World Development Vol. 40, No. 8, pp. 1511–1521, 2012 Ó 2012 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved 0305-750X/$ - see front matter www.elsevier.com/locate/worlddev http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.worlddev.2012.04.005 Fiscal Decentralization and Development Outcomes in India: An Exploratory Analysis KALIAPPA KALIRAJAN The Australian National University, Canberra, ACT, Australia and KEIJIRO OTSUKA * National Graduate Institute for Policy Studies, Tokyo, Japan Summary. — This paper attempts to quantify the impact of fiscal decentralization in India on its social infrastructure and on rural development. Overall, the results in this paper indicate that Government of India within a federal framework has been fostering development equitably across its states, particularly through health and education expenditures aimed at improving human capital development. In this context, the importance of the two tier centre-states decentralization should be noted. However, the third tier of local governance, particularly the state-rural local bodies decentralization has been dismal and has not achieved significant results across states, which warrant the attention of the central and state governments. Ó 2012 Elsevier Ltd. All rights reserved. Key words — fiscal decentralization, development outcomes, Panchayati Raj, Asia, India 1. INTRODUCTION even when there is some controversy over the redistributive role of sub-national governments, their desirability in implementing poverty alleviation policies is generally agreed upon (Brown and Oates, 1987; Ladd and Doolittle, 1982; Pauly, 1973). Second, competition among sub-national jurisdictions may promote innovations and enhance productivity. At the same time, as the decentralized governmental units function within a large country-wide unified market free from impediments to the movement of factors and products, it can provide a congenial environment for the efficient functioning of the market economy. Thus, drawing on the decentralization theorem introduced by Oates (1972), in an ideal decentralized system, existing resources will be allocated to yield the maximum possible output (locating on the production possibility frontiers) and the competitive environment including inter-governmental competition will be conducive for technological progress (shift in the frontier). In reality, the possibility of decentralization failing to overcome regional and local dimensions of poverty and inequality (Prudhomme, 1995; Rodden, 2002) may not be ruled out, mainly because the decision making power on local developmental initiatives is often highly dependent on central government bureaucracy. Further, decentralization may increase the probability of empowering local elites in capturing larger share of public resources at the cost of the poor (Dreze & Sen, 1996). With the recent developments in the political arena where coalition government is at the center, and different regional parties who are mostly the partners of the coalition are at the states, the case study of the Indian experience of decentral- One of the central questions in Development Economics is why some countries have remained poor for a long period of time, though the general policy approaches to combat poverty are well understood. A corollary to the above question is why the similar package of policies differs in efficacy across countries. Similarly, an identical set of policies differs in effectiveness across provinces or states within a country. 1 Drawing on the Post-Washington Consensus, it may be argued that the inability to achieve similar results from policy packages across states is due to the constraints posed by country-specific organizational or institutional factors. One of the major institutional factors directly involved in the delivery of public services and in implementing development policies is the degree of decentralization. Therefore, a key to enhancing the efficacy of policies lies in a better understanding of the extent and process through which various forms of decentralization contribute to development (Appendix I). What do we understand by decentralization? Decentralization can best be understood as a political process in the sense of the devolution of resources, tasks and decision-making power to democratically elected lower-level authorities, which are largely or wholly independent of central government (World Bank, 2000a). It is rational to argue that decentralization facilitates time-specific and location-specific knowledge to implement policies that influence people’s welfare. Decentralization in political, fiscal, and economic systems affects development outcomes in a number of ways. First, decentralized provision of social and physical infrastructures should correspond with the diverse demand conditions in different regions and match their resource endowments better than central provision. Even with regard to the provision of quasi-public goods, identification of target groups of beneficiaries is easier and implementation of policies more effective when undertaken by decentralized governmental units (Ostrom, Schroeder, & Wynne, 1993). Thus, * The authors are thankful to Dr. M. Govinda Rao, Director of NIPFP, New Delhi, Dr. Shashanka Bhide, Dr. Kanhaiya Singh of NCAER, New Delhi, and four anonymous reviewers of this journal for their valuable comments and suggestions on an earlier draft of this paper. Final revision accepted: February 20, 2012. 1511 1512 WORLD DEVELOPMENT ization provides an important context of understanding the ways in which decentralization can influence overall socio-economic welfare and rural development. The Government of India passed a series of Constitutional reforms in 1993 to democratize and empower local administrative institutions beyond the two tiers of the center and the states. The third tier of local governance comprises a three-tiered structure of rural local bodies, and three levels of urban local bodies as per the 73rd and 74th Constitutional amendments, respectively. 2 Since then, the experiences of different states with respect to decentralization vary a lot mainly due to differences in fiscal decentralization, which is a major instrument of overall decentralization. As fiscal decentralization was not initiated by states themselves, but was thrust upon them by the center through the 1993 Constitutional reforms, the attitudes toward decentralization varied across states. Though the literature on fiscal federalism explains the economic gains from decentralized decision making and related issues (Rao & Singh, 2005), there are very few empirical studies examining the causal relationship between fiscal decentralization and development outcomes in India. 