Copyright © 2000. Taylor & Francis Group. All rights reserved. Envoi As I finished the text for the first edition of this book in summer 1992, one former British prime minister was appealing in New York before an audience of American business leaders for Britain permanently to renounce any policies which might lead to a federal Europe and was urging the United Kingdom and the United States to form a free trade area. Another former British prime minister, at the same time, was urging the country at once to enter into a commitment to form a federal union of western Europe. The background against which the book was concluded was so reminiscent of British arguments and views in the 1950s that it was tempting to think that nothing had changed. Yet the twelve governments of the EEC had signed an agreement that the European Community should have a single central bank and currency within ten years, providing that several stringent conditions relating to inflation rates, public debt ratios, and the convergence of exchange rates had been met, and also that for Britain the agreement was reversible by parliament before the due date. That these conditions would actually be met looked scarcely plausible. Now, in 1999, as I revise this text, it looks likely that there will be a European Monetary Union, although its durability is uncertain. Whether or when the United Kingdom will join that Union is more uncertain. The policy of the main opposition party is to renegotiate the Treaty of Rome so that only its commercial clauses will be binding. Without Monetary Union the new political commitments entered into at Maastricht would not justify the change of name from European Community to European Union (EU). The dissent between the United Kingdom and the European Union remains the same as that described in chapter 7. There are other dissidents. The common foreign, defence, and immigration policies to which the Treaty of Maastricht is to lead the way are to be achieved only by international cooperation, not by supranational organizations. They escape any control by the European Commission, the Court of Justice, and the Parliament. Yet the Treaty was nevertheless voted down in a national referendum in Denmark and so many exceptions subsequently made for that country in order to make sure that the additional protocols were accepted in a second referendum that Denmark’s allegiance to the Treaty is even more qualified than the United Kingdom’s. The special treatment for the United Kingdom was acclaimed nationalistically in the press as the ‘victory’ which the prime minister declared it to be. It should be noted that, apart from the particular opposition of Denmark and the United Kingdom to some central aspects of the Treaty, the other states could not agree amongst themselves to an extension of majority voting in the Council of Ministers except on issues which the larger states regarded as relatively unimportant. France opposed an increase in the powers of the European Parliament more energetically than Britain. Should Monetary Union fail, the Treaty of Maastricht will have strengthened the institutionalized interdependence of western European states, but it will not be another step on the road to integration. The United Kingdom has taken up the cause of a wider union embracing much of eastern Europe as well as Scandinavia, which would not be founded on common The European Rescue of the Nation State, Taylor & Francis Group, 2000. ProQuest Ebook Central, http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/kcl/detail.action?docID=243322. Created from kcl on 2021-11-28 22:23:09. Copyright © 2000. Taylor & Francis Group. All rights reserved. Envoi 375 economic and social policies other than relative freedom of trade and markets. Such a union could take its place in that ‘one world system’ which was the goal of Britain’s strategies in the 1950s. The long British struggle of 1955–60 to link the nascent European Economic Community with a European Free Trade Area by the common practice of nondiscriminatory trade rules, but without the other common policies which created the need for the European Economic Community no longer has so strong a foundation in national domestic political consensus. As in other member-states support for the EU, with a strong foundation of common policies as well as the rules of the common market, has grown. Drowning the present European Union in a greater Europe with widely differing economic arrangements between its member-states, bound in a looser institutional framework, might well not command majority support in any of them, including the United Kingdom. When the successive worldwide strategies of the United Kingdom in the 1950s were crossed by the creation and early success of the EEC the British initiatives to link the common market institutionally with a wider free trade area, and later to join the EEC, were strongly motivated by foreign policy considerations. The political foundation of similar economic and social policies which determined the nature of the EEC was, as the previous chapter argued, not lacking in the United Kingdom. In London however the EEC was often misunderstood as an organization held together essentially by its political objectives; that its political cohesiveness came from its economic basis was not understood. That this economic basis gave it a European character, identifying the rescue of the nation-state as a process founded on the development of the European states themselves, was also not understood. No matter how well-disposed much opinion in Germany might be to