State and Politics in India Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN Themes in Politics Series GENERAL ED._ITORS Rlljeev Bharg ava Partha Chatterjee The Themes in Politics series aims to bring together essays on import­ ant issues in Indian political science and politics - contemporary political theory, Indian social and political thought, and foreign policy, among others. Each volume in the series will bring together the most significant articles and debates on each issue, and will contain a sub­ stantive introduction and an annotated bibliography. Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from ---IU:1..i�, l�OF MJCHlGAN. ,... -- State and Politics in India k Edited by Partha Chatterjee DELID OXFORD UNIVERSITY PRESS CALCUTTA CHENNAI MUMBAI 1998 Dl gl tlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN . Oxford Univ:::,sity Press, Great Clarendon Street, Oxford OX2 6DP J 'J j Oxford New York Athens Aue/eland Bangkok Calcutta ·5 /]-1 2 Florence Cape Town Chennai Dar es Salaam Delhi Hong Kong Istanbul Karachi / <J CJ 8 Kuala Lumpur Madrid Melbourne J,,. -.:ico City Mumbai Nairobi Paris Singapore Taipei Tokyo Toronto and associates in Berlin Ibadan ©Oxford University Press 1997 First Published 1997 Oxford India Paperbacks /998 ISBN O /9 564765 3 Typeset by Resodyn, New Delhi 110070 PrinJed in India at Pauls Press, New Delhi 110020 and published by Manzar Khan, Oxford University Press YMCA Library Building, Jai Singh Road, New Delhi I JO 00/ Digiti zed by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 0 _a-5. .S2 4 � �,47 �v--',:l c,. =t/�/O t> ' Note from the General Editors T eaching of politics in India has long suffered because of the systematic unavailability of readers with the best contem­ porary work on the subject. The most significant writing in Indian politics and Indian political thought is scattered in periodicals; much of the recent work in contemporary political theory is to be found in inaccessible international journals or in collections that reflect more the current temper of Western universities than the need of Indian politics and society. The main objective of this series is to remove this lacuna. 'The series also attempts to cover as comprehensively and usefully as possible the main themes of contemporary research and public debate on politics, to include selections from the writings of lead­ ing specialists in each field, and to reflect the diversity of research methods, ideological concerns and intellecrual styles that charac­ terize the discipline of political science today. We plan to begin with three general volumes, one each in contemponry political theory, Indian politics and Indian political thought. A general volume on international politics and specific volumes ofreadings on particular areas within each of these fields will follow. RIJEEV BHAR.GAVA PARTIIA C!-lATfEIUEE Dig1t1zeo by Google Origi�al rrom UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN Digiti zed by Google Onginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN Preface '"T'iiis volume has been planned to provide a general introduc­ .l tion to th e study of politics in contemporary India. Given the limited number of essays that could be fitted into a single volume, several importmt topics and writings have had to be left out. Besides, a few other essays I would have liked to include could. not be reprinted here because of difficulties with getting permis­ sion from the original publishers. However, I am somewhat reas­ sured because several other volumes in this series will take up the subject of Indian politics in greater thematic detail; the essays that have been left out here will doubtless appear in some of those volumes: This volume is primarily addressed to advanced undergraduate and postgraduate students of political science in South Asian uni­ versities. However, given the interest in the subject among many other kinds of readers, it may be of use to a wider readership. I have attempted as far as practicable to keep the discussion up-to­ date. Apart from my consultations with Rajeev Bhargava, my co­ editor in this series, I have g1eatly benefited from the help given by my colleagues at the Centre for Studies in Social Sciences, Calcutta, in particular Dwaipayan Bhattacharya, Pradip Bose, Vivek Dhareshwar and Anjan Ghosh. I must especially thank the members of the staff of the CSSSC library and reprography sections for their unstinting support without which I could not have compiled this volume in the time available to me. Finally, I thank Oxford University Press for its enthusiasm and efficiency in handling the planning and production of this volume. Calcutta P.C. September 1996 Dlgltlzedby Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN .. Acknowledgements "T"'he publishers wish to thank the following for granting permis1. sion to reprint the articles included in this volwne. &momic mul Politi,al Weekly for Sudipta Kaviraj, 'A Critique of the Passive Revolution', 23, 45-7: 2429-44; Yogendra Yadav, 'Re­ configuration in Indian Politics: State Assembly Elections, 19931995', 31, 2-3: 95-104; T.V. �.athyamurthy, 'Impact of Centre­ State Relations on Indian Politics: An Interpretative Reckoning, 1947-1987', 24, 38: 2133-43; MS.S. Pandian, 'Culture and Subal­ tern Consciousness: An Aspect of the MGR Phenomenon', 24, 30: pp. 62-8; Amrita Basu, 'When Local Riots Are Not Merely Local: Bringing the State Back in Bijnor 1988-1992', 29, 40: 2605-21; Rajni Kothari, 'Rise of the Dalits and the Renewed Debate on Caste', 29, 26: 1589- 94 and Flavia Agnes, 'Protecting Women Against Violence? Review of a Decade of Legislation, 1980-1989', 27, 17: WS19-33. Living Media India Ltd for David Buder, Ashok Lahiri and Pran­ noy Roy, 'India Decides: Elections 1952-1995', in David Buder, Ashok Lahiri and Prannoy Roy (eds), India Dtades: Ekaions 19521995, pp. 7-41. Princeton University Press for James Manor, 'Parties and the Party Sys tem', in Atul Kohli (ed;), India's Dmuxracy: An Analysis of Changing Statt Society Relations, pp. 62-98. Cambridge University Press for Paul Brass, 'NationaJ Power and Local Politics in India: A Twenty-Year Perspective', Modern Asian Studies, 18, 1: 89-118; Atul Kohli, 'From Breakdown to Disorder: West Bengal', in Atul Kohli (ed.), Dtm()(Tacy nnd Discontent: India's Gr<1Wing Crisis of Gov"7Jllhility, pp. 267-96, and Sanjib Baruah, 'Politics of Subnationalism: Society versus State in Assam', Modern Asian Studies, 28, 3: 649-71. Myron Weiner for 'India's Minorities: Who Are They? What Do They Want?', in Ashutosh Varshney (ed.), Tht Indian Paradoz: Essays in Indian Politia, pp. 39-75. Dig1t1zeo by Google Origi�al rrom UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN Contents Figures Introduction: A Political History of Independent India Partba Chatterjee l I. THE SYSTEM I. A Critique of the Passive Revolution Sudipta Kavirllj 41 45 II. THE INS1TIVTIONS 2. Parties and the Party System 89 92 James Manor 3. India Decides: Elections 1952-1995 DtlVid Butler, Asholt Lahiri and Prtm1WJ Roy 4. Reconfiguration in Indian Politics: State Assembly Elections 1993-1995 125 5. Evolving Trends in the Bureaucracy B.P.R. VithaJ 6. Impact of Centre-State Relations on Indian Politics: An Interpretative Reckoning 1947-1987 T. V Satbyamurthy 7. Development Planning and the Indian State 208 Yogmdra Y ""8v m. Partba Chatterjee THE POLmCAL PROCESS: DOMINANCE 8. National Power and Local Politics in India: A Twenty-year Perspective Paul Brass D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm 177 232 271 299 303 UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN X Contents 9. From Breakdown to Order: West Bengal AtuJKDbJi 336 10. Culture and Subaltern Consciousness: An Aspect of the MGR Phenomenon 367 11. When Local Riots are Not Merely Local: Bringing the State Back in, Bijnor 1988-1992 390 M.S.S. Ptmditm Amrita B1ZSU 437 IV. THE POLITICAL PROCESS:-RESISTANCE 12. Rise of the Dalits and the Renewed Debate on Caste 439 13. India's Minorities: Who Are They? What Do They Want? 459 14. Politics of Subnationalism: Society versus State in Assam 496 15. Protecting Women against Violence?: Review of a Decade of Legislation, 1980-1989 521 RAjni KDtbari Myron Weiner SanjibBaruab Flavia Agner A Bibliographic Guith D1g1tizeo by Google 566 Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN Figures 3.1 3.2 3.3 3.4 3.5 3.6 3.7 5.1 9.1 Voter Tum-out, All-India Voter Turn-out, Men and Women Average Turn-out in Lok Sabha Elections Unequal Size of Constituencies in 1991 The Impact of Drawing Boundaries on the Results Splits in the Congress Party since 1952 The Janat2 Party and the BJP since 1977 Lines of Authority, Lines of Influence Political Violence in West Bengal, 1955-1985 Digiti zed by Google Ongmal from 127 127 132 139 142 150 151 222 343 UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN Introduction: A Political Hi�tory of Independent India Partha Chatterjee H alf a century may be considered a reasonable time for begin­ ning to write the outline for a political history of inde­ pendent India. The narrative which follows is a running thread that connects the particular accounts and analyses contained in the readings collected in this volume. Continuities and Transformations Territory Independent India was created in August 1947 through a negotiated act of transfer of power from the British rulers of a colonial empire to the political leadership of two sovereign countries, India and Pakistan. The· ,erritories of British India were partitioned between the two new countries on a principle of religious majorities. Thus provinces with Muslim majorities constituted the territories o_f Pakistan, divided into two wings, one in the west and the other in the east. Two provinces - Punjab and Bengal - were themselves partitioned according to the religious composition of the district populations in those provinces. However, even these principles had to be applied with many qualifications, and several exceptions were incorporated into the final award of the Radcliffe Commission which undertook the task of actually drawing the lines of division on the map of British India. There were some 565 princely states over which the British exer­ cised pararnountcy without actually incorporating those territories Dlgltlzedby Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 2 State and Politics in India into the provinces of British India. According to the terms of the transfer of power, the lapse of British paramountcy meant that the rulers of those states regained full sovereignty, although they were also given the option of joining either India or Pakistan. There was furious diplomatic activity on t h e p- art of the new political auth­ orities of India and Pakistan in the days immediately preceding independence to get the princes to sign the instruments of accession to their respective dominions. Vallabhbhai Patel, the deputy Prime Minister of India, took the initiative in this regard to put together a single consolidated territorial entity over which the newly inde­ pendent Indian state would exercise sovereignty.1 The princes were first asked to concede to the Indian union only the powers of defence, external affairs and communications, and were invited to continue participating in the upper house of the Dominion legisla­ ture where a new constitution was being made. In the end, most of the princes of states surrounded by or contiguous to the territory of India - 554 states, to be exact - agreed to join. The states were scattered over many regions - in Kashmir and the Punjab, in Rajasthan, in Gujarat and Saurashtra, in the Deccan, in the Vmdhya regions of central India, in the Chhattisgarh area, in Orissa, in Travancore-Cochin and Mysore, on the borders of Bengal and in the Khasi hills. hnmediately after accession, a con­ certed attempt was made by the leadership in Delhi to consolidate the territories of the states into larger administrative units similar to the provinces. The legal forin of seeking the consent of the ruler was maintained in each case, but the political argument of the inevitability of popular democratic rule was frequently used, often with telling effect. The rulers of the Orissa and the Chhattis­ garh states were persuaded to allow their territories to be merged with the provinces of Orissa and Central Provinces, respectively; in return, they were allowed a privy purse which they would enjoy in perpetuity. This method of merger was also followed in the case of the Deccan and the Gujarat states whose territories were similarly joined with that of the province of Bombay, and for several smaller states in other regions. Two hundred and sixteen states were merged into provinces in this manner. The bulk of the stat�s were, however, clustered in several contiguous areas in Kathiawad, Rajasthan, Punjab, the Vmdhyas and central India. I This is described in detail in V.P. Menon, Tbt Story ofthe lnttgrt,tiun ofthe Indum StllUS (Bombay: Orient Longman, 1961). Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN Introduction 3 After much negotiation, the rulers of these states agreed to form unions of States called Rajmandals with one of them being called the Rajpramukh and acting as the head of the union. Six such unions were formed by integration, viz. Saurashtra, Vindhya Pradesh, Madhya Bharat, Patiala and East Punjab States Union (PEPSU), Rajasthan, and Travancore-Cochin, incorporating 310 states. Mysore, one of the largest states, became an administntive unit on its own, as did a few others. Each union had its own constituent assembly to draft a constitution for 'responsible gov­ ernment, and most rulers thought they would prefer some kind of federal arrangement within their unions. However, some of the states had active democratic movements, often allied with the Indian National Congress, which played an important role in shaping the political relations of the states with the Indian Union. In the end, with the making of the Constitution of India in 1950, all of the constituent assemblies of the Unions resolved to adopt the Indian Constitution. In three cases, however, there were difficulties with accession. In Junagadh, a tiny state in Kathiawad surrounded by Indian territory, the ruling prince signed up for Pakistan. The neighbour­ ing states had all joined India, the population was predominantly Hindu and there was an active Congress movement in the state which demanded unification with India. The matter became part of the series of disputes that now flared up between India and Pakistan and raised the crucial question of whether independence was to be seen as the result of a legal transfer of power from one authority to another or of the assertion of the democratic will of the people. On the question of Junagadh, Pakistan insisted that with the lapse of British paramountcy, each ruler had the right to join either India or Pakistan irrespective of the geographical loca­ tion of'his state or the ethnic composition of its population. India argued that if negotiations with rulers did not produce a satisfac­ tory agreement, the most fair and democratic way of resolving the matter would be to hold a plebiscite among the people of the state. Faced with growing popular agitation and pressure from the In­ dian authorities, the Nll,_wab of Junagadh decided in late October 1947 that he could not liold out any more and fled to Pakistan. The administration of the state was taken over by the Indian government and a referendum was held in February 1948 in which there was an overwhelming vote approving the accession to India. Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 4 State and Politics in India The Nizam of Hyderabad refused to join either of the dominions and insisted on his right to head an independent and sovereign kingdom. Negotiations for accession continued for several months in which the Indian government made many concessions that had not been given to the other states. At the same time, it also insisted that if the Nizam was unwilling to accede, the matter should be settled by a popular plebiscite which the ruling group in Hyderabad was clearly reluctant to race. The Nizam, however, overplayed his hand and in September 1948 Indian troops moved into Hyderabad. The Nizam signed the instruments of accession on the same ternlS as the other princes and in 1950 the Constitution of India came to apply to Hyderabad. InJarnmu and Kashmir too, the Manaraja did not sign in favour of either dominion until late October 1947 when Parhan tribes­ men from across the border in Pakistan threatened to overrun the Kashmir valley. On a request from the Maharaja for immediate military assistance, the Indian government insisted that he fust sign the instruments of accession, which he did. Indian troops were flown in to Kashmir and after pushing back the raiders some distance, a ceasefrre was agreed upon. The Maharaja in the mean­ time had agreed to nominate Sheikh Abdullah, the leader of the National Conference, as Premier. When the Indian government agreed to refer the dispute with Pakistan over Kashmir to the United Nations, it pledged to hold a plebiscite in Kashmir under UN auspices. This plebiscite, however, has never been held. Sub­ sequently, a separate constitution of Jammu and Kashmir was promulgated in 1953; this was therefore the only former princely state which finally got its own constitution, highlighting the very special circumstances of its accession to India. The Jammu and Kashmir constitution largely resembles the Indian Constitution with the important qualification, however, that unlike,the other states of the Indian union, the residual powers belong to the state and not to the union. A part of the original territory of the princely state lying beyond the line of ceasefire is still administered from Pakistan by a government of Azad Kashmir. There were two other vestiges of European colonial rule in India: the Ponuguese colonies in Goa and in a few pockets on the Gujarat coast, and the French settlements in Pondicherry and Chandernagore. In 1954, following an agreement with France, Pondicherry became part of India and was subsequently made a Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN Introduction 5 . Union Territory and Chandemagore was incorporated into West Bengal. The Portuguese government, however, refused to give up its colonial possessions and in 1960 Indian troops occupied Goa and incorporated the Portuguese territories into India. One can see, therefore, that there is nothing natural or im­ memorial about the territorial boundaries of independent India. They exist as the result of a particular mode of transfer of power from British colonial rule and of political negotiations between the leaders of independent India and the rulers of the princely states. The subsequent process of the consolidation of this ter­ ritory into a domain for the exercise of a new governmental power is, of course, a part of the story of Indian politics since inde­ pendence. The only addition to that territory was the incorpora, �on in April 1975 of Sikkim as a constituent state of the Indian union. Earlier, Sikkim was a sovereign kingdom which through treaties with India had a protectorate status. The Constitution The Constituent Assembly which produced the Constitution of the Indian republic in 1950 was not elected by direct universal suffrage but was formed in 1946 as a result of indirect elections by members of the different provincial legislatures who themsel­ ves had been elected by a very restricted electorate. After parti­ tion, as many as 82 per cent of the members of the Constituent Assembly were from the Congress. However, the political leader­ ship was especially careful to include in the Assembly repre­ sentatives of a large range of opinion from different regions of the country and sections of the population, including several leaders such as B.R. Ambedkar, Shyama Prasad Mookerjee or Mohammed Saadulla who during their political careers had often been strongly opposed to the Congress. The Assembly also included many leg;u and constitutional experts. The radically new features of the constitutional system of in­ dependent India, when compared with that prevailing under colonial rule, were, frrst, a sovereign legislature elected by direct universal suffrage without communal representation but with re­ servations for the scheduled castes and tribes and, second, the explicit constitutional guarantee of a set of fundamental rights of all citizens. It provided for a parliamentary system of government Dlgltlzedby Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN , St11te and Politics in India of the British type with an executive responsible to Parliament but with an indirectly elected President as the head of state. It also provided for an independent judiciary with certain powers of judicial review of laws made by Parliament The Constitution was also a federal one, but of a very distinct kind, with state governments responsible to directly elected state legislatures and a distribution of powers between the union and the states that was heavily inclined towards the union. As a federal system, the Indian Constitution was far more centralized than most federations elsewhere, and in this respect often closely fol­ lowed the provisions of the earlier Government of India Act of 1935. The State Apparatus The basic apparatus of governmental administration in inde­ pendent India was inherited from the colonial period, although there soon occurred a huge incrc;ase in its size. It consisted of a small elite cadre belonging to the all-India services and a much larger corps of functionaries organized in the provincial services. The Indian members of the Indian Civil Service, the much ac­ claimed 'steel frame' of the British Raj, were retained after In­ dependence, but a new service called the Indian Administrative Service, modelled on the ICS, was constituted after 1947 as its successor. The crucial unit of the governmental apparatus was the district administration which, under the charge of the disttict officer, was principally responsible as in colonial ti.mes for main­ taining law and order but was soon also to become the agency for developmental work. The basic structure of civil and criminal law as well as of its administration was also inherited from the colonial period. The major difference, of course, was in the creation of a Supreme Court and its position within the new constitutional system. But apart from the new issues that arose regarding the relation be­ tween Parliament and the judiciary, the working of the high courts and district courts maintained an unbroken history from colonial rimes, continuing the same practices of legal tradition and ·precedent. The Indian armed forces too maintained a continuing history from the colonial period. The British ideology of a professional Dlgltlzedby Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN Introductum 7 army strictly under the control of the political leadership was successfully maintained i n the period after independence, and unlike most other countries, there was not even a joint command of the anny, navy and air forces except in the office of the political head of government. Framework of a New Order Tht Reorganization ofSt11tes When the Constitution was inaugurated in 1950, the country was divided into four kinds of states. The Part A states were former provinces of British India, viz. Assam, Bihar, Bombay, Madhya Pradesh, Madras, Orissa, Punjab, Utt2r Pradesh and West Benpl. The Part B states were the products of the integration of the prin­ cely states; they were Hyderabad, Jammu and Kashmir; Madhya Bharat, Mysore, PEPSU, Rajasthan, Saurashtra and Travancore­ Cochin. The Part C states were either the former Chief Com­ missioners' provinces or smaller units formed by the integration of the princely states, viz. Ajmer, Bilaspur, Bhopal, Coorg, Delhi, Himachal Pradesh, Kutch, Manipur, Tripura and Vindhya Pradesh. Finally, there was a Part D state - the Andaman and Nicobar Islands. This particular structure did not follow any coherent principle of organization of territories and was simply the result of a his­ torical cumulation. As f.ar as principles were concerned, the idea that the units of India should be the linguistic provinces was something that the Indian National Congress had upheld since the rise of Gandhi. In 1919-20, the Congress had reorganized its own provincial and district committee structure according to the linguistic principle, disregarding the administrative units of British India. Thus there were Maharashtra and Gujarat provincial com­ mittees in Bombay province, a Kerala PCC when there was no Kerala, an Andhra PCC when there was no Andhra, and s o on. In 1953, after a massive popular agitation, the Telugu-speaking state of Andhra Pradesh was created. This brought up the question of whether the entire structure of states in India should be reor­ ganized according to the linguistic principle. In 1954, a States Reorganization Commission was set up to look into this matter. Following its recommendations, the states were reorganized in Dlgltlzedby Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 8 State and Politia in India I 956. The distinction between the former provinces of British India and the princely states was completely erased. Instead of the four-tier stt11cture, there were now only states and union ter­ ritories. The linguistic principle was recognized in the formation of states, but only partially. The principle, however, continued to be asserted in mass agitations and in 1960 Bombay was divided into Maharashtra and Gujarat,· while Punjab was divided into Punjab and Haryana in 1966. The Congress Party Before Independence, the Congress had run some provincial gov­ ernments only briefly.and had joined the interim government a t the centre only in 1946. Until that time, it was a mass party with a well-developed organizational structure starting with village and taluka units at the bottom and then, in ascendin!J order, district, provincial and all-India committees, each elected by the lower units. At the highest level, the All India Congress Committee (AICC) elected a president and a working committee to look after the regular functioning of the organization as a whole. After Independence, the Congress was in charge of running the central government as well as most of the state governments. It soon became obvious that the entire focus of party activity would now be on the performance of its governmental wing. But this also meant a new centre of leadership around the Prime Minister and his cabinet What would be the relation between the governmental wing and the party wing? Should the Congress president and working committee have a say in the making of decisions by a Congress government? Or should a mass party of such long stand­ ing as the Congress accept that it must now follow the lead given to it by government ministers? These were the questions that were raised within the Congress in the period immediately following Independence. Jawaharlal Nehru was president of the Congress when he became Prime Minister in the interim government in 1946. Soon after, he de­ cided to resign bis party post.J.B. Kripalani, the Congress Socialist leader, succeeded Nehru but immediately ran into serious dis­ agreements with the ministerial wing over the issue of the relation­ ship between party and government. Nehru, along with bis senior colleagues in gove.rnment, felt that the party should only provide Dlgltlzedby Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN ' Introduction 9 long-term guidance in the matter of general policy and could not expect the government to refer every decision to it for approval. Kripalani, on the other hand, thought that the party's position was being undermined. According to him it was the party which kept in constant touch with the people in the villages and in towns and reflected changes in their will and temper. It is 'the party from which the Government of the day derives its power. Any action which weakens the organization of the party or lowers its prestige in the eyes of the people must sooner or later undermine the position of the Governn1ent.2 In November 1947, Kripalani resigned as Congress president; soon he would leave the Congress altogether along with many other socialists. Between 1948 and 1951, the issue of the relationship between party and government remained at the centre of controversy within the Congress. The underlying political tensions arose out of the differences of some sections of Congress leaders with the emerging policies of the Nehru government. The conservative groups, in particular, were in favour of a much tougher policy towards Pakistan and sharply opposed to the proposals for new social legislation on the reform of personal laws and greater state control over the economy. They decided to assert their' hold over the party machinery in order to curb the autonomy of the govern­ ment in pursuing these policies. In the election of the Congress president in 1948, Pattabhi Sitaramayya, the candidate put up by Nehru's supporters, won a narrow victory. But in 1950, the right wing was able to gain ascendancy with the election as president of Purushottamdas Tandon. The death of Vallabhbhai Patel in December 1950 deprived this group of its most powerful figure within the government, and with the first general elections ap­ proaching, the tussle over control of the party organization reached a climax. In August 1951, Nehru resigned from the working committee, claiming that there were serious policy dif­ ferences between him and the party leadership. The parliamentary party expressed its confidence in Nehru's leadership. Within a few weeks, Tandon was forced to resign and the AICC elected 2J.B. Kripalani's speech to AICC'delegates, November 1947, cited in Stanley A. Kochanek, The Congress PIIT'tJ oflnditl: Tbt l)yntmricsofOm-PartyDtm()(T11cy (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1968), pp. 10-11. Dig1t1zeo by Google Origi�al rrom UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 1 O State and Politics in India Nehru as Congress president. For the moment at least, the superiority of the government wing of the party was established by creating a single unified leadership. Nehru continued as Congress president until 1954. By then, the Congress largely came to accept his view that the function of the party was principally to carry to the people the message rep­ resented by the policies of the government. For the next decade . or so, this remained the pattern of relationship between government and party. When U.N. Dhebar was elected Congress presi­ dent in 1954, he said quite clearly: 1t is a mistalce to consider that there is a dual leadership in the country....There is only one leader in India todlly and that is Pandit JawaharlaJ Nehru. Whether he carries the mantle of Congress Pre­ sidentship on his shoulders or not, ultimately, the whole country looks to him for support and guidance.3 The Congress in the St11tes Before 1967, the usual description of the party system in India was 'one-party dominance', the one party being, obviously, the Con­ gress.Sometimes it was also caJleq, simply, the 'Congress system'. In the ftrst three general elections, the Congress won around 45 per cent of the votes and 75 per cent of the seats in Parliament. Compared to that, the largest opposition party (the Socialist party in 1951, the Praja Socialist party in 1957 and the Communist Party of India in 1962) could manage only around 10 per cent of the votes and less than 5 per cent of the seats. The concept of 'one­ party dominance' also implied a similar overwhelming position of the Congress in all of the states. Clearly, this dominance had been built up in course of the decades of organized political activity b y the Congress in the nationalist movement in different parts of the country. However, given the fact that substantial parts of inde­ pendent India were not part of British India, the Congress did not always inherit a position of equal dominance in all the states at the time of independence. In fact, in the 1950s, it was often in those states which included large parts of the territories of former princely states that the competition to the Congress was the 3 Speech by U.N. Dhebar,Janwry 1955, cited in Kochanek. Ctmgrtss P11rty, p. 61. Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN lntroduaion II strongest - states such as Andhra Pradesh, Kerala, Madhya Pradesh, Manipur, Orissa, Punjab, Rajasthan and Tripura. Despite some variations in strength, however, the Congress did rule in every state until 1967. The only exceptions wereJammu and Kashmir where it was the National Conference which was the ruling party (although from 1953, after the removal and arrest of Sheikh Abdullah, the National Conference under Bakshi Ghulam Mohammed virtually became the Kashmir unit of the CongrC$), Kerala which had a CPI-led government for a brief period in 1957-9 (a government that was removed by central intervention) and Nagaland which became a state in 1963 and had a Na ga National Organization government.Just as the governmental wing of the Congress asserted its dominance over the party at the centre, so did Congress rule in the states focus around powerful Chief Ministers. An interesting characteristic of the one-party dominance system i n the Nehru period was the large degree of autonomy that the provincial party units were able to assert in relation to the central party leadership. The PCCs largely became financially independ­ ent, raising their own party funds for running the organization or fighting elections and distributing patronage through their mini­ sters in the state government. Their recommendations for can­ didates for parliamentary or assembly seats were almost always accepted without modification by the central leadership, except when the state party was de,eply divided. Congress politics in the states was dominated in die Nehru period by powerful Chief Ministers like N. Sanjiva Reddy (Andhra Pradesh), B.P. Chaliha (Assam), Sri Krishna Sinha (Bihar), Y.S. Parmar (Himachal Pradesh), S. Nijalingappa (Mysore), Y.B. Chavan (Maharashtra), H.K. Mahatab (Orissa), Pratap Singh Kairon (Punjab), Mohan Lal Sukhadia (Rajasthan), K. Kamaraj (Madras), Sampoornanand and C.B. Gupta (Uttar Pradesh) and B.C. Roy (West Bengal), or occasionally by party bosses such as S.K. Patil in Bombay or Atulya Ghosh in West Bengal who worked in close association with their respective Chief Ministers. The influence and autonomy of the state units in the Congress party structure were shown most clearly in 1964 when the successor toJawaharlal Nehru as Prime Minister was effectively chosen by Kamaraj as Congress pr�ident in as­ sociation with the Chief Ministers and party presidents of the major states. Dig1t1zeo by Google Origi�al rrom UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN I2 State and Politics in India The Developmental State Apart from the dominance of the Congress at the centre and in the states, a very important feature of the framework of political rule , established in the Nehru period ,vas the developmental state, inter­ ' vening in the economy, planning and guiding its growth and trying 1 directly to promote the welfare of the population. This was perhaps I, the principal governmental function t;hat legitimized the position of the Congress leadership within the new post-colonial state. It meant considerable state intervention in the economy, not only through progressive taxation of personal and corporate in­ comes or the provision by the state of public services such as education, health and transport, all of which had become hallmarks / of the new welfare state even in advanced capitalist economies in the period after World War II. In addition, the state in India in the Nehru period consciously chose elements from socialist re­ 1 . gimes such as the Soviet Union in order to create a planned / economy, albeit within the framework of a mixed and not a so­ l cialist economy, where the state sector would control the 'com­ i manding heights of the economy'. The idea was to industrialize ··, rapidly by setting up new public enterprises in areas such as metals, , minerals, machine building, chemical industries, fuel, power and J transport through direct investments by the state. Private capital 1 ! was meant to be confined primarily to the consumer and inter­ / mediate goods sectors. Rapid industrial growth was seen to be the · key to the removal of poverty in the country and the provision of welfare for the people.)A Planning Commission was set up as an expert body relatively ihdependent of the central government with the function of defining the goals and strategies of development and carrying out investment planning. Although the First Five Year Plan was launched in 1951, it was really with the Second Five Year Plan (1956-61), prepared under the guidance of P.C. Mahalanobis, that the characteristic strategy ofIndian indus­ trialization in the Nehru period was inaugurated. The Interregnum End of the Nehru Era Before speaking of how the framework of political rule built i n the Nehru period became unsettled, one further feature of that D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN Introduction I3 framework - India's foreign policy - must be mentioned. Since this will be the subject of a separate volume in this series, foreign policy will not-be discussed at any length in this volume. Neverthe. less, a description of the political order in the Nehru period, and even of its economic strategy, will be incomplete without a mention of the policy of non-alignment. The policy was developed in the context 9f the bipolar world that emerged after World War II with two rival military blocs around the two super powers - the United States and the Soviet Union - claiming to represent two opposed economic and political systems and, indeed, two contending paths of social development. The Indian policy of non-alignment sought to strike a middle ground by refusing to align with either military bloc and choosing a path of state-sponsored development within the social framework of capitalist democracy. Pursuing this foreign policy, the Indian government under Nehru sought to build up a third bloc of non-aligned nations consisting largely of the newly independent countries of Asia and Africa, and to seek the aid of both the Western and the socialist blocs in the economic and technological fields. The border war with China in 1962 was the first major occasion when the wisdom of Nehru's foreign and defence policy was seriously questioned at home. Indian positions at several places along the disputed Himalayan border had to be abandoned as its troops retreated; the policy of non-alignment too seemed to lose credibility because India now had to seek military aid from the United States. Nehru's biographer writes: 'No one who lived in India through the winter months of 1962 can fo:-Eet the deep humiliation felt by all Indians, irrespective of party. Criticism of Nehru's leadership began to be voiced both within and outside the Congress. Hardly a year after the general elections of 1962, which the Congress had, as expected, won, its candidates lost three by-elections to J.B. Kripalani, Ram Manohar Lohia and M.R. Masani, three of the government's bitterest critics. In August 1963, for the first time in sixteen years in power, Nehru's govern:­ ment faced a no-confidence motion in Parliament. There were also reports of Nehru's deteriorating health. The origins and motives of the so-called Kamaraj Plan have been a subject of conq-oversy: it has often been attributed to 4 Sarvepalli Gopal,]1TW11har/al Nthnl:A Biography (Delhi: Oxford University · Press, 1984), vol. 3, p. 232. . Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 14 Statt and Politics in India discussions between two Chief Ministers - Kamaraj of Madras and Biju Patnaik of Orissa.5 The Plan,· as proposed by Kamaraj and accepted by the Congress Working Committee in August 1963, was to ask leading Congressmen in government to leave their posts and devote themselves to the task of revitalizing the party organization. Accordingly, front-ranking ministers such as Morarji Desai, Lal Bahadur Shastri, S.I(. Patil and Jagjivan Ram and Chief Ministers such as Kamara;, Biju Patnaik, C.B. Gupta, Bakshi Ghulam Mohammed and Binodanand Jha of Bihar re­ signed from their governments. In October 1963, K Kamaraj was elected Congress president. The Kamaraj plan has been interpreted in many ways: as Nehru's ploy to reassert his control over the party, as an attempt by left-wingers to remove Morarji Desai and S.K Patil from the government, as a preemptive strategy for a possible battle o f succession. As events unfolded, it became clear that the most significant effect ofthe plan was to give to the Congress presidency and the working committee a degree of authority they had not enjoyed for many years. Indeed, as factional and ideological loyal­ ties were put to the test in those months of crisis, the most powerful group that formed within the Congress was precisely around the new party president. Popularly dubbed the Syndicate, the group comprised Kamaraj, Sanjiva Reddy, Nijalingappa, S.K Patil and Atulya Ghosh, all of them Chief Ministers or party bosses from non-Hindi-speaking states. When Nehru died in May 1964, it was the Syndicate which secured the election by the parliamen­ tary party of Lal Bahadur Shastri as the next Prime Minister. The most important event in Shastri's brief tenure as Prime Minister was the war with Pakistan in October 1965. I t raised his stature immensely and at public meetings he drew crowds as large as Nehru did before him. He worked closely with Kamaraj as party president and in August 1965 played a crucial role in securing, against the open challenge put up by Morarji Desai, Kamaraj's reelection to the post. Lal Bahadur Shastri died inJanuary 1966. This time the work­ ing committee was unable to secure a unanimous succession since Morarji Desai insisted on a vote. The Syndicate decided to put up S Michael Brecher, Nth"'� M11ntlt: Tbt Politics of Sucarsion in JndiJ, (New Yorlt: Frederick A. Praeger, 1966). D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN Introduction 15 Indira Gandhi as its nominee. The Congress members of parlia­ ment chose her against Morarji Desai by a huge margin. Once again, the powerful group of regional party leaders assened its hold over the central structure of political rule. .• The 1967 Ekctions By this time, however, some of the problems of the economic strategy of rapid industrialization began to be felt. By the middle o f the 1960s, there was an acute food shortage in the country, making it necessary for the government to import large quantities o f foodgrains. There was also a severe foreign exchange crisis, exacerbated by hugely increased defence expenditures. Soon after its formation, therefore, Indira Gandhi's government was forced to go in for a large devaluation of the Indian rupee. With high food prices and a slowing down of growth, economic hardship was at its peak. This was reflected in massive, and often violent, politi­ cal agitations all over the country. In this situation, it was only to be expected that in the 1967 elections the Congress would not repeat its earlier overwhelming victories. But the setbacks that occurred surprised even the pes­ simists. The Congress vote dropped by almost 5 per cent, and while it had held 74 per cent of the seats in the previous parliament, it now managed to win only 54 per cent. Even more stunning was the number of states in which it failed to win a majority (or lost it because of defections soon after the elections): there were as many as nine states - Punjab, Haryana, Uttar Pradesh, Madhya Pradesh, Bihar, West Bengal, Orissa, Madras and Kerala -which now had non-Congress governments. This brought in a complete­ ly new situation in Indian politics, not only because the Congress had lost its overwhelming dominance at the centre but also because the federal structure was now called upon to deal with the relations between a Congress government at the centre and several non­ Congress governments in the states. Non-Congress G(f1Jernmmts Although the Congress was defeated in several states in 1967, it was not replaced in power by a single party, except in the case of Madras where the DMK won an absolute majority and Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 16 State and Politics in India C. Annadurai became Chief Minister. The non-Congress gov­ ernments that were formed in the other states were coalitions of several parties, often having little ideological similarity, even though a common minimum programme was usually formulated. Thus in J3ihar, a Samyukta Vidhayak DaJ was formed between the SSJ?; the PSP, the Jana Sangh, the Jan Kranti Dal (which later merged with the Bharatiya Kranti Dal) and the CPI. The SVD commanded a majority in the assembly and Mahamaya Prasad Sinha of the JKD became the first non-Congress Chief Minister of Bihar. In Punjab, all the non-Congress parties in the assembly - the Akali Dal (Sant Group), the CPl(M), the CPI, the Jana Sangh, the Akali Dal (Master Group), the SSP and the Republican Party - came together to form a Popular United Front which elected Gurnam Singh of the Akali Dal (Sant Group) as its leader and Chief Minister. In West Bengal, the two non­ Congress fronts, one led by the C.Pl(M) and the other by the Bangla Congress, came together to fonn the United Democratic Front consisting of fourteen parties. Ajoy Mukherjee of the Bangla Congress became the first non-Congress Chief Minister of West Bengal. In· Kerala, a United Front ministry headed by EM.S. Namboodiripad of the CPl(M) came to power. In Orissa, the Swatantra Party, consisting mostly of former princes, formed a coalition ministry under R.N. Singh Deo with a breakaway Congress group called theJana Congress, led by the former Chief Minister, H.K. Mahatab. In Haryana, where the Congress had won an absolute majority in the elections, the government of Bhagwat Dayal Sharma was defeated in the assembly within a week of assuming office. A large chunk of dissident Congressmen left the party and joined the opposition. A United Front was formed and Rao Birendra Singh became its leader and Chief Minister. In Madhya Pradesh too, there were defections from the Congress, exemplified in particular i by Vjay Raje Scindia, the Rajmata of Gwalior, who left the Con­ gress and declared her support for the Jana Sangh. Four months after the elections, the government of D.P. Mishra was defeated. An SVD ministry, led by G.N. Singh and consisting of Congress defectors, the Rajmata's group, the Jana Sangh, the SSP and the PSP, came to power. In Uttar Pradesh, the Congress could not win an absolute majoiity and was also hampered by a leadership tussle between C.B. Gupta and Charan Singh. Nevertheless, the D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN Introduction 17 Governor asked C.B: Gupta to form the ministry. Three weeks later, the government collapsed when Charan Singh, along with his followers, joined the opposition. Charan Singh became Chief Minister of an SVD ministry. However, it was not as though one-party dominance was re­ placed by an alternating party system. The coming together of opposition parties to form non-Congress governments in the states did not produce the consolidation of an alternative ideo­ logical or organizational formation, nor indeed, as would soon become clear, did it mean the end of Congress dominance. Soon after their formation, the non-Congress governments were them­ selves thrown into crises as they failed to hold their ranks together. Defections became the order of the day as, one after the other, the United Front governments in Uttar Pradesh, Bihar, West Bengal, Haryana, Punjab and Madhya Pradesh were ousted. A Congress government was installed in Madhya Pradesh with the support of defectors, while governments of defectors were in­ stalled with Congress support in Bihar, West Bengal and Punjab. Even these did not last long and president's rule was imposed in Haryana, West Bengal, Bihar, Uttar Pradesh and Punjab. It has been calculated that whereas in the ten-year period between 195 7 and 1967 there had been in all of India a total of 542 legislators changing parties, in a single year following the 1967 elections there were as many as 438 defections.6 This period of the formation and collapse of non-Congress governments in the states also for the first time turned into a major controversy the question of centre-State relations and especially the role of the Governor. In Rajasthan, where no party had an absolute majority, Sampoornanand, the Governor, faced a barrage of criti­ cism when, after much prevarication, he decided to ask Mohan Lal Sukhadia as the leader of the single largest party to form the government. Sampoornanand was accused of having acted in a partisan manner since he refused to consider the loyalties of inde­ pendents, many of whom had expressed their support for the non-Congress United Fl'bnt. The protests led to a situation of serious unrest, forcing the Union government to declare Pres­ ident's rule in Rajasthan for a few months. In Haryana, where defections by legislators reached the most extreme limits, Governor 6 Subhash C. Kashyap, 11,e Politia ofP(IWer: Defections 1171dState Politics in India (Delhi: National, 1974), p. 15. Dlgltlzedby Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 18 St11te and Politics in India B.N. Chakravarty recommended President's rule even when Rao Birendra Singh's ministty commanded a majority since he felt the government had lost stability and was only retaining its majority by engineering repeated counter-defections. In West Bengal, in a situation of growing industrial and agrarian unrest and dissensions within the ruling UDF, the Governor Dhanna Vira, after urging the Chief Minister to set an early date for a trial of strength in the assembly, dismissed Ajoy Mulcherjee's government and installed a minority ministry formed by defectors with Congress support. The action was roundly criticized and led to widespread unrest cul­ minating in the imposition of President's rule. The Congress Split The 1967 elections were a severe blow to the Congress. Not only was the party ousted from power in several states, the period immediately before and after the elections also saw a tremendous weakening of its internal strength, with constant dissension and acrimony in the ranks, rampant factionalism and a tide of defec­ tions. There was a general feeling that the old guard was too set in its conservative ways, mired in corruption and out of touch with the people. The so-called Young Turks belonging to the Socialist Forum within the Congress, who now gathered around Indira Gandhi, were particularly strident in their criticism of the party bosses and blamed them for the election debacle. The Syndicate, on the other hand, began to feel that the Prime Minister was moving away from party control and trying to build up an auto­ nomous centre of power. Things came to a head at the Baµgalore session of the AICC in July 1969. Indira Gandhi presehted to the Congress a set of 'stray thoughts' on economi<policy, arguing for land reforms, restriction of monopolies, nationalization of banks and other radical measures. Although leaders like Morarji Desai were vocal against the proposals, the Syndicate members were quick to see that to oppose them would mean further unpopularity. The Prime Minister's note was passed by the AICC. The Syndicate struck back when the time came to select the Congress candidate for the upcoming Presidential election. Indira Gandhi had suggested the names ofV.V. Giri, theVice-President, or Jagjivan Ram, the most prominent scheduled caste member of her cabinet. But the Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN Introduction 19 Congress parliamentary board overruled her suggestion and in­ stead nominated N. Sanjiva Reddy. As soon as the Ban galore session ended, Indira Gandhi re­ moved Morarji Desai from her cabinet, took up the finance portfolio herself and announced the nationalization of fourteen major banks. At the same time, V.V. Giri decided to contest the election for President as an independent candidate and appealed for a 'vote of conscience'. Nijalingappa, the Congress president, asked for a whip to be issued requiring all Congress legislators to vote for Sanjiva Reddy, the official candidate. Jagjivan Ram and Fakhruddin Ali Ahmed, acting on behalf of Indira Gandhi, declared that all legislators must be allowed to vote 'according to their conscience'. It was a trial of strength between the Syn­ dicate and Indira Gandhi, with parties like the Communists, the other left parties, the Akalis, the DMK and the Muslim League supporting the latter. Giri won the election on second preference votes, securing a majority in the Parliament and in eleven of the states. While the Congress was split right down the middle, that itself would turn out to be a major triumph for Indira Gandhi. The Prime Minister's supponers now demanded a requisition meeting of the AICC to elect a new Congress president. In November 1969, two rival meetings, both claiming to be of the working committee, were held at the same time, one presided over by Nijalingappa and the other by Indira Gandhi. A few days later, Nijalingappa's working committee expelled Indira Gandhi from the pany, whereas the Congress parliamentary pany, at­ tended by 330 out of 432 members, declared this move 'invalid and unjustified'. It was clear that Indira Gandhi had asserted her hold over a majority of Congress parliamentarians. Outside the party, her, popularity was at its peak. A requisitioned AICC meet­ ing was held in November 1969 at which Nijalingappa was re­ moved from the post of party president. A month later, Jagjivan Ram was elected president of what was now called the Congress (Requisitionists). Sixty-two Congress members of the Lok Sabha had declared their opposition to the Prime Minister and, forming a bloc called the Congress (Organization), had joined the opposition. Indira Gandhi's government was now reduced to a minority but con­ tinued in office with the support of the DMK, the CPI, the Akali Dal, the Muslim League and some independents. In September Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 20 State and Politics in India 1970, Indira Gandhi moved a constitutional amendment for the abolition of privy purses and privileges of the former rulers of the princely states. The amendment was very narrowly defeated in the Rajya Sabha, upon which privy purses were abolished by a Pres­ idential order. The order was then struck down as unconstitutional by the Supreme Court. In December 1970, the Prime Minister decided not to continue any further with her minority govern­ ment. For the first time since Independence, Parliament was dis­ solved before completing its full tenn when Indira Gandhi asked for fresh elections. The Congress Restoration The 1971 Elections At the time of its dissolution, the Lok Sabha of 523 seats had a party composition in which the Congress (R) had 228 members, the Congress (0) 65, the Swatantra Party 35, the Jana Sangh 33, the DMK 24, the CPI 24, the CPl(M) 19, the SSP 17 and the PSP 15, besides members of other smaller parties and independ­ ents. For the 1971 elections, Indira Gandhi received the support of the CPI, the DMK, the Akali Dal and a section of the PSP. But she faced an opposition alliance consisting of the Congress (0), the Jana Sangh, the Swatantra Party, the SSP and the BKD. Indira Gandhi's election campaign was stridently populist, the principal slogan being garibi hatao (remove poverty). It was the most massive election campaign undertaken in India until that time. It was also the first time that elections to Parliament were separated from elections to the state assemblies, making national issues the ex­ clusive focus of the campaign. The results were a surprise even to her supporters. The Con­ gress (R) won 350 seats, while the parties of the opposition alliance were routed. Even in the Congress (0) strongholds of Mysore and Gujarat, it was a sweep for the Congress (R). Only the DMK and the Left parties, many of which were now aligned with Indira Gandhi, retained their strength. Ideologically, there seemed to have occurred a decisive leftward swing in the country as a whole. In 1971 again, the political leadership in East Pakistan declared its autonomy from the western wing of the country. There was virtual military occupation of East Pakistan and a massive influx Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN lntroduaum 21 of refugees across the borders into West Bengal and Tripl11"2. Indira Gandhi at this time made a series of international diplo­ matic manoeuvres - signed a treaty of friendship with the Soviet Union, withstood the pressures exerted by the United States and launched a war to liberate Bangladesh. The military action was well-planned and swift and the Pakistan army in the eastern sector surrendered within two weeks. The Bangladesh war boosted Indira Gandhi's image to unprecedented heights and she began to be acclaimed as the leader of one of the world's more powerful nations. It also sealed the close ties between her government and that o f the Soviet Union. Indira's Congress To understand the structure of the restored Congress under Indira Gandhi and how it differed from the Congress in Nehru's time, we will have to consider the changes that had taken place in the country in the two decades since Independence. Many of these changes were, in f.act, the direct result of the policies and actions of the government in the Nehru period. First of all, the idea was now fmnly established that the state was -:, the principal, and in many instances the sole, agent of bettering the 'I condition of the people and providing relief in times of adversity. _ Unlike in the days before Independence, when most modem in­ stitutions of education, health, culture, sports or social welf.are in the country had been set up through voluntary action, by raising contributions from both rich and poor and often under the leader­ ship of nationalist political organizations, now the general expecta­ tion among all classes of people was that _the state must perform this role. The performance of particular parties and leaders came to be judged by how much they had 'done' for their respective constituents. Second, the particular strategy of economic development fol­ lowed in the Nehru period produced a division between large public undertakings in the capital goods and infrastructure sectors and private capitalists, dominated by a few monopoly houses, in ·, the consumer goods sector. The public sector grew rapidly and � the urban middle class and a large section of the working class became dependent upon its-further expansion. Agricultural growth did not receive much attention and by the mid- l960s there was a Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 22 State mul Politics in India massive food crisis. To tackle this, a strategy for a quick increase in foodgrains production through state subsidy of irrigation water, seeds and fertilizers, and government support for minimum food­ grain prices was formulated. Widely known as the 'green rev­ olution', this strategy relied heavily on the enterprise of larger farmers and was first tried out in the better irrigated zones of Punjab, Haryana and western UP. This meant, however, that a new organized class interest - that of the rich farmer - would now become a player in national politics. Third, the political consolidation that the Congress represented as the principal organization of the freedom struggle was now a thing of the past. Most of the leaders of the major opposition parties were themselves former Congressmen who were now no longer prepared to engage in working out a political consensus under the aegis of the Congress. Even within the Congress, the problem of establishing a harmonious relationship between the government and the party, which was first resolved in favour o f the former in the early 1950s and swung towards the latter after Nehru's death, became a bitterly contentious issue in the. late 1960s. The restoration of the Congress under Indira Gandhi relied on several new political strategies. Following the split, the Congress (R} became an organization that derived its identity from its leader. This was not merely symbolic, because even in its organization the Congress now became strongly centralized, with power flow­ ing directly from the central high command. The older phe­ nomenon of Congress rule through strong Chief Ministers was gone: Chief Ministers were now virtually nominated from the centre and held office only as long as they enjoyed the confidence of the high command. Between 1968 and 1989, there were as many as fourteen Congress ministries in Bihar with nine different Chief Ministers; in UP, between 1970 and 1988, there were ten Con­ gress ministries and seven Chief Ministers; in Maharashtra, be­ tween 1975 and 1988, there were eight Congress ministries and five Chief Ministers; in Andhra Pradesh, between 1971 and 1982, there were six Congress Chief Ministers. Second, the developmental ideology of the Nehru era was now purveyed in a new rhetoric of state socialism with the 1 central executive structures of government playing the pivotal role. Other structures of government such as the j�diciary, or D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN lntroduaiOJI 23 the local bureaucracy, or local political leaders were frequently criticiud for being conservative, corrupt, and acting as hindran­ ces to development. Third, welfare packages were now targeted towards specific groups of the population, such as scheduled castes or tribes, or minorities, or workers, or women, and delivered in such a way as to produce the impression that they were a gift of the central \ leadership, Indira Gandhi in particular. In fact, the traditional _J pattern of Congress support - a somewhat paradoxical alliance of urban elites and rural landholding castes at the top with low castes and minority groups below - was accentuated and strengthened in this period. However, whereas the older Con­ gress, with its loose consensual structure, also relied on a populist ideology, the populism of Indira Gandhi's Congress W2S far more centraliud, statist and focused on a single leader. One particular aspect of the new strategy deserves special mention - namely the reorganization of the north-eastern re­ gion. After Independence, this region of the Indian union was administratively organized within the state of Assam, with the two former princely states of Manipur and Tripura becoming union territories in 1956. However, within Assam there were major natural, social and political differences between the plains and the hill regions. The latter, which was almost entirely in­ habited by tribal peoples, was administered in the 1950s through elected autonomous district councils which had some limited legislative powers. However, there was resistance in many areas to the new order. The Naga National Council under the leader­ ship of Angami 2.apu Phiw organiud a complete boycott of the first general elections in the Naga Hills district where not a single nomination paper was submitted and not a single vote was cast. The insurgency continued in the Naga Hills for most of the nen two decades, requiring the constant p�nce of Indian army troops i n the area. Insurgency also arose in the Miro hills in the 1960s and the Miro National Front, led by Laldenga, was out­ lawed. Even in the Khasi and Garo hills, where the Congress had secured a strong following within the political leadership, the 1967 elections proved to be a major setback when the Congress lost most of the seats to the opposition All-Party Hill l!.eaders' Conference. In 1972, the union government effected a major reconstitution of the region by giving full statehood to Meghalaya, Dlgltlzedby Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 24 State and Politia in India Manipur and Tripura and making Arunachal Pradesh (the former North-East Frontier Agency) and Mizoram union territories. The move certainly made possible a political settlement of the unrest in · the hill states in the subsequent years, although it did not necessarily improve the position of the Congress in all the new states. Unrest and Repression Despite Indira Gandhi's massive electoral victory in 1971 and the success of the Bangladesh war, the political scene at this time was marked by considerable unrest. This came from both ends of the political spectrum. On one side, there were large-scale agitations led by the communists and other left parties among the middle classes and workers in industrialized states such as West Bengal. To some extent, the nationalization of banks and mines, and an expanding public sector were meant to satisfy these interests. However, the industrial economy did not show signs of revival and, following the international oil crisis of 1973, there were huge price rises. In 1974, there was a massive country-wide strike by railway workers that was ruthlessly crushed. From the late 1960s, there was also unrest among peasants in many parts of the country. Espe cially in the most backward agricultural regions where feudal-style oppression' by landlords and state officials still prevailed, there now occurred locally or­ ganized resistance by poor peasants and agricultural labourers, often belonging to low-caste or tribal groups. One such move­ ment in a place called Naxalbari in the foothills of Darjeeling district in West Bengal suddenly came into prominence in 1967 when the local organizers belonging to the CPI(M) clashed with the party leadership which wanted them to withdraw the move­ ment in the interest of saving the United Front ministry in West Bengal. By 1969, the radical groups split from the CPI(M) and formed their own party called the CPl(M-L). 'Naxalite' peasant movements spread in West Bengal, Andhra Pradesh, Kerala, Bihar and Punjab, and in all cases were suppressed by the use of massive armed force by state agencies. It was at this time that, alongside a centralized developmental ideology, there also grew a hugely expanded central machinery of police and paramilitary forces for use against political movements. D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN lntroducticm 25 The Defence of India Rules, handed down from colonial times, were widely used against political opponents, and in 1971 a Main­ tenance of Internal Security Act (MISA) was passed specifically for tackling political agitations. The Central Reserve Police Force and the Central Industrial Security Force were also set up at this time, as was the Border Security Force which too was often de­ ployed for internal security purposes. Finally, there was the Re­ search and Analysis Wmg (RAW), the intelligence agency of the government, directly under the charge of the Prime Minister. The waves of unrest that spread through India in the early 1970s were not confined to Communist agitations. In many parts of northern India, especially in Bihar, and then in 1974 in Gujarat, there was widespread agitation against corruption in government, initially led by students but soon ta.king on the form of a popular anti-government movement. Some of the ideological and organ­ izational inspiration here was provided by the Socialist followers of the late Ram Manohar Lohia as well as by Gandhian activists, and at various stages most opposition parties except the Com­ munists joined the movement. But it was galvanized by the leader­ ship given to it by Jaya Prakash Narayan who emerged from political retirement to announce a call for 'total revolution'. This too was a populist movement, making general demands that voiced the discontent of large sections of the people and specifically targeted against the ruling government. But Congress populism at the time of Indira Gandhi was, as one commentator has put it, a 'jealous populism', utterly intolerant of rival populist mobiliza­ tions, and hence violently repressive.7 The government dubbed the movements in Bihar and Gujarat anti-national and fascist, and came down on them with a heavy hand. In June 1975, the Allahabad High Court delivered a judg­ ment on a petition against Indira Gandhi's election to the Lok Sabha in 1971. Finding her guilty of electoral malpractices, the court set aside her election. The opposition parties now began to clamour for her resignation and Jaya Prakash Narayan, at a huge rally in New Delhi on 25June 1975, declared that the government had lost all moral claims to rule. That night, a state of emergency was promulga'ted in India. 7 David Selboume, A.n Eye to India: Tht Umnaslting of a Tyr111111J mondsworth: Penguin, 1977), p. 90. ·-· Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from (Har­ UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 26 State and Politics in India The Emergency Tens of thousands of opposition leaders and activists from all over the country, including fifty-nine members of Parliament, were arrested during the emergency. They were from the Socialist Party, the Congress (0), the CPl(M), the CPI(M -L), the Alc:ali Dal, the DMK, the Bharatiya Lok Dal and the Jana Sangh. A few of those arrested were critics of Indira Gandhi from within the Congress. Twenty-six political organizations from both left and right were banned, including the CPI(M-L) and most other 'Naxalite' groups, the RSS, the Ananda Marg and the Jamait-c­ Islami. Censorship was imposed on the press and the fundamental right of equality before the law (Article I4), the right to life and liberty (Article 21) and protection against arbitrary arrest (Article 22) were suspended. MISA was strengthened by making it vir­ tually unnecessary for the authorities to give .any reasons · for detaining a person. . The DMK government in Tamil Nadu (as Madras was called from 1969) was removed for its 'economic failures' in January 1976 and President's rule imposed. In actual fact, the DMK had resisted the enension of the emergency regime i n Tamil Nadu and the Chief Minister M. Karunanidhi had publicly called for an end to authoritarian rule. In March 1976, the only other non-Congress government in the country, the coalition rninistry in Gujarat headed by Babubhai Patel of the Congress (0), was similarly dismissed for its alleged failure to maint2in law and order. Now all st2tes in India either had Congress governments or were under President's rule. A week after the emergency was declared, the government announced a 20-point programme to 'change the face of India in a truly revolutionary manner'. It included implement2tion of land reforms, liquidation of rural indebtedness, abolition of bonded -labour, socialization of urban land, prevention of tax evasion and punishment to economic offenders, participation of workers in industric;s, and special beneftts to the landless, agricultural workers, weavers, students and 'weaker sections'. This was meant to be the legitimizing instrument for the emergency - a package of beneftts that would be delivered to different sections of the people. In actual fact, the emergency regime gave unbridled power to officials and Congress politicians who used it in an arbitrary, D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN Introduction 27 motivated and frequently violent manner. Some of the emergency actions that caused widespread resentment were the cleaning up of cities by forcibly clearing slums and pavement shops and car­ rying out family planning by forcible sterilization. Apart from the bureaucracy and the police, the Youth Congress under Sanjay Gandhi's leadership became a particularly feared instrument of the Emergency regime. The life of the Lok Sabha, which had been elected in 1971, was extended by a year. In August 1976, a series of constitutional amendments was proposed to severely curtail the powers of the judiciary, to further �ntralizc the federal system and to introduce a set of fundamental duties in addition to the fundamental rights of citizens. The Indian republic itself W2S now to be described as 'sovereign, democratic, secular and socialist'. In November 1976, the amendments were passed by Parliament, the protests of the few opposition members not even being reported by a press acting under censorship laws. At this time, there was little visible opposition to the Emer­ gency regime. Its powers seemed to be unchecked, overcoming every resistance it faced. In January 1977, surprising everyone, Indira Gandhi made the stunning announcement that parliamen­ tary elections would be held in March. The Emergency was not to be withdrawn but its harshness would be toned down, many detenus would be released and the censorship laws relaxed. As soon as elections were announced, four opposition parties - the Congress (0), the Jana Sangh, the Bharatiya Lok Dal and the Socialist party - merged to form the Janata Party which was to have a single list of candidates and a common election symbol. Three expelled members of the Congress - Chandra Shekhar, Krishan Kant and Ram Ohan - also joined the Janata party. A few days later came the sensational announcement by Jagjivan Ram, one of the senior-most members of Indira Gandhi's cabinet, that he had resigned and, along with two former Chief Ministers, H.N. Bahuguna of UP and Nandini Satpathy of Orissa, W2S form­ ing a new party called the Congress for Democracy which would go into an electoral understanding with the Janata party. The Janata party was able to work out a common list of candidates with other parties such as the CPI(M) and the Alcali Dal, so that in as many as 425 of 539 seats there was vittually a straight contest between the Congress and the opposition. This Digiti zed by Google Ongmal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 28 State-and Politics in India was unprecedented in Indian elections until that time. The results were stunning. The Janata party: won an absolute majority secur­ ing 270 seats and of its allies the Congress for Democracy won 28, the Akali Dal 8 and the CPI(M) 22. In all of northern India, from Himachal Pradesh to West Bengal, the Congress won only ftve seats. In the south, however, it won most of the seats it contested - in Andhra Pradesh, Tamil Nadu, Kamataka and Kerala - giving it a total of 15 3 seats. Indira Gandhi herself was defeated from Rae Bareli. Electoral history had been created in India. The ftrst non-Congress government at the centre assumed office with Morarji Desai as Prime Minister. The Janata Government Restaring Democracy The Janata government was the ftrst experiment with operating a coalition government at the centre. In truth, even the experience of the various non-Congress coalition governments in the states. since 1967 had not been inspiring. The immediate task before the new government was to dis.:. mantle the emergency regime and re-lay the foundations of a democratic process. The coercive laws and constitutional amend­ ments enacted during the emergency were rescinded and political prisoners released. A series of commissions were appointed to investigate allegations of illegalities and excesses against ministers and government officials. Of these, the hearings of the Shah Commission in particular produced massive evidence of impro­ prieties committed by those in power during the Emergency, including Indira Gandhi and especially her son, Sanjay. In the meantime, assembly elections were held in several states in June 1978, including UP, Rajasthan and Orissa where the incumbent Congress governments were dismissed and the legis­ latures dissolved. Now once more there were non-Congress gov­ ernments in most of northern India. The Janata government tried to project a different develop­ mental strategy, articulated in a Gandhian rhetoric, focused more on rural areas and relying on giving incentives to farmers and small manufacturers. The possibilities of this strategy were never properly tried out since, almost immediately after coming to Dig1t1zeo b y Google Origi�al rrom UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN Introductum 29 power, the government fell into a crisis because of internal dis­ sensions. On the one hand, although Morarji Desai was accepted as Prime Minister through a consensual method, both Jagjivan Ram and Charan Singh remained aspirants to the post even as they became senior ministers of the cabinet. On the other hand, despite the f�ct that the constituents of the Janata party had formally merged into a single organization, on the ground they largely retained their separate identities. 1n particular, the Jana Sangh, which was organizationally the tightest and ideologically the most articulate of them all, sought to use this opportunity to expand its own bases of support as quickly as possible. In the meantime, many of Indira Gandhi's colleagues in the Congress now began to withdraw their support from her. With evidence mounting in the hearings of the Shah Commission·, there was now a serious possibility of her being prosecuted for the illegalities and excesses of the Emergency. She insisted that the Congress launch a campaign for an end to the commissions. In January 1978, she forced yet another split in the Congress, with most of the organiZ2tion remaining with the president Brah­ mananda Reddy and most of the Congress members of parliament coming with her to form the Congress-Indira. 1n the assembly elections in Andhra Pradesh and Kamataka in February 1978, it w� the Congres s -I which won the majority, while the Reddy group was wiped out. Once again, Indira Gandhi had proved that as f-ar as the Congress was concerned, she was the strongest focus of popular appeal. 1n November 1978, she won a by-election to Parliament from Chikamagalur in Kamataka. Dissensi(l11S One set of troubles. started in UP when in February 1979, the Janata Chief Minister, Ram Naresh Yadav, formerly of the BLD, decided to drop two Jana Sangh ministers from his cabinet. De­ spite efforts at a rapprochement and a change of ChiefMinisters, the rift between theJana Sangh and the BLD widened and affected theJanata governments in the other north Indian states. In April, Chief Minister Karpoori Thakur of the BLD was defeated in the Janata legislature party in Bihar and had to make way for Ram Sundar Das, a former Socialist. 1n June, Devi Lal, Chief Minister of Haryana and also formerly of the BLD, was forced to resign Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 30 State and Politics in India and Bhajan Lal was elected in his place. In the same month, Raj Narain, once again of the BLD, was expelled from the national executive of theJanata party for his criticism of party policies and leaders. Within theJanata leadership configuration, Charan Singh seemed to have been cornered. The other set of troubles centred around allegati9ns of corrup­ tion against K.anti Desai, son of the Prime Minister. The Con­ gress-I in particular was vociferous in this matter, both in and out of Parliament. Soon it became an issue in the rapidly developing conflicts within the Janata government itself. In July 1979, a no-confidence motion was brought against the government b y Y.V. Chavan of the Congress. There began a stream of resigna­ tions from the ministry and defections from the ruling party. It became clear that the government would not be able to get a majority in the house. Morarji Desai resigned. Charan Singh, along with a group of defectors from the Janata Party and in coalition with the Congress, formed a new government with the suppon of the Congress-I and the Left parties. Three weeks later, the Congress-I withdrew its suppon, forcing Charan Singh to resign. N. Sanjiva Reddy, the President, dissolved Parliament and announced fresh elections to the Lok Sabha. The Congress-I Decade Dominance and Opposition Faced with a divided opposition, the Congress-I won a comfort­ able majority in Parliament in the January 1980 elections, sweep­ ing Andhra Pradesh, Kamataka, Tamil Nadu (in alliance with the DMK), Gujarat, Madhya Pradesh, Orissa, Himachal Pradesh and Punjab and winning substantially from Bihar, Maharashtra, Rajas­ than and Uttar Pradesh. A few months later, Sanjay Gandhi, who had emerged as the principal driving force in the Congress-I organization, died in a plane crash. Since political developments from the 1980s are covered in detail in the readings collected in this volume, we do not need to spend much time here on a general survey of the period. Some of the significant features of the Indira Gandhi regime of 1980-4 are as follows. The main form of rule continued to be one of central command D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN Introduction 31 and control. In Congress-I party affairs, the dominance of the central high command, consisting of people close to the Prime Minister, was practically total. In matters of government, the emphasis was on centralization of powers in the hands of the central executive, with key bureaucrats often playing a more cru­ cial role than government ministers. In economic matters, the signs were now clear that a different path of development was being sought from that which had been followed in the early 1970s. The emphasis was now on freeing the private sector in industry from the regime of tight government control, liberalizing imports and promoting exports. In political matters, the attempt was to break up opposition cons�lidations, at the centre and in the states, by promoting dissension in their ranks, usurping their political platforms and, on several occasions, by using the powers of the central government to disturb non-Congress governments in the states. Thus several moves were made in this period to win the so-called 'Hindu vote' for the Congress-I. Dissensions were promoted within the AlcaJi Dal in Punjab by backing extremist elements against the moderate leadership. The issue of federal relations became extremely bitter with the opposition parties com­ ing together to save non-Congress state governments from central intervention. One of the most dramatic effects of the growing feeling that the central government was acting in an authoritarian manner with respect to the states was the stunning election victory in January 1983 of N.T. Rama Rao's Telugu Desam Party, formed only a few months before on an explicit emotional appeal of 'restoring the pride of the Telugu people'. In Kamataka too, theJanata party defeated the Congress-I to form a government with Ramakrishna Hegde as Chief Minister. The CPI(M)-led LDF government of E.K. Nayanar in Kerala fell in October 1981 and the Left Front government led by Jyoti Basu in West Bengal remained in a siniation of constant confrontation with the centre. But regional opposition took on the character of insurgencies in Assam and Punjab. The movement against 'infiltrators' in Assam turned from a student agitation into a mass movement and became particularly violent after 1983 when the centre attempted to hold assembly elections, practically by force, and to install a Congress-I govern­ ment. In Punjab, the extremist fringe of the Alcali Dal, under the· leadership of Jarnail Singh Bhindranwale, became increasingly Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 32 State and Politics in India assertive, demanding a sovereign state ofKhalistan. In June 1984, the Indian army entered the Golden Temple in Amritsar and, after a pitched battle, captured a number of terrorists and large stocks of arms, but left numerous dead, including Bhindranwale himself. In October 1984, Indira Gandhi herself was killed by members of her own security guard, ostensibly in retaliation for the attack on the Golden Temple. Her assassination led to riots against the Sikh community in several spots in India, but most viciously in the capital, New Delhi. Rajiv G(lTldhi's Regime Rajiv Gandhi was appointed Prime Minister in an extraordinary way. Unlike in the 1960s, no formal body of the Congress was called into play to elect a new leader. Rather, Rajiv Gandhi, who held no significant position of leadership either in the party or in government, was first appointed as Prime Minister by the Presi­ dent, Zail Singh, on the advice of a few senior Congress leaders, and only later were the approvals of party organs such as the working committee and the legislature party obtained. It showed once more how strongly personalized the nature of authority had become in the Congress-I. The eighth general election took place in December 1984 in the shadow of Indira Gandhi's assassination. It produced the largest ever victory for the Congress-I. Most opposition parties, except for the Telugu Desam and to some extent the CPl(M), were decimated. One of the first acts of the Rajiv Gandhi govern­ ment was to pass an anti-defection law to prevent legislators from switching parties. The new government, under a young leader without a political past, attempted to project an image of change, promising to sweep away hidebound practices and lethargic routines. In particular, the economic policy of fewer government controls, liberal imports and greater reliance on the private sector was sought to be given a new ideological stamp. Politically, some attempt was made to shake up the organization of the Congress, but soon it became clear that a command structure based on rational bureaucratic principles rather than on personal loyalties would be difficult to put in place without a thorough democratiza­ tion of the party itself. This the political leadership was unwilling to risk. Instead, the older form of Congress-I politics, with power Dlgltlzedby Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN flowing directly from a small group of the Prime Minister's close advisors, soon reasserted itself. The agitations in Punjab and Assam had not subsided. Rajiv Gandhi attempted to arrive at political settlements in both states. In Punjab, an 'accord' was signed with the Akali Dal leader H.S. Longowal and assembly elections were held in September 1985. Unfortunately, Longowal himself was assassinated by extremists during the election campaign. But the Akali Dal won an absolute majority for the fust time in the Punjab assembly and formed a government under Surjit Singh Barnala. The Barnala government, however, was caught in an unenviable position between extremists on the one side and an interventionist central government de­ manding tough action on the other. Amidst mounting terrorist actions, the government was dismissed in May 1987 and Pres­ ident's rule declared. In Assam, the 'accord' led to assembly elec­ tions in December 1985 in which the former student leaders, now organized. as a political party called the Asom Gana Parishad, won a clear victory to form the government with Prafulla Mahanta as Chief Minister. In 1986, the former rebel leader of Mizoram, L.C. Laldenga of the Mizo National Front, who had already struck a deal with the central government in 1982 to end his insurgency, signed an 'accord' with Rajiv Gandhi that gave full statehood to Mizoram and made him the Chief Minister. This period also saw a distinct deterioration in the communal situation in the country. From the early 1980s, there were in several cities in Gujarat, Ahmedabad in particular, repeated out­ breaks of communal violence. In 1986, an old dispute about the status of a mosque in the small town of Ayodhya in Uttar Pradesh suddenly took a new tum when a district judge, presumably on instructions from political authorities, ordered the padlock to be removed and allowed Hindus to worship at the place. Agitations began throughout the country claiming that the mosque had been built b y Mughal rulers after demolishing a Hindu temple at the same site and demanding the building of a new Rama temple there. In the meantime, in 1987, a judgment of the Supreme Court awarding alimony to a divorced Muslim woman contrary to the provisions of the Muslim law led to protests from conservative. Muslim bodies. The central government gave in and passed a law ensuring that Muslim law would take precedence over secular law in such cases. These developments led to a unprecedented Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 34 State and Politics in India organization of acrimonious debates over communal issues on a national scale. Another mobilization that had a significant impact in the l 980s was the farmer's movement Its origins lay in the green revolution, and through the 1970s, the rich peasants turned capitalist farmers had become vocal in their demand for greater state support for agricultural production and marketing. This interest had been well represented in Indira Gandhi's Congress in the early I 970s, but from the period of the Emergency, it became identified with opposition politics and Charan Singh became its principal ideo­ logue. The interesting change that occurred in the 198()5 was the emergence of large and effective non-party movements of farmers, such as the Bharatiya Kisan Union led by Mahendra Singh Ti.kait, the ShetkariSangathana ofSharadJoshi or the Karnataka Farmers' Association led by M.D. Nanjundaswamy. These movements have sought to act more as pressure groups, periodically staging huge demonstrations and intensive campaigns, but not directly identify­ ing with any political party. One of the features of the centralization strategy followed by both Indira and Rajiv Gandhi in the 1980s was the complete control exercised by the central Congress-I leadership over party funds. With massively expanded campaign expenditures, the Congress-I nevertheless actively discouraged candidates and local units from raising their own election funds and preferred campaign materials to be produced centrally (often on the advice of advertising agencies specifically hired for the purpose) and distributed to the constituen­ cies. This was to ensure a homogeneous and centrally controlled campaign and also to reduce the influence of locally powerful forces on local Congress-I units. The huge party funds were now collected centrally, mostly as kickbacks from large international deals con­ cluded by the central ministries or public sector companies. One such deal, a defence purchase involving the Swedish ar­ maments manufacturer Bofors, became the centre of controversy when it was alleged that large kickbacks had gone to politically influential people surrounding the Prime Minister himself. The issue became particularly charged when Vishwanath Pratap Singh, an important minister in Rajiv Gandhi's cabinet, resigned in 1987, protesting against corruption in the Congress-I. The issue snow­ balled to become tlte principal focus of opposition unity in the 1989 general elections. A National Front, led by the Janata Dal, Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN lntroduaitm 3> managed to arrive at scat adjustments with the Bharatiya Janata Party. The Congress-I was defeated, securing only 197 seats in the Lok Sabha. The National Front could not win a majority on its own, but formed a government with V.P. Singh as Prime Minister with the outside suppon of the BJP and the Left parties. Into the l 990s Rise md Fa/J of the National Front The National Front government lasted only a year. It was de­ pendent on outside suppon, and fmally it was its relation with the BJP, established in the interest of defeating the Congress-I, that snapped. The communal situation had become especially charged, with the Hindutva forces, now organized in the so-called Sangh Parivar consisting of the BJP, the RSS and the Vishwa Hindu Parishad, carrying out a huge campaign to build a temple at the site o f the Bahri mosque in Ayodhya. In the state assembly electiollS in March 1990, the BJP won majorities in Madhya Pradesh and Himachal Pradesh where, for the first time, they formed their own governments. In Rajasthan, the BJP formed a coalition government with the Janata Dal. The crisis that soon ovenook the National Front government was both internal and external. Internally, the principal difficulty centred around the position of Devi Lal, the deputy Prime Min­ ister, whose son, Om Prakash Chauthala, who had become Chief Minister of the Janata Dal government of Haryana, had been charged with gross election rigging. Put under great pressure, including a threat of resignation from the Prime Minister himself, Chauthala was forced to resign, but Devi Lal became a sworn antagonist of the government. In August 1990, Devi Lal was dropped from the cabinet. The external crisis built up over the confrontation with the BJP. In June 1_990, the VHP declared that they would go ahead with the building of the temple at Ayodhya and the BJP aMounced that its leader L.K Advani would take a Rama rath procession through the length and breadth of the country, mobilizing sup­ pon for the temple. In August 1990, V.P. Singh aMounced that the government would implement the recommendations of the Mandal Commission made several years earlier for the reservation Digiti zed by Google Ongmal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 36 St11u 1111d Politics in India of 27 per cent of government jobs for the Other Backward Classes. The announcement led to violent protests by upper-caste students and youth in many cities all over India. In October, Advani's rath procession was stopped in Bihar on the orders of Janata Dal Chief Minister Laloo Prasad Yadav and the BJP leader arrested. A few days later, VHP volunteers trying to enter the site of the mosque in Ayodhya were fired upon by armed police deployed by the UP government of Mulayam Singh Yadav. The crisis was now complete. In early November, sixty-eight MPs of the Janata Dal left the party with Chandra Shekhar and Devi Lal as their leaders to form the JD (Samajwadi). Two days later, the National Front government was defeated in a confidence vote in the Lok Sabha - the BJP, the Congress-I and the JD (S) voting against the government. The Chandra Shekhar Government Chandra Shekhar became Prime Minister of a minority govern­ ment with Congress-I support. In Gujarat and Uttar Pradesh too, the former JD Chief Ministers Chimanbhai Patel and Mulayam Singh Yadav continued in power with Congres s -I support: The government was entirely at the mercy of the Congress-I and did not even make a pretence of formulating a coherent policy. In March 1991, Chandra Shekhar resigned. The ninth Lok Sabha was dissolved less than a year and a half after its formation. Halfway through the general elections in May 1991, Rajiv Gandhi was assassinated at an election meeting in Tamil Nadu by suspected Tamil militants from Sri Lanka. The death of the Congress-I leader affected the results in the remainder of the elections. The Congress-I did not win a majority but; with 232 seats, became the single largest party. No coalitions being pos­ sible, P.V. Narasimha Rao, elected leader of the Congress legis­ lature party, was appointed Prime Minister. Congress in Power and in Decline The most important shift carried out by the new government was to bring economics to the forefront of the political debate. ,, Manmohan Singh, who became the finance minister, was a senior government economist who was now given the task of steering Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN Introduction 37 through the political process a. policy of structural adjusnnent of the economy required as a condition for getting loans from the International Monetary Fund. The policy of liberalization and loosening of government regulations which had taken place in small doses through the previous decade was now sought to be accelerated into a package of economic refonns that would attract large foreign invesnnents. Although the government was in a minority in the Lok Sabha, it managed to pass several controversial measures and survive votes of no-confidence because the BJP and the NF-left bloc would not combine to bring it down and force yet another general election. In the meantime, the BJP stepped up its campaign for the building of a temple at the disputed site in Ayodhya. InJune 1991, it had won the UP elections on this issue. With its own govern­ ment in the state, its mobilization reached a peak. On 6 December 1992, /car stValcs stormed the premises, encountering little resis­ tance, and demolished the mosque in a matter of hours. The event sent shock waves through the country. The government ofKalyan Singh w:as dismissed in UP, and a few days later the BJP govern­ ments in Himachal Pradesh, R.ajasthan and Madhya Pradesh were dismissed as well. However, the central government seemed quite indecisive on how to deal with the situation politically. InJanuary 1993, there were massive killings of Muslims in &mbay and Gujarat. The communal situation was at its worst ever since In­ dependence. The situation in Kashmir also became particularly disturbed. In the mid-1980s, opposition politics inJammu and Kashmir had found a voice in the participation of the National Conference in the conclaves of non-Congress parties all over India demanding greater autonomy for the states. In 1986, after Farooq Abd�ah went into an alliance with the Congress-I, the resentment against the power of the centre was diverted into more militant activities. President's rule was declared in Jammu and Kashmir in 1990 and, for the next few years, it was a story of constant confrontation between Indian security forces and a variety of armed militant organizations, leading to thousands of deaths and a complete disruption of civic life. ') Narasimha Rao's government, however, displayed great skill in parliamentary rnanOCUYreS in order to s12y in power. In 1993, it won over to its side a block of members belonging to the Ajit Dlgltlzedby Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 38 State and Politics in India Singh faction of the Janata Dal. With by-election victories and small accretions in strength,it finally managed to secure a majority on its own. However, as far as the internal strength of the party was concerned, or indeed its power to gather mass electoral sup­ port, the Congress-I was set on a path of rapid and irreversible decline. By 1995, as many as twelve states - Andhra Pradesh, Bihar, Delhi, Gujarat, K.arnataka,Maharashtra,Rajasthan,Silckim, Tamil Nadu, Tripura, Uttar Pradesh and West Bengal - had governments run by parties other than the Congress-I. Even more significantly, it seemed to have lost its position as centre of the political system. Especially in northern and western India, the BJP was vying for that position, setting the political agenda and profiting from the split in the non-BJP vote. With the emergence of distintt regional party systems in the states, the Congress was now one of the many parties with a position in several of those regional systems. The I 996 Elections The general elections of April-May 1996 confirmed these trends. The BJP made a strong showing in the northern and western states and emerged as the single largest party in Parliament. The Congress-I finished second. The various regional parties, includ­ ing the Janata Dal, the Telugu Desam Party, the DMK, the AGP, the breakaway Congress group in Tamil Nadu led by G.K. Moopanar and the left parties, came together to form an NF-LF bloc, later called the United Front. President S.D. Shar­ ma decided to invite A.B. Vajpayee of the BJP, as leader of the single largest party, to form the government, even though the NF-LF bloc, with Congress-I support, was claiming to have a majority. The Vajpayee ministry lasted barely over a week, by which time it became clear that the BJP would not be able to get the support of a majority in the Lok Sabha. Vajpayee resigned and H.D. Deve Gowda of the Janata Dal, then Chief Minister of K.amataka, was asked to form a ministry after the Congress-I declined to do so. The United Front government passed its first vote. of confidence in June 1996 with the support of the Con­ gress-I and the left parties. It was also the first occasion when a left party - the CPI - joined a government at the centre. Apart from the emergence of the regional parties as a combined Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN Introduction 39 force bidding fur power at the centre, the most recent period of Indian politics has also been marked by the rise in northern India of a new political assertion of the lower caste groups. In terms of their organization, they are variously identified with the Janata Dal, the Samajwadi Party, the Bahujan Samaj Party or qie Samata Party, and even these identities and the pattern of their political alliances are extremely fluid. Nevertheless, along with the rise of communalized political identities, the emergence of the new dalit­ bahujan formations is an important aspect of the changing political structures in India fifty years after Independence. It is possible that future historians will describe the entire period we have covered as the Congress era. Certainly, a narrative of the political history of India as a whole in these fifty years has had to be built around the story of the rise and decline of the Congress as the central active force. It is a measure of the fundamental uncertainties facing Indian politics today that no other force has decisively replaced the Congress. • Dig1t1zeo by Google Origi�al rrom UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN Digiti zed by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN I The System l'""J""\e early attempts to present a systematic account of Indian l. politics after Independence were usually placed within a liberal modernization theory and, more o�en than not, were cel­ ebratory in tone. Certain key institutions of the modem state were shown to have been put in place in the period of British rule; after Independence, it was believed that with a liberal democratic con­ stitutional system and universal suffrage, the Indian political sys­ tem would gradually develop its own processes of democratic decision-making, rational administration �d modem citizenship. Features such as patronage relations based on caste or religious loyalties and solidarities based on ethnicity were regarded as ves­ tiges of underdevelopment that would go �way with greater par­ ticipation of the people in democratic institutions. Later, more complex variants of the modernization theory were produced, most notably by Rudolph and Rudolph in The Modn-nity ofTradi­ tion (1967) and in the collection on Caste in Indian Politics (l 970) edited by_Rajni Kothari, in which it was argued that even elements of 'tradition' such as caste or religion could infiltrate a modem system of political institutions, adapt to it and, by transforming themselves, find an enduring place within it as parts of political modernity itself. The most influential account of the Indian 'system' from this perspective was produced by Rajni Kothari in his Politia in India (I 970). His theoretical tools were largely structural-functional. He identified the 'dynamic core' of the system of political institutions in India in the Congress Party. The whole system worked through the dominance of the Congress. It was a differentiated system, functioning along the organizational structure of the party but • --- Digiti zed by Google Ongmal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 42 State and Politics in India connecting at each level with the parallel structure of government, allowing for the dominance of a political centre as well as dissent from the peripheries, with opposition parties functioning as con­ tinuations of dissident Congress groups, the emphasis being on coalition-building and consensus-making at each level and on securing the legitimacy of the system as a whole. Through an· accommodative system such as this, the political centre consisting of a modernizing elite was shown to be using the powers of the state to transform society and promote economic development. Kothari gave it the simple name 'Congress system'. Kothari's framework was criticized at the time from different perspectives - for overvaluing the consensual character of the system, for overestimating the autonomy of the elite, for taking far too gradualist a view of social and political change, and so on. But its usefulness was overtaken by the events of the 1970s. The rise of militant oppositional movements and the increasing use of the repressive apparatus of the state, culminating in the Emergen­ cy, were clearly phenomena that went beyond the consensual model of the Congress system. From the 1980s, Kothari himself developed entirely different frameworks for presenting empirical as well as normative accounts of Indian politics. Marxist accounts were better able to describe conflicts and the repressive use of state power as systemic features of Indian politics. However, much of the literature, especially that produced by theorists working within rigid frameworks laid down by party programmes, was dominated by a sterile debate over what was called the character of the state. More nuanced accounts that tried not only to describe enduring structures of class power but also specific changes in political processes and institutional practices 1 began to emerge in the l 980s. The essay by Sudipta Kaviraj j reprinted in this section is one of the best examples of this genre , of Marxist writing on Indian politics. The focus is on the state, : I but the analysis takes the state as a site over which several dominant classes try both to outmanoeuvre one another and to work out coalitional arrangements in order to preserve their dominance as a whole. The political process can then be described in terms of changing balances in the ruling class coalition. Politics, in other words, can be given a structure in terms of class forces as well as a history in terms of changing balances. The overall historical pattern is described, following Antonio Gramsci, as the passive Digiti zed by Google Ongmal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The System 43 revolution of capital, making institutional changes understandable in terms of a non-classical history of modernity, but with the interesting variation that the success of the revolution is not as­ sumed: the apparent successes of Indian capitalism could themsel­ ves lead to an institutional failure of the political system. Marxist accounts are often strong in describing the central structures of state power and their relations with dominant or­ ganized forces in Indian society, but when it comes to connecting such an account with local societal .institutions and micro-level political practices, they are on much less sure ground. Other attempts have been made in recent years to theorize Indian politics in terms of certain systematic state-society relations. Rudolph and Rudolph in their later work, In Pursuit of Lakshmi: The Political &ontmty ofthe Indian State (1987), which takes organized interest groups as the principal actors in the system, have tried to periodize Indian politics in terms of the tussle between a 'demand polity' in which societal demands expressed as electoral pressure dominate over the state and a 'command polity' where state hegemony prevails over society. Rao and Frankel in their two-volume edited collection, Dominance and State P(IU)er in Modern India (1990), have made a distinction between public institutions such as the bureau­ cracy and organized industry and political institutions such as legislatures and political parties. The history of politics in inde­ pendent India, they say, is one of the rising power of formerly low status groups such as the lower castes and the poorer classes in the political institutions and the attempt by upper caste and middle class groups to protect their privileges in the public institutions. Atul Kohli in Democracy and Discontent (1991) has described the recent history of the system as one in which, by surrendering to immediate electoral pressures exerted by various social groups, � democratic state institutions have been allowed to decay, leading J to an all-round crisis of govemability. Rajni Kothari in his recent writings has attempted to develop a normative framework that serves less as an explanation and more as a critique of the present political system. He notes that unlike · i in the early decades after Independence, the national political elite / has lost its autonomy and the state has ceased to be an agent of 7 social change and has instead become more and more repressive. ) His argument is that there is a need now to assert, through grass-roots movements and non-party political formations, the Dig1t1zeo by Google Origi�al rrom UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 44 State and Politics in India autonomous force of civil society over a repressive and increasingly unrepresentative state. Another important theorist who has con­ sistently articulated a moral critique of the Indian sate system is Ashis Nandy, in whose view, derived as he says from a modified Gandhian position, the modernist sate has repeatedly failed whenever it has tried to impose on Indian society a set of institu1i tional practices adopted from the modem West that go against i the firmly entrenched everyday practices of collective living in local communities. Social change, if it is to be both successful and just, must emerge out of those collective everyday practices. l Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 1 A Critique of the Passive Revolution· Sudipta Kav_iraj I '"Tlie story of Indian politics can be told in two quite different .l �ays, through two alternative but mutually reinforcing con­ structions. I believe that the wk of a proper Marxist analysis of Indian politics is threefold: first, constructing internally consistent accounts of our political history in these two ways, and then a more theoretical enterprise of making these consistent with each ,, other. One of these would tell the story of structures (if structures are things of which stories can be told)1 - a story of the rise of capitalism, the specificities of transition, the formation and mat­ uration of classes, the internal balance and architecture of the social form, the making and breaking of class coalitions, etc. Such things take long periods to happen, and occur through slow glacial movements. Another story would have to be constructed in terms " of actual political actors, suspending the question of more fun­ damental .causalities for the time being; it must be told in terms of govenµnents, parties, tactics, leaders, political movements, and similar contingent but irreplaceable elements of political narra­ tives. The second story - the narrative of the Indian state • This chapter was first presented at the Indo-Soviet seminar on 'The Indian Revolution' in Leningrad fr o m 14-17 August 1987. I There is a theory which holds that structures are constructs of such a kind that they deflect and obstruct historical reflections. On this untenable idea there is an impressive body of literature, the most well lcnown and long­ winded being E.P. Thompsons's Tbt Pl1Vtrty ofTbeury and Othn-&IIJS (Lon­ don: Merlin Press, 1978). Digiti zed by Google Ongmal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 46 State and Politics in India would be related to the successes (in its own terms) of Indian capitalism and its failures, but is not entirely reducible to them. For in the growth of a late capitalism like the Indian one, the social form of capitalism itself realizes that the state is a historical pre­ condition for much of its economic endeavours and for its political , security. Paradoxically, this state, which seemed remarkably stable / and legitimate when Indian capitalism was relatively weak, has / come into an increasingly serious crisis with the greater entrenc h ment of the social form. 2 Attempted critiques of the Indian polity, to be convincing, must attempt to do the three things I mentioned earlier: they must try to plot the simple narrative line of this crisis, i.e. provide a structure to the simple flow of political events. This is to be taken seriously as a narrative. Stories told of the same thing by various reporters differ: similarly, different types of narratives would differ as to where the ruptures lie, where the continuities, how much significance to accord to which incident, etc. 3 This kind of thing could be called an event-to-event line of causality. But this simpler narrative account must also reveal a deeper causal profile related to a structural causal field:4 it must show fundamen­ tal structural incompatibilities which have expressed themselves through these upheavals. This could be called a structure-to-event causal line. In this chapter, I have tried to show what kind of a ( political model might work in the structural anal is of Indian ys � politics; but it is inadequate in two ways. First, the model itself is l sketchy; and second, I have not worked out how the narrative can be fitted on to the workings of the model adequately. I believe optimistically that such a model has better chances of success than earlier, more wooden, ones generally in use. 2 Some modernization theorists do note this paradox, but they would give it a bland historical solution, by asserting that in the earlier stages the state had to cope with much lower levels of political 'demand'. Present difficulties of the state arise from the fact that these demands have multiplied through greater mobilization but the state's resources for coping with them - its 'supports' - have remained static. This indefensibly marginalizes the ques­ tion of economic development, and is indifferent to the enormous growth of state resources and i ts deliberate aeation of a network of advantage distribu­ tion. 3 In the periodization of Indian politics, Rajni Kothari, for instance, saw the break with the Nehruvian system as coming in 1975. On my reading, this ruj>ture is a much more slow moving affair, and begins much earlier. 4 J.L. Mackie, 'Causes and Conditions', in E. Sosa (ed.), Causation 1111d C1111ditil1'Ulk (London: OUP, 1975). Dlgltlzedby Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The System 47 II Long-term structural compulsions on Indian politics, the choices of both the ruling bloc of propertied classes and the unorche­ strated subaltern classes, arise in several well-known ways: (i) inclusion of the Indian economy in the capitalist in�emational market and its division of labour; (ii) the received structure of colonial economic retardation; and (iii) the fundamental choice exercised by the leadership of the new Indian state in favour of a capitalist strategy of economic growth through a set of basic legal and institutional forms, e.g. the format of legal rights in the constitution, the set of ordinary laws ruling economic and cor­ porate behaviour, the enacanent of industrial policy and other similar initiatives. This was, in a historical sense, a choice which obviously structures all other choices. These structures and their internal evolution have received a great deal of analytical attention from Marxist economists. For an analysis of the state, we have to assume some well-known Marxist propositions on the nature � of India's capitalist development. The social formation in India is generally characterized as a late, backward, post-colonial c a p ­ italism5 which functionally uses various enclaves of precapitalist productive forms.6 Politically, however, it would be wrong to assimilate the Indian capitalist experience into either the model of late-backward European capitalism of the Russian kind,7 or into a lower late-backward form in which the imminent collapse of an immature caritalism makes the possibility of a socialist revolution realistic. Although much of the Indian countryside still shows persistence of semi-feudal forms of exploitation, one can make a case for a characterization of the social form as capitalism, for the judgment involved in such things is not a matter of a simple statistical or spatial predominance. Marx had, in the famous passage of the Grundrisse provided a methodological s However, I do not find the theoretical positions worked out by Hamza Alavi about th e post-colonial state persuasive in the Indian case. 6That is contrary to the traditional linear belief that precapitalism is ingmn-11/ (in this case, taken to mean i n every instance) dysfunctional to capitalist growth and would be liquidated historically. 7 Of the kind analysed by Lenin in his theory of the Russian revolution. Such differences arc clearly marked out i n Lenin's discussions of the colonial question. 8 Of the type exemplifted by China in the Comintern debates from the fourth to the sixth Congresses. D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 48 State and Politics in India injunction about how to characterize such transitional economies through a complex, historically inclined, identiftcation.9 To trans­ late his colourful metaphor is not altogether easy - what does the simile of a predominant light mean in precise economic terms? - but it would be generally accepted that the capitalist fonn predominates in terms of controlling the economic trends of the totality of the social form. The capitalist logic dominates and gives the general title to the economy through its ability to reproduce itself on an expanded scale, set the tone, the targets for the economy as a whole, and therefore to determine the historical logic of the totality of the social formation. Although there are obviously other sectors and types of production in the Indian economy, their reproduction has been subsumed, both economically and politically, under the logic of reproduction o f capital. It is the second part of this nexus which ought to be o f special attention in an analysis of the Indian state. � In countries like India the process of reproduction of capital ldepends crucially on the state. Although the state-capital connec­ ;tion has been extensively studied in empirical economic terms, surprisingly little theoretical use.has been made of this in the study of the Indian state. Still, some minimal generalizations can be made as starting points of a political enquiry. The state in India is a bourgeois state in at least three, mutually supportive, senses. (I) When we say that a state is 'bourgeois' this refers in some way· (though this particular way can be very different in various his­ torically concrete cases) 10 to a state of dominance enjoyed by the capitalist class, or a coalition of classes dominated by the bour­ geoisie. (2) The state form is bourgeois; i.e. the sense in which we speak of the parliamentary democratic form as being historically a bourgeois form of government. This is not just a matter of registering that such forms historically arose during the period of rising capitalism in Europe and spread out through a process of cultural diffusion. Rather, th_e Marxist view would posit a stronger, structural connection between bourgeois hegemony (or domina­ tion) and this form of the state.11 It arranges a disbursing of 9 Karl Marx, Grundris.rt (Middlesex: Penguin, 1973), pp. 106-7. 10 For inst.Ince, the different political trajectories analysed by Gramsci in the Pris<m Notebooks, especially discussions of the passive revolution. 11 The· sense in which Marx said that it is the democratic form which suits the capitalist mode most properly. Dlgltlzedby Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The System 49 advantages in a particular way; and the democratic mechanism works as a usefully sensitive political index as to when the distribu­ tion of disadvantages, which is bound to happen and intensify in a capitalist economy, is becoming politically insupportable. This is the best construction of Marx's idea that democracy was the most appropriate political form for the capitalist mode of produc­ tion. A more Lucacsian view would see this as a homology between a Marxist economy and a market-like political mechanism. Besides, it also lays down norms of management of interest conflicts in a way that even though political grievances accumulate, their politi­ cal articulation does not assume a pitch and form which makes the minimal stability required for capitalist production unobtainable. (3) The state expresses and ensures the domination of the bour­ geoisie and helps in capitalist reproduction and a subordinate reproduction of other types of economic relations by imposing on the economy a deliberate order of capitalist planning. Those direc­ tive functions that capital cannot perform through the market (either because the market is imperfect or not powerful enough, or because such tasks cannot be performed by market pressures) the bourgeois state performs through the legitimized directive mechanisms of the state. The analysis of politics offered below takes such a minimal political economy argument on trust from Marxist economists. But what I offer here, in itself, is not a political economy argument; because I do not subscribe to the view that Marxists trying to understand politics too do the same enquiry as the economists, i.e. their cognitive object is the same. In 1ny view, political scientists should not merely collect the political corol­ laries of the arguments of Marxist economists; their object is dif­ ferent. They study the 'other', the political side. India has then a bourgeois state, but a state that is bourgeois in three different senses. The last two features are less problematic than the first one. A bourgeois format of the state, or the bourgeois character of its legal system, property structure and institutions of governance are clearly and undeniably evident. 12 These are re­ vealed in the Indian Constitution -in its central business of laying Detailed analyses could be fo�d in the worlc of S.K. Chaube and S. Dan.agupta, on the constituent assembly and the judicial processes respec­ tively. More recently, a more philosophically inclined discussion has been presented in Chhatrapati Singh, Law berwem Anarrhy {111d Utopia (Delhi: Oxford University Press, 1985). 12 -- Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 50 State and Politics in India . down some limits and prohibitions through the rights of property, etc., although this serious and decisive core is surrounded by looser reformistic advisory clauses, and based on some necessary illusions of bQurgeois power, like its extreme constructivism: the myth, seriously believed by the early ruling elite; that patterns of laws can direct social relations rather than reflect them, an illusion which made the framers carry the constitutional document to an unreadable and agonizing length. 13 However, the original con­ stitution reflected the accepted social plan or design of the ruling elite at the time of Independence, unlike the subsequent disin­ genuous insertions of ceremonjaJ socialistic principles.14 A second institutional frame was provided by the adoption of the objectives and incre�ingly proliferating institutions of plan­ ning, which explicitly a¢knowledged the role of the state in the reproduction of capital and in setting economic targets in a way compatible with bourgeois developmental perspectives. Clearly, however, f the three reasons for calling our state 'bourgeois' the last twZ are rather external. They depend, in any case, on the fust con ition of this characterization, and it is the first condition which is theoretically most problematic. It is a straightforward case of bourgeois dominance if the state is 'bourgeois' because it reflects a state of bourgeois dominance over society, if the bourgeoisie's political predominance is symmetrical with its directive power over the productive processes in the economy and its moral-ailtural hegemony. In addition to eco. nomic control and directive power, states in advanced capitalist countries in the West employ what Poulantzas calls its 'institu­ tional materiaJity'15 to reinforce, extend and elaborate their dom­ inances. Our third condition can also be expressed in a Gramscian form: one of the crucial legal-formal principles of the capitalist state is the investiture on the state of the title of universality, a legitimate title to speak on behalf of the society 'in general'; this includes an implicit admission that other interests, at least in their raw, economic form constitute a 'civil society' representing the ll Tius is not merely a petty and querulous point. Constitutional documents must be read and understood by the people. The Indian constitution is a lawyer's document, a document of the lawyers, for the lawyers, by the lawyers. 14 Particularly objectionable is the insertion of the term 'socialist' by recent amendment. IS Nicos Poulanu.as, St11tt, PUWtr, S«ill/ism (London: NLB, 1978). Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The System 51 rule of particularity of interests. Clearly, in the Indian case, though it would be wrong to underestimate the survival of democracy for forty years, the Gramscian hegemony model of the capitalist state does not apply in any simple, unproblematic form. 16 It is suggested here that the Indian capitalist class exercises its control over society neither through a moral-cu.ltural hegemony of the Gramscian type, nor a simple coercive strategy on the lines of satellite states of the Third World. It does so by a coalitional strategy carried out partly through the state-directed process of economic growth, \ partly through the allocational necessities indicated by the hourgeois democratic political system. Politically too, as in the fteld of economic relations, the Indian bourgeoisie cannot be accorded an unproblematic primacy, because of the undeniable prevalence of ( precapitalist political forms in our govmumce-, also because the J vulgarly precapitalist form in the political life of rural India must be given appropriate analytical weight. Attributing political dom­ inance to the capitalist class in a society in which the capitalist form of production is still not entirely predominant thus raises some theoretical problems. • Coalitional Relations ofClasses Marxists in India have commonly sought to solve this theoretical difficulty by offering a coalitional theory of class power. 17 Former­ ly, Communist party literature asserted that power in India was exercised by an alliance of two dominant classes, the bourgeoisie (in some cases the monopoly stratum of the bourgeoisie, in others, all fractions of the bourgeoisie as a whole) and the landlords who still enjoyed precapitalist privileges and control. This picture did not standardly include the bureaucratic-managerial-intellectual elite as a distinct and separate element of the rulin,: coalition. In my judgment this was a flaw in the original model,1 and stemmed 16 I have tried to present an argument of this lcind elsewhere: Gramsci and Different Kinds of Difference, seminar on Gramsci and South Asia, Centre for Studies in Social Sciences, Calcutta,July 1987. 17 Since Independence, almost all programmes by almost all communist groups assert that state power in India is controlled by an alliance of classes, although they differ about which classes and their relative political weight. 18 This was a flaw primarily because,though in economic life the public sector and state control on the economy were seen to be important, it appeared Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN -7 I 52 State and Politics in India from the tendency to underestimate the significance of the politi' cal functions of the state and to view the state as merely an expression of class relations rather than a terrain, sometimes an independent actor in the power process. In earlier Marxist analysis of the 1950s or 1960s the historical necessity of a coalition of power was derived from the inability of the bourgeoisie to serious­ ly pursue, let alone complete, a bourgeois democratic revolution. The theory of a ruling 'coalition' highlights another essential point about the nature of class power in Indian society: that capital is not independently dominant in Indian society and state; and for a series of other historical and sociological reasons single­ handed and unaided dominance in society is also ruled out for the other propertied classes. It is a political, long-term coalition which ensures their joint dominance over the state. So the coali­ tion is not an effect or an accidental attribute of a dominance which is otherwise adequate; it is its condjtion. There are several reasons why despite its weakness capital exercises the directive function in the coalition. By its nature, it is the only truly univer­ salizing element ·in the ruling bloc:19 among the ruling groups, the bourgeoisie alone can develop a coherent, internally flexible development doctrine. Precapit:alist elements have not had an alternative coherent programme to offer; their efforts have been restricted mainly to slowing down capitalist transition and ensur­ ing comfortable survival plans for their own class. They have contented themselves by operating not as an alternative leading group, but as a kind of a relatively more reactionary pressure group within the ruling combine trying to shift or readjust the balance of policies in a retrograde direction. In class terms, the ruling bloc in India contained three distinct social groups and the strata internal to or organically associated with them: the bourgeoisie, particularly its aggressive and ex­ panding monopoly stratum, the landed elites (which underwent significant internal changes due to the processes of agrarian trans­ formation since independence) and last, but not least, the bureau­ cratic managerial elite.20 It must not be forgotten that the policies these had no political consequences or effects on class formation and class behaviour. 19 Altho�gh this is not the place for long or detailed theoretical discussions, I find Poulantzas's concept of :1 ruling bloc suggestive but in2dequately clear. 