3 Much of the demonstrated gains are in the nature of assertions or qualitative statements. This study attempts to analyze and quantify the impact of fiscal decentralization in India on its social infrastructure that needs to be supplied by governments as they are not optimally provided by the private sector and on rural development where about 70% of the population lives. In this study, the ratio of per capita expenditure of Panchayati Raj (rural) institutions to per capita expenditure of urban local bodies is used as a measure of states-rural local bodies decentralization in the context of third tier level of local governance. The following section discusses some important issues concerning fiscal decentralization in India. The next section examines the measures of spatial disparity in social infrastructure development across states. The following section analyzes the impact of decentralization on social infrastructure and on rural development. A final section brings out the overall conclusions of this study. 2. FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION IN INDIA—MAJOR ISSUES 4 The basic framework of inter-governmental relationships in Indian federation is given by the Constitutional assignment of functions and sources of finance. The seventh schedule to the Constitution of India specifies the Union list—the exclusive domain of the central government, the State list—the exclusive domain of the state governments, and the Concurrent list where both levels have joint jurisdiction. An important feature of the Constitutional assignments in India is the centripetal bias in the assignment of powers. First, almost all broad based taxes, with the sole exception of sales tax, are assigned to the central government. Second, effectively, states do not have independent borrowing powers. When a state is indebted to the center, it must seek the center’s permission to borrow. As all the states are indebted to the center, their market borrowing is determined by the Union Ministry of Finance in consultation with the Planning Commission and the Reserve Bank of India. Also the states cannot incur overdrafts with the Reserve Bank of India for more than 10 continuous working days. The Constitution not only assigns overwhelming powers to the central government, but also has overriding powers in the event of a conflict in a concurrent jurisdiction. The centripetal bias is not merely the consequence of Constitutional assignment. The adoption of planned development strategy and allocation of resources according to priorities determined by the planning agency have also contributed immensely to the centralization of economic power. Although planning was originally to be implemented in a decentralized manner, the involvement of sub-national governments in resource allocation has in practice been limited. Comprehensive central planning is the negation of federalism; and planning even in a mixed economy framework has significantly contributed to the concentration of economic power with the center. In the event, the potential benefits of decentralization have not been realized. It is worth noting that decentralization elsewhere with the similar characteristic of the center having more power over the states has positive outcomes. For example, though the central government maintains control of certain major expenditures, such as education and health, South Africa’s governance system has been restructured, which allow for the policy implementation on a local level. Such decentralization has significantly contributed to the post-apartheid unification (World Bank, 2000b, chap. 5). Achieving the potential benefits of fiscal decentralization in the Indian federation has been further obstructed by the various fiscal and regulatory impediments to the movement of factors and products across the country (Rao, 2004). Some of these impediments were created for the economic management of supply shortage of essential commodities. The fiscal impediments were the consequence of the free-riding behavior of the states, particularly the attempt to export the tax burden to nonresidents. These impediments, along with high levels of protection, distorted relative prices and created a high cost economy. Another reason for centralization has been the failure to specify the powers and functions of governmental units below the state level, until the 73rd Constitutional amendment was given effect recently. The state governments, following the Balwantrai Committee report, adopted the local self government unit in rural areas (Panchayati Raj), right from the village level. However over the years, in many of the states these institutions became inactive with elected councils being superseded for indefinite periods. In some states, notably in Andhra Pradesh, Karnataka, and West Bengal there was an attempt at rejuvenating these local self governments at the village level by activating them politically, making greater devolution of powers and finances to them and in some cases, consolidating them into more viable economic and administrative units. However, frequent changes in the ruling party in Karnataka and Andhra Pradesh rendered these experiments abortive, though in West Bengal it has continued. With the 1993 Constitutional amendment, however, it is now mandatory to have a uniform system of Panchayati Raj throughout the country. The 11th schedule of the Constitution specifies a list of 29 subjects to be carried out by local governments (Appendix II). Many states have already transferred responsibilities for the 29 subjects listed in the 11th schedule of the Constitution through legislation, in reality not all subjects have been carried out by rural local bodies in those states. For example, among the South Indian states, Karnataka, and Kerala have decentralized their local governance effectively by providing responsibilities to rural local bodies for all 29 subjects not only through legislation, but also through actual implementation (Appendix III). On the other hand, Andhra Pradesh and Tamil Nadu have paid less attention to decentralization. Though Andhra Pradesh has agreed through legislation to transfer 17 out of 29 subjects to rural local bodies, in reality only nine subjects have been given until FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION AND DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES IN INDIA: AN EXPLORATORY ANALYSIS recently. With respect to other states in India, Madhya Pradesh, where 23 out of 29 subjects have been transferred from state to Panchayati institutions, paid more attention to decentralization and human development than any other states in East and West India. In East India though West Bengal and Kerala had similar political parties in power for several years, the former’s progress in state-rural local body decentralization has not been on par with that of Kerala, where 29 out of 29 subjects have been transferred from the state to rural local bodies effectively. However, in another East Indian state of Orissa, 16 subjects have been transferred from the state administration to rural local bodies, particularly to Zilla Parishads. Though the North Indian state of Haryana has legislated that it would also follow the models of Karnataka and Kerala to transfer 29 subjects listed in the 11th Schedule of the Constitution, it is not clear yet when exactly it will be carried out, as only 10 subjects