Journal of Banking and Finance 108 (2019) 105651 Contents lists available at ScienceDirect Journal of Banking and Finance journal homepage: www.elsevier.com/locate/jbf The moderating role of capital on the relationship between bank liquidity creation and failure risk ✩ Chen Zheng a, Adrian (Wai Kong) Cheung b,∗, Tom Cronje a a b School of Economics, Finance and Property, Curtin University, WA, Australia College of Business, Governance and Law, Flinders University, Bedford Park Campus, Adelaide, SA 5042, Australia a r t i c l e i n f o Article history: Received 19 August 2017 Accepted 16 September 2019 Available online 18 September 2019 JEL classification: G01 G21 G28 Keywords: Liquidity creation Bank failure Bank capital Liquidity risk Bank size Crisis a b s t r a c t We examine the role of bank capital in moderating the relationship between bank liquidity creation and the failure risk in U.S. banks over the period of 2003–2014. We find that, conditional on bank capital, bank liquidity creation is related to bank failure risk negatively. The negative relationship is moderated positively (i.e., strengthened) by (changes in) bank capital. This finding is consistent with the view that banks may strengthen their solvency through increased capital in response to the illiquidity risk associated with liquidity creation; and higher capital enhances the ability of banks to create liquidity. The result is robust to different estimation methods, and alternative measures of liquidity creation, bank failure risk, and bank capital. Further analysis shows that the significant and negative effect is more prominent for small banks, and the impact of bank capital was more pronounced during the recent financial crisis of 20 07–20 09. © 2019 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. 1. Introduction According to the modern theory of financial intermediation, liquidity creation is a major function of banks in the economy. Banks create liquidity on the balance sheet by financing relatively long-term illiquid assets with relatively short-term liquid liabilities (Bryant, 1980; Diamond and Dybvig, 1983). Banks also create liquidity by way of off-balance sheet activities, such as providing standby letters of credit and loan commitments to their customers (Holmström and Tirole, 1998; Kashyap et al., 2002; Thakor, 2005). Liquidity creation is risky because it makes banks less liquid (i.e., banks hold illiquid assets when they provide liquidity to the external entities), increases the bank’s exposure to risk, and raises the likelihood and severity of losses associated with having to dispose of illiquid assets to satisfy the liquidity demands of customers ✩ We would like to thank Felix Chan, Robert Durand, Mark Harris, Mostafa Hasan, Tianpei Luo, Lee Smales, and the participants at the seminars/conferences at Curtin University, Edith Cowan University, the 2nd Business Doctoral and Emerging Scholars Conference at Perth in 2017, and the FEBS Conference at Rome in 2018, for their helpful comments and suggestions. Any errors are our own. Cheung acknowledges financial support from the College of Business, Government and Law, Flinders University. ∗ Corresponding author. E-mail address: adrian.cheung@flinders.edu.au (A. (Wai Kong) Cheung). https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jbankfin.2019.105651 0378-4266/© 2019 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved. (Allen and Santomero, 1997; Allen and Gale, 2004). In extreme situations, aggregate increases in liquidity demand can result in bank runs by depositors (Diamond and Dybvig, 1983). Existing literature indicates that an increase in liquidity creation could result in increased bank illiquidity, and this can be considered a main source of banking fragility (e.g., Acharya and Naqvi, 2012; Thakor, 2005; Berger and Bouwman, 2017). Our paper is complementary to this line of research, showing how the liquidity risk-sharing role of bank capital can affect the relationship between liquidity creation and failure risk at individual bank level. Bank capital is important, since it implicates the survival probability of banks in two ways. Firstly, it plays a loss-absorption role because higher bank capital increases the buffers of banks against shocks to asset values (Repullo, 2004; Von Thadden, 2004). Secondly, it also serves a role to reduce risk. According to incentive-based theories, higher bank capital strengthens the incentive of banks to monitor their relationships with borrowers (Holmström and Tirole, 1998), or reduces the excessive risk-taking incentives of banks (Acharya et al., 2016). Prior literature finds that banks manage or strengthen their capital position actively, to hedge against perceived risk exposure (Berger et al., 2008; Distinguin et al., 2013). Higher capital, in turn, favours the ability of banks to create liquidity, as capital helps absorb the greater risk associated with liquidity creation (Repullo, 2004). Further, higher 2 C. Zheng, A. (Wai Kong) Cheung and T. Cronje / Journal of Banking and Finance 108 (2019) 105651 capital may incentivize banks to work harder, leading to more lending and liquidity creation (Donaldson et al., 2018). Hence, ignoring the roles of bank capital could lead to incomplete and, sometimes, erroneous conclusions about the relationship between liquidity creation and bank failure risk. The goal of this paper is to empirically examine the interaction effect of liquidity creation and bank capital on the failure risk of individual banks. By way of preview, our main findings are summarized as follows. First, contrary to what one might initially expect, we find that liquidity creation is negatively associated with bank failure risk in the presence of bank capital. Moreover, this negative relationship is moderated positively (i.e., strengthened) by (changes in) bank capital. This is because banks that create more liquidity, and are then exposed to higher liquidity risk in general, accumulate more capital buffer as an insurance against the illiquidity risk from liquidity creation. The higher capital, consequently, lowers the probability of bank failure and enhances the ability of banks to create liquidity. We consider changes in bank capital, since the incremental changes in bank capital actually capture the liquidity risk-sharing role. Overall, an increase in bank capital will give rise to a further increase in liquidity creation, but a further decrease in bank failure risk, implying that an increase in bank capital will strengthen the negative relationship between liquidity creation and bank failure risk. This result supports the findings of Castiglionesi et al. (2014) that banks may use capital to deal with undiversifiable liquidity risk that cannot be diversified away by interbank markets. The second main finding is that the negative and significant relationship between bank liquidity creation and bank failure risk is mainly applicable to smaller banks, and the impact of (changes in) bank capital on the relationship between liquidity creation and bank failure risk is more pronounced during the recent financial crisis period. The paper related to ours is that of Fungacova et al. (2015) who find that high liquidity creation significantly increases the probability of bank failure of Russian banks. Their result is different from our result probably due to the following reasons. First, Fungacova et al. (2015) concentrate on bank failures during the pre-crisis period (i.e., between 20 0 0 and 2007) when economic conditions were relatively stable and tranquil, while our study covers not only the pre-crisis period but also the crisis and postcrisis periods, during which stringent capital requirements were imposed.1 It is noteworthy that these stringent capital requirements can affect bank risk management in a different way and this endogenous behavior is the main idea on which this paper is based. Prior research finds that bank risk taking is negatively related to capital requirements (e.g., Furlong and Keeley, 1989; Konishi and Yasuda, 2004). Hence, it is expected that the implementation of stricter capital standards during the crisis and post-crisis periods would substantially reduce bank failure risk. Second, unlike Berger and Bouwman’s (2009) liquidity creation measure, which includes both on- and off-balance sheet items, Fungacova et al. (2015) consider on-balance sheet items only because they argue that off-balance sheet activities are insignificant in Russia. However, in our sample, the amount of off-balance sheet liquidity creation is much higher than that of on-balance sheet liquidity creation in the U.S., primarily due to the increase of unused loan commitments. More importantly, prior studies (e.g., Cornett et al., 2011) find that the level of pre-existing unused loan 1 For example, in response to the Global Financial Crisis (GFC), the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (BCBS) proposed a number of post-crisis regulatory framework changes (known as Basel III) designed to address inadequacies of bank risk management. The new capital rules introduced higher capital requirements. More specifically, Basel III increased the minimum tier 1 risk-based capital ratio from 4% to 6%, and the common equity component of tier 1 capital from 2% to 4.5%. commitments was a major contributor to liquidity risk during the financial crisis. Therefore, it is not surprising that we find a negative relationship between liquidity creation and failure risk because banks may strengthen or build up their capital buffers in response to the liquidity risk. The higher capital, consequently lowers the probability of bank failure. Interestingly, Fungacova et al. (2015) also find some limited evidence that banks with very low liquidity creation are inclined to fail. Their explanation is that liquidity creation is one of the most important roles that banks perform in the economy. Therefore, the inability of banks to perform this function likely signals trouble. The findings of our paper support this view. Specifically, we find that banks which create less liquidity are more likely to fail, since they seem to have too low levels of capital buffers to absorb the liquidity risk from their lower liquidity creation activities. It is worth mentioning that in addition to the difference in findings, the research question of our paper differs from that of their study. Complementing the literature on early warning system and bank failure prediction models, they include a liquidity creation variable and investigate whether this variable has incremental explanatory power in predicting bank failures. In this study, we examine the interaction effect of liquidity creation and bank capital on failure risk of banks. We focus on whether bank capital plays a moderating role in the relationship between liquidity creation and bank failure risk. Our paper contributes to the literature by providing evidence that the association between liquidity creation and failure risk depends crucially on bank capital. To the best of our knowledge, no prior study has empirically investigated the role of bank capital in moderating the relationship between liquidity creation and failure risk. This is our first contribution. Our findings also have important policy implications that are particularly relevant today. The extant literature finds that the Basel III liquidity regulations are correlated with liquidity creation.2 In particular, the new standards may have the unintended consequences of reducing liquidity creation and passing on higher costs to the real economy, as banks are required to hold more liquid assets, and are discouraged from holding illiquid loans and liquid deposits (Berger and Sedunov, 2017). Our second contribution is to complement this literature by showing that lower bank liquidity creation caused by stricter liquidity regulations may have a potentially adverse impact on the stability of individual banks when taking into consideration the loss absorption role of bank capital. This finding suggests that capital and liquidity requirements cannot be separated. Policymakers should consider the liquidity risk-sharing function of bank capital as an integrated component of bank liquidity management, and evaluate its effect on the relationship between liquidity creation and failure risk. The third contribution of our paper is to shed new light on the one-size-fits-all approach to bank regulations. Our finding that liquidity creation is associated with bank failure risk negatively in the presence of bank capital is heavily concentrated among the usual notion of “community banks” with assets less than $1 million, implies that small banks increase their capital ratios when they face the higher illiquidity risk associated with liquidity creation. This, in turn, reduces the probability of their default and 2 In the wake of the recent global financial crisis, the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (BCBS) introduced a number of new micro-prudential measures designed to make individual banks more resilient to common and idiosyncratic shocks. This regulatory framework, known as Basel III Accord, not only focused on minimum capital standards as established under the Basel I and II Accords, but also, for the first time, imposed stringent liquidity standards – the Liquidity Coverage Ratio (LCR) and the Net Stable Funding Ratio (NSFR) for banks in its signatory nations. The LCR standard requires banks to maintain unencumbered high-quality liquid assets to survive a severe distress scenario over the short-term horizon (a 30-day period), while the NSFR standard requires banks to finance their medium- and longterm loans with stable sources of funding that are unlikely to run during a crisis. C. Zheng, A. (Wai Kong) Cheung and T. Cronje / Journal of Banking and Finance 108 (2019) 105651 enables them to create more liquidity. This corroborates the observations of Tran et al. (2016), who show some evidence that the impact of capital on liquidity creation appears strongest for small banks. Consistent with DeYoung et al. (2018) who find that imposing new liquidity constraints on small banks is likely to be redundant and expensive, our results lend support to the idea of eliminating (or at least substantially relaxing) the new Basel III binding liquidity constraints from small banks, as they are likely to be medium liquidity creators, and to self-manage their illiquidity risk resulting from liquidity creation actively. The remainder of the paper proceeds as follows: Section 2 discusses the related literature and develops the hypothesis. Section 3 describes the data and sample, introduces the variable definitions, and provides summary statistics. Section 4 presents the baseline regression model and main findings, and shows a battery of robustness checks. Section 5 addresses the endogeneity issue based on an instrumental variable approach and time-dynamic models. Section 6 concludes. 