VON THUNEN MODEL
Johann Heinrich Von Thünen (24 June 1783 – 22 September
1850) was a farmer, landowner, and economic who created
perhaps the first known spatial economic model on land rent
using observations he had experienced.
The key assumptions in the classical model are:


1) a city is centrally located in an “isolated state,”
2) one of the surrounding areas around a town is
wilderness,
 3) land is generally flat,
 4) soil quality and climate are consistent,
 5) farmers transport goods to a market using mainly
carts, and
 6) farmers behave rationally in choosing where to
conduct their activities.
There are generally four main circles around the city that
consist, from nearest to a town and moving outwards, of: 1)
intense farming, 2) forest lands, 3) extensive farming, and 4)
grazing. Rent prices for land are high near a city. The model
generally explains variation of land rent and market activity of
a region around towns.
While in many respects the model seems out of date, and
not to mention focused heavily on a limited type of town or
city with a surrounding landscape more reminiscent of
central Europe, there are key concepts relevant for modern
spatial economics.
For one, distance to market for given goods does have a
relationship with profitability, which von Thünen’s model
demonstrates clearly. This makes the model broadly
applicable for products created near a market, showing that
products made near a town have a potential to be more
profitable, although even here a modern globalized world
means for given products distant labor could lower prices.
In addition to grain agriculture, the theory does have
applicability to modern grazing land use practices. For
instance in Brazil, it was found that land use near
marketplaces that prioritized meat production led to more
intense land use and higher demand for forested land,
leading to greater deforestation near cities in particular. [1]
A diverse agricultural landscape in the western part of Minas
Gerais state in Brazil. Sunflowers, wheat, potatoes, coffee,
rice, soybeans, and corn are among the products of the
region. Photo: International Space Station, NASA, public
domain.
Similarly, land use intensification does appear to have a
relationship in countries where agriculture and grazing play a
prominent role in the economy.[2] Other forestry models have
also found applicability of von Thünen’s ideas in balancing
land management and determining economic benefit from
forestry, where rental income can be combined with
ecosystem service models to create more sustainable
forestry production models.[3]
While the applicability of the classic von Thünen model
appears, at times, relevant for different contexts, in general,
and particularly for highly industrial economies, modifications
of the classical model have become the norm. This includes
the use of multivariate and multi-scale approaches that also
incorporate varied topography rather than pure flat regions.
Such approaches account for varied economic use as well
as connectivity of towns with the wider regional and global
economy.[4] Heterogeneous agents affecting land use
practices and events, while hierarchical formation and
development of urban systems, have become key focus
areas today for spatial economists in helping to explain
urban and landscape dynamics.[5]
Interestingly, von Thünen’s classical land use model has
applicability to different contexts found today. While that is
the case, there are also multiple limitations to von Thünen’s
ideas that modern land use economic models attempt to
address. The longevity of the model, and the fact it is often
still used as a basis of analysis, does make it not only the
first true spatial economic model but it continues to inspire
researchers to develop methods that address its limitations.
Agriculture is a fundamental economic activity that found in virtually every corner of our planet. You
and I depend on agriculture to survive. It is also important to you because the effects of agriculture
on the human population are an essential part of the study of AP® Human Geography. In the early
eighteenth century, Johann Heinrich von Thünen designed one of the very first geographical
models. The von Thünen model was key to solving a big problem in his day—how to balance the
cost of land with the best crop to produce. This study guide will help you understand this model and
how it applies to the AP® Human Geography Exam.
Agricultural (Rural) Land Use Theory
Rural land use is not a matter of chance. Rather, it is almost always the result of logical human
decisions. Long before von Thünen came up with his model on agricultural land use, farmers all
over the world made rational land-use decisions. Von Thünen analyzed these decisions based on
the land’s physical characteristics and its position relative to market centers. His significant
contribution was that he was able to identify and explain the spatial elements that help decide how
to use the land.