the wider free trade area, German governments were ultimately going to bow to de Gaulle’s veto on British membership. Not to have done so would have weakened their domestic electoral power base economically and would have detracted from the European ideology which had stood CDU politicians in such good stead. This does not mean that after 1957 there may not have been a consonance of foreign policy objectives between French and German governments which the Treaties of Rome confirmed and strengthened. But the ability to strengthen that consonance by adherence to a common institutional framework of a new and solemn kind rested on the consonance of domestic policy choices for the rescue of the nation-state. The national strategies of the original six core member-states appear to have remained in place and retained public support, although in France, as has been the case from 1950 and the Schuman proposals, that support often is but a narrow majority and the strategy is always under question. For the later entrants strategies cover a wide spectrum, from clinging to the EU with all its present rules as an instrument of development and modernization to changing it into a looser commercial union and denying its selfproclaimed destiny as an ever-closer political union. The fundamental change in the structure of nation-states and the character of their domestic economic and social policies has, by dividing national electorates, made the EU a more divisive issue than were the European Communities of the 1950s. Does such a consonance now exist, and if not, will one return? Monetary Union will not be durable without it. If between 1953 and 1968 inflation rates touched 4 per cent, if unemployment in Britain or France climbed briefly to 400,000, governments became anxious for the political consensus they had built. Now, there are more than 11 million The European Rescue of the Nation State, Taylor & Francis Group, 2000. ProQuest Ebook Central, http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/kcl/detail.action?docID=243322. Created from kcl on 2021-11-28 22:23:09. Copyright © 2000. Taylor & Francis Group. All rights reserved. Envoi 376 unemployed in Britain, France, Germany and Italy, but governments are still re-elected. Colonies of homeless beggars sleep in parks, under bridges and in the public transport systems. In Britain and France income distribution now is made steadily more unequal while in Italy the trend towards greater equality seems to have stopped. Welfare is, if as yet only marginally, being made once more into a private concern. Industrial labour is a shrinking part of the labour force everywhere. Organized labour shrinks even more and trade union membership has fallen steeply in most countries as part of the total labour force. Agriculture no longer employs enough voters to command the political support of the post-war decades. Farmers carry less weight in shaping policy than the rentiers who have been created by two generations of income and savings accumulation, so that rates of inflation acceptable before 1953 are now regarded as utterly unacceptable and public expenditure is seen as a danger to income. If the motivation for the first common policies of the EEC has changed, or disappeared, the political objective has also been radically altered. The Berlin Wall and the DDR are no more. Germany is now of far greater size and weight in the Community than France and even more so than the United Kingdom. Even before unification its national product was on some measures more than 40 per cent greater than the British and the value of its foreign commodity trade more than 50 per cent greater. One of the Federal Republic’s main reasons for adhering to the Community has also gone; a united Germany is free to shape its own policy in eastern Europe. The historical evidence shows that the real argument has never been about whether it is desirable that a supranational Europe should supersede the nation-state, but about whether the state can find a political and economic base for survival. The surrenders of national sovereignty after 1950 were one aspect of the successful reassertion of the nation-state as the basic organizational entity of Europe. The Community was the European rescue of the nation-state. Since all history is change, that rescue could only be temporary and the process of economic development itself has eroded the political consensus which sustained both nation and supranation after the war. Whereas the general theories of integration propounded during the 1950s and 1960s almost all predicted that integration would continue, because the nation-state would prove increasingly unable to cope with the trend of modern economic development, in this book the historical evidence has been used to derive a fundamentally different theory of integration. This theory is open-ended; it does not forecast any particular outcome. It runs as follows. European states were reborn as puny weaklings into the post-war world. They developed particular bundles of domestic policies to satisfy a coalition of political interests. To support those policies they had available an inherited international order which had accepted to a varying degree the traditional system and principles of interdependence. Some of the domestic policies which they chose could be advanced through this inherited interdependent international economic order. Others could not and required something different, integration, involving a limited surrender of areas of national sovereignty. The close similarity between the sets of domestic