2. Related literature and hypothesis development In this section, we first provide a brief review of the literature to place our paper in context. Our paper relates to three strands of literature: studies analyzing the relationship between bank capital and liquidity creation; research exploring the role of bank capital in failure risk; and papers investigating the relationship between liquidity creation and failure risk. We then formulate different hypotheses/predictions as to how changes in bank capital moderate the relationship between bank liquidity creation and failure risk. 2.1. Bank capital and liquidity creation There are two theories as to how bank capital affects liquidity creation. According to the “financial fragility-crowding out” hypothesis, capital has a negative effect on liquidity creation, because a higher capital ratio makes a bank less fragile, which, in turn, will decrease the monitoring activity of depositors and hamper a bank’s ability to create liquidity (Diamond and Rajan, 20 0 0, 20 01), and a higher capital ratio may reduce liquidity creation through the crowding out of deposits, a key component of liquidity creation (Gorton and Winton, 2017). In contrast, the “risk absorption” hypothesis, implies that there is a positive effect of capital on liquidity creation, because capital helps to absorb the illiquidity risks associated with liquidity creation, expands the risk-bearing capacity of banks and improves the capacity of banks to create liquidity (Allen and Santomero, 1997; Allen and Gale, 2004; Bhattacharya and Thakor, 1993; Repullo, 2004; Von Thadden, 2004). Berger and Bouwman (2009) investigate the relationship between bank capital and liquidity creation using a sample of U.S. commercial banks from 1993 to 2003, and find empirical support for both hypotheses. For large banks, which create by far most of the liquidity, they find a positive relationship, consistent with the “risk absorption” effect, whereas for small banks, the relationship is negative, consistent with the “financial fragilitycrowding out” effect. A small but growing set of empirical studies examine the two-way relationship between capital and liquidity creation, because bank capital and liquidity might be jointly determined. For example, Horváth et al. (2014) find that capital and liquidity creation negatively Granger-cause each other for a sample of Czech banks from 20 0 0 to 2010. Along the same line, Fu et al. (2016) find that there is a significant negative bi-causal relationship between liquidity creation and regulatory capital across 14 Asia Pacific economies from 2005 to 2012. On the contrary, Tran et al. (2016) show a positive bidirectional relationship between liquidity creation and regulatory capital for U.S. 3 banks, after controlling for bank profitability from 1996 to 2013. Distinguin et al. (2013) also find that bank capital and liquidity creation can affect each other for the publicly traded U.S. and European banks during the pre-crisis from 20 0 0 to 2006, but the signs of the effects depend on bank size. 2.2. Bank capital and failure risk Turning to the role of bank capital in failure risk, there are several theories supporting the view that bank capital reduces the probability of bank failure. One set of theories argues that capital acts as a cushion to absorb potential losses, owing to unexpected asset returns (e.g., Repullo, 20 04; Von Thadden, 20 04). Another set of theories focuses on the incentive effects of capital. In these models, either capital induces banks to better monitor their relationship borrowers, thereby, reducing the probability of default (e.g., Holmström and Tirole, 1998), or it attenuates the excessive risk-taking incentives of banks (e.g., Acharya et al., 2016). Collectively, these theories suggest that there is a negative relationship between bank capital and failure risk.3 On the empirical side, papers that precede the recent financial crisis, such as that of Cole and Gunther (1995) and Estrella et al. (20 0 0) find that bank failure risk is driven mainly by low capitalization. Recent papers exploring the determinants of bank failures during the recent financial crisis, find that capital is one of the factors explaining failure (e.g., Cole and White, 2012; Beltratti and Stulz, 2012). Specifically, banks with higher capital buffers have more flexibility to respond to adverse shocks and lower failure risk. 2.3. Bank liquidity creation and failure risk With respect to the relationship between liquidity creation and bank failure risk, there are different views in the literature and the evidence is mixed. One argument put forward by Diamond and Dybvig (1983), and extended by Allen and Santomero (1997) and Allen and Gale (2004), stresses that, as liquidity is created by mismatching long-term assets with short-term liabilities, liquidity creation exposes banks to illiquidity risk: the risk of having to dispose of illiquid assets to meet customers’ liquidity demands. For example, sudden and large withdrawals from demand depositors and borrowers with credit line facilities can force the bank to prematurely liquidate many of its assets at fire sale prices and to fail (Diamond and Rajan, 2011). This view predicts that liquidity creation leaves banks vulnerable to insolvency – the more the liquidity creation, the more the likelihood of bank failure. But another view predicts that liquidity creation is associated with bank failure negatively for two reasons. First, liquidity creation is a primary and crucial function of banking institutions. Since liquidity creation, as a key measure of total bank output, contains information about a bank’s capability to support the macro-economy and facilitate transactions among economic agents through maturity transformation, the inability of the bank to manage its balance sheet and perform a liquidity creation function is likely to be an early warning signal of trouble (Fungacova et al., 2015). Consistent with this line of argument, Chatterjee (2018) finds that lower liquidity creation leads to recessions in the U.S. economy. Second, Berger et al. (2008) show that banks manage their capital ratios actively, to hedge against the perceived risk exposure. Specifically, banks may strengthen or build up their capital buffers in response to the illiquidity risk stemming from liquidity creation (Distinguin et al., 2013). This viewpoint implies that liquidity creation, acknowledged as a risk in existing literature, can be 3 See Berger and Bouwman (2013) for extensive review of existing theories that explain how bank capital could influence a bank’s survival probability. 4 C. Zheng, A. (Wai Kong) Cheung and T. Cronje / Journal of Banking and Finance 108 (2019) 105651 negatively associated with bank failure risk owing to the tendency of banks to adopt methods, with specific reference to the increase in capital, to manage/mitigate the risk. On the whole, existing research has clearly established some possible connections between liquidity creation and bank capital (e.g., Berger and Bouwman, 2009; Distinguin et al., 2013), between liquidity creation and failure risk (e.g., Diamond and Dybvig, 1983), and between bank capital and failure risk (e.g., Berger and Bouwman, 2013). In particular, theory suggests that bank capital may be related to liquidity creation positively or negatively, depending on whether the risk absorption hypothesis or the financial fragilitycrowding out hypothesis prevails. As for the relationship between liquidity creation and failure risk, theory also suggests that the relationship can be either positive or negative. When it comes to the relationship between bank capital and failure risk, the consensus is that the relationship is negative. However, almost no research to date has empirically analyzed the impact of changes in bank capital on the relationship between liquidity creation and bank failure risk. The purpose of this paper is to fill this void in the literature. Considering the abovementioned research findings, it is evident that there are four (i.e., 2 × 2 × 1) possible predictions/hypotheses regarding the role of bank capital in determining the relationship between liquidity creation and bank failure risk. Suppose liquidity creation is associated positively with failure risk and bank capital is related positively (negatively) to liquidity creation (failure risk), the first prediction/hypothesis is that an increase in bank capital is expected to weaken the positive relationship between liquidity creation and failure risk because such an increase will give rise to a further increase (decrease) in liquidity creation (failure risk). Similarly, if liquidity creation is now associated negatively with failure risk but the positive (negative) relationship of bank capital with liquidity creation (failure risk) remains intact, the second hypothesis/prediction is that any increase in bank capital could strengthen the negative relationship between liquidity creation and failure risk because a further increase in liquidity creation that is induced by an increase in bank capital will come with a further decrease in bank failure risk. However, whenever the impact of bank capital on liquidity creation and failure risk is the same (i.e., negative), then the third (fourth) prediction/hypothesis is that any increase in bank capital could strengthen (weaken) the relationship between liquidity creation and bank failure risk, depending on whether the relationship is a positive (negative) one. This is because if the impact of bank capital on liquidity creation and failure risk is negative, any increase in bank capital will give rise to a further decrease in liquidity creation and a further decrease in failure risk, which in turn strengthens (undermines) the positive (negative) relationship between liquidity creation and bank failure risk. 3. Sample, data and variables descriptions 3.1. Sample and data The sample of banks in this paper consists of all FDIC insured U.S. institutions over the period from 2003: Q1 to 2014: Q4. The 2003 to 2014 time period is unique in that it contains data before, during and after the largest financial crisis in recent history. It starts five years before the Global Financial Crisis (GFC) and ends five years after the GFC, to allow for the long-term effect of this exogenous shock on the relation between bank liquidity creation and failure risk. The data is obtained from several sources. Quarterly financial data is sourced from the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation Statistics on Depository Institutions (FDIC SDI), which contains detailed on- and off-balance sheet information for all FDICinsured institutions. Bank failure information is obtained from the FDIC’s failed banks list. This study makes use of the publicly available dataset of quarterly bank liquidity creation for U.S. commer- cial banks over the observation period that was compiled by Allen N. Berger and Christa Bouwman.4 Macroeconomic data, such as GDP, Federal funds rate, yield spread and gross private savings, are taken from the St. Louis Federal Reserve “FRED” public database. Local market economic and demographic data are sourced from the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) (e.g., per capita personal income, total employment and population) and the Federal Reserve Board website (e.g., Senior Loan Officer Opinion Survey on Bank Lending Practices (SLOOS)). All the aforementioned data sources are merged together to construct the dataset for this study. 3.2. Variables Bank failure risk serves as the dependent variable in this study. Since the z-score has been extensively used to measure banks’ insolvency risk, we focus primarily on each bank’s z-score, which is inversely related to the probability of bank insolvency. Specifically, z-score = (roa + car)/σ (roa), where roa is the return on assets, car is the ratio of equity to assets, and σ (roa) is the standard deviation of roa. For the derivation of σ (roa), we use the standard deviation of a bank’s roa over the previous twelve quarters. Intuitively, the measure represents the number of standard deviations that a bank’s roa must decline from its expected value to become insolvent once equity is depleted (Roy, 1952). Accordingly, a higher z-score indicates a lower bank risk. Because the z-score is highly skewed, we follow the literature (e.g., Laeven and Levine, 2009) and use the natural logarithm of the z-score as the risk measure. For brevity, we use the label “z-score” in referring to the natural logarithm of the z-score in the remainder of the paper. For the bank liquidity creation, the main independent variable, we use the measure proposed in the ground-breaking work of Berger and Bouwman (2009). The BB measure (catfat) is a comprehensive single measure of bank liquidity creation that considers all the bank’s on-balance sheet and off-balance sheet activities. To summarize briefly, the BB measure is the weighted sum of all assets, liabilities, equity, and off-balance sheet activities. Since liquidity is created when banks finance illiquid assets (e.g., business loans) with liquid liabilities (e.g., transaction deposits), a positive weight of 1/2 is given to both illiquid assets and liquid liabilities. Thus, transforming $1 of illiquid commercial loan into $1 of liquid transaction deposit creates $1 of liquidity for the public. Similarly, since banks destroy liquidity when they use illiquid liabilities (e.g., subordinated debt) or equity to finance liquid assets (e.g., cash, treasury securities), a negative weight of −1/2 is given to liquid assets, illiquid liabilities, and equity. Thus, taking $1 of liquid asset from the public and giving the public $1 of illiquid subordinated debt or equity destroys $1 of liquidity. All semi-liquid assets and liabilities (e.g., residential real estate loans) are assigned a neutral weight of zero. Off-balance sheet activities are assigned weights consistent with those assigned to functionally similar on-balance sheet activities. As is standard in the bank liquidity creation literature, the BB measure is normalized by gross total assets (GTA)5 so that the measure is comparable across banks, rather than dominated by the largest banks. The BB is calculated as follows: cat f at = 0.5 × (il l iquid assets + l iquid l iabil ities + il l iquid guarantees ) + 0 × (semiliquid assets + semil iquid l iabil ities + semiliquid guarantees ) − 0.5 × (1) (liquid assets + illiquid liabilities + equity + liquid guarantees + liquid derivatives ) 4 We are grateful to Christa Bouwman for providing the bank liquidity creation data. It is downloadable from Christa Bouwman’s personal website (https://sites. google.com/a/tamu.edu/bouwman/data). 5 Gross total assets (GTA) equal total assets plus allowances for loan and lease losses and the allocated risk transfer. C. Zheng, A. (Wai Kong) Cheung and T. Cronje / Journal of Banking and Finance 108 (2019) 105651 This study controls for CAMELS-type variables because the CAMELS6 rating is often used by U.S. regulators to evaluate the safety and soundness of commercial banks. The values of the CAMELS ratings are confidential and not publicly available, thus, we use proxy variables to capture the key features of the CAMELS system. They are: the ratio of equity capital to total assets as a proxy for capital adequacy (ca); the ratio of all nonperforming loans to total assets as a proxy for asset quality (aq); the cost-toincome ratio as a proxy for management capability (mc); the ratio of net income to total equity as a proxy for earnings (roe); the ratio of cash and balances due from depository institutions to total assets as a proxy for liquidity (liq); and the loans-to-deposits ratio as a proxy for sensitivity to market risk (ltdrt). Furthermore, this study employs the following ratios as bank controls: the ratio of non-interest income to total income (noniirt) as a measure of income diversification (DeYoung and Torna, 2013); the Basel I risk-weighted assets of banks divided by total assets (ristak) as a measure of credit risk (Berger and Bouwman, 2013); the ratio of commercial real estate loans to total loans (commre) as a proxy for commercial real estate investment (Berger and Bouwman, 2013); and the natural logarithm of bank deposits (lndep) as a measure of stable liabilities (Gatev and Strahan, 2006). Turning to the macroeconomic and local market variables, the Federal funds rate (fedfunds) is used to control for the effect of monetary policy. This study also employs the spread between 3month U.S. T-Bills and 10-year U.S. Treasuries (spread), the log of Gross Domestic Product (lngdp) and the log of Gross Private Savings (lngpsave) as macro control variables. Loan demand depends on regional and nation-wide economic conditions as well as on individual bank conditions. To control for varying levels of loan demand, this study employs the Senior Loan Officer Opinion Survey on Bank Lending Practices (sloos). The sloos data is available from 1982: Q2 onwards, and provides quarter-by-quarter national level reports of how strong the loan demand was based on observations of senior loan officers at the application desks. It includes information such as the net percentage of domestic banks reporting stronger demand for auto loans, credit card loans, government mortgage loans, commercial and industrial (C&I) loans, etc. The Herfindhal-Hirschman Index (hhi_dep) is used to measure the level of competition for deposits among banks in local markets. Per capita personal income (lnperinc), total employment (lnemploy) and total population (lnpop) are used as measures of local economic and demographic conditions. The definitions and abbreviations used for the main variables are contained in Appendix 1. 