Comperative political economy of Post-Soviet Georgia: Varieties of Capitalism. After the disintegration of the Soviet Union, the analytical dualism between capitalism and socialism almost completely disappeared. Until this period more comparative institutional analysis has been done between these two generalized types. This is not to say that there has been no study of differences within capitalism, although in recent decades the West has been dominated by various frameworks of comparative institutional analysis that examine differences within capitalism (Amable, 2003); Today, one of the most common analytical frameworks is "varieties of capitalism" (VOC), which analyzes the comparative advantage of national economies based on the study of institutions and institutional complementarities (Hall & Soskice, 2001). According to this theory, the competitiveness of the national economy depends on the institutional responses to the problems of collective action produced by transaction cost economics in the following areas: corporate governance, relations between firms, industrial relations, management, employee-employer relations, and vocational training/education/innovation. Under this framework, there are two successful types of coordination, which in turn represent the types of capitalism. In the first, coordination is more market-oriented (liberal market economies), while in the second, coordination is based more on non-market, strategic relationships (coordinated market economy) . Criticism of the classical approach of the VOC is carried out from many theoretical angles (e.g., critique of methodological nationalism and functionalism), although the most productive contribution, in this case, has been made by scholars who were oriented towards Visegrad and central-eastern European countries. In parallel with the European integration of central-eastern Europe and the former socialist countries, they noted that the classical theory of the VOC could not explain the capitalist forms and institutional arrangements in those countries. One such approach develops the concept of a "dependent market economy" in which the Visegrad countries are considered primarily (Nölke & Vliegenthart, 2009). The point is, the "VOC" focuses on national firms and studies national economies. This significantly limits the scope of analysis in a globalized economy. For example, in Visegrad economies, foreign direct investment is the dominant source of funding, while most large firms are transnational corporations, which significantly determines coordination in other areas and develops different institutional complementarities. In regions where the penetration of foreign capital is not just high but also dominant, it is necessary to bring an international dimension to the institutional analysis. In this respect, the concept of "dependent market economies" differs from the classical approach of the "VOC", which implicitly relies on ideal types and considers other systems in terms of transition or deviation - a hybrid form. Unlike liberal transistology, according to this theory, convergence is not necessary for the formation of dynamic capitalism, and "dependent market economies" are just as complete formations as liberal and coordinated market economies. The Visegrad countries experienced significant economic development using comparative advantages in the assembly and production of relatively complex and durable consumer goods. "These comparative advantages are based on institutional complementarities between skilled, but cheap, labor; the transfer of technological innovations within transnational enterprises; and the provision of capital through foreign direct investment"(Nölke & Vliegenthart, 2009). Unlike classical (Latin America) "dependency theories", here "dependency" is not presented as stagnation of the economy or as a complete subordination to other (core) economies. Local businesses and the state have certain developmental goals, however, because the speed and direction of capital accumulation are determined from the outside (Evans, 1979, p. 27), they can only achieve "dependent development" (Cardoso, 1982). In economic sense, a “dependent” economy is defined by the fact that the dynamic components required for capital accumulation and expansion are not located within the national economic system (e.g., strong national innovation system, financial resources, strong national firms) (Cardoso, 1982). for this reasons comperative advantage of visegrad countries are are constantly being threatened by countries located further to the east and will continue to remain limited to segments of their economies. Innovation always comes from outside, embodied in products and processes designed elsewhere. Production in DME’s is “based always on established methods and technologies so that these countries can never lead with the newest (Myant,2018) ”. For this and other reasons, the growth of such countries is limited. It is easy to see that Georgia is a dependent economy (although we do not have a consistent and concise description of it yet), but we have not yet studied the degree of integration into world markets, the level and quality of foreign capital penetration, the national innovation system, no institutional complementarities in comperative perspective, etc. The theory of "dependent market economy" maintains the empirical approach developed within the VOC, thus its practical significance exceeds the classical theory of dependency theory. By combining dependency theory and the VOC methodological framework, we can form a more complete picture of national economies and provide an institutional analysis of them. The use of current methodologies of comparative political economy is rare in the Georgian academic space. Much of the institutional research conducted in Georgia is still locked in the ideological discourse of the Cold War, in which the dichotomy between homogeneous market and socialist economic systems dominates, and the country's current poverty is directly linked to incomplete transformation into a market economy. This significantly limits the scientific analysis of the current situation and the critical reflection on it. The homogeneous perception of capitalist countries gives impetus to the understanding in which peripheral countries are considered in the transition to a successful homogeneous market economy. This teleology excludes the existence of diversity within capitalism and limits the area of practical action. Georgia is and continues to be integrated into the world market economy, although this is not followed by the accumulation of knowledge about these processes and the production of local knowledge. Georgian scholars need to contribute to the current academic debate in Europe, in this case in the field of comparative political economy. In the study, we will use the quantitative and qualitative methods developed recently in comparative political economy to typify Georgian capitalism, explain the nature of development and study perspectives. bibliography Magnin, Éric. Delteil, Violaine. Vercueil, Julien. (2018) La dépendance dans les relations entre capitalismes nationaux : quelle portée analytique ?. Revue de la régulation. DOI: 10.4000/regulation.14340 Hall Peter A., and David Sockice. 2001. “Introduction”. In Hall, Peter A., and David Soskice, eds. Varieties of Capitalism: The Institutional Foundations of Comparative Advantage. Oxford ; New York: Oxford University Press, https://scholar.harvard.edu/files/hall/files/vofcintro.pdf (67 გვ) Bruff I., Ebenau M., May C. (2015) Fault and Fracture? The Impact of New Directions in Comparative Capitalisms Research on the Wider Field. In: Ebenau M., Bruff I., May C. (eds) New Directions in Comparative Capitalisms Research. International Political Economy Series. Palgrave Macmillan, London. https://doi.org/10.1057/9781137444615_3 Andreas Nölke, Arjan Vliegenthart, Enlarging the Varieties of Capitalism: The Emergence of Dependent Market Economies in East Central Europe, World Politics, Volume 61, Number 4, October 2009, pp. 670-702 https://www.jstor.org/stable/pdf/40263536.pdf Palma, Gabriel, 1978. "Dependency: A formal theory of underdevelopment or a methodology for the analysis of concrete situations of underdevelopment?," World Development, Elsevier, vol. 6(78), გვ. 881-924. Gerőcs, T., & Pinkasz, A. (2017). Debt-Ridden Development on Europe’s Eastern Periphery 1. In Global Inequalities in World-Systems Perspective (pp. 131-153). Routledge. Becker, J., & Jäger, J. (2012). Integration in crisis: A regulationist perspective on the interaction of European varieties of capitalism. Competition & Change, 16(3), 169-187.