policies chosen by Western European countries meant that integration was a path which could be chosen with reasonable hopes of success on several occasions. The choice between interdependence and integration was made according to the capacity of either system of international order to best advance and support domestic policy choices. The European Rescue of the Nation State, Taylor & Francis Group, 2000. ProQuest Ebook Central, http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/kcl/detail.action?docID=243322. Created from kcl on 2021-11-28 22:23:09. Copyright © 2000. Taylor & Francis Group. All rights reserved. Envoi 377 For example, when Italian governments selected emigration as a priority policy choice, an interdependent international order advanced such policies better than an integrationist one; the Six narrowly restricted at first the free movement of labour within their area, while Italians followed their historical pattern of worldwide migration. By the time that integration did provide special advantages in welfare for migration within the Community emigration was already becoming less of a priority policy choice for Italian governments. Similarly, when countries such as Denmark, France or Norway wished to pursue domestic policies which entailed large deficits in their foreign balances for several years, they were able to construct in the EPU an accepted, manageable framework of interdependence, which allowed them to borrow internationally on a much greater scale than the IMF could allow. This was maintained even against strong British opposition by countries like the Federal Republic whose foreign balances were in surplus. But when Belgium wanted to advance its policy of a gradual, managed decline of its coal industry integration was a better choice, because accepting in this case the full implications of interdependence would have meant the speedy extinction of most of the industry. Most strikingly, when faced with the inappropriateness of tariffs as well as of quotas to the industrial and commercial policies they wished to advance, the Six were able to use an integrationist framework to develop a new and altogether more appropriate form of foreign commercial policy, and for them a very successful one. With much travail they were eventually able to use the same framework to advance their policies of agricultural income support. It depends, however, entirely on the nature of national, domestic policy choices whether the international framework which is needed to support them will be integrationist or not. The theory developed here predicts therefore that anything may happen in the future, unless another theory able to predict the future choice of domestic policies could make it more specific. It allows for further stages of integration, even as far as full political union; it allows for the present level of integration to be maintained unchanged; and it allows for the abandonment of the integration that has taken place. The outcome will be decided by the choice of domestic policies. The historical evidence also suggests, however, that the last outcome is less likely than the others. When states chose to advance policies by integration one of the advantages that resided in that choice was the greater irreversibility of the commitment. To construct a wholly new framework for foreign commercial policy would have been too risky an undertaking without a commitment from the Federal Republic, which was as near as it was possible to come in international relations to a permanent commitment that it would continue to function as the key piece in that framework. There were other advantages in integration too which could lead to its choice. It offered a central enforceable law in place of that international law which has never been enforced and whose weakness is also a prime weakness of most frameworks of interdependence. It also offered the possibility of reducing the number of international actors within the framework. We have seen how this possibility attracted the Netherlands to the idea of a Common Agricultural Policy; the CAP functioned like a cartel from which Holland’s superior rival as an agricultural exporter, Denmark, could be excluded. For the integration which has taken place to be renounced might therefore require events of a cataclysmic order, because the costs of renouncing it would be so high. The European Rescue of the Nation State, Taylor & Francis Group, 2000. ProQuest Ebook Central, http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/kcl/detail.action?docID=243322. Created from kcl on 2021-11-28 22:23:09. Copyright © 2000. Taylor & Francis Group. All rights reserved. Envoi 378 To use either a framework of interdependence or an integrationist framework to advance national policies requires a similarity of national policy choices between a sufficient number of states. There is less latitude for policy differences within integration than within interdependence. Since either is chosen in order to advance the national interest, the likelihood is that within the European Union new common policies will only emerge if the circumstances of the period 1945–68 can be repeated and most of its member-states choose similar sets of domestic policies. And, to continue with the extrapolation from the historical evidence, they are only likely to do that if such policies sustain a fresh political consensus which itself will sustain the nation-state. There has been a sea-change in national economic policies and the way in which the European nation-state is managed since the early 