3.3. Descriptive statistics Panel A of Table 1 contains summary statistics for the variables used in the analysis. The mean value of z-score is 2.799, similar to the z-score value in Imbierowicz and Rauch (2014) who find that the average z-score for the sample of all U.S. commercial banks during the period 1998–2010 is 3.434. The average bank liquidity creation scaled by gross total assets (catfat) is 0.311, which is generally comparable to those in Berger et al. (2017b). For example, the mean value of catfat is 0.230 in their study. The mean value of capital adequacy (ca) and asset quality (aq) indicates that the sample banks have strong capital positions and higher quality of assets. Panel B provides Pearson correlation coefficients across dependent variables and key independent variables. Contrary to our expectations, the bank liquidity creation variable, catfat, is correlated to bank failure risk significantly and positively, as measured by the 6 Each acronym of CAMELS stands for capital adequacy; asset quality; management; earnings; liquidity; and sensitivity to market risk. 5 z-score and faildummyq. However, these correlations give a general idea only of the bivariate relations, and do not control for other factors (e.g., bank capital) in a rigorous fashion as shown in our regression analyses below. The data confirms the negative relation between changes in bank capital (࢞ca) and bank failure risk, proxied by the z-score and faildummyq, indicating that equity acts as a buffer against the probability of bank failure. These results suggest that ignoring bank capital may lead to erroneous conclusions about the effects of bank liquidity creation on failure risk. Panel C reports the number and percentage of bank failures by year in our sample from 2003 to 2014. As shown, failures of the U.S. banks were relatively infrequent between 20 03 and 20 07, but increased dramatically in the second half of 2008. Indeed, U.S. regulators shut down 25 banks in 2008 versus only 10 banks during the entire 20 03–20 07 period. Bank failure remained at elevated levels: 140 in 2009, 157 in 2010, and 92 in 2011; before declining to 51 in 2012, 24 in 2013, and 18 in 2014. The Panel D univariate test shows that failed banks differ strongly from non-failed banks. We find that failed banks on average create more liquidity than non-failed banks (catfat). These results are in line with our correlation findings in Panel B. The evidence here further reiterates that ignoring the interactions between bank liquidity creation and bank capital may lead to flawed conclusions about the impact of liquidity creation on failure risk. As expected, and consistent with previous empirical evidence (e.g., Cole and White, 2012), failed banks on average have lower capital ratios (ca), but higher costs-to-income (mc) and loans-to-deposits ratios (ltdrt). They have a larger fraction of commercial real estate loans (commre) and nonperforming loans (aq). Not surprisingly, failed banks have a negative average return on equity (roe), and a high level of credit risk exposure (ristak). Interestingly, the reported liquidity ratio (liq) is higher for the failed banks. This finding is consistent with Cleary and Hebb (2016) who find that troubled banks may build up liquidity in anticipation of future distress. 4. Multivariate analysis 4.1. Empirical model and main results We specify the following empirical model to examine the interaction effect of bank capital and liquidity creation on the failure risk of individual banks: Bank Failure Riski, t = β0 + β1 Liquidity Creationi,t−1 + β2 Liquidity Creationi,t−1 × Bank Capitali,t +β3 Bank Capitali,t + β4 Bank Characteristicsi,t−1 + β5 Macroeconomic Characteristicsi,t−1 + β6 Local Market Characteristicsi,t−1 + T ime, State and Bank F ixed E f f ects + εi,t (2) In this equation, the dependent variable is Bank Failure Riski,t , measured by a bank’s z-score, referring to the failure risk of bank i in the quarter t. Liquidity Creationi,t -1 is proxied by the BB measure (catfat). Since capital ratios in subsequent years are usually highly correlated, we take the first difference of this variable (࢞Bank Capitali, t = Bank Capitali, t − Bank Capitali,t-1 ) to measure the incremental changes in bank capital that capture the liquidity-risk sharing role, which is the variable we are actually interested in. Given a relationship between changes in liquidity creation and bank failure risk (i.e., β 1 ), the interaction term of Liquidity Creation and ࢞Bank Capital is used to test for the four hypotheses/predictions. Further, we control for bank-specific characteristics,7 macroeconomic conditions and local market influences. Among the controls, we 7 We include bank capital (ca) as a control variable to capture any effects other than the liquidity-risk sharing role of incremental changes in bank capital (࢞ca). 6 C. Zheng, A. (Wai Kong) Cheung and T. Cronje / Journal of Banking and Finance 108 (2019) 105651 Table 1 Descriptive statistics. Panel A: Summary statistics (1) Variables N (2) Mean (3) Sd (4) Min (5) P25 (6) P50 (7) P75 (8) Max z-score faildummyq faildummyy catfat ca ࢞ca aq mc roe liq ltdrt noniirt ristak commre lndep fedfunds spread lngdp lngpsave crisisdummy sloos hhi_dep lnperinc lnemploy lnpop 2.799 0.001 0.005 0.311 0.108 6.95e-06 0.003 0.784 0.047 0.065 0.772 0.852 0.689 0.248 11.795 1.604 2.036 9.581 7.961 0.214 0.402 0.476 10.450 10.693 11.296 0.414 0.032 0.073 0.178 0.036 0.051 0.005 0.169 0.077 0.062 0.201 1.744 0.132 0.153 1.170 1.869 1.140 0.115 0.181 0.410 25.330 0.299 0.263 1.939 1.831 1.734 0.000 0.000 −0.155 0.049 −0.171 −0.001 0.479 −0.363 0.008 0.240 −5.052 0.342 0.001 9.865 0.070 −0.512 9.339 7.702 0.000 −60.400 0.027 9.898 7.351 7.849 2.502 0.000 0.000 0.196 0.086 −0.024 0.000 0.689 0.021 0.026 0.645 0.289 0.604 0.129 10.972 0.130 1.529 9.502 7.787 0.000 −16.700 0.250 10.267 9.207 9.933 2.774 0.000 0.000 0.322 0.100 −3.33e-06 0.001 0.761 0.046 0.042 0.788 0.578 0.699 0.233 11.638 0.510 2.249 9.587 7.922 0.000 1.400 0.402 10.432 10.223 10.885 3.084 0.000 0.000 0.435 0.120 0.024 0.004 0.842 0.084 0.079 0.910 1.041 0.782 0.344 12.407 2.940 2.875 9.667 8.137 0.000 19.600 0.620 10.611 12.138 12.625 3.902 1.000 1.000 0.718 0.272 0.171 0.031 1.637 0.230 0.343 1.262 11.379 0.976 0.691 16.064 5.260 3.578 9.786 8.230 1.000 45.500 1.000 11.243 15.496 16.088 296,538 297,610 73,690 297,607 297,607 297,609 297,609 297,566 297,607 297,607 297,607 297,472 297,609 297,607 297,609 297,609 297,607 297,607 297,607 297,610 297,607 297,607 297,508 297,508 297,508 Panel B: Correlation matrix of key variables z-score faildummyq catfat ࢞ca z-score faildummyq catfat ࢞ca 1.000 −0.042∗ ∗ ∗ −0.162∗ ∗ ∗ 0.082∗ ∗ ∗ 1.000 0.009∗ ∗ ∗ −0.046∗ ∗ ∗ 1.000 0.025∗ ∗ ∗ 1.000 Panel C: Number of failed banks by year from 2003 to 2014 Year Bank count Number of failed banks Percentage of failed banks 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 All 7074 6977 6882 6797 6717 6593 6393 6171 5902 5751 5548 5337 76,142 3 4 0 0 3 25 140 157 92 51 24 18 517 0.04% 0.06% 0.00% 0.00% 0.04% 0.38% 2.19% 2.54% 1.56% 0.89% 0.43% 0.34% 0.68% Panel D: Univariate test Variables Non-failed banks Failed banks Mean difference t-statistics for equal means catfat ࢞ca ca aq mc roe liq ltdrt noniirt ristak commre lndep 0.311 −0.001 0.108 0.003 0.784 0.047 0.065 0.772 0.852 0.689 0.248 11.795 0.363 −0.015 0.055 0.005 1.239 −0.274 0.091 0.801 −0.024 0.776 0.352 11.921 −0.052∗ ∗ ∗ 0.014∗ ∗ ∗ 0.053∗ ∗ ∗ −0.002∗ ∗ ∗ −0.455∗ ∗ ∗ 0.321∗ ∗ ∗ −0.026∗ ∗ ∗ −0.029∗ 0.876∗ ∗ ∗ −0.087∗ ∗ ∗ −0.104∗ ∗ ∗ −0.126 −5.05 25.24 26.05 −5.50 −46.91 72.80 −7.34 −2.47 8.70 −11.47 −11.78 −1.86 Note: There are four panels in this table. Panel A presents summary statistics for all variables used in our models. Panel B reports Pearson correlation matrix of key variables. Panel C lists the number of and percentage of failed banks by year in our sample. Panel D provides univariate test results on means for the sample of failed and non-failed banks. ∗ , ∗ ∗ , and ∗ ∗ ∗ represent significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% level, respectively. See Appendix 1 for variable definitions. C. Zheng, A. (Wai Kong) Cheung and T. Cronje / Journal of Banking and Finance 108 (2019) 105651 7 Table 2 Baseline OLS regression. Variables catfat ࢞ca catfat × ࢞ca Bank-specific characteristics: ca aq mc roe liq ltdrt noniirt ristak commre lndep Macroeconomic characteristics: fedfunds spread lngdp lngpsave Local economic characteristics: hhi_dep lnpop sloos lnperinc lnemploy Constant Year_quarter FE Bank FE State FE Observations Adjusted R2 Dependent variable: z-score (1) (2) (3) (4) 0.096∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 10.913∗ ∗ ∗ (0.21) 5.565∗ ∗ ∗ (0.54) 0.067∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 9.767∗ ∗ ∗ (0.21) 7.019∗ ∗ ∗ (0.52) 0.018∗ (0.01) 8.617∗ ∗ ∗ (0.17) 6.553∗ ∗ ∗ (0.40) 0.019∗ ∗ (0.01) 8.609∗ ∗ ∗ (0.17) 6.579∗ ∗ ∗ (0.40) 8.734∗ ∗ ∗ (0.05) −3.762∗ ∗ ∗ (0.08) −0.543∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) −1.008∗ ∗ ∗ (0.04) 0.009 (0.01) −0.135∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 0.005∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) −0.101∗ ∗ ∗ (0.02) 0.014∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) 0.001 (0.00) 8.076∗ ∗ ∗ (0.05) −3.843∗ ∗ ∗ (0.08) −0.416∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) −0.567∗ ∗ ∗ (0.03) 0.004 (0.01) −0.035∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 0.004∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) −0.056∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 0.012∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) 0.001∗ ∗ (0.00) 8.226∗ ∗ ∗ (0.04) −0.010 (0.03) −0.098∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 0.975∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) −0.046∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 0.006 (0.01) 0.001∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) −0.024∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) −0.005∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) 0.000 (0.00) 8.228∗ ∗ ∗ (0.04) −0.008 (0.03) −0.098∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 0.975∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) −0.047∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 0.006 (0.01) 0.001∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) −0.024∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) −0.005∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) 0.000 (0.00) 0.054∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) 0.054∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) −0.356∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 0.158∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 0.048∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) 0.052∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) −0.198∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 0.205∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) −0.082 (0.07) 0.052∗ (0.03) 0.659 (0.65) 0.043 (0.18) −0.002 (0.00) 0.061∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) −0.000 (0.00) 0.232∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) −0.068∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 1.891∗ ∗ ∗ (0.06) No Yes No 220,188 0.462 −0.005∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) 0.012∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) 0.000∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) 0.050∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) −0.019∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) 1.801∗ ∗ ∗ (0.04) No No Yes 220,188 0.671 −0.001∗ (0.00) −0.002 (0.00) −0.001∗ ∗ (0.00) 0.016∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) 0.001 (0.00) −5.336 (7.01) Yes Yes Yes 220,188 0.959 1.703∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) Yes Yes Yes 220,260 0. 959 Note: This table presents the results of multivariate OLS regression model (i.e., Eq. (2)) analysing the interactive effects of bank capital and liquidity creation on the insolvency risk of individual banks. Bank liquidity creation is proxied by the BB measure, i.e., catfat. Change in bank capital (࢞cai,t ) is the absolute change from the year t-1 to t of bank i’s equity-to-total assets ratio. z-score measures the distance from insolvency. A higher z-score value indicates that a bank is less likely to default. The variable descriptions are in Appendix 1. Regressions include different fixed effects (FE) estimations (Year_quarter FE, State FE and Bank FE). Columns (1)–(3) include bank controls, macroeconomic controls and local economic controls; Column (4) includes bank controls only. Robust standard errors clustered by bank are in parentheses. ∗ , ∗ ∗ , and ∗ ∗ ∗ represent significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% level, respectively. also include bank, year-quarter and state fixed effects. Justification for the inclusion of bank fixed effects is derived from the argument that unobserved, time-invariant bank-level heterogeneity exists. The inclusion of year-quarter fixed effects captures changes specific to individual year-quarters. We also include state fixed effects to control for the influences of unknown time-invariant differences across states. Standard errors are clustered at bank level to account for cross sectional dependence. Table 2 presents the regression results. As shown, the coefficient of the Liquidity Creation variable (catfat) is positive and sig- nificant across all specifications, indicating increasing liquidity creation results in higher z-score and reduced riskiness. Consistent with our second prediction/hypothesis, we find a positive and significant coefficient for interaction terms between liquidity creation and changes in bank capital. This suggests that given the incremental increases in bank capital, a high level of liquidity creation is associated with a high z-score value, which indicates a low level of bank failure risk. In other words, any increase in bank capital strengthens the negative relationship between liquidity creation and bank failure risk. Further, the coefficient of changes in 8 C. Zheng, A. (Wai Kong) Cheung and T. Cronje / Journal of Banking and Finance 108 (2019) 105651 bank capital (࢞ca) is statistically significant and related positively to z-score, implying that high changes in capital ratio are associated with low levels of insolvency risk. All in all, the result verifies the importance of the liquidity-risk sharing role of bank capital. Specifically, bank capital acts as a buffer to absorb the higher level of illiquidity risk that comes with high levels of liquidity creation. More capital, in turn, reduces the probability of bank failure and enables banks to create more liquidity. Therefore, the negative relationship between liquidity creation and failure risk is moderated positively (i.e., strengthened) by (changes in) bank capital. This evidence is in line with the “risk absorption” hypothesis in the literature (see Section 2.1). 4.2. Robustness checks We check the robustness of these main findings in terms of (1) different bank size groups; (2) crisis vs. non-crisis periods; (3) alternative measures of bank failure risk; (4) alternative measures of bank liquidity creation; (5) different bank capital measures; and (6) the role of managerial ability. Our results remain unchanged and provide qualitatively similar conclusions. 