Reflections on India's Five-Year Plan Author(s): C. N. Vakil and P. R. Brahmananda Source: Pacific Affairs , Sep., 1952, Vol. 25, No. 3 (Sep., 1952), pp. 248-262 Published by: Pacific Affairs, University of British Columbia Stable URL: https://www.jstor.org/stable/2752802 JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org. Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of the Terms & Conditions of Use, available at https://about.jstor.org/terms Pacific Affairs, University of British Columbia is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Pacific Affairs This content downloaded from 210.212.249.227 on Wed, 03 Feb 2021 06:44:39 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Reflections on India's Five-Year Plan C. N. Vakil and P. R. Brahimananda DURING the period of almost one year since its publication, the Draft Outline of the Five-Year Plan for the economic develop- ment of India has been the subject of discussion in the central and state legislatures, state governments, industrial and labour associations, chambers of commerce, committees of political parties, economists, engineers and other sections of the Indian community, many of which have communicated their views to the Planning Commission, its author, in response to a request for criticism and suggestions. Although it is too early to anticipate the exact form of the final Plan, it should be useful to consider some of the suggestions that have been offered, since the Commission intends to take due note of these in preparing the final Plan. The object of the present article, then, is to examine certain of the major criticisms that have been made and to indicate the nature of the conflicts and difficulties that confront the planners under existing circumstances.' At the outset it must be stressed that the Planning Commission had to work under extremely difficult conditions. The country was experiencing strong inflationary pressures, and both the central and the state governments had already embarked upon numerous projects of various kinds on the assumption that ample financial resources therefor would be available. There was no clear or consistent policy governing price control, foreign trade, allocations of resources, or other crucial matters. The activities of the different parts of the public, or government-managed, sector of the economy had not been systematised, nor had there been much effort to coordinate them with those of the private sector. The government's attitude towards the private sector vacillated, and its views regarding nationalisation underwent periodic revision. Projects contemplated both by the public and by the private sectors appeared to exceed greatly the capacity of the country to produce or to acquire the necessary construction and other materials. There was no clear-cut scheme of priorities, and the different state 1 For a discussion of the background and aims of the Plan, see V. K. R. V. Rao, "India's First Five-Year Plan-A Descriptive Analysis", Pacific Affairs, March I952. 248 This content downloaded from 210.212.249.227 on Wed, 03 Feb 2021 06:44:39 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Reflections on India's Five-Year Plan governments were pursuing conflicting objectives. The full implications of the acceptance of social welfare commitments and of the pursuit of ethical policies were not yet quite understood; and scarce resources, which were more urgently required for building up capital equipment, were being used for various welfare measures. The limitations of the economic system and the significance of the inelasticity of production in industry as well as in agriculture had not been perceived; and at different stages the government was tightening and relaxing controls. In fine, there was no systematic effort to view each problem in a national perspective, to emphasise the national point of view as against the views of separate sections, or to concentrate on the formulation of measures which would ease the problems of the country on a long-term basis. One of the most significant achievements of the Planning Commission has been its attempt to appraise the financial resources that will be available during the period of the Plan (1951-52 to 1955-56) and to shape various projects according to their availability. At the end of i950 it was calculated that the total cost of central and state schemes then under way would amount to thirty-five billion rupees, and it was hoped that these schemes would be completed within six years. The Planning Commission concluded, however, that no more than II.2 billion rupees can be raised during the period with which it is con- cerned. Its main task, therefore, was one of pruning-not an enviable task, inasmuch as it had to engage in protracted bargaining with each department of the Centre and with each state government in order to persuade them to curtail their projects. As the central and the state governments were already committed to a number of development schemes, the Commission was left very little opportunity to effect a new pattern of distribution of resources. If it had introduced new projects of its own, these could have been undertaken only at the cost of others on which expenditures had already been made. In its pruning, the Commission held that, since food deficiencies represented the most pressing problem, the bulk of the available resources should be devoted to the construction of irrigation and multi-purpose development projects. It also took the view that the objective of the Plan should be the establishment of an appropriate economic base which, after the first five-year period, would permit an acceleration of development. For this purpose, a sizable proportion of available resources would have to be devoted to the development of public utility services. Moreover, 249 This content downloaded from 210.212.249.227 on Wed, 03 Feb 2021 06:44:39 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Pacific