Hyle A (2010) Procedural methodology for a grounded meta-analysis of qualitative case studies. Int J Consum Stud 34:412–418 Starr MA (2014) Qualitative and mixed-methods research in economics: surprising growth, promising future. J Econ Surv 28:238–264 Stevens L, Sys C, Vanelslander T, Van Hassel E (2015) Is new emission legislation stimulating the implementation of sustainable and energy-efficient maritime technologies? Res Transp Bus Manage 17:14–25 Stopford M (2009) Maritime economics, 3rd edn. Routledge, Oxon Storberg-Walker J (2007) Understanding the conceptual development phase of applied theory-building research: a grounded approach. Hum Resour Dev Q 18:63–90 Strand I (2011) A game changer for the shipping industry? An analysis of the future impact of carbon regulations on environment and industry. PricewaterhouseCoopers AS, Oslo References 171 Stålhane M, Andersson H, Christiansen M, Fagerholt K (2014) Vendor managed inventory in tramp shipping. Omega 47:60–72 Sugden R (2011) Salience, inductive reasoning and the emergence of conventions. J Econ Behav Organ 79:35–47 Suh S-C, Park N-K (2010) The charter fixing negotiation procedure with asymmetric impatience in a game theory framework: case studies in coal and ore transactions. Asian J Shipping Logistics 26:247–261 Symeonidis L, Prokopczuk M, Brooks C, Lazar E (2012) Futures basis, inventory and commodity price volatility: an empirical analysis. Econ Model 29:2651–2663 Tamvakis MN (2007) Commodity trade and finance. Informa, London Tetley W (2004) Good faith in contract: particularly in the contracts of arbitration and chartering. J Marit Law Commer 35:561–616 Tezuka K, Ishii M (2008) Strategic behavior and the determination of spot prices in shipping freight markets: a game theoretical approach. Paper presented at the international association of maritime economists conference (IAME2008), Dalian, 2–4 April 2008 Tezuka K, Ishii M (2011) An application of non-cooperative game to an equilibrium freight rate with capacity constraint under uncertainty. Paper presented at the international association of maritime economists conference (IAME2011), Paper ID: 724, Santiago de Chile, 25–28 Oct 2011 Tezuka K, Ishii M, Ishizaka M (2012) An equilibrium price model of spot and forward shipping freight markets. Transp Res Part E 48:730–742 Thakur M, Hurburgh CR (2009) Framework for implementing traceability system in the bulk grain supply chain. J Food Eng 95:617–626 Thakur M, Wang L, Hurburgh CR (2010) A multi-objective optimization approach to balancing cost and traceability in bulk grain handling. J Food Eng 101:193–200 Thomas DR (2006) A general inductive approach for analyzing qualitative evaluation data. Am J Eval 27:237–246 Thomas G, James D (2006) Reinvesting grounded theory: some questions about theory, ground and discovery. Br Educ Res J 32:767–795 Thomson W (1883) Electrical units of measurment. In: Thomson W (ed) (1889) Popular lectures and addresses, vol 1. Macmillan and Co., London, pp 73–74 Todd P (2016) Principles of the carriage of goods by sea. Routledge, Oxon Traut M, Gilbert P, Walsh C, Bows A, Filippone A, Stansby P, Wood R (2014) Propulsive power contribution of a kite and a Flettner rotor on selected shipping routes. Appl Energy 113:362–372 Trimarchi P (1991) Commercial impracticability in contract law: an economic analysis. Int Rev Law Econ 11:63–82 Trodden DG, Murphy AJ, Pazouki K, Sargeant J (2015) Fuel usage data analysis for efficient shipping operations. Ocean Eng 110:75–84 Tsereklas-Zafeirakis A, Aravossis K, Gougoulidis G, Pavlopoulou Y (2016) A proposed methodology for the technoeconomic