4.2.1. Size effect We re-estimate the OLS regression model Eq. (2) using subsamples of banks based on different size cut-offs. Four different sets of cut-offs are used. First, following the methodology of Berger and Bouwman (2009), the sample is split into large banks (GTA exceeding $3 billion), medium banks (GTA between $1 billion and $3 billion), and small banks (GTA up to $1 billion). Second, we use alternative cut-offs ($5 billion and $10 billion, respectively) separating medium and large banks while the small bank definition remains at the $1 billion cut-off. Third, we run regressions categorizing all banks as either small or large using a cut-off of $10 billion GTA. Finally, very large banks may be considered too-big-to-fail (TBTF), and in the event of distress, they tend to receive government support. To make sure that our large bank results are not overly influenced by TBTF banks, we re-run our $10 billion cut-off analysis while excluding these banks. Following the 2010 Dodd-Frank Act, we define TBTF banks as those with GTA exceeding $50 billion. As shown in Table 3, the coefficient of catfat is positive and statistically significant for small banks while it is insignificant for medium and large banks, indicating that the positive relation between liquidity creation and z-score is more prominent for small banks. Table 3 also shows that the coefficient of the interaction terms catfat × ࢞ca remains positive and statistically significant in all subsamples of small banks, but it is statistically insignificant, or only weakly significant, for medium and large banks. This is not surprising, given that access to external funds is limited for small banks. Since small banks face greater information asymmetry which makes it costly for them to access the interbank market, they have strong incentives to hoard capital in order to avoid financing constraints and costly default. Thus, small banks may increase their capital ratios when they face increasing illiquidity resulting from liquidity creation (Distinguin et al., 2013). This would, in turn, reduce the probability of bank failure and enhance the ability of banks to create liquidity. In contrast, large banks tend to have lower capital ratios. Large banks can more easily access funding from national or international capital markets and incur lower costs when raising new equity on short notice. Large banks may use their diversification advantage to operate with greater leverage and lower capital ratios, and (for the largest, most inter-connected financial firms) may have access to explicit and implicit government protection (“too-big-to-fail” policy). Therefore, they may underestimate liquidity risk and be less likely to strengthen their capital accordingly. 4.2.2. Crisis vs. non-crisis periods During the GFC, banks tended to hold a large capital buffer to strengthen their solvency and to better assume losses arising from forced early liquidation of illiquid assets and mortgage backed securities at fire sale prices, so a bank capital buffer played a more prominent role in alleviating the illiquidity risk from liquidity creation during the crisis period than during the non-crisis period. We examine how the effect of Liquidity Creation on Bank Failure Risk varied with the changes in bank capital during the crisis and non-crisis periods using a triple-interaction term in the following regression model: Bank F ailure Riski, t = β0 + β1 Liquidity Creationi,t−1 + β2 Bank C apitali,t + β3C risisdummyt + β4 Liquidity C reationi,t−1 × C risisdummyt +β5 Liquidity Creationi,t−1 × Bank Capitali,t + β6Crisisdummyt × Bank Capitali,t (3) + β7 Liquidity Creationi,t−1 × Bank C apitali,t × C risisdummyt + β8 Bank Characteristicsi,t−1 + β9 Macroeconomic Characteristicsi,t−1 + β10 Local Market Characteristicsi,t−1 + T ime, State and Bank F ixed E f f ects + εi,t The triple interaction term, Liquidity Creation × ࢞Bank Capital × Crisisdummy, is our main variable of interest. Recalling that a positive coefficient of Liquidity Creation implies that increased liquidity creation is associated with a higher z-score value, i.e., a lower probability of bank failure, the positive sign on the triple interaction term would suggest that the marginal effect of Liquidity Creation on Bank Failure Risk is stronger for banks with higher incremental increases in capital during the financial crisis period compared with the non-crisis period. Following existing literature (e.g., Berger and Bouwman, 2013), we assigned the crisisdummy variable a value of one from the third quarter of 2007 to the fourth quarter of 2009, and zero otherwise. Table 4 contains the crisis regression results. As shown in Panel A of Table 4, the coefficient of the triple interaction terms, catfat × ࢞ca × crisisdummy, is large, positive, and highly statistically significant and economically non-trivial across all specifications. These findings suggest that during the crisis period, bank liquidity creation is related to bank failure risk negatively for banks with high incremental increases in bank capital. Furthermore, the negative and statistically significant coefficient of the interaction terms, catfat × crisisdummy, indicates that, in the absence of any changes in bank capital, bank liquidity creation is the major contributor to bank failure risk during the crisis period and, thus, supports our preliminary results in Section 3. Finally, consistent with the main results in Table 2, the coefficient of the Liquidity Creation variable (catfat) is positive and statistically significant in all specifications, and the coefficient of the interaction terms of catfat with ࢞ca remains positive and statistically significant, suggesting that bank liquidity creation affects a bank’s z-score (the probability of bank failure) positively (negatively). This relationship is strengthened by incremental increases in bank capital. Findings here suggest that the interaction effect of liquidity creation and bank capital on failure risk is more pronounced during the GFC, supporting the view that the effects of capital on survival could be even stronger during crises, and banks with relatively high capital ratios are in better shape during these times (Berger and Bouwman, 2013). The 20 07–20 09 financial crisis and subsequent government assistance (e.g., TARP capital bailout) affected the banking sector in many aspects. This raises a potential concern that our results may be driven by the crisis and post-crisis data. To mitigate this concern, we use pre-crisis data only to validate the robustness of the main results. The results, reported in Panel B of Table 4, show that C. Zheng, A. (Wai Kong) Cheung and T. Cronje / Journal of Banking and Finance 108 (2019) 105651 9 Table 3 Results of OLS estimates sorted by bank size. Panel A: $1 billion and $3 billion size cutoff VARIABLES catfat ࢞ca catfat × ࢞ca Baseline Controls Year_quarter FE Bank FE State FE Observations Adjusted R2 Dependent variable: z-score (1) (2) (3) Small banks 0.021∗ ∗ (0.01) 8.765∗ ∗ ∗ (0.16) 6.654∗ ∗ ∗ (0.38) Yes Yes Yes Yes 202,791 0.965 Medium banks 0.026 (0.05) 8.394∗ ∗ ∗ (1.29) 6.027∗ ∗ (2.90) Yes Yes Yes Yes 10,905 0.910 Large banks 0.075 (0.05) 10.724∗ ∗ ∗ (0.88) −0.763 (1.47) Yes Yes Yes Yes 6492 0.930 Dependent variable: z-score (1) Small banks (2) Medium banks (3) Large banks 0.021∗ ∗ (0.01) 8.765∗ ∗ ∗ (0.16) 6.654∗ ∗ ∗ (0.38) Yes Yes Yes Yes 202,791 0.965 0.040 (0.05) 8.344∗ ∗ ∗ (1.13) 5.652∗ ∗ (2.42) Yes Yes Yes Yes 12,882 0.901 0.073 (0.06) 11.621∗ ∗ ∗ (0.89) −1.985 (1.61) Yes Yes Yes Yes 4515 0.952 Dependent Variable: Z-score (1) Small banks (2) Medium banks (3) Large banks 0.021∗ ∗ (0.01) 8.765∗ ∗ ∗ (0.16) 6.654∗ ∗ ∗ (0.38) Yes Yes Yes Yes 202,791 0.965 0.067 (0.04) 8.930∗ ∗ ∗ (1.02) 4.000∗ (2.21) Yes Yes Yes Yes 14,448 0.907 0.010 (0.05) 11.487∗ ∗ (1.16) −1.118 (2.04) Yes Yes Yes Yes 2949 0.954 Panel B: $1 billion and $5 billion size cutoff Variables catfat ࢞ca catfat × ࢞ca Baseline Controls Year_quarter FE Bank FE State FE Observations Adjusted R2 Panel C: $1 billion and $10 billion size cutoff Variables catfat ࢞ca catfat × ࢞ca Baseline Controls Year_quarter FE Bank FE State FE Observations Adjusted R2 Panel D: $10 billion size cutoff Variables catfat ࢞ca catfat × ࢞ca Baseline Controls Year_quarter FE Bank FE State FE Observations Adjusted R2 Dependent variable: z-score (1) Small banks (2) Large banks with TBTF banks∗ (3) Large banks without TBTF banks 0.018∗ (0.01) 8.597∗ ∗ ∗ (0.17) 6.669∗ ∗ ∗ (0.40) Yes Yes Yes Yes 217,239 0.960 0.010 (0.05) 11.487∗ ∗ ∗ (1.16) −1.118 (2.04) Yes Yes Yes Yes 2949 0.954 0.041 (0.07) 12.004∗ ∗ ∗ (1.41) −1.007 (2.69) Yes Yes Yes Yes 1809 0.961 Note: This table presents the results of OLS model (i.e., Eq. (2)) examining the interactive effects of bank capital and liquidity creation on the insolvency risk of individual banks across three subsamples. Bank liquidity creation is proxied by the BB measure, i.e., catfat. Change in Bank Capital (࢞cai,t ) is the absolute change from the year t-1 to t of bank i’s equity-to-total assets ratio. z-score measures the distance from insolvency. A higher z-score value indicates that a bank is less likely to default. We sort the sample banks into large, medium and small banks based on different size cut-offs across Panels A–D. The variable descriptions are in Appendix 1. For brevity, we report only specifications that include all the control variables and all fixed effects in this table. Robust standard errors clustered by bank are in parentheses. ∗ , ∗ ∗ , and ∗ ∗ ∗ represent significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% level, respectively. ∗ TBTF banks = “too-bigto-fail” banks. 10 C. Zheng, A. (Wai Kong) Cheung and T. Cronje / Journal of Banking and Finance 108 (2019) 105651 Table 4 Results of OLS estimates during the crisis and non-crisis periods. Panel A: The OLS regression results during the crisis and non-crisis periods Dependent variable: z-score Variables (1) catfat ࢞ca catfat × ࢞ca crisisdummy catfat × crisisdummy crisisdummy × ࢞ca catfat × ࢞ca × crisisdummy Bank Controls Other Baseline Controls Year_quarter FE Bank FE State FE Observations Adjusted R2 0.063∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 12.155∗ ∗ ∗ (0.24) 3.396∗ ∗ ∗ (0.62) −0.054∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) −0.027∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) −3.809∗ ∗ ∗ (0.35) 6.594∗ ∗ ∗ (0.98) Yes Yes No Yes No 220,188 0.468 Panel B: The OLS regression results using pre-crisis data only Dependent variable: z-score Variables (1) catfat ࢞ca catfat × ࢞ca Baseline Controls Year_quarter FE Bank FE State FE Observations Adjusted R2 ∗∗∗ −0.171 (0.03) 8.564∗ ∗ ∗ (0.27) 5.019∗ ∗ ∗ (0.68) Yes No Yes No 86,744 0.535 (2) (3) (4) 0.057∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 11.284∗ ∗ ∗ (0.23) 4.150∗ ∗ ∗ (0.60) −0.061∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) −0.031∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) −4.603∗ ∗ ∗ (0.36) 8.055∗ ∗ ∗ (0.99) Yes Yes No No Yes 220,188 0.676 0.021∗ ∗ (0.01) 8.798∗ ∗ ∗ (0.18) 5.298∗ ∗ ∗ (0.44) −0.032 (0.12) −0.019∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) −0.531∗ ∗ (0.26) 3.759∗ ∗ ∗ (0.72) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes 220,188 0.960 0.022∗ ∗ (0.01) 8.790∗ ∗ ∗ (0.18) 5.323∗ ∗ ∗ (0.44) −0.013∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) −0.019∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) −0.533∗ ∗ (0.26) 3.759∗ ∗ ∗ (0.72) Yes No Yes Yes Yes 220,260 0.960 (2) (3) 0.005 (0.01) 6.522∗ ∗ ∗ (0.25) 8.881∗ ∗ ∗ (0.63) Yes No No Yes 86,744 0.746 −0.057∗ ∗ ∗ (0.02) 8.327∗ ∗ ∗ (0.22) 5.167∗ ∗ ∗ (0.52) Yes Yes Yes Yes 86,744 0.972 Note: Panel A of this table presents the results of multivariate OLS regression model (i.e., Eq. (3)) examining the interactive effects of bank capital and liquidity creation on the insolvency risk of individual banks during the crisis and non-crisis periods. Bank liquidity creation is proxied by the BB measure, i.e., catfat. Change in Bank Capital (࢞cai,t ) is the absolute change from the year t-1 to t of bank i’s equity-to-total assets ratio. z-score measures the distance from insolvency. A higher z-score value indicates that a bank is less likely to default. crisisdummy is a dummy variable equal to one during 20 07:Q3-20 09:Q4, and zero otherwise. The key explanatory variable is the triple interaction term catfat × ࢞ca × crisisdummy. Panel B presents the results based on the pre-crisis data only to address the concern that our results may be driven by the crisis period and beyond. The variable descriptions are in Appendix 1. Robust standard errors clustered by bank are in parentheses. ∗ , ∗ ∗ , and ∗ ∗ ∗ represent significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% level, respectively. the coefficient of the interaction terms, catfat × ࢞ca, is still positive and statistically significant at the 1% level, even when the crisis and post-crisis periods are excluded, alleviating the concern. 4.2.3. Alternative measures of bank failure risk While we focus on examining the z-score of individual banks as a measure of a bank’s insolvency risk, the results are robust to using alternative bank failure risk measures. In this section, we use a binary performance variable as a proxy for bank failure risk. First, we use quarterly data to predict whether a bank will fail in the next 1, 2 and 3 quarters (short-term horizon), and in the next 8, 12 and 20 quarters (long-term horizon) after a specific financial report date (faildummyq). If failure occurs, it is flagged as “bad” and is assigned the value of one. Otherwise, it is flagged as “good” and is assigned the value of zero. Second, we use end-of-year data to predict whether a bank will fail sometime in the next 1, 2, 3 and 5 years after a specific financial report date (faildummyy). Note that these two measures are related to bank failure risk positively while z-score is related to bank failure risk negatively. Results in Panels A and B, Table 5, corroborate those obtained in Table 2, and do not change our main conclusion that incremental increases in bank capital strengthen the negative relationship between liquidity creation and failure risk. Across all specifications, the Liquidity Creation variable (catfat) enters a negative and statistically significant coefficient, suggesting liquidity creation is related to bank failure risk negatively. The coefficient of the interaction term, catfat × ࢞ca, is again statistically significant and negative, regardless of whether the bank failure risk dummy is measured in terms of faildummyq or faildummyy. In Panels A and B, we estimate the regression model using OLS specification, thereby, imposing a linear probability model on the binary choice dependent variable, rather than the more commonlyused logit form.8 Nonetheless, to check the robustness of our re- 8 We do so for three reasons. First, the logit model suffers incidental parameter bias and inconsistent estimation problems if fixed effects are included. That is, the inclusion of fixed effects in a logit specification would cause the number of parameters to grow with the number of observations, meaning that the parameter estimates cannot converge to their true value as the sample size increases, yielding biased parameter and standard error estimates (Berger et al., 2017a). Second, our focus is to find out what variables are useful in explaining bank failure, rather than in forecasting the predicted values of bank failure. As such, the issue of whether the predicted values may go beyond zero and one is not our concern. Third, the key variable of interest is the interaction term between changes in bank capital and liquidity creation. In linear regressions, any interaction effect is fully captured by the C. Zheng, A. (Wai Kong) Cheung and T. Cronje / Journal of Banking and Finance 108 (2019) 105651 11 Table 5 Alternative measures of bank failure risk. Panel A: Quarterly data for bank failure risk dummy Dependent variable: faildummyq Variables (1) Next 1 quarter (2) Next 2 quarters catfat ࢞ca catfat × ࢞ca Baseline Controls Year_quarter FE Bank FE State FE Observations Adjusted R2 −0.008∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) −0.210∗ ∗ ∗ (0.03) −0.169∗ ∗ ∗ (0.06) Yes Yes Yes Yes 221,159 0.086 −0.012∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) −0.295∗ ∗ ∗ (0.03) −0.205∗ ∗ ∗ (0.07) Yes Yes Yes Yes 221,159 0.129 (3) Next 3 quarters (4) Next 8 quarters (5) Next 12 quarters (6) Next 20 quarters −0.012∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) −0.295∗ ∗ ∗ (0.03) −0.205∗ ∗ ∗ (0.07) Yes Yes Yes Yes 221,159 0.129 −0.094∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) −0.855∗ ∗ ∗ (0.08) −1.751∗ ∗ ∗ (0.22) Yes Yes Yes Yes 221,159 0.398 −0.105∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) −0.729∗ ∗ ∗ (0.08) −1.459∗ ∗ ∗ (0.22) Yes Yes Yes Yes 221,159 0.514 −0.074∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) −0.423∗ ∗ ∗ (0.07) −0.707∗ ∗ ∗ (0.18) Yes Yes Yes Yes 221,159 0.741 Panel B: End-of-year data for bank failure risk dummy Dependent variable: faildummyy Variables (1) next 1 year (2) next 2 years catfat ࢞ca catfat × ࢞ca Baseline Controls Year_quarter FE Bank FE State FE Observations Adjusted R2 −0.049∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) −1.090∗ ∗ ∗ (0.11) −0.493∗ (0.28) Yes Yes Yes Yes 73,233 0.284 −0.087∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) −1.299∗ ∗ ∗ (0.14) −1.642∗ ∗ ∗ (0.38) Yes Yes Yes Yes 73,233 0.419 Panel C: Results of nonlinear (logit) model Dependent variable: faildummyq Variables (1) All banks (2) Small banks catfat ࢞ca catfat × ࢞ca Baseline