20 Though I advocate the inclusion of this group into the ruling bloc of c�sses, D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The System >3 followed by the ruling bloc often had consequences for its own structure and internal formation. For instance, as a result of the policies pursued over the long term, the strucrure of the classes themselves, especially of the latter two classes, underwent trans­ formation. Although the redistributive aims of the land reforms were frustrated, they had some long-term effects on the class structure of agrarian society, particularly its upper social strata. Over the longer term, as a result of the decline of feudal landlords, a newer segment of rich farmers came to replace them in areas where the green revolution took place - a class of capitalist farmers. This has had, on all accounts, serious consequences for Indian politics. Similarly, the third element has also undergone a remarkable expansion in its size, areas of control and power in step with the development of the state-directed apparatus of economic growth. Traditional Marxist accounts of the ruling coalition suffered, in my view, because they saw the bureaucratic elite as being too straightforwardly subordinate to·the power of the bourgeoisie, and saw what was basically a coalitumal and bargaining relation as a purely instrumental one. Actually, this third group was a crucial element in the ruling coalition of classes. Although not bourgeois in a direct productive sense, culturally and ideologically it was strongly affiliated to rJ:ie bourgeois order. This cl� was, even before Independence, as some historical works show, the repos­ itory of the bourgeoisie's 'political intelligence' worlcing out a 'theory' o f development for Indian capitalism, often 'correcting' more intensely selfish objectives of the monopoly elements by giving them a more reformist and universal form:21 With the constant growth of the large public sector some genuine points of conflict between this bureaucratic elite in government and bour­ geois entrepreneurial classes began to develop. Most significantly, however, they perform a distinct and irreducible function in the ruling bloc and its sprawling governmental apparatus. It is not only true that they mediate between the ruling coalition and the it is important to define the boundaries of this social group with precision. To include the entire administration in the ruling bloc would be absurd, but Iwould include the high bureaucratic elite and industrial management groups. 21 Bipan Chandra, 'Jawaharlal Nehru and the Indian Capitalist Class, 1936' in Nati111111/ism tmd Colonialism in Modern India (New Delhi: Vikas, 1979), i n which G.D. Birla's behaviour i s more startling than Nehru's. . Dlgltlzedby Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 54 State and Politics in India other classes, they also mediate crucially between the classes within the ruling coalition itself. They also provide the theory and the institutional drive for bourgeois rule. Finally, a coalition is always based on an explicit or implicit from protocol, a network of policies, rights, immunities derived • both constitutional and ordinary law which sets out, over a long period, the .terms of this coalition and its manner of distribution of advantages. Changes in the structure, economic success and political weight of individual classes give rise naturally to demands for changes in its internal hierarchy and a renegotiation of the terms of the protocol; and discontented social groups use options over the entire range of'exit, voice and loyalty'.22 To understand the centrality of the third element, and also how the logic of politics intersects with the logic of the economy, I suggest a further distinction between what is generally known as dominance { in Marxist theory and a different operation or terrain of what could be called governance. Domination is the consequence of longer term disposition of interests and control over production arrangements; and in this sort of calculation the dominant classes in Indian society would be the bourgeoisie, especially its higher strata and the rich farmers. This is clearly distinct from governance which refers to the process of actual policy decisions within the apparatuses of the state. Surely the stable structure of class dominance constrains and structures the process of governance, but it is quite different from the first. 'fhis could be extended to suggest that the movement of public policies would be captured by a different concept which refers to configurations of vertical clientilist benefit coalition that these policies create among the subordinate classes. Concessions to agricultural lobbies 1nay create an affinity of interests among the large and the small farmers, or say, all those who sell agricultural produce on the market. Such benefit configurations are real and influence the policy-makers' calculations of short-term political advantages accruing from pol­ icies. These also ensure that actual political configurations do not become symmetrical to class divisions in society. Evidently, this does not turn the small peasant into a part of the ruling bloc. But while it would be nonsensical to see him as a part of the ruling classes, it would be seriously unhelpful for political analysis l 22 A. Hirschman, Exit, sity Press, I970). Digi tized by Voict andLoyalty (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard Univer­ Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The System 55 to ignore such short-term nexuses of interest built up by directions of p_olicy, since what are generally known as welfare programmes explicitly used in this way. We Gan account for some crucial shifts in political alliances in terms bf such deliberate changes in benefit coalitions produced by public policy. The coalitional nature of the ruling group has another serious implication for political analysis. The groups that are included in the coalition do not share equal power: power within the ruling bloc is evidently hierarchical. But if any of these classes is seriously dissatisfied and leaves the ruling bloc, that not only alters the structure of the coalition, but threatens it with political disaster. Theoretically, it follows, any serious political move for each class or its representatives within the coalition is two valued. These moves are of course in a general sense directed against the classes outside the bloc, but the choices of these moves have real effects on the internal politics of the ruling bloc. If a common objective, say, in industrial policy, can be achieved by three differently worked out policy options, x, y, z, their preference for these options would be often differently ranked by different components of the niling bloc. These would result in different states of distribution of long­ term and short-term benefits, and among these benefits very often fig ures the purely political strategic advantage of having a favourable format of procedure of decisions. This sort of a coalition theory may help us understand concrete moves and decisions of political life and link these with configurations of class interests, rather than standard academic coalition theories which use in­ dividuals as their standard political actors and plot coalition move­ ments in reference to a formal minimality norm.23 are m I have suggested elsewhere24 that the story of Indian politics since 1947 ought to be seen in terms of a crucial initial stage of politica_l realignments, followed by four fairly commonsensically divided periods i n our political life. 23 Cf. Riker's well-known discussion on the size principle in Tb tttryofPolitiC11I COillition (New Delhi: Oxford and IBH, 1970), pp. 71�24 'Economic Development and the Political System', paper for colloquium on Indian Economic Development, University of Economics, Vienna, O c ­ tober 1982. D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 56 State and Politics in India Realignments 1946-1950 In politics often beginnings, despite their contingent character, take on the nature of fundamental constraining structures over the long term. No state is able to erase its .beginnings completely: initiatives taken in formative years of the state tend to acquire foundational and determining character simply because of their historical priority. Political scientists have been, in my view, inat­ tentive towards the significance of this period of fast and crucial historical change;25 and consequently, discussions on Indian pol­ itics suffer from a myth of exaggerated continuity between the late years of colonial rule and the early years of independent power. The Congress which assumed power in 1947 was not in many respects the Congress that won Independence. The post-war years, after it was generally known that Independence was coming in the immediate future, naturally saw a series of quick political changes. Besides, the formal constitutional structure that was adopted set the framework of the moves of different social classes and political actors for quite a long time, until constitutional and formal language fell into sudden disuse after 1969-71;26 Clearly, this period formed a crucial stage in the history of the Indian national movement. Earlier the objective of the movement was the rather abstract one of making Independence possible; now the objective of every political group within the broad national movement changed into struggling for determination of the struc­ ture of power of the independent state - not an abstract end of 25 Recently, after the archives have been opened for these years, there has been considerable interest among historians about this formative period; however, not much historical research is yet available. 26 Ordinari.ly, the period of large-scale disregard for constitutional rules is set at 1975. But it ought to be noted that many of the initial moves against bourgeois democratic legal norms were begun and legitimized in the imme­ diately preceding period of the 'left tum'. The judiciary, for instance, was attacked as conservative and opposed to the parliamentary tendency towards progressive legislation. This was an argument_ taken from British political arguments of the 1930s. Of course, it is possible to make a case that the courts generally incline to be conservative, but Indira Gandhi used this to loosen bourgeois constraints over her government, not to strain towards socialism. Unfortunately, leftists willingly surrendered their arguments to her, in return for small favours. These were used systematically to justify precapitalist irresponsibility in governance. Much of the present wrecking of bourgeois democratic instirutional norms was done with the help of a disingenuous use of radical rhetoric. D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Syrtem 57 sovereignty, but a far more concrete question of the form of the society and material allocation of advantages. Different political groups showed their common appreciation of this historical fact in their differing ways. Muslim separatism became more strident in demanding a separate state. Communists registered the same urgency by intensifying their struggles for acknowledgement of peasant rights. Congress groups responded to this climate of approaching power by greater ideological polarization and crys­ tallization of political factions. And Gandhi, most interestingly and unpredictably of all, responded by suggesting that the Con­ gress, bearing the imprint of an earlier age, ought to be disbanded in a typically theatrical conve,rgence 0£.the symbols of fulfilment and denouement. Alongside these secessions from the earlier ambiguous unity of a single nation:dist'movement there w.ere significant internal re­ alignmen�within the Congress. Congress's paradox of continuity began from its very early days. It is not only that Indira Gandhi's Congress was very different from Nehru's although claiming con­ tinuity, Nehru's Congress itself was different from the organiza­ tion it inherited. Within the apparent hegemony of the Congress over the national movement, these· two years saw serious political realignments; and what is more, many of these tended to nullify earlier historical shifts in the Congress organization in a relatively radical direction. After 1942, Socialists and their assorted allies came to occupy an important position in the Congress in the Hindi belt, an area that has been since the mid-1960s the despair of radical groups. Popular mobilization of a spontaneous form be­ came widespread and began erupting outside the formal structure of the Congress. In the years just before Independence, the Con­ gress was rising as a paradoxical mass wave, a wave which made its coming to power irresistible, but also a wave that the Congress leadership wished to see controlled rather than encouraged. For it may have meant, if it continued indefinitely, the crystallization of an early radical popular challenge to its new government. When the Congress assumed power, since questions of social design and distribution of advantages through the legal form had become central, polarization within the party naturally became more intense. Thus the tussle between Nehru and Patel should be seen as a serious conflict of strategy within the ruling coalition, the outcome of which would have seriously affected the fate of Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 58 State ll1Jd Politics in India the state, the nature of the economy and the even purely social formation of these classes themselves. This was not, as sometimes claimed, a struggle between a bourgeois and a radical petty bour­ geois programme of development of the nation; but equally cer­ tainly, it was no mere personal tussle for power between individual factions. It was a conflict between two quite different strategic perspectives within the general direction of capitalist dexelop­ ment. And a victory of the more reactionary segment within the Congress could have meant great differences in public policy regarding the public sector, the extent of state control, the play of market forces, the nature of planning and foreign policy. Strategic differences assumed a sharp form between an old style, liberal, laissez-faire form of capitalist programme, and a refor­ mistic state-centred strategy advocated by the Nehru supporters within the party. Eventually, the historical outcome of this strat­ egy conflict turned .out to be deeply paradoxical. Through a combination of economic reasonableness and fortuitous events (like Patel's sudden death) the comparative reformists around Nehru won the strategic debate within the Congress, though their complete dominance in policy-making had to wait till the Second Plan. But something else, less newsworthy and noticeable, also happened at the same time within the Congress party. This highly spectacular victory of the reformists concealed a more fundamental weakening of their forces. Through a series of politi­ cal squabbles, socialists who were within the Congress gradually left the party - to form most of the time relatively ineffective and regionally limited opposition groups. Subsequently, the so­ cialist groups in north India followed suicidal moves common among political parties under pressure of declining mass support. Under Lohia's influence, they went in for slogans and motifs which they thought would stop the erosion of their base and turn north India into a socialist fortress. Actually, it eventually turned into a prison. Adoption of the parochial agenda saved their base temporarily in the north, but ensured that it could not extend its appeal or mass base in other parts of India. It was a heavy price to pay for an advantage which eventually did not last. Besides, the strong anti-communism of the socialists also precluded any collaboration between the two major left parties outside the Congress; though, had they worked together as a joint political pressure group for radicalization of social policies and their D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Syrtan 59 implementation, it could possibly have counteracted the disin­ genuousness of Congress land reforms. However, the paradox was that the Congress was formally wedded to what we now describe as Nehruvian reformist pro­ gramme at a time when the radicals inside the Congress became woefully wealc, and whatever little striking power they had was mainly concentrated at the centre. From the early years of the government, because of the federal distribution of powers, prac­ tically all measures adopted towards any reform of the agrarian structure were effectively countermanded by its own recalcitrant and more conservative state and local units. The Nehru govern­ ment, thus, began its career by playing false to its own adopted programmes. And the quick decline of socialist influence in the states of Bihar and UP where there had been strong peasant mobilizations in the not too distant past remains one of the large uninterrogated phenomena of recent Indian politics. The depar­ ture of the reformist elements from the Congress led to a feeling among the small elite around Nehru of being encircled within their own party organization. It provided the initial condition for, and pressure towards, a 'passive revolution' strategy. Experimentation 1950-1956 Out of this historical situation arose the enormous programme of a capitalist 'passive revolution'27 that the Congress adopted in the Nehru period. First, of course, the programme of serious bourgeois land reforms was abandoned through a combination of feudal resistance, judicial conservatism and connivance of state Congress leaderships.28 Legal arrangement of property institu­ tions, sanctioned by the constitution, reinforced such opposition and gave it juridical teeth. Thus the only way in which agrarian transformation could talce place was through a conservative, grad­ ualist and 'molecular'29 process. Feudal and other conservative resistance could, in principle, be broken down if the Congress encouraged the mobilization of the masses and was willing to use the already achieved mobilizational levels for radical purposes 27 Gramsci, Prison Notebooks. 28 For a dettiled account of this process, see, Francine Frankel, India's Political &onomy (Princeton: Princeton University Press; 1978). 29 Gramsci, Prison Noteboolts. D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 60 State and Politics in India consistent with its own programmes. But one of the central decisions of the Nehru government was on this question: even though it sometimes did not abrogate its reformistic programmes, it decided to give them a bureaucratic rather than a mobilizatiOMi form. For the Congress leadership, clearly, the political task after assuming power was to demobilize its own movement, not to radicalize it further. It also discreetly renounced promises of distributive justice which had come to constitute part of its in­ formal programme in the last stiges of national movement. The basic contradiction of Congress politics in these early years has been analysed in detiil in recent academic literature: needs of long-term economic strategy and ideological legitimation in a poor country made an abstractly redistributive programme im­ perative; but the ends of mobilizing the -effective levers of power in the countryside during ordinary times made dependence o n rural magnates equally unavoidable.3° No party can, after all, expropriate its own power (as opposed to electoral) base. Although the Congress was content to accept the continuanc:e of semi-feudal rural power, elsewhere in the economy, it adopted massive plans for capitalist development. But such plans can as­ sume quite different institutional forms and political trajectories: Evidently, the Indian elite decisively rejected a trajectory of satel­ lite growth, a common destiny which befell most other newly independent Third World stites. Consistent with this general objective, the ruling elite adopted a plan for heavy industrialization and institutional control of capitil goods industries through the state sector, a largely untried experiment at the time in the under­ developed countries. Economic plans led to some serious shifts in the internal power distribution of society, though primarily within the elements of the ruling bloc itself. Political mistrust of foreign capital and, to a lesser extent, of the potential power of private capital in India led to much of this new, crucial and politically privileged segment of the economy to be given over to a new and fast growing public sector, in the face of strong political opposition from internal conservatives.31 T}ie larger theory and the economic projections for this huge state-controlled sector, which, in turn, controlled some crucial 30 F_rankel, lndu,'s Politic11I &rmtm,y. 31 The politics of planning and the public sector, alas, remains a seriously under-researched area. Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN TheSyrtmi 61 parts of the larger economy by financial mechanisms, came from a new bureaucracy of economic and technical personnel who entered into the earlier, more limited format of the colonial law and order bureaucracy, and changed its structure and practices. Planning assisted and ideologically justified an enormous expan­ sion of a 'welfare bureaucracy' which set in motion some internal conflicts in the adtninistrative apparatus of the state, e.g. the debate about the relative decisional weight of technocrats and bureau­ crats, and more crucially, the division of their respective domains of control. At the general level, however, they had some common interests. They gratefully accepted the chance for a quick pro­ liferation o f bureaucratic occupations and a consequent tendency· to bring under bureaucratic administration any new field of social activity. And since the decision about how much the bureaucracy should expand was made by the bureaucracy itself, though oc­ casionally under some thinly assumed disguises of committees and commissions, it is not surprising that this sector spread rapidly in size and increased its strategic control at the expense of more traditional controllers of productive resources. This led in the long run to the growth of a large non-market mechanism of allocation of resources, a process which was originally justified by 'socialist' arguments of controlling private capitalist power, but shown by later events to be increasingly prone to arbitrary distribution of economic patronage by politicians. Originally, this social group had enthusiastically supported the spread of an intricate regime of controls through licences, permits and government sanctions, which they saw slipping out of their grasp and being put to retrograde uses. So that, eventually, this entire state-directed eco­ nomic regime could be singled out for criticism for its political arbitrariness and inefficiency; although actually the public sector is criticized by using examples that travesty its functioning. 32 Anyway, politically this allowed the bureaucracy to have control over other people's time frames, if not actual decisions. The more Nehru was politically weakened inside the party organization, the lZ The ways of the Congress party are truly inscrutable. It expels leading members for being too vocal about economic scandals and kickbacks, but allows Vasant Sathe, an equally important member, to launch frontal attacks on the public sector, presumably an important part of its own economic programmes. Evidently, the Congress follows a special logic in defining consistency and programmatic loyalty. Dig1t1zeo by Google Origi�al rrom UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 62 State and Politics in India greater the resistance at the state level to his reformist policies, the more he was forced into the passive revolution logic of bureau­ cratization, which saw the people not as subjects but as simple objects of the development process. The theoretical understanding behind this development �trategy was also in several ways exces­ sively rationalistic: it falsely believed that external 'experts' nat­ urally knew more about people's problems and how to solve them than those who suffered these problems themselves. By the mid­ l950s such an over-rationalistic doctrine became a settled part of the ideology of planning and therefore of the Indian state, 'The state', or whoever could usurp this title for the time being, rather than the people themselves, was to be the initiator and, more dangerously, the evaluator of the development process. A partly superstitious reverence for natural science, undeservingly ex­ tended to economists, sociologists and similar other pretenders to absolute .truth,33 justified a theory which saw popular criticisms of state-controlled growth as 'civic disorders'. Every advance of this rhetoricized bureaucracy in the control of social life was celebrated as a further step towards a mystical socialistic pattern of society in which although 'socialists' controlled state power, economic and distributive inequality of other sorts rapidly increased. Al­ though it is important to undermine its unfounded and arrogant 'socialistic' claims, it would be unrealistic not to see that this state, under this particular balance of its ruling bloc, worked out a fairly elaborate theory of import-substituting industrialization and ran a limited, in the sense of unevenly spread, system of parliamentary democracy. Two points, however, have to be mentioned about the internal balance of the regime. Successful functioning of this re­ gime depended on, first, the existence of a strong constitutional­ legal system, which enforced legal responsibility; and second, it worked successfully in the early years because the relation between the bourgeoisie and the new bureaucracy was relatively antagonis­ tic rather than collusive. Bourgeois political interests attempted . This group of course emphatically includes political scientists who had convinced themselves that the truisms they uttered about Indian politics were different from popular wisdom by the important fact that theirs were pro­ duced by the application of the scientific method. I have omitted them from the list because the spirit of the age has not been in their favour, and they were given much less advisory importance than their colleagues in the dismal science. Although their labours in the spread of a degenerate form of positiv­ ism was second to none, they never made it to the high advisory councils. B Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The System 63 to ftght it out frontally, in an ideological battle, trying to argue through political doctrine that a more market-oriented approach would be better for economic growth, than to allow the ceremonial programme to stay and buy surreptitious reprieve from its rigours through large-scale corruption. Both these conditions were reversed in later years. Consolidation 1956-1964 To emphasize these features of the political economy of the Nehru years is not to deny that modern India is still held together by a partially infringed frame which is a legacy of his period, despite the best efforts of the party he had once led to break down its structural principles during the rule of his political successors.34 Unforrunately, Indira Gandhi and Rajiv Gandhi can be seen only as his filial, not his political, inheritors. If his policy frame has not been entirely destroyed, it is certainly not from any want of effort from his party or those who followed him into power. Nehru's historical importance is signalized by the fact that any programme of bourgeois reconstruction still s_peaks of a return to his 'system' as opposed to the later Congress performance in the political and economic fields. It is false to claim, as Nehru's official admirers often do, that Nehru was a political theorist who had worked out a prior strategy for 'independent capitalist development' which he slowly unfolded when in power. In fact, he was no theorist; but he had an over­ whelming sense that political programmes in countries like India must be set in the frame of objectives in the historical long-term, so that, for him, political ideology meant an interpretation of historical possibilities rather than populist gimmicks. Nehru's re­ gime thought seriously that reduction of poverty would necessarily be slower in a state in which legal bourgeois rights to property exist; Indira Gandhi's regime cheerfully promised its abstract erad­ ication in the elections of 1971, though none of the conditions which forced Nehru's hesitation had changed. Although no theorist, Nehru certainly had a statesmanly nose for reading 'the dialectic of the concrete', and he picked up the elements of a fairly 34 I have tried to deal with this in 'On the Crisis of Political Institutions in India', Contributions to Indian Sociology, No. 2, 1984. Dlgltlzedby Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 64 State and Politics in India coherent social and political design as he went along, mainly reading the logic of colligation between one basic policy and the next. Use of political power by a ruling elite involves serious recursive calculations about effects ofearlier policies and ensuring conditions of success of one policy by means of others. If the bloc in power survives over a long enough time, this makes it likely that a coherent policy design would gradually emerge. But here again a prior political condition is that the elite must feel securely in power and work on a certain short-term dissociation between political objectives of continuance and economic distribution and creation of resources. It is this which can allow tying up resources in investments with longer periods of gestation, against the temp­ taion to use resources in the form of direct subsidies to volatile sections. Since Nehru's regime never had serious doubts about its electoral future, it could embark on programmes like the Second Five-Year Plan; for later governments similar uses of economic resources under government control became politically unfeasible. Although Nehru did not enter office with a fully worked out programme, he did eventually create a distinct policy design. In its final form, its elements we1e internally coherent. Political stability and realization of independence of decision required an improvement in the food situation, since American food aid, from early on, was used to exert political pressure on basic policy issues. This meant that in foreign policy India should seek alternative. sources of international support. Parallel considerations of pro­ tecting political sovereignty of developmental decisions led to the major thrust of the Second Plan towards primary sector industrial­ ization. Gathering the results of these policies depended to a large extent on keeping these sectors of the economy under direct control of the state. Driven by political-economic calculations of this kind, the Indian state opened up its diplomatic relations with the USSR. Of course, a whole range of external cirel.imstances helped this process of a surprising connection between the leading socialist state and the country in the Third World in which capitalism had a somewhat greater chance of success. This was greatly helped by the fact that the USSR pursued in its foreign policy minimal objectives as opposed to the unpractically maxi­ malist ones of the US. 35 This mutual need was the ground for H A simple definition of minimal and maximal objectives in international politics would be as follows. When state A wishes state B to do what it wants Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN Tbt Systtm 65 early friendship between the two countries rather than an Indian attempt to build a version of socialism, or Soviet assistance to a regime trying to build a 'non-capitalist form' of society.36 However, there were two ways in which the Nehru model was subvened by later political initiatives: much of it was an inversion 'from inside' as it were, as in case of bureaucratic control over the economy- turning the power of overriding market mechanisms by the state over to the service of arbitrary granting of favours to pliable corporate houses, companies and individuals. On some questions, however, there was a more explicit reversal of formal government policy about generation of growth and managing its distributive effects. One significant element of the Nehruvian growth model discussed at length during the finalization of the Second Plan was the connection between the industrial and agrar­ ian strategies, a doctrine decisively rejected during Indira Gandhi's regime. A strong push towards industrialization in the heavy.in­ dustrial sector was supposed to be related to a parallel drive for land reforms through a large programme for cooperativization. This involved pressing reluctant and procrastinating state govern­ ments to enact more serious land reform legislation. Government doctrine asserted that requirements of raising surplus resources for the massive industrialization, increasing agricultural produc­ tivity, preventing a fast cost-push inflation could be served by change and redistribution of control over land and resources in the rural sector in a more egalitarian direction. The Nehru regime, with its finer sensibilities about legal propriety, felt legally hand­ icapped, because land came under the state list in the constitutional division of powers.37 Indeed, the federal division of powers could be seen in terms of our model as a coalitional proposal directed it to do, that could be called a maximal target; a minimal objective i s one when A wants B to do something different from what its rival C wishes B to do. 36 The famous controversy in communist circles about the article by Modeste Rubinstein arguing that the Nehru government w:is proposing to follow a non-capitalist path. Ajoy Ghosh wrote a remarkably scathing reply to this article. 37 It is interesting t o note that lndi.ra Gandhi's regime increasingly freed itself of these legal encumbrances, leading to a general decline of the institutional system. Initial arguments in favour of this softening of bourgeois legal norms were made by using 'socialist' ideas; but, remarkably, the room for manoeuvre created by this has never been utilized for radical reforms. Dig1t1zeo by Google Origi�al rrom UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 66 State and Politics in India at the regional bourgeoisie and dominant agriculrural interests giving them relative autonomy in their own regions. Insistent requirements of capitalist development now threatened to infringe that agreement within the protocol. Besides, the decline of the zamindars and direct feudal landholders left the field free for accumulation of power in the hands of a stratum of richer farmers who wished to inherit political immunities implicit in the initial protocol. This introduced a con- flict of interests within the struc­ ture of the ruling coalition in India, the effects of which were significant in the long run. Nehru's policy initiatives in the late 1950s and early 1960s led to a double process of polarization in politics. Government initiatives in three interrelated areas -crea­ tion of heavy industries in the public sector, increasing reliance on Soviet assistance in their construction, and the pressure from the planning element in government for changes in the agrarian sector towards cooperativization -led to sharp criticism of the Congress. Individual capitalists, sometimes even the entire class, have to be pardoned for occasionally failing to see what was to be beneficial to the system as a whole. These Nehruvian policies, celebrated now as a triumphant design for successful construction of retarded capitalism, came under strong fire from a panicking combine of representatives of proprietary classes. The Congress's industrial policies were interpreted as the thin end of the socialist stick; land reform proposals, shamefully mild and solidly bour­ geois, appeared to them as a programme of an agrarian revolution from above; the public sector, intended merely to displace the cen­ tre of control towards the state, was seen as an attack on private enterprise. For the fust time, a large right-wing coalition of con­ servatives inside and outside the ruling party seemed to be emerg.mg. Political consequences of such misreadings of Congress policy were considerable. Two trends of political realignments began soon after the adoption of the Second Plan package of policies. Grievances against industrial policy and related issues led to the formation of a Swatantra party; but more significant changes happened in the rural political scene. Congress pressure for co­ operativization came just at the time when the beneficiaries of the agrarian changes were enjoying the first impulse of their power. This led to serious shifts within the ruling bloc. Although in terms of distribution of unequal benefits, the rural elite' must be Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The System 67 considered to have been part of the ruling coalition, they con­ stituted undoubtedly its most quiescent part. Imaginary threats of disadvantage,38 but, more concretely, grievance against the fact that they were not getting a larger share of advantages and that their rising economic power was insufficiently translated into pol­ itical authority because they thought the rules of the parliamentary game constantly wrong-footed them, made them increasingly res­ tive. 39 The farmers' groups, in other words, demanded a more equal share of the fruits of inequality. There was large-scale exodus of farmer support from the Congress and formation of regional farmers' groupings. This should be seen in my judgment as a move by these two subordinate and quiescent groups to set up relations across the boundary of the coalition with other dispossessed groups.40 All over India, but particularly in the more agriculturally successful states, peasant parties sprang up and became part of the growing opposition blocs in the fourth general elections. Their typical leaders were Charan Singh and Rao Birendra Singh - the latter more typical than the former, because he later rejoined the Congress. Because his self-respect was not plastic enough, Charan Singh could not do that. Some of these disgruntled elements retained their loyalty to the protocol by announcing that they would retain their Congress labels with suitable adjectival modi­ fication.41 The fates of the two critical realignments were even­ tually very different. Relative success of the policy of heavy industrialization and the Second Plan was soon generally accepted by even the recalcitrant bourgeois groups; and the Swatantra party consequently sank into political irrelevance. But the session of the farmers' lobbies over much of northern India, led first to a political 38 There is always a hypothetical calculation of possible benefits made by classes and groups quite apan from threats of disadvant2ge. 39 Most of these demands are spelt out clearly in Charan Singh's treatise on development, Jndu,'r &unomic Polity (Delhi: Vws, 1978). 40 If the whole society is made up of the letters of the alphabet, and abc are i n 't hat order wielders of power, if c is disgruntled, it can es12blish alliances across the bowidaries of the ruling coalition with d e f . . . 1bis would bring instability to the coalition where a + b + c was a amditi1111 for their being in power. But e's leaving the a b c coalition would not be read properly if we do not see thi� leaving itself as an offer to return to an a c b coalition. 41 The cowiay-was full of non-national Congresses of all kinds - Bangla Congress, Kenia Congress and so on -asserting the reassuring concreteness of the regional identity as opposed to the greater abstracmess ofthe national one. Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 68 State and Politics in India debacle of the Congress then to internal changes in Congress policies. Their withdrawal ofsupport from the Congress weakened it seriously in both class and party tenns; and the Congress leader­ ship saw it as a double-valued move: an exercise of the exit option, which concealed a proposal to remrn if the protocol was restruc­ tured in their favour. In coalitional politics every threat is an offer. Changes in Congress policy in agriculmre towards a 'technical' solution of the food problem, through heavy government invest­ ment in 'advanced' sectors which was known to be likely to result in an accentuation of rural inequality, showed that the Congress had read this move correctly and was prepared to make alterations in its policies to accommodate ambitions of regional £-armers' groups.42 Foreign policy issues so heavily dominated the last years of the Nehru period that some of the long-term consequences of his programme of passive revolution took longer than normal time to surface. Imbalances left behind by Nehru's government affected policies of the successor regimes. Its imbalances threatened to rupmre the coalitional unity of the ruling bloc by creating a rift of interest between the bourgeois, bureaucratic, urban segment and regional bourgeois interests and agrarian propertied classes.43 This picmre of the Nehru period should not be taken as an unhistorically one-sided and pessimistic one. Although all Third World societies with ambitions of capitalist growth have failed, I do not deny that the Indian society has failed much better than others.44 There are undoubted advantages of the Indian case over 42 Surprisingly, the farmer lobbies were proper examples of the theory that there are wunarked, but very significant frontiers of regional consciousness. Thus a potential national combine of such groups -which would have been formidable, if not simply overwhelming-has not really come into existence. Peasant lobbies seem incomprehensibly tr�pped within frontiers of regional consciousness; for some reason, they cannot recognize an entirely absttact we, linlced entirely by modern economic interests, unsupported by any direct­ ly available form of historical se l fconceptualization like ]at, or Kmnma, or such et,1ltural identity. If they describe themselves as inhabitants of UP, this would indicate a more absttact consciousness of territoriality. 43 For an economic pursuit of this phenomenon, see Ashok Mitra, Ttrms of Trade and Cum Rtl4tu,,u (London: Franlc Cass, 1977).. 44 Nothing illustrates th.is more clearly than the abandonment in the I970s of the argument popµlar with Western bourgeois theorists that India and Pakistan were two opp0$Cd models of development for Third World societies. Although the attachrnent oflarge Western democracies for an oppressive and Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The System 69 other competing models like Pakistan, or now, more fashionably, South Korea. It is obviously better than the tinpot but nonetheless vicious dictatorships in Latin America and also some unproduc­ tively austere regimes in Africa given prematurely lyrical reception by radicals in the 1960s. Such successes of the Nehru regime are accepted, but remain unstated here, because I primarily intend to draw something of a causal line from what we consider our 'best' period to our worst. Instability 1965-1975 Contradictions of the policies of the Nehru period su.rfuced after the somewhat artificial national unity of the mid-l 960s disap­ peared. Nationalist hysteria naturally created a temporary alliance of sentiment which brought together political forces from the hard right to the mild left into an easy patriotic combination that isolated the communists, especially the CPl(M). But the arti­ ficiality of this was shown by the fact that in three years after Nehru's death, left forces could regroup sufficiently to form coali­ tion governments in states. India passed through a deep political crisis in the few years after Nehru's death, a crisis that, in policy terms, was fraught with the most serious retrograde possibilities. An orchestration of pressures - from both internal and external reaction - created a situation in which the Nehruvian plan for a reformist capitalism with its policies of public sector, state control over resources, planning, a relatively anti-imperialist foreign policy could all be renegotiated.45 Indira Gandhi's government initially gave in to some of these pressures, its most celebrated collapse being the acceptance of devaluation of the rupee. In the fourth general elections, Congress fortunes declined alarmingly, and it was evi­ dent that to get out of the deepening politico-economic crisis, the party needed some drastic measures. Initiatives taken by Indira Gandhi in the years after 1967 showed that in her view the <;:ongress was facing a crisis of legitimacy. Unlike the years after economically unsuccessful tyranny like Pakistan was always difficult to ex­ plain, now Pakistan has become too obvious an ideological liability and is defended by purely security arguments. 4S I have sketched this out more fully in 'Indira G.indhi and Indian Politics', EPW. September 1986. Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 70 State and Politics in India Independence, it was not seen as a force of redistributive change, but a conservative party underwriting social inequality. Legit­ imacy could be reviewed by restating the objectives of distributive justice with dramatic splendour. Some changes in economic policy were evident from the early years of the new regime, particularly, the reversal of the earlier poli cy on agriculture with an implicit acceptance of the inequitous social consequences of the new line and gradual decline of emrhasis on planning46 and the policy of large public investments.4 Politics of the Indian state and the Congress party entered into a different historical stage by the fourth general elections. Earlier, electoral survival of the Congress, the simple control over govern­ ments which was a precondition for making and shaping policies, was never in question although Nehru's electoral majorities were never dramatic. Going by purely electoral statistics, Nehru would appear retrospectively to have been permanently insecure, enjoy­ ing unspectacularly simple 1najorities in Parliament. By contrast, Indira Gandhi and Rajiv Gandhi would appear unassailably secure, riding great waves of popular affection. This only shows, in the face of much political science of the last twenty years, that electoral 'behaviour' is a rather poor indicator of what a people politically do to themselves. Actually, there was a displacement of the ques­ tion at the heart of these elections. Formerly, the major question was not whether the Congress would remain in power. It was assumed that it would; the debate was about its policies. After 1967, every time, except in the last elections, the question was 46 Planning had become too much of a slogan for the Congress to be dropped altogether, and the concept carried pleasant reminders of Nehru. Although the thing could not be dropped entirely, its substance could be hollowed out and thrown overboard. Economists who are critiC:11 of government poli cy have concentrated too much on the technical economics of the plans, rather than their larger ideological concept. To an untechniC:11 eye, whatever its mathematical triumphs in recent years, planning seems to have degenerated increasingly into an accounting and housekeeping operation rather than a directive mechanism for the productive forces of the economy. Planning was a blessing for the self-reproducing bureaucracy. Every claim for creating the post of an unproductive, and possibly corrupt, bureaucrat could be said to be in the general interest of the country's economic progress. Thus although we have much less of planning, we have, happily, a much larger commission. 47 Several Marxist economists have forcefully stressed this point. Cf. Pranab Bardhan, Politic#/Economy ofDrot/opmmtinlndill (New Del hi: Oxford Univer­ sity Press, 1985). Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The System 71 whether it would remain in power or not. Thus pre-1967 politics revolved around real ideological issues - what should be the path of national development, what would be the distributive character of economic growth? After 1967, the attention of Congress politicians went entirely into electoral issues and the matter of staying in power. In my view, contrary to what is often said, Indira Gandhi's politics became decidedly less ideological.48 By a populist move Indira Gandhi solved this electoral crisis of her party.49 But long-term effects of her policies have created a crisis of a different kind. Congress politics was marked by a paradox of.continuity. No one would normally claim that Indira Gandhi wished to take the country on a very different line of development or diverge sharply from the policy design left behind by Nehru; yet probably no one would claim either that she left this design unaltered, or deny that her initiatives or interpreta­ tions have had serious negative consequences for the Nehruvian model.50 48 For the conttaryview, cf. R . Ulyanovslcy, Socialism tmd rhe Newly lndepmdent N11tiims(Moscow: Progress Publishers, 1974), and his other occasional writ­ ings on Indian politics. 49 I have suggested that this has altered the significance of elections and turned them into plebiscites, in 'Indira Gandhi and Indian Politics'. 50 Some criticisms of the argwnent of this chapter at the seminar where it was presented touched on this point. Several critics thought that the line was too heavily 'strucruralist' in the sense that it did not recognize the possibility that politics of indubitably bad consequences could have originated in 'innocent', defensible and entirely understandable intentions. Structuralism need not deny the necessary ulltidiness of political life and the complex, asymmetric relation between intentions and consequences. It is simply r e ­ quired, in the face of such criticism, to state a sufficiently complex theory of intentionality and accept a weak truth in these objections. Surely, Indira Gandhi did not wish to wreck the Indian state, but equally certainly, she ne,arly did. Part of the problem lies i n our ambiguous use of the verb phrase 'Indira Gandhi did x' which is undetermined between 'intended to do x' and 'effected x'. Even unacadernic observers of politics would admit, I suppose, that between two lists, the first of which showed what Indira Gandhi wished to but failed to do, and another showing what she perhaps did not deliberately intend but nonetheless caused, the second would be the analytically more serious one. A structural argwnent need not entirely erase intentions, only de-emphasize them. It has no quarrel with the reporting of intentions as long as that does not displace the causal line. For instance as long as intentional arguments do not go into rationalizing forms saying 'Indira Gandhi intended to eradicate poverty, but unfortunately, and unmipont1ntly, she could not', they are not seriously harmful. It is in this sense that S. Gopal's book tells Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 72 State and Politics in India It is not necessary to retell the melancholy narrative of how quick but indecisive victories contributed to a long-term crisis of the state and how the state structure was centralized to such an extent that ..political difficulties of the leader or the government party became generalized into a crisis of the entire state.51 We shall simply mention the political shifts introduced by her 'pragmatic' transla­ tion of Nehru's political strategy.52 In one sense,. Indira Gandhi faced a situation similar to the one Nehru had encountered, with the difference that she obviously, in the mid-1960s, lacked Nehru's irreplaceability within the party. Thus by the logic of the situation she had to intensify the passive revolution features of the Nehru period, often, however, to a point where these tended to subvert their own original purpose. Control over government initially, because of the parliamentary format o f political power, depended on her control over the party. Since after Nehru effective power within the Congress had shifted to the state bosses, and they could and did mount an offensive against her leadership position, she set about systematically undermining state Congress caucuses. This had two types of effects: first, party posts and patronage at the state levels shifted towards less effective leaders, who had no political base in their states. Though on some occasions the process of replacement of older Congress leaders by the new type was accompanied by ideological rhetoric - for in­ stance the new leaders being dedicated removers of poverty- this was not taken seriously by the public nor the pretence kept up for too long. No one suspected the new leaders of ideology. In the event, most of them proved themselves to be men of astonishing doctrinal suppleness. In the days of the socialist forum they thought only socialism could end Indian people's sufferings; but during the Emergency they were quick to appreciate the advantage of the Brazilian path; and some, the subtlest of all, declared in the days of the Shah Commission how they had nothing to do with the Emer­ gency regime but helplessly enjoyed its benefits. Second, after the fall of the earlier, older generation of state leaders, Indira Gandhi's Congress did not allow electoral processes to be revived, and these half the story of the Nehru era and gives an account of Nehru's intentions. To use our argument a trifle lightheartedly, it requires a complement which would State more fully Nehru's consequences. SI 'On the Crisis of Political Institutions in India'. S2 Ibid. Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN Tht System 73 organizations, nominated from the centre, remained completely ineffective. The resultant ineffectiveness of state Congress machinery made it inevitable that power would be shifted even more towards a bureaucracy53 which would soon declare ·itself 'committed' to unspecified ideals.54 This should not be seen as an argument that prettifies older state leadership of the Congress. Earlier leaders of the Congress like Atulya Ghosh, S.I(. Patil or Nijalingappa never enjoyed great moral stature and dealt in quite a malodorous form of patronage politics, and thus Congress did not have much moral eminence to lose. But the new leaders were not products of even local factional conflicts; they were simply imposed on state parties externally. They were not even significantly hated, but were merely unspeakable non-entities. In such circumstances, it was hardly surprising that although securely in power as long as they enjoyed the confidence of the central leadership, these leaders lacked the ability to resolve state problems or serious regional conflicts, and tended to send up all local issues for a central settle­ ment. But the advisers of the Gandhi regime read their shirking of responsibility as a touching mark of loyalty. Although this showed their loyalty to the centre and kept them gainfully underemployed, it tended to overload the centre in terms of the sheer number of decisions. In effect, this also shifted the power of decision from those who knew state politics to those who knew it less, and accounts perhaps for the wildly fluctuating pragmatism of Congress rule in the states after 1971.55 The new state leaders lacked the 53 A s the internal linkages in the party rurned increasingly one-way, gover­ nance required some two-way flow, and it shifted to the only alternative a degenerating bureaucracy. S4 A committed bureaucracy was an odd idea. And it was not consistent with the professed purposes for which this idea was advanced. If this meant that the bureaucracy would remain committed t o the elected government, the idea was redundant, because it was meant to be so anyway. If it meant commitment to a party irrespective of its electoral fate, this was blasphemous, because it went right against the principle of den1ocracy. If it meant a comminnent to socialism, it was the most paradoxical of all, because socialis1n is a matter of policies; and either before or after the bureaucracy's commitment to the government, the government failed to commit itself to socialism. If it meant a coded appeal to leaders for preferment to a small coterie of politicians and bureaucrats for their commitment to socialism in some n1istily distant past, this was understandable and part of a solid tradition of sycophancy stretching into medieval times. SS Congress pragmatism was fluctu2ting in the following sense; various social Dig1t1zeo by Google Origi�al rrom UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 74 State and Politics in India ability to hold political equilibria in the states by creation and manipulation of interest coalitions and factional politics - an unpleasant but efficacious art that Congress leaders had perfected ·· in the earlier period of condominium with a more distant, non­ interfering centre. Destruction of state-level Congress organizations was not ac­ cidental, for it happened not only at the time Indira Gandhi was under pressure, but continued way beyond 1971 when she was in uncontested control of the party and the state, and the Congress went on in unembarrassed cheerfulness with nominated state com­ mittees, reducing state leaders to mere clients rather than sup­ porters of the central-authority.56 Thus Indira Gandhi changed the Congress into a highly centralized and undemocratic party organization, from the earlier federal, democratic and ideological formation that Nehru had led. It should be a minor issue of Indian politics that the party which vowed to defend democracy in India could not retain it within its own folds. Also the earlier unstated doctrine was that a strong centre could be based only on powerful states; in he-r regime, the power of the state governments and of the centre began to be interpreted in entirely zero-sum terms, irrespective of whether states were controlled by the Congress or opposition parties.57 Eventually, we wimess a further paradox of power. The Indira regime's answer to a general sense of gathering crisis was an obsessive centralization that defeated its own purpose. She was arguably a more powerful Prime Minister than Nehru in terms of control over the party and the state. But she presided over a system which, though more centralized, had actually be­ come far weaker. lobbies - ordinarily caste and regional groupings - perpetually contended for control within the Congress party. Access to high government positions made it possible to restructure govern.mental benefits in their favour. Often, one interest lobby of this lcind would be replaced by another, and immediately restrueture benefit legislations t o the utter detriment of consistency in gov­ ernment policy. In recent years, this has happened most frequently through caste-related reservation legislations, for example in Gujarat in the very recent past. 56 Tendencies of this kind towards atrophy of the party mechanism have been studied for quite sometime, not surprisingly, more often by liberal academics than by Marxists. 57 The central Congress leadership appears as suspicious of an H.N. Bahuguna as of a Jyoti Basu, an extraordinary attitude if one took party divisions seriously. Digiti zed by Google Ongmal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The System 75 Gradually, the redundancy of state parties also extended to the centre, and effective power shifted entirely to governmental echelons. Ceremonial leadership of the Congress party became a redundant function: either Indira Gandhi herself was the leader but derived her legitimacy from being the Premier; or when it was someone else, his position was purely decorative. This develop­ ment implied the destruction of one of the checks within the Nehruvian structure: the party could often balance the govern­ mental wing. Except in times of elections, Indira Gandhi ran what could ironically be called a partyless government, in which, sym­ bolically, some of her minor office functionaries assumed more importance in terms of access, timing, powers of facilitating and delaying decisions than senior party leaders. But this decline of the party could not have happened had not Indira Gandhi changed the entire nature of politics. This new, populist politics turned political ideology- a serious disputation about the social design during the Nehru era - into a mere electoral discourse, use of vacuous slogans not meant to be trans­ lated into government policies. Shift of the Congress to populist politics quickly set up a new structure of political communication in which Indira Gandhi could appeal directly to the electorate over the heads of the party organizations. The relation between the party and its leader was turned around: instead of the organization carrying her to power, she carried them. Naturally, the Congress became a less serious political mechanism because both of its · significant functions were slowly taken away: elections were won by Indira Gandhi's ability to directly appeal to the masses; daily governance was slowly given over to the official government ma­ chinery and an increasingly politicized administration. During its great electoral victories in the early 1970s, amidst the celebrations, the Congress party as a political organization died an unremarked death. A natural correlate to this was the gradual shift of political (as opposed to administrative) tasks to the higher echelons of the bureaucracy which became increasingly more powerful at the cost of becoming more politicized.58 As the logic of modern S8 'Politicization' here docs not mean the bureaucracy's devotion to social programmes on ideological lines, but to a personal leadership of the state. Ironically, it became so devoted that i t lost all capacity for self-defence when the high coterie fell for the seductions of the 'Brazilian path'. Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 76 State and Politics in India bureaucracies is centralist, this aided the tendency towards a mind­ less centralization of increasingly irresponsible power. Counter­ vailing institutions gave way, through a simultaneous decline of Parliament and the court - though the firSt was less remarked because much of its humiliation and ineffectiveness was self-in­ flicted. Majorities became so large as to make their tending and discipline unnecessary, leading eventually to the comic situation of the present Congress party worrying about the attendance of its members in crucial debates in Parliament. 59 Although short­ sighted bureaucrats may have initially rejoiced at this accession to power, often misreading this as an instrument of reformist policies, it was gradually realized that bureaucrats could not always perform tasks of political leaders, and the decline of procedural civilities of capitalist democracy could be eventually used to the detriment of all elements. Particularly fatal was the loan that the CPI lobbies made to the Congress of its own slogans, symbols, argument and language - to their own detriment as it turned out in 1976. A remarkable feature of the new politics was the quickening of the political -cycle. Indira Gandhi had carried her party to power in 1971 on promises which were more radical and propor­ tionately more unrealistic than-earlier programmes. Factors which obstructed the realization of milder promises still remained and equally prevented any realization of the stronger promise, if of course this was taken literally. Governments had to pay the price of such populism sooner than expected. Under Nehru, electoral majorities of the Congress had never been comparably large; yet none of those administrations had difficulty in seeing through their appointed constitutional terms. Remarkably, after Indira Gandhi's victory in 1971, no government has actually lasted its term. By 1973, Indira Gandhi's large parliamentary majority notwithstanding, she was in deep political crisis. The Janata gov­ ernment, with a large majority, lasted barely three years. Indira Gandhi, in her second tertn in power, was politically in trouble at the time of her death. This calls for some explanation. In fact, the textbook translation of electoral majorities into administrative capability to rule was failing to take place. Indeed, it seems that 59 The Congress party had to issue a particularly stem admonition to its members to respect the whip. There was an alarming tendency among par­ liamentarians of the ruling party to take their massive majority for granted and pursue other interests, when Parliament was in session. Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The System 77 the larger the majority of the government, the more difficult it finds the general business of orderly governance. I have claimed elsewhere that this is due to a change in the narure of elections - which was initiated by the government party, but later used by the electorate to register its protest against the current political dispensation. Elections have rurned increasingly into populist referendwns, in which a highly emotive, rhetorical issue is placed before the elec­ torate immediately before the polls, screening off from view the mixed record of an incwnbent regime. This gave these govern­ ments exaggerated electoral majorities without clear mandates; but, more significantly, it destroyed the effectiveness of the electoral mechanism as a register of popular dissatisfaction. Thus govern­ ments which a few months earlier achieved massive mandates could face equally massive popular movements, as happened in Gujarat in 1974. Popular criticism of governmental performance, deprived of its legitimate channel in elections because of populism spilled out on to the streets. Indira Gandhi's answer to previous electoral instability under opposition rule in the states was not 111uch better than the earlier situation. Instability was not reduced, but internal­ ized. Instead of unstable opposition coalitions following one upon the other, now equally unstable Congress coalitions followed in quick succession; and since Congress did not have a cle_ar pro­ gramme in tenns of policies they could follow widely divergent trajectories in distributing benefits to social groups. Evolution of the Congress in the years of Indira Gandhi ought not to be seen in purely party or governmental terms. I have suggested that the Congress debacle in the late 1960s was related to a threatened secession of the rich agrarian groups from the ruling coalition. But as every threat is an offer, it represented their willingness to return to the fold with the terms of the protocol renegotiated in their favour. Under the pressure of the Emergency, and partly through the systematic concessions given to the agrarian rich, the Congress gradually got them back into its fold. Congress organizational positions were laid open to these politicians sometimes unused to the subtleties of bourgeois demo­ cracy. Agricultural policy of the government showed reluctance to either tax or impose other levies on the major beneficiaries of the process of green revolution. The Emergency, of course, overshadowed all other political Dlg ltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 78 State and Politics in India questions for sometime. Although initially defended by seemingly economic arguments, the Emergency regime soon ran out of arguments of justification in redistributive terms. Politically, how­ ever, it showed an extreme point of centralization. It showed literally how a personal crisis of the leader could be turned into a political crisis of the state. It showed how through a combination of centralization and suspension of normal constitutional proce­ dures of responsible government, actual power could shift to extra-constitutional caucuses. In a country with such a rich and varied culture of past tyranny, this is a particularly dangerous trend. It also showed finally how an excessively authoritarian· regime blocked off its own channels of communication to the extent of believing that it could win elections after the Emergency. Historically, however, the experience of the Emergency demon­ strated that� solution to India's political ills should not be sought in an authoritarian alternative. Democracy had lumbered on un­ tidily for thirty years; authoritarianism took less than two years to make the country ungovernable for itself. Crisis 1975-1987 Though the period after the death of Nehru was one of political instability, the character of political turmoil and the sense of pessimism associated with it were of a different character from the present gloom. What declined then was ·a government party and not the institutional structure of the state. Slowly such distinctions have become obliterated, and the general tone of thinking in India has become perceptibly darker, moving from political disquiet to a deeper historical pessimis1n. And this sense of apprehension about the fragility of Indian democracy, and pessimism about the tasks which the young state had once hopefully set itself, is natural­ ly deeply associated with the dark experience of the Emergency years. There has been a great deal of debate about the significance of the Emergency period: whether it was inevitably caused by a crisis of capitalism or simply a generalization of a personal crisis in an excessively centralized state; whether it was an aberration or showed a more insistent long-term tendency towards author­ itarianism. Although the form in which the political crisis erupted during the Emergency has gone into the past, I think it can be argued that that period marked the beginning of quite a different Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The System 79 kind of difficulty for the political order in India. This is a process in which a crisis laden ruling group is drawing the party, the governmental system, eventually the state itself, into crisis. Em­ pirically the assertion that the period since 197 5 has been one of almost uninterrupted political disorder hardly needs demonstra­ tion. Occasionally the crisis has changed form, terrain, expression, nodal points - in structuralist language, its site, and its bearers. But a sense of a historical crisis - a sense of increuing vul­ nerability and exhaustion of the state in face of self-produced disorders - has scarcely ever disappeared, in the last ten years. The way the Emergency ended showed that authoritarianism blocks off its own channels of political communication and re­ sponse, and makes a violent retribution highly likely. Emergency did not improve either the state's economic performance or ad­ ministrative functioning, and appeared a gratuitous exchange of bourgeois authoritarianism for bourgeois democracy. But it made some earlier detractors of 'bourgeois' democracy see its limited advantages - something that had not appeared clearly to some radical groups in thirty years when rights were available became clear in nineteen months when these were denied. An ironical 'gain' of the Emergency years has been a greater appreciation of the value and vulnerability of bourgeois democracy, when no higher form seems to be in sight. The end of the Emergency, however, did not see an alteration of this crisis politics. The Janata regime failed its mandate in all possible ways. First, it wrongly translated a matter of principle into a question of personal vendetta, which invited the nation to read the principles and issues involved in the experience in a wholly misleading way. Second, it entirely misjudged a negative vote against the Emergency into a positive vote for its more conservative policy inclinations. To put it rhetorically, its leaders first thought this was a vote of no-confidence by the nation against the Nehru model of policies; while, in fact, it was a vote calling for a return from the Emergency rule of Indira Gandhi to the policies of Nehru, a vote for the past Congress against the present one. In any case it did not have a long enough term to clearly work out its policies on major politico-economic questions; so that its supporters and critics can carry on an infructuous debate maintaining that if it had been in power for a long term this would have been, respectively, for better or for worse for India than under the Congress regime. Its Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 80 State and Politics in India internal factional squabbles, its inability to set its own terms of policy, its acceptance of the terms that an out of power Indira Gandhi set to it, converged to bring about an ignominious depar­ ture from ineffective power into abusive exile. But its greatest failure was in not being able to restore politics to policies and principles of bourgeois democratic govern1nent. In faet, its attacks on Indira Gandhi actually increased the indistinctness of persons and institutions. The joyous enthusiasm with which the liberal intelligentsia joined these personal debates and debased questions of principle into a ledger of personal qualities contributed to this denouement As a result, what could be turned into an occasion for restating an agenda of political principles went waste. As the Janata party failed to pose questions of principle, Indira Gandhi's return to power in 1980 did not involve any serious critical self-reflection on the part of the Congress. Consequently, several tendencies opposed to bourgeois principles of democratic gover­ nance, introduced during the Emergency, came back with her restoration to power. Equation of the fate of a nation with that of the Nehru family, open support for hereditary succession to power, total suspension of electoral forms within the Congress remained entirely unchecked and uncriticized within the ruling party, due mainly to the ineptness of the Janata party in posing a principled challenge. These were simply the more dramatic instances of a reintroduction of retrograde, nearly feudal, forms of irresponsible power in the bourgeois state apparatus itself. And since the state occupied such a large space in modem Indian society and was, in a true sense, the educator of the educators, appointer of appointers and patton of patrons, these deformations travelled rapidly down the system into quick subversion of principles and formats of equality of opportunity and merit at every level of institutional life. It helped do away with bourgeois principles of recruitment and advance, and replaced them with a system of patronage in the huge network of public institutions, starting from the planning me­ chanism to the socially irrelevant universities.60 The dominant 60 Indeed, the kind of decline the universities hnve undergone, their pitiful collective inability to ensure the imparting ofskills which their degrees certify, could have been tolerated by the society only because they were in a large measure irrelevant. Had it been otherwise, there would have been strong ·counterpressures from interested groups lilce the entrepreneurial class and the middle classes, to malce them deliver the goods. Dig1t1zeo by Google Origi�al rrom UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN Tht System 8I patronage groups in such a system changed rapidly, along with bewilderingly quick changes of policy orientation - an abject indecisiveness rationalized in the name of pragmatism. 'fhe 'cor­ rect' ideology in the early 1970s was a vague espousal of socialism uninsistent on its policy realization. Those who attained eminence from this political group were replaced during the Emergency by politicians who favoured the 'Brazilian path' and forced sterilization as solutions to the country's economic problems, and confused improvement of society with beautification of its capital cities. Subsequently, even these leaders made way for a newer group of 'modernist' politicians, believers in the powers of modern advertis­ ing and a judicious combination of religious and electronic super­ stition. What was remarkable about Indira Gandhi's leadership was the equal tolerance she extended to such diverse 'ideological' groups and the equal willingness to unsentiment.ally distance herself from them when the occasion arose. Indira Gandhi's rule, not­ withstanding its rhetoric, resulted in a decline of political ideology, a delinking of power from ideological and social programmes. This has led to a general debasement of political ideology in the popular mind (except obviously.i n states ruled by left parties who treat ideology as serious business) to which the opportunism and per­ sonalism of her opposition made a distinguished contribution. Eventually, her last years came to be dominated by two regional movements, which, though superficially antithetic, were actually linked to each other by internal relations of a structural sort. These were related because they show two poles of the intensification of regional inequality due to unrestricted and unreflexive capitalist development. At the time of her tragic death, Indira Gandhi faced, for the third time in her eventual political career, a threat of encirclement by difficulties and insurmountable problems. And even if she had fought the elections it is likely that she would have won with a fur reduced and insecure 1najority. 1-ler career illustrated the deeper crisis of Indian polity: that even dramatic electoral victories were indecisive and could tum dramatically quickly into their opposite. Indira Gandhi's period in power, underneath the misleading formal continuity of the Congress syste1n, revised some of the fundamental premises of the Nehru model. These are not acciden­ tal or style differences, but of principles of structuring the political order. The Nehru elite tried to take a historical view of the Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 82 State and Politics in India possibilities of social change, and came to the conclusion, written into its social theory, that construction of a modern, relatively independent capitalism required a reformist and statist bourgeois programme. Indira Gandhi's successor regime gradually aban­ doned the element of historical thinking as a matter of dispensable luxury and went for what it rationalized to itself as a more prag­ matic programme. It reduced even the planning apparatus, en­ trusted by Nehru with the task of serious long-term developmental reflection, to more short-term accounting, though depending on its statistical ability to turn the poverty of the people into the wealth of the nation. Its pragmatism led it to abandon some of the points of the Second Plan kind of strategy.61 Gradually the govern­ ment allowed a massive campaign to gain momentum for privatiza­ tion of industry and other economic activities, reducing public investment, altering the nature of the investment where it still existed. Its successor regime also started plans for extending this policy of liberalization towards greater foreign collaboration in order to obtain more sophisticated technology. Politicians within the cabinet have begun to launch open attacks on the public sector on the grounds of its inefficiency, though much of the inefficiency is due to the interference and wasteful exploitation of its facilities by the government bureaucracy and politicians. It abandoned the earlier strategy of institutional changes for agricultural growth in favour of a green revolution strategy unaccompanied by any re­ distributive controls. Political changes were equally vital. The Congress government under Indira Gandhi gradually allowed a profitable breakdown of bourgeois frameworks of formal propriety since they were oc­ casionally inconvenient encumbrances in its path. In bourgeois political systems, there must be a reliable relation between the structure of classes and the format of parties.62 Abandonment of ideological politics by the ruling party and cheerful retaliatory imitation by opposition groups causes this relation to break down through defection, bending of constitutional norms, etc. This 61 There is a fairly large and incisive literarure in Marxist economics about this tum in the nature of government economic policies and the consequent retrogressive trends in planning. 62 This does not mean, however, that a single class would be represented by a single party. It simply means that for social pressures to work through the party system, there must be some reliability of party progra1nmes. Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The System 83 might destroy popular faith in democratic institutions. Besides, the breakdown of ground rules of political behaviour tends to make the political world unfamiliar and unrecognizable to political actors themselves, encouraging behaviour that is blind, wild and anomic. The Congress under Indira Gandhi, in effect, renegotiated some of the fundamental definitions of Indian political life. Two of these crucial principles were those of 'the national' and 'the secular'. Some amount of regional politi<:,il articulation was un­ avoidable in the aftermath of Independence. Capitalist develop­ ment increased the economic power of two regionally conscious groups, the rich farmers and the regional bourgeois interests. In the face of the first wave of regional movements in the 1950s, the Nehru government had made a relatively clear distinction between cultural and economic questions, and had conceded the first kinds of demands. Demands for linguistic states or the use of vernaculars in state administration, occasionally even negative sensibilities like opposition to the introduction of Hindi, were accepted through a generally consultative process. Strikingly, acknowledgement of such demands did not wealcen the process of centralization of planning decisions about the economy. Decisions regarding devel­ opment investments were left, partly due to the political quies­ cence of these groups, to the central planning machinery. Under Indira Gandhi, the situation changed drastically. Increasing pres­ sures were now mounted for regional allocation of heavy industries and other such symbols of regional prestige. It is misleading to believe the vulgar theory that opposition parties alone pressed for economically unjustifiable regional demands. Indeed, many of these regionalisms were first articulated within the ruling party itself, Congress often absorbing regionalist leaders.63 Indira Gandhi's state increasingly gave way to such internal regionalisms. Often it would have been better to describe the Congress as the only party which was hospitable to regionalisms of all areas with a thin crust of the central leadership and naturally the central bureaucracy providing a failing counterweight. Worse, occasional­ ly the regime played one regionalism against another, as it also did with religious communities, hoping to benefit electorally from The two clear examples of Congress hospitality to regionalism in recent times are the handling of the Andhra agitations of a dec.ide ago, and the early encouragement to breakaway groups from the Akalis in the hope of splitting the Ahli vote in Punjab. 63 Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 84 St.ate and Politirs in India their double insecurity. Surely, these were clever manoeuvres in the short run but which actually, in the long run, undermined the bases of nationalism. In fact, the region of the national capital came to develop a pampered regionalism of its own. Evidently, similar things happen with regard to communalism too. Concessions given to religious communities as cq,nmunities undermined the theory of a common individual citizenship and created grounds for a rapid increase of majority communalism. Telling Muslims or other minority communities that their fate was secure only with the ruling party, implied keeping such in­ securities alive. Most seriously, the government allowed a subver­ sion of secular principles of the state by increasingly invoking the religious principle of sarvadharmasa'11tllnvaya, entirely incompatible with democratic secularism. The Indian state today declares itself to be multireligious, a complete reversal of the Nehruvian prin­ ciple that there was an equality of all religions to be practised as private affairs of individuals. Finally, the inability of the Congress government to clearly denounce the communal riots after Indira Gandhi' death provided a significant encouragement to the forces of Hindu communalism. The state curiously believes even today that the best way of controlling religious fanaticism is to lend the government­ controlled media to religious leaders, and give the greatest coverage on TV to routine religious practices. During the Nehru period, Dussera, Diwali, Id, Christmas celebrated, presumably, with customary enthusiasm, passed off unnoticed by radio, in contrast with the present coverage by secular television. A state armed with such suicidal weapons does not need communal par­ ties for its destabilization. Remarkably, the subversion of the definition of secularism was not done by communal forces and political parties, but accomplished by the state. Lack of historical self-analysis by the state or its supporting intelligentsia and its conversion to a doctrine of pragmatism meant, in effect, that even normal rational procedures of reflec­ tion on effects of earlier policies have been abandoned in favour of exclusive search for electoral power. Its correlate, pointed out by econor,nists, is a tendency to channel resources increasingly into 'dole' programmes rather than creation of productive resour­ ces, which have longer gestations periods and cannot be adapted to the eventful electoral calendar, Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN Tbt Systtm 85 Politicians of the Nehru era would have been surprised if told that forty years after Independence, the state they had set up would be riven by conflicts over two retrograde forces - regionalism and communalism. And the regionalism that threatens to engulf the polity today is quite clearly a consequence of the inequities of the capitalist growth process. Governments have been consistently inattentive to regional economic inequality inherited from the colonial period. Capitalist development has intensified these im­ balances even further. Nowhere is this revealed more than in the internal incompatibility between regional demands. Regionalism in Punjab is essentially an anti-redistributive agitation which in­ sists on retaining and extending the economic advantage of the state, particularly of the farmers, over other states, regions and classes. The Assam agitation presses what are, in essence, re­ distributive demands on the central government; and the two kinds of demands are incompatible. 64 The centre also sometimes plays up regional demands with an incredible shortsightedness. At pres­ ent, it is mildly encouraging the causes in Gorlchaland and fighting the consequences in Punjab, a subtlety of approach truly worthy of the present Indian elite.65 A crisis can be called structural, not conjunctural, if it arises from inside the basic laws of movement of a system, rather than from externalities. Several aspects of the present crisis of the Indian state need to be noted. It is not a simple crisis of the economy translated deterministically into a political disorder. Some of the culrural processes of crisis have hardly anything to do, directly at least, with the logic of economic development. No deep economic logic made it destroy elementary definitions of secularism. The cheerful indifference with which it has allowed 64 It is remarbble how the logic of regional demands of the 1950s and the 1970s differs. The demand for a linguistic state, once conceded in one case strengthened the case of other, simil:irly placed areas. In case of the demand for economic resources, the game is principally zero-sun1, with the share of one state cutting against the share of all others. 65 Since the writing of the chapter the state has brought about a truce in the hill areas of West Bengal, but how far aod how long it holds is to be seen. The few years of Rajiv Gandhi's rule have been strewn with the debris of pacts and accords. He has made more pacts than Metternich; and the fact that internal conflicts in tl1e lndiarrstate are attended to in a style of diplonucy says something about the processes of national integration that the Congress has set in motion. D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 86 Stllte and Politics in India . the education system to decline is certainly not induced by eco­ nomic necessity. This has given the state a great choice of weapons with which to deal self-inflicted wounds on its own structure. Interestingly, these trends have appeared not because capitalism has not been able to develop adequately but precisely because of the manner of its growth. So with greater growth of capitalism, these incompatibilities are likely to intensify and not ease off. The idea that capitalism is a social form implies that to expand or to simply carry on, its economic structures require some political-institutional compliments. There are certain types of political-institutiona1 forms which constitute preconditions for purely economic reproduction of capitalist society. Indian capital­ ism is in a state of a serious political crisis. Conservative economists would argue, though I think unconvincingly, that the Indian economy has done reasonably well, if you ignore distributive performance of the system; no political analyst can, however, claim that the Indian state has done reasonably well in quite the same sense. It is reacting defensively, adopting un'dcmocratic and precapitalist responses on vital issues. Most alarmingly, it is in­ creasingly proving incapable of providing the most vital precon­ dition foe bourgeois development, provision of political stability. The state's difficulties should be seen as a structural crisis. Political crisis may break out through mismanagement of political options by rulers, or sub-optional decisions by the ruling bloc. A, crisis is structural if it arises out of self-related difficulties, because· it emerges not out of the failure of the social form, but its successes. It is not a condition of 'abnormality' which could be expected to disappear with a change of leaders or parties. It is coming to be a condition of stressful, violent normalcy of this late, backward, increasingly unreformist capitalist order. It is different even from a standard Gramscian case; because here even a passive revolution has not succeeded, but is lapsing into failure. Those who would see present difficulties as 'failures' of Indian capitalism would find it difficult to explain. It is the 'successes' of Indian capitalism that have caused them. So if it becomes more 'successful' in the ways it has pursued over the last twenty years, these problems would not go away, but perhaps intensify. The tragic thing is that the crisis of ruling class politics plunges not only the ruling bloc, which has ruptured its protocol, into serious disorder, but the whole country, the festival of which we are Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 11,e System 87 celebrating. Exhaustion of the politics of the ruling bloc does not automatically prefigure a radical alternative. It is a particularly sad chapter of a story which had begun with the promise of something like an 'Indian revolution', an understandably unprac­ tical and sentimental beginning which promised to 'wipe every tear from every eye•. Even ifwe consider only the socially relevant tears, the promise is as distant today as at the romantic time when it was made. Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN II The Institutions O ne set of institutions such as Parliament and the judiciary, executive apparatuses such as the bureaucracy and the police, and the formal structures of union-state relations and the electoral system, have been formed directly by the Constitution. Another set of institutions, such as political parties and the party system, is part of the political process that mediates between state and society. In this volwne, we have chosen to look fll'St at the party system in order to emphasize the guiding role of the political process in the working of the state machinery. The chapter by Manor traces in detail the changes that came about in the party system in the transition from the 'Congress system' of the Nehru period to the Congress-I decade of the 1980s. Despi_te the apparent dominance of the Congress, Manor notes the crucial weakening in its institutional links with its bases of social support on the one hand and the apparatuses of government on the other. The chapter by Yadav carries on the story to the current phase of the demise of the Congress as the centrepiece of a national party system and the emergence of several distinct party systems in the regions. As he notes, the situation continues to be in a state of considerable flux and no stable patterns have yet emerged, making it especially difficult to provide a single coherent account of the political process. The electoral system is described in the chapter by Butler, Lahiri and Roy. The Indian form of single-member constituencies with a fust-past-the-post rule makes for a very distinct kind of electoral system that has important consequences for the party system as well. It means, for instance, that with many parties and in the absence of electoral alliances, a party which has the support - Dlgltlzedby Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 90 State and Politics in India of about 30 or 35 per cent of the electorate, but whose support is more or less evenly distributed over the constituencies, could come away with a very large majority of the scats. Qn the other band, with electoral alliances, the opposition parties could also win large majorities in the legislature without any significant swing in voters' preferences. This chapter provides an introduction to the field of election analysis, which bas attracted a lot of attention in recent years in India. We then move on to consider institutions that are directly shaped by constitutional arrangements. A common source of several controversies surrounding the interpretation of the Indian Constitution lies in the fact that although it has been modelled on the British parliamentary system, it is a written document and not, as in Britain, a centuries-old collection of customs, practices and statutes deeply embedded in the history of the country's public institutions. In India, most of the institutions of the modem state have their origins in the colonial period in which British ideas of the rule of law were mixed up with the absolutist notion of the right of conquest. . An important question that has reappeared in many Indian debates over the Constitution is the conflict between using the legal powers of the state to bring about change in social institu­ tions and practices, at the same time constraining political au­ thorities to act within the law. Through the 1950s and 1960s, courts were widely accused of a conservative bias in defending the rights of property holders against land refonns legislai;ion. In the early 1970s, when Indira Gandhi's government nationalized private banks and abolished the privy purses of former princes, and the Supreme Court held that Parliament could not change the basic structure and framework of the Constitution, the issue was posed as one between 'the will of the people' as represented in parliamentary sovereignty and the position of the court in binding legislators to remain within the law as laid down by the Constitution. After the experience of the E�ergency, there ap­ pears to have emerged a wider consensus that the main body of the Constitution, and especially the fundamental rights, ought to remain protected. On the other hand, since the 1980s, there has been a new spell of judicial activism in which the courts have acted 'in the public interest' to monitor the work of the executive branches of government to see whether the law is being followed, Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutions 91, and particularly to uphold the rights of vulnerable sections of citizens. This role of the judiciary has assumed particular import­ ance in a conten where many institutions of the state are seen as having lost their integrity and credibility. Due to constraints of space, we have been unable to include in this section any readings focusing directly on the Constitution or the judiciary. However, there are some references to the relevant literature in the bibliography. With regard to the bureaucracy, one set of issues concerns the relationship between a permanent bureaucracy and the changing politic:.al leadership; the second set concerns issues raised by the role of the bureaucracy in c:.arrying out developmental and welfare projects; and the third set of issues concerns the internal social composition of the bureaucracy. All these are discussed in the chapter by Vithal. The question of relations between the union and the states has been much debated. The chapter by Sathyamurthy looks at these debates on Indian federalism and the changing patterns of centre-­ st.ate relations through the entire period since Independence. Another institution that has played a crucial role through this period is that of economic planning, which has functioned in an ambiguous mode as an expert technocratic activity outside the arena of politics as well as the principal legitimation of the political leade,-ship's claims of bringing about economic growth and social equity. My chapter in this section discusses the way in which this ambiguous function of planning operates as an institution of the sute. Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 2 Parties and the Party System James Manor P olitical systems in which diverse parties compete freely for mass electoral suppon are increasingly hard to fmd in the less developed nations, even in those that experienced British rule for a long time thought to yield durable systems of liberal, repre­ sentative government. But India, after nearly four decades of self-government and eight general elections, and despite hair­ raising traumas and persisting threats to open, competitive politics, still qualifies. Nevertheless, in recent years, decay within parties and increasingly destructive conflict among parties have so eroded the strength of the open political system that its survival is in question. There is, consequently, an urgent need for rebuilding, both within individual parties and in relations among them. Since his election victory in the last week of 1984, Prime Minister Rajiv Gandhi has begun, somewhat hesitantly, the process of rebuilding within the formal institutions of state. He has also, at least for the time being, restored a modicum of civility to relations between his ruling Congres s -I party and the opposition, and this has, in turn, led to an improvement in relations between the central government in New Delhi and opposition-controlled govern­ ments at the state level. Rajiv Gandhi has also indicated, through scorching criticisms, that he is well aware of the wretched con­ dition of his own party.1 But he may also have missed his oppor­ tunity to rebuild it. If that is indeed true, then he could eventually experience the kind of vulnerability that caused him and his I Times ofIndia, Delhi, 29 Dece1nber 1985, and Times, London, 30 December 1985. D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutions 93 mother before him to seek all-out confrontation with opposition parties. It could even lead civilian elites to abandon faith in parties and in open, competitive politics. This chapter seeks to delineate the changes that have occurred within India's parties, especially the Congress party, and within the party system since Independence, and to explain how forces within the sphere of party competition have contributed to those changes. At first glance, it may seem that few dramatic changes have actually occurred within and among India's parties. It may appear that the victory of the Congress party in the 1984 general election closely resembles all but one of those that have come before the aberration being 1977 - and that one need only dust off and update the classic studies of the party system that Rajni Kothari and W.H. Morris-Jones produced some years ago.2 To adopt that view, however, is to overlook a number of basic changes in Indian politics over the last two decades that have substantially altered conditions within parties, relations among parties, and, partly because parties have provided the main links between state and society, state-society relations. Some of these changes were dis­ guised by the result of the 1984 election, but they remain realities nonetheless. To emphasize the changes that have taken place, this chapter is divided into four s_ections that deal with the three main phases in the evolution ·of India's parties and party systems, the periods from 1947 to 1960, from 1967 to 1977, from 1977 to 1984, and the year following the election in the last week of 1984. It is not yet clear whether this last period should be seen as a fourth distinct phase in the process, but enough has changed since the election to justify a separate discussion. 2 Rajni Kothari, 'The Congress "System" in India', Asian Survey, December 1964, pp. 1161-73, much of which w:ts foreshadowed in his 'Fonn and Substance in Indian Politics', &rmumic Wttkly, April-May 1961, pp. 846-63; W}'.lldraeth H. Morris-Jones, 'Parliament and Dominant Party: The Indian Experience', and 'Dominance and Dissent: Their Interrelations in the Indian Party System', in Morris-Jones, Politics Mainly Indian (Madras: Orient Long­ man, 1978), pp. 196-232. Both Kothari and Morris-Jones provided helpful suggestions during the preparation of this chapter. I am also grateful to Stanley A. Kochanek for many useful comments on the initial draft. Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 94 State and Politics in India From 1947 to 1967 To understand India's parties and party system from Independence in 1947 to 1967, just after Indira Gandhi fust became Prime Minister and the year of the fourth general election, we can do no better than to tum to the accounts that Kothari and Morris-Jones provided. Their views are sufficiently similar, though t hey are developed independently, to be considered together here. They described a 'dominant party system', that is a multiparty system, in which fre.e competition among parties occurred but in which the Indian National Congress enjoyed a dominant position both in terms of the number of seats that it held in Parliament in New Delhi and the state legislative assemblies, and in terms of its immense organizational strength outside the legislatures. It is extremely important that we recognize that Congress was dominant in both spheres. Indeed, it was its dominance at the organizational level that was more important, for on that rested its legislative superiority. The might, the reach, and the subtlety of its organization also enabled it to dominate the actions of bureaucrats who were charged with the implementation of policies and laws at regional and, especially, at subregional levels. In this first period, India had a party system characterized b y 'dominance coexisting with competition but without a trace o f alternation',3 because opposition parties had little hope of prevent­ ing the Congress from obtaining sizeable majorities in the legis­ latures despite the ruling party's failure, on most occasions, to gain a majority of valid votes cast. Neither, by and large, did opposition parties share power in coalitions with Congress at the state level So here was a 'competitive party system ... in which the compet­ ing parts play rather dissimilar roles'. The ruling Congress party was 'a party of consensus' and the opposition parties were 'parties of pressure'.4 That is to say, the opposition parties played a role that was quite distinctive.... Instead of providing an alternative to the C o n ­ gress party, they function by influencing sections within the Congress. They oppose by making Congressmen oppose. Groups within the ruling partyassume the role of opposition parties, often quite openly, 3 Morris-Jones, 'Domillllnce and Dissent', p. 217. 4 Kothari, 'The Congress "System"', p. 1162. Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutions 95 reflecting the ideologies and interests of other P.artics. The latter influence political decision-making at the margin.5 In other words, there was 'a most important "openness" in the relations between Congress and the other parties ... a posi­ tive communication and interaction between them'. This meant that the main hope that opposition leaders had of exercising politi­ cal influence was to 'address themselves ... to like-minded ... groups in the dominant party'.6Those efforts by opposition groups generated ideas and pressure within the ruling party's organiza­ tion, which was sophisticated enough to detect them and com­ municate them upward to the leaders who could respond to them.7 These comments begin to reveal the extraordinary dimensions of Congress dominance in that period. It was within Congress, and not between Congress and the opposition �arties, that the major conflicts within Indian politics occurred. It was within Congress that nearly all the groups that mattered in Indian politics could be found. The party possessed a large number of skilled operatives who were able to arrange bargains between important social groups, to interpret the logic of politics at one level of the system to people at higher and lower levels, and to knit together the varied regions and subcultures of the subcontinent. The Con­ gress organization was also the main instrument that knit together state and society, which is to say that it was India's central in­ tegrating institution.9 As a consequence, one did not find in India, as in the West, 'a relationship between the government and the party organization in which the latter plays an instrumental and subsidiary role'. 1° Congress was more important than that, and arguably more important than all of the formal institutions of state put together. Congress occupied not only the broad centre of the political spectrum, but most of the left and right as well. This relegated s Kothari, 'Fonn and Substance', p. 849. 6 Morris-Jones, 'Dominance and Dissent', p. 218. 7 Kothari, 'The Congress "System"', p. 1163, and Morris-Jones, 'Parliament', pp. 207-18. 8 Kothari, 'The Congress "System"', p. 1163. 9 I have set this argument out more fully in two articles: 'Indira and After. The Decay of Party Organization in India', Tbt Round T"blt, October 1978, pp. 315-24; and 'Party Decay and Political Crisis in India', Tbt W11Shington Q,utrttr/y, Summer 1981, pp. 2 5-40. 10 Kothari, 'The Congres., "System"', p. 1162. Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 96 State and Politics in India the opposition parties not only to the margins of Congress, but to the margins of the political and party systems as well. To make matters worse, these parties often found themselves on opposite sides of the Congress, which killed any hope of their making common cause against it. 11 To save themselves from absorption by, or the loss of defectors to, the Congress, opposition parties tended to develop rigorous ideologies and tightly disciplined or­ ganizations. Congress was able to maintain its position as a party occupying most of the space in the political system because 'there [was] plurality within the dominant party which [made] it more repre­ sentative, [provided] flexibility, and [sustained] internal competi­ tion. At the same time, it [was] prepared to absorb groups and movements from outside the party and thus prevent other parties from gaining strength'. 12 The task of creating and sustaining the immensely broad Congress coalition in that first phase was, at least in the view of Morris-Jones, facilitated by the complexities and ambiguities of Indian society, which prevented polarization (in class terms or any other terms) and the formation of contradictions that might fracture such an all-embracing alliance of interests. This insight differs from, but complements, Myron Weiner's ar­ gument that the task of building the Congress coalition was eased by traditional values and roles of conciliation that Congressmen astutely took up, 13 and the Rudolphs' contention that traditional elements of the caste system assisted the development of modem, representative politics in lndia. 14 But however much the social background may have helped, and however important Congress's role in the winning of Inde­ pendence may have been in placing the party in a dominant position in the first place, the survival of Congress dominance depended on the efficient functioning of the party organization. Of crucial importance was its effectiveness in distributing the resources, which it acquired from its control of state power, II Morris-Jones, 'Dominance and Dissent', pp. 2I9-20. 12 Kothari, 'The Congress "System"', pp. 1164-5. 13 Myron Weiner, 'Traditional Role Performance and the Development of Modern Political Parties: The Indian Case', JqurnaJ of Politics, November 1964, pp. 830--49. 14 Lloyd I. and Susanne Hoeber Rudolph, Tht Modtmity ofTrllllition: PoJitiaJ Devtlop,,,mt in India (Chicago: University of Chicago Press! 1967), p. 1 Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The lnstitutiuru· 97 among existing and potential clients in exchange for their political support. This management of resources, at which many within the Congress organization excelled, was· essential to the proper functioning of the 'conciliation machinery within the Congress, at various levels and for different tasks, which (was] almost con­ stantly in operation, mediating in factional disrutes, influencing political decisions in the States and districts'. 1 The same skill at allotting patronage also enabled the Congress to co-opt and absorb within itself groups whose grievances had 'been ventilated through agitations launched by the opposition parties'. This was reinforced by the Congress's 'policy of neutraliz­ ing some of the more important sources of cleavage and dis­ affection' and by the leadership's tendency 'to preserve democratic fonns, to respect the rule of law, to avoid undue strife', and to show 'great sensitivity on the question of respect for minorities.' 16 From 1967 to I 977 The second phase extended from 1967 to the defeat of the Congress party at the general election of 1977, which occurred in the immediate aftermath of the Emergency. It is of course possible to see the Emergen cy, which extended over nineteen months from 26June 1975, as a separate phase in this story. But a chapter-length study cannot do justice to a more elaborate disaggregation. It is, nevertheless, worth noting that the Emer­ gency constituted both an intensification of certain trends from the period between 1969 and 1975 and, at the same time, some­ thing of a hiatus between phases two and three, during which opposition leaders were jailed, the party system and open politics were closed down, even Congress leaders were intimidated, and Mrs Gandhi attempted, only partly successfully, to centralize power within the ruling party. Some of the earliest and most perceptive comments on the party system between 1967 and 1977 came from studies by Morris-Jones and Kothari after the 1967 general election, which occasioned important changes.17 One important feature of the old system that persisted was, in Kothari's words, 'the central role of the Congress IS Kothari, 'The Congress "System"', p. 16 Ibid., pp. 1168-70. D1g1t 1zeo by Google 1168. Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 98 State and Politics in India in maintaining and restructuring political consensus'. But he also argued that: The soci o e-conomic and demographic profile of the polity is chang­ ing rather fast.... The mobilization of new recruits and groups into the political process . . . has given rise to the development of new and more differentiated identities and patterns of political cleavage. . . . [This gave rise to] the expectation of freer political access ... and a greater insistence on government performance. Intermediaries and vote banlcs, while of continuing importance, have become increasingly circumvented as citizens search for more effective participation in the political market place and develop an ability to evaluate and make choices. 18 As a result, 'the dominant party model has started to r,j-ve way to a more differentiated structure of party competition.' Morris-Jones also emphasized the emergence of 'a market polity' in India. This was; of course, nothing very new. 'There was plenty of competition and bargaining before 1967', but it had taken place 'largely within the Congress, between groups and in semi-institutionalized form.'20 In the 1967 election, however, which saw the Congress los,e power in six states, the competition had grown too severe to be contained by the party's internal bargaining, so that 'dissident Con�essmen played an important role in the weakening of the party . .. in perhaps every "lost" State except Tamil Nadu.'21 This brought a number of opposition parties fully into the market place, and competition that had previously occurred within the Congress was now brought into the realm of interparty conflict. Competition also increased in as much as opposition parties formed coalition governments in every state they controlled except Tamil Nadu, and 'coalition govern­ ments are themselves small markets'.22 17 Rajni Kothari, 'Continuity and Change in the Indian Party System', Arum Survey, November 1970, pp. 93 7-48; and W.H. Morris-Jones, 'From Mono­ poly to Competition in India's Politics', in Morris-Jones, Politia Mainly Indian, pp. 144-59. 18 Kothari, 'Continuity and Change in the Indian Party System', p. 939. 19 lbid. Morris-Jones also noted that 'the market of politics has expanded by the participation of new groups in government', 'From Monopoly to Com­ petition in India's Politics', p. 156. 20 Morris-Jones, 'From Monopoly to Competition in India's Politics', p. 154. 21 Ibid. 22 Ibid. D1gii'tzeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutions 99 That election also made centre-state relations an important feature of interparty competition. Bargaining had long been an impo rtant element of relations between New Delhi and the states, even in Nehru's day when Congressmen held sway at both levels. After Nehru's death, the power of state-level Congress leaders had become both greater and more apparent. The 1967 election created conditions in which quite serious conflict might have arisen between centre and states, but, thanks mainly to the finesse of Union Home Minister Y.B. Chavan, this did not occur.23 Another new phenomenon after 1967 was a 'pretty regular and continuous "defectors market". ' 24 It is easy to forget that this was so, for our minds tend to rush onward to the dramatic splitting of the Congress in 1969 and Mrs Gandhi's subsequent surprises, which gained her the political initiative and the great election victory of 1971. But defection was an important element in the aftermath of the 1967 election and two points should be made about it. First, defectors flowed both ways, both into and out of the Congress. More flowed out, however, than in, causing the fall of Congress governments in three states.25 Second, the highly disciplined, ideologically oriented parties of the Marxist left and the Hindu chauvinist right remained almost entirely immune to this new trend. ·(The Communists experienced a split over ideo­ logical issues in 1969, but that was different from defection.) In other words, the parties to the far right and left tended to remain 'hard' in that they retained tough shells through which people did not pass in and out, and in that they maintained their organizational integrity through centralization, discipline, and ideological consistency. They also retained narrower social bases than most of the other parties in that period and narrower bases than the Communist Party of India (Marxist) (CPI[M)) and the Jan Sangh/Bharatiya Janata Party (BJP) have developed in the post-1977 years. They nonetheless moved very cautiously along the road to more moderate policies, a road down which, Stanley A. Kochanek observed, other opposition parties were motoring once the possibility of power presented itself.26 23 Ibid., p. 153. 24 Ibid., p. 155. 2S Ibid., and Kothari, 'Continuity and Change in the Indian Party System', p. 946. 26 Stanley A. Kochanek, Tbe Ctmgress P1trty of India (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1968), p. 446. D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 100 State and Politics in India The 1967 election had created a siruation in which Congress 'dominance was strikingly diminished' because its 'performance in the art of governance was subjected to harsh judgment by sup­ w porters and opposition alike'.27 It was a siruation marked by 'am­ � biguity, blurred lines, flexibility and flux', but this was not seen to 't represent disintegration. Indeed, the actors in the system had �' adjusted with such 'amazingly little difficulty' that 'the stability of « the regime appears more assured than ever before'. This was true b because the regime had, among other things, 'moved away from ( any degree of dependence on one outstanding leader'. If this raised b questions about the need for 'clarity and firmness of decision', it 0 was reassuring in as much as decisions 'also re �uire reconciliation b p of very varied interests if they are to succeed'. 8 The schism in the Congress in 1969 was a major shock to the a political system in India. Partly as a result, Mrs Gandhi's version � of the party faced a largely united opposition in the general elec­ F tion of 1971. B.D. Graham has compared the polarization of C India's parties into something close to two opposing blocs in 1971 I (and 1977) to a few key elections in the Third French Republic t• when similar polar blocs emerged. This did not occur often in t France, but when it did, it indicated that a 'crisis of regime' had t developed and that the two blocs were disputing fundamental issues about the nature of the political order. 29 Mrs Gandhi's !' decision to split her country's central political institution produced l such conditions in India in 1971, conditions that altered the shape r of the party system at that election. This happened again in 1977 C when the threat to all liberal institutions created a widely shared t perception that a 'crisis of regime' had occurred. Such perceptions t did not arise among most opposition leaders in l 980, as I have s ( argued elsewhere,30 or in 1984. I 27 Kothari, 'Continuity and Change in the Indian P,1rty System', p. 947. 28 Morris-Jones, 'From Monopoly to Competition in India's Politics', pp. 158-9. Kothari was slighdy less optimistic than Morris-Jones on d1is count. Ibid., p. 948. 29 I am grateful to B.D. Graham for bringing his argument to my attention in numerous conversations. See also Graham, 'Theories of the French Party System under the Third Republic', Politic11/St1ulits, February 1964, pp. 21-32. JO James Manor, 'The Electoral Process Amid Awakening and Decay', in P�ter. Lyon and James Manor (eds), TrllTISfer 11nd Trtmsformati<m: Politic11/ Instit11tions in tht Nrw Crmmwnwtalth, (Leicester: Leicester University Press, 1983), pp. 87-116. -- - ' Digitized by � Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN ' I ( l . I The lnttitutums 101 Mrs Gandhi's victory in the 1971 election made it appear, in words Morris-Jones used soon afterwards, that 'the end of the dominant party had been too readily proclaimed in 1967' and that 'now it is back'. This led him naturally to expect that the opposition parties would be 'forced to operate less by confrontation than by interaction with segments of the centre mass'.31 They were not, however, given many opportunities for interaction by the new Congress. Mrs Gandhi adopted a more confrontational posture, both towards opposition parties at the .national level and towards opposition-controlled governments in various states.32 She also took a more aggressive line with her own party, and this soon produced what Kochanek has rightly called 'a new political process' as the Prime Minister created 'a pyramidical decision-making struc­ ture in party and government'. Although this prevented threats to her personal power, it tended to centralize de­ cision making, weaken institutionalization, and create an overly per­ sonalized regime. Moreover, the new political process proved unable to manage the tensions and cleavages of a heterogeneous party operat­ ing in a heterogeneous society, federally gPVemed. A major crisis in the system followed. 33 The new system ·entailed, crucially, the abandonment of intra­ party democracy, a change that has never been reversed. Positions in the Congress organizations at all levels were filled by appoint­ ment from above rather than by election from below. This change caused people at all levels to tend to tell people above them what they thought those people wanted to hear, so that the ograniza­ tion's once formidable powers as an information-gathering agency soon wasted away.34 The centralization of power within the party did not, however, mean that factionalism ceased to be a problem. Instead, partly because centralization reduced the leaders' ability to manage conflict, partly because Mrs Gandhi set leaders and factions at the regional level against one another and partly be­ cause she had largely abandoned the use of bargaining, conflict JI Morris--Jones, 'From Monopoly to Competition in India's Politics', p. 187. 12 Bhagwan D. Dua, Prtsidmtilll Rule in lndiA, 1950-1974: A Sttldy in Crisis Politics {New Delhi: S. Chand, 1979). 33 St:.1nley A. Kochanek, 'Mrs Gandhi's Pyramid: The New Congress', in Henry C. Hart (ed.), Indira Gandhi's India (Boulder: Westview, 1976), pp. 104-5. 34 This is developed further in Manor, 'Party Decay'. Dig1t1zeo by Google Origi�al rrom UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 102 State and Politics in India within the organization grew more severe and dysfunctional.All of this reduced the party's ability to cope creatively or even ade­ quately with conflicts that arose from a society facing increasing economic hardship.35 Not surprisingly, this created openings for the opposition, and by 1974, under Jayaprakash Narayan's leadership, an opposition movement had acquired real substance and momentum. Mrs Gandhi's reaction, which set the tone of relations between her Congress and nearly all opposition parties (with the exceptions of the Communist Party of India and, at times, one or the other of the two main patties in Tamil Nadu) for many years to come, was severe. As Kochanek put it: Dissent within the Congress, party opposition and press criticism ceased to function as thermostats measuring discontent. They were now interpreted as anti-party, anti-national, and traitorous, or even foreign-inspired.... Opposition party attempts to mobilize and ex­ press local pevances, valid or not, were perceived as law and order problems.3 The opposition's response was similarly forceful and stubborn, with fasting and agitational techniques brought to the fore. Mrs Gandhi, who found herself under growing pressure from within her own party (indeed, it was thence that the main threat came in mid-I 97 5), turned increasingly to a small circle of confidants in which her son Sanjay figured most prominently. He began to treat the opposition to the threats, smears, and organized violence that remained his trademark until his death in mid-1980. There followed the Emergency, during which relations be­ tween Congress and the opposition reached their nadir. Not only were opposition activists faced with imprisonment, but power within Congress was further centralized. The organization of the Congress itself, in some regions where it provided a base for potential rivals to Mrs Gandhi, was systt:matically dismantled the most vivid example being the Maharashtra machine that had been created by Y.B. Chavan. But the centralizing often had the opposite effect to that which was intended. It cut off still further Mrs Gandhi and her circle from reliable information from states beyond the Hindi belt, so JS Kochanek, 'Mrs Gandhi's Pyramid', pp.109-11. 361bid.,p.114. D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutums 103 that, for example, the Chief Ministers of Karnataka and Andhra Pradesh were repeatedly able to submit reports of huge numbers of vasectomies, none of which had occurred. And instead of homo­ genizing the regions as intended, centralization made possible the assertion of their natural heterogeneity, so that they actually di­ verged from one another.37 Mrs Gandhi's centralizing violated the basic logic by which India had been governed under both the Crown and Nehru's Congress. According to that logic, the in­ fluence of people at the apex of national and regional political systems penetrates down through the systems most effectively by means of compromise. Attempts to rule by diktat paradoxically weaken the centralizers, as happened to Mrs Gandhi.38 From 1977 to 1984 The third phase in the evolution of India's parties and party system extends from the defeat of Indira Gandhi's Congress in the elec­ tion of March 1977 to the election victory of the Congress led by her son Rajiv in the last week of 1984, following her assassination. I choose the 1984 election and not the assassination as the end of this phase because it is only thereafter that a set of new, and quite different, trends emerge. The years from 1977 to 1984 were, broadly speaking, a time of abrasive conflict and bad feeling be­ tween political parties and a period marked by decay and fragmen­ tation within parties. I will deal with all of that presently, but first it is necessary to identify several larger themes in this period of India's politics that provide the context essential to an under­ standing of the changes within parties and the party system. Two great themes, which had become plainly evident before 1977 and which dominated the phase thereafter, were awakening and decay. The awakening occurred among the great mass of India's voters, as people at all levels of society became increasingly aware of the logic of electoral politics, of the secrecy of the ballot, and of the notion that parties and leaders should respond to those whom they represented. It was more advanced among prosperous groups, but it also occurred among the poor.39 As a result, disad37}:mes Manor, 'Where Congress Survived: Five States in the Indian General Election of 1977', Asi1111 Survty, August 1978, pp. 7 8 5 803. 38 Manor, 'Party Decay.' 39 See, for example, John 0. Field, Cunsolidating Dnnocracy: Politicization 1111d D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN I 04 State and Politics in India vantaged rural dwellers largely ceased to vote according to the wishes of the landowning groups that continued to dominate life in the villages. Voters became more assertive and competitive, and their appetites for resources from politicians grew. Interest groups crystallized and came increasingly into conflict, so that it became harder to operate a political machine that could cater to every organized interest, as the Congress had very nearly done in the Nehru years. India became increasingly democratic and increas­ ingly difficult to govern. The second great theme that marked this period was the decay of political institutions, which is to say, a decline in the capacity of institutions to respond rationally, creatively, or even adequately to pressures from society."° This decay affected both the formal institutions of state and most political parties, including, above all, the Congress party. It was partly the result of systemic problems of ossification within the party. But it was quite substantially the result of the tendency of Indira Gandhi and her associates to centralize power and to deinstitutionalize. The awakening of the electorate and the decay of institutions combined to generate five further changes as by-products. The first of these was a change in the way that elections were won and lost, or to put it more plainly, a change from the days before 1972, when incumbent governments at the state and na­ tional levels usually won re-election, to a period in which they usually lost.41 This follows quite logically, for the decay of ruling parties and the formal institutions through which they govern has meant that incumbents have been less able to respond to society at a time when the expectations and assertiveness of the electorate have increasingly demanded responses. The second change was a marked decline in confidence in the state as an agency capable of creative social action (as opposed Ptn'tis11111bip in India (New Delhi: Manohar, 1980); and D.L. Sheth (ed.), Citizens 1111d Parties: �as of Compttitivt Politics in India (Bombay: Allied, 1975). 40 Samuel P. Huntington, 'Political Development and Political Decay, World Politia, April 1965, pp. 386-430. 