1 FIN201 | Managerial Finance - BASE | Fall 2021 SESSION 10: MID-COURSE REVIEW Professors Peter DeMarzo & Paul Pfleiderer Stanford Graduate School of Business 2 SESSION 1: INTRO Stanford Graduate School of Business 3 GOOD DECISIONS Every decision has future consequences Some are Costs … and some are Benefits What makes a Good Decision? Value of Benefits > Value of Costs Stanford Graduate School of Business 4 Decision making follows from valuation The net benefit of a decision is referred to as its Net Present Value: NPV = Value of Benefits − Value of Costs = Contribution to Stakeholder Value Good decisions have positive NPV! 5 competitive market A market in which an asset or good can be either bought or sold at the same price. When a competitive market price exists, it determines the asset’s value for all investors. law of one price If an asset trades in a competitive market, then all equivalent assets must trade for the same price in every market. Competitive prices are information! 6 RULES OF TIME TRAVEL FV: Compound (multiply by 1+r) to move cash flows forward in time PV: Discount (divide by 1+r) to move cash flows backward in time A2A: Only compare or combine values at the same point in time Stanford Graduate School of Business NPV SUMMARY (RISK-FREE CASE) To compute the NPV of an investment: Determine incremental cash flows from the decision • Negative for outflows, positive for inflows • Show the cash flows in a timeline Use the current interest rate to convert risk-free cash flows to present values Combine present values of all costs and benefits NPV = ∑ t Stanford Graduate School of Business FCFt (1 + rt )t NPV represents the net benefit (in terms of $ today) from making the investment 8 SESSION 2: TIME VALUE OF MONEY Stanford Graduate School of Business 9 PERPETUITIES Perpetuity A series of equal payments at equally spaced intervals that goes on forever. C1 PV = r 0 1 2 3 C C C Growing Perpetuity A perpetuity with cash flows that grow at a constant rate g each period. C1 PV = r−g Stanford Graduate School of Business 0 1 2 3 4 C C x (1 + g) C x (1 + g)2 C x (1 + g)3 10 ANNUITIES Annuity Equal payments at the end of N equal intervals 0 1 2 N C C C 1 1 C C C − = 1 − PV (annuity) = r r (1 + r )N (1 + r)N r Stanford Graduate School of Business 11 ANNUITIES Annuity Equal payments at the end of N equal intervals 0 Growing Annuity 0 1 2 N C C C 1 2 N C C(1+g) C(1+g)N-1 N+1 C(1+g)N N C 1 C(1 + g)N C 1+ g PV (growing annuity) = − = 1 − N r−g r−g r − g 1 + r (1 + r) Stanford Graduate School of Business 12 KEY FORMULAS FOR CALCULATING PRESENT VALUES PV of cash flows (generally) CFt 𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃 = � t t (1 + rt ) Applications: net-present value 𝑁𝑁𝑁𝑁𝑁𝑁 = � Stanford Graduate School of Business 𝐹𝐹CFt t t (1 + rt ) Perpetuity and versions thereof 𝐶𝐶1 𝑟𝑟 PV of constant eternal payments 𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃0 = PV of eternal payments growing at constant rate (Applications: e.g. Terminal value, Dividend discount model) 𝐶𝐶1 𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃0 = 𝑟𝑟 − 𝑔𝑔 PV of annuity (buying a perpetuity today and selling a perpetuity in N) (Applications: e.g. mortgage payments, retirement income, ..) 