Revenue reforms of Alauddin Khalji The Delhi Sultanate ruler Alauddin Khalji (r. 1296-1316) implemented a series of major fiscal, land and agrarian reforms in northern India. He re-designated large areas of land as crown territory by confiscating private properties and by annulling land grants. He imposed a 50% kharaj tax on the agricultural produce, and ordered his ministry to collect the revenue directly from the peasants by eliminating the intermediary village chiefs. Market reforms of Alauddin Khalji In the early 14th century, the Delhi Sultanate ruler Alauddin Khalji (r. 1296-1316) instituted price controls and related reforms in his empire. Alauddin's courtier Amir Khusrau states that Alauddin's objective was the welfare of the general public. However, Ziauddin Barani (c. 1357) states that the Sultan's objective was to subjugate the Hindus and to maintain an unprecedentedly large army (the low prices would make low salaries acceptable for the soldiers). Alauddin fixed the prices for a wide range of goods, including grains, cloth, slaves and animals. He banned hoarding and regrating, appointed supervisors and spies to ensure compliance with the regulations, and severely punished the violators. The reforms were implemented in the capital Delhi, and possibly, other areas of the Sultanate. They were revoked shortly after Alauddin's death, by his son Qutbuddin Mubarak Shah. Contents o o o o o o o o o o o o o o 1Background 2Objective 3Establishment of markets 4Mandi (grain market) 4.1Price controls 4.2Appointment of market controller 4.3Government-run granaries 4.4Anti-hoarding measures 4.5Ban on regrating 4.6Ban on taking surplus grain home 4.7Daily reports 4.8Rationing during drought 5Sera-i Adl 5.1Establishment 5.2Price fixing 5.3Registration of merchants 5.4Prevention of regrating 5.5Permit for buying expensive fabrics 6Slave and animal market 6.1Price-fixing o o o o 6.2Elimination of merchants 6.3Supervision of brokers 6.4Investigations 7General markets 8Extent of implementation 9Impact 10Revocation 11Notes 12References 12.1Bibliography 13External links Background[edit] The main source of information about Alauddin's reforms is Ziauddin Barani, a Delhi Sultanate chronicler who wrote around half-a-century after Alauddin's death.[1] Barani provides a numbered list of Alauddin's regulations, but his account does not contain the verbatim text of the royal orders. Barani's has reproduced the regulations from his memory, organizing them in a logical sequence.[2] Barani's account, at least his narration of Alauddin's price control measures, is corroborated by other writers who mention the reforms with lesser detail. [1] Alauddin's courtier Amir Khusrau mentions the price control measures, attributing these to Alauddin's desire for public welfare.[3] The 16th century chronicler Firishta also describes the reforms, and besides Barani, his account seems to be based on Shaikh Ainuddin Bijapuri's now-lost Mulhiqat-i Tabaqat-i Nasiri. While Bijapuri was not a contemporary of Alauddin, he may have had access to other lost works that described these reforms. [4] Objective[edit] Alauddin's courtier Amir Khusrau, in his Khazainul Futuh (1311), states that Alauddin reduced and fixed prices because of his "great regard for general prosperity and abundance, and for the happiness and comfort of the select as well as the commons."[3] A later anecdote also states that Alauddin implemented his price control measures for the welfare of the citizens. This anecdote was mentioned by the 14th century writer Hamid Qalandar, and is originally said to have been narrated by Malikut Tujjar ("Prince of Merchants") Qazi Hamiduddin to the Sufi saint Nasiruddin Chiragh Dehlavi, during the early reign of Firuz Shah Tughlaq (r. 1351-1388). Hamiduddin told Nasiruddin that he once entered Alauddin's chamber, and found him engaged in deep thought. Alauddin told Hamiduddin that he wanted to do something for the benefit of the common people, because the God had made him the leader of these people. Alauddin stated that he considered giving away all his treasures and property, but then realized that the benefits of such a distribution would not reach all the people. He then got the idea of lowering and fixing the price of grains, which would benefit all the people.[5] Contrary to these accounts, Barani states that Alauddin (who was a Muslim) introduced these reforms to be able to maintain an unprecedentedly large army, and to subjugate his Hindu subjects.[1] According to Barani, the 1303 Mongol invasion of Delhi prompted Alauddin to raise a large army to deal with the Mongol threat. However, such a large army would be a drain on the state treasury, unless the soldiers' salaries could be lowered substantially. Alauddin was the first Sultan of Delhi to pay all his soldiers in cash.[6] He determined that the maximum salary he could pay to a well-equipped cavalryman as 234 tankas,[a] with an additional 78 tankas for a cavalryman with two horses.[7] It appears that the cavalryman was expected to maintain his own horse and equipment from this salary.[6] An increase in this salary would exhaust the treasury in 5– 6 years. Alauddin's ministers told him that such low salaries would be acceptable to the soldiers, if the prices of necessary commodities were reduced.[7] Alauddin then asked his counsellors for ways to reduce the prices without resorting to tyranny, and on their advice, decided to regulate the market prices.