evaluation of energy efficiency retrofits: a bulk carrier case study. J Ship Prod Des 32:130–137 Tsioumas V, Papadimitriou S (2015) Excess returns in the spot market for bulk carriers. Marit Econ Logistics 17:399–415 UNCTAD (1990) Charter parties—a comparative analysis. UNCTAD, Geneva Urquhart C, Lehmann H, Myers MD (2010) Putting the ‘theory’ back into grounded theory: guidelines for grounded theory studies in information systems. Inf Syst J 20:357–381 Vandeventer B (1975) Analysis of basic provisions of voyage and time charter parties. Tulane Law Rev 49:806–844 Veenstra AW, van Dalen J (2011) Ship speed and fuel consumption quotation in ocean shipping time charter contracts. J Transport Econ Policy 45:41–61 Vergara J, McKesson C, Walczak M (2012) Sustainable energy for the marine sector. Energy Policy 49:333–345 172 References Viola IM, Sacher M, Xu J, Wang F (2015) A numerical method for the design of ships with wind-assisted propulsion. Ocean Eng 105:33–42 Von Neumann J, Morgenstern O (2004) Theory of games and economic behavior: sixtieth-anniversary edition. Princeton University Press, Princeton NJ Vose D (2009) Risk analysis—a quantitative guide, 3rd edn. Wiley, Chichester Watson D, Head A (2013) Corporate finance: principles and practice, 6th edn. Pearson Education Limited, Harlow Weingartner HM (1969) Some new views on the payback period and capital budgeting decisions. Manage Sci 15:B594–B607 WESTAC (1998) Grain handling and transportation system profile. WESTAC, Vancouver Wijnolst N, Wergeland T (2009) Shipping innovation. IOS Press BV, Amsterdam Wilson J (2014) Essentials of business research: a guide to doing your research project, 2nd edn. SAGE Publications Ltd., London Wilson JF (2010) Carriage of goods by sea, 7th edn. Pearson Education Limited, Harlow World Bank (2016) Data—indicators. Available via: http://data.worldbank.org/indicator. Accessed 4 Feb 2016 Yang D, Liu M, Xie J (2010) The application of game theory in maritime transport.’ Paper presented at the international association of maritime economists conference (IAME2010), Paper ID: 1_15_04, Lisbon, 7–9 July 2010 Zhang G, Ding Y, Milojević S (2013) Citation content analysis (CCA): a framework for syntactic and semantic analysis of citation content. J Am Soc Inform Sci Technol 64:1490–1503 Zhou Q (2010) Damages for repudiation: an ex ante perspective on the golden victory. Sydney Law Rev 32:579–593 Index A Adverse selection, 7, 53, 55, 153 Agency costs, 19, 50 Agent, 7, 19–21, 49, 51–56, 62, 65, 74–78, 80, 83, 85, 87–89, 91, 94–96, 98, 105–107, 153, 154, 156, 157 Asymmetric information, 153 Content analysis, 7, 9, 28, 29, 31, 39, 105, 108, 154, 157 Contract, 4, 6, 7, 9, 17, 19, 23, 31, 32, 34, 37, 38, 44, 50–55, 57, 62–64, 98, 104–108, 153–155, 158, 159 Contract law, 37 B Bargaining, 7, 9, 37, 39, 49, 51, 52, 57, 63, 65, 98, 105–107 Bulk carrier, 111, 153 Bunker costs, 62 Buyer, 51, 53, 57, 68, 98, 105, 154 D Debt, 60, 61, 154, 159 Design improvements, 3, 14, 16 Discount rate, 59, 60 Distribution, 44, 73–75, 77, 79, 83, 86, 87, 89, 90, 94, 113–115, 117, 118, 157 Duty, 33, 36, 37, 45, 109 C Capital costs, 18, 55, 61 Carrier, 4, 6, 7, 19, 23, 25, 32–34, 36, 42, 44, 49–54, 57–59, 62, 69, 74, 77, 83, 87, 89, 94, 98, 105, 106, 158 Cash flows, 36, 59, 60, 62, 155–157 Charterer, 4, 6, 7, 17–19, 23, 25, 32–34, 36, 37, 39, 42, 44, 49–54, 57, 59, 74, 77, 83, 86, 89, 94, 98, 100, 105, 106, 154, 156, 158, 159 Chartering negotiations, 9 Charter party, 4–9, 13, 18, 20, 23–25, 28, 29, 31, 32, 34, 36, 37, 44, 51, 63, 64, 103–109, 154, 158, 159 Clauses, 4–9, 16, 21, 23–28, 37, 39–41, 64, 104, 105, 