41 Jbis had clearly been the predominant trend since the state assembly elections of 1972. The general election of 1984 is an exception to this pattern, but it occurred under extraordinary and emotionally charged circumstances that are unlikely to occur again. Digiti zed by Google Ongmal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutions 10; to an agency with the coercive power to maintain order). This occurred within the Congress led by both Gandhis. It was demon­ strated by Indira Gandhi's abandonment of reformist rhetoric in the election of 1980 and of serious attempts to create legislation for the betterment of society between 1980 and 1984, and by Rajiv Gandhi's preference for the private sector. But this decline was also observable within many opposition parties, among many intellectuals who were critical of Mrs Gandhi, and among large numbers of people in local arenas all across the subcontinent. There were exceptions - notably on the Marxist left, among certain elements of the Hindu chauvinist right, and in some parties at the regional level - but the predominant trend was nonetheless clear. Tbe third change, which was closely related to the second, was the tendency for society and politics to diverge. As political in­ stitutions, especially parties, became less able to respond rationally to appeals that arose from society, social groups tended to give up on politics and politicians and to tum inwards, battening on par­ ochial sentiments and whatever internal resources they possessed. This led to an increase i n conflict between social groups as the social-political divergence and the decay of political institutions reduced the state's capacity to manage and defuse conflict.42 A fourth change entailed the blurring of the relatively clear lines that had existed between many political parties and their social bases, both at the national level and in many Indian St3tes. This was a destabilizing, and potentially destructive, trend, par­ ticularly as the awakening ofthe electorate made it more important than ever that parties develop solid, clearly perceived links to social bases of manageable size.43 The last of the five changes was a growing divergence between the logic of politics at the national level and the political logic in various state-level arenas. The most obvious sign of this was the emergence in the early 1980s of regional parties in several St3tes. But even within the Congress party, during the Emergency, See Times (London), 18 May 1984. I have developed this further in NtJI) S«iny, 12 August 1982. 43James Manor, 'Blurring the Lines between Parties and Social Bases: Gundu Rao and the Emergence of a Janata Government in �matab', in John R. Wood (ed.), StilU Politia in C(llltmrportny lndi11: Crisis or Cuntinuity? (Boulder: Westv:iew, 1984), pp. 139-Q. ·42 Dlgltlzedby Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN I06 State and Politics in India state-level units often went their own way.44 This, like the ap­ pearance of regional opposition parties, was an unintended result of the excessive centralization of power by Mrs Gandhi. With these themes in mind, let us now consider the third phase in the evolution of India's parties and party system. This period, from 1977 to December 1984, was marked by freer competition between political parties but also by· greater instability in the party system and within many parties. It was a time characterized b y abundant alternation between parties in power at the state and national levels, by continued decay and fragmentation within par­ ties, by a tendency towards personalized control of parties or splinters by eminent and not-so-eminent politicians, and by great fluidity within the party system as factions llnd rumps and in­ dividuals defected or realigned themselves this way and that. The defeat of the Congress led by Mrs Gandhi in 1977 and the election of the Janata party - which was actually a motley coali­ tion of parties - brought immense changes to the party system. Defeat caused the Congress to disintegrate. Some Congress ac­ tivists left Mrs Gandhi because th ey had secretly disapproved of the Emergency, others because they had had enough of her son Sanjay's bizarre and often vicious egotism. Some believed that they could revive the 'real' Congress in the absence of its former, and supposedly discredited, leader, whereas others saw little reason to stay now that Congress had lost access to the political patronage that had been its life blood. Even before her defeat, Mrs Gandhi had imposed something very close to personal and dynastic rule on the political system and the party. Defeat only intensified this tendency within the Congress, or her version of it. At a 'time when so many were deserting her, her already extravagant distrust of other politicians intensified and personal loyalty became an even more precious commodity. The reconstitution of her version of the Congress party in January 1978 under the label of the 'Indian National Congress-Indira', or the 'Congress-I', was emblematic of this increased personalization. As the badly divided Janata party in­ creasingly demonstrated its incapacity to govern satisfactorily and Mrs Gandhi's prospects improved, waves of deserters redefected 44 Manor, 'Where Congress Survived'. I have also dealt with this in 'Where the Gandhi Writ Doesn't Run', The &onomist, 15 May 1982, pp. 55-6. D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutions I07 to her camp. Each wave tended to operate as a new faction in an already factionalized Congress-I, and the inability of Indira and Sanjay Gandhi to apply standards consistently to these retur­ nees actually catalysed further division and strife. Latecomers were sometimes humiliated or sometimes inexplicably promoted over the heads of old loyalists. In this atmosphere, every group thought it had a chance and so remained a contentious force. This process continued even after Mrs Gandhi's return to power inJanuary 1980 and Sanjay's death six months later. TheJanata government that held power between March 1977 andJuly 1979 was a hastily assembled coalition of quite different opposition groups united mainly by their opposition to Mrs Gandhi and the Emergency. Victory at the polls meant that those objectives had been realized, and the natural divisions among them then began to emerge. The Janata party contained elements of the old Congress-0, the mainly conservative but secularist remainder of the out-faction after the 1969 Congress split. Alongside it stood the Jan Sangh, a party of the Hindu chauvinist right, whose main support came from high caste, middle class people in urban areas, particularly in the Hindi­ speaking states of north and central India. Third was the Bharatiya Lok Dal (BLD), mainly representing prosperous small peasant proprietors in the Hindi belt. It sought to reallocate resources away from the urban, industrial sector towards agricul­ ture. Fourth was the Socialist Party, whose base included some of the rural poor of north India and sizeable hut scattered pockets of support among urban labour unions. Finally, there was the Congress for Democracy, a group led out of Mrs Gandhi's Congress after the Emergency byJagjivan Ram, one of her most formidable ministers and the leading Scheduled Caste politician. Its support was greatest among poor, low caste rural dwellers. Given the heterogeneous composition of the Janata party and the fierce ambitions of its three leading figures - Morarji Desai, Jagjivan Ram, and BLD leader Charan Singh - it is no surprise that the government was unable to achieve much cohesion. One result was a loosening of ties between the national and state levels within both the party and the political system. 'fhe factions that tended to dominate the Janata party in the national Parlia­ ment were antagonistic to those that held sway in severalJanata­ controlled states. This antagonism set the national and state D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 108 Stille and Politics in India governments at loggerheads on some important questions, a trend that was reinforced by friction between the Janata regime in New Delhi and opposition-controlled governments in several other states. This made it impossible to reverse the tendency of the Indian federation to become an increasingly loose union. It was not that secession threatened national unity. That problem has always been greatly exaggerated by observers who have failed to see that insufficient solidarity exists at the state level to fuel separatism. But the threat of secession prepared the ground for further deterioration of centre-state relations when Mrs Gandhi, returning to over-centralization after 1980, generated regional movements in reaction and then dealt even more aggressively - and unconstitutionally - with those movements when they had taken power in several states. When the Janata government disintegrated in mid-1979, many of the elements that had formed it also splintered. This paralleled the disintegration that had occurred on the Congress side after the I 977 election, and the result was a confusing array of frag­ mentary parties, many of which were. little more than personal cliques presided over by individual politicians. In this conteit, · Mrs Gandhi's Congress-I appeared to be the only coherent national party - even though its own organization was in considerable disarray- and this image enabled it to take advant­ age of the strong popular reaction against the Janata government and win the I980 election. The diff'iculties of the anti-Congress-I parties in making common cause persisted from the early 1980s through the election preparations during the third quarter of 1984. The assassination of Mrs Gandhi on 31 October 1984 seemed to ensure an emotion-based victory for her son and party, making oppo:;ition unity still more difficult to achieve. This victory has led many observers to write off the opposition over the middle and even the long term, but such a judgment is premature, as the evidence from 1967 to 1984 shows. It should fll'St be recalled that Mrs Gandhi appeared to be in a similarly unassailable position in 1972, and that mismanagement led her into severe political trouble within only three years. If such errors should recur, the Indian electorate, which is even more aware and assertive today than in the early 1970s, is unlikely to be any more patient than on that occasion. Every state in India, like the nation as a whole, has now had at least one spell of non-Congress Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutions 109 government. Opposition rule is no longer unthinlcable anywhere. Misgovemance will generate a credible opposition. Second, some opposition parties possessed greater promise and substance (real or, in some cases, potential substance) than the 1980 and 1984 election results implied. These parties retained either the support of important groups or ideological resources and respectable organizations or both. Stanley Kochanek has use­ fully identified four broad tendmcies in Indian politics that unite particular elements in society around certain sets of ideas.45 These are a communist tendency, a socialist tendency, a non-confessional rightist tendency, and a confessional rightist tendency. All of these have at times been represented by non-Congress political parties. The Congress has at times allied itself with and borrowed a limited number of ideas from the communist tendency. It has also at times moved into the territory on the political spectrum normally in­ habited by the other three tendencies and in so doing has drawn support away from opposition parties there. In recent years, the socialist tendency can be said to have been somewhat in eclipse, both within Congress and in the opposition. The main party of the non-confessional right, the Swat:antra, has long since passed away, but the Congress under Indira Gandhi, and especially under her son Rajiv, has begun to give assertive expression to views associated with that tendency. We shall see presently how the parties of the confessional right and the communist left have fared in recent years and how the Congress-I has moved into the ter­ ritory traditionally occupied by the former. Let us first note, however, that one other possible tendency is also unlikely to pass from the scene: that represented by the peasant proprietary group in the Hindi-speaking areas and cham­ pioned by Charan Singh under various labels (Lok Dal, Bharatiya Lok Dal, Dalit Mazdoor Kisan party). Charan Singh himself is aged and infirm and unlikely to play an important role again. But this force has sufficient cohesion to figure in future anti-Congress­ ! alliances unless Rajiv Gandhi's new economic policies develop in ways that attract it to his party. We should pay particular attention to the CPl(M), and the BJP, which is a successor to the old Hindu chauvinist Jan Sangh. These were the two most potent 'hard' parties of the late 1960s, ' 45 I am grateful to Stanley A. Kochanek for suggesting this approach to me. Digiti zed by Google Ongmal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 110 State and Politics in India and they are the only two opposition parties that are patently able to rejuvenate themselves by recruiting large numbers of young idealists. They have also managed to broaden their bases. This last comment may sound strange in the aftermath of the 1984 election, in which the CPl(M) lost ground in West Bengal and suffered embarrassments in Kerala, and in which the BJP was reduced to a parliamentary delegation of two. But it should be noted that the CPl(M) still came first in a solid majority of assembly segments in West Bengal, and it did so because it has managed, since coming to power there in 1977, to cultivate a solid base among the rural majority, a success managed partly because it has organizational efficiency in West Bengal that is said to surpass even that of the party in Kerala.46 If the decay of other parties and some sort of socio-economic crisis should make it possible for the CPI(M) to extend the West Bengal model to other states - an eventuality that seems highly unlikely at present - we may look back on this acquisition of a rural base as a crucial change. The CPl(M) has also managed this broaden­ ing without ceasing to be a 'hard' party, without losing or gaining people through defections, and without suffering too much erosion of discipline or ideology. It is nonetheless more flexible and pragmatic than it used to be, as is exemplified by electoral pacts in states where it is a minor party. The BJP presents a different picture. It remains a corporate entity of real institutional sinew and has not suffered from the drift toward personal rule that has done so much damage to many other opposition parties and, of course, to the Congress-I. And although it lost a large number of Rashtriya Swayamsevak Sangha (RSS) activists to the Congress-I during the 1984 election, it is generally agreed by observers in India that it retained a majority of these and that many who decamped to the ruling party are likely to return, especially after Rajiv Gandhi's moves away from Hindu chauvinism in 1985. To put that statement into perspec­ tive, it helps to recall that the RSS has no fewer than 700,000 swayamsevaks, or full-time activists, in the fteld.4 7 The figure dwarfs that of any other party, including the Congress-I, which has surprisingly few people spending most of their time working J. 46 I base this on conversations with Thomas Nossiter. 47 I am grateful to B.D. Graham for confirming reports India on this matter. Dlgltlzedby Google that I received in Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutions 111 for the organization. In addition, in many states, Congress per­ sonnel are startlingly ineffective. In Kamataka, for example, the Congress president had to go outside the party to find an efficient organizing general secretary. 48 A large minority of the RSS swayamsevaks are adolescents, but many of them are capable of important political work.49 The BJP has not, however, remained the kind of 'hard' party that it once was and that the CPl(M) largely remains. It is far less penetrable than the other non-Communist parties, but it has become less parochial and uncompromising in its tactics and ideology, and hence more porous than it used to be. It has both lost and accepted a surprising number of defectors in the last five years, and it was possible to identify a number of people during the 1984 election campaign who had one foot in the BJP and another in other non-Congress and non-Communist parties, so that the boundaries between it and some other parties became slightly blurred.so Let us now tum to an astonishing development of the early 1980s, the adoption by Indira Gandhi of themes that have tradi­ tionally belonged to the Hindu chauvinist right. To many who are familiar with Congress in Nehru's time or in Mrs Gandhi's earlier years as Prime Minister, it may be difficult to believe that this happened. Yet it appears that at some point during 1982, Congress-I leaders recognized that a confrontational posture to­ wards the overwhelmingly Muslim National Conference party in Kashmir and the Sikh extremists in Punjab (whom Mrs Gandhi's confidants, Sanjay Gandhi and Zail Singh, had initially encouraged in order to divide the opposition Akalis) might gain them the support of many Hindus in the Kashmir and Delhi elections. When numerous activists of the RSS deserted the increasingly 48 Interview with a high official of the Kamatalca Congress-I, 8 January 1985, in Bangalore. 49 Jnterview with B.D. Graham, London, 8 February 1985. so Widespread RSS suppon for the Congress-I became apparent from numer­ ous interviews with BJP and Congress-I activists in several Indian states during December 1984 and January 1985. See also Times ofIndia (Delhi), 23 December 1984; the repon from Ambala in the Hindust1m Timts (Delhi), 14 December 1984, and the discussion of the open letter by veteran RSS leader Nanaji Deshmukh offering suppon to the Prime Minister in the Jndum I',zp,w, Bombay, 26January 1985. D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 112 State and Politics in India liberal BJP to support Congress-I candidates in those elections, the tactic seemed to have worked surprisingly well. It began to seem an even more attractive option after the defeat of the Congress-I in the southern states ofKamatak.a and Andhra Pradesh in January 1983. That defeat led Congress-I leaders to suspect that the south iµight not support them at the nen par­ liamentary election, and that they would therefore need to look to northern and central India for most of their Lok Sabha seats. Because their party organization was in such disarray that it could not cultivate much of a following through patronage - the main mode of operation during the 1960s - an evocative theme like Hindu chauvinism, which could be conveyed to voters through talk of threats to national unity from anti-national minorities, began to seem all the more useful. It is impossible to regard this rightward shift as an accident, as something that happened with Congress-I leaders realizing too late that it was occurring and merely acquiescing. Too much of what took place required wilful action by Mrs Gandhi and then her son Rajiv. Indeed, as early as August 1982, after ��entators like Pran Chopra had warned against the dangers of courting the Hindu majority in north India by generating communal anxieties, I asked a general secretary of the AICC-1 if that really could be the Prime Minister's intention. He responded, not bydenying that this was her aim, but by seeking to justify it as a creative strategy. 51 It remained the strategy of Congress-I leaders right through the election of 1984. Although it may seem difficult to believe that Hindu chauvinism and .anti-Sikh sentiments were important ele­ ments in the Congress-I election campaign, such was, in fact, the case. For example at a November rally in Delhi, Rajiv Gandhi refused to prevent the city's Sikh mayor (a member of his own party) from being shouted down and then went on to use the word 'bad/a', revenge, in a speech that followed. He also refused to criticize the Hindu extremist organization, the RSS, which at every previous el�tion had supported the Jan Sangh/BJP, but which swung heavily, and in some cases openly, behind the Congress-I on this �casion. The Prime Minister further refused to disavow RSS support, thereby conforming to the precedent set by his mother in mid-1983 in Kerala where the Congress-I received RSS SI Interview with Satyanarayana Rao, Deihl, 18 August 1982. Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutions 113 backinf2 - and one of his leading party spokesmen even declined to admit that it was a communal organization.53Sikh opinion was outraged and many Congress-I leaders were privately alarmed when two sitting MPs in Delhi who were said by an independent investigation to have been involved in the anti-Sikh riots of November were kept on the Congress-I ticket and when a third activist, also allegedly involved, was given a ticket that had been denied to a Sikh incumbent. The anti-Sikh theme cropped up in numerous subtle and not-so-subtle remarks in speeches by Congress-I leaders, in posters that appeared in some localities showing Mrs Gandhi being gunned down by turbaned assassins, and in one of the party's full-page advertise­ ments that appeared nationwide in most English and indigenous language newspapers. The advertisement began with the question 'Will the country's border finally be moved to your doorstop?' and, after mentioning 'Assam, Punjab ... ', described the anti112tional forces: They put a knife through the country and carve out a niche for their cynical, disgruntled ambition disguised as public aspiration. They raise a flag and give this niche the name of a nation. They sow hatred and grow barbed wire fences, watered with human blood. But it's you who step out and bump into the fences and bleed while they cash your vote to buy their ticket to power. In case the anti-Sikh implications of much of this were not sufficiently clear, the text asked 'Why should you feel uncom­ fortable riding in a taxi driven by a taxi driver from another state?'54 Because a great many taxis in north India are driven by Sikhs, the message was clear. It is essential that we understand the logic by which this strategy was reached, because it has major implications for the party system. First of all, both the Congress-I general secretary who tried to justify Hindu chauvinism to me in 1982 and, I believe, Mrs Gandhi 52 See, for example, Dtwm Htrllld, 12 August 1983. 53 Sec the sources cited in note SO. 54 Sec, for example, Tbe Suttmum, Delhi, 1S December 1984. D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 114 State and Politics in India saw the move to the communalist right as an exercise similar to her move toward the Marxist left in and after 1969. It was a means of undermining the parties that stood to the right of the Con­ gress-I - mainly the BJP, but also to a degree the Lok Dal, which had elements within it susceptible to Hindu chauvinist appeals. It was clearly from the right that the main threat to the Congress-I was anticipated.55 The move to the right was also probably based on a curious belief by Mrs Gandhi that only she (and her son) stood between India and serious communal strife. So, still more curiously, she apparently believed that, by catalysing communalist sentiments, by becoming the main mouthpiece for Hindu communalism, she was protecting India from the dangers of it. She appears to have rationalized this dangerous quest for short-term political ad­ vantage by concluding that communalism was safe only in her hands and that by taking it up, she could disarm it as she had leftist sentiment after 1969. I heard echoes of this view in Decem­ ber 1984 from several Muslim intellectuals who were clearly frightened by the anti-Sikh, Hindu chauvinist content of Rajiv Gandhi's election campaign and who were seeking desperately for a benign explanation. Congress-I leaders also adopted what Rajni Kothari has cor­ rectly termed 'the rhetoric of all-out confrontation', in which the opposition parties were repeatedly attacked as anti-national for­ ces. We should recognize that this intolerant view of the opposi­ tion is in a sense a logical outgrowth of the history of the Congress. During the struggle for Independence, Congress sought and claimed to speak for all Indians, to be, as its name implied, an Indian national coming together. After 1947, this theme survived as Congress attempted to be, what B.D. Graham has called, 'a rally of the people as a whole'.56 It is thus not altogether surprising that some Congressmen tend to see the party and the nation as identical, or that they tend to see opposi­ tion forces as anti-national. It was, however, far from inevitable that Congress leaders should adopt this narrow, intolerant view. Jawaharlal Nehru gen­ erally did not, although he sometimes slipped into this idiom when ss Pranab Mukherjee's comments in Tmus, London, 29 December 1983. S6 B.D. Graham, 'Congress as a Rally', South AsiJm Rroiw, January 1973, pp. 111-24. Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutions 115 discussing communalist parties, but Indira Gandhi often did, and so, in the 1984 election campaign, did her son. He claimed, for example, that the opposition parties were 'receiving assistance from certain foreign powers, which were interested in making India weak' and that conferences of opposition leaders 'had sown the seeds of poison' that endangered national unity. He alleged that the Janata party, the Bharatiya Janata party, and the Dalit Mazdoor Kisan party had links with Sikh extremists living in Britain.57 He offered no evidence to support these charges, and none of them appears to have any substance. Mr Gandhi also described the Chief Minister of Andhra Pradesh, N.T. Rama Rao, as a 'secessionist', a charge he has subsequently admitted to be false.58 On a visit to Janata-ruled Kamataka, he implied that the Janata party had assisted those who had murdered Mrs Gandhi. This was untrue, as were his assertions that the Janata party 'was working hard to divide the country, and 'shielding extremists',59 and that two prominent members of that party were collaborators with Pakistan.60 Why did Congress-I leaders adopt this confrontational ap­ proach? Two different reasons come to mind. First, although it caused a change in relations within the party system, confronta­ tion was also a symptom of changes that had already occurred. By the early I980s both the Congress-I and most opposition parties had become so porous that a substantial leakage of per­ sonnel out of any of them became a very real possibility. And the more that Congress-I and most opposition parties suffered organizational decay, ideological laxity, and the imposition of personal control by those at the apex, the more they rese1nbled each other. Potential defectors from one to the next therefore felt that they had less distance to travel. By confronting and reviling the opposition parties, Congress-I leaders sought to im­ pede defections to the opposition by erecting barriers between their party and the other parties, and by putting distance between the Congress-I and the others. In this respect, there is a curious similarity between the confrontational election campaign and the 57 Hindustan Times, Delhi, 13 December 1984 and Indian F.xprtss, Delhi, 26 December 1984. sa Tbe Hindu, Madras, 7 December 1984. 59 Hindustl,n Times, Delhi, 18 December 1984. 60 Tbe Stllt.el""'111, Delhi, 18 December 1984. Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 116 State and Politics in India post-election and anti-defection law. Both are designed to erect the kind of walls around the ruling party that its organization had had the strength to generate in the J960s, but which had wasted away when the organization decayed after 1969. The second reason for the choice of this confrontational ap­ proach is that, give.n the nature of Congress-I rule between J 980 and 1984 and the assumptions that had underpinned it, the Gandhis had few other options. I have already noted that by the time Mrs Gandhi assumed power in 1980, she had lost confidence in the state as an agency for creative action in society. As a result, next to no serious attempts were made by the authorities during her last premiership to develop carefully designed social program­ mes. There were, therefore, few new legislative achievements between 1980 and 1984 to which Congress-I leaders could point. Indeed, their election speeches and the party manifesto made virtually no reference to government programmes after 1980. It seemed at times as if some other party had been in power during that period. The only major reference in the manifesto to positive developments after 1980 was to advances on the economic front, where credit tended to go to ll)arket forces and not to the govemment.61 The government had sought, in the period after 1980, to direct popular attention to a number of major 'spectaculars' in order to justify the existence of a state in which the Prime Minister had lost confidence. Much was made of the Asian Games, the Com­ monwealth Heads of Government Conference, Antarctic explora­ tions, and the like. But Congress-I leaders rightly sensed that these were not election winners. They also rightly believed that Mrs Gandhi would have great difficulty obtaining a majority in. the election,62 and, given the absence of any major legislative achieve­ ments and the presence of a highly unreliable party organization, they were driven to present Mrs Gandhi as a figure of stability amid increasing instability and to continue to court the votes of the Hindu majority across north India by making appeals based on Hindu chauvinism and the notion that India's unity was in jeopardy. If a party adopts that set of themes, it is impelled by the logic of chauvinism and its 'India-in-danger' message to raise 61 lndum N11ti<1fllll Crm grtss (I) Ekt:tirm Mtmifttto, 1984, New Delhi, 1984. 62 This is based on interviews with a large nwnber of Congress-I officials in December 1984. D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The lnstitiaions 117 alarms and to excoriate the opposition as dangerous, anti-national destabilizers. A brief comment is needed here on the manner in which Rajiv Gandhi and his party won the election of 1984. At least five factors appear to have had a significant impact, although, as I have argued elsewhere, we will probably never be able to say with certainty what their relative importance was.63 First, there was, of course, a sympathy factor after the murder of Mrs Gandhi, but its impact has probably been overestimated. It was a 'factor' rather than a 'wave'. Another obvious element was the abject failure of most opposition parties, especially the so-called national parties, to provide a credible alternative to the Congress-I. Yet both of these seem to have been less important than three other things. First, Rajiv Gandhi's youth, his freshness, and his apparent lack of a political past helped him to represent himself both as a figure of stability and continuity, on the one hand, and as a figure of renewal and ch:µige, on the other. As R�ni Kothari wrote long ago, this was an unbeatable combination. A second crucial factor was the widespread (and, I believe, erroneous) perception that national unity was in danger. This fear was crystallized in many people's minds by the trauma of the assassination and was relentlessly exploited by the Congress-I. Finally, there was a related Hindu backlash that was encouraged by the Prime Minister and his party. To point to these factors as decisive is to identify this election as distinct from most of the national and state-level elections since 1972. Those earlier elections tended to be decided on concrete issues and, particularly, on the quality of the incumbent gov­ ernment's performance. The 1984 election was decided at the level of anxieties, images, evocations, and symbols. The result bespoke an aggrieved and fearful assertiveness together with a desperate need for hope and some prospect of renewal in government. In order to see how things had changed by the end of this phase, let us recall some of the specific observations that Morris-Jones and Kothari made about the party system. In late 1984, India still had a multiparty system that permitted free competition, a system in which one party, bearing the name of Congress, occupied a dominant position in the New Delhi Parliament and in many state 63 James Manor, 'The Indian General Election of 1984', Ekctural Swdiu, August 198S, pp. 149-S2. 64 Rajni Kothari, 'Government by Mandate', Sm,irulr, January 1972, p. 23. D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 118 State and Politics in India assemblies. However, the Congress-I no longer possessed a party organization strong enough to place it in a dominant position outside of the legislatures. The 1984 election landslide was achieved in spite of serious organizational weaknesses. The Congress-I organization was in­ substantial, highly corrupt in many regions, wracked by factions that engaged in severe conflicts, unrepresentative of the broad array of social groups for whom it claimed to speak, and very inefficient at delivering goods and services to them and at arrang­ ing bargains between them. It was very short of idealists, intellec­ tuals, and, most essentially, honest, skilled managers. Those it possessed were often excluded from positions of influence. The party was, therefore, in no fit condition to administer governments at the state and national levels in a rational, reliable, effective manner. It was also distinctly short of policies in many spheres (although the new Prime Minister has begun to change that), and where such policies existed, it lacked the personnel at the district and subdistrict levels to ensure that bureaucrats actually imple­ mented them. Neither was it true any longer that this was a dominant party system 'without a trace of alternation'. Most elections at the state and national levels since 197 2 have led to alternations (indeed, every Indian state has now had a spell of non-Congress govern­ ment), as an awakening electorate has made re-election increas­ ingly difficult to achieve. And it is hard to see how the 1984 Lok .Sabha result, which was substantially the product of the extra o r ­ dinary circumstances in which it occurred, can be expected to change that basic tendency in the system. Opposition parties in the post-1980 period did not have much influence over sections of the Congress-I in the legislatures the latter dominated. There was little 'positive communication and interaction between them'. This was partly explained by the in­ creasingly confrontational approach that various parties, most not­ ably the Congress-I, adopted toward rival organizations and by the expectation within many opposition parties that they might one day defeat the Congress-I. But it is more adequately explained by the decay that had occurred within many political parties, again, most notably, within the Congress-I. The Congress no longer contained an organization rational enough to enable rightist or leftist factions within it to produce results by applying pressure on --· Digitized b� Google Ongmal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutions 119 party leaders or within the councils of the party. Information seldom flowed freely from one level of the organization up to the next, because the abandonment of intra-party democracy had caused party operatives to tell those at higher levels only what they thought the latter wanted to hear. And even when pressure or information did flow up through the hierarchy, it seldom elicited an adequate or logical response from an organization crippled by harsh factional fighting and, in many areas, galloping normless­ ness. So opposition groups saw little point in seeking to strike up good relations with like-minded Congressmen. The decay within the Congress-I also made it impossible for the party to conduct itself with enough efficiency to manage within itself, as it once had, most of the major conflicts in Indian public life, to interpret the logic of politics at one level to the levels above and below, or to play the central role in integrating India's many and varied regions, subcultures, and social groups. Indeed, many social groups received such inadequate or even harmful responses from Congress-I politicians, or were so dis­ mayed by the normless or criminal behavior of Congressmen in many regions, that they have turned away from the Congress party and, because many opposition parties have also suffered decay, from politics in general. In these circumstances, Congress-I leaders after 1982 or so sometimes adopted the opposite of their former policy of arrang­ ing accommodations between social groups, subcultures and re­ gions, and actually sought to set them against one another. This enabled the ruling party to absorb within itself discontented groups who saw it as the only party capable of providing stability amid chaos - which the Congress-I had itself wilfully helped to generate. But these actions and reactions may ultimately cause more problems than either the Congress or the political system can cope with and may, in the long term, present opportunities for rival parties on the extremes of the party system. There still may have been in this phase considerable validity i n Morris-Jones's suggestion, made in the late 1960s, that com­ plexities and ambiguities in Indian society prevent the political system from having to face the kind of serious conflict that societies more prone to polarization and contradiction might generate. I t has always been difficult to measure this, for it entails the enumeration of dogs that do not bark. But there is no doubt Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 120 Stllte and Politics in India that a great many more contradictions existed in Indian society in the early 1980s than in the 1960s, contradictions between interest groups (caste, class, communal, regional, and issue­ speciftc), most of which had not crystallized in the 1960s. Some of them had not fully formed even in 1984, but they had acquired enough substance and collective self-consciousness amid the gen­ eral political awakening to produce conflict that could no longer be defused by bargaining and co-optation.65 This would have been true even if the ruling party had possessed the means to perform those tasks well, which it did not This is not to say that India was on the brink of a social crisis or breakdown. As I have argued at length elsewhere, Indian society is particularly well equipped, in both structure and habits of mind, to insulate itself from damage that might result from decay and anomic forces originating in the political sphere.66 But it still needs to be recognized that in the 1980s this society threw up conflicts and problems that made it well-nigh impossible to maintain the sort of broad coalition that gave Congress its dominant position in the party system in the 1960s (and which may have given the Congress-I its huge victory in the 1984 election). During this third phase, between 1977 and 1984, the Congress was a good deal less assiduous than it had been in the period described by Kothari and Morris-Jones in its efforts 'to preserve democratic forms, to respect the rule of law, and to avoid undue strife'. Neither did it sho)' 'great sensitivity on the question of respect for minoriries'.67 Because these were traits that assisted it in defusing and even in reaping benefits from opposition-led agita­ tions, it is possible that recent changes may, over time, reduce its capacity . . for accommodation and thereby create opportunities for oppos1aon groups. In their later reassessments of the party system, Kothari and Morris-Jones emphasized two major, interconnected points. The first was the continuing ability of Congress, even after the 1967 election, to play the central role in maintaining and restructuring 65 See, for example, R.I. Duncan, 'Levels, the Communication of Program­ mes, and Sectional Strategies in Indian Politics', D. Phil. thesis, University of Sussex, 1977. 66 James Manor, 'Anomie i n Indian Politics: Origins and Potential Wider Impact', Ecimamic and Political Weekly, 18 May 1983, pp. 725-34. 67 Kothari, "The Congress "System"', pp. 1168-70. Dlgltlzedby Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutions 121 political consensus in India. The second was the continuing growth of a 'market' polity, that is to say a polity basedon bargaining. Most of the important bargaining in that period still occurred within the Congress, among factions, among representatives of social groups, and between people at different levels and in different regions. But bargaining also occurred between the Congress and the opposition parties. Much of this sounds unfamiliar in the light of events over the last decade or so. It is certainly possible to say that the 1984 election victory ofRajiv Gandhi represented both the maintenance and the restructuring of political consensus. But we need to ask whether his party is capable of continuing to sustain and renew that consensus week in and week out throughout the government's term in office. This seems unlikely, mainly because by 1984 it was incapable of arranging and maintaining political bargains that are essential to that task. One feature, though not the central one, of the 'market' polity to which Morris-Jones called attention was an increase in defec­ tions. This raises a difficult issue that has never been fully ex­ amined: to what extent can defections be seen as contributions to the maintenance and restructuring of consensus in Indian politics? I submit that a defection can be seen as such a contribution, provided it is primarily the result of discontent among a legislator's supporters over unacceptable treatment by the party to which he or she originally belonged, and provided the switch to another party was.mainly intended to obtain better treatment. Such defec­ tions represent rational responses from social or subregional groups to parties' misdeeds or omissions, and they serve to remind parties of the need to maintain consensus. Many defections in the period that Morris-Jones described were not of that nature, however. Many, indeed, appear to have been undertaken by individual legislators to enhance their position in terms of power, money, or both.68 Defections of this kind are clearly part of the 'market' polity, for bargains of a sort are being made. But such privateering is likely to impede the maintenance and restructuring of consensus, for such defectors are responding to a logic other than that which governs the maintenance of consensus. The defections that became such a prominent feature 68 It is not always easy to identify the motives of defectors. See for example, Kochanek, Th� Crmgrus PllnJ, pp. 293 and 447. Digiti zed by Google Ongmal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 122 State and Politics in India of Indian politics in the 1980s tended overwhelmingly to be re­ sponses to large cash payments by the Congress-I, which, as the ruling party could alone command such vast financial resources. In fairness, however, it should be emphasized that more than a few defectors and near-defectors were turning to the Congress-I out of frustration with unresponsive leaders. This was especially true in Andhra Pradesh before August 1984, where N.T. Rama Rao was excessively autocratic.69 It should be apparent to anyone who glanced at newspaper reports from India between 1982 and 1984 that very serious centre-state conflict had developed in cases where opposition parties were in power at the state level. In the post- l 967 period, Y.B. Chavan was able to maintain relatively civil relations with opposition-led state governments because the Congress did not adopt a confrontational posture towards the opposition and be­ cause it was entirely possible that Congress might join opposition parties in coalitions at the state level:This happened several tunes during the period. It is not the sort of thing that happened in the 1980s, however, except in Kerala, where extraordinary cir­ cumstances applied. The Congress-I was pugnacious towards the opposition, because the personality of its leaders (or at least its former leader) inclined in that direction and because it needed to be stand-offish once so little separated the decayed Congress-I from decayed opposition parties. 1984 Onwards The final phase in the evolution of India's parties and party system is the period since the eighth general election in the last week of 1984. Our conclusions in this section must be tenuous for, at this writing, the phase is only twelve months old. In the year since his election victory, which he achieved by reviling and confronting the opposition parties, Rajiv Gandhi has been more accommodating in his dealings with the opposition than his mother ever was. I-le has also been more conciliatory toward regional movements and parties, some of which he had sought to topple from power at the state level through bribery70 69This is based on a large number of interviews with legislators and journalists in Hyderabad, 11 and 12 January 1985. 70 See, for example, /ndi1111 Expren-, Bombay, 1 January 1984. D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutions 123 and manoeuvres of dubious constitutionality. This has earned him appreciative comments from the opposition Chief Ministers of Karnataka and Andhra Pradesh. Moreover, his agreements with leaders of regional movements in Punjab and Assam, and the subsequent elections in those states are among the greatest achievements of his first year in office. Some doubts still linger, however, about his commitment to accommodation. His abrupt change from an assertive to a con­ ciliatory stance in Assam lost him a great deal of support among those who had been attracted by the former approach. The same thing may also have occurred in Punjab during 1985. Because his turnabout entails a departure from the Hindu chauvinism of recent years and because this will disappoint many voters in other states, he may eventually find the cost of conciliation too great. It is also possible that he will feel able to pursue accommodation only so long as he feels politically secure, that if he begins to feel vul­ nerable he may revert to the confrontational stance of 1984. But for the present, the predominant trend is towards a reconstruction of the tolerably good relations with the opposition that charac­ terized the p r eIndira Gandhi years. Rajiv Gandhi's main preoccupation during his first year in office has been a reordering within the formal institutions of state. He has concentrated on changing personnel within both the bureaucracy and ministerial ranks of the central government, though not, to any significant degree, at the state level. He has sought to persuade officials at intermediate levels to take the initiative more often in order to break the log jams that had immobilized much of the central government in his mother's day. He has also rid the Prime Minister's secretariat of the unqualified personnel who held posts thanks to their fierce loyalty to Indira Gandhi, and h e has decentralized power somewhat by curtailing the power of the secretariat.71 All this may suggest a reordering of affairs within the Congress party. The Prime Minister appeared to indicate that intention in late 1985 when he shifted key aides from his secretariat to leading party posts, but very little was said or done about the party until the last week of 1985. Then in Bombay on 28 December, the hundredth anniversary of the Indian National Congress, the Prime Minister delivered 71 James Manor, 'India: Rebuilding amid Awakening and Decay', History, March 1986. D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm Currrot UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 124 State and Politics in India the most scorching critique of the party ever uttered by one of its leaders.He spoke of 'cliques ...enmeshing the living body of the Congress in their net of avarice'. He complained of Congress operatives' 'self-aggrandisement, their corrupt ways, their linkages with vested interests ... and their sanctimonious posturings ... ', and he added that 'corruption is not only tolerated ... but even regarded as a hallmark of leadership'.72 This attack on the Congress party, which was quite accurate, is likely to produce one of two outcomes. Given the wretched state of the party, Rajiv Gandhi may take drastic action to cleanse Congress, or he may conclude that there is so little hope of restoring a modicum of rationality and probity to the party that no serious effort will be made.If he takes the latter route, he will, in effect, be gambling that he can get along without a party organization. He will be depending on the performance of the formal institutions of state, manned by his ministers and bureau­ crats, on his personal appeal, and on innovations such as the liberalization of the economy and the introduction of microtech­ nology to win him the support of the electorate. In a political system in which parties, particularly the Congress party, have been the main instruments for integrating and governing the nation, for detecting and responding to discontentment and pressures from interest groups, for managing social conflict and for cultivat­ ing electoral support through the distribution of resources, in such a system, to do without a papy organization is to ask for trouble. Even a powerful executive presidency on Gaullist lines - which is an option under consideration - is unlikely to perform ade­ quately the roles formerly played by party organization. Nevertheless, the evidence from Rajiv Gandhi's first fifteen months in power suggests that he may eventually be compelled to do without a strong Congress organization and even to seek a radical reduction in the importance of parties in the political system. The Prime Minister appears already to have dallied too long to revive the Congress-I. During the first few months after the murder of his mother, he had and spumed a clear opportunity to make radical changes in the party. That opportunity appears now to have passed and is unlikely to arise again. 72 Times ofIru!ia, Bombay, 29 December J 985 and Times, London, 30 Decem­ ber 1985. Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 3 India Decides: Elections 1952-1995 David Butler, Ashok Lahiri and Pranno:, Ro:, Voters and Constituencies I ndia has had a system of universal adult suffrage ever since becoming a republic in 1950.1 Everyone over 21 has been entitled to vote2 in any election to the Lok Sabha or to the state legislative assemblies, the Vidhan Sabhas. 3 With the passing of the 62nd amendment to the Constitution in 1988, the voting age was lowered to 18. The whole country is divided into 4061 Vidhan Sabha con­ stituencies which are grouped together to form the 543 Lok Sabha constituencies.4 Normally, seven assembly constituencies are I Though India became independent on 15 August 1947, the Republic was only proclaimed and the Indian Constitution came into force on 26January 1950. The first elections were held twO years later. 2 According to the Constitution, 'every person who is a citizen of India and who i s riot less than twenty-one years of age on such date as may be fixed in that behalf by or under any law ... and is not otherwise disqualified ... on the ground ofnon-residence, unsoundness of mind, crime, or illegal practice, shall be entitled to be registered as a voter.' J The Indian Parliament consists of two Houses: the Council of states or the Rajya Sabha, and the House of the People or the Lok Sabha. All the members of the Rajya Sabha, except twelve nominated by the President of India, are elected by the elected members of the Vidhan Sabhas. 4 The size of the Lok Sabha has varied over the years, as follows: 1952-489; 1957-494; 1962-494; 1967-520; 1971-518; 1977-542; 1980--542; 1984-542; 1989-543; 1991-543; 1995-543. Changes in the number of seats have occurred mainly as a result of fresh delimitation reports. Between 1984 and 1989, the number of Lok Sabha seats was raised from 542 to 543 Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 126 State and Politics in India arranged to form one Lok Sabha constiruency, but this can vary from one state to another. In Uttar Pradesh, for example, there are five assembly constiruencies to each Lok Sabha constituency, i.e. 85 MPs and 425 Ml.As. A person who is 'ordinarily resident' and registered to vote in a Vidhan Sabha constiruency is also eligible to vote in the corresponding Lok Sabha constiruency. However, not every eligible person actually votes. Some are absent from the constiruency in which they are ordinarily resident, or are preoccupied with work, or are unwell. Some stay away merely because of bad weather or apathy. The average voter rurnout in Indian elections has been 56.6 per cent, varying from the low of 45. 7 per cent in 1952 to the record rurnout of64.l per cent in 1984.5 The upward trend in voter rurnout indicates a greater invol­ vement of the electorate as more and more voters become aware of the electoral system and understand the power of their ballot (India's first four elections had an average rurnout of 52 per cent, while in the most recent four elections the turnout has averaged 60 per cent). The turnout among men voters has consistently been higher than among women but the participation rate has improved faster among women than among men. Female turnout increased 20 percentage points from 38.8 per cent in 1957 to 57.3 per cent in 1989. But strangely the last election in 1991 because one extra seat was allotted to Daman and Diu once Goa became a state with two seats on 30 May 1987. For simplicity throughout this chapter we speak o f the Lok Sabha in terms only of its popularly elected members. But Article 371 of the Constitution authorizes the President to nominate up to two members to ensure the representation ofthe Anglo-Indian community. Thus, although we record the 1991 House as having 543 elected members, it in fact contained 545 MPs including two nominated members. S Turnout is computed as the total votes polled (valid plus invalid) as a percentage of the electorate i n contested scats (the electorate i n uncontested scats is omitted). All turnout figures must have a margin oferror. The electoral register can never be fully up to date and every register has its mistakes both in duplicate names and in omissions. The accuncy of Indian electoral registers is reasonably high, but must vary considerably between different regions and localities. It should also be remembered that a small proportion of people who actually go to the polls fail to record a valid vote, usually by inadvertence but occasionally deliberately. The new system of voter identity cards may cause problems in defining turnout and electorate size. Once the system is introduced, the electorate will need to be defined as those persons over 18 who have an identity card. Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN Tile Institutions 127 65% 60 Average _55. _56.6% - - -50 45 40 1952 '57 '62 '67 '71 '77 '80 '84 '91 Figure 3.1 Voter Turnout, A llIndia - 70% MEN' -- 60- - Men's Average §3 ... a.�- +-�1---+--+- +----t - ----t�-t--- 50- - - Women's Average �MEN 51.4% 30 1957 '62 '67 '71 '77 '80 '84 '89 '91 Figun 3.2 Voter Turno11t, Men and Women Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN TABLE 3.1 Turnout. in Lok Sabha Elections (percentage) 0 '"" c- 0 a0 � C z < m ::,:, !!?o :;!�" ..,, - 0� 6 �3 n :c z State ALL INDIA Andhra Pradesh Arunachal Pradesh Assam• Bihar Goa Gujarat Haryan a HimachaJ Pradesh Jammu & Kashmirb Karnataka Kcrala Madhya Pradesh Maharashtra Manipur Meghal c aya Mizoram Nagaland Orissa Punjabd Rajasthan Sikkim Tamil Nadu 1952 45.7 44.7 - 47.7 40.5 25.3 - 51.9 71.0 45.0 52.4 51.1 - 1957 47.7 43.9 - 46.6 42.9 37.6 - 52.8 66.6 38.0 55.7 52.7 - 1962 55.4 64.7 - 52.8 47.0 58.0 35.6 - 59.3 70.6 44.8 60.4 65.3 - 1967 61.3 68.7 - 59.3 51.5 68.4 63.8 72.6 51.2 55.2 63.0 75.6 53.5 64.8 67.2 - Election Year 1971 55.3 59.1 - 50.7 49.0 55.9 55.5 64.4 41.2 58.1 57.4 64.5 48.0 59.9 48.9 - 35.4 55.3 38.4 36.1 55.0 40.6 23.6 65.4 52.4 43.7 71.1 58.3 53.8 43.2 59.9 54.0 S<i,1 12,1 68,8 26,6 21.8 - - - - - 1977 60.5 62.5 56.3 54.9 60.8 62.8 59.2 73.3 59.2 57.9 63.2 79.2 54.9 60.3 60.1 49.9 49.9 52.8 44.3 70.1 56.9 - 62.1 1980 57.0 56.9 68.6 53.4 51.9 69.5 1984 64.1 69.0 75.5 79.7 58.8 55.4 71.8 57.9 58.7 58.7 61.5 64.8 57.7 62.2 51.9 56.8 81.7 51.2 56.1 63.9 46.3 62.7 54.7 44.7 {i{i,8 66.8 66.4 65.7 ·77.1 57.5 61.7 85.7 54.5 - 66.5 56.3 67.6 57.0 57.6 23,0 1989 62.0 70.4 59.2 - 60.2 58.2 54.6 64.4 63.9 31.6 67.5 79.3 55.2 59.9 71.8 51.9 58.3 74.7 59.3 62.7 56.5 72.0 66,9 1991 56.7 61.4 51.3 75.3 60.4 42.4 44.0 65.8 57.4 - 54.8 73.3 44.4 48.8 69.7 53.6 58.6 77.1 53.8 - 47.2 71.6 63,9 Average 56.6 60.1 62.2 52.0 52.3 61.3 56.0 67.4 49.2 54.7 59.3 71.9 49.3 58.1 65.4 52.2 44.6 64.8 44.2 63.3 51.6 61.5 66.0 Continued 128 Tahk J.l (conlj State 0 ,§ <.' N ::l. er "" 0 a0 � Tripura Uttar Pradesh West Bengal Union Territories A & Nlslands Chandfr h Dadra Nagar Haveli Daman & Diu Delhi Lakshadweep Pondichemr • Nous: C z < m ::,:, !!?o :;!�" ..,, - 0� 6 �3 n :c Gl z )> 1952 1957 1962 57.9 - 57.8 - 68.8 - 47.7 38.4 40.5 64.7 47.8 48.6 68.0 51.0 55.8 FJection Year Average 1967 1971 1977 1980 1984 1989 1991 67.3. 49.2 76.7 69.5 50.0 63.9 78.5 65.4 78.3 70.5 62.9 69.8 71.0 67.4 68.5 84.5 63.9 72.8 78.8 68.9 74.6 71.7 65.7 72.9 64.3 57.8 66.5 74.2 64.6 71.9 64.5 87.0 54.5 54.3 85.0 67.0 48.5 80.4 60.8 63.3 85.2 74.8 54.5 66.0 69.5 - 74.9 60.8 46.0 61.9 75.8 - 70,1 70.1 56.4 60.2 - 71.3 84.6 73.6 80.0 50.0 70.7 - 64.9 88.8 80.4 77.3 55.8 78.6 - 72,3 83.9 51.3 79.7 66.7 67,7 72,2 No elections were held in Assam in 1989. No elections were held inJammu & Kashmir in 1991. C The seat was uncontested in 1984. d Elections were held in February 1992, seven months after the 10th General Elections. Andhra Pradesh refers to Hyderabad in 1952. Karnataka refers to Mysore from 1952 to 1962. Kerala refers to Travancore-Cochin in 1952. Maharashtra refers to Bombay from 1952 to 1957. Tamil Nadu refers to Madras from 1952 to 1962. Goa refers to Goa, Daman & Diu from 1967 to 1984. b 129 130 State and Politics in India recorded a drop i n women's participation to only 51.4 per cent. The male turnout only rose 5 percentage points from 5 5.8 per cent in 1957 to 61.6 per cent in 1991. In other words, the gender gap in turnout (measured by the number of percentage points by which male turnout is higher than female turnout) has almost halved: from male turnout being 17 per cent higher in 1957 to 10.2 per cent in 1991. Voter turnout in urban areas has always been higher than in rural areas - by around 6 to 8 per cent. The statewise turnout figures (fable 3.1) broadly indicate that turnout tends to be higher in the southern states and in West Bengal (particularly during the period when West Bengal had non-Congress governments). Kerala, the state with the highest literacy rate, has traditionally had by far the highest turnout in the country: even in 1952, 71 per cent voted. But West Bengal's growth in participation, as the state became increas­ ingly politically volatile, has been the most dramatic: the turnout in 1991 was 76. 7 per cent, the highest in any state, almost twice the 1952 figure of 40.5 per cent. More detailed information about voters -their age distribution, their literacy level, their division by caste, religion and occupation is available from · the Census. Census data are unfortunately not published on a constituency basis but only by districts, which makes it difficult to carry out any detailed socio-economic analyses of election results. Who is the Indian voter? How do the various demographic groupings divide among the parties? It is only with the extensive use of polls that these questions can be answered. There are no satisfactory data on who voted how in most of India's elections, but the very large-scale surveys of 1991 give a profile of the Indian voter for that year. India Today commissioned MARG and Prannoy Roy to conduct an exit poll in which 90,005 people were ques­ tioned on how they had voted. Each voter's caste, sex and religion were recorded. Exit polls tend to be more accurate and the enor­ mous sample sizes make these data a very useful source for analys­ ing election results. The summary results of the 1991 exit poll in Table 3.2 provide perhaps the most reliable indicator of the dif­ ferences in voting behaviour among various groups in India. Their answers give a clearer indication of the sections of the population from which each party was drawing its support. One reservation should be made about the electorate, especially Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN ··I TABLE 3.2 Exit Poll Results 1991 Congress 0 .§: ::,: N "n ii C") 0 - � � :x, � 0 :::! o§:" 0� ..,, "' :;:: _30 - n ::c Q )> z Total Refused/ DK 36.1 36.5 32.6 20.9 I 3.7 14.8 4.6 3.4 7.5 8.7 5.5 I 5. 7 100 100 (5.1) up to 21 21-30 31-40 41-50 51+ 30.3 34.3 37.0 38.0 41.0 39.2 34.5 30.6 30.3 29.8 13.5 13.2 14.0 15.2 12.4 5.0 4.5 4. 9 4.6 4.2 7.0 7.7 7.8 7 �-.5 5.0 5.7 5.7 5.2 5.0 100 100 100 100 100 (2.5) (3.6) (5.4) (6.8) (9.6) Men Women 35.5 37.5 33.3 31.1 14.7 11.7 4.3 5.2 7.I 8.3 5.1 6.1 100 100 (4.7) (6.5) Brahmin 30.4 35.0 28.4 43.5 29.9 53.4 45.4 27.4 59.2 41.1 49.6 23.5 34.9 19.4 3.4 30.0 4.5 8.5 11.5 12.4 17.0 8.5 28.0 6.2 2.3 5.7 1.8 2.4 7.3 0.2 2.5 13.8 6.1 13.7 13.9 0.4 1.0 2.7 1.4 11.7 4.9 4.7 3.8 22.2 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 100 (5.0) (5.8) (5.8) (4.7) (5.2) (8.7) (3.8) (7.8)_ 35.8 36.3 41.2 29.8 12.6 14.0 2.3 5.4 4.6 8.4 3.5 6.1 100 100 (7.0) .. _(4.8) AGE SEX Kshatriya z < m Others OVERALL Exit Poll Actual CASTE C JJ'JPI ]ll1Ultll DaV ]111111ta Dal CPI/ Shiv Sma TDP CPI(M)_ @. Vais'r SCIS OBC Other Hindu Muslim Other Religion LOCATION Rural Urban - - - - -- . 5.5 7.0 7.2 6.5 131 132 State and Politics in India J& K PUNJAB CHANDIGARH ARUNACHAL PRADESH RAJASTHAN ;:;, UTl'AR ,. /'"' ") PRADESH -�·. ----..__, .......··· ..·,. ..... ·• ', ·. .. .....,.....,.... ,.... ,·.. BIHAR : ,.... ., -._, .) r--.., GUJARAT,/ . MADHYA PRADES� ·--� .: .:.!....--·.-.. ..�.'...�·-··--.. . ...•....·-········. .. ,· .. ,,_...,..,..,. . ....-......... ': DAMAN &DIU DADRAlt NAGAR HAVEL! :� <-..:· ! ... : ... ,..MAHARASHTRA • ··� : �-- •· ......,;---· · GOA ··j A&N LA Nore: ISLANDS f'igurt 3.3 Avera ge Turrw,a in Lak Sabha EltctitmS No elections were held in Assam in 1989,J & Kin I 991 and in Pw1jab elections were held in February 1992. Digiti zed by Google Ongmal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutions 133 in a study that covers a period of more than forty years. lne differences in electoral outcomes between one election and the next in a single constituency, or in the country as a whole, are not solely due to voters changing their party allegiance. The electorate is not a fixed group of persons - it is a continually changing body as electors die and new electors come of age and as electors move from one region to another or even immigrate. The annual turn­ over through death and coming of age will never be less than 2 per cent. The turnover through migration varies widely but may often be higher than that. In the five years between two successive elections the turnover among those who compose the electorate in a particular constituency may easily exceed 20 per cent However, these factors do not usually produce much instability in voting patterns. In the absence of other information, the best way to predict how a constituency will vote is to see how it voted last time. For most people voting is a habit and party loyalties endure. Moreover, children tend to inherit their parents' and grandparents' politics, so that mortality and coming of age makes less difference than might be supposed. Immigrants too, often move to an area because their new neighbours are similar people and they quickly adopt their political habits. The area itself usually stays relatively constant, exposed to much the same problems, the same mass media and the same leaders in election after election. Therefore, although it should be remembered that the electorate is a changing entity, there is no need to worry seriously that the turnover of voters will invalidate comparisons between the results of successive elections. The Election Commission is an independent body, established under the constitution. The Election Commissioner has a five­ year term and cannot be dismissed except through impeachment; his powers over the timing and conduct of any election are very great6 Despite political attacks and adverse court judgements, the independence and the neutrality of the Commission has been 6 The Election 1952 1958 1967 1972 1973 1977 Commissioners: SulrumarSen 1982 K.V.K.Swidaram 1985 S.P.SenVerma 1990 1995 NagendraSingh T.Swaminathan S.L.Sha.kdhar D1g1t 1zeo by Google R.K. Trivedi R.VS . . PeriShastri T.N. SQSban T.N. Seshan M.S.Gill G.VG . . Krishnamurthy Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 134 State and Politics in India generally recognized. On 1 October 1993 the President signed two notifications prepared by the government which radically altered the structure at the top of the Election Commission. Instead of one Chief Election Comtnissioner, the Election Com­ mission would be a multi-member body with three Election Com­ missioners and the two new Election Commissioners would have equal status as the Chief Election Commissioner. The Chief Elec­ tion Commissioner and other Election Commissioners (Condition of Service) Amendment Ordinance 1993 was later converted into an Act of Parliament known as the Election Commission (Condi­ tions of Service of Election Commissioners and Transaction of Business) Act 1994. The Act severely reduces the power of the Chief Election Commissioner by stating that all decisions must be by majority vote among the three Commissioners. This chapter is mainly about the computation of votes and not about the forces surrounding their casting. Indian elections are complex affairs and sometimes there is corruption, intimidation and violence. Booth-capturing has long been known in Bihar and in recent contests it has been reported from many parts of north­ ern India. For this and other improprieties, the Election Commis­ sion has made increasing use of its powers to order a repoll at particular booths or over whole districts or constituencies. In 1991 repolls were ordered in several constituencies because of booth­ capturing, violence or other ele<!toral malpractices. The Commis­ sion has also begun to stagger voting over a longer period to time with different parts of a state voting on different dates. This allows all the security forces to concentrate on one area and then move to the next area - rather than spread the forces thinly across the entire state. In the most recent assembly elections in Bihar in March 1995, voting took three weeks and was done in hve phases. The Election Commission, however, is not in a position to check every abuse. The existence of electoral fraud provides one more argument against the pursuit of extreme mathematical pre­ cision in the analysis of votes. The periodic alteration of constituency boundaries also pro­ vides many difficulties for electoral analysts. Fundamental to any modern electoral system is the principle of equality of suffrage a vote should have as much value in one constituency as in any other. Every elected member should represent an equal number -of voters. But the actual division of the country into constituencies D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Imtitutions 135 is influenced both by administrative convenience and by the desire of legislators to establish a close connection with their own elec­ torates. The conflict between the twin objectives of equality of suffrage and administrative convenience inevitably leads to ine­ quality in constituency size. But the main reason why constituency boundaries need periodic revision is because the population grows a t widely differing rates in differing localities. The Constitution (Article 82) prescribes that a fresh drawing of boundaries should take place after each Census. The first delimitation of constituen­ cies in 1952 (which was carried out directly under the President) came in for sharp criticism and the Election Commission proposed, successfully, that an independent Delimitation Com­ mission should be formed to make recommendations which Par­ liament would then approve. · Lok Sabha seats, on the whole, have been allotted to the states in proportion to their population (see Table 3.3). Table 3.4 ranks states according to their average constituency size. The states with the largest constituencies are the most under-represented in the Lok Sabha. However, among the major states the deviation from average is less than 12 per cent. For example Rajasthan is the most under-represented: each MP has an electorate 11.7 per cent larger than the all-India avera ge. The Delimitation Commission con­ ducted a minor revision of boundaries in 1956, and comprehensive revisions in 1966 and 1976. The 1991 elections, however, were fought in 543 constituencies with boundaries that had been un­ changed since 1977, though one seat was added (the number was 542 until 1989) when Goa got an extra seat on becoming a state. The constituencies which were drawn up in 1976 by the Delimita­ tion Commission have been used for five elections. By contrast only two of the first five elections (1967 and 1971) were fought on the same boundaries (though the only difference between 1957 and 1962 was due to the division of double-member seats into two constituencies each). In 1976, the Constitution was amended to postpone the ne;1tt delimitation until after the year 2001. This was in response to fears expressed by the states that if they were successful in im­ plementing population control under the national family planning schemes, they might lose some of their representation in the Lok Sabha. Therefore, the 1977, 1980, 1984, 1989 and 1991 elections were fought on the same boundaries and it is likely that the current Dig1t1zeo by Google Origi�al rrom UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 136 State and Politics in India TABLE 3.3 Size and Representation of States in the Lok Sabha � :.l � � s: l 2 3 4 s 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 IS 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 ., 27 28 29 30 ii ;� 79,454,881 50,453,647 48,632,193 41,392,460 West Bengal 42,617,973 Andhra Pradesh 37,708,721 Madhya Pradesh 39,917,777 Tamil Nadu 28,839,296 lumataka 24,882,508 Gujarat 26,513,502 Rajasthan 19,804,564 Orissa 19,657,976 Kerala 11,873,952 Assam 97,258,97 Haryana 60,731,56 Delhi Himachal Pradesh 30,761,82 15,610,85 Tripura 201,704 Sikkim 12,321,49 Manipur Goa 754,319 519,315 Arunachal Pradesh 942,513 Meghalaya 57,892 Daman & Diu 31,665 Lakshadweep 593,305 Pondicherry Dadra & Nagar 75,009 Haveli Nagaland 814,836 Mizoram 414,412 372,792 Chandigarh A& N Islands 169.120 Unar Pradesh Bihar Maharashtra 't- 3i � �� ! � .. J:�� 15.9 10.l 9.8 8.3 8.6 7.6 8.0 5.8 5.0 5.3 4.0 3.9 2.4 2.0 1.2 0.6 0.3 neg 0.2 0.2 0.1 0.2 neg neg 0.1 neg 0.2 0.1 0.1 neg 't- � .. �...,. � � -E v., -'( .,. ...E - ��� ij� �C;j 85 54 48 42 42 c..;t � ...;: " 40 39 28 26 25 21 20 14 10 7 4 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 I I I I I 1 1 "" � 16.2 10.3 9.1 8.0 8.0 7.6 7.4 5.3 5.0 4.8 4.0 3.8 2.7 1.9 1.3 0.8 0.4 0.4 0.4 0.4 0.4 0.4 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 0.2 Nott: Jamrnu & Kashmir, 6 scats and Punjab, 13 scats, arc not included a s elections were not held there in 1991. D1g1tizeo by Google ---- Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutions 137 TABLE 3.4 Average Electorate Size Per Constituency in 1991 l� ll :::Sa� J � !:? :.i � � 1 Rajasthan 2 Kamaaka 3 Tamil Nadu 4 Andhn Pradesh 5 Maharashtra 6 West Bengal 7 Kerala 8 Haryana 9 Gujarat 10 Orissa 1 1 Madhya Pndesh J2 Uttar Pndesh 13 Bihar 14 Delhi 15 Assam 16 Nagaland 17 Tripura 18 Himac;:hal Pndesh 19 Manipur 20 Pondicherry 21 Meghal aya 22 Mizoram 23 Goa 24 Chandigarh 25 Arunachal Pndesh 26 A & Nislands 27 Sikkim 28 Dadn & Nagar Haveli 29 Daman & Diu 30 Lakshadweep All India Nou: t. �� f I � .. � i! :.i � !:? t. t 26,513,502 28,839,296 39,917,777 42,617,973 48,631,193 41,392,460 19,657,976. 9,725,897 24,882,508 19,804,564 37,708,721 79,454,881 50,453,647 6,073,156 11,873,952 814,836 1,561,085 3,076,182 1,232,149 593,305 942,513 414,412 754,319 372,792 519,315 169,120 201,704 25 28 39 42 48 42 20 10 26 21 40 85 54 7 14 1 2 4 2 1 2 1 1 I 2 1 1 1,060,540 1,029,975 1,023,533 1,014,714 1,013,150 985,553 982,899 972,590 957,020 943,074 942,718 934,763 934,327 867,594 848,139 814,836 780,543 769,046 616,075 593,305 471,257 414,412 377,160 372,792 259,658 169,120 201,704 75,009 57,892 31,665 1 1 1 75,009 57,892 31,665 498.363.801 525 94£264 flti �.. � 0 ·1 � oJa 11.72 8.50 7.82 6.89 6.73 3.82 3.54 2.46 0.82 -0.65 -0.69 -1.53 -1.57 -8.60 -10.65 -14.16 -17.77 -18.99 -35.10 -37.50 -50.36 -56.34 --00.27 -60.73 -72.65 -82.18 -89.38 -92.10 -93.90 -96.66 Jammu & Kashmir, 6 seats and Punjab, 13 seats arc not included as no elections were held there in 1991. Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 138 Statt and Politics in India TABLE 3.5 Major Changes in the Constituency Map Between Successive General Elections �� ·af ;s ·� �i 3<3 't;, s -� �ti3 � � 't;, 401 1952 � ...,, ti t...,, � c:.:: � ...,, ti t...,, .. c:.:: ...t! "' .. ��u ti� � I,.. � t .. c,, ..e,N ti� i 72 26 1957 403• 76 31 1962 494b 76 31 1967 520 77 37 1971 518c 76 37 1977 542 78 38 1980 1984 198\? 542d 542 543• 79 78 78 40 41 41 1991 543 78 41 Notes: 3 b C d e 't;, .. � bO � la: �J c,,u Delimitation under President First Delimitation Commission Two-member Constituencies Abolition Act (1961) Second Delimitation Commission (1963) Punjab Reorganization Act (1966) Third Delimitation Commission (1973) Goa, Daman and Diu Reorganization Act The one triple-member constituency that existed in 1952 was abolished and the number of double-member constituencies was increased to ninety-one The ninety-one double-member constituencies were divided. The representation of Himachal Pradesh was cut from six scats to four on becoming a state. In 1980, elections were not held in 13 constituencies (I2 in Assam and I in Meghalaya) where there were no c:2ndidates. So there were never more than 529 me1nbers in the 1980-4 Lok Sabha. On 30 May 1989, Goa became � state ,vith two Lok Sabha seats while Daman and Diu remained a union territory with one Lok Sabha seat Prior to that Goa, Daman and Diu were one union territory with two Lok Sabha seats. D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The lnstitutiMIS I39 constituency boundaries will not b e changed this century. In 1987, the Chief Election Commissioner did urge the Government of India to authori:ze an immediate redrawing of constituency boun­ daries within states, without changing the statewise allocation of seats in the Houses. In 1990 a bill to give effect to this was brought before Parliament but the V.P. Singh government fell before it could be enacted. Another bill was placed before a Lok Sabha committee in 1993 but the prospect of action seems remote. In addition to changes brought about by the four Delimitation Commissions, the constituency map of the country has changed several times a s a result of modifications of the Delimitation Order which Parliament has approved on other occasions (fable 3.5). Such changes were introduced, for example, after the Bombay Reorganization Act, 1960, .which bifurcated Bombay into Maha­ rashtra and Gujarat. Another important alteration was brought about by the Two-Member Constituencies Abolition Act in 1961. Multiple-member seats had led to the creation of extraordinarily large constituencies, high electioneering costs and the absence of 70 63.9 60 oi 50 i:: � .5 40 '° -:I"'30 ..c: u ., a, C: •• � 27.5 20 10 1.2 1.7 2.3 2.5 1.0 BELOW250 500 750 1,000 1250 1,500 250 Average 95o 1500 CONSTITUENCY SIZE 1INTHOUSAND> Figure 3.4 UntfWI Siu efCon.rtitutncits in 1991 Dlgltlzedby Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 140 State and Politics in India �r TABLE 3.6 Variations in Electorate Size :.:; � ..'.3 d � lf l "fl c,,d � � r: t 1952 4,19,186 68,130 Bilaspur SM Bhilwara 3,50,437 1952 8,04,512 DM S urguja-Rajgarh Mandi-Mahasu 1,63,252 1957 5,05,891 OuterManipur SM Guntur 3,20,908 1957 9,26,313 DM S itapur Mahasu 1962 7,64,016 1,60,883 Bombay Mahasu City North 14,505 1967 6,44,638 Bombay L,M&A North.East Islands 14,977 1971 8,58,936 Bomba� L,M&A North- ast Islands 19,471 1977 8,60,316 Madras Central Lakshadweep 1980 9,16,054 20,117 Bombai Lakshadweep Nonh- ast 1984 10,82,419 Bomba � North- ast 1989 15,74,973 Outer Delhi 1991 17,44,592 Thane 21,964 Lakshadweep �:s. � ;:, • � � 1 :§ s Qe Cl) _ 1;, ... .e .i �-a�! 3,56,477 55,197 0.155 7,12,555 67,554 0.095 3,87,501 46,727 0.121 8,13,513 54,672 0.067 4,40,677 52,161 0.118 4,'78,853 79,741 0.166 5,29,140 84,759 0.160 5,92,119 97,563 0.165 6,56,071 1,08,665 0.166 7,38,225 1,25,373 0.174 30,069 9,43,413 1,71,650 0.182 Lakshadweep 31,665 9,56,552 1,75,542 0.184 Lakshadweee Notes:, SM • single-member and DM • double-member constituencies. Th� sWldard deviation measures the atent that the size of constituencies diverge from the mean size by using the formula: .../!.(r;- .r)2 /(n - 1) "."here r is the constituency size. However, even if the dispersion remains the same, the st:tndard deviation would tend to increase when the mean constituency size increases over time. Consequently, the standard deviation is divided by the mean to give a measure called the 'coefficient of variation' which provides a more accurate comparison across time. D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm --IJNIVERSI� OF-�ICJ-!IGA� -" · . . - The Institutions 141 a close relationship between the electorate and the legislators. AH multi-member constituencies ceased to exist from 1962. The differences in the size of constituencies in India have been significant and have increased over time, (fable 3.6). The co­ efficient of variation rose from 0.118 in 1962 to 0.184 in 1991. Figure 3.4 shows the unequal size of constituencies in 1991. The principle of equality of suffrage has never been fully met in the drawing and redrawing of boundaries. Whether this has benefited the ruling party (or any other party) and led to un­ fairness in the relation of seats to votes can be tested by analysing the distribution of party support over large, medium and small constituencies. The overall figures suggest that no party has gained any significant advantage by the unevenness of constituen­ cy size. As Table 3.7 shows, the electorate size in Congress and non-Congress seats has been remarkably similar - and any small· advantage has shifted to and fro. TABLE3.7 Party Differences in Electorate Size FJection Average FJectorate Year in Congress Seats 1991 1989 1984 1980 9,41,464 9,80,814 7,30,514 6,70,955 Average Difference Percentage FJectorate in in Electorate Difference Non-Congress Size fr<»n 50-50 Seats 9,68,631 9,45,492 7,65,444 6,73,599 I I I 27,167 35,322 34,930 2,644 0 Constituency delimitation has the potential to affect the elec­ toral outcome in a major way in any democracy that uses the first-past-the-post system. However, in India there appear to be no grounds for misgivings on this account so far. The manner in which delimitation can have a major effect on electoral outcomes can be simply illustrated (Figure 3.5). Let us suppose that a town containing four equal-sized wards or localities has to be divided into two constituencies and that there are two parties in the town, Reds with 55 per cent and Blues with 45 per cent. If the town is divided into two constituencies on a North­ South basis (i.e. A+B and C+D) each party gets one seat (Red gets the North with 150 voters and Blue wins the South with 130 Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 142 State and Politics in India B A RED 80 RED 70 RED 30 RED 40 BLUE 70 BLUE 60 Figure ;,j Tbe lmpilCt ofDr1111Jing Bo11ndaritr on the Results voters). But if it is divided on an East-West basis (i.e. A+C and B+D), Reds get both the seats (Reds win 110 votes in the West and 110 votes in the East). Partisan drawing of constituencies to favour a particular party is what has come to be known as 'gerrymandering'. The term was coined in the 1820s after Governor Elbridge Gerry of Mas­ sachusetts drew a constituency specially designed to secure the election of an adherent. A critic remarked that it looked like a salamander on the map. 'No', was the reply, 'call it a Gerrymander'. In India there have been surprisingly few allegations of ger­ rymandering. It was alleged that the second Delimitation Com­ mission favoured the Congress party in Punjab at the expense of the Akali Dal. Similarly, it was claimed that the first Commission created a new double-member constituency in Orissa to defeat a leader who had defected from the Congress to the Swatantra party. There have not been any legal challenges to the Commission's Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutums 143 proposals since the Kothari case in 1967 when the Supreme Court refused to interfere with any of the Commission's orders on the ground that Article 329 of the Constitution precludes any judicial interference in the delimitation of constituencies. One special feature of the Indian electoral system relates to the reservation of seats in the Lok Sabha for scheduled castes and scheduled tribes. Article 330(2) provides that a number of seats proportionate to their numbers in the population should be re­ served for scheduled castes (SC) and scheduled tribes (SI). These seats should be allocated to states in due proportion to the number of SCs and STs within its borders. In 1952 and 1957, where scheduled castes or scheduled tribes constituted more than 50 per cent of the population in a constituency, it was automatically categorized as SC or ST. In other cases a double-member seat was created. In these double-member constituencies everyone had two votes and the SC (or Sl) candidate who got most votes would be elected, even if he did not come first or second. After double­ member constituencies were abolished in l 961, the Delimitation Commission tried to draw boundaries so that they could allot SC and ST seats in areas where these categories were particularly concentrated.7 There were 78 SC and 41 ST seats in the 1991 general elections. Constituencies lie at the roots of Westminster democracy. The first House of Commons in 1295 started with citizens from each constituency in England being summoned to send members to represent it in London. To this day MPs, not just in Britain but in every country that has followed its pattern, regard themselves as spokesmen for their particular defmed piece of territory. Th ey develop a special attachment to it Obviously they hope to con­ solidate support with a view to securing re-election, but they also see their constituency as pan of their own ego, their sense of identity as 'the member for X'. Constituencies may be the arith­ metic unit at the centre of election analysis, the cells within which the statistics of votes are assembled. But we must always remain aware that there exists that sensitive human reality behind the figures, the relationship between elector and elected. 7 In one case in north Bengal, there was a triple-member constituency with one guaranteed SC seat and one guaranteed ST seat. This was abolished before the 1957 election. Dig1t1zeo by Google Origi�al rrom UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 144 State and Politics in India Parties and Symbols Parties are at the centre of Indian politics, as they are in all major democracies. The choices facing the voters are simplified by the fact that politicians find it necessary to ally with each other under party labels. Opinion polls in India have repeatedly shown that people generally vote more for the party than for the candidate. But parties vary greatly in their support base and in their per­ manence. They may be rooted in religion, or region, or caste, or in specific issues, or in general ideologies, or based on leadership of a charismatic individual. Parties may also be solid, lasting as­ sociations, creating deep loyalties that continue from generation to generation, or they may be ephemeral groupings that endure only for a year or two before they split or amalga mate or simply disappear. India has experience of every type of party. In India, as in most but not all democracies, parties have to be formally registered with a central body. The Election Commission allots symbols to parties so that illiterate voters can identify them in the secrecy of the booth. Before Independence, different types of voting methods were used in different parts of the country for the limited elections that took place. These included the marking system (with polling staff assisting voters to mark the ballot paper - which involved an obvious loss of secrecy) and the 'colour box system' (where a distinctive coloured box was allotted to each candidate and the voter had to cast his vote in the box belonging to his candidate). After surveying all the different voting proce­ dures, the Indian Franchise Committee of 1931 advocated the use of either the colour box system or the symbol system. For the first general elections in 1952, the Election Commission chose the balloting system, a compromise between the colour box and the symbol systems. Each candidate was allotted one symbol from a list approved and published by the Commission after taking into account the preferences of the candidate. Each polling station had as many ballot boxes as the number of candidates in the constituency with the symbols of the candidates pasted outside the ballot boxes. As symbols were granted constituency-wise, a p o s ­ sible confusion was that the same symbol could be allotted to candidates of different parties in different constituencies. Dif­ ferent ballot boxes also endangered the secrecy of the ballot. It was only in the third general election in 1962 that multiple ballot Dlgltlzedby Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The lnrtitutions 145 boxes were replaced with just one box and the more secret 'mark­ ing system' now used was introduced. Each ballot paper has both the name and the symbol=Gf each candidate. Voters express their choice by marking the ballot paper in the appropriate space. In 1982, the first experiment was made with electronic voting machines at some polling stations in the Parur assembly con­ stituency in Kerala. These ingenious battery-operated devices were designed in India and were the first in the world to be used in such simple first-past-the-post elections. They n1erely required the voter to press a button on the voting machine marked with a candidate's name and the allotted symbol. The design looked very similar to a ballot paper with buttons where crosses are normally marked. These machines were used successfully in ten further contests. But in the meantime the Parur election had been chal­ lenged because of the use of voting machines. On 5 March 1984 the Supreme Court disallowed the voting machines on the grounds that the expression 'votes shall be given by ballots', used in Section 59 of the Representation of the People Act (1951), does not cover the recording of votes by voting machines. The Election Com­ mission recommended that the Act should be amended and sub­ sequently the Law Minister said that this would be done in time for the ninth general election. However, this did not happen. In 1990 a government committee, charged with looking at the ethical and practical problems involved, reported favourably on the pro1>9sa1. The Act has now been amended enabling the Election C'..ommission to use the machines. But the batteries have gone dead ahd will have to be manufactured again. Therefore it is unlikely that electronic voting machines will be used for the 1996 Lok fiabha elections. For the first general election, the Commission recognized 14 'national parties' and 60 'state parties' on the basis of the claims presented by various political groups. No objective criterion such as performance in the last election was available to be used. Each national party had a symbol reserved exclusively for its candidates throughout India, while each state party had a symbol reserved for i� candidates in the state. All other candidates were supposed to choose a symbol from the list of 'free' symbols. After the first general election the four parties that received more than 3 per cent of the nationwide Lok Sabha vote were recognized as 'na­ tional parties'; twelve parties won over 3 per cent of the vote in D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 146 State and Politics in India the state Vidhan Sabha elections and these were recognized as 'state parties'. After the second general election in 1957, the concept of a 'national party' was abandoned (it was later reintroduced at the time of the 1971 election). Recognition of a party was granted on a state-by-state basis to parties which had polled 3 per cent of the vote both in the Lok Sabha contests in the state as well as in the Vidhan Sabha election. However, for the fourth general election in 1967, the Election Commission, while continuing with the procedure of granting recognition on a state-by-state basis, discarded the practice of making it necessary to win 3 per cent of the vote in both the Lok Sabha and Vidhan Sabha elections. The new criterion was the percentage of votes either in the preceding Lok Sabha or in the preceding Vidhan Sabha elections. The cut-off point for recognition was raised from 3 per cent to 4 per cent of the votes. Moreover, in order to discourage the tendency of parties to field candidates indiscriminately merely to boost the party's total votes, any votes cast for candidates who forfeited their deposits were to be disregarded in the calculation. Shortly after the fourth general election in 1967, the Election Commission issued the Election Symbols (Reservation and Al­ loonent) Order, 1968, which introduced the present system under which associations and bodies must register with the Commission as political parties. A registered political party is not automatically 'recognized'. Recognition is granted to a party (again on a state­ by-state basis) on the basis of one of two criteria: either (i) its exist�nce and participation in political activity for a period of five years or (ii) its securing at least 4 per cent of the votes cast in the state for Lok Sabha or Vidhan Sabha elections (after excluding the votes polled by the party's candidates who forfeited their deposits). The votes polled by a member of the Lok Sabha or Vidhan Sabha who joined a party after the election is not counted for the purpose of calculating the threshold required for recognition. From the second general election onwards, the procedure for judging whether a candidate belonged to a political party involved a declaration by the candidate as well as endorsement by party functionaries. The 'Symbols Order' also contained procedures for resolving disputes when recognized parties split into rival sections or when two or more political parties amalgamated. Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutions 147 Any candidate belonging to a party that is not 'recognized' is officially recorded as an Independent. For example, candidates of the Telugu Desam, which emerged from nowhere to full power in Andhra Pradesh at its first election in 1983, were initially classified as Independents. This kind of problem often makes it difficult to compare the performance of a party over time. With painstaking research, many of the Independent candidates in earlier elections could be reclassified as nominees of unrecognized parties so that this anomaly in election records could be com­ pletely removed. No party in India has survived the last forty years without splits or amalgamations. In the early l 950s, for example, the Provincial Zamindara League (Punjab) merged with the Kirshikar Lok party. The Republican Party of India and the Akali Dal each split. The Socialist party, first divided into the Praja Socialist party and the All India Socialist party and then came together in 1964 to form the Samyukta Socialist party only to break up once again within a year into the Samyulcta Socialist party and the Praja Socialist party. It was not until after the fifth general election in 1971 that the two parties merged once again to form the Socialist Party of India. From the mid:. 1960s onwards, party splits and amalgamations became more frequent. In 1964, a substantial section broke away from the Communist Party of India to give birth to a new party called the Communist Party of India (Marxist) which has now emerged as the dominant faction. The Swatantra party, which was formed in 1961, took into its fold the Janata party of Bihar, the Indian Democratic Congress of Madras and the United Inde­ pendent Front of Madhya Pradesh. The Indian National Congress faced its first serious split (in the post-Independence period) in 1969. The party divided into two groups, one led by S. Nijalingappa and the other led by C. Subramaniam (later by Jagjivan Ram); these constituted the anti­ Mrs Gandhi and pro-Mrs Gandhi groups respectively. The Elec­ tion Commission recognized both as national parties and allotted them separate symbols (charkha-being-plied-by-a-woman and a calf-and-cow). The original Congress symbol was frozen. The name was allotted to the pro-Mrs Gandhi, Jagjivan Ram group. The Commission's decision that the party presided over by Jag­ jivan Ram should be recognized as the Indian National Congress D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 148 State and Politia in India was challenged, but the Supreme Coun upheld the Commission's ruling and the other Congress faction came to be known as the Indian National Congress (Organization). In an unprecedented step just before the I977 election, four national parties (the Indian National Congress [Organization], Bharatiya Lok Dal, BharatiyaJan Sangh and the Socialist party) merged informally to form the Janata party. These parties also had an electoral understanding with the Communist Party of India (Marxist). This meant that for the first time the opposition to the Congress party was almost wholly united except for the Communist Party of India, which supported the Congress. Since the Janata party was not formed by a deJure merger, the Election Commission could not grant legal recognition to the new party. Consequently, it fought throughout India (except for Tamil Nadu and Pondicherry) under the symbol ploughman-within-wheel (chakra-haldhar) which was acrually the symbol of one of its constiruent parties, the Bharatiya Lok Dal. In Tamil Nadu and Pondicherry, where the Bharatiya Lok Dal did not have any organization, the Janata party contested under the symbol of a charkha of the Indian National Congress (Organization). For this reason the tables - both in the official Election Commission Reports and in this Chapter - refer to theJanata party in 1977 as the BLD, the official name under which it contested the TABLE 3.8 Nwnber of Recognized Parties in the General Elections Election Year 1952 1957• 1962• 1967 1971 1977 1980 1984 1989 1991 • Total 74 16 16 21 25 23 25 26 28 36 National Parties 14 4 State Parties 60 12 16 21 17 18 19 19 20 27 8 5 6 7 8 9 There were no national parties in 1962 and 1967 as parties were given recognition only on a st:tte-by-state basis. Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The lnstitutionr 149 election. The Janata party was only recognized as a national party after the 1977 election and the symbol of the chakra-haldhar was then reserved for it. Indian democracy was never so close to a two-party system as · it was during the 1977 election. However, the next few years saw a complete change. Soon after its defeat, the Indian National Congress split into two groups - one led by Indira Gandhi and the other by K. Brahamananda Reddy (and later by Devraj Urs). After a protracted struggle between the two groups, the Commis­ sion decided to freeze the earlier Congress symbol of the calf-and­ cow, and allot two different symbols to the two groups. Both were declared national parties. The symbol of the 'hand' was given to the Indian National Congress-I and the 'charkha' to the Indian National Congress-U. (The 'I' and 'U' stood for the names of the leaders of each of the parties: Indira Gandhi and Devraj Urs). Figure 3.6 records the splits and other changes in the Congress party since 1952. TheJanata party also went through major convulsions. By July 1979, it split into two groups, one led by Chandrashekhar and the other by Charan Singh and Raj Narain. The Election Commission continued to recognize the Chandrashekhar group as the Janata party with the chakra-haldhar symbol. The other faction was recognized as a national party with the nameJanata Party (S), (the 'S' in this case stood for 'secular') and the symbol of a farmer­ ploughing-the-field was allotted to it. This party, however, soon became popularly known as the Lok Dal. Consequently there were six national parties on the eve of the seventh Lok Sabha elections in 1980 - the two Congress parties, the two Janata parties and the two Communist parties - the CPI and CPl(M). After die Congress victory in 1980, the disintegration of the Janata party continued. The two Janata parties split further. The Janata party divided into theJanata party led by Chandrashekhar and the Bharatiya Janata party led by Atal Bihari Vajpayee. The Bharatiya Janata party was essentially the same as the old Jana Sangh. Although the Jana Sangh had merged with the Janata party in 1977, it had always maintained a separate identity and the break in 1980 was a relatively painless process. The old symbols - the umbrella and the lotus (earlier with the Jana Sangh) - were allotted to the two groups. Similarly, the Janata party (S) broke into two groups -Janata party (S)-Raj Narain Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 150 Stlltt and Politics in India Elections 1952 1957 . 1962 11117 INC Indian National Congrwu . � ' i INC 1971 (11 a 25Janl llldl1n �lllllonal CGng,111 INC(O) lndl1n Nlh.-.1 CongNN (0fganlullon) � 1971 (Mardi) . 19n • 1978 •., (Mardi) INC(O) ..,._ - - (8LD) o,,1tl>ol oacopl In T- - t,e Jlinela ca1 1a•11C1 - INC(O) o,,1tl>ol &, .I. INC lndl1n Nllb'lal Congl9• (2 Feb) lrd1n � CongNN � 1 � lndllr, 1979 (� New) d 1980 .I. INC (23 July) lndlr'llllonllConglwt 1981 1984 1989 1991 r.!�J"b..(Un) lndlln Congi111 (Socllllt) @) � . T-ards 1998 -i N.D."=rI,i...� • - : 0.0,..., IO lonMI Ellclcl1 � ._.uon ' Figurt J.6 Splits in tbt Congnss Ptmy sinct 1952 Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 11,e lnstitutio,u 151 ' � ,� BlD � soc INC(O) BJ& I ' � I 19" I JANATA PARTY • • JANATA PARTY CHARANSIGi . 19'(1 , • JANAYA .-.......1 JANATA PARTY HlOWI aiARANSINGH 1984 . I JANATA PARTY CHANDAA SHEIOWI A'UTA PARTY RAJ � I I • -I I' • BJP VAJPAYEE LOI( DAL QWW4 SN3H • lf:r� 1989 LOI( DAL (I) ,.. 11M. • JMATA V.P. SIG! � C..... 1991 - I .IMATA 11M. VJ. SINGH UIIAJWADI PARTY c:=� IWVAM �� Towdl 111118 .J ...I I SAIWIADI JAIIATA IWITY OMlMHIOWI ' • Fig,,rr J. 7 Tbt ]tm11t11 Ptmy 1111d BJP sirtct I 977 Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 152 State and Politu:s in India andJanata Party ($)-Charan Singh. Their symbol farmer-plough­ ing-the-field was froun and two new symbols, bicycle and woman respectively were allotted to the two parties. However, after Raj Narain's death, the scene changed again and Charan Singh led the Lok Dal during the 1984 elections. The disintegration of the Janata party was virtually complete by 1984 when its components contested as four separate national parties: Indian Congress (Socialist), Bharatiya Janata party, Lok Dal and the Janata party. In addition some of the breakaway groups contested as recognized state parties. The Congress faced a disunited opposition everywhere except in a few states either where strong state parties had emerged (as in Andhra Pradesh where N.T. �ama Rao's Telugu Desam swept the polls) or where the opposition had organized itself into a local coalition (as in Kerala). An important development that has had a major impact on the nature of party politics in India was the Act commonly referred to as the 'Anti-Defection Act!. (The official title was The Con­ stitution [Fifty-second Amendment] Act, 1985). The aim of the Act is to stop members who are elected as representatives of one party 'crossing the floor' to join another party after the election. Defections had become so frequent that it tended to undermine the party system, particularly since the reason for changing parties was often not related to ideological or policy differences but took place in response to other inducements. By preventing defections from the Congress, the Act was also intended to provide greater security to Prime Minister Rajiv Gandhi and to help him to hold on to his 400 elected MPs. The Act was to prove of major importance in the party realignments of 1990 and 1991. The Anti-Defection Act specifies that if a member of any house (Parliament or legislative assembly) votes or abstains from voting, contrary to the direction issued by the political party to which he belongs, he shall be disqualified from being a member of that house. However, if one-third or more of the members of a party break away, the Act recognizes this as a 'split' in the party and does not disqualify the members of the breakaway faction. It also recognizes the 'merger' of parties where not less than two-thirds of the members of a party have agreed to the merger. Finally, the Act states that no court shall have any jurisdiction over any matter connected with the disqualification of a member. The D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutions 153 decision is entirely the responsibility of the Speaker of the house and only technical issues can be taken to court. The Anti-Defection Act, which was brought in by Rajiv Gandhi only fifteen weeks after coming to power, played a significant role in maintaining the stability of his government. During his five­ year rule, although there was considerable dissent within the party, i t never reached a point where one-third of the MPs could get together to cause a split. Before the Anti-Defection Act, individual MPs could leave a party without being disqualified. What would stan as a trickle of defections would sometimes end up in a flood; this is now severely curtailed. Nevertheless, the Rajiv Gandhi government was shaken by a major loss when a senior leader, the popular Finance Minister, V .P. Singh, resigned.8 In the run-up to the 1989 elections, V.P. Singh played a major role in uniting opposition parties to fight the Congress. He first persuaded several parties, the}anata party, Lok Dal (A), Lok Dal (B) and others to merge under the label Janata Dal. The next step was the formation of a National Front against the Congress. Parties in the National Front, the Janata party, DMK, CPI, CPI(M), Congress (S), AGP and other small parties retained their identity but agreed on a common platform to defeat the Congress. In the final process of opposition unity, the National Front came to an agreement with the BJP on sharing seats. The aim was to ensure that every constituency had only one opposition candidate facing the Congress. In some states the agreement was total (e.g. Rajasthan, Gujarat); in many states only partial agreement could be achieved (Madhya Pradesh, Orissa) and in some states there was virtually no agreement (e.g. Maharashtra, Uttar Pradesh). .Despite the Congress winning 39.5 per cent of the vote in the 1989 general elections, it lost heavily in terms of seats. Although it remained the largest single party, the number of seats it won fell by more than half, from 415 in 1984 to 197 in 1989. This was seen as an overwhelming mandate for a change and all the opposi­ tion parties agreed to get together to form a government. V.P. Singh was sworn in as Prime Minister on 2 December 1989, leading the Janata Dal which had won only 143 seats. The CPI, • 8 He resigned as Defence Minister after his portfolio was changed i nJanuary 1988. D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 154 Stm nJ Politics ;,, lndill CPl(M) and the BJP agreed to support the government 'from the outside'. This meant they would not form part of a coalition government but would vote with the Janata Dal to ensure a maj­ ority in theLok Sabha. Once again the Anti-Defection As:t played a role in keeping the Janata Dal together after serious inner party differences began to emerge. It was eventually the BJP withdrawing support, rather than a split in theJanata Dal, that brought the V.P. Singh govern­ ment down on 7 November 1990. However, immediately after the collapse of the government, the Janata Dal split. A group led by Chandrashekhar and backed by the former deputy Prime Min­ ister Devi Lal gathered enough support from MPs to cross the one-third barrier and be recognized by the Anti-Defection Act as a separate party calledJanata Dal (Secular). The JD(S) was supported 'from the outside' by the Congress and formed the new government with Chandrashekhar sworn in as Prime Minister on 10 November 1990. However, the Speaker later disqualified eight MPs who had left the Janata Dal to join the JD(S). After the Speaker's ruling, the party position on 11 January 1991 is listed in Table 3.9. TABLE 3.9 Party Position inLok Sabha on 11 January 1991 Congress-I Janata Dal (incl. 2 associates) BJP Janata Dal (S) CPl(M) CPI ADMK Abli Dal RSP Forward Bloc National Conference BSP ]MM Shiv Sena Dlgltlzeo by Google 195 77 86 54 33 12 11 4 4 3 3 3 3 3 TDP Muslim League IPF MGP MCC Congress (S) Muslim Majlis KCM SSP ABHM GNLF Independents Vac:ancics 2 2 l l 1 1 l l 1 1 1 10 29 543 Total Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutions 155 Clearly, the survival of the JD(S) and of Prime Minister Chandrashekhar depended on the fragile support provided by the Congress. This did not last long. The Congress withdrew its support and India's tenth general elections followed. The Parlia­ ment that finally emerged (after Punjab elections in February 1992) had a different but equally complex pattern. Elections in India are normally spread over two or three days. This is partly to avoid special holidays which always occur in. one state or another but it is also to allow the Election Commission to redeploy its pPll-monitoring facilities. In 1991 the polls were scheduled for 20, 23 and 26 May. But a few hours after he himself had voted in Delhi on 20 May, Rajiv Gandhi was assassinated. The polls due on 23 May and 26 May were postponed to 12 June and 15 June. It is a sad irony of 1991 that the Congress fared measurab­ ly better in the sympathy wave following their leader's death. In the votes cast on 20 May, there was a 5.7 per cent swing away from Congress. In the votes cast in June, there was a 1.6 per cent swing in favour of the Congress party. This history of party splits and mergers shows how difficult it is to assess the evolution of support for a party over time. For example what was the increase in the Congress party's popularity between the fourth and fifth general elections in 1967 and 1971? This question is not easy to answer, since there were two Congress parties in 1971, the 'Requisitionists' and the 'Organization.'9 Similar problems arise with the Socialists, with the Communists, and above all with the constituents of the Janata party after 1977. Votes and Seats India's first-past-the-post syste.m of voting has been tested time and again in Britain and many other democracies based on the Westminster system, such as Canada, New Zealand and Jamaica. It is based on contests between individual candidates in single­ member constituencies; victory goes to the contestant who gets more votes than any other. When there are several candidates, a The pro-Mrs Gandhi, Indian National Congress faction led first by C. Subramaniam and later byJagjivan Ram has been known in popular parlance by various names such as Congress 0), Congress (R), etc. The Election Commission recognized this party simply as the Indian National Congress. 9 D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 156 State and Politics in India seat can be won on remarkably small percentages. For example, in 1991 the Congress won the Rae Bareli seat in Uttar Pradesh with only 23 per cent of the vote.10 Under this system, there is no simple or uniform relation be­ tween the proportion of votes a party wins nationally and the proportion of seats it secures in the Lok Sabha. It would, indeed, be possible for a party with support spread evenly across the country to win 100 per cent of the seats with a great deal less than half the votes, provided there were several other parties splitting the rest of the votes. Even if there were only two parties fighting, it would be possible to win all the seats with only a little over half the votes. The voting system is one which, almost invariably, exaggerates a small lead in votes into a much larger lead in seats. There has been a tendency, therefore, to despair about predict­ ing party strength in the Lok Sabha. The relationship between seats and votes has often been portrayed as largely random. That used to be the general attitude in Britain, 'Canada and Australia. Over time, in each of these countries formulae have been devel­ oped which reveal a relatively predictable pattern in the system's tendency to produce an exaggerated majority for the winning party. There is, however, no single relationship that holds good for all first-pas t -the-post systems -or even for one country at all points in time. One neat general formula that has long attracted attention is the 'Cube Law'. This suggests that, in a first-past-the-post system, majorities will normally be exaggerated by a law of cubic propor­ tion. In other words, if votes are divided in the ratio A : B, seats will be divided in the ratio A3 : B3• For many years this seeme� to match what was happening in British elections. However, in the 10 Rae Bareli, Uttar Pradesh, 1991 Ctmdidate Sheila Kaul (W) Ashok Kumar Singh Ram Sh.inkar Verma Yashpal Kapoor Sudarshan Ram Others {19� Dlgltlzeo by Google Party Cong JD BJP SJP BSP Aarllll Vote 1,02,331 98,414 91,850 75,128 36,018 40!050 443 791 Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN % Vote 23. 1 22.2 20.7 16.9 8.1 9.0 100.0. The Institutions 157 last two decades, the formula has !=eased to fit the facts. Those who want to predict the seat outcome .fmd that it is far safer simply to extrapolate from the actual distribution of votes in each con­ stituency in the most recent election.1 1 The Cube Law, works best in a two-party situation. The 1977 Lok Sabha elections showed that it is applicable to· the Indian system too, when it is close to a two-party situation. The Janata party secured 41.3 per cent of the votes in 1977 and the Congress got 34.5 per cent According to the Cube Law the division of seats between the parties should have been 283 to Janata party and 164 to the Congress. The actual division of seats was 295 to 152, fairly close to the Cube Law prediction. The Congress party has never won more than 48.1 per cent of the total votes polled in any of India's ten general elections. Yet it has formed the government in eight of these ten elections, six times with a substantial majority (see Table 3.10). In fact, 60 per cent of all constituency contests for the Lok Sabha have resulted in Congress victories although the party has on average secured only 42 per cent of the vote. The large, stable majorities which have kept the Congress in power for all but four years since Independence are larg�ly due to the splintering of the anti-Congress vote. Over the last ten elections, and especially more recently, the number of candidates contesting elections has risen dramatically. While on average seven candidates have fought per constituency, in the last three elections this has gone up to thirteen (see Table 3.11). The number of parties fighting each election has also risen sharply. One reason why the number of candidates has increased is because serious contenders find that it is convenient to have an ever increasing number of friends with an official right to appoint observers at the polling stations and the count. When over 100 candidates stand in a single constituency (as it happened in East Delhi in 1991), it is plain that bulk of them are not deluded hopefuls, but just names put down for a purpose. One side effect of this plurality of contenders is that, if any of them dies during the campaign, the contest has to be countermanded. The extent to which Congress has benefited from the existence of many opposition parties is demonstrated by Table 3.12 which 11 See J. Curtice and M. Steed in D. Butler and D. Kavanagh (1987). Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN TABLE 3.10 Congress Votes and Seats 0 1n· "' 3 :l[ CJ J % votes % seats 1952 45.0 76.0 1957 47.8 77.0 1962 44.7 73.5 1967 40.8 55.0 El«tion Year 1971 1977 43.7 34.5 68.l 28.5 Average 1980 42.7 66.7 1984 48.l 76.7 1989 39.5 37.3 1991 36.5 44.5 42.3 60.3 � TABLE 3.11 Number of Candidates Per Constituency and Number of Parties in Each Election Average Ekction Year C z < m :» !i:?o :;;I ,g_ .,,,,. _3 n -Cl 0 i; Average �didates per consorucncy No. ofparties 1952 1957 1962 1967 1971 1977 1980 1984 1989 1991 3.9 74 3.2 16 4.0 29 4.6 24 5.4 53 4.5 62 8.6 36 10.2 37 11.6 118 16.7 144 7.3 60 :;: <) ::i: )> z 158 The lnstitutiuns I59 shows the number of seats that the Congress and the other parties have won for every 1 per cent of the vote. In most election years, for each percentage vote cast in its favour, Congress won more than twice the number of seats won by the opposition. TABLE 3.12 Number of Seats Won for Every I Per Cent of Votes Election Year .... t--, t--, °' °'.... t--, "' i °' °' °' .... °' .... .... .... °' .... °' .... °' .... °' .... °' .... °' .... � t--, � t--, 'C � CIQ .. � � � Congress 8.1 7.8 8.1 6.9 8,1 4.5 8.3 8.6 5.0 6.4 7.2 Other Parties 2.3 2.4 2.4 4.0 2.9 5.9 3.1 2.4 5.5 4.6 3.6 'Swing' is one of the standard instruments of electoral analysis. It is a simplified measure of the change in the strength of the dominant party or p;p-ties between one election and the next In what have been predominantly two-party systems of Britain and New Zealand, it has been defined as the average of the change in percentage margin between the two leading parties. 12 For example, if party A won the first election by a margin of 6 per cent and the second by two per cent, then the swing against it between the two elections is ((6%-2%)/2) .. (4%n) "' 2%. Of course, this 2 per cent swing is also exactly equal to the drop in percentage votes won W,A, which is in tum equal to the percentage gain in votes by B. 1 This direct relation between a change in a party's vote and the change in margin breaks down when there are more than two parties. Whether the swing is calculated from state or nationwide totals of votes, or from a single constituency, it offers a convenient ----------------------- For an exact dilCUSSion of British de6nitions of swings see M. Steed's Appendix in D. Buder and A. King (1965). 12 13 . El«tion Candidate A Candidate B Manzin of victo!l Dlgltlzeo by 1 53 47 6% Google 2 51 49 2% Cbtmge in % Swing Vou -2 +2 ,6-2)/2 • 4/2 • 2%. Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 160 State and Politics in India measure of a change in a party's popularity. The variations in swing in different parts of the country or different types of constituencies can provide revealing insights into the possible causes underlying voting trends. But the 'swing' concept is above all a tool for estimating the likely relationship between seats and votes. If there is uniform nationwide behaviour (i.e. every constituency has exactly the same swing), it is possible, knowing the swing in one seat, to calculate exactly the total number of seats a party would win. Applying the swing to the results of the last election it is possible to calculate how many constituencies would change hands. Nationwide be­ haviour will, of course, never be completely uniform. However, in most cases the regional or local deviations from uniformity the high swings and the low swings - tend to cancel each other out. In British and Australian elections over the last forty years, the results in terms of seats have been extraordinarily close to those that could have been predicted by assuming a nationwide uniform swing. This traditional concept of swing, however, as defined for two­ party systems, is not wholly appropriate in the multi-party situa­ tion in India. Nonetheless, the pre-eminence of the Congress party over the years does allow 'swing' to be redefined for the Indian situation. The simple Indian solution is to consider swing as the 'increase or decrease in the Congress percentage of the vote between one election and the next'. 14 On this basis swing can be used to explain the relation between seats and votes in India almost as neatly as the British definition has done in the United Kingdom. However, the multi-party Indian system has an additional com­ plication. The splitting of votes between opposition parties has been almost as important as the swing in influencing the final outcome of Indian elections. Since 1952 the Election Commission has recognized or registered more than 200 parties. The degree of opposition unity, or lack of it, has varied from election to election and has produced anomalous results. Table 3.13 shows there is no straightforward link between swings in votes and the margin of victory. 14 In the analysis of state elections the dominant or the most consistent party over the years may not be the Congress. In states like West Bengal for instance, it may be preferable to compute swing with reference of the CPI (M), or in recent years to use the Telugu Desam in Andhra Pradesh. Dg t r l l lzeo by Goggle ·--'- Original from - ___ jJt,JIVERSITY OF MICHIGA!!._ The Institutions 161 In every election except 1991, an increase in votes has been matched by an increase in seats and a decrease _by a decrease in seats. But as the last line in Table 3.13 shows, the relationship has been very variable. In 1991 it broke down completely. Congress lost votes and gained seats. The increased division of the opposi­ tion, discussed in the following pages, has allowed Congress to win extra seats over the years on a split non-Congress vote. For our analysis of elections over the years and for our inter­ pretation of opinion polls, we have developed a generalized meas­ ure of vote-splitting: the Index of Opposition Unity (IOU). This index is designed to isolate the split factor in Indian elections from the normal measure of change in party popularity: the swing factor. Using this index, changes in the margin of victory in any constituency can be broken down into two components: the 'swing' and the 'split'. Although this methodology can always be used in ex postf11t:to analysis, it can only be applied as a method of forecasting if the swing and split factors are reasonably homogeneous across the nation (or if their deviations can be reliably detected by opinion polls). How far swings and splits are homogeneous in India, with its heterogeneous electorate divided by caste, language and re­ ligion, is di�ed later in this chapter. The number of parties contesting an election, or the average number of candidates for each seat, provides a crude measure of the unity of the opposition. But if there are a number of minor parties or independent candidates in the field, each attracting a tiny fraction of the total vote, this can be a misleading indicator. An alternative way of judging the unity of the opposition is to use the sum of the percentages of the two leading parties as an indicator of how near the system is to a two-party situation. This offers a simple index of how close the two parties are to duopoliz­ ing voting support. But this measure fails on two counts: first, it is dependent on the percentage vote of the ruling party and, second, it says very little about the distribution of votes amongst the opposition parties. S'ome improvement on this measure of opposition unity can be achieved by extending it to cover the percentages of the top three or top four parties. Table 3.14 shows the figures for India's ten General Elections. But even this is not satisfactory. A measure of opposition unity, D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN TABLE 3.13 Congress: Votes to Seats Relationship 1952- 1957- 1962- 1967- 1971- 1977- 1980- 1984- 1989- All Eke7 7 7 9 91 71 62 80 4 "' ""' ;;; Q. CJ 0 � (v Averogt Eltaion Year 0 .a,.. Averogr 1962-89 tums Change in Congress % vote Change in Congress scats Change in number of seats per 1% swing in votes -3.1 2.8 7 -10 2.5 3.2 -3.9 -78 20.0 2.9 69 23.8 -9.2 -198 21.5 8.2 199 24.3 5.4 62 11.5 -8.6 -218 -3.0 35 24.5 n.a. 5.2 97 15.9 6.4 137 20.9 Average • average of absolute figures. TABLE 3.14 Sum of Percentage Votes of Largest Parties C z < m ;;o !cc!o �.§: o& .,, =r :;: _3 n ::c C> ,, z )> Averogr Eltaion Year Sumof% Votes of Top 2 parties Top 3 parties T0p4earpes 1952 1957 S6 61 65 S8 67 73 1962 ss 63 69 1967 1971 1977 1980 59 54 61 67 76 80 83 62 71 77 so 64 1984 ss 62 68 1989 57 69 7S 1991 57 68 75 S8 66 72 162 The Jnstitutitms 163 if it is to be realistic and compatible with a measure of swing, should possess three main properties: 1. It should reflect the keenness of the competition provided by the opposition by measuring its cohesion. 2. It should be such that any change in the index is easy to relate to or compare with a change in votes as well as a change in the margin of victory. 3. It should be simple to use at every level - constituency, region, and nation. The following Index of Opposition Unity (IOU) goes some way to achieve these three objectives: IOU = Vote of the largest oppositionparty 100 Sum of votes of all the opposition parties x This implies that, in a situation where there were three opposi­ tion parties with votes of 30 per cent, 20 per cent and 10 per cent, the IOU would be: 30 30 X 100= ro°X 100=50 30+lO+ lO If there is only one opposition party (i.e. if the opposition is fully united), th e IOU is clearly 100. Thus the IOU can vary between zero and 100; the higher it is, the greater the unity of the opposition. Table 3.15 shows that the level of opposition unity has been low, averaging only 72 over the ten elections. It reached a high of 9 0 in 1977 when the opposition came together to fight the Con­ gress after the Emergency, but it then disintegrated to its lowest point of 65 in 1980. This 25-point slump in the IOU was a major reason for the Congress landslide victory in 1980. In 1989 there was a widely held view that the opposition was very united; in fact, the IOU indicates that opposition unity ac­ tually was only 3 points higher than in 1984; and the IOU of 77 in 1989 was far below the level reached in 1977. In 1989 three states showed major differences from their normal levels of IOU. Rajasthan (90) - a total seat adjustment raised the IOU to near 1977 levels; in Orissa (91)- the highest level of opposition unity since 1962 was recorded; and in Bihar (71) the IOU, although low by national standards, was the second highest ever achieved in that state. Dlgltlzedby Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 164 State and Politics in India TABLE 3.15 Index of Opposition Unity 1962-1991 r-- ALL-INDIA Andhra Pradesh Assam Bihar Gujarat Haryana Himacha!Pradesh .... r--- °' °' .... °' .... .... \C) �ction Year --r--r--°' .... °' <>o °' °' °' .... g: .... � � � ;::, � 71 90 65 74 77 66 72 74 86 64 90 90 74 77 41 65 66 51 90 71 73 48 58 86 55 63 71 65 63 86 88 93 82 84 92 90 87 50 76 91 57 65 87 49 68 83 60 62 93 77 82 78 80 77 Karnataka 76 74 88 93 59 86 63 61 75 88 85 89 95 94 88 89 89 90 Kerala Madhya Pradesh 56 62 82 92 62 73 77 77 73 Maharashtra 67 72 75 93 70 71 72 65 73 Orissa 92 75 52 90 57 79 91 71 76 70 65 57 69 92 77 71 61 Punjab Rajasthan 62 76 83 94 60 66 90 74 76 73 91 94 87 89 92 81 77 86 Tamil Nadu 52 51 61 91 50 57 64 45 59 Uttar Pradesh 80 74 58 89 86 92 90 76 81 West Bengal 67 76 83 98 79 89 81 69 80 Delhi Note: The computation ofIOU was carried out constituency by constituency and then aggregated to the st:1tc and the all-India level. 67 74 60 59 82 67 62 In 1991, the Congress gained 35 seats although its vote fell by 3 per cent. This was due, of course, to the drop in opposition unity from 77 to 66. The year I991 was also the only election in which the Congress won more seats even though there was a swing in votes against it. Opposition unity can be achieved either by parties coming together to fight under a single common symbol - as in the 1977 elections -or, as in 1989, by 'seat adjustments' in which different parties agree not to fight from the same seats. Historically Kerala, which has had almost the largest number of parties of any state, is a good example of how 'seat adjustments' can result in what is, in effect, a two-party situation. The average IOU in Kerala, at 90, D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutions 165 is the highest for any state in the country because all the major parties have always allied with one of the two main political fronts (either the Left Democratic Front or the United Democratic Front). Consequently, the contest in each constituency has almost always been between only two serious parties, each one belonging to one of the two opposing fronts. Over the years, the opposition to the Congress has tended to be far more disunited in the northern states than in the south. Most of the states with an IOU below the all-India average are in the north. In fact, since 1962 three of the largest northern states - Uttar Pradesh (85 seats, with an average IOU of 59); Bihar (54 seats, IOU 63); Madhya Pradesh (40 seats, IOU 73) - have had among the lowest levels of opposition unity in the country. Over the years, the low levels of opposition unity in these states helped to ensure clear Congress majorities in the Lok Sabha. In 1989, the biggest debacle for the Congress occurred in Rajasthan, where it lost every single seat (having won them all in 1984). The Congress was wiped out not only because of a large swing against it, but also because it fuced a highly united opposi­ tion: the BJP and the Janata Dal came to an agree1nent on fielding only one candidate in every seat in the state. In 1991, opposition unity collapsed and Congress moving only from 37 per cent to 44 per cent of the vote jumped from 1 to 13 seats in Rajasthan. A higher than normal level of opposition unity in several other states also contributed to overwhelming setbacks for the Congress: in Orissa the IOU increased from 79 in 1984to91 in 1989;in Gujarat the .I 989 IOU of 92 was the highest for any state in the country. But in many of the other northern states opposition unity talks broke down over how many seats each party should be allocated. Consequently, the level of IOU in these states (notably Uttar Pradesh, Bihar and Madhya Pradesh) was low; and the primary reason for the Congress defeat in these states was a massive swing against the party. As in most of the previous elections, the opposition was united in the southern states of Andhra Pradesh,Tamil Nadu and Kerala. But in Karnataka the Janata Dal government split and its members stood against each other. With the BJP also fighting separately, the result was a low IOU and a sweep for the Congress. Levels of opposition unity can vary widely not only between states but also from one election to the next. Among the important Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 166 State and Politics in India states and union territories, the highest IOU ever recorded w a s 98 in Delhi in 197 7 and the lowest was 41 in Assam in 1991. The IOU has risen or fallen by up to 40 points between two elections. These large variations in IOU have had a major impact on elec­ toral change in India. In addition to its purely arithmetic or mechanical impact on margins of victory, opposition unity also has an important political and psychological effect on election results. There is no doubt that the opposition loses seats because of the purely arithmetical impact of a fall in the IOU. But there is also an important additional effect on the perceptions of the voter. If the opposition is perceived by the voter to be disunited, a certain proportion of the electorate may either not vote at all, or vote instead for a more cohesive party. This secondary political effect of a low IOU would add t o the percentage of votes for the ruling party. Consequently, voter perception of a disunited opposition could lead to a rise in votes of the ruling party and record a swing in its favour. The combined effect of a drop in IOU, in terms of its arithmetic impact as well as its political or psychological impact on voting behaviour, has been a major factor in determining the outcome of Indian elec­ tions. The average voter's perception of a united opposition was, perhaps, most significant in the 1989 elections, even though i n arithmetic terms the IOU was not very high. A comparison of the last two elections highlights the signi­ ficance of the psychological and the arithmetic impact of op-, position unity. In 1989, it appeared as though the opposition parties were presenting a united front against the Congress. The unity talks before the elections went smoothly and the leadership of V.P. Singh was implicitly assumed. Apart from the diverse factions of the Lok Dal and the Janata party coming together, the Communist parties and the BJP were obviously keen on supporting a V.P. Singh-led opposition in order to defeat Rajiv Gandhi's Congress. Agreements on seat adjustments were reached in a number of states; in several others agreements seemed imminent. These agreements received wide publicity across the country's electorate. In several states, however, talks between the BJP and the Janata Dal broke down at the last moment before the elections. Despite the confused post-election situation, the overriding pre-election impression left with the voter was that the opposition was almost as united as it had Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN • The Institutions 167 been in 1977. This perception of unity perhaps added consid­ erably to the swing against the Congress. The non-Congress parties began the 1991 election campaign without any semblance of a united front against the Congress. The highly publicized and eventual collapse of the J anata Dal govern­ ment destroyed any remaining perception of unity among voters. In the end, the 1991 elections recorded an IOU of 66, the second lowest level in twenty years. It was only the second time that the IOU dropped from the previous election. Since the change in IOU is often more significant than its level, the 11 point decline be­ tween 1989 and 1991 had a major impact on the number of seats won by the Congress. The unity of the non-Congress parties was at its lowest in Uttar Pradesh which had the lowest ever IOU of 45. However, the Congress could not take advantage of this because of a huge swing away from the party. The Congress vote in Uttar Pradesh dropped to a dismal 18.3 per cent, by far its lowest popular vote; caused by a negative swing of 13 .5 per cent from the already low level reached in 1989. In fact, with the Congress no longer the dominant, or even a significant party in Uttar Pradesh (42 of its candidates lost their deposits in 1991) it is perhaps time to select new parties to go into the calculation of IOU in the state. With the BJP emerging as the dominant party in Uttar Pradesh (al­ though it won only 32.8 per cent of the vote it was clearly the largest party) the IOU for Uttar Pradesh should perhaps be computed with reference to the parties opposing the BJP. The IOU of the non-BJP parties for Uttar Pradesh was a low 32 in 1991 and explains why the BJP won 51 out of 81 seats (or 61 per cent) and 32.8 per cent of the vote. For years the Congress has benefited from a divided opposition - now in Uttar Pradesh it is the BJP's tum. In fact, in many other states the IOU should no longer be computed for non-Congress parties. Wherever the Congress is no longer the dominant party the IOU should be computed for the parties opposing the dominant party. The central focus of electoral analysis is the percentage margin of victory. Election studies do not look merely at who won or lost but also at the size of a candidate's majority and the causes for any change in his percentage margin of victory compared with the previous election. The fact that a particular candidate Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN • 168 State and Politics in India won in two consecutive elections may be less significant than the fact that his margin of victory was reduced from 25 per cent to 5 per cent. The electoral analyst's main concern must be to explain the factors behind this drop of 20 percentage points in his majority. In a two-party system, only a change in popularity can cause the margin to change. In a multi-party system, the situation is more complex. Margins change not only because of a swing in votes but also because of a change in the degree of unity between opposition parties. A simple formula can be devised to explain this:IS Swing factor (change in popularity) + Split factor = Change in Margin (change in opposition unity) In Indian elections the importance of swings in popularity compared with changes in levels of opposition unity has varied from one election to another. Decomposing the change in margin shows that over all the eight elections (i.e. from 1962 to 1991), changes in opposition unity - the split factor - has contributed as much as one-third to changes in margins of victory (see Table 3 .16). The remaining two-thirds were due to swings in votes. The first strong impact of the split factor was in the 1980 election when the opposition defeat could be attributed as much to the drop in opposition unity between 1977 and 1980 as to the swing back in favour of the Congress. IS (M,-M,_1)=(X,-X,_1)(1 + I , _1)+(1,_1 -1,)(100-X,) Change in margin • the swing factor + the split factor X • Percencige votes for the ruling party. M • Margin of victory. I "' Index of opposition unity (expressed here as a proportion and not as a percentage, i.e. 0 < I < I). Subscript rand t-1 indicate the years of the two elections for which the change in margin is being decomposed. We call the first expression on the right hand side the swing factor and the second one the split factor. The overall 'split factor' is, strictly speaking, sensitive to f]le swing in votes and there is a n important interaction between the 'swing factor' and the 'split factor'. How­ ever, we find that the simple decomposition given here, despite the abstraction from the interaction terms, is a useful one for analytical purposes. Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN -.I The Institutions 169 TABLE 3.16 Congress Victory Margins: Reasons for Change, Impact of Swing and Split on Congress Margins 1962-7 1967-71 1971-7 1977-80 1980-4 1984-9 1989-91 Change in Congress Margin over Largest Other Pa� ( %2 • Average • Nott: Change in Margin Caused by: Swing Factor Split F114.tor (%) (%) -7.5 16.9 -38.5 29.6 4.6 -21.6 3.5 -8.0 · 18.4 -25.0 15.1 10.8 -19.7 -3.6 0.5 -1.5 -13.5 14.5 -6.2 -1.9 7.1 17.5 14.4 6.5 Average of absolute figures. A negative swing factor implies a swing away from Congress, a nega­ tive split factor implies an improvement in opposition unity. Contrary to popular belief, the Janata party victory in the I 977 election was much more due to a huge swing away from the Congress than to the sudden unity of the opposition. In the 1984 elections, the large swing of 5.4 per cent in favour of the Congress caused margins of victory to go up by 10.8 per cent, but this was counteracted by an improvement in opposition unity which re­ duced the margin by 6.2 per cent. The net of these two opposing trends yielded a 4.6 per cent net improvement in the average Congress margin of victory. In the 1989 elections, the voter's perception that the opposition was united was important. It gave the opposition credibility as a viable alternative to the Congress. As the impression spread that the opposition could form a government, the notion that a vote for them would only be a wasted vote was reduced. This perception of opposition unity is likely to have contributed to the large swing away from the Congress. Consequently, the psychological or polit­ ical impact of opposition unity was more important than the pure arithmetic impact of the increase in IOU in the 1989 elections. Table 3.16 shows that the fall in the Congress margin of victory of -21.6 per cent between 1984 and 1989, was overwhelmingly Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 170 State and Politics in India because of the swing factor (which contributed as much as 19.7 per cent to the drop in margin), while the greater unity of the opposition was less significant (contributing only 1.9 per ceµt to the decline in margin). In the 1991 elections the Congress vote fell to its second lowest point ever, dropping to 36.5 per cent. If opposition unity levels had not changed, this negative swing of 3 per cent would have shattered the Congress party: it would have ended up with around 125 seats and lost its position as the largest party. However, despite this drop in popularity between 1989 and 1991, the Congress won an extra 35 seats. This is explained by a large gain the Congress made from a very disunited opposition (see Table 3.16). Although the impact of swings and splits have varied over time, a broad rule of thumb applies: the effect of a 1 percentage point swing is, on average, equivalent to a 3 percentage point change in the IOU (Table 3.17). In other words, a swing of 1 per cent in favour of the Congress could be countered by a 3 percentage point improvement in opposition unity. TABLE 3.17 Comparison of Swing and Split Factors 1962-7 1967-71 1971-7 1977-80 1980-4 1984-9 1989-91 -Average Change in Margin Caused by 1%Swing 1%Change in % Change in IOU IOU to Offset 1 % Swing 1.77 1.59 1.69 1.99 1.58 1.71 1.78 1.26 0.32 0.65 0.55 0.47 0.60 0.61 1.41 5.05 2.58 3.45 3.36 2.85 2.92 1.73 0.64 3.23 Table 3.13 shows that in recent years a I per cent swing in votes causes between 20 and 25 seats to change hands. The 3 per cent swing away from the Congress in 1991 would, therefore, have meant about 60 to 70 fewer seats for the Congress. On the other hand, th.e IQ_U dropped 11 percentage points between 1989 and 1991. Table 3.16 shows that this 11 point drop in IOU is roughly equivalent to a 4 per cent swing in favour of Congress. Dig1t1zeo by Google Origi�al rrom UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutions 171 Consequently, the impact of the drop in IOU was to add about 80 to 100 seats to the Congress. It was the net effect, therefore, of the 3 per cent negative swing causing a loss of 60 to 70 seats, and the 11 point drop in IOU causing an addition of 80 to 100 seats, that in the end led to Congress gaining 35 seats in the last elections. Although the swing and change in IOU 'by definition' explain changes in the margin of victory, neither of these measures should be interpreted mechanically. The swing is merely a final index which measures the net impact of a multitude of political issues, social and caste trends and underlying economic realities. The IOU too is only a summary measure of the alliances that political parties form and the electorate's perception of these alliances, real or imagined. The simplicity of these indices should not hide the complexities of the relationships that they measure. It would be wrong, for instance, to oversimplify the IOU and say that 'a divided non-Congress vote always helps the Congress'. This may not be true in some circumstances. For example if the opposition to the Congress is the BJP and the Janata Dal, both being strong parties, the IOU may be low. But instead of the non-Congress voter support being divided, the Janata _Dal and Congress may be competing for the same support base. In other words, in this situation the n o n -B JP vote would be split. A low IOU would then help the BJP rather than the Congress. Of course, if the Janata Dal is eating into the Congress vote, this would be reflected in a lower percentage vote for the Congress - i.e. a larger swing away from the Congress. It is, therefore, only true to say that 'a divided non-Congress vote always helps the Con­ gress, for a given percentage Congress vote'. Moreover, the 'swing-IOU' formula is further complicated by voter perceptions creating a relationship between the IOU and the swing. In the current political situation it may be more sensible to use the swing and IOU in a more disaggregated manner, at a state level rather than an all-India level. For example in Rajasthan, where the BJP is the dominant party, an alternative analysis would be to measure swing in terms of changes in the BJP vote and compute IOU in terms of the non-BJP vote. In this way a state­ by-state analysis may provide more accurate forecasts. If the electorate behaved uniformly across the country, it would be easy to predict elections. Voting trends in one constituency could then be projected to the entire nation. In fact, no country D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 172 State and Politics in India behaves uniformly, but the swing in some countries is more uni­ form than in others. Britain offers a notable example of uniform swing, with a standard deviation of only 2 per cent. In contrast, the swings in elections to the United States House of Repre­ sentatives have shown a standard deviation of around 6 per cent. In India, while there has been appreciable variation in the swing across different states, the swings in votes have tended to be more uniform than is generally recognized. Even at the all-India level, in most elections, the great majority of the country has moved in the same direction, though the magnitude of the swing in different regions varied. Voting patterns in state elections are often closely related to those in national contests. A good or a bad performance by a state government of one party can have a massive impact on that party's Lok Sabha vote in the state. In the Andhra Pradesh state election of 1983, the Telugu Desam breakthrough was followed by a statewide anti-Congress sweep (against the national tide) in the 1984 Lok Sabha elections. But in the 1989 Lok Sabha elec­ tions, the discrediting of the state Telugu Desam government was matched by an overwhelming swing to Congress (also against the national tide). In 1991 when Congress was winning nationally, there was something of a return to Telugu Desam. The pattern, however, is not consistent and there is certainly no exact fit between state and national voting. While much more research needs to be done in this important area, it is clear that swings tend to be increasingly uniform as the focus shifts from India as a whole to the state level or down to homogeneous zones within states. In any case, the swings at the state level tend to be uniform enough to make reasonably accurate forecasts of seats. Consequently, these can be made when the swing in only a few constituencies is known, either from opinion polls or from the first reports once the counting begins. One reason why the all-India swing has become less uniform since the early 1980s is the growth of strong regional parties. In 1962 regional parties accounted for 6.3 per cent of the total opposition vote, but by 1984 this had risen to 20.8 per cent of the vote. In 1989 this dipped again to l 0.4 per cent.16 Of the Elections in Assam were not held in 1989 and partially held in 1980. If elecrio.ns had been held, the vote of the regional parties would have gone up further. 16 D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutions 173 opposition MPs elected in 1984, as many as 57 per cent were from regional parties. Regional factors have been increasingly manifest i n Lok Sabha contests and have made the variation in swing between states more and more significant. In the 1989 elections, however, the sharp decline in the popularity of Telugu Desam in Andhra Pradesh and the dominance of the Congress in the southern states resulted in a significant drop in the repre­ sentation of regional parties. In Punjab, however, the Akali Dal (Mann) virtually eclipsed all the other factions of the Akali Dal; it won 6 out of the 8 seats that it contested. Its victory resulted in a militant regional representation in the Lok Sabha. At the same time the violent form of regionalism in Assam once again prevented elections being held in that state. The 1991 elections and the events after it indicate that region­ alism may be increasing once again. Most poll and by-election results indicate that the Telugu Desam's popularity is rising (despite the split into the NTR and the Chandrababu Naidu groups) and so is OM.K's in Tamil Nadu. And while the violence in Punjab has abated, in Kashmir it has risen sharply. There are fashions in electoral interpretations. Disaster has regularly been predicted for Inclian democracy. In the mid 1970s it was said to be threatened by the autocracy of Mrs Gandhi. In the early 1980s it seemed to be the rise of regional and separatist parties as the takeover of Andhra Pradesh by Telugu Desam, coinciding with publicity for violent breakaway movements notably in Punjab, Kashmir and Assam, led to fears about the break-up of India. Anxieties about autocracy and about threats to Indian unity will persist. . There will be both ebb and flow in the intensity of these womes. Today it is the rapid growth of the BJP that is producing conflicting views ranging from fears about the rise of religious fundamentalism to hopes for a change to a clean, efficient ad­ ministration. However, the hope that the BJP would provi<l� a change, a clean break from the Congress has been undermined by the rise of dissidence in the party (starting in Gujarat and spreading to other states). It is clear that election campaigns are increasingly aggressive and violent as caste and religious differences have be­ come an integral part of politics in India. The end product of any voting system is to produce a legislature which will give support to a government. In the Westminster D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 174 State and Politics in India system, a government must command a parliamentary majority. Eight out of ten Indian elections have produced a definite result, a clear majority for a single party. That is the norm for most countries using first past-the-post voting on the British model. But among parliamentary democracies elsewhere in the world it is the exception. Where there is proportional representation it is most unusual for one party to win a clear majority. Coalition government or minority government provided the usual pattern. India, of course, has had experience of coalitions at the state level. In 1989, the Lok Sabha elections for the first time failed to produce a clear majority and coalitions, in one form or the other, ruled India in 1990 and 1991. At the state level there are many similar examples. Usually they have not lasted long (although Kerala provides an instance of enduring inter-party understandings). Do governments have a shelf-life? According to one model, often expressed in textbooks, once a government takes office it is forced to implement unpopular measures so that the accumulation of grievances inevitably erodes its support until in the next elec­ tion, when it inevitably loses its majority. However, although in a democratic system all governments are liable ultimately to fall, there is no regular pattern to their decline. After a setback in 1967, Mrs Gandhi increased the Congress's majority in 1971. For four­ teen yearsJyoti Basu's CPM government in West Bengal has gone from strength to strength electorally. Since 1950 British govern­ ments have increased their majority in Parliament in general elec­ tions just as often as they have had it reduced or eliminated. In Western democracies the incumbent party is believed to hold an advantage at elections. In India this may not be true. Tough and unpopular decisions are more common in a democracy which is poor and has a developing economy. Since the last General Elections, the electorate seemed to vote strongly against which­ ever government was in power at the state and national levels (Table 3.18). In the early years of Indian democracy after Independence, the electorate appeared to be less volatile. Table 3.19 reports the swing between each of the last elections and shows that while the average swing till 1971 was 3.2 per cent, since 1971 this has more than doubled to 6.9 per cent. Only in 1977 was there a change, when the Congress government was decisively thrown out of power for the fust time at the national level. Since then D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Instituti011S 175 TABLE 3.18 Is There an Incumbent Disadvantage? Incumbent 1991 Lok Sabha electi011S 1991 Vu/ban Sabha eleai011S Assam Haryana Kerala TamilNadu Uttar Pradesh West Bengal Pondicherry Gqypnmp,t Incumbent Won/Lost AGP JD CPl(M) DMK BJP CPl(M) Congress Lost Lost Lost Lost Lost Won Won BJP Congress BJP Lost Lost Lost Congress Congress Congress SKSP Lost Lost Won Lost JD Congress Congress JD Congress Won JD Lost 1993 Vidh11n Sabha electi011S Himachal Pradesh Madhya Pradesh Rajasthan Uttar Pradesh Delhi 1994 Vidhan Sabha elections Andhra Pradesh Karnatalca Goa Sikkim 1995 Vu/ban Sabha elections Bihar Gujarat Maharashtra Orissa Arunachal Pradesh Mapipur Summary: Incumbent Lost: 15 ti1nes Lost Lost Lost Won MEP Won: 5 times -.... .... Lost TABLE 3.19 Increase in Voter Volatility -"-I :1 ci ""' 0\ 0\ Swing Average (ibs'1J11"l t-- .... � 0\ t-- t-- 0\ t-0\ r!. 'C 2.8 -3.1 -3.9 2.9 3.2 Digi tized by Google I ;r l l � t-0\ .... -9.2 8.2 0C) 0\ .... 0C) 0\ 0\ J. 0\ .... 0C) 5.4 -8.6 -3.0 6.9 Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 176 State and Politics in India swings in voter behaviour have become more extreme and na­ tional and state governments have been voted out with increasing regularity. The electorate seems to be increasingly dissatisfied with the government's performance and is constantly looking for a change. In addition the Indian electorate appears to have ma­ tured over the years in its understanding of the power of the ballot. The average voter now seems to be more aware that he has a powerful weapon at his command and is using it more ruthlessly. The party system has changed and will continue to change. But there is a basic regularity in the relation between seats and votes which appears to remain. What has altered, however, is the dom­ inance of the Congress party: certainly at the state level and possibly even at the national level. This implies that the IOU will no longer always refer to parties opposing the Congress. The IOU should be computed for parties opposing the dominant party in a state. For example in West Bengal where the CPI (M) is dominant, the IOU should apply to all parties in opposition to the CPI (M). Similarly, in Andhra Pradesh, the IOU should be computed for parties opposing the dominant party in the state, the Telugu Desam. Whichever party is selected as the dominant party with the rest as opposition, the basic arithmetic relationships between swing, IOU and changes in margin of victory are not affected. The underlying method of translating votes into seats is likely t o remain valid and, for the time being, it provides a solid basis for the exercises in forecasting which are described in the next chapter. Dlgltlzedby Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 4 Reconfiguration in Indian Politics: State Assembly Elections 1993-1995* Yogendra Yadav A future historian may remember the three rounds of assembly elections held in sixteen states from November 1993 to March 1995 as having ushered in a new phase in democratic politics in India. 1 This is not because they announced with a bang a completely new kind of politics. On the contrary, the verdict is far from obvious, shrouded as it is in a series of apparently localized •This chapter has profited from discussions at the national seminar 'Assembly Elections and their Political Implications' organized by the Indian Council of Social Science Research at New Delhi on 9-11 May 1995, and from presentationsmade at the Centre for Political Srudies,JNU, Centre for Public Affuirs, Delhi, and at Departments of Political Science of MS University of Baroda, Pune University and University of Hyderabad. I wish to thank my colleagues at the Centre for the Srudy ofDeveloping Societies for stimulating discussions, Rustam for a critical reading and Sanjay, Kanchanji, Himanshu, and Hila! for helping me with the tables. I am grateful to Manoranjan Mohanty and Ghanshyam Shah for reminding me of the larger concerns beyond electoral politics and to Bashiruddin Ahmed and Rajni Kothari for inspiration and encouragement. I The sixteen states included in this overview are Himachal Pradesh, Rajas­ than, Delhi, Madhya Pradesh, Mizoram, Uttar Pradesh (1993); Andhra Pradesh, Kamatalc.a, Goa, Sikkim (1994); and Gujarat, Maharashtra, Orissa, Manipur, Arunachal Pradesh and Bihar (1995). The three north-eastern states ofNagaland, Meghalaya and Tripura which went to polls in early 1993 have been excluded from the analysis. This overview also avoids any independent consideration of the political trajectory of these states and the state-specific patterns of electoral outcome which I have analysed in a series of articles in Frontline from November I993 to May I 995. D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 178 State and Politics in India verdicts and the notorious contingencies of routine politics, such that, at the end of the day, there is no clear winner. Besides, on the face of it, there is no clear pattern in the messy verdict of this first major set of elections since the demolition of Bahri masjid, inauguration of the New Economic Policy and the departure of the last charismatic leader of the Nehru dynasty. The future, however, may place these elections in a different light and bring out the significance denied to us by our proximity. In fact, it might indicate that without much noise or drama, quietly and almost casually, these state elections have provided the first full view of the post-Congress polity. It is a complex picture as compared not 'only to the sweeping electoral waves of the 1970s and 1980s but also to the uncertain verdicts of the last two general elections. But that is precisely what makes it cognitively more valuable to a student ofIndian politics. In other words, what appears like a mess needs to be recognized as a new pattern. Though it may have to wait till the forthcoming Lok Sabha elections or a little longer to be recognized as such, this new pattern holds the key to making sense of the future ofIndian politics. While it would be inaccurate to characterize the change as 'realignment', for the Indian electorate has never been aligned with parties in the classical Western sense, it may also not be appropriate to see the new pattern either simply as a radicalization of democracy or as a plain degeneration. The reconfiguration intensifies the tension between two fundamentally conflicting tendencies in Indian politics. While the process of democratiza­ tion has advanced further, thanks to higher mobilization and greater politicization, particularly of the marginal sections, this democratic upsurge has not been translated effectively into the institutionalized world of politics. Electoral volatility has opened up fresh possibilities without leading to transformative politics. Political parties have expanded their reach but their legitimacy has been deeply eroded. The consolidation of the party system at the state level cannot be aggregated at the national level. The Congress definitely shows signs of a long-term decline at a time when the task of occupying the middle ground has become im­ possibly difficult. The effective regionalization of the polity has been accompanied by an equally powerful internal homogeniza­ tion and the creation of a thin, slippery terrain. Radical concerns find a place in the political discourse but in an exclusivist and D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutions 179 fragmentary mode. Finally, the second democratic upsurge takes place at a time when the logic of carrying on democracy without prosperity is beginning to tell, when economic limits to politics have got more pronounced and, as a result, the democratic enter­ prise itself faces a serious, if not immediate, threat. If democratic politics is headed for a crisis, it is a crisis with transformative potential. That this pattern should reveal itself in the electoral arena first is hardly surprising. Over the last two decades, elections have acquired a political salience they did not have in the first phase of democratic politics in India. As all the institutions which mediated between political power and the people have collapsed one after another, the institution of elections continues to be one of the few bridges available for political traffic. Consequently, all the political aspirations, demands and competing claims to power must be mediated through the mechanism of elections; the pro­ cess and the outcome of elections are one of the few reliable indicators available to a student of politics today to read public opinion and to measure other changes in the larger environs of politics. Needless to say, elections are not a mirror of political reality. As a representational device, elections are better compared is 'out there', but to a camera: . in a sense it merely records what . it all depends on who holds it, in which direction and with what focus. Like aesthetic representation, mechanisms of selectivity, erasure and highlighting are inevitably at work in political rep­ resentation. And what is more, like a camera, elections go much beyond recording the political reality; in a way, they create a reality of their own in that life is led for the sake of representation. Something of that is true of contemporary India, thanks to the new role elections have come to play in political life. The outcome of rpe state assembly elections, 1993-5, can be used to trace the outlines of a new phase in democratic politics, provided we view it i n a framework sensitive to the complexities of the relationship between elections and politics.2 Although a good deal of the reluctance of a whole generation of Indian political scientists to study elections can be explained by a sociology of academic knowledge (accidents of academic socialization,political correctness or simply the fear of numbers), there is a genuine intellectual basis for this reserve. 2 D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 180 State and Politics in India Second Democratic Upsurge? The beginning of a new phase in democratic politics is often marked by a spurt in political participation and the intensification of the citizen's involvement in politics. In the case of the elections under discussion, however, higher participation and more intense politicization points to much more than a change in political season: it attests to some of the deeper continuities in India's democratic career. Here is evidence that the democratic revolution inaugurated on the basis of universal adult franchise more than four decades ago is still on, that the mechanism of competitive politics still retains its dynamism and its capacity to draw out newer sectors and sections in a society which has historically lacked a political centre, that notwithstanding the media folklore of an apathetic, indifferent and apolitical public, politicization continues to be a defining feature of the constitution of public arena in contemporary India, and that a continuously expanding circle of participants in politics, rather than a progressively radical political agenda, continues to be the predominant mode of democratization today. At the same time this trend also serves to remind us of some of the discontinuities and the resultant dilemmas and dangers confronting democratization. While there is undoubtedly some­ thing to celebrate about greater electoral participation, the en­ thusiasm needs to be moderated by the recognition that over the years, electoral participation has come to stand for political par­ ticipation in a way it never did before, that the increasing salience The routinization of election research by run-of-the-mill election studies which followed the first generation of vigorous and sensitive survey research evoked a peculiar response among Indian political scientists: critique of nar­ rowly focused, badly executed and poorly theorized election studies turned into a critique of election studies as such. Instead of a creative confrontation of various approaches to the study of the phenomenon o f election, the debate turned into a rather gross opposition between those who would and those who would not study elections. Any study of elections came to be associated with borrowed jargon, mindless use of statistics, spurious fieldwork and irrelevance, not to speak of political conservatism. The disasttous consequen­ ces this association had both for election studies and the understanding of Indian politics are amply evident in post-1971 literature (if we dare a study not by the time of its publication but by the election it studied). The present chapter is based on the conviction that students of Indian democracy need to revitalize and, at the same time, reorient the study of electoral politics. D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutions 181 att2ched to the act of voting as the privileged symbol or the . defming moment of citizenship is not unrelated to a slide towards its becoming a momentary symbol, and that the crowding of the arena of electoral contestation is at least partly due to the shrinking institutional space for non-electoral modes of efficacious political activity. TABLE4.l Participation Trends in Major Assembly Elections 1952-1995 Year of Election States 1952 1957 1960-2 1967 1971-2 19-77-8 1979-80 1984-5 1989-90 1993-5 22 13 15 20 21 24 16 18 18 16 Total Turnout Total Seats (per cent) Contestants 3283 2906 3196 3487 3131 3723 2589 3131 3028 2770 45 48 58 61 60 59 54 58 60 64 15,361 10,176 13,665 16,507 13,768 22,396 17,826 26,963 35,187 40 773 Contestants e_er Seat Total lndee_endents 4.7 3.5 4.3 4.7 4.4 6.0 6.9 8.6 11.6 14.7 1.9 1.4 1.3 1.9 1.6 2.2 3.2 5.4 7.0 9.1 A 'major' round of assembly elections is denned here as one which involved, within a year or two, elections to at least 2000 assembly constituencies. Source: Up to 1979-80, from V.B. Singh and Shanlcar Bose, Sutt Elections in Jndu,: D11t11 Htmdbook on Vidbtm Sabha Ekctions, 19$2-8$ (New Delhi: Sage, 1987), vol. I, p. 14; the rest compiled by CSDS Data Unit. Nott: First, a look at gross figures at the aggregate level. It is, of course, easy to over-read into figures, but for students of Indian politics this professional hazard is less of a danger at the moment than the ridiculous fate of missing altogether the simple message of some basic data which stare in their face. Time series data of voters' turnout and the number of candidates in state assembly elections over the last four decades presented in Table 4.1 clearly show an upward secular trend. In both these respects the 1993-5 Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 182 State and Politics in India elections represent a new peak. Although the 60 per cent turnout mark was crossed as early as in 1967, the average turnout in all the major rounds of assembly elections (involving elections in at least 2000 assembly constituencies) hovered around 60 per cent with the exception of post-:Janata disillusionment when it touched 54 per cent. An average of more than 64 per cent in these elections indicates a decisive break with that somewhat stagnant level. It means an increase of 4 per cent over the previous round of assembly elections held in 1989-90, not to mention a sizeable 9 per cent increase over the 1991 Lok Sabha elections. The nwnber of candidates has risen more steadily over the decades, though here again there is a marked acceleration in the 1990s. Beginning with a flat decadal growth rate of about one candidate per con­ stituency, reflecting a steady intensification of electoral contests, it starts jumping by leaps and bounds around the mid-l 980s. The 1993-5 rounds have continued this upward trend in the nwnber of contestants, taking it past fourteen per seat, and a larger share of independents in it. If the 1960s were characterized by the first democratic upsurge, the 1990s are witnessing the second demo­ cratic upsurge in post-Independence India. At a disaggregate level, however, the deceptive simplicity of this picture gives way to complex and difficult questions about the meanings embedded in this upsurge. A glance through 'fable 4.2, which presents the turnout figures at the state level over the last three assembly elections, brings out various aspects of a complex picture. First of all, the increase in participation is quite widespread without being uniform. Except a very marginal fall in Bihar which had already experienced a significant increase in the previous elections, every state registered a noticeably higher turnout. Every state has its own pace and timing, but their trajectories do not appear to be moving in different directions. This round of elec­ tions saw Gujarat, Maharashtra, Madhya Pradesh, Orissa and, of course, Uttar Pradesh 'catch up' with the participation rate in the rest of the country; consequently, they contributed much more to the average growth rate of 4 per cent than the rest. Once we tum to accounting for the observed variations in turnout, the limitations of some of the obvious hypotheses and data available to us become clear. Neither the level of turnout reached in different states in this election nor the differential rate of increase in turnout lends itself to a neat explanation. If the rise Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN Tbt Institutwns 183 TABLE4.2 Percentage Turnout in Assembly Elections 1984-1995 States Andhra Pradesh Arunachal Pradesh 1984-5 Uttar Pradesh 66.7 76.3 55.l 55.6 47.7 71.9 69.6 66.3 48.6 87.3 58.3 70.6 51.4 54.0 62.6 44.8 Total 55.3 Bihar Delhi Gujarat Goa Himachal Pradesh Kamataka Madhya Pradesh Manipur . Maharashtra Mizoram Orissa Rajasthan Sildcim 1989-90 1993-5 lntrtast 67.6 68.9 62.2 54.3 51.l 68.7 66.7 63.8 52.8 80.6 61.l 80.4 55.5 56.S 69.5 48.5 71.l 81.4 61.8 61.8 64.7 71.7 71.7 68.8 59.0 88.8 72.0 80.8 73.8 60.6 81.0 57.1 13.6 3.0 5.0 5.0 6.2 8.2 10.9 0.4 18.3 4. I 11.5 8.6 60.3 64.2 3.9 3.5 12.3 --0.4 Notes: 1. Table en{ries in the last column arc fur pcrcent2ge increase in turnout in the 1993-S assembly election as compared to the previous usembly election in 1989-90. 2. Table entties fur 1984 and 1989 in the case ofDelhi are for turnout in Lok Sabha elections; Delhi did not have an asseinbly then. 3. Turnout in the 1991 election to UP assembly was 47.l per cent. Sount: CSDS Dat2 Unit. to power of a new political force representing a new social con­ stituency explains the massive mobilization ·in Maharashtra, Uttar Pradesh and Sikkim, it doesn't quite apply to the routine alterna­ tion in Madhya Pradesh and Orissa. The closely contested nature of elections may account for higher mobilization in Orissa, but Rajasthan did not experience it under similar conditions. Besides, the completely one-sided verdicts in Himachal and Aodhra re­ corded a similarly high level of electoral participation. Something of the intensity which struggles over extension of suffrage have historically generated, can be found in today's India in Bihar and D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 184 State 11nd Politics in India Uttar Pradesh along with Sikkim in a manifest form. Perhaps the same process is at work in a latent manner in the rest of India barring the southern states where the political rise of backward castes has already been accomplished. It may be hypothesized therefore that the fundamental force which has given rise to the second democratic upsurge is the enfranchisement of the backward castes. One must hasten to add that this process of enfranchise­ ment takes different political routes in different states; it is not just that the logic has worked itself out to varying stages in dif­ ferent states but that different states have a somewhat autonomous logic, . depending upon the specificity of their political con&guranon. In the absence of longitudinal survey data on patterns of in­ dividual participation by social background, it is difficult to verify this understanding. But a quick examination of the intra-state variations in turnout partly supports it. Practically everywhere rural constituencies report a higher turnout (8, IO and 17 per cent higher i n Gujarat, UP and Maharashtra, respectively) than urban constituencies. The popular impression of a higher Muslim rur­ nout is not borne out by an examination of turnout in constituen­ cies with higher concentration of Muslim votes. The reserved (SC) constituencies generally recorded a lower turnout than the rest, but it need not reflect patterns of dalit participation; in all prob­ ability i t is an outcome of the lower intensity and enthusiasm of non-dalit voters i n. these constituencies. On the other hand, the reserved (ST) constituencies, which are invariably areas with con­ centration of tribal population, recorded higher than average rur­ nout in Andhra, Gujarat and Maharashtra. Some backward regions like Vidarbha and Marathwada in Maharashtra, east Delhi and Bundelkhand in UP recorded a higher than average turnout. But the evidence on this score is equivocal. Other backward regions like Vindhya Pradesh and Chhattisgarh in MP and Poorvanchal in UP reported lower turnout; Telengana in AP and western Orissa reported average turnout. In sum, it is not just backward­ ness but its effective politicization or otherwise which seems to make the crucial difference. This, rather mixed evidence, is in­ sufficient to support the hypothesis about the relationship between the enfranchisement of backward castes and the rise in turnout What it does reaffirm is India's difference from the stereotypical Western models of political participation, and that India's path to Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN - The lnstitutums 18 5 democratization lies through an effective politicization of pen.: pheries, both spatial and social. TABLE 4.3 Contestmts Per Seat in Assembly Elections 1984-1995 States Andhra Pradesh Arunachal Pradesh Bihar Delhi Gujarat Goa Himachal Pradesh Karnatab Madhya Pradesh Manipur Maharashtra Mizoram Orissa 1984-5 6.7 3.8 13.0 6.2 8.0 4.3 8.0 7.6 6.0 7.7 4.5 5.4 7.5 Rajastlµn Sikkim 6.0 14.0 Total 8.6 Uttar Pradesh 1989-90 5.7 1993-5 10.9 2.9 24.9 18.8 13.9 2.8 20.0 10.3 6.3 7.7 6.6 9.1 13.1 4.1 13.0 4.0 6.2 15.4 6.1 11.1 11.4 5.6 16.4 3.0 9.6 12.1 3.6 5.8 14.4 23.0 11.7 14.7 Notes: 1. Delhi did not have assembly elections during 1984-5 and 1989-90. 2. The number of contestlnts per seat in Uttar Pradesh assembly election, 1991, was 18.S. Suuru: CSDS Data Unit. The disaggregated figures on the number of candidates per constituency by states (fable 4.3) are relatively easy to explain, partly because the level of differentiation is much higher in this case than in turnout. Here again, the general tendency is towards greater number of candidates with the passage of time. But the rate of growth and the current level vary from state to state, depending mainly on th_e'party system. Arunachal Pradesh still exhibits the low and stagnant level associated with one-party dom­ inance. States-. which have reached or are. close to a two-party Digiti zed by Google Ongmal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 186 Suzte and Politics in India system occupy the middle ground with an average of a little over 10 candidates. The general trend is towards a higher nwnber, though a consolidation of two-party system in Rajasthan, Himachal Pradesh and Madhya Pradesh was accompanied by a reduction in the nwnber of contestants in the 1993 elections. The fragmented party systems of UP and Bihar stand out as exceptions and largely account for the two outliers with an average of 2 3 and 24.9 candidates per constituency, respectively, which considerably affect the national average. Besides party fragmentation, the entry of the OBCs on the centre stage of politics also contributes to the sudden rise in the number of contestants. Making sense ofhigher electoral participation in this new phase of democratic politics remains an intellectual challenge which students of Indian politics are yet to take up. It would take con­ siderable research effort, both quantitative and qualitative, to ex­ plain the overall trend and its internal variations. The preliminary observations offered here are by way of drawing attention to this phenomenon. What needs much more attention though, than simply analysing the figures, is the question of significance of this trend for the polity. That is directly related to the terrain of meanings embedded in the act of participation, electoral or other­ wise, which calls for political research informed by anthropological techniques. But some points can be made straight away. First, electoral participation reflects more enthusiasm and involvement in the polity on the part of the common citizen than the English press and its academics would have us believe. Second, the degree of intensity varies from state to state, depending upon the range of political choices which confront the electorate. A higher turnout in Orissa does not necessarily mean a more intense involvement than, say, Bihar. A better predictor of the level of involvement, thirdly, is the social community. Political participation is still mediated by communitarian identities and reflects something of the cleavage between the mobilized and the hitherto unincor­ porated communities. The contestation for power between these two types of communities in the electoral arena continues to draw citizens' deeper sense of the self in the act of political participation. For the millions .of slum- and unauthorized colony-dwellers in Delhi, sections of dalits and Muslims in Uttar Pradesh, OBCs in Bihar and, to some extent; in Maharashtra and Sikkim, it was not Digiti zed by Google Ongmal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutions 187 an ordinary election this time; at stake were not just their material interests . but their identity and dignity and, in some cases, th�ir very ClDStCDCC. Fourth, while greater participation and involvement does in­ dicate a higher level of politicization, it does not necessarily mean a corresponding increase in the citizen's commitment to and trust in the political order. The simultaneity of involvement and aliena­ tion which has characterized the Indian electorate3 has been further accentuated in the 1990s. And what is more, this alienation does not result from traditional cynicism towards governmental authority (contra Eldersvcld and Ahmed); it is fumJy rooted in the experience of post-Independence politics. Finally, it is now clear that it does not make sense to read the meanings involved in electoral participation through the tradition/modernity dicho­ tomy. Greater participation is definitely not a sign of modern­ ization, for its reasons are anything but modem. Nor is it b y any means a traditional response. The state assembly elections have taken the Indian polity a step further in the effective creolization of the modem ideas, ideals and institutions of democratic politics in a non-European setting. • The consequences of this upsurge in participation for the process of democratization need to be understood in their com­ plexity. Surely, greater participation is good news for the vitality of the processes of democratization; it does show that these processes still retain their dynamic capacity to mobilize citizens, especially the hitheno unincorporated sections. By drawing more people and politicizing them, the electoral mechanism does pro­ vide a base for radicalization of democracy; it also creates neces­ sary, though insufficient, conditions for the forging of political cleavages which cut across social cleavages and thus contribute to democratic consolidation. However, participation in a democratic process does not by itself lead towards participatory democracy. It all depends on what kinds of meanings the new participants bring with them and whether this influx can be institutionalized. In this respect the signals from the assembly elections of 1993-5 seem ambivalent. Since the participatory urge in this instance arose mainly out of 3 This phenomenon was fust recognized and theorized by Samuel Eldersveld and Bashiruddin Ahmed in Citiuns 1111d Politics: Mass Politi",/ Bthtr11ior1r in lnditJ (Chicago and London: University ofChicago Press, 1978), pp. 214-16. D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 188 State and Politics in India partisan allegiance, it may not result in a higher level of support for the democratic order. Especially in the case of new entrants, the act of participation is inextricably tied to specific expectations. More often than not, these expectations are linked to cultural codes which do not jell with the norms of the existing democratic institutions. Consequently, the recent participatory upsurge can further intensify the serious problem of institutional consolidation of democracy. In this sense the second democratic upsurge throws up a challenge to the future of democratization - a challenge arising not from the failure of democratic enterprise to take off, but from its continuous, if partial, success. Electoral Volatility or Transformative Politics? The most visible outcome of the assembly elections of 1993-5 is the large-scale change in governments at the state level. With the minor exceptions of Arunachal Pradesh, Goa and Rajasthan and the major exception of Bihar, all the states witnessed the defeat of the ruling party at the polls. 'Vote against incumbent' by an angry, volatile electorate suggests itself as an explanation of the outcome. Even Goa and Rajasthan do not appear to be serious exceptions, for the ruling parties nearly lost the elections; at any rate a massive turnover of elites characterized these cases of governmental sta­ bility. It would seem, therefore, that Indian politics has reached a critical phase characterized by an increasingly volatile electorate and a party system in advanced stages of decomposition. The state-wise figures of Pedersen's Volatility index in the last three elections reported in Table 4.4 provide some reason to qualify such an alarming picture. On an average, the aggregate vote swing between 1993-5 assembly elections and the previous elections held mostly in 1989-90 revolves around 15 per cent. Compared to Westem democracies, where the process of bind­ i n g -i n -over-long-time of partisan loyalties has resulted in a cr y s ­ tallization of party system, the level of volatility is bound to appear rather high.4 However, the experierrce of four decades of electoral Dalton, Back and Flanagan report an average of 8.7 per cent volatility for seventeen advanced industrial democracies for the period 1970-7. Russel J. Dalton, Scott C. Flanagan and Paul Allen Beck (eds), Eltmral Cbtmgt in AdvtmetdIndustrial Dnnocrll<its: RtalignmmturDealignmmt? (Princeton: Prin­ ceton University Press, 1984), p. 10. 4 D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVER�ITY OF MICHIGAN - ---�- �· - The Institutions 189 TABLE 4.4 Volatility in Assembly Elections 1980-1995 1980-5 1990-5 Orissa Rajasthan Sikkim Uttar Pradesh 4.2 30.5 13. l 6.0 58.3 13.3 11.4 6.0 27.2 9.5 20.5 31.0 9.3 63.7 12.1 1985-90 Total 21.0 29.7 18.5 States Andhra Pradesh Anmachal Pradesh Bihar Gujarat Goa Himachal Pradesh Karnatab Madhya Pradesh Manipur Maharkhtra Mizoram 12.6 28.5 24.9 43.7 24.6 23.1 35.3 20.1 48.5 34.4 37.1 54.9 19.6 16.6 21.9 13.9 15.6 15.4 26.8 19.5 15.1 24.0 11.6 13.1 13.9 11.2 24.6 18.1 44.2 10.8 Notes: 1. Table entries are for Pedersen's Volatility Index. Tiiis simple meas­ ure of aggregate volatility is the sum of cwnulative per cent gains in vote share of all the parties which have improved their perfo� mance as compared to the previous elections, plus the vote share of new parties, if any. The three columns present the scores for 19845, 1989-90 and 1993-5 assembly elections, respectively as compared to the previous election in that state. 2. Table entry for Uttar Pradesh in the third column stands for 19913; the relevant score for 1989-91 is 32.5. 3. Average stands here for simple mean and is therefore subject to undue influence of extreme values of very small states like Goa and Sikkim. Sourc�: Computed from data at CSDS Data Unit. politics in India is enough to demonstrate the inappropriateness of this yardstick which cannot but discover India in a state of perpetual pre-alignment. It may be analytically more rewarding to give up this teleological expectation in favour of a model which takes continuous volatility as the structural attribute of competitive politics in the Indian context. Electoral volatility is but another Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 190 State and Politics in India name for a continuously open-ended negotiation by the citizens with the organized vehicles of politics. The stubborn refusal of the Indian voter to live up to models of 'political learning' by developing rigid partisan loyalties is not just a potential malady; it is also the potential source of transformativc politics. Viewed in this light, the level of electoral volatility in the recent assembly elections is neither very high nor alarming. What is distinctive about the 1993-5 assembly elections, in fact, is a reduc­ tion in electoral volatility and the stabilu.ation of its pattern. Except for Sikkim and Andhra Pradesh, the level of aggregate volatility between 1980-90 and 1993-5 is lower than between 1985 and 1989-90 in all the states which went to polls this time. The swing between 1980 to 1985 was much lower in several cases, but the pattern of 1993-5 is more evenly spread acr� different states. If it is useful to mark significant electoral shifts in India with the label 'critical elections', the assembly elections of 1989-90 are surely a better candidate for it than those of I 993-5. The turn of the decade brought in a new political configuration in much of the Hindi heartland and western India. The long-term effect of the recent assembly elections would be to consolidate the trend, modify its direction and translate it into a new pattern of government control. Since the aggregate measure employed here does not permit any robust inference about individual or sectional volatility, the im­ plications of this phenomenon for the future of democratization remain less than clear. It is possible, on the one hand, that the moderate level of aggregate volatility conceals a massive vote switching by citizens and communities. On the other hand, the available indirect evidence about India's recent electoral past sug­ gests that the volatility is much less than it appears, since much of it is accounted for by the young and the newly mobilized voters opting for the party of change.5 On current evidence, there are very few reasons to believe that the aggregate figures are completely off the mark in measuring vote-switching. Nor does a shift in voting S For� thesis see, William G. Vanderbok, 'Critical Elections. Contained Volatility and the Indian Electorate', in Richard Sisson and Ramashray Roy (eds), Divtnity tmdDominanct m Indian Politics, Vol I: Changing Basa ofCongrm Support (New Delhi: Sage, 1990). For an insightful analysis of electoral volatility see, Claus Orum Mogensen, 'Political Disordei:.and Electoral Vol­ atility i n India: An Ecological Study of Eight National Elections, 1957-89', unpublished MA dissert:ition,Institute for Statskundskab, Aarhus University, Denmark, 1994. D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The lnstitutiuns 191 habit appear to be a ficlde decision for the Indian voter. Over the years, the proportion of sophisticated voting has registered an increase. To that extent the phenomenon of electoral volatility continues to carry the seeds of transformative politics, notwith­ standing the complete non-realization of this possibility today. Post-Congress Polity? Whether the possibilities of transformative politics opened by the democratic upsurge and electoral volatility get reali:zed would depend upon how these changes are processed through the ap­ paratus of organi:zed politics, namely political parties. In this respect the assembly elections of 1993-5 have ushered in a new era in Indian politics. These elections mark the beginning of the third phase in the reconfigura tion of the pattern of party competi­ tion or, to use the old-fashioned jargon, the party system. The first phase of the famous 'Congress system' characterized by single-party dominance, lasted the fust two decades after In­ dependence. It was the big Congress versus small and fragmented forces of the opposition at the state as well as the national level. Congress successfully defied Duverger's law - which expected a two-party system to emerge in a plurality electoral system - by incorporating political competition and consociational arrange­ ments within its boundaries and yet holding it together through a delicate management of factions. The second phase, let us call it the 'Congress-Opposition system', was still characterized by one-party salience, though no longer dominance, of the Congress. Beginning of the plebiscitary mode of electoral politics saw the emergence of genuine competition to the Congress, both at the state and at the national level, often aided by electoral waves. Despite remaining out of power very often, the Congress retained a salience in the party system not only because it continued to command greater popular support than any opposition party, but also because it was the core around which the party system was structured. This phase saw the emergence ofbipolar consolidation in various states without yielding a b�larity at the national level. This system of'multiple bipolarities' was structured in such a way phrase from E. Sridhann who was kind enough to share his unpublished research and insights with me. 6 I borrow this Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 192 State and Politics in India that Congress was the only common factor across different pat­ terns of bipolarity in different states. The third phase inaugurated by the state assembly elections o f 1993-5 has decisively brought to an end the dominant multi-party system of the previous era. It definitely signals a move towards a competitive multi-party system which can no longer be defined with reference to the Congress. It may as yet be too early to expect a fully worked out picture of what the post-Congress system would look like. However, some of its features may be noted with refer­ ence to the recent assembly elections. First, it marks the near completion of the process of bipolar consolidation all over the country. Most of the southern and the eastern states had already entered the era of two-party competi­ tions. These elections extended it to Rajasthan, Gujarat, Maha­ rashtra and Sikkim, either by eliminating the minor forces in a hitherto multi-party system, or by throwing up a second party in a hitherto single-party dominant system. These elections were also marked by an intensification of political competition among the leading parties, whether in bipolar or multipolar competitions. It must be added, however, that the move towards bipolarity is never fully realized. There is a tendency, wimessed for instance in Andhra Pradesh, for the two leading parties to slip back somewhat in terms of the space they jointly occupied. In this sense, state politics in India is likely to both promise and frustrate .. the realization of Duverger's law. The data presented in Table 4.5 shows the rather high level of fractionalization in most of the states despite the bipolar consolida­ tion. States like Bihar, Manipur and Uttar Pradesh fall in the category of multi-party systems tending towards atomization. The entry of the BJP in Kamataka and SDF in Sikkim has contributed to a sudden jump in fractionalization score, while Orissa has experienced it without any new entrant. Andhra Pradesh, Delhi, Himachal, MP, Rajasthan and Sikkim continue to be comfortably bipolar. Second, the outcome of these elections makes the consolidation of bipolarity at the state level to add up to anything like a two-party system at the national level more improbable than ever before. The multiple bipolarity in the previous phase at least had Congress as a common factor. The assembly electio� of 1993-5 have removed even that. With the effective marginalization of the - Dig1t1zeo by Google Origi�al rrom UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The lnrtitutions 193 TABLE4.5 Party Fractionalization in Assembly Elections 1985-1995 States Andhra Pradesh Anmachal Pradesh 1984-5 .644 Bihar Delhi Goa Gujarat Himachal Pradesh Karnataka Madhya J>radesh Maharashtra Manipur .804 .631 .598 .639 .652 .768 Rajasthan .835 .643 .721 Sikkim Uttar Pradesh .789 Mizoram Orissa .555 1989-90 .641 .698 .851 .684 .746 .678 .707 .724 .801 .790 .621 .777 .476 .810 1993-5 .691 .716 .869 .674 .843 .711 .630 .777 .677 .855 .825 .726 .712 .699 .677 .807 Nata: 1. Table entries are for Rae's Fractionalization Index measured by summating the square of decimal vote share of each party and then subtracting the value obtained by 1. The closer the scores are to 1.0, the higher the party fnctionalization and vice versa. Since this index docs not recognize party alliances, it shows higher fnctional­ ization than exists on the ground in a state like Maharashtra. 2. Blank entries arc for states where there was no assembly election or the data is not available. Source: Computed from data at CSDS Data Unit. Congress from the real arena of electoral competition in UP and Bihar, the two largest states, these elections have begun an ap­ parently irreversible process of the reconfiguration of party sys­ tem. To be sure, it continues to be a case of multiple bipolarities, i.e. the existence of two-party systems at the state level, the diver­ sity ofwhich collates to give the appearance of a multi-party system at the qational level. It is more fragmented than before, but it is not the kind of fractionalization which is bound to result in atomization. Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 194 St11te tmd Politia in India Third, with the Congress gradually vacating the central posi­ tion (both in th e sense of occupying and denning the middle ground and being most prominent) there is likely to be a vacuum in the party system·at the national level. It is becoming more and more difficult and slippery to occupy the middle space in national politics. The Co11gress could do so earlier by constandy negotiat­ ing with the median points of the various ideological and social cleavages which divide Indian society, in order to make them coincide. In the last decade or so, the changes in the discursive terrain of these cleavages have resulted in the drifting apart of the various median points, making it more difficult than ever before to forge a correspondence required to be located i n the centre of emerging political configuration. Fourth, the decline of a dominant, centrist, catch-all party which retained its pre-eminence through cross-sectional mobiliza­ tion, had already started ·resulting in the rise of exclusivist parties with sectional political agendas. Situated on the peripheries of the party system, parties like the BSP are an outcome of the Congress's diminishing appeal across all sections of the society. Some of these may only prove 'flash parties' and might disappear as quickly as they emerged, but some of them are here to stay. Ironically, most of these political formations, which serve as instruments of demo­ cratization of society in favour of the hitherto disenfranchised sections, are themselves completely undemocratic in their or­ ganizational set-up as well as style of functioning. Finally, the above-mentioned features of the emerging con­ figuration of party formations need to be viewed against the baclc­ dr�p of the serious erosion of parties as organized vehicles of politics. The erosion is taking place from within as well as from without.There are indications that the well-known collapse of the organizational structure of the Congress is being replicated in that of its rivals as a result of the very logic of occupying the middle ground of politics. A near identification of parties with elections, their increasing inability to setde competing claims to power at the time of nom­ inations, and their inability to maintain an organic relationship with the electorate are some of the tendencies which cut across the political spectrum today and have been intensified in the recent past. This form of internal collapse contributes to and is in turn reinforced by the growing loss of legitimacy and trust in the parties Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The l'llltitutions 195 among the citizens. Over the last decade or more, this intense dissatisfaction with political parties has taken the fonn of with­ drawal among some sections of society, from the arena of electoral politics in favour of social and non-party political movements. The assembly elections of 1993-5 illustrated various consequences of this withdrawal ranging from middle class cynicism to attempts at forging a political alternative to the established political parties, None of the latter came anywhere close to crossing the minimum threshold of popular support required in the plurality system. However, its effects on the institutionalization of the party system should not be overlooked. The Indian party system is undergoing institutionalization and de-institutionalization simult1neously. On the one hand, the reach of the parties has increased and their capacity to draw allegiance expanded at the expense of non-party competitors. On the other hand, the depth or the intensity of the allegiance has been very sharply undermined, reducing the act of voting for parties to an instrumental moment. Viewed in this perspective, the apparently messy and localized character of the electoral outcome of 1993-5 begins to make sense and the infinite details of the performance of various parties yield something of a pattern. The summary description of electoral outcome in all these states presented in Table 4.6 brings out some of the broader patterns. It is a useful index, first of all, of the decline of the Congress. Notwithstanding its limited electoral success in those states, like Orissa, MP and Himachal, where there was no other alternative to a very unpopular and arbitrary regime, the electoral outcome has only confirmed the suspicion that a long-term decline of the Congress has begun. Its performance in these election-: cannot be described merely as a series of electoral defeats; there are several reasons to believe that what the Congress faces is a deep and enduring erosion in its support base. To begin with the most obvious, not only did the Congress lose power in many states, it has been relegated to the rank of the third party in the assemblies of UP, Bihar and Kamataka. At least in UP and Bihar the Congress may not count any more in deciding the way electoral battle lines are drawn. Second, its share of popular vote has suffered a serious erosion. Taking all the sixteen states into account, its vote share fails to touch the 30 per cent mark. In aggregate terms it means a decl(ne of 7 per cent votes as compared to Congress votes in Digiti zed by Google Ongmal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN TABLE 4.6 Vote Share by Parties in Assembly Elections 1993-1995 St11tes INC IJ']P JD Andhra Pradesh Anmachal Pradesh Bihar Delhi Gujarat Goa Himachal Pradesh Karnataka Madhya Pradesh Manipur Maharashtra Mizoram Orissa 32.3 50.6 16.5 34.4 32.7 37.6 49.4 27.3 40.7 30.1 31.0 33.1 39.4 38.7 15.0 15.1 28.3 3.8 3.4 13.1 42.8 42.5 9.0 36.1 16.7 38.8 3.7 12.8 3.1 7.9 38.6 0.2 33.3 22.5 0.1 17.3 27.6 12.7 2.8 2.8 2.2 4.9 0.2 1. 5 0.4 1.1 33.2 3.9 12.1 6.0 1.1 0.2 1.0 35.4 6.9 1.7 0.2 12.3 13.1 0.6 1.5 ,5 "' " -< 0. CJ C z < !!!o � .ii -"· ,, -� Rajasthan - - - CPI CPM BSP St11tt - - 5,6 0.3 - - - 0.8 0.5 0.3 0.2 0.9 - 0.7 1.0 0.2 0.5 1.0 Pta,t, 1 1.3 TOP - JP 1.3 SP 1.9 SP - MGP - 1.4 2.2 1.0 KCP 6.8 SP - MPP 1.4 SHS - MNF 0.5 JMM 0.4 SP - SDF 10.7 SP Voter St11tt Voter IND 0TH . Pta,ty 2 42.2 2.5 6.8 JMMS 0.5 - 22.2 UGDP - - 7.1 0.6 23.7 16.6 40.4 2.0 0.1 42.0 18.1 - 3.7 8.3 - KRRS - 2.6 FPM BRP SJP - 6.1 2.9 - SSP - 1.4 - 35.2 6.3 26.2 14.0 6.0 19.3 14.0 9.2 7.0 5.9 5 .1 22.0 23.4 10.1 12.9 5.9 6.9 9.0 9.0 0.0 10.6 2.6 2.7 7.5 3.3 4.4 4.3 13.4 6.1 0.9 5.2 1.5 9.5 -;;: g Sikkim Uttar Pradesh Total z Sormt: Data available at CSDS Data Unit, based on constituency-wise election results released by the chief election officer of 0'!!. � ::i: - - - - - - the concerned states. 196 The Institutions 197 these states in the 1991 Lok Sabha elections. Even after allowing for the usual fragmentation of votes of a national party in the assembly elections, the swing is of a serious order. In Bihar and UP its vote share has fallen well below the 20 per cent mark and in Karnataka and Sikkim below the 30 per cent mark. In these states, the Congress stands at the receiving end of the logic of plurality system which might further hasten its decline. The third evidence of Congress decline comes from the fall in the Congress's success in retaining its own seats. This fall has taken place even in a state like Madhya Pradesh where the Congress otherwise did well in the elections. Apart from statistics of electoral outcome, there is a lot more to substantiate the hypothesis about the decline of the Congress. An average Congress vote is more 'shallow' than before in that it is not backed by a deep conviction or loyalty; quite often it is a reluctant vote open to shift in the near future. Besides, the erosion of support for the Congress among the Muslims is quite evident by now. The available evidence from academic surveys in Bihar and Maharashtra substantiates the view that given an effective choice (and in some cases even in its absence) the Muslim voters would rather choose any party but the Congress. The evidence about tribal and dalit votes is still unclear. The popular impression tends to underestimate the resilience of the Congress among these marginal sections. These elections also demonstrated the Congress's loss of institu­ tionalized will to power which had characterized its days of dom­ inance in Indian politics. Consequently it has lost the drive even to win the elections. Its failure to subordinate familial considerations to winnability at the time of selection of candidates, its meek acceptance of institutionalized rebellion and its failure to manage factions are various manifestations of the loss of institutionalized will to power (not to be confused with personal ambitions). Though it is difficult to predict the trajectory of Congress decline in the short run, it is absolutely clear that the Congress would do much worse in the forthcoming Lok Sabha elections than it did in 1991. With some risk, it can also be predicted that the Congress is headed for its lowest ever vote share in any general election to the Lok Sabha. What remains to be seen is how its votes translate in terms of parliamentary seats. As far as the medium and the long run is concerned, there does not seem to be much hope for the Congress. Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 198 St11te and Politia in India Shon of miraculous reinvention, there is no W2}' the existing Con­ gress can serve as a vehicle for the enfranchisement of backward castes or the recent democratic upsurge. A failure in this respect spells doom for a party in the times to come. I t is not that the Congaess will disappear overnight or that it will disappear at all; but it may tum into just another party, one among many. Such a possibility immediately raises the question of alrematives. The eleaoral outcome of 1993-5 does throw some light on popular. support of various non-Congress parties, though it is too early to talk about their long-term pro,,peus. Of these, the BJP's perfor­ mance bas been watched most keenly and has aroused some con­ troversy, not bcc:mse the evidence is equivocal but because the interpreters are narrowly partisan. On balance it is clear that al­ though the BJP's apparendy inevitable march to power has slowed down and has suffered many upsets, it has not quire been reversed. During the 1993-5 elections the BJP has consolidated its dramatic gains in 1989 and 1991 parliamentuy elections, despire a marginal loss of l per cent between 1991 and 1993-5 in these states. With the benefit of hindsight, it is better to see the BJP's defeat in Himachal, MP and UP as a point-er to the limits of the non-political route to power rather than a final rejection of the BJP. Currently the BJP shows many signs of a party on the rise. In the course of the 1993-5 elections it spread out to newer areas (north R.ajasthan, west UP, Marathwada and south Gujarat, to mention a few), newer segments of society (Sikhs in Delhi, QBCs in UP and Maharashtra, tribals in Gujarat and R.ajasthao) and strengthened its support base among the youth. In the short-term future, the BJP is likely to make further gains within the limits set by the absence of its effectivepolitical reach in the coastal belt from Kerala to West Bengal. But its coming to power at the centre would be conditional upon its overcoming this limitation and thus con­ verting a large nwnber of its potential supporters into actual voters. It also needs to successfully internalize the social cleavages of Indian society and transform its organization significantly to channelize the recent democratic upsurge. These are difficult tasks. The politi­ cal developments of the last year have shown that despite possessing an institutionalized political ambition, the BJP has not found it easy to handle caste cleavages. The gap between the 'demand' and 'supply' side of politics is most evident in the case of political formations vying to be the Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutions 199 'third force' in the electoral arena. Paradoxically, although social constituency of the third force has expanded due to the recent democratic upsurge, electoral support for its leading party, the Janata Dal, has sharply dwindled. The results of assembly elections held during 1993-5 conftnn the trend which had already emerged in the 1991 Lok Sabha elections. Uajike the BJP, theJD has failed to consolidate its nationwide gains of 1989-90 and has managed ·to survive only in a few regional pockets. However, in those pockets it has not lost very much since 1991. While a good deal of the ]D's failure to make use of the historic opportunity of 1989 must be accounted for by its organizational and leadership failure to put together a credible party, there is perhaps more to it. Perhaps the newly enfranchised constituency of the marginal so­ cial groups is not yet amenable to macro political appeals. They are drawn into the arena of competitive politics via partisan al­ legiance to issues and organizations which are primarily local or at best regional in character. That makes it structurally more · difficult for a single political party to effectively represent this emerging social constituency; regional political formations are the most likely carriers of democratic upsurge in this new phase of democratic politics. In this perspective it is easy to see why the Janata Dal has survived only in those states where it functions, for all practical purposes, as a regional political party which has its own identity, leadership and nearly independent ideology. The project of building a viable and credible political force which may occupy the third space in Indian politics is going to be crucial for institutionalizing the second democratic upsurge witnessed in the recent elections. The failure of the Janata Dal illustrates how difficult it is to occupy the middle ground in national politics which is now being vacated by the. Congress. The legacy of the national movement enabled the Congress to occupy and define the middle ground of various ideological and social cleavages. The resultant enduring loyalties of a cross-section of the electorate to the Congress ensured its electoral success. Any new political formation without such a historical advantage finds this ground too slippery now. If it tries to catch all, it loses any distinctiveness and thus ends up catching none. If, on the other hand, it tries to acquire and maintain distinctiveness, it ends up being exclusivist and loses its capacity for cross-sectional mobilization. 'The political extinction D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 200 State and Politics in India faced by Janata Dal in most parts of the country is directly related to this dilemma. It also explains some of the problems which confront the BJP today. The absence of a straight path to the occupation of the middle ground has encouraged enterprising political actors to force their entry through different routes. Of these, the two which yielded electoral rerurns involved the forging of a 'master cleavage'. The BJP worked on the master cleavage of Hindus versus Others with the help of a sustained communal propaganda and followed it up with routine political work in local terms. The electoral outcome shows that Hindu consolidation is bound to be temporary and fragile, open to other cross-cutting cleavages. Laloo Yadav's strat­ egy in Bihar aimed at another master cleavage: high caste versus low caste, backed up by a symbolically charged theatre of empower­ ment He reaped the electoral harvest as the BJP did in some states following the rath yat1·a. It is not clear if his attempt at creating dalit-Muslim-OBC combine would have a longer lease of life than the BJP's attempt at Hindu consolidation. Apart from proble1ns of longevity, both these routes to the centre of politics suffer from inherent limitations from the vantage point of radical democracy. Whither Democratization? This preliminary sketch of the picture of Indian politics as seen from the window of elections must also note, however fleetingly, some of the larger processes which constitute a background to the more obvious movement of parties and leaders. A comparison of the snapshot of 1993-5 elections with elections of the previous phase of Indian politics brings out some of the enduring structural changes which have silently redefined the terrain of electoral politics. Three of these changes need to be foregrounded here: one, the simultaneous regionalization and homogenization of the political terrain; two, new forms of political articulation and in­ vention of social cleavages; and three, the changing terms of political discourse. All three changes directly bear upon the long­ term prospects of democratization. In a sense the most significant outcome of these elections is the lack of a neat pattern which cuts across different states. It brings into sharp relief the regionalization of Indian polity at the end of two decades of plebiscitary politics at the national level. D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVEF\S1�.OF"'.1l�HIGAN. The Institutions 20 I A comparison with any of the previous 'national' rounds of as­ sembly elections - 1971-2, 1977-8, 1979-80, 1984-5, or even . 1989-90 - suggests a sharp contrast. In each of these earlier rounds there was a clear nationwide verdict: one-party coalitions swept across states, barring exceptions. At the end of the 1993-5 round of assembly elections, the political path of India is more variegated than ever before. The number and the ideological range of political formations which have a share in the cake of state power is unprecedented in post-Independence India. Thus these elections have quietly accomplished what the par­ liamentary elections of 1989 and 1991 could not fully do, namely to put an end to the age of nationwide electoral waves. This era, which began with the parliamentary elections of 1971, was char­ acterized by a series of plebiscites which resulted in mobilization for or against the Congress, which cut across special boundaries of constituencies, states and regions (with the partial exception of the north-south divide) and thus eliminated the local character of electoral contests. The latest verdict may not have quite restored the local character of elections, but it did bring back the assembly elections to their original context, namely state politics. From the horizon of a future historian one of the most noticeable outcomes in these elections is the rupturing of the 'Hindi heartland', the home ground of electoral waves in the 1970s and 1980s. This region rarely saw any deviation from the direction of national waves; at the end of the 1993-5 round, the four largest states in this region were being governed by four rival political formations. It is not as if the processes of integration and homogenization which made electoral waves possible have been reversed. In fact, these elections did witness several waves in different states (Himachal Pradesh, Delhi, Madhya Pradesh, Andhra Pradesh and Gujarat) or in different regions of the state (eastern UP, north Bihar, Konkan and Bombay). The difference of course is that the direction of these waves varies from state to state. The locus and the operative level of the logic of electoral wave has shifted from nation to states. A state like Madhya Pradesh illustrates very well the extent to which processes of political integration have levelled intra-state differences in politicization and party preferences. Thus this regionalization should not be interpreted as the first step towards localization of political competition; it may be more useful to see it :as a typically Indian path to homogenization. Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 202 State 11nd Politics in India Unlike in the West, this process would not obliterate all differen­ ces and create a mass society; here it would mean, paradoxically, ftrst a segmentation and then effective homogenization within that segment or sector while rl'taining and foregrounding dif­ ferences v i sa-vis other sectors. These segments could be ter­ ritorial or social, but the vehicle of their integration is in most cases competitive politics; no wonder, differences and conflicts are built into this model of sectoral homogenization. There is no doubt that an effective regionalization of a polity of this size would strengthen the process of democratization. However, it is possible to overstate tliis argument if one neglects the internal regimentation which accompanies it. In a similar way, the second long-term trend, namely the new mode of political articulation of social cleavages also leaves an ambiguous message for the future of democratization. The most significant trend of the recent assembly elections in this respect was the acceleration of the delayed but inevitable rise of the OBCs to political power in north India. The process began in Bihar ftrst of all, thanks to the legacy of socialist politics among the backward castes. This election did not merely continue this long-term pro­ cess but would be remembered as a landmark in the political rise of OBCs. First, because it has expanded beyond the boundaries of Bihar into UP. Second, it put a stamp of inevitability and irre­ versibility on this trend by handing a decisive defeat to the most determined resistance to the rise of OBCs in the Bihar elections of 1995. Although currently OBC politics in different states is very unevenly placed (if Bihar and UP define one end of the spectrum, Orissa and Rajasthan lie at the other end, apparently untouched by this wave), its extension to the remaining s.tates is now a matter of time. The constitution and then the rise of OBCs as a political community are examples of how marginalized groups can make an unorthodox and unanticipated use of the levers of competitive politics to make a place for themselves. Here is a living exam1>le of what Benedict Anderson had called 'imagined communities'. The expression 'OBCs' has indeed travelled a long way from a. rather careless bureaucratic nomenclature in the document of the Constitution to a vibrant and subjectively experienced political community. It also confirms the continuing creative role of politics in articulating and, in the process, transforming social cleavages D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutions 203 in contemporary India. Needless to say, as much of the contem­ porary social science has reminded us, the redrawing of social cleavages takes place by forging new identities through shared narratives of the past and, sometimes, of the future. This election also witnessed another, though less successful, route to the same end. Attempts at creating a social coalition of the marginalized sections of the arena of electoral politics were made not just in UP, Bihar and Maharashtra but, in a less visible form, elsewhere too. The break-up of the SP-BSP alliance and the disastrous performance of the Bahujan Mahasangh serve to remind us that this coalition building is a very delicate and difficult operation, bordering on the impossible. And in the absence of an effective ideological chain of equivalence among these sectional concerns, the resultant coalition can produce at best stapled iden­ tities which can come apart very easily. The other major development in this respect was the realign­ ment of the Muslim community following the destruction of the Bahri Masjid. It will take some more time, perhaps a few more elections, for the new pattern to settle down, but it is clear that there has been considerable disenchantment with the established leadership and the Congress party among Muslims all over the country. Although this dissatisfaction is not yet captured by a new political formation, it is clear that the early fears of Muslims being forced into exclusivist politics were exaggerated. In the long run, the events of 6 December may have given the various com­ munities which happen to profess Islam a new supra-local Muslim ·• identity. This development parallels the emergence of supra-local caste identities in the recent elections. Increasingly, caste is not a local consideration which works in favour of a candidate of one's own caste. Now caste identities and affiliations are imagined at the level of the state. The disengagement of caste from its localized context is but another manifestation of sectoral homogenization discussed above. On balance, then, the consequences of a new casteism are likely to strengthen the process of democratization. At the same time it needs to be remembered that in the absence of political mediation of sectional claims characteristic of the Congress system, the over­ all effect may not be as benevolent as one might expect. If the experiments at coalition making continue to fail, it is likely that Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 204 State and Politics in India the newly acquired identities will get hardened and would conse­ quently be less open to political negotiations. In this respect India is gradually ceasing to be an exception to the social cleavage theory of party system which expects political parties to form strictly along the demographic fault-line in multi-ethnic societies. It is not that the demographic, cultural and political expressions o f social cleavages have come to coincide in India. However, we have taken some steps in that direction in the last few years. Finally, a look at the world.of ideas or the ideological field as reflected in the mirror of the state assembly elections. The last few years have wimessed a sea change in the terms of political discourse. The collapse of the Soviet Union, the end of the Cold War, the triumphant entry of globalization and liberalization, and the rise of communalism have significantly reshaped the concerns, issues and positions in the elite discourse on Indian politics. These elections provided an occasion to fmd out if some of these changes have been reflected in popular discourse as well. Is there a signific­ ant value change underlying the recent political reconfiguration? Have recent issues successfully drawn new ideological cleavages which cut across the old ideological lines, or have they been absorbed by the latter? Are we wimessing an intensification of ideological polarities? It is easier to answer these questions with reference to the production end of the ideological field than its reception. The changes effected by various political formations in their ideologi­ cal postures are rather well known. They basically involve the redeployment of the nationalist vocabulary for newer ends. Be­ hind the usual rhetoric of opposition, practically all the major political formations agreed to shift the political agenda to the right as understood in the old left-right ideological continuum. Acceptance of unrestricted entry of foreign firms, retreat not only from a regime of controls, but also from social welfare program­ mes, tacit acceptance that the majority will prevail in communal disputes, acceptance of 'tough' policy on Kashmir - all these have come to constitute the national consensus across political divisions. Very few polities can claim to have made the transition from the old to the new world with so little discursive contest­ ation. The amazing ease with which the old rhetoric of socialism has· given way to the new lingo of global capitalism is not only a comment on how thin the old ideology had worn, but also on D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutions 205 how defenceless India's political establishment is in the face of the latest from the West. These elections also provided an in­ stance of the resilience of the political processes and their capacity to absorb sharp ideological polarities such as the dispute around reservations. Any generalization about the reception of political ideas in the register of popular sensibilities can at best be suggestive in the absence of any serious research on this aspect of Indian politics. On the face of it, it does not seem that anything like an ideological polarity has emerged in the structure of popular political beliefs. Rather, ideological cleavages in the public arena do not get articu­ lated as opposite opinions on shared issues and concerns. In India ideological polarity takes the form of mutually exclusive discursive fields rooted in social cleavages. Often defined by the master cleavage of English versus the vernacular and further subdivided by social hierarchy, these different ideological communities are characterized b y very low internal polarization and a higher polar­ ization across the discursive boundaries. More often than not, ideological polarization is rooted in incomprehensibility of dif­ ferent actors situated in different circles of intelligibility. What appears as an ideological difference is mostly a function of social origins, for ideas do not disseminate in a social vacuwn. They travel along established trails which closely follow sociological fault-lines. That is why higher ideological issues are not accessible to the subalterns. Even if they are, they are clothed in local costumes and are inevitably received through the lens of local partisanship. This is what accounts for the differential response to issues like Manda! and Mandir, not to speak of even more remote ones like the New Economic Policy or the Uniform Civil Code from the localized registers of popnJar sensibility. The problem of radical incomprehension is not confined to subaltern reception of elite ideologies; this logic also works the other way round. The new democratic upsurge does not merely mean a greater number of voters, it also means a massive influx of new beliefs not shaped by the high ideology of liberal demo­ cracy. The subaltern acceptance of the democratic invitation inevitably means a reshaping of the political agenda in accordance with their tastes, convictions and expectations. Whether it is Mayawati's venomous utterances or Laloo Yadav's histrionics, the vocabulary of politics has come to reflect, even if momentarily, Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 206 State 1171d Politics in India the world of popular culture. Seen from the vantage point of high ideologies, this is nothing less than an ideological degenera­ tion, or rather, scandal. The assembly elections did not and could not have bridged this radical incomprehensibility. The reshaping of the political agenda to reflect the influence of popular beliefs in the public arena remains a major ideological challenge in contemporary Indian politics which, if not met, can corrode the legitimacy of the democratic political order. • What is to be Done? As interventions in an essentially contested cognitive domain, interpretations of politics cannot escape the politics of interpreta­ tion. Therefore the political agenda implicit in the reading of electoral politics offered above is best explicated, even if in an abbreviated manner. For those who take the consolidation and radicalization of democracy as the agenda of transformative pol­ itics today, the challenge is to take the recent participatory upsurge to its radical conclusion. It is a two-pronged political challenge. It is an organizational challenge on the one hand, involving the forging of a new political instrument capable of responding to the democratic upsurge in a way the established political formations are unable to. The creation of an organization capable of tapping the enormous energy released into the political process by the entry of hitherto unincorporated sections into mainstream politics and the intervention of non-party political formations, working at the grass-roots level and reflecting the federal character of Indian society within its organization without ceasing to function at the all-India level or rejecting the task of building a democratic or­ ganizational structure, is surely a historic need today. But history does not fulfil its own needs. On the other hand, it is an ideological challenge requiring innovative institutional designs which may reduce the existing disjunction between the cultural codes of or­ dinary citizens and the imported institutions of modem liberal democracy, incorporation of new issues thrown up by social move­ ments into the political agenda and the creation of a chain of democratic equivalence among various such issues within a single ideological framework. Such a proposal might sound hopelessly ' romantic in the face of shrinking horizons of political possibilities. But the limits of political possibilities are drawn and redrawn as Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutions 207 much by human imagination and agency as by the external world of causality and structures. This is one lesson well worth remem­ bering in a society which has, in the last one hundred years, wimessed an extraordinarily creative and transformative role of politics. D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 5 Evolving Trends in the Bureaucracy B.P.R. Vithal �e bureaucracy in India is neither monolithic nor homo­ .l geneous. This would, perhaps, be !JUe of any bureaucracy, to the extent that it reflects the social and class composition of society at large and of the ruling class in each society in particular. In the case of India, however, heterogeneity of the bureaucracy was consciously planned by the British in view of the peculiar circumstances of their rule. To begin with, the administration of the East India Company - in India - was entirely in the hands of Company servants who were British nationals. "When they first became rulers (from being mere traders), they acquired that statuS by grants which were in the nature of feudal grants which the then rulers of India were customarily giving to their own citizens. Finally, the Company took over the role of the major feudatory, namely the Emperor in Delhi. For some time the Company re­ tained only this role and as such the question of Indians becoming direct employees of the Company in any administrative capacity did not arise. With the dominion in India extending, and the complexity of its administration increasing, Indians had to be brought in to take up subordinate positions. The entire structure underwent a change as a result of the Crown taking over the administration directly and. more so, as a consequence of the educational policy of Macaulay, which aimed to 'form a class who may be in'terpreters between us and the millions whom we govern'. This class, which to this day substantially rules India, came to be known by the Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institution; 209 widely prevalent term 'babus'.1 With the entrance of Indians into it, British administration which was vertically integrated became highly articulated. It consisted of three modules (which could also be described as echelons or levels). It is necessary to describe these three echelons briefly because the evolution of Indian bureaucracy, its changing self-perception, and its relations with the public in general and politicians in particular, have varied significantly. The top echelon consisted of the covenanted services (now lmown as the All India Services), of which the most typical and best-lmown service was the Indian Civil Service (ICS).2 The British concept of the ICS was unique not merely as a colonial service but, at the time of its original conception, also as a tool of administration itself. After the ancient Chinese system, this was, perhaps, the first Civil Service to be deliberately and con­ sciously constituted on the basis of recruitment by means of examination. The role conceived for this service was also unique because it heralded the transformation of the British administrator from ruler to guardian.3 When Indians were taken into the ICS, the initial screening and separation from their origins and their admission to a new culture was effected through the educational system and, subsequently, their training in the Oxbridge milieu. The Service succeeded, by and large, in building up a tradition of integrity and professional competence that helped to impart to it a unique aura. Whatever may have been its negative aspects, by virtue of its being the Service of a foreign ruler, were removed with Inde­ pendence. But its aura burgeoned and continued to attract young men and women to the All India Services. Inflation considerably reduced its material and monetary attractions, though many young men and women still chose it partly because of its continuing prestige and, also, partly as a means of serving the country without undue sacrifice. As Nehru once remarked, the IAS definitely be­ came Indian; some of its members tried to be civil; and service I E.P. Moon, The B,-itish Cmque$t and D<miini<m of India (London: Verso, 1990). 2 We shall continue to use the tenn 'Covenanted Services', because not only are all its connotations not fully brought out by the term 'All India Services', but also it is homophonic with 'Coveted Services' which would be an apt malapropism. 3 P. Mason, Mm Wbo RrdedIndia, 2 volumes (London:Jonathan Cape, 1985). Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 210 State 1111d Politics in India was at least one of its motives. Subsequendy, professions and management posts in the private sector became economically at­ tractive. Passing the entrance examination of the Indian Institute of Technology became as much a cause for celebration as passing the Indian Administrative Service (IAS) e,aroination once used to be. However, over the years, with professional employrnent op­ portunities not growing adequately and with the tenns and con­ ditions of such employment not always being much more attractive than those of the IAS (except in the case of large industrial houses or the multinationals), the higher administrative and allied services again became an attractive option. Those who were motivated to serve found that the variety of work of an IAS officer added to the challenge and attraction of the Service, while the power and opportunities available for senior civil servants in an administra- _ _ tion with a large number of bureaucratic restrictions and controls made it attractive for those who liked the trappings of authority. In 1985, when Rajiv Gandhi became Prime Minister, the approach of the government towards the services underwent a dramatic change. P. Chidambaram, the Minister for Personnel, brought his influence to bear on the bureaucracy, in an effort to make it more professional. This resulted in an improvement in the emoluments of the central government services to make them comparable with other professions in trade, commerce, and in­ dustry. However, this policy was attacked on the ground that it was financially ruinous. The effect of the changes was to make the higher civil services more attractive to young persons seeking professional careers. A conscious effort was made in the media to 'sell these Services', and the higher civil services came to be looked upon as a good career prospect. This by itself need not have resulted in a change of motivation· among new entrants, because the pursuit of a career, in a profes­ sional sense, would need the same skills and attitudes that the earlier approach would have eJ\couraged. However, a .'hard sell' of the civil services also encourages certain elements who can best be described as 'careerists'. Such a change of attitude would tend to underplay the earlier 'service' aspect of the higher civil services and, �tead, emphasize the opportunities available for exploiting the power of the state which administers, controls, and dispenses patronage. That the public are also aware of these particular . advantages is evident from the· fact that the valuation of these · Dlgltlzedby Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutions 211 services in the dowry market has gone up. The dowry market in Indian society serves the same purpose in evaluating relative job prospects as the share market does for fmancial invesonents in Western countries. The next echelon in the administration is another unique Brit­ ish contribution, namely the gazetted officers (GOs). Such officers could be Indians even at a time when Indians had not yet been admitted to the Indian Civil Service. They were given certain status and symbols, and privileges of office, which distinguished them from the mass of lower officialdom, who were also Indians and who then came to be known as non-gazetted officers (NGOs). It is interesting to note that, apart from other conditions, one of the distinguishing features of these services was that their postings and transfers were to be published in the official gazette! By such innocuous and token formalities, the British managed to generate status and authority. This was a device which Indians also readily understood and relished because it reflected, in administration, their own concept of the 'twice-born' who, by merit of birth (recruionent) and by peculiar rituals (gazetting), were differen­ tiated from and placed on a higher level than the ordinary people (i.e. the NGOs). An interesting example of the grip exercised by this idea on the Indian psyche, which persisted even after Inde­ pendence, is the Andhra Pradesh secretariat In that part of it which was inherited from the Madras Presidency, there were NGOs (evdn as late as in 1959) who would wear trousers and a jacket but not a tie, because it was assumed that only GOs were entitled by custom to don a necktie! The next tier down consisted of NGOs who constituted the rest of the administration. The term 'non-gazetted officer' is itself a novel classification for, during the colonial period, 'officers' were, by definition, 'gazetted', and all 'non-gazetted' government servants were referred to as 'officials'. But with Independence, the new government sought to 'decolonize' the bureaucracy by erasin g the distinction between gazetted and non-gazetted government servants by referring to'both as 'officers'. By a similar process o{ upgradation, peons became attenders and were accorded the status of Class IV government servants. There was, however, one top layer of this part of the ad­ ministration in the civil services which acted as a link between the administration as a whole and the gazetted officers, or in Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 212 State and Politics in India some cases directly with the covenanted services. These were officials who occupied the key posts of personal assistants to the members of the covenanted services or those holding top level superintending posts. In the army, the non-commissioned officers (NCOs) represented this particular level between the other ranks (ORs) on one side, and the commissioned officers (COs) on the other. In the civil services, the picture became somewhat blurred because the category of gazetted officers was interposed between the covenanted services and the NGOs. The importance of this level here lies in the link it provided between the higher civil services on the one hand, and the mass of the civil service on the other. The character of this link evolved from the way in which British officials deployed the particular Indian functionary in their entourage. The relationship between the British official and his personal assistant was maintained by mutual respect. Indian administrators in general have not been able to emulate the example of their British forbears in this respect, perhaps because both belong to the same cultural milieu. This relationship of mutual respect has been preserved to a much greater extent in the military by means of an artificial ethos built within and around the armed services. In the civil services, by contrast, democratization of the civil administrations since Inde­ pendence has stood in the way of the British colonial convention being continued. As a consequence, i n tra -service links have tended to become rigidly formalized and the different echelons have drifted apart. It is interesting to note that, in a few cases where the peculiar mystique of these posts has been retained, they have sometimes become conduits of corruption involving officers of the higher echelons. Each of the three echelons of administration, namely the cov­ enanted services, the gazetted services and non-gazetted services, has evolved in its own way since Independence. The most im­ portant changes in respect of the n o n -gazetted services relate to their unionization. This has resulted in a greater homogeneity in their outlook, despite the fact that there are usually several unions representing different categories within the non-gazetted cate­ gory. Gazetted officers as a group have generally lost out during the post-Independence period. The distinction between gazetted officers and non-gazetted officers helped the government in deal­ ing with strikes by the latter, but the resulting benefit to the D1g1t1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The lnstitutums 213 gazetted officers was insufficient to compensate the sense of alienation between the two categories inherited from the Raj. For with Independence, the government's efforts to improve the status of gazetted officers foundered on the rock of translating them into monetary equivalents. Separation from non-gazetted services has been followed by gazetted officers enjoying commen­ surate non-monetary benefits. As a consequence, gazetted officers, including professional services such as doctors and engineers, have tended to unionize. Their problems, however, fall into a different category because they raise issues concerning generalists vmus specialists, which are not discussed here. Administrators as a Sociological Category How do these three categories fit into the paradigm provided by Bardhan's concept of 'professionals' as a 'proprietary class' exploit­ 'ing their 'cultural capital' and extracting 'rent' income from their scarce educational and technical sail, .and Rudra's related concept of the class of 'intelligentsia'. In his discussion of these various concepts, Vanaik has stated that bureaucratic elites at the Centre are far less susceptible to the pressure of the agrarian bourgeoisie ... [while) in the States[,] the more lo­ calized the bureaucracy, the more subordinated it is to the power of. the rural rich. The industrial bourgeoisie clearly exercises greater authority on the bureaucracy at the Centre. 4 The NGOs and the GOs, being employees of the state govern­ ments, are mostly subject to pressures from �-agrarian bourgeois elements which are strongly represented iri the state governments and legislatures. The IAS officer is subject to pressures from the industrial bourgeoisie when (s)he is at the centre while (s)he is subject to pressure by the a&1;�ian bourgeoisie when (s)he works at the state level. Most politicians, however, are still graduating from agrarian bourgeois politics at the state level to politics at the central level. Politicians rooted in the modern urban-industrial , complex, with interests ):r.rfdly distinguishable from those of the industrial bourgeoisie, are still few in number. This has helped strengthen the role of the IAS officer at the centre because, among 4 A. Vanaik, Tbt PainfiJ Transition: Bourgeois Dtmocracy in India (London: Verso, 1990). D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 214 State and Politics in India the many central services directly employed by the central govern­ ment with whom (s)he has to compete when (s)he is at the centre, (s)he belongs to the only category of officers which has direct working acquaintance with the politician at the state level. The insights o f IAS officers into the mutual interests of agriculture and industry (or their mutual contradictions) are, therefore, likely to be sharper than those of other functionaries at the centre. While their relations may thus be synergic, it still does not make them a 'Net11-Babu' class, as Krishna maintains.5 Class interests and cultural background could be expected to fuse together only at the lower level of district politician and the NGO. Again, at the top level, an urban-orientated industrial-professional-higher civil ser­ vice class may well be emerging. In discussing the role of the bureaucracy in the liberalization programme, Vanaik righ�y points out that the caution in regard to this programme arises 'not because of subterranean resistance from a bureaucratic class [but because] significant sections of the state elite along with important sections of the industrial bour­ geoisie are themselves concerned that liberalization should not proceed too far too fast. >6 It would, therefore, be relevant to point out that a liberalization programme has been launched with great speed; we now have to explain the reasons behind that speed, rather than those underly­ ing the cautious approach of the earlier phase. Resistance to the liberalization programme is now characterized as ·mainly 'bureaucratic' in character. Of course, wider issues such as the role played by international capital, international financial institutions, industrial and agrarian bourgeoisie, etc. are involved. But what concerns us in this discussion is that there has been a noticeable change in the attitude of the bureaucratic elite. Part of this change is intellectual and professional in origin, but other motivations have also come into play. It is necessary to draw attention at this point to the recent acceleration, especially since the 1980s, of professionalization with­ in the IAS, the main generalist service. Even in the ICS, a certain informal specialization in finance did take place. Now, as part of the modern concept of 'career development', specialization, after s Ibid., p. 23. 6 lbid. D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutions 215 an initial period of common District experience, is being guided and encouraged within the IAS. Specialization leading to jobs in the economic ministries is the most sought after. The interface with and transition to international financial bodies (such as the Inter­ national Monetary Fund and World Bank) takes place from this point onwards. As in all interface phenomena, a certain intellectual seepage occurs at this level. Very soon the players on either side of the international divide find themselves having more in common than the national officials and those whom they are supposed to represent 1bis is also reinforced by the fact that the discipline of economics, in which those concerned with these decisions are specialists, has been iiitemationalized with a single ruling paradigm and ideology within the framework of which professionals work together. Jt cannot be deqied, however, that pan of the motivation arises from the fact that: international financial.institutions provide im­ portant and attractive career prospects for generalist professionals. Equally importantly, the composition of the IAS itself has under­ gone a chl!,Dge. In recent years, several persons with qualifications , in engineering or management or eQOnomics have entered the Service. Children of senior bureaucrats and professionals now exercise their fust option in favour of professional courses, whilst the IAS itself is ahnost invariably only a second choice. To the extent, therefore, that the liberalization programme would be expected to result in increased opporrunities for trained profes­ sionals in the economy as a whole, the senior bureaucrat would now look upon it as. opening a broader an<! rnore varied career spectrum for the next generation of his/her class than public sector employment, which is all that the exisd,ng model has to offer. Thus, whilst a large part of the IAS is now identifying with th e aspirations o f the industrial bourgeoisie, there are still a number of officers who are interested in agl}lrian problems with which they are .familiar because of their intimate acquaintance with the countryside. Therefore, the. higher civil service is not simply the site occupied by 'political elites'; a significant fraction of it has, over the last twenty-five years, become involved in 'intra-coalition conflicts' which have become an important feature of politics a t the state level. D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 216 State and Politics in India Politicization of the Civil Services Against this general background, let us consider the phenomenon of politicization of the services. When Rajiv Gandhi drew atten­ tion (1985) to the need to eliminate power-brokers from the political arena, he also emphasized the need to depoliticize the services. Without going into a discussion of the tenn 'politic­ ization', we shall use it in the broad sense in which it is generally understood. Politicization, in the sense of alignment with a politi­ cal party, is hardly applicable to the civil services except in the case of those whose sympathies lie with one or other of the cadre parties. Politicization in the sense of commitment to an ideology is rare even among card carrying members of non-cadre parties which are really loose coalitions of different groups and interests. In recent years, however, this situation has changed. Even though the Congress party was defeated in 1977, up to 1989 it was widely regarded as the party with power. The defeat of the Congress in the 1977 election was seen as a reaction to the Emer­ gency rather than as signalling change of a paradigmatic nature. The Janata government's poor performance _gave-i:ise to-a-wide­ spread belief that the Congress party was the natural ruling party in India. In 1989, however, this outlook was completely shattered. The prospect of a single party monopolizing power indefinitely became truly remote only after the ninth general election. With the onset of the changed outlook, political parties staned to take a hard look at their proposed programmes: In the tenth general election (1991), the preparation of the manifestos of the different parties were, for the ftrst rime,_ given serious attention because they could constitute the bases on which coalitions would have to be forged. Therefore, politicization, in the sense of com­ mitment to the principles of a party, is now (unlike in the past) possible. However, even today, those elements in the bureaucracy that are believed to be politically committed would consist of sympathizers of either of the communist parties or the BJP, which represent the two tendencies with clear-cut programmes and deep commitment. Politicization of the services, therefore, largely refers to civil servants playing politics. In most cases, the motivation underlying politicization lies in the furtherance of one's career or in taking advantage of opportunities to engage in corruption. In the case D1g1tizeo by Google -· . - - -- Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN .. The Institutions 217 of the NGOs as a category, however, politicization of a more academic nature, arising from strong unionization, has been pos­ sible. The NGOs - in most states as well as at the centre are now fairly well organized into unions. Therefore, they tend to form collective perceptions of which govemment(s) is/are likely to adopt a sympathetic view to their demands. Their approach is generally econornistic in character. Political' parties attach much importance to securing the sup­ port of the NGOs. In fact, the importance attached to NGO support is often out of proportion to their numerical size as potential vote banks. Rather, their. importance is seen to rest in their opinion-forming. role. Nearly 7 S per cent of the NGOs are teachers, police constables, and Class IV officers. These categories of government employees are widely distributed. They wield considerable influence and prestige in different segments of so­ ciety. In recent years, however, the importance attached to em­ ployees' unions arises not only because they influence opinion, but also because they play ah important role in the election process itself. They are entrusted with the conduct of elections. No booth capturing - except in the most blatant and violent cases - would be possible without the cooperation, or at least connivance, of this category of civil servants. This fact alone has tended to ·give added importance to transfers 0£ officials on the eve of elections - a faetor which can influence the electoral process in no small measure. The politicization of the NGOs (mainly, though not solely, through unionization) has, therefore, acquired considerable importance. Politicization at other levels of the civil services, particularly in the higher civil service, proceeds from different considerations. Personal aggrandizement plays a much more important role. These categories are also involved in the electoral process but influence is brought to bear on higher civil servants on an in­ dividual basis and not on a group basis (as is the case with NGOs). H politicization at lower levels is related to unionization, at higher levels it is the relationship between the civil servant and the politician (usually a minister) which is important. In the past, factional struggles within the tuling party, rather than patty affiliations as such, have influenced this relationship. The political executive in a number of states has made use of senior civil servants in dealing with inner-party dissidence. This has been Dlgltlzedby Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 218 State and Politics in India true of the centre to date, because of the genealogy of the Prime Ministers and the Presidential style of functioning that they seem to prefer. With the far-reaching recent changes in political equations at · the centre, here too politicization of the civil servant is becoming evident. Straightforward and strict officers can be posted to de­ partments under the control of dissident ministers; with no overt effort, the ministers could be compelled to stick to the straight and narrow path. On the other hand, posting an accommodating offtcer'to a department would automatically result in making the task of the minister concerned easier. The same logic would also apply to elected local bodies (district boards and below) which the state government may wish either to curb or to encourage. District officers can be posted with the object of undermining a dissident politician in his/her home base. Outlined above are instances of the political executive using the flexibility available within the administration in order to serve its purpose. While it does not automatically follow that these proce­ dures result in politicization, they do initiate and encourage the process. For in the absence of flexible or accommodating civil servants, it would be impossible to initiate procedures that would lead to politicization. The willingness of a civil servant to assist a minister in the efficient formulation or implementation of a pro­ gramme does not, by itself, constitute evidence of politicized be­ haviour on the part of the former, Thus there may be (in fact there are) enthusiastic officers whose strong conviction enables them to implement certain programmes, say in the social welfare and social justice spheres. Indeed, a number of enthusiastic officers are identified and posted to such programmes because it is in the interest of any political party in power to do so in order to win elections. Thus it should not be assumed that when officers show enthusiasm or work closely with a minister, or some other political authority, they are necessarily engaging in politicized behaviour. Display of enthusiasm by officers who have no axe to grind can be easily recognized. Their nonconformism may earn them the reputation of mavericks. There are a number of cases in which an officer's enthusiasm is motivated by the prospect of reaping politi­ cal dividends. Great dynamism brought to bear on the implemen­ tation of a costly project by an officer of doubtful integrity can give rise to a difficult choice between the interests of rectitude on Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The lnrtitutions 219 the one hand, and the effective and speedy implementation of a worthwhile programme on the other. The postings of officials in the Indian bureaucracy are expected to be based on the principle that ministers and officials should be able to function smoothly on the basis of institutional arrange­ ments and not on the grounds of personal likes and dislikes, though it is understood that there can be exceptions in extreme cases ot mutual incompatibility. However, in the course of working to­ gether a mutual understanding and a sense of parmership does often develop between civil servants and their political superiors. The basis o f this may be honourable or dubious. If the political head chooses the same official repeatedly, because the particular official's abilities are well known from previous experience, (s)he may give the impression that his/her motive in making the ap­ pointment is 'political'. A senior official of the Government of India is reported to have remarked that 'we are all well trained animals but some of us like to become pets'. It is the 'pet' relation­ ship that is suspect. The statement itself may be regarded as evidence that there are senior officials in the Government of India who are still inclined to resist such practices. In the states, how­ ever, the attempt to enforce any consistent rule in these matters has long since been abandoned. Certain specified posts belong to another category of 'political appointment'. These are made on the principle that they cm only be filled by officers with whom the political party in power can function smoothly. This applies to certain key posts such as the Chief Secretary of a state or the secretaries to the Government of India, or even certain sensitive posts identified in the Constitution. The practice at present is that, within the constraints of certain conventions of seniority, the Chief Minister or the Prime Minister (as the case may be) exercises her/his prerogative in making the selection of Chief Secretary, Director General of police, and Cabinet Secretary and other secretaries. In these cases, a degree of discretion must be left to the political executive. Actual practice is in broad conformity with this requirement. However, the ele­ ment of political choice.has not been openly acknowledged to date, the justification given for selection or otherwise being on the basis o f 'neutral' criteria. This - it must·be said - is less than fair practice. It is necessary, therefore, for the procedure to be formal­ ized and certain convention_ s openly established. This applies also . Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 220 State and Politia in India to certain other appoinnnents which are formally acknowledged as 'political appoinnnents' (e.g. certain ambassadorships). A s a corollary, the officers so posted should automatically vacate their office when the government changes hands. Once they have been appointed on the basis of the political criterion, they cannot claim that they should continue in such posts (beyond the tenure of the political executive which appoints them in the fust place) on the grounds that they are experts. 'Political interference' is a phenomenon related to, but different from, politicization as such. In a democracy, whether it be pres­ idential or parliamentary, a political executive heads the executive branch of government. (S)he thereby derives legitimate authority to take executive action through the bureaucratic apparatus, in accordance with her/his political commitment and within the con­ straints o f the Constitution. An action of a political nature con­ veye d as a direction by the political executive to the bureaucracy under its control will, therefore, be a legitimate one, even if it is based on political considerations or has political consequences. The term 'interference' is, however, applied to actions which involve political pressure or exercise of influence through channels other than legitimate ones. Political interference can take place both vertically and laterally. It might, at fust sight, appear unusual that interference should be exercised vertically, as executive power can be exercised through legitimate channels. However, this occurs wherever an inter­ mediate bureaucratic level resists directions of a political nature and cannot be overruled because of the legal or constitutional legitimacy of such resistance. For instance, a minister may have a secretary who resists taking action along the lines desired - and has good reasons for doing so - which the minister is unable or unwilling (sometimes for reasons of adverse publicity) to overrule formally. In such cases, it is sometimes easier to influence the lower levels to initiate action along the lines desired by the minister, so that when the matt� reaches the secretary's level, it is s/he who would have to overrule a report or a proposal that has come from below. These are cases where political interference takes place vertically down the line to lower levels with a view to weakening or sub­ verting the authority of the higher bureaucratic levels. It is such interference that establishes a contact between the higher political Digi ti zed by Googl...a;e -= Ongmal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN Tht Institutions 221 executive and lower officialdom and, eventually, leads to either a politicization of the lower officials or encourages corruption. Political pressure is exercised laterally when a person who is occupying a position of political importance finds that (s)he has no formal authority over the bureaucracy at that level. For in­ stance, members of the legislature are politically import.ant and influential persons. Their views are expected to be given due :weight b y the bureaucracy, but they cannot order the bureaucracy in the way in which a minister can. Nevertheless, members of the legislature frequently try to exercise pressure over bureaucrats to induce them to take certain actions. There is often an implied threat that if they are not obliged, they would raise the issue in the legislature or they would approach the minister. When certain powers are devolved to local bodies and the officials concerned are placed under their control, the formal lines of authority that previously ran through the official bureaucracy are transferred to the local body whose chairperson now exercises authority over the staff. Nevertheless, the political executive at the state level, such as a minister, on the one hand, and other political officials, such as members of the legislature, on the other, tend to exert pressure directly over the bureaucracy ofthe local body instead ofindirectly through its chair. Political interference of these various types undermines the morale of the bureaucracy. It also leads to either politicization or corruption. Figure 5. I gives, in schematic form, the formal lines of authority and informal lines of influence or interference. The 'Committed' Civil Servant During the Emergency, civil servants were expected to be 'committed'. It is difficult to define this concept. H 'politicization' is linked to political parties, 'commitment' is linked to beliefs, ideologies, or values and,'therefore, to programmes based on these. But it may also have. a negative connotation when the stress is on commitment to certain personalities and their political futures. There. is clearly. a difficulty in the Indian system, where the civil service remains permanent but governing political parties change. Hopefully, there will always. be officers in the civil service who, b y temperament or by convicdon, feel committed to a programme devised by the party which happens to be in power. This would Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 0 ,5 "' fil !:I Level Bureaucracy State Direct Authority Political Executive CJ 0 ('v District < m ::x, Village V, 0 � .ii5 · 0'!!. ,, a i3 n :! Gl )> z Devolves by Devolution ------- - ­ Legislature Legislation Statutory Authority --::=·---- -·-- ·=--=--=- -Zilla l ...