Heterogeneous Analysis of Institutional Quality on Economic Growth in SubSaharan Africa Ojapinwa, Taiwo Victor Department of Economics, University of Lagos, Lagos-Nigeria ojapinwataiwo@gmail.com/+2348034172740 Abstract The hierarchy of institutions hypothesis suggests that, various institutions exert different effects on growth. Based on this argument, this study first disaggregates institutions into three economic, political and governance and analyzes their individual effects on growth. The study further unbundles institutions into nine - rule of law, control of corruption, governance effectiveness, voice and accountability, political stability/absence of terrorism, regulatory quality, business freedom, private property right and economic freedom to separate their individual effect and determine which of the institutions is most fundamental to growth. This study employ a panel data set of 25 African countries over the period 1996-2015 based on availability of data on the variables. Based on system Generalised Method of Moments (GMM), the study reveals that economic institution is crucial to growth and rule of law is the most fundamental to other institutions. Thus, rule of law is foundational to every other institution especially as a good strategy in fighting corruption. This provides empirical support for hierarchy of institution hypothesis in SSA with the lesson that, a one-size-fits-all institutional reform strategy to promote growth may likely be counterproductive. Understanding which institutions that is most fundamental to growth therefore requires studying detailed and welldefined institutions conditional on thorough unbundling. Thus, attaining economic growth in Sub-Sahara Africa may therefore have a considerable bearing on vigorous judicial reforms entrenched in speedy hearing and determination of cases with adequate sanctioning. Keywords: unbundling, institutions, rule of law and economic growth. JEL Code: O11, E02, O17, O43 1 Introduction The last decade has recorded a growing acceptance of the idea that institutions are fundamental to economic growth. Adam Smith (1776) eloquent articulates how society with well-organized institution can influence investment behaviour, incentives and equilibrium growth rates in the economy (Acemoglu & Robinson 2013). With quality institutions, people in the society can secure returns on physical capital, human capital and new ideas which would lead to economic progress (North 1990). Otherwise, people would invest in rent-seeking and economic stagnation would ensue (Angeles 2010). Institutions are humanly devised rules that shape human interaction (Acemoglu et al 2005). Different types of institutions can therefore depends on the domain they structure (Braunfel 2016). Political institutions, for instance provide structure for the interplay of political actors. They regulate how elites within the state interact and determine to what extent the executive branch is subject to checks and balances. An independent judiciary is important for strong rule of law, economic freedom, but may also act as elite that places certain constraints on 1 the executive branch of government. Of primary importance to economic outcomes are the economic institutions in society such as the structure of property rights and the presence and perfection of markets (Adam Smith 1776). Economic institutions are said to be important because they have direct effect on growth unlike political institutions that have indirect effects (Flachaire et al 2011). Although several empirical studies (Hall & Jones 1999, Aron 2000, Rodrik et al. 2004, Nawaz et al 2014, Orayo 2016, Mullings 2018, Arshad 2019 among others) have reported that institutions are fundamental cause of growth, but most of the studies are without recourse to Acemoglu et al (2005) argument that different institutions exert different impact on growth. The lumping of all institutions, despite the distinct role different institutions play in growth process might have obscured World Bank (2002) question, which institution is most fundamental for growth. This study unbundle institutions into different parts based on Acemoglu et al (2005) hierarchy of institutions hypothesis, which argue that, different institutions exert different impact on growth. Institutions are first unbundle into three - economic, political and governance institutions and further into nine (rule of law, control of corruption, governance effectiveness, voice and accountability, political stability/absence of terrorism, regulatory quality, business freedom, private property right and economic freedom). The unbundling of institutions addresses the fundamental problem of lumping all institutions under the same subcategory, thereby answering the question: which institutions matter most for growth, an issue which is said to be the most controversial in the institution-growth literature. This study is crucial since it would lay to rest the question, which institutional reform should SSA government embark upon first, given that the subgroup is frantically embarking on various institutional reforms at the same time just to achieve sustainable growth. This study is justified since it separates different effects of institutions on growth and determines which one is most fundamental. The rest of the paper is organized as follows: Section 2 reviews empirical literature. Section 3 is the theoretical framework and 4 describes the methodology. Section 5 presents the results. In Section 6, we deepen the discussion of the results by determine how closely related are the institutional variables employed and section 7 concludes with policy implications. 2 Literature Review: From Proximate to Fundamental and to Unbundling Traditional neoclassical growth models postulate that the main causes of economic growth are exogenous physical capital accumulation and technological progress. In contrast, new growth theory links the real cause of growth to knowledge capital, with a prominent role for knowledge spillovers (Romer 1986, Grossman & Helpman 1991). The case between traditional versus new growth has not received final judgment when researcher like North & Thomas (1973), Hall and Jones (1999), Rodrik et al (2004), Acemoglu et al (2005) among others argue that, the fundamental cause of growth may lie more on the Smith principle of properly-organized markets, where quality institutions are front and center (Bruinshoofd 2016). Acemoglu et al (2005), for instance argue that knowledge capital, physical capital and technology are just proximate causes and that institutions are the fundamental causes of growth. 2 North (1981) defines institutions as the rule that shape incentive structure in the society which may increase or hamper economic activities. Easterly (2013) builds on the case that, any type of economic progress that is to be sustainable should be built on respect of the rights of the individual in the society. Better performing institutions may improve growth by increasing the volume of investment (Rodrik 2008). Alexiou, Tsaliki, and Osman, (2014) support the findings that the quality of the institutional environment is highly fundamental in defining economic prosperity for Sudanese economy. This result is not different from the study of Nguyen, Su, and Nguyen (2018) that investigated the impacts of institutional quality on economic growth for 29 emerging economies over the 2002-2015 period based on System Generalized Method of Moments (SGMM) estimators and found positive and significant impacts on economic growth.it should be noted that many of the results above found positive effects although without focusing on the channel effect of institutions on growth. This result is similar to that of Góes (2015), who finds institutional quality to be crucial for real per capita income growth. Other studies like Rodrik (2004), Hall & Jone (1999), Nawaz et al (2014), among others also favoured institutiongrowth enhancing argument. Meanwhile studies like Arshad (2019) argues that the impact of institutions on growth might be overstated and emphasized the importance of measuring their impact in general –rather than specific effects, which also crucial for policy diagnosis. Arshad (2019) empirically, explores the role of institutional quality on economic growth while focusing on the channel of foreign direct investments. Using dataset of 104 countries based on a dynamic panel data analysis, the study provides evidence that both FDI inflows and institutional quality cause stronger economic growth. Similarly, Yushi and Borojo (2018) examine the impacts of quality of institutions on growth through infrastructural