[8] Barani also states that the Hindu traders indulged in profiteering, and Alauddin wanted to punish the Hindus. However, much of Delhi's overland trade with Western and Central Asia was controlled by Khorasani and Multani merchants, many of whom were Muslims, and were impacted by Alauddin's reforms. Moreover, the cheap prices resulting from Alauddin's price control measures benefited the general public, which included the Hindus.[9] Establishment of markets[edit] Alauddin implemented price control measures by setting up following types of markets in Delhi:[10] 1. 2. 3. 4. Mandi, the central grain market, plus grocery shops in every neighbourhood Sera-i Adl, the central market for manufactured commodities and imported goods Markets for slaves and animals General markets for other commodities Mandi (grain market)[edit] Price controls[edit] Alauddin's administration fixed the price of grains in Delhi as follows:[11] hideGrain Price (in jitals[a]) per mann[b] Wheat 7.5 Barley 4 Rice 5 hideGrain Price (in jitals[a]) per mann[b] Pulses and gram 5 Moth 3 The prices were lower in smaller towns.[13] The Delhi Sultanate chronicles do not elaborate how these numbers were arrived at, but both Khusrau and Barani state that the prices were not allowed to increase during Alauddin's lifetime, even when the rainfall was scarce.[11] Appointment of market controller[edit] Alauddin appointed Malik Qabul Ulugh Khani as controller of the grain markets, and a friend of Malik Qabul as an assistant controller. The Sultan granted Malik Qabul extensive territories as iqta', and placed a large cavalry and infantry under his charge.[14] Alauddin also appointed one of his own close associates as an intelligence officer of the grain market.[2] The controller strictly regulated the market prices, and informed Alauddin of any violations. The government strictly punished the shopkeepers who tried to sell goods above the regulated price, and those who tried to cheat by using false weights.[15] The traders considered Alauddin's regulations as burdensome, and frequently violated them; the drastic punishments led to further resentment among the traders.[16] Government-run granaries[edit] Alauddin's administration set up granaries, and stocked them with grain collected from the peasants.[15] According to Barani, the government's share of the grain in the crown territory (khalisa) in the Doab region was collected in kind, and taken to the governmentrun granaries in Delhi. In the Jhain region, half of the government's share was collected in kind and taken to the Jhain town; when needed, the stores were transferred to the government-run granaries in Delhi.[2] Firishta mentions that the government's share was collected and stored in various towns, not just Delhi.[13] The stores in the government-run granaries were released and sold at fixed price during the times of scarcity.[15] See also: Revenue reforms of Alauddin Khalji § Direct revenue collection Anti-hoarding measures[edit] Alauddin's administration mandated registration for the transporters who bought the farming produce from the peasants and carried it to the towns.[15] The government banned hoarding, and held the transporters, their agents and their families collectively responsible for any violations.[15] Alauddin placed the transporters under the controller of the grain market. His administration arrested the former leaders of the transporters, and handed them over to the controller, Malik Qabul. Alauddin asked Malik Qabul to keep them in chains until they collectively agreed to abide by certain conditions imposed on them, and gave sureties for each other. These conditions required the transporters to adhere to Alauddin's regulations.[2] The transporters were also ordered to settle in the villages at specific distances along the Yamuna River, so as to ensure rapid transport of grains to Delhi.[17] They were required to bring their families, cattle and goods to their new residences. A supervisor was appointed to oversee their operations. [2] According to Barani, because of these changes, the transporters brought so much grain to Delhi that no releases were required from the government-run granaries.[2] Ban on regrating[edit] Alauddin banned regrating, the practice of buying goods at a lower price and selling them at a higher price. All the government officials in the Ganga-Yamuna Doab region were required to guarantee that they would not permit any regrating in their area of authority. If any regrating was discovered in a particular territory, the officials in-charge were answerable to the throne. The regrated grain was confiscated by the government, and the violator was severely punished.[2] According to Barani, such regulations made it impossible for a merchant, a peasant, a grocer or anyone else to sell even minute quantities of grains above the regulated price.[2] Ban on taking surplus grain home[edit] Alauddin's administration allowed the cultivators to take limited quantity of grain from fields to their homes for personal consumption.[13] Alauddin required his revenue officers to sign written agreements promising that they would take severe measures to ensure that the cultivators in the Doab region were unable to take the surplus grain to their houses for regrating. This would force the cultivators to sell the grain to the transporters at low prices.[18] Barani states that the cultivators were also given the option of taking the surplus grain to the market themselves, and selling it there for a profit, at the prices fixed by Alauddin. Firishta clarifies that the cultivators could sell the grain at the markets in the nearest town: they were not required to visit the central market in Delhi.