The Court should ….. The V amendment to the Constitution holds that private property shall not be taken for public use without just compensation. The taking might take different forms. It can be happen through a formal condemnation action, a judicial proceeding and court determination of the just compensation, determined on the value of the property on the market (highest and best use). It might be “by conditioning”, when the use of land is restricted by a regulation or the terms of a permit. Taking might finally take the form of inverse condemnation, when there is a regulation of the land that is so substantial to deprive any beneficial use of it. The taking might refer not only to land but also to personal property (Horne). There are different forms of taking. First of all, a physical taking occurs when there is a concrete occupation of the property. In order to have a physical taking it is not necessary to have a complete condemnation of the land. Even a minor occupation of the property to devote it to a public use constitutes a taking. Hence, it requires the Government to provide just compensation (Loretto v. Teleprompter Manhattan CAVT Corp). Another form of physical taking is granting right of public access to a private property (see Nursery v. Hasid, where the Supreme Court stated that when the right to exclude third parties from the property is violated there is a physical taking). LOSS OF BENEFICIAL USE (prohibition) prohibition of any use is taking under Lucas A more subtle form of taking can occur when the government operates a regulatory restriction reducing the practical use of property. A regulation might deprive a property of “all economically beneficial or productive use of land”, also known as “inverse condemnation” (see Lucas v. South Carolina Coastal Council) Not all prohibitions of use constitute a taking. In fact, under the common law principle known as the nuisance theory, the use of the land might be restricted to prohibit a nuisance or danger. Under this principle, a State could prohibit a use of the land that constitutes a nuisance without having to pay any compensation. It follows from that the a State cannot prohibit a use of the land that does not constitute a nuisance without paying just compensation. For example, if the State imposes the loss of all beneficial uses of the land for aesthetical purposes, then the restriction will be qualified as a taking (see Lucas v. South Carolina Coastal Council). A regulation is a taking only when it completely frustrates the owner’s reasonable expectations and renders the property useless, unless it was a nuisance. Two main elements must be evaluated to determine whether there is a taking: “the character of the action and on the nature and extent of the interference”. If the restrictions permit a reasonable beneficial use of property, and are authorized by a law that promotes general welfare, then there is not a taking (Penn Central Trans. Co v. NY City.). PERMITS (state imposing conditions) Generally, a State may impose on permit conditions that further a legitimate government goal. However, not every condition is admissible. There must be a reasonable nexus between the condition imposed and the intended use of the land. Nollan v. California Coastal Commission INTENSE REGULATION what about a regulation that does not prohibit but regulates intensely, so that I cannot use as I had intended Generally, a state can regulate property in the public interest even the regulation impacts negatively the value of land. Government regulation that only incidentally infringes on the owner’s use of property is not considered a taking, nor is regulation that outlaws the noxious or dangerous use of property. (eg, zoning laws) The Supreme Court has held that such statutes do not constitute a Fifth Amendment taking that deserves compensation. (Miller v. Schoene, the Supreme Court decided that the destruction of one class of property to save another by Virginia state was a legitimate exercise of the state’s power. Hadacheck v. Sebastian, where the Court held that governments have a broad authority to regulate actions that re harmful to the general public. While property may be regulated to a certain extent, if regulation goes too far (makes it commercially impracticable to engage in the economic activity under consideration) it will be recognized as a taking. Thus, it will require fair compensation. Pennsylvania Coal Co. v. Mahon In determining whether the Takings Clause (and its protections) applies, one has to determine if there is a governmental “taking” (physical or regulatory) and if the taking of property was for public use. If there was a taking for public use, the next question is if “just compensation” was or should have to be paid to the property owner. If this is not the case, the Amendment V is violated. A state can impose conditions on the owner, but only if it advances a governmental purpose and there is a connection between the permit and the conditions created. “Government regulation can constitute a taking if a regulation goes "too far," which, according to Justice Holmes, occurs when that regulation makes it commercially impracticable to engage in the economic activity under consideration. Here, we are confronted with …. Regulatory? Justifiable interest? Reasonable? Some beneficial use? Central controls. NO TAKING. No beneficial use? Mohan controls. TAKING.