𝐶𝐶1 1 𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃0 = 1− 𝑟𝑟 1 + 𝑟𝑟 𝐶𝐶1 1 + 𝑔𝑔 𝑃𝑃𝑃𝑃0 = 1− 𝑟𝑟 − 𝑔𝑔 1 + 𝑟𝑟 PV of growing annuity (Applications: e.g., retirement income) 𝑁𝑁 𝑁𝑁 13 SESSION 3: INTEREST RATES Stanford Graduate School of Business 14 THE ROLE OF INTEREST RATES Recall that a key input in our NPV calculation is the cost of capital, which depends on interest rates: NPV = ∑ t FCFt (1+ rt )t For a typical project • Costs occur upfront (initial investment in equipment, R&D, etc.) • Benefits occur in the (sometimes distant) future When interest rates go up • Benefits are discounted at a higher rate, reducing their PV • If the cash flows are the same ⇒ NPV falls When interest rates fall • Benefits are discounted at a lower rate, raising their PV • If the cash flows are the same ⇒ NPV rises Stanford Graduate School of Business Low interest rates stimulate investment 15 CAGRS, RATES, AND APRS CAGRS CAGR = compound annual growth rate RATES Given rate r per period • Expresses a total gain in terms of a growth rate per year • CAGR = (Final / Initial)1/N – 1 Equivalent 𝑛𝑛−period interest rate = 1 + 𝑟𝑟 APRs 𝑛𝑛 Given an APR with K compounding intervals/yr K Equivalent Annual Rate : Stanford Graduate School of Business APR 1+ = 1+EAR K −1 16 COMPUTING LOAN PAYMENTS To compute loan payments, we can use the fact that Loan Balance = PV(future payments) where the PV is calculated using the loan interest rate Most consumer loans (mortgages, car loans) have equal payments over the life of the loan 0 1 2 N-1 N c c c c Annuity Factor 1 1 L c × 1− = N th r r (1 ) + • Given any 3, we can solve for the 4 … • These are called fully amortizing loans Stanford Graduate School of Business given N payments and discount rate r 17 KEY POINTS TO REMEMBER To compute loan payments To EVALUATE a loan To compare alternatives Loan Balance = PV(Loan Pmts) using the loan rate Cost = PV(Loan Pmts) at your opportunity cost Always focus on the • What is your best alternative use of the funds (with comparable risk)? cash flows of each alternative Be sure to discount based on opportunity cost of funds Compare PVs Stanford Graduate School of Business 18 THE YIELD CURVE • Often the 1-yr, 2-yr, … 10-yr interest rates are not identical • This can be depicted in a graph called a Yield Curve U.S. Treasury Zero Coupon Yield Curve (2/18/11) 5% Yield to Maturity Interest rates depend on the investment horizon 4% 3% 2% 1% 0.34% 0.85% 1.32% 1.87% 2.35% 2.82% 1 2 3 4 5 6 Maturity (years) When discounting risk-free cash flows • Discount cash flow in year t using the rate rt from the yield curve Stanford Graduate School of Business 3.37% 3.88% 0% 0 NPV = C0 + 3.13% 3.65% C3 C1 C2 C4 + + + + ... 2 3 4 1.0034 1.0085 1.0132 1.0187 7 8 9 10 19 TAXES AND INFLATION If interest is taxed at rate 𝜏𝜏 • $1 => $1 + interest – tax on interest = $1 + r –𝜏𝜏r • Effective after-tax return = r (1 – 𝜏𝜏) • Same formula applies if interest on a loan is tax-deductible Given (nominal) interest rate r and inflation i • Purchasing power grows at the real interest rate 1+rreal = Stanford Graduate School of Business growth in money 1+r = growth in prices 1+ i When rates are low rreal ≈ r − i 20 SESSION 4: BONDS Stanford Graduate School of Business 21 PRICE VS YIELD TO MATURITY (YTM) A bond can be quoted in two ways 1.) Price observed in the market 2.) Yield to Maturity (ytm) – determined by the price and the contract characteristics The yield to maturity (ytm) is the discount rate that equates the discounted cash flows to the price c+F c c c + + + + Price = 2 3 M 1 + ytm (1 + ytm ) (1 + ytm ) (1 + ytm ) › F (or FV) is the face value in $ Remember: these are fixed when the bond is issued. They do › c is one coupon payment in $ not change over time! › The Price of the bond and its ytm can and usually do change over the lifetime of the bond, based on changes in market conditions FIN-201 | FALL 2019 22 THE ZERO-COUPON TREASURY YIELD CURVE, YTMS AND PRICING Treasury Zero-Coupon Yield Curve 10.00% 9.00% 8.00% 7.00% 6.00% 5.00% 4.00% 3.00% 2.00% 1.00% 0.00% 4.09% 4.98% 5.78% 6.50% 7.15% 7.74% 8.26% 8.74% Assume you own a three-year 10% coupon bond with FV equal to 1,000. Assume coupons are paid annually. Using the yield curve, we can find the price of the bond: 100 100 100 + 1,000 Price = + + 