- � C � Political Organization �cretariat • · Coll ector 1 --·------- __ � - - i r- -- Lower Officialdom ' T Answerable to Legislature I Pllrisbad - Election to PR- 7 Panchayat Dark Line-� ­ Formal, Legitimate, Official Flows Light Line --- Informal, Unofficial, Influence or Interference Elected to Local Leadership Figure 5.1: Lints ofAuthority, LJnes of Injluma 222 The lnstituti<m.r 223 be a fortuitous circumstance. On the other hand, there may be those who are neutral politically, but still have the capacity to implement the programme efficiently and honestly. There may also be officers opposed to a particular programme for a variety of personal principles. Such officers should be relieved of respon­ sibility for that programme, but not penalized. This would not apply in the case of opposition to principles incorporated in the Constitution (for example 'untouchability is against the law'). A civil servant cannot, for example, plead un­ willingness to implement welfare schemes for the 'Scheduled castes', 'dalits', and 'scheduled tribes' on the grounds that (s)he is opposed to the abolition of untouchability. Rather, we are referring to examples such as the case of a senior Muslim official in Hyderabad state (in pre-Independence days) whose wish not to be Commissioner of Liquor Excise because of his religious conviction was respected by the government. In other words, subject to constitutional limitations, an element of agreement between the authority and the official should be allowed in the process of selection for postings. But the commitment that was elicited during the Emergency appeared to border on the brink of becoming a 'loyalty test', implying that 'if you are not com­ mitted, you are omitted'. On the other hand, some officials exploited the idea of committed civil s�rvice as a means of rapid professional advancement. As against those officials who, during the Emergency, may have used their professed commitment as a means of advancement, there have always been those1 often belonging to younger age groups, who htnJe been committed - in the positive sense of the word - to ideals and values. Any political party in power can, with justification, select such officials and put them in charge of programmes with a social content, which will then be well imple­ mented. Conversely, when a party in power wants to 'soft-pedal' certain schemes (which may be identified with its predecessor), its instinct would favour the transfer of such officers. A transfer by itself is entirely innocuous and within the government's remit (particularly those newly come into power), but in such cases the transfers might signal the intentions of the new government. Commitment, however, need not be identical with, or even result in, political affiliation. It is, therefore, necessary to examine how politicization of the civil service appears to have spread in a Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 224 State and Politia in India system i n which genuine political affiliation or commitment is not widespread. Political affiliation, in the sense of a more than usu2l affinity to those belonging to the political executjve, arose in the early phase of Independence. It was more_..or less characterized by the common class background of those who constituted such groups. Immediately after Independence, not only were the Congress leaders who took office widely accepted and respected but they also shared the social background of the senior civil servants whom · they inherited from the colonial state. Thus, for example, the Nehrus' social background was no different from that of the senior ICS officers of those days; even Patel, who was from a run] background, had trained as a barrister in London; Rajagopalachari aetually felt more at home with the ICS officers when he wa., Prime Minister of Madras (1937-9) than with certain elements in the Congress party (which .would later support Kamaraj). Against such a background, not only did the senior civil servants experience no difficulty in functioning closely and loyally with the political executive, but they could do so to an extent which today could be labelled 'po liticization'. The political process subsequent to Independence gave rise to changes in the class composition of the political executive that were more &r-reaching and rapid than changes i n the social com­ position of the civil services. Recruitment to the political executive, especially at the state level and below, came to be increasingly based on vernacular education, whereas recruitment to the civil services continued to take place for a long time through the English medium. The growing disparity between the class back­ ground of the political executive and the civil servants was, there­ fore, a reflection of the difference between the criteria for entty into the two spheres. As a consequence, the political executive came to represent a much wider social and class span than the civil . servtces. The Caste Factor The entty of the caste factor into the civil services changed the nature of the processes outlined above. Even without formal reser­ vation, caste was an unstated but relevant factor which entered the process of recruitment both to the political executive and to the Dig1t1zeo by Google Origi�al rrom UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Inrtitutums 225 civil services. In the initial phase, the upper castes were heavily represented in both spheres and the general congruence in outlook between them could not be separated easily from their class ori­ gins. With the introduction of caste reservation in the services, the composition of the services changed progressively. However, despite reservation, the representation of the scheduled castes (SCs) and backward classes (BCs) in the services is still below the percentages stipulated in the statute. In Andhra Pradesh (as at the beginning of 1989) the proportion of SC employees in the services as a whole was close to the statutory figure of 15 per cent. But if this figure is disaggregated, w e will find that the overall percentage is made up of 22 per cent SC employees in the Class IV category, 12 per cent i n the Class category, 5.5 per cent in Class II, and only 4 per cent in Class I (against a statutory figure of 15 per cent in each Class). This is partly due to the earlier imbalance not yet having been rectified, but it is also due to the fact that, even in fresh placements, the Employment Exchanges have been able to place only 57 per cent of the vacancies reserved for the SCs. Therefore, in the higher services the proportion of SCs is only in the range of 4 to 6 per cent. The backward classes would be better represented than the SCs, but would still not meet the reservation figure. Nevertheless, a s a result , of these reservations the services now have the same spread of castes as the political executive. In this respect, there has been a decisive shift in the caste composition of the services. The spread of castes occurs even in categories where there is n o formal reservation. For instance, there is no statutory provision for a proportionate number of different castes in the cabinet. Equally, there are no such provisions for Vice Chancellors of universities or the higher judiciary. In fact, however, an informal caste rotation does apply to all these categories. There is thus a rainbow coalition not only in the political executive and the civil services, but also in the judiciary and all other important public offices. As a result, the gravitational pull between different spheres of life, including the political executive and the civil services, operates along caste lines. Thus, for example, durin_g an earlier period, an officer wishing to use political influence would go to the minister with whom he worked or had previously worked, or who belonged to his !fistrict. But, since the 1970s and 1980s this situation hu changed radically." Officers now go, to ministers m ' D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 226 State and Politics in India belonging to the same castes. Each minister, whose appoinnnent owes much to his importance as leader of his caste, considers himself to be the protector and godfather of all the officials in the government who belong to his caste. The civil servants, for their part, .reciprocate such a sentiment, though there are rare cases of choice running counter to such a practice. This raises the question of whether only those officials belong­ ing to a particular caste can be entrusted with the task o f im­ plementing, efficiently and enthusiastically, schemes intended for the welfare of that caste. There may be officials belonging to other castes who are genuinely devoted to the welfare of the SCs and BCs. In some cases, they may even be the most suitable among the officers available for the task. In such a case, should a less suitable officer be selected merely because (s)he belongs to a particular caste? Here a distinction has to be made between schemes which are purely of a welfare nature and schemes which are intended to protect specific castes or instil confidence in them. In the former case, the efficiency and enthusiasm of the official should be given greater weight than his/her caste origin. The position is, however, different where the confidence of the caste is an important factor. Many instances are known in which SCs fmd it easier to represent their grievances to a Collector belonging to their own caste. Even solicitude expressed by a high caste person may carry a hint of condescension or patronage. The response of the SCs is reflected in the difference between their attitude to Gandhi and their feelings towards Ambedkar. The latter symbolizes what the SCs can achieve by themselves whereas the former represents, at best, only· support, sympathy and an admission of guilt. New links between the bureaucracy and the political executive at different levels have been developed along caste lines during the last twenty years. There are also other horiwntal links de­ veloping as a result of the process of politicization already outlined and institutional changes such as the strengthening of the local bodies to which a number of functions have been devolved. At the same time, the traditional vertical linkages of the bureaucracy through the conventional line of control and authority are being weakened if not altogether vitiated. They are weakened partly as a consequence of these very horiwntal links, which provide an opportunity for the lower levels to bypass their superiors through Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutions 227 the political channel. The vertical link has also suffered on account of the weakening of the normal mechanisms of control and promotion. Acute controversy surrounds the question of whether merit, as differentiated from seniority, can be a criterion for promotion without undermining the vertical links of control. Thus there is a great deal of scepticism about the integrity of superior officers and a corresponding readiness to believe com­ plaints alleging caste prejudice. The link of administrative control has also been weakened by judicial intervention, which deals even with such trivia as transfers. All that is needed is an allegation of mala fides and all that is required is a stay order. Neither proof nor final orders carry any importance because of the inordinate time consumed by the judi­ cial process. Officers against whom adverse remarks :ire passed in assessment reports are given an opportunity to appeal against them. This procedure can lead to the author of an adverse remark having to spend more time justifying it th.an the subject of the remark defending him/herself. These processes have resulted in an erosion of discipline in the bureaucracy. Yet the same bureaucracy can be periodically shaken into action and made to perform tasks of considerable administrative com­ plexity with great efficiency. The conduct of elections, despite growing complaints about booth-capturing, is one such example; disaster management is another. Such instances point to the fact that if a clear-cut objective is given and intervention (except orders through the direct line of command) is absent, the administrative machinery can still deliver the goods. But a vast proportion of the normal work of the administration does not deal with such well­ defined and specific tasks. Public bureaucracy, by definition, must develop the general capacity to deliver the goods. Such capacity should not be dependent upon the nature of the task that the bureaucracy is called upon to perform. There arc of course constitutional and sometimes moral limits to the nature of the tasks that an administration can be called upon to handle. But within these limits, a spirit of neutrality must be cultivated. The Indian bureaucracy has been considerably weakened in this respect. It is doubtful whether the bureaucracy today can be regarded as an instrument of change. Its composition reflects many of the contradictions inherent in the society. In the implementation of any programme of change, the conflicts that Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 228 State 1111d Politia in India may arise in the society at large are lilcely to.be replicated within the microcosm of the bureaucracy, thereby affecting its efficiency. Sometimes, however, the class heterogeneity of the bureaucracy and the class coalition within the political executive reinforce each other. In the case of a programme such as land reform, in which the ruling coalition itself is unable to resolve its inner contndic­ tions, contradictory signals are sent through legislative measures and then through administrative implementation. The former are radical in content but the latter is crippled by confusion and prevarication. It may be genuine confusion arising out of the mixed character of the bureaucracy, or it may be confusion engineered by certain elements in the ruling coalition acting in collusion with similar elements in the heterogeneous bureaucracy. If, however, a political executive is elected to power which follows objectives, its programmes may be obstructed by i n tr a -bureaucracy conflicts. The communist parties have not found the bureaucracy an easy instrument for the pursuit of class-orientated objectives. A party such as the BharatiyaJanata Party is also likely to encounter similar difficulties. On the other hand, an interesting experiment has been launched recently in the sphere of literacy. Literacy progiaimnes are being implemented under the overall guidance of the District Collector; but the key staff are selected from among the officials on the basis of aptitude and willingness to carry out the work. Literacy pro­ grammes have the advantage of not provoking political resistance. The impression given is that the staff on these programmes fall into three broad categories - nearly 50 per cent are enthusiastic about the programme; nearly 25 per cent are in it merely for the sake of duty; and the remainder bear an attitude of sullen and barely concealed resistance. The general attitudes prevailing within the bureaucracy may well. follow a similar pattern. Many have arisen over a long period of more or less one-party rule. The bureaucracy has been exposed to the dynamics of genuine political plurality at the centre only during the last few years. In certain states, however, such a development has taken place over a longer period. These changes may well result in a renewed appreciation of the need to restore the neutrality o f the civil services. Meanwhile the way forward seems t o point to the maintenance of a distinction between programmes with a social content and activities basic to an administration and mostly of a D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN - �- The Institutions 229 regulatory nature. The bureaucracy is still an instrument uniquely suited to discharging the latter type of functions, provided the damage to its morale and efficiency is repaired. The other types of programmes, with a high social content, may be better implemented by political executives down the line. This would require a strengthening of local bodies (i.e. Panchayati Raj institutions), which should be given responsibility for the implementation of such programmes. They would be better fitted t o take the kind of decisions that would be required in respect of value-loaded social programmes because they can reap political dividends through success or pay a political price through failure. That this point is widely appreciated is evident from the move to amend the Constitution in order to provide for such institutions. However, it is not yet sufficiently appreciated that, as a conse­ quence of such a development, conflicts in the past between the political executive and the bureaucracy will now surface as con­ tradictions between different levels of political executive. For thir­ ty years, the main contradiction in the Panchayati Raj was between the officials and non-officials. Today, it would appear that the main contradiction in this area is between the elected members of higher and lower level bodies. This has had an unexpected effect on the bureaucracy. At the time of Independence, the civil services of the local bodies consisted of their own employees (with the exception of executive officers). One of the administrative features of the post­ Independence developments has been to convert all these services into government services (on the persistent demand of employees), by a process of'provincialization'. As a result, the formal horizon­ tal links between the Panchayati Raj institutions and their own civil services have become weak. This has made intervention by the state government in the functioning of such institutions, through the control that they can exercise over their civil services, more frequent. Simultaneously, however, Panchayati Raj has also increased the informal horizontal links between civil servants and politicians. This has resulted, on the one hand, in an increase in opportunities for political intervention at all levels and, on the other, in greater politicization of the civil services (Figure 5.1). A reversal of the process of vertical integration of the services that has been under way since Independence is, therefore, neces­ sary, not only for statutory devolution to work effectively but also Dlgltlzedby Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 230 State and Politics in India to remove confusion in the lines of administrative control. How­ ever, given current political realities and the strength of unioniza­ tion of the civil services, it is doubtful whether any such process can even be initiated, let alone succeed. Nevertheless, the fact remains that if what one is looking for is an instrument of social change, the bureaucracy is hardly the appropriate vehicle. One ought to look to political institutions such as the Panchayati Raj on the one hand, and political cadres on the other, which at the present time exist only in the communist parties and the BJP. Note The comments and observations made in this chapter are based mainly but not entirely - on the author's experience of administration in the state of Andhra Pradesh. Nevertl1eless, some qualifications in regard to their gen­ eral applicability are necessary. The stamp of the British period has long remained on Indian administra­ tion, although it is slowly fading. Colonial administration made a basic dis­ tinction between the areas in eastern India which were brought under Permanent Serdemcnt and tl1e rest of the country where the Ryotwari Set­ tlement was imposed. Even today, the Permanent Settlement can still explain certmn features of the social and agrarian situation in eastern India. British administration had distinct features in me Madras Presidency (based in Fort St George), the Bombay Presidency, me Bengal Presidency and adjoining territories (under the aegis of Fort William), and me north Indian Hindi heartland and Frontier states, the Indian parts of which are now represented by Pw1jab and Haryana. The present observations and comments would broadly apply to the states in southern India and western India (what used to be me Madras and Bombay Presidencies). However, in southern India, conditions in Kerala have a distinctive quality: 1. There is a high literacy r.ite, particularly among women, with attendant impact on me social structure; 2. the Muslim and Christian con1mu11ities are characterized by social and cultural features which differ from those of the two communities else­ where in India (this is accompanied by Kerala's political distinctive­ ness); 3. there is a strong communist movement in the state; and me social structure of Kerala, unlike other states, i s not village-based. 4. Conditions in the state of Tanul Nadu have also diverged considerably from me initial pattern co1nmon to tl,e Presidency of Madras as :i whole, mostly because of me influence of the Dravidian political movement and me long and continuous control of the state by parties mat have emerged from that movement. With these qualifications it can be said iliat conditions are comparable D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm �- - UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutions 231 within these two regions and therefore the observations contained in this chapter are broadly applicable t o both. The conditions prevailing i n the Hindi region and the eastern states have always differed from those in the south and the west, and therefore, some at least of the obserwtions made here are not applic:able to those states. The observations il1 this chapter may well apply to states in which the Congress party has enjoyed long and uninterrupted stints in power, with the exception ofstates in which cadre parties mch u the CPI, CPI (M), and BJP have displaced it from power. Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 6 Impact of Centre-State Relations on Indian Politics: An Interpretative Reckoning 1947-1987 T. V. Sathyamurthy D wing the last four decades, the Indian state has addressed the task of coping with the tensions arising in different regions of th� country by resorting to a variety of means, depend­ ing upon the particular facet -economic, political, constitutional or cultural/linguistic - involved in each specific conflict. Shifts have occurred in the major thrust of centre�tate1 conflicts and contradictions since Independence which - by virtue of their magnitude and in view of the political actors involved - can be best analysed by appropriate periodization. The interest of these conflicts for the student of politics stems from the following main considerations: (1) Major political tensions within the ruling party at the centre - the ruling Congress party in its different transmogrifications, undivided Congress, Congress (R), and Congress-I, except during the brief post-Emergency interregnum of 1977-9/1980 - as well as tensions between it and a wide variety of opposition parties, which offer more or less plausible alternative centres of power in I The constitutional, political and financial aspects of centre-state relations during the first three decades of Independence are reviewed in the author's work entitled India sin£e lntkpmdmce: Studies in the Droelopmmt of the PU1Dtr ofthe lndum Sutt: Vohmu I: Cmtn-Sutt Relations: The Case ofKn-ala (Delhi: Ajanta Publications, 1985), pp. 20-101. Dlgltlzeo by G 008l e __ _ � ���SITY OF MICHIGAN Original from The lnstitutums 233 different regions (and also at the centre, albeit in coalition)2 are clearly reflected in the unfolding of centre-state tensions in any given period. (2) Major economic tensions have tended to follow parallel lines. On the one hand, the contradiction between the rising urban and rural working classes (consisting of unskilled, semi-skilled and skilled industrial workers, and their multiplex trade unions rooted in the major political formations in the country - Congress, the Communist Party of India (CPI), the Socialist Party (SP), the Janata party OP), and the Communist Party of India-Marxist CPl(M); and unevenly and sporadically organized agricultural workers and poor peasants) and the ruling classes has, at least since the early 1970s, been successfully deflected by the state. Not only have working class organizations become fragmented and emas­ culated, but also the ideological underpinnings which impaned class 'militancy' to them have been undermined as a consequence of the emergence of a number of trade union satrapies of which the Bombay textile millworkers under Datta Samant' constitute but the most recent and dominant example. At the same time, the logic of economic development under Indian conditions of dependence and unevenness4 has rendered the working class as a whole unstable in composition. The instability of the working class, during recent decades, has been endemic due to the rationalization of industry and sudden shifts from labour­ intensive to capital-intensive production, and the large-scale trans­ formation of subsistence agriculture into cash crop agriculture. As a result, widespread displacement of labour has occurred, leading to the expansion of marginalized, unorganized and seasonal migrant 2 The tension between and within different political panics is analysed in the author's essay entitled 'Maturity at the Polls: Contradiction, Dissent and Dissidence', Delhi and Calcutta: Tbt Sundi,y StatmNm, 16January 1983. 3 Datta Samant is but one ex.ample of trade union initiative being grasped from the well-established unions by ambitious individuals. During the 1970s, for example, A.K. Roy, a communist trade union leader, broke away from the communist trade unions and established a personal following among workers in eastern India. 4 See, for example, AshokMitrn, TtrmSofTr,uk in India's&anomiclxvt/opmtnt (London: F. Cass, 1976); A.K. Bagchi, P,·iwte Irrvmmmt in India: 1900-1939 (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1972); and Francine Frankel, India's Po/itiCl,I &onomy 1947-1977 (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1977). Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 234 St11tt 11nd Politia in lndill labour forces which are, politically and economically, even weaker than the unionized workforce.S On the other hand, as I have argued elsewhere,6 there h� been an intensification of the horiwntal contradiction 'U1ithin the dom­ inant class during recent decades. The conflict, at least in the short run, between the industrial bourgeoisie (which has been, o n the whole, the greatest beneficiary of central planning and public sector expansion policies of the central government) and the rising rich and middle peasant classes (which have effectively displaced the 'feudal' landed classes of the colonial period) has not been easy to contain. By adopting the green revolution strategy, the Indian state created conditions under which the devdopment of agricul­ ture took place along lines that ensured not only a sharp differen­ tiation of rural classes and contradiction between them in the countryside (i.e. between the rich and middle peasants on the one hand, and the poor peasants and landless labourers on the other), but also a divergence of interests between the industrial bour­ geoisie and the rural rich. This horiwntal conflict has been activated since 1972 when, for the first time, India attained self-sufficiency in food. Throughout the 1970s and .1980s, the tension between the in­ dustrial capitalist forces and the rural rich has been :sggr avated, with centre state relations providing the political arena in which it is manifested. Except during the brief period (1978-9) when Chaudhuri.Charan Singh was successively Finance Minister and caretaker Prime Minister, the central government has been seen invariably as the custodian, by and large, of the interests of India's national industrial bourgeoisie in this conflict. Over the last two decades, the state governments (especially in regions where the green revolution has been successful - for example Punjab, s For an excellent study illuminating this process, seeJan Breman, 'Seasonal Migration and Co-operative Capillllism: The Crushing of Cane :md of Labour by the Sugar Factories of Bardoli, South Gujarat' (in two parts), Tbt ]ou1'7llllefPt11StmtSl1Jdits, vol. 6, nos land 2, October 1978 andJ:muary 1979, pp. 41-70 and pp. 168-209. 6 T.V. Sathyamurthy, 'State Power and Social Confticts in India',Mirin.rrrt-, vol. 21, no. 38, 23 June 1983, pp. 1-8; 'Piloting a Nation into the Twenty-first Century: The Changing Context ofState Power and Class Contradiction in India', &OMmic muJ Political Wetltly, 20 (20 July 1985): 29, pp. 1218-22; 'India Since Independence: A Research Note on the Development of the Power of the Indian Stllte', South Ari4 Rtst11rcb, vol. 6, no. 1, May 1986, pp. 39-50. Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutions 235 . Haryana and Uttar Pradesh) have emerged as the natural champions of the interests of the rich and middle peasant classes.7 This aspect of power sharing between the centre and the states has undergone some modification since the assumption of power by the Rajiv Gandhi government. (3) Cultural and linguistic differences, which have no doubt contributed to the political idiom specific to centre-state relations right from Independence, are generally given too much or too little importance in the two major strands of the literature functionalist and Marxist. Whilst political and economic conflicts develop centre-state conflict dimensions of their own, conflicts involving linguistic and cultural (and even communal) dimensions have tended to assume significance under certain circumstances. 8 First,· language and culture are emphasized (especially in the regions lying outside the Hindi-speaking heartland of India, em­ bracing Uttar Pradesh, Bihar, Madhya Pradesh and Rajasthan) as features unique to the different 'nationalities' comprising India.9 Demands for an equitable distribution of political power and privileged access for weaker regions to economic resources are often couched in the language of demands for greater autonomy for the different states as well as for a more generous investment of central plan resources in remoter regions far away from the 'heartland'. Second, poorer states which do not have an active classes, which roughly correspond to middle castes in a number of heartland states, have come to dominate the entire spectrum of political parties including Congress (or Congress-I) and the Socialist Party (for ex­ ample Bihar) but not the communist parties. 1bis has been particularly true since the Emergency. See, for CDmple, T.V. Sathyamurthy, 'State and the People' (in two pans), Tbt St11tmn11n, Calcutta and Delhi, 14 and 1S March 1985. 8 The most recent instance of linguistic and cultural passions flaring up at apparently short notice is provided by Goa (1986). Not unconnected with the unrest in the region has been a recent decision of the Indian cabinet to introduce legislation in the Lok Sabha conferring statehood on Goa, thus inducing the twenty-fifth state of the Indian wuon since Independence. A few months ago, another union territory in north-eastern India, Mizoram, w:as also given the political status of a state. See, for example, 'Mizo Fighters Seek Ballot-box Victory', Tbt Times, London, 17 February 1987. 9 Sec, for example, T.V. Sathyamurthy, 'Indian Nationalism and the "Na­ tional Question"', Millmnium: Jourtllll efJnttmlltiaru,J Studies, vol. 14, no. 2, Swnmer 1985, pp. 172-94; and Prabsh Karat, umgrugt tmd N11ti-1ity in JndiJ, (Madras: Orient Longman, 1973). 7 These D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 236 State and Politics in India 'producing' class capable of accumulating surplus through agricul­ tural or small industrial economic activities have shown themselves to be specially skilled in raising the banner of rebellion against the centre. Thus the Assam agitation10 must be distinguished from move­ ments such as Udayachal,Jharkhand and Gorkhaland movements in which the sheer despair of oppression by a majority community is believed to justify rebellion. The difficulties in the relations between the centre on the one hand, and on the other, small but strategically significant states on India's periphery can be legit­ imately viewed in terms of pressures generated by the ruling elements of the various 'nationalities' involved. Thus, for example, the ruling elements in the societies of Jammu and Kashmir and the 'seven sisters' of the north-east (with the exception ofTripura), which may be more or less adequately characterized as 'non­ productive' petit bourgeois forces, have been involved during re­ cent decades in constant agitation to secure increased flow of resources from the centre and the state governments' right to exercise control over them. In the existing literature on the cultural and linguistic dimen­ sions of centre-state relations, one strand lays far too great an emphasis on aspects relating to such questions as 'Hindi imperial­ ism',11 'unitarization of the federal polity'12 by manipu�ting the Indian Constitution, and 'foreign influences'.13 Another strand tends (mistakenly) to dismiss these as unimportant in preference to locating centre-state conflicts in the tensions and contradictions between classes qua classes, without providing a detailed empirical characterization of the class configuration developing in India and of the role played by the Indian state in the process of its unfolding. The characterization of the roots of the Assam agitation has been the subject of acute controversy which is still being carried on in the columns of such journals as &u,wmic tmd Politic"/ Wttk/y (especiaJly during the period i980-5), Mainsm11111 (especially during 1982; 1985), Frontier (since 1980). II See, for example, a recent well-researched Ph.D. thesis submitted to the University of Barcelona by Pilar Casamada entitled English in India, 19471980 (Barcelona: 1987, unpublished). 12 See, for example, Subrat:1 Mitra, 'Competing Models of the State in Indian Political Discourse' (a paper presented at the Political Studies Association Conference) (Aberdeen, 1987, under publication). I l See, for example, various articles in the two special issues on the Punjab, St111inar, nos 294 and 326, February 1984 and October 1986, Delhi. 10 .. - D1g1t1zeo by - Google ·-- Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN - The Institutions 237 Only very tiny segments of the literature show evidence of an appreciation of the complex character of the inter-weaving be­ tween linguistidcultural and political/economic factors underly­ ing centre-state conflicts in independent India. 14 During the fust four decades of Independence, three major shifts have occurred in the pattern assumed by centre-state con­ flicts. The original impetus for these was provided by the cultural and linguistic divisions between heartland or hinterland states in which Hindi is spoken and the states/regions on the periphery in which non-Hindi languages predominate. Whilst the importance of the centre-state conflicts of the 1950s for the unity of India was magnified and exaggerated out of proportion outside India,15 they were viewed within India as no more than teething troubles of the new federation in which power was shared between like-minded politicians and mutually compatible economic groups in the states and at the all-India level. 16 Even so, it is worth remembering that intra-Congress rivalries between state-level leaders and the centre did take place i n the political aanosphere surrounding a not-as-yet sufficiently fortified Indian state. As political opposition to the Congress party grew in the states on the periphery, apparently cultural and linguistic divergences acquired economic overtones and developed into competition be­ tween different segments of the ruling elements in a number of states for control over the executive power in governments. With electoral success, state-based 'nationality' movements in regions such as Tamil Nadu, along with much weaker national opposition parties have been able to mount a steadily accelerating challenge to the centre's power. 17 14 This author is currently engaged in researching a series ofvolumes on this theme with a view to producing an empirically substantiated characterization of state power in India since independence. The second volume of the series entitled /ndi11 sinct lndtpmlim<e: St1uiies in the Dtvelopmtnt oftht Puwn- ofthe Indian St11tt: Volume 2: Ctntrt-St11te Relations: Tbt Cast oftht Punjab is currently under preparation. IS For example Selig F. Harrison, Indui: Tht Most D11ngtr0us Dt<lllks (Prin­ ceton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 1960). 16 A glimpse of the amity that prevailed in the relationship between the centre and the states during the first fifteen years of Independence is provided in the recently published correspondence between Prime Minister Nehru and the ChiefMinisters of different states. 17 T.V. Sathyamurthy, 'Indian Nationalism'. D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 238 State and Politicr in India The relationship between the Congress party and the opposi­ tion parties in general and provincially based opposition in par­ ticular was modulated in a rapidly changing political atmosphere in which the Indian state was being steadily strengthened and its coercive power was becoming capable of ever more rapid deploy­ ment throughout the country. Even so, within a period of less than two decades ending with the Emergency, centre-state rela­ tions had come full circle with the dawning of the realization that the era of massive centralization of power in the state as in the central ruling party did not automatically result in the victory of the centre over the states. However, since the end of the Emer­ gency, and to an even clearer extent since the induction of the Rajiv Gandhi government to power, an entirely new chapter of co-existence between rival segments of powerholders at the centre and in the states seems to have been begun in the history of independent India. The periodization suggested in this article is as follows: (1) the era of linguistic/cultural differentiation within a framework of unchallenged unity and integrity of the Indian state (1947-67); (2) the era of centralization following the challenge from the states (1967-77); (3) a brief interregnum of attempts to redress the balance of influence in favour of the centre (1977-84); and (4) the era of coalition and co-existence between the centre and the states (from 1985). I The political emphasis of the Indian Constitution rapidly shifted from a confederal to a federal to a unitary conception of the Indian union during the brief lifetime of the Constituent Assembly.18 The overwhelming popularity of the Congress party throughout the country at the time of Independence, ensuring a homogeneous government at the centre as well as in all the states, enabled the Indian government to successfully create the impression that the Constitution was federal in character and power would be shared between the two levels of government rather than imposed by the centre on the states. 18 See, for ex:imple, Granville Austin, Tbt Indian Constitutiun: Tbt Comentun.: ofa Natiun (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1966); and Chandra Pal, St11ttAutonomy m Indian Federalism: Eme,ging Trtnds (Delhi: Deep and Deep, 1984). Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The lnstituti011S 239 The pressure in favour of linguistic states intensified during the initial stages in the provincial Congress organizations in the non-Hindi regions, except in Tamil Nadu where a widespread popular opposition to Hindi led by non-Congress elements went hand in hand with demands for a Tamil state defined by the regional language which emanated from the Tamil Nadu Pradesh Congress. Very early on, the Indian state established a double standard in the measures that it adopted to �eal with mass agita­ tions (for example the linguistic agitation of Telugu-speaking Andhra people led by the Congress) and class agitations (for example the Telengana agitation, also in Andhra) led by the Communist Party of India (CPI). 19 Even though national leaders (for example Nehru) were not nearly as keen after Independence as they had been before on the idea of linguistic states, the Congress party organization (which continued to bear the imprint of Sardar Patel's style of functioning even after his demise) was not averse to the idea of strengthening the state governments as a means of maintaining its mass following. During the period 1947-57, there was no other party in any of the Indian states which posed a sustained electoral challenge to the Congress.20 With the CPI tamed after Telengana into a par­ liamentary opposition force (after being forced to all but give up its insurrectionary or revolutionary role) and the Congress at the helm both at the centre and in the states,21 the centre appeared to yield to linguistic pressures in line with the ruling party's commitment, during the nationalist struggle, to redivide India into politically homogeneous states reflecting the country's national unity in culturaVlinguistic diversity. As a result of the recommendations of the high powered States Re-organization Commission (SRC), large new states were brought into existence: Andhra Pradesh,Maharashtra, Gujarat and Kamataka. Nevertheless, the general understanding of the non­ contradictory (in fact, even mutually complementary) character of the power-holders at the centre and in the states underlying the 19 See, for example, P. Sundarayya, Ttknglffl4 Ptopk'sStn,gglt 1111d Its Lmrms (Calcutta: Desh Raj Chadha, 1972). 20 PSP in coalition with other minor parties did pose a challenge to Congress dominance in Kerala for a short time, but its leader Pattom Thanu Pillai was bought off by the Indian government with the Governorship of the Punjab. 21 Except in Kerala (1957-9). -- Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 240 State and Politics in India fust great spurt of recarving the internal boundaries of multi­ lingual India did not extend to three specific areas. In the case of Uttar Pradesh, a powerful argument was ad­ vanced by K.M. Panikkar (one of the three members of the SRC) to the effect that the opportunity provided by linguistic events to redraw state boundaries should also be taken advantage of to divide the administratively unwieldy and economically unevenly developed state of Uttar Pradesh into two more viable states. This recommendation, in the form of a lengthy dissenting minute, was greeted with such hostility by the ruling party that it was widely believed to be animated by a touch of 'Hindi imperialism' and 'hegemonism of the north'. The linguistic demands of the Punjabi-speaking population, lar­ gely but not exclusively Sikh in composition,22 were ignored by a provincial leadership dominated by Hindus which engaged in politi­ cal manipulation of the linguistic census in such a manner as to cre­ ate a false impression to the effect that the Punjab was a largely Hindi-speaking region. Nehru believed that the Punjab should be regarded as a special category of state (bordering as it does on Pakis­ tan} to which the restrictions of'unitarism' rather than the flexible adjustments characteristic of 'federalism' ought to apply. In the case of Assam, compounded by the rising tensions of the north-east as a whole,23 the linguistic conflict which took on a new dimension (by virtue of the fact that the economic, educational and administrative life of the state was dominated by an immigrant upwardly mobile Bengali community, and the economic future of the mass of the people belonging to the Assamese linguistid cultural nationality was being imperilled by the regular exodus of 22 Between 1947 and 1966 Punjab included the predominantly Hindu Haryana and parts of Rajasthan. Since 1966, with the redrawing of state boundaries resulting in the creation of Haryana, the Punjab became a Sikh­ majority state by a small margin. This margin has since increased. 23 Tension developed along the two broad lines of the various tribal peoples of the sprawling north-east region (Assam and NEFA) seeking autonomy, and thi: indigenous Assamese-speaking population seeking to free itself of the Bengali economic and administrative stranglehold on Assam. Over a period of twenty years, the north-eastern stretch of the country was divided into seven states and union territories (of which Arunachal Pradesh and Mizoram have been conferred statehood during the last two years), Assam itself be­ coming truncated with the formation of Meghalaya. See T.V. Sathyamurthy, N11tionalim1 in the Contm1pornry World: Political and So.iologiCJll Perrpectivtr (London: Frances Pinter, 1983), chapter 8. Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutums 241 Bengali people - 1nainJy poor Muslim peasants and landless labourers - from East Pakistan into Assam) was not given the attention that it deserved until it exploded into a big violent crisis for the first rime in 1962. In the north-east as in the north-west, arguments of national integrity, unity and security were invoked to suppress political demands in Assam that were met as a matter of course in other parts of the country. By and large, however, 'federal' India, during the period 194767, was characterized by political homogeneity. The power of the state, as indeed power in the states, was wielded by the same political force represented by the Congress.24 No great conflict had yet surfaced between the captains of industry who envisaged a dominant role for the state in the modernization of the Indian economy on the one hand, and on the other, the newly arisen 'rural rich' whose interests in the states were largely represented by the Pradesh Congress leaders in control of executive power.25 During this period, significant economic changes were intro­ duced mainly through the instru1nent of central planning. The expansion of industry throughout the country under the aegis of the state, the widening of the market accompanied by i ts penetra­ tion of wider and wider sections of the population, the vastly increased scope for the expansion of private industry in general and small and medium industries in particular, and the opening up of the whole of the country to entrepreneurs from any part of i t wishing to invest, produce and sell, contributed to a process of economic unification of India and of giving its rising industrial bourgeoisie a 'national' (as differentiated from a sectional, regional or partial) identity. The Indian national bourgeoisie, for its part, welcomed these changes and the opportunities that they presented for industrial expansion and diversitication.26 24 Only in Kerala was a CPI-led government formed after the state assembly election of 1957 which was prevented from completing its normal legislative term by the centre at the instigation of the national and Pradesh Congress organizations. 2s The relationship between Prime Ministers Nehru and Shastri on the one hand, and on the other, the ChiefMinisters of the larger states of the Indian Union was cordial and more or less equal. In fact, Chief Ministers of states such as Madras, Bombay (latterly Maharashtra and Gujarat}, West Bengal, Uwr Pradesh and Bihar were accorded greater respect than union cabinet ministers within the Congress hierarchy. See note 17. 26 See, for example, Prarnit Chaudhuri, The Indian &urumzy: Puvmy IINI Droe/opmmt(London: Crosby Lockwood Staples, 1979), especially pp. 17-75. Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 242 State and Politics in India The agrarian economy of India, also in the throes of far-reaching transformation, however, presented a somewhat different picture. Indian agriculture was even more unevenly developed than Indian industry. The social and political changes required to place Indian agriculture on a modem footing were enormous in comparison to the modest beginnings which most Congress governments were prepared to contemplate during the first three five-year plans.27 Even though the days of the pre-capitalist landlord class of the colonial period were numbered, feudal relations of production continued to exercise sway in many parts of India.28 The rise of a new class of more or less 'capitalistically' orientated rich and middle peasantry (drawn largely from the ranks of the 'tenantry' of the colonial era) on the one hand, and on the other, the emergence of a 'wage' conscious landless labour class and poor peasantry (in place of bonded serfs in a state of perpetual indebtedness) with a potential claim to the land tilled by them, was a slow process, the full dynamic of which had not yet begun to unfold itself. The drama of subsequent decades, located in a plot dividing the agrarian and industrial segments of the Indian capitalist class into mutually antagonistic elements- combining together to constitute an increasingly fractured ruling class impinging upon a rapidly fraginenting political system - was scarcely discernible, except as a distant portent, so long as Congress successfully appeared to perform the tasks of a ruling umbrella party capable of serving the interests not only of antagonistic classes but also of mutually an­ tagonistic segments within the same class. On the eve of the fourth general election (1967), India presented a picture, the main components of which were a considerably more powerful state (than at Independence), capable of exercising coer­ cive power on the mass of the population more or less at will, an economy dominated at the national level by the state acting mainly in the interests of the national bourgeoisie and a rising class of as See, for eX2mple, B.H. Farmer, Agricultural Colunizatiun in lndill sinct /ntkpmdmcr(Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1974), especially pp. 87-117, 211-26, and 261-98. 28 On the long and fruitful debate on the mode of production in Indian agriculture which deals with this question, see Alice Thomer, 'Serni­ Feudalism or Capitalism? Debate on Classes and Modes of Production in lndia',&r,,u,mir11ndPolitic11/Wttkly, vol.13, nos49-S l, 4,11 and 18 December 1982, pp. 1961-8; 1993-9; and 2061-6. 27 Digiti zed by Google Ongmal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The lnstitutiuns 243 yet not strongly differentiated rich and middle peasantry, and a polity in which the intra-party differences of the Congress revolv­ ing round the question of the relative autonomy of the states within the federal framework of the Indian constitution were rapidly yield­ ing place to conflicts of a substantial nature between the Congress party on the one hand, and on the other, the national and regional opposition parties belonging to the entire political spectrum from the left to the right29 The failure of successive Congress administrations at the centre and in the states to alleviate the harsh economic conditions of the mass of the Indian people led to widespread alienation and disaf­ fection throughout the country which were reflected in the dis­ astrous performance of the ruling party in the 1967 general election in a number of states and in its much reduced majority i n the Lok Sabha. II Of the several opposition governments which took power in the states during the interregnum between the indecisive fourth gen­ eral election and the much more decisive fifth general election (1971), the government of Tamil Nadu led by the Dravida Mun­ netra Kazhagam (DMK) pany3° was the first to take on board the question of centre-state relations on a political level in a systematic manner. In the other states where the Congress party had lost control, executive power was wielded for brief uncertain periods (interspersed with intervals of President's rule under the Governor) by far-flung coalitions. They were inherently unstable by virtue of their. eclectic political colouration, and their sole purpose seemed to be to keep themselves afloat in the face of the machinations of the Congress party which manifested a decisive proclivity to en­ couraging defections from almost all n o n c- adre parties (especially in the Hindi-heartland states) with the aid of monetary and other incentives.31 29 T.V. Sath yamurthy, 'Marurity at the Polls'. 39 T.V. Sathyamurthy, 'Dravidtt Mrmmtra Kilzbaga111 in the Politics ofTamil Nadu: 1947-1971', in B.N. Pandey (ed.), uadn-sbip in South Asia (London: Asia Publishing House, 1977), pp. 426--60; R.L. Hardgrave Or),Tbt Dravidian Mwnnent (Bomb ay: Popular Pralcashan, 1965). 31 In more recent years, Congress-I has been known to have purchased Digiti zed by Google Ongmal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 244 State and Politics in India On the left of the political spectrum, the 1964 split of the undivided CPI had the effect of hamstringing the much more popubr CPI(M) in West Bengal, Tripura, and Kerala. For the CPI(M) was, on the one hand, not well placed (especially in West Bengal) to cope with opposition from Naxalires or Communist Party of India (Marxist-Leninist) (CPI-M-L) elements32 without unleashing violence and resorting to desperate measures, whilst on the other, it was unable to prevent the CPI from slipping into the role ofthe Trojan horse of the left by edging closer and closer to the new brand of shibboleth socialism that the ruling party was propagating during the run up to the 1971 general election. Although the CPI(M) did raise the issue of centre-state rela­ tions during the 1967-9 United Front experiments in Kerala, West Bengal and Tripura (in which it shared executive power with other parties), its substantive contribution to the debate had been minimal. The Rajamannar Repon,33 commissioned by the Tamil Nadu government, was the fust detailed official document pub­ lished by a state government to deal with various aspects of the political, fmancial and economic relations between the centre and states.34 The ruling party at the centre was much more concerned during this period with refurbishing its image in the eyes of the mass of the Indian electorate, whilst the Indian state embarked upon a strong programme of containing popular unrest, of destabilizing popularly elected but opposition-controlled state governments, and of attempting to emasculate and crush left parties in general and the CPI(M) in particular. The already impressive and far­ reaching coercive power wielded by the Indian state apparatus was massive floor crossings from opposition parties to the Congress prior to the swearin gin - ceremony ofnewly elected state legislatures, for example Haryana (1982). JZ See, for example, Mohan R.un, Maoism in India (Delhi: Vikas, 1971), especially pp. 38-77 and 122-36. Jl Government ofMadras, Report on Cmm-Statt Re/ations(Chairman:Justice P.V. Rajamannar) (Madras: Government Press, 1968). 34 The Rajamannar Report should be read in conjunction with others such as K. Santhanam, Union-State Relations in India (Bombay: Asia Publishing House, 1960) and P.B. G.ijendraga dkar, The Constitution ofIndia: Its Philosophy 1111d Batie Ponuitrus (Nairobi: Oxford University Press, 1969), especially pp. 63-88. See also T.V. Sathyamurthy, India Since lndtpnuknct Vol I, pp. 68101. D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutions 245 funher augmented in the performance of these repressive tasks by repeatedly invoking the need to safeguard India's unity, integrity, and security from internal and external threats. The strategy adopted by the leadership of the Congress party to improve its public standing consisted of provoking an internal split aimed at cleansing the organization of the baleful influence o f the so-called 'Syndicate' and entrenching the sway of a catchy brand of pseudo-radical populism championed by those in posi­ tions of influence who favoured a greater centralization of power and a much more dirigiste orientation to politics in the states. It was, in fact, during this period that the practice was begun of the central organization of the party imposing its own nominees for the Chief Ministershifs of Congress-ruled states and of changing their incumbents at will. 5 At the same time, the practice of demo­ cratic election of office-bearers at various levels within the party was brought to an indefinite standstill.36 Thus even though the immediate reason behind the 1969 crisis within the party was pro­ vided by intra-party differences over who should be the Congress nominee in the presidential election (1969),37 the organizational 35 During the second phase of this period (1971-7), Chief Ministers of Congress-ruled stlltes (for example Gujarat, Bihar, Utt2r Pradesh, Maha­ rashtra and Andhra Pradesh) were changed frequently and i n an arbitrary f.ishion by the Congress Parliamentary Board. During the Indira Gandhi (Mark II) government's rule (1980-4) Chief Ministers in Congress-I-ruled stlltes (with the single exception ofVishwanath Prat2p Singh ofUmr Pradesh who resigned before he was asked to leave) were changed at the Prime Minister's whim. 36 Thus, despite extravagant promises to the contrary on the occasion of the centenary celebration ofthe Congress party (December 1985), Congress-I is yet to carry out inner parry election at any level. It would appear that the parry has become too sclerotic to submit itself to the upheaval of election. 37 See T.V. Sathyamurthy, 'Crisis i n the Congress Party: The Indian Pres­ idential Election of 1969', Tht WM'ld Today (November 1969). Prior to the 1969 crisis there was only one instance of the presidential candidate's nomina­ tion for a second time (1956) being under inner party discussion because of Rajendra Prasad's known opposition to the Hindu Code Bill. Since 1969, however, there have been at least two major occasions on which constitutional issues have arisen on the question of the correct relationship between the President and the elected executive. The first concerned the manner in which N. Sanjiva Reddy was thought to have handled the question of whether o r notJagjivan Ram should be invited to form a government when Desai lost a confidence vote in the Lok Sabha (1979). The second concerns the major difference of opinion over the role of the President between Prime Minister D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 246 Stllte 1171d Politia in India changes initiated during the 1969-70 period were to have far­ reaching effects on the internal working of the Congress party, on the role of the Indian state in dealing with legitimate opposition, and on the role of the Indian Constirution and the machinery of government established under its provisions. During the period 1969-75, attempts were made b y the centre to clamp down on opposition which manifested itself mainly in the form of trade union agitation by organized sections of labour, a brief but unconvincing return on the CPl(M)'s pan to revolu­ tionary activity38 after its retreat from the parliamentary path compelled by the ruthless application of state power against the organization and its cadres, and the mass movement (especially but not only in Bihar and Gujarat) against corruption under Jaya Prakash Narayan's leadership.39 Compared to these large-scale manifestations of discontent,40 the challenge - already watered down in content and portent due to years of less than incorruptible exercise of power, to say the least - posed b y a regional opposition party in control of executive power in a single state (DMK of Tamil Nadu) was negligible. The centre under the Congress party and the Tamil Nadu state under DMK had become habituated to a regimen of c o -existence without wires being crossed between the two sides about the extent of leeway a state could expect from the centre. All this notwithstanding the political wisdom enshrined in the celebrated Rajamannar Report The impetus for the Indian Emergency (1975-7) was thus derived not from any contradiction between the different instru­ ments of federal power representing the centre and the states, but predominantly from political challenges that sprang from outside the confines of government and which were interpreted by the Indian.state as a threat to its integrity and security rather than as demands for a new democratic mandate for the control of its power. The full impact of the Emergency can only be understood Rajiv Gandhi and President Zail Singh (1986-7). See, for example, the article entitled 'The President: Deepening Crisis' in India Today, 31 May 1987, p. 27. 38 See, for example, Achin Vanaik, 'The Indian Left', Nw Ltft Rroiw, no. 159, September/October 1986, pp. 49-70. 39 See R . Rajagopalan, 'Background to India's State of Emergency', The Black Liberator, vol. Z, no. 4,January 1975-August 1976, pp. 313-19. 40 See Anm Shourie, Sympt<mis ofFascism (New Delhi: Vikas, 1978). D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The lnstituti<ms 247 against a background of three related considerations. First, with the success of the green revolution, powerful political forces rose to the surface in a number of regions which represented the interests of the 'rural rich', more specifically the rich peasantry and the middle peasantry.41 Whilst the Congress party was in a position to put itself forward as the champion of the interests of the rich and middle peasant classes through the ranks of its re­ gional elites, its influence among these classes was being eroded for two major reasons: (1) The centre came under increasing pressure from industrial capital to release some of the surplus derived from agriculture for furthering the industrialization and modernization of the Indian economy. With the achievement of self-sufficiency in food, it was argued, the balance between industrial capital and agricultural capital should be reconstituted by government policy at the state level aimed at reducing grants, keeping down procurement prices and introducing a measure of agricultural taxation. (2) The rural poor (and in particular, landless labourers and poor peasants), largely consisting of low caste people and Muslims, who looked up to the Congress party which they supported in elections, bore the brunt of local oppression by landowning castes whose interests were served by the ruling party as well as several regionally based opposition parties.42 Over a period of time, the rural poor became disenchanted with the Congress as well as with other non-left regional parties.43 Except in Kerala, West Bengal and Tripura where the CPI and CPI(M) had shown themselves 41 In Kenia and West Bengal, as well as in certain parts of Andhra Pradesh where the CPI had long been active i n the countryside, rich peasant domina­ tion was limited in comparison to that in states such as Unar Pradesh. 42 These parties generally championed different caste members o f the rural rich classes. Thus in Bihar, the Lok Dal championed the c:iuse of the lower of the four landowning castes (the upper ones being served by the Congress party), whilst in Andhra Pradesh the Telugu Desam party reflects on balance the interests of the Kamma landowning caste. 43 Even during the brief periods in which they were in office (1967-9 in certain states, 1977-80 in the centre, and since 1982 in certain states), non-left regional parties have shown themselves to be incapable of or unwilling to address the problems of the poorer peasantry and landless labour. Of special interest is the role played by the DMK and AIADMK in Tamil Nadu where, during the last twenty years, the content of politics has been systematically Jumpmiud as a consequence of the indifference with which the state govern­ ment deals with the democratic demands of the agricultural poor. D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 248 State and Politics in India capable of introducing limited but enlightened land reform, and in Kamataka where the relative lack of entrenched rich peasant power enabled the Congress Chief Minister Devraj Urs to imple­ ment (during the l970s) a liberal land and agricultural policy, the plight of the poor peasantry and landless labourers rapidly wor­ sened throughout India in an economic aonosphere of downward differentiation leading to an expansion of the ranks of agricultural (and especially landless) labourers. The Emergency simply added a new dimension of state oppression and tyranny to the economic and social oppression that they suffered in their daily lives. All the more ironic, in view of the government's claim in its iO-point (and Sanjay Gandhi's five-point) justification of the Emergency that it was solely inspired by concern for the welfare of th e poor and oppressed. Moreover, the 1969 split, far from healing the rift within the Congress, simply had the effect of opening the floodgates of factionalism, groupism and dissidence even wider. In order to deal with the process of internal disintegration and the momen­ tum rapidly gained by the growing contradiction within the party between those in control of state power (for example the central leadership personified in the Prime Minister)44 on the one hand, and on the other, the Pradesh-level leaders, power was con­ centrated in the hands of a coterie which enjoyed the confidence of the Prime Minister and her family. The Pradesh Congress organizations were pitted against opposition parties (for example, the Bharatiya Kranti Dal [BKD] and its various subsequent frag­ mentations and transmogrifications) which put themselves for­ ward as champions of the rich and middle peasant classes in their struggle against a centre eager to seize the political opportunity to compel them to agree to a policy of transferring surplus from agriculture to industry by reversing the terms of trade between the two sectors of the economy. They were also confronting the central Congress leadership which took advantage of endemic dissidence within the ruling party45 to impose its own nominees as Chief Ministers of Congress-ruled state governments and leaders of the various Pradesh Congress organizations. 44 During the Emergency, the Congress president (Deb Kanta Barua) earned notoriety by making the statement 'India is Indira and Indira is India', a slogan which he was to rue after the Emergency ended. 4S See note 36. Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN Tht Institutions 249 The Pradesh Congress organizations were thus undermined and their leaders (with individual exceptions) lost touch with the mass of the people. At the same time, money power became a substitute for mass contact. A huge parallel economy fuelled by black market money became the engine through which such a basic transformation of the Congress organization was achieved in such a brief period of time. Several leaders who had a talent for making the right contacts with black market barons emerged within the organization resulting in support for the government being purchased rather than won by argument and persuasion.46 The Indian state did little to curb the black economy which, from the early 1970s onwards, had become the demi-goddess presiding over the fortunes of the ruling party of the government. Further, the literature on political developments in India rightly lays stress on the enormous increase in the coercive power of the state during the last quarter of a century and the consequent undermining of democratic processes, values and elementary lib­ erties guaranteed under the Indian Constitution. At the same time, popular democratic resistance to the government's arbitrary politi­ cal behaviour has also markedly increased during the last two decades, though it is not invariably manifested in a concerted manner except when electoral opportunities become available.47 Established political parties including cadre-based organizations had failed to provide adequate leadership in channelling popular discontent i n a democratic and constructive manner. However, during the Emergen�, they did take part in a joint organized democratic resistance to the central government's arbitrary rule which spread far beyond the confutes of party-based action to 46 For example, Lalit Narayan Mishra (mysteriously lcilled in Samastipur in 1974), ChiefMinister A.R. Antulay ofMaharashtra and Kamalapathi Tripathi (until recently the 'working president' of the Congress-I party). Even before Indira Gandhi became Prime Minister, money politics was introduced in a substantial manner by S.K. Patil, a member of the Congress 'Syndicate'. 47 See, for example, Rajni Kothari, 'The Non-Party Political Process', &o­ Mmic ,md Political Weekly, volume 19, no. 4, 4 February 1984, pp. 216-24; 'Will the State Wither Away?', The /IIJ1StT11ted Weekly ofIndi11, 8 July 1984, pp. 8-14; D.L. Sheth, 'Grassroots Initiatives in India', &/111Q/11ic 1171d Politic11/ Weekly, volume 19, no. 6, 11 February 1984, pp. 2S9-62. 48 New organizations were established for the promotion of the democratic rights and civil liberties of the people. These have remained active since the end of the Emergency (for exa1nple PUCL and PUDR). ·- D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 250 State and Politics in India mass-based opposition. The success of such a general strategy of opposing the Emergency was reflected in the resounding defeat suffered by the ruling party at the centre and in a majority of the states in the general and state legislative assembly elections held in 1977. Centre-state relations, during the 1969-77 period, were prac­ tically reduced to a state of near non-existence as a problematic of federal politics in India. Unitarism triumphed under the aegis of a strong state whose power was controlled by a ruling party which had lost its democratic mainspring. Centre-state relations were, at Independence, orchestrated in accordance with an equi­ librium model in which politically homogeneous states on the one hand and the centre on the other acted as countervailing forces in the evolution of a powerful post-colonial state. At the end of the Emergency and on the eve of the 1977 general election, however, they had undergone a paradigm shift characterized by a puissant centre presiding over a federation of thoroughly en­ feebled states. The Indian state itself was no longer controlled by a popular mass party functioning through a complex and reticulated or­ ganization but by a clique of powerful elements which could be relied upon to strike terror among potential opponents of the . , new brand of politics.49 The 1977 elections exposed the shallow­ ness of the achievements of the Congress as the ruling party and helped reverse the process of paradigmatic shift described in this section by strengthening democratic opposition to the regime and once again bringing out the question of centre-state relations into the open as one of fundamental importance for the future of the Indian state. m The 1977 general election provided the first occasion for the transfer of the control of state power from the Congress party to the loose-knitJanata coalition representing a variety ofruling class interests5° without putting on an artificial gloss of homogeneity 49 During the Emergency, Sanjay Gandhi, the Prime Minister's son, led such elements. so In an interesting discussion, Sudipta K:iviraj argues that as power has D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutions 25I to cover their disparateness and contradictions. Even though the new ruling coalition, unlike the Congress party, WllS both or­ ganizationally and ideologically weak, it did preside over a state which had become immensely strengthened during the previous three decades.s• Despite its impressive majority in the Lok Sabha,Janata's grasp of state power was, however, severely compromised by its lack of political clout and by the chronic inability of its ageing leaders to unite together on a positive programme.s2 The abrupt change from an autocratic unitarist to an entropic polyglot pattern of wielding state power was accompanied by centrifugal tendencies plaguing the very heart of the political system in its day-to-day functioning. Yet the new leaders (who were uncompromisingly 'consti­ tutionalist' in their determination to restore the primacy of par­ liamentary institutions and their practices -in spirit as in letter) shared the political orientation of their predecessors on the ques­ tion of centre-state relations.Sl They were not basically sym­ pathetic to demands for increased autonomy from the states except in certain well-defined spheres, and certainly not when accumulated i n the Indian state, paradoxically, institutions designed to safe­ guard democratic functioning of the state have weakened. In this author's view, this disjuncture between the power of the state and the institutions of democratic rule has in no way undermined the ordinary people's &ith in parliamentary institutions and civil and democratic rights for the citizens or even the preference shown by the powerful classes to cling to the rule of the civil constitution in times of crisis. See Sudipta Kaviraj, 'On the Crisis of Political Institutions in India', Contributions to lndilm Socio/or;, (N= Series), volume 18, no. 2, 1984, pp. 223-43. SI T.V. Sathyamurthy, 'India since Independence'. S2 With the exception of Jayaprakash Narayan who acted as peacemaker between the querulous parmers of the Jana ta leadership, all the others were busily engaged in publicly undemuning each other. Thus Prime Minister Moratji Desai, Home Minister Chowdhury Charan Singh and deputy Prime Minister Jagjivan Ram were always at odds with one another. The Janata coalition did not need an enemy to destabilize it. It acted as its own worst enemy. Within eighteen months, a formidable parliamentary majority was whittled down and the ruling coalition had disintegrated into two or three mutually hostile coalitions bent on destroying the government. SJ The Prime Minister of the Jana ta government and deputy Prime Minister Jagjivan Ram (as well as Chowdh ury Charan Singh) were reared in the same political tradition as their predecessors in office whose view of centr-tate relations was cast in the unitary rather than in a loose federal mould. Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 252 St11te 11nd Politics in India they were couched in combative political terms. Their grounds for believing that a strong centre and weak states did not represent an unhealthy combination were similar to the arguments advanced by the Congress party when it was in power. The sudden removal of the Congress party from the centre, followed by the election of a number of state governments led by parties other than the Congresss4 breathed new life into the ques­ tion of centre-state relations which had been put under constitu­ tional sedation following the systematic destabilization by the centre and the Congress party of the non-Congress state govern­ ments during the period 1967-70. The resurgence of interest in this question in post-Emergency India was manifested in three different forms. (1) States in which there was a strong tradition of Congress rule, where its popularity had not suffered during the Emergen­ cy,55 found themselves on the defensive for the first time since Independence. Their governments attempted to raise the ques­ tion of the autonomy of states by protesting against imagined encroachments by the centre which was under the control of the traditional opposition forces. The very act of restoring the Con­ stitution to its p r e 1- 975 condition by the new government at the centre was criticized by the Congress Chief Ministers of the southern states of Kamataka and Andhra Pradesh, and by the Pradesh Congress organizations as a deliberate attempt to curtail state autonomy. In the event, not much political mileage could be derived from such protests. S6 (2) Following Janata's landslide victory in the 1977 general 54 Upon its receiving a big majority in the 1977 election, the Janata govern­ ment dismissed a number of state governments where Congress was in power. This controversial decision, which was sustained by the Supreme Court, was followed by state assembly elections in a number of states. In several states Janata coalitions took power. In West Bengal and Tripura, CPI(M)-led United Left Front coalitions received substantial majorities. In K.erala, which went to the polls at the time of the parliamentary election (March 1977), electoral choice had gone against the grain of the rest of the country and a Congress-led coalition won by a narrow majority. ss For example Andhra Pradesh and K.amatalca (and, t o a lesser degree, Maharashtra). 56 Characteristically, the Congress-led Andhra Pradesh government blamed the central government for failing to come to its rescue when the state was faced with famine, floods, drought and other disasters. . . -. Digiti zed by Google - Ongmal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The lnstitutionr 253 election, a number of non-Congress governments won majorities in the state assembly elections that followed in its wake in many states. Janata, CPI(M)-led United Left Front (ULF) and other governments57 took control of executive power based on substan­ tial majorities in the assemblies. In putting the centre-state rela­ tions issue back on the political agenda, the leaders of these new ruling parties/coalitions were seeking not to confront the centre but rather to raise a number of crucial questions affecting eco­ nomic development.ss In other words, the question ofcentre-state relations was raised by a number of state governments as a means of readjusting the relations between the two sides and of achieving a modus vivendi that would take account of genuine economic and political grievances. Despite the new Prime Minister's personal reluctance to depart from his predecessor's general line on the subject, the Janata government - itself new to the art of wielding political power and accustomed much more to an oppositional than to a governmental role - was, by and large, prepared to accommodate these pressures mainly by a return to the Constitu­ tion and by reactivating such instruments as the National Devel­ opment Council (NOC).59 The Janata government also reviewed . the process of planning, sp,cifically with the aim of bringing about a mutually acceptable readjustment of fiscal allocations by the centre to the states, and of �tiating agricultural procurement policies from a much more differentiated perspective than that to which the centre had been accustom� in the past under successive Congress Prime Ministers.60 (3) From the perspective of centralists/unitarists, agitation for greater political autonomy for the states assumed its most dan­ gerous form whenever it was advanced in the name of more or less direct mass democratic political participation of aggrieved segments of the people. Thus in the Punjab, in Jammu and S7 A SAD-led government was formed in the Punjab; the AIADMK govern­ ment of Tamil Nadu had a big majority in the Tamil Nadu legislative assembly. S8 For aa.mple questions relating to the method and criteria of allocation of resources for development, and how the interests of the regional classes and social groups represented by the new parties in control of fedenJ and state power should be presented. S9 It consists of the Prime MiniStcr and Chief Ministers. 60 With the exception of the brief interrcgillllD (1964-6) when Lal Bahadur Shastri was Prime Minister. ' - D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 254 State and Politics in India Kashmir,61 in Assam, and in several of the north-eastern states, pressure for a radical reordering of centr�tate relations did not arise during this period (1977-84) from political parties/coalitions in control of state governments as such. Rather, it arose from powerful political movements enjoying a degree of mass popu­ larity62 which they were in a position to augment by carrying the banner of political protest and by raising demands of a basic nature which would have been stifled in the past by a powerful centre on the grounds that states on India's periphery were specially sensitive and vulnerable to foreign penetration and in­ filtration. During the Janata interregnum, these popularly based forces seriously reared their heads for the first time with the covert encouragement of Congress-163 whose main aim was to expose the political weakness of the Jana ta, to undermine it by exploiting its inner contradictions, and to bring its rule to an end b y whatever means available. In the Punjab, the Congress-I strategy took the form of sup­ porting Jamail Singh Bhindranwale as a fundamentalist Trojan horse within the political sphere of the Shiromani Akali Dal (SAD) and the Shiromani Gurudwara Prabandhak Committee (SGPC). As a result, the SAD-led government (1977-80) was successfully destabilized more or less simultaneously with the bringing down of the Janata itself.64 61 Jammu and Kashmir has a Constitution of its own. Its special status is recognized in Article 370 of the Indian Constitution. See Roop Kishen Bhatt, 'Kashmir: The Politics of Integration', in Iqbal Narain (ed.), Statt Politics in India (Meerut: Meenakshi Pralcashan, 1976), pp. 146-76; for a recent analysis of political changes in that sensitive state, see Balraj Puri, 'Fundamentalism in Kashmir, Fragmentation inJammu', &unomic and Political Wttkly, volume 22, no. 22, 30 May 1987, pp. 835-7. 62 In many instances, as in the case ofTelugu Desam, for example, the political forces that arise out of these move1nents reflet.'t the interests of narrow segments of the population. 63 For example Jamail Singh Bhindranwale's emergence as a leader of the fundamentalist Sikh mass could not have been smooth and sudden without the collusion of Zail Singh, one of Indira Gandhi's closest followers. 64 The Janata government was brought down in July 1979. In a series of moves i n which Indira Gandhi, President Sanjiva Reddy, Chowdhury Charan Singh and Raj Narain were involved, Jagjivan Ram, who could have formed an alternative government under Janata, was sidelined. Charan Singh fanned a government which was toppled in a fortnight. D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutions 255 It is important to note that the Janata party in particular and the Janata government as a whole were deeply opposed to the fundamentalist Sikh political forces which gave an entirely new twist not only to the spirit of the Ananadpur Sahib resolution,65 but also to the question of state autonomy itself. They were equally disapproving of the Assam students' movement and of p �ulist movements such as the Mizoram National Front (MNF). But, unlike the Indira Gandhi (Mark I) government (in its 1969-77 phase) which deployed all the political and governmental power a t its command to thwart such movements, the Janata coalition found itselftoo much at odds internally to be able to give attention to these new tensions and contradictions entering the picture o f centre-state relations in the aftermath of the ruling Congress party's defeat67 When Congress-I was returned to power in 1980 under Indira Gandhi (Mark the crises which it had helped keep stoked up when it was out o f power had already become firmly embedded in the political life. of the country. My aim here is to outline the strategy a4opted by the new Congress-I government to deal with centre-state tensions during its four years in power.68 The Janatil was a weak and badly organized political coalition which accidentally gained control over an extremely powerful state. The weakness of the ruling coalition during the 1977-9 interregnum was reflected in the reduced effectiveness of the state i n dealing with political tensions and conflicts.69 By the same token when the Congress-I took power, its hold over the state was m, 6S T.V. Sathyamurthy, 'India's Punjab Problem: The World Toda:,, March 1986, pp. 46-50. Edging towards a Solution?', 66 'Mizoram: Vote ofHope' (editorial), &ontmtic and Political Weekly, vol. 22, no. 9, 28 February 1987, p. 347. 67 The internal dialectic ofthe Indian ruling class was reftected in a deepening of the horizonail divisions within it. Janata was sim_ply a political reftection of th e impasse which had been reached earlier dunng the decade (1972-7) in the intra-ruling class relations between the national industrial capital and the agricultural rich. 68 See T.V. Sathyamurthy, 'Centre-State Relations: A Pre-Election Reckoning', Eamomicand Po/itia,I Weekly, vol. 19, no. 38, 29 September 1984, , pp. 1692-5. 69 The industrial policy of the government under George Fernandes and its agricultural poli cy under Bamala (and Charan Singh) reflected the conflictual nature of the relations between the rival segments of the bourgeoisie. See Charan Singh, India's Eamomic Nigbtmart (Delhi: Allied, 1981). Digiti zed by Google Ongmal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 256 State and Politics in India qualitatively different from what it had been under the Indira Gandhi (Mark I) government. Democratic opposition in different forms, once given a power­ ful voice not only by parties other than the Congress-I enjoying executive power in certain states, but also by mass-based opposi­ tion movements challenging the centre's right to limit the demo­ cratic rights of the people, could no longer be stifled. Congress-I was returned to power by an elcct0rate which foundJanata want­ ing, but which had by no mean� forgotten the Emergency .or forgiven its perpetrators. There was no doubt in 1980 that the Congress-I government was elected as a lesser evil and not as a popular alternative to the Janata. The reinheritance of state power by the Congress-I in 1980 was marked by two other major shifts in Indian politics. First, the agricultural bourgeoisie had emerged as a formidable national force capable of claiming a share of central state power. It was n o longer to be confined to the narrower limits of state politics. Chowdhury Charan Singh, as caretaker Prime Minister (July 1979-January 1980) became the political symbol of the insistent demands in favour of a shift in the terms of trade between industry and agriculture which had gathered momentum during the mid1970s. Even though it was not yet in a position to sustain itself in control of the commanding heights of state power, the agricultural bourgeois class had so successfully entrenched itself in the state structures that no ruling party (including Congress-I)could afford to underestimate its importance. The increased political restive­ ness of a number ofstate governments - not limited only to those governed by opposition parties but also extending to such impor­ tant Congress-I-ruled states as Maharashtra - should be viewed as a reminder that India's agricultural bourgeoisie has come to stay as a dominant class force .with considerable potential for national cohesion in the foreseeable future. Second, during its brief tenure, theJanata government, released from the stranglehold of its predecessor's socialist shibboleths and slogans, embarked upon the second stage of the Indian state's task of strengthening capitalist development in India.70 It took the Under the first five five-year plans, state policy gave great emphasis to heavy industry which the national industrial bourgeoisie could not be ex­ pected to develop out of its own capital resources. See Ranjit K. Sau, Jndil,', 70 Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from __ UNIVERSITY OF MlCHIGA N_ . _ The Institutions 257 initiative to open up the Indian manufacturing industry to power­ ful thrusts of foreign and multinational capital under the guidance of George Fernandes, the 'socialist' Minister for Industries. The task of financing the engines of capitalist development of the gigantic, but nevertheless chronically dependent, Indian economy would, the Janata government believed, require subst:mtial par­ ticipation of foreign capital. Whilst eager to continue the Janat:a policy of encouraging foreign capital in Indian industry, the Indira Gandhi (Mark II) government was unable to reverse the democratic political trends set ,in the country as a consequence of the re-emergence of self-confidence among different (and especially the relatively deprived) segments of the ruling class and its supporters among the petit-bourgeoisie and the intelligentsia (as well as organized labour) during the 1977-80 interval. Notwithstanding attempts made by the Indira Gandhi (Mark II) administration to reintroduce the Emergency by the back­ door,71 indecision and drift were the characteristic features of its policy towards the various regionally based opposition parties and popular movements in different pans of India. The Prime Minister continued to espouse the view that opposition to the centre was ipso faao against the interest and integrity of the nation. But the ruling party which controlled state power was far too riven by internal dissension72 (the main feature being the revolt of the agricultural middle classes) and by confliqts appearing in the seem­ ingly menacing guise of protests by different nationalities, to prevent the creeping paralysis of the system of conflict manage­ ment that a democratic polity backed by a powerful state ought to be in a position to wheel into action. Paradoxically, the centralizing and autocratic approach adopted by the Indian government to centr�tate relations and to such regionally based opposition to the centre as the Assam students' &onomi, Gntwtb: Cunstrllint1 and Prospects (Calcutta: Orient Longman, 1973) for a background to these developments. 71 See, for example, Ashok Mitra's three pan essay entitled 'The Legacy of Indira Ga.ndhi', 11,t lllustr11ud Wttk� efIndi11 (15 December, 22 December 1985 and 5 January 1986). 72 See, forenmpl e ; Achin Vanaik, 'TheRajiv Congress inSearch ofStability', Nn11 Left Reuit'IJI, no. 154, November/December 1985, pp. 55-82, especially pp. 55-70 and 76-7. Digiti zed by Google Ongmal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 258 State and Politics in India movement, as exemplified in a repeated resort to President's rule in the offending states, had the effect of exposing the limitations of deploying the main force in the form of an unbridled use of the coercive power of the state apparatus in order to stifle democratic dissent At the same time, not only was the Congress-I severely defeated in a series of state legislative assembly elections during the period 1982-4, but also essentially democratically organized opposition to the centre in such states as the Punjab, Assam, and Jammu and Kashmir quickly acquired an overlay of communalism and 'extremist' violence. Operation Bluestar and the eventual as­ sassination of the Prime Minister thus appeared as the obverse and reverse of the same coin. IV Indira Gandhi's efforts to restore the balance of influence in centre-state conflicts in favour of the centre failed because she was not willing to change her political methods of the early 1970s in the changed socio-economic circumstances of the 1980s. The Janata coalition had an adequate understanding of the tensions brewing in the relations between the national industrial bour­ geoisie and the agricultural bourgeoisie which could only be re­ solved by loosening the political grip of the centre over the states and by establishing a broad consensus between the different op­ posing segments of the ruling class dominating different spheres of the economy and in acute competition with each other for resources for development. Its failure lay in its inability to build a ruling political party capable of reflecting such a consensus as an alternative to the Congress party. The failure of the Indira Gandhi (Mark II) government lay in the fact that the Prime Minister refused to acknowledge the need for a coalition between the agricultural and industrial (as well as other) segments of the dominant class, preferring instead an im­ mobilized state to a centre in which different interests would be reflected as they manifested themselves at the level of the state and in society at large. In an epoch demanding power-sharing between competing segments of the ruling class, the anomalous political behaviour of the Indira Gandhi (Mark II) government resulted in a petrification of the centre's resources for compromise and consensus. Digiti zed by Google ---- UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN-· ' Ori ginal from The Institutions 259 Rajiv Gandhi's government (from I 985) has not depaned from the style of functioning of the Indira Gandhi (Mark Il) govern­ ment; however, its instinctive understanding of the social and economic forces at odds with one another in the Indian polity is somewhat more pragmatic and Jess rigid than that of its predeces­ sor. The development of centre-state relations during the present period must be viewed within a larger framework of the major tensions and contradictions of contemporary Indian society. Under the Rajiv Gandhi government, the rhetoric of forging ahead into the twenty-first century73 is being used to justify in­ egalitarian policies as well as an economic strategy directed towards an expansion of industrial capacity and towards increasing the resilience of industrial capital. Whilst the economic trend set in I977 of injecting significant amounts of international and multina­ tional capital has been given an additional fillip by the present government, theJanata government's policy of even-handed treat­ ment of the industrial and agricultural bourgeoisie no longer fits in with its general economic orientation. The needs of the agricultural bourgeoisie - a crucial class rooted in the states - which is committed to a general policy of modernization, expansion of its productive base, and a more rapid reproduction of capital in its sphere (all with the continued aid of the state) can no longer be given the same importance as those of the industrial bourgeoisie. It is a characteristic feature of the Indian political economy that agricultural and industrial capital cannot, in the long run, expand simultaneously within an indigenous framework. Each segment of the bourgeoisie would inevitably regard the preponderant de­ velopment of the other as taking place at its expense. In recent years this trend has been increasingly discernible. Dependent capitalist development under acutely uneven con­ ditions of development of production relations cannot take place without giving rise, in the long run, to conflicts between different segments of capital or without transforming existing intra-ruling class conflicts from a basically non-antagonistic to an increasingly antagonistic state. But in adopting Rajiv Gandhi as its most fa­ vourite candidate to date for piloting the ship of state into the future, the industrial bourgeoisie of India may have been prema­ turely confident of the potential for growth inherent in Indian 73 T.V. - Sathyamurthy, 'Piloting a Nation'. Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 260 State and Politia in India capital and of its own capacity to withst:md, even with the aid of state power, the vigorous onslaught of the rural rich that is bound to follow sooner than might be anticipated. It is against this general background that centre-state relations during the fmal phase of this discussion must be viewed. Since its accession to power under Rajiv Gandhi's leadership, Congress-I has had to face sineen state legislative assembly elec­ tions. Of these, ten states went to the polls within six months of the eighth general election (1985). State legislative assembly elec­ tions in the Punjab (1985), Assam (1986) and Mizoram (1987) were called on the basis of accords signed between the govern­ ment at the centre and leaders of popular movements based in the states. Of the three most recent state legislative assembly elections (March 1987), those in West Bengal and Kerala were regular quinquennial ones required under the Constitution. The election inJammu and Kashmir took place after a brief interrup­ tion of President's rule during which a deal had been hammered out between the National Conference (Nq (led by Farooq Ab­ dullah)74 and the Congress-I. These developments throw into bold relief three trends of importance for the future of centre­ state relations in India. In the heartland states and in the states in peninsular India, the Congress-l's strategy of frightening the electorate by means of warnings that state governments controlled by parties other than Congress-I could be starved of development resources was counter-productive to varying degrees. The sense of disgruntle­ ment of local elites (predominantly rural in character, with some links with the wider economy through small industrial enterprises, especially in the south) laced with popular support for 'demo­ cratic' values (in the given conten) led to opposition parties being returned to power with comfortable majorities.75 In Uttar Pradesh the 1982-3 period, Abdullah had been a key opposition Chief Minister who mustered support for a sustained agitation of the states against the centte. In the event, his government was toppled by Congress-I machina­ tions which resulted in detaching a clique led by Abdullah's brother-in-law (GM. Sadiq) from the NC. Overnight the government ofJammu and Kash­ mir changed hands and GM. Sadiq became Chief Minister dependent upon Congress-I support in the state legislative assembly. 75 Since 1982, Telugu Desam in Andhra Pradesh and Janata in Kamatalca appear to have consolidated their position by winning two successive state assembly elections. In the former case, the clumsy effort to topple a popular 74 During D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The lnrtitutions 261 and Bihar, the Dalit Mazdoor IGsan Party (DMKP)76 emerged as a substantial force on the opposition benches of the legislative assembly with the Congress-I in a majority.77 In Maharashtra, the People's Democratic Front (PDF), a coali­ tion representing powerful agrarian interests, established itself as a substantial presence in the assembly, though not in a majority, after a successful campaign demanding crop protection insurance by the state and better procurement prices for jowar and cotton. The Congress-I's two-pronged strategy of dealing with a potential crisis in Maharashtra consisted of replacing the locally chosen compromise candidate for Chief Minister's post by a more power­ ful figure from the central cabinet and of wooing Congress-S, the most influential segment of PDF, back into the Congress-I fold. 78 The case of Maharashtra also illustrates a fundamental weakness of the political organization of the Congress-I. We have already noted that the erosion of internal democracy was an imponant factor in the debilitation of the ruling party in a number of states. Central dictation as to who should be Chief Minister as well as the arbitrary removal and replacement of elected and incumbent Chief Ministers of the Congress-I-ruled states with lightning rapidity and without proper consultation have sharpened the con­ trast between them and the states in which executive power is held by opposition panies which invariably function according to well­ recognized democratic principles, practices and procedures.79 government gave rise to mass protest of unprecedented intensity spreading fa r beyond the boundaries of Andhra Pradesh (1984). 76 T.V. Sathyamurthy, 'Piloting a Nation'. 77 The existence of such a large number of legislators belonging to a party exclusively devoted to the interests of the rich .ind middle peasantty (even though the party has been subject to numerous splits based on personal rivalries among the leaders and particularly on the question of who should succeed Chowdhury Charan Singh as party leader) is itself a factor contribut­ ing to the instability of the Congress-I majority and to increased dissidence within the ruling party. 78 With S.B. Chavan as Chief Minister and Sharad Pawar, the Congress-S leader and influential spokesman ofthe agricultural lobby, back in Congress-I, a brief respite has been gained in the conflict between different segments of the dominant elements of Maharashtra's politic:il economy. But it is 1nore than likely that within a brief period of time the struggles which have persisted in Maharashtra since the mid-l970s will reswne. 79 Even in regional parties such as the AIADi\1K and Telugu Desam which -- Digiti zed by Google Ongmal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 262 StaU llnd Politics in Jndu, The second broad trend relates to t�ons arising in states closely linked to the heartland where a political backlash bas affected the relations between the different segments of the re­ gional elite. In Gujarat, for example, where the numerical propor­ tion between 'forward' and 'backward' classes/castes80 is more balanced than that prevailing in states such as Tamil Nadu, say, the policy of showing positive discrimination towards 'backward' castes, pursued by successive Congress governments of the state, was believed by 'forward' castes to have resulted in unfair disad­ vantage to them over the years in the spheres of education, em­ ployment, social welfare, etc. The movement led by the late Jayaprakash Narayan during the mid-I 970s against government corruption caught on in a big way in Gujarat. After the Emergency, however, fresh agitation for social and economic justice was moW1ted by the socially 'forward' but by then deeply aggrieved castes. Their leaders claimed that 'forward' castes had indeed been rendered economically 'backward' as a result of . three decades of Congress governments' policy affecting their mterests. The central government, led successively by Janata, Indira Gandhi's Congress-I, and Rajiv Gandhi's Congress-I has been unable to deal with this intra-elite strife in Gujarat in an effective manner because of the fear that (I) a reversal of the policy of 'reservation' under pressure would be a cure worse than the disease because well-entrenched political and socio-economic forces rep­ resenting the interests of 'backward' castes/classes would be up in anns81 and (2) Gujarat is not alone in racing the problem of the imbalances where decades of working a policy of 'reservation' has come home to roost in the form of new pressures which cannot be satisfuctorily dealt with by a mechanical reversal of existing policy. 82 The case of Gujarat is of particular significance in view of the fact that its relations with the centre have always been close, even as its influence on the national economy has been considerable. 83 depend upon the charisma of a single leader, a semblance of local de,nocracy is observed either in the. party organ or in the election of local authorities with a modicum of devolution. 80 'Forward': 'Baclcward' castes - 3: 4. 81 &um,mi, and Politu:11/ Weekly, vols 18, 19 and 20 (various issues), 1983-5. 82 Jbid. 83 T V. . Sathyamurthy, 'Indian Nationalism'. D1g1t 1zeo by Google -� - Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutions 263 But the ruling Congress-I, which was returned to power in the 1985 state legislative assembly election with a sizeable majority, had so completely miscalculated the mood of the middle class elements belonging to the 'forward' castes, that its administration was brought to a halt by strikes and social clashes84 within weeks of assuming power. The centre's response to the crisis in Gujarat was to change the Chief Minister rather than to give political leadership by tackling the question of 'reservation' in a sensitive manner. Thus even though Gujarat poses no great threat to the existing scheme of federal relationships in India, it illustrates the practically intractable nature of the socio-economic tensions and contradictions that can emerge under the specific conditions of adjusting political power relationships between unequally devel­ oped segments of ruling elites exemplified in the context of this discussion. To the third tier of development of centre-state relations in contemporary India belongs the far more complicated questions posed by those states in which the economic logic of protest is overlaid by a clearly augmented consciousness of cultural, com­ munal, linguistic, jurisprudential and other forms of neglect on the part of the Indian state. At the present moment, Punjab and Assam clearly belong to this category, but the states on India's land periphery (for example Jammu and Kashmir and the north­ eastern states such as Miroram)85 are equally susceptible to such pressures. Such social and cultural aspects of their role accrue to · these peoples as minorities or separate nationalities (not to be confused with 'nations')86 and they can only be brought into the mainstream by taking cognizance of their susceptibilities which have been suppressed by a stepping up of coercion on the part of the state apparatus. The Rajiv Gandhi government's initiatives in respect of the Punjab question have, to date, wavered between extending the olive branch of conciliation to the aggrieved Sikh community in . 84 T.V. Sathyamurthy, 'Piloting a Nation'. 8S See, for example, Balraj Puri, 'Fundamentalism in Kashmir, Fragmentation in Jammu', &un11111ic IITld Political Wtekly, vol. 22, no. 22, 30 May 1987; and Udayon Misra, 'Assam: All Assam Students' Union - Crisis of Identity', Eanwmic IITld Political Weekly, vol. 22, no. 13, 28 March 1987, pp. 535-o. 86 T.V. Sathy.unurthy, N11tionalism in the Cuntmtpur11ry Wurld, chapters 2 and 3. --- - Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 264, State and Politics in India the hope of isolating Sikh 'extremists' on the one band, and on the other, lapsing into a continuation of the repressive policy orientation of the Indira Gandhi (Mark II) government. 87 The Longowal-Rajiv Gandhi accord (1985) seemed to open a fresh chapter of healing the rupture between the centre and the state of Punjab based on a serious attempt on the fonner's part to remove the political, social and economic grievances embodied in the Anandpur Sahib resolution of the SAD. But the Akali Dal government which took power in September 1985 received no · real support from the centre which was content to blame the popularly elected state government for the persistence of terrorism and o f tension and conflict between the Sikh and Hindu com­ munities. Not a single undertaking by the centre outlined in the Longowal-Rajiv Gandhi accord was carried out. Apart from the centre's belief that the administration of Punjab could not be left entirel in the hands of the government duly elected for the purpose,ri8 it was subject to enormous pressure from elements within Congress-I, particularly in neighbouring Haryana89 (and, to a lesser degree, Rajasthan) which successfully 87 T.V. Sathyamurthy, 'Problems i n Punjab' (an essay in three pans), Tbt St11tmtt4n, Calcutta and Delhi, 12, 13 and 14 December 1983; 'Punjab: The Real Problem', The llluttr11ttd Weekly ofIndia, Bombay, 4 March 1984, pp. 36-43. 88 See, for example, Special Feature on 'Haryana: A Fortress Besieged', lnduz Today, vol. 12, no. 10, 16-31 May 1987, pp. 38-43. 89 The Haryana state legislative assembly election, along with the West Bengal and Kerala polls, was held (17June 1987) in the expectation that a spectacular victory in it would enable the centre to retrieve its fast eroding popularity. The main contenders were the Lok Dal-B led byChaudhury Devi Lal, a senior opposition figure representing the interests of the lcuJaJcs and · the middle peasantry Qoined by the largely urban-based BJP) on the one side, and by Congress-I on the other Qoined in a marrillgt tk cunvtn1111Ct by a Lok Dal splinter purporting to represent the interests of the Chaudhury Charan Singh dynasty). Even although the Haryana opposition parties' campaign started on local issues in general, and on the divergence and conflict of interests between Haryana and the Punjab, it soon fanned out to issues of national importance on which the Haryana electorate was called upon to pronounce a verdict. The latter included the corrupt and authoritarian be­ haviour of the centre bedevilled as the ruling party then was by a mounting catalogue of scandals reaching well beyond the pale of national politics into the international arena. Of particular importance to the main thesis argued in this discussion is the importance attached by Chaudhury Devi Lal, during the election campaign, to rich and middle peasant interests. This was reflected in his attack against the central government's mode.mization policies, which Dig1t1zeo by Google Origi�al rrom _ UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutions 265 frustrated even the tentative moves which the Indian government appeared to be ready to initiate in relation to the demands .of Punjab. The Punjab situation deteriorated despite Chief Minister Barnala's determination to sustain the credibility and viability of the SAD government until, finally, the centre dismissed it (May 1987) on the ground that it was no longer capable of restoring law and order. In fact, however, the immediate motivation for dismiss­ ing the popularly elected government of Punjab and imposing President's rule lay in the fact that the state legislative assembly election in Haryana was fast approaching90 in which the Congress­ I would have to acquit itself well if the massive erosion of the popularity of the Rajiv Gandhi government as signified in the r�ults of the March 1987 state legislative assemblies' elections in different parts of India was to be staunched.91 h e sometimes couched in 'rural versus urban' terms and on other occasions in terms of a confilct between the Western-oriented upper class minority and the mass of the people! (See, for example, the editorial, &o,u,mic 1171d Politiad Wttkly, vol. 22, no. 25, 20 June I 987, p. 959). The significance of this state assembly election thus went far beyond the confines of the Pwljab versus Haryana issue. One of the main planks of the platform of the Lok Dal-B election campaign consisted of a promise to write off all loans under Rs 15,000. In fact, it even threatened, albeit for brief moment only, to add to the uncertainty prevailing in the constitutional conflict then still under way between the Prime Minister and the President (Zail Singh); for were the opposition to win a decisive victory in one of the heartland states, there could well be a concerted effort on the part of the non-left opposition parties to provoke a split within the ruling party by malcing use of the presidential election that was due to take place inJuly 1987. The spectacular victory won by Lok Dal-B-BJP alliance even exceeded the 1977 victory of theJanata party in Haryana. Devi Lal's nyaya yatrt1 thus ended in the coalition led by him winning more than 75 per cent of the total seats, with Lok Dal-B itself winning a clear majority in the assembly. Congress-l's defeat in Haryana may thus be said to have increased the chances of its future in the rest of the heartland being problematic during the interval between the Haryana state assembly election and the ninth general election due in 1989. 90 See, for example, Special Report on 'Haryana Election Analysis: A Delicate Balance', Indi11 Today, vol. 12, no. II, 1-15 June 1987, pp. 32--4. 91 West Bengal returned the Left Front to power with an enhanced majority (and a majority for the CPI(M) component); Kerala returned a Left ·Front coalition to power, defeating the United De1nocratic Front which, under the leadership of Congress-I held power from I982 to 1987;J amrnu and Kashmir returned the National Conference under Abdullah's leadership to power. NC fought the election with the support of Congress-I. �'t"•" by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 266 Statt and Politics in India The Punjab and Assam crises point out different dimensions of the question of centre-state relations. In Punjab, the main dif­ ficulty arose from the Sikh view of the link between politics and religion on the one hand,92 and on the other, the reluctance of the Hindus to identify themselves primarily as Punjabis rather than as a part of the Hindu mainstream of India. The crisis engulfing Assam arose out of the indigenous Assamese population feeling outnumbered and marginalized in its own home ground. To some degree the problem faced by the Assamese in relation to the Bengalis and Bangladeshis has also been experienced by the different 'tribal' peoples of the north-east in relation to non-tribal settlers in their midst.93 By 1973, the proportion of indigenous Assamese to the total population of the state had dropped by over 20 per cent to well below 50 per cent, spreading alarm among a population which, only in 1967, had achieved a new stability with the formation of Meghalaya.94 The formation of Bangladesh, far from allaying the fears of the indigenous population, aroused anxiety afresh with each successive wave of Bangladeshi immigration into Assam.95 The ruling party at the centre and in Assam was unconcerned about the impact of this massive influx of Bengali Muslims for the understandable reason that they,96 in contrast to the Assamese inhabitants of the Brahmaputra valley (in the upper reaches of Assam), could be relied upon to give electoral support to the Congress. But the resulting social disruption posed a threat to the communally organized agrarian economy of the state because the new immigrants who were accustomed to radically different methods of cultivation sought to establish themselves on die land that they cultivated as individual owners. issues specially devoted to the Punjab, entitled 'The Punjab Tangle' (no. 294, February 1984) and 'Punjab Perspectives' (no. 326, October 1986) deal with this aspect of the Punjab crisis in several contributions. 93 See T.V. Sathyamurthy, N11ti111Ulimr in tbt Crmtem/Jllf'ary Wwld. 94 Ibid., chapter 8. 9S During the 1960s and 1970s, when Assam's importance to the Indian economy rose with the sinlcing of oil wells, massive influxes ofBengalis from East Pakistan • Bangladesh continued, variously estimated at one to two million. By 1973, the proportion ofindigenous Assamese to the total popula­ tion of the st2te had dropped to less than 50 per cent. 96 Along with a section of the tribal population, tea garden workers as well as other non-Assamese people living in the Barak vaUey of lower Assam. 92 Smut11r D1g1t1zeo by Orlgmal frcm Google ------UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN -. -. The Institutions 267 The defeat of the Congress party in the state legislative assemb­ l y election in 1978 was followed by the emergence of a mass movement, led by ·the students, highlighting Assamese grievan­ ces.97 It focused attention on one main demand arising out of a grievance going back to the 1960s. Declaring that the East Pakistan/Bangladeshi immigrants were 'foreign' nationals, the student movement demanded that they should be repatriated to their 'homeland' or sent to any other part of India. The Janata government of the state (1978-80) was paralysed by strikes, blockades, and demonstrations which evoked massive support from the population. When the Indira Gandhi (Mark II) administration took power, the Janata administration in Assam was summarily dismissed. Its place was taken by a much less popular Congress-I administration which was defeated in the legislature within a short time. The state could not be governed by the centrally appointed bureaucrats who stepped into the political vacuum resulting from the collapse of elected government. The student-led movements continued to demand that the Assamese people and not the centre had the right to disenfranchise 'foreign nationals' in the state as a prelude to expulsion. A constitutional imbroglio of unparalleled intensity was thus injected into the very heart of the dispute between the centre and the state of Assam. Even though the central government maintained a pretence of keeping negotiations alive with the student leaders, the Prime Minister was unwilling to resolve the dispute in a spirit of accommodation. The state legislative as­ sembly election, called in February 1983, ended in widespread mayhem and murder.98 A government of questionable legitimacy was installed in power in a political atmosphere which reeked of 97 By l979 (November), popular discontent in Assam with the centre cry s ­ tallized around two student organizations - the All Assam Student's Union (AASU) and the All Assam Gana Sangr:im Parishad (MGSP). Between them, the two organizations were able to bring public life to a complete halt for prolonged periods. Their challenge to the centre with the support of the mass of the Assamese people belonging to different socio-economic groups was at times reminiscent of the 4 May 1919 Movement in China. 98 ln one area (Nellie) alone, many hundreds were massacred on election day. The boycott called by the Assam students in Assamese constituencies had been so successful that in one parliamentary constituency only 11 electors turned up to ast their votes on election day! Digiti zed by Google Ongmal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 268 State and Politics in India divisions between Assamese and 'tribals', Assamese and Bengalis, Hindus and Muslims, and Hindus and Christians. The Rajiv Gandhi government's approach to the Assam ques­ tion appeared to be at least as positive in character as its Punjab initiative. The new Prime Minister seemed to appreciate that in order to maintain the rtatus quo in broad terms in the country as a whole, the national 'ruling classes' ought to share state power with political forces dominant in the various regions. The Assam accord was signed in an improved atmosphere as a prelude to a fresh state legislative assembly election.99 It is worth noting that the original demands of the student leaders which had been rejected by the Indira Gandhi (Mark II) government on the grounds that they were constitutionally impertinent and injurious to India's integrity were accepted by the Rajiv Gandhi govern­ ment on purely pragmatic considerations. By thus distancing itself from the lame duck Congress-I gov­ ernment, on the eve of the 1985 state assembly election, the centre weakened its already enfeebled position even further. In October 1985, the student movement gave birth to the Asom Gana Parishad (AGP), the first regional party in Assam's history which came to power on a platform emphasizing its simultaneous­ ly national and regional character. 100 The communal polarization of the state had reached such serious proportions that the new goven1ment was obliged to begin its career cautiously under the careful scrutiny of the All Assam Students' Union (AASU) which has kept its identity entirely separate from that of AGP. During the last seventeen months of its existence, the AGP government has not been signally successful in gaining the cooperation of the centre in the implementation it, the centre undenook to ensure that all illegal immigrants who entered the state during the 1961-71 period (especially 1966-71) would be disenfranchised (though they might be allowed to stay in the state) until 1995, and to expel those immigrants who had illegally entered Assam across the porous Bangladesh border after the cut-off date of 25 March 1971. 100 The AGP contested 117 out of a total of 125 assembly seats and 11 out of 12 Lok Sabha seats. It won 64 asse1nbly seats and Congress-I 25, and 7 Lok Sabha seats and Congress-I 4: The United Minorities Front (UMF) which broke away from Congress-I because of its opposition to the Assam Accord won 17 Asse1nbly seats and one Lok Sabha seat. AGP, Congress-I and UM. F gained 35 per cent, 23.4 per cent and 11 per cent of the total votes polled, respectively. 99 Under D1g1t1zeo Orlgmal frcm by G e l 0oge,..._<:::a.�� ----··1Jti!JY.��Sll:.'( QF MICHIG�f'I The Institutions 269 of the Assam Accord, especially with reference to the 'foreigners issue'. With the centre far too slow to respond to these pressures and the AASU radicalizing rapidly on the issues underlying the tensions engulfing Assam since the mid- l 970s, the AGP govern­ ment has lost a good deal of its initial momentum. 101 As in the Punjab, so too in Assam the centre has been caught in a con­ tradiction between an awareness of the need to enlist the coopera­ tion of regional elites and an unwillingness to modify the centralist orientation of the Indian state to which the Indian government has long become habituated. During the last four decades, independent India has undergone a transformation from a homogeneous polity in which power was shared between the centre and the states under the control of the ruling Congress party into one in which control is shared between a centre which has continued to be governed by the Congress partyand the states in which a variety of different parties (of which the Congress-I is one) have won executive power in the legislative assemblies. A vigorous and determined effort on the part of the Indira Gandhi (Mark I) government to prevent this change from setting in by destabilizing non-Congress state governments and imposing the central leadership's writ on Congress-controlled state govern­ ments in an arbitrary manner failed. But the Indian state has continued to grow in power and has been able to increase its coer­ cive capacity steadily throughout the post-Independence phase. Since the end of the Emergency, attempts have been underway to accommodate the horizontal conflicts between the two main segments of the ruling class (namely, the national industrial bour­ geoisie and the regional bourgeoisie, mainly but not exclusively rural in character). These have resulted in the emergence of fairly stable regional parties well entrenched in a number of states, in a strengthening of national parties such as the CPI(M) and Janata in certain states, and in enhancing the influence of the rural element in the agriculturally important states where Congress -control of the state legislative asse1nbly is becoming predicated IOI See, for example, Udayon Misra, 'Assam: All Assam Students' Union', pp. 535-6. The loss of momentwn lus been further exacerbated by the economic problems caused by the recent floods (August-September 1987). See, for example, 'Assam: Some Boeing, Some Flying', &1J111111tic and Political Weekly, vol. 22, nos 36 and 37, 5-12 September 1987, pp. 1515-16. --- - Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 270 State ll1Jd Politics in India more and more on its capacity to collaborate and to share power with its competitors. 102 India may well be on the verge of a new era of power sharing in which, despite new uncertainties over the correct constirutional relationship between the elected represent­ atives in control of state power on the one hand and the indirectly elected President on the other,103 powerful states can benefit from a strong Indian state controlled at the centre b a coalition of parties representing diverse ruling class interests.tc04 genres of opposition have thus developed - one, opposition in the fonn of st:1tes governed by parties/coalitions opposed to the Congress-I and the other i n the form of internal opposition in agriculturally impoltlnt st:ltes &om rich and middle peasant classes irrespective of whether their supporterS vote Congress-I or one of the peasant parties. The former has now become so entrenched that they express opposition to the centre in a more or less concerted form through periodic meetings of Chief Ministers of non­ Congress-1 states (Madras, Vijayawada, Calcutta, Srinagar, Bangalore during the 1980-4 period, and Delhi in April 1987). See, for example, this author's 'Southern Chief Ministers' Meeting', &onamic lffld Po/itict1I Weekly, vol. 18, no. 15, 9 April 1983, pp. 576-9; Sumit Chakravarty, 'Meeting of Chief Ministers', M11instrum, 2 May 1987, pp. 3-4, 34. 103 The crisis in the relationship between the President and the Prime Minister (1986-7) is without precedent and holds a portent of deep potential signifiance for the Indian Constitution and its political expression. No clear analysis has yet appeared. about its nature and import, but a number of thoughtful observations have been published all the same. See, for example, Prabhu Chawla, 'The President: Deepening Crisis' ,Indi11 Todlly, 31 May 1987, p. 27. 104 Recent developments, not only in the states lying outside the heartland but also in the heartland states such as the Punjab, Haryana and Uttar Pradesh would point in this direction. Furthermore, the general drift of the political implications of the main findings of the Sarlcaria Commission report, the twists and turns in the political processes underlying the consolidation of national opposition to Congress-I around the National Forum (which in­ cludes regional and central opposition parties) in general and the Janata Dal (embracing different centrist parties of the national opposition) in particular, and last but not least, the tendencies evidenced by the results of the elections tc;> the state legislative assemblies of Tamil Nadu, Nagaland and Mizoram in January 1989, would seem to contain intimations of the hernlding of a new era in centre-state relations on the eve of the next decade. 102 Two Digiti zed by Google - Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 7 Development Planning and the Indian State • Partha Chatterjee A )though it is a virtual truism that the state is the central actor .l"1in any programme for planned economic development, its role in planning is not for that reason any less problematical. What does it mean to say that 'the state' acts? Does it act on its own? Do others act through it? Who does it act upon? On other entities outside the state? Or does it act upon itself? To talk about the state as an 'actor' is to endow it with a will; to say that is acts according to coherent and rational principles of choice is further to endow it with a consciousness. How is this will and conscious­ ness produced? These are not, one would presumably agree, questions with which the economic literature on planning has concerned itself. For the most part, that literature has taken what it calls 'socio­ political conditions' as parametric for its exercise. What the state thinks as politically necessary or feasible is 'given' to the planner; it is determined by a process of politics that is extraneous to the planning exercise perse. The task of the planner is to work out the consistencies between different objectives, weigh the costs and benefits ofdifferent alternatives and suggest an efficient or optimal mix of strategies. Planning, many would say, is an exercise in instrumental rationality. And yet it is curious that when debates about planning have led to fundamental disagreements within the discipline, economists have not managed to hold themselves back • I am grateful to Asok Sen, Gautam Sen, the participants of the London conference, and my colleagues in the Kanlrurgachhi Hegel Qub, for their comments on earlier drafts of this chapter. - - Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from ·- UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 272 State and Politics in India from arguing about the relative priorities among 'socio-political' objectives or about their political feasibility and have defended or attacked particular planning strategies by appealing to conside r a ­ tions that are presumably external to their practice. As someone whose professional preoccupation is to marvel at the ways in which logic becomes perpetually in1plicated in rhetoric, knowledge in power, I am not surprised by this transgression of avowed disciplinary boundaries. My own practice within my hap­ pily i l l -defined discipline has taught me (notwithstanding the fact that some of my colleagues still go on pretending that they can usefully do for politics what the economists have done for the economy: may they remain at peace with their intellects!) that not only are instruments chosen according to goals that are desired, but goals themselves are very often fixed because certain instruments have to be used. Indeed, instruments in politics can become goals in themselves, just as the very declaration of an objective can become an instrument for something else. The once-fashionable debate about the separability of means and ends was, as far as I can understand it, only another way of establishing their unity. To me, then, the interesting question is not whether the idea of a domain of instrumental rationality clearly demarcated from the-disorderly terrain of political squabble can be logically sustained. Rather, the interesting question is how this very assertion of a technical dis­ cipline of planning can become an instrument of politics, i.e. of the exercise and contestation of power. I will address my question directly to the experience of Indian planning. But in order to do that, let me begin with a bit of history. Planning for Planning1 In August 193 7, the Congress Working Committee at its meeting in Wardha adopted a resolution recommending to the Congress Ministries the appoint1nent of a Committee of experts to consider urgent and vital problems the solution of which is neces­ sary to any scheme of national reconstruction and social planning. Such solution will require extensive survey and the collection of data, as well as a clearly defined social objective. I This section is largely based on Raghabendra Chanopadhyay, 'The Idea of Planning i n India, 1930-1951 ', Australian National University, 1985, u n ­ published Ph.D. thesis. D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN -· The Institutions 273 The immediate background to this resolution was the forma­ tion by the Congress, under the new constitutional arrangements, of ministries in six (later eight) provinces of India and the ques­ tions raised, especially by the Gandhians (including Gandhi him­ self) about the responsibility of the Congress in regulating (more precisely, restricting) the growth of modem industries. The left within the Congress, including its two stalwarts,Jawaharlal Nehru and Subhas Chandra Bose, sought to put aside this nagging ideological debate by arguing that the whole question of Congress policy towards industries must be resolved within the framework of an 'all-India industrial plan' which this committee of experts would be asked to draw up. Accordingly, Bose in his presidential speech at the Haripura Congress in February 1938 declared that the national state 'on the advice of a Planning Commission' would adopt 'a comprehensive scheme for gradually socializing our en­ tire agricultural and industrial system in the sphere of both pro­ duction and appropriation'. In October that year, Bose summoned a conference of the Ministers of Industries in the Congress min­ istries and soon after announced the formation of a National Planning Committee with Nehru as chairman. Of the fifteen members of the Committee, four (Purushottamdas Thakurdas, A.O. Shroff, Ambalal Sarabhai and Walchand Hirachand) were leading merchants and industrialists, five were scientists (Megh­ nad Saha, A.K Saha, Nazir Ahmed, V.S. Dubey and J.C. Ghosh), two were economists (K.T. Shah and Radhakamal Mukherjee) three, if we include M. Visvesvaraya who had just written a book on planning - and three had been invited on their political credentials - J.C, Kumarappa the Gandhian, NM. Joshi the labour leader and Nehru himself. The Committee began work in December 1938. The National Planning Committee, whose actual work vir­ tually ceased after about a year and a half, following the outbreak of the War, the resignation of the Congress ministries and finally Nehru's arrest in October 1940, was nevertheless the first real experience of the emerging state leadership of the Congress, and of Nehru in particular, with working out the idea of 'national planning'. Before making a brief mention of the actual contents of the discussions in that Committee, let us take note of the most significant aspects of the form of this exercise. First, planning appears as a form of determining st.ate policy, ·- , .. ..- - Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 274 St4U llnd Politia in India initially the economic policies of the provincial Congress mini­ stries, but almost immediately afterwards the overall framework of a coordinated and consistent set of policies of a national state �t was already being envisioned as a concrete idea. In this re­ spect, planning was not only a pan of the anticipation of power by the state leadership of the Congress, it was also an anticipation of the concrete forms in which that power would be exercised within a national state. Second, planning as an exercise in state policy already incorporated its most distinctive element: its con­ stitution as a body of uperts and its activity as one of technical evaluation of alternative policies and determination of choices on 'scientific' grounds. Nehru, writing in 1944 5, mentioned this as a memorable part of his experience with the NPC: We had avoided a theoretical approach, and as each particular prob­ lem was viewed in its larger context, it led us inevitably in a particular direction. To me the spirit of co-operation of the members of the Planning Committee was particularly soothing and gratifying, for I found it a pleasant contrast to the sqU2bbles and conflicts of politics.2 Third, the appeal to a 'committee of experts' was in itself an important instrument in resolving a political debate which, much to the irritation of the emerging state leadership of the Congress, was still refusing to go away. This leadership, along with the vast majority of the professional intelligentsia of India, had little doubt about the central importance of industrialization for the develop­ ment of a modem and prosperous nation. Yet the very political strategy of building up a mass movement against colonial rule had required the Congress to espouse Gandhi's idea of machinery, commercialization and centralized state power as the curses of modem civilization, thrust upon the Indian people by European colonialism. It was industrialism itself, Gandhi argued, rather than the inability to industrialize, which was the root cause of Indian poverty. This was, until the 1940s, a characteristic part of the Congress rhetoric of nationalist mobilization. But now that the new national state was ready to be conceptualized in concrete terms, this archaic ideological baggage had to be jettisoned. J.C. Kumarappa brought the very first session of the NPC to an impasse by questioning its authority to discuss plans for industrial­ ization. The national priority as adopted by the Congress, he said, 2 Jawaharbl Nchru,J111J1UffllU Nthnl's Spe«Jia, (New Delhi: 19S4) vol. 2. D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutions 275 was to restrict and eliminate modem industrialism. Nehru had to intervene and declare that most members of the Committee felt that large-scale industry ought to be promoted as long as it did not 'come into conflict with the cottage industries'.Emphasizing the changed political context in which the Congress was working, Nehru added significantly: Now that the Congress is, to some extent, identifying itself with the State it cannot ignore the question of establishing and encouraging large-scale industries. There can be no planning if such planning does not include big industries ... [and] it is not only within the scope of the Committee to consider large-scale industries, but it is incumbent upon it to consider them. 3 Kumarappa kept up his futile effort for a while after virtually every other member disagreed with his view and finally dropped out. Gandhi himself did not appreciate the efforts of the NPC, or perhaps he appreciated them only too well. 'I do not know', he wrote to Nehru, that it is working within the four corners of the resolution creating the Committee. I do not know that the Working Committee is being kept informed of its doings.... It has appeared to me that much money and labour are being wasted on an effort which will bring forth little or no fruit.14 Nehru in tum did not conceal his impatienceJWith such \risionary' and 'unscientific' talk and grounded his own position quite firmly on the universal principles of historical progress: 'We are trying to catch up, as far as we can, with the Industrial Revolution that occurred long ago in Western countries.'5 The point here is not so much whether the Gandhian position had already been rendered pofitically unviable, so that we can declare the overwhelming consensus on industrialization within the NPC as the 'reflection' of an assignment of priorities al,ready determined in the political arena outside. Rather, the very in­ stitution of a process of planning became a means for the deter­ mination of priorities on behalf of the 'nation'.The debate on the need for industrialization, we may say, was politically resolved by successfully constituting planning as a domain outside 'the • 3 Jaw.iharlal Nehru, Jll'IV11btm11I Nthn,'s Spttrbts. 4 M.K. Gandhi, Colkcttd Works {New Delhi: 1958), p. 56. S JaWllharlal Nehru,J11W11b11rl,,/ Nt""4's Spttcbts, p. 93 D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 276 State and Politics in India squabbles and conflicts of politics'. As early as the 1940s, planning had emerged as a crucial institutional modality b y which the state would determine the material allocation of productive resources within the nation: a modality of political power constituted out­ side the immediate political process itself. The Rationality of the New State Why was it necessary to devise such a modality of power that could operate both inside and outside the political structure constructed by the new post-colonial state? An answer begins to appear as soon as we discover the logic by which the new state related itself to the 'nation'. For the emerging state leadership (and as the bearer of a fundamental ideological orientation this group was much larger than simply a section of the leaders of the Congress, and in identifying it the usual classification of left and right is ir­ relevant), this relation was expressed in a quite distinctive way. By the 1940s, the dominant argument of nationalism against colonial rule was that it was impeding the further development of India: colonial rule had become a historical fetter that had to be removed before the nation could proceed to develop. Within this frame­ work, therefore, the economic critique of colonialism as an ex­ ploitative force creating and perpetuating a backward economy came to occupy a central place. One might ask what would happen to this nationalist position if (let us say, for the sake of argument) it turned out from historical investigation that by every agreed criterion foreign rule had indeed promoted economic develop­ ment in the colony. Would that have made colonialism any more legitimate or the demand for national self-government any less justified? Our nationalists would not have accepted a purely nega­ tive critique of colonial rule as sufficient and would have been embarrassed if the demand for self-rule was sought to be filled in by some primordial content such as race or religion. Colonial rule, he would have said, was illegitimate not because it represented the political domination by an alien people over the indigens: alienness had acquired the stamp of illegitimacy because it stood for a form of exploitation of the nation (the drain of national wealth, the destruction of its productive system, the creation of a backward economy, etc.). Self-government consequently was legitimate be. cause it represented the historically necessary form of national Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutions 277 development. The economic critique of colonialism then was the foundation from which a positive content was supplied for the independent national state: the new state represented the only legitimate form of exercise of power because it was a necessary condition for the development of the nation. A developmental ideology then was a constituent part of the self-definition of the post-colonial state. The state was connected fO the people-nation not simply through the procedural forms of representative government, it also acquired its representativeness by directing a progra1nme of economic development on behalf of the nation. The former connected, as in any liberal form of gov­ ernment, the legal-political sovereignty of the state with the sover­ eignty of the people. The latter connected the sovereign powers of the state directly with the economic well-being of the people. The two connections did not necessarily have the same implications for a state trying to determine how to use its sovereign powers. What the people were able to express through the repre­ sentative mechanisms of the political process as their will was not necessarily what was good for their economic well-being; what the state thought important for the economic development of the nation was not necessarily what would be ratified through the representative mechanisms. The two criteria of representative­ ness, and hence of legitimacy, could well produce contradictory implications for state policy. The contradiction stemmed from the very manner in which a developmental ideology needed to cling to the state as the prin­ cipal vehicle for its historical mission. 'Development' implied a linear path, directed towards a goal, or a series of goals separated by stages. It implied the fixing of priorities between long-run and short-run goals and conscious choice between alternative paths. It was premised, in other words, upon a rational consciousness and will, and in so far as 'development' was thought of as a process affecting the whole of seciety, it was also premised upon <mt consciousness and will - that of the whole. Particular interests needed to be subsumed within the whole and made consistent with the general interest. The mechanisms of civil society, work­ ing through contracts and the market, and hence defining a domain for the play of the particular and the accidental, were already known to be imperfect instruments for expressing the general. The one consciousness, both general and rational, could - D1g1t 1zeo by - ' .. � Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 278 State and Politia in India not simply be assumed to exist as an abstract and formless force, working implicitly and invisibly through the particular .interests of civil society. It had, as Hegel would have said, to 'shine forth', appear as an existent, concretely expressing the general and the rational. Hegel's penetrating logic has shown us that this universal ra­ tionality of the state can be concretely expressed at two institu­ tional levels - the bureaucracy as the universal class and the monarch as the immediately existent will of the state. The logical requirement of the latter was taken care of, even under the r e ­ publican constitutional form adopted in India, by the usual pro­ visions of embodying the sovereign will of the state in the person of the Head of state. In meeting the former requirement, however, the post-colonial state in India faced a problem that was produced specifically by the form of the transition from colonial rule. For various reasons that were attributed to political contingency (whose historical roots we need not explore here), the new state chose to retain in a virtually unaltered form the basic structure of the civil service, the police administration, the judicial system including the codes of civil and criminal law, and the armed forces as they existed in the colonial period. As far as the normal executive functions of the state were concerned, the new state operated within a framework of rational universality whose principles were seen as having been contained (even if they were misapplied) in the preceding state structure. In the case of the armed forces, the assertion of unbroken continuity was rather more paradoxical, so that even today one is forced to witness such unlovely ironies as regiments of the Indian army proudly displaying the trophies of colonial conquest and counter-insurgency in their barrack-rooms, or the Presidential Guards celebrating their birth two hundred years ago under the governor-generalship of Lord Cornwallis! But if the ordinary functions of civil and criminal administration were to continue within forms of rationality which the new state had not given to itself, how was it to claim its legitimacy as an authority that was specifically different from the old regime? This legitimacy, as we have mentioned before, had to flow from the nationalist criticism of colonialism as an alien and unrepresentative power that was exploitative in character and from the historical necessity of an independent state that would promote national development. It was in the universal function of 'development' of Dig1t1zeo by Google,___ Origi�al rrom llNIVERSl,:X. OF MICHIGA!'J The Institutions 279 national society as a whole that the post-colonial state would find its distinctive content. This was to be concretized by embodying within itself a new mechanism of developmental administration, something which the colonial state, because of its alien and ex­ tractive character, never possessed. It was in the administration of development that the bureaucracy of the post-colonial state was to assert itself as the universal class, satisfying in the service of the state its private interests by working for the universal goals of the nation. Planning, therefore, was the domain of the rational determina­ tion and pursuit of these universal goals. It was a bureaucratic function, to be operated at a level above the particular interests of civil society, and institutionalized as such as a domain of policy­ making outside the normal processes of representative politics and of execution through a developmental administration. But as a concrete bureaucratic function, it was in planning above all that the post-colonial state would claim its legitimacy as a single will and consciousness - the will of the nation - pursuing a task that was both universal and rational - the well-being of the people as a whole. It is in its legitimizing role, therefore, that planning, constituted as a domain outside politics, was to become an instrument of politics. If we then look at the process of politics itself, we will discover the specific ways in which it would also become impli­ cated in the modalities of power. Planning and Implementing We could first describe the political process in its own terms and then look for the connections with the process of planning. But this would take us into a lengthy excursion into a wholly different disciplinary field. Let us instead start with the received under­ standing of the planning experience in India and see how the political process comes to impinge upon it. Chakravarty has re­ cently given us a summary account of this experience from within the theoretical boundaries of development planning.6 From this perspective, the political process appears as a determinate and 6 Sukharnoy ford, 1987). Chakravany, Droelopmmt Planning: Tbt Indian F.rptrinKt ( O x ­ - D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm ··· - - UNIVERSITY OF ..M!CHtGAN ... _ -- 280 State and Politics in India changing existent when the question arises of 'plan implementa­ tion'. He discusses the problems of plan implementation by treat­ ing the 'planning authorities' as the central directing agency, firmly situated outside the political process itself and embodying, one might justifiably say, the single, universal and rational con­ sciousness of a state which is promoting the development of the nation as a whole.7 An implementational failure, Chakravarty says, occurs when (a) the planning authorities are inefficient in gather­ ing the relevant information, (b) when they take so much time to respond that the underlying situation has by then changed, and (c) when the public agencies through which the plans are to be implemented do not have the capacities to carry them out and the private agencies combine in 'strategic' ways to disrupt the expec­ tations about their behaviour which the planners had taken as 'parametric'. Chakravarty adds that the last possibility - that of strategic action by private actors - has greatly increased in recent years in the Indian economy. Let us look a little more closely at this analysis. What does it mean to say that plans may fail because of the inadequacy of the information which planners use? 'fhe premise here is that of a separation between the planner on the one hand and the objects of planning on the other, the latter consisting of both physical resour­ ces and human economic agents. 'Information' is precisely the means through which the objects of planning are constituted for the planner: they exist 'out there', independently of his conscious­ ness and can appear before it only in the shape of 'information'. The 'adequacy' of this information then concerns the question of whether these objects have been constituted 'correctly', i.e. con­ stituted in the planner's consciousness in the same form as they exist outside it, in themselves. It is obvious that on these terms an entirely faultless planning would require in the planner nothing less than omniscience. But one should not use the patent impossibility of this project to tum planning into a caricature of itself. While the epistemological stance of apprehending the external objects of consciousness in their intrinsic and independent truth continues, as is well known, to inform the expressly declared philosophical foun­ dations of the positive sciences, including economics, the actual practice of debates about planning is more concerned with those 7 Ibid., pp. 40-2. Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutions 281 objects as they have been constituted by the planning exercise itself. Thus if it is alleged that planners have incorrectly estimated the demand for electricity because they did not take into account the unorganized sector, the charge really is that whereas the 'unorganized sector' was already an object of planning since it was knuum that it too was a consumer of electricity, it had not been explicitly and specifically constituted as an object since its demand had not been estimated. The point about all questions of 'inade­ quate information' is not whether one knows what the objects of planning are: if they are not known the problem of information cannot arise. The question is whether they have been explicitly specified as objects of planning. It is here that the issue of the modalities of knowledge and implementation become central to the planning exercise. All three Conditions which Chakravarty mentions as leading to faulty im­ plementation concern the ways in which the planner, representing the rational consciousness of the state, can produce a knowledge of the objeets of planning. In this sense, even the so-called im­ plementing agencies are the objects of planning for they represent not the will of the planner but determinate 'capacities': a plan which does not correctly estimate the capacities of the implement­ ing agencies cannot be a good plan. Consequently, these agencies - bureaucrats or managers of public enterprises - become en­ tities which act in determinate ways according to specific kinds of 'signals' and these the planner must know in order to formulate his plan. The planner even needs to know how long his own machinery will take to implement a plan, or else the information on the basis of which he plans may become obsolete. If one is not to assume omniscience on behalf of the planner, how is this information ever expected to be 'adequate'? It is here that the rationality of planning can be seen to practise a self­ deception - a necessary self-deception, for without it it could not constitute itself. Planning, as the concrete embodiment of the rational consciousness of a state promoting economic develop­ ment, can proceed only by constituting the objects of planning as objects of knowledge. It must know the physical resources whose allocation is to be planned, it must know the economic agents who act upon these resources, know their needs, capacities and propensities, know what constitutes the signals according to which they act, know how they respond to those signals. When D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 282 State and Politics in India the agents relate to each other in terms of power, i.e. relations of domination and subordination, the planner must /mow the relevant signals and capacities. This knowledge would enable him to work upon the total configuration of power itself, use the legal powers of the state to produce signals and thereby affect the actions of agents, play off one power against another to produce a general result in which everybody would be better off. The state as a planning authority can promote the universal goal of development by harnessing within a single interconnected whole the discrete subjects of power in society. It does this by turning those subjects of power into the objects of a single body of knowledge. This is where the self-deception occurs. For the rational con­ sciousness of the state embodied in the planning authority does not exhaust the determinate being of the state. The state is also an existent as a site at which the subjects of power in society interact, ally and contend with one another in the political process. The specific configuration of power that is constituted within the state is the result of this process. Seen from this perspective, the planning authorities themselves are objects for a configuration of power in which others are subjects. Indeed, and this is the paradox which a 'science' of planning can never unravel from within its own disciplinary boundaries, the very subjects of social power which the rational consciousness of the planner seeks to convert into objects of its knowledge by attributing to them discrete capa­ cities and propensities can turn the planning authority itself into an object of their power. Subject and object, inside and outside the relations are reversed as soon as we move from the domain of rational planning, situated outside the political process, to the domain of social power exercised and contested within that pro­ cess. When we talk of the state, we must talk of both of these domains as its constituent fields, and situate one in relation to the other. Seen from the domain of planning, the political process is only an external constraint, whose strategic possibilities must be known and objectified as parameters for the planning exercise. And yet, even the best efforts to secure 'adequate information' leave behind an unestimated residue, which works imperceptibly and often perversely to upset the implementation of plans. This residue, as the irreducible, negative and ever-present 'beyond' of planning, is what we may call, in its most general sense, politics. D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutions 283 The Politics of Planning - I Let us return to history, this time of more recent vintage. Chakra­ varty says that in the early 1950s, when the planning process was initiated in India, there was a general consensus on a 'commodity­ centred' approach.8 That is to say everyone agreed that more goods were preferable to less goods and a higher level of capital stock per worker was necessary for an improved standard of living. Obviously, the central emphasis of development was meant to be placed on accumulation. But this was not all. Chakravarty also says that in the specific context in which planning was taken u� in India, accumulation had to be reconciled with legitimation. 'Adoption of a representative form of government based on uni­ versal adult suffrage did have an effect on the exercise of political power, and so did the whole legacy of the national movement with its specifically articulated set of economic objectives.' These two objectives - accumulation and legitimation - produced two implications for planning in India. On the one hand, planning had to be 'a way of avoiding the unnecessary rigorm of an industrial transition in so fur as it affected the masses resident in India's villages'. On the other hand, planning was to become 'a positive instrument for resolving conjlia in a large and heterogeneous subcontinent' (emphases mine). What did these mean in terms of the relation between the state and the planning process? In the classical forms of capitalist industrialization, the original accumulation required the use of a variety of coercive methods to separate a large mass of direct producers from their means of production. This was the 'secret' of the so-called 'primitive ac­ cumulation', which was not the result of the capitalist mode of production but its starting-point, and in a concrete historical process, it meant 'the expropriation of the agricultural producer, of the peasant, from the soil'. 10 The possibility and limits of original accumulation were set by the specific configuration in each country of the political struggle between classes in the pre-capitalist social formation but in each case a successful tran­ sition to capitalist industrialization required that subsistence pro­ ducers be 'robbed of all their means of production and of all the a Ibid., p. 7. 9 Ibid., pp. 2-3. 10 Karl Mark, C11pit41 (Moscow: Progress, 1971), vol. I, pp. 667-70. - Digiti zed by Google Ongmal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 284 State and Politics in India guarantees of existence afforded by the old feudal arrangements'. 11 Whatever the political means adopted to effect this expropriation of direct producers, and with it the destruction of pre-capitalist forms of community concretely embodying the unity of producers with the means of production, they could not have been legitim­ ized by any active principle of universal representative democracy. (It is curious that in the one country of Europe where a 'bourgeois' political revolution was carried out under the slogan of liberty, equality and fraternity, the protection of small-peasant property after the revolution meant the virtual postponement of indus­ trialization by some five or six decades.) Once in place, accumulation under capitalist production proper could be made legitimate by the equal right of property and the universal freedom of contract on the basis of property rights over commodities. Original accumulation having already effected the separation of the direct producer from the means of production, labour power was now available as a commodity owned by the labourer who was entitled to sell it according to the terms of a free contract with the owner of the means of production. As a political ideology of legitimation of capitalist accumulation, this strictly liberal doctrine of 'freedom', however, enjoyed a surpris­ ingly short life. But in the third and fourth decades of the nineteenth century, when the first phase of the Industrial Revolu­ tion had been completed in Britain, the new context of political conflict made it necessary to qualify 'freedom' by such notions as the rights to subsistence, to proper conditions of work and a decent livelihood. In time, this meant the use of the legal powers of the state to impose conditions on the freedom of contract (on hours of work, on minimum wages, on physical conditions of work and living) and to curtail the free enjoyment of returns from the productive use of property (most importantly by the taxation on higher incomes to finance public provisions for health, education, housing, etc.). While this may be seen as being con­ sistent with the long-term objectives of capitalist accumulation, on the grounds that it facilitated the continued reproduction of labour power of a suitable concretized quality, it must also be recognized that it was a political response to growing oppositional 11 T.H. Aston and C.H.E. Philpin (eds), Tbt Brmntr Dtbatt: Agrllrilm Cltus Strwture1111d &orurmicDrotlopmmt in Pr tlndustria/ Europt (Cambridge: Cam­ bridge University Press, 1987). Digiti zed by Google Ongmal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutions 285 movements and social conflict. As a political doctrine of legitima­ tion this meant, first, the creation of a general content for social good which combined capitalist property ownership with the production of consent through representative political processes, and second, the determination of this content not mediately through the particular acts of economic agents in civil society, but directly through the activities of the state. The course of this journey from the strictly liberal concept of 'freedom' to that of 'welfare' is, of course, coincidental with the political history of capitalist democracy in the last century and a half. What we need to note here is the fact that as a universal conception of the social whole under capitalist democracy, the elements of a concept of 'welfare' had already superseded those of pure freedom and were available to the political leadership in India when it began the task of constructing a state ideology. The 'unnecessary rigours' of an industrial transition, conse­ quently, meant those forms of expropriation of subsistence pro­ ducers associated with original accumulation which could not be legitimized through the representative processes of politics. This was, our planner would say, a parametric condition set by the political process at the time when planning began its journey in India. Yet accumulation was the prime task if industrialization was to take place. Accumulation necessarily implied the use of the powers of the state, whether directly through its legal and administrative institutions, or mediately through the acts of some agents with social power over others, to effect the required degree of dissociation of direct producers from their means of produc­ tion. As Chakravarty himself says, the development model first adopted in India was a variant of the Lewis model, with a 'modern' sector breaking down and superseding the 'traditional' sector, the two significant variations being that the modem sector itself was disaggregated into a capital goods and a consumer goods sector, and instead of capitalists in the modem sector the major role was assigned to a development bureaucracy.12 Despite these variations, the chosen path of development still meant conflicts between social groups and the use of power to attain the required form and rate of accumulation. Since the 'necessary' policies of the 12 Sulchamoy Chakravarty, Dtvtlapmmt Pl1111ning: Tht Indian Exptrim.t ford University Press, 1987), p. 14. Digiti zed by Google Ongmal from (Ox­ UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 286 Stilte and Politics in India state which would ensure accumulation could not be left to be determined solely through the political process, it devolved upon the institution of planning, that embodiment of the universal rationality of the social whole standing above all particular inter­ ests, to lay down what in fact were the 'necessary rigours' of industrialization. Given its location outside the political process, planning could then become 'a positive instrument for resolving conflict' by determining, within a universal framework of the social good, the 'necessary costs' to be borne by each particular group and the 'necessary benefits' to accrue to each. But who was to use it in this way as a 'positive instrument'? We have still to address this question. The specific form in which this twin problem of planning accumulation with legitimation -was initially resolved, especially in the Second and Third Five-year Plans, is well known. There was to b e a capital-intensive industrial sector under public owner­ ship, a private industrial sector in light consumer goods and a private agricultural sector. The first two were the 'modern' sectors which were to be financed by foreign aid, low interest loans and taxation of private incomes mainly in the second sector. The third sector was seen as being mainly one of petty production, and it was there that a major flaw of this development strategy was to appear. It has been said that the Second and Third Plans did not have an agricultural strategy at all, or even if they did, there was gross over-optimism about the long-term ability of traditional agriculture to contribute to industrialization by providing cheap labour and cheap food. 13 The problem is often posed as one of alternative planning strategies, with the suggestion that if suitable land reforms had been carried out soon after Independence, a quite different development path may have been discovered which would have avoided the 'crisis' in which the planning process found itself in the middle of the 1960s. The difficulty with this sugges­ tion, if we are to look at it from a political standpoint, is precisely the confusion it entails regarding the effective relation between the whole and the part, the universal and the particular, in the aets of a state promoting and supervising a programme of planned capitalist development. To discover the nature of this relation, we ·need to look upon planned industrialization as part of a process of what may be called the 'passive revolution of capital'. 13 Ibid., p. 21. Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutions 287 Passive Revolution Antonio Gramsci has talked of the 'passive revolution' as one in which the new claimants to power, lacking the social strength to launch a full-scale assault on the old dominant classes, opt for a path in which the demands of a new society are 'satisfied by small doses, legally, in a reformist manner' - in such a way that the political and economic positions of the old feudal classes are not destroyed, agrarian reform is avoided, and especially the popular masses are prevented from going through the political experience of a fundamental social transformation. 14 Gramsci, of course, treats this as a 'blocked dialectic', an exception to the paradigmatic form of bourgeois revolution which he takes to be that ofJacobin­ ism. It now seems more useful to argue, however, that as a historical model, passive revolution is in fact the general frame­ work of capitalist transition in societies where bourfeois hege­ mony has not been accomplished in the classical way.1 In 'passive revolution' the historical shifts in the strategic relations of forces between capital, pre-capitalist dominant groups and the popular masses can be seen as a series of contingent, conjunctural mo­ ments. The dialectic here cannot be assumed to be blocked in any fundamental sense. Rather, the new forms of dominance of capital become understandable, not as the immanent supersession of earlier contradictions, but as parts of a constructed hegemony, effective because of the successful exercise of both coercive and persuasive power, but incomplete and fragmented at the same time because the hegemonic claims are fundamentally contested within the constructed whole. 16 The distinction between 'bour­ geois hegemony' and 'passive revolution' then becomes one in which, for the latter, the persuasive power of bourgeois rule cannot be constructed around the universal idea of 'freedom'; some other universal idea has to be substituted for it.17 In.the Indian case, we can look upon 'passive revolution' as a 14 Antonio Gramsci, Stkt:tiuns frr,m Pris<ln Nottboolcs (New York, 1971). IS Asok Sen, 'The Frontiers ofthe Prison Notebooks' in &rmomic 111111Politiuzl Wttk/y: Rroit-w ofPoliti"'/ &onomy, vol. 23, no. S, 1988, pp. PE 31-6. 16. Ajit Chaudhuri, 'From Hegemony to Counter Hegemony', &onumic 111111 Politi"'/ Wttkly: Rroit'W ofPolitical &onomy, vol. 23, no. S, 1988, pp. PE 19-23; Partha Chatterjee, 'On Gramsci's "Fwidamentil Mistike" ', &onumic qnd Politiuzl Wttk/y: Rroirw ofPolitictd &onomy, vol. 23, no. S, 1988, pp. 24--6. 17 I am grateful to Kalyan Sanyal for suggesting this point Dlgltlzedby Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 288 S111t� tmd Politics in India process involving a polirial-ideological programme by which the brgcst possible nationalist alliance is built up against the colonial power. The aim is to form a politically independent nation st:ice. The means involve the creation of a series of alliances, "-ithin the organizational structure of the national movement, between the bourgeoisie and other dominant classes and the mobilization� under this leadership, of mass suppon from the subordinate clas­ ses. 'fbe project is a reorganization of the political order, but it is moderated in two quite fundamental ways. On the one hand, ic does not attempt to break up or transform in any radical way the institutional structures of 'rational' authority set up in the period of colonial rule. On the other hand, it also does not undertake a full-scale assault on all pre-capitalist dominant classes: rather, ic seeks to limit their former power, neutralize them where neces­ sary, attack them only selectively, and in general bring them round to a position of subsidiary allies within a reformed state structure. The dominance of capital does not emanate from its hegemonic sway over 'civil society'. On the contrary, it seeks to construct a synthetic hegemony over the domains of both civil society and the pre-capitalist community. The reification of the 'nation' in the body of the state becomes the means for constructing this hege­ monic structure, and the extent of control over the new state apparatus becomes a precondition for further capitalist develop­ ment. It is by means of an interventionist state, directly entering the domain of production as mobilizer and manager of investible 'national' resources, that the foundations are laid for industrializa­ tion and the expansion of capital. Yet the dominance of capital over the national state remains constrained in several ways. Its function of representing the 'national-popular' has to be shared with other governing groups and its transformative role restricted to reformist and 'molecular' changes. The institution of planning, as we have seen, emerges in this process as the 1neans by which the 'necessary rigours' of these changes are rationalized at the level, not of this or that particular group, but of the social whole. For the development model adopted in India, the 'modem' sector is clearly the dynamic element. Industrialization as a project emanated from the particular will of the 'modem' sector; the 'general consensus' Chakravarty refers to was in fact the consensus within this 'modern' sector. But this will for transformation had to be expressed as a general project for the 'nation', and this Dlgltlzedby Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutions 289 could be done by subsuming within the cohesive bQdy of a single plan for the nation aJl of those elements which appeared as 'constraints' on the particular will of the 'modei'n' sector. If land reform was not attempted in the 1950s, it was not a 'fault' of planning, nor was it the lapse of a squeamish 'political will' of the rulers. It was because at this stage of its journey the ideological construct of the 'passive revolution of capital' consciously sought t o incorporate within the framework of its rule not a repre­ sentative mechanism solely operated by individual agents in civil society, but entire structures of pre-capitalist community 'taken in their existent forms. In the political field, this was expressed in the form of the so-called 'vote banks', a much talked about feature of Indian elections in the 1950s and 1960s, by which forms of social power based on landed proprietorship or caste loyalty or religious authority were translated into 'representative' forms of electoral support. In the economic field, the form pre­ ferred was that of 'community development' in which the benefits of plan projects meant for the countryside were supposed to be shared collectively by the whole community. That the concrete structures of existent communities were by no means ho1no­ geneous or egalitarian but were in fact built around pre-capitalist forms of social power, was not so much ignored or forgotten as tacitly acknowledged, for these were precisely the structures through which the 'modernizing' state secured legitimation for itself in the representative processes of elections. It is, therefore, misleading to suggest as a criticism of this phase of the planning strategy that the planners 'did not realise the nature and dimen­ sion of political mobilisation that would be necessary to bring about the necessary institutional changes' to make agriculture more productive. 18 Seen in terms of the political logic of 'passive revolution', the strategy called for was precisely one of promoting industrialization without taking the risk of agrarian political mo­ bilization. This was an essential aspect of the hegemonic construct of the post-colonial state: combining accumulation with legitima­ tion while avoid�ng the 'unnecessary rigours' of social conflict. Rational strategies pursued in a political field, however, have the unpleasant habit of producing unintended consequences. Al­ though the objective of the Indian state in the 1950s was to lay 18 Sukha1noy Chakravarty, Drotlopmmt Planning, p. Dlgltlzeo by Google 21. Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 290 State and Politics in India the foundations for rapid industrialization without radically dis­ turbing the local structures of power in the countryside, the logic of accumulation in the 'modem' sector could not be prevented from seeping into the interstices of agrarian property, trade, patterns of consumption and even production. It did not mean a general and radical shift all over the country to capitalist farming, but there were clear signs that agrarian property had become far more 'commoditized' than before, that even subsistence peasant production was deeply implicated in large-scale market transac­ tions, that the forms of extraction of agricultural surplus now combined a wide variety and changing mix of 'economic' and 'extra-economic' power and that a steady erosion of the viability of small peasant agriculture was increasing the ranks of marginal and landless cultivators. Perhaps there were conjunctural reasons why the 'food crisis' should have hit the economic, and immedi­ ately afterwards, the political life of the country with such severity in the mid-l960s. But it would not be unwarranted to point out a certain inevitability of the logic of accumulation breaking into an agrarian social structure which the politics of the state was unwilling to transform. There were other consequences of this phase of planned in­ dustrialization under state auspices which were to be of consider­ able political significance. The Politics of Planning - II The object of the strategy of 'passive revolution' was to contain class conflicts within manageable dimensions, to control and mani­ pulate the many dis persed power relations in society to further as best as possible the thrust towards accumulation. But conflicts surely could not be avoided altogether. And if there were conflicts between particular interests, mobilizations based on interests were only to be expected, especially within a political process of repre­ sentative democracy. In fact, the very form of legitimacy by elec­ toral representation, in so far as it involves a relatirm between the state and the people, implies a mutual recognition by each of the organized and articulate existence of the other, the general on the one hand and the particular on the other. Mobilizations, conse­ quently, did take place, principally as oppositional movements and in both the electoral and non-electoral domains. The response of Dig1t1zeo by Google Origi�al rrom UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutions 291 the state was to subsume these organized demands of particular interests within the generality of a rational strategy. The form of this strategy is for the state to insist that all conflicts between particular interests admit of an 'economic' solution 'economic' in the sense of allocations to each part that are consis­ tent with the overall constraints of the whole. Thus a particular interest, whether expressed in terms of class, language, region, caste, tribe or community, is to be recognized and given a place within the framework of the general by being assigned a priority and an allocation relative to all the other parts. This, as we have seen before, is the form which the single rational consciousness of the developmental state must take - the form of planning. It is also the form which the political process conducted by the state will seek to impose on all mobilizations of particular interests: the demands therefore will be for a reallocation or a reassignment of priorities relative to other particular interests. It is curious to what extent a large variety of social mobilizations in the last two decades have taken both this 'economic' form and the form of demands upon the state. Mobilizations which admit of demographic solidarities defined over territorial regions can usually make this claim within the framework of the federal dis­ tribution of powers. This could be either a claim for greater shares for the federal units from out of the central economic pool, or for a reallocation of the relative shares of different federal units, or even for a redefinition of the territorial boundaries of the units or the creation of new units out of old ones. On the one hand, we therefore have a continuous process of bargaining between the union and the states over the distribution of revenues which is sought to be given an orderly and rational form by such statutory bodies as the Finance Commissions, but which inevitably spills over into the disorderly immediacy of contingent political con­ siderations such as the compulsions of party politics, electoral advantage or the pressures of influential interest lobbies, and which takes the form of an ever-growing series of ad hoc alloca­ tions that defy ration·al and consistent justification. On the other hand, we also have many examples of demands for the creation of new states within the federal union. While the solidarities over which these demands are defined are cultural, such as language or ethnic identity, the justification for statehood invariably carries with it a charge of economic discrimination within the existing - .,.,.--- �ig,u,.., by Google__ Origi�al rrom UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 292 State and Politics in India federal arrangement, and is thus open to political strategies operat­ ing within the 'economic' framework of distribution of resources between the centre and the states. For mobilizations of demographic sections which cannot claim representative status of territorial regions, the demands made upon the state are nevertheless also of an 'economic' form. This includes not only the demands made by the organizations o f economic classes, but also by social segments such as castes or tribes or religious communities. Examples of the management o f class demands of this kind are, of course, innumerable and form the staple of the political economy literature. They affect virtually all aspects of economic policy-making and include things like taxation, pricing, subsidies, licensing, wages, etc. But for the economic demands of 'ethnic' sections too, the state itself has legitimized the framework by qualifying the notion of citizenship by a set of discriminatory protections for culturally underpriv­ ileged and backward groups (lower castes, tribes) or minority religious communities. The framework has virtually transformed the nature of caste movements in India over the last fifty years from movements of lower castes clai1ning higher ritual status within a religiously sanctified cultural hierarchy to the same castes now proclaiming their ritually degraded status in order to demand protective economic privileges in the fields of employment or educational opportunities. In response, the higher castes, whose superiority has historically rested upon the denial of any notion · · of ritual equality· with lower castes, are now defending their . economic privileges precisely by appealing to the liberal notion of equality and by pointing out the economic inefficiencies of discriminatory protection. The point could therefore be made here that the centrality which the state assumes in the management of economic demands in India is not simply the result of the large weight of the public sector or the existence of state monopolies, as argued; for instance, by Bardhan 19 or Rudolph and Rudolph.20 Even otherwise, a dev­ elopmental state operating within the framework of representative politics would necessarily require the state to assume the role of Pranab Bardhan, Tht Political Economy of Drot/opmmt in India (Oxford, 1984). 20 Lloyd H. Rudolph and Susanne H. Rudolph, In Search of uzkshmi: Tbt Political Ecurwmy oftht Indian State (Chicago, 1987). 19 Digiti zed by Google Ongmal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Institutions 293 the central allocator if it has to legitimize its authority in the political domain. The Ambiguities of Legitimation There is no doubt that the fundamental problematic of the post­ colonial state - furthering accumulation in the 'modem' sector through a political strategy of passive revolution - has given rise to numerous ambiguities in the legitimation process. In the field of economic planning these ambiguities have been noticed in the debates over the relative importance of market signals and state commands, over the efficiency of the private sector and the inefficiency of the state sector, over the growth potential of a relatively 'open' economy and the technological backwardness of the strategy of 'self-reliance', and over the dynamic productive potential of a relaxation of state controls compared with the entrenchment of organized privileges within th!! present strucrure of state dominance. It is not surprising that in these debates, the proponents of the former argument in each opposed pair have emphasized the dynamic of accumulation while those defending the latter position have stressed the importance of legitimation (although there are arguments which defend the latter on the grounds of accumulation as well). What should be pointed out, however, is, first, that these ambiguities are necessary consequences of the specific relation of the post-colonial developmental state with the people-nation; second, that it is these ambiguities which create room for manoeuvre through which the passive revolution of capital can proceed; and third, that these ambiguities cannot be removed or resolved within the present constitution of the state. Let me briefly illustrate this point. Given the political process defined by the Indian state, the ambiguities of legitimacy are expressed in the well-known forms of'interest-groups'. These are the variety of permanent associations of businessmen, profes­ sionals and trade unions as well as temporary agitational mobiliza­ tions based on specific issues. There are competing demands in this sector, and the state may use both coercive and persuasive powers to allocate relative priorities in satisfying these demands. But the overall constraint here is to maintain the unity of the 'modem' sector as a whole, for that, as we have seen before, stands Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 294 St11tt and Politia in India forth within the body of the state as the overwhelmingly dominant element of the 'nation'. The unity of the 'modem' sector is spe­ cified in terms of a variety of criteria encompassing the domains of industrial production, the professional, educational and service sectors connected with industrial production, and agricultural pro­ duction outside the subsistence sector, and also embracing the effective demographic boundaries of the nwket for the products of the 'modem' sector. The identification of this sector cannot be made in any specific regional terms, nor docs it coincide with a simple ruraVurban dichotomy. But because of its unique standing as a particular interest which can claim to represent the dynamic aspeet of the nation itself, the entire political process conducted by the state, including the political parties which stake their claims to run the central organs of the state, must work towards produc­ ing a consensus on protecting the unity of the 'modem' sector. Any appearance of a fundamental lack of consensus here will resonate as a crisis of national unity itself. Thus the political management of economic demands will require that a certain internal balance- an acceptable parity- be maintained between the several fractions within the modem sector. Seen from this angle, the analysis of the 'political economy' of Indian planning as a competitive game between privileged pressure groups within a self-perpetuating 'modem' sector21 will appear one-sided, for it misses the fundamental ambiguity of a state process which must further accumulation while legitimizing the 'modem' sector itself as representative of the nation as a whole. Indeed, more profound ambiguities appear in the relations be­ tween the 'modem' sector and the rest of the people-nation. On the one hand, there is the system of electoral representation on a territorial basis in the form of single-member constituencies. On the other hand, competing demands may be voiced not only on the basis of permanent 'interest group' organizations but also as mobilizations building upon p r eexisting cultural solidarities such as locality, caste, tribe, religious community or ethnic identity. It would be wrong to assume that no representative process works here. Rather, the most interesting aspect of contemporary Indian politics is precisely the way in which solidarities and forms of 21 Pranab Bardhan, The Politial &mwt.y ofDtvelopmmt; Lloyd H. Rudolph and Susanne H. Rudolph, In St'"fb ofLakshmi. ' • D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN Tbt lnstitutums 295 authority deriving from the pre-capitalist community insert them­ selves into the representational processes of a liberal electoral democracy. This allows, on the one hand, for organizations and leaders to appear in the domain of the sate process claiming to represent this or that 'community', and for groups of people threatened with the loss of their means of livelihood or suffering from the consequences of such loss to use those representatives to seek the protection, or at least the indulgence, of the state. On the other hand, the state itself can manipulate these 'pre-modem' fonns of relations between the community and the state to secure legitimacy for its developmental role.22 An instance of the latter is the shift from the earlier strategy of 'community development' to that of distributing 'poverty removal' packages directly to selected target groups among the under­ privileged sections. The new strategy allows for the state to use a political rhetoric in which inccrmediate rungs of both the social hierarchy (local power baron-., dominant landed groups) and the governmental hierarchy (local officials and even elected political representatives) can be condemned as obstacles in the way of the state trying to reach the benefits of development to the poor and the package of benefits directly presented to �ups of the latter as a gift from the highest political leadership. 3 From the stand­ point of a rational doctrine of political authority, these fonns of legitimation .doubtless appear as 'pre-modem', harking back to what sociologists would call 'traditional' or 'charismatic' authority. But the paradox is that the existence, the unity and indeed the representative character of the 'modem' sector as the leading element within the nation has to be legitimized precisely through these means. There is the other side to this relation of legitimation: the ambiguous image of the state in � pular consciousness. If, as has been pointed out in some studies, 4 it is true that the state appears in popular consciousness as an external and distant entity, then, 22 Kalyan K. Sanyal, 'Accumulation, Pove")'. and the State in the Third World',&rm-ic""'1Politia/ Wttkly: Rt'Vi=ofPolitiCIIIEconumy, vol. 23, no. 5, 1988, pp. 31�. 23 Arun Patnaik, 'Grarnsci's Concept of ;Hegemony: The Case of Develop­ ment Administration in India', &-kIndPolitiCIII Wttkly: Rt'VitTIJ ofPolitiCIIJ Eamomy, vol. 23, no. 5, 1988, pp. PE 12-18; Atul Kohli, TbtSt11tttmdP11Verty in lndiJ,: Tbt Politia ofRefo?,1Cambridge, 1987). 24 Partha Chatterjee, Bm(-1: Tb, umd Qutstiun (Calcutta, 1985). ' Digitized by ---· - Gooole C, Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN ' 296 State and Politics in India depending upon the immediate perception of local antagonisms, the state could be seen either as an oppressive intruder in the affairs of the local community or as a benevolent protector of the people against local oppressors. The particular image in which the state appears is determined contextually. But this again opens up the possibility for the play of a variety of political strategies of which the story of modern Indian politics offers a vast range of examples. Such ambiguities show up the narrow and one-sided manner in which the 'science' of planning defines itself - a necessary one-sidedness, for without it the singular rationality of its practice would not be comprehensible to itself. From its own standpoint, planning will talk about the inefficiency and wastage of the public sector, about the irrationality of choosing or locating projectS purely on the grounds of electoral expediency, about the granting o f state subsidies in res ponse to agitational pressure. The con­ figuration of social powers in the political process, on the other hand, will produce these inefficient and irrational results which will go down in the planning literature as examples of implemen­ tational failures. Yet in the process of projecting the efficiency o f productive growth as a rational path of development for the nation as a whole, the particular interests in the 'modern' sector must. shift on to the state the burden of defraying the costs of producing a general consent for their particular project. The state sector, identified as the embodiment of the general, must bear these social costs of constructing the framework of legitimacy for the passive revolution of capital. What we have tried to show is that the two processes - one of 'rational' planning and the other of 'irrational' politics - are inseparable parts of the very logic of this state conducting the passive revolution. The paradox in fact is that it is the very 'irrationality' of the political process which continually works to produce legitimacy for the rational exercise of the planner. While the planner thinks of his own practice as an instrument for resolving conflict, the political process uses planning itself as an instrument for producing consent for capital's passive revolution. It is not surprising then to discover that the rational form of the planning exercise itself supplies to the political process a rhetoric for conducting its political debates. 'Growth' and 'equity' - both terms are loaded with potent rhetorical ammunition Digiti zed by Google Ongmal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The lnstitutirms 297 which can serve to justify as well as to contest state policies that seek to use coercive legal powers to protect or alter the existent relations between social groups. We have shown how the very form of an institution of rational planning located outside the political process is crucial for the self-definition of a developmen­ tal state embodying the single universal conkiousness of the social whole. We have also shown how the wielders of power can constrain, mould and distort the strategies of planning in order to produce political consent for their rule. What is science in the one domain becomes rhetoric in the other; what is the rational will of the whole in the one becomes the contingent agglomera­ tion of particular wills in the other. The two together - this contradictory, perennially quarrelsome and yet ironically well­ matched couple - comprise the identity of the developmental state in India today. -·- - Dig1t1zeo by Google Origi�al rrom UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN Google DlgJtlzed I y Ong1rc11 from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN III The Political Process: Dominance .. I t is a truism that dominance and resistance must be seen as two integrally related aspects of the same structure and process of political power. We have divided the chapters in the remaining two sections into 'dominance' and 'resistance' only to focus better on each of these two aspects in tu,rn. An important problem that faced the analyst of Indian politics in the first two decades of Congress dominance was to explain how the myriad fonns of local power all across the country were tied together over districts and states to give the Congress party i ts overwhelming position of power. The usual line of explanation 1 started by assuming that the Congress for the most part did not put in place a new structure of power in the localities but rather built up its dominance by incorporating within its own structure of rule the existing dominant groups in the various localities. The much acclaimed accommodative political style of the Congress system was thus a way of superimposing the Congress structure on the existing structures of local pqwer. The most common way in which these local elites were brought and kept together within the Congress fold was through the faction. There were Cotigress factions in each party forum and at each level of the organization. Through complex and changing alliances between these factions, the ruling party arranged to satisfy to the best of its ability the interests of all the elite groups dominant at different levels of the political system. In regions where there was a dominant caste or dominant caste coalition, as in Maharashtra or Gujarat or Mysore -- .-... ...... _ �,gitized by Google _ _____ _ Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 300 State and Politics in India or Andhra Pradesh, lineage and caste ties could be usefully mobi­ lized for purposes of securing winning percentages of votes in the majority of the constituencies. In other areas, there would be complex coalitions of caste, ethnic or religious factions at the district and state levels put together through the mediating skills of powerful Congress leaders. This form of aggregating local powers into Congress domin­ ance at the state and national levels changed considerably in the period from the early 1970s when Indira Gandhi emerged as the unquestioned leader of the ruling party. She changed the mediat­ ory form of politics into what has been called a plebiscitary one. The 1967 elections showed that the powerful regional Congress leaders of the earlier period were no longer reliable vote gatherers. Indira Gandhi's refurbished Congress did not try any longer to cobble together electoral support by mobilizing the resources of locally dominant groups. Rather, by separating parliamentary elec­ tions from state assembly elections and by relying on the much higher rates of voter participation, it turned the general elections into a plebiscite on the leadership of Indira Gandhi. This enabled the Congress to build an elector.n support bloc of low castes and minorities led by uppe r caste elites. It also meant that locally dominant middle castes were often alienated from the Congress, but this was consistent with the general technique of dominance through centralization of powers rather than through dispersed and mediated powers. Some of these techniques of dominance, and the changes in them over two decades, are illustrated in the chapter by Brass. One apparent advantage of the plebiscitary form of dominance was that by separating the periodic moments of elections from the everyday business of exercising and negotiating local power it could leave the structures of dominance in the localities largely undisturbed. In any case, the local elites would often prove in­ dispensable in the matter of daily governance. This meant, fust of all, that despite the apparent stability of Congress dominance at the upper levels of the power structure, its bases of support at the local levels were not regularly renewed through any con­ tinuous process of organized political activity. Second, given the dissociation of the central power structure from the regional and local arenas of political life, it became possible for these local powers to acquire, over time, the shape of distinct regional power Digiti zed by Google Ongmal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Political Pt·ocess: Dominance 301 structures, each with a dynamic of its own. Paradoxically, there­ fore, it was the very attempt to centralize the process of dom­ inance during the Congress-I period that created the possibility for the emergence of regional political systems in the states. Third, when the plebiscitary form worked against the Congress-I, as in 1977 or 1989 or 1996, or indeed in a large number of state elections during this period, its support bases seemed to evaporate overnight across huge regions. Of the alternative forms of dominance that have emerged in the states, four patterns can be described. First, where local powers are allowed to negotiate through a democratic process in the localiti�, where developmental programmes of the state are effectively tied· to these local negotiations, and where the overall structure is closely monitored and controlled by a tightly or­ ganized party machinery. The most successful example of this form of regional dominance is to be found in West Bengal, where the Left Front government has created a record of stable political rule unmatched in India in the last two decades. The chapter by Kohli describes this pattern. The second pattern is where a plebiscitary form is sought to be instituted at the state level, supported by ideological props of cultural autonomy and often, in the more effective cases, by the charismatic appeal of a leader, and where a set of populist pro­ grammes of the government becomes the means of legitimizing dominance. This pattern can be seen most prominently in Tamil Nadu and Andhra Pradesh. The fragility of such do1ninance, dependent as it is on the continuing charisma of the leader, on his or her plebiscitary standing at the time of elections and on the sustainability of populist programmes, has also been demonstrated in the recent history of those two states. The chapter by Pandian describes one aspect of this pattern. The third pattern consists in the attempt since the late 1980s to forge majority electoral support by appeal to Hindutva. It is not as though religious majoritarianism was not tried before as a tactic of dominance: it has always been available as a means of building local or regional electoral solidarities and was often used even by the Congress for this purpose. However, the perceptible weakening of Congress dominance in recent years is directly re­ lated to the current attempt by the IlJP to tie together local power structures over large regions into a parliamentary majority. There - .. - - Digi tized by Google- ·-- Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 302 St11te tmJ Politics m India ' are two aspects to this attempt: on the one hand, to demonstrate the ability to build and preserve large and oomplex �ances in th e same way that the Congress once did, and on the other, t o sustain an atmosphere o f communal confrontation in order to activate when necessary the ideological sentiments of religious major­ itarianism. The communal riots in the 1980s were a crucial part of the process of building up these sentiments. The chapter b y Basu shows in detail how one such local riot was connected in complex ways with much larger structures of power. The fourth pattern is that of building majorities through an alliance of backward castes, dalits and minorities. This is the new dalit-bahujan movement that has become particularly significant in north India in recent years. Its electoral success� so far have been relatively fragile, the Janata Dal government In Bi.bar being the only case where it has held power for any length of time. To what extent this represents a viable strategy of dominance is as yet not clearly demonstrated. It must be emphasized that all four patterns are emergent fonns of do1ninaoce and therefore still retain a significant aspect where they can invoke the idiom of resistance. Thus despite two decades in government, the Left Froot in West Bengal can i-epresent itself as resisting the dominance of the all-India ruling classes and as voicing the demands of peasants and workers. The charismatic appeal of an MGR or an NTR rests, even after theiE death, on the image of a saviour of the poor. The support for Hindutva is often expressed as a feeling of outrage against the way Hindus are supposedly discriminated against in their own country. And the element of resistance in the new dalit movement, even in its quest fo r power, is so strong that we have discuss.ed it i n our last section on 'Resistance'. D1g1t 1zeo by Google ___ Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 8 National Power and Local Politics in India: A Twenty-year Perspective· ' Paul Brass l'""'fiie study of federal political systems, particularly parliamen­ .L tuy or representative federal political systems, such as those in the United States, Canada, or India involves complexities that d o not exist in unituy states such as Great Britain or France. In the first place, there are three or more institutional levels in such systems, each of which has its own arena in which political strug­ gles take place. Second, the balance of power among the levels in federal systems varies in different systems and in the same system • This chapter is an expanded version of my Kingsley Martin Memorial �. sponsored by the Centre of South Asian Studies, University of Cambridge and delivered on 2 March 1983. It is based on research conducted i n India between September 1982 and January 1983, during the tenure of a Faculty Research Fellowship of the American Institute of Indian Studies (AIIS). During much of my stay in India, I was a guest of the Institute of · Public Administration, University of Lucknow, to whose Director, Dr D.P. Singh, I owe a great debt for his hospitality and patience. The article w.as written during my residence at St John's College as ao Overseas Visiting Scholar for two tcmlS. During my residence at St John's Col!_e�, I also held a grant from the Social Science Research Council (SSRC) (US) in support of my research. This article is part of a larger project on Structures of Local Power in Contemporary North India, supported by both AIIS and SSRC. Mr Sunil Singh assisted me in field research and Ms E. Mann in newspaper rcacarch and the typing of various versions of the original manuscript. I am grateful to the agencies and persons above, none of whom, however, bear any responsibility for the accuracy of the facts and interpretations pr. o­ vided in the article. Dlgltlzedby Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 304 State and Politics in India at different times. Third, the study of the extraparliamentary organizations such as political parties, and of social movements, also becomes a more complex task since it cannot be assumed that a political party or social movement with the same name is the same sort of formation in New York and Mississippi or in Uttar Pradesh and Tamil Nadu. Moreover, in federal systems with a high degree of regional cultural diversity, each federal unit in the country may have a distinctive configuration ofextraconstitutional political formations and social forces. This is certainly the case in India, the most culturally diverse of all existing federal parliamen­ tar y systems in the world today. Fourth, politics in federal systems takes place bdween levels as well as within levels, again i n far more complex ways than in unitary systems. The analysis of federal parliamentary systems such as India's is, therefore, an especially challenging task for political scientists or historians who wish somehow to convey either a whole view of the system at a particular point in time or in its historical develop­ ment. Even if one aspires for less than a whole view, an initial question must be: at what level or entry point into the system can one learn most about the dynamic processes that are characteristic of the system as a whole? For many years after Independence, many political scientists thought Indian politics could not be un­ derstood at all except at the state and district level. This view was so widely held, in fact, that serious detailed political studies of many of India's most powerful central institutions have yet to be done. Others have argued that the society, in all its diversity, has been held together by one or another major national institution - the 'steel frame' of the Indian Administrative Service (IAS) or the gelatinous mass of the Indian National Congress being two leading candidates. In recent years, particularly since the imposi­ tion by Mrs Gandhi of an authoritarian 'Emergency' regime from 1975 to 1977, it has been often argued that the Indian political system has become increasingly centralized and nationalized and that the essential characteristics of the Indian political system can now be read only through the study of executive power and par­ ticular·central institutions. Twenty years ago, when I did my initial fieldwork at the district and state level, focusing on the Congress organization, I thought I had identified the critical levels of the Indian political system and the inner dynamics of its politics. It appeared to me then Digiti zed by Google Ongmal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Political Process: Dominance 305 that there was a vast difference between the politics of national integration, of government and opposition, of planning, of secu­ larism, and of rapid industrialization which Nehru symbolized and the politics of faction, caste, patronage, nepotism, com­ munalism, and mixed subsistence and cash crop agriculture that operated at the state and district level.1 Moreover, I thought then that the latter patterns had a greater reality than the former and that the answer to the old question, 'After Nehru, what?' was the bubbling up to the national level of the politics of the state and localities. Fortunately, I didn't put my predictions into print, for that is not quite what happened. For a while after Nehru's death, par­ ticularly in the period from 1967 to 1971, when there was per­ sistent instability at the state level in most of the Indian states, and when Mrs Gandhi seemed unable to consolidate her power at pie central level, it seemed that the tendencies were clearly in the direction of localization, factionalization, and ruralization. What neither I nor most other observers bargained for was the tenacity of Mrs Gandhi, her adherence to the basic elements of N�hru's policies and strategies, and her willingness to assert ruthlessly the prerogatives of executive authority and the goals of national integration and rapid industrialization at the cost, if necessary, of state autonomy, opposition freedom, and individual civil liberties. Yet, equally surprisingly to many observers, Mrs Gandhi withdrew in 1977 the Emergency she imposed in 1975 and held free elections in which she and the Congress were thrown out of power in a stunning opposition victory. As the victorious Janata coalition disintegrated in internecine conflicts and personal squabbles during the next three years, it seemed at last that national, state, and local politics had become as one. However, again in 1980, Mrs Gandhi and the Congress returned to power with a two-thirds majority in Parliament and a renewed commitment to old policies. It appears, then, that the system will not move decisively in one These contrasts were noted at the time in two important articles: one by W.H. Morris-Jones, 'India's Political Idioms', in C.H. Philips (ed.), Politics - and an­ and Sodtty in India (London: Allen and Unwin, 1963), pp. 1 3 354, other by Myron Weiner, 'India's Two Political Cultures', in his Political Changt in South Asia (Calcutta: Firma K.L. Mukhopadhyaya, 1963), pp. 1151 52. Digiti zed by Google Ongmal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 306 State 1111d Politics in India way or another, that the centre and its goals will not prevail over state and local patterns and that, conversely, state and local politics will not percolate upwards and tranSform national politics. And that leads me to my theme and argument, namely that there is a persistent tension and dynamic in the system between two sets of goals and two patterns of politics, that one set and one pattern will not prevail over the other, but that the system is characterized by interpenetration between the two and mutual dependence of one upon the other. This tension and dynamic takes place in a system in which national power is extremely difficult to build and maintain because of the enormous size, diversity, and fragmenta­ tion of the country, among other reasons. Although I believe this dynamic interpenetratioQ is essential to understanding the system and is a permanent aspect of it, its features are not themselves unchanging. The balance of power among levels has changed in the past twenty years and will, no doubt, change again. Some institutions have declined in impor­ tance while others have enhanced their power. Patterns ofpoliti­ cal mobilization have also changed. However, there are many continuities as well. I want to emphasize one of these continuities in this chapter, namely the persistence of structures of local power independent of party organization, but not independent of government, which must be taken into account by any leader or party that seeks to build national power in India's political system. The Changing Context of Indian Politics Four important political changes have affected the nature of the dynamic tensions in the Indian political system in the past twenty years. The first has been the disintegration of the Congress organization as an institutionalized force at the local level. The second has been the decline in power of independent state pol­ iticians, of powerful bosses with links to the district which sus­ tained them in control of or in struggles for control of the provincial Congress organization and the state government. The third has been the nationalization of some issues that were less prominent twenty years ago or were considered local issues. These issues include the condition of India's poor and landless, the treatment of minorities, particularly Muslims, alleged atrocities Digiti zed by Google Ongmal from ____ UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Politiclll Process: Domintmte 307 committed against scheduled castes2 by some of the landed castes, land refonns, and the general state of law and order. A fourth change has been a succession of attempts by national leaders, particularly Mrs Gandhi, to centralize power by ruling through ordinances, by frequent and arbitrary imposition of President's rule over the state governments, by direct control of local party decisions on such matters as distribution of tickets to contest elections for the state legislative assemblies as well as Parliament, by the creation of new centralized institutions of police and intelligence, and by other means. The economic and social context in which politics takes place at the district level has also changed and continues to change, though not quite with revolutionary speed. The major changes, most of which cannot be discussed in this brief chapter, include the following: the so-called green revolution in agriculture, re­ newed efforts in the 1970s to enforce land ceilings legislation, the increased political assertiveness at the local level of the middle peasant castes, the increased prominence of issues concerning the well-being of s�eduled castes, the poor, and the landless, the increased salience of issues of law and order, the increasing importance of issues concerning the well-being, safety and cul­ tural identity of the Muslim minority, increased problems of student unrest, and the expansion o f government employment and the consequent increased importance of state employment and state employees as factors in the local political economy. It will be noticed that many of these issues were prominent twenty or more years ago and that I have used terms such as 'increased prominence' or 'increased importance' to refer to them. Even those terms may be an exaggeration for some of the issues and problems noted above. The point is that none of the changes taking place are revolutionary and most involve continuities with the past. Most important, there is great local variation in the speed and the impact of these changes. The changes that are most relevant to the issues to be discussed in this chapter concern land ceilings and law and order. In so fa r as land ceilings are concerned, pressure from the central govern­ ment in the 1970s led to renewed efforts by the state governments 2 Scheduled castes i s the official term used for persons of low or 'untouchable' caste in India, who are also often referred to as harijans. Digiti zed by Google Ongmal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 308 State and Politics in India to enforce more effectively land ceilings legislation and to reduce the permissible ceilings. This change has resulted in increasing the pressure on the descendants of the former great zamindars and talukdars who have managed to hold on to extensive landholdings during the post-zamindari abolition years. Like most·such laws in India, land ceilings are selectively enforced and their enforcement leaves some remarkably big new fish out of their net, but it is a continuing factor in the local political context. The second change relevant to this article concerns law and order. New problems of law and order have arisen partly out of the new tensions in the countryside between landowning cul­ tivators and their labourers. They have also arisen because of the addition of a new dimension to an old problem, namely the as­ sociation of local politicians with criminals and dacoits and the entry of the latter directly into politics in some places. Another major new source of violence in the countryside has been the police themselves, who now and then wreak havoc in the villages for their own reasons. The result is that control over the local police has become a very critical matter for district politicians. These several changes in local patterns of law, order, and violence mean that district politics now cannot be properly understood unless one can unravel the interconnections among criminals, politicians, and the police. The major changes that have taken place in the Congress and in its socio-economic environment in the past twenty years have affected the Congress support bases and local structures of power in important ways. First, electoral support for the Congress eroded in the 1960s to the point where its dominance and control over government were threatened. The Congress no longer has a monopoly over power at the higher levels of the Indian polity. Second,. the internal struggle for control over the Congress or­ ganization that led to the split in the Congress in 1969 and the rise of Mrs Gandhi to the position of pre-eminent leader of the Con­ gress had severe consequences for the party organization, par­ ticularly in the north, but elsewhere in India as well. In so far as the critical north Indian state of Uttar Pradesh (UP) is concerned, a weakened Congress organization became increasingly dependent on segments of the locally dominant landowning communities. A major new opposition force, the BKD of Charan Singh, emerged out of one of the former Congress groups, with a reliable base o f Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN - The Politi,·al Process: Dominance 309 support among the middle peasantry. In order to build sufficient electoral support. therefore, the Congress has had to try to combine elements from the top and the bottom of north Indian society, from the old landed groups and from the poor and the minorities. Finally, the old pattern of aggregating power from the bottom up, which enhanced the importance of state and local factions and leaders in the Congress, was replaced by a syste1n of control from the top down. Mrs Gandhi, like her father, has intervened decisively in state and local politics fro1n time to time. Unlike her father, however, she has intervened n1ore frequently and with less effectiveness and has relied upon advisers who lack adequate knowledge of, and genuine authority in, local political arenas. In the remainder of this chapter, I will illustrate the changes I have discussed above and the mutual dependence that has arisen as a consequence of the1n between national power and local politics. My illustrations will be drawn from two districts in UP, in which I did fieldwork in 1961-2 and to which I returned in October and November 1982. The two districts are Gonda in Oudh and Deoria in eastern UP on the Nepal and Bihar border. They illustrate rather different aspects of the local political eco­ nomy of the state of UP. Gonda, as part of Oudh, was a district dominated by great landed estates before Independence. The great former talukdars have continued to play irnportant roles in local politics. Deoria, in contrast, was never dominated by the great estates, though there were three i1nportant ones in the district. Rather, it has been a district that has been noted for its small landholdings and was, in 1962, one of the poorest and most agriculturally backward districts in the state with an agricultural economy based on intensive paddy cultivation, a large force of mostly landless agricultural labourers, and hardly any oppor­ tunities for off-farm employment outside of a declining sugar industry. In the past twenty years, however, Deoria has experi­ enced a number of changes in its politics and political economy - considerable agricultural change, increased assertiveness of the backward or middle status agricultural castes, and the rise of the Lok Dal, the latest incarnation of the agrarian political party of Chaudhuri Charan Singh. These two districts, therefore, provide a sufficient contrast, and one of them has undergone sufficient change, to make a comparison of structures of local power and politics in them of broad interest. -- Dlgltlzedby --- Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN . 3IO State and Politicr in India Structures of Local Power Gonda: The Persistence ofLocal Power In 1962, the most impressive structure of local power I found in my research in five districts of UP was that maintained by the ex-Raja of Mankapur in Gonda district.3 Although the Mankapur estate was only the fourth largest talukdari estate in the district in revenue payments and collected revenue only from 149 villages, it had become politically the most important estate in the district even before Independence. After Independence, despite the pas­ sage of legislation eliminating the tax-farming system that had sustained the economic and political power of the great landlord families of Oudh and other parts of UP during British rule, the heir of the Mankapur estate, Raghvendra Pratap Singh, succeeded in maintaining substantial economic resources and impressive po­ litical power in the district until his death in 1964. In fact, he dominated the Congress organization in the district after Inde­ pendence until 1956, when he left it to go into opposition. His departure from the Congress at that time left the district organiza­ tion in disarray, but left him still by far the most powerful political force in Gonda. Raghvendra Pratap was a Raja in the grand manner, not in the sense that he lived ostentatiously, but in his natural enjoyment and exercise of power and authority. Moreover, he revelled in politics, which he entered of his own volition during the nationalist movement. His son and sole heir, Anand Singh, is of an entirely different temperament fron1 his father. He dislikes politics, and does not enjoy, in the obvious manner of his father, the exercise of power over men. However, like his father, he does enjoy the life in Mankapur: the peace, tranquility, and security of the great palace; the loyalty of the local population who are eager to be of service to the scion of the Mankapur estate, whose protection they want; and the satisfactions of an agricultural life involving the control of land and the resources derived from the produce of the land. In order to maintain such a life style, however, it is not possible to remain aloof from politics. In 1964, therefore, when his father died, Anand, who was then 3 See Paul R. Brass, Fat:tif1fllll Politics in tm lnditm State: Tbt Cungrtn Pany in Utt11r Pradesh (Berkeley: University ofCalifornia Press, 1964), chapter 4. Dlgltlzedby Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN I The Political Process: Dominance 311 only in his mid-twenties, was in a difficult situation. His father had fought successfully against the Congress for eight years and had maintained his hold over the district in the face of several major campaigns involving the importation into the district of persons from outside with great fmancial or political resources to challenge him. Anand, in contrast to his father, preferred not to continue to fight in a perpetual state of siege against powerful outside forces, but to work within the existing structures of external power. Con­ sequently, he joined the Congress and contested the legislative assembly elections successfully in 1967.. Thereafter, for ten years, he consistently miscalculated the direction of the political currents and found himself and his estate under unrelenting pressure from external authorities. In 1969, when theCongress split, Anand chose to remain with the Congress (0). Although in 1971, he succeeded in winning the parliamentary election on the Congress (0) ticket in the face of the massive victories of the Congress led by Mrs Gandhi nearly everywhere else in north India, he found himself politically isolated thereafter. The Congress returned to power in the state of UP and with a two-thirds majority at the centre. The pressure by the state authorities against the former landlords in­ creased with the passage of new land ceilings legislation in UP and the publication of a report by the state government that identified various former zamindars and talukdars, including Anand Singh of Mankapur, as still in possession of vast illegal landholdings. In 1972, after the war with Bangladesh, when 1nany n o nCongress MPs and MLAs decided to join the Congress-I, Anand also joined the ruling party. His decision to enter the Congress-I did not protect him from further pressures irom the state government when, during the Emergency, Mr H.N. Bahuguna became the Chief Minister of UP. Anand himself lost an election for the first time in the great anti- . Congress wave of 1977, and the Janata party came to power in the state and country thereafter. Remarkably enough, in the face of this series of political blunders and miscalculations, when I returned to Mankapur in 1978, in 1980, and for an extended period in 1982, I found Anand Singh as relaxed as always, the Mankapur palace in excellent condition, a consider­ able personal following at his command, and his political influence at a peak by 1982.4 is drawn primarily from interviews conducted by me in Gonda district in November 1982. 4The information in the rest ofthis section - - � Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 312 Statt and Politicr in India Although the wealth and lands still under the control of Anand Singh cannot be identifted precisely because they are under litiga­ tion, there is no doubt that he commands great economic resources. He maintains that he retains only that amount of land to which h e is entitled under land ceilings legislation and that the rest has been given to educational trusts and to former tenants or has been sold off. Others say he continues to control directly or through trusts approximately 1500 acres of land, on which he grows foodgrains, sugar cane, mangoes, teak and other forest products, and various other cash crops such as citronella. Anand also maintains a variety of agro-based and agro-related enterprises, divided into sixteen departments. His lands, trusts and enterprises extend throughout the countryside around Mankapur, scattered here and there, in a radius of approximately 10 kilometres. Anand has sufficient economic resources at his command to retain an extensive and loyal political following and to control the important political and economic institutions in the district - the cooperative banks, the land development committees, the coopera­ tive cane unions, the block development committees. He also con­ trols the police. Whenever Anand is in Mankapur, local people acknowledge his power by their visits to the palace to request his aid on every kind of matter from providing emergency medical transportation to adjudication of local disputes over land to requests for intervention with the local administration for postings, permits, and redress of grievances of all sorts. Those who recognize the authority of Mankapur can also be assured of police protection when they need it and of freedom from police harassment In 1980, in her successful strategy to return to power, Mrs Gandhi chose to rely whenever possible on men like Anand Singh, who could be counted upon to deliver votes. Anand himself contested for Parliament and won the Mankapur seat with a massive majority. In the distribution of tickets for the Congress in both the January 1980 parliamentary and the June 1980 legis­ lative assembly elections, Anand was given control over all but two legislative assembly tickets. All but those two were won by the Congress in Gonda in its most impressive victory in that district since Independence. In the normal course, a man who can deliver nine out of eleven legislative assembly and two out of two parliamentary seats in a district could be expected to demand and receive an important Dlgltlzedby Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Political Process: Dominance 313 ministry or two in the state and central governments for himself and/or his followers. However, Anand does not like state and national politics. He prefers to spend as much time as possible in Mankapur and begrudges the time he must spend in Lucknow and Delhi. His main interest is in the survival of his estate, his palace, and, therefore, his local political influence. Consequently, Anand chose to ask for a factory for his backward and remote district lac.king in any industry rather than for a ministry for himself or his closest supporters. The story of how Anand Singh acquired a factory for his district reveals how national policy and local politics are nowadays often directly linked without intermediation through the state level. Sometime in 1981, the central government proposed to set up four fertilizer gas plants in four districts of UP, of which Gonda was to be one. However, when the technical information concern­ ing the appropriateness of the four sites was fed into the computer, negative results were received back on two sites - Amethi in Sultanpur district and Gonda. Amethi being the constituency of Sanjay and later Rajiv Gandhi, the computer ultimately corrected the results for Sultanpur district but not for Gonda. Anand, there­ fore, went to see the Prime Minister once again to remind her that he wanted a factory for his district, in response to which Mrs Gandhi promised Anand a new telecommunications factory to be built by the French at a cost of Rs 300 crores to employ 5000 persons. Once again, technical studies were done concerning the feasibility of the proposed site for the factory and were fed into the computer, which again gave negative results. At one point, Anand suggested to the Industries Minister that the computer might be used to 'fetch the votes then next time'. He advised Mrs Gandhi that the computers were giving negative results only be­ cause the Indian Administrative officers and technicians and the French collaborators preferred a more attractive place such as Bangalore, which would also have good educational facilities for their children, to a remote and backward district such as Gonda. At this point, Mrs Gandhi awarded the factory to Gonda district, basing her decision on its backwardness and consequent need for new industry and employment. By awarding the telecommunica­ tions factory to Gonda, the centre also was acknowledging the political value of Anand Singh and his capacity to deliver votes. Preliminary work is now going on at the site of the ·factory, - .... ..,- - D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 314 St11te 1111d Politics in India which is to be constructed only a couple of kilometres away from the palace atMankapur on barren land that was provided by Anand himself. In bringing the first major modem industry to Gonda since Independence, Anand has provided the possibility of consid­ erable new employment for some of his constituents and the prospect of generating enensive further industrial, commercial, and employment opportunities that are expected to be provided b y the creation of some thirty to forty ancillary industries. Anand himself is expected to set up one or two ancillary industries of his own, for which sites have already been selected. This incident of the telephone factory brings out several impor­ tant features of contemporary politics in India, some of which are different from the days of Nehru's dominance; The first feature is the demonstrable high value of a persisting structure of local power such as that at Mankapur. The second is the necessity for anyone who wishes to maintain such a structure to go into politics at the local level and to develop external linl<s at the im portant decision points outside the district The third feature and one that is dif­ ferent from twenty years ago is the fact that the important external links are in Delhi, in fact in the office of the Prime Minister. The state government and politicians had nothing to do with this de­ cision. Twenty years ago, the ChiefMinisters would have vied with each other before Nehru to demand the siting of such a valuable project in their state. The fourth point follows from the third. Centralization of power in the hands of the Prime Minister i n India's political system in effect means that the Prime Minister is free to decide whose local support is most critical for her own persistence in power. For the power of the Prime Minister and Congress power at the centre are dependent upon those at the state and local levels who can deliver votes and seats and who cannot be ignored. In north India, direct relations between powerful persons at the local level and those at the centre, including the Prime Minister and her close advisers, have become common, although not always to mutual advantage and satisfaction, as the following contrasting case from Deoria district suggests. Deoria: The Persistence ofDivisiun In Deoria, as in Gonda district, the Congress under the leadership of Mrs Gandhi and her son, Sanjay, attempted t o work through __ Dig1t1zeo by Google Origi�al rrom UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Political Process: Domintm&e 315 local structures of power to establish a stable support base in the countryside. However, in Deoria, there are no local structures of power comparable to Manlcapur, the district has for long been a highly politicized one, and inter-party competition bas been very keen. In 1962, the Congress in Deoria district was weak, frag­ mented, and f-actionalized. Inter-party competition between the Congress and the Socialist parties was intense. The politics of the district focused especially upon two issues: the problems of sugar, especially the issue of the cane price, and struggles centring around the increasing political assertiveness of the backward castes in a district whose politics and local instirutions were then dominated by the elite castes of Brahmans, Rajputs, and Bhumiban. The district then was a symbol of extreme poverty and backwardness that provided a solid base for the Socialist parties.s In 1982, as in 1962, inter-party competition in Deoria district was very keen. However, there was an outward change in its form. In the intervening years, the_Socialist movement had disappeared. The more moderate leaders, many of them of elite caste status, had joined the Congress in the 1960s. The more radical leaders, some of elite caste status, but others of middle caste status, con­ tinued in opposition but joined with the agrarian, backward--caste­ oriented movement of Chaudhuri Charan Singh. The present political form of that movement in UP and in Deoria district is the party known as the Lok Dal. As a consequence of the disin­ tegration of the Socialist movement and the rise of the Lok Dal as the principal opposition party in Deoria district., conflict be­ tween the elite and backward castes has become somewhat more sharply focused, though by no means as yet completely polarized. As for the Congress in Deoria district in the intervening years, it acquired some new strength in the 1960s as a conse­ quence of the incorporation of the moderate socialist leaders into it. Since the two most prominent moderate Socialist leaders were of Bhumiliar caste,6 the Congress also strengthened its support amongst this powerful local caste and its clients. How­ ever, the Congress remained throughout these years in Deoria district a highly fragmented party, with its leadership drawn principally from persons of elite caste status, especially Bnhmans s See Brass, FIICti11n11I Politia, chapter 6. 6 Genda Singh and Ramayan Rai. - � - D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIQA./:! ......,_ 316 State and Politics in India and Bhumihars, and its support base mostly among those same castes along with some support from the lower castes and the Muslim minority. Moreover, in successive elections during the past twenty years, the backward castes have made their presence felt increasingly as voters and candidates, mostly in opposition to the Congress. In 1980, in their search for allies in north India who could help to bring them back to power at the centre, Mrs Gandhi and her son, Sanjay, found in Deoria district another member of a landed family who seemed well-suited to their needs. Although Deoria district was not, like Gonda district, dominated by great landed estates before Independence, there were three substantial estates in the district. Of the three, the best-endowed fmancially was Padrauna, which at one time owned three sugar mills as well as landed property. The Padrauna Rajas were Sainthwar by caste, a local backward caste considered by m.any people to be part of the Kurmi caste category. In 1980, Mr C.P.N. Singh of the Padrauna estate was recruited by Sanjay Gandhi to contest for Parliament . on the Congress-I ticket and, having done so successfully, was made a minister of state in the Government of India. It is also generally believed in the district that he was given the major say in the distribution of tickets for the June 1980 legislative assembly elections in Deoria district. In this way, it would seem, the Con­ gress would have the double advantage of a base in a powerful and wealthy landed family in the district, through a person from a backward caste. In contrast to Gonda district, however, the strategy of relying upon C.P.N. Singh to control the district failed. The Lok Dal won six of thirteen seats in the district and a candidate from another opposition party won a seventh, leaving the Congress with less than half the seats in the district. Moreover, in 1982, the Congress was bitterly divided in Deoria district and the leadership of Mr C.P.N. Singh was held in contempt by some of the strongest local leaders of the Congress. Three reasons for the failure of the Congress in Deoria to acquire as much strength as in Gonda have been given already the higher degree of politicization in the district, the greater traditional strength of the opposition, and the comparative weak­ ness of the Padrauna estate in comparison to Mankapur. Still, on the face of it, the Congress leadership might have hoped for a Digiti zed by Google Ongmal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Political Process: Dominance 317 more favourable result i n electoral terms and, at the least, a much less badly divided party.Let us examine, therefore, in more detail the leadership of C.P.N.Singh, the manner in which he acquired it, and the way in which he has exercised it.7 First of all, it is felt by even the mildest of his critics in the Deoria Congress that C.P.N. Singh's leadership was not earned independently. For example one of the oldest and most faithful Congressmen of the district was asked about C.P.N.Singh and gave the following reply: Respondent:He has no political ground. How can that be? PRB: Background, he has nothing. Res: So how did he become a 1ninister in the central govern­ PRB: ment? Res: Now the policy is quite different. . . . Previously the main point of consideration used to be sacrifice and work. Now sacrifice and political-social work or public wor.lc [are] in the background. PRB: And what is in the fore ground? ... Foreground, how far he has ... got contacts with the Res: leadership.... Is it a fact that Mr C.P.N.Singh was simply an appointee PRB: of Sanjay Gandhi? Res: That is a fuct.That is a fact. A rather more embittered and hostile Congressman opposed to the leadership of C.P.N.Singh put the matter more strongly.He claimed that the father of C.P.N.Singh had been patronized by the British and had fought against the Congress and that the son himself had originally entered politics in 1969 in opposition to the Congress as a candidate of Charan Singh's BKD, 'though he was not political at any time ...by thinking, by working, by any means.' After the election, he left the BKD and joined the Congress. Res: [In 1980, C.P.N. Singh] became MP and now he is minister. He has no backing, he has no following, ... no ...political thinking. PRB: But he is [the] only central minister in the Congress govern­ ment from Deoria district? How can this be? The information in the rest of this section, unless otherwise indicated, is dr�wn primarily from interviews conducted by me in Deoria district in October 1982. 7 - � - _olgltlz•dby Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 318 State and Politics in India Res: Yes.I don't know why ...Ab, Mr Sanjay Gandhi is no more in the world.... PRB: So we can't spcalc ill of him! Res: We can't say about him.... (But,] perhaps Mr C.P N.Singh is not [even a] member of [the] Congress Party ...in Deoria district. PRB: But he was a man of Sanjay Gandhi? Res: Undoubtedly. According to this view, the selection of C.P.N.Singh to be the leader of the Deoria district Congress had nothing to do with his political background or lack of it, his position in the Paclrauna estate, or his backward caste status, but was because of his personal and familial connections with Sanjay Gandhi.His wife is the cousin of the Punjabi industrialist, Kuldip Narang, who bas had close connections with Maneka Gandhi, the wife of Sanjay Gandhi. Because of these connections, it is alleged, he was made Minister of State for Defence while Sanjay was alive and later was given the portfolio of technology.8 He was brought into the central government for the first time in March 1980 without having had any previous parliamentary or ministerial experience. Those close to C.P.N. Singh reject these allegations.However, it is not disputed by anyone that, as one person put it, Mr C.P.N. Singh 'was a great follower of [Sanjay Gandhi]', that he had known him since 1971, that he 'admired him', and that he felt Sanjay Gandhi 'was really what India needed'.Moreover, in so far as the Emergency of 1975 to 1977 is concerned, with whose most un­ popular measures Sanjay Gandhi was identified, C.P.N. Singh is known to feel that there was nothing 'wrong with it'. When his detractors say that C.P.N. Singh has no background, they mean that he has not been a loyal Congressman throughout, that he did not build his political career by establishing a local, · grassroots following, and that he was not closely and steadily involved in district-level politics. However they are interpreted, the facts are that he entered politics in 1969 to fight against the Congress after a local Congress MLA interfered with his authority over his employees on his own farm. He was offered the BKD 8 In February 1983, in a cabinet reshuffle, Mr C.P.N. Singh lost the portfolio of Science and Technology, among others, and was left with only Non­ Conventional Energy Sources: Hindu, 5 Februa.r y 1983. He resigned from the government a few days thereafter. Digiti zed by Google Ongmal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Political Process: Dumin11111:e 319 ticket after meeting with Charan Singh and won the election with a large majority. In 1970, he left Charan Singh and joined Mrs Gandhi. However, in 1974, he was denied the Congress ticket. He also did not contest in 1977. Then, in 1980, he was given the Congress ticket for Parliament. It is true, therefore, that C.P.N. Singh began his political career in opposition to the Congress, that he lacked sufficient influence in the party to obtain a ticket in either 1974 or 1977, and that he acquired his political influence in the district after receiving the ticket for Parliament in 1980 and a position in the Ministry thereafter. He won the Parliamentary scat itself partly because there were two strong non-Congress candidates against him who divided the opposition vote. The primary reasons for C.P.N. Singh's failure to effectively lead the Congress in Deoria district, however, are.the inadequacies of his resource base in the north of the district and the antagonism he aroused among the important Brahman and Bhumihar leaders in the southern part of the district. It is claimed that he was given control over the selection of candidates in 1980 by Sanjay Gandhi and that he was given such control more because of his personal and family connections than because of the strength of his political base in the district.Moreover, instead of seeking an alliance with the dominant Brahman and Bhumihar Congressmen in the southern part of the district, he is said to have simply cut them from the list of candidates, and that, too, at the last minute and in a humiliating manner. According to the account of the matter given by his rivals, they left Delhi by train on the day before the final date for filing nomination papers, assured that they had the nominations, only to learn from the newspapers upon their arrival in Deoria that they had, in fact, not been allotted the tickets. Although C.P.N. Singh claims he had absolutely nothing to do ·with the selection of candidates for the legislative assen1bly, both those who did not receive the tickets and those who did believe that C.P.N. Singh played a critical role in the final decision. The way in which the list of candidates was allegedly determined in 1980 is described by one of the local leaders of the Deoria Con­ gress who was cut from the list: . . . the district leaders of the Congress were debarred Res: from the ticket.. . PRB: Because of Sanjay Gandhi, you mean... Res: Due to C.P.N. Singh. Why, SanjayGandhi will not know who D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 320 State and Politics in India is X, and who is this leader, or that leader, [or anybody in] this district organization .... He was completely in the hand of Mr C.P.N.Singh....And this district was allotted to C.P.N. Singh in the same way some districts were allotted to Mr X, Mr Y, Mr Z, who were nearer to Mr Sanjay Gandhi. And they allotted tickets to their friends or their relations and the politi­ cal rivals were debarred....And we are political rivals. Although those close to C.P.N.Singh deny that he played any such role in the distribution of Congress tickets in Deoria district, there is no doubt that he has seen himself in the role of diminishing the influence of the previously dominant leaders from the southern part of the district and from the northern part as well. He claims, in fact, to have broken the influence of such leaders, whom he considers 'manipulators'. In C.P.N. Singh's view, his rivals 'don't matter', 'if they manage to get tickets, they will never win' an election.Rather, 'they are zero.They have done nothing except manipulate things from the top'. It deserves to be noted that the criticisms that the two sides in Deoria make of each other are identical, namely that they have no genuine local sources of in­ fluence and popularity based on work in the district, but depend for their local position on influence with powerful persons in the state capital or in Delhi. A comparison of the local leadership of C.P.N.Singh in Deoria district with that of Anand Singh in Gonda district will help to bring out several features of the relationship between national power and local politics in contemporary India. First, in both cases, it should be noted that the Congress leadership in Delhi sought allies from the most powerful local families with the greatest economic and/or political resources.The Congress operates more than ever before through existing structures of local power, which its economic policies are supposedly designed to eliminate. Second, it is obvious that, if the national leadership is going to rely on one person primarily for local leadership, they are taking a considerable risk. In Gonda, they chose the scion of the most powerful local landed estate, a man in full control of that estate's own resources and with extensive local influence beyond his own estate.In Deoria, they chose a man who was a member of an estate once the largest in the district. But that estate never occupied a comparable position in Deoria to that of Mankapur in Gonda; the present Padrauna estate is divided economically and politically into Dlgltlzedby Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Political Process: Dominance 321 two main segments and several subsections, C.P.N. Singh does not control all its resources, and its political influence has not extended very far from its original domain. This contrast brings out a significant difference between pat­ terns of local control now and twenty years ago, namely that the national leaders in Delhi lack the local knowledge that state leaders had then. Twenty years ago, candidate selection in the Congress was a grand and complex struggle that took place at three levels primarily - the district, the state, and the centre. The state leadership played a pivotal role in the process, though the final decisions were often made in Delhi. The results often led to discontent at the local level and to disaffected Congressmen con­ testing against or sabotaging the election campaigns of the official candidates. But everyone knew who everyone else was. The state leaders knew their local allies and their allies' enemies. They could go to Delhi and say to the national leaders that Mr X in con­ stituency X is an appropriate or inappropriate candidate because he has worked or not worked hard in that constituency for a long time, because his caste is such and such and the caste composition of the constituency is as follows and, for these reasons, he will or will not be a good candidate. The national leaders in Delhi nowa­ days do not have this kind of local knowledge. They do not wish to leave the decisions to state leaders or even allow them too big a role in the process, for then they become dependent on the state leaders. So they take a chance and select, with partial knowledge, one local man to do the job for them. Sometimes th ey choose sensibly, as in Gonda, sometimes they choose less sensibly, as in Deoria. Finally, despite the differences between the local leadership of Anand Singh and C.P.N. Singh, their relationships with the na­ tional leadership bring out clearly the mutual dependence between the two.Moreover, despite the apparent centralization of decision­ making power in New Delhi, it is the national leadership that is more dependent on effective local leadership than vice-versa. Anand Singh needs the help and patronage of the central govern­ ment to expand his economic resources and his political influence. But the structure ofMankapur's local power has persisted through· several generations in the face of considerable external opposition. In Deoria, C.P.N. Singh lacks a strong independent base such as that of Anand Singh. The national leaders lack local knowledge. - D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 322 State and Politics in India Therefore, they remain dependent upon ineffective local leader­ ship and do not know how to find an alternative. The Manipulation and Control of Incidents of Violence It would be an extraordinarily difficult, in fact an impossible, task to build national power in India solely through the methods of material exchange that I have just described. To build power and broad support in any large-scale system, political leaders must be able to move large numbers of people, preferably whole blocs of voters, with appeals to their ideals, values and emotional needs. The primary emotional need for most people in all societies, as Thomas Hobbes pointed out vividly long ago, is for a sense of personal safety and security. In India, that primary need is often unsettled and replaced by fear of violence and sudden death or loss of property. Such fears exist particularly among Muslims in South Asia, the atrocities recently perpetrated in Assam being the worst example of the legitimate bases for their fears since Inde­ pendence. They also exist among many low caste people who fear the power of the landed men to beat them, kill them, or steal their lands. They exist generally among poor people who fear the local power of the police. They also exist a1nong the rich and high caste people in large parts of north India, who fear the apparent decline in law and order generally, and who demonstrate their fear by going out with guns in the evenings and sleeping with guns close by their bedsides. Consequently, there is no issue more likely to make a broad emotional appeal to large numbers of people in India than issues of law and order and violence. The manipulation of incidents of violence by political leaders to appeal to the emotional needs of whole categories of voters has been a central feature of Indian politics for a decade now. I now want to show how such incidents are used, with two examples, again, from Deoria and Gonda districts. In these examples, I will demonstrate that a critical element in the relationship between local and national leaders is the ability of the fonner to control the local police, to prevent local incidents of violence from occur­ ring, if possible, and most important to prevent them from being used by the opposition as a symbolic issue against the government when they do occur. Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Political Process: Dominance 323 Deoria: Local Violence as a National Symbolic Resource In January I980, an incident occurred in Narainpur village in Deoria district, which received national attention in the press, in Parliament, and in the state legislative assembly. An old woman of the village, grandmother and sole support of two young children whose parents were dead, was crushed to death by a passing bus. The villagers stopped the bus and demanded compensation for the woman's cremation expenses and for the maintenance of the two children left alone. After son1e time, the driver was allowed to leave with the understanding that the owner of the bus would be informed of the incident by him. Accounts of the incident differ from this point on.9 According to the villagers, the owner came to the village with a police party, a crowd collected, the police did not like the look of the crowd and began caning the people, and the people retaliated. Later, the villag�rs were taken to a nearby bus stand with the understanding that they would be given the desired compensation. In the presence of the local member of the legislative assembly (MLA), the bus owner, and the police, it was decided that Rs 5000 would be paid after two or three days to the villagers for the cremation of the old woman and the upbringing of the two children. However, after the bus owner and the MLA departed, the villagers allege that they were surrounded by the police, kept under surveillance for three hours and not permitted to leave until th ey signed or made their thumb impressions upon a document presented to them, after which they were beaten one by one, subjected to various indignities and injuries, and had their belongings stolen before they were released. Later in the night, a party of police and goondas (toughs) from the surrounding villages descended on Narainpur and beat the villagers again, after which a number of them were taken to the Captainganj police station for further beatings, where the legs of some villagers were broken and where all were subjected again to indignities, after which they were taken w a jail in another town. The account of the local police differs somewhat. According to one account, the villagers stopped another bus two or three days after the death of the grandmother, beat up the driver, and decided. to detain the bus until compensation was paid to them. When the 9 Unless otherwise indicated, the information on the Narainpur incident in this section comes front my interviews in Deoria district in October 1982. __ ... . ,g tized by � i Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF Ml€t-llGAfl.l •·. ·•· 324 State 1111d Politia in India Captainganj station officers and constables happened to pass by, they stopped, asked the people to release the bus, and promised them that compensation would be paid. However, someone in the crowd pointed towards the station officer and shouted that he had accepted a bribe from the bus owner, whereupon the people began beating the station officers and constables. Later, a larger party of police came to the village, arrested the people who had beaten up the police personnel, and registered a case against them. According to another police account, the villagers were correct in saying that the sub-inspector had been bribed and had given only a small proportion of the amount paid by the bus owner to the villagers. Consequently they were enraged on that account when they at­ tacked the police party. According to this same account, when a larger police party returned, th ey beat up all the men mercilessly. A case was then filed by the villagers against the police. The Narainpur incident took place on 14 January 1980, just after the parliamentary elections which brought Mrs Gandhi and her Congress-I back to power at the centre, but before the state legislative assembly elections held in ten states in June 1980, in which Mrs Gandhi extended her power to the state level by winning majorities in nearly all of them. The Narainpur incident was a major symbolic issue made use of by Mrs Gandhi and the Congress-I to demonstrate the incompetence of the Janata gov­ ernment still ruling in UP and in other states and its alleged mistreatment of Muslims and scheduled castes and the consequent need for mid-term legislative assembly elections. It could be used to suggest mistreatment of both Muslims and scheduled castes because the village is predominantly Muslim and also contains a large population of scheduled castes. The first headlines on the incident in the national press on 29 January referred to a 'Mass Rape Incident' and to 'Mass Rape, Plunder by UP Cops'. 10 Later news stories placed the Narainpur incident in the context of other 'excesses committed [in the coun­ try] on its weakest sections'.11 There were reports that a Muslim man and a Harijan woman had been murdered.12 Three days after the first notice of the incident in the national press, Mr Sanjay Gandhi himself visited the village and said that what 'happened 10 Indian &press and Times oflndui, 29 January II Ltiukr, 30 January 1980. 12 Hindu, 9 February 1980. Digi tized by Google 1980. Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Politiazl Process: Domintm&e 325 in Narainpur was unprecedented. There was not a single girl or woman in Narainpur who was not raped. Nor was there a single man who was not beaten up. T o cap it all, there is not a single house which was not looted'.13 He later said that the Narainpur incident was one of several 'cases which showed that the state Government was encouraging disruptionists to spread terror', as a consequence of which 'the people in the state were feeling insecure'.14 In an exchange of letters with the Chief Minister of the state, Mrs Gandhi said, 'I doubt if there has been any other instance of such magnitude since independence.' As fo r the police firings that took place during the Emergency, they were 'negligible in comparison with what happened in the Pantnagar police firing or now in Narainpur'. 15 On 9 February, Mrs Gandhi herself, with a large entourage of Congress-I political leaders and ministers, proceeded to Narainpur and, after meeting the villagers, report­ edly said her visit had given her an 'emotional moving feeling' and made her 'feel very angry with a system which allowed that sort of thing to happen'. She said that 'her government would try to give whatever relief was possible'. 16 However, Sanjay Gandhi and Mrs Gandhi did not visit Narain­ pur only to console the villagers and to promise them justice and relief. The incident occurred in a constituency long dominated by the opposition and held at the time by a Lok Dal representative. The state government was in the hands of the Janata party and the Lok Dal. The Congress-I was seeking a pretext to dismiss the UP government, preferably in disgrace, to enhance its chances of winning a big majority in the state legislative assembly elections that would soon be called, Mr Sanjay Gandhi put the incident to such political use after his visit to Narainpur when he demanded that the UP government resign because of its failure to prevent or to respond effectively to the Narainpur incident.17 Mrs Gandhi also made similar use of her visit to Narainpur, after which she 11 Lelllkr, l February 1980. 14 Hmdu, 9 February 1980. IS Ibid., On the Pantnagar police firing, which' also occurred during the period ofJaiµt:1 rule in UP, see Paul R. Brass, 'Institutional Transfer ofTechnology: _ The Land-Grant Model and the Agricultural University at Pantnapr', in Robert S. Anderson, Soma, Politia, lffld tbe AgriaJtund Rl'DOltltitm in AM (Boulder, Colorado: Westview Press, 1982), pp. 103�3. 16 St11tm,uni, 8 Febnwy 1980. 17 Lelllkr, l February 1980. D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 326 State 1111d Poutics in India reportedly said that the'Banarasi Das government has no right to exist'. 18 The union Home Minister, who makes the legal case for dismissal of a state government in the central cabinet, said on 11 February that'the Union Government would invoke its constitu­ tional powers if incidents like Narainpur happened in states'.19 On 18 February, the President of India, acting on the advice of the cabinet, dismissed the UP government and nine other state gov­ ernments in India and ordered elections to be held in them inJune 1980. Although the case for dismissing these governments was made on legal constitutional grounds and had a precedent, the Narainpur incident was the principal symbolic pretext used to . justify the dismissal before the public. The leaders of the Janata and Lok Dal parties, of course, defended the UP government. The UP Chief Minister said that 'the Narainpur incident had "been blown out of all proportion" and was being used "as a handle to malign the State Govern­ ment"'.2 0 He accused Mrs Gandhi of'making political capital out of a human tragedy'.21 As a consequence of the furore created over Narainpur, a com­ mission of inquiry was appointed to examine the incident. The commission submitted its report to the state government of UP on 3 July 1981, when the Congress was back in power. The report dismissed as totally without foundation the charges of rape of any woman in Narainpur, although it did support the charge that there. had been severe beatings and 'wrongful confmement' of villagers. The printing of the report was delayed for nearly a full year and was not placed before the House until 22June 1982 and then only on the last day of the monsoon session, thereby preventing any debate on it.22 I t is not entirely clear how the Narainpur story broke on to the state and national stage. It appears, however, to have become magnified because of the failure of local politicians to control the police and because of internal rivalries between segments of the ruling coalition in the state government. The local MLA was a Lok Dal member. He attempted to intervene to pacify the villagers 18 LeiUkr, 8 February 1980. t9 LeiUkr, 11 Fcbruary 1980. 20 Le11der, 12 February 1980. 11 Times ofIndia, 9 February I980. 2 2 Hindu, 11 September I982. Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Political 'Process: Dommtmct 327 and prevent further incidents, but could not prevent the police from going back to the village to beat the villagers again. He, therefore, reported the incident to the Chief Minister. The Chief Minister, Mr Banarasi Das, was an appointee of the Lok Dal segment of the coalition and had been made Chief Minister against the wishes of the Janata segment in an earlier and uneasy com­ promise. Janat2 party workers also found out about the case and reported it to the Chief Minister, who then sent one of his min­ isters to Deoria district and to Narainpur to investigate. The minister came back to Lucknow with his report of mass rape, plunder, and 'the death of two persons' in the village and blamed it on 'st2te government officials [who] wanted to destabilize the Lok Dal ministry' at the bidding of the Congress-I. The Lok Dal MLA attributed the incident to upper caste police officers who wanted to ' "punish" voters, mostly Muslims, who had supported him in the previous elections'.13 It was after the Janata-Lok Dal state government itself revealed the incident that the Congress-I leaders entered the scene. Although accounts of the incidents at Narainpur continue to differ somewhat, the available evidence three years after the events suggests the following f.icts and ele1nents in the situation. First, there is no evidence that Muslims were selected for harassment because they were Muslims, or that Harijan women were raped. Nor were there any deaths except that of the old woman killed by the bus. Second, the local judicial system was not brought into play and is, in fact, of no use whatever in such a situation, which is not uncommon in rural India. Consequently, justice must be worked out locally among the villagers, the guilty or responsible parties, the police, and the politicians. Third, in the absence again of ·effective local political control, such issues become confrontations between the local population and the local police. These confron­ t2tions are not ordinary or even extraordinary police actions involv­ ing maintaining law and order and crowd control. They are pitched battles, waged with venom andviciousness, in which the police may initially be understaffed and, therefore, may get beaten up them­ selves, but will certainly return with larger forces and superior power to take revenge. Fourth, if there is no stable structure of local power to handle such a situation effectively, it will go out of control 23 Timu ofIndia, 29 January I 980. Dlgltlzedby Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 328 State and Politicl· in India and become magnified into a political issue in the larger arenas of state and national politics. Finally, once the issue is introduced into external arenas, it is shaped t o fit larger purposes that have very little to do with the actual circumstances. In this case, the issues in the external arena included the following: the competence of the state government and its right to rule, the treatment of low caste people and Muslims by the Janata-Lok Dal government, the gen­ eral state of law and order in the country in recent years and in the p os tIndependence period, and who was responsible for its alleged deterioration. Finally, it should be evident that these violent inci­ dents are at once an enormous liability to any government under whose rule they occur and a great resource for the opposition. The stakes involved are the stability of the existing government and the outcome of the next election. In the immediate aftermath, such incidents may be used to embarrass an existing government and even may be used as a pretext to dismiss it. In the longer period after such an incident, in preparation for the next election, the purpose of the opposition will be to demonstrate that the incident in question is but a reflection of the broader inability of the govern­ ment to protect, or even its deliberate policy to harass, certain 'sections' of the population, particularly Muslims and low castes. The danger for the ruling party, therefore, and the hope of the opposition is that a whole bloc or blocs of voters in the state or country will be turned in the next election through the manipula­ tion of local violent incidents. Gonda: The Importance of Local Control ofthe Police That incidents of local violence need not be magnified, distorted, and manipulated for external use in wider political arenas can be demonstrated by comparing the Narainpur incident with a similar incident that occurred in the village of Kurman Purwa in Gonda district in July 1982. At this time, the Congress was in control of. the district, the state, and the central government. As in the Narainpur incident, the principal events are not difficult to estab­ lish, but the details and the explanations vary. 24 In so far as the events are concerned, it appears that a party of police and local toughs descended on the village inhabited entirely 24 All information in this section is derived from interviews conducted by me in Gonda district in November 1982 . . D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Political Process: Dominance 329 b y persons of low and backward caste status on the night of 13 July 1982 and engaged in a brawl.with the villagers wl)ose outcome was indecisive; that is to say the villagers gave back-as good as they received. However, a second and larger party returned that night and beat the villagers, and possibly dragged the women out 'of their houses, and did some damage and looting. On the 17th, the police returned with a decree of confiscation and allegedly removed grain and other property of the villagers. The villagers say that a number of their men were also taken to the police station that night and robbed there and that six of them were left in jail for nearly three months. Between the 13th and the 17th, the local Congress MLA in­ tervened and was promised by the police that no further retaliatory action would be taken against the villagers. As in the Narainpur incident, however, the local MLA was not able to control the police, who returned to the village on the 17th despite their promises not to do so. Anand Singh also intervened personally in an attempt to keep the situation under control. However, the local police apparently w�re not even restrained by his intervention. Between 13 July and 9 August, the Congress MLA from the adjacent constituency and the local opposition also became in­ volved in the incident. By most accounts, the police violence perpetrated at Kurman Purwa was carried out by the local police constables on their own, without the authority or support of the station officer. However, the Congress MLA from the adjacent constituency, Umeshwar Pratap Singh, wished to have the station officer transferred because the officer was not willing to accept his authority locally. Both the Superintendent of Police and Anand Singh wished to transfer the constables, but retain the local station officer, whom they both considered to be a good and loyal (to them) police officer. Umeshwar Pratap, therefore, joined with the opposition to protest against the police atrocities committed at Kurman Purwa. At this point, Anand Singh and the Superinten­ dent of Police considered it best to have all the local officers, including the station officer, transferred in order to defuse the situation. When the station officer was transferred, Umeshwar Pratap withdrew from the protest, which then became entirely an opposition affair. Opposition involvement took two forms. The runner-up candidate for MLA in the constituency in which the incident D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 330 St11te and Politia in India occurred, an attorney and local leader of the Democratic Socialist Party (DSP), rushed to the village and made inquiries on the spot. He also agreed to act as attorney on behalf of the villagers. Second, in cooperation with the local Communist party, he or­ ganized political protest meetings on 27 July and 9 August 1982. To these meetings, CPI and DSP leaders from all parts of the district and several state party leaders also came. The opposition leaders demanded that a judicial inquiry be held into the police atrocity at Kw-man Purwa, that the cases pending against the innocent villagers of Kurman Purwa be withdrawn, and that the police personnel involved in the incidents be punished. None of the opposition demands were conceded. Anand Singh did not intervene beyond seeing to the transfer of the officers. He clearly wanted the incident to be kept as quiet as possible. Although he was not able to keep it out of the hands of the opposition and the press entirely, it did not acquire anywhere near the publicity associated with the Narainpur incident. There are three versions of the reasons for the police atrocities. One is that it arose out of a quarrel between a Kahar villager of Kurman Purwa and a Gosain of the neighbouring village in which the Gosain enlisted the aid of the police on the basis of friendship and/or bribery to retaliate against the Kahar. The second is that the Kahar and other villagers of Kurman Purwa who deal in cattle had a successful day at the Tuesday cattle market in Colonelganj and that the police learned that they had made some money and. went to the village to rob them. The third version is that the police went to Kunnan Purwa for some reason or other and were beaten by drunken villagers, after which the police returned with a larger party. In one variation on this version, both the villagers and the police were drunk. Whichever account one accepts of the Kunnan Purwa incident, it is of a different type from the Narainpur incident. In Narainpur, an accident precipitated a quarrel between the villagers and the police in which it is not at all clear who struck first, though there is not much doubt that the police struck last and hardest. In Kunnan Purwa, most accounts of the incident suggest an un­ provoked attack by the local police on the villagers, precipitated in most versions by enmity between persons of neighbouring villages of clifferent castes. H�re, then, were solid materials for a ca,;e to be made of police D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Political Process: Dominance 331 atrocities committed against persons of low and backward caste origins. However, such an issue can be expanded only through collaboration between locally knowledgeable politicians and inter­ ested outside leaders. Since the Congress controlled the con­ stituency and the district, it was in the interests of the local MLA and Anand Singh to keep the issue quiet and to settle it peacefully, without further fuss. They were prevented from doing so by the activities of a renegade Congress Ml.A. whose sole interest in the matter was to get the local police officers who refused to obey him transferred, and by the local opposition politicians who naturally wished to capitalize on_ the issue. The Congress MLA's activities were stopped by satisfying his demands. Anand Singh, at ftrst reluctant to transfer the station officer, ultimately agreed to do so when it became clear that the local police were continuing to harass the villagers. The activities of the local opposition could not be stopped, but they were not deeply threatening because the opposition parties involved were the least effective ones in the politics of the district and the state. The two leading opposition parties in UP, the Lok Dal and the Bharatiya Janata Party, had no interest in becoming involved in an incident from which other parties stood to gain. The central political significance of the Kurman Purwa incident is its clear demonstration of the national importance of effective local control over the police. Before and since the Kurman Purwa i.ncident, the most powerful political leader of the district, Anand Singh, has had to face challenges to his and the SP's control over the district police from a local CongressMLA who himself wishes to control the police in his area for his own purposes. In the Kurman Purwa incident, the police broke free of all political constraints, thereby providing the potential for a symbolic political issue of state and national importance focusing on police atrocities and victimization of middle and low caste people. The incident probably had very little, if anything, to do with caste victimization. It does, however, reveal the local police in a characteristic mode - implicated directly in local conflicts, open to bribery, capable of loot and harassment of innocent persons, and a potential danger to the exercise of national power when they cannot be controlled effectively at the local level and cannot be used to restrain and conceal potentially embarrassing situations instead of creating them. Although the police in Gonda, as in Deoria district, thus __ o,g,t,zeo by Go_ggle Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 332 St11te 11nd Politics in /ndill provided the opposition with a symbolic issue to be used against the ruling party, they were prevented from doing so partly by circumst2nces and partly by quick action taken by Anand Singh to defuse the situation. The circumstances include the relative ineffectiveness of the local opposition, the non-involvement of major opposition leaders from outside the district, and the fact that the state legislative assembly was not in session at the time. However, Anand Singh's role was also important in keeping the matter under control. In this way he demonstrates his value to the leadership at the centre through his ability to prevent the opposi­ tion from using a local incident as a symbolic resource in the national political arena as well as to deliver votes in the district. Conclusion The four brief case studies that I have presented from two districts in one state of north India cannot tell us everything that we want to know about the relationships between national power and local politics and the changes that have taken place in the relationships between the two during the past twenty years. However, I believe . they illustrate some critical features of the ways in which the Indian system of federal politics works and the ways in which it has changed. The following features are fundamental to under­ standing both. First, national power lacks a furn institutional base independent of government. Twenty years ago, there were two principal in­ stitutional avenues towards and sources of, national power - the Indian National Congress and the Government of India. More­ over, they were interdependent Politicians could move back and forth between the two and use one as a base for influence in the other. To ignore one and concentrate on the other, moreover, was the surest way to ensure that one's tenure of power would be brief. Nowadays, the party organizational avenue to national power is closed. Second, when the Congress was a major avenue to power in Indian politics; it was also in touch with the people in the districts and localities. It was an instrument of information and knowledge as well as of power. Or rather, it was powerful because its members and leaders had roots in the villages and towns throughout the countryside. Assuch, it was a formidable instrument for gatherµig Dlgltlzedby Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Political Process: Duminance 333 votes. In north India at least, the Congress as such is no longer a significant electoral machine. Yet Mrs Gandhi and the Congress continue to win elections, usually with greater pluralities than other parties in most states and in the country as a whole. How is it done? Two methods are now used. One is to attempt to nationalize issues and to appeal to blocs of voters through such issues. The second, which lias been the princ;ipal method discussed in this article, is to work through local notables who are believed to maintain an extensive structure of local power or some other broad base of local influence that can be used to gather votes. An example of the first method is Mrs Gandhi's slogan of 'garibi h/ltll()' (abolish poverty), which has been part of her broad appeal to the poor and landless of the country and has involved the introduction of many government programmes for their benefit. Other examples include Congress and non-Congress slogans, ap­ peals to, and programmes for, the benefit of backward _classes, Muslims and other minorities, scheduled castes, and the middle peasantry. It is in this context that violence in the countryside is particularly relevant, for it provides a convenient basis for sym­ bolizing the plight of certain categories of voters. Mrs Gandhi and other politicians do not visit these scenes of violence only to shed tears, btit with very clear and specific political goals in mind. The attempt to nationalize politics and create national con­ stituencies of voters has been only partly successful: only certain categories of voters have been affected; even fewer have developed stable loyalties to the Congress or to non-Congress parties; and i t has not displaced local considerations for most categories of voters. The attempt has, however, been successful enough to make the parliamentary and legislative assembly elections far more ex­ citing than in Nehru's days for the results have, in the last decade, turned partly upon big swin gs in the voting patterns of large categories of voters, particularly in the north, leading to great electoral 'waves' such as the 'Indira waves' of 1971 and 1980 and the Janata wave of 1977. It is in the hope of precipitating such waves by moving blocs of voters that politicians in India manipu­ late and exploit such incidents of violence as that at Narainpur. However, such shifts in voting patterns by large blocs of voters are only part of the story, especially in determining the results of state legislative assembly elections. In the districts, structures of Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 334 St11tt and Politia m l111U11 local power persist that are sometimes strong enough to stand aga�t a wave and are even more critical when there is no wave. These local structures of power are also critical in preventing local incidents of violence from being exploited in wider arenas to precipitate such waves, as in Kurman Purwa. Therefore, links must be established and maintll.ined with persons who can still control or are perceived to rontrol a local clientage, or a local bloc of votes. My third point, therefore, is that the continuing importance of the localities and districts of India and of local structures of power in a society so diverse and fragmented as India means that central­ ization of power cannot be truly effective in that country under a representative regime. I have tried in the examples given in this article to show that the system is, in fact, not really centralized but is based upon linkages of dependency among different levels and particularly between the centre and the districts. My fourth concluding point is that there are three main per­ sisting sources of power in contemporary Indian politics outside the electoral process. The first is government, that is to say government patronage and protection. Government is the source of valued goods and services in contemporary India, from seeds and fertilizers to government jobs to places in educational in­ stitutions to whole factories. Control of government is also the main source of protection: from harassment by its own officers on such matters as enforcement of land ceilings, or from police violence. The second source of power is a persisting structure or network of influence such as arises from control over the land or prestige within a local caste group. The third source of power arises from networks of kin-clan-cast e -personal ties in groups that interpenetrate party, bureaucracy, and educational institutions. -It is through such a network, for example, that it is believed that C.P.N. Singh became close to Sanjay Gandhi and rose to become a minister in the central government. It should be noted, moreover, that all three of these sources of power are interdependent. Government patronage is meaningless without persons and groups to whom it is to be distributed. Local structures of power cannot persist without control over or in­ fluence in government institutions. Networks of group and per­ sonal influence are important most of all because they give access to government patronage by 1neans other than party or a local Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Political Process: Dominance 335 ' structure of power. Such networks extend throughout north India. They are innumerable and pervasive. They are more important than party ties. In such a system, which I have described elsewhere as highly pluralized, decentralized, and fragmented,25 politicians may try to build national power in two ways. They may do so by careful, patient cultivation of linkages from top to bottom through bar­ gaining, compromise, and exchange. They may also attempt to bypass the persisting structures of government, local and group power through appeals to large categories of voters on transcen­ dent or very dramatic issues. The fust pattern is a politics of patronage. In Nehru's days, it involved building power from below, leaving satraps in com­ mand at the district and state levels, and leaving national policy­ making to the cabinet, the Planning Commission, and the senior bureaucrats. The second pattern is a politics of crisis that plays upon or manufactures dramatic issues. It is a pattern that has often been used by Mrs Gandhi and distinguishes her political style significantly from that of her father. The second pattern, however, does not really transcend but only covers or attempts to hide a persistent politics of patronage that, as I have noted, involves linkages of mutual dependency between the centre and the districts, with the centre prepared to hand over whole districts to individuals, sometimes with advantageous, sometimes with disadvantageous results. The system, therefore, shifts back and fonh between jobbery and demagoguery and fails to confront effectively major issues concerning the economic future of India and the spread of lawlessness and violence in the countryside. 25 Paul R. Brass, 'Pluralism, Regionalism, and Decentraliung Tendencies i n Contemporary Indian Politics', in A. Jeyaramam Wilson and Dennis Dalton (eds), Tbt Statu ofSouth Asilt: Probltms ofN11tirmal Integration (London: C. Hurst, I982), pp. 223-64. Digiti zed by Google Ongmal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 9 From Breakdown to Order: West Bengal Atul Kohli "l X Test Bengal is something of an exception in India's contem­ VV porary political landscape. Whereas many states have ex­ perienced political instability over the past two decades, West Bengal has been relatively well governed since 1977. That stability has been remarkable because it has not been the result o f low levels of political mobilization; West Bengal was probably India's most politically mobilized and chaotic state in the late 1960s. West Bengal's restoration and maintenance of political order naturaJly direct our attention to the issue of how growing crises of gover­ nability can be reversed. This chapter traces the roots of West Bengal's recent stability to the fact that a well-organized reformist party has remained in power. The Communist Party of India, Marxist (CPl[M]}, has repeatedly been elected to office in West Bengal since 1977. The party is communist in name onJy and is essentially social­ democratic in its ideology, social programme, and policies. The party's disciplined, effective organization has minimized the de­ bilitating elite factionalism and the relatea elite-led mobilization and counter-mobilization so common in some other states. The CPI(M) has also consolidated a coalition of the middle and lower strata by implementing some modest redistributive programmes. That systematic incorporation of the poor has reduced the attrac­ tiveness of populism and its emphasis on deinstirutionalization. And 6.nally, the CPl(M) has adopted a non-threatening approach toward property-owning groups, whose roles in production and economic growth remain essential for the long-term welfare of the state. Dlgltlzedby Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Political Process: Dominance 337 The CPl(M)'s rule in West Bengal has not been without its share of problems. The CPl(M) may be well organized, but its relations with other parties, especially other leftist parties, have occasionally led to political discord. Two years of ethnic strife in one of West Bengal's sixteen districts- the 'Gorkhaland' troubles in Darjeeling - cast doubt on the CPI(M)'s capacity to accommodate non-class types of conflicts. The CPl(M)'s attempts to maintain an alliance of the middle and lower groups have generated serious problems for its ongoing programme of redistribution. Moreover, like other ruling communist parties elsewhere, the CPI(M) is beginning to give rise to a 'new class' of privileged members who are resented by those excluded from the perks of power. The CPl(M) type of rule in West Bengal does not offer a model for the rest of India. Even if it did, there are historical and cultural reasons because of which it would not be likely to be replicated. Thus a discussion of the West Bengal experience serves not a prescriptive purpose but an important analytical fwiction. In spite of its many problems, West Bengal under the CPl(M) is probably India's best-governed state: the coalition that supports the CPl(M) is relatively stable; the gap between the government's commitments and its capacities is modest; and political violence along caste, class, o r religious lines has been minimal. An understanding of how the CPl(M) has achieved such effective government tends to re-enforce m y earlier emphasis on the political causes of the governability crisis in India. The Background West Bengal is relatively industrialized, but it also has more rural poverty than many other states in India.1 The roots of its industry 1 This d,iscussion builds on my earlier work on West Bengal politics: Atul Kohli, 1 From Elite Activism to Democratic Consolidation: Political Change in West Bengal', i n Francine Frankel and M.S.A. Rao (eds), Domiffllfl(t 11114 St11tt Prt11Jtr inModn-n lndi11: Dtelim ofII SrxilllOrdtr, 2 vols (Oxford University Press, 1989-90), vol. 2; idem, Tbt Sutt 11114 PU1Jmy in lndill: Tbt Politia of Rtform (Cambridge University Press, 1987), chapter 3; ide1n, 'Communist Reformers in West Bengal: Origins, Features and Relations with New Delhi', in John R Wood (ed.), St11tt Politia in Crmtmipor'"] lndu,: Crisisor Crmtmuityl (Boulder, Colo.: Westvicw Press, 1984), pp. 81-102; idem, 'Parliamentary Communism and Agrarian Reform: The Evidence from India's Bengal',Asum Survey,July 1983, pp. 783-809. D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm ·- UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 338 State 11nd Politics in India are traceable back to the colonial period, as are the origins of its agrarian structure, which supports a large population on little land. The agrarian structure has undergone some important chan­ ges since the zmnindari abolition. Towards the bottom of the landownership hierarchy, nearly half the population owns no land o r has access to less than one acre of land.2 These are the rural poor. In the recent past, a substantial rural minority used to be tenant farmers. That, however, has changed over the past decade. Legislative and political changes introduced by the CPI(M) g6v­ ernment have modified the old forms of tenancy; new arrange­ ments have emerged under which tenants enjoy almost permanent leases on land. The pattern of landholding in the middle range (1-10 acres) h as changed only minimally over the past three decades. The big changes have come at the top of the pyramid. Both the area under cultivation and the number of farmers cultivating large landhold­ ings (above 10 acres) have declined. That reflects both the pressure of land reform legislation and, more important, the division of property at inheritance. The agrarian structure of contemporary West Bengal is characterized by numerous cultivators with access to middle- and small-size landholdings and a very substantial population of landless labourers. Certain peculiarities of the caste and community make up of West Bengal are also important. Nearly half the population of the state is not 'mainstream' Hindu. It comprises rather scheduled castes and tribes (27 .5 per cent) and Muslims (20 per cent). Among the Hindus, moreover, the caste divisions do not follow the 'normal' fourfold division.3 There are no indigenous Kshatriyas or Vaishyas in Bengal. The numbers of the twice-born castes are also relatively small (about 7 per cent), certainly in comparison with the neighbouring state of Bihar. The line of demarcation between Brahmans and such 'clean Sudras' as Vaidyas and Kayas­ thas is not sharp. The Brahmans will 'take water' from these clean Sudras, though intermarriage remains rare. 2 For land datll, see Kohli, The St11te tmdPwmy;,, lndui, Table 3.4 on p. 118, and for more detailed discussion of the changing agrarian sttucture, see chapter 3. l Srudies of caste in Bengal includeJyotirmoyee Sarma, Caste Dy,um,ia RNmg the Bengali Hindus (Calcutt.I: Firma KLM Private Ltd. 1980); Hitesranjan Sanyal, Social Mobility m Bmgal (Calcutt.I: Papyrus, 1981). Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Political Process: Dominance 339 The patterns of landownership according to caste in West Bengal have important political consequences. Many Brahmans in West Bengal, as in other states, own sizable pieces of land. How­ ever, landownership by caste in West Bengal is extremely hetero­ geneous. There are no castes that can be considered dominant statewide. In addition to the Brahmans, other clean Sudras like the Kayasthas are concentrated in certain districts and own con­ siderable amounts of land there. In other districts, landownership is in the hands of 'lower Sudras' who farm, such as the Sadgops, Namasudras, Aguris and Kaivartas.4 Unlike the situation in many other Indian states, therefore, political concerns in West Bengal do not readily crystallize along statewide caste cleavages. Although caste remains politically significant at the local ·level, the absence of dominant castes at the state level opens up possibilities for political parties to forge coalitions along lines other than caste. Both in the cities and in the countryside of Bengal, the domina­ tion of the privileged over their subordinates was not as con­ solidated as in many other parts of India. Thus the Bengali lower castes and classes provided radicalizable political material. s Al­ though we should not overestimate lower class radicalism in con­ temporary West Bengal, the fact is that mere elite radicalism, without peasant and worker support for the CPJ(M), could not have led to a democratically elected communist government. Another important factor in the success of the left in West Behgal has been an effective, centralized political party. I have argued elsewhere that the origins of that can be traced to the terrorist backgrounds of many communist leaders.6 Thus a signi­ ficant minority of Bengali political activists already understood the significance of disciplined organizations before they were introduced to communism.' Such recent communist leaders as 4 For an excellent historical study that traces how that pattern ofcontrol over land evolved, see Ramalekha Ray, Change in Bmga/ Agr11rilm S«itty, 17601850 (New Delhi: Manohar, 1979). S For discussion of labour activism in the first half of this century, see R.C. Majumdar, History ofBmgal, (Calcutta: G. Bhardwaj, 1971-8) vol. 4. 6 See Kohli, 'From Elite Activism to Democratic Consolidation'. For histori­ cal details of Bengal's terrorist past, see Majumdar, History ofBmglli, vol. 4, chapter 5. 7 For interviews that establish links between 'old terrorists' and the 'new communists', see Gautam Chattopadhyay, Communism and Bmg11/'s FrttM111 M1111emtnt (New Delhi: PPH, 1970). Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 340 State and Politu:s in India Pramode Das Gupta, Hare Krishna Konar and Binoy Chowdhury were all former terrorist revolutionaries who later convened to communism. Having embraced the new ideology, the organiza­ tional principles of democratic centralism must have come easily to that group. Discipline, hierarchy, and party before all else were the values integral to the political terrorist subculture. In all probability, those political-cultural traditions have facilitated the growth of relatively cohesive parties in contemporary West Ben­ gal. Of course, this is not to ignore the legendary factionalism and sectarianism of the Indian left.8 Nevenheless, the CPl(M) in West Bengal stands out today as a cohesive political force in India, and the long tradition of disciplined organization is at least partly responsible for this political characteristic. By the time of Independence, radical politics had already es­ tablished strong roots in Bengal. A small but significant number of the political elite had embraced communism; and the lower classes - workers and peasants - had shown ample susceptibility to radical appeals. The political traditions of the area further enabled the radical elite to organize a small but disciplined party, which would in time grow into the ruling party. None of this should lead to a view that Congress was an in­ significant force in post-Independence West Bengal. On the con­ trary, Congress in West Bengal, as elsewhere in India, emerged as the most popular party. The Congress party was India's nationalist party, and West Bengal, though somewhat on the periphery, was still very much a part of India. Thus the euphoria of nationalism carried West Bengal along and led to the Congress's electoral victory in West Bengal. Bengali leaders like Atulya Ghosh and B.C. Roy, who were close to Nehru, were able to ride the wave of first generation nationalism; they formed popular governments that ruled West Bengal for nearly fifteen years.9 The historical factors that contributed to Congress's weakness have already been mentioned. A few additional changes following Independence further reinforced those tendencies. First, many among the Bengali elite held Congress responsible for the parti­ tion and loss of nearly half of Bengal to Pakistan. Thus Inde­ pendence had been a mixed blessing for the Bengalis: as part of 8 The theme offactionalism was emphasized by Marcus Fnnda, RildiCJIJPo/ma in Wtst Bmglll (Ca�bridge, Mass.: M.I.T. Press, 1972). 9 Ibid. Dig itized by Ongmal from Goqgle - - - UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Political Process: D1m1in111Ue 341 India, they had gained sovereignty; as a region with a strong 'subnational' identity, however, they had suffered considerable loss. The historical ambiguity of the Bengalis toward Congress was only reinforced. Second, zamindari abolition in the 1950s eliminated the inter- · mediaries between the government and thejotedars. It was the latter who controlled land and exercised influence at the village level. Unlike the situation in other parts of India, the emergence of fatedars as local influentials did not always bode well for the Con­ gress. Although those groups had benefited from Congress's ac­ tions, and thus quite a few were attracted to the national party, there were many such village-level influentials who had opposed Con­ gress in the pre-Independence period. Thus their loyalty to the Congress was tenuous. Bengalijotedars were also heterogeneous in terms of their caste composition. They could not easily be as­ sembled to form a cohesive caste base for the Congress party, as were, for example, the Vokkaligas and the Lingayats in Karnataka, or the Kammas and the Reddis in Andhra Pradesh. Finally, the already precarious political hold of the landowning castes over their subordinates was further weakened as adult suffrage spread and new attempts at mass political mobilization were undertaken. TABLE 9.1 Seats Won by Major Political Parties in West Bengal Assembly Elections 1952-1987 l Congress CPl(M) CPI Forward Bloc Suurre: Notes: -- - r:--- °' i--. ¥"' 'C 'C t'-t'-Oo °' °' °' °' °' °' °' °' °' °' ... ... ... ... ... ... ... � r:--- � 150 152 157 127 55 28 46 50 43 80 16 30 14 8 13 13 21 � � 105 216 20 49 40 113 14 177 174 .187 13 35 2 7 11 3 0 25 28 26 Computed from the reports of the Election Commission. a The other significant parries that have come and gone and are not listed here include the Bangla Congress, the Praja Socialist Party, and the Revolutionary Socialist Party. The latter continues to be significant; it won 20, 19 and 18 seats in the 1977, 1982 and 1987 assembly elections, respectively. b The newly fonnedJanata party won 29 seats in 1977, only tovanish completely in the 1982 elections. c Data from /ndu, Todlly, lS April 1987. D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 342 St11te 11nd Politics in buiitz Thus the Congress in West Bengal never put down deep roots. Prior to Independence, the Congress had never led a government in the British-controlled legislatures. Following Independence, Congress inherited natiorwist legitimacy and thus managed to rule West Bengal for nearly fifteen years. Both before and after that fifteen-year interregnum, West Bengal was controlled by a n o nCongress political force. Therefore, those fifteen years ap­ pear in retrospect to have been exceptional. As Table 9.1 shows, the Congress in West Bengal has steadily lost its electoral base since 1962. What has captured the Bengali political imagination is a party that has emphasized the themes of regional nationalism and the anti-rich solidarity of the middle and lower classes. The Decade of Chaos 1967-1977 The story of the changing patterns of politics in West Bengal is illustrated in Figure. 9.1. The data support a commonly held impression: there was significant increase in political violence and rioting in the late 1960s and early 1970s in West Bengal. The fairly sharp decline shown in 1972 appears more significant than it was, because in the aftermath of the Bangladesh war, Indira Gandhi virtually obliterated democratic politics in West Bengal and utilized state terror to eliminate many of the revolutionary groups. A 'normal' political process resumed only in 1977, and under the CPl(M) government the level of political violence has actually declined. The main analytical components of the West Bengal story are fairly straightforward. The decline of the Congress in the mid1960s created a power vacuum within West Bengal that was not filled until 1977, when the CPl(M) emerged as the new ruling party. The intervening period was a period of turmoil. Coalitional instability and the related ineffectiveness of the government com­ bined with socio-economic conflict to yield civil disorder and political instability. The electoral decline of the Congress in the mid- l 960s was a nationwide phenomenon. In that limited sense West Bengal was part of a national trend. But a number of factors exacerbated the impact of Congress's decline in West Bengal: the first generation nationalist leaders had passed away and no one arose to take charge of the West Bengal Congress. More than in many other states, Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The PolitiCIII Process: Dominance 343 400 300 200 100 1955 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 Fipn 9.1 PolitiuJ Viokn« in West Bengal 1955-1985 (number ofriots pa-million popuilltion) Nou: The data for 1955-82 are from an annual publication: Government of India, Ministry of Home Affairs, Crime in lndiil (New Delhi: Gov­ ernment Press). Data for 1_ 983 and 1984 are not available. The figure for 1985 is an estimate provided by government officials. Congress in West Bengal had remained a personalistic force. 'Tall leaders' like Atulya Ghosh and B.C. Roy had managed to create a party machine that kept factionalism within limits and helped tnnsform nationalist aspirations into electoral victories. Aher the death of B.C. Roy in 1962, however, Congress's factionalism became more obvious. Even before the national Congress party experienced its major electoral setback in 1967, the Congress in West Bengal had split; the fo�ation of the offshoot party, the Bangla Congress, further weakened the centrist alternative that Congress had offered within West Bengal. Second, two consecutive droughts in the mid-l960s had led to food shortages, inflationary pressures, and political difficulties for the Congress throughout India. The situation was especially dif­ ficult in West Bengal. Following the partition, West Bengal had l'llken in more refugees than any other state in India. That had Digiti zed by Google Ongmal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 344 State and Politia in India increased the demand for food, especially grain. The partition had created another disequilibrium: a large proposition of the state's arable land had come to be devoted to the production of cash crops. Prior to partition, F.ast Bengal had produced many of the raw materials necessary for industrial production. As those sources of supply began to be cut off, the scarcity of raw materials led to high prices; the 'rational peasant' began producing cash crops. An un­ fortunate side effect was a decline in food production. Thus the impact of the mid-l960s drought in West Bengal was fairly serious. A third important factor that was at work in West Bengal in the mid- l960s was the significant political presence of leftist parties. The leftist parties, including the undivided Communist Party of India (CPI), the Forward Bloc, and the Revolutionary Socialist Party, had won respectable numbers of seats in both the 1957 and 1962 elections (Table 9.1). Their collective share of the vote in each election was more than one-third of the total. They had taken advantage of a faction-ridden Congress confront­ ing a worsening food situation and declining popularity. Food shortages, especiallf, provided a significant issue for political mobilization. Strikes and demonstrations against the Congress government became common. As Figure 9.1 shows, rioting and violence continued to increase throughout 1965 and 1966, leading up to the crucial elections in 1967. It was at those elections that the Congress was finally defeated. Congress remained the largest single party within West llengal; it won 127 of the 280 assembly seats (Table 9.1). A number of other parties, however, including the two main communist parties (the CPI had split into the CPI[M] and CPI in 1964) and the Bangla Congress, succeeded in forming a United Front (UF) coalition government. The formation of the UF government in 1967 led to a decade of chaos in West Bengal. The ftrst UF government lasted less than a year. It was replaced, for two months, by a Congress-led coalition. When that also came apart, presidential rule was imposed. A second UF government was formed in 1969; it was also replaced by presid­ ential rule in 1970. A coalition government with the Congress as the leading force again came to power in 1971; that also did not last long. Aft.er the Bangladesh war in 1971, Congress fmally swept to power with a huge majority, but under a considerable cloud of suspicion of electoral fraud. The democratic process in West Bengal was resumed only after the 1977 elections. Digiti zed by Google Ongmal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Political Process: Duminance 345 Figure 9.1 shows the sharp increase in political violence that accompanied governmental instability between 1967 and 1971. The data indicating that increase were collected by the police and did not include figures on the state terror unleashed against various political groups during 1972-7. The independent group Amnesty International has documented the extent of the violence. 10 A de­ scriptive conclusion is inescapable: the decade of 1967-77 in West Bengal politics was characterized by a severe govemability 'Crisis. What were the roots of that crisis? The causal dynamics clearly were quite complex. Both socio-economic conflict and anomic unrest played their parts. The decisive variables, however, were political. It is clear in retrospect that coalitional instability during that period made the government relatively ineffective as an agent of law and order, and that opened the door for a variety of conflicts. Moreover, competing factions among the political elite mobilized their forces, over which they soon lost control, thus adding to the chaos. And finally, Indira Gandhi used the cloak of the Bangladesh war to impose presidential rule and eliminate many of her armed political enemies. The crisis subsided only after resumption of the democratic process in the 1977 elections and the electoral victory of a relatively cohesive political party. Both the cities and the countryside o( West Bengal were en­ gulfed in political violence during that period. Violence was mainly of two types: seemingly 'revolutionary class violence', typified by the rebellion in Naxalbari, and the land grab movements en­ couraged by the UF government, especially by the CPI(M). Before analysing those factors, it is important to recall some of the traits of the UF government. The ideologically divergent parties within the UF were nearly as wary of each other as they were of the Congress. They spent considerable energy devising political strategies that could help transform their temporary hold on government into an expanded political base. The CPI(M) was the major force in that coalition government, especially after 1969. The CPl(M) adhered to a more revolutionary line during that period. It defined its main task in government as 'expanding and strengthening worker and peasant alliance'. In practice, that led to a two-pronged political strategy: neutralizing the tendency of 10 The reportwas discussed byMarcus Franda, 'Rural Development, Bengali Marxist Style', American Universities Field Staff Reports, Asia, no. 15, 1978, p. 4. D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 346 St11te and Politia in India the state to be an agent of 'class repression' from above, and using its party organization to mobiliu the lower classes from below. The CPI(M) repeatedly sought and eventually gained control over the ministries of labour, land and land revenue, and home (which controlled the police). An important aspect of the CPl(M)'s ruling strategy - an aspect that would eventuaJly con­ tribute heavily to the fall of the UF government - was to order the police not to interfere in 'class struggles'. The CPI(M) thus neutralized the regional state apparatus as an agent of political order. Whatever the merits of such a strategy for fomenting revolution in nation states in general, as a regional strategy its effectiveness was highly doubtful. The CPl(M) had only neutral­ ized the 'near state' and thus invited the wrath of the more 'distant state' (i.e. invited federal intervention). It took the CPI(M) some time to internalize one of the hard lessons of realpolitik: its powers were lim.ited. Meanwhile, the neutralization of the police provided encouragement for many of the subsequent conflicts within West Bengal. The best-known peasant rebellion of the period clearly was the conflict in Naxalbari in the north of West Bengal. There have been thorough studies of that rebellion. 11 For our purposes, its details are not important. What is important is to find the main causes of the rebellion. General explanations in tenns of 'exploitation' of the peasantry, though clearly part of the overall equation, will not suffice, because peasant exploitation in India is widespread, but rebellions are not. The Naxalbari rebellion, moreover, was not really a peasant rebellion; its protagonists were mainly semi-nomadic tribals, the Santhals. Not being socialized in the rigid and hierarchical Hindu caste structure, the Santhals of the area had often rebelled in the past. The border location of Naxalbari facilitated- revolutionary organization. In addition, tea plantations dominated the local agriculture in Naxalbari, and they provided better conditions for political organization than would the atomistic family-owned smaJl farms common in many ·other areas. Given those contributing 'ecological' conditions, the decisive 11 See, for exan1ple; Shanlcar Ghosh, Tht Nualitt Movtmmt (Calcutta: K.L. Mukhopadhyay, 1974), especially pp. 24-35; Biplab Dasgupta, Tht NIIZlliitt Movement (Bombay: Allied Publishers, 1975), especially pp. 1-14; Franda, Radical Politia in West Bengal, chapter 6. Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Political Process: D'1mmtmct 347 causes of the rebellion were political. The local Santhals had been organized by a militant subgroup of the CPl(M). After the CPI(M) came to power in 1967, the local party officers decided to take advantage of their new power. They undertook a militant land grab movement. Local tribals, armed with primitive bows and arrows and spears, provided the main force for the movement. The tribals claimed 'above-ceiling' land to be legally theirs. (fhere was legislation on the books stipulating a ceiling on the amount of land that one could own.) They forcibly occupied such land, and, if necessary, they killed the landlords, thus establishing 'liberated' areas. That land grab 1novement spread to some sixty villages and lasted nearly two months. It is clear in retrospect that the move­ ment would not have gained strength but for the fact that the UF government, especially the CPI(M), decided to keep the police out of the conflict. A militant peasant rebellion led by the CPl(M)'s own cadres had put the CPI(M) leaders in a dilemma: the CJ,>I(M) in government was responsible for protecting basic constitutional rights, including the rights to private property and life; however, the CPI(M) was reluctant to use state repression against its own revolutionary cadres. The CPI(M) sought to resolve that dilemma by pursuing a two-pronged strategy: keeping the police out of the conflict, and simultaneously trying to impose the party line on its own cadres. The CPl(M)'s strategy failed. The local cadres con­ tinued to undertake militant mobilization, including the killing of landowners in the name of 'revolutionary justice'. Because the scope of the 'revolution' was limited to one comer of one region ·m a giant-size nation state, the results were predictable. Eventually the CPl(M) had to dismiss the leaders ofNaxalbari from the party, and the UF government ordered the police back into Naxalbari to restore order. The 'revolutionary movement' collapsed within weeks. Most of the leaders were imprisoned. The ease with which the entire movement was crushed strongly sup­ ports the argument that the temporary withdrawal of state �wer had been the most important factor in the short-term success of the Naxalbari uprising. To the extent that such deliberate absten­ tion from the use of state power is a somewhat unusual occurrence in functioning states, theNaxalbari uprising can be viewed as an aberration. More generally, a broader insight of comparative pol­ itics also gains support from that experience: disintegration of state D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 348 St11te and Politics in India power may well be an important precondition for transformation of latent socio-economic hostilities into overt conflict. 12 Before analysing other types of agrarian conflicts during that period, especially those led by the CPI(M) itself, it is important to note that both the temporary success of the Naxalbari uprising and the subsequent state repression had significant political con­ sequences. The uprising led to the creation of a third communist party, a Marxist-Leninist party that did not believe in parliamen­ tary democracy, but instead was committed to fomenting a revolu­ tion by following a 'Maoist' strategy of 'armed struggle'. The temporary success of the uprising created an overinflated sense of efficacy among the Naxalites; they began acting as if a Chinese­ style peasant revolution was possible in India. The participation of the CPI(M) in the government that repressed the Naxalbari uprising alienated the more militant Bengalis from the CPI(M)'s 'reformism'. Thus the stage was set for battle: an alienated milit­ ant minority whose members had recently renewed their sense of political efficacy versus a fragmented state. that, in spite of its strong leftist orientation, stood delegitimized in the eyes of the militants. That same theme of the role of an ineffective state, or, more precisely, a state deliberately made ineffective, ran through the other major agrarian conflict of the period, namely the land grab movements initiated by the CPI(M). For reasons of both ideologi­ cal commitment and power, the CPI(M) leadership was committed to expanding its peasant base. The brief pockets ofNaxalite success had shown how strongly the peasants felt about the 'land question'. Not wanting to be left behind, the CPI(M) began pursuing its own limited version of land grab movements. Hare Krishna Konar was the CPl(M)'s radical land minister. He sought to identify and to redistribute all bmami lands (above­ ceiling lands registered under false names) and to ensure the occupancy rights of sharecroppers. Because the CPI(M) was not fully in control of the government, it could not use the state machinery to attain those goals. Instead, its strategy was, again, to keep the state - especially the police, but also local administrators and, if possible, the courts - out of land conflicts and to use 12 For a broader statement of this hypothesis with reference to co111parative and historical material s, see Theda Skocpol, St11tts 1111d Sod11I RroolutianI (Cambridge University Press, 1979). Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Political P,·ocess: l)(),njnm,ce 349 party-led mobilization to implement land refonns.13 Because of the short durations of the two UF governments, major redistribu­ tion did not occur. The important aspect of that experiment, therefore, was not any concrete realization of the redistribution programme but rather the political dynamics set in motion. The CPl(M) sought to limit the reach of the state from above and to mobilize from below. Two important consequences fol­ lowed. First, even limited gains by the CPl(M) were politically threatening to the other partners in the coalition government Every redistributive success meant new and more loyal supporters for the CPl(M). The membership of the CPI(M)-affiliated Kisan Sabha (the peasant organization) rose during that period from approximately a quarter of a million to more than half a million. The other coalition partners did not want to be left out of the game of political competition. They sought to enter the fray, attempting their own versions of land redistribution, sometimes even competing with the CPl(M) over the same piece of land. As one analyst pointed out, 'there were innumerable physical clashes between the major political parties in the United Front between 1969-70 in which two or more parties attempted to seize the same plot of land'. 14 Clearly, political competition within the ruling coalition became a source of socio-economic conflict and violence. A second consequence was that the CPl(M) leadership often failed to control its own 'enthusiastic' local cadres, which led to 'excesses' in land grabbing and to nwnerous physical clashes. During my fieldwork in the early 1980s, for example, a number of local observers reported that the party line on the land question under Hare Krishna Konar was quite confusing. Konar, on the one hand, would trwnpet revolutionary rhetoric, suggesting that militant confiscation of land was integral to the party's pro­ gramme. On the other hand, the real party line was to act with restraint on the issue, that is to use the land programme differen­ tially according to local circwnstances and mainly to enhance the party's electoral and organizational position. The need to make adjusnnents for local variations necessitated a decentralized strat­ egy. Not all local cadres, however, were totally clear on how far and how fast the land programme should move. The more 13 For details, see Franda, Radie•/Politicsin West Bmg"', especially pp. 182-90. 14 Ibid., p. 184. Digiti zed by Google Ongmal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 350 State and Politics in India militant cadres chose to take Konar's highly rhetorical speeches as representative of the party line, and they moved fairly rapidly and decisively during 1969-70. l'hat was certainly true, for ex­ ample, in parts of Midnapore and 24 Parganas where I did fieldwork. The results were increasing nwnbers of physical clashes between landowners and CPI(M) cadres and a simultaneous rush of newspaper stories proclaiming the breakdown of law and order in West Bengal. The UF experiments in West Bengal created peculiar condi­ tions under which those who were in power, or, more precisely, exercised partial power, came to have a vested interest in foment­ ing radical mobilization. Political fragmentation within the state and deliberate, elite-led mobilization in the civil society thus com­ bined to generate considerable violence in the agrarian sector. The nature of the violence in West Bengal changed midway through the decade of chaos unleashed by the UF experiments. The second ftve years of the chaotic decade, especially the periods 1971-2 and 1975-7, were characterized by increasing state repres­ sion. Because the violence in that period was unleashed by the government, official statistics do not reflect it well. The exact numbers of 'revolutionaries' and other political enemies who were killed or imprisoned will never be known. There is no doubt, however, that the extent of such repression was significant. During my field visits to West Bengal in 1979-80, 1982, 1984 and 1986, nearly everyone I interviewed, including Congress leaders who were in a position to know,15 admitted that the government had committed atrocities during 1971-7. Scattered evidence gathered from those who were close to the situation during that continuing crisis of governability provides a picture of wide-ranging, brutal repression by the Congress government. After each of the two UF governments was dismissed, New Delhi established direct control over West Bengal. Two important 'administrative' changes created a fra1nework in which govern­ mental repression would be relatively free of constitutional con­ straints. First, it was decided that a police shooting would not require a 'compulsory executive inquiry'. That protection gave the I5 Especially relevant here was an interview with Subrato Mu.kerjee (Calcutta, 3 May 1986), who was West Bengal's Home Minister between 1972 and 1977. For references to pre-1984 interviews, see Kohli, The State and Puverty ·· in lndi•, chapter 3. Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN Tht Political Process: Dominance 351 police a free hand in their dealings with 'extremists', especially Naxalites. The second crucial change was that 'Naxalite problems' came to be assigned to the same detective department that was responsible for common criminals. Having thus abolished the distinction between political extremists and criminals, and having freed the police from virtually all political oversight, the govern­ ment had set the stage for state-sponsored terrorism. Two scholars, Sajal Basu, who is now an observer for Amnesty International in Calcutta, and Shankar Ghosh, who was a cor­ respondent at that time for the Times of India, independently recorded what they wimessed fust-hand during the early 1970s. 16 Their accounts help fill out the picture of what went on in those years. For example S:ijal Basu reported that Congress's electoral victory in 1972 was accompanied by 'widespread rigging and fraud'. During the period leading up to the election and imme­ diately thereafter, the police and the ma.rtans (hired hoodlums) unleashed what was known as 'white terror'. He described the aftermath of the UF experiment in the following terms: 'Pseudo­ revolutionary violence of the later sixties has been replaced by the counter-terrorism of the establishment that culminated in the violent election of 1972.' 17 Shankar Ghosh provided further details. For example he re­ ported that after the Birbhum Naxalite rebellion fizzled out, the consequences of'police action' were'not that there [were] no more killings; in fact the daily average was three to four, which was higher than the average during the peak period of the Naxalite movement'. 18 As another example the most brutal of the police massacres of Naxalites clearly was the Cossipore-Baranagar inci­ dent in the summer of 1971, six weeks after the establishn1ent of presidential rule in June 1971. More than 150 young men with Naxalite sympathies were murdered within days. Ghosh, who covered the story for the Hindusthtm Standard, reported that 'dead bodies were everywhere - bodies with heads cut off, limbs lost, eyes gouged out, entails ripped open. They were there in the streets in broad daylight. Later they were carried in rickshaws and 16 See Sajnl Basu, Wtst Bmgal: Tht Violmt Yt111T(Calcutta: Prachi Publications, 1979); Ghosh, Tht Naxalite Muvnnn:,t. 17 Basu, West Bmgal, pp. 80-3. 18 Ghosh, The Naxalite Muvnnmt, p. 155. -- -. - - D1g1tizeo by Go<?gle Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 352 State and Politics in India handcans and thrown into the Hooghly [the Ganges)'. 19 Ghosh also captured weU the general mood within West Bengal as Indira Gandhi turned the police loose to do the 'dirty work': Panic and terror among the people at that time was so high that no one could stay at home at night, no young man could think of not being implicated in cases of arson and murder to be instituted by the police, no middle-aged man could avoid severe beating up in course of interrogation in a police loclc:-up.20 And finally, Ghosh's conclusion concerning the scope of the state repression is noteworthy: Even in the absence of published figures it may be safely assumed that the number of Naxals killed exceeds the number of those killed by Naxals. There should be no doubt that the Naxalite movement in India [the largest concentration of which was in West Bengal) has taken a toll of several thousand lives.21 One prong of the government's strategy was to kill Naxalites and anyone suspected of being associated with them. The other was simply t o imprison anyone suspected of being a threat to 'law and order'. Again, firm evidence on the extent of such imprison­ ments is not available. We lc:now little about those who were imprisoned for political reasons and under what circumstances. The imprisonments went on during the first half of the 1970s and increased considerably during 1975-7, the period of the national Emergency, when even the minimum constitutional niceties could be set aside. Amnesty International estimated that around that time nearly 25,000 people, mostly members of the CPI(M) and Naxalites, were imprisoned for political reasons.22 The exact numbers of people killed and it11prisoned for political reasons in West Bengal during the 1970s will never be lc:nown. Nevertheless, the important point for this study is that for much of that period the democratic rights of many citizens were violently ripped away, and repression of the left, especially the revolutionary left, virtually became the norm. The socio-economic situation of the state also suffered adverse consequences. Much of the sig­ nificant decline in industrial production in West Bengal was due 19 The author quotes his own newspaper story in his book. Ibid., p. 167. 20 Ibid., pp. 155-6. 21 Ibid., pp. 178-9. 22 Reponcd in Franda, 'Rur.il Development, Bengali Marxist Style', p. 4. Dlgltlzedby Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Politial Process: Dominance 3 53 to capital flight during the fi.rst half of the crisis, that is during the two UF experiments, when labour militancy rose sharply. The second half of the chaotic decade brought many reverses in the land redistribution prognmmes. For example whatever modest gains the CPl(M) and other leftist parties had made in securing tenancy rights came undone, as did their progress in the redistribu­ tion of disputed lands. Again, exact figures will never be known. It was clear during my fieldwork in 1979, however, that eviction of tenants during 1971-7 had been a crucial factor behind the CPl(M) government's decision in 1977 to give the highest Eriority to policies that would ensure the rights of sharecroppers. 3 Crises of govemability are defined with reference to three criteria: coalitional instability, policy ineffectiveness, and, most important, escalating violence in politics. It is clear from the discussion in this chapter that West Bengal indeed experienced a severe crisis of govemability during 1967-77: it proved nearly impossible to form a ruling coalition; much of the government's energy was devoted not to dealing with issues of socio-economic development but rather to managing political conflicts, and viol­ ence became the norm for settling political disputes. Although many factors contributed to the increase in political violence, two related political variables must be emphasized in this analysis of the origins of the crisis: a fragmented and ineffective state ap­ paratus, and an elite-led, deliberate mobilization for short-term political gains. As the focus of this study now shifts to the political changes since 1977, the contrast between developments in the two periods will further substantiate this analysis: the emergence of cohesive party rule has led to the development of a more con­ solidated state and has focused the attention of the ruling elite on long-term developmental goals, thus ameliorating West Bengal's crisis of gc;1vernability. The Decade of the CPl(M): A Government that Works The CPI(M) emerged as West Bengal's ruling party in 1977 and has won all subsequent elections. The past decade in West Bengal has been relatively free of political violence. Prior to an analysis of what the CPl(M) has done to provide a moderately effective 23 For discussion, see Kohli, Tbe St11te 111111 Pwmy in India, chapter 3. Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN . ... 354 State and Politics in lndill government, another question must be addressed: how did the CPI(M) manage to become the state's ruling pany? The answer is not complicated. Table 9.2 shows the shares of the popular vote received by the major parties in West Bengal between 1967 and 1982. This table reveals three important facts, each of which requires some explanation: the crucial year in which the CPl(M) enlarged its power base was not 1977, but 1971; the 1972 elections were aberrational from the point of view of the CPI(M) and the CPI(M) emerged victorious in 1977 when the two centrist parties, Congress-I and the newly formedJanata, split the non-communist vote. TABLE 9.2 Percentages of Vote Won by Major Parties i n West Bengal Assembly Elections 1967-82 Par!:J. CPI(M) Other Left Front parties Janata Congress-I CPI Others Total S11U1Tt: 1967 18.1 1969 19.6 1971 33.8 1972 27.5 1977 35.8 1982 38.5 7.5 10.7 8.5 6.6 41.l 6.5 26.8 40.4 6.8 22.5 29.8 8.6 19.3 49.1 8.4 8.4 10.5 20.5 23.4 2.7 7.1 9.9 0.8 35.7 1.8 13.3 100 100 100 100 100 100 Compiled from the reports ofthe Election Commission. In 1971 the CPl(M) emerged from the two UF experiments as a major contender for power. Because the CPl(M) already had a strong base in the urban working class, the significant increase in its share of the popular vote in 1971 must be attributed to a successful mobilization drive in the countryside. As discussed ear­ lier, the CPl(M) during that period chose to keep the police out of agrarian conflicts and simultaneously mobilize both the middle and the lower rural strata. The resulting increase in the member­ ship of the Kisan Sabha - an organization of peasants with small landholdings - has already been noted. The Krishak Mazdoor Sabha (an agricultural labourers' organization) also made signi­ ficant membership gains during that period.24 And finally, the 24 For det:iils, see Sengupt:i, CPl(M). D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Politic.al Process: Domin1111Ce 355 CPl(M)'s concerted efforts to secure tenancy rights for sharecrop­ pers, as well as its periodic efforts at land redistribution, must have established a significant degree of political affinity between the CPl(M) and the Bengali peasantry. Why, then, did the CPl(M) do poorly in the 1972 elections? As a comparison of Tables 9.1 and 9.2 will show, the CPl(M)'s share of the popular vote did not drop nearly as dramatically (from 33.8 to 27.5 per cent) between the 1971 and 1972 elections as did the number of seats it won (instead of 113 seats in a house of 280 in 1971, it won only 14 seats in 1972). The dramatic decline in its legislative representation was primarily a function of the nature of the first-past-the-post electoral system. The CPl(M)'s share of the vote in 1972 was, in spite of the sign ificant decline since 1971, still substantially higher than it had ever been in the 1960s. What requires explanation, therefore, is why Congress's popu­ larity went up fairly sharply and why the CPl(M)'s share of the vote declined by some 6 percentage points. In the absence of detailed public opinion surveys, only the major issues that may have influenced public 'moods' can be noted. Congress's popu­ larity was in alJ likelihood improved because of Indira Gandhi's decision to intervene in the civil war in East Pakistan that led to the 'liberation' of Bangladesh. Given a sense of shared cultural identity with Bengalis across the border, that action by Indira Gandhi must have attenuated the normal hostility of Bengalis toward New Delhi and may even have inclined them temporarily to view Indira as a leader on their side. The decline in the CPl(M)'s share of the vote, in t11m, was in part simply the flip side of Congress's gain, but in part it must also be attributed to some combination of the following: the pervasive, intimidating presence of the army during the elections; the imprisonment of thousands of CPl(M) members; and, ofcourse, the electoral fraud and rigging that many independent observers have noted, if not documented. The third set of factors requiring explanation in the CPI(M)'s rise to power included some post-Emergency developments..The CPI(M) had clearly expanded its power base significantly during the two UF experiments. A number of changed circumstances finally helped the CPI(M) transform that popular base into a . decisive electoral victory. First, the Congress party in West Bengal, as elsewhere throughout India, had lost considerable popu­ larity because of the Emergency. The newly formed Janat:r par.ty Digiti zed by Google Ongmal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 356 State and Politics in India was the main beneficiary of that decline. Because the CPl(M) was already a well-established force within West Bengal, it appears that what happened was that the non-left vote was split between Congress and theJanata party (Table 9.2). Additionally, the CPI, because of its close association with Indira Gandhi throughout the Emergency, lost a significant share of its popular support. It is probably fair to assume that much of that decline benefited the other leftist parties of West Bengal, including the CPI(M). The CPl(M) thus emerged from the 1977 elections as the party with the largest share (35.8 per cent) of the popular vote (Table 9.2). If one includes the other leftist parties that were in alliance with the CPl(M) in the Left Front, their total share of the vote approached 50 per cent. In India's first-past-the-post electoral system, especially under the circumstances of a split in the centrist vote, it is not surprising that the Left Front won nearly 80 per cent of the total seats (Table 9.1). It is also important to note, however, that the CPI(M) alone won 177 seats in a house of 280, more than sufficient to form a comfortable majority government, all on its own. Part of the explanation for the CPl(M)'s· effective ruling strat­ egy since 1977 is its changed ideology. By the time the CPl(M) came to power in 1977, it had moved away from a revolutionary inclination to a reformist orientation. I have discussed this in detail elsewhere,25 but it is important to repeat the main points: First, the political experience under the Emergency gave the CPl(M) a clearer understanding of the value of democratic institutions; the CPl(M)'s capacity to mobilize support and increase power was found to be heavily dependent on the openness of the political process. The CPl(M) thus increasingly diminished its rhetoric of 'a dictatorship of the proletariat' and committed itself to preserv­ ing India's democratic institutions. Second, the government's in­ ability to control mobilized forces during the UF experiments led to a clarification of the 'types of struggles' that the party would encourage. As a result, labour militancy and gheraoes in the fac­ tories, and land grab movements in the countryside, came to be replaced by 'legal' and 'constitutional struggles'. And finally, re­ lated to both of those changes, the CPl(M) began defining who the 'enemy' was and who its allies were according to political 2S See Kohli, Tbt St11tt tmd Povmy in India, chapter 3. Digiti zed by Google Ongmal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Political Process: Dominance 357 standards rather than class criteria; members of nearly all social classes - except for big industrialists and wealthy landowners, especially 'non-productive' absentee landowners - were wel­ comed into the party. That new commitment to reformism made the CPI(M) more a social democratic party and less a traditional communist party. Two irnpor:tant features of the CPI(M), however, continued to distin­ guish it from other Indian parties. First and foremost, the CPI(M) retained the democratic centralist pattern of internal party or-· ganization, �d that made it a much more cohesive party. Second, in spite of attempts to broaden its membership, the CPI(M) has remained primarily a party of the middle and the lower strata, with an explicit commitment to reforming the social structure along class lines. The post-1977 CPl(M) in West Bengal is best understood as a well-organized, class-oriented reformist party. The CPI(M)'s slow but steady evolution toward a reformist party increasingly made it a viable alternative in a democratic capitalist setting. The experience of fmally coming to power with a significant majority further accentuated the CPI(M)'s reformist tendencies. Once it formed a majority government, two dramatic changes followed. First, the CPI(M)'s political horizons shifted from the short-term concerns of mobilizing and expanding its power base to the longer-term concerns of consolidating its newly acquired power. Related to that was a second important change: the CPI(M)'s political prospects for the future increasingly became a function of its capacity to provide effective government. That further shifted the party's political attention away from mobiliza­ tional activities. The search was on for strategies to create political stability, facilitate economic growth, and, within those constraints, back up its rhetoric with some genuine land redistribution. Now, it should be clear that nearly all ruling parties in the various states in India would like to facilitate political stability, economic growth, and some redistribution. Two traits distinguish the CPI(M): it was slower than other parties to accept those 'ordinary goals' as governmental goals; more i1nportant, having accepted that ideological shift, its political capacity to pursue those goals has turned out to be greater than that of numerous other Indian parties. The differences in political capacities, in turn, are traceable back to the organizational cohesiveness of the CPl(M). A well-developed party organization has enabled the CPl(M) _____ _oigiti,edby Go9gle Ongmal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 358 State and Politics in India • to devise and implement a fairly well-designed ruling strategy that is periodically updated. The strategy has three main components: imposition of the party's reformist ideology on disciplined cadres, thus making the more 'normal' debilitating factional conflicts and personal ambitions of the political elite subservient to larger or­ ganizational goals; implementation of modest but genuine re­ distributive programmes, thus solidifying the coalitional base with something more than rhetoric and symbolic gains; implementa­ tion of 'pragmatic' policies to placate the propertied groups and encourage production based on the principle of profit. In the last twelve years i.e. 1977-89, that the CPl(M) has been in power, it has achieved some success in all of these areas. Im­ mediately after coming to power, the C.Pl(M) had the difficult task of limiting the expectations of the economically disadvantaged. Instead of making empty promises that could not be kept - a recurring recipe for short-term political gain and long-term dis­ aster -the CPl(M) from the beginning set a cautious ruling tone: The aim of our programmes is to alleviate the sufferings of the rural and urban people and to improve their conditions to a certain extent. We do not claim anything more, as we are aware that without struc­ tural changes in the socioeconomic order it is hardly possible to bring about any basic change in the conditions of the people.26 Because 'structural changes' cannot be expected to be imple­ mented in a single region of a large country, the CPI(M) has been able simultaneously to point out the factors that it cannot control (thus shifting the blame to New Delhi) and to minimize what people can expect from the state government it does control. One reason that the CPl(M) has succeeded in minimizing de­ institutionalizing populism since 1977 is that it is a well-disciplined ruling party. Empty populist promises are often made by leaders atte1npting to hold together unstable coalitions. By contrast, at both the elite and mass levels, the CPl(M)'s support structure has been relatively stable. Party discipline has forced competing fac­ tions to work within politically feasible boundaries. Modest but concrete rewards have, in turn, strengthened the CPl(M)'s coali­ tional base among the middle and lower strata. The gap between 26 Government of West Bengal, Left Front Guvemmmt m Wtst Bmglll: Eight Years (Calcutta: Department of Information and Cultural Affairs, 1985), from the Foreword by Jyoti Basu, Chief Minister of West Bengal, pp. 1 2. - Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Politiclll Process: DominllrKt 359 promises and results, therefore, has been narrower in the CPI(M)'s West }Jeng'21 than in many other parts of India. , It is important to elaborate on this last statement: though the CPl(M) has promised less, it has done more, especially for the lower sttata, than most other ruling parties in Indian states. The most successful of the CPl(M)'s programmes has been one aimed at enhancing the security of. tenants in the countryside. This programme, called 'Operation Barga', has ensured tenurial rights and improved incomes for as many as one-quarter of all the rural households in West Bengal. As discussed elsewhere, the role of the disciplined, cadre-based party has been central in the im­ plementation of this reform programme.27 Keeping in mind that the security of these tenants had often been threatened in the past, especially under Congress governments, the political bond that has now been established between the sharecroppers of West Beng'21 and the CPl(M) becomes readily understandable. The CPl(M) has not come up with anything as successful as Operation Barga for the landless labourers. The labour-abundant agrarian economy, with its high levels of underemployment, has proved a formidable obstacle. The CPl(M) has put its energy into · strengthening the political organization of landless labourers. Al­ though the results have been less than spectacular, West Benp has little of the open brutal repression of the kind seen in Bihar. This is in part a function of a less oppressive caste structure, but it is also related to the organizational presence of the CPI(M) in the Bengali countryside. Familie� with small landholdings provide the CPI(M)'s main political base. Many of the party's ideologically loyal cadres arc from this social background. Additionally, the CPI(M) has sought to build its own version of '1nachine politics' to incorporate this social stratum. The revamped ptmd,ay11ts (local governments), for eumple, provide one crucial component in this design.28 The CPl(M)'s popularity has enabled it to win the largest number of local government positions. The CPl(M) has also 'decentralized' power in the special and limited sense of giving p1171(hllJllts sub­ stantial resources for local development. These activities have been closely supervised through the party hierarchy and have been 27 For documentation and details, see Kohli, Tbt Sutt 1111d Pwtrty in lndu, chapter 3. 28 For a detailed discussion, see ibid., chapter 3. Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 360 State and Politics in India aimed at minimizing corruption and waste of public resources. Although this has not eliminated charges of corruption, especially because the CPl(M) is no less partisan than other parties in select­ ing its own supporters for positions of authority, it has nevertheless had two important consequences. First, many of the local develop­ ment programmes sponsored by New Delhi - especially such programmes as the Food for Work Programme (later renamed the Employment Guarantee Scheme) - have been better imple­ mented in West Bengal than in other states. Second, systematic governmental penetration into the countryside has enabled the CPl(M) to sustain a powerful network of supporters. Landless labourers, sharecroppers, and small landowners con­ stitute the majority of the rural population in West Bengal. These are also the groups that have become the CPl(M)'s main sup­ porters, enabling the CPl(M) to win three consecutive state elec­ tions. As one would expect in the case of a leftist party, larger landowners, businessmen, and industrialists tend to oppose the CPl(M). It is important to note, however, that the CPl(M) has gone out of its way to make itself acceptable to such groups. For example the CPl(M) has argued that subsidized agricultural inputs and 'fair prices' for agricultural products are necessary to ensure agricultural production. It has also offered numerous incentives to industrialists so as to increase invesnnent. Although these policy initiatives are clearly not sufficient to turn property owners into CPl(M) supporters, th ey do go some distance towards creating a workable relationship between the leftist government and the society's producers of wealth. An additional point concerning the relationship between the CPl(M) government and property-owning groups is worth noting. The memory of the chaotic UF experiments is still fresh in the minds of Bengali businessmen. They also know that the CPl(M) has a strong organizational network among workers and peasants. Whereas in principle the business community would definitely prefer Congress to the CPl(M) in power, the practical issue is more complex: it is not at all clear to property-owning groups that they would be better off with another party in government and the CPl(M) as the opposition. Since coming to power, the CPI(M) has restrained both labour militancy in factories and land grab movements in the countryside. During my visits to West Bengal, I heard numerous landowners and representatives of Chambers of Dig1t1zeo by Google Origi�al rrom UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Political Process: Dominance 361 Commerce acknowledge this restraining role of the CPI(M). If forcibly removed from power, the CPI(M) could make West Ben­ gal ungovernable. That possibility has restrained Bengali property owners from inviting New Delhi's intervention in West Bengal politics. This emphasis on the CPl(M)'s effectiveness in government is not meant to draw attention away from the serious problems that remain unsolved in West Bengal; some of these are intrinsically difficult problems, and others are of the CPl(M)'s making. First, the CPl(M)'s simultaneous attempts to sustain an alliance of the middle and lower strata and to avoid any further alienation of property-owning groups have placed serious constraints on any further redistribution of wealth. The problem of severe bottom­ level poverty is not likely to be solved by political intervention alone. Second, business groups and industrialists have not received guarantees sufficient to encourage them to bring substantial new investments into West Bengal. That is readily understandable: if the CPl(M) should lose an election, the party leadership could again unleash labour militancy. Third, the CPl(M)'s sustained rule is giving rise to a powerful 'new class', and that naturally evokes hostility among all those left out of the power game. The presence of entrenched cadres in an atmosphere of limited industrial dynamism and minimal new redistribution has begun to create a sense of political stagnation in West Bengal. If the CPI(M) fails to correct these tendencies, they could lead to its undoing. Such possibilities raise an important question: was the price that the CPl(M) paid to restore. order too high, that price being political stalemate and the related problem of economic sluggishness? Whatever its future, the CPI(M) has two other important problems over which it does not have full control. First, one of West Bengal's sixteen districts, Darjeeling, experienced consid­ erable political strife between 1986 and 1988. That turmoil pitted one of West Bengal's ethnic minorities, the Gorkhas, against the Bengali-dominated CPI(M) government. The Gorkha demands varied from greater political autonomy within West Bengal to a separate Gorkha state - Gorkhaland - in India. The issue was eventually settled in mid-1988, when the CPI(M) made some concessions and Gorkha leaders accepted an arrangement that would leave Darjeeling a part of West Bengal but also would give Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 362 St11tt and Politia in India Gorkha leaders considerable financial and administrative control within their district. Prior to the final settlement, however, the Gorkhaland agita­ tions during 1986--8 caused considerable loss of life and property in Darjeeling. The dynamics of that conflict are not difficult to understand. Darjeeling is a small district in the mountainous north of Bengal. Of West Bengal's nearly fifty million people, only one million live in that remote district. The district is nevertheless quite important; it has strategic importance because of its proxi­ mity to China, and it has economic importance because of tea plantations and tourism. More than 80 per cent of the district's people are non-Bengali Gorkhas. The Gorkhas are both racially and linguistically distinct from the Bengalis. The Bengalis tend to view· the Gorkhas as 'backward' people who are relatively innocent in the ways of the world and who make good domestics and hardworking labourers. The Gorkhas of Darjeeling were never politically integrated into either the Congress or the CPI(M). In the past, a Gorkha League usually won the political support of many Gorkhas and then often formed a coalition with the ruling party in Calcutta. The increasing identification of the CPI(M) in West Bengal as a Bengali party and the growing political awareness among a new generation of Gorkha leaders altered that pattern in the 1980s. During the past decade the Gorkhas have demanded greater politi­ cal control over their own affairs. The CPI(M) had itself argued for such rights for the Gorkhas in the 1970s, when the Congress was in power in West Bengal. Once in power, the CPl(M) dragged its feet on Gorkha de­ mands. That was mainly because any major concessions to Gorkhas could have hurt the CPI(M) politically with its major constituency, the Bengalis. What complicated that fairly normal give and take of politics was that the leaders of the Congress party saw in the conflict an opportunity to weaken the CPl(M). Follow­ ing the Punjab pattern of a few years earlier-when Indira Gandhi had decided to support Bhindranwale as a vehicle for weakening the Akali Dal - the Congress leadership decided to promote the Gorkha leader, Subash Ghising. Thus encouraged, the Gorkha movement became increasingly strident in its demands against the CPI(M) government. The Congress leadership, however, was clearly of two minds Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Political Process: D<miina11Ce 363 on the issue of Gorkhaland. Given Rajiv's reconciliatory position on Punjab and Assam in 1985, one faction within the ruling circles appears to have argued that national interests should come before Congress's political interests. That line of thinking would have suggested that the Gorkhaland agitation should not be encour­ aged, lest it become one more major ethnic strife. Conversely, the difficulties that Gorkha agitations would create for the CPl(M) must have been far too tempting a political opportunity for the Congress to resist. That both of those arguments were operating i s evidenced in the confusing policy position of the Congress: between 1986 and 1988, the Congress went back and forth several times in encouraging and discouraging Ghising and the Gorkha movement.29 The conflict was eventually settled when Congress leaders decided that the creation of a new state for Gorlthas was out of the question. That had always been the CPl(M)'s position. The Gorkha movement was far too insignificant a political force to win out against both the national government and the West Bengal government. It was able to flourish only because of the political space created by a conflict between New Delhi and Calcutta. Once New Delhi had clarified its position, and the CPI(M) had offered some concessions that clearly fell short of a separate state but were nevertheless significant, Gorkha leadership had little choice but to accept the deal. The Gorkhaland crisis demonstrated that whereas the CPl(M) was quite adept at dealing with class conflict, its capacity to manage ethnic conflict was questionable. Conversely, it was also the case that the CPI(M)'s organizational cohesiveness enabled it to devise a consistent policy position. Unlike Congress's con­ flicting positions and mixed signals - probably reflecting fac­ tional divisions or, worse, changing leadership whims - that encouraged the conflict, the CPl(M)'s consistent and compromis­ ing position eventually facilitated conflict resolution. The second major political problem in West Bengal over which the CPI(M) government has little control is the organizational decline of the Congress party. Of course, its organizational get a quick sense of the confusion in Congress's policy toward Gorkha­ land, see the following news coverage in India Todlly: 15 January 1987, pp. 32-3; 28 February 1987, pp. 26-7; 15 May 1987, pp. 32-3; 15 January 1988, pp. 32-4. 29 To D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN • 364 State and Politia in India disintegration does not negate Congress's continuing capacity to attract popular support (fable 9.2). Congress remains India's major national party and therefore attracts considerable support in all of India's states. Within West Bengal, the Congress's main support comes from several groups: non-Bengalis, especially in Calcutta; those who are ideologically anti-left; many of the rich peasants and most of the very large landowners; many of those in business, trades, industry, and com111erce; a significant minority 1:>f the numerically significant Muslims; and those generally de­ prived of governmental patronage and benefits. The main significance of Congress's organizational decline is not in its reduced capacity to attract popular support. The main significance lies elsewhere. Nearly all observers of West Bengal politics are agreed - even those who do not assess the CPI(M) favourably - that an electoral victory by Congress would mean less effective government for West Bengal. The Congress party of West Bengal is deeply factionalized, and its leadership is of very low quality, composed mainly of former Youth Congress rowdies who moved in to fill the vacuum created by the disintegration of the old Congress. Thus electoral support for Congress in West Bengal mainly reflects anti-CPI(M) sentiments and support for the national leadership of Congress. For the time being, almost no one expects that the West Bengal Congress could offer effective government. Related to that, factional squabbles within the Congress con­ tinue to be sources of civil unrest in West Bengal. Much of that conflict is concentrated in urban areas. Given the CPl(M)'s organ­ izational cohesiveness and control over the government, Congress in West Bengal has shied away from aggressive mobilizational strategies. Congress would likely be a loser in any such direct conflict. Given Congress's internal make-up, however, if the CPl(M)'s hold on power were to weaken, Congress's resurgence would undoubtedly generate considerable political turmoil in West Bengal. In sum, West Bengal is not without its share of serious political problems, some of which are inherent to the region, whereas others reflect poorly on the CPI(M), and yet others are of Con­ gress's making. In spite of these, West Bengal under the CPl(M) remains a relatively well-governed state. This assessment is espe­ cially significant if one keeps the points of comparison in mind: Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Political Procesr: Dtmmill11Ce 365 the chaotic decade of 1967-77 in West Bengal, and the growing turbulence in such neighbouring states as Bihar. When assessed relatively, the coalition underlying the CPI(M) rule in West Bengal is stable. The CPl(M)'s record on economic policy is not spectacular, but not without merit: its growth record is no wor&e than those of many other Indian states, and its redistribution record is distinctively superior. The m_o�t impres­ sive achievement of the CPI(M), however, has been restoration of political order - and that without repression. Moreover, West Bengal remaihs relatively free of communal conflicts of various types, including caste and religious conflicts. This is especially impressive in view of the fact that nearly 20 per cent of the Bengalis in West Bengal are Muslims. The cwnulative results are clearly evident in Figure 9.1. What is mainly responsible for this moderately effective ruling pattern is a well-organized ruling party that has put together a coalition of middle and lower groups, has not made extravagant promises but has delivered more re­ distribution than most other Indian parties, and has contained the usual debilitating intra-elite conflicts and the related attempts to politicize existing socio-economic cleavages. Conclusion After having been one of India's most chaotic states in the late 1960s, West Bengal has emerged in the 1980s as one of India's better-governed states. Surely there are lessons in this turnaround for any study of India's growing crisis of govemability. For pur­ poses of this concluding discussion, these lessons can be broadly divided into prescriptive and analytical. The prescriptive lessons are limited. What has worked in West Bengal may not work in other states in India - and_ is even less likely to provide an a l lIndia model. The emergence of the CPI(M) as a disciplined ruling party in West Bengal is a product of an unusual socio-political configuration -its long regional traditions of elite radicalism and centralized organizations, the weakness of caste as a principle of political organization, and the historical weakness of the Congress party. A different set of conditions could facilitate the emergence of left-of-centre parties as ruling parties in some other Indian states (for example Kerala). Given the ab­ sence of strong leftist traditions in most states, however, and given D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm -. UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN ·--- .... 366 State and Politics in India the widespread presence of caste and communal cleavages, the CPl(M) type of rule is not likely to emerge in much of India. Even if it did, the outcome under different circumstances might not be as favourable. In spite of the limited utility of the West Bengal case for generating any direct prescriptions, the analytical implications are very important. The West Bengal case highlights the significance of a well-organized reformist party for generating political order. The roots of the political chaos between 1967 and 1977, though complex, were mainly two related political conditions: the frag­ mentation of the state itself and virulent elite-led mobilization. The emergence of the CPI(M) as a ruling party tamed many of the conflicts within West Bengal. As a well-organized party with a clear electoral majority, the CPI(M) was able to create a cohesive government and fill the existing power vacuum. Or­ ganizational discipline also enabled the CPl(M) to limit elite fac­ tionalism and the debilitating elite-initiated political conflicts that often follow. Thus, organizational cohesion at the heart of the state was crucial for taming political chaos. It is important to reiterate in this conclusion that organizational cohesion is a necessary, but not sufficient, variable in the explana­ tion. If cohesive party rule is also to be democratic, the ruling party must put together a sustainable majority coalition. This is where the significance of implementable reforms and thus the party's reformist ideology comes into the picture. If the ruling party is not willing to reform or not capable of implementing reforms, one of two outcomes is likely: either the party will rapidly lose power or it will be attracted to deinstitutionalizing populism, thus exacerbat­ ing the long-term problem of establishing legitimate order. The CPl(M)'s reformist orientation has enabled it to pursue some redistributive programmes without fundamentally alienating property-owning productive groups. The CPI(M)'s performance in West Bengal has by no means been spectacular; it has left quite a few problems unresolved, and it has created some new problems. At the same time, however, it is undeniable that a reform-oriented, disciplined party has generated moderately effective government in West Bengal. D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 10 Culture and Subaltern Consciousness: An Aspect ,. of the MGR Phenomenon M.S.S. Pandian I S ocial scientists working within the broad Marxist framework have achieved substantial advances in understanding varied forms of protest movements, revolts and anti-establishment or­ ganizations in India. Two volumes on peasant struggles in India edited by AR. Desai1 and six volumes of'subaltern studies' edited by Ranajit Guha2 would bear ample testimony to this achievement. To study protest movements and revolts is to inquire into the counter-hegemonic projects of the subaltern classes. While it is no doubt important to study these counter-hegemonic projects and draw lessons from them, it is equally important to recognize that such projects are few and far between in time and space. In other words, the dominant reality has been one of the subaltern classes accepting the hegemony of the elite through such processes like deference to the elites and emulation of elite values. • This chapter would not have been written but for the encouragement and intellectual partnership ofS.V. Rajadurai and V. Geetha. I have also benefited a lot from my discussions with the following friends: Aron Pamaik, Baron De, Anjan Ghosh, R.S. Rao, Nirmal Sengupta,Sarajit Majwndar, A. Venbta­ chalapathy, J. Jeyaranjan and S. Anandhi. My thanks are due to all of them. I A.R. Desai, Pt1111tnt Stn,gglts in J,uJi11 (Delhi: Oxford University Press, 1979); and Agrllriim Struggles in Jndill 11fttr lndepmdmn (Delhi: Oxford University Press, 1986). 2 Ranajit Guha (ed.), S""4lttrn Stwlits: Wriringr on South AsiJm History mu/ Society; vols I VJ - (Delhi: Oxford Unive.rsity Press, 1982-9). D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 368 State and Politics in India However, there is hardly any study on how the ruling elites produce consent from the subaltern classes in concrete situations. 3 This lack in the current scholarship has already been pointed out by some scholars.4 The present essay takes this as a point of departure and makes a modest attempt to explore into subaltern consciousness while under hegemony, through a case study of the immense popularity enjoyed by the late M.G. Ramachandran (MGR) among the people of Tamil Nadu. 5 There are specific reasons for choosing the MGR phenomenon as a concrete instance to analyse the problem. The eleven-year rule of MGR did not cause any particular structural changes in the economy to benefit the subaltern classes in Tamil Nadu. Their material conditions indeed worsened during this period.6 On the other hand, his government ruthlessly used the state machinery to put down even the mildest of protests from workers, peasants, fisher people, teachers, government employees, etc. Also, his rule diluted unrecognizably the cultural gains achieved by the subaltern classes due to the drawn-out struggles of the Dravidian movement 3 James Freeman's excellent srucly of Mull, a scheduled aste labourer in a Orissa village (Untaucbabk: An J,u/ilm Lift Hirtary [London: George Allen and Unwin, l 979])and Michael Moffutt's srudy of Pariyans o f Endavur village in Southern Chengleput district (An Untoru:h11bk Ctmmnmity in South lndu: Strumnt1111d C1111Smsus (Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1979]) are two of the exceptions. 4 Swnit Sarkar, 'The Condition and Narure of Subaltern Militancy: Bengal from Swadeshi to Non-co-operation,, . 1905-1922', in Raruijit Guha (ed.), Subaltern Studies, (Delhi: Oxford University Press, 1984) vol. m; Arun Pat­ naik, 'Gramsci's Concept of Commonsense: Towards a Theory of Subaltern Consciousness in Hegemony Process', &onomican;/Political Wttk/y, vol. xxm, no. 5,January 1988. S M.G. Ramaclundran presided over Tamil Nadu as its Chief Minister from 1977 to 1987 with a brief break in 1980. He was born in Kandy in Sri Lanka in 1917. Driven by poverty, he began his career as a child actor in plays by joining at a tender age Madurai Origirutl Boys Company owned by M. Kandaswamy Pillai. After protracted struggle, he emerged as an immensely popular 6.ln1 star on the Tamil screen. Along with his acting career, he became active in DMK politics. In 1972 he founded a separate party, Anna Dravida Mwmetra Kazhagam, which w:is rechristened as All-India Anna Dravida Munnetra Kazhagam during the Emergency. After prolonged medical battle and ill-health, he died on 24 December 1987 as the most popular leader of the poor in Tamil Nadu. 6 MIDS, Tllfflil N111m &momy: Pttfo,nllmCt a,u/ Imm (New Delhi, Bombay and Calcutta: Oxford and IBH, 1988). D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Political Process: DominllnCt 369 during its early progressive phase. Given this, one would expect that the subaltern classes would have resented MGR's politics. On the contrary, MGR enjoyed a stable, if not growing, popularity among the poor in Tamil Nadu throughout his tenure in office. His party polled a third of the total votes in every election, and his followers exhibited an almost personal bond with him through­ out. When he died on 24 December 1987, several lakhs of people converged on the city of Madras and his funeral witnessed an unprecedented spectacle of grief. Besides, thirty-one of his fol­ lowers committed suicide.7 Thus the 'ascribed' consciousness and the 'actual' consciousness of the subaltern classes are substantially divorced in Tamil Nadu. {It is because the material life conditions of the subaltern classes do not produce the immediate conscious­ ness of their existence, that their 'actual' consciousness can be effectively mediated. Thus it has been possible for MGR to pose real problems and offer imaginary solutions.) For this reason, an exploration into the MGR phenomenon would further our under­ standing of how the elite produce consent among the subaltern classes. Moreover, there exist only a few studies on the MGR pheno­ menon.8 All these studies, except Sivathamby's, are empiricist, sometimes adulatory, and do not raise questions concerning the subaltern consciousnessvis-a-vis the MGR phenomenon. (fhis is a secondary reason for taking up the MGR phenomenon for the study.) However, I must hasten to add that the chapter is not going to explore all aspects of the MGR phenomenon. The phenomenon being multi-layered and complex, I will take up only one of its aspects for analysis: how a specific image of MGR was presented on the screen, where in the cultural mosaic of the subaltern classes this image is rooted, how and why this image became popular and what the nature of its ideological content is. 7 The St11tm,um, 17 January 1988. 8 Robert L. Hardgrave, 'When Stars Displaced the Gods: The Folk Culture of Cinema in Tamil Nadu', in Essays in tbt Political Sociokigy of &!utb India (New Delhi: Usha, 1979); Stephen Samuel, 'Film and Politics in Tamil Nadu: 1947-1980' (unpublished Ph.D. thesis, University ofMadras, 1983); R. Than­ davan, 'All India Anna Dravida Munnetra K.izhag:1111 - A Study' (un­ published Ph.D. thesis, University of M,1drns, 1983); K.irtigesu Sivathamby, The T11111il Filmsas a Medium ofPoliticalCrmrmunicflrion (Madras: New Century Book House, 1981). Digiti zed by Google Ongmal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 370 State and Politics in India II Before we embark on a discussion of the phenomenon itself, it is important to spell out a few things about the central analytical category employed in the essay, i.e. the category of common sense of 'the philosophy of the non-philosophers' developed and elab­ orated by the Italian Marxist Antonio Gramsci. Gramsci developed the category of common sense as a critique of the Enlightenment tradition which held the worldview of the common people as devoid of any sense and at the same time, as a critique of the pre-Enlightenment tradition as well which celebrated their world­ view as the philosophy.9 According to Gramsci, common sense is the ensemble of cul­ tural presuppositions by which the subaltern classes make sense of the world they live in. This worldview or consciousness is pre-theoretical, unsystematic, inchoate and contradictory. In Gramsci's words, 'Its fcommon sense's] fundamental characteristic is that it is a conception which, even in the brain of one individual, is fragmentary, incoherent and inconsequential, in conformity with the social and cultural position of those masses whose philo­ sophy it is'. 10 This consciousness is primarily dominated b y sedi­ ments of the ideologies of the elite: .•. this same group {subaltern classes) has for reasons of submission and intellectual subordination, adopted a conception which is not its own but is borrowed from another group; and it affirms this concep­ tion verbally and believes itself to be following it, because this is the conception which it follows in 'normal times' - that is, when its conduct is not independent and autonomous but submissive and subordinate.11 However, common sense is not completely regressive carrying 9 On Gramsci's category of 'common sense', see: Alberto Michael Cirese, 'Gramsci's Obsetv2tions on Folldore', in Anne Showstack Sasoon (ed.), Ap­ proatht.f to Gramsci (London: Writers and Readers, 1982); Alastir Davidson, 'Gramsci, the Peasantry and Popular Culture',Journ11/ ofPellSlfflt Studies, vol. 1, no. 4,July 1984; Arun Pamaik, 'Gramsci's Concept ofCommonsense', and Denzil Saldanha, 'Antonio Grarnsci and the Analysis ofClass Consciousnew. Some Methodological Considerations', &vrwmic tmd Politiul Wttkly, vol. 23, no. 5,January 1988. 10 Antonio Grarnsci, Stlrttiuns frum the Prison Notebooks (New York: Interna­ tional Publishers, 1973), p. 419. 11 Ibid., p. 327. Dlgltlzedby Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Political Process: Dominance 371 only the elements of dominant ideologies, but contains progres­ sive, autonomous elements as well which assert themselves when the subaltern classes act against the elite 'occasionally and in flashes', This is the healthy nucleus that exists in 'common sense', the part of it which can be called '-good sense' and which deserves to be made more unitary and coherent 12 This contradictory character of common sense gives it a certain plasticity, i.e. it can be selectively appropriated and reconstituted by different political forces. Given Gramsci's own political con­ cerns, he suggested that any movement of the people should develop a critique of the common sense by 'basing itself initially, however, on common sense in order to demonstrate that "every one" is a philosopher'13 and it should make the good sense or the progressive elements within the common sense 'more unitary and coherent'.14 In other words, Ideology, in this meaning of common sense, is not just an instrument of domination or a set of false beliefs. Rather it is a terrain of struggle. It is the site on which the dominant ideolo§Y is constructed but it is also the site of resistance to that ideology.1 The present chapter is about how dominant ideologies succeed in this site of struggle and produce consent among the subaltern classes. This process is illustrated, as I have already suggested, by exploring the screen image of MGR and its insertion in the pre­ existing common sense of the subaltern classes in Tamil Nadu. I shall begin with how MGR's image was constructed in films. m Varanthira R.ani (a popular weekly with a circulation of about three lakh copies) predicted, in its issue dated 15 February 1987, that 12 Ibid., p . 328. 13 Ibid., p. 330. 14 According to Gramsci [ibid., pp. 332-3]: 'Ifit [Philosophy ofPraxis] affirms the need for contact between intellectuals and simples it is not in order to restrict scientific activity and preserve unity at the low level of the masses, but precisely in order to construct an intellectual-moral block which can mllke politically possible the intellectual progress of the mass and not only ofsmall intellectual groups.' IS Roger Simon, 'Gramsci: A Glossary of Revolution', Mar.rim, TodllJ, April 1989. Digiti zed by Google Ongmal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 372 State and Politics in India the then Tamil Nadu state assembly would be dissolved and fresh elections held. Though the prediction proved wrong, the basis for this prediction was itself interesting and significant. The predic­ tion was made in the knowledge that new prints of MGR starrers were being produced! MGR films were repeatedly screened during election campaigns and the All World MGR Fans Association (which had about 10,000 branches in Tamil Nadu) served as the backbone of the AIADMK.16 MGR himself openly admitted: 'Fans Association and party are not different.'17 There has always existed a symbolic relationship between films and politics of Dravidian parties in Tamil Nadu. While this may sound like a truism, yet it is important to detail the modes through which films have sought to intervene in politics. This has hap­ pened in one of three ways: There have been films that have indulged in direct political propaganda, for instance Parashakthi, Velaikari and Oor lravu. More usually, reference to party symbols, and anagrammatic usage of party leaders' names in songs and in the course of dialogues have been a common feature of DMK­ style political propaganda. An interesting third usage has been the mixing of docu1nentary footage with.shots of the actual film in question. In Pantrm and Thangarathnmn, during the course of a dialogue sequence, as an answer to a query, the scene shifts to reveal documentary shots of DMK party conferences. And, of course, M. Karunanidhi and C.N. Annadurai were film script­ writers, and there has been no dearth of film personalities being involved in party politics in Tamil Nadu. In fact, film actors beginning with N.S. Krishnan, K.R. Ramaswamy, S.S. Rajendran and, of course, MGR have always drawn crowds, especially to party conferences. MGR began his acting career in films in 1936 with Ellis R. Duncan's Sati Leelavati. His acting career spanned forty years and 13 6 films and for the first twenty years, he, by and large, acted in mythological roles. 18 Only from the late 1950s he was seen in 16 Soon after MGR founded Anna DMK in 1972, the DMK promoted an organization called 'Ta1nilar Padai'. The members of 'Ta1nilar Padai', who were mostly urban lumpens, tried their best to disrupt the screening of MGR starrers. 11 Thuglak, 1 February 1984. 18 MGR appeared as Vishnu in Dakshayagam (1938), as Indra in PrahladJI (1939), as Parameswara in S,.; Murugan (l 946) and as Indirajit in Stttha Jantm11m (1947). Digiti zed by Google Ongmal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Political Process: Dumina11ce 373 social roles, achieving recognition in this regard with Thirudathe ( l 96 l ). Henceforth, MGR's screen roles comprised several stereo­ typed characters all of which constituted 'MGR'. A characteristic MGR role was that of a working man com­ bating every day oppression. Thus he had acted as a peasant, fisherman, rickshaw puller, carter, gardener, taxi driver, quarry worker, shoeshine boy, cowherd, etc. In fact, many a successful MGR films were titled thus: Thozhilali (l 964) (worker), Vivasayee (1967) (peasant), Padakotti (1964) (boatman), Mattukara Ve/an (1970) (cowherd Velan), Rickshawkaran ( l 971) (rickshaw puller), and Meenava Nanban (1977) (fisherman's friend). Even in films where he assumes dual roles, it is the subaltern MGR who is given cinematic prominence. A striking example is Mattukara Ve/an (1970) in which he acts both as a cowherd and a lawyer. The cowherd outsmarts the lawyer throughout. Aptly enough the film was named after the cowherd. These films are ostensibly about the oppression faced by the poor with MGR, of course, being constituted as one a1nong them. By employing a carefully constructed system of mise en stene, these films, celebrate his subalternity and create a 1nood for the audience to identify themselves with him. We shall cite just one such element of mise en scene here, that is food which constitutes the central concern of the everyday struggle of the poor. In Thozhilali (1964) MGR, as a manual worker, drinks gruel from an earthen pot and licks pickle from off his fingers. In Kanavan (1968) he asks for Neerakaram (water in which previous day's cooked rice has been soaked) in his rich wife's house. In Ninaithathai Mudippavan (I 97 5), he eats Ragi dosai, drinks sukku kappi (a hot concoction made of dry ginger, jaggery and water) and expresses his desire to have cold rice and cooked cereal. MGR's films endow these food items with a specific semiotic significance. It is immaterial whether the poor actually eat these kinds of food, though they often do. What is being presented here is a food-sharing structure that integrates MGR the Hero with the subaltern masses. In Mattukara Ve/an (1970), a cowherd MGR in1personates as a lawyer. When good food is served to him, he laps it up avariciously without botherin u about upper class n1anners, smearing his face in the process. 1 Along with food, other props like the design and colour 19 The films I cite in the course of the chapter are only ex.imples. The patterns presented repeat with little variation in a large number of MGR films. D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 374 State and Politics in India of the costumes are also used to define MGR as a subaltern on the screen. The social universe of MGR films is a universe of asymmetrical power. At one eµd of the power spectrum are grouped upper caste men/women, landlord/rich industtialists, literate elites and, of course, ubiquitous male - all of whom exercise unlimited authority and indulge in oppressive acts of power; at the other end of the spectrum can be found the hapless victims - lower caste men, the landless poor, the exploited workers, the illiterate simple­ tons and helpless women. Power is seen as all-pervasive, omni­ potent and undifferentiated while its victims are always already meek, beaten and homogeneous in their suffering. Thus we have landlords who try to grab peasants' land (Vivasayee (1967)), rural rich who wield whips on farmhands (Yenga Veetu Pillai (1965)), moneylenders who exploit the poor (Padakotti (1964)), industtial­ ists who dismiss workers at their whim (Thozhilali (1964)), avari­ cious men who desire others' property (Mukar11Si [1966)), city slickers who leave poor rural girls pregnant (Theier Thiruvizha (1968)), casteists who do not allow their lower caste servants to enter their houses (Nadodi [1966)), married men who desire other women (Vivasayee [1967)), etc. The conflict between these superordinate oppressors and MGR as a subaltern, and its resolution form the core of his films. MGR, in the course of the conflict, appropriates several signs of authority of those who dominate. In a semi-feudal social formation whc;re a wide specttum of everyday practices like speech, dress, body language and food are semiologically differentiated into signs of authority and deference, this .appropriation of signs of authority by a subaltern is significant.20 Let us take up three such signs which 20 For a general discussion on this, with illustr.ition fro1n peasant insurgencies in colonial India, see: Ranajit Guha, FJmrmtary Asperts ofPtllSlmt lnsurgmcy in India (Delhi: Oxford University Press, 1983), chapter 2. On this semiological differentiation of everyday practices into signs of authority and deference note what Brenda E.F.Beclc, Pt11s1111t Society in Kllnh (Vancouver: University of British Columbia Press, 1972), p. 155, writes ' ... Food passes between so1ne groups but not between others, and guests of a given community are invited to sit on the porch of some honies but in the courtyard of others, Ranking i s also implied in the form of address used between groups, and by subtle body gestures that accompany conversation. For exa1nple a ,nan of one community may cover his mouth when speaking, or. stoop slightly and look at the ground, while another from a caste that Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Politiclll Process: Dominance 375 repeatedly and prominently appear in MGR films. They are: (a) the authorityto dispense justice and exercise violence; (b) access to education; and (c) access to women. (a) He fights oppression as an individual - though belonging to a subaltern class. As Sivathamby put it, 'The world of conflict exists as a world centred around the hero and his personal eman­ cipation �bolizes the emancipation from the social evil depicted.'2 The odds he has to face and overcome in his struggle against injustice are insurmountable for ordinary mortals; but he brings humanly impossible situations under control and establishes justice. MGR's role as an individual adjudicator, unfolds itself with particular emphasis on the stunt sequences that are present in any MGR film. These sequences are an articulated expression of his struggle against oppression: an unarmed MGR fights an armed claims superiority to the first may stand erect, fold his arms on his chest, and look straight ahead. Adjustment io clothing can also serve as indicators of status. Women generally draw the end of their sari over both shoulders when in the presence of superiors. Men, similarly, lower their long s.kirt like vesti . . . so as to cover their calves when they wish to indicate deference.' Tiie widesp�d prev:alence of such feudal semioticity in Tamil Nadu has been established in several studies (Shastri Ramachandran and K. Manoharan, Agriculturlll u,brn,rrn in T11111il Nlldu [Delhi: Lolcayan Reports and Papers 6, 1981]; J.H.B. Den Buden, 'Social Stratification as Expressed through Lan­ guage: A Case Study of South Indian Village', Contribution tJJ Indian Soriology [NS], vol. 13, no. 1, January-June 1979; Anthony Good, 'A Symbolic Type and Its Transformation: The Case of South Indian Ponlcal', Contributions to lndiAnSo<iology, vol. 17, no. 2,July-December 1983, pp. 232-33; Uma Ramas­ wamy, Work, Union mu/ C01nmunity: JndunrilllM1111 in &iutb lndu, [New Delhi: Oxford University Press, 1983) ..PP· 104, 108; Chandrasekara V, Naidu, St,,,u Asptm ofAgro-E.vnmnic Trtmsjurm,,tion in Ttm,il N11du - A CtUt Study of &ulthinulplllti-11111 Vil'4gt, Working Paper No. 86 [Madras: Madras Insti� of Development Studies, 1988), pp. 119-20 and E. Muthaiah, 'Nalliravu Chadangugal - Samuga Panpattu Manithdayiyal Paarvai', Ar11ichi, January 1989 [in Tamil)). Several news reports have also brought out this fact. (For eumple see:],mior Viklltlffl, 25 September 1985, 23 October 1985, 21 M ay 1986, 23 November 1988 and 3 May 1989.) Again, this is true not only among the Hindus as ably shown by Poomam M.X. Demel, C11stt Ditcrimin4tion 11gmut Cbristums of&bediJed Castt Origin 1J1itbin Christian Cummimitia: A Study of T'fVO Villllgrs in T11111il N11du, Chidambaram, 1988 (unpublished M.Phil. thesis submitted to the Annamalai University) in his study of the relationship between Vanniar Christians and Harijan Christians. 21 Kartigesu Siv:athamby, Tllmil Films, p. 41. Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 376 State and Politics in India adversary single-handedly or engages in fighting the landlord's hirelings. For instance in Maadapura (1962) MGR with a fractured arm in sling fights with a mafia chief. Also, in quite a nwnber of ftlms, MGR demonstrates his skills in the extremely popular rural martial art of siiambam. These fast-moving sequences are so popu­ lar that MGR fans can recount effortlessly how many of them there are in different films and provide graphic details of them. Everytime a new MGR film is released, film magazines carry letters from MGR's fans expressing their admiration of MGR's fighting skills.22 It is not just that MGR fights exploitation and oppression but he is always invincible in his struggle. He can only win and he wins with remarkable ease. He can bend crowbars and maul fero­ cious tigers with bare hands. In fact, MGR's invincibility has become a byword in popular consciousness and MGR himself has acquired cultic power. For example in Mana/ Kayiro, a non-MGR starrer, it is significant that a cowardly character, inspired by MGR appearing with a whip in his hand in the poster of a hit ftlm of yester years (Enga Veett, Pillaz) is suddenly transformed and beats up and defeats the villain.23 MGR's role as a subaltern hero fighting for justice reveals two· aspects: First, MGR appropriates to himself the right to dispense justice. Second, he appropriates the right to emplol physical violence. Both are in real life monopolies of the elite.2 (b) The second sign of authority of the superordinate classes which MGR appropriates on the screen is education/literacy. In Padakotti (1964) MGR is the only literate fisherman in the whole fishing hamlet. In Thazhampoo (1965) he is the first postgraduate 22 The comments in these letters run as follows: 'MGR's fight from the rickshaw is wonderful', 'MGR who fights from the rickshaw is indeed an youth', 'MGR rotates like a top and fights. No actor in the world can fight like him' (see, Cinema l<Adir, March 1970 and August 1971). 23 Stephen Samuel, Film ll1Jd Politics m Tamil Nadu, pp. 2 7 23. 24 It would be interesting to note here what E.J. Hobsbawn, BJmdits (Har­ mondsworth: Penguin Books, 1985), p. 3 5 writes about social bandits: 'These are the men who establish their right to be respected against all comers, including other peasants, by standing up and fighting - and in so doing automatically usurp the social role of their "better" who, as in the classic medieval ranking systetn, have the monopoly of fighting. They may be th e toughs, who advertise their toughness by their swagger, their carrying of anns, sticks or clubs, even when peasants are not supposed to go armed, by the casual and ralcish CO!!rume and manner which symbolize toughness.' Dig1t1zeo by Google Origi�al rrom UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Political Process: D<l11f.inani:e 377 in the family of an ordinary plantation worker. In 1'hozhilali (1964), MGR, a manual worker, spends endless nights reading and earns a degree. In Pana Thottanz (1963) and Naan Yean Piranthaen (1972), he pledges his house to acquire literacy. In Petra/than Pillaiya (1966), MGR, a honest tramp, adopts an abandoned child and yows to give him English medium, education! In MGR films the hero's use of literacy as a weapan ofstruggle against oppressian is often contrasted with its use as a weapon of oppression in the hands of the elite. In Padakotti (1964), the villain who is a rich fish trader forces the poor and illiterate fishermen to put their thwnb impressions on promissory notes, keeping them ignorant of their contents. But MGR, the only literate fisherman in the hamlet appears on the scene, reveals what is written in the promissory notes and saves the illiterate from the manipulations of the trad�r. In Yenga Veett, Pillai (1965), MGR, a literate worker, exposes the landlord's plan to grab other people's property through fake documents. Thus literacy, hitherto a privilege of the elite, now becomes an instrument of subversion in the hands of a subaltern hero, a challenge to education as a sign of authority. (c) The third sign of authority which MGR appropriates on the screen relates to women. In a n1ale-dominated society where the landlords could easily rape peasant girls and have concubines as a status symbol, access to and control over women's bodies is a sign of authority. Here, control over men of subaltern classes is exer­ cised inter alia, by emphasizing their inability to defend their women from being molested and raped. MGR deftes this norm. In his ftlms, he starts off as a poor 1nan hut ends up marrying a rich woman or as a lower caste man 1narrying an upper caste wo1nan. If a powerful villain comes in his way, the poor MGR invariably succeeds. In Mattukara Ve/an (1970) he marries the daughter of a lawyer who earlier throws him out of his house for being a poor cowherd. The pattern repeats in Thazhampoo (I 965), Peria ldathu Penn (1963), Yenga Veett, Pillai (1965) and Pana Thot­ t11111 (1963). In Nadadi (1966) and N11T11 Nadu (l 969), a lower caste MGR marries an upper caste wo1nan. In ftlms like Pa//andu Vazhga (197 5),Ayirathil 0,1,van (1965), Mahadevi (1957), Theier Thin,viz­ ha (I 968) and Padakotti (1964) MGR 1narries the desired girl after intense struggle against powerful villains. It is significant that in MGR ftlms, the upper class/caste women always desiiea lower class/caste MGR. In this sense, MGR seems Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 378- State and Politics in India to grant women the 'freedom' to fall in love and get married despite class/caste difference. This 'subversion' of norms granted a certain notional freedom to women and at the saane ti.tne asserted the virility/valour of men and subaltern classes. These three instances are not the only ones where MGR ap­ propriates the signs of authority. In subtler and surer ways, he likewise uses other signs of authority such as dress, body language, etc. When the rest of the poor submit to the rich with folded hands, MGR confronts them, standing erect, with arms akimbo. Unlike others, he refuses to tie the towel around his waist, which is a sign of deference, but instead ties it around his head. And MGR was well aware of the significance of such a presentation. In his words: It is not enough if you are a good man. You must create an image that you are a good man. Every man must have an image. Take Nagi Reddy or S.S. Vasan or myself. Each of us has a distinct image. The image is what immediately strikes you when you see a person or hear his name. You put forward an image of yourself if you want to get anywhere.25 Where and how does this screen image of MGR fit into the pre-existing cultural presuppositions or common sense of the sub­ altern classes in Tamil Nadu? It is in the heroic ballads which are a dynamic element of subaltern common sense in Tamil Nadu that one may look for answers. IV The border area between Tiruchi and South Arcot districts is a country of dense cashew forests. Sometime in the recent past, in certain villages in this area, there existed a degrading custom that every woman has to spend her marital night with the village Nattanmai or the headman. This custom was put an end to when KodukoorArumugam beheaded threeNattanmais. Kodukoor Aru­ mugam is still a hero of the poor in the region, celebrated in folk songs.26 25 N. Krishnaswamy, 'From Hero to Mesiah ... Step by Step', lndilm&prm, i1adras, 9 January 1988. 26Jtmiur ViJ:11um, 9 September 1987. Though the report does not give details, it is only evident that .the women thus degraded should have belonged to poorer households/lower castes. Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN • The Political Process: Dominance 379 Throughout the Tamil countryside, there are such folk heroes. To name a few: Muthupattan, Chinnanadan, Chinnathambi, Jambulingam and Madurai Veeran. They are remembered from generation to generation through popular heroic ballads. Chinnathambi is a Ch�kkiliar (an untouchable leather worker). Lowly Chinnathambi accepted the local king's offer of a reward for venturing into the forests to kill wild boars which were de­ predating peasants' crops. He valour launched him on a successful career which was traditionally denied to Chakkiliars. He became the commander of the garrison guarding the king's fort at Thiruk­ kurunkuti. The jealous upper caste Maravas, who were the tradi­ tional commanders of the garrison, murdered him. But the people from among whom Chinnathambi rose to power did not allow him to die; they immortalized him in ballads which are in circula­ tion in Tirunelveli district. 