Reflections on the Markets‘ Invisible Hand Arnis Vilks HHL Leipzig Graduate School of Management 31/08/2021 Bahir Dar University 1 Agenda 1. 2. 3. 4. Lots of Quotes The First Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics Discussion The Inverse Invisible Hand 31/08/2021 Bahir Dar University 2 The Gradual Encroachment of Ideas “…the ideas of economists and political philosophers, both when they are right and when they are wrong, are more powerful than is commonly understood. Indeed the world is ruled by little else. Practical men, who believe themselves to be quite exempt from any intellectual influences, are usually the slaves of some defunct economist. Madmen in authority, who hear voices in the air, are distilling their frenzy from some academic scribbler of a few years back. I am sure that the power of vested interests is vastly exaggerated compared with the gradual encroachment of ideas. Not, indeed, immediately, but after a certain interval; for in the field of economic and political philosophy there are not many who are influenced by new theories after they are twenty-five or thirty years of age, so that the ideas which civil servants and politicians and even agitators apply to current events are not likely to be the newest.” (John Maynard Keynes) 31/08/2021 Bahir Dar University 3 The Invisible Hand “As every individual .. endeavours as much as he can both to employ his capital in the support of domestic industry, and so to direct that industry that its produce may be of the greatest value; every individual necessarily labours to render the annual revenue of the society as great as he can, he generally, indeed, neither intends to promote the public interest, nor knows how much he is promoting it. … by directing that industry in such a manner as its produce may be of the greatest value, he intends only his own gain, and he is in this, as in many other cases, led by an invisible hand to promote an end which was no part of his intention. Nor is it always the worse for the society that it was no part of it. By pursuing his own interest he frequently promotes that of society more effectually than when he really intends to promote it.” (Adam Smith, 1776) 31/08/2021 Bahir Dar University 4 The Butcher and the Brewer “...man has almost constant occasion for the help of his brethren, and it is in vain for him to expect it from their benevolence only. He will be more likely to prevail if he can interest their self-love in his favour, and show them that it is to their own advantage to do for him what he requires of them. Whoever offers to another a bargain of any kind, proposes to do this. Give me that which I want, and you shall have this which you want, is the meaning of every such offer. ... It is not out of the benevolence of the butcher, the brewer, or the baker that we expect our dinner, but from their regard to their own interest.” (Adam Smith, 1776, again) 31/08/2021 Bahir Dar University 5 In Managerial Economics “…the most famous inference from Adam Smith’s Wealth of Nations is that as each of us seeks our own personal gain we are led by an ‘invisible hand’ to promote the overall good of society” (Hirschey & Bentzen, 2014) 31/08/2021 Bahir Dar University 6 In Managerial Economics, Continued “Smith is saying that by pursuing its self-interest – the goal of maximizing profits – a firm ultimately meets the needs of society... Profits signal to resource holders where resources are most highly valued by society. By moving scarce resources toward the production of goods most valued by society, the total welfare of society is improved. As Adam Smith first noted, this phenomenon is due not to benevolence on the part of firms’ managers but to the self-interested goal of maximizing the firms’ profits” (Baye & Prince, 2013) 31/08/2021 Bahir Dar University 7 In Highbrow Economics “…from Adam Smith’s invisible hand on, the classical economists held that competitive equilibrium yielded what was in some none-too-well-defined sense an optimal allocation of resources” (Arrow and Hahn, 1971) 31/08/2021 Bahir Dar University 8 The First Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics …is regarded as “a formal expression of Adam Smith’s ‘invisible hand’” (Mas Colell et al., 1995), and the invisible hand is described as, e.g., the “intuition, that decentralized competitive markets produce out of the self-interested behavior of economic agents an optimal distribution of resources” (Aliprantis et al., 1989) 31/08/2021 Bahir Dar University 9 The Arrow-Debreu Model …describes an economy of the following kind: It consists of consumers and producers, where each consumer has preferences over the commodity bundles he might consume, and he chooses a most preferred one that he can afford. What he can afford, depends on the prices, on the resources the consumer owns, and possibly profit income from firms that he has shares in. Each firm, on the other hand, choose a production plan that maximizes profits subject to the constraints which are due to their technological knowledge. Profits are then distributed to the firms’ shareholders. 