channels. Yushi and Borojo (2018) specifically study institutions in terms of border and transport efficiency, physical and communication infrastructure on overall and intra-Africa trade. The study covers 44 African countries and their 173 trade partners for the periods 2000–2014. While the findings disclose that the marginal effect of the quality of institutions in terms of physical and communication infrastructure on trade flow lead to increasing growth, the marginal effect of border and transport efficiency on trade decreases growth. The investigation of Mullings (2018) into the existence and strength of the interaction between institutional quality and globalization on real economic growth was also channel based. Based on a panel dataset covering 82 countries and spanning 25 years (1986–2010), the author employs dimensionality reduction techniques to identify key components of institutional quality: the rule of law, civil liberties and political rights. The empirical results reveal that while institutional quality robustly and positively affects growth, the direct effect of economic globalization was not significant and the interaction effects, perhaps as a consequence, are muted over the review period. Direct and interaction effects of institutional quality and economic globalization on growth were, however, observed for the sub-sample of developing countries. It should be noted that all the empirical studies above reported that institutions are fundamental cause of growth, without recourse to Acemoglu et al (2005) argument that different institutions exert different impact on growth. Braunfel (2016) argues that different effects of institutions depend on the domain they structure. The lumping of all institutions, despite the distinct role different institutions play in growth process also been queried by World Bank (2002). The world 3 bank have specifically argued that homogenous assumption of possible distinct effects of institutions on growth might have obscured the different channels through which institutions operate, an issue that is crucial to a better understanding of the fundamental cause of growth. Acknowledging the importance of separating measures of institutions, Kormendi and Meguire (1985), Helliwell (1992), Mauro (1995), Knack and Keefer (1997), Angeles (2011) focus on one aspect of institutions and economic growth. Kormendi and Meguire (1985) specifically examine the relationship between civil liberties growth and find positive relationship. The work of Helliwell (1992) on democracy and growth finds negative relationship. Using ethnolinguistic fractionalization as instrument to accounting for issue of endogeneity, Mauro (1995) discovers that bureaucratic efficiency is fundamental to high investment and growth. Murphy et al. (1999), Svensson (2005), Blattman (2012) all focus on issue related to corruption-growth nexus, although with different conclusion. While Murphy et al. (1999) considers corruption as a headwind, Svensson (2005) calls corruption a ‘grease the wheels’ instrument, or Blattman (2012) ‘speed money’. Easton and Walker (1997) on the other hand find that economic freedom is an important explanatory variable for steady-state levels of income. Knack and Keefer (1997) provide evidence on the relevance of property rights and economic growth for US. Using evaluations of contract enforceability and risk of expropriation, the authors found that rates of convergence to US level of incomes increase notably when property right variable was included in growth regressions. Flachaire et al (2011) observe that majority of the above studies either lumped different versions of institutions into one or just focused on one aspect, hence unable to determine which institution that is most fundamental. Flachaire et al (2011) focus on the question: which institution is more important between political and economic. The study asserts that, political institutions set the stage in which economic institutions and policies were implemented. Other studies that attempted to distinguish various measures of institutions are Vijayaraghavan and Ward (2007) and Orayo (2016). Vijayaraghavan and Ward (2007) incorporate three institutional variables (security of property rights, governance size and political freedom) but concluded that security of property rights and sizes of government are the most significant institutions that explain variations growth rates. The work of Orayo (2016) considers six different institutional variables based on World Bank governance indicators (voice and accountability, political stability and absence of violence, government effectiveness, regulatory quality, rule of law and control of corruption). Results from static analysis and ordinary least square (OLS) suggest that voice and accountability is significant for the growth of Kenya and Uganda, quality of regulation for Kenya and Tanzania and rule of law for Kenya. It could be observed that, results from empirical studies either suggest collective classification of institutions or focus on one aspect without separating different institutional effects on growth which have left hanging the question; which institution is fundamental for growth? This study attempts to bridge the literature-gap by unbundle institutions and determining which institutional quality is most fundamental to growth, an aspect that has not received adequate attention in SSA, 4 where overarching vision and policy framework for accelerating growth are in dire need for agenda 2030. This study is therefore unique. 3 Theoretical Framework: The Hierarchy of Institutions Hypothesis The argument that different institutions exert different impact on growth provides a natural starting point for separating the effects of distinct institutions on economic development. In their pioneering work, Acemoglu et al (2005) point to the importance of distinguishing types of institutions. They separate the role of contracting, economic institutions, and political institutions in growth process. Economic institutions are said to be important because it gives the creator of an idea certain exclusive rights over its creation; notably the right to benefit from its commercial exploitation through a legal monopoly (Angele, 2010). These rights take mainly the form of patents and copyrights. Without property rights, economic agents in the society may not have the incentive to invest in physical or human capital or adopt more efficient technologies. People who invest in new capital or in the case of intellectual property rights- new ideas expect to have the freedom to use and profit from them as they deem it fit. If that condition is not met i.e if people believe that their capital may be expropriated or their ideas stolen, they will refrain from making those investments in the first place. The more likely it is that the sovereign will alter property rights for his or her own benefit, the lower the expected returns from investment and the lower in turn the incentive to invest (North & Weingast, 1989, p. 803). Economic institutions are also believed to be the outcome of the interpretation, upholding, and enforcement of laws by the legal system (Angele 2010). Where government decisions concern the rule of law in the legal system, they can be seen as inputs into the production of property rights. The rule of law, especially for developing countries, may be the area of economic freedom that is most important in laying the foundations for economic growth, and in advanced economies, deviations from the rule of law may be the first signs of serious problems that will lead to economic decline (Feulner, 2013). Political institutions are argued to define, for instance, constraints on the executive branch, rights of political participation, and accountability through forms of election. The key characteristics of political institutions are accountability, and checks and balances in the political decision-making process. Stronger constraints improve the representation of different interest groups and constrain despotic behavior, leading to policies that serve the majority, and induce long-term stability and development (Acemoglu et al. 2014b). Political institutions regulate accountability of politicians. While these rules sometimes affect the legal system, they cover a much broader area (Braunfels, 2016). Where political decisions concern property laws and the organization of the legal system, they can be seen as an input (into property rights productions). Legal scholars have associated strong rule of law increased confidences in the judicial system (Feulner, 2013). Cass (2001) argue that strong rule of law is a critical factor in empowering individuals, ending discrimination, and enhancing competition that can guarantee sustainable growth. 