[18] Daily reports[edit] Alauddin sought daily reports about the grain market from three independent sources:[19] 1. The market superintendent 2. The intelligence officers 3. The secret spies The 16th century chronicler Firishta states that although Alauddin was illiterate at the beginning of his reign, he gradually acquired the ability to read these reports, which included hastily-scribbled notes written in Persian script.[18] Any variance in the reports from the three sources resulted in punishment for the market superintendent. The officials were aware that Alauddin received reports from three different sources, and thus, found no opportunity to deviate from the market rules.[19] Rationing during drought[edit] Even during the times of scarce rainfall, there was no increase in the grain prices during Alauddin's reign. When the rains failed, the grocers of every neighbourhood (mohalla) in Delhi were given a daily allowance of grain from the central market. The allowance was determined by the population of the neighbourhood. People were also allowed to purchase ½ mann[b] of grain directly from the central market at one time. The allowance was higher for the landless nobles and other distinguished men, and varied on the number of their dependants.[18] Alauddin ordered his officers to maintain law and order in market during times of drought. If a stampede resulted in the death of a helpless citizen, the law required the superintendent in-charge of the market to be punished.[18] Sera-i Adl[edit] The Sera-i Adl (literally "Place of Justice") was an exclusive market in Delhi for manufactured and imported goods. The goods sold at Sera-i Adl included cloth, sugar, herbs, dry fruits, butter (including ghee) and lamp-oil.[20] Establishment[edit] Alauddin established the Sera-i Adl on an extensive piece of unused land near the Green Palace (Koshak-i Sabz), on the inner side of the Badaun Gate. The market remained open from morning to the afternoon prayer. The Sultan ordered every specified commodity to be sold only at the Sera-i Adl at the prices fixed by his administration. Any violation of this regulation resulted in confiscation of the commodity, and punishment to the seller.[20] Price fixing[edit] Alauddin's administration fixed the prices of the various commodities sold at Sera-i Adl.[21] Although the control over prices of such goods was not vital for the state, Alauddin probably wanted to keep the nobles happy, or he may have feared that high prices of these goods may affect the prices of other goods.[6] Barani gives the prices for some of these commodities as follows:[21] hideCommodity Price[a] per Silk - Khuzz-i Delhi 16 tankas unspecified Silk - Khuzz-i Konla 6 tankas unspecified hideCommodity Price[a] per Silk - Mashru shiri (fine) 3 tankas unspecified Silk - Shirin (fine) 5 tankas unspecified Silk - Shirin (medium) 3 tankas unspecified Silk - Shirin (coarse) 2 tankas unspecified Silk - Salahati (coarse) 2 tankas unspecified Cotton - Burd (fine) with red lining 6 jitals (seemingly a copyist's mistake) unspecified Cotton - Burd (coarse) 36 jitals unspecified Cotton - Astar-i Nagauri (red) 24 jitals unspecified Cotton - Astar (coarse) 12 jitals unspecified Cotton - Chadar 10 jitals unspecified Fine-woven cotton cloth 1 tanka 20 yards Coarse-woven cotton cloth 1 tanka 40 yards Crystallized sugar (misri) 2.5 jitals 1 sir Coarse sugar 1.5 jitals 1 sir hideCommodity Price[a] per Brown sugar 1 jital 3 sirs Ghee 1 jital 1.5 sir Sesame oil 1 jital 3 sirs Barani does not provide prices of all the commodities, but states that they can be estimated from the above list. Firishta adds that 5 sirs of salt could be purchased for 1 jital.[22] Registration of merchants[edit] Alauddin ordered all the merchants of his empire (not just Delhi), both Hindu and Muslim, to be registered with the Ministry of Commerce. Their businesses were regulated. The merchants of Delhi were required to sign a written agreement promising to bring the imported commodities to Sera-i Adl, and to sell them at the officially fixed rates. Barani states that these merchants brought such large quantities of goods to Sera-i Adl that the goods accumulated in Delhi and remained unsold.[22] Prevention of regrating[edit] After Alauddin fixed the prices of cloth, several merchants would purchase costly cloth at Sera-i Adl in Delhi and sell it outside Delhi a higher rate.[22] To avoid such regrating, Alauddin appointed the rich Multani merchants as officers of Sera-i Adl, and asked them to sell their goods directly to the public, in such a way that these goods did not fall into the hands of the other merchants.[22] The Multani merchant-officers were given 2 million tankas from the treasury, possibly as a subsidy,[22] or as an advance.[6] Permit for buying expensive fabrics[edit] Alauddin ordered that certain expensive fabrics, which were deemed unnecessary for the general public, could be bought only with a permit. These permits had to be issued personally by specific state-appointed officers (Parwana Ra'is). The officers issued permits to amirs, maliks, and other important persons in accordance with their incomes. This ensured that people could not buy such fabrics at a cheap price in Delhi and sell it elsewhere at a higher price.[23] Slave and animal market[edit] Price-fixing[edit] Alauddin also fixed the prices for slaves and animals. Barani gives the following prices for slaves:[24] Slave prices hide Type of slave Price[a] Female slave for domestic work 5-12 tankas Female slave for Concubinage 20-40 tankas Handsome, young male slave 20-30 tankas Slave experienced in work 10-15 tankas Inexperienced young slave 7-8 tankas Barani states that very few slaves were sold for 100-200 tankas: if an expensive slave, whose normal price would be 1,000-2,000 after Alauddin's death, appeared in the market, nobody would buy it because of the fear of Alauddin's spies. [24] The supply of horses in Delhi had improved as a result of Alauddin's conquest of Gujarat, which was an important hub for the Indian Ocean trade. However, only Alauddin's government was allowed to buy good quality horses, which were important for raising and maintaining an efficient army.