Controls Year_quarter FE Bank FE State FE Observations Pseudo R2 ∗∗∗ −0.007 (0.00) −0.305∗ ∗ ∗ (0.03) −0.145∗ (0.09) Yes No No No 221,159 0.586 ∗∗∗ −0.006 (0.00) −0.281∗ ∗ ∗ (0.03) −0.146∗ (0.09) Yes No No No 203,657 0.593 (3) next 3 years (4) next 5 years −0.102∗ ∗ ∗ (0.02) −1.197∗ ∗ ∗ (0.13) −1.420∗ ∗ ∗ (0.37) Yes Yes Yes Yes 73,233 0.532 −0.070∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) −0.680∗ ∗ ∗ (0.09) −0.636∗ ∗ ∗ (0.29) Yes Yes Yes Yes 73,233 0.761 (3) Medium banks (4) Large banks −0.015 (0.01) −0.515∗ ∗ (0.22) −0.482 (0.52) Yes No No No 10,993 0.560 −0.024∗ ∗ (0.01) −0.526∗ ∗ ∗ (0.16) 0.275 (0.38) Yes No No No 6509 0.602 Note: This table presents the results of multivariate regression model (i.e., Eq. (2)) in which the dependent variable is alternative measures of Bank Failure Risk. In Panel A, we use quarterly data to predict whether a bank will fail in the next 1, 2 and 3 quarters (short-term horizon), and in the next 8, 12 and 20 quarters (long-term horizon) after a specific financial report date (faildummyq). If failure occurs, it is flagged as “bad” and is assigned the binary value of one. Otherwise, it is flagged as “good” and is assigned the binary value of zero. In Panel B, we use end-of-year data to predict whether a bank will fail sometime in the next 1, 2, 3 and 5 years after a specific financial report date (faildummyy). Panel C uses a logit specification instead of OLS and shows marginal effects for all banks and for different sizes of banks. Large banks, medium banks, and small banks are banks with more than $3 billion, between $3 billion and $1 billon, and less than $1 billion gross total asset (GTA), respectively. Bank liquidity creation is proxied by the BB measure, i.e., catfat. Change in bank capital (࢞cai,t ) is the absolute change from the year t-1 to t of bank i’s equity-to-total assets ratio. The variable descriptions are in Appendix 1. Robust standard errors clustered by bank are in parentheses. ∗ , ∗ ∗ , and ∗ ∗ ∗ represent significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% level, respectively. sults, we use the logit regression framework that includes all the control variables from the baseline OLS specification. However, fixed effects are excluded to avoid incidental parameter bias. Following the methodology developed by Norton et al. (2004), we compute marginal effects and standard errors for the nonlinear model to ensure correct inferences, and report the results in Panel C. Column (1) shows that for the full sample, the marginal effect of coefficient on the interaction term. However, this does not carry over in nonlinear models such as the logit model. The literature on the interpretation of interaction term coefficients in logit (i.e. non-linear) regression estimations tells us that the statistical significance of the coefficient as well as its sign and magnitude cannot be interpreted in the same way as the coefficient of a linear regression (Norton et al., 2004). Instead, the direction of influence, as well as the significance of the interaction term, might vary across different observations. the interaction term, catfat × ࢞ca, remains negative and significant, albeit much smaller in magnitude. In Columns (2)–(4), we sort the sample banks into large, medium, and small banks, and again find that the interaction effect of bank liquidity creation and changes in bank capital is significant for small banks, but insignificant in the medium and large bank subsamples. 4.2.4. Alternative measures of bank liquidity creation In this section, we use alternative measures of liquidity creation to check the robustness of our results presented earlier. First, we create yearly-deciles of liquidity creation by recoding the BB measure (catfat) each year in ten categories labelled from 1 (lowest decile) to 10 (highest decile). The results in Panel A of Table 6 show positive, statistically significant coefficients of catfatdecile and the 12 C. Zheng, A. (Wai Kong) Cheung and T. Cronje / Journal of Banking and Finance 108 (2019) 105651 Table 6 Alternative measures of bank liquidity creation. Panel A: Yearly-deciles of liquidity creation Dependent variable: z-score Variables (1) (2) catfatdecile ࢞ca catfatdecile × ࢞ca Bank Controls Other Controls Year_quarter FE Bank FE State FE Observations Adjusted R2 0.001∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) 8.556∗ ∗ ∗ (0.16) 0.373∗ ∗ ∗ (0.02) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes 220,188 0.959 0.001∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) 8.548∗ ∗ ∗ (0.16) 0.374∗ ∗ ∗ (0.02) Yes No Yes Yes Yes 220,260 0.959 Panel B: Sub-components of liquidity creation Dependent variable: z-score Variables (1) (2) (3) (4) ∗∗∗ lc_offbal 0.257 (0.02) −0.133∗ ∗ ∗ (0.02) lc_a 0.074∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) lc_l −0.022∗ ∗ (0.01) 8.672∗ ∗ ∗ (0.16) lc_onbal 10.411∗ ∗ ∗ (0.14) 2.001 (1.62) ࢞ca lc_offbal × ࢞ca 10.061∗ ∗ ∗ (0.10) 8.893∗ ∗ ∗ (0.22) 6.299∗ ∗ ∗ (0.44) lc_a × ࢞ca 10.664∗ ∗ ∗ (1.01) lc_l × ࢞ca 8.316∗ ∗ ∗ (0.45) Yes Yes Yes Yes 220,188 0.960 lc_onbal × ࢞ca Baseline Controls Year_quarter FE Bank FE State FE Observations Adjusted R2 Yes Yes Yes Yes 220,188 0.959 Yes Yes Yes Yes 220,188 0.959 Panel C: High, medium and low liquidity creators Dependent variable: z-score 5th and 95th percentile (1) High liqu- (2) Medium liq- (3) Low liquVariables idity creators uidity creators idity creators catfat ࢞ca catfat × ࢞ca Baseline Controls Year_quarter FE Bank FE State FE Observations Adjusted R2 Yes Yes Yes Yes 220,188 0.959 15th and 85th percentile (4) High liqu- (5) Medium liq- (6) Low liquuidity creators idity creators idity creators 25th and 75th percentile (7) High liqu- (8) Medium liqidity creators uidity creators (9) Low liquidity creators −0.001 (0.04) 12.289∗ ∗ ∗ (2.50) −3.714 (3.65) Yes 0.036∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 9.096∗ ∗ ∗ (0.15) 6.037∗ ∗ ∗ (0.41) Yes −0.050 (0.06) 9.144∗ ∗ ∗ (0.52) 24.570∗ ∗ ∗ (5.15) Yes 0.036 (0.02) 11.836∗ ∗ ∗ (1.00) −2.113 (1.69) Yes 0.044∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 8.879∗ ∗ ∗ (0.22) 7.233∗ ∗ ∗ (0.63) Yes −0.018 (0.03) 8.461∗ ∗ ∗ (0.26) 16.094∗ ∗ ∗ (2.03) Yes 0.036∗ (0.02) 10.987∗ ∗ ∗ (0.66) −0.074 (1.20) Yes 0.062∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 8.686∗ ∗ ∗ (0.34) 8.136∗ ∗ ∗ (1.00) Yes −0.029 (0.02) 8.260∗ ∗ ∗ (0.23) 13.812∗ ∗ ∗ (1.36) Yes Yes Yes Yes 11,275 0.952 Yes Yes Yes 198,377 0.960 Yes Yes Yes 10,536 0.973 Yes Yes Yes 33,763 0.952 Yes Yes Yes 154,311 0.961 Yes Yes Yes 32,114 0.973 Yes Yes Yes 56,123 0.952 Yes Yes Yes 110,208 0.961 Yes Yes Yes 53,857 0.973 Note: Panel A of this Table presents coefficient estimates from regressions of z-score on the interaction term between yearly-deciles of liquidity creation and changes in bank capital. We create yearly-deciles of liquidity creation, i.e., catfatdecile, by recoding the BB measure into categorical ones. Panel B presents coefficient estimates from regressions of z-score on the interaction terms between components of liquidity creation measures, which are off-balance sheet liquidity creation (lc_offbal) in Column (1), asset-side liquidity creation (lc_a) in Column (2), liability-side liquidity creation (lc_l) in Column (3), and on-balance sheet liquidity creation (lc_onbal) in Column (4), and changes in bank capital. Panel C of this table reports coefficient estimates from regressions of z-score on the interaction term between bank liquidity creation and changes in bank capital by liquidity creation levels. In Columns (1)–(3), high liquidity creators are those banks in the 95th percentile, medium liquidity creators are banks between the 95th and the 5th percentile, and low liquidity creators are banks in the 5th percentile of the BB measure. In Columns (4)–(6), high liquidity category includes banks in the 85th percentile, medium liquidity category includes banks between the 85th and the 15th percentile, and low liquidity category includes banks in the 15th percentile of the BB measure. In Columns (7)–(9), high liquidity creators are those banks in the 75th percentile, medium liquidity creators are banks between the 75th and the 25th percentile, and low liquidity creators are banks in the 25th percentile of the BB measure. Bank liquidity creation is proxied by the BB measure, i.e., catfat. Change in bank capital (࢞cai,t ) is the absolute change from the year t-1 to t of bank i’s equity-to-total assets ratio. z-score measures the distance from insolvency. A higher z-score value indicates that a bank is less likely to default. The variable descriptions are in Appendix 1. Robust standard errors clustered by bank are in parentheses. ∗ , ∗ ∗ , and ∗ ∗ ∗ represent significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% level, respectively. C. Zheng, A. (Wai Kong) Cheung and T. Cronje / Journal of Banking and Finance 108 (2019) 105651 13 Table 7 Alternative measures of bank capital. Variables catfat ࢞ca catfat × ࢞ca Bank Controls Other Controls Year_quarter FE Bank FE State FE Observations Adjusted R2 Dependent variable: z-score (1) (2) Tier 1 risk-based Tier 1 risk-based (3) Total risk-based (4) Total risk-based (5) Leverage (6) Leverage 0.077∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 2.523∗ ∗ ∗ (0.07) 7.596∗ ∗ ∗ (0.20) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes 220,188 0.938 0.074∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 2.451∗ ∗ ∗ (0.07) 7.221∗ ∗ ∗ (0.20) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes 220,188 0.937 0.075∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 2.444∗ ∗ ∗ (0.07) 7.230∗ ∗ ∗ (0.20) Yes No Yes Yes Yes 220,260 0.937 −0.010 (0.01) 7.262∗ ∗ ∗ (0.18) 6.472∗ ∗ ∗ (0.44) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes 220,188 0.944 −0.009 (0.01) 7.240∗ ∗ ∗ (0.18) 6.516∗ ∗ ∗ (0.44) Yes No Yes Yes Yes 220,260 0.944 0.078∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 2.517∗ ∗ ∗ (0.07) 7.605∗ ∗ ∗ (0.20) Yes No Yes Yes Yes 220,260 0.938 Note: This table presents coefficient estimates from regressions of z-score on the interaction term between bank liquidity creation and changes in bank capital by replacing the equity-to-total assets ratio with three traditional regulatory capital ratios. They are the total risk-based capital ratio, the tier 1 risk-based capital ratio, and the leverage ratio. The total risk-based capital ratio is measured as core capital (tier 1) plus supplementary capital (tier 2) over risk-weighted assets. The tier 1 risk-based capital ratio includes only core capital in the numerator, which is divided by risk-weighted assets. The leverage ratio is calculated by dividing core capital (tier 1) by total average assets rather than risk-weighted assets. Bank liquidity creation is proxied by the BB measure, i.e., catfat. Change in bank capital (࢞cai,t ) is the absolute change from the year t-1 to t of bank i’s three regulatory capital ratios, respectively. z-score measures the distance from insolvency. A higher z-score value indicates that a bank is less likely to default. The variable descriptions are in Appendix 1. Robust standard errors clustered by bank are in parentheses. ∗ , ∗ ∗ , and ∗ ∗ ∗ represent significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% level, respectively. interaction term catfatdecile × ࢞ca, and, thus, are congruent with our main findings. Second, we use four sub-components of liquidity creation: off-balance sheet-side (lc_offbal), asset-side (lc_a), and liability-side (lc_l) liquidity creation, and on-balance sheet liquidity creation (lc_onbal); to check whether our main results still hold in different components of bank liquidity creation. Panel B displays the results from a regression of z-score on the interaction terms between components of liquidity creation and changes in bank capital. The coefficient of the liability-side liquidity creation component is positive and statistically significant. Further, the coefficient of the interaction term remains statistically significant and positive for the liability-side liquidity creation component. This suggests that liability-side liquidity creation is the driving force behind our findings. Third, we examine whether the interaction effect of bank liquidity creation and changes in bank capital varies with the liquidity creation levels of banks. We divide banks into “high liquidity creators”, “medium liquidity creators” and “low liquidity creators” subsamples. Following the categorization of high and low liquidity creators in Díaz and Huang (2017), we define high, medium, and low liquidity creators as those in the top 25% (75th percentile), between top 25% (75th percentile) and bottom 25% (25th percentile), and bottom 25% (25th percentile) of the BB measure (catfat) each year, respectively. We also use two alternative cut-offs, i.e., 15% and 85%; and 5% and 95%, to examine the sensitivity of our results to an alternative bank classification method. As the results in Panel C of Table 6 show, the coefficient of the Liquidity Creation variable (catfat) is insignificant for the categories of high and low liquidity creators, but it is positive and highly significant for medium liquidity creators. More importantly, we find that the coefficient of the interaction term, catfat × ࢞ca, is again statistically significant and positive for medium liquidity creators, and the effect is comparable in magnitude to that shown in Table 2. This result suggests that the interaction effect on failure risk between bank liquidity creation and changes in bank capital is even more pronounced for medium liquidity creators. One possible explanation for the result is that medium liquidity creation banks are likely to be those in the small bank subsample, because most of the sample banks fall into the category of medium liquidity creators, while Table 3 shows that the majority of the banks in our sample are small banks. These banks may strengthen their capital buffer to ab- sorb the illiquidity risk associated with liquidity creation. Increased capital buffer would, in turn, reduce the probability of bank failure and improve banks’ ability to create liquidity. 4.2.5. Alternative measures of bank capital In our main analysis, we use the ratio of equity capital to total assets (ca), as our measure of bank capital. To examine whether our results are robust to an alternative definition of bank capital, we also measure bank capital using three traditional regulatory capital ratios: the total risk-based capital ratio, the tier 1 risk-based capital ratio, and the leverage ratio. The total risk-based capital ratio is measured as core capital (tier 1) plus supplementary capital (tier 2) over risk-weighted assets. The tier 1 risk-based capital ratio includes only core capital in the numerator, which is divided by risk-weighted assets. The leverage ratio is calculated by dividing core capital (tier 1) by total average assets, rather than riskweighted assets. The empirical results where the ratio of equity capital to total assets is replaced by regulatory capital ratios are presented in Table 7. Table 7 shows that the coefficients of catfat and the interaction term, catfat × ࢞ca, are positive and statistically significant at the 1% level in four of the six specifications, while their magnitudes are similar to those in the baseline findings in Table 2. Hence, our main results are reinforced. 4.2.6. The role of managerial ability Andreou et al. (2016) investigate the impact of managerial ability on bank liquidity creation and bank risk-taking behavior as prior literature has revealed that managerial ability is an important factor in terms of influencing firm performance (Demerjian et al., 2012). They find that higher ability managers create more liquidity and take more risk, yet during times of financial crisis, higher ability bank managers reduce liquidity creation as a way to deleverage their balance sheets. It is thus worth considering whether our main results persist in the presence of managerial ability, and whether they are driven/moderated by high ability managers.9 Following Andreou et al. (2016), we estimate managerial ability measure in two steps. The first step is to compute bank profit efficiency score using stochastic frontier analysis (SFA). Since this measure 9 We are grateful to an anonymous reviewer for suggesting this point. 