have been actually undertaken by rural local bodies. (Planning Commission, 2006). Though there are several reasons for this varied interest in decentralization across states, one major reason is the number of elected representatives, such as Members of Parliament (MP) and Members of Legislative Assemblies (MLA). The MP Local Area Development Funds and MLA Local Area Development Funds allotted by the center and state governments are often used to dilute the powers of rural local bodies such as Panchayats (AnilKumar, 2009). The 1993 amendment also provides for regular elections to these Panchayats and objective methods of devolution of resources by appointing State Finance Commissions (SFC). However, SFC’s recommendations generally are not taken in tandem by most states due to various factors including lack of confidence in the analytical procedures followed by SFC. At present, the shortcomings of lack of proper data and expertise in SFC are being rectified gradually in many states (Planning Commission, 2006). The above discussion brings out two important features. First, the potential economic benefits of fiscal decentralization in the Indian federation could not be achieved fully due to the centripetal bias in the constitution and the centralization of economic powers due to planning and other developments. Of course, it is extremely difficult to quantify the loss of potential output or welfare due to the absence of the desired degree of fiscal decentralization. Second, there has been a significant inter-state variation in the degree of fiscal decentralization and other institutional situations. This has impacted differently on states. Therefore, the analysis of different states should lead to a better understanding of the economic dynamics of fiscal decentralization. Another important feature of the Indian fiscal federalism is the existence of severe vertical and horizontal imbalances (Rao, 2005). States have been assigned expenditure responsibilities far in excess of their revenue resources. In particular, the Constitution assigns predominant responsibility of building social and physical infrastructure for rural development to the states. Also, being closer to the people, the states have to cater to the needs of the poor much more responsively than the central government. Furthermore, the capacity to raise revenues varies widely among the states. Variation in per capita incomes even among the 14 general category states is almost 1:4. 5 General purpose transfers are required to offset these vertical and horizontal imbalances. Additionally, for services with a high degree of inter-state spillovers or those in the nature of merit goods, specific purpose transfers are necessary to ensure availability of certain minimum levels. To ensure this, specific purpose transfers, preferably with matching requirements are necessary. 1513 In India, both general purpose and specific transfers are given, but their design and implementation leave much to be desired. The Finance Commission, a statutory body, and the Planning Commission give general purpose transfers, but neither has been able to design the transfers to offset fiscal disadvantages of the states with low revenue capacity and high unit cost of providing public services (Rao, Shand, & Kalirajan, 1998). In fact, the two agencies sometimes have worked at cross purposes. The bulk of the transfers given by both agencies is on the basis of general economic indicators and is not targeted to offset fiscal disadvantages of the states with low revenue capacity and high unit cost of public services. The practice of filling projected budgetary gaps by the Finance Commissions has created disincentives for prudent fiscal management. Thus, the general purpose transfers have not served the objectives of either equity or efficiency to the desired extent. There are a number of problems in the design of specific purpose transfers given for poverty alleviation. The proliferation of specific purpose transfers for a variety of purposes has constrained the availability of resources for spending on poverty alleviation and has spread the resources thinly across several programs. The volume of resources available for transfer to poverty alleviation is inadequate to make any impression on the poverty problem (Kalirajan & Singh, 2010). Nor is the design of the transfer system targeted to alleviate poverty (for details, see Rao & Das-Gupta, 1995). Thus, the design and implementation of inter-governmental transfer systems in India leave much to be desired. This is another factor creating the divergence between the potential and actual rural development outcomes and there are inter-state differences in these divergences. Further, inter-governmental transfers create different degrees of fiscal autonomy to different states and these influence development outcomes differently. When states in India are compared for fiscal autonomy and development outcomes, it may be observed that local institutions of decentralization are more effective in states where land reforms and social movements have been successful in promoting social egalitarianism (Bardhan, 2002). 3. IS THERE SPATIAL DISPARITY IN SOCIAL INFRASTRUCTURE DEVELOPMENT? As the major objective of decentralization is to provide easy access to local public goods that improve social infrastructure, we first examine the status of some of the indicators of social infrastructure across states. An effective functioning of decentralization across states is expected not to widen spatial disparity in social infrastructure development. We adopt the measure of weighted coefficient of variation to examine the trends in spatial balance in the basic social development indicators: Infant Mortality Rate (IMR), Life Expectancy at birth (LE), Literacy Rate (LR), Telecom Density per thousand population (TD), and per capita Electricity Consumption (EC) in kwh, and the results are given in Tables 1 and 2. The trends clearly show that there is a reduction in disparity in literacy rate, and life expectancy at birth. In the case of infant mortality rate, the trend appears to show a slightly increasing disparity in later years (Table 1). For example, in 2006, Madhya Pradesh had the highest infant mortality rate with 74 deaths in 1000 births, followed by Orissa at 73 and Uttar Pradesh at 71. On the other hand, the mortality rates in Kerala, Maharashtra, and Tamil Nadu were 15, 35, and 37 respectively, as these states have effective primary health care delivery systems reaching down to the poorest section of 1514 WORLD DEVELOPMENT Table 1. The pace of development and spatial balance in development: selected human development indicators Year 1983 1988 1990 1991 1993 1995 1999 2000 2001 2003 Life expectancy at birth Average CV 60.2 61.1 59.2 59.7 60.5 61.2 62.1 62.3 62.5 63.0 0.7398 0.7299 0.7541 0.7472 0.7376 0.7298 0.7197 0.7175 0.7157 0.7107 Year Infant mortality rate (per thousand) Average CV 121 123 107 95 77 53 66 54 62 0.0565 0.0650 0.0681 0.0685 0.0708 0.1237 0.0670 0.0680 0.0824 1971 1976 1981 1986 1991 1994 1998 2005 2006 Year Literacy rate 1971 1981 1991 2001 2002 Average CV 32.8 42.2 51.2 63.9 64.2 0.0830 0.0655 0.0575 0.0370 0.0322 Note: The coefficient of variation is calculated over data for 15 major states of India. The CV is estimated as a weighted measure using population shares of the states as weights. Table 2. The pace of development and spatial balance in development: selected infrastructural development indicators Year Telecom density (% popln.) 