Affairs the railways, which had been subjected to constant wear and tear since the beginning of the last war, would require rehabilitation, as would the transport system in general. In view of these demands on the country's limited resources, not much would remain for industrial development, which the Commission consequently left mostly to private initiative, although suggesting certain controls for the purpose of coordinating the activities of the public and private sectors of the economy. The perspective governing the Planning Commission's recommendations for implementation of the Plan was similar to that adopted in determining the allocation of resources. Finding that discrepancies in the controls governing competitive crops, and the prevalence of high prices for commercial crops, had led to a large-scale diversion of acreage from food to commercial crops,2 the Commission recommended that the prices of the latter also should be controlled and that price incentives should be consistent with the over-all priorities established by the Plan, since, if food production was to have first priority, farmers should not be offered maximum incentives to grow commercial crops. To convert the basis of Indian agriculture from subsistence to mixed farming and thus to increase its efficiency, the Commission suggested various organisational measures, chief among these being the constitution of joint village management boards which would treat each village as a single unit of management and pool and allocate its resources. The Commission recognised that the food problem in India is caused by the growing disequilibrium between population and supply, and that it can be met only by relatively long-term correctives; meanwhile, as minimum interim measures, it proposed monopoly procurement of foodgrains and urban rationing in all states. In the matter of taxation, the Commission accepted the view that any increase in direct tax rates would harm the capital market, and suggested a voluntary moratorium on the payment of dividends for a limited period in order to encourage reinvestment of profits in industry. Holding that the development of small-scale and cottage industries should proceed on lines complementary to those of large-scale industries, it suggested the levy of a cess on the latter in order to assist small-scale industries and the apportionment of raw materials as well as markets between the two groups. In regard to family planning, it 2 Competitive crops in different parts of the country include cotton and jowar, sugar cane and paddy, jute and paddy, and oilseeds and millet. 250 This content downloaded from 210.212.249.227 on Wed, 03 Feb 2021 06:44:39 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Reflections on India's Five-Year Plan merely recommended that the government should supply facilities for sterilisation and for the provision of contraceptive advice on economic as well as physical grounds. The Commission had to choose between competing objectives and to withstand conflicting pressures. Given the limited supply of resources, it had to make a choice between agriculture or industry and between reserving maximum support for the public sector or allowing relatively more leeway for private capital formation. It had also to decide between measures designed to achieve greater immediate equality of incomes at a lower level of aggregate production, and others calculated to increase total production and thus to provide an opportunity later for an absolute increment in the income of each citizen; it took the position that radical redistribution measures would reduce the volume of savings and thus the rate of capital formation. The Commission had also to decide whether to give first priority to the needs of small-scale industries or to those of large-scale ones; in view of the widespread public support for them, it was obliged to suggest some measures for re-allocating resources to small-scale industries, even at the Cost of efficiency. Concerning the extension of government activities in industry, the Commission had to choose between broadening the scope of nationalisation or concentrating the limited resources of the public sector on the expansion of its productive capacity; it preferred the latter course. In the interest of raising agricultural efficiency, it had to decide whether to recommend collectivisation or redistribution of land to small peasants; it proposed joint village management boards as a compromise, for these are to increase the size of the management unit while permitting peasant landownership. In respect of labour, it proposed that wage increases be avoided, but sug- gested only a voluntary moratorium on dividend payments. In short, the Commission, whose aim was to formulate a programme which would attract the widest possible support among the national community as a whole and at the same time operate within the institu- tional framework formulated in the new Constitution, evolved a Plan that avoids extreme courses of action. IT is not surprising that such a Plan should have met with a mixed reception. A plan which seeks to follow a middle way in economic policy and in the allocation of resources is unlikely to satisfy the expectations or demands of extreme elements in the community. Thus, 251 This content downloaded from 210.212.249.227 on Wed, 03 Feb 2021 06:44:39 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Pacific Afairs while some sections hold that the Five-Year Plan has gone too far, others insist that it has taken no commendable steps forward; it is termed realistic by some and impractical by others. Very few have realised that, since the Plan had to be compatible with the over-all objectives of national policy described in the Constitution and clari- fied by government statements, the scope of the Commission's efforts and the extent to which fundamental structural changes could have been suggested were