In the time since von Thünen, changes in communications and transportation technologies and
progress in food preservation methods, such as refrigeration, have changed the significance of
some of his theory’s variables. However, the basic concepts of the von Thünen model are still valid.
This AP® Human Geography study guide will help you understand how his theory is used to explain
agricultural land use and the changing spatial patterns in rural areas.
Who was Von Thünen and why is He Important to AP® Human
Geography?
Access to markets has been, and still is, a huge problem for farmers all over the world. The agrarian
revolution that accompanied the industrial revolution caught the eye of a German economist-farmer
named Johann Heinrich von Thünen. He owned a large farming estate near the German city of
Rostock, and for more than 40 years, he kept precise records of his estate’s transactions.
His attention to detail turned into a passion for a subject that still is of interest to economic
geographers of today—the effects of distance and transportation costs on the location of productive
activity. Von Thünen’s model helps explain the relationship between the cost of land and the cost to
transport the crop to market. Using all the data he collected, von Thünen began to write about the
spatial structure of agriculture. He published his studies under the title The Isolated State, and his
conclusions are still being discussed and debated among geographers today.
The Von Thünen Model
Von Thünen called his model The Isolated State because for the purpose of analysis, he wanted to
establish a self-contained country. This country would be devoid of outside influences that would
disturb the inner workings of the economy.
In essence, he created a pseudo-regional laboratory, where he could identify the factors that would
affect the locational distribution of farms surrounding a central urban area. Von Thünen made some
limiting assumptions to accomplish this experiment.
First, he stated that the soil and the climate would be uniform throughout the region. Second, there
would be no river-valleys or mountains to interrupt a flat land area. Third, there would be a single,
centrally located city in the Isolated State, surrounded by an empty, unoccupied wilderness. Fourth,
von Thünen contended that the farmers would transport their own goods to market (no FedEx here),
and that they would do so by oxcart, overland, straight to the city.
Von Thünen integrated these assumptions with what he had learned while running his estate. He
then asked himself: What would be the best spatial arrangement of agricultural activities within this
Isolated State?
The von Thünen model incorporated four areas surrounding the city center. He concluded that farm
products would be grown in a series of concentric zones outward from the central market city. The
cost of transporting different farm products to the central market determined the agricultural use of
the land around the city. The most productive activities were located closest to the market on more
expensive land, and less productive activities were further away on cheaper land.
The Four Zones of the Von Thünen Model
The first and innermost belt, which was outside the central marketplace, would be a zone of
intensive agriculture and dairying. Farmers who supplied fresh milk and dairy products to the city
needed to be close to the marketplace or risk spoilage. Other crops that spoiled easily and yielded
the highest returns, such as fruits and vegetables, would also be grown nearest to the central city
because this accessible farmland was in high demand and, therefore, very expensive. Today,
regions of specialty farming, such as in South Florida and California’s Central Valley, do not always
conform to von Thünen’s concentric rings.
The second zone, he said, would be an area of forest, used for firewood and fuel. These forest
resources could be grown further out from the center city and used for fuel and building materials.
You might think that the forest zone being located so close to the city center a bit odd, but
remember, during the time that von Thünen lived, the forest was still important as a source of
building materials and fuel. That changed with the onset of the industrial revolution. Modern
applications of his model no longer have the forestry ring.
There are still, however, a great number of cities that are considered preindustrial. Take Addis
Ababa, for example. The capital city of Ethiopia still contains a broad and continuous belt of
eucalyptus forest surrounding the city, positioned just about where von Thünen predicted it to be.
The third zone is a belt of increasingly extensive field crops, such as grains for bread and tubers.
Grain could be grown, harvested and stored easily and cheaply until needed. Since grains last
longer than dairy products and are much cheaper to transport than forest resources, they could be
situated further from the city market.
Ranching and animal products occupy the fourth and outermost zone. Livestock is raised in the
outer ring where cheap pasture land is plentiful. In von Thünen’s day, livestock taken to market were
driven to the city market “on the hoof,” and did not have the luxury of refrigerated trucks to carry
processed meat.