1980 1985 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1998 1999 2000 2003 2004 2006 2007 Average CV 0.38 0.40 0.47 0.48 0.52 0.55 0.62 0.71 0.83 1.00 1.20 1.68 2.37 2.68 4.24 5.69 10.74 15.85 0.3350 0.1661 0.1717 0.1720 0.1726 0.1670 0.1654 0.1603 0.1592 0.1606 0.1629 0.1275 0.1499 0.1498 0.1555 0.1618 0.1250 0.1139 Year Electricity consumption (kwh) Average (per cap.) CV 97 121 150 168 196 232 247 263 288 306 336 359 387 396 0.1157 0.1322 0.1335 0.1298 0.1352 0.1285 0.1244 0.1268 0.1197 0.1234 0.1235 0.1597 0.1523 0.1488 1975 1980 1983 1985 1987 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1996 2002 2004 2006 See Note to Table 1. Table 3. Trends in state’s own revenue receipts and revenue expenditures Year 1990–91 1995–96 1999–00 2000–01 2001–02 2002–03 2003–04 2004–05 2005–06 State’s own receipts to total receipts (%) State’s rev. expend. to total expend. (%) State’s own rev. receipts to state’s rev. expend. (%) 35.2 39.2 38.6 37.8 40.2 38.28 37.54 38.10 37.07 54.6 57.0 56.4 56.0 56.9 54.31 56.27 56.28 56.59 53.1 58.6 49.8 48.6 50.0 56.01 53.83 60.05 56.07 Source: Table 7 in Rao, Sen, and Jena (2008). population (Kapoor, 2009). Further, what is alarming is that rural infant mortality is higher than urban infant mortality rate in all states. On examining the per capita expenditure on social sectors, which includes health at village level, through Panchayati Raj institutions given in Table 6, it is evident that per capita expenditure on social sectors at the rural level have been very low in Madhya Pradesh (Rs. 110), Orissa (Rs. 57), and Uttar Pradesh (Rs. 44) compared to the best performing states of Kerala (Rs. 742) and Maharashtra (Rs. 821). Also, malnutrition due to poverty and other factors such as poor access to hospitals due to lack of infrastructure such as roads and transportation in rural areas, and the number of scheduled caste and (A) Vertical transfer Transfers from center to states as percentage of gross revenue receipts of the center Period Finance Commission transfers Share in central taxes (%) 1 VII FC VIII FC IX FC X FC XI FC (first 2 years) (B) Horizontal transfer Criteria Share in grants (%) Other transfers 2 3 Total transfers through Finance Commission (2 + 3) (%) 4 22.39 20.25 21.37 21.4 20.93 1.96 2.52 3.42 2.34 5.20 24.35 22.77 24.79 23.75 26.13 Nonplan grants (nonstatutory) (%) Total other transfers (5 + 6) (%) Total transfer (4 + 7) (%) Grants through Planning Commission (%) 5 6 7 8 12.11 13.56 14.48 10.57 10.39 1.66 1.54 1.06 0.63 0.82 13.77 15.1 15.54 11.19 11.21 38.11 37.86 40.33 35.79 37.2 Weight (%) Formula of 12th Finance Commission (2005–10) Population Income Area Tax effort Fiscal discipline 25.0 50.0 10.0 7.5 7.5 Gadgil formula used in X plan (2002–07) Population Per capita income Tax efforts Fiscal management 60.0 25.0 7.5 7.5 Source: Authors’ compilation from various Planning Commission plan reports and Finance Commission reports. FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION AND DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES IN INDIA: AN EXPLORATORY ANALYSIS Table 4. Finance Commission (FC), Planning Commission, and nonstatutory transfer of resources from the center to states 1515 1516 WORLD DEVELOPMENT scheduled tribes living are seen as major reasons for high infant mortality in some states (Kapoor, 2009). The trends in infrastructure development, which include telephone density and per capita electricity consumption, also show a general improvement, particularly in very recent times (see Table 2). Thus, there has been an improvement in recent times in four out of the five development indicators considered, and the progress appears to be more spatially balanced than before recognizing the importance of the center–states decentralization. The movement toward more equitable levels of performance amidst rising development indicates that there are factors facilitating spatially equitable social infrastructure development. Which are the factors contributing to such equality? Is fiscal decentralization a significant contributing factor? Answers to these questions are attempted in the following pages. 4. FACTORS FACILITATING SPATIALLY EQUITABLE DEVELOPMENT The central government intends to ensure equal access to basic services such as primary education, primary health care, infrastructure such as roads, drinking water, electricity and communication services across states. State governments then are responsible for implementing a higher proportion of general government spending than in most developing countries with the exception of China. However, Table 3 shows that states could finance their current expenditures or revenue expenditures by their own revenues only by about 56%. Therefore, the center shares some of its revenues from sources such as income tax and excise duties with states. The norms for allocation of resources from the center to states are mostly “formula” based, which depend on factors such as tax efforts of states without any distinction of economic backwardness. 6 There are two main institutions that are constitutionally created for every 5 years by the President of India to transfer resources from the center to states and they are the Finance Commission and Planning Commission. Both institutions first fix the amount of tax revenues that needs to be transferred from the center to states, which is called “vertical transfer,” and then distributes the allocated amount to states, which is called “horizontal transfer” using different formulas. The Planning Commission also does specific purpose transfers for various central schemes implemented by different ministries of the central government without using any formula, which are called “nonstatutory” transfers (Rao and Chelliah, 1995). Table 4 shows the vertical transfer from the center to states over the years, which indicates the overall transfer of about 38% of center’s revenues to states. The formula used for horizontal transfer by the XII Finance Commission covering the period 2005–10 is given in Table 4 along with the Planning Commission’s Gadgil formula used in the X Plan (2002–07). 