restricted. As the Commission itself has remarked, the Plan could not be the medium for radical institutional changes which might lead to wide differences of opinion among different sections of the community. It had, therefore, to adjust the tempo of sug- gested change to the climate of social opinion as expressed in the new Constitution and elaborated by spokesmen of the political party in power. It is clear, then, that the Commission wished to avoid supporting the extreme courses advocated on the one hand by proponents of unrestricted private enterprise and on the other by exponents of unlimited government intervention and control. It is hardly astonishing that private business and industrial circles have received the Plan with some satisfaction. The Commission's clear statement that during the next five years the government should not expand the scope of its industrial activities afforded a welcome sense of security to private interests desirous of expansion. At the same time, industrial circles were disappointed that the Plan held out no hope for a reduction in direct tax rates; they argued that it left development of the entire industrial field to the private sector without, however, meeting the latter's need for development funds. In pressing for tax relief, the industrial community tended to exaggerate the soundness of the financial position of the central government. On the other hand, the revenue surpluses envisaged in the Plan depend in large measure upon the continuance of large export-duty collections, which in turn depend upon the maintenance of foreign demand for several export commodities required abroad for defense stock-piling purposes. Impartial observers have reminded the Commission that this source of revenue is contingent on foreign stock-piling programmes and hence is impermanent. At present, in fact, the I952-53 budget indicates sharply reduced collections, with the result that, instead of a surplus of 260 million rupees in the Central Budget as anticipated in the Five-Year Plan, barely forty million are available from 252 This content downloaded from 210.212.249.227 on Wed, 03 Feb 2021 06:44:39 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Reflections on India's Five-Year Plan revenue sources for capital projects. Under these circumstances, assuming that the projects in the public sector must be completed and that the objectives of the Five-Year Plan should be achieved, there is little room for relief of direct taxation. Moreover, the government has argued that private funds released as a result of any such relief would not necessarily be invested constructively but might be used instead for speculation or consumption. A reduction in direct taxation might, therefore, excite dissatisfaction among the poorer sections of the country and thus dampen the general enthusiasm for the Plan as a whole. The. industrial community has expressed the belief that the restrictions contained in the Industries Act, which authorises the government to determine the location as well as the minimum size of any new manufacturing unit, will tend to discourage private investment. It has, however, welcomed the Planning Commission's suggestion that development councils be established in various industries. It has disagreed with the emphasis placed by the Commission on the need for development of small-scale industries, which it regards as relatively inefficient, and has shown some disappointment over the Commission's failure to recommend removal of price controls. The Commission's exhortations to private enterprise to realise its responsibility and to take voluntary measures to increase its productive efficiency have in general not been relished by the business community, which has responded by pointing to the need for equal stress on efficiency in government enterprises. The importance given to agriculture as against industry has also been criticised, on the score that there can be no permanent basis for economic development without appropriate industrial expansion. Exception has been taken particularly to the Commission's lack of emphasis on the establishment of capital goods industries and on the expansion of industries producing steel and pig iron, which are in acutely short supply. It cannot be denied that some of these criticisms possess merit. The extension of government control over the location as well as over the size of manufacturing units is inappropriate in a time of lagging industrial development. It is one thing to emphasise the need for redis- tribution of industries and another to impose restrictions on their location, unless the government is prepared to offer counter-balancing advantages in the areas of its choice. Arbitrary emphasis upon decentralisation may inhibit expansion, since if new industrial units must be located in a region which does not offer advantages available elsewhere, 253 This content downloaded from 210.212.249.227 on Wed, 03 Feb 2021 06:44:39 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Pacific Aflairs the probability is that they will not be established at all. The government must chocse between a policy which seeks to maximise the rate of development for a given period before concerning itself with the factor of location and one which emphasises immediate decentralisa- tion at the possible expense of over-all economic development.3 The regions selected for development in the Five-Year Plan undoubtedly have potential resources and will develop in time; but since the impor- tant factor is the relative ability of a region to contribute to output within a given period, it appears necessary to strike a balance between the objective of decentralisation on the one hand and that of development on the other, so that in the endeavour to increase production in some regions more output is not sacrificed elsewhere. The pace of economic development depends upon the creation of a production surplus, and any measure