Beyond the ranching area would be the wilderness. Eventually, since transportation costs increase
with distance, there would be a line across which it would be uneconomical to produce crops. This is
the area that the wilderness would begin. This isolated the region from the rest of the world.
Is the Von Thünen Model Still Applicable Today?
Some geographers argue that models like von Thünen’s do not apply to our world today. But it is a
great tribute to von Thünen that his work still retains the attention of many geographers. The
economic-geographic landscape has changed considerably since his time, but geographers still
compare present-day patterns of economic activity to the von Thünenian model. Over time,
geographers use and modify the traditional models to find new ways to look at rural land-use
patterns.
What are the factors that explain why agricultural land-use patterns today differ from those
developed by von Thünen’s model in 1826? The major spatial change, since von Thünen’s time, is
the change in transportation technology, which allowed the Isolated State to move from a microscale to a macro-scale. Some other factors are modern refrigeration and food preservation
methods, government policy on rural land use, global markets, and the multi-use of agricultural
products. The fact that forests no longer occupy a zone close to the marketplace is true because we
do not use wood as our main source of fuel. Today, we depend on other sources like coal and
nuclear energy.
The Von Thünen Model on the AP® Human Geography Exam
In the AP® Human Geography Course Description, the idea of the von Thünen model falls under
the category of “Agriculture, Food Production, and Rural Land Use”. On the AP® Human Geography
Exam, you could be asked to use the von Thünen model to explain rural land use and the
importance of transportation costs associated with the distance from the city market. You most likely
be asked to use the model to explain the contemporary distribution of the agricultural regions, such
as dairy and grain farming.
To help you apply this study guide to the exam, here is an FRQ from the 2007 AP® Human
Geography Exam (Question 1):
1. The drawings above reflect agricultural activities in the hinterland of a large urban area.
1.
Apply the underlying principles of von Thünen’s agricultural land-use model to predict
the locations of the activities shown in X and Y relative to a large urban area.
2.
Choose either activity X or activity Y and apply the underlying principles of von
Thünen’s agricultural land-use model to explain the location of the activity.
3.
Discuss two factors that explain why agricultural land-use patterns today differ from
those developed by von Thünen’s model in 1826.
For Part A, make sure you apply the underlying principles of von Thünen’s agricultural land-use
model to predict the locations of the activities shown in X and Y relative to a large urban area. You
must identify the location of both agricultural activities relative to the city. Activity X is a farmer
providing fresh produce, which comes from the intensive farming area. Activity Y depicts extensive
field crops, which are grown farther from the city marketplace.
For Part B, you need to choose one of the two activities and apply the underlying principles of von
Thünen’s agricultural land-use model to explain the location of the activity. Activity X is intensive
agriculture, and the land is of higher value when producing perishable goods that are accessible to
the market. This allows the farmers to maximize their profit. In activity Y, extensive agriculture is
grown on lower-value land with less accessibility to the market. Since the products are less
perishable, the farmer can maximize their profit with cheaper land. To get full credit, explain why the
concept caused this type of farming to locate at X or Y.
For Part C, you will need to discuss two factors that explain why agricultural land-use patterns today
differ from those developed by von Thünen’s model in 1826. Those factors include refrigeration and
food preservation, improved transportation, regional/global markets, and government policy.
Wrapping up the Von Thünen Model
In conclusion, the von Thünen model, explains the reasons why we use agricultural land the way we
do. His theory concluded that farm products would be grown in a series of concentric zones outward
from the central marketplace and the cost of transporting different farm products to the city center
determined the rural use of the land surrounding the city. The most productive activities will be
located closest to the market on more expensive land, and less productive activities will be located
further away on cheaper land. The role of distance in the development of the spatial pattern of the
economy remains the subject of many modern studies and geographers today. All owe von Thünen
credit for formulating the crucial questions answered in his model.