1 + 2.00% (1 + 3.10% )2 (1 + 4.09% )3 3.10% 2.00% 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Price = 98.04 = 1,167.48 To calculate the yield to maturity we start knowing the price and search for single discount rate that discounts the all the cash flows so that their sum equals the known price. + 94.08 + 975.36 Note that this bond is trading “Above Par” $1,167.48 > $1,000 100 100 100 + 1,000 1,167.48 = + + 1 + ytm (1 + ytm )2 (1 + ytm )3 Through trial and error or an Excel function (e.g., IRR) we find that: ytm = 3.969% 23 DURATION: A MEASURE OF A BOND’S SENSITIVITY TO INTEREST RATE CHANGES Duration (D) is measured in years. It is a weighted average of the number of years in the future that each cash flow of the bond is received. The weight for year t is PV of cash flow in year t PV of all cash flows t =M D= ∑ PV ( c ) × t t =1 t =M t ∑ PV ( c ) t =1 t A bond with a duration equal to D will decrease in value by approximately D% for a 1% increase in yields increase in value by approximately D% for a 1% decrease in yields % change in value ≈ − D × ( change in yield) Note the minus sign: an increase in rates leads to a decrease in value. 24 BOND PRICES WHEN YIELDS CHANGE The duration and the sensitivity of the bond price to changes in the yield » Increases with bond maturity (if coupon is unchanged) » Decreases with the coupon rate (if maturity is unchanged) If you sell a bond at the same YTM as you bought it for, you will earn its YTM If you sell a bond at the different YTM than you bought it for, you will earn … » More than the initial YTM if its yield has fallen » Less than the initial YTM if its yield has risen 25 BALANCE SHEET EFFECTS OF RATE CHANGES For a firm whose assets and liabilities are essentially like bonds (fixed payments in the future) we can calculate how its balance sheet values would be affected by a change in interest rates. Amount Duration % change in value for a 1% increase in rates New value % change in value for a 2% increase in rates New value Asset 1 100.00 5.5 −5.5% 94.50 −11.0% 89.00 Asset 2 150.00 3.0 −3.0% 145.50 −6.0% 141.00 Asset 3 300.00 4.0 −4.0% 288.00 −8.0% 276.00 Total Assets 550.00 528.00 506.00 Liability 1 50.00 2.5 −2.5% 48.75 −5.0% 47.50 Liability 2 150.00 1.0 −1.0% 148.50 −2.0% 147.00 Liability 3 150.00 0.0 0.0% 150.00 0.0% 150.00 Total Liabilities 350.00 347.50 344.50 Shareholder Equity 200.00 180.75 161.50 9.625% Loss 19.25% Loss 141.00= 150 × (1 − 6%) 26 SESSION 5: INVESTMENT DECISION RULES Stanford Graduate School of Business 27 THE NPV RULE To evaluate an investment decision • Estimate the (incremental) cash flows Ct at each point time • Estimate the opportunity cost of capital rt • Risk-free project: risk-free rate (from the yield curve) • Risky project: risk-free rate + appropriate risk premium • Compute NPV: NPV = ∑ t “Rate of return available taking comparable risk” Ct (1 + rt )t • Take the alternative with the highest NPV The NPV Rule is the most reliable estimate of value creation Stanford Graduate School of Business 28 INTERNAL RATE OF RETURN (IRR) IRR = discount rate that makes project NPV = 0 • “Return on Investment” (ROI) generated by the project NPV ($ millions) • IRR Rule: 40 35 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 (5) 0% (10) Accept projects with IRR > Cost of Capital Stanford Graduate School of Business NPV Profile IRR = 32% 5% 10% 15% 20% Discount Rate 25% 30% 35% 40% 29 INTERNAL RATE OF RETURN (IRR) The IRR Decision Rule Only works if all negative cash flows precede positive cash flows: −, −, −, +, +, +, + In that case: IRR Rule = NPV Rule IRR when deciding to accept or reject a project A BIGGER Problem: Never use IRR to compare or rank projects • IRR can only tell you if project is better than doing nothing • It