14 C. Zheng, A. (Wai Kong) Cheung and T. Cronje / Journal of Banking and Finance 108 (2019) 105651 Table 8 Results of OLS estimates for models with managerial ability variable. Panel A: Baseline OLS regression in the presence of managerial ability Dependent variable: z-score Variables (1) (2) (3) catfat ࢞ca catfat × ࢞ca ma 0.142∗ ∗ ∗ (0.02) 11.626∗ ∗ ∗ (0.26) 4.050∗ ∗ ∗ (0.67) −2.235∗ ∗ ∗ (0.43) 0.142∗ ∗ ∗ (0.02) 11.637∗ ∗ ∗ (0.26) 4.028∗ ∗ ∗ (0.67) −2.221∗ ∗ ∗ (0.43) 0.036∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 9.497∗ ∗ ∗ (0.18) 5.045∗ ∗ ∗ (0.45) −2.000∗ ∗ ∗ (0.25) madecile (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) 0.141∗ ∗ ∗ (0.02) 11.636∗ ∗ ∗ (0.26) 4.054∗ ∗ ∗ (0.67) 0.142∗ ∗ ∗ (0.02) 11.648∗ ∗ ∗ (0.26) 4.031∗ ∗ ∗ (0.67) 0.037∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 9.484∗ ∗ ∗ (0.18) 5.056∗ ∗ ∗ (0.45) 0.073∗ ∗ ∗ (0.02) 10.040∗ ∗ ∗ (0.24) 4.816∗ ∗ ∗ (0.69) 0.973 (0.73) 0.073∗ ∗ ∗ (0.02) 10.040∗ ∗ ∗ (0.24) 4.817∗ ∗ ∗ (0.69) −0.003∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) −0.003∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) −0.001∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) crisisdummy 0.083 (0.20) −0.548 (0.34) ma × crisisdummy madecile × crisisdummy Bank-specific characteristics: ca 8.870∗ ∗ ∗ (0.07) aq −3.600∗ ∗ ∗ (0.10) mc −0.655∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) roe −1.235∗ ∗ ∗ (0.05) liq −0.022 (0.02) ltdrt −0.198∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) noniirt 0.006∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) ristak −0.071∗ ∗ ∗ (0.02) commre 0.016∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) lndep 0.001 (0.00) Macroeconomic characteristics: fedfunds 0.054∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) spread 0.056∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) lngdp −0.260∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) lngpsave 0.075∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) Local economic characteristics: hhi_dep −0.002 (0.00) lnpop 0.058∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) sloos −0.000∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) lnperinc 0.220∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) lnemploy −0.066∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) Constant 1.880∗ ∗ ∗ (0.07) Year_quarter FE No Bank FE Yes State FE No Observations 154,882 2 0.435 Adjusted R 0.001 (0.00) 0.084 (0.20) −0.000∗ (0.00) 8.874∗ ∗ ∗ (0.07) −3.600∗ ∗ ∗ (0.10) −0.656∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) −1.236∗ ∗ ∗ (0.05) −0.022 (0.02) −0.198∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 0.006∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) −0.072∗ ∗ ∗ (0.02) 0.016∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 0.001 (0.00) 8.437∗ ∗ ∗ (0.06) −0.024 (0.03) −0.115∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 0.939∗ ∗ ∗ (0.02) −0.053∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) −0.021∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 0.001∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) 0.057∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) −0.001 (0.00) −0.000 (0.00) 8.872∗ ∗ ∗ (0.07) −3.602∗ ∗ ∗ (0.10) −0.654∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) −1.235∗ ∗ ∗ (0.05) −0.023 (0.02) −0.199∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 0.006∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) −0.070∗ ∗ ∗ (0.02) 0.016∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 0.001 (0.00) 8.876∗ ∗ ∗ (0.07) −3.601∗ ∗ ∗ (0.10) −0.655∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) −1.235∗ ∗ ∗ (0.05) −0.023 (0.02) −0.198∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 0.006∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) −0.071∗ ∗ ∗ (0.02) 0.016∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 0.001 (0.00) 8.437∗ ∗ ∗ (0.06) −0.024 (0.03) −0.117∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 0.937∗ ∗ ∗ (0.02) −0.051∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) −0.021∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 0.001∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) 0.056∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) −0.001 (0.00) −0.000 (0.00) 8.564∗ ∗ ∗ (0.11) −0.030 (0.04) −0.133∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 0.871∗ ∗ ∗ (0.02) −0.050∗ ∗ ∗ (0.02) −0.019 (0.01) 0.001∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) 0.023 (0.02) −0.004 (0.00) 0.000 (0.00) 8.564∗ ∗ ∗ (0.16) −0.030 (0.04) −0.133∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 0.871∗ ∗ ∗ (0.02) −0.050∗ ∗ ∗ (0.02) −0.019 (0.01) 0.001∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) 0.023 (0.02) −0.004 (0.00) 0.000 (0.00) 0.054∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) 0.056∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) −0.262∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 0.075∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) −0.092 (0.07) 0.064∗ (0.03) 1.147∗ (0.62) 0.185 (0.18) 0.054∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) 0.056∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) −0.260∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 0.074∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 0.054∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) 0.056∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) −0.261∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 0.075∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) −0.092 (0.07) 0.064∗ (0.03) 1.154∗ (0.62) 0.176 (0.18) 0.020 (0.02) 0.086∗ (0.05) 1.579 (1.12) 0.278 (0.25) 0.019 (0.02) 0.086∗ (0.05) 1.575 (1.12) 0.278 (0.25) −0.002 (0.00) 0.057∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) −0.000∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) 0.221∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) −0.065∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 1.804∗ ∗ ∗ (0.07) No Yes Yes 154,882 0.435 −0.001 (0.00) −0.005 (0.00) −0.001∗ ∗ (0.00) 0.013∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) 0.004 (0.00) −11.402∗ (6.76) Yes Yes Yes 154,882 0.962 −0.002 (0.00) 0.058∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) −0.000∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) 0.220∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) −0.065∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 1.892∗ ∗ ∗ (0.07) No Yes No 154,882 0.435 −0.002 (0.00) 0.057∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) −0.000∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) 0.221∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) −0.065∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 1.814∗ ∗ ∗ (0.07) No Yes Yes 154,882 0.435 −0.001 (0.00) −0.005 (0.00) −0.001∗ ∗ (0.00) 0.013∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) 0.004 (0.00) −11.387∗ (6.77) Yes Yes Yes 154,882 0.962 −0.000 (0.00) −0.005 (0.00) −0.002∗ ∗ (0.00) 0.012∗ ∗ (0.01) 0.005 (0.00) −16.443 (12.38) Yes Yes Yes 86,161 0.961 −0.000 (0.00) −0.005 (0.00) −0.002∗ ∗ (0.00) 0.012∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 0.005 (0.00) −16.405 (12.37) Yes Yes Yes 86,161 0.961 (continued on next page) C. Zheng, A. (Wai Kong) Cheung and T. Cronje / Journal of Banking and Finance 108 (2019) 105651 15 Table 8 (continued) Panel B: Baseline OLS regression in the presence of managerial ability by bank size Dependent variable: z-score (1) (2) (3) (4) Variables catfat Small banks 0.056∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 9.722∗ ∗ ∗ (0.18) 4.962∗ ∗ ∗ (0.44) −1.474∗ ∗ ∗ (0.23) ࢞ca catfat × ࢞ca ma Medium banks −0.009 (0.05) 9.735∗ ∗ ∗ (1.38) 3.876 (3.15) −4.769∗ ∗ ∗ (1.33) Large banks 0.044 (0.07) 10.961∗ ∗ ∗ (1.02) 0.435 (2.20) −6.657∗ ∗ ∗ (1.68) madecile Year_quarter FE Bank FE State FE Observations Adjusted R2 Yes Yes Yes 138,588 0.970 Yes Yes Yes 10,319 0.915 Yes Yes Yes 5975 0.932 (5) (6) Small banks 0.058∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 9.712∗ ∗ ∗ (0.18) 4.966∗ ∗ ∗ (0.44) Medium banks −0.007 (0.05) 9.728∗ ∗ ∗ (1.38) 3.887 (3.17) Large banks 0.055 (0.07) 10.958∗ ∗ ∗ (1.06) 0.533 (2.27) −0.001∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) Yes Yes Yes 138,588 0.970 −0.004∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) Yes Yes Yes 10,319 0.915 −0.004∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) Yes Yes Yes 5975 0.931 Panel C: Interaction effect of liquidity creation, bank capital and managerial ability on failure risk Dependent variable: z-score Variables (1) (2) (3) (4) ∗∗∗ catfat 0.144 (0.02) 11.736∗ ∗ ∗ (0.26) 3.642∗ ∗ ∗ (0.66) −5.184∗ ∗ ∗ (0.99) ࢞ca catfat × ࢞ca ma ∗∗∗ 0.144 (0.02) 11.747∗ ∗ ∗ (0.26) 3.621∗ ∗ ∗ (0.66) −5.161∗ ∗ ∗ (0.99) ∗∗∗ 0.037 (0.01) 9.529∗ ∗ ∗ (0.17) 4.890∗ ∗ ∗ (0.44) −0.480 (0.56) madecile −3.625∗ ∗ ∗ (0.76) ma × ࢞ca −3.599∗ ∗ ∗ (0.75) 8.061∗ ∗ ∗ (2.73) 8.037∗ ∗ ∗ (2.74) 3.872∗ (2.06) 3.798∗ (2.06) No Yes No 154,882 0.435 No Yes Yes 154,882 0.436 0.092 (0.02) 13.638∗ ∗ ∗ (0.50) 0.983 (1.33) 0.093 (0.02) 13.633∗ ∗ ∗ (0.50) 1.010 (1.33) 0.054∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 9.817∗ ∗ ∗ (0.33) 4.703∗ ∗ ∗ (0.93) −0.006∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) −0.006∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) −0.000 (0.00) −0.340∗ ∗ ∗ (0.08) −0.337∗ ∗ ∗ (0.08) −0.058 (0.05) 0.009∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) 0.009∗ ∗ ∗ (0.00) −0.003∗ ∗ (0.00) 0.495∗ ∗ (0.22) No Yes No 154,882 0.435 0.486∗ ∗ (0.22) No Yes Yes 154,882 0.435 0.055 (0.15) Yes Yes Yes 154,882 0.962 0.341 (1.50) catfat × madecile × ࢞ca Year_quarter FE Bank FE State FE Observations Adjusted R2 (6) ∗∗∗ −4.568∗ ∗ ∗ (1.67) catfat × madecile catfat × ma × ࢞ca (5) −1.129∗ ∗ (0.53) madecile × ࢞ca catfat × ma ∗∗∗ Yes Yes Yes 154,882 0.962 Panel D: Interaction effect of liquidity creation, bank capital and managerial ability on failure risk – high, medium and low liquidity creators Dependent variable: z-score 5th and 95th percentile 15th and 85th percentile 25th and 75th percentile (9) (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) Variables catfat ࢞ca catfat × ࢞ca ma catfat × ma ma × ࢞ca High liquidity creators 0.113 (0.09) 17.816∗ ∗ ∗ (3.33) −18.066∗ ∗ (8.75) 4.604 (4.66) −19.348 (11.81) −16.282∗ ∗ ∗ (5.64) Medium liquidity creators 0.047∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 9.655∗ ∗ ∗ (0.17) 4.180∗ ∗ ∗ (0.43) −0.256 (0.50) −0.749 (1.32) 1.343∗ (0.73) Low liquidity creators −0.133 (0.10) 4.578 (2.89) 2.103 (7.78) −1.529 (3.88) −14.028 (10.02) −5.808 (4.45) High liquidity creators 0.049 (0.03) 11.781∗ ∗ ∗ (1.21) −2.075 (3.35) −0.267 (1.82) −5.382 (5.10) −5.763∗ ∗ (2.65) Medium liquidity creators 0.057∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) 9.944∗ ∗ ∗ (0.18) 3.614∗ ∗ ∗ (0.46) 0.138 (0.60) −1.084 (1.62) 0.152 (1.04) Low liquidity creators −0.043 (0.04) 5.352∗ ∗ ∗ (1.12) 6.695∗ ∗ (3.05) −1.666 (1.89) −7.900∗ (4.75) −6.520∗ ∗ ∗ (2.21) High liquidity creators 0.036 (0.02) 10.935∗ ∗ ∗ (0.76) 0.894 (2.06) −0.177 (1.28) −2.287 (3.52) −3.923∗ ∗ (2.00) Medium liquidity creators 0.063∗ ∗ ∗ (0.02) 10.017∗ ∗ ∗ (0.22) 3.444∗ ∗ ∗ (0.55) 1.286 (0.82) −3.986∗ (2.26) 0.339 (1.98) (continued Low liquidity creators −0.011 (0.03) 7.773∗ ∗ ∗ (0.67) 3.733∗ (1.93) −1.020 (1.35) −7.046∗ ∗ (3.48) −3.157∗ ∗ (1.61) on next page) 16 C. Zheng, A. (Wai Kong) Cheung and T. Cronje / Journal of Banking and Finance 108 (2019) 105651 Table 8 (continued) Panel C: High, medium and low liquidity creators Dependent variable: z-score 5th and 95th percentile catfat × ma × ࢞ca Year_quarter FE Bank FE State FE Observations Adjusted R2 42.178∗ ∗ ∗ (15.28) Yes Yes Yes 7731 0.965 −1.106 (2.07) Yes Yes Yes 139,168 0.967 15th and 85th percentile −4.395 (11.62) Yes Yes Yes 7983 0.961 15.935∗ ∗ (7.52) Yes Yes Yes 23,616 0.964 3.483 (3.09) Yes Yes Yes 108,007 0.970 25th and 75th percentile 2.033 (5.94) Yes Yes Yes 23,259 0.961 10.780∗ (5.70) Yes Yes Yes 39,383 0.965 5.640 (5.68) Yes Yes Yes 77,018 0.971 −3.134 (4.48) Yes Yes Yes 38,481 0.962 Note: This table presents the OLS regression results in the presence of managerial ability. In Panel A, Columns (1)–(3), managerial ability (ma) is included as an additional variable in our baseline OLS regression model. Following Andreou et al. (2016), we use Stochastic Frontier Analysis (SFA) to obtain bank profit efficiency score, and regress the score on a set of bank-specific variables. The residual from this regression is part of efficiency score that cannot be explained by bank-specific factors and hence should be attributed to management ability. We also create yearly-deciles of managerial ability (madecile) by recoding managerial ability measure (ma) each year into ten categorical ones labelled from 1 (lowest decile) to 10 (highest decile) in Panel A, Columns (4)–(6). Columns (7) and (8) of Panel A show the results during the financial crisis period. We split the sample into small, medium, and large banks, and perform our analyses separately for these three sets of banks in Panel B. Small banks have GTA up to $1 billion, medium banks have GTA exceeding $1 billion and up to $3 billon, and large banks have GTA exceeding $3 billion. To examine whether our main results are driven/moderated by managerial ability, we include a triple interaction term (catfat × ma × ࢞ca and catfat × madecile × ࢞ca) in the regression model in Panel C, and further separate banks into high, medium and low liquidity creators by their liquidity creation levels in Panel D. In Columns (1)–(3) of Panel D, high liquidity creators are those banks in the 95th percentile, medium liquidity creators are banks between the 95th and the 5th percentile, and low liquidity creators are banks in the 5th percentile of the BB measure. In Columns (4)–(6), high liquidity category includes banks in the 85th percentile, medium liquidity category includes banks between the 85th and the 15th percentile, and low liquidity category includes banks in the 15th percentile of the BB measure. In Columns (7)–(9), high liquidity creators are those banks in the 75th percentile, medium liquidity creators are banks between the 75th and the 25th percentile, and low liquidity creators are banks in the 25th percentile of the BB measure. Bank liquidity creation is proxied by the BB measure, i.e., catfat. Change in bank capital (࢞cai,t ) is the absolute change from the year t-1 to t of bank i’s equity-to-total assets ratio. z-score measures the distance from insolvency. A higher z-score value indicates that a bank is less likely to default. The variable descriptions are in Appendix 1. Regressions include different fixed effects (FE) estimations (Year_quarter FE, State FE and Bank FE). Robust standard errors clustered by bank are in parentheses. ∗ , ∗ ∗ , and ∗ ∗ ∗ represent significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% level, respectively. captures both bank-specific and manager-specific efficiency drivers, the second step is to disentangle managerial ability from bankspecific effects. To this end, we derive a measure of managerial ability as the residual from a Tobit regression of bank profit efficiency score on five bank-specific characteristics (i.e., bank size, number of full-time equivalent employees, bank age, leverage, and free cash flow) and year_quarter fixed effects. The sample for the managerial ability regressions contains 154,882 bank-year_quarter observations, representing a reduction of approximately 30%. Sample attrition in these regressions is primarily due to additional data requirements for constructing the managerial ability variables. The results of this analysis are presented in Table 8. First, managerial ability (ma) is included as an additional variable in our baseline OLS regression model (see Panel A, Columns (1)–(3)). We also create yearly-deciles of managerial ability (madecile) by recoding the managerial ability measure (ma) each year in ten categories labelled from 1 (lowest decile) to 10 (highest decile) (see Panel A, Columns (4)–(6)). Despite the smaller sample size, the coefficient of the interaction term, catfat × ࢞ca, remains positive and statistically significant. Furthermore, the magnitude of the estimate is comparable to that reported in Table 2. Perhaps most notably, we find that the estimated coefficients of the managerial ability variables (ma and madecile) are related to a bank’s z_score negatively, suggesting that more able managers can better manage, and in fact do take more risk, which is in line with the findings of Andreou et al. (2016). Second, two additional checks are conducted