1980s. After 1973 the relationship between foreign trade and economic growth in Western Europe altered; the rate of growth of trade between Community member states declined proportionately to the rate of growth of their trade with the outside world. Worse from their point of view, they began to lose their share of the Community market in many industrial products. If the first trend could be construed by some as healthy, because it was an expansion of exports to a wider area, the second could not. Whereas among the trends analysed in chapter 4 one was the growing competitiveness of Western Europe’s manufactures against American goods and the gradual reduction of the share of the Western European market taken by American industry, the trend between 1973 and 1982 was for Japanese and American manufacturing to take a growing share of the Community market. This appeared to be especially the case in the products of new electronic technologies, but also in cars. German manufacturing, while losing none of its lead in capital goods technology, remained fixed in the mould into which the patterns of supply and demand of Western Europe’s high-growth years had set it. The manufacturing sectors of the other countries, shaped as they had been around the same pattern dominated by Germany, were even less able to respond to Japanese competition. In those high-technology sectors where economies of scale and the gains in productivity associated with learning-by-doing were supposed to be greatest, and which were supposed to have been especially encouraged by the common market, European manufacturing was now falling behind. One result was that non-tariff barriers, especially state subsidies and national monopolies over state and local authority purchasing, began again to proliferate in intra-West-European trade. The Community was commercially less integrated by 1981 than it had been in 1973. This was seen as reducing the international competitiveness of each of its member-states. The change in economic ideologies which came with the return of unemployment accompanied by often high inflation rates led to experimentation with the privatization and deregulation of the mixed economy. Although this change came with a different timing in different member-states, it had at first a common objective, to return to the high growth rates of national income of the years before 1974. The concern with stimulating supply rather than demand led to the idea that a further liberalization of the Community market could support certain of these new aspects of national economic policy and on this one aspect a Community consensus did come to prevail. The shift in ideologies meant that the Community policy of standardizing national regulations on each manufactured product in order to minimize the number of surviving non-tariff barriers could be abandoned for a different procedure. The European Council at Milan in March 1985 took the decision to, in the Commission’s language, ‘complete the internal market’ by the The European Rescue of the Nation State, Taylor & Francis Group, 2000. ProQuest Ebook Central, http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/kcl/detail.action?docID=243322. Created from kcl on 2021-11-28 22:23:09. Copyright © 2000. Taylor & Francis Group. All rights reserved. Envoi 379 Single European Act. The possibility of doing so by a much simpler method than before lay to hand in earlier decisions of the Court of Justice, that there must be a mutual recognition inside the Community of products manufactured in any one member-state. The mutual acceptance by member-states that less regulation of the Community market would improve their international competitiveness led them to use this principle to remove regulations, rather than to continue on the previous basis of increasing their number, and this was embodied in the Single European Act. The programme of market ‘completion’ by removing restrictive regulations was, theoretically, due to be completed by December 1992. It is far from complete. European economies made a particularly strong recovery in the economic upswing after 1983. This was of course attributed in many countries, most vociferously in Britain, to putting the new economic ideologies into practice. It appeared as though western Europe was moving towards a new policy consensus. In this new consensus national government was to have a much smaller role to play, although it was only in the late 1980s and only in some countries that the national budgets which had sustained demand in the earlier period began to diminish as a share of GDP and they are everywhere still a much larger share than they were in the 1950s. The smaller role for the machinery of national government in the new consensus allowed a greater relative role for the Community; the European Commission could appear as a more potent agent of deregulation of markets precisely because its supranationality gave it a greater scope and effectiveness. The clearest indication however that the reduced role of national government did not mean any diminution of nationalism was that its admired champion was Margaret Thatcher. The Single European Act was imbued with nostalgia. While it was a serious attempt to revive the concept of integration as an extra stimulus to national income growth, it relied on the intellectual framework of the 1950s as a guide to what should be done in the new circumstances. The concept of economic growth still remained the one possible ideology that could span the widening gap in economic and political ideas between and within the