7 The Gadgil formula that is binding the Planning Commission need not have any sanctity for the Finance Commission (Rao, 2005). Whether the instrument of decentralization has worked in achieving spatial equitable distribution in social infrastructure development in the Indian context? We examine this dimension of the process in the following section. (a) Disparities in state government expenditures What has been the pattern of expenditures across states since the beginning of a policy regime which has been more reliant on markets to deliver growth than in the past? We have used revenue (or broadly, current expenditures) of the state governments for analysis as they make up about 77% of total expenditures today. Within revenue expenditures, “development expenditures” make up to 80% of the spending. The development expenditures refer to expenditures on various socio-economic development programs in the social sectors and economic sectors. The “development expenditures” of the state governments are grouped into two broad categories: social services and economic services. The social services include health and education. The economic services include development programs in different sectors of the economy particularly in infrastructure. For example, revenue expenditures on programs relating to agriculture, roads, electricity, and industries are grouped under economic services. These are not capital expenditures but relate to expenditures on operation and maintenance of on-going programs. Data were obtained from the Handbook of Statistics on State Government Finances (RBI, 2004) and previous publications on State Finances by the Reserve Bank of India (RBI). The state level population estimates are obtained by interpolating decadal Census estimates to obtain per capita expenditures for the states. The values in current prices are deflated by the wholesale price index to obtain expenditures and GSDP in real or constant prices. The trends in government development expenditures, are examined in a regression model in the framework of the “convergence analysis.” The methodology of income convergence analysis of Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1995) provides a useful tool to examine whether the disparity across states in state government expenditures is increasing. The conditional convergence regression model we used is: 1 PCREt 1 ln ¼ a0 þ a1 ln PCREt0 þ a2 t t0 t t0 PCREt0 ln PCY t0 þ a3 DCI þ u ð1Þ where PCRE = per capita real state government expenditures. PCY = per capita real gross state domestic product (average of 3 years ending in year t or t0 in all cases except for 1980– 81 where the average is for 3 years beginning in 1980–81; the averages are taken to remove abnormal data points). t0 = beginning year of the time period. t = ending year of the time period and rest of the variables are as defined earlier. DCI = fiscal decentralization index, which is the share of state’s revenue including statutory transfers to state’s expenditures. Given our interest in welfare indicators, we have extended the analysis to cover four types of development expenditures of the state governments: (1) expenditure on economic services within development expenditures; (2) expenditure on social services within development expenditures; (3) expenditure on medical and public health services within social expenditures; and (4) expenditure on education services within expenditures on social services. We have examined the pattern of expenditure for the periods of 1993–94, when the Constitutional reforms were passed to empower the third tier of local governance, to 1999–2000. Our interest is to examine if the expenditures across states are likely to be “converging” or “diverging” over time. The convergence would imply that the disparity is likely to be declining and divergence would imply the opposite. In the above equation, if the coefficient “a1” is positive, the per capita expenditures of the different states would be moving at different rates, with the “higher expenditure state” increasing expenditures faster than the “lower expenditure states.” Therefore, there would be no convergence of per capita expenditures FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION AND DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES IN INDIA: AN EXPLORATORY ANALYSIS 1517 Table 5. Results of regression analysis of inter-state disparity in state government expenditures ** Expenditures PCREt0 PCYt0 STPOP DCI Eco. services Social services Pub. health Education 0.3129(0.2952) 0.2627**(0.1292) 0.2772**(0.1355) 0.2028**(0.1004) 0.2882(0.2416) 0.1955**(0.0899) 0.2174**(0.1080) 0.2072**(0.1033) 0.1762**(0.0807) 0.1881**(0.0920) 0.1825**(0.0875) 0.1954**(0.0961) 0.1774**(0.0878) 0.1375**(0.0640) 0.1448**(0.0723) 0.1220**(0.0589) Significant at the 5% level. Table 6. Per capita expenditure through urban local bodies and Panchayati Raj Institutions in India, 2002–03. State Per capita expenditure through urban local bodies (Indian Rupees) Per capita expenditure through Panchayati Raj Institutions (Indian Rupees) Himachal Pradesh Madhya Pradesh Tamil Nadu Manipur Kerala Andhra Pradesh Gujarat Punjab Chhattisgarh Rajasthan Maharashtra Goa West Bengal Uttaranchal Karnataka Uttar Pradesh Orissa Tripura Jharkhand Jammu & Kashmir Assam Bihar Haryana Meghalaya Mizoram 854 762 727 720 693 657 653 639 614 523 489 443 426 398 329 315 395 287 192 192 174 162 143 124 33 59 110 153 37 742 898 783 108 355 382 821 419 30 46 1147 44 57 253 0 851 3 40 24 25 34 All states average 463 316 Source: (Basic data) Report of XII Finance Commission, 2005. across states and the disparity would increase over time. If the coefficient is negative, then the per capita expenditures would be converging or disparity would decrease over time. If the coefficient is zero, then again disparity would not be rising. The role of per capita real GSDP in the equation is to control for overall “initial conditions” of the state economy. If the average income (per capita GSDP) is larger in one state as compared to the other, the expenditures may also be higher because of the availability of larger resources (through own taxes) to that state. Once we control for this variable, the pattern that remains should reflect the influence of the other factors, including the devolution of resources from the central government to the states, on the tendencies of the states to spend. In order to control for this latter aspect of central government transfer and also the capacity of the state to collect revenue, the Decentralization Index (DCI) has been used as another controlling variable. The results obtained from applying the ordinary least squares method of estimation to Eqn. (1) with different dependent variables with concerned independent variables explained above are summarized in Table 5. The expenditures on “social services” show a statistically significant convergence pattern more consistently than the expenditures on “economic services.” In fact, the expenditures on “economic services” show no convergence. Thus, state government expenditures on social sectors appear to be pro-spatially equitable than the expenditures on “economic services.” It is a known fact that India lacks in infrastructure when compared with China. Infrastructure such as highways and airports are not well developed in states like Bihar, Madhya Pradesh, and Orissa, while they are reasonably developed in states like Tamil Nadu, Karnataka, and Maharashtra. Why does such diversity in infrastructure exist across states? The answer points to several factors including socio-political factors and it is beyond the scope of this paper. Within the “social services,” expenditures on both “health” and education’ services show statistically significant convergence for in the post-reform periods indicating that the mechanisms driving these expenditures are based more uniformly on the needs of population across all regions of the country. The coefficients of decentralization index are positive and significant at the 5% level for social services, medical and public 1518 WORLD DEVELOPMENT health, and education expenditures. These results support the thesis that greater center–states two tier level of decentralization improves overall economic growth, which in turn facilitates higher expenditure on social services. 