[6] Alauddin's administration fixed the prices for horses as follows, after consulting experienced brokers:[23] Horse prices hide Type of horse Price[a] Grade I 100-120 tankas Grade II 80-90 tankas Grade III 60-70 tankas Horse prices hide Type of horse Price[a] Small Indian pony (tattoo, not suitable for the cavalry) 10-25 tankas Barani gives the following prices for animals:[24] Prices for other animals hide Animal Best-quality beast of burden Price[a] 4-5 tankas Male cattle for breeding purposes 3 tankas Cows for meat 1.5-2 tankas Cows for milk 3-4 tankas Buffalo for meat 5-6 tankas Buffalo for milk 10-12 tankas Fat goat or sheep 10-12 jitals Barani states that the best-quality beasts of burden, which cost 4 tankas (maximum 5 tankas) during Alauddin's reign, cost 30-40 tankas a few decades after his death.[24] Elimination of merchants[edit] During Alauddin's reign, any man who wanted to join the cavalry had to appear for a review with a horse and equipment. The state would reimburse the cost of the horse, if the candidate passed the review and joined the army, and if his horse died or became useless during the service. However, the candidate was expected to pay for his horse before the review. Taking advantage of this situation, several wealthy people entered into the business of purchasing and rearing horses, and colluded with the brokers to raise prices.[23] As part of his market reforms, Alauddin ordered these horse merchants to be arrested and imprisoned in remote forts. Capitalist investors were banned from participating in the horse trade.[4] Alauddin also eliminated the merchants from the markets for other animals and slaves.[23] Barani does not mention who sold slaves and animals after the merchants were arrested. The later writer Firishta clarifies that Alauddin imprisoned the merchants only temporarily: After the prices had stabilized, they were allowed to buy and sell horses on the condition that they would not violate Alauddin's price-fixing regulations.[4] Supervision of brokers[edit] Alauddin's administration closely supervised the brokers participating in the slave and animal markets.[23] The brokers were responsible for grading the goods and estimating their prices.[4] Before Alauddin's reforms, the leading brokers would help the wealthy merchants raise the prices, and took commissions from both the merchants and the buyers.[23] As part of his market reforms, Alauddin ordered the brokers to be screened carefully to prevent any price rises. The erring brokers were imprisoned with the merchants in remote forts.[4] Investigations[edit] As the horses were required for Alauddin's army, he gave special attention to horse trade. He ordered the leading horse brokers and their horses to be brought before him for a detailed investigation every forty days or two months. Barani states that the brokers were treated so harshly that they wanted to die. Alauddin also appointed spies to the slave and animal markets, and thoroughly analyzed their reports.[4] General markets[edit] According to Barani, Alauddin's Ministry of Commerce (diwan-i riyasat) dictated the prices of all the goods sold in the general markets spread across Delhi. These prices were determined by Alauddin and his staff according to the production cost of the goods.[24] Barani mentions that Alauddin's price control measures were directed at all kinds of goods, "from caps to socks; from combs to needles; from vegetables, soups, sweetmeats to chapatis."[25] Alauddin selected Yaqub Nazir as his Minister of Commerce, and also appointed him as the censor, and the superintendent of weights and measures. Barani describes Yaqub Nazir as an honest but "rude and cruel" man. The Minister appointed a superintendent for every market to ensure that the shopkeepers adhered to the price list sanctioned by Alauddin's administration. The superintendents were also responsible for maintaining proper prices for the commodities that could not be included in the official price list. [26] Yaqub Nazir regularly checked the prices in the general markets, and meted out humiliating punishments to the erring shopkeepers. These punishments scared the shopkeepers into reducing their prices. However, the shopkeepers used other methods to make illegal profits, including use of false weights, sale of low-quality commodities, and lying to young and ignorant customers. To address this problem, Alauddin started sending child employees of the royal pigeon-house to make test purchases, which would be reviewed by Yaqub Nazir. Barani states that if a shopkeeper did not give full weight to the child customer, the Minister would carve out double the due weight of flesh from the shopkeeper's body. Such severe punishments finally ensured adherence to Alauddin's price-fixing regulations in the general markets.[26] Extent of implementation[edit] Barani states that Alauddin's market reforms (such as price control) were implemented in the city of Delhi, the capital of the empire. He states that the regulations implemented in Delhi tended to be followed in other towns, but does not explicitly state if this was the case with Alauddin's reforms.