INVESTIGATION INTO THE IMPACTS OF UN POPULATION PROJECTIONS ON THE COSTS OF CLIMATE CHANGE Word count: 1785 Ryan Truesdale r.truesdale@student.rug.nl 1. Introduction The earth’s population has grown exponentially in the last few hundred years, owing to various developments in agriculture, medicine and technology as a whole. Development of fertiliser led to increased food availability and advances in modern medicine, such as anti-biotics, resulted in declining mortality rates. The industrial revolution may be seen as the kick-start of the high growth rates that bring us to the enormous population of today [Bavel, 2013]. At the same time, population growth and climate change are unquestionably linked. World population and atmospheric CO2 concentration (which is responsible for rising temperatures) display virtually identical curves over time [Onozaki, 2009]. The key difference between the two, however, is that whilst population growth shows signs of slowing down, rising CO2 levels do not, as other factors come into play increasing the emissions per capita. Nonetheless, it has been suggested that the most effective way of reducing one’s long term carbon emissions is to have one fewer child [Wynes and Nicholas, 2017]. This is due to the lifetime of emissions associated with every new person brought into the world. In this study, the range of possibilities arising from the UN’s probabilistic future population estimates are investigated. The study looks at the effects of different levels of population growth on climate change associated economic losses of different economic groups. The study will also consider how differences in population growth estimates affect the point at which 2 degrees warming is expected to be exceeded if significant changes are not made. 1. Methodology This study uses a simple Integrated Assessment Model (IAM) to determine the economic impacts of climate change, based on United Nations (UN) probabilistic population predictions. An IAM combines data and knowledge from multiple sources and disciplines to show the effects of human behaviour on the natural world, in addition to the effects of the natural world on our economic systems. IAMs are of particular use in answering “whatif?” questions, due to the linkages between different sections of the model. These linkages mean that changing any one aspect affects all other sections, without having to collect additional data, allowing the full impacts of a decision to be considered. This quality is also useful for exploring trade-offs between aspects, and giving a full account of sideeffects that may otherwise be missed. The IAM used in this study is adapted from that described in Richard Tol’s textbook “Climate Economics: Economic Analysis of Climate, Climate Change, and Climate Policy” [Tol, 2014]. It consists of six interlinking parts: The Carbon Cycle, Climate, Growth (Solow), Emissions (Kaya), Abatement, and Impact. Of particular interest in this study are the Growth and Impact, which contain the input population variable and the output costs and temperature respectively. For population data from 1960 until 2018, data was collected from the World Bank and split based on the World Bank income groups. “Rich” relates to the High income countries, “Middle” to Upper-middle income countries, and “Poor” to Lower-middle and Low income countries combined. For the years following, the UN’s quinquennial probabilistic population estimates up to 2100 were used, together with the existing data, in order to perform a 6th order polynomial regression. The resulting equation was used to populate the post-2018 population in the Solow growth model. As the data is based on a line of fitting, it does not fully match the input population estimates, but does provide a value for every year up until 2100. The UN provide five population estimates, for the median and the upper and lower 80% and 95% prediction intervals of the probabilistic projections. This study uses the Median and the Upper and Lower 95. Predicted values take into account the past experiences of each country, and use that to predict the future experiences of countries with similar conditions, including potential uncertainty [UN, 2019]. 1.1. Carbon Cycle This section calculates atmospheric CO2 concentration (Equation 1) as the sum of the amount of CO2 in each of five boxes, i, at a given time, t (Equation 2). αi is the CO2 retained in a box until the next time period, γi is the share of emissions entering a box, β is a unit conversion factor for billion tonnes of C to CO2 ppm, and M*t-1 is the total emissions in the previous year. αi and γi differ between boxes. Future emissions are received from the abatement module. πΈππ’ππ‘πππ 1. 