which delays the achievement of this goal may prove to be disadvantageous when viewed in an over-all perspective. In recent years increasing responsibilities for labour welfare have been imposed upon private industries, which have resisted this trend on the ground that it has a depressant effect upon the rate of reinvestment of profits. In considering this problem, one must realise that a backward economy undergoing rapid industrialisation faces different conditions than do advanced countries. In the United Kingdom, for example, the emphasis on labour welfare and social security measures came more or less at the close of the Industrial Revolution. In a coun- try such as India, on the other hand, unless the government provides for transfers of resources from capital to labour for welfare purposes, it is likely to lose the political support of a large section of the population. The present climate of social opinion differs from that of i50 years ago. Unless private business realises that welfare measures are 3 The pursuit of decentralisation as an objective in itself can produce startling results. For example, the Five-Year Plan contemplates an expansion in electric-power output of about one million kilowatts, mainly in the less developed regions of the country and without adequate consideration for the needs of developed and rapidly expanding manufacturing complexes such as that in the Bombay-Poona region, which contributes seventeen per cent of India's total industrial production and about one-third of its direct tax revenues. Inadequacy of local power supplies had necessitated the rejection of applications for an estimated ioo,ooo kw. of power in the region by the end of 1951. Owing to insufficient rainfall in the catchment area of the hydroelectric system, an acute power shortage has prevailed in the entire region since October 195i, and a twenty-three per cent cut in industrial consumption had to be imposed for a nine-month period. It has been estimated that the resulting hypothetical loss in terms of value of output exceeds Rs.6oo million. 254 This content downloaded from 210.212.249.227 on Wed, 03 Feb 2021 06:44:39 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Reflections on India's Five-Year Plan essential to the maintenance of a democratic system in the country, a "mixed" economy will be able to function only with difficulty. The case for private enterprise in undeveloped countries rests upon its willingness to accept a large share of social responsibilities. Labour welfare measures are a condition of public support for private enterprise. The transition would be smoother if enlightened sections of the Indian business community understood more fully the implications of acceptance of a mixed economy in a backward country. ANOTHER corollary of a mixed economy is the system of controls by which the government allocates the available resources to various fields of activity in such a manner that its scheme of social priorities is fulfilled. In a country suffering from inflationary pressures and desirous of undertaking a large-scale development programme, controls -particularly those governing prices-have a significant function. The Planning Commission has advocated the continuance of certain price controls. Sections of the business community, however, believe that a relaxation of controls would serve to increase industrial production. It is difficult to find much substance in their argument. For example, when the government experimented with partial control of the sugar industry, manufacturers had to sell a certain percentage of their output to the government at a fixed price; the remainder could be sold in the free market. A noticeable increase in sugar production resulted, but at the cost of reduced acreage in foodgrains In the same way, the increased foreign demand for oilseeds led to a reduction in the acreage devoted to cereals. Unless much land is reclaimed for cultivation, or unless new irrigation works permit an increase in the cultivated area and in the yield from existing acreage, the prospect for improved agricultural output seems to be limited in the short run, which is to say that an increase in prices of agricultural commodities would not lead to a rise in aggregate output. Higher production depends upon large-scale capital investments of a type far beyond the reach of the ordinary farmer. In the case of industry also, the extension of specific price incentives to a particular group might create difficulties by encouraging the manufacture of one product at the expense of another. In an undeveloped economy which suffers from shortages both of monetary and of real capital and from an inadequacy of complementary resources 255 This content downloaded from 210.212.249.227 on Wed, 03 Feb 2021 06:44:39 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Pacific Affairs (such as technical skill and new land), the effectiveness of price incentives is definitely limited. Since several industries in India depend upon imported raw materials, an increase in the price of manufactures will not necessarily bring about an improvement in the supply of raw materials, unless foreign-exchange earnings improve. A greater price incentive will not necessarily set in motion the various processes that must precede an expansion of any particular industry. Capital must be raised, equipment must be imported, technicians and skilled labour must be found, and the industry must acquire the requisite raw materials. Unless these complementary processes are coordinated, the price stimuli will not induce an increase in the aggregate productive capacity of the system, so that more of one product can be manufactured without causing a diminution in the manufacture of another. By itself the price incentive appears too weak to achieve the desired responses in an undeveloped country and, if pressed too far, may aggravate inflationary pressures, since an increase in the