cannot be used to choose between projects • This is a common error! Note: these problems are common to all return-based decision metrics Stanford Graduate School of Business 30 IRR RULE & MUTUALLY EXCLUSIVE PROJECTS Don’t use IRR when projects differ in… • • • Scale of cash flows + Do you prefer a return of 500% on $1 ($5 return) or 20% on $1 million ($200,000 return)? Remember: You can’t eat IRR! Timing of cash flows + Projects A and B require $100 investment have IRRs of 25%. Project A lasts 1 year, and B lasts 5 years. + If your cost of capital is 10%, which is better? Risk of cash flows + Project R has an IRR of 30%. Project S has an IRR of 29%. + If R is risky, and S is completely safe, which is better? Stanford Graduate School of Business 31 LEVERAGE AND IRR • We can increase the IRR by adding leverage • Suppose Bidder #3 proposes a lease instead: Pay $20M upfront, then $35M per year Bid #3 Lease Bid #3L Year 0 -100 80 -20 Year 1 60 -35 25 Year 2 60 -35 25 • Should you take Bid #3L rather than Bid #3? c.) No, it is negative NPV and will decrease total NPV Stanford Graduate School of Business Year 3 60 -35 25 IRR 36% 15% 112% NPV $44.1 –$4.1 $40.0 Beware: IRR is easily manipulated! 32 PROFITABILITY INDEX What if Engineering Headcount is the critical constraint: • Suppose max headcount ~ 130 Project Project B Project A Project F Project G Project H PROJECT X Project D Project E Project C Total Stanford Graduate School of Business NPV 61.8 79.9 72.4 52.8 43.3 45.0 30.6 20.9 56.3 463.0 “Bang for your Buck” Profitability Index = Engineering Headcount 10 15 20 20 20 25 20 15 45 190 Value Created Resource Consumed NPV/EHC 6.18 5.33 3.62 2.64 2.17 1.80 1.53 1.39 1.25 2.44 Total Headcount 10 25 45 65 85 110 130 33 SESSION 6-7: CAPITAL BUDGETING Stanford Graduate School of Business 34 IMPORTANT INSIGHTS When evaluating the earnings contribution of a decision… • Track changes to each earnings line item based on the incremental effect of the decision (with vs. without) Include: Exclude: • Firm-wide effects (not just the business unit) • Sunk costs E.g. cannibalization or complementarities • Opportunity costs (alternative uses of required resources) • Price changes due to inflation, market changes, etc. Stanford Graduate School of Business • Interest expenses or financing costs 35 NETPHONE INCREMENTAL EARNINGS NetPhone Incr. Income (With vs. Without) Year 0 Year 1 Year 2 Year 3 Year 4 52.5 52.5 52.5 52.5 Cost of Sales (24.0) (24.0) (24.0) (24.0) Gross Profit 28.5 28.5 28.5 28.5 (2.5) (2.5) (2.5) (2.5) (5.0) (5.0) (5.0) (5.0) (23.0) 21.0 21.0 21.0 21.0 (23.0) 21.0 21.0 21.0 21.0 (23.0) 21.0 21.0 21.0 21.0 (8.4) (8.4) (8.4) (8.4) 12.6 12.6 12.6 12.6 Total Sales Operating Expenses: R&D (22.5) Selling, General & Admin (0.5) Depreciation/Amort Operating Income Other Income/Loss EBIT Interest Income/Expense Income Before Tax Taxes (Incremental) Net Income Stanford Graduate School of Business 9.2 (13.8) 36 FREE CASH FLOW From Earnings to Free Cash Flow (FCF) 1. FCF = EBIT – Taxes + Depreciation – Inc. in NWC – Capital Exp. 2. Depreciation: not a true cash expense, just a tax deduction 3. Capital expenditures should be included at the time they are incurred 4. NWC = Net Working Capital = Inventory + Cash Requirements + Receivables – Payables NWC is the capital needed to “run the business” Adjusts for the lag between when goods are manufactured and paid for, and when the cash from the sale is actually received. Firm Buys Inventory Firm Pays for Inventory Inventory Firm Sells Product Accounts Receivable Accounts Payable Cash Out Cash In Cash Cycle Stanford Graduate School of Business Firm Receives Payment 37 NETPHONE INCREMENTAL EARNINGS Year 0 Year 1 Year 2 Year 3 Year 4 Total Sales - 52.5 52.5 52.5 52.5 - Cost of Sales - (24.0) (24.0) (24.0) (24.0) - 60 days / 365 = 16% 36 days / 365 = 10% Year 5 Calculation Year 0 Year 1 Year 2 Year 3 Year 4 Year 5 Inventory None - - - - - - Cash Requirements None - - - - - - Accounts Receivable 16% of Sales - 8.4 8.4 8.4 8.4 - Less: Accounts Payable 10% of COGS - (2.4) (2.4) (2.4) (2.4) - - 6.0 6.0 6.0 6.0 - 6.0 - - - (6.0) Net Working Capital Increase in NWC NWCt-NWCt-1 What if sales were growing? … or shrinking? Stanford Graduate School of Business 38 NETPHONE INCREMENTAL EARNINGS Incremental Earnings Year 0 Year 1 Year 2 Year 3 Year 4 52.5 52.5 52.5 52.5 Cost of Sales (24.0) (24.0) (24.0) (24.0) Gross Profit 28.5 28.5 28.5 28.5 (2.5) (2.5) (2.5) (2.5) (5.0) (5.0) (5.0) (5.0) Total Sales R&D (22.5) SG&A (0.5) Depreciation Year 5 EBIT (23.0) 21.0 21.0 21.0 21.0 Taxes 9.2 (8.4) (8.4) (8.4) (8.4) Net Income (13.8) 12.6 12.6 12.6 12.6 Free Cash Flow Year 0 Year 1 Year 2 Year 3 Year 4 EBIT (23.0) 21.0 21.0 21.0 21.0 9.2 (8.4) (8.4) (8.4) (8.4) Plus: Depreciation - 5.0 5.0 5.0 5.0 Less: Inc. in NWC - (6.0) - - - 6.0 11.6 17.6 17.6 17.6 6.0 Less: Taxes Less: CapEx Free Cash Flow Stanford Graduate School of Business Year 5 (20) (33.8) 39 DCF SUMMARY From Earnings to NPV Free Cash Flow Cost of Capital • Net cash generated or consumed by decision • What investors could earn taking similar risk elsewhere EBIT - Tax on EBIT Unlevered Net Income* + Depreciation - Increase in NWC - Cap Ex Free Cash Flow *Also known as NOPAT = Net Operating Profit After Tax Stanford Graduate School of Business • r = rf + risk premium NPV • Value created above and beyond what investors could have earned investing elsewhere 40 BEYOND NPV So, we have computed the project’s NPV – are we ready to make a decision? The real value of a financial model is that it allows us to • Understand the true sources of value in an investment • Allocate resources more efficiently within the firm • Reevaluate and reoptimize our decisions Stanford Graduate School of Business 41 SENSITIVITY ANALYSIS NPV allows us to determine the $ value and break-even point for each parameter Base Case Worst Case Market Penetration Best Case 7.5% 30% $55 Phone ASP Production Cost $75 $7.25 Cannibalization Receivable Days Cost of Capital -20 -10 0 10 530 30 15% 32.1% 9% 20 30 Project NPV ($ m) Stanford Graduate School of Business $51.81 149% 20% 75 12.4% $8.12 $5 60% Break Even 40 50 42 FCF: A MORE DIRECT METHOD Recall our FCF formula: = EBIT × (1 − τ) + Dep − CapX − ∆NWC FCF EBIT =( Rev − Costs − Dep ) Depreciation Tax Shield and so… FCF =( Rev − Costs ) × (1 − τ) + τ × Dep − CapX − ∆NWC After-tax profits Total investment And so 𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶 𝑖𝑖𝑖𝑖 𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹 = Δ𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹 = ∆𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅𝑅 − ∆𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶 × (1 − 𝜏𝜏) + 𝜏𝜏 × ∆𝐷𝐷𝐷𝐷𝐷𝐷 − ∆𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶𝐶 − ∆ Δ𝑁𝑁𝑁𝑁𝑁𝑁 Stanford Graduate School of Business 43 SUMMARY OF THE COURSE THUS FAR… Finance is about decision making • Good decisions maximize shareholder value: select projects with the highest net present value (NPV) To calculate NPV we need: • Free cash flows and • Discount rate (cost of capital) Remember: • Earnings are not free cash flows • Money has a time value • Investors demand a premium for taking risk Which assumptions and risks matter most? What are the scenarios to consider? How might you improve NPV further? What is your expected NPV across key scenarios? Use DCF Model to test assumptions and learn drivers of value and sources of risk Stanford Graduate School of Business 44 SESSION 8-9: VALUING FIRMS Stanford Graduate School of Business 