[9] The later writer Firishta suggests that the price control regulations were implemented in the territories other than Delhi as well.[27] Impact[edit] Alauddin's reforms allowed him to raise a powerful army, which decisively defeated the Mongols.[25] Alauddin's courtier Amir Khusrau greatly praises his reforms, portraying them as public welfare measures.[28] He states that the low fixed prices of grains and supply from the royal granaries benefited the public during the times of scarce rainfall. [3] According to an anecdote mentioned by the 14th century writer Hamid Qalandar, even after the Sultan's death, people respected Alauddin for reducing and fixing the price of grains: they made pilgrimages to his tomb to have their prayers fulfilled.[28] The cheap prices enabled the general public to indulge in frequent enterainment activities. Hamid Qalandar, who wrote during the early reign of Firuz Shah Tughluq (r. 1351-1388), quotes Nasiruddin Chiragh Dehlavi as follows:[29] In those days entertainments were common. During the days of the pilgrimages and on the last Wednesday of the month of Safar it was difficult to find (sitting) accommodation in the public enclosures, in the public gardens or by the side of the tanks. There was music and dancing on every side. These feasts would cost a tanka or more.[29] According to Nasiruddin, even beggars could afford cotton-stuffed garments during Alauddin's reign. In fact, an officer called Kafur Muhrdar would distribute such garments among the poor.[29] According to historian Banarsi Prasad Saksena, the contemporary Muslims had limited participation in the business because of Islamic restrictions (see riba). Alauddin's reforms must have caused "discomforts" to the two leading Hindu mercantile communities: the Nayakas (who traded grains) and the Multanis (who traded cloth). Saksena believes that these discomforts were compensated by guaranteed profits resulting from Alauddin's price fixing.[12] Revocation[edit] Alauddin's market reforms ended a few months after his death, when they were revoked by his son Qutbuddin Mubarak Shah. This led to an increase in prices, and consequently, wages. Mubarak Shah also released a large number of prisoners that Alauddin's administration had arrested for various reasons.[30] Notes nspiracies and rebellions by Hindu chiefs in rural areas during his early reign. Besides ensuring sufficient revenues for the royal treasury, the objective of these reforms was to subjugate the powerful chiefs and nobles who could challenge Alauddin's authority. According to chronicler Ziauddin Barani, he also asked his advisers for reforms to subjugate the Hindus whose wealth was a "source of rebellion and disaffection" like the nobility. Most of Alauddin's reforms were revoked by his son Qutbuddin Mubarak Shah shortly after his death, but a few of them served as a basis for the agrarian reforms introduced by rulers of India in the 16th century.[1] Contents o o o o o o 1Background 2Objective 3The reforms 3.1Confiscation of private lands 3.2Direct revenue collection 3.350% tax proportional to land area 3.4Other taxes 4Implementation 4.1Staff 5Revocation and legacy 6References 6.1Bibliography 7External links Background[edit] Alauddin Khalji was the first ruler of the Delhi Sultanate to undertake large-scale fiscal and revenue reforms. His predecessors had largely relied on the pre-existing administrative set-up.[2] Ziauddin Barani, who wrote around half-a-century after Alauddin's death, is the main source of information for Alauddin's reforms. [3] The countryside was largely under the domain of traditional Hindu authorities (khods, muqudaams, choudharies) who controlled the agricultural production. They served as the middlemen through whom the rural population was controlled. Alauddin saw them as rebellious and an impediment of smooth functioning of the government. [4] The land-holders exacted as much tax as possible from the peasants and gave only due share to the state. The surplus revenue made them rich and overbearing. The domineering behaviour of the Hindu chiefs always desiring for independence was also mentioned by Jalaluddin Firuz Khalji.[5] Barani mentions Alauddin's complaint against these Hindu middlemen in detail (translated by Dietmar Rothermund and Hermann Kulke):[4] I have discovered that the khuts and mukkadims [local tax collectors and village headmen] ride upon fine horses, wear fine clothes, shoot withride upon fine horses, wear fine clothes, shoot with Persian bows, make war upon each other, and go out for hunting; but of the kharaj [land revenue], jizya [poll tax], kari [house tax] and chari [pasture tax] they do not pay one jital. They levy separately the khut’s [landowner’s] share from the villages, give parties and drink wine, and many of them pay no revenue at all, either upon demand or without demand. Neither do they show any respect for my officers. This has excited my anger, and I have said to myself: 'Thou hast an ambition to conquer other lands, but thou hast hundreds of leagues of country under thy rule where proper obedience is not paid to thy authority. How then wilt thou make other lands submissive?' — Barani[6] Objective[edit] After facing multiple rebellions by his nephews and officers in 1301, Alauddin implemented four measures to prevent rebellions.[7] He aimed at preventing rebellions by weakening the nobility.[8] He also viewed the haughtiness as well as direct and indirect resistance of the traditional Hindu village heads, who controlled the countryside and agricultural production, as the main impediment in his rule.