ECON2101 Intermediate Microeconomics Technology Aleksandra Balyanova 1/21 The supply side of the market Having studied consumer choice (under certainty and uncertainty) and derived demand, we now turn to the firm side of the market. We will 1. 2. 3. 4. Model firm technology (now) Derive from the firm’s technology its cost function, i.e. the cheapest way for it to produce any given output level (next) Derive from its cost function its supply function, i.e. how much it will supply to the market for any given price of its output (later) Aggregate individual supply to study market supply and long run equilibrium in a perfectly competitive market (even later) 2/21 Firms Firms are complex and heterogenous organisations. • • They employ different types of resources to produce a variety of goods and services sold to consumers in different markets. They employ a wide variety of incentive schemes and compensation structures (to varying effect!) to induce lower-level employees to perform in a way desired by higher level management In modelling the firm, we abstract from all of these details. Our bare-bones model of the firm depicts it only as a “black box” that transforms inputs (like labour and capital) into output. The firm’s technology is the process by which inputs are turned into outputs. 3/21 Technology Example 1: • You are a firm that transforms the input “hours spent studying” into the output “Micro 2 mark”. The technology by which you do so can be modeled by the production function √ f (h) = h i.e. your mark increases rapidly at the beginning, but as you spend more and more time studying, your mark increases more slowly (the marginal product of h is decreasing - more on this later). Notice that if you study for 9 hours, you can get a maximum mark of 3, but you can also “waste” some of your effort and get a mark of 2, or even a mark of 0. 4/21 Technology When the technology is modeled by f (z), for any input quantity z, f (z) describes the maximum possible output. 5/21 From 1 input to N inputs A single, price-taking firm operating in a market economy uses N inputs (capital, labour, raw materials, etc.) and transforms them into output q. Denote inputs by zn ≥ 0. An input vector is z = (z1 , . . . , zN ) The N + 1-dimensional input-output vector (z, q) is a feasible plan for the firm if q can be produced given z, given the firm’s available technology. Given an input vector (z1 , . . . , zN ), the maximum output that can be produced is f (z1 , . . . , zN ). The function f : RN + → R+ is the firm’s production function. A plan is feasible if q ≤ f (z1 , . . . , zN ) The collection of all feasible plans is the production set. 6/21 From N to 2 inputs Much like with the consumer optimisation problem, we will focus on the two-input case. • Similar reasoning as for consumer problem: two inputs is the minimum needed to capture the fact that there may be choices to be made about how to produce a given output 7/21 From N to 2 inputs Example 2: • • • • 1 1 Suppose the production function of the firm is q = f (z1 , z2 ) = 2z13 z23 The firm can produce q = 8 using (z1 , z2 ) = (8, 8) But there are other ways - e.g. z10 , z20 = (64, 1) and z100 , z200 = (1, 64) In fact, any (z1 , z2 ) such that z1 × z2 = 64 can be used. Isoquants The q-output isoquant is the collection of all input vectors that yield output level q using the firm’s available technology. The map of isoquants is an equivalent way to describe the production function. 8/21 Isoquants Isoquants are to the production function what indifference curves are to the utility function: mappings of combinations of inputs (of the function) that yield the same output (of the function). 9/21 Marginal production Marginal production The production function f : RN + → R+ represents the maximum amount of output that can be produced using an input vector z = (z1 , . . . , zN ). Isoquants are representations of different combinations of inputs that yield the same output level. • • This does not mean that all input combinations are economically equivalent. A profit maximising firm asks what is the most cost effective way to produce q. Marginal Products Given a differentiable production function f : RN + → R+ , the marginal product of input n = 1, . . . , N at b z is the rate of change of output as the quantity used of input n changes slightly ∂f bz for n = 1, . . . , N MPn b z = ∂zn 10/21 Technical rate of substitution To be able to eventually determine what is the most cost effective way to produce an output q, we explore the trade-offs involved in input use. Fix an input vector b z at which the output level is f b z = q. Totally differentiating this expression gives ∂f b z ∂z1 ∂f dz1 + · · · + b b z ∂zN dzN = 0 When focusing on changes in two inputs only, say input l and input k, we have dzj = 0 for all j 6= k, l. Rearranging, we see that ∂f b z /∂zl MPl b z dzk =− =− dzl ∂f b z /∂zk MPk b z This expression captures the rate at which the firm has to decrease input k to marginally increase its use of input l while keeping output constant. 11/21 Technical rate of substitution Given a differentiable production function f : RN + → R+ „ the technical rate of substitution between input l and input k at b z is TRSl,k MPl b z bz = MPk b z For inputs 1 and 2, the TRS1,2 at zb1 , zb2 is the absolute value of the slope of the isoquant at that input vector. 12/21 Commonly used production functions Perfect substitutes Let f : R2+ → R+ be given by f (z1 , z2 ) = az1 + bz2 This production function represents perfect substitution between inputs 1 and 2. 13/21 Perfect substitutes To employ one extra unit of input 1 without changing the production level, the firm gives up ba units of input 2. 14/21 Perfect complements/fixed proportions Let u : R2+ → R be given by f (z1 , z2 ) = min {az1 , bz2 } This production function represents perfect complementarity between inputs 1 and 2. 15/21 Perfect complements/fixed proportions The firm uses at least ba units of input 2 for each unit of input 1. When inputs are in the “ideal” ratio, additional units of either do not affect output (if the other input is fixed). 16/21 Cobb Douglas Any production function of the form f (z1 , z2 ) = Cz1a z2b with C , a, b > 0 is called a Cobb Douglas production function. 17/21 Cobb Douglas e.g. Example 2, 1 1 f (z1 , z2 ) = 2z13 z23 Isoquants are hyperbolic, approaching but never touching either axis CD technology captures smooth substitutability between inputs 18/21 Technology: exercise 1 Firm 1 has technology given by f1 (z1 , z2 ) = 2z1 + z2 Firm 2 has technology given by f2 (z1 , z2 ) = z1 + 2z2 The two firms merge. As a result, the new firm has access to the production methods that were available to both firms. The joint firm’s production function is then fj (z1 , z2 ) = max {2z1 + z2 , z1 + 2z2 } Depict the joint firm’s isoquant for q = 8. Label the TRS along the isoquant. 19/21 Technology: exercise 1 The joint firm’s production function is then fj (z1 , z2 ) = max {2z1 + z2 , z1 + 2z2 } Depict the joint firm’s isoquant for q = 8. Label the TRS along the isoquant. • • When 2z1 + z2 > z1 + 2z2 , i.e. when z1 > z2 , Firm 1’s method is more productive: q = 2z1 + z2 . Substituting in q = 8 and rearranging, we have that below the 45◦ line, the isoquant is given by z2 = 8 − 2z1 When z1 < z2 , Firm 2’s method is more productive: q = z1 + 2z2 . Substituting in q = 8 and rearranging, we have that above the 45◦ line, the isoquant is given by z2 = 4 − 21 z1 20/21 Technology: exercise 1 • • Below the kink when z1 > z2 - the joint firm is using Firm 1’s method and the isoquant is given by z2 = 8 − 2z1 Above the kink when z2 < z2 - the joint firm is using Firm 2’s method z2 = 4 − 12 z1 21/21