price incentive offered one sector will raise costs in others. While employment of price incentives may induce greater manu- facturing efficiency in economically advanced countries, it does not necessarily have a like effect in undeveloped countries, such as India, which suffer from serious shortages in capital equipment and technical personnel. An increase in manufacturing efficiency is contingent upon an improvement of existing processes; if the new method involves less labour than the old, problems of displacement will result. In a rapidly developing community in which industries expand at such a pace that they can absorb labour displaced elsewhere, the problem may not be acute, but in India mechanisation will intensify the frictions of the transitional period. Any increase in agricultural production by means of mechanisation will bring about displacement of labour which cannot be absorbed under existing conditions. As long as the aggregate supply of most commodities falls woefully short of total demand, and as long as the possibilities of a speedy expansion in their over-all production are sharply restricted, the nation must depend upon price controls to allocate resources in accordance with the pattern of social priorities established by the government. The complaints of private business on this score are justified insofar as the controls have operated unsatisfactorily because of administrative defects and a lack of integration among the various controls. An improvement in administrative efficiency would go far to abate prejudice 256 This content downloaded from 210.212.249.227 on Wed, 03 Feb 2021 06:44:39 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Reflections on India's Five-Year Plan against controls, which are necessary for the smooth operation of the economy. THE priority given by the Planning Commission to agriculture as against industry has aroused considerable dissatisfaction. This decision was governed in part by the urgent need to solve the food problem through an increase in the agricultural potential. But in reserving the lion's share of resources for agriculture, the Commission ignored the necessity for expanding industrial capacity in order to ensure a supply of the construction materials required for irrigation projects, among other things. It is reasonable to ask whether the country's long-term problems will be solved by the pattern of allocation recommended by the Commission. Population pressure is compelling the diversion of ever larger resources to agriculture in order to feed the people-a problem whose solution can be anticipated only if more irrigation projects and fertiliser plants are built and vast areas are reclaimed-activities requiring capital-intensive investment. The problem of agricultural production in India is not merely one of organisation. More tractors and greater mechanisation will not effect significant increases in output. Apart from geographic factors and the suitability of different kinds of land for the use of machinery, mechanisation will not lessen the dependence upon rainfall. The capacity of any community to divert resources to the construction of permanent capital equipment such as irrigation systems depends upon the supply of construction materials, which depends in turn upon the productive capacity of the industries that manufacture them. Although India possesses large deposits of iron and other important mineral ores as well as considerable unused land, these potential resources can be exploited only with the aid of large-scale capital equipment applied over a long period. If the Planning Commission had made provision for a substantial expansion of construction-materials industries as well as of some capital goods industries, it would have set the scene for speedier development of potential resources at a later date. Had industrial rather than agricultural development received priority, the method of capital formation involved would have been more roundabout than that in fact proposed, but it would probably have yielded better results in the long run. Another aspect of the rivalry between agriculture and industry concerns the likely response of farmers to economic stimuli, upon 257 This content downloaded from 210.212.249.227 on Wed, 03 Feb 2021 06:44:39 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Pacific Afairs which the success of several of the measures proposed by the Planning Commission will depend. As the vicissitudes of the grow-morefood campaign recently demonstrated,4 the average farmer's response to various forms of assistance is extremely limited and is likely to remain so until he has acquired greater education and understanding and has been freed from dependence on the vagaries of rainfallprocesses which will require considerable time. On the other hand, the employment of stimuli on the same scale in the industrial field will attain better results more quickly. If the country could wait indefinitely, it could go on investing in agriculture, even though the response was limited. In fact, however, unless the problem of poverty is solved soon, social upheavals may rend the entire fabric of the existing system. It is in this sense that an expansion of the industrial potential, which would indirectly benefit agriculture, may be regarded as possibly more advantageous than concentration on agriculture alone. Since, then, the agricultural problem must be attacked through measures undertaken in the industrial field, there is ground for complaint that the Commission should have earmarked greater resources for industrial development.5 THE Five-Year Plan has been subjected to severe criticism also be- cause of its modest objectives. It seeks to restore prewar living standards, and envisages a gross rate of investment of barely four per cent of the national income. Several sections of the community have been extremely disappointed by the modesty of these goals; for public response to a development plan depends upon what it promises, and this one offers only meagre rewards. Yet the modesty of the planners was due not to a deficiency of imagination but rather to the existence of certain limitations, over many of which they lack control. The extent to which the rate of investment can be raised does not necessarily depend upon the size of the aggregate national income. The factors determining a country's investment potentialities include the distribution of income, the capacity for saving, the public response to an austerity programme, the period to which such a programme can 4 See, for example, K. G. Sivaswamy, "Indian Agriculture-Problems and Programmes", Pacific Abairs, December I950. 