108, 109, 154 COGSA, 32 Commodity, 6, 17, 54, 55, 57, 61, 66, 73, 75, 77, 78, 80, 83, 85, 87–91, 95, 96, 98–100, 105, 107 Common law, 33, 35, 36, 45 E EEDI, 3, 4, 13–16, 99, 108 EEISS, 49, 59, 63, 76, 77, 80, 85, 88, 91, 95, 96, 98 Effort level, 53, 54, 74, 76, 83, 85, 87, 88, 94, 96 Elevator, 68, 69 Energy efficiency, 4–9, 13, 14, 16, 19–21, 24–27, 29, 31, 34, 36–38, 40, 44, 45, 49, 51–55, 57, 59, 62–64, 74, 77, 83, 87, 93, 94, 98–100, 103–109, 155 Energy efficient technologies, 4, 16, 20, 36, 99 Energy saving equipment, 16 Environmental awareness, 8 Environmental commitment, 36, 44, 106 Environmental stewardship, 37, 38, 44, 55, 56, 64, 78, 80, 89, 91, 99, 104, 108 Equilibrium, 50, 57, 59, 60, 62, 63, 75–81, 83–85, 87, 88, 90–93, 95–99 Equity, 36, 60, 61, 154, 159 Exploratory research, 25 © Springer International Publishing Switzerland 2017 G.A. Psarros, Energy Efficiency Clauses in Charter Party Agreements, Springer Series on Naval Architecture, Marine Engineering, Shipbuilding and Shipping 3, DOI 10.1007/978-3-319-50265-6 173 174 F Focused coding, 6, 7, 27–29, 31, 105 Freight contract, 17, 32, 78, 80, 89, 91, 98 Freight rate, 4, 17, 49–51, 54, 56, 57, 59, 61, 62, 75, 76, 79, 80, 84, 87, 90, 91, 95 Fuel consumption, 4, 15–17, 28, 34, 40, 50, 53, 62, 79, 90, 105, 107, 109 G Game theory, 7, 9, 49–51, 63, 103, 105–107, 155 Good faith, 37, 109 Grain, 9, 65, 66, 68, 69, 71, 75, 79, 83, 84, 87, 90, 94, 95, 98, 99, 103, 106, 111, 156 Grounded theory, 6, 8, 9, 23, 25, 27, 29, 105, 155 H Hague-Visby Rules, 18, 32, 33, 155 Hamburg Rules, 18, 33, 155 Handymax, 71, 74, 75, 77, 79, 83, 86, 100, 106, 112 Handymax bulk carrier, 71 Handymax vessel, 156 Hidden action, 53, 156 Hidden knowledge, 156 Hire, 4, 8, 17, 18, 41, 49, 61, 73, 107, 154, 156, 158 I Implied duties, 18 Incentive, 156 Incentive mechanism, 5, 7, 9, 63, 103, 106 Inductive approach, 24 Information, 7, 19, 20, 24, 25, 27, 29, 33, 34, 49, 50, 52, 53, 55, 56, 61–63, 72, 78, 106–108, 115, 153, 156–159 Information rent, 156 Initial coding, 6, 9, 27, 29, 31, 39, 105 M Moral hazard, 7, 53, 156 N Nature, 156 Negotiation process, 7 Negotiations, 7, 37, 44, 49, 50, 53, 55–57, 65, 98, 106, 109, 156 Index NPV, 59, 61, 62, 107 O Obligation, 4, 6, 33, 37, 45, 52, 64, 104, 109 Operating costs, 18, 61, 75, 79, 84, 87, 90, 95 P Panamax, 71, 86, 89, 90, 94, 112 Panamax bulk carrier, 71 Panamax vessel, 156 Period charter, 17 Pollution, 13, 36, 45, 104 Principal, 7, 19, 20, 27, 34, 49, 51–56, 61, 65, 73–75, 77, 78, 80, 83, 85–89, 91, 94–96, 98, 105, 107, 156, 157 Principal-agent problem, 157 Probability, 36, 55, 57, 72, 73, 75, 77, 79, 80, 84, 85, 89–91, 95, 96, 113, 157 Q Qualitative research, 24 Qualitative research objectives, 5, 6, 23, 24, 104, 106 Quantitative research objectives, 6, 7, 103, 105 R Rational behavior, 49, 157 RFR, 61, 75, 77, 79, 80, 84, 85, 87, 88, 90, 91, 95, 96 Risk, 17, 34, 36, 38, 44, 50, 51, 59–62, 98, 100, 106 Rotterdam Rules, 18, 33 S Screening, 21, 53, 55, 158 Seaworthiness, 18, 28, 34, 39 SEEMP, 14, 16, 55, 56 Seller, 51, 53, 57, 98, 105 Sensitivity analysis, 74 Sharing scheme, 6, 35, 37, 38, 49, 51, 52, 59, 62, 77, 100, 105, 106, 109 Ship-owner, 4, 18, 23, 33, 154 Shipper, 4, 6, 7, 17, 19, 23, 25, 32, 33, 44, 49–54, 57, 59, 74, 77, 83, 86, 89, 94, 98, 105, 154 Signaling, 158 Spot market, 17, 20, 50, 68, 100 Index 175 T Terminal, 68 Time charter, 7, 17–19, 21, 32, 40, 50, 53, 61, 62, 83–85, 94–96, 98–100, 106, 156 V Voyage charter, 7, 17, 32, 34, 39, 42, 49, 50, 54, 61, 73, 100, 105 Voyage costs, 42, 61, 73, 79, 90 U Uncertainty, 16, 19, 62, 72, 73, 99, 100, 115, 157, 159 Utility, 159 W WACC, 60