5 In summary, the distinctive characteristic of institutions is that they regulate relations between private parties, while economic institutions structure the top down relation by protecting citizens from elites and powerful individuals. Political institutions define the interaction of elites at the state level and the bottom up control of the state by citizens. Braunfels (2016) observes that, an independent judiciary is important for good economic institutions, but may also act as certain constraints on the executive branch of government. Although there are crucial differences among different institutions, each of them importantly covers dimensions the other does not. 4 Methodology- Model Specification To develop more satisfactory answer to question of why some countries are much richer than others and why some countries grow much faster than others, Acemoglu et al (2005) argue that differences in human capital, physical capital, and technology are only proximate factors, while institutional factors are fundamental. In other to determine if the role institutional quality on growth is fundamentals in SSA, our study follows the model specifications of Acemoglu et al (2005) thus: yi ,t yi ,t 1 Insit X i ,t i ,t 1 IID 0. 2 , t IID 0. 2 , i ,t IID 0. 2 where i all errors are independent of each other and among themselves. i indexes countries, t denotes time, yi ,t is the growth rate of GDP per capita measured as the log GDP growth per capita in year t. yi ,t 1 is the logarithm of GDP growth per capita lagged one year (a method that helps fix dynamism issues) (Baltagi & Levin 1986). Insi,t represents institutional quality index, Xi,t represents a matrix of control variables (investment, growth in population, trade openness, human capital development, government consumption, landlocked, legal formalization) and i ,t is an error term. As mentioned earlier many theoretical models show that institutions are likely endogenous E ( i ,t / Ins) 0 . Accordingly, Glaeser et al (2004) argue that, it was the subsequent economic development that allows South Korea to adopt a more inclusive institutional arrangement. This therefore naturally set the stage for the possibility of endogeneity between institutions and economic growth (Bruinshoofd, 2016). This is not different from the classical modernization theories (Moore, 1966) that development positively affects rule of law through the rise of the middle class and the demand for representation and protection from one another and the state (Waggonner, 2016). Estimating model (1) directly would generate biased estimators (Arellano & Bond 1991, Waggonner 2016). We handle this problem by introducing a set of instruments for Ins . Then we can express (Ins)i,t in terms of these instruments Gi,t as equation (2) 6 Ins i ,t g Gi ,t i ,t 2 where, for simplicity, g(Gi,t ) is assumed to be parametric, say g (Gi ,t ) bGi ,t . We choose lagged explanatory variables as instruments (Arellano & Bover 1995). Thus, (2) can be written as 3 Ins i,t bzi,t 1 i,t where Z represents all the explanatory variables in (1). We assume that E ( i ,t / Zi ,t 1,ui ,t ) E ( i ,t / ui ,t ) . It then follows that E ( i ,t / ui ,t ) 0, since E i ,t / Ins 0 . Hence, one decomposed i ,t into i (ui ,t ) i ,t , where i (ui ,t ) E ( i ,t / ui ,t ) and i ,t i ,t E ( i ,t / ui ,t ) . Equation (1) then becomes (4) yi ,t yi ,t 1 Ins i ,t X i ,t i i ,t i ,t 4 We replace the unobservable i ,t by the observable i ,t Ins i ,t Zi ,t 1 . Then equation (4) becomes equation (5) y i ,t yi ,t 1 Ins i ,t X i ,t i i ,t i,t 5 Where the error i,t i ,t i i ,t i i ,t . One can use Arellano and Bover (1995) weighting matrix estimator to obtain consistent estimation of parameters and in model (5), say ̂ and ˆ . Then substitute ̂ and ˆ into the model (6) y i ,t yi ,t 1 Ins i ,t X i ,t i i ,t i,t 6 where i,t denotes the new composite error term that accounts for the estimation of and . One crucial argument of Acemoglu et al (2005) hierarchy of institutions hypothesis is that, different institutions affect economic growth through different channels (Flachaire et al 2011, Ivlevs & King 2015). Bettin and Zazzaro (2008) argue that quality and stable political system, respect for rule of law, effective policy implementations would generally influence motivation to more investment that could eventually influence equilibrium growth rates; in particular, to the extent that intermediaries tend to promote capital investment. They also tend to raise rates of growth. In order to investigate which institution that is fundamental to growth in SSA, we unbundle institutional quality based on Braunfels (2016) that separate institutions into three types contracting institutions, economic institutions and political institutions thus: yi,t yi ,t 1 1EInsi ,t 2 PInsi ,t 3GIns X i,t i (i ,t ) i,t 7 7 Where EIns is economic institutions, Pins is political institutions and Gins is governance institutions. other definitions are as before. To estimate the model above, we use the GMM weighting estimators proposed by Arellano and Bover (1995) and Blundell and Bond (1998) to obtain consistent estimates of f Ins i ,t and i (uˆi , t ), say f Ins i ,t and ˆí (ui ,t ) . It is of course f Ins i ,t the estimated function that we are interested in, since it captures the marginal impact of the separate institutional quality variable on per capita growth clean of any endogeneity. One can further unbundle equation (8) to accommodate more number of institutional quality variables as follows: yi ,t yi ,t 1 1Geffi ,t 2CoCi ,t 3 PolAvi ,t 4 Roli ,t 5 Rqi ,t 6VAi ,t 7 Efreei ,t 8 P Ri ,t 9 Bufi ,t 8 X i ,t i ( i ,t ) i ,t (see summary statistics table 1 or correlation table 2 for the definition of the institutional quality variables in model 8. An important contribution of this study is of course the use of many institutional quality variables as well as ensuring distinct effects based on average high correlation value among endogenous variables. Sanderson and Windmeijer (2016) developed a test that allows evaluating if the effects of multiple endogenous variables can be separately identified based on average high correlation value. The test is designed for the limit where the endogenous variables are distinctly correlated such that π1 is close to a linear transformation of π2 and π3, in which case, such institutional variable is expected to be significantly related with the other variables. The inconsistencies observed in the studies above might not be unconnected with the fact that author assumed away the fundamental issue of dynamism and endogeniety in estimating the relationship between institution and growth. This jettisoning of the issue of endogeneity call for worry especially based on its methodological relevance in institutions-growth dynamic. Rodrik (2004) and Acemoglu, Johnson, Robinson, and Yared (2009) agree that traditional empirical literature generally carries problems like endogeneity, measurement errors and omitted variables bias, making it difficult to disentangle the web of cause-effect between prosperity and institutions. Acemoglu et al (2009) conclude that the best way to solving endogeneity inherent in institutionsgrowth dynamics may be the use of panel generalized method of moment (GMM). GMM is efficient in solving endogeneity and other econometric problem since it provides more reliable and robust inference (Temple, 1999). Another advantage of the estimation techniques is that the model need not be homoscedastic and serially independent (Nawaz et al, 2014). Although there are variants of panel GMM, this study in particular, adopt system GMM estimation based on Arellano and Bover (1995) and Blundell and Bond (1998), to confront issues of endogenity and 8 adjust for dynamism at the same time. The Arellano-Bover/Blundell-Bond estimator augments Arellano-Bond by making an additional assumption that first differences of instrument variables are uncorrelated with the fixed effects. It builds a system of two equations – the original equation in levels and the transformed one in differences – and is known as system GMM. This method allows more instruments and hence leads to improved efficiency. Although ArellanoBover/Blundell-Bond has one and two step variants, this study makes use of the two-step because it is more robust and asymptotically more efficient than the one step (Nickel 1981, Baltagi & Levin 1986, Nawaz et al, 2014). 