5 It is to be hoped that in Part Two of the Five-Year Plan, whose execution will hinge upon foreign assistance, the Commission will provide more adequately for industrial development. 258 This content downloaded from 210.212.249.227 on Wed, 03 Feb 2021 06:44:39 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Reflections on India's Five-Year Plan be prolonged, the rate of population growth, the capacity to secure resources necessary for the execution of investment programmes, and so forth. To take the most important factor, it is clear that as long as sup- plies of capital equipment, easily cultivable new land, skilled labour, basic raw materials, etc. are limited as at present, and as long as increases in the rate of supply of these resources also are restricted, the mere investment of more money will not produce greater real investment. In an economy with a limited capacity to produce materials as well as to procure equipment and technical personnel, an increase in the rate of investment beyond a certain point must be counterbalanced by a decrease in the amount of resources available for consumption. That is to say, in India consumption and investment generally compete for the limited resources available. Since the supply of resources is limited, the effect of merely increasing the rate of mone tary outlay in the construction of various projects will be to inflate prices, and in consequence some projects will have to be slowed or left uncompleted, if they are not entirely abandoned. It would definitely not be to the interest of the country to embark upon enterprises for whose completion adequate resources are not assured. Rather, prudence dictates that it undertake only whatever volume and pattern of investment can be sustained with the aid of resources that are likely to become available. One of the serious technical limitations of the Five-Year Plan is its concentration in the main on the monetary and financial aspects of the resources necessary for its execution, without any accompanying systematic effort to calculate in detail the requirements of the various projects in terms of physical resources. While the financial aspects of a plan may be consistent, its "real" aspects may reveal glaring weaknesses. Unless the various types of supplies required for its different projects are available in the right quantities at the right time, its schedule cannot be maintained and several of its targets will be only partially attained. In view of the restricted supplies of such basic materials as lumber, pig iron and steel and the difficult foreignexchange position, it is questionable whether even the modest rate of expansion envisaged in the Plan will be achieved without appreciable foreign aid. Under these conditions, an increase in the rate of investment will depend largely upon the extent to which resources can be diverted 259 This content downloaded from 210.212.249.227 on Wed, 03 Feb 2021 06:44:39 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Pacific Afairs from consumption to investment. As is well known, the low Indian standard of living places serious limitations upon savings. An austerity programme which demanded greater sacrifices on the part of highincome groups might, however, evoke more enthusiastic popular response. In the development process, the total response of the nation to the Plan will depend upon the extent to which sacrifices are made by all sections of the Indian community, in which marked inequalities in wealth and income exist. If the government should impose a general austerity programme involving greater sacrifices by the relatively well-to-do, the resulting public response would probably serve to accelerate the pace of economic mobilisation. There has been a tendency in economic theory to emphasise the consequences of inequalities in income and wealth. From the standpoint of social tension, what matters is the extent of inequality in the enjoyment of income. Conspicuous consumption in undeveloped countries, where the majority lives in bare poverty, is doubly undesirable: not only does it utilise resources that would otherwise be available for investment, but it also diminishes popular support for any national plan calling for austerity. In this sense, the Planning Commission seems to have overlooked the significance of the need for an austerity programme in order to increase resources available for capital formation as well as public enthusiasm for its Plan. It would be difficult to estimate to what extent the pace of economic development could be accelerated by increasing the austerity required of the people, but one result would be certain: the forces clamouring for radical social and economic reforms would be weakened thereby. Moreover, if the wealthier groups were prepared to forgo the consumption of luxury articles and to place national interests above personal interests, the atmosphere in the country would be very different from what it is today. Particularly in undeveloped countries, the degree of individual response to economic inducements is not necessarily dependent wholly upon the size of the monetary incentives offered. The response of labour, for example, to calls for increased production is affected