member-states. This was so even in the United Kingdom where the post-war consensus was represented as a huge political error and the source of the country’s present troubles, not surprisingly since it was to Britain that it had brought the least benefits at the time. Reliance on the same basic idea that national income growth could best be stimulated by eliminating the constraints which the narrow confines of European national markets impose led to a revival of the federalist initiative based on the assumption that one market must mean one money, one money mean one central bank, and one central bank mean political union. Europe has been there before. This was the American argument in ECA in 1950 when some officials hoped that the European Payments Union would lead within two years to a Western European central bank. The same argument was made at the end of the 1960s when the Community adopted the Werner Report proclaiming the necessity of a common currency. After the adoption of the Werner Report the gaps between the Community currencies’ exchange rates with each other widened. It is true that throughout the 1980s exchange rates between most Community currencies were kept within fixed margins by various devices such as the European Monetary System. But these were almost as wide for the strong currencies, and wider for the weaker ones, than the margins of fluctuation which the British wanted to introduce in the 1950s when one of their motives was to The European Rescue of the Nation State, Taylor & Francis Group, 2000. ProQuest Ebook Central, http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/kcl/detail.action?docID=243322. Created from kcl on 2021-11-28 22:23:09. Copyright © 2000. Taylor & Francis Group. All rights reserved. Envoi 380 break up the EPU and eliminate all possibility of a Community currency which might rival sterling. In 1988 the European Commission tried to bring the pressures of those business and financial groups who believe they would benefit from Monetary Union to bear on central bankers through the Committee for the Study of Economic and Monetary Union. It was a measure of the way the political system in the 1980s had swung more towards representing the interests of capital. The central bankers themselves wished to assert their independence from the politicians who subjected them to so subordinate a role during the heyday of the post-war political consensus, and there is now a much more powerful political constituency arguing that this would be advantageous. An independent European central bank, so ran the argument, could liberate monetary policy from the inflationary importuning of national politicians trying to win elections. This had a strong appeal to the much greater share of the population than in the 1950s living off inflexible sources of income, especially the much greater proportion of aged and retired people. The once-and-for-all gain from reducing the uncertainties caused by exchange rate fluctuations and from the elimination of the transaction costs arising from having eleven separate currencies in the Union is calculated to be no greater than the small static gains to trade estimated in 1956 to result from the removal of tariffs by the Treaty of Rome. As in the earlier case of commodity trade, it is on the unquantifiable dynamic forces which would be released by the change to one money that the advocates of European Monetary Union rely for the force of their argument. But which policies would best release these dynamic forces, if they exist? It is perfectly possible in present political circumstances, even in the western European country which has consistently had the lowest rates of inflation, to have a tight monetary policy and a highly inflationary budget deficit if that is what political priorities demand, as the history of Germany since 1989 shows. In spite of the hopes that an anti-inflationary consensus across western Europe would be strong enough to generate common anti-inflationary policies, it was not. The intergovernmental discussions on currency union would probably never have got as far as the Maastricht negotiations in December 1991 had not the Soviet Union withdrawn its protection from the German Democratic Republic. European Monetary Union, fading as the basis for a political consensus, became for France the gage that Germany would remain within the integrationist framework in which it had been earlier fixed. It was the gaps in the Berlin Wall that led the Strasbourg European Council in December 1990 to call for a treaty on Monetary Union. By that date Monetary Union had come to be seen by France as the renewal of Germany’s commitment to, and control by, the ‘West’. This recalls the central political condition which has been required in the past from every act of integration. To succeed, every step in the creation of the Community had always to be at the intersection of two tensions; the advancement of national policies had to be combined with a guarantee that Germany would be more safely contained within the framework. Only when both objectives could be simultaneously achieved were countries ready to abandon elements of national sovereignty. The advancement of national policies was easier within an integrationist framework when the number of nations was small. Even when it is possible to find the crucial point of intersection between the pursuit of national economic advantage and the retention of Germany within a common political structure the complexity of the deals required is now much greater. The difficulty was seen most clearly in the field of