4.3 Data Sources, Definition of variables and Summary of Statistics To determine which of the institutions is most important to growth, this study employs a panel data set of 25 African countries over the period 1996-2015. The choice of the countries and periods are based on the availability of data on variables. Our outcome variable is growth of gross domestic product. Other variables include investment, trade openness, population growth, university education enrolment and institutions. Investment is measured as the gross fixed capital formation as a percent of GDP. Trade openness is the sum of exports and imports divided by the GDP. The data employed are from different sources. The dataset are from different sourcesWorld Bank’s World Development Indicators (WDI), heritage foundation (HF), United Nations Educational, Scientific, and Cultural Organization (UNESCO) Institute for Statistics and International Monetary Fund (IMF) Balance of Payments Statistics Yearbook and data files. Out main outcome variable (growth of gross domestic product) is from the WDI. University Education (Enrolment) is sourced from United Nations Educational, Scientific, and Cultural Organization (UNESCO) Institute for Statistics database. Trade-openness is sourced from International Monetary Fund (IMF), Balance of Payments Statistics Yearbook and data files. Dummy variables based on legal formalism (UK and French legal origin) and landlocked are part of our explanatory power. The data on the institutional variables are collected from the Worldwide Governance Indicators (WGI) published by the World Bank and Heritage Foundation. The WGI database provides six different measures capturing different dimensions of the institutional framework. These indicators include: (i) control of corruption, (ii) government effectiveness, (iii) political stability and absence of violence/terrorism, (iv) regulatory quality, (v) rule of law, and (vi) voice and accountability. That of HF provides (1) economic freedom, (2) property right, (3) business freedom. All institutions estimate gives the country's score on the aggregate indicator in units of a standard normal distribution ranging from -2.5 to +2.5. The low value indicates bad quality institutions and vice versa. The level of institutional quality across SSA countries nevertheless remains a missed bag (see figure 1). On average, countries like Boswana and Mauritius are the best performed while Namibia follows. Sudan got the weakest scores on average. The same pattern of performance can be observed in term of control of corruption. (See appendix figure 3 as Sudan, Nigeria, Burundi, Cameron and Congo. Republic suffer most on control of corruption). Mauritius is the best performed SSA countries in terms of rule of law followed by Botswana and Namibia and Sudan and Guinea remain the worst hit. On average, the best performing countries in SSA are Botswana, Namibia and Mauritius. These countries do not record any negative index in terms of institutional quality variables. Thanks for 9 their significant inclusive institutional reforms. These performances consolidate the World Economic Forum Global Competitiveness Report 2014-2015 Rankings for Sub-Saharan Africa where Mauritius, Boswana and Namibia are consistently in leading position. The greatest strengths of these countries according to the report are their transparent and efficient government spending, well-protected property rights, strong judicial independence, well organized labour market, low levels of corruption in regional comparison and a sound macroeconomic environment (World Economic Forum 2015 & 2017). This phenomenon may let us into important conclusion that quality institutions are basic requirements for economic success and long term progress in Mauritius, Boswana and Namibia. Fig 1: Average levels of institutional qualities across SSA, 1996-2015 1 Mauritius Botswana 0,5 unit change, -2.5 to 2.5 Namibia 0 -0,5 0 5 Benin Burkina Faso -1 10 Ghana 15 Mali Gambia, The Madagascar Kenya Cameroon Comoros Cote d'Ivoire Congo, Rep. Guinea Burundi 20 Senegal 25 30 INSQ Tanzania Swaziland Uganda; Niger Rwanda 0,633153504 Togo Nigeria -1,5 Sudan -2 Sources: Author’s This study first unbundles institution into three measures: economic, political and governance institution. Economic institution is a composite average data of economic, business, private property right and rule of law following Adam Smith well-organized market argument. Political institution is a measure of degree of stability of democracy following Owen et al. (2009) and governance institution is based on government consumption expenditure. Institutions are further unbundled into nine. Economic freedom measures the extent to which property rights are protected and the freedom that individuals have to engage in voluntary transactions. This measure takes into account the respect of personal choices, the voluntary exchange coordinated by markets, freedom to enter and compete in markets, and protection of persons and their property from aggression by others. A political institution is the degree of stability of democracy. This measure takes into account the competitiveness of executive recruitment, the openness of executive recruitment, the constraints on the executive, and the competitiveness of political participation. Descriptive statistics on the variables use for this study are presented in table 1. 10 Table 1 show that, the annual average GDP per capita growth rate is 1.42 over the period 19962015. The annual average investment as percent of GDP is 24 over the same period. The annual average inflation across the full sample is 2.92, while annual average openness of trade is relatively high in SSA (4.13) as compared to population growth rate (2.59). Table 1: Descriptive statistics Variable Min Std. Dev Mean Max GDP capita growth 1.42 3.51 -2.30 Investment 2.92 3.71 1.02 Govt Consumption 2.60 4.15 1.52 Trade openness 4.13 5.15 2.88 Population growth 2.59 7.98 0.13 Control of corruption -0.55 1.24 -1.51 Pol stab & Abs of Viol -0.52 1.18 -2.65 Rule of law -0.62 1.05 -1.72 Regulatory quality -0.50 1.12 -1.67 Voice & Accountability -0.56 1.02 -1.88 University 6.34 39.72 0.55 Education(Enrolment) Landlock 0.32 1 0 British Legal origin 0.56 1 0 French Legal origin 0.44 1 0 Economic freedom 3.97 4.34 2.30 Property right 3.58 4.31 2.30 Business freedom 3.99 4.44 3.36 Source: author’s Table 2: Correlation coefficient of different institutions, 1996 to 2015 GEFF COC PSAVT ROL RQ VA Govt Effectiveness 1 Contr of corruption 0.8155 1 15 11 Pol stab/ Abs of 0.632 0.703 1 Viol Rule of law 0.8732 0.8364 0.7827 1 1 8 Regulatory quality 0.902 0.781 0.647 0.8673 1 10 13 Voice & 0.726 0.661 0.68812 0.8056 0.7339 1 Accountabil 11 N 0.70 0.39 0.34 0.44 0.79 0.57 0.90 0.62 0.54 0.70 5.77 500 500 500 500 500 500 500 500 500 500 500 0.46 0.49 0.49 0.30 0.40 0.21 500 500 500 500 500 500 LEFREE LPR LBUF Economic freedom Property right Business freedom 0.53225 0.58222 0.60419 0.369 0.58621 0.58720 0.155 0.452 0.45626 0.428 0.62616 0.56523 0.56523 0.63614 0.62317 0.265 0.469 0.432 1 0.351 0.376 1 0.61818 Sources: Author’s derivation. Note that the highest correlation coefficient, regulatory quality and government effectiveness (.902) is dropped in further unbundling model. This is to avoid multi-colinearity problem. Table 1 depicts correlations for the various institutions employed in this study. As shown in the table, there general positive correlation between institutions variables. Rule of law shows strong positive correlation coefficient with 0.873. For instance, the correlation between rule of law institutions and control of corruption index is 0.836. This is expected based on the theoretical argument that the two variables are intrinsically related. This high correlation may be a first indicator that, increase in rule of law may be a good strategy in fighting against corruption. While correlations between economic freedom and rule of law institutions are 0.626, that of business freedom and rule of law is not quite different from the same coefficient. These results indicate that economic and business freedom has something in common. The high correlation coefficients in most of the institutional variables employed underlines the strong relationship among the variables. However, regulatory quality and government effectiveness record the highest correlation coefficient of 0.902, suggesting multi-colinearity problem. To solve the regression indeterminacy and infinite standard error that this may cause, this study separates regulatory in the main model. 