by the behavior of other sections of the community. If the government wishes to see a new spirit animate the country, it will need to enforce uniform treatment far more strictly than has hitherto been the case. There is no social justification for permitting different rations for different parts of the country, nor is it equitable to seek a voluntary moratorium on dividends on the part of capital while imposing a compulsory wage260 This content downloaded from 210.212.249.227 on Wed, 03 Feb 2021 06:44:39 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Reflections on India's Five-Year Plan freeze on labour. It is unjustifiable, in the existing social and political climate, to perpetuate great inequalities in landownership merely because the government is not in a position to pay compensation immediately to the dispossessed owners. Recent reverses suffered by the Congress Party in some regions have indicated that land reform is popularly regarded as overdue. Compensation should be paid, but possibly on a sliding scale inasmuch as payment in full in all cases might serve to perpetuate existing inequalities of income and might also delay reform. What is at issue is not merely a conflict between landlord and peasant or between the landlord and his state government, but a wideranging problem which deeply affects the economic, social and political future of the country as a whole. Since, unless the pace of land reform is hastened, the consequences may be catastrophic, any sound programme for economic development should contain provision for some degree of land redistribution if a social revolution is to be averted. THE conclusion that emerges from a study of the Indian economic situation is that the problem of poverty must be attacked on several fronts and over a lengthy period. Because of the large size and rapid growth of the population and the seriously limited resources available for capital expansion, the pace of economic change can be only gradual. The Five-Year Plan is the first official planning effort in India to have considered the significance of the limitations imposed by the realities of the economic situation. Its authors have not yielded to the temptation to make wild promises of plenty and prosperity in the near future, but instead have shown that the road ahead is long and arduous. Any sudden rash of large-scale organisational changes at the present juncture would not necessarily transform the productive capacities of the economy or free the country from the need for hard work. The economic position of India today is somewhat different from that which prevailed in countries similarly situated a few years ago. For example, the Indian food problem is caused by the widening gap between productive capacity and demand. In the last fifty years India has changed from an exporter of food and raw materials to a largescale importer of both. The partition of the subcontinent increased the dependence on foreign raw materials of the two large manufacturing industries of India, jute and cotton, and aggravated the disequilibrium existing between the country's population and food supply. The food problem is not merely one of inadequate distribution, which might be 26i This content downloaded from 210.212.249.227 on Wed, 03 Feb 2021 06:44:39 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms Pacific Affairs overcome by government control of marketable surpluses, but rather one of insufficient production, which can be remedied only by largescale investment. In a country such as the Soviet Union of a few years ago, the problem was more one of effecting certain improvements in organisation so that ampler supplies could be made available to the non-agrarian population or for export. In India the scope for increasing total production and the resources available for capital investment by means of sweeping organisational changes appears to be limited. The population problem can hardly be solved in a few years unless many people are permitted to starve. The growth in population is creating not merely food-supply difficulties but severe balance-of-payments difficulties as well. Without foreign assistance and the sterling balances, food imports would consume more than one-fourth of normal foreign-exchange earnings-and their requirements are increasing. Full comprehension of these difficulties impelled the Planning Commission to be realistic in the selection of its goals and the formulation of its recommendations. It adopted a democratic approach to the problems involved and agreed to modify its draft plan in response to expressed public sentiment. Though possibly somewhat roundabout, this approach should yield more enduring results than one involving extensive coercion, which, under existing circumstances, could hardly effect a rapid or significant improvement in the lot of the masses. It was only through pioneering enterprise and hard work that the stand- ard of living was raised in the West, and it is a truism, however un- palatable it may be to the wishful thinker, that no country has become prosperous overnight. The difficulties of the transitional period in India will be so much the less if conflicting interests within the nation are reconciled, if a livelier spirit of voluntary sacrifice appears among the different groups, and if foreign capital is forthcoming in large amounts and in the desired fields. Yet the magnitude of the problem of poverty is such that, at best, foreign capital, even if it should be made available in increasing quantity, can only lighten the burden somewhat. Most of the effort and resources must come from within the country. The margin of difference represented by an inflow of foreign capital might, however, alter the entire picture by affording the necessary impetus to local efforts. Bombay, Jane 1952 262 This content downloaded from 210.212.249.227 on Wed, 03 Feb 2021 06:44:39 UTC All use subject to https://about.jstor.org/terms