45 VALUING SECURITIES What determines the value of an investment today? • Value of Investment = PV(Cash Flows) • This is the $ amount you would need today to replicate those cash flows on your own at competitive market prices • Valuation Principle Stanford Graduate School of Business Law of One Price: In competitive markets, equivalent opportunities must trade for the same price • Why? “No Arbitrage” • Price of any Security = PV(Cash Flows) • E.g. bonds Today we’ll consider how to apply this to value: • Stocks (equity) → Dividends, repurchases • Firms (business enterprise) → Free cash flows 46 METHOD I: COMPS / MULTIPLES Equity multiples • Price/Earnings • Price/Book Enterprise Value multiples • EV/EBIT • EV/EBITDA • EV/Sales Stanford Graduate School of Business Estimate Share Price ≈ EPStarget x (P/E)peers Estimate EV ≈ EBITtarget x (EV/EBIT)peers Estimate Share Price ≈ EV + Cash – Debt # Shares 47 VALUATION BY COMPARABLES Advantages Disadvantages • Easy to explain, simple to apply • No way to incorporate unique qualities, special circumstances, synergies, etc. • Reflects current market conditions • Seems to rely on few assumptions • Provides a quick “reality check” • Lack of precision • Relies on other firms being “correctly” valued • Provides no information regarding target growth rates or other metrics for future performance • Encourages short-term view Stanford Graduate School of Business 48 METHOD II: EQUITY PAYOUTS For a 1-yr investment: We can rearrange this as or Dividend Yield + Capital Gain Rate Total Return The expected total return of the stock should equal the expected return available on other securities with similar risk Stanford Graduate School of Business 49 DIVIDEND-DISCOUNT MODEL N-year Horizon: Div1 Div 2 Div N + PN P = + + ... + 0 2 1 + rE (1 + rE ) (1 + rE )N In the limit: “Buy and Hold” Investor • Assuming the firm is never acquired, Div1 Div 2 ... P= + += 0 2 1 + rE (1 + rE ) ∞ Div n ∑ (1 + r )n n =1 E That is, the stock price should equal the present value of all future dividends Stanford Graduate School of Business 50 CONSTANT EXPECTED GROWTH To apply the DDM, we need to forecast future dividends • This is hard to do!! Simplifying assumption: • Div/share expected to grow at constant long-run rate g • Best applied to mature firms 0 1 2 3 -P0 Div1 Div1×(1+g) Div1×(1+g)2 Dividends can be valued as a constant growth perpetuity: P0 = Div1 rE − g or equivalently, = rE Div1 +g P0 Three main drivers of stock prices: 1 Higher dividends Stanford Graduate School of Business 2 Higher growth 3 Lower interest rates or risk premia 51 PAYOUTS AND THE P/E MULTIPLE Price of Equity = PV of total payouts = P0 Suppose the firm pays out a target fraction of its earnings: Value of Equity PV (Divs & Repurchases) = # shares # shares × Total Payout Rate EPS Retained Earnings × Retention Rate (= 1 – TPR) Then if ge is the expected growth rate of earnings Stanford Graduate School of Business P0 = Dividends + Repurchases (Total Payout Rate) × EPS1 rE − g e or 52 METHOD III: ENTERPRISE VALUE AND DCF = The Enterprise Free Cash Flow • This is the underlying business that the firm operates • E.g. the rental property Stanford Graduate School of Business Share Price, Market Cap Bond Price, Debt Value Enterprise Value + Debt Equity • Interest • Dividends • Principal • Share buybacks 53 METHOD III: ENTERPRISE VALUE AND DCF Market Value Balance Sheet Assets Cash Enterprise Value = PV(FCF) Liabilities Debt Tangible Plant/Prop/Equip Net Working Cap, etc. Intangible IP, Human Cap, Brands, etc. Last Step Share Price = Equity Value / Shares Outstanding Equity Enterprise Value = Equity + Debt – Cash = PV(FCF) Value of Equity Stanford Graduate School of Business = PV(FCF) + Cash – Debt Net PV from all ongoing and