5 πΆπ‘ = ∑ πΆπ,π‘ 1 πΈππ’ππ‘πππ 2. ∗ πΆπ,π‘ = (1 − πΌπ )πΆπ,π‘−1 + πΎπ π½ππ‘−1 1.2. Climate This module calculates the cumulative increase in mean surface air temperature since pre-industrial times in a given year, TtA (Equation 3). λ1 and λ2 model the effects of radiative forcing on temperature, and λ3 and λ4 represent exchange of heat between the oceans and the atmosphere. TtO represents the temperature of the oceans (Equation 4). Radiative forcing is determined by atmospheric CO2 concentration from the Carbon Cycle module. πΈππ’ππ‘πππ 3. π΄ π΄ ) ππ‘π΄ = ππ‘−1 + π1 (π2 πΉπ‘ − ππ‘−1 π π΄ + π3 (ππ‘−1 − ππ‘−1 ) πΈππ’ππ‘πππ 4. π π΄ π ππ‘π = ππ‘−1 + π4 (ππ‘−1 − ππ‘−1 ) 1.3. Growth The growth module follows the Solow model, which calculates economic output in a specific year and region (or in this case income group), Yr,t* (Equation 5), depending on available capital, Kr,tα (Equation 6), population, Lr,t1-α, and the total factor productivity, Ar,t [Solow, 1956]. α is the “capital share”, δ is the deprecation rate of capital, Ir,t (Equation 7) is investment, and s is the saving rate. πΈππ’ππ‘πππ 5. πΌ ∗ ππ,π‘ = π΄π,π‘ × πΎπ,π‘ × πΏ1−πΌ π,π‘ πΈππ’ππ‘πππ 6. πΎπ,π‘ = (1 − πΏ)πΎπ,π‘−1 + πΌπ‘,π‘−1 πΈππ’ππ‘πππ 7. πΌπ,π‘ = π ππ,π‘ 1.4. Emissions The emission module is based on the Kaya identity (Equation 8). Mr,t* are the emissions in a region (or income group) at a given time, Lr,t is the population (from the Solow model), and Yr,t is the economic output (also from the Solow model). πΈππ’ππ‘πππ 8. ∗ ππ,π‘ = πΏπ,π‘ × ∗ ππ,π‘ ππ,π‘ × πΏπ,π‘ ππ,π‘ 1.5. Abatement The abatement module includes the costs, Br,t*, of lowering the emissions calculated in the emissions module (Equations 9, 10, 11, and 12). β is a coefficient for cost based on the emission control rate, Rr,t, and Br,t is the economic burden of abatement. πΈππ’ππ‘πππ 9. ∗ ππ,π‘ − ππ,π‘ 2 ∗ ∗ π΅π,π‘ = π½( ) ππ,π‘ ∗ ππ,π‘ πΈππ’ππ‘πππ 10. ∗ ππ,π‘ = (1 − π π,π‘ )ππ,π‘ πΈππ’ππ‘πππ 11. 2 π΅π,π‘ = π½π π,π‘ πΈππ’ππ‘πππ 12. ∗ ππ,π‘ = (1 − π΅π,π‘ )ππ,π‘ 1.6. Impact The impact module gives the economic losses (or gains) resulting from rising temperature, based on parameters ψ1, ψ2, and ψ6. π·π‘ gives the economic impact as a percentage of annual output (Equation 13). ππ‘ is the increase in global average temperature since the pre-industrial era. πΈππ’ππ‘πππ 13. π·π‘ = π1 ππ‘ + π2 ππ‘2 + π6 ππ‘6 2. Results & Discussion 2.1. Results In Figure 1, it can be seen that, up to a certain amount of warming, rising temperatures provide economic benefits, particularly for rich countries, as reported in [Tol, 2010]. However, as emissions increase further, the economic consequences become increasingly severe across all economic groups. It can also be seen that all of the population predictions are very similar up until around 2050, with differences only appearing when the economic impact begins to decrease and losses are incurred. Similar divergence in economic impact is seen across all economic groups, and all groups see the higher population estimates resulting in greater eventual losses. In total, poorer countries’ economies are affected more by the rising temperatures, despite their smaller contributions to climate change, which aligns with the idea of the tragedy of the commons in which a few reap the benefits of degradation, but all bear the cost [Forster Lloyd, 1833]. Poor countries are affected to a greater extent for three reasons, outlined in [Tol, 2014]: Their economies are largely dependent on weather-dependent industries, they tend to be in hotter places less able to withstand further warming, and they lack funds and technical know-how to adapt to changes. Figure 2 shows a starkly different picture however. On a per capita basis, rich countries face far greater costs. Once again, greater populations result in greater losses. As the differences between the impacts of the Rich countries’ losses appear starker, it may be the case that higher population growth (and population to begin with) in poor countries results in a greater ability to share the economic load. Figure 3 shows the warming based on each of the population estimates. Whilst significant differences are present between the highest (Upper 95) and lowest (Lower 95) estimates for population, with a difference of 0.9 billion in the 2050 predictions, the model displays little variation in terms of the point in time at which global warming will exceed 2 degrees compared to the pre-industrial era (covering a 2 year range). This suggests that, whilst population is important in terms of emissions, other factors may be coming to the fore in the future. 