monopoly and competition Competition is directly influenced by the means through which companies produce and distribute their products. Different industries have different market structures—that is, different market characteristics that determine the relations of sellers to one another, of sellers to buyers, and so forth. Aspects of market structure that underlie the competitive landscape are: (1) the degree of concentration of sellers in an industry, (2) the degree of product differentiation, and (3) the ease or difficulty with which new sellers can enter the industry. a. Level of product differentiation among sellers (similar or different) b. invest fractions of income to be devoted to get market information, advertising and promotion, product design, with the result that resources are in a sense “wasted” and costs increased, c. seller concentration d. barrier to entry e. need legal protection from destructive competition f. Price and other market warfare g. Competition is directly influenced by the means through which companies produce and distribute their products Concentration of sellers a. Seller concentration (number of sellers) b. Their comparative shares of industry sales. c. Who is to determine the selling price Perfect competition Market conduct and performance in atomistic industries provide standards against which to measure behaviour in other types of industry. The atomistic category includes both perfect competition (also known as pure competition) and monopolistic competition. In perfect competition, 1. a large number of small sellers supply a homogeneous product to a common buying market. 2. In this situation no individual seller can perceptibly influence the market price at which he sells but must accept a market price that is impersonally determined by the total supply of the product offered by all sellers and the total demand for the product of all buyers. Monopolistic competition In the more complex situation of monopolistic competition (atomistic structure with product differentiation), market conduct and performance may be said to follow roughly the tendencies attributed to perfect competition. The principal differences are the following. First, a. individual sellers, because of the differentiation of their products, are able to raise or lower their individual selling prices slightly; they cannot do so by very much, however, because they remain strongly subject to the impersonal forces of the market operating through the general level of prices. b. Rivalry among sellers is likely to involve sales-promotion costs as well as the expense of altering products to appeal to buyers. This is a competitive game that all will play but that nobody, on average, will win, and the long-run equilibrium price will reflect the added costs involved. In return, however, buyers will get more variety. c. Sellers are unlikely to be equally successful in their sales-promotion and product policies, some will receive profits in excess of a basic interest return on their investment; such profits will come from their success in winning buyers. Monopoly 1. As the sole supplier of a distinctive product, the monopolistic company can set any selling price, provided it accepts the sales that correspond to that price. 2. Market demand is generally inversely related to price, and the monopolist presumably will set a price that produces the greatest profits, given the relationship of production costs to output. By restricting output, the firm can raise its selling price significantly—an option not open to sellers in atomistic industries. Oligopoly Rivalry among sellers a. In the simplest form of oligopolistic industry, sellers are few, and every seller supplies a sufficiently large share of the market so that any feasible and modest change in his policies will appreciably affect the market shares of all his rival sellers, inducing them to react or respond, b. Thus, in an oligopoly viable collusive agreements among rival sellers are quite possible. They may be express agreements established by contract or tacit understandings that develop as a pattern of reactions among sellers to changes in each other’s’ prices or market policies becomes customary. c. In numerous other Western countries, formal collusive agreements (often called cartels if comprehensive in scope) are legal.