social policy in the The European Rescue of the Nation State, Taylor & Francis Group, 2000. ProQuest Ebook Central, http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/kcl/detail.action?docID=243322. Created from kcl on 2021-11-28 22:23:09. Copyright © 2000. Taylor & Francis Group. All rights reserved. Envoi 381 Maastricht Treaty. Over most of the Community the element of the old consensus which has survived most strongly is a commitment to social welfare. Even the poorest memberstates were ready at Maastricht to accept a general declaration about the need for Europeanization of legislation on the length of the working week, on minimum wages and on provision for maternity leave, a complex document which reasserted the importance of labour to the political consensus. The argument for ‘harmonization’ (upwards) of wages and welfare made so vigorously by Belgium in 1950–2 and France in 1956–7 against Germany is now made by Germany against the others. The same concessions as before were made, except by the United Kingdom. To howls of patriotic fervour from the daily press a British prime minister successfully insisted on Britain’s right to keep lower wages, lower social security benefits, and to continue to discriminate legally against trade unions. If these truly constitute an advantage in intra-Union competition, it may be only because the lower-paid are less able than the better rewarded to take advantage of the opportunities offered by the EU for Joyce’s ‘silence, exile, and cunning’. It was not merely an intellectual exercise to derive a new theory of integration which fits the historical facts. It will not be simply decided by accidental pragmatism whether the European states do move to a further stage of integration or whether they content themselves with further experiments in interdependence. The choice depends on the way national political consensuses are reformulated. If the new economic and social policies which began to take shape in western Europe in the mid-1980s establish a common pattern, some of them may be better advanced within an integrationist framework whereas strong differences in national policy choices will make the Maastricht agreements a marginal comment on the flow of Europe’s history, like the 1953 proposals for a European Political Community. There has not been before a major international currency without a government supporting it. Domestic politics in Europe will determine the Euro’s fate, not central bankers. The conclusion is not just that political science need not relapse into pragmatism but that there is an explanation of integration, albeit of little predictive power by itself, which fits the historical facts and helps in understanding what choices can and should be made over the next decade. For the rescued and reconstructed European nation-state the ultimate basis for its survival is the same as it always was, allegiance. The well-attested secondary allegiance paid to Community institutions in member-states shows that the supranation, like the nation, if it endures and provides a consistent and effective level of organization can count on the loyalty of its ‘citizens’. Over the forty years of its existence the Community has been a remarkably benign institution in comparison with the nation-state. It has no police, no prisons, no soldiers. Its law intrudes only into a very small number of areas and in many of those it is seen as an improvement on national law. Most of the attacks in the name of ‘freedom’ on regulations from Brussels can be readily identified as a cover for vested interests. The freedom to swim in a tide of sewage, like the freedom to dine at the Ritz, is a somewhat abstract principle on which to ask people to condemn a political organization. Even a free labour market within the Union threatens the social status of only small numbers of people and is obviously not the threat from immigration which they most fear. The European Rescue of the Nation State, Taylor & Francis Group, 2000. ProQuest Ebook Central, http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/kcl/detail.action?docID=243322. Created from kcl on 2021-11-28 22:23:09. Copyright © 2000. Taylor & Francis Group. All rights reserved. Envoi 382 The expression, and perhaps even the sentiment, of prejudice against fellow Community citizens is an increasingly unusual occurrence. For the citizens of memberstates to denounce each other in the language commonly used by one alleged nationality in eastern Europe about another in general provokes only satirical ridicule. This makes a humane contrast with forty years of communist nationalist government as it does with western Europe’s earlier history. It is admittedly an alliance of sentiment between the rich and mostly white. None the less, the sense of a common allegiance to something beyond the nation has developed with the sense that the supranation may in certain respects open channels for political action which would remain blocked within the nation itself. This, and the weakening of prejudice, suggest that the present European Parliament could function with the same democratic ease as national parliamentary assemblies, providing it had something to do. What little it has so far had to do has been defined by the instrumentality of the Community as an integrationist solution to national problems. The evolution of the Community’s political machinery has had little to do with European federalism or with abstract demands for a European constitution as a desirable thing in itself, because the programme of the European federalists was