to see whether the empirical results for the whole sample period also hold during the financial crisis. We follow Andreou et al. (2016) and include the liquidity creation measure (catfat) for the crisis and post-crisis periods from 2007 to 2014; a bank’s pre-crisis managerial ability measures (ma and madecile) estimated in 2006; a crisis indicator variable (crisisdummy); and the interaction term between the indicator variable for the crisis period and the managerial ability measures (ma × crisisdummy and madecile × crisisdummy). As can be clearly seen from the two checks in Columns (7) and (8) of Panel A, the coefficient of our main variable of interest (catfat × ࢞ca) remains statistically significant and positive, although the effect of managerial ability becomes insignificant. Third, the sample is split into small, medium, and large banks, with separate analyses for these three sets of banks in Panel B. The small banks have GTA up to $1 billion, medium banks have GTA exceeding $1 billion and up to $3 billon, and large banks have GTA exceeding $3 billion. The results are qualitatively similar to the findings presented in Panel A of Table 3 and do not change our main conclusion that the impact of change in capital is the strongest for small banks. As expected, the coefficients of catfat and catfat × ࢞ca are positive and statistically significant for small banks whereas they are insignificant for medium and large banks. Again, we find a negative and statistically significant relation between managerial ability (ma and madecile) and a bank’s z_score, which is inversely related to bank risk taking. Fourth, to examine whether our main results are driven/moderated by managerial ability, we include a triple interaction term (catfat × ma × ࢞ca and catfat × madecile × ࢞ca) in the regression model. As can be seen from Panel C, the coefficient of the interaction term is positive but only weakly significant in four specifications that include bank fixed effects or bank and state fixed effects (see Columns (1), (2), (4) and (5)). However, the coefficient is not statistically significant in the regression model with time fixed effects (see Columns (3) and (6)), suggesting that managerial ability is largely a temporal effect (i.e., temporal change in ma and madecile) rather than a cross sectional effect (i.e., cross sectional heterogeneity in ma and madecile). Further, we separate banks into high, medium and low liquidity creators by their liquidity creation levels. As shown in Panel D, the coefficient of the triple interaction term catfat × ma × ࢞ca is large, positive, and statistically significant for high liquidity creators only. Overall, our main results remain qualitatively unchanged if we include managerial ability as an additional variable in our regression. However, we find limited evidence that the results are driven/moderated by managerial ability. C. Zheng, A. (Wai Kong) Cheung and T. Cronje / Journal of Banking and Finance 108 (2019) 105651 17 Table 9 Interaction effect of liquidity creation and bank capital on failure risk in a 2SLS setting. Panel A: The 2SLS regression results for all banks Variables First stage Dependent variable: Bank Liquidity Creation (catfat) (1) Second stage Dependent variable: z-score (2) 0.011∗ (0.01) 8.406∗ ∗ ∗ (0.26) 6.556∗ ∗ ∗ (0.64) catfat −0.086∗ ∗ ∗ (0.01) −0.602∗ ∗ ∗ (0.03) 0.977∗ ∗ ∗ ࢞ca catfat × ࢞ca catfat_average Baseline Controls Year_quarter FE Bank FE State FE Observations Adjusted R2 First Stage F-Test of Excluded Instrument Hausman Endogeneity Test (0.00) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes 220,188 0.987 F-stat = 2.0e + 05, p-value = 0.000 Yes Yes 220,188 0.923 F-stat = 396.84, p-value = 0.000 Panel B: The 2SLS regression results by bank size Dependent variable: z-score $1 billion and $3 billion size cutoff Variables (1) Small banks (2) Medium banks catfat ࢞ca catfat × ࢞ca Baseline Controls Year_quarter FE Bank FE State FE Observations Adjusted R2 0.013∗ (0.01) 8.468∗ ∗ ∗ (0.25) 6.590∗ ∗ ∗ (0.63) Yes Yes Yes Yes 202,698 0.931 0.023 (0.03) 8.432∗ ∗ ∗ (1.41) 9.805∗ ∗ ∗ (2.81) Yes Yes Yes Yes 10,489 0.909 (3) Large banks $1 billion and $5 billion size cutoff (4) Small banks (5) Medium banks (6) Large banks −0.039 (0.07) 11.191∗ ∗ ∗ (0.98) 0.079 (1.12) Yes Yes Yes Yes 6350 0.909 0.013∗ (0.01) 8.468∗ ∗ ∗ (0.25) 6.590∗ ∗ ∗ (0.63) Yes Yes Yes Yes 202,698 0.931 −0.067 (0.06) 11.313∗ ∗ ∗ (0.76) −0.348 (1.32) Yes Yes Yes Yes 4419 0.911 0.033 (0.02) 8.559∗ ∗ ∗ (1.26) 8.545∗ ∗ ∗ (2.19) Yes Yes Yes Yes 12,480 0.873 Note: This table presents the 2SLS regression results. The instrument variable for the BB measure is the eight-quarter lagged average values of bank liquidity creation (catfat_average). Panel A reports the results for the entire sample. In Column (1), the first-stage estimation is shown, using catfat_average as the instrument to obtain the predicted value of liquidity creation. In Column (2), we use the predicted value of liquidity creation from the first-stage to estimate the relationship between liquidity creation and failure risk. Panel B reports the results for different sizes of banks. In Columns (1)–(3), small banks, medium banks, and large banks are banks with less than $1 billion, between $1 billion and $3 billion, and more than $3 billion GTA. In Columns (4)–(6), small banks, medium banks, and large banks are banks with less than $1 billion, between $1 billion and $5 billion, and more than $5 billion GTA. Bank liquidity creation is proxied by the BB measure, i.e., catfat. Change in bank capital (࢞cai,t ) is the absolute change from the year t-1 to t of bank i’s equity-to-total assets ratio. Z-score measures the distance from insolvency. A higher z-score value indicates that a bank is less likely to default. The variable descriptions are in Appendix 1. Robust standard errors clustered by bank are in parentheses. ∗ , ∗ ∗ , and ∗ ∗ ∗ represent significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% level, respectively. 5. Controlling for endogeneity 5.1. Instrumental variable (IV) or two stage least squares method A potential endogeneity issue clouds the interpretation of our main results. For example, distressed banks may be aware of their unsound operations and may adjust their liquidity creation. To address this reverse-causality problem, our first identification strategy is an instrumental variable (IV) approach. In particular, eight-quarter lagged average values of bank liquidity creation (catfat_average) are used as the instrumental variable, since lagged values are more likely to reflect earlier bank decisions and may not affect the contemporaneous failure risk directly. The use of an eight-quarter average, rather than a single lagged quarter value, may reduce the effect of short-term fluctuations and problems with the use of accounting data (Berger and Bouwman, 2009). Identification of the IV model requires a strong correlation between the instrument and the endogenous variable. It is reasonable to expect that the average of eight-quarter lagged bank liquidity creation is highly correlated with the contemporaneous bank liquidity creation. For the instrument to be valid it should not be affected by the dependent variable, and not affect the dependent variable except through the endogenous variable. It is logically impossible for the failure risk of the bank to affect past bank liquidity creation. Also, it is unlikely that the eight-quarter lagged average values of liquidity creation affect a bank’s failure risk directly, except through their effect on contemporaneous bank liquidity creation. We find that in the first stage of our 2SLS estimations the eight-quarter lagged average values of liquidity creation (catfat_average) is positively and statistically significantly related to 18 C. Zheng, A. (Wai Kong) Cheung and T. Cronje / Journal of Banking and Finance 108 (2019) 105651 Table 10 Interaction effect of liquidity creation and bank capital on failure risk using time-dynamic models. Panel A: The system GMM regression results Dependent variable: z-score $1 billion and $3 billion size cutoff Variables (1) All banks (2) Small banks (3) Medium banks z-scoret-1 catfat ࢞ca catfat × ࢞ca Baseline Controls Observations Sargan/Hansen Test p-value ∗∗∗ 0.478 (0.04) −0.880 (0.71) 7.594∗ ∗ (3.53) 35.596∗ ∗ (14.55) Yes 220,158 31.15 0.150 ∗∗∗ 0.507 (0.04) −0.714 (0.71) 7.614∗ ∗ (3.54) 38.500∗ ∗ (15.11) Yes 202,596 21.87 0.587 ∗∗∗ 0.636 (0.03) −0.835 (1.02) 11.026 (10.04) 22.022 (22.80) Yes 10,402 14.55 0.933 Panel B: The dynamic OLS regression results for all banks Dependent variable: z-score Variables (1) (2) catfatt-1 8.617∗ ∗ ∗ (0.17) 6.553∗ ∗ ∗ (0.40) 8.977∗ ∗ ∗ (0.17) Yes Yes Yes Yes 220,188 0.959 Yes Yes Yes Yes 145,537 0.954 Panel C: The dynamic OLS regression results for small banks Dependent variable: z-score Variables (1) (2) 8.765∗ ∗ ∗ (0.16) 6.654∗ ∗ ∗ (0.38) 0.005 (0.01) 9.158∗ ∗ ∗ (0.21) 4.712∗ ∗ ∗ (0.57) Yes Yes Yes Yes 72,059 0.947 (3) 9.157∗ ∗ ∗ (0.16) 0.023∗ ∗ (0.01) 9.347∗ ∗ ∗ (0.22) 5.261∗ ∗ ∗ (0.43) catfatt-2 × ࢞ca catfatt-3 × ࢞ca Baseline Controls Year_quarter FE Bank FE State FE Observations Adjusted R2 (3) 0.003∗ (0.01) catfatt-3 catfatt-1 × ࢞ca 0.603∗ ∗ ∗ (0.06) −2.383 (1.87) 22.985∗ ∗ ∗ (6.12) −14.036 (13.96) Yes 4410 25.01 0.405 0.021∗ ∗ (0.01) catfatt-2 ࢞ca 0.665 (0.04) −0.326 (1.50) 10.350 (11.79) 16.448 (29.04) Yes 12,404 10.21 0.994 (7) Large banks 5.241∗ ∗ ∗ (0.44) catfatt-3 × ࢞ca catfatt-1 0.507 (0.04) −0.714 (0.71) 7.614∗ ∗ (3.54) 38.500∗ ∗ (15.11) Yes 202,596 21.87 0.587 ∗∗∗ −0.007 (0.01) catfatt-2 × ࢞ca Baseline Controls Year_quarter FE Bank FE State FE Observations Adjusted R2 0.662 (0.05) −1.353 (1.40) 14.500∗ (8.25) 13.074 (19.83) Yes 6330 15.85 0.894 ∗∗∗ 0.018 (0.01) catfatt-3 catfatt-1 × ࢞ca ∗∗∗ $1 billion and $5 billion size cutoff (5) Small banks (6) Medium banks ∗ catfatt-2 ࢞ca (4) Large banks Yes Yes Yes Yes 202,791 0.965 Yes Yes Yes Yes 133,816 0.961 4.813∗ ∗ ∗ (0.60) Yes Yes Yes Yes 66,207 0.956 (continued on next page) C. Zheng, A. (Wai Kong) Cheung and T. Cronje / Journal of Banking and Finance 108 (2019) 105651 19 Table 10 (continued) Panel D: The dynamic OLS regression results for medium banks Dependent variable: z-score Variables (1) (2) catfatt-1 0.005 (0.04) catfatt-2 catfatt-3 ࢞ca catfatt-1 × ࢞ca 8.394∗ ∗ ∗ (1.29) 6.027∗ ∗ (2.90) 8.957∗ ∗ ∗ (1.25) catfatt-3 × ࢞ca Yes Yes Yes Yes 10,905 0.910 Yes Yes Yes Yes 6715 0.954 Panel E: The dynamic OLS regression results for large banks Dependent variable: z-score Variables (1) (2) catfatt-1 10.724∗ ∗ ∗ (0.88) −0.763 (1.47) catfatt-2 × ࢞ca 11.597∗ ∗ ∗ (0.89) −0.034 (0.06) 10.812∗ ∗ ∗ (1.36) −1.553 (1.83) catfatt-3 × ࢞ca Baseline Controls Year_quarter FE Bank FE State FE Observations Adjusted R2 (3) −0.016 (0.05) catfatt-3 catfatt-1 × ࢞ca 8.159∗ ∗ (3.60) Yes Yes Yes Yes 3247 0.936 0.075 (0.05) catfatt-2 ࢞ca 0.023 (0.04) 8.574∗ ∗ ∗ (1.64) 7.494∗ ∗ ∗ (2.85) catfatt-2 × ࢞ca Baseline Controls Year_quarter FE Bank FE State FE Observations Adjusted R2 (3) 0.026 (0.05) Yes Yes Yes Yes 6492 0.930 Yes Yes Yes Yes 4129 0.940 −1.428 (2.51) Yes Yes Yes Yes 2014 0.934 Note: This table reports the estimation results of two time-dynamic models. The first one is a dynamic two-step system GMM panel estimator as proposed by Arellano and Bover (1995) and Blundell and Bond (1998) with Windmeijier’s (2005) finite sample correction (see Panel A). The null hypothesis of the Sargan test (or Hansen test) is that the instruments used are not correlated with residuals (over-identifying restrictions). The second one is a dynamic OLS regression results by including the one-, two-, and three-period lagged liquidity creation and their interaction terms (see Panels B-E). Panel B reports the results for the entire sample. Panels C-E report the results for different sizes of banks. Small banks, medium banks, and large banks are banks with less than $1 billion, between $1 billion and $3 billion, and more than $3 billion GTA. Bank liquidity creation is proxied by the BB measure, i.e., catfat. Change in bank capital (࢞cai,t ) is the absolute change from the year t-1 to t of bank i’s equity-to-total assets ratio. z-score measures the distance from insolvency. A higher z-score value indicates that a bank is less likely to default. z-scoret -1 is the lagged value of the dependent variable in GMM estimator. The variable descriptions are in Appendix 1. Robust standard errors clustered by bank are in parentheses. ∗ , ∗ ∗ , and ∗ ∗ ∗ represent significance at the 10%, 5% and 1% level, respectively. the contemporaneous bank liquidity creation (see Column (1) of Panel A, Table 9). These results affirm that the selected instrument is closely related to the endogenous variable, the BB measure, and statistical tests validate the strength and relevance of the instrument variable. For all banks, the results for the second-stage regressions are reported in Column (2) of Panel A, Table 9. The positive and statistically significant coefficient of catfat × ࢞ca by and large confirms our earlier results, easing concerns of endogeneity bias. In other words, incremental increases in bank capital strengthen the negative relationship between liquidity creation and failure risk. Panel B displays the two second-stage regression results for different sizes of banks.10 In Columns (1)–(3), small banks, medium banks, and large banks are banks with less than $1 billion, between $1 billion and $3 billion, and more than $3 billion GTA. In Columns (4)–(6), small banks, medium banks, and large banks are banks with less than $1 billion, between $1 billion and $5 billion, and more than $5 billion GTA. The results clearly show that the coefficients of catfat and catfat × ࢞ca remain positive and statistically significant for small banks. Thus, the findings on bank size are consistent with the OLS findings. All in all, most of our earlier results hold up in 10 We omit reporting the first stage results by bank size from our 2SLS to save on space, but these are available upon request. 20 C. Zheng, A. (Wai Kong) Cheung and T. Cronje / Journal of Banking and Finance 108 (2019) 105651 our instrumental variable estimation, and the analysis broadly confirms our main results. 5.2. Time-dynamic models11 To tackle the endogeneity issue and account for the dynamic properties of our panel, our second identification strategy is the generalized method of moments (GMM) estimation technique. This methodology was advanced by Arellano and Bond (1991), and further developed by Arellano and Bover (1995) and Blundell and Bond (1998). The fact that bank failure risk, liquidity creation and bank capital tend to be interrelated over time prescribes the use of a dynamic model. We rely on the system GMM,12 which has better finite sample properties in terms of bias and root mean squared error than that of the difference GMM, by using a system of two equations in level and in first difference. Further, GMM estimators have one- and two-step variants. We use the two-step estimator because it is asymptotically more efficient relative to the first step estimator, especially for the system GMM. However, the two-step estimates of the standard errors tend to be severely downward biased, thus we use the Windmeijer’s (2005) finite sample correction to report standard errors. As this approach leads to a relatively high number of internal instruments, we use the collapse option as proposed by Roodman (2009). We report the Sargan/Hansen test of over-identifying restrictions, where the null hypothesis is that the instruments used are appropriate. The results of these statistical tests confirm the validity of the instruments used in our model. Panel A, of Table 10, shows the results using the system GMM estimator. Our results from Column (1) document a substantial, positive, and highly significant interaction effect of liquidity creation and changes in bank capital, catfat × ࢞ca, on a bank’s z-score, supporting the view that the negative relationship between liquidity creation and bank insolvency risk is moderated positively by changes in bank capital. We also report the GMM regressions by bank size. Results in Columns (2)–(7) show that the reported positive coefficient of catfat × ࢞ca on a bank’s z-score is statistically significant only for small banks, while this coefficient is not significant for the medium and large bank subsamples. Hence, these results corroborate those obtained with the OLS results. Following the methodology of Berger and Sedunov (2017), our third identification strategy is to analyze the dynamic interaction effect of liquidity creation and bank capital on bank failure risk by including one-, two-, and three-period lagged liquidity creation variables along with their interactions with changes in bank capital. Panel B of Table 10 presents the dynamic OLS regression results for all banks. Panels C-E present the results for small, medium and large banks, respectively. We find that the coefficients of one-, two, and three-period lagged interaction terms, catfat × ࢞ca, are positive and statistically significant for small and medium banks, but the coefficients of lagged catfat are significant for small bank subsamples only, confirming that the interaction effect is more pronounced for small banks. 