5 Empirical Results - Proximate and Fundamental Factors impact on Growth restated Table 3 presents the results based on the impact of proximate, others and fundamental factors. The results are based on 25 SSA countries over the period 1996-2015. The results pass a battery of diagnostic tests. The Hansen J 18.5 with 0.67 statistics of over identifying restrictions confirms that the instruments employed are acceptable and healthy i.e., uncorrelated with the error term, and that the excluded instruments are correctly excluded from the estimated equation. Across all estimations, this study finds that initial income as a measure of past realisation of growth has positive impact on its current levels. We have estimated 3 models in table 3 to explain the differences in growth models. Model 1 represents the proximate factors that include – population growth, human capital and domestic investment. This model is also known as humancapital augmented version of the Solow type or conventional model (Easterly & Levine 1997). As expected, the result indicates that increase in domestic investment leads to growth in SSA. On average, one point increase in domestic investment increases economic growth by 0.3 point. This result is in line with economic growth theories - classical, neo-classical and endogenous growth theories which posit that, domestic capital formation is generally a catalyst for rapid growth and development of any economy, be it developed, developing or under-developed. It also supports the idea that rapid domestic investment is capable of increasing the pace of economic growth and ensuring swift structural transformation of the economy (Romer 1986, Fashola 1998, Easterly 2001, Barro & Sala-i-Martin 2003 & Aghion et al 2005). Accordingly, these results show that domestic capital formation plays crucial role in economic growth of SSA. Similarly, Population growth rate is positive and significant, though with very small magnitude on economic growth. This positive but very small relational impact could be as a result of the rapidly increasing 12 1 population in SSA which adds a substantial number to the total population every year with low per capita income and employment rates which implies ‘a circular constellation of forces tending to act and react upon one another in such a way as to keep a poor country in a state of poverty’. The coefficient of university enrolment that proxy human capital development based on linear specification is though positive but not significant. The coefficient turns positive and significant via non- linear dimensions. This results support the argument that the relation between human capital and growth is not quite simple. One possible explanation is the argument that it takes some time before increase in enrolment can affect growth. This throws in a sound of warning that government or any other investor in education should not expect instant impact on growth. This study is also unaware that a better measure of human capital could be training rather school enrolment (Temple, 1999). Model 2 extends Model l, by introducing geographic, historical and trade variables (landlocked, British and French legal formalism and globalization) which are considered exogenous (Hall & Jones, 1999). Comparing the results of extended model (2) and baseline model l, the coefficients of the entire proximate factors only reduce slightly, even with the introduction of the so called other variables. The coefficient for landlocked is positive and significant in model 2. Trade openness is also positive and significant, indicating that, countries that are more open to trade improve more on growth rate. The results for legal origin are similar, positive and significant. Table 3: Proximate and Fundamental Factors impact on Growth Variables GDP capita growth(-1) Domestic investment Population growth University Education(Enrolment) University Education(Enrolment)2 Proximate factor Model 1 0.220 (3.376)* 0.334 (10.230)* 0.172 (4.865)* 0.007 (1.467) 0.0026 (0.746)* Trade openness Landlock British Legal origin French Legal origin Institutions 13 Trade, Geography &Legal formalism Model 3 Fundamental Model 3 0.193 (3.179) 0.237 (2.395)** 0.116 (3.052)** 0.185 (3.133)* 0.237 (2.396)** 0.031 (3.052)** 0.0028 (3.041)** 0.066* (0.012) 0.135 (1.649)*** 0.800 (2.003)** 0.910 (2.508)** 0.0018 (1.951)*** 0.067* (0.013) 0.125 (1.629) 1.273 (2.395)** 1.378 (2.694)** 0.136 (2.165)** 25 25 Instrument rank 25 23.23(0.67) 26.78(0.78) Hansen J Stat(Prob J-Sta) 18.5(0.67) 81.33(0.0000) 89.10(0.000) F statistics 78.17(0.000) 0.66 0.67 Stand Error value 0.67 25 25 Number countries Observation(panel) 450 480 500 Source: Standard errors in parentheses ***p<0.1, **p<0.05, *p<0.01 The similar in the coefficients of both British (common law 0.8) and French (civil 0.9) support argument that the differential barrier in the two types of law have rapidly torn, hence suggests reform convergence (La Porta et al 2008). Model 3 reveals the results for the inclusion of institutional quality (INSQ). Institutional quality (though overall) shows a positive and significant effect on growth in SSA countries. On average, a unit increase in institutional quality suggests around a 0.1 point increase in economic growth. The results favour the institutional quality – growth enhancing view that, institutions matter for growth as they shape the incentives in the society, in particular as they influence investments in physical and human capital and technology, and the organization of production (Adam Smith 1776, North 1990, Acemoglu, Johnson & Robinson 2005, Zouhaier 2012). The findings are consistent with that of Keefer & Knack (1997), Rodrik et al. (2004), Acemoglu & Robinson (2013), Iqbal & Daly (2014), Nawaz et al (2014), Bruinshoofd (2016), Mullings (2018), Arshad (2019). Comparing the significance level of domestic investment (5%) population growth (5%) and university enrolment (5%), we could safely conclude that both proximate and fundamental factors are major causes of growth in SSA. It is although argue that proper understanding of the role of institutions should not be limited on its overarching definition. This is based on the argument that lumping all institutions would obscure the separate effects which institution can have on growth. Based on Acemoglu et al. (2005) hierarchy of institution hypothesis, this study therefore first unbundles institutions into economic, political and governance in the next session. 5.2 Unbundling Institutions into Economic, Political and Governance Table 4 shows the result of separate effects of institutions on economic growth. Model 1 shows the overarching role while model 2 shows the role of political, economic and governance institutions. As expected, the results show a strong positive relationship between past realization of economic growth and their current levels. Based on model 2, economic institution exhibits positive influence on economic growth as before. The result presupposes that economic institutions matter for growth in SSA. Specifically, a unit increase in economic institutional quality suggests around a 0.66 point increase in economic growth. This result favour Adam Smith eloquent description of how economic institution with well-organized market place matter and matter a lot for growth. It also resonant Acemoglu et al (2005) believe that: ‘of primary 14 importance to economic outcomes are the economic institutions in society such as the structure of property rights and the presence and perfection of markets’. The results favour the growthenhancing view of economic institutional quality argument by World Bank (2002) and the empirical works of Flachaire et al (2011). The elasticity of political institution with respect to growth is positive but not significant. This might be as a result of not trusting political institutions enough, in particular regarding their commitment enough to a transparent policy arena, suggesting limited role of political institutions on growth in SSA. The effect of governance institutions (proxy by governance consumption) is negative and insignificant. This confirms the argument in the literature that government involvement in everything (spending) can hardly lead to growth in an environment that is enmeshed with corruption (remember Tony Blair’s fantastically corrupt euphemism). Specifically, a unit improvement in a country’s regulatory quality (RQ), lead to 0.27 unit decrease in growth, suggesting that, the more government regulates, the more economic decline in SSA. This result further unsettled the argument that too much regulation of government is damaging to growth prospect. This is an indication that government has been enmeshing itself in unnecessary regulation over the year in SSA. Government may have to provide unbiased and minimum regulation so as to fairly referee the business