2.2. Limitations This IAM considers abatement cost, so does not truly consider the costs of the damages of climate change, or the loss of opportunities it presents. It also ignores factors like health which deteriorates as climate change occurs, and the associated non-warming environmental impacts so presents a limited scope. As it uses the past to predict the future, it projects the habits and trends of today onto future generations who may behave differently. As it is based on trends, it ignores event based influences, both human and natural, that may have tremendous impacts. As IAMs are so large, a large amount of time must be put in collecting data, and large models often end up as “black boxes” where it is difficult to understand what is going on inside. The model assumes that membership of each income group is fixed, and does not account for countries increasing or decreasing their wealth and entering a different income group, which would result in changes to their environmental impacts. In 2019-2020, seven countries were assigned new income groups [The World Bank, 2019], most notably Argentina, which represents 0.6% of the World’s population. It is important to note that the UN population predictions do not include adjustment based on the potential effects of climate change. In reality population growth is affected by climate change in a dynamic feedback loop, as climate change leads to falling fertility rates and higher mortality rates than otherwise, for a number of reasons [Van Bavel, 2013]. As this study uses population predictions, rather than predicting population itself, the relationship in the model is one-way; growing population leads to rising temperatures. 3. Conclusion This study shows that whilst all income groups receive substantial economic losses from climate change, poor countries are overall worst off. However, on a per capita basis, rich countries pay a far higher price, owing to their smaller populations. Whilst the UN’s population estimates show substantial differences, the timeframe in which the world will exceed 2 degrees warming will not be substantially affected by differing growth scenarios, meaning that no matter the case, urgent action is needed to avert the climate crisis. Whilst IAMs have extensive limitations, they provide a valuable insight into the relationship between human behaviour and environmental impacts, due to their ability to link data from socioeconomic and physical disciplines. 4. References Van Bavel, J. (2013). The world population explosion: causes, backgrounds and projections for the future. Facts, Views & Vision in ObGyn, 5(4), 281–291. Retrieved from http://www.ncbi.nlm.nih.gov/pubmed/24753 956 Lloyd, W. F. (1980). W. F. Lloyd on the Checks to Population. Population and Development Review, 6(3), 473. https://doi.org/10.2307/1972412 Onozaki, K. (2009). Population Is a Critical Factor for Global Carbon Dioxide Increase. Journal of Health Science, 55(1), 125-127. https://doi.org/10.1248/jhs.55.125 Solow, R. M. (1956). A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 70(1), 65. https://doi.org/10.2307/1884513 Tol, R. S. (2010). The Economic Impact of Climate Change. Perspektiven Der Wirtschaftspolitik, 11, 13-37. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.14682516.2010.00326.x Tol, R. S. (2014). Climate economics: Economic analysis of climate, climate change and climate policy. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar Publishing. United Nations. (2019). World Population Prospects - Population Division. Retrieved June 18, 2020, from https://population.un.org/wpp/Download/Pr obabilistic/Population/ The World Bank. (2019, July 1). New country classifications by income level: 2019-2020 [Web log post]. Retrieved 2020, from https://blogs.worldbank.org/opendata/newcountry-classifications-income-level-20192020 Wynes, S., & Nicholas, K. A. (2017). The climate mitigation gap: education and government recommendations miss the most effective individual actions. Environmental Research Letters, 12(7), 074024. https://doi.org/10.1088/1748-9326/aa7541