future investments 54 DCF: KEY STEPS STEP 1: FCF STEP 2: Terminal Value STEP 3: Discount STEP 4: Share Price Stanford Graduate School of Business - Net Investment FCF = EBIT × (1 − τ) − ∆NWC + Dep − CapX V10 = = V0 P0 = rwacc FCF11 − ( Long-run growth ) or EV multiple V10 = EBIT10 × Long-run EBIT FCF10 V10 FCF1 FCF2 ... + + + + 1 + rwacc (1 + rwacc ) 2 (1 + rwacc )10 (1 + rwacc )10 V0 + Cash − Debt # shares 55 EXAMPLE: QUALCOMM VALUATION Based on analysts projections, FYE 2011 Basic DCF Stock Valuation QCOM 1 Year Revenues 2011 14,957 yoy growth EBIT Taxes Net Investment Additions to NWC FCF 2 wacc discount factor Present Value 28.0% 20.0% 80.0% 0.0% 9.50% Total Enterprise Value Cash & Marketable Securities Total Firm Value Debt & Capital Leases Other Securities / Pensions Total Equity Value (diluted) shares outstanding Value per Share actual price Stanford Graduate School of Business 3 2012 19,295 2013 21,224 2014 23,193 2015 25,177 2016 27,150 2017 29,080 2018 30,938 2019 32,691 2020 34,308 2021 35,756 2022 37,008 29.0% 10.0% 9.3% 8.6% 7.8% 7.1% 6.4% 5.7% 4.9% 4.2% 3.5% 5,402 (1,080) (3,470) 0 852 5,943 (1,189) (1,544) 0 3,211 6,494 (1,299) (1,575) 0 3,620 7,050 (1,410) (1,578) 0 4,052 7,602 (1,520) (1,578) 0 4,504 8,142 (1,628) (1,545) 0 4,969 8,663 (1,733) (1,486) 0 5,444 9,154 (1,831) (1,403) 0 5,920 0.834 2,678 0.762 2,757 0.696 2,819 0.635 2,861 0.580 2,883 0.530 2,884 0.484 2,864 10,012 (2,002) (1,159) 0 6,851 121,476 0.404 51,782 10,362 (2,072) (1,001) 0 7,289 0.913 778 9,606 (1,921) (1,293) 0 6,392 Terminal 0.442 2,824 $75,130 21,978 $97,108 (1,077) $96,031 1,702 56.42 $55.00 5 4 Terminal Value 6 𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹𝐹11 $7289 = 𝑟𝑟𝑤𝑤𝑤𝑤𝑤𝑤𝑤𝑤 − 𝑔𝑔 9.5% − 3.5% = $121,476 = projected value of firm in 2021 𝑉𝑉10 = Initial Multiples 13.9 x TEV/EBIT+1 5.0 x TEV/Rev Terminal Multiples 11.7 x TEV/EBIT+1 4 3.4 x TEV/Rev 56 BOTTOM LINE ON DCF Advantages Disadvantages • Makes assumptions explicit • Many degrees of freedom (manipulable) • Fundamentals-based (avoid bubbles) • Sensitive to terminal value assumption • Allows adjustment for firm profitability, growth, investment, and tax efficiency • Not directly tied to current market pricing • Provides performance metrics and targets, and insight into “investor expectations” • Allows sensitivity analysis • Encourages long-term view Remember: Stanford Graduate School of Business • Budget for growth • Cross check terminal value (multiples, growth rate) • Discount using weighted-avg. cost of capital (rwacc) 57 TYPES OF MULTIPLES Equity multiples • Price/Earnings • Price/Book Enterprise Value multiples • EV/EBIT or Operating Income • EV/EBITDA • EV/Sales Stanford Graduate School of Business Estimate Share Price ≈ EPStarget x (P/E)peers Estimate EV ≈ EBITtarget x (EV/EBIT)peers Estimate Share Price ≈ EV + Cash – Debt # Shares 58 VALUATION BY COMPARABLES Advantages Disadvantages • Easy to explain, simple to apply • No way to incorporate unique qualities, special circumstances, synergies, etc. • Reflects current market conditions • Seems to rely on few assumptions • Provides a quick “reality check” • Lack of precision • Relies on other firms being “correctly” valued • Provides no information regarding target growth rates or other metrics for future performance • Encourages short-term view Stanford Graduate School of Business 59 REMEMBER Each approach to equity valuation has advantages and disadvantages Be cognizant of the implicit and explicit assumptions embedded within each method • Premiums paid • Profit margins, Growth Rates • Comparables • Free cash flows • Discounted cash flow analysis • Discount Rates, Terminal values The best analysis combines insights from all 3 methods to reach a decision Stanford Graduate School of Business