competition. When government abandons its neutrality, either through outright corruption or through misguided efforts at social engineering that involve picking an economy’s winners and losers, the predictable results are a loss of efficiency, a reduction in productivity, and eventual economic stagnation. This resonates Adam Smith government has no business in business argument, although often misinterpreted. The results in model 2 provide information regarding distinct effects of institutions - economic, political and governance on growth. The separation has shown that economic institution is more important as compared to political institutions in SSA countries. Furthermore, we have found that different institutions perform differently role on the growth of SSA. These findings have supported Acemoglu et al (2005) hierarchy of institution hypothesis and Zhuang, et al. (2010) and Flachaire et al( 2011) view that different institutions perform differently in growth process. Table 4: unbundling institutions on growth in SSA, 1996-2015 Variables GDP capita growth(-1) Institutions Institutional qualities(Model 1) Unbundling Institutional qualities(Model 2) 0.106 (9.176)* 0.104 (23.43)* 0.896 (0.013) Economic Institutions 0.667 (2.955)** 0.116 (3.052)** Political institutions 15 Further unbundling Institutional qualities (Model 3) 0.185 (3.133)* Govt Consumption -0.142 (-1.134) Govt effectiveness 0.024 (0.809) 0.084 (1.142) 0.082 (0.036)*** 0.648 (0.787) Control of corruption Political stability Rule of law Regulatory quality -0.272 (-3.612)** Voice & accountability -0.068 (-1.266) 1.213 (6.088)* Economic freedom Private property right 0.111 (0.143) 0.273 (1.886)*** 25 19.5(0.68) 0.66 .65 25 Business freedom Instrument rank Hansen J Stat(Prob J-Sta) S.D dependent var Stand Error value Number countries 25 18.5(0.67) 0.65 25 20.7(0.69) 0.66 .66 25 Observation(panel) 450 500 500 Source: Standard errors in parentheses ***p<0.1, **p<0.05, *p<0.01 :Our (Hansen J. 18.5(0.67) probability value) of over identifying restrictions confirms that the instruments used are uncorrelated with the residuals, hence acceptable and healthy. In order to give explicit answer to the question: which institution matter most for growth in SSA? Model 3 further unbundles institutions into nine, measures based on World Bank and Heritage foundation measures (rule of law, control of corruption, governance effectiveness, voice and accountability, political stability/absence of terrorism, regulatory quality, business freedom, Private property right and economic freedom). The coefficient of governance effectiveness is 0.024. This indicates positive but not significant relation with growth. Our coefficient of political stability (PS) is positive and significant. This result is not very different from the earlier one since it was positive, but not significant, suggesting limited role of formal institutions on growth in SSA. 16 Interestingly, the coefficient of economic (1.213) and business (0.273) freedom are positive and significant. These results show that, the more people the society are freed to pursue their individual economic/business, the more the growth prospect. On average, a unit point increase in economic freedom increases growth by 1.2 unit and business freedom by 0.2 unit. The freemarket economy is though conditionally depends on open competitive environment with a level playing field according to Adam Smith. We find voice and accountability (VA) and government effectiveness indices (GEI) to be insignificant on growth in SSA. The result for voice and accountability is not surprising as it reinforces how government in SSA does not take the voice/demand of their citizen serious (remember the on-going demand for restructuring by Nigerian). Unexpectedly, rule of law (ROL) is positive but insignificant. This is not different from the results from control of corruption. The similarity in the results for rule of law and control of corruption may be intrinsic. It supports the perspective that a weak rule of law implies high level of corruption. This is in line with the World Bank idea that strengthening the rule of law is a fundamental way of controlling corruption. The lack of significance of rule of law index is not unexpected since it captures the perceptions of the extent to which African do not have confidence in and abide by the rules of society, and in particular the quality of contract enforcement, property rights, lack of confidence in the police, and the courts, as well as the likelihood of crime and violence. The lack of statistical significance of rule of law in SSA should not be misconstrued as unimportant, rather should be seen as consistent with the poor performance of rule of law and control of corruption in SSA. This insignificant relationship may be due to Bratton and Gyimah-Boadi (2016) argument that, on average, citizens express more trust in informal institutions such as religious and traditional leadership than in formal executive agencies and the state (AEO 2017). This underscores Dahlberg and Holmberg (2016) position that, trusts in judicial institutions, electoral process and are among the crucial enablers for a country’ success with democracy. The legislative institutions and the electoral agencies- key layers in a democracy- are argued to even have lower levels of trust (AEO 2017). The poor implementation of rule of law and ineffective control of corruption seems to be undermining all efforts to growth SSA. Also As opined by Rodick (2002), if the rules of the game were a mess, corruption would strive (OECD 2017) and no amount of tinkering with macroeconomic policy would produce the desired results. It should be noted that, of all the institutional quality variables, rule of law and control of corruption appear to have insignificant impact in the long term growth in SSA. Should we conclude that, rule of law and control of corruption do not matter in SSA growth prospects? Does this mean that increase in rule of law and controls of corruption are intrinsically related as argued by the traditional argument? See the next session. 7 How Closely Correlated are Institutions in sub-Saharan Africa? How exactly, institutions measures hang together in SSA can be determined through correlation and regression coefficient? This is by determining the institution that exhibits the highest average 17 correlation coefficient (Haggard et al 2008). Based on institutions correlation table 2, rule of law is found to have the highest average correlation coefficient. This is the first indication that, rule of law is the most central to other institutional measures. What is then the relationship between rule of law and other institutional quality variables? Regression result (Table 5) suggests that, every institutional qualities employed in the study is highly sensitive to rule of law. The results also show that regression of rule of law on each institutional quality variable is a good fit. Rsquared (62%) and adjusted Rw (84%) for control of corruption can be seen to be the highest. This result resonates the idea that rule of law is intrinsically related to control of corruption (Mendonca & Fonseca 2012). Table 5: Impact of Rule of Law on other Institutions in SSA Variable Govt COC RQ Efree Buf VA PSAVT PR Eff Rule of law 0.777 16.330 0.808 0.763 9.953 11.11 0.939 1.137 41.58 20.450 40.05 33.9 17.58 16.05 32.2 28.08 R-squared 60 62 61 44 32 57 53 39 Adjust Rw81 84 81 62 38 74 62 53 squared Sources: Author’s This supports the argument of Fuelner (2013) that, the better the rule of law, the better the control of corruption and richer the nation. It is also in line with Rodrik (2008) assertion that stable, predictable laws encourage investors which is an underlying prerequisite for growth of other institutions. All these go with the Amartya Sen’s assertions that ‘if you expand people's capabilities within a true independence of judiciary, they will do things that help countries grow rich. Freeing people to take advantage of their capabilities usually means lifting the oppressive burden of the state and guaranteeing certain basic rights (Smith 1776, Rodrik 2008). The results support Berg and Saie (2013) idea that strong rule of law is not a mere adornment to development; it is a vital source of progress which creates an environment in which the full spectrum of human creativity can flourish, and prosperity can be built. These results also clearly reaffirm United Nations Economic Commission for Africa (2016) position that, though a number of institutional qualities are important to achieve sustainable growth in African countries, strong rule of law still holds