irrelevant to immediate political needs. Many of them in any case, perhaps the majority, were opposed to the domestic policies of the nation-states. Attempts to mobilize political support for surrenders of sovereignty by evoking the idea of one federal democratic Europe were by no means always helpful to integration. Opposition to the Community, as well as support for it, could be mobilized around the same idea. The absolute defenders of national sovereignty, those for whom no solution to the problem of governance is acceptable other than a national one, can easily misrepresent the process of integration as the end of the nation. The truth is that whenever the Community member-states had to implement their surrenders of sovereignty they produced an arrangement which left almost all political power with the nation-state. This was still the case after 1989 with the French proposals for a closer political union. It is not through a federalizing of the state’s remaining powers that Paris sees a guarantee of Germany’s fidelity to the present framework, nor through granting greater powers to the European Parliament. This is not surprising, when in the past to equip the European Communities with a parliament which replicated national democracy would have been needlessly to curb the states’ powers to manage what was a restricted political device to provide additional support for policies already determined by national political parties. If parties have organized themselves only in a superficial way in the European Parliament, that is because no more has been needed. The political machinery of the Union resembles the court of the eighteenth-century German Empire. There is a numerous and deferential attendance around the President of the Commission. A hierarchical bureaucracy attends to the myriad small facets of relationships with the surrounding greater powers, the member-states, for every decision has to be finely attuned to the wishes of the real political power to which the Union’s continued existence is useful. The struggles to appoint to its offices are like those within the Imperial Diet. The history of national parliaments suggests that important popular demands will only focus on the European Parliament if the power of raising taxation is shifted to the Union level; ‘No taxation without representation’ appears as the one political slogan to keep its validity for more than two centuries. Until then it is within the nation that political parties The European Rescue of the Nation State, Taylor & Francis Group, 2000. ProQuest Ebook Central, http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/kcl/detail.action?docID=243322. Created from kcl on 2021-11-28 22:23:09. Envoi 383 Copyright © 2000. Taylor & Francis Group. All rights reserved. have to fulfil their task of organizing a democratic consensus. It seems beside the point to denounce the European Community for an undemocratic and bureaucratic pursuit of policies which were themselves the choice of national democracies. If that however is construed as evidence that the nation-states themselves are not truly democratic, or that in internationalizing policies they are seeking to restrict the force of postwar democratic pressures, there is little in the argument of this book to refute those conclusions. Indeed there is much to suggest that the post-war role of more democratic political parties in formulating the immediate post-war domestic policy choices on which consensus depended was only a temporary phase and that these parties, especially since 1968, have become increasingly part of the executive. Federalism is only a bogeyman; denouncing it a way of avoiding the real issues. National sovereignty is another bogeyman; preserving it is another way of avoiding the real issues. Elevating national sovereignty into an absolute irreducible entity, giving to it a mystical attribution, is to deny the historical record of the development of the European state. The evidence is that in the recent past sovereignty has been only a legal and administrative convenience, like the state itself. The argument that the Europeanization of policy necessarily usurps national democratic control treats the abstract concept of national sovereignty as though it were a real form of political machinery. The states will make further surrenders of sovereignty if, but only if, they have to in the attempt to survive. Appealing though the idea of a united Europe is, the strength of the European Community does not lie in that abstract appeal. It lies in the uncertainty of the nationstate’s destination. The European rescue of the nation-state, a positive and beneficent experience for the majority of people, marked some limits of the state’s capacity to satisfy by its own powers and within its own frontiers the demands of its citizens. Equally positive national policy responses may demonstrate other limits to the state’s capacity. In this sense, there may at any time emerge a force within the developed nation-state which may propel it towards integration. But whether the states make that choice still depends absolutely on the nature of domestic policy choices and thus on national politics. In whose interests will the brutal power of the state continue to exist? Who will run it? And for whom? It is the answers to these questions which will determine the future of the European Union. The European Rescue of the Nation State, Taylor & Francis Group, 2000. ProQuest Ebook Central, http://ebookcentral.proquest.com/lib/kcl/detail.action?docID=243322. Created from kcl on 2021-11-28 22:23:09.