31/08/2021 Bahir Dar University 10 General Competitive Equilibrium Such an economy is “competitive” in the sense that all consumers and producers are so-called “price takers”: For given preferences, endowments, firm shares, and technologies, they all base their plans what to buy and sell solely on the market prices for all the goods. The individual, decentralized plans will not in general be consistent with each other. A general equilibrium is said to obtain, if the system of market prices ensures that they do: At equilibrium prices aggregate supply for each good just equals aggregate demand. 31/08/2021 Bahir Dar University 11 The First Fundamental Theorem of Welfare Economics … says that an allocation of goods that is induced by competitive equilibrium prices must be efficient in the sense of Vilfredo Pareto (often called Pareto-optimal). An equilibrium allocation is called Pareto-efficient, if there is no other technologically feasible allocation that would be preferred by all consumers to the equilibrium one. 31/08/2021 Bahir Dar University 12 Pareto-Efficiency is not „Social Optimality“ The older terminology „Pareto-optimal“ should be used with utmost caution: Efficiency neglects many criteria most people would require of something called „optimal“. In particular, it completely neglects distributional justice. If all our consumers are selfish, then an allocation of goods that gives everything to a few, but lets all others starve – is Pareto-efficient. In the age of increasing inequality of the global wealth distribution, it would seem absurd to ignore distribution and identify social optimality with mere efficiency. 31/08/2021 Bahir Dar University 13 The Paretian Liberal A famous paper by Amartya Sen considers the following case: Lewd and Prude have to decide whether to read „Lady Chatterley‘s Lover“ – considered as a great work of art by many, but as obscene and pornographic by others. The preferences are as suggested by the names, but: if only one of the two can read the book, Lewd prefers Prude tor read it in disgust, and Prude abhors the thought of Lewd reading and enjoying the book. 31/08/2021 Bahir Dar University 14 The Paretian Liberal One will expect that Lewd reads the book, and Prude does not: That is the Nash and market outcome. One may argue that everybody should decide only for himself – not for the other one. This can be regarded as a “liberal principle”. However, the example shows that it may conflict with the Paretian principle – to regard a change as “beneficial for society”, if it makes everyone better off. 31/08/2021 Bahir Dar University 15 Externalities Prevent Pareto-Efficiency The second problem with the „fundamental theorem“ is that consumers‘ preferences are only defined for the commodity bundles they buy or sell. If instead consumers‘ well-being depends on the choices of others – as in Sen‘s example, not even Pareto-efficiency of the competitive equilibrium allocation can be expected. And of course – in the age of environmental pollution and global warming such „external“ effects are of utmost importance. And they are quite ubiquitous. 31/08/2021 Bahir Dar University 16 Public Goods … are just a special case of external effects. And just like externalities they are traditionally regarded as a case of „market failure“. The very terminology of „market failure“ suggests that competitive markets are still often regarded as the benchmark – and that one should look for remedies whenever markets fail. Deregulation of state monopolies and attempts to „internalize“ external effects are cases in point. 31/08/2021 Bahir Dar University 17 Monopolies … may sometimes be technologically more efficient than competitive markets: Imagine a technology, that allows one to produce with L workers L² units of a product – then a monopoly that uses L=2 workers, can produce 4 units of the product, but if you „deregulate“ and split up the monopoly in 2 competing firms, they jointly can produce only 1²+1²=2 units of the product. 31/08/2021 Bahir Dar University 18 Adam Smith again: “Whoever offers to another a bargain of any kind, proposes to do this. Give me that which I want, and you shall have this which you want, is the meaning of every such offer. ... It is not out of the benevolence of the butcher, the brewer, or the baker that we expect our dinner, but from their regard to their own interest.” 31/08/2021 Bahir Dar University 19 Agreement for mutual benefit 31/08/2021 Bahir Dar University 20 Invisible Hand, stylized: Individuals‘ behaviour motivated by self-interest Benefit for others („society“) 31/08/2021 Bahir Dar University 21 The Inverse Invisible Hand, stylized: Individuals‘ behaviour motivated by the wish to benefit others („society“) Benefit for individuals so motivated 31/08/2021 Bahir Dar University 22 Heuristics in Managerial Decision-Making Dominant heuristics: „Maximize profits!“ Alternative heuristics: „Try to help others!“ E.g., „Bottom-of-the Pyramid“-Approach, „Social Business Approach“. 31/08/2021 Bahir Dar University 23 Thank you for your attention! VILKS@HHL.DE 31/08/2021 Bahir Dar University 24