6. Conclusions We argue that the liquidity risk-sharing role of bank capital in moderating the relationship between liquidity creation and failure risk is underexplored. Given the coming joint regulatory capital and liquidity constraints set forth in Basel III, it is important for bank regulators and policymakers to understand this role. In this paper, we seek to fill the void in the literature by examining empirically how change in the capital ratio interacts with liquidity 11 We thank the reviewer for suggesting this time-dynamic technique. We use the “xtabond2” procedure in Stata for the system GMM estimates. Please refer to Roodman (2009) for the estimation procedure in detail. 12 creation in affecting the failure risk of individual banks. To examine this interaction, we use a dataset of all FDIC insured U.S. commercial banks spanning the period from 2003:Q1 to 2014:Q4. The main findings are as follows. Firstly, we find a fairly robust and significant negative relationship between liquidity creation and bank failure risk. Further, this negative relationship is moderated positively (i.e., strengthened) by bank capital. This evidence is consistent with the liquidity risk-sharing role of bank capital. Specifically, banks that create more liquidity and are then exposed to higher liquidity risk may find it optimal to strengthen/increase their capital buffer as a cushion to absorb the illiquidity risk resulting from bank liquidity creation. Higher levels of bank capital would, in turn, reduce the probability of bank failure and improve banks’ ability to create liquidity. In other words, an increase in bank capital will give rise to a further increase in liquidity creation, but a further decrease in bank failure risk, implying that an increase in bank capital will strengthen the negative relationship between liquidity creation and bank failure risk. The implication of this finding is that it is of extreme importance to consider the use of bank capital as a risk-sharing device because banks may actively manage their capital ratios in response to the perceived risk exposure. Secondly, the moderating effect of bank capital on the relationship between liquidity creation and failure risk is more prominent for small banks. This result is important but not surprising, since it is generally accepted that small banks have limited access to external funds and, thus, they have a strong precautionary motive for holding more capital buffer as a hedge against adverse liquidity shocks. As a consequence of the bigger capital cushion, the failure risk will be lower for small banks. Finally, we also find that the interactive effects of bank capital and liquidity creation on failure risk, were more pronounced during the recent financial crisis period. This implies that bank capital may have been especially important in mitigating liquidity risk associated with liquidity creation during the crisis period. This study has important policy implications for governments and policy authorities as it provides novel insights for the design of prudential regulation and supervision of banks. The financial crisis of 20 07–20 09 has prompted the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (BCBS) to introduce a new regulatory framework, known as Basel III, to strengthen the capital and liquidity risk management of banks. As discussed in the Introduction, Basel III liquidity requirements, i.e., liquidity coverage ratio (LCR) and the net stable funding ratio (NSFR), also constrain a bank’s capability to create liquidity unnecessarily, as they require banks to hold more liquid assets and maintain a sustainable maturity structure of assets and liabilities (Berger and Sedunov, 2017). Complementing this strand of literature, our work shows that lower levels of liquidity creation caused by stringent Basel III liquidity regulations may trigger a possibly unintended consequence in that they increase the risk of bank failure due to inadequate capital buffers. The findings in this paper suggest that capital and liquidity requirements cannot be separated. Policymakers should consider the liquidityrisk sharing function of bank capital as an integrated component of bank liquidity management, and evaluate its effect on the relationship between liquidity creation and bank failure risk. Furthermore, the results clearly indicate that one size does not fit all when it comes to capital and liquidity regulation. Our findings suggest that small banks could be exempted from having to comply with the new Basel III potentially binding liquidity constraints, as they strengthen their capital base actively when they are exposed to increasing illiquidity due to liquidity creation, and they are important liquidity creators (i.e., they are likely to create medium levels of liquidity). Capital buffer has the desired effect in reducing bank risk. On the contrary, it appears that large banks may underestimate liquidity risk and maintain low capital ratios, possibly because they are more likely to receive government funding support C. Zheng, A. (Wai Kong) Cheung and T. Cronje / Journal of Banking and Finance 108 (2019) 105651 due to their “too-big-to-fail” position, or because they have broader access to external financing, or because they may use their diversification advantage to operate with lower capital ratios. These potential reasons why large banks maintain low capital buffers are interesting and important topics. More research in this area may be helpful. Supplementary materials Supplementary material associated with this article can be found, in the online version, at doi:10.1016/j.jbankfin.2019.105651. Appendix 1. Variable definitions Variable Definition Panel A: Bank liquidity creation and bank failure risk variables catfat z-score faildummyq faildummyy Dollar amount of “catfat” liquidity creation normalized by gross total assets. The “catfat” measures the liquidity created on and off the balance sheet, following Berger and Bouwman (2009). z-score has been widely used in the recent literature as a measure of bank risk, which equals the return on assets plus the capital asset ratio, divided by the standard deviation of the return on assets. z-score measures a bank’s distance to insolvency. Accordingly, it is inversely related to the probability of default. It is recommendable to use its natural logarithm because of its high skewness (e.g., Laeven and Levine, 2009). A binary performance variable is used to indicate whether a bank fails in the next quarter after a specific financial report date. If failure occurs, it is flagged as “bad” and is assigned the binary value of one. Otherwise, it is flagged as “good” and is assigned the binary value of zero. A binary performance variable is used to indicate whether a bank fails in the next year after a specific financial report date. If failure occurs, it is flagged as “bad” and is assigned the binary value of one. Otherwise, it is flagged as “good” and is assigned the binary value of zero. Panel B: Bank-specific variables ca aq mc roe liq ltdrt noniirt ristak commre lndep The ratio of equity capital to total assets The ratio of all nonperforming loans (all loans 90 days past due plus all loans charged off) to total assets The cost-to-income ratio The ratio of net income to total equity The ratio of cash and balances due from depository institutions to total assets The loans-to-deposits ratio The ratio of non-interest income to total income The bank’s Basel I risk-weighted assets divided by total asset The commercial real estate loans divided by total loans The natural logarithm of total bank deposits Panel C: Macroeconomic variables fedfunds spread lngdp lngpsave crisisdummy The Federal funds rate The spread between 3-month US T-Bills and 10-year US Treasuries Natural logarithm of Gross Domestic Product Natural logarithm of Gross Private Savings of all US households A dummy variable that equals one from the third quarter of 2007 to the fourth quarter of 2009 and zero otherwise Panel D: Local market variables sloos hhi_dep lnperinc lnemploy lnpop Net percentage of domestic banks reporting stronger demand for auto loans, credit card loans, government mortgage loans, and C&I loans Bank-level HHI of deposit concentration for the local markets in which the bank is operating Natural logarithm of per capita personal income in a county Natural logarithm of total employment in a county Natural logarithm of total population in a county 21 References Acharya, V.V., Mehran, H., Thakor, A.V., 2016. Caught between scylla and charybdis? Regulating bank leverage when there is rent seeking and risk shifting. Rev. Corp. Finance Stud. 5 (1), 36–75. Acharya, V., Naqvi, H., 2012. The seeds of a crisis: a theory of bank liquidity and risk taking over the business cycle. J. Financ. Econ. 106 (2), 349–366. Allen, F., Gale, D., 2004. Financial intermediaries and markets. Econometrica 72 (4), 1023–1061. Allen, F., Santomero, A.M., 1997. The theory of financial intermediation. J. Bank. Finance 21 (11), 1461–1485. Andreou, P.C., Philip, D., Robejsek, P., 2016. Bank liquidity creation and risk-taking: does managerial ability matter. J. Bus. Finance Account. 43 (1–2), 226–259. Arellano, M., Bond, S., 1991. Some tests of specification for panel data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. Rev. Econ. Stud. 58 (2), 277–297. Arellano, M., Bover, O., 1995. Another look at the instrumental variable estimation of error-components models. J. Econom. 68 (1), 29–51. Beltratti, A., Stulz, R.M., 2012. The credit crisis around the globe: why did some banks perform better. J. Financ. Econ. 105 (1), 1–17. Berger, A.N., Bouwman, C.H.S., 2009. Bank liquidity creation. Rev. Financ. Stud. 22 (9), 3779–3837. Berger, A.N., Bouwman, C.H.S., 2013. How does capital affect bank performance during financial crises. J. Financ. Econ. 109 (1), 146–176. Berger, A.N., Bouwman, C.H.S., 2017. Bank liquidity creation, monetary policy, and financial crises. J. Financ. Stab. 30, 139–155. Berger, A.N., Bouwman, C.H., Kim, D., 2017a. Small bank comparative advantages in alleviating financial constraints and providing liquidity insurance over time. Rev. Financ. Stud. 30 (10), 3416–3454. Berger, A., DeYoung, R., Flannery, M., Lee, D., Öztekin, Ö, 2008. How do large banking organizations manage their capital ratios. J. Financ. Serv. Res. 34 (2), 123–149. Berger, A.N., Guedhami, O., Kim, H.H., & Li, X. (2017). Economic policy uncertainty and bank liquidity creation, SSRN Working Paper. Berger, A.N., Sedunov, J., 2017. Bank liquidity creation and real economic output. J. Bank. Finance 81, 1–19. Bhattacharya, S., Thakor, A.V., 1993. Contemporary banking theory. J. Financ. Intermed. 3 (1), 2–50. Blundell, R., Bond, S., 1998. Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic panel data models. J. Econom. 87 (1), 115–143. Bryant, J., 1980. A model of reserves, bank runs, and deposit insurance. J. Bank. Finance. 4 (4), 335–344. Castiglionesi, F., Feriozzi, F., LÓRÁNth, G., Pelizzon, L., 2014. Liquidity coinsurance and bank capital. J. Money Credit Bank. 46 (2–3), 409–443. Chatterjee, U.K., 2018. Bank liquidity creation and recessions. J. Bank. Finance 90, 64–75. Cleary, S., Hebb, G., 2016. An efficient and functional model for predicting bank distress: in and out of sample evidence. J. Bank. Finance 64, 101–111. Cole, R.A., Gunther, J.W., 1995. Separating the likelihood and timing of bank failure. J. Bank. Finance 19 (6), 1073–1089. Cole, R.A., White, L.J., 2012. Déjà Vu all over again: the causes of U.S. commercial bank failures this time around. J. Financ. Serv. Res. 42 (1–2), 5–29. Cornett, M.M., McNutt, J.J., Strahan, P.E., Tehranian, H., 2011. Liquidity risk management and credit supply in the financial crisis. J. Financ. Econ. 101 (2), 297–312. Demerjian, P., Lev, B., McVay, S., 2012. Quantifying managerial ability: a new measure and validity tests. Manage. Sci. 58 (7), 1229–1248. DeYoung, R., Distinguin, I., Tarazi, A., 2018. The joint regulation of bank liquidity and bank capital. J. Financ. Intermed. 34, 32–46. DeYoung, R., Torna, G., 2013. Nontraditional banking activities and bank failures during the financial crisis. J. Financ. Intermed. 22 (3), 397–421. Diamond, D.W., Dybvig, P.H., 1983. Bank runs, deposit insurance, and liquidity. J. Polit. Econ. 91 (3), 401–419. Diamond, D.W., Rajan, R.G., 20 0 0. A theory of bank capital. J. Finance 55 (6), 2431–2465. Diamond, D.W., Rajan, R.G., 2001. Liquidity risk, liquidity creation, and financial fragility: a theory of banking. J. Polit. Econ. 109 (2), 287–327. Diamond, D.W., Rajan, R.G., 2011. Fear of fire sales, illiquidity seeking, and credit freezes. Q. J. Econ. 126 (2), 557–591. Díaz, V., Huang, Y., 2017. The role of governance on bank liquidity creation. J. Bank. Finance 77, 137–156. Distinguin, I., Roulet, C., Tarazi, A., 2013. Bank regulatory capital and liquidity: evidence from U.S. and European publicly traded banks. J. Bank. Finance 37 (9), 3295–3317. Donaldson, J.R., Piacentino, G., Thakor, A., 2018. Warehouse banking. J. Financ. Econ. 129 (2), 250–267. Estrella, A., Park, S., Peristiani, S., 20 0 0. Capital ratios as predictors of bank failure. Econ. Policy Rev. 6 (2), 33–52. Fu, X., Lin, Y., Molyneux, P., 2016. Bank capital and liquidity creation in Asia Pacific. Econ. Inq. 54 (2), 966–993. Fungacova, Z., Turk, R., Weill, L., 2015. High liquidity creation and bank failures. IMF Working Paper. International Monetary Fund. Furlong, F.T., Keeley, M.C., 1989. Capital regulation and bank risk-taking: a note. J. Bank. Finance 13 (6), 883–891. 22 C. Zheng, A. (Wai Kong) Cheung and T. Cronje / Journal of Banking and Finance 108 (2019) 105651 Gatev, E., Strahan, P.E., 2006. Banks’ advantage in hedging liquidity risk: theory and evidence from the commercial paper market. J. Finance 61 (2), 867–892. Gorton, G., Winton, A., 2017. Liquidity provision, bank capital, and the macroeconomy. J. Money Credit Bank. 49 (1), 5–37. Holmström, B., Tirole, J., 1998. Private and public supply of liquidity. J. Polit. Econ. 106 (1), 1–40. Horváth, R., Seidler, J., Weill, L., 2014. Bank capital and liquidity creation: granger– causality evidence. J. Financ. Serv. Res. 45 (3), 341–361. Imbierowicz, B., Rauch, C., 2014. The relationship between liquidity risk and credit risk in banks. J. Bank. Finance 40, 242–256. Kashyap, A.K., Rajan, R., Stein, J.C., 2002. Banks as liquidity providers: an explanation for the coexistence of lending and deposit-taking. J. Finance 57 (1), 33–73. Konishi, M., Yasuda, Y., 2004. Factors affecting bank risk taking: evidence from Japan. J. Bank. Finance 28 (1), 215–232. Laeven, L., Levine, R., 2009. Bank governance, regulation and risk taking. J. Financ. Econ. 93 (2), 259–275. Norton, E.C., Wang, H., Ai, C., 2004. Computing interaction effects and standard errors in logit and probit models. Stata J. 4, 154–167. Repullo, R., 2004. Capital requirements, market power, and risk-taking in banking. J. Financ. Intermed. 13 (2), 156–182. Roodman, D., 2009. How to do xtabond2: an introduction to difference and system GMM in Stata. Stata J. 9 (1), 86–136. Roy, A.D., 1952. Safety first and the holding of assets. Econometrica 20 (3), 431–449. Thakor, A.V., 2005. Do loan commitments cause overlending. J. Money Credit Bank. 37 (6), 1067–1099. Tran, V.T., Lin, C.T., Nguyen, H., 2016. Liquidity creation, regulatory capital, and bank profitability. Int. Rev. Financ. Anal. 48, 98–109. Von Thadden, E.L., 2004. Bank capital adequacy regulation under the new Basel Accord. J. Financ. Intermed. 13 (2), 90–95. Windmeijer, F., 2005. A finite sample correction for the variance of linear efficient two-step GMM estimators. J. Econom. 126 (1), 25–51.