8 These results are in conformity with studies on decentralization in other countries. For example, Faguet (2004) found that decentralization in Bolivia increased the responsiveness of public investment by local governments to local demands. His empirical tests demonstrated that patterns of investment in human capital and social services, such as education and water supply and sanitation, improved significantly after decentralization. 9 Further, the significant and positive coefficients of DCI in these equations imply that state governments do pay special attention toward the improvement of human capital, though the central transfer to states does not give any special priority for education and health in states (Table 4). The initial condition of average per capita GSDP does not influence the dynamics of expenditures on economic services, though it significantly influences expenditures on social services. The above results indicate that the two tier level of decentralization appears to be an important instrument facilitating convergence of “social services” expenditures across states. However, what is more important is to examine whether decentralization has contributed to rural development within the third tier of governance (states-rural local bodies decentralization) because 70% of India’s population still lives in rural areas. Therefore, next, we examine the impact of states-rural local bodies decentralization on rural development within the third tier of governance, which has bearings on the effective functioning of overall decentralization. Table 6 shows states’ per capita expenditure through Urban Local Bodies and Panchayati Raj Institutions in India during the period 2002–03. The average figure for Urban Local Bodies-all states per capita expenditure was Rs. 463, while the average sum for Panchayati Raj-all states per capita expenditure was Rs. 316. Though the average figures do not differ very much, the figures across states vary widely. 10 Many states’ per capita expenditure through Panchayati Raj Institutions was much below the all states average. Thus, the state-wise figures do provide an indication about whether Panchayati Raj Institutions are functioning effectively or not. Karnataka State has been in the front in terms of effective functioning of Panchayati Raj Institutions, which is followed by Andhra Pradesh, Maharashtra, Gujarat, and Kerala. We use the Gross State Domestic Product from agriculture and allied sector (GSDPA) at constant (1999–2000) prices as a proxy for rural development and we use the state level data published by the Central Statistical Organization. We use the ratio of per capita expenditure of Panchayati Raj (rural) institutions to per capita expenditure of urban local bodies (RPEUL) as a proxy measure for three tier level of decentralization. We use the panel data from 25 states covering the periods of 2000–01 to 2002–03. The following regression model was formulated: ln GSDPAit ¼ a þ b1 ln RPEULit þ b2 ln Fertit þ b3 ln Laborit þ b4 ln Rainit þ b4 ln Areait þ uit ð2Þ where Fert is the amount of fertilizer used in tons; Labour is the number of agricultural labor force; Rain is the amount of rainfall in millimeters; and Area refers to the gross cropped area in hectares. In Eqn. (2) the subscripts “i” and “t” refer, respectively, to the state and year. Eqn. (2) was estimated using the fixed effects estimation using data from the period of 2000–01 to 2002–03 and the estimates of the equation are as follows: ln GSDPA ¼ 3:5421 þ 0:0288 ln RPEUL þ 0:1826 ln Fert ð0:8543Þ ð0:0223Þ ð0:0815Þ þ 0:2177 ln Labor þ 0:4289 ln Rain þ 0:5627 ln Area ð0:0982Þ ð0:2122Þ ð0:1735Þ ð3Þ All the estimated coefficients shown in Eqn. (3) are significant at least at the 5% level except in the case of the variable RPEUL, which is significant at the 10% level only. As our main interest is to examine whether the third tier level of local governance, which is the states-rural local bodies decentralization, has contributed to rural development across states in India, we only explain the result of the coefficient of the variable RPEUL. The above results indicate that the contribution of the ratio of per capita expenditure of Panchayati Raj (rural) institutions to per capita expenditure of urban local bodies is dismal. In other words, the states-rural local bodies decentralization has not been conducive to rural development in many states in India. Nevertheless, the estimation confirms that decentralization contributes positively to rural development by facilitating a very small increase in rural development across states. However, the magnitude of increase is not impressive, given the emphasis for the third tier of decentralization in the 10th and 11th Five Year Plan statements. The implication is that decentralization needs to be more effective in promoting and facilitating the activities of Panchayati Raj Institutions and the impetus should come from the state governments rather than forcing it from the central government. 5. CONCLUSIONS The economic and Constitutional reforms of the 1990s have given more space to the markets in the allocation of resources as compared to the state relative to the pre-reform days. What implication does this have to the spatial equity in development? The state continues to be responsible for the supply of public goods including basic human capital and infrastructural development services across the country. Analyses presented in this study suggest that the mechanisms by which state governments provide for resources for such services do not continuously lead to higher inter-state disparity. If this pattern is a result of equitable sharing of central resources by the states or the effective functioning of decentralization, this element of state behavior is important in keeping the inter-state disparities from widening. Further, the results also point out that the expenditures on basic services such as health and education are pro-spatially equitable than the economic services. Overall, the results in this paper indicate that Government of India within a federal framework has mechanisms that foster development equitably across its states, particularly through health and education expenditures aimed at improving human capital development. In this context the importance of decentralization should be noted. However, the