[9] He sought to reduce the power of his Hindu population and according to Barani, he asked "the wise men to supply some rules and regulations for grinding down the Hindus, and for depriving them of that wealth and property which fosters disaffection and rebellion."[10] According to Barani, after his initial measures against the nobles, Alauddin asked his advisors for suggestions on how to subjugate the Hindus, whose wealth — like that of the nobles — could potentially lead to disloyalty and rebellions. His advisers suggested taking away revenue assignments from the landlords, one law for revenue from both landlords and tenants as well as ending collection charges so "the revenue due from the strong might not fall upon the weak".[11][7] Historian K. S. Lal says that the statement of Barani that Alauddin undertook a series of measures to "crush the Hindus" was a sentiment of an orthodox historian rather than a fact of the matter. He says that though Barani lends a communal colour to Jalaluddin's complaint against their behaviour, it was clear that the Hindu middle-class was well-off and not inclined to servility.[5] Historian Banarsi Prasad Saksena believes that Barani used the word "Hindu" to refer to the upper-class Hindu chiefs: he did not include the Hindu peasants under this term.[12] Historian Satish Chandra believes that Alauddin's measures were taken against the "privileged sections in the countryside" in general.[1] The reforms[edit] Confiscation of private lands[edit] The Delhi Sultanate included the territory governed directly by the emperor's government, as well as the territories governed by his vassals. The crown territory governed by the emperor was called khalisa, and its revenues went directly to the royal treasury. The vassals (called rais, ranas and rawats) had the freedom to determine the tax rate for their subjects. Many of them were expected to maintain their own armies, and provide military support to the crown when required.[13] The Sultans of Delhi also made several land grants and assigned territories to their nobles as iqta's. The iqta' holders had the right to collect taxes in their territories: the money would be used to raise a local army that would support the Sultan when needed, and a part of money would be remitted to the Sultan.[14] As part of his land reforms, Alauddin brought a large tract of fertile land under the crown territory, by eliminating iqta's, grants and vassals in the Ganga-Yamuna Doab region extending from Meerut to Kara.[14] After assassinating his predecessor Jalaluddin in 1296, he had made a large number of land grants to gain support of the nobles. However, after consolidating the power, in 1297, he deposed a large number of nobles who had earlier served Jalaluddin.[15] He confiscated their property, and resumed their iqta's into the crown territory.[16] Sometime later, probably after Haji Maula's rebellion in 1301, Alauddin decided to confiscate more private wealth as part of his measures to weaken those capable of organizing a rebellion. He confiscated a large number of lands that had earlier been held as private property (milk), and re-designated them as part of the crown territory. He also annulled several land grants, including those awarded to religious or charitable organizations (waqf) and those exempt from service obligations (inam).[17][16] Direct revenue collection[edit] Before Alauddin's reforms, the Delhi Sultanate did not collect the land revenues directly from the peasants. The peasants surrendered the land revenues to intermediary chiefs, known as khuts, muqaddams, and chaudharis, who represented villages or groups of villages.[18] These chiefs surrendered a fixed part of the revenue to the Sultanate's Ministry of Revenue, irrespective of how much revenue they extracted from the peasants.[8] Apparently, the Sultanate's government did not have adequate staff in the rural areas, and as long as the intermediary chiefs paid their pre-determined share of revenue, the government did not bother about how they treated the peasants. [12] Alauddin noticed that the intermediary chiefs fought against each other, flaunted their lavish lifestyle, and some of them did not remit revenues to the crown. He sought advice from Qazi Mughisuddin of Bayana on how to suppress these chiefs. [12] Subsequently, his administration decided to collect the revenues directly from the cultivators. All cultivators, from the village chiefs to the peasants, had to remit half of their revenues to the crown. The village chiefs lost all their privileges.[19] Alauddin's government accepted the revenue in both cash and kind. In the fertile regions near Delhi, the government preferred taking revenue in kind: the grain collected as a result was taken to the state granaries. The peasants were not allowed to take the surplus grain to their homes, and were compelled to sell it in the market or to the transporters at a low price.[20][21] See also: Market reforms of Alauddin Khalji § Ban on taking grain home 50% tax proportional to land area[edit] Before Alauddin's reforms, the land revenue for each territory represented by an intermediary was fixed irrespective of the cultivation area in that territory. The fixed amount was probably based on tradition.[18] Alauddin's administration changed this convention, and determined the revenue amount based on the area under cultivation and the produce per biswa.[18] This practice of determining the revenue amount based on the land area was known to the Hindu kings, and was followed in southern India during Alauddin's time. However, it seems to have fallen into disuse in northern India, and Alauddin was the first Muslim emperor of India to implement it.