a central place. This is the part the government of the world's newest country, Kosovo, seems to be toeing when it say, its priority is to improve the rule of law in order to reduce corruption and build up the state. Moreover, given the poor performance of rule of law that exists for African economies, it is not impossible that the poor performances of the rule of law determine the lack of control of corruption (OECD 2017), and the reason for lack of sustainable growth in SSA (bearing on fantastically corrupt euphemism). The result implies that increase in rule of law represents a good strategy in the fight against corruption in SSA. 7 Conclusion and Policy Implications Several studies in the literature have concluded that institutions are fundamental for growth enhancement and suggested that government in the less developed countries should vigorously 18 pursue institutional reforms. This has left many less developed countries with no choice than to continually grasp with trying to strengthen all institutions at the same time, without first identifying which institutions is most fundamental to growth, as advised by Hirshman (1958: 109-10) in his unbalance growth strategy (implied though). This study attempts to answer the question, which institution is most fundamental to economic growth by first unbundles institutions into three - economic, political and governance institutions and further into nine rule of law, control of corruption, governance effectiveness, voice and accountability, political stability/absence of terrorism, regulatory quality, business freedom, private property right and economic freedom. The study concludes that economic institution is important to growth than political institutions in SSA countries. While the study reveals that economic institution is crucial to growth, rule of law is reported to be a good strategy in fighting corruption, hence the most fundamental of all the institutional quality indicators. Attaining economic growth in Sub-Sahara Africa may have a considerable bearing on vigorous judicial reforms entrenched in effective control of corruption. Government should pay close attention to detail in the implementation of judicial reform, given that reforms must address the need for cultural changes in those responsible for making the system work. It is necessary to understand what current practices need to be changed and then to develop training programs for judicial workers not only to impart the values and culture of the new system but in order that they fully understand the new procedures they will be carrying out. Government should ensure that all institutions affected by judicial reform are included in the reform process. For example, reform in criminal law procedure will be weakened if it includes only judges and prosecutors but not public defenders or investigative services. Proper judicial reform would bread well-organized market where private property rights are protected This may be important to growth because it would give creator of an idea certain exclusive right over its creation, notably the right to benefit from its commercial exploitation through legal monopoly. It would also lead to just society, where individual can pursue their personal human, physical investment interest without fear. The police reform must be visibly supported from the top, especially the investigative arm of law enforcement for more efficient and effective justice/service delivery. Successful judicial reform underscores the importance of creating special courts solely for the purpose of hearing and speedily determining case like complex corruption and financial crimes with adequate sanctioning. Joining of OECD Anti-Bribery Convention which has an arsenal of legal instruments to fight international and complex corruption through criminalizing bribery in international arena would promote justice delivery. Provision of institutional frameworks that encourage reporting and adequate protection of whistleblower would help in fight against corruption which guarantees just society. Provision of information technology assisted justice system would enhance justice system by ensuring that information is adequately captured and processes speedily, finalized and ready on demand. This requires, as well, measures to ensure adherence to the principles of supremacy of law, equality in the eye of the law (following principle of isonomy), accountability to the law, fairness 19 in the application of the law, separation of powers, participation in decision-making, legal certainty, avoidance of arbitrariness and procedural and legal transparency. This study provides empirical support for hierarchy of institution hypothesis in SSA with the lesson that, a one-size-fits-all institutional reform strategy to promote growth and development may likely be counterproductive. Finally, and just as crucial, researchers should keep in mind that understanding which institutions that is most fundamental to growth requires studying detailed and well-defined institutions and is conditional on thorough unbundling. Reference: Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S. & Robinson, J. A. (2001), The colonial origins of comparative development: an empirical investigation. American Economic Review 91(5), 1369–1401. Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S. & Robinson, J.A. (2002), Reversal of fortune: geography and institutions in the making of the modern World Income Distribution,’ Quarterly Journal of Economics 117(4), 1231–1294. Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S. & Robinson, J. A. (2005), Institutions as a fundamental cause of long-run growth, in: Aghion, P. and S. N. Durlauf (eds.), Handbook of Economic Growth, Volume 1A, Elsevier B.V., 385–472. Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S. Robinson, J. A & Yared, P. (2009). Re-evaluating the modernisation hypothesis. Journal of Monetary Economics 56:8, 1043–1058. Acemoglu, D. & Robinson, J. A. (2013), Why nations fail: The origins of power, prosperity and poverty, Profile Books: London. Acemoglu, D., Gallego, F.A., & Robinson, J.A (2014b) Institutions, human capital and development, Annual Reviews of Economics. African Economic Outlook (2017). Entrepreneurship and industrialization. Angeles, L (2010), Institutions and economic development. new tests and new doubts. Aron, J. (2000). Growth & institutions: A review of the evidence. The World Bank Research Observer, 15(1), 99-135. Aghion, P., & Howitt, P.W. (2005), Growth with quality-improving innovations: An integrated framework. In: Aghion, P., Durlauf, S.N. (Eds.), Handbook of Economic Growth, vol. 1A. Elsevier, Amsterdam. 20 Alexiou, C., Tsaliki, P & Osman, H.R. (2014), Institutional quality and economic growth: empirical evidence from the Sudanese economy, Economic annals, Volume LIX, No.203 / October – December 2014 UDC: 3.33 ISSN: 0013-3264. Anderson, T. W. & Hsiao, C. (1982), Formulation and estimation of dynamic models using Panel Data. Journal of Econometrics 18:1, 47–82. Arellano, M. & Bond, S. (1991), Some tests of specification for Panel Data: Monte Carlo evidence and an application to employment equations. The Review of Economic Studies 58:2, 277–297. Arellano, M. & Bover, O. (1995), Another look at the instrumental variable estimation of error-components models. Journal of Econometrics, 68:1, 29–51. Arshad, H. (2019), Foreign direct investments, institutional quality, and economic growth, the Journal of International Trade & Economic Development, DOI: 10.1080/09638199.2018.1564064 Baltagi, B.H. & Levin, D. (1986), Estimating dynamic demand for cigarettes using Panel Data: the effects of bootlegging, taxation, and advertising reconsidered. Review of Economics and Statistics, 68, 148–155. Baltagi, B.H. (1998). Econometric analysis of Panel Data. 3rd Edition p.147, John Wiley & Sons Ltd, The Atrium, Southern Gate, Chichester, West Sussex, England. Barro, J.A & Sala-i-Martin, X.X (2003), Economic Growth, McGraw-Hill, New York et al. 2003. Blundell, R. & Bond, S. (1998). Initial conditions and moment restrictions in dynamic Panel Data Models. Journal of Econometrics 87:1, 115–143. Bratton, M. & Gyimah-Boadi, E. (2016). Do trustworthy institutions matter for development? corruption, trust, and government performance in Africa, Dispatch 112, Afrobarometer. Braunfels, E. (2016). Further unbundling institutions, institute for Samfunnsøkonomi Norwegian School of Economics, Department of Economics, discussion Paper.r Bruinshoofd, A (2016) Institutional quality and economic performance. Cass, R. (2001). The Rule of Law in America. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins Univ. Press. Dahlberg, S. & Holmberg, S. (2016). The importance of electoral and judicial trust for regime supports, review of public administration and management, Vol. 4, doi.org/10.4172/2315-7844.1000182. Easterly, W. (2001), The Elusive Quest for Growth: Economists’ Adventures and Misadventures in the Tropics, The MIT Press, Cambridge (MA). 21 Easterly, W. (2013), The Tyranny of Experts: Economists, Dictators, and the Forgotten Rights of the Poor, Basic Books, New York. Easton, S. T., & Walker, M.A. (1997), Income, growth, and economic freedom. American Economic Review, May 1997, 328-32. Góes, C. (2015), Institutions and growth: a GMM/IV Panel VAR Approach, IMF Working Paper WP/15/174. Grossman,G.M., Helpman, E. (1991).Innovation and growth in the global economy. MIT Press, Cambridge. Fashola, M. A. (1998). Macro-Economic Theory Highlights and Policy Extensions for Less Developed Economies: p. 98, Concept Publications, Lagos, Nigeria. Flachaire, E., Garcìa-Peñalosa, C & Konte, M (2011). Political versus economic institutions in the growth process. Feulner, E.J (2013) The Rule of Law Special focus section- The Rule of Law 2013 Index of Economic Freedom. Glaeser, E., La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silanes, F. and A. Schleifer (2004), ‘Do institutions cause growth?,’ Journal of Economic Growth 9(3), 271–303. Haggard, S. MacIntyre, A. & Tiede, L. (2008), The rule of law and economic development. Annual Review of Political Science 11: 205-34. Hausmann, Ricardo, Rodrik, D & Andres Velasco, (2005). Growth diagnostics. (unpublished; Cambridge, Massachusetts: John F. Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University). Helliwell, John F.(1992), Empirical linkages between democracy and economic growth. NBER Working Paper No. 4066. Hirschman, A. O. (1958), The Strategy of Economic Development. Yale University Press, New Haven, Connecticut. Iqbal, N. & Daly, V. (2014), Rent seeking opportunities and economic growth in transitional economies. Economic Modelling 37:0, 16–22. Ivlevs, A. & King, R. (2015), Emigration, remittances and corruption experience of those staying behind, Working papers of the Department of Economics, No 0008/2015- University of Perugia (IT) from Università di Perugia, Dipartimento Economia. Keefer, P. & Knack, S. (1997). Institutions and economic performance: Cross-country tests using alternative institutional measures. Economics and Politics, 7(3), 207-227. 22 Mauro, P. (1995), Corruption and Growth. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 110:3, 681–712. Mendonca, H. F. & Fonseca, A. O. (2012), Corruption, income, and rule of law: empirical evidence from developing and developed economics. Brazilian Journal of political Economy, Vol 32 n0 2 (127), pp. 305-314. Mullings, R. (2018), Do institutions moderate globalization's effect on growth? Journal of Institutional Economics, 14(1), 71-102. doi:10.1017/S174413741700008X Murphy, K. M., Shleifer, A., & Vishny, R.W. (1993), Why is rent-seeking so costly to growth? The American Economic Review 83:2, 409–414. Moore, B. Jr. (1966). Social origins of dictatorship and democracy: Lord and peasant in the making of the modern world. Beacon Press, Boston. Nawaz, S., Iqbal, N. & Khan, M.A (2014),* The impact of institutional quality on economic growth: Panel Evidence, The Pakistan Development Review 53:1 (Spring 2014) pp. 15–31. Nguyen, C. , Su, T. and Nguyen, T. (2018), Institutional quality and economic growth: The case of emerging economies. Theoretical Economics Letters, 8, 1943-1956. doi: 10.4236/tel.2018.811127. North, D. C. (1990), Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance, Cambridge University Press, New York. North, D. C. (1981), Structure and Change in Economic History, W. W. Norton & Co, New York. North, D.C., Thomas, R.P. (1973), The rise of the western world: A new economic history. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK. North, D.C., Weingast, B.R. (1989), Constitutions and commitment: Evolution of institutions governing public choice in seventeenth century England. Journal of Economic History 49, 803-832. OECD (2017), Putting an end to corruption-OECD better policies better lives. Orayo, J.A (2016), A comparative study on contribution of governance on economic growth in the East African Community Countries, International Journal of Regional Development ISSN 2373-9851, Vol. 3, No. 2. Owen, A.L., Videras, J., & Davis, L. (2009), Do all countries follow the same growth process? Journal of Economic Growth, 14(4), 265-286 23 Rodrik, D. (2000), Where did all the growth go? External shocks, social conflict and growth collapses, CEPR working paper 1789. Rodrik, D., Subramanian, A., & Trebbi, A., (2002). Institutions rule: The primacy of institutions over geography and integration in economic development, National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper, No.9305. Rodrik, D. (2004), Getting institutions right, Harvard University April 2004. Rodrik, D. (2008). One economics, many recipes: globalization, institutions and economic. Rodrik, D. (2006), Goodbye Washington Consensus, Hello Washington Consensus? A review of the World Bank’s economic growth in the 1990s: Learning from a decade of reform, Journal of Economic Literature 44(4), 973–987. Rodrik, D. (2014b), An African Growth Miracle? National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper No. 20188 Issued in June 2014 NBER Program(s): DEV IFM ITI PR. Romer, P. M. (1986), Increasing returns and long-run growth, Journal of Political Economy 94(5), 1002–1037.] Sanderson, E. & Windmeijer, F. (2016). A weak instrument F-test in linear IV models with multiple endogenous variables. Journal of Econometrics, 190(2):212 221. Smith, A. (1776), The Wealth of Nations: Books I – III, Penguin Classics, London, 1999. Svensson, J (2005). Eight questions about corruption, Journal of Economic Perspectives— Volume 19, Number 3—Summer 2005—Pages 19 – 42. Temple, J. (1999) The New growth evidence, Journal of Economic Literature Vol. XXXVII (March 1999), pp. 112-156. United Nations Economic Commission for Africa (2016) Measuring corruption in Africa: The international dimension matters, African governance report IV. FRICGOVEREPOIV Vijayaraghavan, M. & Ward, W.A (2007), Institutions and economic growth: Empirical evidence from a cross-national analysis, center for international trade, Working Paper 001302, Clemson University. Waggannor, C. (2016), Rule of law corruption and income. Review of public administration and management, Vol. 4, doi.org/10.4172/2315-7844.1000182. World Bank, (2002), World Development Institutions for Markets. New York: Oxford University Press. 24 Report: Building World Economic Forum (2015). The global competitiveness report 2014–2015. World Economic Forum (2017). The global risks report 2017. Yushi, J. and Borojo, D.G (2018), The impacts of institutional quality and infrastructure on overall and Intra-Africa trade. Economics Discussion Papers, No 2018-75, Kiel Institute for the World Economy. http://www.economicsejournal.org/economics/discussionpapers/2018-75. Zhuang, J., De Dios, E. S. & Lagman-Martin, A. (2010) Governance and institutional quality and the links with economic growth and income inequality: With Special Reference to Developing Asia. Asian Development Bank. Zouhaier, H. (2012), Institutions, investment and economic growth International Journal of Economics and Finance Vol. 4, No. 2; February 2012. URL: http://dx.doi.org/10.5539/ijef.v4n2p152 www.ccsenet.org/ijef. 25 Appendices: Appendix 1 F1gure 1 Average performance of rule of law across SSA, 1996 to 2015 1,5 1 Mauritius Botswana unit of change 0,5 Namibia 0 0 -0,5 -1 -1,5 Ghana 10 20 Senegal 25 30 Gambia, The 15 TanzaniaUganda; Mali Benin Madagascar Burkina Faso Swaziland0,509724721 Niger Rwanda Togo Kenya Comoros Cameroon Cote d'Ivoire Nigeria Burundi Congo, Rep.Guinea Sudan 5 -2 Source: Author’s Appendix 1 F1gure 2: 26 ROL Fig 3: Regulatory quality acrross SSA,1996 to 2015 1 unit of change Mauritius Botswana 0,5 Namibia 0 0 -0,5 -1 Uganda; Ghana 5 10 15 20 Senegal 25 0,056194962 30 Burkina Faso Kenya Benin Tanzania Gambia, The Mali Swaziland Madagascar Niger Rwanda Cote d'Ivoire Togo Cameroon Nigeria Guinea Burundi Congo, Rep. Comoros RQ Sudan -1,5 Source: Author’s Appendix 1 F1gure 3 Fig 4: Control of corruption across SSA, 1996 to 2015 1 Botswana Mauritius Namibia unit change 0,5 0 0 5 Burkina Faso -0,5 Benin -1 10 Ghana 15 Madagascar Gambia, The Mali Cote d'Ivoire Comoros Guinea Kenya Cameroon Congo, Rep. Burundi -1,5 Source: Author’s 27 Rwanda 20 25 Senegal Swaziland Niger Nigeria 30 TanzaniaUganda; Togo 0,868814757 Sudan COC