slowly rising disparities in economic services across states, which has implications for increasing disparity in some social sectors such as infant mortality, warrant the attention of the central and state governments. Further, as decentralization could contribute more to rural development, the structural aspect of decentralization needs to be re-examined. Therefore, drawing on Hayami (2001), it is conjectured that such tendencies arise mainly due to lack of appropriate and efficient institutions at the state governments levels in India, which indicates the need for further institutional reforms. For example, many states have not taken effectively the recommendations of their state finance commissions, whose responsibility FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION AND DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES IN INDIA: AN EXPLORATORY ANALYSIS is to recommend the extent and type of fiscal decentralization to the third tier level of decentralization, due to various factors including lack of confidence in the data and analytical procedures followed by SFC. This emphasizes the need for institutional reforms at state level. Also, the MP Local Area Development Funds and MLA Local Area Development Funds allotted by the center and state governments, which are often used to dilute the powers of rural local bodies such 1519 as Panchayats need to be restructured to make them complementary to resources given to local bodies. In this context, it is worth noting the following statement that appears in the Planning Commission’s 11th Five Year Plan: “Much higher levels of human development can be achieved even with the given structure of the economy, if only the delivery system is improved” (Planning Commission, 2008, p. 2). NOTES 1. A comprehensive study that has analyzed the different responses of the states to the reforms initiated by the Central Government of India is by Howes, Lahiri, and Stern (2003). 2. However, the focus in this paper is only on rural areas. 3. There are studies in the literature examining the impact of fiscal decentralization on economic growth. Martinez-Vazquez and Mcnab (2003) have provided a comprehensive review on the relationship between fiscal decentralization and economic growth. They argue that a direct relationship between fiscal decentralization and economic growth remains an open question. Nevertheless, Davoodi and Zou (1998) through cross country analysis found a negative relationship between fiscal decentralization and economic growth in developing countries. 4. Fiscal decentralization or autonomy of a state is given by the extent to which it is able to finance its public expenditure from the revenue sources assigned to it. Thus, one measure of fiscal decentralization will be the share of a state’s own revenue in its expenditures. However, as the statutory transfers are mandated in the Constitution and given on the basis of recommendation by the Finance Commission, an independent Constitutional body, the revenue from shared taxes and statutory grants can be considered on par with that of the states’ own revenues. Therefore, an alternative measure is given by the share of state revenue including statutory transfers to denote fiscal decentralization. 5. The Planning Commission of India has named the states into “special category states” and “general category states” for the purpose of providing financial assistance from the centre. A special category state gets preferential treatment in federal assistance and tax breaks because of harsh terrain, backwardness and other social problems. Remaining states are called “general category states.” These states are Andhra Pradesh, Bihar, Gujarat, Haryana, Karnataka, Kerala, Madhya Pradesh, Maharashtra, Orissa, Punjab, Rajasthan, Tamil Nadu, Uttar Pradesh, and West Bengal (see Appendix I). 6. Jha (2007) has provided a concise discussion on the issues concerning the principal constituents of the resources transfer formula between the first and second layers of governments in developing countries. He has argued that the relative weights on these constituents will often be determined by country-specific circumstances. 7. In the Indian case, decentralization has come about more from the center than the states. Many states did not find the need to decentralize below their administrative level until the Constitution was amended in 1993, which also insisted the need for instituting State Finance Commission. Decentralization was initiated to provide easy access to public goods locally. There were 247,033 rural bodies known as Panchayats and 3682 urban bodies in 2005. Nevertheless, Constitution grants strong powers to the central government, including the control of the central executive over state legislation, and the right to take over state administration in a state of emergency (Rao, 2005). 8. Zhang and Zhou (2001) observed a statistically significant negative effect of fiscal decentralization on Chinese provincial economic growth, and a statistically significant positive effect of decentralization on state growth in India. 9. These results are in contrast with those of some studies. For example, West and Wong (1995) argued that increased fiscal decentralization led to unequal provision of basic services such as education and health in China in sub-provincial units in three different provinces. 10. No clear pattern can be observed in transfers at local level. There is no doubt that the level of development of the states is a factor influencing the success of decentralization in terms of raising revenues. The indication is that India needs to improve its institutional framework to be conducive to the success of decentralization at local level. REFERENCES Anilkumar, V. (2009). Federalism and decentralisation in India: Andhra Pradesh and Tamil Nadu. Institute for Social and Economic Change, Working Paper 208. Bangalore: ISEC. Bardhan, P. (2002). Decentralization and governance in development. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 16(4), 185–205. Barro, R., & Sala-i-Martin, X. (1995). Economic growth. New York: McGraw-Hill. Brown, C. C., & Oates, W. E. (1987). Assistance to the poor in a federal system. Journal of Public Economics, 32(3), 307–330. Davoodi, H., & Zou, H. (1998). Fiscal decentralization and economic growth: A cross-country study. Journal of Urban Economics, 43(2), 244–257. Dreze, J., & Sen, A. K. (1996). India: Economic development and social opportunity. Delhi: Oxford University Press. Grover, V., & Arora, R. (1996). Encyclopedia of India and her states (Vol. 1). New Delhi: D&D Publishers. Faguet, J. P. (2004). Does decentralization increase government responsiveness to local needs? Evidence from Bolivia. Journal of Public Economics, 88(3–4), 867–893. Hayami, Y. (2001). Development economics. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Howes, S., Lahiri, A., & Stern, N. (Eds.) (2003). State level reforms in India. New Delhi: MacMillan. Jha, R. (2007). Fiscal policy in developing countries: A synoptic view. ASARC Working Paper 2007/01. Australia South Asia Research Centre, The Australian National University, Canberra. Kalirajan, K., & Singh, K. (2010). Economic liberalization strategies and poverty reduction across Indian states. Asian Pacific Economic Literature, 24(1), 26–42. Kapoor, S. (2009). Infant mortality in India: District-level variations and correlations. Department of Economics, University of California, Riverside (mimeo). 1520 WORLD DEVELOPMENT Ladd, H., & Doolittle, F. C. (1982). Which level of government should assist the poor?. National Tax Journal, 35(3), 323–336. Martinez-Vazquez, J., & Mcnab, R. M. (2003). Fiscal decentralization and economic growth. World Development, 31(9), 1597–1616. Oates, W. E. (1972). Fiscal federalism. New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich. Ostrom, E., Schroeder, L., & Wynne, S. (1993). Institutional incentives and sustainable development: Infrastructure policies in perspective. Oxford: Westview Press. Pauly, M. V. (1973). Income redistribution as a local public good. Journal of Public Economics, 2(1), 35–58. Planning Commission. (2006). Democratic decentralization and Panchayati Raj Institutions. Eleventh Five Year Plan Rural Development Working Groups. New Delhi: Planning Commission. Planning Commission (2008). Eleventh five year plan 2007-2012, volume 1-inclusive growth. New Delhi: Oxford University Press. Prudhomme, R. (1995). The dangers of decentralization. World Bank Research Observer, 10(2), 201–220. Rao, M. G. (2004). Transition to market and normative framework of federalism in India. Paper presented at the conference on fiscal federalism, University of Torino, August 27–28. Rao, C. H. H. (2005). Essays on development regional disparities and centrestate financial relations in India. New Delhi: Academic Foundation. Rao, M.G., & Chelliah, R. J. (1995). A Survey of research in Fiscal Federalism in India. Indian Council of Social Science research, New Delhi. Rao, M. G., & Das-Gupta, A. (1995). Intergovernmental transfers and poverty alleviation. Government and Policy, 13(1), 1–23. Rao, M. G., Sen, T. K., & Jena, P. R. (2008). Issues before the 13th Finance Commission. Economic and Political Weekly, XLIII(36), 34–41. Rao, M. G., Shand, R. T., & Kalirajan, K. P. (1998). State electricity boards: A performance evaluation. The Indian Economic Journal, 46(2), 51–66. Rao, M. G., & Singh, N. (2005). Political economy of federalism in India. Delhi: Oxford University Press. RBI (2004 and selected previous issues). State Government Finances. Mumbai: Reserve Bank of India. Rodden, J. (2002). The dilemma of fiscal federalism: Grants and fiscal performance around the world. American Journal of Political Science, 46(3), 670–687. West, L. A., & Wong, C. P. W. (1995). Fiscal decentralization and growing regional disparities in rural China: Some evidence in the provision of social services. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 11(4), 70–84. World Bank. (2000a). Overview of rural decentralization in India: Vol. I. Unpublished Report. Washington, DC: The World Bank. World Bank (2000b). World development report 1999–2000. In Decentralization: Rethinking government. Washington, DC: The World Bank. Zhang, T., & Zhou, H. (2001). The growth impact of intersectoral and intergovernmental allocation of public expenditure: With applications to China and India. China Economic Review, 12(1), 58–81. APPENDIX I. SIZE AND INCOME OF INDIA’S STATES AND UNION TERRITORIES (2005–06) Sl. No. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 State/UT Population million GSDP Per capita GSDP Rs billion Billion US$ Rs US$ Andhra Arunachal Pradesh Assam Bihar Jharkhand Goa Gujarat Haryana Himachal Jammu & Kashmir Karnataka Kerala Madhya Pradesh Chhattisgarh Maharashtra Manipur Meghalaya Mizoram Nagaland Orissa Punjab Rajasthan Sikkim Tamil Nadu Tripura Uttar Pradesh Uttaranchal West Bengal Pondicherry 80.4 1.2 28.5 90.2 29.1 1.6 54.6 23.1 6.6 10.9 56.0 33.4 65.9 22.7 104.2 2.5 2.5 1.0 2.5 38.8 26.5 61.8 0.6 64.9 3.4 181.9 9.2 84.8 2.6 2360 29 575 802 622 124 2198 1064 255 265 1680 1190 1163 519 4381 57 63 27 57 785 1097 1242 18 2235 94 2798 262 2347 68 53.32 0.66 13.00 18.11 14.06 2.80 49.65 24.03 5.75 5.99 37.94 26.88 26.28 11.73 98.95 1.29 1.43 0.61 1.28 17.74 24.79 28.06 0.41 50.49 2.12 63.19 5.91 53.02 1.4525,712 29,369 25,086 20,186 8891 21,377 79,389 40,221 45,974 38,457 24,397 29,999 35,601 17,649 22,873 42,056 22,684 25,699 27,027 22,736 20,251 41,420 20,095 31,186 34,424 27,694 15,382 28,572 27,668 588 663 567 456 201 483 1793 909 1038 869 551 678 804 399 517 950 512 581 610 514 457 936 454 704 778 626 347 645 625 All India 1116.1 32,757 739.93 29,350 663 FISCAL DECENTRALIZATION AND DEVELOPMENT OUTCOMES IN INDIA: AN EXPLORATORY ANALYSIS APPENDIX II. SUBJECTS THAT STATES CAN DEVOLVE TO PANCHAYATS AS PER THE 11TH SCHEDULE (ARTICLE 243-G) Agriculture, including agricultural extension. Land improvement, implementation of land reforms, land consolidation, and soil conservation. Minor irrigation, water management, and watershed development. Animal husbandry, dairy, and poultry. Fisheries. Social forestry and farm forestry. Minor forest produce. Small scale industries, including food processing industries. Khadi, village, and cottage industries. Rural housing. Drinking water. Fuel and fodder. Roads, culverts, bridges, ferries, waterways, and other means of communication. Rural electrification, including distribution of electricity. Nonconventional energy sources. Poverty alleviation program. Education, including primary and secondary schools. Technical training and vocational education. Adult and nonformal education. Libraries. Cultural activities. Markets and fairs. Health and sanitation, including hospitals, primary health centers, and dispensaries. Family welfare. Women and child development. Social welfare, including welfare of the handicapped, and mentally retarded. Welfare of the weaker sections, and in particular, of the scheduled castes and the scheduled tribes. Public distribution system. Maintenance of community assets. Source: Grover and Arora (1996). 1521 APPENDIX III. ASSIGNMENT OF FUNCTIONS FOR RURAL LOCAL BODIES THROUGH LEGISLATION AND ACTUAL ACTIVITIES UNDERTAKEN, 2004–05 State Transfer of subjects through legislation Subjects covered under activity mapping Andhra Pradesh Assam Arunachal Pradesh Bihar Chhattisgarh 17 subjects 29 subjects Goa Gujarat Haryana Himachal Pradesh Karnataka Kerala Madhya Pradesh Maharashtra Manipur Orissa Punjab Rajasthan Sikkim Tamil Nadu Tripura Uttar Pradesh Uttaranchal West Bengal 6 subjects 15 subjects 29 subjects 26 subjects 29 subjects 29 subjects 23 subjects 18 subjects 22 functions 25 subjects 7 subjects 29 subjects 28 functions 29 subjects 29 subjects 12 subjects 14 subjects 29 subjects 9 Subjects 29 subjects 3 subjects 25 subjects 27 subjects, except forests and drinking water supply 18 subjects 14 subjects 10 subjects 25 subjects 29 subjects Source: Planning Commission (2006, pp. 34–37). 29 subjects 29 subjects 23 subjects 22 subjects 7 Subjects 12 subjects 9 subjects 21 subjects 9 subjects 15 subjects