[22] The amount demanded by the Hindu rulers ranged from one-sixth to one-third of the agricultural produce, depending on the situation of the kingdom. The Muslim Sultans of Delhi who preceded Alauddin do not seem to have demanded more than one-third of the produce in tax either.[22] However, Alauddin imposed a 50% kharaj (Islamic tax on agricultural land) in a substantial part of northern India. The cultivators were required to pay half of the agricultural produce as tax: this was the maximum amount allowed by the Hanafi school of Islam, which was dominant in Delhi at that time.[3] Alauddin's administration forced the village chiefs to pay same taxes as the others, and banned them from imposing illegal taxes on the peasants.[23] The demand for tax proportional to land area meant that the rich and powerful villages with more land had to pay more taxes.[23] By suppressing the village chiefs, Alauddin projected himself as the protector of the weaker section of the rural society.[24] According to Barani, the 50% land tax greatly reduced the wealth of the Hindus who dominated the agriculture.[22] To prevent any rebellions, the imperial administration deprived the village chiefs of their wealth, horses and arms. Barani states that "it was impossible for the Hindu to raise his head": The fear of Alauddin made these chiefs so obedient, that a single foot soldier from the revenue office would "tie the necks" of twenty village chiefs together, and "kick and thrash them for the realization of the tribute".[25] According to Barani, the financial condition of these Hindu village chiefs became so bad that their wives had to work for wages in houses of Muslims.[26] Historian Kishori Saran Lal believes that while the Hindus suffered most from these reforms (as they dominated the agriculture), the others - including noblemen, traders, and cultivators - were also negatively impacted.[27] Other taxes[edit] Apart from the kharaj, Alauddin's government levied a tax on residences (called ghari) and a tax on grazing (called chara'i). Unlike kharaj, these taxes were not sanctioned by the Islamic law.[28] For the farmers with milk animals, Alauddin's administration fixed and assigned the pastures.[29] In addition, Alauddin's government imposed the jizya tax on its non-Muslim subjects.[30] Women and children, as well as those with mental disorders and intellectual disability, were exempt from jizya.[31] The Muslims were obligated to contribute zakat instead.[32] Alauddin demanded four-fifth share of the spoils of war from his soldiers, instead of the traditional one-fifth share (khums).[32] Implementation[edit] Alauddin's revenue reforms were not implemented throughout his empire. These reforms were limited to certain crown-governed territories, which included parts of the Indo-Gangetic plains from Punjab to Uttar Pradesh, Rajasthan, and Malwa.[29] By the time of Alauddin's ascension, the imperial rule in the central region of the Sultanate (the upper Ganges valley and the eastern Rajasthan) had been consolidated, which allowed Alauddin to take up the reforms in these areas.[33] The responsibility for implementing these reforms was given to a minister with the title naib wazir. Two different recensions of Barani's Tarikh-i-Firuz Shahi name the minister differently as Malik Yaklakhi and Sharaf al-Din Qa'ini.[28] The minister implemented the new laws uniformly across several crown-governed territories. These territories included Delhi; present-day Uttar Pradesh (including Rohilkhand and the Ganges-Yamuna Doab, but excluding Awadh and Bihar); the Punjab region (except Multan); parts of present-day Rajasthan; and Malwa.[34] For the first time in India, the crown established a direct relationship with the cultivators on such a large scale.[29] Staff[edit] A large number of officials were recruited for implementing the new laws: tribute demanders, revenue collectors, government agents, accountants, auditors, clerks, and office managers. The employees were expected to know Persian (the official court language) as well as the local language, which suggests that the staff must have included Hindus.[29] Initially, there was widespread corruption among the revenue employees, who misappropriated the state funds and extorted money from the taxpayers. To address this problem, Alauddin created a new department called Divan-i-Mustakhraj, which was responsible for investigating and realizing the arrears from the revenue collectors. Alauddin increased the salaries of the revenue employees, and instituted punishments for the erring employees. However, these measures did not reduce the corruption to satisfactory levels. Therefore, he resorted to more severe punishments for the corrupt revenue staff.[35] The revenue ministry regularly checked the registers of the village accountants, and strictly punished the corrupt officials.[24] By Alauddin's own estimates, 10,000 corrupt revenue officials were punished in Delhi alone.[36] Barani mentions that it was impossible for the revenue officials to take bribes from Hindus and Muslims, or to obtain money dishonestly in any other way.[24] According to him, death was considered preferable to being a revenue official, and people would not marry their daughters to a revenue clerk.[36] This seems to be an obvious exaggeration: the government service continued be considered prestigious during Alauddin's reign, and the government officials were sought after as marriage partners.[1] Revocation and legacy[edit] Some of Alauddin's land reforms were continued by his successors, and were a basis of the agrarian reforms introduced by the later rulers such as Sher Shah Suri and Akbar.