27 The ballad on Chinnanadan also belongs toTirunelveli district. Chinnanadan alias Kumaraswamy married his two-year old cousin when he was eighteen. But he fell in love with a lower caste girl, Ayyamkutty, and refused to accept his cousin as wife. Though he had to forgo his family property, he did not flinch from his resolve. While he was murdered by his own kin, his wife and Ayyamkutty committed suicide. The cult of Chinnanadan is alive in four vil­ lages and there are shrines dedicated to him around the small town of Eral inTirunelveli district.28 Madurai Veeran ballad and cult are very popular especially in northernTamil Nadu. Madurai Veeran, like Chinnathambi, was a Chakkiliar who eloped with King Bommanna's daughter and defeated his army single-handedly and with much valour. His spreading fame earned him the admiration of the king ofTiruchi and he worked for him combating the upper caste Kallar bandits. He recklessly flirted with women of the royal household and finally managed to carry away the kjng's sweetheart, VeJlaiammal. An incorrigible adventurer and violator of sexual and caste norms, Madurai Veeran was finaJly quartered by the king of Tiruchi.29 It is not only that he is remembered in ballads and through several hundred shrines dedicated to him, but his pictures decorate the toddy and arrack shops in Madurai and Ramanathapuram districts. 27 V. Vanamamalai, /11ttrprtt11tirms of Tamil Folk Crrations (Triv-andrum: Dravidian Linguistic Association, 1981), pp. 161-3. 28 Ibid, pp. 160-1. 29 Ibid. Digiti zed by Google Ongmal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 380 State and Politics in India The last of the ballad that I would cite is that of Muthupattan, a rebellious Brahman. After discarding his sacred thread and removing his tuft, he skinned carcasses, ate beef and drank liquor - all these in order to marry two Chakkiliar · girls, Timmakka and Pommakka. This Brahman-turned dalit protected the cattle of his father-in-law from marauding bandits backed by local landlords.He was finally murdered by the bandits by deceit.30 .Near Papanasam dam, there is a temple dedicated to him. And there are such other revered heroes like Kathavarayan and Kou­ thalamadan.31 The common characteristics of these tales of love and valour are only too evident. In the words of Vanamamalai: 32 All the heroes ... are l o wcaste men who protect crops (Chinna­ tha1nbi), protect the cattle (Muthupattan), protect the rights of the lower caste women (Hanuma, Kouthalamadan, Jambulingam), chal­ lenge sexual caste norms (Muthupattan, Chinnanadan) challenge the privilege of the higher caste groups and demand equal rights for the lower caste men with talent and skill (Chennanna and Lak:shmanna). 33 The analysis of the heroic ballads so far when read together with the points made about the celluloid image of MGR in the previous section, would show that there is remarkable correlation between MGR on the screen and heroes of the ballads. However, the relationship between the themes of MGR films and ballads is not only one of unity, but of divergence as well.This divergence in the themes demonstrates how MGR &ltns have appropriated the bal­ lads and reconstituted them. This divergence is important to see the differences in the ideological content of the films and ballads. V For at least two reasons the heroic ballads constitute a progressive element/good sense in the ambiguous and contradictory mosaic 30 Ibid., pp. 15 5-8. 31 Stuart H. Blackburn, 'The Folk Hero and Class Interest in Tamil Heroic Ballads', Asian Folklore Studies, vol.37, no. 1, 1978. 32 V . Vanamamalai, Interprttatitm.r ofT11111iJ Polle Crtatiims, pp. 172-3. 33 The same conclusion has been arrived at by other folkJore scholars like Stuart H. Blackburn, 'The Folk Hero' and Tey Loordu, 'K:ithai Padalga lin Iyalbugal', in S.V. Subrn·manian (ed.), Ta111il Nattupp11ra !ya/ Ayyu (Madras: International Institute of Tamil Studies, I 979) (in Tamil). D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Political Process: Dominance 381 of the common sense of subaltern classes. First, in a social milieu where common people's life is disrupted by landlord-instigated adventures like crop destruction, denial of irrigation water, dis­ pensation of arbitrary justice, �nd raping of peasant girls, the people will naturally aspire towards a condition of stability in life processes. But if people aspire for adventures, these are adventures carried out on account of their own free will to achieve what they consider to be just.34 Thus the people's aspiration that can be read in the popularity of heroic ballads is an aspiration to use their free will to get justice done. Second, Madurai Veeran, Muthupattan, Chinnanadan and others, in their deaths affirm their essential humanity and this defiance of established norms and vindication of a common hu­ manity have endeared them to subaltern classes ever since. The ballad-like MGR films are bereft of this progressive con­ tent. At this point, one should reme1nber that cinema, especially the Tamil cinema in question here, follows a linear narrative sequence with the beginning rising to a climax and dovetailing to a neat finish. In these closed narratives, contradictions are rather ironed out than being allowe� to intensify leading to a rupture of the narrative. In MGR films the closure is such that a neat solution is offered for the injustice within the moral economy of the system itself. In other words, the subaltern protagonist in the film, i.e. MGR, establishes what is considered to be just within the system and thus reaffirms the system itself. It is a world of transformed exploiters with untransformed property and power relations. In Yenga Veetu Pillai (l965) and in Vivasayee (1967), the cruel land­ lords become 'good' landlords. In Ayirathil Oruvan {1965) the pirate king who oppresses the poor undergoes a change of heart, but remains a king. In Nadodi (1966), the rich casteist finally gives his daughter in marriage to MGR who is a poor man and of lower caste origin. The moral economy of the system is reaffirmed through a different mode in films where MGR acts as an elite hero. Here he often plays the role of a renouncer: in Naan Anaiyittal (1966), MGR constructs hundreds of houses on his land and asks the poor to occupy the houses and coloniz.e the land. In Nadodi {1966), he 34 See Antonio Gramsci, Stltaumsfrom Cultural Wrirmgr(London: Lawrence and Wishart, 1985), pp. 3 72-4 for an elaboration of this argument. Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 382 State and Politia in India gives away his plantation to the workers. In Ithaya .Kani (197'5), he divides the profit equally between himself and workers. The ex­ amples can be multiplied. Here an appeal to the idea of sacrifice was really an appeal to the power that flowed from inequality. In order to be able to 1nalce sacrifices one needs to po�ss; he who did not possess could not sacrifice. The glory of the renouncer belonged to the "possessor"; to tallc of sacrifice was to taJlc of possession, and hence of power. 35 Thus the glory in these films is to the 'possessor' and not to the dispossessed, unlike in ballads.36 This transformation of the folk hero of the ballads into a non-problematic hero on the screen who seeks justice within the moral economy of the system is a reconstitution of the former hero to serve elite interests.37 This reconstitution is possible as the common sense of the subaltern classes is -largely contaminated by the sediments of elite ideologies. For instance there are folk songs in rural Tamil Nadu which adulate the 'good' landlords. 38 But this is not all. The subaltern classes give assent to the reconstituted narrative since, as far as they are concerned, fragments of their reality are presented in these narratives. Besides the speedy and effective dispensation of justice and redressal of afflictions allow a 3S Dipesh Chakrabarty, 'Trade Unions in a Hierarchical Culture: The Jute Workers of CaJcum, 1920-50', in Ranajit Guha (ed.), Subt,Jtn-n Studies, (Delhi: Oxford University Press, 1984), vol. m. 36 For a n example of how this category of renouncer was used by the Indian National Congress to mobilize people during the nationalist struggle, see, David Hardiman, The Cuming of tbt Devi: Adivasi Anmion in Westtna lndu (Delhi: Oxford University Press, 1987), pp. 169-70. 37 The effons to change the radical content of ballads is a regular process. In this regard, Vanamamalai, lnttrprtt11tions of Tmnil Folk Crt11tions, p. 187 cites an important instance. In the recent recitals of Muthupattan ballad, rus wives are narrated as Brahman girl's brought up by a Chal<lciliar. Unlike in the original ballad, they are not Chaldciliar girls. On inquiry it was found that Muthupavalai of Kallidaikurichi who sings the ballad was pressurized by upper caste Vellalars and Brahmans to change the ballad. In the same way, there are puranic insertions in ballads which portray lower caste Madurai Veeran and Kathavarayan as Brahmans (Simon Blackburn, 'The Folk Hero', pp. 140-3). Here one must bear in 1nind that ballads are, essentially,oral narratives that stand to be transformed over periods of time, often reflecting the reconstituted social milieu. Thus they are open-ended and capable of infinite reinte.rpret2tions. 38 Vanamamalai, lnt�rprr:utions o[Ttrmil Folk Creations, p. 10 I and Aru Alagap­ pan, N11ttuppar11 Padlllg11/-Tbirfl1UJ'll11, (Madras, 1973) (in Tamil). D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Political Process: Dominm,ce 383 measure of vicarious pleasures to creep into their otherwise im­ poverished lives. VI In the previous section we have noted the thematic divergence between ballads and MGR films and the ideological content of this divergence. The question is how MGR, whose presentation on the screen is ideologically regressive, could e1nerge as a hero for the whole of the Tamil-speaking area, while the heroes of the ballads could not. Two things have to be borne in mind here: one, the process by which the localized folk heroes have been reconstituted as pan­ Tamil heroes through the mediation of MGR, the actor figure. Two, the selective appropriation of follc traditions that has care­ fully distilled away the defiance and the bravado of folk heroes to project a non-subaltern figure as the quintessential Tamil hero. The first was made possible through the technology of filmic form itself and through the political lineage granted to MGR by party support - both of which helped the emergence of the first all­ Tamil hero. The second, can be seen in the alternate kind of hero, promoted by Tamil Nadu's political elite. A stark example of the second type of heroes in Tamil Nadu would be that ofVeerapandya Kattabomman. Kattabomman was a feudal chieftain of Panchalamkurichi in southern Ta1nil Nadu who fought the British in his own interest and was eventually executed by them at Kayattaru on 17 October I799. The elite in Tamil Nadu have made this non-subaltern a hero of the whole Tamil-speaking area. Sivaji Ganesan erected a memorial for him in Kayattaru in l970;l9 the then DMK government renovated the ruins of his mud fort at Panchalamkurichi at a cost of seven lakh rupees in 1974.40 Every year a Kattabomman festival is organized at Kayattaru with state patronage, and during the festival various forms of folk art depicting Kattabomman's life are performed.41 39 Cinnru Klldir, August 1970, pp. 70-3. 40 M. Karunanidhi,Nmch,Jiku Needhi, vol. II: Trnmu1galPathipag11111 (Madras, 1987) (in Tamil) pp. 421-3. 41 Note that ABVP and RSS observe Kattabomman's death anniversary every year (see, M111111V11r Sakti, l November 1988, p. 14). Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 384 State and Politics in India An extremely popular film on the life of Kattabomman was made in Tamil with Sivaji Ganesan in the lead role.42 Now let us turn to the first type of hero - i.e. MGR in the Tamil context. Unlike the folk heroes who are disadvantaged not to reach a wide audience, MGR had access to the medium of cinema. In dealing with the role of cinema in projecting a par­ ticular presentation of MGR and its effectiveness in reaching a wide audience, one has to analyse two aspects: (a) social context of cinema as a medium compared to other forms of performance and (b) the popularity of cinema as a medium in Tamil Nadu. Cinema as a medium is relatively 'democratic'; cinema tickets being comparatively cheap, it is possible even for the poor to watch a film once in a way. Moreover, the seating arrangement within any cinema hall is not according to one's social status, but according to whether one can afford a ticket or not This is important because in witnessing shows of performing arts in rural Tamil Nadu, the order of seating of patrons is done hierarchically depending on social position. 'The cinema hall was the first performance centre in which all the Tamils sat under the same roof. The basis of the seating is not on the hierarchic position of the patron but essentially on his purchasing power'.4 These two factors -the affordability of witnessing a spectacle on the screen and cinema hall as 'social equalizer' - made film an extremely popular entertainment for the subaltern classes. The popularity of the medium can be gauged from the fact that most of the village monographs brought out by the Census of India, 1961 record watching films as the only entertainment of the rural people in Tamil Nadu. It is indeed a thin line that divides enter­ tainment from ritual and various kinds of social festivities. In fact, watching MGR films has become almost a ritual in itself. One can witness crowds gathered to watch MGR films, burning camphor before huge cut-outs of him, distributing water to the populace - as one would before a deity during temple festivals. In addition, the proliferation of cinema halls in Tamil Nadu is extensive. In the whole of India, next to Andhra Pradesh, Tamil Nadu has the largest number of cinema halls. On 31 March 1986, Tamil Nadu had a total of 2153 cinema halls out of which 820 are 42 The film bagged the best actor award in the Afro-Asian Film Festival held at Cairo in 1960. 43 Kartigesu Sivathamby, T(1111il Films, pp. 18-19. D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Political Process: Dominance 385 temporary halls.44 The temporary cinema halls which are located in rural and semi-urban areas, are usually 'touring talkies' that are shifted from one place to another. The price of the ticket is very nominal. The 'touring talkies' are almost exclusively visited by the rural and semi-urban poor, while the rich, given their social status, go to the nearby town to watch films in proper cinemas. This means that throughout Tamil Nadu, people have access to cinema halls and cinema is a very popular medium among the people. While heroic ballads can circulate only within a limited locality due to elite hostility and non-availability of such an elite­ controlled medium like cinema, films could present MGR to a wide audience throughout the state. MGR could thus emerge as a hero of the Tamil-speaking area as a whole. VII At least one important question remains: How did the subaltern classes fail to differentiate the screen image of MGR from MGR in real life? One of the reasons could be the large-scale circulation of a constructed imllginary biography of MGR that projectS his real life as not being different from his life on screen. Political platforms, newspapers, pamphlets, films, calendars and party posters were used with remarkable skill in constructing this biography. The process of this biography-construction could be the subject of a full length essay and I shall cite only some stark examples here to illustrate this process. MGR's early life was no doubt a life of misery. When· he was just two and a half years old, he lost his father. Due to acute poverty, he had to forgo schooling and join a drama troupe as a child actor. It took him many years of hardship as a low-paid stage artiste before he could gain a foothold in films. His modest beginnings and acute poverty of early days were well-propagated through public speeches, pamphlets, party newspapers, etc. MGR himself often referred to his early days of sweat and tears.45 For instance, in an All India Radio talk on 30June 1982 on the free noon-meal scheme for school-going children in Tamil Nadu, he said, This scheme is an outcome of my experience of extreme starvation 44 Scrte_n, 19 December 1986. 4S R . Thandavan, p. 159. Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 386 State and Politia in India at an age when I knew only to cry when I was hungry. But for the munificence of a woman next door who extended a bowl of rice gruel to us and saved us from the cruel hands of death, we would have departed from this world long ago. The inexpensive biographies of MGR which are sold in village fairs and urban pavements and bought by the literate poor also provide graphic details of MGR's poverty.46 Thus MGR is not only an elite person who tells tales of other peoples' oppression on the screen but is himself a victim of oppression telling his own tales and those of similarly placed men and women. If MGR is a renouncer of wealth in films, he is, as these constructed biographies would have it, a renouncer of wealth in real life as well. Even before MGR became Chief Minister of Tamil Nadu, his munificence was well propagated. Hardgrave.47 . wntes: MGR is a symbol of hope for the poor in South India. Without children, he has adopted the poor as his wards.He is always the first to give for disaster relief; he supports orphanages and schools. . .. MGR's generosity is well advertised, for it is the grist of his fume. When fires had destroyed some Madras hutments, he gave a la.kb of rupees for relief and announced that the hundredth day of a film then running would not be celebrated because of the slwn dwellers' s u f ­ ferings.... As one fun puts it, 'He is always there when the huts are burnt.' The party organization of DMK had an enormous role in propagating MGR as a real life renouncer of wealth. DMK leaders, including its founder and popular leader, late C.N. Annadurai, repeatedly projected MGR as a giver of wealth to the poor.48 Pro-DMK dailies like Dr11Vida Nadu and Murosoli, and magazines like Mutharam, celebrated MGR's munificence. A DMK propa­ ganda song used during the 1962 elections ran as follows: The Palm of Bharatha Kaman Became pink because of For example see, Kalaipadam Velan, Nam Yt11n Pir11rnhtn? Pur11tehi Tb11llziv11r MGR (Madras, undated), p. 26. Jeya Ponmudi, S11thy11 M11inthtm SadtmJli(Madns: Sri Laxini Pir.isuram, 1988), p. 6. I shall refer to such books as 'Popular Biographies' in the rest of the chapter. 47 Robert L. Hardgrave Jr., 'When S�rs Displaced the Gods', p. 102. 48 For the collection of speeches by CN. Annadurai on MGR, see: R. Srinivasa1Purthy (ed.), MGR: Ym ldt,ya Ktmi: Anna (Madras: Sathya Thai Patipagam, 1984). 46 Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Political Process: Domin1111Ce 387 His munificence. But the whole body of Dravida Kaman Became pink because of His munificence everyday.49 The Dravida Kaman is of course MGR. The 'popular biographies' which circulate among the poor, again, celebrate MGR as a renouncer. One of the events which is repeatedly mentioned in these biographies is MGR's auctioning off of a sword made of 110 sovereigns of gold to raise war funds during the 1962 lnde>-China war. Often it is rhetorically posed, 'who will have the large heart to donate 110 sovereigns of gold'. People do have an obsessional attachment to gold and such nar­ ration effectively poses MGR as a renouncer of wealth.so If MGR gave up his acting career and became the Chief Minister, it is because, according to these biographies, he was a renouncer: If he produces four or five films, he can earn crores of rupees. He lcnows this very well. Then why is he not acting in films? If he decides to act in films, no law can prevent him.... Do you know what is the reason for his giving up film acting? He wants to serve the people of Tamil Nadu. He wants to wipe out their problems....51 MGR's supposed invincibility was, time and again, constructed by various kinds of media so much so that he was conferred a degree of immortality in real life as on the screen. He was pres­ ented as one who was thrice-born: The fust one was when he was actually born like the rest of us; the second birth was when he survived an attempt made on his life by his fihn world associate and popular Dravida Kazhagam propagandist, M.R.Radha, on 12 January 1967, and his third birth was when he recovered beyond expectations from his debilitating illness in 1984. In fact, unlike most of the DMK leaders, MGR's birthday was never celebrated and his age was a secret. After 196 7, his followers were encouraged to celebrate 13 January, the day on which MGR recovered from bullet injuries, as his birthday. In his autobiography, he writes: 'As 49 M11'4i Mur11m, 6July 1987. SO See, for example: Vetri &lv11rMGR Vem, V 11r11lllru, (Madras: Sri Thanalax­ mi Puthaga Nilayam, undated), p. 35. Kalaipadam Velan, N111111 Ytim Pirm­ thm? Pur11tchi Tb11/lliv11r MGR (Madras, undated), p. 48. SI Kalaipadam Velan, N111111 Yt1111 Pir1111thm?, p. 63. Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 388 St11tt and Poiitia in India you all know, I was shot at on 12 January 1967. People think that I died on that day and I was reborn on the next day. That is why they greet me on that day.'s2 Thus through particular constructions of MGR's biography, bis films were portrayed as an imitation of his real ·life. One can cite several examples of the effectiveness of this obliteration of distance between the cinematic and the real. G.K. Ramaswamy in bis study on MGR fan clubs notes: The members are not able to go beyond the impressions created through the films and MGR's character is believed to be what is depicted in his films. This is clear fro1n the fact that when the followers were asked to substantiate their contention that MGR is good or a principled man, they invariably cited instances from his films.SJ The most resounding proof of how people do not differentiate MGR, the image and MGR, the real, can be had from what his followers did during his serious illness in 1984. In 0/hi Vilakku (1970), MGR's hundredth film, MGR carries on a losing battle with death. A widow to whom MGR has provided asylum sings to god, with inconsolable sorrow, to spare MGR's life and take away hers instead. This very song echoed throughout Tamil Nadu when MGR was ailing. If god replied to this song of grief in the film by sparing MGR's life, it could happen in real life also! He survived. When he finally died, it was so sudden that the people were not given an option! VIII The significance of MGR as a phenomenon and the elite who supported him, thus, lies in the recognition that the mosaic of common sense or the untheorized philosophy of the subaltern classes is an important terrain of political intervention. By using this site of struggle, which is often ignored by other political forces and by reconstituting a progressive element of the common sense for reactionary politics, MGR could join the ranks of Madurai S2 M.G. Ramachandran, 'Naan Yean Pirnnthen', part 45,Arwnd., Vik11um, 14 February 197 l. S J G.K. Ra1naswamy, 'The MGR Manrams: A Study in Political Sociology' (Wlpublished M.Phil thesis, University of Bangalore, 1979), p. 5S. D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Political Process: Dominance 389 Veeran, Muthupattan and Kathavarayan and supersede them. MGR's success rests, to a large extent, on this. Unfortunately, the various shades of political dissent in Tamil Nadu, ranging from the DMK to the CPI-ML, dismissively characterize MGR as a 'lunatic' and a 'clown'. It is ti.me these self-jlssured 'philosophers' sit up and take a few lessons from 'lunatic:$' and 'clowns' - of course, not to practise MGR-style reactionary politics but to appropriate its 'other'. Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 11 When Local Riots are Not Merely Local: Bringing the State Back in, Bijnor 1988-1992* Amrita Basu I n October 1990 the town of Bijnor, in western Uttar Pradesh, experienced a major Hindu-Muslim riot. Official sources es­ timate that 87 people were killed; unofficial estimates range from 198 to 300.1 This was among the most serious of the many riots that took place in the wake of the Bharatiya Janata Party's (BJP) campaign to build a temple at the supposed birthplace of Lord • A number of people offered valwtble comments on an earlier version of this chapter. They include Zoya Hasan, Roger Jeffrey, Marie Kesselman, Arul Kohli, Austin Sarat, and members of the CFIASoudi Asia Seminar at Harvard University. I am also grateful for research and writing support from the Karl Lowenstein fellowship and the John D. and Catherine T. MacArthur foun­ dation. I Estimates of casualties vary widely. Official estimates, according to Raj Kumar, the current district magistrate are: 87 persons lcilled, 127 injured (of which 42 were identified as serious injuries and 85 as simple injuries) and 1038 cases of arson and looting. Kumar noted that the previous district magistrate had reported only 36 people killed; after he had been replaced, many more people had come forward and filed reports. The district magistrate had no record of how these figures broke down by religious commwtity. However all unofficial estimates, including those of militant Hindu na­ tionalists, report much higher casualties, mostly among Muslims. Nanclaji, the pracharak of the RSS in Bijnor, estimates that 14 Hindus and 184 Muslims wer,: lcilled. According to J. B.L. Shanna, a reporter for the D11milt J11grn who toured Bijnor right after the riots, 75 Hindus and 225 Muslims were lcilled and 400-500 people were injured. Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Political Process: Dominance 391 Ram in Ayodhya. Other violent events took place in the cities of Ahmedabad and Baroda in Gujarat, and in Shamili and Gorakhpur in UP; tensions were also reported in Allahabad, Faizabad and Bareilly. Bijnor 1988-1991 Over the course of several visits to Bijnor, I asked caste Hindus and Muslims from a range of social backgrounds for an account of the riot ofOctober-November 1990. Although their accounts differed in many important respects, the people with whom I spoke sharply demarcated the years before 1988 in which communal violence had been absent, from the succeeding years. However, they considered the riots of 30 October-3 November a continuation and culmina­ tion of a series of other events. The four incidents that they repeatedly mentioned were: the municipal council elections in November 1988, a conflict over a plot of land in town on 25 August 1990, the banning of the so-called ram jyotis from Bijnor on 4 October ancl a rally organized by the Chief Minister on 9 October. Nagar Palika Elections Many Hindu men and women in Bijnor traced Hindu-Muslim tensions back to the 1988 nagarpa/ilea (municipal council) elections in which a man named Zafar Khan was elected chair.2 The.two principal contenders for the position were Sandip Lal and Zafar Khan. Some powerful groups like the BJP combine and the Bijnor Times news �aper, backed Lal and characterized Khan as a com­ munal man. The evidence cited was that two years earlier, during 2 In nwnerous cities and towns I found that BJP members had infiltrated municipal councils in order to strengthen their urban base of supfort. Such an approach parallels the CPl(M)'s strategy of gaining contro over the panchayats to strenl!'then its base in rural West Bengal. I have used pseuclonyms to describe all the people I interviewed with the exception of public officials whose actions are subject to open scrutiny. 3 The tenn BJP combine refers to the nexus of organizations which are affiliated with the BJP, most prominently the 'parent organization', the Rashttiya Swayamsevak Sangh (RSS) and the religious organization, the Vishva Hindu Parishad (VHP). S1naUer affiliated groups include the Durga Vahini (the women's wing ofthe VHP), the Bajrang Dal (the VHP's youth wing), and the · BJ P's mahila morcha (women's organization). The RSS Dig1t1zeo by Google Origi�al rrom UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 392 State and Politics in India the Meerut riots, he had collected relief funds for the Muslim victims. His detractors further accused Khan of souring Hindu­ Muslim relations by bringing baclc the bodies of Muslims who had been killed in a riot in a neighbouring town so they could be buried in Bijnor.4 As we will see below, Bijnor's demographic composition - of 48 per cent Muslims and 42 per cent caste Hindus and 8 per cent untouchables - posed an important challenge to Hindu organizations.5 However, Lal represented a poor alternative to Khan. Lal was relatively uneducated; he was reputed to be personally corrupt after the riots even BJP members admitted that he and his sons had acquired vast new wardrobes as a result of having looted Muslim shops. Politically, he was an opportunist. Between 1957, when he became active jn politics, until 1992, he shifted party allegiances seven times: from the Jan Sangh, to Congress-I, to the Swatantra Party, back to Congress, to the Lok Dal, Janata Dal and fmally to the Janata Dal-S (JDS, the Chandra Shekhar faction). Many of these shifts were prompted by his desire to achieve elected. office. By the spring of 1991 the J anata Dal had expelled him from the party. A local intelligence officer explained that in his anger that the JDS had not nominated him to run in the 1991 legislative assembly elections, Lal had engaged in the production of ex­ plosives which he planned to detonate in the home of the JDS candidate. However, the bomb self-detonated in Lal's own home. By contrast, Khan was a highly educated, sophisticated lawyer. In 1988 he appeared to be the obvious alternative, particularly to educated, middle class people. Muslims also coalesced around Khan; according to the BJP, electoral turnout was much greater among Muslims than caste Hindus. The competition which surrounded the nagar palika election exercises tight conttol over these organizations and ensures that they work closely together. 4 When I questioned Zafar Khan about the incident he admitted .he had brought back the dead bodies but denied that his actions were communal. How could his action he considered communal, he asked? The families of the young men who had been killed were friends and neighbours. Khan felt he owed it to the community to grace the dead with a proper burial. S The proportion of Muslims in Bijnor district is larger than in any other rural district in UP. In the district as a whole, the scheduled caste and Muslim population outnumbers caste Hindus; this has especially significant conse­ quences for parliamentary and legislative assembly elections. Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Political Process: Dominance 393 continued in its aftermath. The nagarpalika consisted of 24 mem­ bers, I 8 of whom were elected, 11 among them Muslim and 7 Hindus. Unlike the Muslims, many of the Hindu members were political activists. Ram Gopal was the local Shiv Sena president, Raghuvir Singh, the local Vishva Hindu Parishad (VHP, translated the World Hindu Organization) president, and Tilakwala, the head of the Bajrang Dal. There were six other nagarpalika mem­ bers: three of them were nominated to reserved seats for won1en and scheduled castes; the other three included an MLA, MP and the chair. A core group of elected members plotted to undermine Khan through allegations that he was misusing public funds and political office to serve partisan (Muslim) ends and discriminate against caste Hindus. As we shall see, their strategy was to use any means possible to gain majority support. Singh, a lawyer by profession and Khan's keen competitor, provided his explanation of how Khan had communalized Bijnor politics by misusing his office. He alleged that Khan had expended 80 per cent of the nagar palika's funds on sanitation and street lighting in Muslim neighbourhoods and only 20 per cent of these funds in Hindu neighbourhoods. Of the land under the nagar palika's control, the allegation continued, Khan had allotted 95 per cent of it to Muslims and only 5 per cent to caste Hindus (the latter in the form of a 'dharamsala' for scheduled castes). Furthermore Khan had sought to ensure that Muslims would monopolize political office. Although customarily if the chair of the nagarpaJilta was a Muslim, a Hindu was appointed as the vice chair, Khan had appointed Mustafa Aziz a Muslim, the vice chair. Moreover with one exception, Khan had appointed Muslims to all the other key posts on the 1111gt,rpalilta. Through these actions, Singh claimed, Khan was trying to build his future as a Muslim leader. Singh reported that over the past three years, Khan's Hindu opponents had done whatever they could to remove him from office. Singh had already gained the support of two of Khan's allies on the nagar paiika: Nikhil Sharma, a scheduled caste, and Ashraf Hasan, a Muslim. However, even this skilful move had not borne fruit for the Chief Minister had intervened to protect Khan by changing the nominated 111Jgar paiika members, for reasons that will be explained below. The opposition in tum brought charges of undue interference against the former Chief Minister. It. also Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 394 StiJU 'lfflil'P.o/itics in India brought charges against the district magistrate for refusing to hear its,.no-oonfidence motion. Given the possibility that the Chief Minister would continue to protect Khan, the opposition had simultaneously. pursued another strategy. It had coordinated with to ensure Deepak:Mehra, • editor and proprietor-of the Bijnor Times, that.the newspaper would discredit Khan and pave the Wllf for his def.eat i n th� 1993 ruzgarpalua elections: (Although DeepakMehra was,not a BJP supporter his ambitions to chair the nag11r palilta made h'im an ally of Hindu groups in ·this struggle.) The pages of the Bijnor Tima were filled �th stories which tlenig:rated Khan and sought to·build up · an ·alternative Muslim leadership which locally dominant caste Hindus could control. One example concerned aMuslim ·woman who-was raped by police constables while in the cmtody of the:superintendent of police. The·Bijnor Tna provii:Jcd: extensive coverage of the incident in order to discredit Khan fo., his inaction. While aqcusing Khan of concern for the• most vulnerable bcimg an opportunist who had' members of his. community, it 'praised. two· members of the Muslim, communi·ty, AshrafHasan·and Niaz Zaidi, fcir organizing a . demonstration in protest>. (Coverage of rape and other atrocities· agaiilst ,women, particularly Hindu women; were otherwise COD-'' spicuously absent from the Bifaar' Times.) · Zafar :JChan responded .to:thesecharges in some detail over the course of several· lengthy interviews. First he challenged the notion ·that he ha·d demonstrated Hvouritism to Muslim wards. Khan showed me a letter whiah he had sent to the eighteen wad members who·were elected to the· nagar palaa, authorizing them to ov.eriee sanitation: fun ·their particular wards; He, then showed me.led gers they had.initiated, consenting·to undertake this work. Another ledger contained a page which was divided into colwnns: on the first column was a list containing the names of the ward members and on an adjoining column the names of two sanitation workers for each ward. A third column was left blank for ward supervisors to sign every month, thereby certifying that the work had been performed satisfactorily. Another led ger contained sim­ ilar. information about street lighting. Khan showed me copies of the.ledgers between 1989 and 1991; Hindu members in wards 2, 6, 7; 11, 12, 17 and 18 had all reguJarly signed them. Khan had sent copies of these documents to the district magistrate for safe-keeping. own D1g1tizeo by Google no Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Politiclll Process: Domnumtt 395 Khan also clarified the process whereby officers were selected to serve on the nagar paJiluls subcommittees. He explained that the entire council, and not the chair alone, appointed the vice chair. Khan had favoured a Hindu vice chairman and proposed Pyare Lal for the post. He proposed that Radhika Seth, who had been nominated to fill the seat reserved for a woman, should serve as assistant vice chair. However, by that time his opponents had won Pyare Lal over to their side so he declined the post Radhika Seth also refused the appointment. In what he later regarded as poor judgment, Khan then entrusted the council to decide upon another vice chair. He continued, The meeting that day went on for a long time and we ·were unable to decide on a vice chair before we adjourned. So we scheduled another meeting. The day before this meeting was to be held I dropped in at Pyare Lal's house. I found my opponents assembled there. They had met without me and made Wajid Khan the vice chair and Sharif Mujahid [both Muslims] the assistant vice chair in order t o discredit me and divide my supporters. Khan did not let the matter rest there. He appealed to the administration to nullify the decision on the grounds that he had been deliberately excluded from the meeting. Khan consulted with the Commissioner in Morababad who declared that the resolu­ tions which the meeting had passed had no legal standing. In addition to the allocation of posts, these resolutions had reduced the chairman's fiscal and administrative powers. Khan also con­ sulted with the district government counsel who told him - in a letter that Khan showed m e -that members had to be told about nagarpaiilta meetings at least three days before they were held. If the chair was absent, he had to appoint a presiding officer who would attend the meeting in his place. In the absence of such measures, meetings of even a majority of nagar palika members would have no legal standing. However in the long run, Khan could not win the battle over political appointments. K.L. Joshi, Shanna and Seth, who had earlier supported him, had turned against him. The other four Hindu members of the nagar palika had long been his bitter opponents and appointing one of them as vice chair would have been suicidal. The press widely publicized the fact that Zafar Khan's two principal lieutenants were both Muslims. The allegation that Khan had allocated other influential posts D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 396 St11te 1111d Politia in India on the 1111g11r paJiluz to Muslims proved equally unfounded. Every year the chair appoints 1111g11r paliluz members to serve as subcom­ mittee conveyors to oversee octroi, construction, lighting, taxa­ tion, health and sanitation, and five subcommittees on cultural and recreational activities. Khan showed me official letters of appointment that he had drafted. In the f1ISt year that h e was chair, five of the posts were occupied by Muslims and another five by caste Hindus. In his second year as chair, although the persons within particular posts rotated, caste Hindus and Muslims were represented in equal numbers. Indeed, caste Hindus were over-represented for 11 of the 18 elected 1111g11r palilta members were Muslims and only 7 were caste Hindus. Moreover, by the second year, Khan knowingly appointed caste Hindus who were attempting to undermine him.6 Khan reported that on two different occasions his opponents had brought no-confidence motions against him by enlisting the support of a majority of the twenty-four municipal council mem­ bers. Included among those who signed the resolution was Kanshi Ram, an ex-officio member of the Bijnor nag11rpalika and a voting member of the recently elected municipal legislative council. The district magistrate agreed to the nagarpalika's request that Kanshi Ram be allowed to vote at its meetings. With the support of thirteen nagarpalika members, the opposition was confident that the state administration would support its no-confidence motion against Khan. When Khan learned of this ploy, he amassed evidence to prove that Kanshi Ram was an ex-officio member who did not have voting rights on the Bijnor nagar palika. But even without Kanshi 6Zafar Khan provided me following account of the allocation of posts in _the first and second years, respectively on the municipal council when he was chairman. I have noted members' religious identities in parentheses. Nikhil Shanna (Hindu): Octroi chairman: Mustafa Aziz (Muslim) L.K. Chaudhury (Hindu): health and sanitation: Surendra Bishnoy (Hindu) Ralcesbwar Pal (Hindu): convenor of music conference: Rakeshwar Pal Ram Gopal (Hindu): k:avi samelan: S.L. Rajagopal (Hindu) Praveen Kashyap (Hindu): k:avali: Avdesh Khanna (Hindu): wrestling: same Zaidi (Muslim): mushera: same Sharif Ahmad (Muslim): tu: Rafiudin (Muslim) Rais Ahmad (Muslim): lighting:.Niaz Ahmad (Muslim) Niaz Ahmad (Muslim): oonstruction: Sh:irifAhmad (Muslim) Dlgltlzedby Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Political Process: Drmsinance 397 I. E111; ulxm g, l2ll cultun ttetSa hen modi igh di luslim is W!II :mbct by dr 0 WIii OJICII! ng di meit ulLlh vooq L Th (lnj ortd 11 dd 100(1 pfOl! lull JnSii iJi i; ie-, inJvl I Ram's support, his opponents would have been disqualified be­ cause they had excluded Khan from voting. By including Khan and excluding Ram, support for the no-confidence motion fell from 13 to 11. To prevent the recurrence of such an incident, Khan then informed Mulayam Singh Yadav who changed the three nominated municipal council members. In June 1990 Khan's opponents tried once again to disqualify him by winning over the newly nominated members. They suc­ ceeded in gaining the support of Chandra Shamber, a scheduled caste. However, Khan recounte(I, he was able to get the nom­ inated members disqualified by showing that they had missed three consecutive meetings. Once again the Chief Minister changed the nominated members and foiled the no-confidence motion. At this stage, following upon its unsuccessful attempts it would seem, the opposition's strategy shifted from institutions to the streets. Disputed Plot ofLand The most serious Hindu-Muslim conflict that Bijnor had ex­ perienced until that point erupted on 25 August l990. Singh, Goel and Khan's other opponents, now joined by other members of Hindu organizations, alleged that Khan's anti-Hindu sentiment had most clearly emerged around a dispute concerning a vacant plot of land in a Hindu locality in the centre of town. Nandaji of the RSS claimed that the land belonged to a Hindu man who was living in Lucknow. When he had failed to pay his taxes on time the 1111gar palika had threatened to take over his land, whereupon he submitted the amount he owed. However, Khan cancelled his lease and allotted the land to aMuslim. Singh added a sensational twist to the story: the newMuslim tenant had planned to open a butcher shop where beef would be sold. In the meanwhile, accord­ ing to this accoWlt, the nag11r paJika had denied caste Hindus' request to build a dharamsala on the land. Rummaging through nagar palika files, Khan pulled out its property registry. On it was marked the plot of land (measuring roughly 41 by 55 and 39 by 26 -feet) adjoining a mosqu�. The req>rds indicated that the municipal council did, in fact, own this land. It had leased out a small parcel of it to Hari Das from Lucknow but had regained possession when he had ceased to pay Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 398 State and Politia in India his rent. Khan then showed me letters he had received from various groups and individuals, who were seeking to 'rent nagar palika land in different parts of town. Among these WU a request from a group of scheduled castes for land on which build a dharamsala in another part of town, to which the nagar alika had agreed. Overall, most of the requests that the municipa\ council had authorized came from caste Hindus rather than from Muslims. In the case of the disputed land, the nagarpalika.only received one request for rental and that was from a Muslitn; as mandated by the rules governing the council, a majority of its members had approved his lease. Had the chairman tried to usurp the council's powers by making a unilateral decision, his detractors would cer­ tainly have publicized his actions. Nowhere in the files was there a letter from caste Hindus requesting authorization to build a dharamsala on this land. Early on the morning of August 2 5 a small group of caste Hindus encroached upon the disputed plot of land and declared their intention of constructing a temple upon it. Among them were militant young activists of the Bajrang Dal and Shiv Sena, joined by older RSS and BJP members. 'Tilakwala', the local head of the Bajrang Dal who acquired his name from the enormous tilak (red mark) that covered most of his forehead, provided a vivid account of the events. Tilakwala's excitement was almost uncon­ tainable as he recounted the incident. We got up early in the morning and set off for the land bearing murtis of Vishnu and Lakshmi.When we arrived there we installed our idols, lit our incense and began doing Ramayana paath on the land. Later in the day we began constructing the mandir wall. Some time later Muslims came to the mosque for prayers. My friends were afraid of a fight but most of us held our ground. In fact we began to read our Ramayana paath even louder. By 8 pm the crowd at the spot had grown. Many im portant caste Hindus of the town joined us. All the time rumours kept circulating that the Muslims were gathering anns and planning to attack us. We had come heavily armed ourselves. I heard the Musluns shouting threatening slogans. A little while later the Muslims began throwing stones at us. At midnight the SDM, ADM and the police arrived at the spot. The Muslims began stoning then1 and hit a policeman [sic]; the police were enraged and opened fire. They killed two Muslims. Then the police took our murtis and destroyed the wall we had been building. D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Political Process: Duminance 399 The next day the police took us to the kotwal's office to bring charges against us but Hindu lawyers went on strike to protest our arrests. The Hindu shopkeepers joined the protest by closing down their shops for two days. Outside the kotwal's office caste Hindus organized a steady stream of people to court arrest: first women and children, then men. The women told the officers: 'If you won't allow us to have our mandir we will do Ramayana paath right here' and they did puja right outside the kotwal's office. Kalyan Singh [the current ChiefMinister of UP) came from Lucknow to encourage us. Nandaji, an RSS pracharak, provided additional details: What infuriated the Muslims were rumours that caste Hindus had captured their mosque. That was what made them collect stones and arm themselves. But we felt secure because we were in a Hindu locality and we thought we could gain co1nmunity support. In the morning we must have been twenty-five people, but by evening there were hundreds there with us. Even the policemen who had arrested ten Shiv Sena activists secretly told u s that they were on our side. Khan reponed that he wanted to avoid confrontation at all costs. He refused to accompany a group of Muslims to the spot on the 25th afternoon. The group then approached Niaz Zaidi, a more aggressive Muslim leader, who consented. However, other than some stone throwing, Muslims' response to Hindu aggres­ sion was extremely mild. Khan said that the administration had asked him whether he believed that the Hindu activists who were being held in custody should be released. He consented for fear that relations between the two communities would otherwise detetjorate further. The administration released the activists and took temporary control of the disputed land. To many caste Hindus this in itself was a victory, for the Muslim to whom the land had been allotted was thereby deprived of it. Several aspects of the struggle over leadership of the nagar palika and the land are significant. Although Khan persuasively demonstrated that the charges his Hindu opponents had brought against him were unfoundec:1, they succeeded in depicting him as a communal leader who discriminated against caste Hindus. Furthermore, the nagar palika, which has limited responsibilities for municipal governance, became publicly associated with the hated state. The next step was for Hindu groups to transfer this hatred of Khan on to a more powerful leader, Mulayam Singh Yadav. Dlgltlzedby Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 400 State 11nd Politics in India B1111ning ofRmn Jyotis The second incident to which people widely referred took place on 4 October. The VHP had planned a 'asthi kalasb' ceremony which entailed organizing a group of'ramjyotis' (devotees of Ram) to wind their way through the state with burning torches in hand, seeking to keep alive the tire it had ignited in Ayodhya. The Chief Minister had declared that the ramjyotis' entry would be banned, and the barrage over the Ganges river, which provided the only entry point into town, had been cordoned off. The ram jyotis arrived at the river banks the day before they had announced, on 5 October. What subsequently transpired was told to me by Rani Bansal, from the Durga Vahini, Ritu Chandra of the BJP mahila morcha and Rukha, a rasbtra sevilta. In Rani Bansal's words: I was stunned when I learned that the ramjyotis stood at the barricades, unable to enter Bijnor. I dropped everything and ran from one house to the next calling women to join us. Women poured out of their houses with babies in their arms. Some of them had gathered arms, stones, sticks, whatever they could tind to defend themselves. I did not even have time to put on my chappals - I marched bare feet for 12 kilometres. Along the way we kept calling people out to join us. By the time we reached the bridge there must have been 10,000 of us. We did not need any leaders to tell us what to do. With our bare hands we tore down the barricades and threw them into the river. The police just stood by and watched. No one tried to stop us. Bansal's romanticized recollection of the event, and her highly inflated account of the numbers of people in attendance, convey some sense of the empowerment women experienced in defying the state that day.7 More reliable accounts suggest that 1200-1500 people gathered together. I n what became a victory procession, the group marched back to town with the ramjyotis. Ashok Varma reported that he had asked the district magistrate how he planned to stop the procession and was told:'There is nothing we can do. There are far too many people here for us to stop them.' This entire episode was largely organized by women for whom this provided an important opportunity to dramatically break with their traditional roles by engaging in direct action. Yet their ac­ tions had the blessings of their husbands and fathers for the VHP 7 This particular event was a C.ltalyst for women's activism in Bijnor which then continued into the_period of the riot. Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN . The Political Process: Dominance 40I had decided to enlist women in this phase of its RamJanmabhoomi campaign. The incident provided an imponant precedent for wo­ men's subsequent activism, culminating, as we will see below, in their leading a procession through the Muslim quaners of Bijnor where violence broke out on 30 October. Mulayam Singh Yadav's 'Communal Harmony Rally' The founh incident that people agreed had sparked serious com­ munal tensions was a rally that Mulayam Singh Yadav held in Bijnor on 9 October. This was one of a number of 'communal harmony rallies' that the former Chief Minister had organized throughout the state. Their purpose, he stated in an interview, was to assure Muslims that he would prevent the rath yatra from entering the state and would do everything possible to ensure their safety. Instead, in grotesquely ironic fashion, the rally itself became the occasion for violence in which 3 people died -2 caste Hindus and I Muslim - 30 shops were looted and burned to the ground, and 95 people were arrested.8 Although everyone I spoke to regarded the rally as a critical marker of the further deterioration of Hindu-Muslim relations, they disagreed as to why this was the case. Mulayam Singh's sharpest critics, all of whom were caste Hin­ dus, contended that he had encouragedMuslims to arm themselves and use force when necessary in self-defence. He had succeeded in whipping up Muslims' passions and fears to the point that those in attendance filled their trucks with stones as they left the rally to return home. Some people felt that Muslims had come to the rally anticipating a fight. A few miles outside Bijnor, Muslims attacked the car of Janardhan Agarwal, the district president of the VHP. Agarwal described the incident as follows: I was on my way to Kiratpur with my family when I saw a mob heading towards Bijnor. When they saw my car they surrounded it. They threw stones at the car and damaged it. They would have killed me if some caste Hindus had not come to my rescue. Meanwhile rumo� circulated that I had been killed. Naturally there was some reaction. Others, both Muslim and Hindu, denied that Mulayam Singh's B In a grossly exaggerated estimate, the Bijnqr Tm,es reported thi)t 200 people had been killed as a result of the rally. Bijnqr Timrs, 11 October 1990. D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 402 Statt and Politics in India speech had been inflammatory. They claimed, as a report in the Pioneer newspaper corroborated, that he had blamed the Ram Janmabhoomi campaign for riots and accused Hindu organiza­ tions of distributing arms but urged Muslims not to retaliate.9 However, these observers felt that the sheer sight of thousands of Muslims from outside the district had frightened caste Hindus and provoked a backlash. In this vein, Ashok Varma recalled that he had opposed the rally in his editorials and predicted that it would ferment :l riot. Khan reported that although the BSP o f which he was a member had supported the rally, he had opposed it and refused to attend. Sandip Lal, the principal local organizer of the event, denied that Mulayam's speech had been inflammatory. What was pro­ vocative, he asked, about stating that he would not allow the mosque in Ayodhya to be destroyed? What was provocative about stating that he would abide by a court verdict on the status of Babri masjid/Ram Janmabhoomi? What was provocative about ensuring Muslims' safety? Lal held the BJP combine responsible for the violence. While declaring a boycott of the rally, the com­ bine had arranged for ten truckloads of caste Hindus to come to Bijnor from surrounding towns on 9 October. These people had fanned out to line all the major access points to Bijnor from where they tried to stop those who were headed to Bijnor from attending the rally. Once Mulayam Singh began speaking, Hindu groups returned to the town and set fire to effigies of Mulayam Singh. When the rally was over, caste Hindus once again lined the main roads and attackedMuslims as they returned home. Several other people confirmed Lal's tale of the BJP combine's complicity. Among the most revealing was Tilakwala, who boasted of the bonfires that the Bajrang Dal and Shiv Sena had lit to burn the Chief Minister's effigy. 'We shouted slogans calling Mulayam Singh a donkey', he laughed, 'and we carved his name on a donkey's back'! According to local intelligence sources, the BJP combine had been making plaps to obstructMulayam Singh's rally weeks earlier. The combine also planned the incident involving Agarwal and then circulated rumours that Agarwal had been kidnapped and killed, although in fact he had never been physically attacked. Like the land dispute, the 9 October rally further polarized 9 The Pionerr, 13 October 1990. Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Political Process: Dominance 403 Hindu and Muslim communities. Shopkeepers, a key constituency of the BJP, once again closed their shops for four days to protest the rally. The police arrested runety-five people, all of whom were caste Hindus. The Shiv Sena and its affiliates orgaruzed demonstrations outside the administrative headquarters in Bijnor, protesting the anti-Hindu character of the government, and ques­ tioning why it had only arrested caste Hindus. The government caved in under this pressure and dropped all charges against those who had been arrested for vandalism, looting and violence; sup­ port for Hindu organizations continued to grow. The Riot The BJP-VHP combine had arranged for thousands of so-called kar sevaks (voluntary workers) to converge on Ayodhya from all over the country on 30 October. Acting on instructions from the Chief Minister, the admirustration arrested 63 7 of these young men from various points surrounding Bijnor, at Balwali, Hardwar, and the barrage near the Ganges.10 Since there was no room for them in the local jail, it detained them in a girls' intermediate college in Bijnor. The next day, on the 26th, the kar sevaks launched a protest against 'prison conditions', demanding better food, sanitation, and other ameruties. That evening they at­ tempted to escape. The police intervened and opened fire. Al­ though K.L. Joshi, a Dainik Jagran reporter, visited the jail and found that the police had only killed one person, it was rumoured that the police were gunning down kar sevaks by the dozens. On 27 and 28 October shopk.eepers closed down their shops with allegations that the government had treated the kar sevaks in­ humanly. The following day several hundred people marched from the Arya Samaj manair to the collector's office where it engaged in a )ail bharo antic/an' (fill the jails campaign of volun­ tarily courting arrest). Hindu women from Bijnor were at the forefront of this protest. Many observers derued that kar .revaks had been mistreated while in confinement. Asbok Vanna reported that he had in­ spected the girl's intermediary college and found that the kar sevaks were better housed, fed and clothed than the large majority of prisoners. Furthermore, the term imprisonment was highly 10 The Bijm,r Tmus, 21 October 1990, p. 4 . Dig1t1zeo by Google Origi�al rrom UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 404 Statt and Politia in India misleading, for security at the girls' college was minimal; the kar · sevaks would usually spend the evenings in town fermenting disturbances and return to their lodgings at night. By 30 October, the day when the kar revaks reached Ayodhya, tensions dramatically escalated. The VHP had organized a large group of women to assemble outside the Arya Samaj mandir to do 'lrirtan' that morning. They were joined by the hundreds of kar sevaks who had been detained en route to Ayodhya. The atmosphere was extremely tense. Around 11 am, a police officer who had been listening to the radio rushed to the mandir with news he claimed he had heard over the BBC: the kar sevaks had reached Ayodhya, placed their flag on the mosque and started to demolish it. Within an hour, a victory procession of several hundred people marched through Bijnor shouting slogans about their determination to build a temple in Ayodhya. The procession marched towards Ghanta Ghar, a clock tower in the centre of town where the road forked, dividing the Muslim and Hindu quarters. The group disagreed over which way to proceed. The more militant members prevailed and the procession marched through the Muslim section. Muslim families had congregated on their rooftops from which they watched the procession with horror and fear. The Hindu demonstrators shouted ugly, provocative slogans like: 'Musalmlum kth do hi statm, Pakistan aur kabristan' (There are two places where Muslims belong: Pakistan and the graveyard) and 'Ttlligakt Dab11r ka, masjid girao babar ka' (by applying Dabar [a brand name] oil eradicate Babar's mosque), 'Hindu bachcha ram ka, Musamum h11ram ka' (Hindus are the children of God; Muslims are bastards). At some point along the way Muslims began to pelt stones at the processionists who responded in kind. Then one of the most tragic and inflammatory incidents of that day took place. Mushir Ahmed, a Muslim d0ctor who had a clinic in the centre of town, saw that Hindu women who were at the forefront of the procession were getting caught in the crossfire and provided them shelter. The account that follows was provided by Fazlul Hyder, a Muslim veterinarian. Ahmed was the most humane and secular-uunded person. He had kept his clinic open that day because he felt that people should resist chauvinistic attempts to divide the two conununities. That was also why he took those woJl}en into his clinic. But a rumour spread that Digiti zed by Google Ongmal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Political ProctSS: Drmtinanct 405 Ahmed had abducted Hindu women; some angry Hindu men broke into the clinic and murdered him. When Muslims carried Ahmed's body back to moh11Jla Charshiri where he had lived, people went out of their minds with grief and rage. A group of Muslims marched to Barwan [the neighbouring Hindu mohaJ/a] and attacked the caste Hindus there. Once the viol­ ence started, some other Musli111s joined in because they wanted to settle scores with a Hindu from Barwan who had been having a love affair with a Muslim's wife. Several hours later the Muslims had killed twelve people in Barwan. By the evening the administration had declared a curfew and all the Muslims went home. But RSS and VHP men roamed through the town spreading rumours that Muslims in Barwan were raping, kidnapping and murdering Hindu women. Significantly, Muslim violence in Barwan was directed at OBCs, a relatively vulnerable, subordinate group among caste Hindus. Upper caste Hindus later capitalized on this by plyingjhuggir with both relief as well as BJP propaganda. Riots in Bijnor as in other parts of the country galvanized caste Hindus to overcome caste divisions and confront their common enemy. The period of Muslim violence against caste Hindus was short­ lived. Sharma from the DainikJagran reported that whereas Mus­ lims observed the curfew, for they were afraid that they would be pulverized if they stepped out, caste Hindus roamed freely through the town, looting Muslim shops. What the administration termed a curfew in fact trapped Muslims within their walled quarters while giving caste Hindus free reign. From 31 October to 3 November, violence took on a wholly different character: it was no longer perpetrated by one com­ ml,lllity against the other but rather b y the state against Muslims. During this phase, as elaborated in greater detail below, district administrators, the police and above all the Provincial Armed Constabulary (PAC) accompanied by local Hindu residents, traclc­ e d down Muslim shops which they looted and destroyed. They searched out Muslim men and women, tortured them and shon them at point-blank range. It would do great injustice to the riot victims to shift too quickly to questions of causality without first providing a fuller account of the violence itself. As Gyan Pandey aptly notes, the liberal media often assumes that even if one community has suffered disproportionately more, objectivity necessitates equal Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 406 State 1111d Politics in India time to both communities.11 To rectify the distortions associated with such attempts at evenhandedness, the account below mainly relies upon Muslims' testimony. I visited the mohallas which had experienced the most severe violence, and spoke to informants I met there who then put me in touch with others. All of the people I describe below are ordinary men and women; none of them were political leaders or activists. The fll'St Muslim mohal/a I visited was Charshiri, a site of some of the most severe violence. I 1net Abdul Shamim sitting on the stoop of his house and asked him to describe the violence that he had personally witnessed. He recounted: The PAC arrived here on JI October around 2.30 pm. Some boys from the Bajrang Dal and Shiv Sena were identifying houses. One of the PAC members was holding a gatore [an instrument used to spray pesticides in the fields] which was filled with petrol. Th ey systemati­ cally went fro1n one house to the next, spraying each house with petrol and setting it on fire. There is a masjid across the street [he points it out to me] where about nine Muslims had taken shelter. I saw the PAC march in, drag people on to the streets, and beat them severely. None ofthese people tried to escape. But the [SOM] subdivisional magistrate ordered the PAC to open fue and shoot seven people.Two men who had been beaten severely still lay there. The PAC poured kerosene over them and burned them. The PAC did not w;ant to shoot them because their bodies were covered with bruises so instead the officers burned them to death. Shamim took me to visit his friend Abdul Sarkar who lived a few homes away from him to introduce me to some of the. people who had personally experienced the violence. We found the old man sitting in his bed which I was told he rarely left. Tears streamed down his face as he spoke: They killed both of my sons, 1ny two only sons. I am a widower and now I have no one in this world ... they killed both of my sons.... The SOM and sub-inspector ofpolice came to my house and searched for arms. We have no arms but I had collected 40,000 rupees for my older boy's wedding; he was to be married on 5 June. That was all 11 Another example of the way in which scholarly biases against Muslims are manifest is found in the tendency for works which purport to address the problem of communalisn1 in India to confine their attention to Muslim comn1unalism as ifHindu comrnunalism was non-existent. Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN I The Political /lrocess: Dominance 407 the ,noney I had. They took the n1oney, then they hauled my sons out of the house and shot them. When the sub-inspector who had been searching my house leaned over, his identification card fell out of his pocket. I kept it and made copies of it. Then I wrote to the Prime Minister and enclosed a photocopy of the ID. I said 'This officer .has killed my son. I saw hi.m shoot my son with my own eyes. What sort of a government do you run?' The government then awarded n1e Rs 1,00,000 in compensa­ tion. Shamim gave me a copy of the ID card bearing a picture of a clean-cut young man who must have been about the same age as his own son. For several weeks I carried it around with me and often stare4 at the photograph as if it would give me some ex­ planation for these senseless murders. When I would imagine to myself that I had surely heard the worst because I could not bear to hear more, thea: were always 1nore people, often with strikingly similar stories to tell. Within the same 11UJhal/a Jived a widower named Habib Afshar. When we heard that the PAC was invading Muslim ho1nes and killing innocent people, we wanted to run away. But where could we go? A cmfew was in force and the police had been given shoot on sight orders - which meant that any Muslim roaming the streets would be at great risk. So we could not run away. We were trapped in our. houses like prisoners. On the 31st afternoon, the PAC accompanied by Ra,npal and Jaspal, two local [Hindu) boys, broke into 1ny house. They looted my house and took all my savings. Then they dragged my son out of the house and tied his feet to a 'bail gari' (ox drawn cart) and took off. Once we could safely leave the house we searched everywhere amidst the st.cnch of decaying corpses. I could not give up hope until I found his body . near the railway crossing. He was my only son. He lived . with me. He supported me. He was 1ny reason to live. I visited Qasaban, a small, isolated, extremely poor Muslim mahalla, accompanied this time by a few Muslims whom I had met in other moha/Jas. Since I wanted to meet some Muslim women, they had brought me to the home of a widow who had suffered greatly. In or<ler to reach her house we had to pass through a long, narrow cobblestone path lined on either side by high walls. We went to a small house where I met a woman who must have been in her late thirties and her 5-year old daughter. The child sat by Digi tized b y Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 408 St11te and Politia in India my side looking haunted and sometimes terrified. Her mother spoke: It happened on the 31st afternoon. Four PAC men entered my house and said they had learned we were storing anns so they had come to search my house. Then they made all of us leave the house except for my 14-year old girl. They spent the whole night in the house violating my daughter. [She breaks into uncontrollable sobs.] I was outside, banging on the door, throwing my whole body against the door, trying to get in. The next day they brought her out to the courtyard and locked me inside. They doused her with kerosene and burned her to hide all proof of rape and murder. My home has become like a prison now. I wanted to run away but I bad no place to go and for days I lay awake all night afraid that th ey would come back and attack us. The Bij,wr Times reported that four mosques {but no temples) had been destroyed. I spoke with the imam ofNi,trani masjid, near B24 mohalla Charshiri, a frail and saintly man, whose home ad­ joined the mosque. He reported: On the 31st afternoon the PAC barged into my house. My daughters Tasleen, Nusrat and Rani were with me. They stripped Rani and took her to the other room. Then the SP [superintendent of police) and SDM entered the house. I thought that they would stop the PAC but instead the SP was shouting orders: 'shoot, shoot, shoot!!' They seemed to have lost control of their senses. The SDM shouted at us 'we have destroyed your chairman Zafar Khan and now we will destroy all your imams' [religious leaders)! After they had left my house I watched them from my courtyard. Twenty-one Muslims were killed in this moba/Ja and five arc missing; I saw the PAC kill three of them with my own eyes. And I saw that the SDM wa. s goading them on. Most of the violence was confined to urban Bijnor but there were reports of some violence in the surrounding villages, above all in ·Rampur Baldi which was about a mile east of Bijnor. Al­ though judged by the extent of construction, Baldi bore greater resemblance to an urban area than a village, most of its residents depended on agriculture for a livelihood. Patterns of agricultural production were quite typical of western UP as a whole. Baldi contains 256 houses of which 106 are Muslim and 150 Hindu. According to one account by Sharma from the Dainik Jagran, the damage done included: 17 people killed, 15 missing, and 620 • D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN . The Political Process: Domintma 409 injured; 21 houses were burned and 66 looted; 223 people were arrested. Sharma reported that although he did not have precise figu res of the damage incurred by each community, Muslims had suffered much more than caste Hindus. My first interview was with a Muslim family who owned about 6 acres of land and a spacious pucca house surrounded by a large courtyard. According to a woman in her late thirties: There is no history of communal violence here - not at all. When we heard news of the tensions in Bijnor we wanted to leave but our Hindu neighbours persuaded us to stay on. They said, 'Whatever happens in Bijnor, you know you are safe here.' At the time we believed them but now we feel that they deceived us. On the first night hoards of people descended on the village. Most of them had come from the town. With them were so1ne members of the PAC. They went to the Hindu homes and asked for help. Our neighbour Rakesh was helping them. When the Muslims saw this, most of them ran away. Some went to Bakshwala [a neighbouring village]; so1ne hid in the fields. We left at that time too. Those who remained here were killed. After about four days, the police came and found us and escorted us back to our houses. What a sight we found when we returned. The woman walked with 1ne through her compound. The granary had been set on fire and all the stored grain had been burned; the walls and roof of the granary were charred black. She then led me to the field where the tube well had been damaged and the plough dismantled. Inside her house was a small store­ room which had been ransacked and all the household valuables - money, jewellery, and equipment-had been looted. The most lasting damage was to their agricultural equipment. Since they could not afford to repair it, work on the land had virtually come to a standstill. The theft of the m9ney they had been accumulating meant postponing their son's marriage. I asked this woman how she explained what had happened. She responded: It all began on 9 October with Mulayam Singh's rally. We did not attend; in fact we were opposed to it but it made people very angry. Then there has been this whole Ram Jan1nabhoomi issue. Frankly we don't care whether a mosque or a temple stood there. What does it matter to us? And it didn't matter much to our neighbours either until recently. But now they have changed. Now we no longer trust them and we never can trust them again. Because when the mobs came here, Hindus became caste Hindus. Digiti zed by Google Ori ginal from -- UNIVERSITY . OF MICHIGAN 410 St11te 11nd Politia in India Her comment suggests how the identities of even those Mus­ lims who were indifferent to the Ayodhya dispute were redefined by it. Once caste Hindus had asswned the role of aggressors, Muslims inevitably became defined as victims. Makin g Sense of the Bijnor Riot One of the central paradoxes in explaining Hindu violence against Muslims is why caste Hindus, who form the dominant economic community, should feel threatened by the relatively powerless Muslim population. Most Muslims in Bijnor are poor; they are employed as workers in the sugar factory, rickshaw drivers, ar­ tisans, and craftspeople. The past few years have not wimessed the growth of a Muslim business class; remittances from the Gulf have not made their way back to Bijnor. If, compared to caste Hindus, Muslims are economically weak, they are also politically quiescent. Not even their most hostile Hindu critics claimed that Muslim fundamentalist organizations had been very ·active in Bijnor. There is only one respect in which Muslims dominate over caste Hindus and that is numerically. The town of Bijnor has a population of 65,000 of whom 48 per cent are Muslims and 42 per cent caste Hindus; 8 per cent of the Hindu population are scheduled castes. These statistics have acquired overwhelming significance in Bijnori politics. Interviews with Hindu men and women revealed an obsessive concern with the size of the Muslim population; given larger families among Muslims than caste Hin­ dus, they said, caste Hindus would soon be reduced to an insigni­ ficant minority. The more numerous, the argument continued, the more aggressive Muslims would become, for it was only their minority status that had kept Muslims' violent tendencies in check. Struggles over control of the nagar palik11 mimic struggles over parliamentary seats at the national level. In the system of vote bank politics, the critical question is how many seats parties can claim, not what they plan to do with the power they acquire. As in the national electoral context, some of the most acrimonious disputes on the nagar palika centred on the question of how the sympathies of women and scheduled castes would alter the balance of power. In Bijnor, caste Hindus openly enacted their fears by attempting Digiti zed by Google Ongmal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Politial Process: Damintmce 411 to appropriate and transform public spaces. As caste Hindus de­ fiantly marched through the heart of the town, they drove Muslims off the streets and on to their roofto ps or into their houses, thereby claiming public spaces as their own. But the demonstrations did not simply intend to confine Muslims to ever smaller spaces: they wanted to establish that there were no safe spaces for Muslims, and certainly none that.they could share with caste Hindus. It is in this context that the murder of Mushir Ahmed must be seen. Mushir Ahmed had doubly violated the strictures of Hindu mobs: he had defied their attempt to keep Muslims in their homes on 30 October, and he had also provided shelter to Hindu women. The state was also complicit in redefining public spaces as Hindu. For example according to innumerable sources, when the administration placed Bijnor under curfew, caste Hindus were able to secure passes which allowed them to move about freely, whercls Muslims were trapped inside their homes. Ironically, even the rt1m jyotis who were being detained in the girls' intermediary college had more freedom than Muslims to wander through the streets at night Some of the most serious incidents of violence took place when PAC and government officials forced their way into Muslim homes during the curfew period. The message was clear: there were no safe spaces for Muslims in Bijnor; their alternatives were either death or departure. The strategy apparently bore fruit: six months after the riots, many Muslim homes remained boarded up. Friends and neighbours of the departed reported that they had either relocated to other parts of town or left permanently. Caste Hindus' appropriation of what had traditionally .been a shared public space is significant in several respects. As explored below, it finds its corollary in the attempt to establish Hindu electoral supremacy. But to dwell further on the symbolic dimen­ sions of this attempt, in October-November 1992, caste Hindus appeared to be punishing Muslims for the wrongs they had al­ legedly committed over the centuries.12 One has only to recall 12 One way of understanding the repetition of r.vents, which adds a deeply disturbing, even haunting, quality to the violence in Bijnor, is by exploring the manner in which events are linked in temporal sequence through m e t.1 phor and metonymy as Veena Das describes in the case of liindu violence agai11st Sikhs in 1985. In Das's illustration, Hindus madeSikhs metonymically imitate the fate of the assassinated Prime Minister.Similarly in Bijnor, Hindus sought revenge against Mugbal rulers several centuries earlier and demanded Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN - . 412 S111te and Politia in lndill caste Hindus' charge that Muslims feel no loyalty to India; their true loyalties arc pan Islamic. Why else would they cheer for Pakistan during cricket matches? Why do they sclJ swcclS in the streets of Bijnor when Pakistan defeats India? Reall too the fears Hindu organizations expressed at the growth of Muslim economic and political influence. As if to rectify these supposed injustices, the curfew confined Muslims to their homes while allowing ram jyotis who were supposedly imprisoned to roam freely through the streets. The pattern of killings also suggeslS a symbolic resolution of Hindu fears of Muslims. My interviews with Muslims who had lost family members shows that the killings were not random: few women, older men and children had been killed; the major targets were young men, many of whom were soon to b e married. I n losing their sons, parenlS were deprived of the principal income earners in the family and of the possibility of grandchildren. In several cases families reported that the money, jewels and clothing that they had been accumulating for their sons' marriages had been taken. This particular form of looting seems to be designed to ensure that Muslims will be defecscless in the future. The rioters were also quite explicit in their attempts to cripple Muslims across the class spectrum. Muslim rickshaw pullers found their riclcshaws burnt to ashes, Muslim shopkeepers found their shops looted and Muslim farmers in Bakli found their agricultural equipment smashed. Similarly, some of the resentment against Zafar Khan must have been based on economic resentment, both at his relative affluence as well as his control over ""gllT JJillika resources. The caste Hindus who attempted to claim the plot of land on 25 August probably realized that this was a valuable piece of real estate. What then explains the Bijnor riot? In turning to the literature on communal riots for some guidance, one finds that two ex­ planations stand out. The fust approach argues that communal violence is of a primordial nature in that it expresses people's retribution by building a temple a t a site adjoining a mosque. This act in Bijnor was metaphorically linlced in tum to Hindus' attempts to build a temple in honour of Ram at Ayodhya. Veena Das, 'Introduction: Communities, Riots, Survivors-The South Asian Experience', in Veena Das (ed.), Minon of Violmct: Communitit1, Riots 1111d Surviwn in S1111th Asi4 (Delhi: Oxfurd University Press, I 990), pp. 26-7. Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Political Process: Dominance 413 most deep-seated, irrational anxieties and fears. The second ap­ proach depicts communal violence as closely associated with eco­ nomic rivalries. Neither approach fully explains the Bijnor riots. Participation in communal violence was to some extent irrational; for example it contradicted the material interests of shopkeepers, who form an important part of the BJP's constituency. Even violence that is employed in a purposeful fashion may become increasingly irra­ tional as it unfolds. However, people usually riot for reasons that are complex, multifaceted and rational. Furthermore, the primor­ dialist approach ignores the role of external agents in orchestrating what might appear to be a spontaneous outpouring of primordial sentiment Both points are illustrated by caste Hindus' fears of being reduced to an insignificant minority.Judged by the superior resources and influence that caste Hindus command within the society, such fears are patently irrational. However, judged by the BJP's aspiration to dominate electorally in the town of Bijnor, where Muslims from the 1najority of the population, such fear become more comprehensible. Some of the problems with the pri1nordialist perspective are reflected in the concept of communalism. The term communal lumps together diverse explanations for prejudice and violence, which it assumes are related both to one another and to tensions concerning religious identifications. In Bijnor, the use of the term communal to describe either Khan or his opponents, obfuscates the diverse reasons for people's attitudes.Because DeepakMehra, editor of the Bijnor Times, was one of Khan's major opponents, I assumed initially that he was sympathetic to the BJP. When I asked him why a photograph of Karl Marx hung above his desk, he answered, somewhat defensively, that he was a Marxist. Deepak Mehra was in fact so critical of the BJP that he said that some Hindu militants had threatened to burn his office down during the riots. Deepak Mehra's vendetta against Khan was motivated by the agreement he had struck with Sandip Lal, I was told by the editor of the Dainik Jagran. If elected, Lal had agreed to allot nagar palika land to the Bijnor Times group. Similarly, Sandip Lal, who was one of Khan's most fervent opponents, was closely allied with Mulayam Singh Yadav, the BJP's most important critic. Recall that Lal was one of the principal organizers of the 9 October rally which was said to have Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 414 Stt1te MUI Politia in India contributed to communal tensions in Bijnor. Yet Lal, like Deepalc Mehra, used the tenn communal to describe Khan for it was the easiest way to discredit him. Moreover the tenn 'communal' that they used was inevitably and dangerously vague. Khan was com­ munal because h e was attempting to build up a Muslim vote bank they alleged, as if he was the first to employ this strategy. But the term communal also implied that Khan had employed more dangerous, divisive and potentially violent means of pitting caste Hindus against Muslims. Two important points emerge from this analysis: first, the BJP's growth provided Khan's diverse rivals with a common language with which to depict him: not simply as an ambitieus and possibly opportunistic individual but as a Muslim chauvinist who would damage Hindu interests by furthering his own. Second, the four events beginning with the nagar plllika rivalries and ending with the riots are related in the minds of many Bijnoris with whom I spoke. At the same time it is important for external observers t o remember that the growth of the BJP lent coherence t o what might have otherwise remained a discrete set of rivalries. If on the one hand we must reject an idealized picture of communal harmony in the past, we must also challenge the seem­ ing timelessness of Hindu images of Muslim villainy. Even the most bigoted Hindu families reported that they had traditionally hired Muslim workers as domestic servants; it is unlikely that they would have done so if they had seriously questioned Muslims' trustworthiness. This does not mean that tensions between Hindu and Muslim communities were entirely absent Mohan Ram said that there were longstanding tensions between Muslims and his community (scheduled castes) in Raiteen mohalla: Muslims ex­ pected to be greeted with 'salaam' and complained that their neighbours played loud religious music while th ey were doing namaz. However, such derisive depictions of Muslims could only become the source of violent conflict through the BJP's attempts to construct stably derisive images of Muslims throughout north­ ern· India. Notions of the Muslim man as rapist, Muslim woman as subjugated, and all Muslims as anti-national, are part of the standard currency of Hindu communal ideology throughout the country because the BJP has polarized these conceptions. As I note below, one of the BJP's greatest achievements has been to create an aura of spontaneity around its carefully Digiti zed by Google Ongmal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Politiclll Process: D01ninanct 415 orchestrated initiatives. Some of the slogans which caste Hindus shouted in Bij�or on 30 October were exactly the same as the slogans in Ayodhya, and during riots in Indore, Jaipur and New Delhi between October-December 1990. Similarly, although there is a linguistic tendency to speak of rumours spreading in the passive tense as if they had spread themselves, there is strong circumstantial evidence that the BJP combine was in fact respon­ sible for circulating rumours which provoked violence, including the notion that Zafar Khan had allotted Hindu land to Muslims, that the VHP presidentJanardhan had been kidnapped and killed on 9 October, and that Mushir Ahmed had abducted Hindu women on 30 October. The circulation of numerous, vicious rumours, also helps explain why ordinary Hindu 1nen and women would suddenly tum on their Muslim neighbours. What n1ade these rumours so credible is that they were often spread by institutions that enjoyed widespread legitimacy: the press, administration, and political parties. For or­ dinary citizens who relied on these official channels of information, particularly at a time when everything most precious to them was at stake, it would make sense to abide by ominous warnings. The role of rumours, in other words, is critical in dispelling assumptions o f either prlmordialism or false consciousness on the part of the ordinary Hindu men and women who silently wimessed or actively participated in the riots. Similarly, the local press played a critical role in exacerbating tensions between Hindu and Muslim communities. The growth of towns like Bijnor in western UP, in which literacy rates are relatively high, has created a large market for newspapers. In the town of Bijnor itself, one Urdu language paper and five Hindi papers were widely read: Amar Ujala, Bijncr Times, Dainik Jagran, Chungari, and the Uttar Bharat Timu. The combined circulation of these newspapers was several lakhs in the Bijnor township. But even smaller papers like the Bijnor Times and Amar Ujala, which were restricted to Bijnor proper, had beco1ne very influential because of detailed coverage of local issues. Nor was their inter­ vention exclusively editorial. Several newspaper proprietors had become active in local politics: Deepak Mehra, senior editor of the Bijnor Times and Kashya p of the Uttar Bharat Times, had both stood for nagar palika elections. The biases of larger newspapers like Dainik Jagran emerged in Dig1t1zeo by Google Origi�al rrom UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 416 Stlltt and Po/itia in India their reporting on Ayodhy:a. Indeed, the Press Council of India censured the Dainik Jagrtm for its biases in this context. Local papers, of which the Bijnor Times is the most important example, described events surrounding the Bijnor riot in a highly inflam­ matory fashion. Concerning the Chief Minister's raily, for ex­ ample, the paper reported on 11 October that 100 people had been killed and injured, thereby inflating the casualties and con­ flating injuries and deaths; that same day the Dainik Jagran re­ ported that only three people had been killed. Similarly, while the Dainik Jagran of 29 October reported that three kar sroalts had been injured by bullets and twenty others in a subsequent fight, the Bijnor Times reported a day later that security forces had violently attacked and injured 100 kar sroalts. To add pathos to the account it stated that many of those injured had not even been bandaged. It quoted some women who had visited these kar sevaks as commenting that not even the British had acted in such a repressive fashion. On 31 October the Bijnor Times offered an account that held Muslims responsible for the violence. It reported that stones from rooftops pelted down on a peaceful Hindu procession which then forced caste Hindus to respond. The report stated: 'It has become clear that today's rioting was pre-planned. Until the 30th morning the fight was between the government and majority community; no one thought that the minority community would get involved'. As if to remove any ambiguity that might have arisen from this account, the Bijnor Times featured an article on 1 November entitled 'Riots Pre-Planned'. The reporrstated that the riots could not have been spontaneous for it would have been illogical for people to attack a peaceful procession. It noted that the first shop to be burned belonged to a Hindu. Moreover, all the violence emanated from the Muslim moha/Jas. Compared to the primordialism argument, the economic ap­ proach provides a more plausible explanation for what transpired in Bijnor. Whereas Muslims hardly engaged in any looting of Hindu shops, caste Hindus looted Muslirns' goods and burnt their shops to the ground. Similarly in Bakli, caste Hindus not only looted Muslims' houses but destroyed their means of production. In the events preceding the riots, economic rivalries most likely fuelled Hindu resentment of Muslims. One source of resentment. against Zafar Khan that transcended party divisions may have Dlgltlzedby Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Political Process: Duminance 417 been his economic standing and his control over nagar paJika resources. However, the economic explanation is inadequate, for the BJP combine orchestrated much of the material damage that was inflicted upon Muslims. This in tum suggests that for both the BJP combine and its followers, economic and political motivations were closely interwoven. Most of the looting and destruction of Muslim shops took place between 1 and 5 pro, when the curfew was in effect. Given the need for curfew passes to leave home during this time, the numbers involved with this looting must have been relatively small. Fur­ thermore, my intelligence informant reported that Hindu shop­ keepers had emptied their shops by this time. For example the police had fowid that one affluent Hindu shopkeeper was storing ninety-two television sets in his home for his friends in anticipation of the riots.13 The elaborate arrangements associat� with trans­ porting heavy consumer durables out of their shops belies the notion of a spontaneous riot. It seems more likely that Hindu shopkeepers took advantage of the riots by looting Muslim shops than that they provoked the riots in order to engage in looting. Another excellent example of the close relationship between the economic and political dimensions of the riots concerns the arms production in Bijnor. Muslim and Hindu informants re­ ported that arms production had proliferated for several years preceding the riot. In the villages bordering Moradabad and Bij­ nor, arms production had become a lucrative cottage industry. In Nagina, Ahmed reported, a gun that normally cost Rs 500 was selling for twice that price during the riots. Although the in­ dividuals who produced arms and explosives may have been eco­ nomically motivated, the political context enabled them to act. Ashok Varma reported that he had met the seniormost admini­ strative officials in 1988 and told them they should stop the arms build up on the part of both commwiities, but they had not heeded his warnings. Khan, the ADM who been posted to Bijnor after the riots, said that for the first time in years the administration had stopped freely issuing licences for gwis. Since taking office it had brought 125 cases against the manufacturers of illegal arms. 13 Titis officer informed me that many of these Hindus had made significant amouncs of money from insurance cl:lims on goods which they had hidden during the riots. Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 418 State and Politics in India Thus while many individuals inight have still hoped to profit from arms manufacturing, political considerations precluded their pur­ suing economic motivations. The close relationship between the economic and political dimensions of the riots is best explored by returning to the question of why Zafar Khan was the object of such virulent hatred. To the extent that caste Hindus provided any ·one explanation for the riots, it centred upon his role. Indeed Khan had received so many death threats that the district magistrate had hired a full-time bodyguard to protect him. What was most striking was that Khan was so often accused not only of communalizing the local administration but also of subsequently instigating violence. However, nobody questioned the fact that Khan had opposed and even boycotted Mulayam Singh Yadav's rally. Nobody alleged that Khan had even been at the site of the violence on 30 October or in the days that followed. What then made Zafar Khan so threatening? I would argue that Khan represented a seriqus threat to Hindu communal groups by virtue of his position in the nag/ITplllik11. As different as they appear, antipathy towards the state and a despera­ tion to capture state power may be closely related. Both sentiments demonstrate an appreciation of the access to life chances that control over the state yields. Atul Kohli notes, The 1nore control a governn1ent has over its people's access to life chances in a society, especially in a society in which alternative routes to satisfactory livelihood are scarce, the more the everyday struggles of livelihood take on a political character. Getting one's children admitted to a school, getting a loan to buy an irrigation pump, getting a job on a new public-works project, helping a relative g� a job iri the municipal govern1nent - all of these require the influence of someone in power.14 As both the struggles over leadership of the nagar p11Jika and the land demonstrate, the resources which people sought are at once economic and political, material and symbolic. Khan's rivals resented his chairpersonship in part because it enabled him t o allocate valued resources; similarly, the land on which Hindu groups sought to build a temple was both materially and sym­ bolically valuable. But, as Kohli points out, these conflicts arc 14 Atul Kohli, Dmu,cracy and Piscontent: India's Gnn»mg Crisis ofGwer,u,bility (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991), p. 198. D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 1'he Political Process: Dominance 419 ultimately political because they are provoked by political parties and a highly interventionist state. What made Khan especially threatening was not that he had communalized Bijnor politics, as his rivals alleged, but the very opposite: by virtue of the diverse support he enjoyed and continued to cultivate, he prevented the BJP from gaining caste Hindus' unified support. Recall that Khan was elected chair of the n11gar paiika with significant H.i,ndu sup­ port. Not surprisingly, his rivals' first move was to try and win over Khan's scheduled caste and Muslim allies, for, without their support, caste Hindus could not achieve electoral dominance. Moreover Khan did not confine his broad-based alliances to the 1111garpaiika. He also sought to cultivate them in the Bahujan Samaj Party (BSP), a party of scheduled castes, and by forging linb with the then Chief Minister, Mulayam Singh Yadav. The BSP, a re­ gionally based political party which represented a relatively small force in national politics, was a major force in the Bijnor political scene. In 1989 a woman named Mayavati had been elected t o PjlI'liament from Bijnor. A scheduled caste herself, Mayavati con­ structed her coalition from an alliance of scheduled castes and Muslims against middle and upper caste Hindus. Intense Hindu resentment at the nagar paiika's decision to allot scheduled castes land to build a dharamsala must be viewed in the context of the recent scheduled caste-Muslim alliance under the BSP's aegis. In some striking ways, Mayavati's appeals simply inverted those of the BJP. For example the alliances that she created were based upon the arithmetic of caste and communal electoral calculations. Rhetorically her style resembled that of inflammatoryi3JP leaders in that it was impassioned, exclusionary, and often vulgar. At one of Mayavati's public meetin gs she coined the slogan, 'Musalman­ Harijan bhai-bhai, yeh Hindu yahan kaiseh aye?' (freely translated: Muslims and Harijans are brothers, how did the caste Hindus get here?) In another speech, she described BJP leaders as impotent. Much of her campaign for the 1990 elections focused on her determination to prevent the construction of a temple in Ayodhya. One important explanation for why the BJP found Khan so threatening was that he was the BSP's most prominent leader in Bijnor. Khan commented: What were the real sources of Hindu resentment against me? I had helped the BSP to forge a powerful scheduled caste/Muslim com­ bination in this area. When Mayavati first won the elections in 198 5 Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 420 Stilt� 1171d Politia in India she did not have Muslim backing. But by 1989 she won because of it This was what caste Hindus resented most. Then during the riot, in many areas scheduled castes provided protection to Muslims. This bas been one of the BSP's major achievements. A further source of Khan's unpopularity was his close relation­ ship with Mulay.am Singh Yadav. Recall that when faced with harassment by Hindu 1111gar paiika members, Khan simply ap­ pealed to Mulayam Singh Yadav who had the nominated members replaced. If Zafar Khan was hated by many caste Hindus in Bijnor, Mulayam Singh Yadav was despised by virtually all of them. Mulayam Singh was a Yadav, a member of the so-called other backward castes (OBCs), a group which had traditionally rejected the BJP and its predecessor, the Jan Sangh, which were based among the middle and upper castes. Furthermore, Mulayam Singh Yadav was a strong supporter of the Manda! Commission recom­ mendations to reserve 27 per cent of seats in pub_lic employment for the 3000 caste groups which constitute the OBCs. Historically, the rise of the 'backward castes' represented the mos_ t profound challenge to established patterns of dominance in state politics. 15 Only a few months earlier, the country had been rocked by agita­ tions against the V.P. Singh government's decision to implement the Manda! Commission recommendations. Mulayam Singh Yadav had also emerged as one of the most outspoken critics of the BJP and its Ramjanmabhoomi campaign. In October he had held 'communal harmony rallies' throughout the state where he vowed to prevent the 'kar sevaks' from making their way to Ayodhya. Many caste Hindus in Bijnor described his speeches as highly inflammatory and claimed that he had polarized Hindu-Muslim relations by resorting to repressive IS Zoya Hasan relates two concurrent developments in Uttar Pradesh in the decade beginning in 1967: the politicization and 1nobilization of the middle and backward castes and the decline of Congress party dominance. She argues that through OBC support, Charan Singh's Bharatiya Lok Dal was able to challenge the political dominance of Brahmans and Thakurs. One important consequence, which was to have salutiry consequences for the BJP, was renewed cooperation between Brahmans and Thakurs from the 1980s o n ­ wards. Zciya Hasan, 'Power and Mobilization: Patterns of Resilience and Change in Uttar Pradesh Politics', in Francine R Frankel and M.S.A. Rao (eds), Dam;,11mce mid State Pl1ll)tr in Modern India: Dtcline of II Social Order .(Delhi: Oxford University, 1989), p. 189. D1g1t 1zeo by Google Orlgmal frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Political Process: Dominance 421 means. However, Mulayam Singh was placed in a 'no win' situa­ tion: although banning the kar sevalcs from entering the state was likely to backftre, allowing them to enter see,ned likely to provoke even greater violence. The antipathy of the middle and upper castes towards Mulayam Singh Yadav sheds new light on the events which preceded the 30 October riot. It calls into question assumptions of primordialism and single-minded material calculation. Rather, it suggests the significance of popular antipathy to the state combined with ex­ pressions of caste dominance in explaining opposition to the Chief Minister's rally on 9 October. Similarly, two of the women who had participated in the 24 October events described the actions of the state as being the major source of their rage. When the kar sevaks in the girl's intermediary college went on a hunger strike, it was images of state repression that once again galvanized women . . into acnon. A slightly different way of understanding the hatred that upper caste Hindus expressed towards Zafar Khan and Mulaya,n Singh Yadav, along with Mushir Ahmed, the third protagonist in this story, is by noting the way all three men transgressed caste and 'communal' boundaries. 16 Hindu support had enabled Khan to become chair of the nagarpalika; his rivals thus sought to refashion Khan as a communal leader to deprive him of Hindu support. Mulayam Singh had similarly challenged notions of a pan Hindu identity by forging a caste-based alliance among OBCs, untouch­ ables and Muslims. Although he was not a political leader and had no political ambitions, Mushir Ahmed posed a threat to Hindu nationalists by seeking to protect Hindu women just when tensions in Bijnor were becoming explosive. 1-Iis simple gesture challenged Hindu chauvinist depictions of the sexually predatory Muslim man raping the pure and vulnerable Hindu woman. The political di­ mensions of this struggle are extremely significant: by the I 990s Hindu nationalism was both cause and effect of the narrowing of social identities. Attempts by Khan, Mulayam Singh and Mushir Ahmed to keep identities fluid, had thus become increasingly threatening to the BJP's project. Compared to the attention that the BJP's attempt to harden communal identities has received, relatively little attention has· 16 I am gr.1teful to Udh ay Mehta for this insight. Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 422 St11tt 1111d Politics in India been accorded to its preoccupation with caste. However, in many respects Muslims simply provide the BJP with a nee� ttope in order to fulfil its more critical objective of overcoming caste divisions among caste Hindus. Events in Bijnor can be fruitfully reinterpreted from this perspective. The upper caste Hindus who opposed Khan's. leadership were undoubtedly enr2ged by Khan's · temporary alliances with a scheduled caste nagar paJi& member and an OBC ChiefMinister. Had Khan allotted the land in town to a Muslim, it might have been less infuriating than his decision to allot it to scheduled castes for a dhar2msala. Similarly, Hindu communal groups were enraged.by Mayavati and Mulayam Singh Yadav identifying them as 'brahmans, Baniyas, and Thakurs' and thereby uncovering their attempt to speak on behalf of all caste Hindus. Rok ofthe BJP Combine One of the major sources ofBJP·strength in Bijnor is the close links it has forged with the RSS, VHP, Bajrang Dal, Shiv Sena, and Arya Samaj. Sometimes the distinctions between these organizations are barely discernible: Rajiv SociTilalcdari, recoUl)ted thatVishan Bhir, an RSS 'pracharalc' had visited Bijnor and made him the district president of the Bajrang Dal and the president of the BJP's youth wing, thereby rendering distinctions between these two organiza­ tions insignificant. In the course of my research, I found members of these organizations constantly visiting each other's homes, sug­ gesting that they enjoyed close personal relations. On each of the occasions described earlier, there was extensive co-ordination among Hindu organizations. On 25 August Shiv Sena and Bajrang Dal activists closely co-ordinated with the BJP in planning the occupation ofnagarp11Jik11 land. Similar co-ord�­ tion was evident on 4 October when the Durga Vahini, rashtra sevikas and BJP mahi/a morcha organized women to accompany the ram jyotis to Bijnor. 17 The BJP has been the chief beneficiary of 17 At times tensions between Hindu organizations in Bijnor were evident. Ram Gopal complained that while the BJP mouthed empty rhetoric about Hindu rashtra, if often moderated its stance in the electoral context and distance<! itself from the more radical Hindu organizations; the Shiv Sena was much more consistent in its stance. Confirming Gopal's view, Dineshji asserted, despite evidence tQ the contrary, that the RSS refused to ally with the Shiv Sena, The BJP's strategy ofallying with militant Hindu organizations Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Political Process: Duminance 423 these close relationships among Hindu organizations. When one adds together the membership of local chapters of the RSS, BJP, VHP, Bajrang Dal, Durga Vahini, BJP mahila morcha, Shiv Sena, and Arya Samaj, the network of influence that the BJP combine has established bears greater resemblance to an urban guerilla army than that of a political party. Atnidst sociai cultural and religious . organizations, the BJP stands out as being the only political party. The BJP has played a double game. As a political party it has sought to demonstrate its moderate, responsible character, at times by distancing itself from militant Hindu groups like the Shiv Sena. However, at other times it has relied upon these groups to cultivate the anti-Muslim fervour which is critical to building a liindu electoral constituency. F u r ­ thermore, its ties with social, cultural and religious organizations appear to link the BJP with traditional values and thereby confer upon it a legitimacy that most political parties lade. For example in Bijnor the BJP is closely identified with the Arya Samaj, which has been active there since 1901. Although the Arya Samaj.has de­ generated over the years, it is still respected because of the leading role it once played in social reform and women's education. A second source of BJP strength is the considerable autonomy that national leaders accord to local party units to interpret and implement the party's larger objectives. This approach sets the BJP apart from the two major competing ,nodels. The Congress party allows local units a high degree of latirude but does so from weakness rather than strength for its party organization is in shambles. The CPl{M), by contrast, maintains a more centralized party apparatus and allows for little spontaneous initiative at the local level. 18 In contrast to the CPl(M), which generally designates the precise timing of demonstrations, BJP leaders in New Delhi do not determine exactly when riots will occur. Rather they en­ courage local leaders to create an environment in which at some point a spark will lead to a forest fire. Thus the BJP combine in Bijnor created several opportunities for riots, on 25 August, 9 and · 24 October and finally 30 October. The likelihood of a riot continuously increased with each successive incident. at the local level while ,naintaining a principled ideological distance from them worked to the BJP's advantage. 18 SeeAmrita Basu, TwoFMuofProtut: Contrasting ModesofWomnu'A(tivim, in ]ndi11 (Berkeley: University of California Press, 1992). D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 424 State and Politics m India Leading activists carefully orchestrated the 25 August incident with litde popular support. This probably explains why Hindu leaders dropped their. demand to build a temple on nagar palika land. Scheduled castes were most explicit about their disinterest in the issue. A man I interviewed from mohalla Raiteen asked rhetorically why they should help construct a temple from which they would be excluded. By 9 October, popular support for Hindu organizations had grown. Again it was the local leadership that made elaborate plans to obstruct the Chief Minister's rally by plastering the town with anti-Mulayam posters, persuading caste Hindus to boycott the event, organizing a bandh, and preparing effigies of the Chief Minister. However, the leadership succeeded in sufficiently arous­ ing passions that in some villages caste Hindus stoned Muslims as they wound their way home. The Durga Vahini's leading role in 'freeing' the ram jyotis on 24 October was partly a response to VHP directives that it shoulder the Hindu cause while men were away in Ayodhya. But if women's actions were not wholly spontaneous, nor were they wholly orchestrated. By 30 October, in comparison with the preceding incidents, high-ranking male leadership was less visible and popular participation was more extensive. A third skill that the BJP has employed has been to link events at local and national levels. Consider the following �pie: on 25 August a small group of caste Hindus protest against the anti-Hindu bias of the Muslim leader of the town. They do so by seeking to build a temple on land near which a mosque presently stands. Tilakwala commented: 'There was a masjid on the land; it was just like Bahri masjid. We used to think of it as the same masjid and we even referred to it that way.' In an exact repetition of their actions in Ayodhya, caste Hindus instal idols and begin to worship there. Similarly, in protesting against the banning of kar sevaks and their subsequent detention within the town, the BJP seemed to be linking events in Ayodhya and in Bijnor. If Bijnor occupied a more prominent place on the Indian map one might be tempted to trace events in Ayodhya back to earlier events in Bijnor. lnstead, Bijnor seemed to be the BJP's dress rehearsal for its performance in Ayodhya. The riots placed Bijnor on the national map and defined its national identity in communal terms. However, it is not religious belief that incited people's passions Digiti zed by Google Ongmal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Political Process: DMninance 425 on either 25 August or 30 October. None of the caste Hindus who were interviewed described their actions in these terms. Moreover, the small group of caste Hindus who occupied the land on 25 August attracted very little support .from the broader Hindu com­ munity. Even Tilakwala admitted that what had finally infuriated people was the arrest of ten people who had occupied the land. Ten days after the arrests the Commissioner of Moradabad had informed Khan that he was going to release the detainees because he could no longer withstand public pressure. In the 25 August incident, as with the banning of ram jyotis from Bijnor and the 'prisoners' strike, the BJP identified a theme which had deep cultural resonance: a group of innocent people had been martyred by an unjust state. The BJP embodies and exacerbates peoples' ambivalent at­ titudes towards the state. On the one hand, the BJP affirms peoples' deep-seated alienation from the state and from the Con­ gress system in particular while attempting to channel this aliena­ tion arounc\ the state's supposed appeasement of Muslims. In this context, Abbay Saxena, the local VHP president, informed me that there were two incidents which formed milestones in the BJP combine's growth in Bijnor: Rajiv Gandhi's decision to-over­ turn the Supreme Court verdict on Shah· Bano and V.P. Singh's decision to declare Prophet Mohammed's birthday a national holiday. On the other hand, given the BJP's electoral aspirations, it cannot afford to simply convey disinterest or distrust in the state. Rather it implies that if elected, a BJP government would remedy all of the state's current failings. In both its distrust as well as its reliance on the state, the BJP identifies a deeply felt popular ambivalence towards the state. Role ofAdministration In analysing the role of the local administration in Bijnor, three phases might be distinguished. In the first phase, which spanned the period between 25 August and 30 October, despite provocation by Hindu communal groups, the state was indecisive, unprepared and relatively inactive. For example Hindu militants occupied the nagar pa/ilea land early on the morning of 25 August. Although Khan had notified the police by 10.30 am, they did not arrive at the spot until 9 pm. By this time the gathering was larger, more D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 426 St11te 11nd Politics in India vociferous and harder to disperse than it had been several hours earlier. Furthermore as if to compensate for their earlier inaction, upon arriving at the spot, the police quickly opened fire, thereby killing two Muslims who had been entirely peaceful. Given the backdrop of the 25 August incident and of a com­ munally charged context nationwide, the administration's lack_ of prep;u:ation for the 9 October rally was even more surprising. According to several informants, it had not made adequate security arrangements along the major roads leading to and from Bijnor. Even if the administtation had somehow not anticipated violence earlier, by the time Muslims had assembled in Bijnor it should have recognized that tensions were running high, for fights had broken out at several spots along the way. During the several hours in which Muslims were attending the rally, the administration could still have deployed more forces to ttouble spots but it failed to do so. Similarly, when crowds rushed to the site of the Ganges river to bring back the ram jyotis, local police and government officials did not even attempt to stop them. Rani Bansal commented that a few uniformed police watched helplessly as the crowds dis­ mantled the barricades. The combination of the government's early bravado - as in Mulayam Singh's vow that not even a bird would enter the state - and its later inaction increased people's sense of efficacy. Several women described the sense of empower­ ment they experienced at defying what had earlier appeared to be inviolable government resttictions. Those who argue that the governll\ent was unprepared because Bijnor had no history of communal violence forget the warnings that the government had received on 2 5 August, 4 October and 9 October. Even aside from these incidents, there was other evidence too of an explosive political climate. For example schools and colleges had stopped functioning on 25 August and had not yet reopened. Furthermore, on 27 October, a huge meeting took place in front of the Arya Samaj, to plan a procession for the following week. According to an eyewitness who wished to remain anonymous, Shiv Shankar, the additional disttict magistrate (ADM) who was at the meeting, made no attempt to disband it although section 144 prohibiting such gatherings was in effect at the. time. Numerous lower ranking government officials were apparently also present. Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Political Process: D01ninance 427 However, the most shocking descriptions of government inac­ tion pertain to the events that transpired between 30 October and 3 November. Four different sources provided almost identical accounts of pleading with the leading administrators to stop the procession. Sandip Lal saw the procession assembling outside the Arya Samaj temple on the 30th morning and asked the district magistrate (OM) to call it off but the OM apparently informed him that there was nothing he could do to stop it even though Lal said he reminded the OM that the law was on his side. Zafar Khan sought out the superintendent of police that same morning to request that he place Bijnor under curfew. 'The SP was evasive', Khan reported, 'he said he would discuss it with the DM. Then he disappeared and for the next several hours as tensions were mounting, they were nowhere to be found'. Two of the most noteworthy accounts were provided by gov­ ernment officials. J.P. Gerola, deputy magistrate, was one of the few officers who was not transferred out of Bijnor after the riots. Thus he.was among the few offi�ials who could provide an eyewit­ ness account of the riot. Gerola reported that he had accompanied the deputy superintendent (DSP) to the Arya Samaj mandir on the 30th morning. When I saw the huge mob assembled there I pleaded with the ADM and the DSP. 'Call off the procession or there will be trouble,' I told them. The DSP replied, 'We have discussed matters with the Hindu leaders and they have assured us that nothing will go wrong.' I said 'Even if the leaders are responsible, they cannot speak on behalf of the whole conununity.' But no one would listen to me. An intelligence officer who remained in Bijnor after the riot provided a second official report. When he saw that the procession could no longer be halted, he asked the DM to prevent it from passing through the Muslim quarters. The DM apparently re­ sponded that there was nothing he could do to stop it because women and children headed the procession. He and others also suggested that the administration immediately impose a curfew but it failed to do so until 31 October at 1.30 am. Shortly after the procession began, the first phase, which had been marked by inaction, came to an end and the second phase of n1ore aggressive official complicity commenced. Muslim fam­ ilies described in detail the atrocities that Hindu officers had committed, for the image of supposedly neutral officials engag ing Digi tized by Google Original frcm UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 428 Stau and Politics in India in brutal violence ,vas so vividly etched in their minds. The precise cause of the administration's more ag�essive stance was Muslim violence against caste Hindus in Barwan, which was precipitated in turn by caste Hindus' murder of Mushir Ahmed. According to Ashok Varma, when the ad,ninistration and police witnessed the casualties that Muslims had inflicted on caste Hindus they sought revenge, 'At that stage', Vem1a continued, 'Hindu or­ ganizations were no longer necessary.' The deprofessionaJization of the civil services had reached a point such that officers could display their naked communal identities. The third phase of violence commenced on 31 October when the Provincial Armed Constabulary arrived in Bijnor and began to comb Muslim resid­ ential quarters. The violence that occurred during this phase was of the most extreme and brutal form that Bijnor had experienced in the course of the riot. However, the entry of the PAC did not supplant either government officials or members of Hindu or­ ganizations. Indeed, an interview with a group of PAC members who were still stationed outside '3ijnor was extremely revealing in this respect These officers were at pains to emphasize that they had never been to Bijnor before and knew nothing about the lay-out of the town. Thus they were accompanied and directed by police, administrative officials and often some members of Hindu organizations. Sunil Mehra, editor of the Bijnor Times, reported that the administration further confused people by misleading them about its own actions.19 On 1 November the Inspector General of Police told the press that 1000 people had been arrested in connection with the riot; the radio broadcast this information. Four days later the senior superintendent of police announced that only 326 people had been arrested. After the riots, the Chief Minister had the entire administration changed. The new administration was reputed to be extremely secular in orientation and diverse in its composition; the district magistrate in the new administration was a scheduled caste, and the ADM and SOM were Muslims. Since December when this administration had been appointed, there had been no reports of communal violence in Bijnor. I asked the district magistrate 19 Raghuvansi, 'When Hell Broke Out as Riots Took an Ugly Tum' (un­ published paper, n.d.). D1g1tizeo by Google Origlr.al from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Political Protess: Dominance 429 whether he had taken action to prevent the recurrence of riots and he replied, During asthi kalash the VHP workers toured the state, carrying urns containing ashes of the kar sevaks who had been killed in Ayodhya. In other parts of the state this provoked riots so we maintained very tight security to niake sure that they could not enter our town. We faced an even more dangerous situation on 16 April when Muslims observe Id. The BJP had planned a rally that day. We put our forces on alert. We created thirteen police assistance centres in the town and we encouraged people to report to these booths if there was any trouble. We did not allow the BJP to pass through Muslim localities and we banned loud speakers and provocative slogans. In Nagina the pillar of a mosque was damaged that day. At night we posted officers to guard the spot and quietly had it repaired. By the morning Muslims went to Nagina to do namaaz and did not even notice the damage.. The district magistrate said that he had relied heavily on peace committees, made up of local residents, on more effective use of intelligence officers and more preventive measures to detect and ease communal tensions. What explains the complicity of the local ad1ninistration in the riot? And why did the form that state co,nplicity assumed change from inaction to ;ictive intervention? The contradictory actions of the state a t the national, regional, and local levels should warn us against depicting the state as a monolithic entity. This in turn has several implications. First, it suggests that we should not exag­ gerate the abyss between the local state and civil society. In the context of Bijnor, the middle and upper castes shared many of the same values, including opposition to the Manda) Commission recommendations, whether they happened to be situated within civil society or within the state. However, for a variety of reasons, government bureaucrats preferred not to openly defy the Chief Minister's orders; instead they engaged in foot-dragging and pas­ sive resistance. For example while formally agreeing to the Chief Minister's diktats, local administrators did not make security a r ­ rangements for his rally; nor did they keep ram jyotis out ofBijnor. It would be misleading, however, to explain the bureaucrats' inaction as wholly purposeful. Their indifference reflected the erosion of their sense of moral responsibility. This was related in tum to the absence of procedural mechanisms to ensure Digiti zed by Google Ongmal from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 430 · State and Politics in India accountability. Even when the complicity of administrative of­ ficials in the Bijnor riots was amply docwnented, these officials were not demoted, let alone fired. Rather, they were transferred to positions which were of equal rank with their earlier posts. The weakening of state institutions provides an additional ex­ planation for the passivity of the local administration. Whereas strong states intervene decisively to prevent riots or limit their spread, weak states are more likely to alternate between inaction and repression when matters get out of their control. A weak state at the local level is susceptible to the appeals of the BJP which has made government bureaucrats one of its prime targets. The fre­ quency of changes in administrative personnel in Bijnor, as a result. of both civil disturbances and frequent elections, further weakened the administration and contributed to political instability. A weak state also hindered effective communication between high-rank­ ing administrators on the one hand, and between the police, the PAC and their superiors on the other. A third explanation for the ineffectiveness of the local ad­ ministration has to do with an erosion in the chain of political command between centre and periphery. 20 The Congress system traditionally maintained national control over state administra­ tions who in turn controlled local administrations. However, with the demise of the Congress system, conflicts and divergences increasingly characterized relations between local, state and na­ tional governments. For example although on the surface Mulayam Singh Yadav and V.P. Singh appeared to have agreed upon a strategy for blocking Advani's rath yatra, closer inspection shows that they were quite divided about how to handle it. Con­ flicts between them inadvertently contributed to the growth of the BJP which in turn provoked communal violence. The argument thus far may be useful in explaining the local administration's 'passive aggression', but is less helpful in explain­ ing the violent behaviour of top-ranking local officials. Once tensions had exploded on the 30th afternoon, people acted in unpredictable and unusual ways. Zafar Khan co1nmented that he 20 Howard Spodek describes a si.Jnilar phenomenon when he amibutes the Ahmedabad riots of 1985 in part to the erosion ofthe Congress party's chain of command in Gujarat Spodek, 'From Gandhi to Violence: Ahmedabad's 1985 Riots in Historical Perspective', Motkm Asum Studies, vol. 23, no. 4, 1989, p p . 765-95. Dlgltlzeo by Google Original from UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN The Politiad Process: Domintmce 431 had always enjoyed cordial relations with the DM and his staff and would never have thought them capable of committing viol­ ence against Muslims. The transformation of their relationship with Muslims in the course of the riot may neither have been prediet2ble before the riot nor even wholly explicable in its aftermath. If people's actions were informed by a range of complex motivations, one of the few moments in which caste Hindus displayed explicitly communal hatred of Muslims was when local administrators engaged in violence themselves. When officials witnessed Muslim aggression, 'hindus became Hindus'. Muslims' tendency to initiate violence against the police and PAC, based on the justified assumption that they were there to protect caste Hindus, further communalized officials. Conclusion This chapter has sought to raise a variety of questions about prevailing approaches to the study of 'communal' riots. First, it seems imperative that scholarship on riots incorporate both the view from above and the view from below, for each perspective illuminates only part of the story. The external, contextual view that is illuminated in Engineer's work, helps explain changes in the character of the state from the Nehruvian secular model to its opportunist majoritarian incarnation under Indira Gandhi to its more open pandering to communal forces under Narasimha Rao. Without this sense of historical evolution it would be difficult to explain why Bijnor experienced riots in 1990 rather than thirty or forty years earlier. However, if this focus on 'the big picture' is necessary to situate Bijnor within the changing national context, its perspective is also partial. Particularly in the Indian context where the history of the state is so closely intertwined with the history of the Congress party, state-centred analyses tend to be inattentive to societal influences. Conversely, the advantage of ethnographic analysis at the local level is its more holistic character. In their attempt to remove Khan from the Bijnor nagar palika, for example, Khan's rivals simultaneously sought political power, control over eco­ nomic resources and Hindu dominance. A similar range of m�tiva­ tions were at work in rivalries over the disputed plot of land. My Dig1t1zeo by Google Origi�al rrom UNIVERSITY OF MICHIGAN 432 State and Politics in India point is that a close examination of conflictS at the local level reveals the interweaving of economic, political and social strands that are more difficult to disentangle at the national level. This study of the local level also shows that the BJP often benefits from a greed for power that is not implicitly communal. Though in retrospect we may come to see the causes of its growth as linear and uniform. In Bijnor, Zafar Khan's opponents were not all BJP supporters. Indeed, his principal rival, Sandip Lal, was a close associate of Mulayam Singh Yadav. Lal's animosity towards Khan arose from rivalry over chairing the nagar palika. In Bijnor, as in many towns in northern India, the BJP sought to gain control over the nagar palika to expand its networlcs of influence; it thus capitalized on the opposition various individuals expressed towards Khan. And yet it is important to emphasize that the caste Hindus' relationship with political parties in Bijnor was far from uniform in the period preceding the riot. Third, I seek to complicate our understanding of the concept of agency by exploring the ways in which it is often inextricably linked to victimization. Bijnor's caste Hindus imagined themselves to be persecuted by Zafar Khan, whose power and influence they greatly exaggerated. Their sense of rage at