[1] Other regulations of Alauddin were revoked by his son Qutbuddin Mubarak Shah a few months after his death. Mubarak Shah reinstated the lands incorporated by Alauddin into the crown territory to their private owners. He also released a large number of prisoners that Alauddin's administration had arrested for various reasons, including corruption.[37] Alauddin's practice of appropriating four-fifths of the spoils of war from the soldiers continued until the reign of Firuz Shah Tughluq, who switched back to the traditional demand of one-fifth share (khums).[32] 1. Centralized administration: Ala-ud-Din attempted to translate his theory of Kingship that the king was the representative of God on earth and that he was there to rule, through the administrative practices. His word was law. He was an absolute despot. He possessed unlimited powers. He was the head i.e. Commander in Chief of the army, head of the executive, head of the judiciary and the sole authority in enforcing religious matters. image source: livelystories.com/wp-content/uploads/2015/05/Jesuits_at_Akbars_court.jpg ADVERTISEMENTS: All powers of affairs of the state were centralized in him. He used to say, “I do not know whether this is lawful or unlawful, Whatever I think to be for the good of the state or suitable for the emergency that I decree.” In the words of Ashraf, “the Sultan of Delhi was in theory an unlimited despot, bound by no law, subject to no material check and guided by no will except his own.” The prevailing circumstances needed such a strong monarch to run the affairs of the state effectively and without any kind of interferenc. 2. Administration free from the influence of the ulemas: In the words of Dr. Ishwari Parsad, “Ala-ud-Din was opposed to the interference of the Ulemas in matters of state and in this respect he departed from the tradition of the previous Sultans of Delhi. The law was to depend upon the will of the monarch and had nothing to do with the law of the Prophet. This was the guiding maxim of the new monarch.” Dr. R.P. Tripathi has observed, “Kingship could exist without any special religious support and that the outlook of a King was very different from that of the clergy. This was the greatest contribution of Ala-ud-Din.” ADVERTISEMENTS: 3. Role of Ministers: The Sultan appointed trusted ministers to assist him in the running of administration. Their advice was in no way binding on the Sultan. There were 10 ministers to assist him. Next to Sultan was the ‘Wazir’, who was both a civil and military officer. Among the ministers, mention may be made of the ‘Amir-Kohi’ incharge of agriculture and ‘Shahana-i-Mandi’ and ‘Dewan-i-Riyat-looking after markets. 4. Provincial administration: The entire country was divided into 11 provinces. Each province was under a governor who enjoyed his position at the pleasure of the Sultan. ADVERTISEMENTS: 5. Judicial administration: According to Prof. K.S. Lai, the Sultan was as relentless and unflinching in administering justice as Balban. The Sultan was the fountain of justice. He was the final court of appeal. Next to him was ‘Qazi-ul-Qazat or Lord Chief justice. Then were other junior judicial officers. The punishments inflicted upon the accused persons were very severe. Mutilation of limbs and torture were very common. 6. Efficient system of espionage: The system of espionage organised by Ala-ud-Din was very systematic and effective. According to Zia-ud-Din Barani, “No one could stir without his (Ala-ud-Din’s) knowledge and whatever happened in the houses of the Maliks and Amirs, officers and great men was communicated to the Sultan. Day and night did they tremble in their own houses an account of the activity of the patrol. Nor did they do anything nor utter a single word which would subject them to reproof or punishment.” A similar account of the espionage is given by Moreland, “He (Ala-udDin) organised so effective a system of espionage that no body dared to whisper a seditious word. The jovial atmosphere of the capital turned into suspicious gloom but conspiracy for the time being was at its end.” 7. Administrative measures to check the power of the nobles, and their tendency to revolt: After having wide-range consultations, Ala-ud-Din came to the conclusion that following were the causes of revolts: (i) Inefficiency of the spy system resulting in the ignorance of the Sultan regarding the state of affairs in the country. (ii) Existence of huge wealth with the nobles resulting in leisure time leading to conspiracies. (iii) Drinking parties among nobles bringing them close to each other and encouraging them to conspire. (iv) Social intercourse and inter-marriages among the families of nobles making them a compact body dangerous to the state and also forming antagonistic groups among themselves, leading to rivalry. For exercising control over the activities of the nobles, the king took the following measures: (1) Organisation of an efficient spy system. (2) Confiscation of jagirs given to nobles, on one pretext or the other. (3) Prohibition of the sale and use of wine and other intoxicating drugs. (4) Restrictions on social gatherings and inter-marriages among the nobles. 8. Administrative measures for the market control: 9. Organisation of the postal system: Ala-ud-Din established a proper postal system for establishing a regular contact with various parts of the empire. In his book “Medieval Routes in India,” Dr. H.C. Varma writes that Sultan Ala-ud-Din posted several horsemen and clerks in the news posts. From the accounts of Ibn Batutah and Barani, it appears that postal system was in good condition during Ala-ud-Din’s reign.